97-14628. Access Charge Reform; Price Cap Performance Review for Local Exchange Carriers; Transport Rate Structure and Pricing; Usage of the Public Switched Network by Information Service and Internet Access Providers  

  • [Federal Register Volume 62, Number 112 (Wednesday, June 11, 1997)]
    [Rules and Regulations]
    [Pages 31868-31939]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 97-14628]
    
    
    
    [[Page 31867]]
    
    _______________________________________________________________________
    
    Part II
    
    
    
    
    
    Federal Communications Commission
    
    
    
    
    
    _______________________________________________________________________
    
    
    
    47 CFR Parts 61 and 69
    
    
    
    Access Charge Reform; Price Cap Performance Review for Local Exchange 
    Carriers; Transport Rate Structure and Pricing; Usage of the Public 
    Switched Network by Information Service and Internet Providers; Rules
    
    Federal Register / Vol. 62, No. 112 / Wednesday, June 11, 1997 / 
    Rules and Regulations
    
    [[Page 31868]]
    
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
    
    47 CFR Parts 61 and 69
    
    [CC Docket Nos. 96-262, 94-1, 91-213, 96-263; FCC 97-158]
    
    
    Access Charge Reform; Price Cap Performance Review for Local 
    Exchange Carriers; Transport Rate Structure and Pricing; Usage of the 
    Public Switched Network by Information Service and Internet Access 
    Providers
    
    AGENCY: Federal Communications Commission.
    
    ACTION: Final rule.
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    SUMMARY: On December 23, 1996, the Commission adopted a Notice of 
    Proposed Rulemaking in this docket, seeking comment on how the 
    interstate access charge regime should be revised in light of the local 
    competition and Bell Operating Company entry provisions of the 
    Telecommunications Act of 1996 and state actions to open local markets 
    to competition, the effects of potential and actual competition on 
    incumbent LEC pricing for interstate access, and the impact of the 
    Act's mandate to preserve and enhance universal service. In this Report 
    and Order, the Commission adopts many of the rules it proposed. These 
    rule revisions are intended to foster competition, move access charges 
    over time to more economically efficient levels and rate structures, 
    preserve universal service, and lower rates.
    
    DATES: The following rules or amendments thereto, shall become 
    effective July 11, 1997 47 CFR 69.103, 69.107, 69.122, 69.303, 69.304, 
    69.307, 69.308, and 69.406. The following rules or amendments thereto, 
    which impose new or modified information or collection requirements, 
    shall become effective upon approval by the Office of Management and 
    Budget (OMB), but no sooner than June 15, 1997: 47 CFR 61.45, 61.47, 
    69.104, 69.126, 69.151, 69.152, and 69.410. The following rules, or 
    amendments thereto, in this Report and Order shall be effective January 
    1, 1998: 47 CFR 61.3, 61.46, 69.1, 69.2, 69.105, 69.123, 69.124, 
    69.125, 69.154, 69.155, 69.157, 69.305, 69.306, 69.309, 69.401, 69.411, 
    69.501, 69.502, and 69.611. The following rules, which impose new or 
    modified information or collection requirements, shall become effective 
    upon approval by the Office of Management and Budget (OMB), but no 
    sooner than January 1, 1998: 47 CFR 61.42, 61.48, 69.4, 69.106, 69.111, 
    69.153, and 69.156. The Commission will publish a document in the 
    Federal Register at a later date announcing the effective date for the 
    sections containing information collection requirements.
    
    FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Richard Lerner, Attorney, Common 
    Carrier Bureau, Competitive Pricing Division, (202) 418-1530. For 
    additional information concerning the information collections contained 
    in this Report and Order contact Judy Boley at 202-418-0214, or via the 
    Internet at jboley@fcc.gov.
    
    SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a summary of the Commission's Report 
    and Order adopted May 7, 1997, and released May 16, 1997. The full text 
    of this Report and Order is available for inspection and copying during 
    normal business hours in the FCC Reference Center (Room 239), 1919 M 
    St., N.W., Washington, DC. The complete text also may be obtained 
    through the World Wide Web, http://www.fcc.gov/Bureaus/Common__Carrier/
    Orders/1997/fcc97158.wp, or may be purchased from the Commission's copy 
    contractor, International Transcription Service, Inc., (202) 857-3800, 
    2100 M St., N.W., Suite 140, Washington, DC 20037. To seek comment on 
    the rules adopted in this Report and Order, the Commission released 
    Access Charge Reform, CC Docket No. 96-262, Notice of Proposed 
    Rulemaking, 62 FR 4670 (January 31, 1997); Price Cap Performance Review 
    for Local Exchange Carriers, CC Docket No. 94-1, Second Further Notice 
    of Proposed Rulemaking, 60 FR 49539 (September 25, 1995); and Price Cap 
    Performance Review for Local Exchange Carriers, CC Docket 94-1, Fourth 
    Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 60 FR 52362 (October 6, 1995). 
    This Report and Order contains proposed or modified information 
    collections subject to the Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995 (PRA). It 
    has been submitted to the Office of Management and Budget (OMB) for 
    review under the PRA. OMB, the general public, and other Federal 
    agencies are invited to comment on the proposed or modified information 
    collections contained in this proceeding. Please note that the 
    Commission has requested emergency review and approval of this 
    collection by June 10, 1997 under the provisions of 5 CFR 1320.13.
    
    Paperwork Reduction Act
    
        This Report and Order contains either a proposed or modified 
    information collection. As part of its continuing effort to reduce 
    paperwork burdens, we invite the general public and the Office of 
    Management and Budget (OMB) to take this opportunity to comment on the 
    information collections contained in this Report and Order, as required 
    by the Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995, Public Law 104-13. Please note 
    that the Commission has requested emergency review and approval of this 
    collection by June 10, 1997 under the provisions of 5 CFR 1320.13. OMB 
    notification of action is due June 10, 1997. Comments should address: 
    (a) Whether the proposed collection of information is necessary for the 
    proper performance of the functions of the Commission, including 
    whether the information shall have practical utility; (b) the accuracy 
    of the Commission's burden estimates; (c) ways to enhance the quality, 
    utility, and clarity of the information collected; and (d) ways to 
    minimize the burden of the collection of information on the 
    respondents, including the use of automated collection techniques or 
    other forms of information technology.
        OMB Approval Number: 3060-0760.
        Title: Access Charge Reform Report and Order.
        Form No.: N/A.
        Type of Review: Revised Collection.
        Respondents: Business and other for profit.
        Number of Respondents: 13.
        Estimated Time Per Response: 138,714 hours.
        Total Annual Burden: 1,803,282 hours.
        Estimated costs per respondent: $2,400.
        Total Annual Estimated Costs: $31,200.
        Needs and Uses: In the Access Charge Reform First Report and Order, 
    the Commission adopts, that, consistent with principles of cost-
    causation and economic efficiency, non-traffic sensitive (NTS) costs 
    associated with local switching should be recovered on an NTS basis, 
    through flat-rated, per month charges. The information collections 
    resulting from this Report and Order are as follows:
        a. Cost Study of Local Switching Costs: The FCC does not establish 
    a fixed percentage of local switching costs that incumbent LECs must 
    reassign to the Common Line basket or newly created Trunk Cards and 
    Ports service category as NTS costs. In light of the widely varying 
    estimates in the record, we conclude that the portion of costs that is 
    NTS costs likely varies among LEC switches. Accordingly, we require 
    each price cap LEC to conduct a cost study to determine the 
    geographically-averaged portion of local switching costs that is 
    attributable to the line-side ports, as defined above, and to dedicated 
    trunk side cards and ports. These amounts, including cost support, 
    should be reflected in the access charge
    
    [[Page 31869]]
    
    elements filed in the LEC's access tariff effective January 1, 1998.
        b. Cost Study of Interstate Access Service That Remain Subject to 
    Price Cap Regulation: The 1996 Act has created an unprecedented 
    opportunity for competition to develop in local telephone markets. We 
    recognize, however, that competition is unlikely to develop at the same 
    rate in different locations, and that some services will be subject to 
    increasing competition more rapidly than others. We also recognize, 
    however, that there will be areas and services for which competition 
    may not develop. We will adopt a prescriptive ``backstop'' to our 
    market-based approach that will serve to ensure that all interstate 
    access customers receive the benefits of more efficient prices, even in 
    those places and for those services where competition does not develop 
    quickly. To implement our backstop to market-based access charge 
    reform, we require each incumbent price cap LEC to file a cost study no 
    later than February 8, 2001, demonstrating the cost of providing those 
    interstate access services that remain subject to price cap regulation 
    because they do not face substantial competition.
        c. Tariff Filings. The Commission also suggests several information 
    collections relating to tariff filings. Specifically, the Commission 
    adopts its proposals to require the filing of various tariffs, with 
    modifications. For example, the FCC directs incumbent LECs to establish 
    separate rate elements for the multiplexing equipment on each side of 
    the tandem switch. LECs must establish a flat-rated charge for the 
    multiplexers on the SWC side of the tandem, imposed pro-rata on the 
    purchasers of the dedicated trunks on the SWC side of the tandem. 
    Multiplexing equipment on the EO side of the tandem shall be charged to 
    users of common EO-to-tandem transport on a per-minute of use basis. 
    These multiplexer rate elements must be included in the LEC access 
    tariff filings to be effective January 1, 1998.
    
    Synopsis of Report and Order
    
    I. Introduction
    
        1. In passing the Telecommunications Act of 1996, Public Law 104-
    104, 110 Stat. 56 (codified at 47 U.S.C. secs. 151 et seq.) (1996 Act), 
    Congress sought to establish ``a pro-competitive, deregulatory national 
    policy framework'' for the United States' telecommunications industry. 
    With this Order, we begin the third part in a trilogy of actions 
    collectively intended to foster and accelerate the introduction of 
    competition into all telecommunications markets, pursuant to the 
    mandate of the 1996 Act.
        2. In the Local Competition Order, we set forth rules to implement 
    section 251 and section 252 of the Communications Act of 1934, as 
    amended. Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions of the 
    Telecommunications Act of 1996, CC Docket No. 96-98, First Report and 
    Order, 61 FR 45476 (August 29, 1996) (Local Competition Order), Order 
    on Reconsideration, CC Docket No. 96-98, 61 FR 52706 (October 8, 1996), 
    petition for review pending and partial stay granted, sub nom. Iowa 
    Utils. Bd. v. FCC, 109 F.3d 418 (8th Cir. 1996). As with all of Part II 
    of Title II of the Communications Act, those sections, and the rules 
    implementing them, seek to remove the legal, regulatory, economic, and 
    operational barriers to telecommunications competition. Among other 
    things, sections 251 and 252 provide entrants with the opportunity to 
    compete for consumers in local markets by either constructing new 
    facilities, leasing unbundled network elements, or reselling 
    telecommunication services.
        3. In the Universal Service Order, which we adopt in a companion 
    order today, we take steps to ensure that support mechanisms that are 
    necessary to maintain local rates at affordable levels are protected 
    and advanced as local telecommunication markets become subject to the 
    competitive pressures unleashed by the 1996 Act. Federal-State Board on 
    Universal Service, CC Docket No. 96-45, First Report and Order, FCC 97-
    157, ______ FR ______ (released May 8, 1997) (Universal Service Order). 
    When it enacted section 254 of the Communications Act, Congress 
    detailed the principles that must guide this effort. It placed on the 
    Commission and the states the duty to implement these principles in a 
    manner consistent with the pro-competition purposes of the Act, as 
    embodied in, for instance, the interconnection provisions of the Act. 
    It stated that ``[t]here should be specific, predictable and sufficient 
    Federal and State mechanisms to preserve and advance universal 
    service.''
        4. Congress also specified that universal service support ``should 
    be explicit,'' and that, with respect to federal universal service 
    support, ``[e]very telecommunications carrier that provides interstate 
    telecommunications services shall contribute, on an equitable and non-
    discriminatory basis, to the specific, predictable, and sufficient 
    mechanisms established by the Commission to preserve and advance 
    universal service.'' As explained further in the Joint Explanatory 
    Statement of the Committee of the Conference, Congress intended that, 
    ``[t]o the extent possible, * * * any support mechanisms continued or 
    created under new section 254 should be explicit, rather than implicit 
    as many support mechanisms are today.'' Congress directed the 
    Commission, by May 8, 1997, to complete a universal service proceeding 
    that ``include[s] a definition of the services that are supported by 
    Federal universal service support mechanisms and a specific timetable 
    for implementation.''
        5. Through our accompanying Universal Service Order, we establish 
    the definition of services to be supported by federal universal service 
    support mechanisms and the specific timetable for implementation. 
    Further, through this First Report and Order in our access reform 
    docket and our Universal Service Order, we set in place rules that will 
    identify and convert existing federal universal service support in the 
    interstate high cost fund, the dial equipment minutes (DEM) weighting 
    program, Long Term Support, Lifeline, Link-up, and interstate access 
    charges to explicit federal universal service support mechanisms. As 
    detailed below, we will identify the implicit federal universal service 
    support currently contained in interstate access charges through three 
    methods.
        6. First, we will reduce usage-sensitive interstate access charges 
    by phasing out local loop and other non-traffic-sensitive (NTS) costs 
    from those charges and directing incumbent local exchange carriers 
    (LECs) to recover those NTS costs through more economically efficient, 
    flat-rated charges. Because NTS costs, by definition, do not vary with 
    usage, the recovery of NTS costs on a usage basis pursuant to our 
    current access charge rules amounts to an implicit subsidy from high-
    volume users of interstate toll services to low-volume users of 
    interstate long-distance services.
        7. Second, we will rely in part on emerging competition in local 
    telecommunications markets, spurred by the adoption of the 1996 Act, to 
    help identify the differences between the rates for interstate access 
    services established by incumbent LECs under price cap regulation and 
    those that competition would set. The prices for interstate access 
    services offered by competing providers presumably will not contain any 
    implicit universal service support such as that embedded in the 
    incumbent LECs' access charges. Consequently, the introduction of 
    competition inevitably will help to
    
    [[Page 31870]]
    
    remove implicit support from the incumbent LECs' access charges where 
    competition develops and also will help to identify the extent of 
    implicit support in other areas.
        8. Third, we will engage in further deliberations on a forward-
    looking economic cost-based mechanism that we will use to distribute 
    federal support to rural, insular, and high cost areas, beginning in 
    1999. Based on cost studies the states will conduct during the coming 
    year (or, at a state's election, based upon Commission-developed proxy 
    methods), an estimate of the forward-looking economic cost of providing 
    service to a customer in a particular rural, insular, or high cost area 
    will be calculated. We will distribute federal universal service 
    support based on the interstate portion of the difference between 
    forward-looking economic cost and a nationwide revenue benchmark. The 
    amount of the support will be explicitly calculable and identifiable by 
    competing carriers, and the support will be portable among competing 
    carriers, i.e., distributed to the eligible telecommunications carrier 
    chosen by the customer. It will be funded by equitable and non-
    discriminatory contributions from all carriers that provide interstate 
    telecommunications services. Through this First Report and Order, we 
    direct that federal universal service support received by incumbent 
    LECs be used to reduce or satisfy the interstate revenue requirement 
    otherwise collected through interstate access charges. Accordingly, 
    through both our Universal Service Order and this First Report and 
    Order on access reform, interstate implicit support for universal 
    service will be identified and removed from interstate access charges, 
    and support will be provided through the explicit interstate universal 
    service support mechanisms.
        9. Although these three steps will set in motion a process that 
    will remove implicit universal service support from access charges, it 
    will not remove all implicit support from all access charges 
    immediately. This result is fully in accord with Congress's directives. 
    Although Congress said in the Act that ``support should be explicit'', 
    it did not provide that ``support shall be explicit.'' Congress's 
    decision to say ``should'' instead of ``shall'' is especially pertinent 
    in light of Congress's repeated use of ``shall'' in the 1996 Act. 
    Moreover, in the Act's legislative history, Congress qualified its 
    intention that ``support mechanisms should be explicit, rather than 
    implicit,'' with the phrase ``[t]o the extent possible.'' Thus, 
    Congress recognized that the conversion of the existing web of implicit 
    subsidies to a system of explicit support would be a difficult task 
    that probably could not be accomplished immediately. As explained 
    below, we conclude that a process that eliminates implicit subsidies 
    from access charges over time is warranted primarily for three reasons. 
    First, we simply do not have the tools to identify the existing 
    subsidies precisely at this time. Second, we prefer to rely on the 
    market rather than regulation to identify implicit support because we 
    are more confident of the market's ability to do so accurately. Third, 
    even if we were more confident of our ability to identify all of the 
    existing implicit support mechanisms at this time, eliminating them all 
    at once might have an inequitable impact on the incumbent local 
    exchange carriers.
        10. Nor, by our orders today, do we attempt to identify or 
    eliminate the implicit universal service support mechanisms established 
    by state commissions. We recognize that states are initially 
    responsible for identifying implicit intrastate subsidies. For the 
    reasons stated above, we believe the Commission has discretion under 
    the statute to employ pro-competitive, deregulatory policies to aid in 
    the reform of the existing, complex system of universal service. Where 
    pro-competition policies, such as those set forth in sections 251, 252 
    and 253, can force prices for telecommunications services to 
    competitive levels, and, as a result, eliminate or, at least, 
    substantially eliminate implicit support, the Act grants us the 
    authority to rely on such policies over a period of time. We find that 
    the Act does not require, nor did Congress intend, that we immediately 
    institute a vast set of wide-ranging pricing rules applicable to 
    interstate and intrastate services provided by incumbent LECs that 
    would have enormously disruptive effects on both ratepayers as well as 
    the affected LECs. Indeed, the congressional mandate that we implement 
    pro-competitive, deregulatory policies is a continuing reminder that, 
    wherever feasible, we should select competition instead of regulation 
    as our means of accomplishing the stated statutory goals. Reliance on 
    competition is the keystone that unifies our universal service and 
    access reform orders.
        11. Nevertheless, implicit intrastate universal service support is 
    substantial. States have maintained low residential basic service rates 
    through, among other things, a combination of: geographic rate 
    averaging, high rates for business customers, high intrastate access 
    rates, high rates for intrastate toll service, and high rates for 
    vertical features and services such as call waiting and call 
    forwarding. By not mandating immediate Commission action to eliminate 
    these policies and instead by ordering that the Commission and the 
    states together achieve universal service goals, Congress intended that 
    states, acting pursuant to section 254(f) of the Communications Act, 
    must in the first instance be responsible for identifying intrastate 
    implicit universal service support. Indeed, by our decisions in this 
    Order and in our companion Universal Service Order, we strongly 
    encourage states to take such steps.
        12. To achieve the vital, historic, and congressionally-mandated 
    purposes of universal service in every state in an era in which 
    competition replaces monopoly, it is necessary that the states and the 
    Commission develop new and effective mechanisms of complementing the 
    activities of each other. Therefore, as states implement their 
    universal service plans, we will be able to assess whether additional 
    federal universal service support is necessary to ensure that quality 
    services remain ``available at just, reasonable, and affordable 
    rates.'' Our decisions in this Order are meant in part to provide some 
    elements of the plan and time sufficient to discharge responsibly an 
    aspect of the federal role in this federal-state universal service 
    partnership.
        13. In this First Report and Order, we also take the actions 
    necessary to permit the market, in the first instance, to expose any 
    implicit universal service support that we may fail to identify as we 
    implement our federal mechanisms for supporting universal service in 
    insular, rural, and high cost areas and to drive access rates toward 
    levels that competition would be expected to produce. Our decision also 
    fulfills the congressional intent that we eliminate the rules that have 
    helped to sustain de facto or de jure monopolies in access markets and 
    instead create the conditions for competitive entry on a sustainable, 
    long-term basis. That requires, among other things, that we phase out 
    opportunities for inefficient entry that are created primarily by 
    anomalies in the current, monopoly-oriented regime. Consequently, this 
    Order sets forth a plan for removing distortions and inefficiencies in 
    both the current ``rate structures'' (the term used to describe the 
    manner in which a particular charge is assessed, such as through a per-
    minute-of-use fee or a flat-rated fee) and ``rate levels'' (the term 
    used to describe the aggregate size of a particular access charge). By 
    rationalizing the access charge rate structure, we ensure that charges 
    more accurately reflect the manner in which
    
    [[Page 31871]]
    
    the costs are incurred, thereby facilitating the movement to a 
    competitive market. We also establish, in this First Report and Order, 
    a prescriptive mechanism to ensure that, through the operation of price 
    caps and by other means, interstate access charges in areas where 
    competition does not develop will also be driven toward the levels that 
    competition would be expected to produce. The Price Cap Fourth Report 
    and Order, which is also the Second Report and Order in this docket and 
    which is also adopted today, modifies the X-Factor in accordance with 
    this plan. Price Cap Performance Review for Local Exchange Carriers, 
    Fourth Report and Order in CC Docket No. 94-1, and Access Charge 
    Reform, Second Report and Order in CC Docket No. 96-262, FCC 97-159, 
    ______ FR ______ (adopted May 7, 1997) (Price Cap Fourth Report and 
    Order).
        14. In a subsequent order in the present docket, we will provide 
    detailed rules for implementing the market-based approach that we adopt 
    in today's Order. That process will give carriers progressively greater 
    flexibility in setting rates as competition develops, gradually 
    replacing regulation with competition as the primary means of setting 
    prices and facilitating investment decisions. A separate order in this 
    docket will also address ``historical cost'' recovery: whether and to 
    what extent carriers should receive compensation for the recovery of 
    the allocated costs of past investments if competitive market 
    conditions prevent them from recovering such costs in their charges for 
    interstate access services.
        15. By our orders today, we reject the arguments made by some 
    parties that section 254 compels us immediately to remove all universal 
    service costs from interstate access charges. Making ``implicit'' 
    universal service subsidies ``explicit'' ``to the extent possible'' 
    means that we have authority at our discretion to craft a phased-in 
    plan that relies in part on prescription and in part on competition to 
    eliminate subsidies in the prices for various products sold in the 
    market for telecommunications services. Moreover, we have met section 
    254's clear command that we identify the services to be supported by 
    federal universal service support mechanisms and that we establish a 
    specific timetable for implementation. Under that timetable, we will 
    over the next year identify implicit interstate universal support and 
    make that support explicit, as further provided by section 254(e). As 
    with any implicit support mechanism, universal service costs are 
    presently intermingled with all other costs, including the forward-
    looking economic costs of interstate access and any historic costs 
    associated with the provision of interstate access services. We cannot 
    remove universal service costs from interstate access charges until we 
    can identify those costs, which we will not be able to do even for non-
    rural LECs before January 1, 1999.
        16. Coupled with the modifications implemented in our Universal 
    Service Order, the changes we put in place today will provide far-
    reaching benefits to the American people. This Order will restructure 
    access charges, resulting in lower long-distance rates for many 
    consumers, while substantially increasing the volume of long-distance 
    calling. It will promote the spread of competition by replacing 
    significant implicit subsidies with an explicit and secure universal 
    service support system. It will foster competition and economic 
    prosperity by creating an access charge system that is both efficient 
    and fair. We believe that the changes implemented by this Order are 
    necessary to meet the goal set forth in the 1996 Act--``opening all 
    telecommunications markets to competition.''
    
    A. Background
    
    1. The Existing Rate System
        17. For much of this century, most telephone subscribers obtained 
    both local and long-distance services from the same company, the pre-
    divestiture Bell System, owned and operated by AT&T. Its provision of 
    local and intrastate long-distance services through its wholly-owned 
    operating companies was regulated by state commissions. The Commission 
    regulated AT&T's provision of interstate long-distance service. Much of 
    the telephone plant that is used to provide local telephone service 
    (such as the local loop, the line that connects a subscriber's 
    telephone to the telephone company's switch) is also needed to 
    originate and terminate interstate long-distance calls. Consequently, a 
    portion of the costs of this common plant historically was assigned to 
    the interstate jurisdiction and recovered through the rates that AT&T 
    charged for interstate long-distance calls. The balance of the costs of 
    the common plant was assigned to the intrastate jurisdiction and 
    recovered through the charges administered by the state commissions for 
    intrastate services. The system of allocating costs between the 
    interstate and intrastate jurisdictions is known as the separations 
    process. The difficulties inherent in allocating the costs of 
    facilities that are used for multiple services between the two 
    jurisdictions are discussed below.
        18. At first, there was no formal system of tariffed charges to 
    determine how the BOCs and the hundreds of unaffiliated, independent 
    LECs would recover the costs allocated to the interstate jurisdiction 
    by the separations rules. Instead, AT&T remitted to these companies the 
    amounts necessary to recover their allocated interstate costs, 
    including a return on allocated capital investment.
        19. In the 1970s, MCI and other interexchange carriers (IXCs) began 
    to provide switched long-distance service in competition with AT&T. 
    However, AT&T still maintained monopolies in the local markets served 
    by its local subsidiaries, the Bell Operating Companies (BOCs). The 
    BOCs owned and operated the telephone wires that connected the 
    customers in their local markets. Other independent (non-Bell) LECs 
    held similar monopoly franchises in their local service areas. MCI and 
    the other IXCs were dependent on the BOCs and the independent LECs to 
    complete the long-distance calls to the end user.
        20. For much of the 1970s, MCI and AT&T fought over the fees--the 
    access charges--that MCI should pay the BOCs for originating and 
    terminating interstate calls placed by or to end users on the BOCs' 
    local networks. That battle took place before federal regulators, as 
    well as in the federal courts. In December 1978, under Commission 
    supervision, AT&T, MCI, and the other long-distance competitors entered 
    into a comprehensive interim agreement, known as Exchange Network 
    Facilities for Interstate Access (ENFIA), that set rates that AT&T 
    would charge long-distance competitors for originating and terminating 
    interstate traffic over the facilities of its local exchange 
    affiliates. Several years afterwards, AT&T's divestiture was completed, 
    separating the local exchange operations of the BOCs from the rest of 
    AT&T's operations, including AT&T's long distance business. The BOCs 
    maintained monopoly franchises in their local market, but by splitting 
    them off from AT&T's long-distance business, the federal courts removed 
    an incentive for the BOCs to favor AT&T's long distance business over 
    its competitors. Now AT&T competed directly with MCI and the other 
    competitors to provide interstate service, and all of the competitors 
    paid the BOCs for the service of providing the necessary access to end 
    users.
        21. In 1978, the Commission commenced a wide-ranging review of the 
    system by which LECs were compensated for originating and
    
    [[Page 31872]]
    
    terminating interstate traffic. In 1983, following the decision to 
    break-up AT&T, the Commission adopted uniform access charge rules in 
    lieu of earlier agreements. MTS and WATS Market Structure, Third Report 
    and Order, CC Docket No. 78-72, Phase 1, 48 FR 10319 (March 11, 1983) 
    (MTS and WATS Market Structure Third Report and Order), recon., 48 FR 
    42984 (September 21, 1983), second recon., 49 FR 7810 (March 2, 1984). 
    These rules governed the provision of interstate access services by all 
    incumbent LECs, BOCs as well as independents. The access charge rules 
    provide for the recovery of the incumbent LECs' costs assigned to the 
    interstate jurisdiction by the separations rules.
        22. The Commission uses a multi-step process to identify the cost 
    of providing access service. First, the rules require an incumbent LEC 
    to record all of its expenses, investments, and revenues in accordance 
    with accounting rules set forth in our regulations. Second, the rules 
    divide these costs between those associated with regulated 
    telecommunications services and those associated with nonregulated 
    activities. Third, the separations rules determine the fraction of the 
    incumbent LEC's regulated expenses and investment that should be 
    allocated to the interstate jurisdiction. After the total amount of 
    interstate cost is identified, the access charge rules translate these 
    interstate costs into charges for the specific interstate access 
    services and rate elements. Part 69 specifies in detail the rate 
    structure for recovering those costs. That is, the rules tell the 
    incumbent LECs the precise manner in which they may assess charges on 
    interexchange carriers and end users.
        23. Determining the costs that an incumbent LEC incurs to provide 
    interstate access services and that, consequently, should be recovered 
    from those services, is relatively straightforward in some cases and 
    problematic in others. Some facilities, such as private lines, can be 
    used exclusively for interstate services and, in such cases, the entire 
    cost of those facilities is assigned to the interstate jurisdiction by 
    the separations rules. Most facilities, however, are used for both 
    intrastate and interstate services. The costs of some of these 
    facilities vary depending on the amount of telecommunications traffic 
    that they handle. The separations rules typically assign these traffic-
    sensitive (TS) costs on the basis of the relative interstate and 
    intrastate usage of the facilities, as measured, for example, by the 
    relative minutes of interstate and intrastate traffic carried by such 
    facilities. By contrast, the costs of other facilities used for both 
    interstate and intrastate traffic do not vary with the amount of 
    traffic carried over the facilities, i.e., the costs are non-traffic-
    sensitive. These costs pose particularly difficult problems for the 
    separations process: The costs of such facilities cannot be allocated 
    on the basis of cost-causation principles because all of the facilities 
    would be required even if they were used only to provide local service 
    or only to provide interstate access services. A significant 
    illustration of this problem is allocating the cost of the local loop, 
    which is needed both to provide local telephone service as well as to 
    originate and terminate long-distance calls. The current separations 
    rules allocate 25 percent of the cost of the local loop to the 
    interstate jurisdiction for recovery through interstate charges. The 
    general process of separating these costs between the interstate and 
    intrastate jurisdictions is discussed by the Supreme Court in Smith v. 
    Illinois Bell Tel. Co., 282 U.S. 133 (1930).
        24. The Commission has recognized in prior rulemaking proceedings 
    that, to the extent possible, costs of interstate access should be 
    recovered in the same way that they are incurred, consistent with 
    principles of cost-causation. Thus, the cost of traffic-sensitive 
    access services should be recovered through corresponding per-minute 
    access rates. Similarly, NTS costs should be recovered through fixed, 
    flat-rated fees. The Commission, however, has not always adopted rules 
    that are consistent with this goal. In particular, the Commission 
    limited the amount of the allocated interstate cost of a local loop 
    that is assessed to residential and business customers as a flat 
    monthly charge, because of concerns that allowing the flat charges to 
    rise above the specified limits might cause customers to disconnect 
    their telephone service. The residual cost of the loop not recovered 
    from end users through the flat charge is recovered through a per-
    minute-of-use charge assessed to long-distance carriers.
        25. Through the end of 1990, the vast majority of access revenues 
    were governed by ``cost-of-service'' regulation. Under cost-of-service 
    regulation, incumbent LECs calculate the specific access charge rates 
    using projected costs and projected demand for access services. Thus, 
    for example, if an incumbent LEC projects that it will provide 10,000 
    total minutes of switching for interstate calls and estimates that it 
    must generate $1,000 dollars in revenue in order to recover the costs 
    of switching that are allocated to the interstate jurisdiction by the 
    separations rules, the access charge for local switching would be set 
    at $0.10 per minute ($1,000/10,000 minutes). In 1991, however, we 
    implemented a system of price cap regulation that altered the manner in 
    which the largest incumbent LECs established their interstate access 
    charges. While most rural and small LECs remained subject to all of the 
    Part 69 cost-of-service rules, generally the largest incumbent LECs are 
    now subject to price cap regulations set forth in Part 61 of our rules.
        26. Price cap regulation fundamentally alters the process by which 
    incumbent LECs determine the revenues they are permitted to obtain from 
    interstate access charges for access services. Briefly stated, cost-of-
    service regulation is designed to limit the profits an incumbent LEC 
    may earn from interstate access service, whereas price cap regulation 
    focuses primarily on the prices that an incumbent LEC may charge and 
    the revenues it may generate from interstate access services. Under the 
    Part 69 cost-of-service rules, revenue requirements are based on 
    embedded or accounting costs allocated to individual services. 
    Incumbent LECs are limited to earning a prescribed return on investment 
    and are potentially obligated to provide refunds if their interstate 
    rate of return exceeds the authorized level. By contrast, although the 
    access charges of price cap LECs originally were set at the cost-of-
    service levels that existed at the time they entered price caps, their 
    prices have been limited ever since by price indices that have been 
    adjusted annually pursuant to formulae set forth in our Part 61 rules. 
    Price cap carriers whose interstate access charges are set by these 
    pricing rules are permitted to earn returns significantly higher than 
    the prescribed rate of return that incumbent LECs are allowed to earn 
    under cost-of-service rules. Price cap regulation encourages incumbent 
    LECs to improve their efficiency by harnessing profit-making incentives 
    to reduce costs, invest efficiently in new plant and facilities, and 
    develop and deploy innovative service offerings, while setting price 
    ceilings at reasonable levels. In this way, price caps act as a 
    transitional regulatory scheme until the advent of actual competition 
    makes price cap regulation unnecessary. Price Cap Performance Review 
    for Local Exchange Carriers, Second Further Notice of Proposed 
    Rulemaking in CC Docket No. 93-124, and Second Further Notice of 
    Proposed Rulemaking in CC Docket No. 93-197, 60 FR 49539
    
    [[Page 31873]]
    
    (September 26, 1995) (Price Cap Second Further NPRM).
        27. Although price cap regulation eliminates the direct link 
    between changes in allocated accounting costs and change in prices, it 
    does not sever the connection between accounting costs and prices 
    entirely. The overall interstate revenue levels still generally reflect 
    the accounting and cost allocation rules used to develop access rates 
    to which the price cap formulae were originally applied. Price cap 
    indices are adjusted upwards if a price cap carrier earns returns below 
    a specified level in a given year. Moreover, a price cap LEC may 
    petition the Commission to set its rates above the levels permitted by 
    the price cap indices based on a showing that the authorized rate 
    levels will produce earnings that are so low as to be confiscatory. In 
    the past, all or some price cap LECs were required to ``share,'' or 
    return to ratepayers, earnings above specified levels. The new rules 
    adopted in the companion Price Cap Fourth Report and Order remove this 
    limit on the maximum returns that can be earned by price cap incumbent 
    LECs.
    2. Implicit Subsidies in the Existing System
        28. Both our price cap and cost-of-service rules contain 
    requirements that inevitably result in charges to certain end users 
    that exceed the cost of the service they receive. To the extent these 
    rates do not reflect the underlying cost of providing access service, 
    they could be said to embody an implicit subsidy. Some of these 
    subsidies are due to the rate structures prescribed by our rules, which 
    in some cases prevent incumbent LECs from recovering their access costs 
    in the same way they have been incurred. For example, although the cost 
    of the local loop that connects an end user to the telephone company's 
    switch does not vary with usage, the current rate structure rules 
    require incumbent LECs to recover a large portion of these non-traffic-
    sensitive costs through traffic-sensitive, per-minute charges. These 
    mandatory recovery rules inflate traffic-sensitive usage charges and 
    reduce charges for connection to the network, in essence creating an 
    implicit support flow from end users that make many interstate long-
    distance calls to end users that make few or no interstate long-
    distance calls.
        29. Several Federal-State Joint Boards have observed that 
    additional subsidies and distortions may be due, not only to the rate 
    structure, but to the separations rules that divide costs between the 
    interstate and intrastate jurisdictions. For example, the current 
    separations rules require larger incumbent LECs to allocate the costs 
    of their switching facilities between the interstate and intrastate 
    jurisdictions on the basis of relative use (i.e., if 30 percent of the 
    minutes of use handled by the LEC's switching facilities are interstate 
    long-distance calls, 30 percent of the LEC's switching costs are 
    allocated to the interstate jurisdiction and recovered through 
    interstate access charges). Our rules, however, permit smaller 
    incumbent LECs to allocate a greater share of their switching costs to 
    interstate access services than would result from the relative use 
    allocator. These smaller incumbent LECs multiply the interstate use 
    ratio by a factor (as high as 3) specified in the separations rules. In 
    its Recommended Decision, the Joint Board on Universal Service observed 
    that these separations rules ``shift what would otherwise be intrastate 
    costs to the interstate jurisdiction,'' thereby allowing such LECs to 
    charge lower prices for intrastate services. Federal-State Joint Board 
    on Universal Service, CC Docket No. 96-45, Recommended Decision, 61 FR 
    63778 (December 2, 1996) (Joint Board Recommended Decision). The Joint 
    Board found that this allocation structure, known as DEM (dial 
    equipment minute) weighting, is ``an implicit support mechanism that is 
    recovered through the switched access rates charged to interexchange 
    carriers by those carriers serving less than 50,000 lines.'' Joint 
    Board Recommended Decision. Similarly, in the Marketing Expense 
    Recommended Decision, another Federal-State Joint Board observed that 
    the separations rules allocate a share of the incumbent LECs' retail 
    marketing expenses to the interstate jurisdiction that is unreasonably 
    high, given that the interstate access services consist primarily of 
    wholesale service offerings. Amendment of Part 67 (New Part 36) of the 
    Commission's Rules and Establishment of a Federal-State Joint Board, CC 
    Docket No. 86-297, Recommended Decision and Order, 52 FR 15355 (April 
    28, 1987) (Marketing Expense Recommended Decision). To the extent these 
    and other separation rules do not apportion costs between the 
    jurisdictions in a manner that reflects the costs incurred to provide 
    service in each jurisdiction, they might be viewed as generating 
    subsidies from the interstate to the intrastate jurisdiction. These 
    subsidies effectively require incumbent LECs to charge higher rates for 
    interstate services and lower rates for intrastate services than would 
    otherwise occur if the subsidies were eliminated.
        30. This ``patchwork quilt of implicit and explicit subsidies'' 
    generates inefficient and undesirable economic behavior. For example, a 
    rate structure that requires the use of per-minute access charges where 
    flat-rated fees would be more appropriate increases the per-minute 
    rates paid by IXCs and long-distance consumers, thus artificially 
    suppressing demand for interstate long-distance services. Similarly, 
    the possible overallocation of costs to the interstate jurisdiction 
    may, for some consumers, increase long-distance rates substantially, 
    suppressing their demand for interstate interexchange services. 
    Implicit subsidies also have a disruptive effect on competition, 
    impeding the efficient development of competition in both the local and 
    long-distance markets. For example, where rates are significantly above 
    cost, consumers may choose to bypass the incumbent LEC's switched 
    access network, even if the LEC is the most efficient provider. 
    Conversely, where rates are subsidized (as in the case of consumers in 
    high-cost areas), rates will be set too low and an otherwise efficient 
    provider would have no incentive to enter the market. In either case, 
    the total cost of telecommunications services will not be as low as it 
    would otherwise be in a competitive market. Because of the growing 
    importance of the telecommunications industry to the economy as a 
    whole, this inefficient system of access charges retards job creation 
    and economic growth in the nation.
        31. Despite the existence of distortions and inefficiencies, the 
    current system of cross-subsidies has persisted for over a decade. The 
    structure has been justified on policy grounds, principally as a means 
    to serve universal service goals. By providing incumbent LECs with a 
    stream of subsidized revenues from certain customers, the system allows 
    regulators to demand below-cost rates for other customers, such as 
    those in high-cost areas.
    3. The Telecommunications Act of 1996
        32. The existing system of implicit subsidies and support flows is 
    sustainable only in a monopoly environment in which incumbent LECs are 
    guaranteed an opportunity to earn returns from certain services and 
    customers that are sufficient to support the high cost of providing 
    other services to other customers. The new competitive environment 
    envisioned by the 1996 Act threatens to undermine this structure over 
    the long run. The 1996 Act removes barriers to entry in
    
    [[Page 31874]]
    
    the local market, generating competitive pressures that make it 
    difficult for incumbent LECs to maintain access charges above economic 
    cost. For example, by giving competitors the right to lease an 
    incumbent LEC's unbundled network elements at cost, Congress provided 
    IXCs an alternative avenue to connect to and share the local network. 
    Thus, where existing rules require an incumbent LEC to set access 
    charges above cost for a high-volume user, a competing provider of 
    exchange access services entering into a market can lease unbundled 
    network elements at cost, or construct new facilities, to circumvent 
    the access charge. In Section VI.A of this Order, we conclude that 
    access charges may not be assessed on unbundled network elements since 
    they are not part of the ``cost'' of providing those elements, as 
    defined in 47 U.S.C. sec. 252(d)(1)(A)(i). In this way, a new entrant 
    might target an incumbent LEC's high-volume access customers, for whom 
    access charges are now set at levels significantly above economic cost. 
    As competition develops, incumbent LECs may be forced to lower their 
    access charges or lose market share, in either case jeopardizing the 
    source of revenue that, in the past, has permitted the incumbent LEC to 
    offer service to other customers, particularly those in high-cost 
    areas, at below-cost prices. Incumbent LECs have for some time been 
    claiming that this process has already made more than trivial inroads 
    on their high-volume customer base.
        33. Recognizing the vulnerability of implicit subsidies to 
    competition, Congress directed the Commission and the states to take 
    the necessary steps to create permanent universal service mechanisms 
    that would be secure in a competitive environment. To achieve this end, 
    Congress directed the Commission to strive to replace the system of 
    implicit subsidies with ``explicit and sufficient'' support mechanisms. 
    In calling for explicit mechanisms, Congress did not intend simply to 
    require carriers to identify and disclose the implicit subsidies that 
    currently exist in the industry. Rather, as we determine in the 
    Universal Service Order adopted today, Congress intended to establish 
    subsidies that were both ``measurable'' and ``portable''--
    ``measurable'' in a way that allows competitors to assess the 
    profitability of serving subsidized end users; and ``portable'' in a 
    way that ensures that competitors who succeed in winning a customer 
    also win the corresponding subsidy. A system of portable and measurable 
    subsidies will permit carriers to compete for the subsidies associated 
    with high-cost or low-income consumers. In the long run, this approach 
    may even allow us to set subsidy levels through competitive bidding 
    rather than through regulation. By contrast, under the current system 
    of implicit subsidies, the only carriers that will serve high-cost 
    consumers are those that are required to do so by regulation and that 
    are able (because of their protected monopoly positions) to charge 
    above-cost rates to other end users.
        34. In the Universal Service Order, we establish ``explicit and 
    sufficient'' support mechanisms to assist users in high-cost areas, 
    low-income consumers, schools, and health care providers. By creating 
    explicit support mechanisms, we establish a system to advance the 
    universal service goals of the 1996 Act that is compatible with the 
    development of competition in the local exchange and exchange access 
    markets. By creating a portable and measurable system of subsidies, we 
    utilize the power of the market to serve universal service goals more 
    efficiently. That order, in short, guarantees that Congress's universal 
    service goals are met in a way that conforms with the pro-competitive 
    and deregulatory goals of the 1996 Act.
    
    B. Access Charge Reform
    
        35. In light of Congress's command to create secure and explicit 
    mechanisms to achieve universal service goals, we conclude that 
    implicit subsidies embodied in the existing system of interstate access 
    charges cannot be indefinitely maintained in their current form. In 
    this Order, therefore, we take two steps with respect to the rules 
    governing the interstate access charges of price cap incumbent LECs. 
    First, we reform the current rate structure to bring it into line with 
    cost-causation principles, phasing out significant implicit subsidies. 
    Second, we set in place a process to move the baseline rate level 
    toward competitive levels. Together with the Universal Service Order, 
    these adjustments will promote the public welfare by encouraging 
    investment and efficient competition, while establishing a secure 
    structure for achieving the universal service goals established by law. 
    Further, the process we set in place to achieve these goals avoids the 
    destabilizing effects of sudden radical change, facilitating the 
    transformation from a regulated to a competitive marketplace. With the 
    limited exceptions identified in Section V, the scope of this 
    proceeding is limited to price cap incumbent LECs. As we explain in 
    that section, the need for access reform is most immediate for these 
    carriers, since they are most vulnerable to competition from 
    interconnection and the availability of unbundled network elements. 
    This proceeding will affect the vast majority of all access lines and 
    revenues, because price cap regulation governs more than 90 percent of 
    all incumbent LEC access lines. We will initiate a separate proceeding 
    later this year to examine the special circumstances of small and rural 
    rate-of-return LECs.
    1. Rationalizing the Rate Structure
        36. In this Order, we reshape the existing rate structure in order 
    to eliminate significant implicit subsidies in the access charge 
    system. To achieve that end, we make several modifications to ensure 
    that costs are recovered in the same way that they are incurred. In 
    general, NTS costs incurred to serve a particular customer should be 
    recovered through flat fees, while traffic-sensitive costs should be 
    recovered through usage-based rates. The present structure violates 
    this basic principle of cost causation by requiring incumbent LECs to 
    recover many fixed costs through variable, per-minute access rates. An 
    important goal of this Order is to increase the amount of fixed costs 
    recovered through flat charges and decrease the amount recovered 
    through variable rates.
        37. Common Line Costs. Because the costs of using the incumbent 
    LEC's common line (or ``local loop'') do not increase with usage, these 
    costs should be recovered through flat, non-traffic-sensitive fees. The 
    current rate structure, however, generally allows an incumbent LEC to 
    recover no more than a portion of its interstate common line revenues 
    through a flat-rated Subscriber Line Charge (SLC), which is capped at 
    $3.50 per month for residential and single-line business users, and 
    $6.00 per month for multi-line users. The remaining common line 
    revenues must be recovered through a per-minute Common Carrier Line 
    (CCL) charge assessed on IXCs (which, in turn, may recover these 
    charges through their prices to long-distance customers). In order to 
    align the rate structure more closely with the manner in which costs 
    are incurred, we adjust access rates over time until the common line 
    revenues of all price cap LECs are recovered through flat-rated 
    charges.
        38. For primary residential and single-line business lines, 
    however, we decline to implement this goal by increasing the SLC 
    ceiling above its existing $3.50 level as urged by many companies, 
    including price cap LECs and IXCs. We do not wish to see increases in 
    the price of basic dial tone charged by local exchange carriers to 
    their end users for
    
    [[Page 31875]]
    
    fear that such increases might cause some consumers to discontinue 
    service, a result that would be contrary to our mandate to ensure 
    universal service. We agree with the Joint Board's finding that 
    increasing the SLC ceiling may make telecommunications service 
    unaffordable for some consumers. Consequently, to the extent that 
    common line revenues are not recovered through the customer's SLC, we 
    conclude that LECs should recover these revenues through a flat, per-
    line charge assessed on the IXC to whom the access line is 
    presubscribed--the presubscribed interexchange carrier charge, or PICC. 
    Where an end user does not select a presubscribed interexchange 
    carrier, we allow an incumbent LEC to collect this charge directly from 
    the end user. Further, in order to provide IXCs with the opportunity to 
    incorporate these changes into their business plans, we set the PICC 
    for primary residential and single-line business lines at not more than 
    the existing flat-rated line charges for the first year, and we 
    gradually increase the ceiling thereafter until it reaches a level that 
    permits full recovery of the common line revenues from flat charges 
    assessed to both end users and IXCs. To the extent that the PICC 
    ceiling prevents full recovery of average per-line common line revenues 
    for primary residential and single-line business lines, the residual 
    amount will be recovered through the PICC imposed upon non-primary 
    residential and multi-line business lines. As described in Section 
    III.A below, as the PICC associated with primary residential and 
    single-line business lines increases, the amount of common line 
    revenues associated with those lines that is recovered through the PICC 
    imposed upon non-primary residential and multi-line business lines will 
    fall to zero.
        39. For non-primary residential and multi-line business lines, we 
    conclude that affordability concerns do not require us to retain the 
    current ceiling on the monthly SLC. Consequently, we raise the SLC 
    ceiling for these lines to the level that permits incumbent LECs full 
    recovery for their common line revenues, but never more than $3.00 
    above the current SLC ceiling for multi-line business lines today, 
    adjusted for inflation. The $3.00 increase in the SLC cap for these 
    lines is measured on a per-month basis. Almost all subscribers will pay 
    SLCs below, and often substantially below, the ceiling. The increase in 
    the SLC ceiling for multi-line businesses will be implemented in the 
    first year. To ameliorate the impact that a dramatic increase in the 
    SLC ceiling might have on residential customers, however, the increase 
    for non-primary residential lines will be phased in over time. The data 
    indicate that raising the SLC ceiling to this level will permit 
    incumbent price cap LECs to recover their average common line revenues 
    from 99 percent of their non-primary residential and multi-line 
    business lines. For the remaining lines, many of which are located in 
    rural areas, the SLC ceiling for non-primary residential and multi-line 
    business lines will ensure that end-user charges are not prohibitive or 
    significantly above the national average, thereby advancing universal 
    service goals of affordability and access. We have also taken account 
    of concerns raised by rural carriers and consumers groups that the 
    increase in the SLC for non-primary residential lines and multi-lines 
    could lead to substantial price increases in rural areas. Consequently, 
    we are adopting these changes only for price cap incumbent LECs and 
    will review rate structure modifications affecting small, rural 
    carriers in a separate proceeding.
        40. In summary, the plan we adopt here phases out significant 
    implicit subsidies in the access charge rate structure, while taking 
    into account universal service concerns of affordability and access. 
    The resulting rate structure is more closely aligned with cost 
    principles. Under this plan, most price cap incumbent LECs will recover 
    their interstate common line revenues through flat-rated SLCs and 
    PICCs.
        41. Switching and Transport Charges. Following the same pricing 
    principle that flat charges should recover fixed costs and variable 
    charges should recover variable costs, we make several modifications to 
    the rate structure for switching and transport services. Among other 
    things, we move the cost of line-side ports to the common line and 
    require their recovery through flat-rated charges. To the extent 
    permitted by the record, we also direct incumbent LECs to reassign 
    costs in the Transport Interconnection Charge (TIC) in order to comply 
    with principles of cost causation and the D.C. Circuit's recent 
    decision in CompTel v. FCC, 87 F.3d 522 (D.C. Cir. 1996).
    2. Baseline Rate Level Reductions
        42. The rate structure changes that we implement in this Order 
    eliminate some of the distortions that have characterized the access 
    charge system for over a decade. These changes, however, are not alone 
    sufficient to create a system that accurately reflects the true cost of 
    service in all respects. To fulfill Congress's pro-competitive mandate, 
    access charges should ultimately reflect rates that would exist in a 
    competitive market. We recognize that competitive markets are far 
    better than regulatory agencies at allocating resources and services 
    efficiently for the maximum benefit of consumers. We conclude, 
    consequently, that competition or, in the event that competition fails 
    to develop, rates that approximate the prices that a competitive market 
    would produce, best serve the public interest.
        43. The rate restructuring we implement in this Order results in 
    substantial reductions in the charges for usage-rated interstate access 
    services. These reductions move these access charges a long way towards 
    their forward-looking cost levels. Furthermore, in addition to these 
    rate structure adjustments, we also take several steps in this Order to 
    address specific cost misallocations that cause access charges to be 
    set above economic costs. For example, we require incumbent LECs to 
    make an exogenous cost adjustment to reflect the full amortization of 
    certain equal access costs. We also issue a Further Notice of Proposed 
    Rulemaking to consider our tentative conclusion that certain General 
    Support Facility (GSF) costs should be reallocated to detariffed 
    services.
        44. We recognize that the prescriptive measures that we implement 
    today represent the first step toward our goal of removing implicit 
    universal service subsidies from interstate access charges and moving 
    such charges toward economically efficient levels. In the NPRM, we 
    identified two separate ways to continue this process in the future--a 
    prescriptive approach in which we actively set rates at economic cost 
    levels, and a market-based approach that relies on competition itself 
    to drive access charges down to forward-looking costs. We conclude in 
    this Order, based on our experience in exchange access and other 
    telecommunications markets and the record in this proceeding, that a 
    market-based approach to reducing interstate access charges will, in 
    most cases, better serve the public interest. Although the Commission 
    has considerable expertise in regulating telecommunications providers 
    and services efficiently for the maximum benefit of consumers, we 
    believe that emerging competition will provide a more accurate means of 
    identifying implicit subsidies and moving access prices to economically 
    sustainable levels. Further, as discussed above, we believe that this 
    approach is most consistent with the pro-competitive, deregulatory 
    policy contemplated by the 1996 Act. Accordingly, where
    
    [[Page 31876]]
    
    competition is developing, it should be relied upon in the first 
    instance to protect consumers and the public interest.
        45. We acknowledge that a market-based approach under this scenario 
    may take several years to drive costs to competitive levels. We also 
    recognize that several commenters have urged us to move immediately to 
    forward-looking rates by prescriptive measures utilizing forward-
    looking cost models. We decline to follow that suggestion for several 
    reasons. First, as a practical matter, accurate forward-looking cost 
    models are not available at the present time to determine the economic 
    cost of providing access service. Because of the existence of 
    significant joint and common costs, the development of reliable cost 
    models may take a year or more to complete. This situation might be 
    contrasted with that addressed in our Local Competition Order, where we 
    endorsed the use of cost models to estimate the cost of providing 
    unbundled network elements. There, we observed that unbundled elements 
    have few joint and common costs, so that devising accurate cost models 
    for unbundled network elements is more straightforward.
        46. In addition, even assuming that accurate forward-looking cost 
    models were available, we are concerned that any attempt to move 
    immediately to competitive prices for the remaining services would 
    require dramatic cuts in access charges for some carriers. Such an 
    action could result in a substantial decrease in revenue for incumbent 
    LECs, which could prove highly disruptive to business operations, even 
    when new explicit universal support mechanisms are taken into account. 
    Moreover, lacking the tools for making accurate prescriptions, 
    precipitous action could lead to significant errors in the level of 
    access charge reductions necessary to reach competitive levels. That 
    would further impede the development of competition in the local 
    markets and disrupt existing services. Consequently, we strongly prefer 
    to rely on the competitive pressures unleashed by the 1996 Act to make 
    the necessary reductions.
        47. To the extent that some commenters contend that the immediate 
    elimination of all implicit subsidies is mandated by the 1996 Act, we 
    disagree. Neither in the 1996 Act nor its legislative history did 
    Congress state that all forms of implicit universal service support 
    shall be made explicit by May 8, 1997. To the contrary, Congress stated 
    that the conversion of implicit subsidies to explicit support is a goal 
    that ``should be'' pursued ``[t]o the extent possible.'' Congress most 
    certainly did not state that we must reach that goal by May 8, 1997. 
    Rather, it directed that, by that date, we issue rules that ``shall 
    include a definition of the services that are supported by Federal 
    universal service support mechanisms and a specific timetable for 
    implementation.'' Our companion order satisfies that timetable, and 
    this Order establishes a process that will eliminate some implicit 
    subsidies quickly and more gradually eliminate others.
        48. We are confident that the pro-competitive regime created by the 
    Act and implemented in the Local Competition Order and numerous state 
    decisions will generate workable competition over the next several 
    years in many cases, and we would then expect that access price levels 
    to be driven to competitive levels. We also recognize, however, that 
    competition may develop at different rates in different places and that 
    some services may prove resistant to competition. Where competition has 
    not emerged, we reserve the right to adjust rates in the future to 
    bring them into line with forward-looking costs. To assist us in that 
    effort, we will require price cap LECs to submit forward-looking cost 
    studies of their services no later than February 8, 2001, and sooner if 
    we determine that competition is not developing sufficiently for the 
    market-based approach to work. We anticipate that the tools needed to 
    complete these cost studies will be available soon, well before this 
    deadline. Indeed, our Universal Service Order requires comparable cost 
    models to be ready by 1998. We will then review competitive conditions 
    and the submitted cost studies.
        49. As we acknowledged in the NPRM, a market-based approach will 
    permit and, indeed, require us progressively to deregulate the access 
    charge regime as competition develops. In a subsequent order, we will 
    examine specific issues concerning the timing and degrees of pricing 
    flexibility. That order will identify the competitive triggers that 
    must be met to justify relaxation of specific regulatory constraints. 
    We also recognize the need to examine whether incumbent LECs should be 
    compensated for any historical costs that they have no reasonable 
    opportunity to recover as a result of the transformation from a 
    regulated to competitive marketplace. We recognize that this issue may 
    raise difficult questions of both law and equity, and we intend to 
    respond fully to concerns about historical cost recovery in a 
    subsequent order to be issued this year.
        50. Finally, we adopt in this Order our earlier tentative 
    conclusion that incumbent LECs may not assess interstate access charges 
    on information service providers (ISPs). We find that our existing 
    policy promotes the development of the information services industry, 
    advances the goals of the 1996 Act, and creates significant benefits 
    for the economy and the American people. With respect to second and 
    additional residential lines, which are often used by consumers to 
    access ISPs, our goal is to move towards price levels and structures 
    that reflect underlying costs, and thereby to create a neutral market 
    environment in which these lines neither give nor receive subsidies. We 
    will address fundamental questions concerning ISP usage of the public 
    switched network as part of a broader set of issues under review in a 
    related Notice of Inquiry. See Usage of the Public Switched Network by 
    Information Service and Internet Access Providers, CC Docket No. 96-
    263, Notice of Inquiry, 62 FR 4670 (January 31, 1997).
        51. Section II of this Order provides an overview of the rate 
    structure adjustments adopted today. Section III offers detailed 
    explanations of these changes, which include adjustments to the rate 
    structure for the common line, local switching, transport, SS7, and 
    switching, and modifications to the TIC. In Section IV, we adopt a 
    market-based approach to reducing access charges and address several 
    specific rate level adjustments. In Section V, we determine which of 
    the changes adopted in this Order should apply to rate-of-return LECs.
        52. Section VI touches upon several additional issues, including 
    the applicability of access charges to unbundled network elements, our 
    treatment of terminating access, and ISPs. We also discuss 
    modifications that may be needed to reconcile our access charge rules 
    with the Universal Service Order released today. In Section VII, we 
    issue an FNPRM to seek comment on proposals to alter the current 
    allocation of GSF costs and to allow incumbent LECs to impose a PICC on 
    special access lines.
    
    II. Summary of Rate Structure Changes and Transitions
    
        53. In rationalizing the switched access rate structure in this 
    Order, our primary goal is to ensure that traffic-sensitive costs are 
    recovered through traffic-sensitive charges and NTS costs are recovered 
    through flat-rated charges, wherever appropriate. Because many NTS 
    costs are currently recovered through per-minute charges, the
    
    [[Page 31877]]
    
    principal effect of our Order is to reduce the amount recovered through 
    per-minute interstate access charges and increase the amounts recovered 
    through flat-rated charges. We phase in these changes over time to 
    ameliorate any disruptions these adjustments might cause end users.
    
    A. Common Line Rate Structure Changes
    
        54. Because the cost of using the incumbent LEC's common line does 
    not increase with usage, the costs should be recovered through flat 
    non-traffic-sensitive fees. In this Order we increase the amount of 
    common line revenues recovered through flat-rated charges over time 
    until incumbent LECs can recover all of their interstate common lines 
    revenues through NTS fees.
        55. Primary Residential and Single-Line Business Lines. We agree 
    with the Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service that the SLC 
    ceiling for primary residential and single-line business lines should 
    not be increased, because a higher SLC could make telecommunications 
    service unaffordable for some consumers. To the extent common line 
    revenues cannot be recovered through the customer's existing SLC, we 
    conclude that LECs should recover these revenues through a flat, per-
    line charge (the ``primary interexchange carrier charge'' or ``PICC'') 
    assessed, not on the end user, but on the end user's presubscribed 
    interexchange carrier. Where an end user does not select a 
    presubscribed interexchange carrier, we allow a price cap LEC to 
    collect this charge directly from the end user. We set a ceiling on the 
    PICC at the level of existing per-line charges for the first year.
        56. In order to give IXCs an opportunity to adjust to the new 
    charge, we gradually increase the PICC ceiling over the next several 
    years until it reaches a level that permits full recovery of common 
    line revenues--plus a portion of ``residual TIC'' revenues. To the 
    extent that the ceiling on the primary residential and single-line 
    business PICC does not allow for full recovery of these common line 
    revenues immediately, the remaining revenues will be recovered through 
    a PICC imposed upon non-primary residential and multi-line business 
    lines, and through per-minute charges.
        57. As the PICC ceiling for primary residential and single-line 
    business lines increases, the amount of common line revenues 
    transferred to non-primary residential and multi-line business lines 
    will fall to zero. At that point, all common line costs for primary 
    residential and single-line business lines will be recovered through 
    flat-charges on those lines.
        58. Non-Primary Residential and Multi-Line Business Lines. Because 
    affordability concerns are not as significant for these lines, we 
    permit a modest increase in the SLC to permit recovery of the price cap 
    LEC's average per-line common line revenues, but never to more than 
    $3.00 above the SLC ceiling for multi-line business lines today, 
    adjusted for inflation. To ameliorate the impact that an increase in 
    the SLC might have on residential customers, the increase in the SLC 
    ceiling will be phased in for non-primary residential lines over 
    several years.
        59. We also establish a flat-rated PICC on non-primary residential 
    and multi-line business lines. This PICC will cover common line 
    revenues that exceed the ceilings on SLCs and primary residential 
    PICCs. It may also recover some residual TIC revenues and certain 
    marketing expenses, as discussed below. We set a ceiling on this PICC 
    in the first year of $1.50 for non-primary residential lines and $2.75 
    for multi-line business lines, and permit those ceilings to increase 
    gradually thereafter. We anticipate that the actual PICC imposed upon 
    multi-line business lines will, on average, decrease from 1998 to 1999, 
    and for every year thereafter, and will fall to less than $1.00 by 
    2001.
        60. To the extent that the ceilings on SLCs and PICCs do not allow 
    recovery through flat charges of all common line revenues, LECs shall 
    be permitted to impose a per-minute CCL charge assessed on originating 
    minutes. To the extent that the sum of a LEC's originating local 
    switching charge and any residual per-minute CCL, TIC, and marketing 
    expense charges exceeds the sum of its originating local switching, 
    CCL, and TIC charges on December 31, 1997, the excess shall be 
    collected through a per-minute charge on terminating access. We expect 
    that this will only apply to a few LECs, and to none beyond 1998. As 
    the PICC cap for non-primary residential and multi-line business lines 
    increases--and as revenues transferred from primary residential and 
    single-line businesses fall to zero--the per-minute CCL charge will 
    fall to zero, too. Eventually, we anticipate that most, if not all, 
    price cap LECs will be able to recover the full per-line revenues 
    associated with non-primary residential and multi-line business lines 
    through the SLC, after taking into account the assistance provided 
    through the explicit high-cost universal service support mechanisms. In 
    addition, residual TIC revenues will also be recovered through the PICC 
    on non-primary residential and multi-line business lines. As described 
    more fully below, to the extent that the PICC ceilings prevent full 
    recovery of the residual TIC, the remaining amount will be recovered 
    through a per-minute residual TIC.
    
    B. Other Rate Structure Changes
    
        61. Switching. The traffic-sensitive costs of local switching will 
    continue to be recovered through per-minute local switching charges.
        62. For price cap LECs, the NTS costs associated with line ports 
    will no longer be included in the local switching charge, and instead 
    will be recovered through the flat-rated common line charges discussed 
    above. Price cap LECs will also assess a monthly flat-rated charge 
    directly on end users that are subscribing to integrated services 
    digital network services, digital subscriber line, or other services 
    that have higher line port costs than basic, analog service. This 
    charge recovers the amount by which the cost of the line port exceeds 
    the cost of a line port for basic, analog service. Costs of local 
    switching attributable to trunk ports are moved to a separate service 
    category within the traffic-sensitive basket. These costs will be 
    recovered through flat-rated monthly charges collected from users of 
    dedicated trunk ports and per-minute, traffic-sensitive charges 
    assessed on users of shared trunk ports. The new rate structure also 
    includes an optional call set-up charge.
        63. Transport. Effective July 1, 1998, the unitary rate structure 
    option for tandem-switched transmission is eliminated and the costs of 
    tandem-switched transmission must be recovered through the existing 
    three-part rate structure. For price cap LECs, a new flat-rated monthly 
    charge recovers the NTS costs of tandem switching attributable to 
    dedicated ports. A new per-minute rate element recovers the costs of 
    multiplexers used between tandem switch DS-1 port interfaces and the 
    DS-3 circuits used to transport traffic from tandem to end offices. For 
    all incumbent LECs, the formula used to compute the tandem-switched 
    transport rate is based on actual usage of the circuit, rather than an 
    assumed 9000 minutes of use per month.
        64. For all incumbent LECs, certain costs currently recovered 
    through the TIC are reassigned to specified facilities charges, 
    including tandem-switching rates. For price cap LECs, those costs of 
    the TIC that remain (the ``residual TIC'') are recovered through the 
    PICC. To the extent that the PICC ceiling prevents recovery of the 
    entire residual TIC
    
    [[Page 31878]]
    
    through the flat-rated PICC, the remaining portion will be collected 
    through a per-minute residual TIC. As the ceilings on the PICCs 
    increase, a larger percentage of the residual TIC will be recovered 
    through the PICC. Beginning in July 1997, price cap reductions will be 
    targeted to the per-minute residual TIC until it is eliminated. We 
    expect that the per-minute TIC charge will be eliminated in two to 
    three years. Residual per-minute TICs shall be assessed only on 
    incumbent LEC transport customers, and therefore shall no longer be 
    assessed on competitive access providers (CAPs) that interconnect with 
    the LEC switched network at the end office.
        65. SS7 Signalling. Price cap LECs may, but are not required to, 
    adopt a rate structure for SS7 signalling that unbundles SS7 signalling 
    functions, as was permitted in the Ameritech SS7 Waiver Order. 
    Ameritech Operating Companies Petition for Waiver of Part 69 of the 
    Commission's Rules to Establish Unbundled Rate Elements for SS7 
    Signalling, Order, DA 96-446 (1996) (Ameritech SS7 Waiver Order).
        66. Retail Marketing Expense. Price cap LECs may no longer recover 
    certain marketing expenses through per-minute access charges assessed 
    on IXCs. These expenses are recovered from end users through per-line 
    charges on second and additional residential lines and multi-line 
    business lines, subject to ceilings on SLCs. Any residual shall be 
    recovered through the PICCs on these lines and then through per-minute 
    charges on originating access, subject to the exception described in 
    Section III.A, below.
    
    III. Rate Structure Modifications
    
    A. Common Line
    
    1. Overview
        67. In the 1983 MTS and WATS Market Structure Third Report and 
    Order, the Commission established a comprehensive mechanism for 
    incumbent LECs to recover the costs associated with their provision of 
    access service required to complete interstate and foreign 
    telecommunications. The access plan distinguished between traffic 
    sensitive costs and NTS costs incurred by an incumbent LEC to provide 
    interstate access service An incumbent LEC's NTS costs of providing 
    interstate access, or costs that do not vary with the amount of usage, 
    include the common line, or ``local loop,'' which connects an end 
    user's home or business to a LEC central office.
        68. In the MTS and WATS Market Structure Third Report and Order, 
    the Commission emphasized that its long range goal was to have 
    incumbent LECs recover a large share of the NTS common line costs from 
    end users instead of carriers, and to recover these costs on a flat-
    rated, rather than on a usage-sensitive, basis. The Commission 
    recognized, however, that a sudden increase in the flat rates imposed 
    by LECs on end users could have a detrimental effect on universal 
    service. For this reason, the rules adopted in 1983 apportioned charges 
    for common line costs between a monthly flat-rated end-user SLC and a 
    per-minute CCL charge assessed to the IXCs. The SLC is based on average 
    interstate-allocated common line costs, which the incumbent LEC may 
    average over an entire region or over a study area, depending on how it 
    files its interstate tariff. These charges currently are the lesser of 
    the per-line average common line costs allocated to the interstate 
    jurisdiction or $3.50 per month for residential and single-line 
    business users, and $6.00 per month for multi-line business users. Any 
    remaining common line revenues permitted under our price cap rules are 
    recovered by incumbent price cap LECs through per-minute CCL charges 
    assessed on the IXCs, and are ultimately recovered by IXCs from end-
    users through long distance toll charges.
        69. Because common line and other NTS costs do not increase with 
    each additional minute of use transmitted over the loop, the current 
    per-minute CCL charge that recovers loop costs represents an 
    economically inefficient cost-recovery mechanism and implicit subsidy. 
    A rate structure that recovers NTS costs through per-minute charges 
    creates an incentive for customers to underutilize the loop by 
    requiring them to pay usage rates that significantly exceed the 
    incremental cost of using the loop. Additionally, a rate structure that 
    forces high-volume customers to pay significantly more than the cost of 
    the facilities used to service them is not sustainable in a competitive 
    environment because high-volume customers can migrate to a competitive 
    LEC able to offer an efficient combination of flat and per-minute 
    charges, even if the competitive LEC has the same or higher costs than 
    the incumbent LEC.
        70. The Federal-State Universal Service Joint Board stated, in its 
    Recommended Decision, that primary residential and single-line business 
    lines are essential to the provision of universal service, and that 
    current rates for local services are generally affordable based on 
    subscribership levels. The Joint Board also concluded that the SLC, as 
    a charge assessed directly on local telephone subscribers, has an 
    impact on universal service concerns such as affordability, and 
    recommended that the Commission leave the current SLC ceilings in place 
    for primary residential and single-line business lines. In our 
    companion Universal Service Order, consistent with that recommendation, 
    we conclude that we should not raise the current $3.50 SLC ceiling on 
    primary residential and single-line business lines.
        71. We adjust the SLC ceilings for multi-line business lines and 
    residential lines beyond the primary connection. Adjusting the SLC 
    ceilings for multi-line business lines and non-primary residential 
    lines will permit incumbent LECs to recover directly from end users 
    more of the common line revenues permitted under our price cap rules 
    for those lines and will reduce the amount of NTS costs related to 
    these lines that are currently recovered through CCL charges. Where the 
    SLC ceilings do not allow the incumbent LEC to recover its price cap 
    common line revenues through end-user charges, the remaining, or 
    ``residual'' amount will be recovered through flat, per-line charges 
    assessed to each customer's presubscribed interexchange carrier. This 
    presubscribed interexchange carrier charge, or ``PICC'', will increase 
    gradually until the incumbent price cap LECs'' full interstate-
    allocated common line revenues permitted under our price cap rules are 
    recovered through a combination of flat-rated SLCs and PICCs. To the 
    extent that the flat-rated charges do not recover, during the initial 
    phase, the full interstate-allocated common line revenues permitted 
    under our price cap rules, incumbent LECs may continue to assess the 
    IXCs a per-minute CCL charge based on the costs not recovered through 
    flat-rated charges. This per-minute charge, however, will be generally 
    much lower than today's CCL charge and will be eliminated once all 
    common line revenues are recovered through a combination of SLCs and 
    PICCs.
    2. Subscriber Line Charge
    a. Background
        72. In the NPRM we proposed to increase the ceiling on the SLC for 
    second and additional lines for residential customers, and for all 
    lines for multi-line business customers, to the per-line loop costs 
    assigned to the interstate jurisdiction. Access Charge Reform Notice of 
    Proposed Rulemaking in CC Docket No. 96-262, Price Cap Performance 
    Review for Local Exchange Carriers and Transport Rate Structure
    
    [[Page 31879]]
    
    and Pricing, Third Report and Order, in CC Docket Nos. 94-1 and 91-213 
    (Price Cap Third Report and Order), and Usage of the Public Switched 
    Network by Information Service and Internet Access Providers, Notice of 
    Inquiry in CC Docket No. 96-263, 62 FR 4670 (December 24, 1996) (NPRM) 
    Alternatively, we proposed to eliminate the ceiling for multi-line 
    business customers and for residential connections beyond the primary 
    connection, especially where the incumbent LEC has entered into 
    interconnection agreements and taken other steps to lower barriers to 
    actual or potential local competition. We sought comment on these 
    proposals. We also invited parties to comment on whether any changes 
    that we adopt to the ceiling on SLCs for incumbent price cap LECs 
    should be extended to incumbent rate-of-return LECs, and on the 
    relationship of any such changes to the Joint Board Recommended 
    Decision. We sought comment on whether to establish a transition 
    mechanism for this increase if the ceilings on SLCs for multi-line 
    business lines and residential lines beyond the primary connection are 
    increased and whether such a transition could be implemented consistent 
    with section 254, the Act's universal service provision. We sought 
    comment on whether geographic averaging of SLCs is an implicit subsidy 
    that is inconsistent with the requirements of section 254(e), and thus 
    on whether we are required to deaverage SLCs.
    b. Discussion
        73. The Commission has had the longstanding goal of ensuring that 
    all consumers have affordable access to telecommunications services. In 
    its Recommended Decision, the Joint Board stated that current rates for 
    local telephone services are generally affordable and that the SLC, as 
    a charge assessed directly on local telephone subscribers, has an 
    impact on universal service concerns such as affordability. The Joint 
    Board further recommended that the Commission maintain the current SLC 
    ceilings for primary residential and single-line business lines, and we 
    adopt that recommendation in our companion Universal Service Order. 
    Numerous parties in this proceeding argue that we should raise or 
    eliminate the SLC ceiling on all lines to permit LECs to recover the 
    full interstate allocated costs of the local loop from end-users. This 
    would increase the average SLC for all residential and single-line 
    business lines from $3.50 per month to $6.10 per month. We conclude 
    that it would be inappropriate to make significant changes to the SLC 
    cap for primary residential and single-line business lines. Primary 
    residential and single-line business lines are central to the provision 
    of universal service. Because of concerns about affordability, and in 
    light of the significant changes that are still underway in this 
    proceeding, in the federal universal service support proceeding, and 
    possible future changes to the separations process, we conclude that 
    the current SLC for these lines should not be raised. Consistent with 
    the Joint Board's recommendation and our conclusion in the Universal 
    Service Order, therefore, the ceiling on the SLC for primary 
    residential and single-line business lines will remain at $3.50 or the 
    permitted price cap common line revenues per line, whichever is less.
        74. With regard to multi-line users, the Joint Board suggested in 
    its Recommended Decision that universal service support should not be 
    extended to non-primary residential lines and multi-line business lines 
    because it found that cost of service is unlikely to be a factor that 
    would cause multi-line users not to subscribe to telephone service. 
    Subsequently, the state members of the Joint Board filed a report with 
    the Commission in which they proposed that we retain high cost support 
    for all lines served in high cost study areas during a transition to a 
    forward-looking cost methodology. Consistent with that proposal, we 
    adopt, in our Universal Service Order, a modified version of the 
    existing high-cost support system and continue support for all 
    residential and business connections in areas currently receiving high 
    cost support until at least January 1, 1999. We therefore continue to 
    provide high cost support for non-primary residential and multi-line 
    business lines at this time, by allocating a lower portion of these 
    costs to the intrastate jurisdiction than would otherwise be the case. 
    In that order, we also express our concern, however, that providing 
    universal service support for non-primary residential and multi-line 
    business lines in high-cost areas may be inconsistent with our long-
    term universal service goals, and that overly expansive universal 
    service support mechanisms potentially could harm all consumers by 
    increasing the expense of telecommunications services for all. We state 
    that we will continue to evaluate the Joint Board's recommendation to 
    limit universal service support to primary residential connections and 
    businesses with single connections.
        75. We conclude here that it is necessary to adjust the ceilings on 
    the interstate SLCs on both non-primary residential and multi-line 
    business lines in order to create a rate structure that supports our 
    long-term universal service goals, is pro-competitive, and is 
    sustainable in a competitive local exchange market. Section 254 of the 
    Act requires that all consumers have access to basic telephone service 
    at just, reasonable, and affordable rates that are comparable among 
    different regions of the nation. This section of the Act also requires 
    that universal service support be achieved through support mechanisms 
    that are ``specific, predictable, and sufficient.'' Because universal 
    service concerns about ensuring affordable access to basic telephone 
    services are not as great for non-primary residential and multi-line 
    business lines as they are for primary residential and single-line 
    business lines, we must take action to remove the implicit subsidies 
    contained in our current interstate access charges. Thus, we are 
    adopting a rate structure that will permit LECs to recover greater 
    amounts of their costs on a flat-rated basis from end users and to 
    reduce the amount of revenues they must recover through per-minute 
    access charges. Our initial implementation improves upon the current 
    rate structure because it reduces subsidies by recovering more costs 
    from the cost causer. It also creates a rate structure that is more 
    pro-competitive than the existing one by providing for greater flat-
    rated recovery of NTS costs. Without these modifications, new entrants, 
    which are not subject to the non-cost-causative rate structure 
    requirements, would be in a position to target the incumbent LECs' most 
    profitable, high-volume customers based on regulatory requirements. A 
    loss of profitable customers would increase the incumbent LECs' costs 
    of providing service to the rest of their customers, especially to 
    those in high-cost areas. Consistent with our universal service goal of 
    ensuring that all consumers receive affordable rates that are 
    comparable in different parts of the nation, however, the SLC 
    adjustments will be subject to ceilings to prevent end-user customers 
    in high-cost areas from paying SLCs that are significantly higher than 
    in other parts of the country.
        76. In virtually all cases, current SLC ceilings do not permit 
    incumbent LECs to recover their average per-line interstate-allocated 
    common line costs. As a result of the existing SLC ceilings, which have 
    been in place for the past decade, incumbent LECs must recover the 
    shortfall through usage-sensitive CCL charges assessed on IXCs. The 
    IXCs in turn recover most or all of these costs from toll users in the 
    form of per-minute
    
    [[Page 31880]]
    
    charges, keeping toll rates artificially high and discouraging demand 
    for interstate long distance services. The high per-minute toll charges 
    also create support flows between different classes of customers. For 
    example, because end-user customers vary widely in their use of 
    interstate long distance services, low-volume toll users do not pay the 
    full cost of their loops while high-volume toll users contribute far 
    more than the total cost of their loops. In addition high-volume toll 
    users, who include significant numbers of low-income customers, 
    effectively support non-primary residential and multi-line business 
    customers.
        77. In order to create a rate structure that supports our long-term 
    universal service goals, is pro-competitive, and is sustainable in a 
    competitive market, we modify our rate structure requirements to permit 
    incumbent LECs to recover costs in a manner that more accurately 
    reflects the way those costs are incurred. Because common line costs do 
    not vary with usage, these costs should be recovered on a flat-rated 
    instead of on a per-minute basis. In addition, these costs should be 
    assigned, where possible, to those customers who benefit from the 
    services provided by the local loop. Accordingly, the SLC ceilings for 
    non-primary residential and multi-line business lines will be adjusted 
    generally to a level that permits incumbent LECs to recover, directly 
    from the end user, their average per-line interstate common line 
    revenues.
        78. For multi-line business lines, the SLC will be adjusted to 
    recover the average per-line interstate-allocated common line costs 
    beginning July 1, 1997. To the extent incumbent price cap LECs, mostly 
    in rural areas, have common line costs that significantly exceed the 
    national average, we establish a ceiling on SLCs for multi-line 
    business lines of $9.00, adjusted annually for inflation. To ameliorate 
    any possible adverse impact of adjustments in SLC ceilings for non-
    primary residential lines, we adopt an approach that will gradually 
    phase in adjustments in the SLC ceilings for these lines. The SLC for 
    non-primary residential lines will be adjusted initially beginning 
    January 1, 1998. For the first year, beginning January 1, 1998, the SLC 
    ceiling for non-primary residential lines will be adjusted to the 
    incumbent LEC's average per-line interstate-allocated costs, but may 
    not exceed $1.50 more than the current SLC ceiling. Beginning January 
    1, 1999, the monthly SLC ceiling for these lines will be adjusted for 
    inflation and will increase annually by $1.00 per-line, until the SLC 
    ceiling for non-primary residential lines is equal to the ceiling 
    permitted for multi-line business lines.
        79. The data indicate that the long term ceilings we are 
    establishing will permit incumbent price cap LECs to recover their 
    average per-line common line revenues from 99 percent of their non-
    primary residential and multi-line business lines. For the few 
    incumbent price cap LECs that have common line costs in certain study 
    areas that exceed the ceiling, the ceiling will serve as an economic 
    safeguard for those customers who would otherwise pay significantly 
    higher SLCs. We conclude that maintaining a ceiling for non-primary 
    residential and multi-line business customers in high-cost areas is a 
    reasonable response to a legitimate universal service concern because, 
    consistent with section 254(b)(3), it ensures that these customers have 
    access to telecommunication services at rates that are comparable to 
    rates charged for similar services in urban areas.
        80. We believe that the approach we adopt should prevent widespread 
    discontinuance of lines by multi-line customers. The record indicates 
    that nationwide, the average interstate allocation of common line costs 
    is only $6.10 per line, and that for more than half of multi-line 
    business lines, the interstate common line costs are below the existing 
    $6.00 ceiling. Therefore, when the SLC ceiling is adjusted July 1, 
    1997, more than half of multi-line business lines will see no immediate 
    increase in their SLC. The $5.00 SLC ceiling for non-primary 
    residential lines for the first year is a net increase of $1.50 per 
    month, and the gradual increase, if any, in subsequent years, is 
    designed to allow these customers time to adjust to the new rate 
    structure. Moreover, we expect the rate structure modifications we 
    adopt in this order to benefit the majority of multi-line customers 
    through reductions in per-minute long distance rates. Thus, for many 
    customers, the access restructuring will lead to an overall reduction 
    in their telephone bill. We also note that, because we are adjusting 
    the SLC on non-primary residential lines only to a level that recovers 
    the average interstate allocated costs attributable to the line, to the 
    extent that a customer chooses not to purchase an additional line 
    because of the SLC increase, it is because the benefits of the second 
    line to that customer are less than the average cost of the line.
        81. Many parties contend that adjusting the SLC ceiling for non-
    primary residential lines and multi-line business lines will affect 
    economic development in rural areas. To respond to this concern, with 
    the limited exception of cost allocation to new elements, discussed in 
    Section V, below, we are limiting application of the rate structure 
    modifications we adopt in this Order to incumbent price cap LECs only. 
    Most consumers in rural areas are served by small rate-of-return LECs 
    that are not affected by the SLC adjustment we are adopting. We will 
    review rate structure modifications affecting small, rural carriers in 
    a separate proceeding when we address access charge reform for those 
    carriers. To the extent there are incumbent price cap LECs that serve 
    high-cost areas of the country and have common line costs that exceed 
    the national average, we are maintaining a ceiling on the SLCs for 
    these lines to ensure that subscribers do not pay rates that greatly 
    exceed the national average.
        82. We are not persuaded by arguments that an upward adjustment to 
    a SLC ceiling that was set over a decade ago, and that has never been 
    adjusted for inflation, would violate section 254(b)'s requirement that 
    consumers in all regions of the nation have affordable access to 
    telecommunications and information services at rates that are 
    reasonably comparable to those services provided in urban areas. The 
    data indicate that if the SLC ceilings for business and residential 
    lines had been adjusted annually for inflation since they became 
    effective in 1984 and 1989, respectively, the $6.00 business SLC 
    ceiling would have increased by 1996 to $9.00 per line, and the $3.50 
    residential and single-line business SLC ceiling would have increased 
    to $4.39 per line. Thus, for multi-line business customers, the SLC 
    ceiling we adopt today is not significantly different from what it 
    would have been, if it had been adjusted for inflation annually. 
    Moreover, to adopt a ceiling lower than $9.00 would effectively create 
    an additional impermissible subsidy for a class of customers not 
    enumerated by Congress in section 254 of the 1996 Act as beneficiaries 
    of fundamental universal service goals. We find that the $9.00 ceiling 
    we adopt today strikes a reasonable balance between our desire to 
    establish a more efficient interstate access charge rate structure 
    consistent with our long-term universal service goals in a competitive 
    local exchange environment, and the need to avoid precipitous rate 
    increases to consumers in high cost areas. Although SLCs in some areas 
    may ultimately be lower than SLCs in high-cost areas, we conclude that 
    $9.00 SLCs remain ``reasonably comparable'' to those in urban areas.
        83. We are also not persuaded that we should maintain the current 
    SLC ceiling
    
    [[Page 31881]]
    
    for non-primary residential lines because of claims that incumbent LECs 
    will be unable to identify second lines for purposes of billing 
    different SLCs to these lines. Additional telephone lines are a well-
    established telecommunications product marketed by LECs. This product 
    is supported by a marketing and billing infrastructure that will enable 
    LECs to distinguish non-primary residential lines for purposes of 
    billing different SLCs. We note that we are not defining ``primary'' or 
    ``non-primary'' lines in this Order. In a further notice of proposed 
    rulemaking in the Universal Service proceeding, we will address this 
    issue, and release an order defining ``primary''and ``non-primary'' 
    residential lines by the end of the year.
        84. We are unpersuaded by arguments that we should forgo these 
    changes on the grounds that increasing the SLC ceilings for non-primary 
    residential lines will create undue incentives for subscribers to order 
    their primary lines from the incumbent LEC and their additional lines 
    from competitors. The changes we adopt in this Order are intended to 
    permit incumbent LECs to move their prices for non-primary residential 
    and multi-line business lines toward more economically efficient levels 
    by substantially reducing implicit subsidies flowing between different 
    classes of customers. Once these subsidies are eliminated and the new 
    universal service regime is fully implemented, incumbent LECs will be 
    able to recover their common line costs from customers through a rate 
    structure that accurately reflects the manner in which these costs are 
    incurred, and through a targeted, portable universal service 
    contribution where necessary. At that point, both incumbent LECs and 
    new entrants should be able to compete efficiently in the local 
    exchange market. Subscribers, therefore, should not have an incentive 
    to use other carriers for their additional lines unless a competitor is 
    operating more efficiently and can offer local exchange service at a 
    lower rate than the incumbent LEC is able to offer. Indeed, the ability 
    of a competitive local exchange carrier to offer local exchange service 
    at a lower rate is precisely the type of competition envisioned by the 
    1996 Act: it will encourage the incumbent LEC to reduce its costs of 
    providing service in order to meet or beat the prices of its 
    competition.
        85. To address the concerns of some commenters that charging a 
    higher SLC for second and additional residential lines will encourage 
    subscribers to order their additional line from competitors, we will 
    permit LECs to charge competitors the higher SLC when the competitor 
    provides a customer with a second line through resale of an incumbent 
    LEC offering. If prior to the development of full competition, we find 
    that disparity between SLC charges on primary and additional 
    residential lines becomes a significant problem, we will reexamine this 
    issue in conjunction with further reforms we adopt in an upcoming 
    order.
        86. Certain incumbent LECs have requested that any rule that 
    increases the SLC ceiling for non-primary residential lines should be 
    optional for LECs. We adopt this proposal in part and will not require 
    LECs to charge a higher SLC for non-primary residential lines. Thus, if 
    an incumbent LEC finds that charging higher SLCs leads to a large 
    number of disconnections, it is free to charge less. To the extent 
    price cap LECs choose to charge a SLC that is less than the maximum 
    allowed, however, they may not recover these foregone revenues through 
    the PICC or CCL charges. This restriction is consistent with our 
    current price cap rules, which prevent LECs from transferring SLC costs 
    to the CCL charge.
        87. Several incumbent price cap LECs argue in favor of deaveraging 
    SLCs, stating that an averaged SLC creates cross-subsidies between 
    high-cost and low-cost areas, in violation of section 254 of the Act. 
    We will resolve this issue, along with issues concerning the timing and 
    degrees of geographic deaveraging, pricing flexibility, and ultimate 
    deregulation in an upcoming order.
    3. Carrier Common Line Charge
    a. Background
        88. Because we are retaining the $3.50 ceiling on SLCs for primary 
    residential and single-line business customers, virtually all price cap 
    LECs will be unable to recover, through the SLC, all of their common 
    line revenues permitted under our price cap rules. In the NPRM, we 
    sought comment on possible revisions to the current CCL charge 
    structure that would allow incumbent price cap LECs to recover these 
    NTS common line costs in a way that reflects the way costs are 
    incurred. We proposed a recovery mechanism suggested by the Joint Board 
    in its Recommended Decision that would permit incumbent LECs to recover 
    common line costs not recovered from SLCs through a flat, per-line 
    charge assessed against each end-user's presubscribed interexchange 
    carrier. The Joint Board suggested that the Commission allow incumbent 
    LECs to collect the flat-rated charge directly from end users who have 
    not selected a primary interexchange carrier (``PIC''). We sought 
    comments on this approach and also invited parties to discuss any 
    potential problems created when end-user customers have selected PICs, 
    but use other IXCs for Internet, fax, interexchange, or other 
    interstate services by ``dialing-around'' the PIC.
        89. We also sought comment on several alternative approaches to the 
    per-minute recovery of interstate NTS loop costs proposed by the 
    Competition Policy Institute (CPI), including a ``bulk billing'' method 
    that would assess a charge against the IXC based upon its percentage 
    share of interstate minutes of use or revenues, a ``capacity charge,'' 
    a ``trunk port charge,'' and a ``trunk port and line port'' charge. We 
    invited parties to comment on whether any changes that we adopt to the 
    recovery of interstate NTS local loop costs for price cap LECs should 
    be extended to rate-of-return LECs, and on the relationship of 
    interstate NTS loop cost recovery to the universal service mechanisms 
    proposed in the Joint Board Recommended Decision. We asked parties to 
    address how such an extension to rate-of-return LECs would affect small 
    business entities, especially small incumbent LECs.
        90. Additionally, we asked parties to address whether an 
    alternative mechanism for recovering common line costs currently 
    recovered through the CCL charge would be necessary if we were to 
    eliminate the SLC ceiling for certain lines. We asked interested 
    parties to address the extent to which any proposed alternative 
    recovery mechanism for recovering common line costs currently recovered 
    through the CCL charge would affect small business entities, including 
    small incumbent price cap LECs and new entrants. We also sought comment 
    on whether section 254(g) precludes an IXC from charging its customers 
    the flat, per-line monthly rate assessed on that line if the amount of 
    that charge varied among customers in different areas within a state or 
    among customers in different states, and if so, whether conditions 
    exist sufficient to require us to forbear from the application of 
    section 254(g) to IXC recovery of flat-rate CCL charges.
    b. Discussion
        91. The $3.50 SLC ceiling for primary residential and single-line 
    business customers prevents most incumbent price cap LECs from 
    recovering, through end-user charges, all of the common line revenues 
    permitted under our price cap rules. To the extent that common line 
    revenues are not recovered through
    
    [[Page 31882]]
    
    SLCs, incumbent LECs will be allowed to recover these revenues through 
    a PICC, a flat, per-line charge assessed on the end-user's 
    presubscribed interexchange carrier.
        92. We adopt the Joint Board's recommendation that incumbent LECs 
    may collect directly, from any customer who does not select a 
    presubscribed carrier, the PICC that could otherwise be assessed 
    against the presubscribed interexchange carrier. Assessing the PICC 
    directly against end users that do not presubscribe to a long distance 
    carrier should eliminate the incentive for customers to access long-
    distance services solely through ``dial-around'' carriers in order to 
    avoid paying long-distance rates that reflect the PICC. Several parties 
    argue that this type of billing arrangement will create administrative 
    difficulties because it will require LECs to prorate charges for both 
    the end user and the IXC when a customer leaves an IXC in the middle of 
    the billing cycle. To avoid any potential administrative difficulties 
    resulting from customers leaving their presubscribed interexchange 
    carriers in the middle of a billing cycle, we will permit LECs to 
    assess the full PICC at the beginning of each billing cycle.
        93. We recognize that this flat, per-line PICC will not prevent 
    customers from ``dialing around'' their presubscribed long distance 
    carrier to obtain interstate service. Collecting a PICC from a 
    customer, however, in and of itself, creates no incentive for a 
    customer to presubscribe to one carrier and use ``dial-around'' service 
    of another. If the presubscribed carrier is an efficient competitor, it 
    should be able to offer usage-based rates comparable to the prices of a 
    competitor, thus eliminating any artificial benefits of ``dial-around'' 
    capability. A combination of lower per-minute long distance rates and 
    attractive long-distance pricing packages that reward customers for 
    increasing their usage of the presubscribed interexchange carrier's 
    services should also help deter customers from using separate long-
    distance carriers for various services solely because of regulation. 
    There is customer contact value in being a customer's presubscribed 
    interexchange carrier. Regulators have long concluded that the 
    convenience of making a long-distance call by simply dialing ``1+'' 
    conveys certain advantages. And the advantages of ``1+'' dialing will 
    only increase if, as many predict, we move to a world in which ``one-
    stop shopping'' for a multiplicity of services becomes the primary 
    paradigm for provision of telecommunication services. We conclude that 
    the record does not support a finding that assessing a charge on the 
    presubscribed carrier will artificially encourage ``dial-around'' 
    traffic to such a degree that we should not adopt access charge 
    modifications that will move substantially toward efficient pricing for 
    common line elements and lower usage charges for long-distance service. 
    If evidence appears to us that our rules do substantially contribute to 
    undue use of ``dial-around'' capabilities to circumvent presubscribed 
    interexchange services, we stand ready to revisit this issue at a later 
    time.
        94. The rate structure we are adopting calls for the single-line 
    PICC ultimately to recover the difference between revenues collected 
    through the SLC and the per-line common line revenues for primary 
    residential lines and single-line business lines permitted under our 
    price cap rules. In order to provide incumbent LECs and IXCs with 
    adequate time to adjust to this rate structure change, we cap the PICC 
    for primary residential and single-line business lines at $0.53 per 
    month for the first year, beginning January 1, 1998, and establish 
    ceilings on increases thereafter. We note that the monthly $0.53 PICC 
    is approximately equal to the current presubscribed per-line charges 
    that are assessed to IXCs for the Universal Service Fund and Lifeline 
    Assistance plan, which are being eliminated in our Universal Service 
    Order. Beginning January 1, 1999, the ceiling on the monthly PICC on 
    primary residential and single-line business lines will be adjusted for 
    inflation and will increase by $0.50 per year until the sum of the SLC 
    plus the flat-rated PICC is equal to the price cap LEC's permitted 
    common line revenues per line. In no event shall the sum of the single-
    line SLC and PICC exceed the sum of the maximum allowable multi-line 
    SLC and multi-line PICC.
        95. Sprint asserts that if LECs recover NTS common line costs 
    through deaveraged rates assessed on IXCs, we must forbear from 
    applying section 254(g) to the extent it requires an IXC to average 
    geographically any flat charges an IXC passes on to its customers. 
    WorldCom asserts that IXCs should be permitted to recover their costs 
    in any manner the market will allow, and that unless the Commission 
    forbears with respect to the application of section 254(g) to these 
    costs, IXCs that operate nationally will be forced to average together 
    numerous subscribers' loop costs, and thus use long-distance rates as a 
    vehicle for cross-subsidies that run counter to the overall policies of 
    section 254 (b) and (c). We conclude that the information in the record 
    before us does not demonstrate that we are required, by section 10(a) 
    of the Act, to forbear from enforcing section 254(g) as it relates to 
    the manner in which IXCs recover their costs.
        96. Section 10(a) of the 1934 Act requires the Commission to 
    forbear from applying any regulation or provision of the Communications 
    Act of 1934 if: (1) enforcement of that provision is unnecessary to 
    ensure that the relevant charges and practices are just and reasonable 
    and not unjustly or unreasonably discriminatory; (2) enforcement of 
    that provision is unnecessary to protect consumers; and (3) forbearance 
    from applying such provision or regulation is consistent with the 
    public interest. We conclude that, on the basis of the current record, 
    IXCs have not demonstrated that forbearance of section 254(g) is 
    warranted at this time.
        97. We find that establishing a broad exception to section 254(g) 
    to permit IXCs to pass through flat-rated charges on a deaveraged basis 
    may create a substantial risk that many subscribers in rural and high-
    cost areas may be charged significantly more than subscribers in other 
    areas. Accordingly, we cannot conclude that enforcing our rate 
    averaging requirement is unnecessary to ensure that charges are just 
    and reasonable. In addition, because assessing subscribers flat-rated 
    charges on a deaveraged basis could lead to significantly higher rates 
    for subscribers in high-cost areas, we find no basis in this record to 
    conclude that it is unnecessary to enforce section 254(g) to ensure 
    protection of consumers or to protect the public interest. In contrast, 
    IXCs cite no countervailing public interest considerations but merely 
    make broad, unsupported assertions of the need to deaverage rates in 
    light of the varying PICC amounts expected to be assessed by incumbent 
    LECs. We also note that IXCs now pay access charges that often vary 
    from location to location and from incumbent LEC to incumbent LEC, and 
    still maintain geographically averaged rates. We therefore conclude 
    that, based on the record before us, the IXCs have not met the test set 
    forth in section 10(a) of the Act, and forbearance of section 254(g) is 
    not warranted.
        98. We note that we will continue to examine the issue of whether 
    conditions exist that require us to forbear from application of section 
    254(g) as it relates to recovery of the PICC costs from subscribers. We 
    will resolve this and other specific issues concerning the timing and 
    degrees of pricing flexibility and ultimate deregulation in an upcoming 
    order.
        99. To the extent that the SLC ceilings on all lines and the PICC 
    ceilings on
    
    [[Page 31883]]
    
    primary residential and single-line business lines prevent recovery of 
    the full common line revenues permitted by our price cap rules, 
    incumbent price cap LECs may recover the shortfall through a flat-
    rated, per-line PICC on non-primary residential and multi-line business 
    lines. The incumbent LECs will calculate this additional charge by 
    dividing residual permitted common line revenues by the number of non-
    primary residential and multi-line business lines served by the LEC. 
    For the first year, the ceiling on the PICC will be $1.50 per month for 
    non-primary residential lines and $2.75 per month for multi-line 
    business lines. To the extent that these PICCs do not recover an 
    incumbent LEC's remaining permitted CCL revenues, incumbent LECs will 
    be allowed to recover any such residual common line revenues through 
    per-minute CCL charges assessed on originating access minutes. The per-
    minute charges shall be calculated based on forecasts of originating 
    access minutes as currently provided in our rules.
        100. We generally will not permit incumbent LECs to recover 
    residual common line revenues through per-minute CCL charges assessed 
    on terminating access minutes, because terminating minutes are not 
    likely to be subject to as much competitive pressure as originating 
    access minutes. As discussed in Section III.D, below, we are similarly 
    adopting a rule that requires that incumbent LECs be allowed to recover 
    certain residual transport interconnection charge costs through access 
    charges assessed on originating minutes. In placing these various 
    residual costs on originating minutes only, however, we do not want to 
    destroy the salutary effects of our access charge reforms by creating 
    higher prices for originating minutes than exist under our current 
    access charge rules. To the extent, therefore, that the sum of local 
    switching charges, the per-minute CCL charge, the per-minute residual 
    TIC, and any per-minute charges related to marketing expenses exceed 
    the current sum of local switching charges and the per-minute CCL 
    charge and TIC assessed on originating minutes, the excess may be 
    recovered through charges assessed on terminating minutes. We emphasize 
    that any such amounts recovered through charges assessed on terminating 
    minutes would be temporary and would be phased out as the non-primary 
    residential SLC ceilings and the PICC ceilings are adjusted, and in any 
    event, no later than July 1, 2000.
        101. Beginning January 1, 1999, the PICC will be adjusted for 
    inflation and will increase by a maximum of $1.00 per year for non-
    primary residential lines and $1.50 per year for multi-line business 
    lines, until incumbent LECs recover all their permitted common line 
    revenues through a combination of flat-rated SLC and PICCs. These 
    increases will cease as the PICCs on primary residential and single-
    line business lines recover more of the common line revenues permitted 
    under price cap rules. In addition, as the incumbent price cap LECs 
    increase their PICCs for primary residential and single-line business 
    lines, they shall reduce the amount recovered from the residual per-
    minute CCL charges and reduce their PICCs on non-primary residential 
    and multi-line business lines by a corresponding amount in accordance 
    with the procedures described below. While the plan we adopt today does 
    not eliminate, even on a flat-rated basis, transitional higher rates 
    for business users, it redistributes collection from a very few high-
    volume users to business users generally. This will permit the charges 
    to be sustainable while we finish refining access charges and implement 
    a forward-looking cost-based universal service mechanism for rural, 
    insular, and high cost areas. We also acknowledge that our plan will 
    require customers with multiple telephone lines to contribute, for a 
    limited period, to the recovery of common line costs that incumbent 
    LECs incur to serve single-line customers. We conclude that this aspect 
    of the plan is a reasonable measure to avoid an adverse impact on 
    residential customers.
        102. As the PICC ceilings on primary residential and single-line 
    business lines increase, the residual per-minute CCL charge will 
    decrease until it is eliminated. After the residual per-minute CCL is 
    eliminated, incumbent LECs shall make further reductions due to the 
    increase in the PICC ceilings for primary residential and single-line 
    business lines, first to the PICCs on multi-line business lines until 
    the flat-rated PICCs for those lines are equal to the flat-rated PICCs 
    for non-primary residential lines. Thereafter, incumbent LECs shall 
    apply the annual reductions to both classes of customers equally until 
    the combined SLC and PICCs for primary residential and single-line 
    business lines recover the full average per-line common line revenues 
    permitted under our price cap rules, and the additional flat-rated 
    PICCs on non-primary residential and multi-line business lines no 
    longer recover common line revenues. As discussed in Sections III.D and 
    IV.D, below, the PICC will recover TIC revenues and certain marketing 
    expenses in addition to common line revenues. Therefore, multi-line 
    PICCs may continue to recover non-common line revenues, even though 
    SLCs and PICCs for primary residential and single-line business lines 
    recover the average per-line common line revenues permitted under our 
    price cap rules. If the incumbent LEC's per-line common line revenues 
    permitted by our price cap rules exceed the SLC ceiling for non-primary 
    residential lines and multi-line businesses, the flat-rated charges 
    will continue to apply to those lines so that the sum of the SLCs and 
    flat-rated charges is equal to the permitted common line revenues. Once 
    the multi-line PICC no longer recovers any common line revenues, the 
    calculation of the SLC will be changed from the average per-line 
    interstate allocation of revenue requirement to the average per-line 
    common line revenues permitted by our current price cap rules. With 
    this change, the LEC will not be able to recover more than the average 
    per-line common line revenues permitted under our price cap rules from 
    any access line. We note that at least one party contends that under 
    our current rules, certain price cap carriers could be required to 
    charge negative carrier common line charges, if the revenues recovered 
    through the SLC, which continues to be developed on a cost-of-service 
    basis, exceed the PCI for the common line basket. This adjustment to 
    the calculation of the SLC will solve any such problem.
        103. We are concerned that assessing PICCs on multi-line business 
    lines may create an artificial and undue incentive for some multi-line 
    customers to convert from switched access to special access to avoid 
    the multi-line PICC charges. A migration of multi-line customers to 
    special access could significantly reduce the amount of revenue that 
    could be recovered through per-minute charges, and would result in 
    higher PICCs for the non-primary residential and multi-line business 
    lines remaining on the switched network. We tentatively conclude that 
    we should therefore apply PICCs to purchasers of special access lines 
    as well. The NPRM, however, may not have provided sufficient notice to 
    interested parties that we might apply certain rate structure 
    modifications to special access lines. We therefore seek comment on 
    this issue in Section VII.A, below.
        104. We reject claims that a flat-rated, per-line recovery 
    mechanism assessed on IXCs would be inconsistent with section 254(b) 
    which requires ``equitable and nondiscriminatory contribution to 
    universal service'' by all
    
    [[Page 31884]]
    
    telecommunications providers. The PICC is not a universal service 
    mechanism, but rather a flat-rated charge that recovers local loop 
    costs in a cost-causative manner. Numerous commenters responding to the 
    NPRM support a flat-rated cost recovery mechanism, and we conclude that 
    the PICC is preferable to the other proposals made in the NPRM. We 
    agree with MCI and the Minnesota Independent Coalition that proposals 
    based on the number of trunks or ports that an IXC purchases from the 
    incumbent LEC may encourage IXCs to use fewer trunks or ports than are 
    needed and thereby have an adverse effect on service quality. We 
    decline to adopt the bulk billing approach set out in the NPRM, as well 
    as Ameritech's proposed Loop/Port Recovery charge and the approach 
    proposed by the Competition Policy Institute, because these mechanisms 
    are substantially affected by usage and do not reflect the NTS manner 
    in which common line costs are incurred. The Alliance for Public 
    Technology's proposed ``facilities charge,'' which is a hybrid system 
    that accounts both for level of use and intensity of use by all 
    telecommunication carriers that use the local network, is flawed 
    because it is based partly on usage and is complex and administratively 
    burdensome. A cost-recovery mechanism that recovers common line costs 
    through flat-rated charges imposed on end-user customers and IXCs is an 
    administratively simple mechanism. Further, under our plan, interstate 
    common line access charges will become more closely aligned with 
    allocated interstate costs than they would be under any of the 
    alternative proposals.
        105. The plan we describe above should move us from the pricing 
    scheme that has been in place for more than a decade to a flat-rated 
    pricing scheme that seeks to promote competition, while balancing 
    universal service considerations. We recognize that the modifications 
    we adopt in this Order do not eliminate all the existing support flows. 
    The modifications, however, do move to eliminate subsidies built into 
    the current rate structure, to an extent that is compatible with 
    preserving the universal service goals of providing support to primary 
    residential and single-line business and to customers in high-cost 
    areas pursuant to the mandate of section 254. As we set final support 
    levels for universal service, address any legal issues related to the 
    transition from embedded to forward-looking economic costs, and factor 
    in the development of competition, we will identify and deal with any 
    remaining legal issues relating to the recovery of these revenues. In 
    addition, the plan we are adopting allows incumbent price cap LECs to 
    recover costs in the manner that reflects the way in which they are 
    incurred. We believe that this realignment of rates with costs will 
    reduce the per-minute access charges assessed on IXCs and benefit 
    consumers through lower long-distance rates, as well as create a pro-
    competitive local exchange market in which LECs will be able to compete 
    more efficiently.
    4. Common Line PCI Formula
    a. Background
        106. When we adopted price cap regulation in 1990, we established a 
    separate common line basket in order to balance the price cap goal of 
    economically efficient prices with important goals, such as universal 
    service, that were reflected in common line rates prior to the adoption 
    of price caps. Because common line costs are non-traffic sensitive, 
    growth in demand leads to a reduction in average per-minute common line 
    charges. Therefore, in the LEC Price Cap Order, we established a price 
    cap index (``PCI'') formula for the price cap basket that differed from 
    the PCI formula we established for the other three baskets, to ensure 
    that carrier common line charges declined as common line demand 
    increased. Policy and Rules Concerning Rates for Dominant Carriers, CC 
    Docket No. 87-313, Second Report and Order, 55 FR 42375 (October 19, 
    1990) (LEC Price Cap Order). Specifically, we added a term, ``g/2,'' to 
    the common line PCI formula, to represent half the growth in demand per 
    line in the prior year. This adjustment was made because we originally 
    concluded that both LECs and IXCs have the ability to influence common 
    line growth, and that both LECs and IXCs should benefit from increases 
    in demand.
        107. In the LEC Price Cap Performance Review, we found that 
    incumbent LECs in fact have little influence over per-minute common 
    line demand, and tentatively concluded that we should remove the ``g'' 
    term from the common line formula, because including an industry-wide 
    moving average X-Factor in the common line formula might tend to 
    double-count demand growth. Price Cap Performance Review for Local 
    Exchange Carriers, CC Docket No. 94-1, First Report and Order, 60 FR 
    19526 (April 19, 1995) (LEC Price Cap Performance Review). We sought 
    comment, in the Price Cap Fourth Further NPRM, whether to apply the 
    same PCI formula to the common line basket that we use for the other 
    baskets if we were to adopt a TFP-based X-Factor. Price Cap Performance 
    Review for Local Exchange Carriers, CC Docket No. 94-1, Further Notice 
    of Proposed Rulemaking, 60 FR 52362 (October 6, 1995) (Price Cap Fourth 
    Further NPRM). We also invited comment on whether we could eliminate g/
    2 from the common line formula if we retain a separate common line 
    formula. In this Order, we adopt a plan that should quickly convert the 
    CCL charge from a per-minute charge to a flat-rated per-line charge 
    assessed on interexchange carriers. We also revise the common line 
    formula to reflect the phase out of the CCL charge.
    b. Discussion
        108. We conclude that the separate common line PCI formula should 
    be eliminated, and that the PCI formula for the traffic-sensitive and 
    trunking baskets should be used for the common line basket, once 
    traffic-sensitive CCL charges have been eliminated. In this Order, we 
    have reduced substantially traffic-sensitive CCL charges, and replaced 
    them with the per-line PICC. The remaining traffic-sensitive CCL 
    charges imposed by incumbent price cap LECs will be reduced and then 
    eliminated over the next two or three years. Once common line costs are 
    recovered solely through per-line charges, increased minutes will not 
    affect common line recovery. Therefore, when the traffic-sensitive CCL 
    charges have been eliminated, it will no longer be necessary to ensure 
    that CCL rates decline as per-minute demand increases. Incumbent price 
    cap LECs that no longer assess per-minute CCL charges will use the same 
    PCI formula for the common line basket as they use for the traffic-
    sensitive and trunking baskets.
        109. In the LEC Price Cap Order, we established ``g/2'' as the 
    common line PCI formula because we believed that because both LECs and 
    IXCs contributed to encouraging common line demand growth, both LECs 
    and IXCs should share in the benefits of common line demand growth. In 
    the LEC Price Cap Performance Review, we tentatively concluded that 
    IXCs contributed more to common line demand growth, but declined to 
    revise the common line formula at that time because we were 
    contemplating eliminating the common line PCI formula completely, and 
    because we did not wish to create unnecessary rate churn. To avoid 
    unnecessary rate churn here, we decide to retain ``g/2'' while carriers 
    continue to charge per-minute CCL charges.
    
    [[Page 31885]]
    
        110. We revise sections 61.45(c) and 61.46(d), which govern the 
    common line PCI and API, respectively, to reflect our revisions to the 
    common line rate structure in the common line PCI formula. First, we 
    redesignate section 61.45(c) as 61.45(c)(1) and adopt a new section 
    61.45(c)(2) that requires price cap LECs to use the separate common 
    line formula only while they continue to charge per-minute CCL charges. 
    Section 61.45(c)(2) also states that the common line PCI will be 
    governed by the same PCI formula LECs use for the traffic-sensitive and 
    trunking baskets. Second, we redesignate section 61.46(d) as 
    61.46(d)(1), and amend section 61.46(d)(1) to recognize that LECs now 
    impose PICC charges as well as CCL charges on IXCs. We also adopt a new 
    section 61.46(d)(2) to govern PICC charges once per-minute CCL charges 
    have been phased out. These revisions are set forth in Appendix C of 
    this Order.
    5. Assessment of SLCs and PICCs on Derived Channels
    a. Background
        111. Integrated services digital network (ISDN) services permit 
    digital transmission over ordinary local loops through the use of 
    advanced hardware and software. ISDN offers data transmission at higher 
    speeds and with greater reliability than standard analog service. Most 
    incumbent LECs currently offer two types of ISDN service, Basic Rate 
    Interface (BRI) service and Primary Rate Interface (PRI) service. BRI 
    service allows a subscriber to obtain two voice-grade-equivalent 
    channels and a signalling/data channel over an ordinary local loop, 
    which generally is provided over a single twisted pair of copper wires. 
    PRI service allows subscribers to obtain 23 voice-grade-equivalent 
    channels and one data signalling channel over two pairs of twisted 
    copper wires. BRI service generally is used by individuals and small 
    businesses, and PRI service generally is used by larger businesses. LEC 
    services other than ISDN use derived channel technology to provide 
    multiple channels over a single facility. The LECs also use derived 
    channel technologies within their networks, for example, to provide 
    customers with individual local loops. In such situations, the end user 
    has not generally requested derived channel service and thus most 
    likely is not aware that the LEC is using this technology.
        112. On May 30, 1995, we released a Notice of Proposed Rulemaking 
    seeking comment on the application of SLCs to ISDN and other derived 
    channel services. End User common Line Charges, CC Docket No. 95-72, 
    Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 60 FR 31274 (June 14, 1995) (ISDN SLC 
    NPRM). In the ISDN SLC NPRM, we noted that our current rules, which 
    assess one SLC per derived channel, may discourage efficient use of 
    ISDN services, and we sought comment on several options, ranging from 
    continuation of the current rules applying one SLC to each derived 
    channel to requiring LECs to assess one SLC per each pair of copper 
    wires or each physical facility. Other options presented in the ISDN 
    SLC NPRM included: (1) basing the application of SLCs on a ratio of the 
    average LEC cost of providing a derived channel service, including the 
    trunk or line card costs, to the average cost of providing an ordinary 
    local loop or T-1 facility; (2) applying one SLC for every two derived 
    channels; (3) reducing the number of SLCs applied to derived channel 
    services while increasing slightly the SLC rates; or (4) giving LECs 
    flexibility concerning the number of SLCs they assess for derived 
    channel services, at the same time adjusting the price cap rules to 
    prevent an increase in CCL charges.
        113. In addition to the comments filed in response to the ISDN SLC 
    NPRM, several BOCs provided data on the relative NTS costs of single 
    and derived channel services. The cost data included information about 
    all NTS cost components, including components located in the central 
    office, such as line cards. As shown in Table 1 below, the cost data 
    indicates that the ratio of NTS loop costs of BRI ISDN to standard 
    analog service is approximately 1 to 1. The ratio of NTS loop costs of 
    PRI ISDN to standard analog service, excluding NYNEX's data, is 
    approximately 5 to 1. As shown in Table 2, NYNEX's data appear to be 
    outliers because the ratios of its outside plant and NTS costs for PRI 
    ISDN to standard analog service are almost twice those of other 
    incumbent LECs. NYNEX's data, therefore, are excluded from the 
    calculation of the average ratio for PRI ISDN to standard analog 
    service.
    
     Table 1.--Ratio of Costs of Standard Analog Service to BRI ISDN Service
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                               Outside plant                
                                                (loop only)    All NTS costs
                                                   costs                    
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    Ameritech...............................          1:1.07          1:1.45
    Bell Atlantic...........................          1:1.01          1:1.36
    NYNEX...................................          1:0.85          1:1.23
    Pacific Bell............................          1:1.05          1:1.13
    US West.................................          1:0.80          1:1.07
    Average ratio of costs..................        * 1:0.96       * 1:1.24 
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    * Averages may differ due to rounding.                                  
    
    
                                             Table 2.--Ratio of Costs of Standard Analog Service to PRI ISDN Service                                        
    --------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                               Outside plant (loop       Outside plant (loop only) costs                                  All NTS costs     
                                                   only) costs               (excluding NYNEX data)              All NTS costs        (excluding NYNEX data)
    --------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
    Ameritech..............................                   1:5.68  1:5.68..............................                   1:8.9   1:8.9.                 
    Bell Atlantic..........................                   1:4.13  1:4.13..............................                  1:15.80  1:15.80.               
    NYNEX..................................                  1:10.94  Excluded............................                  1:27.74  Excluded.              
    Pacific Bell...........................                   1:4.67  1:4.67..............................                   1:8.70  1:8.70.                
    US West................................                   1:5.33  1:5.33..............................                  1:10.60  1:10.60.               
    
    [[Page 31886]]
    
                                                                                                                                                            
    Average ratio of costs.................                 * 1:6.5   1:4.95 *............................                * 1:15.13  1:10.5 *.              
    --------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
    * Averages may differ due to rounding.                                                                                                                  
    
        114. We incorporated by reference, in the current proceeding, all 
    pleadings filed in response to the 1995 ISDN SLC NPRM, as listed in 
    Appendix A of that order. In the NPRM for the current proceeding, we 
    invited comments on the effect of the 1996 Act on determining how many 
    SLCs should be applied to ISDN services. We also sought comment on 
    whether mandatory rate structures or rate caps should be prescribed for 
    ISDN service or other derived channel services.
    b. Discussion
        115. Consistent with the goal of this Order of realigning cost 
    recovery in a manner that more closely reflects the manner in which 
    those costs are incurred, we conclude that we should establish separate 
    SLC rates for ISDN service based on the NTS loop costs of BRI and PRI 
    ISDN service. We agree with the majority of commenters that a SLC for 
    ISDN service equal to a SLC for single-channel analog service 
    multiplied by the number of derived channels exceeds the NTS costs of 
    ISDN service and therefore artificially discourages efficient use of 
    ISDN. We find that basing ISDN SLCs on relative costs is most likely to 
    assign costs of ISDN service to customers who subscribe to, and benefit 
    from, that service. Further, we find that the current SLC-per-derived 
    channel rule requires LECs to assess charges that are not related to 
    the NTS costs of the service provided.
        116. As set out above, the record indicates that the NTS loop costs 
    of PRI ISDN service, excluding switching costs, reflect a cost ratio of 
    approximately 5:1 compared to the NTS loop costs of single-channel 
    analog service. We therefore conclude that we should amend our rules to 
    establish, effective July 1, 1997, a SLC rate for PRI ISDN service 
    equal to five times the incumbent LEC's average per-line interstate-
    allocated common line costs, subject to a ceiling of five times $9.00, 
    adjusted annually for inflation. Similarly, the record shows that the 
    NTS loop costs of BRI ISDN service, excluding NTS switching costs, when 
    rounded to the nearest half SLC, reflect a 1:1 cost ratio relative to 
    the NTS loop costs of single-channel analog service. Therefore, we here 
    amend our rules to provide for a SLC rate for BRI ISDN service equal to 
    the incumbent LEC's average per-line interstate-allocated common line 
    costs, subject to the same ceilings otherwise applicable to non-primary 
    residential lines. Thus, beginning January 1, 1998, the SLC ceiling for 
    BRI ISDN service will be set at the lesser of the incumbent LEC's 
    average per-line interstate-allocated costs, or $5.00. Each subsequent 
    year, beginning January 1, 1999, the SLC ceiling will be adjusted for 
    inflation and increased by $1.00 per line, until the ceiling equals 
    that permitted for multi-line business lines.
        117. The cost data submitted by the BOCs in response to our request 
    for information includes information about all NTS cost components, 
    including components located in the central office, such as line cards 
    and trunk cards. The data confirm that line cards and trunk cards for 
    PRI ISDN service in particular constitute a significant portion of the 
    total NTS costs that are dedicated to the provision of service to the 
    subscriber, and that ISDN line cards and trunk cards are many times 
    more expensive than the cards used for standard analog service. As 
    discussed in Section III.B, below, LECs will be required to recover the 
    difference between the cost of an ISDN line card and the cost of a line 
    card used for basic, analog service through a separate charge assessed 
    directly on ISDN end users. For purposes of determining the rate levels 
    for ISDN SLCs, therefore, we considered only the NTS loop costs 
    associated with providing ISDN service.
        118. As with other non-primary residential and multi-line business 
    lines, incumbent price cap LECs may assess flat-rated PICCs on ISDN 
    service to the extent necessary to recover the shortfall of common line 
    revenues caused by SLC ceilings. Incumbent price cap LECs are permitted 
    to assess one PICC for BRI ISDN service and five PICCs for PRI ISDN 
    service. It is necessary for incumbent LECs to be able to assess up to 
    five PICCs on PRI ISDN service because, as discussed above, the record 
    indicates that the NTS loop costs of providing PRI ISDN service, 
    excluding switching costs, reflect a cost ratio of approximately 5:1 
    compared to NTS loop costs of single-channel analog service. Because 
    the PICC recovers NTS common line costs not recovered through the SLC, 
    prohibiting incumbent LECs from charging as many as five PICCs for PRI 
    ISDN service could prevent them from recovering the common line costs 
    associated with providing PRI ISDN service in cases where the common 
    line costs exceed the SLC ceiling.
        119. Incumbent LECs shall assess PICCs on BRI and PRI ISDN services 
    in conjunction with those on the non-primary residential and multi-line 
    business lines. For the first year, the BRI ISDN PICC will be capped at 
    $1.50 per month, and the PRI ISDN PICC will be capped at $2.75 per 
    month. Each subsequent year these two PICCs shall increase by no more 
    than an inflation adjustment, plus $1.00 and $1.50, respectively.
        120. The record does not contain sufficient information to enable 
    us to determine the relative NTS costs of derived channel services 
    other than ISDN. We therefore limit our decision to BRI and PRI ISDN 
    service. We agree with NYNEX that we should not apply the rules we 
    adopt here regarding SLCs when the LEC uses derived channel technology 
    but the end user has not requested derived channel service. Unless a 
    subscriber orders ISDN or another service that requires derived channel 
    technology, we see no reason to vary from our general rule that the 
    incumbent LEC should charge one SLC for each channel regardless of how 
    it is provisioned.
        121. We are not persuaded by PacTel's argument that ISDN service is 
    not an interstate service and should not, therefore, be regulated by 
    the Commission. ISDN lines are not directly assigned to the intrastate 
    jurisdiction, but are treated as common lines. The Commission's 
    jurisdiction thus includes the interstate-allocated portion of the 
    costs of the ISDN lines. The rules we adopt in this order govern only 
    the manner in which LECs recover the
    
    [[Page 31887]]
    
    interstate-allocated common line costs associated with providing ISDN 
    service.
        122. Before the Commission initiated CC Docket No. 95-72, Bell 
    Atlantic, Pacific Bell, GTE, Cincinnati Bell, U S West, and Bellsouth 
    sought waivers of Section 69.104 of the Commission's rules as it 
    applies to ISDN service. In their petitions, these LECs urged the 
    Commission to amend its rules regarding the application of SLCs to ISDN 
    service. We have amended our rules regarding the application of SLCs to 
    ISDN service. We therefore dismiss the waiver petitions of Bell 
    Atlantic, Pacific Bell, GTE, Cincinnati Bell, U S West, and Bellsouth 
    on the grounds that they are moot.
    
    B. Local Switching
    
    1. Non-Traffic Sensitive Charges
    a. Background
        123. The local switch connects subscriber lines both with other 
    local subscriber lines and with interoffice dedicated and common 
    trunks. A local switch consists of (1) an analog or digital switching 
    system; and (2) line and trunk cards, which connect subscriber lines 
    and interoffice trunks, respectively, to the switch. Because all of 
    this equipment is deployed within the central office, all of its costs 
    are assigned to the central office switching accounts of the 
    Commission's Uniform System of Accounts and to the local switching 
    category of central office expenses for jurisdictional separations 
    purposes. 47 CFR Secs. 32.2001(j), 36.125. The interstate portion of 
    these costs is currently recovered through per-minute local switching 
    charges levied on IXCs. 47 CFR Sec. 69.106.
        124. In the NPRM, we observed that a significant portion of local 
    switching costs may not vary with usage. For example, the cost of line 
    cards or line-side ports appears to vary with the number of loops 
    connected to the switch, not with the level of traffic over the loops. 
    We tentatively concluded that LECs should not recover these costs 
    through per-minute charges. Instead, we tentatively concluded that it 
    is more reasonable and economically efficient to recover costs of 
    equipment dedicated to individual customers, such as line-side ports 
    and trunk ports associated with dedicated transport, through flat-rated 
    charges. Trunk-side ports not associated with dedicated transport and 
    the central processing portion of the switch, on the other hand, are 
    shared among multiple carriers. We asked if these costs are driven by 
    usage or by the number of lines and trunks served by the switch. We 
    sought comment on whether rate structures for shared local switching 
    facilities should consist of usage-sensitive, flat-rated, or a 
    combination of both flat-rated and usage-sensitive rate elements. We 
    asked commenters to recommend methods of identifying non-traffic-
    sensitive (NTS) local switching costs.
    b. Discussion
        125. We conclude that, consistent with principles of cost-causation 
    and economic efficiency, NTS costs associated with local switching 
    should be recovered on a flat-rated, rather than usage sensitive, 
    basis. The record before us indicates clearly that the costs of the 
    line side port (including the line card, protector, and main 
    distribution frame) are NTS. We conclude, therefore, that these costs 
    should be recovered through flat-rated charges. Accordingly, for price-
    cap LECs, we reassign all line-side port costs from the Local Switching 
    rate element to the Common Line rate elements. For price cap companies, 
    these costs will be recovered through the common line rate elements, 
    including the SLC and flat-rated PICC, described above.
        126. LECs incur differing costs for line ports used in the 
    provision of different services. The SLC and PICC cost recovery 
    mechanisms will recover only the cost of a line port used to provide 
    basic, analog service, whether the end user has basic, analog service, 
    or another form of service. As discussed above, data submitted in 
    response to the ISDN SLC NPRM show that ISDN line cards cost 
    significantly more than line cards associated with a basic, analog, 
    subscriber line. To the extent that the costs of ISDN line ports, and 
    line ports associated with other services, exceed the costs of a port 
    used for basic, analog service, price cap LECs will recover this excess 
    amount through a separate end-user charge.
        127. We conclude that the costs of a dedicated trunk port 
    (including the trunk card and DS1/voice-grade multiplexers, if needed) 
    should be recovered on a flat-rated basis because these costs are also 
    NTS in nature. These costs should be recovered from the carrier 
    purchasing the dedicated trunk terminated by that port. Similarly, we 
    conclude that the costs of shared trunk ports should be recovered on a 
    per-minute of use basis from the users of common transport trunks. We 
    therefore establish two separate rate elements for recovery of these 
    costs. Price cap LECs may recover the costs of each dedicated trunk 
    port on a flat-rated basis from the purchaser of the dedicated trunk 
    terminating at the port. In order to ensure that these purchasers of 
    dedicated trunks do not pay the costs of shared trunk ports that they 
    do not use, price cap LECs must also establish a usage-sensitive rate 
    element for recovery of the costs of shared trunk ports. The costs of 
    these shared trunk ports will be recovered on a per minute-of-use basis 
    from users of common transport trunks terminating at these ports. We 
    therefore add a separate category for all trunk port costs within the 
    traffic sensitive basket, 47 CFR Sec. 61.42(e)(1). As with the other 
    categories within this basket, the ``trunk ports'' category will have 
    an upper service band index of +5 percent and no lower service band 
    index.
        128. We do not establish a fixed percentage of local switching 
    costs that incumbent LECs must reassign to the Common Line basket or 
    newly created Trunk Cards and Ports service category as NTS costs. In 
    light of the widely varying estimates in the record, we conclude that 
    the NTS portion of local switching costs likely varies among LEC 
    switches. Accordingly, we require each price cap LEC to conduct a cost 
    study to determine the geographically-averaged portion of local 
    switching costs that is attributable to the line-side ports, as defined 
    above, and to dedicated trunk side ports. These amounts, including cost 
    support, should be reflected in the access charge elements filed in the 
    LEC's access tariff effective January 1, 1998. Once established, this 
    service category, like all others in the traffic sensitive basket, 
    shall be subject to price cap adjustments for inflation and 
    productivity. Although some LECs have obtained authority to 
    geographically deaverage transport rates under a zone density pricing 
    plan, because the costs of trunk ports will remain within the Traffic 
    Sensitive basket, we conclude that trunk port costs should remain 
    geographically averaged for now. We will consider deaveraging of these 
    costs in connection with our assessment of other forms of pricing 
    flexibility in a subsequent Order in this proceeding.
        129. We direct all price cap LECs to include in their tariff 
    filings implementing this Order an exogenous downward adjustment to the 
    Traffic Sensitive basket, 47 CFR Sec. 61.42(d)(2), and corresponding 
    exogenous upward adjustment to the Common Line Interstate Access 
    Elements basket, 47 CFR Sec. 61.42(d)(1) to reflect the recovery of the 
    interstate NTS costs of line-side ports from the Common Line rate 
    elements.
        130. USTA, SNET, and BA/NYNEX argue that we should not codify any 
    specific local switching rate elements. We disagree. In the NPRM, we 
    proposed to eliminate local switching rate
    
    [[Page 31888]]
    
    elements only when an actual competitive presence is established for an 
    exchange access service in a relevant geographic area, as measured by 
    (1) demonstrated presence of competition; (2) full implementation of 
    competitively neutral universal service support mechanisms; and (3) 
    credible and timely enforcement of pro-competitive rules. We 
    tentatively concluded in the NPRM that, in the absence of actual 
    competition, the mere availability of unbundled network elements under 
    efficient rate structures would not provide incumbent LECs with 
    sufficient incentive to adopt efficient, cost-causative access rate 
    elements or structures. The record before us indicates that flat-rated 
    pricing for line ports and dedicated trunk ports is efficient, and 
    reflective of cost causation. We will first amend the baseline switched 
    access rate structure to reflect this determination. Then, in a 
    subsequent Report and Order in this docket, we will determine when and 
    under what circumstances we will allow incumbent LECs greater 
    flexibility in designing interstate access rate structures.
        131. In addition, despite arguments from BA/NYNEX to the contrary, 
    we find that the benefits to be gained from a more efficient, cost-
    causative rate structure outweigh the burden of establishing these 
    flat-rate elements. Independent estimates from Cable & Wireless and 
    USTA, both using NYNEX data, indicate that as much as, or even more 
    than, half of local switching costs may be NTS. Since the current, per-
    minute rate structure for the local switch was established, digital 
    switches have become increasingly predominant in the network. Given 
    USTA's estimate that six percent of the costs of an analog switch and 
    51 percent of the costs of a digital switch are NTS, we find that local 
    switching costs have become increasingly NTS and now warrant the 
    creation of a NTS recovery mechanism. Including NTS local switching 
    costs in per-minute access charges contributes significantly toward 
    unnecessarily high per-minute long distance rates for all customers. 
    Restructuring rates to reflect more accurately cost-causation will 
    promote competition, reduce per-minute charges, stimulate long-distance 
    usage, and improve the overall efficiency of the rate structure.
        132. We also reject proposals to recover the entire NTS portion of 
    local switching costs from the new universal service support 
    mechanisms. In the Universal Service Order, we agreed with the Joint 
    Board that we should establish a ``nationwide benchmark based on 
    average revenues per line for local, discretionary, interstate and 
    intrastate access services, and other telecommunications revenues that 
    will be used with either a cost model or a cost study to determine the 
    level of support carriers will receive for lines in a particular 
    geographic area.'' We find that it would be inconsistent with the Joint 
    Board's recommendation if we were to mandate recovery of NTS local 
    switching costs directly from universal service support mechanisms, 
    independent of the revenue benchmark, and the percentage of high cost 
    support recoverable from the federal universal service mechanisms at 
    this time.
        133. In allocating costs between the intrastate and interstate 
    jurisdictions, the Commission consults with the states through the 
    operation of the Joint Board on Separations. See 47 U.S.C. sec. 410(c); 
    Amendment of Part 67 of the Commission's Rules and Establishment of a 
    Joint Board, CC Docket No. 80-286, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking and 
    Order Establishing a Joint Board, 45 FR 41459 (June 19, 1980). It is 
    not necessary to await action by the Joint Board on Separations before 
    revising the recovery mechanisms applicable to the interstate portion 
    of the costs attributed to line ports and dedicated trunk ports. Our 
    revision of the mechanisms used to recover the interstate portion of 
    the costs in Part 32 local switching accounts that the jurisdictional 
    separations process allocates to the interstate jurisdiction will have 
    no direct effect on that allocation because these costs will continue 
    to be separated in Part 36 based on relative dial-equipment-minutes of 
    use. The fact that local switching costs are apportioned between 
    jurisdictions based on a relative interstate and state usage is 
    irrelevant to the choice of pricing structure for recovering those 
    costs, however. Economic efficiency does not require the jurisdictional 
    separation of NTS costs be based on an NTS (flat) factor. The 
    jurisdictional separations process only determines whether the billed 
    charges (flat or variable) are characterized as intrastate or 
    interstate. Economic efficiency does require that NTS costs, regardless 
    of how they are separated, be recovered in each jurisdiction through 
    flat charges. Thus, there was no loss of economic efficiency when the 
    Commission, agreeing with the recommendation of the Joint Board, 
    simplified the separation of local switching by eliminating the former 
    distinction between NTS and traffic-sensitive costs and creating a 
    single switching category that is assigned to the jurisdictions based 
    on dial equipment minutes. MTS and WATS Market Structure, CC Docket No. 
    78-72, Report and Order, 52 FR 17228 (May 6, 1987).
        134. On the other hand, economic efficiency will be increased if 
    local switching costs (regardless of the jurisdiction to which they are 
    assigned) are recovered through a combination of flat charges for NTS 
    costs and traffic sensitive charges for the remainder. Because, at the 
    time that the Commission established the current jurisdictional 
    separations process, it did not consider the distinction between the 
    switch and the port that we address today, the current jurisdictional 
    separations process does not distinguish port costs from the costs of 
    the local switch itself. 47 CFR 36.125(b). We have the authority and 
    obligation, independent from the Joint Board, to establish appropriate 
    rate structures for recovering the costs the jurisdictional separations 
    process allocates to the interstate jurisdiction. E.g., 47 U.S.C. secs. 
    151, 152, 154(i-j). We take steps today to address the fact that the 
    costs of line ports and dedicated trunk ports are more properly 
    recovered for Part 69 purposes from the Common Line and Direct-Trunked 
    Transport rate elements as NTS charges, instead of from the traffic 
    sensitive Local Switching element. We will, however, examine any 
    jurisdictional separations issues presented by NTS switching costs in 
    our upcoming separations Notice of Proposed Rulemaking.
        135. Costs may vary for shared local switching facilities according 
    to the number of lines connected, or the traffic over those lines. In 
    the former case, the costs of the shared facility may be recovered in 
    the most cost-causative manner by imposing a proportionate share of the 
    costs on each line while, in the latter case, usage-sensitive charges 
    may better reflect cost causation. With respect to such shared local 
    switching facilities, including the switching matrix and shared trunk 
    ports, we gave states flexibility in our interconnection proceeding to 
    establish either per-minute usage charges, or flat-rated charges, as 
    appropriate. Local Competition Order. In the access context, however, 
    we will continue to require price cap incumbent LECs to recover the 
    costs of shared local switching facilities, including the central 
    processor, switching matrix, and shared trunk ports, on a per-minute 
    basis. On the basis of the information in the record before us, it 
    would be difficult to identify the NTS and traffic-sensitive portions 
    of the costs of shared switching facilities and to verify the accuracy 
    of LEC studies attempting to do so. Therefore, until we gain more
    
    [[Page 31889]]
    
    experience with rate structures for unbundled network elements that are 
    implemented pursuant to Sections 251 and 252 and that segregate these 
    costs into traffic-sensitive and NTS components, we will continue to 
    adhere to the current, per-minute rate structure for shared switching 
    facilities.
    2. Traffic Sensitive Charges
        136. In the NPRM, we sought comment on several alternative rate 
    structures for recovery of usage-sensitive local switching costs. 
    Specifically, we sought comment on whether the Commission should 
    require or permit LECs to establish a separate charge for call setup, 
    and if so, whether the charge should be levied on all call attempts, or 
    only completed calls. We also sought comment on whether the Commission 
    should require or permit incumbent LECs to establish peak and off-peak 
    pricing structures for shared local switching facilities, and whether 
    the existing per-minute rate structure adequately reflects the manner 
    in which traffic-sensitive local switching costs are incurred.
    a. Call Setup Charges
        137. Among price cap carriers today, most call setup is performed 
    with out-of-band signalling, generally using the SS7 signalling 
    network. In light of the widely varying estimates of the costs of call 
    setup in the record, we conclude that these costs may be more than a de 
    minimis portion of the costs of local switching. The record indicates 
    that these call setup charges are incurred primarily on a per-call 
    rather than a per-minute basis. By requiring recovery the costs of call 
    setup on a per-minute basis, our current rate structure mandates an 
    implicit subsidy running from customers that make lengthy calls to 
    those that make many short-duration calls. Therefore, we find that we 
    should not continue to require the price cap LECs to recover costs of 
    call setup from per-minute local switching charges.
        138. Accordingly, we will revise Section 69.106 of our rules, 47 
    CFR Sec. 69.106, to permit, but not to require, price cap LECs to 
    establish a separate per-call setup charge assessed on IXCs for all 
    calls handed off to the IXC's point of presence (POP). As noted 
    earlier, because an incumbent LEC originating an interstate call incurs 
    call setup costs even if the call is not completed at the called 
    location, we permit these LECs to recover call setup charges on all 
    originating interstate calls that are handed off to the IXC's POP, and 
    on all terminating calls that are received from an IXC's POP. With 
    respect to originating call attempts, we agree with the California 
    Commission that, when the call is handed off to the IXC's POP, the 
    incumbent LEC's switches and signalling network have performed their 
    functions and the incumbent LEC has incurred the full cost of call 
    setup. We also permit incumbent LECs to impose a setup charge for 
    terminating calls received from an IXC's POP, whether or not that call 
    is completed at the called location, because the incumbent LEC 
    signalling network in either case must perform its setup function.
        139. We conclude that the call setup charge should not be mandatory 
    because some incumbent LECs may determine that call setup costs either 
    are in fact de minimis or are otherwise outweighed by the costs of the 
    network and operations support systems (OSS) upgrades necessary to 
    install measurement and billing systems. In such cases, it would be 
    economically inefficient to mandate a separate call-setup charge 
    because the costs of collecting the charge might exceed the revenue 
    collected from the charge itself. We are aware that, by making the 
    call-setup charge permissive only, we may allow certain incumbent LECs' 
    rate structures to continue to subsidize short-duration calls. We 
    nevertheless conclude that we should not mandate separate collection of 
    a call-setup charge in cases where the LEC determines that the costs of 
    eliminating this subsidy exceed the benefits to be gained. In contrast, 
    we find that those incumbent LECs that either have or obtain the 
    ability to implement a call-setup charge should have the flexibility to 
    adopt this cost-causative rate structure.
        140. No party disputes the fact that incumbent LECs incur costs of 
    call setup for call attempts, in addition to completed calls. Some 
    parties, however, argue that call setup charges should be assessed only 
    on completed calls in order to reduce customer confusion. We anticipate 
    that consumer confusion will be minimal, however, because the call 
    setup charge we permit will be imposed on IXCs, not end users. We find 
    it unlikely that IXCs would choose to pass this charge along to their 
    customers in the form of a separate charge per call attempt. For 
    instance, IXCs today generally charge their customers for completed 
    long distance calls even though they incur access charges for many 
    uncompleted calls as well.
        141. Other commenters state that setup charges imposed on call 
    attempts will result in charges being imposed on a caller that has not 
    received service. LCI asserts that ``customers do not expect to pay for 
    uncompleted call attempts, and the carriers are not entitled to recover 
    their costs of uncompleted call attempts,'' citing the Commission's 
    decision in VIA USA, Ltd, 10 FCC Rcd 9540, 9545 (1995). The text cited 
    from that order, however, addresses only customer expectations that 
    have arisen because our current rules make no explicit provision for 
    the recovery of costs of an uncompleted call. We now find that a call 
    setup charge, assessed to an IXC, should not be prohibited because a 
    rate structure that recovers some switching costs through a per-call 
    setup charge on all call attempts is more cost-causative than one 
    limited to the recovery of costs only from completed calls.
        142. Still other commenters argue that, if we permit call setup 
    charges to be imposed for call attempts, we will, at best, open the 
    door to unauditable billing errors or, at worst, facilitate incumbent 
    LEC fraud and duplicity. These commenters argue that the incumbent LEC 
    will be able to generate additional revenue, or degrade the service of 
    IXC competitors, by blocking calls at its own switch. Based on this 
    record, we conclude that these concerns are not well-founded. By 
    permitting a setup charge only for originating call attempts that are 
    handed off to the IXC's POP, we minimize the originating incumbent 
    LEC's incentive to engage in this type of activity because the 
    incumbent LEC will receive no compensation for calls blocked at its own 
    switch. In addition, incumbent LECs have compelling incentives to 
    deliver interstate calls to an IXC's POP. As competition develops for 
    local service, it appears doubtful that an incumbent LEC would find it 
    advantageous to block deliberately interstate calls placed by their end 
    user customers. Such practices would encourage entry by new competitors 
    and increase the interest of affected end users in finding a more 
    reliable service provider. We also find it unlikely that either 
    originating or terminating incumbent LECs would intentionally risk the 
    collection of often significant per-minute access charge revenues on a 
    completed long-distance call in order to collect additional, much 
    smaller per-call setup charges. Finally, we know of no significant 
    allegations of degraded service quality attributable to the very 
    similar current regime, under which incumbent LECs collect at least a 
    full minute of originating access revenues on uncompleted calls 
    delivered to the IXC's POP. We are prepared, however, to investigate 
    claims that an incumbent LEC is blocking calls in an intentional or 
    discriminatory manner.
        143. Several large business customers that make substantial numbers 
    of short-duration calls, such as those associated
    
    [[Page 31890]]
    
    with credit card authorization, automatic teller machine operation, or 
    other transaction-oriented data transfers, argue that imposing a call 
    setup charge will be disruptive to their businesses and may force them 
    to use alternatives to the public switched network. These commenters 
    are the primary beneficiaries of the subsidy that is implicit in the 
    current recovery of call setup costs on a per-minute basis, running 
    from customers that make lengthy calls to those that make many short-
    duration calls. The existing rate structure may well have encouraged 
    users who make many short duration calls to use the public-switched 
    network in inefficient ways. Rate structures that are aligned with cost 
    causation, on the other hand, should encourage economically-efficient 
    use of the telecommunications network. Transaction-oriented users of 
    the network may be motivated to develop more economically efficient 
    processing methods, with resulting economic benefits. Because this 
    group of IXC customers may need time to adjust to the new rate 
    structure, however, incumbent LECs choosing to impose a per-call setup 
    charge on IXCs may do so, at the earliest, in their access tariff 
    filings effective July 1, 1998. This gives a customer over one year to 
    make any necessary adjustments. This time should be sufficient to 
    mitigate any potential disruptive effects of this rate structure 
    change.
        144. MCI asserts that there may be costs of call setup in addition 
    to those associated with signalling, such as a portion of the switch 
    central processor costs. We limit the costs that an incumbent LEC may 
    recover through call setup charges, however, to those associated with 
    signalling because we agree with MCI that it would be extremely 
    difficult to separate the costs of the switch CPU and other traffic-
    sensitive costs into per-message and per-minute portions and to verify 
    that the allocation has been done properly.
        145. Several commenters caution that, if we permit a call setup 
    charge, we should also ensure that the charge does not overlap with any 
    SS7-related charges now permitted or developed in this proceeding. 
    Because call setup is one function of the SS7 network, some of these 
    costs may already be recovered through the current Part 69 SS7 rate 
    elements. 47 CFR Sec. 125. Currently, Section 69.125 of our rules 
    permits LECs to recover from IXCs only (1) a flat-rated signalling link 
    charge for the Dedicated Network Access Line (DNAL); and (2) a flat 
    rated Signal Transfer Point (STP) port termination charge. 47 CFR 
    Sec. 69.125. While these elements recover the costs of some dedicated 
    SS7 facilities, they do not include the usage-based signalling costs of 
    call setup, including the costs incurred to switch messages at the 
    local STP, to transmit messages between an STP and the incumbent LEC's 
    end office or tandem switch, and to process or formulate signal 
    information at an end office or tandem switch.
        146. Currently, the setup costs of certain calls may be recovered 
    through database query charges, either for the line information 
    database (LIDB), 47 CFR Sec. 69.120, or the 800 database, 47 CFR 
    Sec. 69.118. In addition, incumbent LECs recover some costs associated 
    with the provision of certain signalling information necessary for 
    third parties to offer tandem switching through the ``signalling for 
    tandem switching'' rate element, 47 CFR Sec. 129.
        147. Imposing a call setup charge for interexchange calls should 
    not overlap with any of these existing rate elements. Nevertheless, we 
    clarify that an incumbent LEC choosing to impose a call setup charge 
    may not include in that charge any costs that it continues to recover 
    either through other local switching charges, through charges for 
    dedicated SS7 facilities, or through other signalling charges. In this 
    Order, we also permit incumbent LECs to adopt a more detailed SS7 rate 
    structure, modeled on that currently used by Ameritech under waiver. 
    Ameritech SS7 Waiver Order. This SS7 rate structure may permit LECs to 
    recover a significant portion of their call setup costs without an 
    additional call setup charge. Given estimates in the record that SS7 is 
    used to provide signalling for more than 95 percent of the large LECs' 
    customers, we conclude that, in the ordinary case, a price cap LEC will 
    not need to use both the optional SS7 rate structure and a separate 
    call setup charge to recover the costs of call setup. We recognize, 
    however, that some call setup is still performed using in-band, 
    multifrequency (MF) signalling, rather than out-of-band signalling 
    systems. Because SS7 charges will not recover costs of call setup using 
    MF signalling, we do not prohibit the use of both SS7 and call setup 
    charges. We caution LECs adopting both the optional SS7 rate structure 
    and an additional call setup charge, however, that cost support filed 
    with access tariffs must clearly indicate the allocation of individual 
    costs of call setup between these two recovery mechanisms; the same 
    costs cannot be double-recovered using both mechanisms.
    b. Peak and Off-Peak Pricing
        148. We conclude that we should not now mandate a peak-rate pricing 
    structure for local switching. The record reflects significant 
    practical difficulties that may make it difficult or impossible to 
    establish and enforce a rational, efficient, and fair peak-rate 
    structure as a matter of regulation. For example, the record outlines a 
    variety of difficulties that incumbent LECs will confront in 
    determining peak and off-peak hours with any degree of certainty, based 
    on geographic, user-type, service, and other variations. Moreover, peak 
    usage periods may shift over time as usage patterns change, and as 
    competitors enter the market. Based on these difficulties, some 
    incumbent LECs may find it too costly or too difficult to develop, 
    implement, and maintain a peak-rate structure that will allow them to 
    capture all or most of the benefits this structure could offer.
        149. We do recognize the possible efficiency of a peak-rate 
    structure. Local Competition Order. Accordingly, we will consider 
    whether LECs should have the flexibility to develop such peak and off-
    peak rate structures for local switching on a permissive basis when we 
    consider other issues of rate structure flexibility in a subsequent 
    Report and Order that we will adopt in this proceeding.
    
    C. Transport
    
        150. Transport service is the component of interstate switched 
    access consisting of transmission between the IXC's point of presence 
    (POP) and LEC end offices. Transport Rate Structure and Pricing, CC 
    Docket No. 91-213, Third Memorandum Opinion and Order on 
    Reconsideration and Supplemental Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 60 FR 
    2068, (January 6, 1995) (Third Transport Reconsideration Order). 
    Currently, incumbent LECs offer two basic types of interoffice 
    transport services. The first, direct-trunked transport, uses dedicated 
    circuits for transport between a LEC end office and the LEC serving 
    wire center, or between any other two points the direct-trunked 
    transport customer requests. The second, tandem switched transport, 
    uses common transport facilities to connect the end office to a tandem 
    switch. Common transport circuits may be used to transmit the 
    individual calls of many IXCs and even the incumbent LEC itself. 
    Transport circuits dedicated to a particular access customer connect 
    the tandem switch to the serving wire center. Dedicated entrance 
    circuits carry traffic between the IXC POP and the serving wire center, 
    whether the IXC uses direct-
    
    [[Page 31891]]
    
    trunked transport or tandem-switched transport.
        151. In the NPRM, we expressed concern that some of our current 
    Part 69 rules, see, e.g., 47 CFR Secs. 69.110, 69,111, 69.112, 69.124, 
    may require LECs to recover transport costs through rate structures 
    that do not reflect accurately the way these costs are incurred. We 
    sought comment on possible revisions to many of these rate elements.
    1. Entrance Facilities and Direct-Trunked Transport
    a. Background
        152. Entrance facilities are dedicated circuits that connect an 
    access customer's POP with the LEC's serving wire center. Direct-
    trunked transport facilities are dedicated trunks that carry an access 
    customer's traffic from the LEC end office to the serving wire center 
    without switching at the tandem switch. In the First Transport Order, 
    we mandated an interim rate structure under which entrance facilities 
    and direct trunked transport are priced on a flat-rated basis, which 
    may be distance sensitive. Transport Rate Structure and Pricing, CC 
    Docket No. 91-213, Report and Order and Further Notice of Proposed 
    Rulemaking, 57 FR 54717 (November 20, 1992) (First Transport Order); 
    see also 47 CFR Sec. 69.110. Initial rate levels for direct-trunked 
    transport and entrance facilities were presumed reasonable if they were 
    set equal to the rates for corresponding special access service 
    components (special access service and special access channel 
    termination, respectively). Transport Rate Structure and Pricing, CC 
    Docket No. 91-213, First Memorandum Opinion and Order on 
    Reconsideration, 58 FR 41184, (August 3, 1993) (First Transport 
    Reconsideration Order). In the NPRM, we tentatively concluded that, 
    because direct-trunked transport and entrance facilities appear to be 
    dedicated to individual customers, a flat-rated pricing structure 
    accurately reflected the way LECs incur the costs of these facilities. 
    We sought comment on this tentative conclusion and on whether incumbent 
    LECs should be permitted to offer transport services differentiated by 
    whether the LEC or the IXC is responsible for channel facility 
    assignments (CFAs). A channel facility assignment is the actual 
    designation of the routing that a circuit takes within the incumbent 
    LEC network. This assignment may be made either by an IXC purchasing a 
    dedicated circuit, or the incumbent LEC itself. We also sought comment 
    on whether any rules in addition to the interim rules are necessary to 
    govern rate levels for these services.
    b. Discussion
        153. We conclude that both entrance facilities and direct-trunked 
    transport services should continue to be priced on a flat-rated basis 
    and that charges for these services may be distance-sensitive. In the 
    First Transport Order, we found that such a flat charge would 
    facilitate competition in the direct-trunked transport market and 
    encourage incumbent LECs to make efficient network decisions. For the 
    same reasons, and because this pricing structure is reflective of the 
    manner in which incumbent LECs incur the costs of provisioning these 
    facilities, we confirm that the interim rate structure the Commission 
    adopted for these facilities should be made final.
        154. US West and Sprint make a persuasive showing that, as carriers 
    expand their use of fiber-optic ring architecture and other modern 
    network designs, transport costs should become less distance sensitive 
    because LECs may transport a call along any one of many paths to its 
    destination based on transient network traffic levels. We conclude, 
    however, that we need not amend our Part 69 rules now to reflect the 
    decreasing sensitivity of transport costs to distance. Our rules 
    permit, but do not mandate, the use of distance sensitive transport 
    charges. Therefore, if an incumbent LEC determines that its transport 
    costs have become less distance sensitive, it may reduce or eliminate 
    the distance-sensitivity of its direct-trunked transport rates. For two 
    reasons, we expect that incumbent LECs will adjust their rates to 
    reflect any change in the distance sensitivity of transport costs. 
    First, as US West states, ring architecture will be most prevalent, and 
    therefore, will reduce the distance sensitivity of rates most 
    dramatically, in densely populated areas. When an incumbent LEC obtains 
    authority to deaverage access rates geographically, therefore, it may 
    choose to offer a less distance-sensitive pricing structure in more 
    densely populated areas than it does in less densely populated areas. 
    Such a structure would properly reflect the reduced distance 
    sensitivity of the incumbent LEC's costs in more densely populated 
    areas. Second, as competition develops, incumbent LECs will come under 
    increasing market pressures to maintain rates that reflect the nature 
    of the costs underlying the service. If they choose not to do so, we 
    expect that new market entrants will develop competitive service 
    offerings at prices more reflective of underlying costs.
        155. We decline Ameritech's request in its comments for immediate 
    flexibility to offer new technologies to switched access customers 
    without obtaining a Part 69 waiver or passing a public interest test. 
    In our Price Cap Performance Review for Local Exchange Carriers, CC 
    Docket No. 94-1, Third Report and Order, 62 FR 4657 (January 1, 1997) 
    (Price Cap Performance Review Third Report and Order), adopted along 
    with the NPRM in this proceeding, we eliminated the need for a Part 69 
    waiver for new services, and instead required incumbent LECs to file a 
    petition demonstrating that introduction of the new service would be 
    consistent with the public interest. Such petitions will give LECs that 
    desire to do so the opportunity to make their cases and receive the 
    requested flexibility. See 47 CFR Sec. 69.4(g). This procedure 
    significantly streamlined the prior waiver process, and we conclude 
    that the public interest will not suffer if we do not grant incumbent 
    LECs additional immediate flexibility in this area as part of our basic 
    rate structure modifications. We will give further consideration to 
    Ameritech's request for additional flexibility to offer new 
    technologies to switched access customers as part of our assessment of 
    other aspects of pricing flexibility in a subsequent Report and Order 
    in this proceeding.
        156. We also will consider whether LECs should be permitted to 
    offer direct-trunked transport services that are differentiated by 
    whether the incumbent LEC or the transport customer is responsible for 
    performing channel facility assignments in connection with our 
    evaluation of other forms of pricing flexibility in a subsequent Report 
    and Order in this proceeding. As MCI argues in its comments, it is 
    unclear whether rates for direct-trunked transport where the LEC 
    controls the CFA should be higher or lower than the rates that apply 
    where the IXC controls the CFA. Although the LEC may be able to make 
    more efficient use of its network facilities when it controls the CFAs 
    itself, this efficiency benefit may be offset by the additional costs 
    the LEC incurs in performing the CFA function. We agree with MCI that 
    an incumbent LEC may be able to increase its network efficiency by 
    retaining or assuming control of CFAs, particularly if an IXC orders a 
    relatively large amount of transport capacity. In those cases, however, 
    rate differentiation based on CFA control appears to be the functional 
    equivalent of a volume discount. As a result, we will consider this 
    issue, along with other pricing flexibility issues, in a
    
    [[Page 31892]]
    
    subsequent Report and Order planned in this docket.
        157. In its comments, USTA requests that we forbear under Section 
    10 of the Communications Act, 47 U.S.C. sec. 160, from regulating 
    services in the interexchange basket, special access, collocated 
    direct-trunked transport, and directory assistance. We will address 
    USTA's request along with other pricing flexibility issues, in a 
    subsequent Report and Order planned in this docket.
    2. Tandem-Switched Transport
    a. Background
        158. Tandem-switched transport uses trunks that are shared among 
    many IXCs and the LEC itself to carry traffic between the end office 
    and a tandem switch. The tandem switch routes IXC traffic onto an 
    appropriate dedicated trunk that runs between the tandem switch and the 
    serving wire center. An IXC may use tandem-switched transport either as 
    its primary form of transport in lieu of direct-trunked transport, or 
    to carry traffic that overflows from its direct-trunked transport 
    facilities at peak periods. In 1982, the Modification of Final Judgment 
    (MFJ) established an interim rule that required, until September 1, 
    1991, BOC charges to IXCs to be ``equal, per unit of traffic'' of a 
    given type transported between end offices and facilities of the IXCs 
    within an exchange area or within reasonable subzones of an exchange 
    area. United States v. American Tel. and Tel. Co., 552 F. Supp. 131, 
    233-34 (AT&T Consent Decree, Appendix B, Section B(3)), aff'd sub nom. 
    Maryland v. United States, 460 U.S. 1001 (1983).
        159. The Commission replaced the ``equal charge'' rule in 1993 with 
    an interim rate structure for tandem-switched transport. This interim 
    structure allows IXCs to choose between two rate structures for the 
    purchase of tandem-switched transport. Both options provide for a per-
    minute tandem switching charge. Under the first option, an IXC may 
    elect to pay ``unitary'' per-minute charge for transmission of traffic 
    from the end office, through the tandem switching office, to the 
    serving wire center. This charge may be distance sensitive, with 
    distance measured in airline miles from the end office to the serving 
    wire center. Under the second option, the ``three-part rate 
    structure,'' in addition to the charge for the tandem switch, an IXC 
    may elect to purchase transmission on a bifurcated basis, with the end 
    office-to-tandem portion charged on a per-minute basis, and the tandem-
    to-serving wire center portion charged as direct-trunked transport 
    facilities, i.e., on a flat-rated basis. Under the three-part rate 
    structure, both portions of the transmission charge may be distance 
    sensitive based on the airline mileage to the tandem office.
        160. In adopting the interim rate structure, the Commission stated 
    that initial direct-trunked and tandem-switched transport rates would 
    be presumed reasonable if set based on special access rates in effect 
    on September 1, 1992, using a DS3 to DS1 rate ratio of at least 9.6 to 
    1. First Transport Order. Special access customers use a dedicated 
    trunk running between the customer's premises and the IXC's POP, 
    thereby bypassing the LEC's switched network facilities altogether. 
    This service is primarily used by large volume users in densely 
    populated areas. Per-minute tandem-switched transport rates were 
    presumed reasonable if set using a weighted average of DS1 and DS3 
    rates reflecting the relative numbers of circuits of each type in use 
    in the tandem-to-end office link, and assuming circuit loading of 9000 
    minutes of use per month per voice-grade circuit. Id.
        161. Under the interim rate structure, whether a tandem-switched 
    transport customer elects to purchase tandem-switched transport under 
    the unitary or the three-part rate structure, the LEC imposes a 
    separate, per-minute charge on the tandem-switched transport customer 
    for use of the tandem switch. The Commission set this charge initially 
    to recover only twenty percent of the tandem revenue requirement, in 
    order to: (1) protect small IXCs that use tandem-switched transport as 
    their primary transport mechanism from substantial increases in tandem-
    switched transport rates, see Competitive Telecommunications Ass'n v. 
    FCC, 87 F.3d 522, 526-27 (D.C. Cir. 1996) (CompTel); (2) ensure that 
    the interim rate structure did not ``endanger the availability of 
    pluralistic supply in the interexchange market'' that had developed 
    under the equal charge rule, First Transport Order; and (3) allow IXCs 
    a transitional period to reconfigure their networks to eliminate 
    inefficiencies that had developed under the equal charge rule and to 
    prepare for a fully cost-based rate structure, id. Unlike the direct-
    trunked and tandem-switched transport rates, which are set using 
    overhead loadings based on special access, the tandem switching rates 
    used higher overhead loadings applicable to switched access.
        162. As part of the interim rate structure, the Commission also 
    created the TIC to recover on a per-minute basis from all switched 
    access customers the difference between the Part 69 transport revenue 
    requirement and the revenues projected to be recovered under the 
    interim rate structure. Id. The TIC was explicitly intended to make the 
    transition to the interim rate structure revenue neutral. Id. Among 
    other possible costs, the TIC recovers the remaining 80 percent of the 
    tandem-switching revenue requirement.
        163. Portions of the interim transport rate structure were recently 
    remanded to the Commission by the United States Court of Appeals for 
    the District of Columbia Circuit, CompTel, 87 F.3d 522. With respect to 
    tandem-switching rates and the TIC, the Court ordered us either to 
    implement a cost-based rate structure or offer a ``rational and non-
    conclusory analysis in support of [our] determination that an 
    alternative structure is preferable.'' Id. at 736. With respect to 
    overhead loadings, the Court ordered us either to substantiate that our 
    current method of allocating overhead is cost-based, choose a method 
    that is, or provide a reasoned explanation of our decision to pursue a 
    non-cost-based system. Id.
        164. In the NPRM, we sought comment on several alternative rate 
    structures for tandem-switched transport service facilities, including: 
    (a) maintaining the interim rate structure, which permits the IXCs to 
    choose between the two pricing alternatives above; (b) eliminating the 
    unitary rate option and requiring the IXCs to purchase tandem-switched 
    transport under the three-part rate structure; or (c) developing 
    another, different rate structure. We also sought comment on whether, 
    in conjunction with any of these pricing options, we should apply to 
    tandem switching any of the options for local switching discussed 
    above, including whether we should establish separate flat-rated 
    charges for the dedicated ports on the serving wire center side of the 
    tandem or other NTS components of the tandem switch, and whether usage-
    based or flat rates more accurately reflect shared tandem-switching 
    costs. We also sought comment on whether, in conjunction with any of 
    these options, we should permit or require peak load pricing for usage-
    based charges for tandem-switched transport service, and on whether any 
    portion of tandem-switched transport costs should be recovered from 
    direct-trunked transport customers.
    b. Overview of Rate Structure and Rate Level Changes
        165. In this section, we summarize the changes we make to the 
    tandem-switched transport rate structure and rate levels below. We 
    conclude that we
    
    [[Page 31893]]
    
    should require incumbent LECs to implement a cost-based rate structure 
    for tandem-switched transport in four stages over a two year transition 
    period. Unlike our previous transition plans, however, we set forth 
    today, for the first time, the details of a final, cost-based transport 
    rate structure. We have long recognized that non-cost based rate 
    structures can, among other dangers, (1) threaten the long-term 
    viability of the nations's telephone systems; (2) distort the decision 
    whether to use alternative telecommunications technologies; and (3) 
    encourage ``uneconomic bypass'' of the public switched 
    telecommunications network, raising rates for all. MTS and WATS Market 
    Structure Third Report and Order.
        166. Until today, however, we have limited ourselves to interim 
    transport rate structure plans, such as the equal charge rule and the 
    interim rate structure described above. While the interim rate 
    structure increased the cost-based nature of our transport rate 
    structure, it also included significant non-cost-based elements. We 
    have not, until today, laid out a clear transition plan that describes 
    all the steps necessary to achieve cost-based transport rates. As a 
    result, although all carriers have no doubt been aware of our intention 
    to move to a cost-based rate structure, they have been able only to 
    react to our transitional steps, announced piecemeal. Because we have 
    not announced a definite and detailed end state--a final, cost-based 
    rate structure--we have afforded carriers little opportunity to plan, 
    adjust, and develop their networks in preparation for such a rate 
    structure, despite our lengthy period of ``transition.'' Accordingly, 
    because of the potential magnitude of the rate impact of these changes, 
    we conclude that a four-step implementation over a two-year period will 
    minimize the risk of rate shock and allow transport customers to adjust 
    while we move as expeditiously as possible to cost-based transport 
    rates as required by the CompTel decision.
        167. The first step will occur in incumbent LEC access tariffs to 
    become effective on January 1, 1998. In those tariffs, incumbent price 
    cap LECs must establish new rate elements for recovery of the costs of 
    DS3/DS1 and DS1/voice-grade multiplexers used in conjunction with the 
    tandem switch. The rate element for the dedicated multiplexers on the 
    serving wire center side of the tandem will recover these costs on a 
    flat-rated basis, while the rate element for the multiplexers on the 
    end office side of the tandem will be assessed per minute of use. In 
    addition, incumbent price cap LECs must establish in those tariffs a 
    flat-rated charge to recover the costs of dedicated trunk ports on the 
    serving wire center side of the tandem. None of our existing rate 
    elements currently recovers the costs of either these multiplexers or 
    these dedicated trunk ports. Accordingly, we conclude that those costs 
    are currently recovered through the TIC, and that incumbent price cap 
    LECs must reduce the TIC to reflect the recovery of these costs through 
    the new rate elements. Also on January 1, 1998, all incumbent LECs must 
    take the first of three annual steps to reallocate to the tandem-
    switching rate element tandem switching revenues currently being 
    recovered through the TIC. In tariffs filed to be effective on that 
    date, we require incumbent LECs to reallocate one third of the portion 
    of the tandem switching revenue requirement that they currently recover 
    through the TIC, excluding signalling and dedicated port costs that we 
    reallocate elsewhere, to the tandem switching rate element.
        168. The second step will occur in incumbent LEC tariffs to become 
    effective July 1, 1998. At that time, all incumbent LECs must eliminate 
    the unitary pricing option for tandem switched transport. Instead, 
    incumbent LECs will be required to provide tandem-switched transport 
    under a three-part rate structure as follows: (1) a per-minute charge 
    for transport of traffic over common transport facilities between the 
    LEC end office and the tandem office; (2) a per-minute tandem switching 
    charge; and (3) a flat-rated charge for transport of traffic over 
    dedicated transport facilities between the serving wire center and the 
    tandem switching office. Incumbent LECs will continue to impose 
    separate multiplexing and port charges established on January 1, 1998, 
    as complementary to the three-part rate structure.
        169. The third and fourth steps will consist of the reallocation of 
    the remaining portion of the tandem-switching revenue requirement 
    currently recovered through the TIC to the tandem-switching rate 
    element. All incumbent LECs are to reallocate one half of the remaining 
    portion of tandem-switching revenue requirement recovered through the 
    TIC to the tandem-switching rate element in access tariffs to become 
    effective January 1, 1999, and the final portion of the tandem-
    switching revenue requirement to the tandem-switching rate element in 
    access tariffs to become effective on January 1, 2000. Before 
    performing this reallocation, price cap incumbent LECs must account for 
    X-factor reductions to the tandem-switching revenues permitted under 
    price caps that have occurred since the TIC was created, as described 
    in Section III.C.2.d, below.
    c. Rate Structure
        170. Multiplexing Costs. As discussed above, we direct incumbent 
    LECs to establish separate rate elements for the multiplexing equipment 
    on each side of the tandem switch. LECs must establish a flat-rated 
    charge for DS1/DS3 multiplexers on the serving wire center side of the 
    tandem, imposed pro-rata on the purchasers of dedicated DS3 trunks on 
    the serving wire center side of the tandem, in proportion to the amount 
    of DS3 trunking capacity purchased by each customer. Unlike DS3 rates, 
    rates for DS1 dedicated trunks already include a portion of the DS1/DS3 
    multiplexer needed for transport. First Transport Order. Multiplexing 
    equipment on the end office side of the tandem shall be charged to 
    users of common end office-to-tandem transport on a per-minute of use 
    basis. These multiplexer rate elements must be included in the LEC 
    access tariff filings to be effective January 1, 1998.
        171. We sought comment in the NPRM on the claim that:
    
        The TIC * * * includes the two additional multiplexers needed in 
    order to multiplex a DS3 circuit down to a DS1 level before 
    switching at the tandem, and then back up to DS3 afterward for 
    transmission to an end office. To the extent that analog tandem 
    switches exist, two additional DS1/[voice-grade] multiplexers are 
    needed to achieve the voice-grade interface with the tandem switch.
    
    None of our existing rate elements explicitly recovers the costs of 
    these multiplexers, and we conclude that these costs are currently 
    recovered as part of the TIC. Accordingly, we establish two rate 
    elements for multiplexers used on the serving wire center side of the 
    tandem switch. The first will recover the costs of DS3/DS1 multiplexers 
    used by purchasers of dedicated DS3 transport trunks from the serving 
    wire center to the tandem switch, and may be levied only on purchasers 
    of such DS3 transport. The second will recover the costs of DS1/voice-
    grade multiplexers used on the serving wire center side of analog 
    tandem switches, and should be levied on purchasers of DS1 or greater 
    capacity dedicated transport from the tandem switch to the serving wire 
    center in proportion to the transport capacity purchased on that route. 
    Like serving wire center-side trunks and trunk ports, both DS3/DS1 and 
    DS1/voice-grade multiplexers on the serving wire center side of the 
    tandem switch are dedicated to individual customers. Accordingly, flat-
    rated NTS charges for these multiplexers are appropriate.
    
    [[Page 31894]]
    
        172. On the end office side of the tandem switch, we establish two 
    additional rate elements. The first will recover the costs of DS3/DS1 
    multiplexers used on the end office side of the tandem switch. This 
    rate element will be a per-minute charge imposed on each IXC purchasing 
    common transport on the end office-to-tandem link. This charge will be 
    calculated based on actual minutes of use of the common transport 
    circuits and will be assessed on IXCs in a 1:1 ratio with minutes of 
    use of common transport. As with common transport trunks, because these 
    multiplexers are shared among all users of common transport, traffic-
    sensitive, per-minute charges are appropriate. The second rate element 
    should be assessed only at analog tandems, to recover in a similar 
    manner the costs of DS1/voice-grade multiplexers needed at these analog 
    tandems.
        173. Price cap LECs must reallocate revenues currently being 
    recovered through the TIC to these rate elements and begin recovery of 
    multiplexing costs using these rate elements in their access tariffs to 
    become effective January 1, 1998.
        174. Dedicated Tandem Switch Trunk Port Costs. Price cap incumbent 
    LECs must establish a separate rate element for dedicated trunk ports 
    used to terminate dedicated trunks on the serving wire center side of 
    the tandem switch. LECs incur the costs of these ports on an NTS basis, 
    but currently must recover their costs through per-minute charges for 
    the tandem switch. Because we have allocated 80 percent of tandem-
    switching costs to the TIC, these port costs may currently be recovered 
    through either per-minute tandem-switching charges, or the per-minute 
    TIC. We now take this opportunity to establish a separate rate element 
    for these costs. Price cap LECs must establish a flat-rated element for 
    dedicated trunk ports on the serving wire center side of the tandem, 
    assessed on the purchaser of the dedicated trunk terminated at that 
    port. This rate element shall be a flat-rated charge assessed on the 
    carrier purchasing the dedicated trunk terminated at that port, and 
    must also be included in tariff filings to become effective January 1, 
    1998.
        175. Three-Part Rate Structure. We also direct all incumbent LECs 
    to discontinue the unitary rate structure option for the transmission 
    component of tandem-switched transport, effective July 1, 1998. In 
    their access tariffs that take effect on July 1, 1998, incumbent LECs 
    will be required to provide tandem-switched transport under a three-
    part rate structure as follows: (1) a per-minute charge for transport 
    of traffic over common transport facilities between the LEC end office 
    and the tandem office; (2) a per-minute tandem switching charge; and 
    (3) a flat-rated charge for transport of traffic over dedicated 
    transport facilities between the serving wire center and the tandem 
    switching office. This three part rate structure reflects the manner in 
    which the incumbent LEC incurs the costs of providing each component of 
    tandem-switched transport. By establishing a per-minute, traffic-
    sensitive rate for the shared common transport trunks and the tandem 
    switch, incumbent LECs will recover these costs from each IXC in 
    proportion to its use. The incumbent LEC, in contrast, incurs the costs 
    of the dedicated serving wire center-to-tandem trunk on an NTS basis 
    because, like other dedicated trunks, the LEC must provision the trunk 
    for the exclusive use of one IXC. Once this capacity is dedicated, the 
    cost of the trunk does not vary with the amount of traffic transmitted 
    by the IXC.
        176. The three-part rate structure may cause some tandem-switched 
    transport customers to increase their use of direct-trunked transport 
    relative to tandem-switched transport. As discussed above, making this 
    rate structure change effective on July 1, 1998, will provide tandem-
    switched transport customers that currently take service under the 
    unitary rate structure with notice of this change sufficient to enable 
    them to adjust their networks to provide service in the most efficient 
    way possible, and to mitigate any sudden effect on rates such a change 
    could have if implemented on shorter notice. In order to encourage 
    transport customers to increase the efficiency of their transport 
    networks quickly, we will require incumbent LECs to waive certain 
    nonrecurring charges until six months after the three-part rate 
    structure becomes mandatory. Therefore, from the effective date of this 
    Order until six months after the effective date of tariffs eliminating 
    the unitary pricing option for tandem-switched transport, the incumbent 
    LECs shall not assess any nonrecurring charges for service connection 
    when a transport customer converts trunks from tandem-switched to 
    direct-trunked transport or orders the disconnection of overprovisioned 
    trunks.
        177. When we replaced the equal charge rule in 1991, we stated 
    three principles that would guide our efforts to develop the transport 
    rate structure: (1) to encourage efficient use of transport facilities 
    by allowing pricing that reflects the way costs are incurred; (2) to 
    avoid interference with the development of interstate access 
    competition; and (3) to facilitate full and fair interexchange 
    competition. First Transport Order. In 1991, we stated that the interim 
    rate structure was a reasonable first step toward achieving these 
    goals, because it was more cost-based than the equal charge rule. First 
    Transport Order. Even from its inception, however, we have recognized 
    that the interim rate structure represents significant compromises that 
    cause it to fall substantially short of these goals in many ways. See 
    First Transport Order; Third Transport Reconsideration Order.
        178. First, the unitary rate option does not accurately reflect the 
    manner in which LECs incur costs in providing tandem-switched transport 
    and, therefore, does not provide maximum incentive for IXCs to use 
    transport facilities efficiently. IXCs may order, and LECs must 
    provide, dedicated transport links with NTS costs on the serving wire 
    center-to-tandem route with no assurance that the traffic-sensitive, 
    per-minute revenues collected will cover the NTS costs of the link. As 
    we stated at the time, the unitary rate structure was intended as an 
    interim measure to allow IXCs time to prepare for a fully cost-based 
    transport rate structure. Third Transport Reconsideration Order. IXCs 
    have now had well over a decade since divestiture to so prepare. We 
    agree with the CompTel decision that it is time to bring this period of 
    preparation to a close as expeditiously as possible without causing 
    severe disruption to carriers. CompTel, 87 F.3d at 530.
        179. Second, by bundling the dedicated and common portions of the 
    transmission component of tandem-switched transport into a single, end-
    to-end per-minute charge, the unitary rate structure inhibits the 
    development of competitive alternatives to incumbent LEC tandem-
    switched transport. While we have required incumbent LECs to provide 
    the collocation, signalling, and unbundled network elements necessary 
    for new entrants to compete with incumbent LECs without having to 
    replicate the incumbent LEC's interoffice transport network, see Local 
    Competition Order; Expanded Interconnection with Local Telephone 
    Company Facilities, CC Docket No. 91-141, Memorandum Opinion and Order, 
    59 FR 38922 (August 1, 1994); Expanded Interconnection with Local 
    Telephone Company Facilities, CC Docket No. 91-141, Transport Phase II, 
    Third Report and Order, 59 FR 32925 (June 27, 1994), we have not 
    corrected the non-cost based aspects of our tandem-switched transport 
    rate structure that reduce incumbent LEC
    
    [[Page 31895]]
    
    rates for tandem-switched transport services. Several commenters have 
    noted that the tandem-switched transport market, despite our efforts, 
    is subject only to limited competition. Moreover, several competitive 
    entrants have stated that they have the capability and desire to offer 
    some or all of the components of tandem-switched transport on a 
    competitive basis, but that the present, unitary rate structure 
    inhibits the development of competition in this area. In addition, each 
    component of tandem-switched transport is not equally susceptible to 
    competitive entry; it is relatively easier for a new entrant to compete 
    to provide the dedicated serving wire center-to-tandem link than it 
    would be to compete to provide either the tandem switch itself or the 
    myriad common transport end office-to-tandem links. Thus, in order to 
    permit the fullest development of competitive alternatives to incumbent 
    LEC networks, we need to unbundle reasonably segregable components of 
    incumbent LEC transport services and price them in the manner in which 
    costs are incurred.
        180. Third, the interim rate structure does not best promote ``full 
    and fair'' interexchange competition. The unitary rate structure has 
    facilitated the growth of small IXCs to compete with larger carriers. 
    It has achieved this, however, by requiring incumbent LECs to price 
    facilities with NTS costs on a per-minute, traffic sensitive basis, in 
    order to allow small IXCs to offer interexchange services at rates 
    comparable to those offered by larger carriers without regard to 
    whether the charges paid by the small IXCs cover the costs of the 
    facilities that they use. While this structure has protected 
    ``pluralistic supply in the interexchange market,'' see First Transport 
    Order, our rules should promote competition, not protect certain 
    competitors. We have recently concluded that no carrier is dominant 
    with respect to domestic, interexchange services, Motion of AT&T to be 
    Reclassified as a Non-Dominant Carrier, Order, 11 FCC Rcd 3271 (1995). 
    Therefore, to the extent that we designed the interim rate structure to 
    facilitate the growth of small IXCs in competition with AT&T, we find 
    that such protective rules are no longer necessary. In a competitive 
    market, we believe that we should strive to make our rate structure 
    rules consistent with cost-causation principles, so long as those 
    principles do not conflict with other statutory obligations, such as 
    universal service. As the CompTel decision stated, ``attempt[ing] to 
    recover costs from IXCs that did not cause those costs to be incurred 
    would impart the wrong incentives to both actual and potential 
    providers of local transport, thereby inducing them to offer an 
    inefficient mix of dedicated, [direct-trunked transport], and tandem-
    switched service.'' CompTel, 87 F.3d at 530-531. Because rules that do 
    not reflect cost-causation may cause IXCs to order an inefficient mix 
    of transport services, such rules artificially raise the costs of 
    providing interexchange services. Rules properly reflecting cost-
    causation, in contrast, will benefit LECs, IXCs, and consumers alike by 
    encouraging competitors to provide service using facilities 
    efficiently. In adopting the interim rate structure, we cited AT&T's 
    estimate that the efficiency benefit to consumers of cost-based pricing 
    and competition could reach $1 billion annually. First Transport Order. 
    Our adoption of the three-part rate structure is intended to permit 
    consumers the benefits of even greater service efficiency.
        181. We therefore adopt the three-part structure as the final 
    tandem-switched transport rate structure because this structure most 
    closely reflects the manner in which LECs incur the costs of each 
    component of the overall tandem-switched transport service. When 
    combined with our actions with respect to the TIC, our adoption of 
    actual minutes of use as the appropriate factor for determining per-
    minute rates for common transport circuits, and our allocation of the 
    full cost of the tandem-switch to the tandem-switching rate elements, 
    we expect that this structure will benefit LECs, IXCs, competitive 
    providers of access services, and consumers. Tandem-switched transport 
    facilities are sized to accommodate peak traffic loads, including 
    overflow traffic from IXCs using direct-trunked transport facilities. 
    Several commenters have stated that, until now, these overflow 
    customers have not borne the full costs of these facilities because 
    overflow customers pay only the same per-minute transmission charges 
    applicable to other IXCs. The three-part rate structure will require 
    the IXC purchasing tandem-switched transmission facilities to pay the 
    full NTS costs of the dedicated serving wire center-to-tandem link, 
    without regard for the amount of traffic transported. This benefit, in 
    turn, will substantially increase IXC incentives to use tandem-switched 
    transport efficiently for overflow traffic.
        182. Some commenters argue that we should retain the unitary rate 
    structure because tandem-switched transport, as a service, has 
    traditionally been offered on an end-to-end basis. We agree that the 
    transmission component of tandem-switched transport has in fact been 
    offered on an end-to-end basis, but only pursuant to the requirements 
    of the MFJ and our interim rate structure rules as part of a transition 
    to cost-based rates. We find, however, that the transmission component 
    of tandem-switched transport is not, in fact, provisioned by the 
    incumbent LEC on an end-to-end basis. Purchasers of direct-trunked 
    transport purchase an end-to-end service; they purchase from the 
    incumbent LEC transport capacity between two end points. Tandem-
    switched transport customers, in contrast, purchase use of the tandem 
    switch to route traffic to their POP. By virtue of their decision to 
    choose tandem-switched transport, these customers specifically obligate 
    the LEC to transport their traffic between the serving wire center and 
    the tandem serving a particular end office or group of end offices and 
    to perform the tandem switching function. Because they cause the 
    incumbent LEC to incur the costs of transmitting their traffic between 
    the serving wire center and the tandem, tandem-switched transport 
    customers should, as a matter of cost-causation, pay the costs of 
    reaching the tandem. In providing tandem-switched service, incumbent 
    LECs must provision two separate circuits with distinctly different 
    cost characteristics--one dedicated, and one shared. Tandem-switched 
    service, therefore, is not provisioned on an end-to-end basis between 
    the end office and serving wire center, but in three parts: (1) 
    transmission from one ``end,'' the end office, to the tandem; (2) the 
    tandem switching function itself; and (3) transmission from the tandem 
    to the other ``end,'' the serving wire center. Just as the tandem-
    switched transport customer pays a separate charge for the tandem 
    switch, the tandem-switched transport customer should pay separately 
    for the two distinct transmission components.
        183. Other commenters argue that the three-part rate structure will 
    create LEC incentives to engage in inefficient network reconfiguration, 
    placing tandems far from end offices and serving wire centers simply to 
    increase tandem-switched transport revenues. These commenters further 
    argue that, if we adopt the three-part rate structure, we need to 
    control this incentive by establishing a process for review of the 
    incumbent LECs' tandem deployment decisions. Based on this record, we 
    conclude that these commenters' fears are not well founded. An 
    incumbent LEC would likely incur substantial costs
    
    [[Page 31896]]
    
    to reconfigure placement of its tandem switches specifically to 
    disadvantage IXC users of tandem switched transport. Because we expect 
    the three part rate structure to catalyze the development of 
    competition, we conclude that the incumbent LEC would not be likely to 
    incur such costs. Although the incumbent LEC might be able to increase 
    its tandem-switched transmission revenues in the short term to reflect 
    inefficient routing, as more efficiently configured competitors enter 
    the market, the LEC would not be able to sustain such artificially 
    inflated rates and would then need to incur additional costs to 
    reconfigure its network efficiently. Because, under our new competitive 
    paradigm, a multitude of investment opportunities, including wireless 
    services, video, and interLATA toll, may emerge for incumbent LECs, we 
    agree with Ameritech that ``[s]uch misspent capital outlays and 
    inefficient network configuration simply would not make good business 
    sense.''
        184. Moreover, the redeployment of tandem switches affects network 
    efficiency with respect to both the incumbent LEC's own local and toll 
    traffic, as well as intrastate and interstate access. Therefore, 
    inefficient network reconfiguration would cause harm both to tandem-
    switched transport customers and to the incumbent LEC itself. Any 
    additional transport revenues that the incumbent LEC generated through 
    inefficient network reconfiguration would be at least partially offset 
    by the additional costs of transporting the LEC's own traffic in 
    similarly inefficient ways. As discussed above, as competition develops 
    in the local market, we expect that an LEC would be reluctant to take 
    steps to decrease its own efficiency.
        185. Some commenters argue that we should retain the unitary rate 
    structure because direct-trunked transport and tandem-switched 
    transport circuits often travel along the same routes using the same 
    physical facilities. These commenters argue, therefore, that it would 
    be unfair or discriminatory to require tandem-switched transport users 
    to purchase transmission based on airline mileage from the end office 
    to the tandem to the serving wire center, while users of direct-trunked 
    transport are permitted to purchase the same route on the basis of 
    airline mileage from end office to the serving wire center directly. 
    Other commenters argue that we should require the LECs to offer both 
    types of transport based on actual route miles, revealing actual LEC 
    network efficiencies and inefficiencies.
        186. We disagree with both of these proposed modifications. An IXC 
    purchasing direct-trunked transport requires the incumbent LEC to 
    provide transport service between the end office and the serving wire 
    center. Because the LEC must route direct-trunked transport traffic 
    between only these two points, our rate structure requires the IXC to 
    pay only for the airline mileage between those two points, reflecting 
    the direct mileage route between the locations in the incumbent LEC 
    network designated by the access customer. In contrast, an IXC 
    purchasing tandem-switched transport purchases use of the access tandem 
    switch and therefore requires the incumbent LEC to provide service 
    between the serving wire center and the tandem, and between the tandem 
    and the end office. Under the three part rate structure, the tandem-
    switched transport customer, like the direct-trunked transport 
    customer, pays for the direct mileage between the locations in the 
    incumbent LEC network designated by the customer--for tandem-switched 
    transport, the serving wire center to tandem, and the tandem to the end 
    office. Because the IXC has chosen to make use of the LEC tandem 
    switching facilities, it should pay explicitly for the transport 
    necessary to reach the tandem. The direct-trunked transport customer, 
    in contrast, does not make use of the tandem switching facilities; even 
    if the LEC routes direct-trunked transport traffic through the tandem 
    office, this traffic is not switched at the tandem. While the incumbent 
    LEC may choose to route direct-trunked traffic through the tandem 
    office based on its own assessment of whether it is economically 
    efficient to do so, the direct-trunked transport customer pays only for 
    direct mileage between the locations it designated in the network.
        187. We are not persuaded by arguments that we should retain the 
    unitary pricing structure because the incumbent LEC, and not the 
    tandem-switched transport customer, has selected the tandem location 
    and, consequently, the tandem-switched transport customer should not 
    pay for the direct mileage to and from the tandem location. The 
    incumbent LEC equally chooses the locations of the serving wire center 
    and end office, and yet access customers routinely pay mileage charges 
    to and from those locations, rather than between the end points of the 
    access service--the POP and the end user location. Similarly, we find 
    that the three-part rate structure does not discriminate against IXCs 
    using tandem-switched transport. As discussed above, the tandem-
    switched transport customer, unlike the direct-trunked transport 
    customer, requires the incumbent LEC to route its traffic to the 
    tandem, and so should pay the costs of reaching the tandem. In 
    addition, an IXC operating efficiently often may choose to locate its 
    POP at or close to the tandem, if the tandem-switching office also can 
    function as the serving wire center, thus eliminating virtually all of 
    the dedicated transport costs of the tandem-to-serving wire center 
    link. While such an arrangement may be the most efficient transport 
    architecture for tandem-switched transport, our current unitary pricing 
    structure does not reflect the underlying costs of tandem-switched 
    transport transmission facilities and so does not encourage efficient 
    transport architectures.
        188. The introduction of more modern network architectures, such as 
    Synchronous Optical Network (SONET) rings, does not alter our 
    conclusion that the three-part rate structure most closely approximates 
    the nature of costs associated with each component of tandem-switched 
    transport. WorldCom, for instance, asserts that the ``pyramid'' diagram 
    included in the NPRM as Figure 1 is outdated and submits a diagram 
    illustrating interoffice tandem-switched transport in a ring-based 
    network. WorldCom states that the multiple routing options and the 
    reduced distance sensitivity of transport costs in a SONET environment 
    compel retention of the unitary rate structure. We conclude, however, 
    that the differences WorldCom identifies do not support retention of 
    the unitary rate structure because, even in a ring-based network, the 
    three-part rate structure treats direct-trunked and tandem-switched 
    transport consistently. In a fiber-optic or ring-based network, 
    dedicated, direct-trunked transport circuits are given a constant, and 
    exclusive, time slot assignment on a large, time-division multiplexed 
    fiber-optic cable. The incumbent LEC routes traffic for the IXC 
    purchasing the direct trunk into the dedicated circuit or time slot, 
    where it is received elsewhere on the ring or in the network at the 
    serving wire center. The direction or precise routing of the signal 
    around the ring is irrelevant for purposes of the rate structure 
    because the transport is priced on an airline-mileage basis between the 
    two end points. Capacity dedicated to a particular IXC, however, is not 
    available to the LEC for other purposes.
        189. SONET ring architecture offers the LEC the capability to 
    transport large traffic volumes with redundant routing options, but it 
    does not alter the fundamental nature of tandem-switched transport. 
    Tandem-switched transport is functionally very different from direct-
    trunked transport because, by
    
    [[Page 31897]]
    
    definition, the incumbent LEC must route an IXC's tandem-switched 
    traffic through the tandem switch serving a particular end office. 
    Whether using a SONET ring or not, the LEC must route its tandem-
    switched traffic into one of many shared common transport circuits or 
    time slots allocated for transport between the end office and the 
    tandem switch, and onto a second dedicated circuit or time slot for 
    transport between the serving wire center and the tandem. Despite 
    parties' arguments to the contrary, the precise routing of the traffic 
    to the tandem, including the direction it may take around a SONET ring, 
    is irrelevant to the rate structure because IXCs purchase transport 
    under the three-part rate structure based on airline mileage to the 
    tandem.
        190. As discussed in connection with direct-trunked transport, 
    above, ring network architectures may cause incumbent LECs transport 
    costs to become less distance sensitive. Because our rate structure 
    permits, but does not require, transport rates to be distance 
    sensitive, LECs remain free to establish less distance sensitive 
    transport rates to reflect the changing nature of these costs.
        191. We also decline Teleport's suggestion to establish a flat-
    rated charge for the tandem switch, tied to the amount of dedicated 
    capacity each IXC's serving wire center-side trunk ports provide. While 
    the costs of these dedicated trunk ports are NTS, the record before us 
    does not reflect that all of tandem-switching costs are similarly NTS. 
    Rather, we conclude at this time that the costs of tandem switching 
    likely vary, as do those of local switching, on a traffic-sensitive 
    basis. In light of this conclusion, we find that it would be 
    unreasonable to permit the incumbent LEC to recover all of its tandem-
    switching costs through flat-rated charges. As with the local switch, 
    until we gain more experience with rate structures for unbundled 
    network elements that are implemented pursuant to Sections 251 and 252 
    and that segregate switching costs into traffic-sensitive and NTS 
    components, we will continue to adhere to the current, per-minute rate 
    structure for shared switching facilities.
        192. We also decline to adopt in full suggestions that we (1) 
    retain the unitary pricing structure for tandem-switched transport, 
    while (2) exempting IXCs and competing LECs that do not use the 
    transport facilities supplied by the incumbent LEC from paying the TIC 
    and (3) preventing the incumbent LEC from deaveraging the TIC within a 
    state during a five year transition period. We are modifying our rules 
    to prohibit incumbent LECs from assessing any per-minute residual TIC 
    charge on any switched minutes of CAPs that interconnect with the 
    incumbent LEC switched access network at the end office. In doing so, 
    we adopt a position substantially similar to the second enumerated 
    point, above, which Teleport and CompTel characterize as the ``most 
    important'' feature of this proposal. In addition, we are also taking 
    other measures that will reduce substantially or eliminate the TIC in 
    an expeditious manner. We decline, however, to adopt the other two 
    suggestions. As explained in more detail above, the unitary rate 
    structure is not cost-based in that it requires incumbent LECs to 
    recover costs incurred on an NTS basis through per-minute charges and 
    inhibits the development of competition by bundling reasonably 
    segregable components of tandem-switched transport together and pricing 
    them in a manner that does not reflect cost causation. We conclude that 
    our new paradigm of promoting efficient competition requires that 
    incumbent LECs adopt a cost-based transport rate structure and that 
    entrants providing transport facilities in competition with the 
    incumbent LEC not pay the TIC.
        193. Although in their comments in this proceeding the incumbent 
    LECs virtually unanimously favor the three-part rate structure as most 
    consistent with principles of cost-causation, we recognize that 
    incumbent LECs may face competition from competitors that are not 
    limited to the three-part rate structure we adopt for incumbent LECs 
    today. As such competition develops, the incumbent LEC may wish to 
    respond by offering tandem-switched transport on a unitary pricing 
    basis. We will address issues relating to when incumbent LECs should 
    have the flexibility to offer a unitary tandem-switched transport rate 
    structure in connection with our discussion of other pricing 
    flexibility issues in a subsequent Report and Order that we will adopt 
    in this proceeding.
        194. Peak and Off-Peak Pricing. As with the local switch, we 
    conclude that we should not mandate a peak-rate pricing structure for 
    the tandem switch or common transport at this time. Many of the same 
    practical difficulties with establishing, verifying, and enforcing a 
    rational, efficient, and fair peak-rate structure exist in the context 
    of the tandem switch. We will consider whether incumbent LECs should 
    have the flexibility to develop such peak and off-peak rate structures 
    for local switching on a permissive basis when we consider other issues 
    of rate structure flexibility in a subsequent Report and Order that we 
    will adopt in this proceeding.
    d. Rate Levels
        195. Allocation of 80 Percent of the Tandem Switching Revenue 
    Requirement to the TIC. In establishing the interim transport rate 
    structure, we required incumbent LECs to base their initial tandem 
    switching charge on 20 percent of the interstate tandem-switching 
    revenue requirement. In remanding this portion of the interim rate 
    structure to us, the D.C. Circuit directed us either to implement a 
    cost-based tandem switching rate or offer a rational and non-conclusory 
    analysis in support of our determination that an alternative structure 
    is preferable.
        196. Based on the record in this proceeding, we reallocate much of 
    the remaining 80 percent of the tandem switch revenue requirement back 
    to the tandem switching rate elements in three steps. We conclude that 
    this action is most consistent with cost-causation, and with the 
    general approach we are taking in this Order regarding pricing issues. 
    We do not require all of the 80 percent to be reallocated to tandem 
    switching rates because the tandem-switching revenue requirement 
    includes, not only the costs of the tandem switch, but other costs, 
    such as SS7 signalling costs and tandem port costs, which we are 
    requiring to be reallocated elsewhere.
        197. Furthermore, if we required the price cap LECs to reallocate, 
    dollar-for-dollar, the entire portion of the tandem switching revenue 
    requirement that we reallocated to the original TIC in the First 
    Transport Order, we would deny tandem-switched transport customers the 
    continuing benefits of past X-factor reductions in the revenues 
    permitted under price caps. Therefore, in order to preclude recovery of 
    tandem switching costs in excess of the current revenues permitted 
    under price caps, we direct price cap incumbent LECs first to account 
    in the following manner for the effects of ``GDP-PI minus X-factor'' 
    reductions to the original portion of the tandem switching revenue 
    requirement allocated to the TIC in the First Transport Order. Each 
    price cap LEC first should calculate the percentage of its total 
    original TIC that represented the 80 percent reallocation of its tandem 
    switching costs when the TIC was created. It should then calculate this 
    percentage of its current TIC, which represents the extant portion of 
    the reallocated tandem switching costs. It is this extant portion that 
    the price cap LECs should reallocate to tandem switching as described 
    in the next paragraph.
    
    [[Page 31898]]
    
        198. In access tariff filings to become effective on January 1, 
    1998, incumbent LECs must identify the portion of the tandem-switching 
    revenue requirement currently in the TIC that they reallocate to each 
    rate element, including, as applicable, SS7 signalling, tandem port 
    costs, or other rate elements. They must then reallocate one third of 
    the tandem switching revenue requirement remaining in the TIC to the 
    tandem switching rate element. Effective January 1, 1999, incumbent 
    LECs shall reallocate approximately one half of the remaining amount of 
    the tandem switching revenue requirement in the TIC to the tandem 
    switching rate elements. Effective January 1, 2000, incumbent LECs 
    shall reallocate any portion of the tandem switching revenue 
    requirement remaining in the TIC to the tandem switching rate element. 
    This three-step implementation of this change permits IXCs time to 
    adjust their use of various incumbent LEC transport services, but sets 
    a definite end date in the near future, thus responding to the CompTel 
    decision's concerns regarding the length of the transition to a cost-
    based transport rate structure.
        199. Some commenters argue that, rather than reallocating revenues 
    from the TIC to other rate elements, we should reinitialize tandem-
    switched transport rates to levels reflecting long run incremental 
    costs, making reallocation of TIC revenues to other transport rate 
    elements unnecessary. We have decided in this Order, however, not to 
    reinitialize access rates based on forward-looking cost principles. We 
    have instead determined that the first step in access reform is to make 
    the current system as economically efficient as is possible within the 
    limits of current ratemaking practices. Thus, the focus of this portion 
    of this proceeding is on the development of cost-causative rate 
    structure rules. While we are taking several prescriptive steps using 
    existing ratemaking methods to reduce initial baseline rates, we are 
    generally adopting a market-based approach, with a prescriptive 
    backdrop, to move rates over time to levels reflecting forward-looking 
    economic costs. We disagree with those commenters that argue that the 
    Local Competition Order requires us immediately to prescribe rate 
    levels for access elements based on long-run incremental costs. The 
    Local Competition Order addressed, inter alia, the pricing of unbundled 
    network elements. While unbundled network elements may be used to 
    provide interstate access services, their availability at TELRIC-based 
    prices does not compel adoption of similar rates for access services. 
    We intend instead to rely on the availability of unbundled network 
    elements to place market-based downward pressures on access rates, 
    subject to a prescriptive backstop. We will further address questions 
    related to reinitialization to TELRIC rate levels in connection with 
    our discussion of the prescriptive approach to access reform.
        200. Use of Switched Access Overhead Loadings for Initial Tandem 
    Switching Rates. In setting rates, the interim transport rate structure 
    derived both direct-trunked transport rates and tandem-switched 
    transmission rates using relatively low overhead loadings applicable to 
    special access. Tandem switching rates, in contrast, were set using 
    relatively higher switched access overhead loadings. As a result, the 
    tandem switching revenue requirement became relatively high, in 
    comparison to other transport rate elements.
        201. Several commenters in this proceeding contend that our use of 
    special access overheads in setting direct trunked transport rates was 
    inappropriate because, while special access is used almost exclusively 
    in high density, generally urban areas, direct-trunked transport and, 
    to an even greater extent, tandem-switched transport are used in less 
    dense areas. In these less dense areas, overhead costs associated with 
    transport may be higher than those associated with special access in 
    urban areas. Some commenters have argued that we should either (1) 
    equalize the overhead loading factors for all transport options by 
    directing that the difference in transport rates is equal to the 
    difference in the long run incremental cost of each transport option 
    (DS3, DS1, and tandem-switched transport); or (2) otherwise ensure that 
    transport customers pay an equal dollar amount of overhead per unit of 
    traffic transported.
        202. We conclude that we need to make no change to the overheads 
    attributed to tandem switching. As discussed above, we have decided not 
    to base access prices directly at this time on incremental cost 
    studies, but instead to make significant changes in existing ratemaking 
    practices as the first step in access reform. Our current methods 
    allocate overhead in a reasonable, cost-based manner. In consultation 
    with the Joint Board on Jurisdictional Separations, the Commission 
    established procedures for allocating overhead expenses between the 
    state and interstate jurisdictions. See, e.g., 47 CFR Sec. 36.192, 
    separating Corporate Operations Expenses, USOA Accounts 6710 and 6720, 
    on the basis of the separation of the Big Three Expenses: Plant 
    Specific Expenses, Plant Non-Specific Expenses, and Customer Operations 
    Expenses. Our Part 69 cost allocation rules in turn allocated 
    interstate direct investment to broad categories, including Central 
    Office Equipment (with respect to both local switching and tandem 
    switching) and Carrier Cable and Wire Facilities (with respect to 
    special access, direct-trunked transport, and tandem-switched transport 
    transmission facilities). 47 CFR Secs. 69.305-69.306. Other investment, 
    including overhead, was allocated among these categories in proportion 
    to the dollar amounts of net direct investment allocated to these 
    categories. 47 CFR Sec. 69.309. Similarly, direct expenses, where 
    possible, were allocated to the category to which the expenses are 
    related. E.g., 47 CFR Sec. 69.401. Other expenses, including overheads, 
    are allocated on the same basis as other investment, according to 
    relative dollar amounts allocated to the various categories. 47 CFR 
    Sec. 69.411. The Commission has stated that initial allocation of 
    overheads based on relative costs closely approximates an economically 
    efficient method assuming that the elasticity of demands for the 
    various outputs is not too dissimilar. See, e.g., First Transport 
    Order.
        203. Our Part 69 cost allocation rules, therefore, established 
    category revenue requirements that included overheads allocated 
    generally based on relative costs. Once these initial revenue 
    requirements were established, our Part 69 rules permitted incumbent 
    LECs to recover all costs assigned to each category through the rate 
    elements established for that category. The incumbent LECs were 
    permitted to assign overhead costs among the category rate elements in 
    any way that is just and reasonable and not unreasonably 
    discriminatory. 47 U.S.C. secs. 201-202. We find that it is reasonable 
    to have set overhead loadings for tandem switching consistently with 
    the overhead loadings for local switching, and disagree with those 
    parties that argue that there is no cost justification for the current 
    allocation of overheads to the tandem switch. The direct costs of both 
    kinds of switching are fundamentally the same in that both types of 
    switches are comprised of ports and a switching matrix. By contrast, 
    the direct costs of transmission consist of outside plant and circuit 
    equipment and certain central office equipment. So long as consistent 
    overhead loading methodologies were used across switching functions, 
    and across transmission functions, we find that a
    
    [[Page 31899]]
    
    reasonable cross-over is established for access customers between 
    direct-trunked transport and tandem-switched transport. As competition 
    develops, we can also rely on market forces to pressure incumbent LECs 
    to allocate overheads among rate elements in economically efficient 
    ways. We address issues concerning the use of special access prices to 
    initialize direct-trunked transport rates in the interim rate 
    restructure below in our discussion of the TIC.
        204. We also decline to adopt a requirement for equalized overhead 
    loadings. Overhead loadings are used to assign costs that do not 
    qualify as the direct costs of a particular service. Reasonable 
    definitions of direct costs often leave in the overhead category costs 
    that might reasonably be deemed attributable to a given service. Thus, 
    if all of a carrier's costs are classified as either ``direct costs'' 
    or ``overheads,'' the overhead category will likely include costs that 
    should not necessarily apply uniformly to all services. As a result, we 
    think it desirable not to adopt a policy that is too specific and too 
    rigid, and that might not permit recognition of legitimate differences 
    in costing definitions. Furthermore, in a competitive market, it would 
    be mere happenstance if different products or services of a single 
    company recovered uniform amounts of overhead. If we were to require 
    equalized overhead loadings, we would be interfering with the market 
    discipline on which we are primarily relying. We might, for example, 
    prevent an entrant from realizing a reasonable profit opportunity based 
    on a rigid overhead loading requirement.
        205. In determining that our existing cost allocation rules 
    reasonably allocated overhead to the initial tandem switching rate 
    element and that we thus need not change the overheads currently 
    attributed to tandem switching, we recognize that the D.C. Circuit in 
    CompTel remanded the overhead issue to the Commission for further 
    explanation and stated that the ``cost allocation to the tandem 
    switch'' under the existing allocation rules ``is, by the Commission's 
    own estimation, grossly excessive.'' CompTel, 87 F.3d at 533. The court 
    did not provide a cite for its characterization of the Commission's 
    ``estimation,'' but the court may have been referring to the agency's 
    finding in the First Transport Order that ``most, but not all, of the 
    interstate tandem revenue requirement is attributable to tandem-
    switched transport'' (emphasis added). The Commission in that order 
    also identified only one category of costs--having to do with SS7 
    technology--that appeared to be misallocated to tandem switching. Id. 
    Elsewhere in this Order, we have taken steps to address that 
    misallocation of SS7 costs. That correction having been made, we find 
    that our existing rules reasonably allocate overhead to tandem 
    switching for the reasons discussed above.
        206. Use of actual minutes of use rather than an assumed 9000 
    minutes of use. For tandem-switched transport rates to be presumed 
    reasonable, the interim rate structure requires incumbent LECs to set 
    per-minute tandem-switched transport rates using a weighted average of 
    DS1 and DS3 rates reflecting the relative numbers of circuits of each 
    type in use in the tandem-to-end office link, and assuming circuit 
    loading of 9000 minutes of use per month per voice-grade circuit. First 
    Transport Order. Based on the record before us, we find that continued 
    use of this 9000 minutes of use assumption is no longer reasonable. 
    Many commenters state that their actual traffic levels are 
    substantially lower than 9000 minutes of use per month. Some incumbent 
    LECs, particularly smaller LECs in rural areas, indicate that their 
    actual traffic levels may be as low as 4000 minutes of use per month 
    per voice-grade circuit. Accordingly, we conclude that rates for the 
    common transport portion of tandem-switched transport must be set using 
    a weighted average of DS1 and DS3 rates reflecting the relative numbers 
    of DS1 and DS3 circuits in use in the tandem-to-end office link, and 
    using the actual voice-grade switched access common transport circuit 
    loadings, measured as total actual minutes of use, geographically 
    averaged on a study-area-wide basis, that the incumbent LEC experiences 
    based on the prior year's annual use. Incumbent LECs that deaverage 
    their transport rates under our existing zone-based deaveraging rules, 
    see 47 CFR Sec. 69.123, may similarly deaverage the actual minutes of 
    use figures that they use to calculate per-minute common transport 
    rates.
        207. Our assumption that voice-grade common transport circuits 
    experience uniform loadings of 9000 minutes of use was initially based 
    on 1983 data submitted in the original MTS and WATS Market Structure 
    proceeding. MTS and WATS Market Structure, CC Docket No. 78-72, Phase 
    I, Memorandum Opinion and Order, 48 FR 42984 (September 21, 1983). In 
    using this assumption as part of the interim rate structure, we stated 
    that, ``[t]he 9000 minutes per circuit per month standard serves as a 
    convenient starting point in the context of a short-term, interim rate 
    structure.'' First Transport Reconsideration Order. We rejected at that 
    time requests to develop a loading factor for small LECs that would 
    reflect their actual, substantially lower circuit loading levels, 
    stating that, ``the benefits to be obtained from use of more 
    individualized loading factors are outweighed by the benefits of the 
    administrative convenience of a uniform loading factor and of avoiding 
    verification difficulties.'' Id. Given the new competitive paradigm 
    embodied in the 1996 Act, we conclude that this assumption must give 
    way to charges based on actual usage levels. The same conversion factor 
    is not appropriate for each incumbent LEC. Because the 9000 minute 
    assumption appears to have substantially overstated the actual traffic 
    levels on many circuits, we now conclude that the current rate 
    structure is unlikely to recover the full costs of common transport. 
    Costs that properly should be recovered from common transport rate 
    elements may currently be recovered through TIC revenues. Because the 
    9000 minutes of use loading factor has contributed, possibly 
    significantly, to the level of the non-cost-based TIC, we find that 
    continued use of this factor is no longer reasonable.
        208. We therefore direct incumbent LECs to develop common transport 
    rates based on the relative numbers of DS1 and DS3 circuits in use in 
    the tandem-to-end office link, and using actual voice-grade circuit 
    loadings, geographically averaged on a study-area-wide basis, that the 
    incumbent LEC experiences based on the prior year's annual use. As 
    discussed above, incumbent LECs that deaverage their transport rates 
    under our existing zone-based deaveraging rules may similarly deaverage 
    the actual minutes of use figures that they use to calculate per-minute 
    common transport rates. As they develop transport rates based on actual 
    minutes of use, we require incumbent LECs to use any increase in common 
    transport revenues to decrease the TIC. These rates must be included in 
    the LEC access tariff filings effective January 1, 1998.
        209. We disagree with commenters arguing that the actual number of 
    minutes a circuit is in use is irrelevant in a rate-setting context. 
    These commenters argue that rates should be set based on forward-
    looking cost studies using Commission-determined ``efficient'' traffic 
    levels, which they argue may be far higher than either the actual 
    traffic levels, or the 9000 minutes of use assumption. As explained 
    elsewhere, we are not taking the general approach of prescribing rates 
    at forward looking economic costs, and we decline
    
    [[Page 31900]]
    
    to make an exception in this instance. We are instead reforming access 
    charges so that they more closely reflect the costs imposed by 
    individual access customers. We also do not find it necessary to employ 
    different principles here to ensure that incumbent LECs face sufficient 
    incentives to design their networks to achieve efficient usage levels. 
    LECs subject to price cap regulation already have only limited ability 
    to raise rates to cover the costs of inefficient network designs, and 
    are able to benefit from increased profits as their efficiency 
    improves. In addition, as competition develops for local service, all 
    incumbent LECs will face increasing pressure to provide service as 
    efficiently as possible.
    
    C. Transport Interconnection Charge (TIC)
    
    1. Background
        210. Under our Part 36 separations rules, certain costs of the 
    incumbent LEC network are assigned to the interstate jurisdiction. The 
    Part 69 cost allocation rules allocate these costs among the various 
    access and interexchange services, including transport. In the First 
    Transport Order, we restructured interstate transport rates for 
    incumbent LECs. The restructure created facility-based rates for 
    dedicated transport services based on comparable special access rates 
    as of September 1, 1991, derived per-minute tandem-switched transport 
    transmission rates from those dedicated rates, established a tandem 
    switching rate, and established a TIC that initially recovered the 
    difference between the revenues from the new facility-based rates and 
    the revenues that would have been realized under the preexisting 
    ``equal charge rule.'' Under the equal charge rule, which arose from 
    the AT&T divestiture of the BOCs, the BOCs were required to charge a 
    per-minute, distance-sensitive rate for their transport offerings, 
    regardless of how the underlying costs were incurred. The TIC was 
    intended as a transitional measure that initially made the transport 
    rate restructure revenue neutral for incumbent LECs and reduced any 
    harmful interim effects on small IXCs caused by the restructuring of 
    transport rates. Approximately 70 percent of incumbent LEC transport 
    revenues are generated through TIC charges, or approximately $3.1 
    billion, according to USTA.
        211. The TIC is a per-minute charge assessed on all switched access 
    minutes, including those of competitors that interconnect with the LEC 
    switched access network through expanded interconnection. In the NPRM, 
    we sought comment on how to reduce and eliminate the TIC in a manner 
    that fosters competition and responds to the D.C. Circuit's CompTel 
    remand. We sought comment on different methods of recovering the costs 
    currently recovered by the TIC, including: (1) Giving the incumbent 
    LECs significant pricing flexibility and allowing market forces to 
    discipline the recovery of the TIC, either alone or in conjunction with 
    a phase-out of the TIC; (2) quantifying and correcting all identifiable 
    cost misallocations and other practices that result in costs being 
    recovered through the TIC; (3) combining the above approaches, for 
    example, by addressing directly the most significant and readily-
    corrected misallocations, and then relying on a market-based approach 
    to reduce what remains of the TIC; (4) providing for the termination of 
    the TIC over a specified time, such as three years. We specifically 
    sought comment on the possible reassignment of costs based on several 
    explanations for the amounts in the TIC. The NPRM also sought comment 
    on how the resolution of the issues surrounding the TIC would be 
    affected by decisions on universal service, by the level of any 
    residual costs, and by the adoption of either the market-based or 
    prescriptive approach to access reform.
    2. Discussion
        212. As a per-minute charge assessed on all switched access 
    minutes, including those of competing providers of transport service 
    that interconnect with the LEC switched access network through expanded 
    interconnection, the TIC adversely affects the development of 
    competition in the interstate access market. First, as discussed more 
    fully below, some of the revenues recovered through the TIC should be 
    recovered through other switched access elements, including transport 
    rates other than the TIC. The TIC, as currently structured, provides 
    the incumbent LECs with a competitive advantage for some of their 
    interstate switched access services because the charges for those 
    services do not recover their full costs. At the same time, the 
    incumbent LECs' competitors using expanded interconnection must pay a 
    share of incumbent LEC transport costs through the TIC. Under our 
    expanded interconnection rules and policies, competitors may 
    interconnect with the incumbent LEC's facilities at the end office and 
    supply their own transport. For a more detailed discussion of expanded 
    interconnection, see Expanded Interconnection with Local Telephone 
    Company Facilities, CC Docket No. 91-141, Memorandum Opinion and Order, 
    59 FR 38922 (August 1, 1994). Second, all other things being equal, the 
    usage-rated TIC increases the per-minute access charges paid by IXCs 
    and long-distance consumers, thus artificially suppressing usage of 
    such services and encouraging customers to explore ways to bypass the 
    LEC switched access network, particularly through the use of switched 
    facilities of providers other than the incumbent LEC that may be less 
    economically efficient than incumbent LECs.
        213. As we noted in the NPRM, our goal is to establish a mechanism 
    to reduce and eliminate the TIC in a manner that fosters competition 
    and responds to the D.C. Circuit's remand. To that end, we below 
    identify several costs included in the TIC that should be reallocated 
    to other access elements. We conclude, however, that on the present 
    record, we cannot immediately eliminate the TIC entirely through these 
    reassignments. We establish a mechanism that should substantially 
    reduce the remaining TIC over a short, but reasonable period. In 
    addition, we will in the near future refer a broad range of separations 
    issues to a Joint Board for purposes of determining whether certain 
    costs currently allocated to the interstate jurisdiction and recovered 
    through the TIC more properly should be allocated to the intrastate 
    jurisdiction. Finally, we establish the means by which the remaining 
    TIC amounts are to be recovered.
    a. Reallocation of Costs in the TIC
        214. The record in response to the NPRM clearly establishes that 
    some costs in the TIC should be reallocated to other access elements. 
    USTA, in conjunction with the incumbent LECs, submitted extensive 
    comments setting forth an incumbent LEC consensus explanation of the 
    causes for the sums in the TIC and estimates of the amounts associated 
    with each explanation. While the current rulemaking record will not 
    permit us to prescribe specific amounts that individual incumbent LECs 
    must shift from the TIC to specific access rate elements, it does 
    permit us to direct incumbent LECs to make certain cost reallocations 
    and to require them to calculate the appropriate level of the 
    reallocation in the supporting materials filed with the tariffs 
    implementing the changes. Below, we discuss each of the identified 
    causes of costs being included in the TIC and the extent to which costs 
    should be reallocated to other access elements or categories.
    
    [[Page 31901]]
    
        215. In this Order, we do not address certain rate structure issues 
    relating to incumbent LECs subject to rate-of-return regulation. These 
    LECs account for relatively few access lines. In some instances we 
    direct price cap LECs to allocate costs to new rate elements that do 
    not currently exist for rate-of-return LECs. We anticipate that we will 
    propose similar rate elements in the forthcoming notice of proposed 
    rulemaking addressing rate structure issues for incumbent LECs subject 
    to rate-of-return regulation. Recognizing the expense and difficulties 
    of modifying billing systems, we conclude that, until the rate 
    structure issues are resolved for rate-of-return companies, the costs 
    allocated to new elements and any residual TIC revenues may continue to 
    be recovered by the incumbent LECs that are not subject to price cap 
    regulation through per-minute TIC rates assessed on both originating 
    and terminating access.
        216. As their primary challenge to the incumbent LEC proposals to 
    reallocate costs from the TIC, several parties argue that we should use 
    forward-looking cost principles, or TELRIC, in determining how much to 
    shift from the TIC to other access categories. Some parties advocating 
    the use of such forward-looking cost standards assert that any costs 
    not meeting these forward-looking cost standards should be eliminated 
    from the TIC, and the incumbent LECs should not be permitted to recover 
    those amounts. One group of consumer advocates proposes that we need 
    not complete TELRIC studies before substantially reducing the TIC 
    because BA/NYNEX has already proposed, as part of their access charge 
    reform compromise plan, to eliminate up to 80 percent of the TIC 
    pending a determination of ``service related'' costs by the Commission. 
    We conclude, however, that immediate, widespread, prescriptive action 
    is not necessary to pressure access rates toward market-based levels. 
    Instead, we have determined that the most appropriate first step 
    towards access reform is to make the current rate structure as 
    economically efficient as possible within the limits of past ratemaking 
    practices. These practices include setting rates based on interstate-
    allocated costs, subject to price cap constraints for most large 
    carriers. As we discuss more fully in Section IV, below, we intend in 
    the future to rely primarily on market forces, with a prescriptive 
    backdrop, to move rates toward forward-looking economic cost. 
    Therefore, because we currently are not prescribing a forward-looking 
    cost method for access reform, we will require reassignment of certain 
    TIC revenues based on an analysis of the separated, booked costs 
    already recovered through the TIC.
        217. SS7 costs. Based on the record before us, we conclude that SS7 
    costs that are recovered by the TIC should be removed from the TIC and 
    allocated to the traffic-sensitive basket. The record demonstrates that 
    these costs are related to the signalling function and should be 
    recovered through local switching or signalling rate elements. The 
    costs to be removed are the costs of signal transfer points (STPs) that 
    were included in the tandem-switching category for jurisdictional 
    separations purposes and the cost of the link between the end office 
    and the STP that is used only for SS7 signalling. The incumbent LECs 
    shall distribute the STP costs reallocated from the TIC to local 
    switching or, if the incumbent LEC has established an unbundled 
    signalling rate structure, to appropriate SS7 elements, in tariffs 
    filed to be effective January 1, 1998. The incumbent LEC shall 
    distribute the costs of the link between the local switch and the STP 
    that are included in the TIC to local switching or, if provided, to the 
    call-setup charge. This change means that the incumbent LECs' SS7 
    prices will reflect the full cost of providing SS7 signalling and 
    provide the proper price signals to developers of new services 
    utilizing SS7. We decline to adopt the suggestion of US West that we 
    reallocate SS7 costs to services in the trunking basket. As we conclude 
    below in conjunction with our consideration of the SS7 rate structure, 
    the costs being reallocated are appropriately included in the traffic-
    sensitive basket.
        218. Tandem switching costs. Several parties argue that the tandem 
    switching rate must be set to reflect the cost of providing the 
    service. In the preceding section, we modified the existing tandem-
    switched transport rate structure and revised certain of the pricing 
    rules applicable to elements of tandem-switched transport to establish 
    a cost-based structure and to respond to the court remand in CompTel v. 
    FCC. The revised pricing rules applicable to tandem switching include 
    two separate elements--a flat-rated port charge to be assessed when a 
    port is dedicated to a single customer and a per minute charge to be 
    assessed for the traffic-sensitive portion of the tandem switch. In 
    three approximately equal annual steps, beginning January 1, 1998, we 
    require reallocation of all tandem-switching revenues currently 
    allocated to the TIC to the tandem-switching rate element. As a result 
    of this modification, the total revenues recovered through the tandem 
    switching rates will, subject to price cap limits, increase to the 
    level of costs assigned to the interstate jurisdiction by the 
    separations process at the end of our plan. Equivalent changes to the 
    amounts recovered through the TIC must be made to ensure that over-
    recovery does not occur. After this adjustment, in accordance with the 
    CompTel remand, and to facilitate the development of economically-
    efficient competition for tandem-switching services, the TIC will not 
    recover any costs that are attributable to tandem switching.
        219. DS1/voice-grade multiplexer costs. We conclude that the costs 
    of DS1/voice-grade multiplexing associated with analog local switches 
    should be reassigned to the newly created trunk ports category within 
    the traffic sensitive basket. Analog switches require a voice-grade 
    interface on the trunk-side of the end office switch. Our separations 
    rules assign the costs of DS1/voice-grade multiplexers to the cable and 
    wire category. The costs of these multiplexers associated with switched 
    access were originally included in the Part 69 transport revenue 
    requirement. The revised transport rules adopted in 1992 established 
    transport rates based on DS1 switch interfaces, and thus the rates did 
    not include the costs of DS1/voice-grade multiplexers. The costs of the 
    DS1/voice-grade multiplexers are, therefore, included in the TIC. 
    Therefore, the costs associated with DS1/voice-grade multiplexing 
    associated with analog local switches should be reassigned to the trunk 
    ports category within the traffic sensitive basket, to be considered in 
    conjunction with the development of appropriate rates for trunk ports, 
    in tariffs filed to become effective January 1, 1998. This will make 
    recovery of the costs necessary to use an analog switch port equivalent 
    to the recovery of digital switch port costs, in which the multiplexing 
    function is included in the port itself.
        220. Host/remote trunking costs. We agree with the parties that 
    allege that the costs of host/remote links not recovered by the current 
    tandem-switched transport rates should be included in the tandem-
    switched transport category. The record reflects that the rates for 
    carrying traffic between the host and a remote switch, for which the 
    tandem-switched transport rates, both fixed and per mile, are assessed, 
    do not recover the full costs of this transmission service. These 
    charges for host/remote service are in addition to charges that an IXC 
    is assessed for either direct-trunked transport, or tandem-switched 
    transport, between the serving wire center and the
    
    [[Page 31902]]
    
    host end office. This reassignment will ensure that these transmission 
    costs will be recovered from those using the transmission facilities, 
    and must be included in tariff filings to become effective January 1, 
    1998. We reject NECA's suggestion that we include these costs in local 
    switching on the theory that remote facilities are installed when it is 
    more cost effective to do that than it is to install a new switch at 
    the remote location. That would require all users of local switching to 
    pay for these host/remote transmission facilities. Imposing the host/
    remote transmission cost on the users of host/remote facilities is more 
    cost causative and will facilitate the development of access 
    competition.
        221. Additional multiplexers associated with tandem switching. 
    Based on the record before us, we conclude that an IXC's decision to 
    utilize tandem-switched transport imposes the need for additional 
    multiplexing on each side of the tandem switch. The revised tandem-
    switched transport rate structure provides for these multiplexers. For 
    price cap LECs, recovery of the costs associated with the multiplexers 
    should, therefore, be shifted from the TIC to the tandem-switched 
    transport category as of January 1, 1998, as explained in Section 
    III.C. This realignment of costs helps ensure that tandem-switched 
    transport rates are cost based, as required by the CompTel decision, 
    and facilitates competitive entry for those services.
        222. Use of actual minutes of use rather than an assumed 9000 
    minutes of use. The data in the record provided by USTA and other 
    incumbent LECs support a finding that for many incumbent LECs, 
    especially those serving less densely populated areas, the assumed 9000 
    minutes of use per circuit is far higher than actual minutes of use. A 
    tandem-switched transport rate derived by dividing the cost of a 
    circuit by an assumed usage level does not recover the costs of the 
    circuit when the actual usage is below that level. The costs not 
    recovered through tandem-switched transport rates based on our current 
    9000 minutes of use assumption are being recovered through the TIC. In 
    the preceding section, we conclude that the pricing of tandem-switched 
    transport transmission should be based on the actual average minutes of 
    use on the shared circuits and that such pricing would produce a cost-
    based rate. Accordingly, costs should be removed from the TIC equal to 
    the additional revenues realized from the new tandem-switched transport 
    rates when it is implemented in accordance with the rate structure 
    established in Section III.C.
        223. Central Office Equipment (COE) Maintenance Expenses. The 
    record in this proceeding demonstrates that allocating COE maintenance 
    expenses on the basis of combined COE investment produces 
    misallocations of these expenses among access services. USTA correctly 
    traces this problem to the Part 36 separations rules; the problem is 
    then tracked in our Part 69 cost allocation rules. Under our current 
    rules, COE maintenance expenses are allocated among separations 
    categories, and then access services, based on the combined investment 
    in the three categories of the COE plant being maintained--Central 
    Office Switching, Operator Systems, and Central Office-Transmission--
    rather than on the individual investment in each of those categories. 
    As a result, a portion of the expense of maintaining local switches and 
    operator systems is recovered in rates for common line, transport, and 
    special access even though those do not utilize any local switching or 
    operator systems. Correcting this misallocation through changes to Part 
    36 would require referral to a Federal-State Joint Board and therefore 
    could not be done in this proceeding. The misallocation can, however, 
    be corrected by modifying section 69.401 of our rules, 47 CFR 
    Sec. 69.401, to provide that the COE expenses assigned to the 
    interstate jurisdiction should be allocated on the basis of the 
    allocation of the specific type of COE investment being maintained, and 
    we make the correction here. This will shift some costs to local 
    switching from common line and transport, and result in more cost-based 
    rates. This shift must be reflected in tariff filings to be effective 
    January 1, 1998. We also plan to refer the underlying separations issue 
    to a Joint Board for its recommendation.
        224. Separations-related causes. Several incumbent LECs argue that 
    a substantial portion of the TIC can be traced to decisions separating 
    costs between the interstate and intrastate jurisdictions. As explained 
    by USTA and incumbent LECs, the largest portion of the amounts 
    recovered by the TIC results from the differences in the jurisdictional 
    separations allocation procedures for message (i.e., switched) services 
    and special access services, and from the consequent effects of the 
    Commission's decision to use special access rates to establish 
    transport transmission rates when the Commission restructured transport 
    rates. The current jurisdictional separations process separates the 
    costs of message services based on average cost factors; costs of DS1 
    and DS3 special access services, in contrast, are separated using unit 
    costing methods. Because of the differences in these separations 
    methodologies, special access-derived rates reflect the costs of 
    transport in areas in which special access services are most often 
    offered (urban, higher density areas), and do not reflect the costs of 
    transport in rural, less dense areas. Another alleged separations-
    related cause of the amounts in the TIC is the use of circuit 
    termination counts in the separations process to allocate costs between 
    special access and switched services before they are allocated between 
    federal and state jurisdictions. This practice appears to allocate 
    costs disproportionately to switched services. The incumbent LECs 
    assert that the use of direct costing methods would assign many of 
    these costs to local and intrastate services and to interstate services 
    other than transport. If the Joint Board on Jurisdictional Separations 
    takes action to address this issue, we will then consider what 
    corresponding reallocations should be made.
        225. We find that some of the remaining costs recovered by the TIC 
    result from at least two different causes: (1) the separations process 
    assigned costs differently to private line and message (i.e., switched) 
    services, resulting in costs allocated to special access being lower 
    than those allocated to the message category, even though the two 
    services use comparable facilities--rates for direct-trunked transport 
    and the transmission component of tandem-switched transport, which are 
    switched services, therefore, do not recover the full amount of 
    separated costs; and (2) the cost of providing transport services in 
    less densely populated areas is higher than that reflected by transport 
    rates derived from those special access rates. The existing record is 
    inadequate to permit us to identify more costs that could clearly be 
    reallocated to interstate services. Furthermore, the record indicates 
    that some residual TIC costs may be appropriately allocated to 
    intrastate services. Because we will soon be considering a NPRM of 
    Proposed Rulemaking to refer to a Joint Board questions regarding 
    separations, we will leave the determination of the ultimate allocation 
    of the remaining costs recovered by the TIC until the conclusion of 
    that proceeding.
        226. Incumbent LEC parties generally contend that special access 
    rates provided an acceptable initializing pricing level for transport 
    transmission services in geographic areas where significant amounts of 
    special access
    
    [[Page 31903]]
    
    services are provided, but do not reflect the cost of providing 
    transport service in low-density areas in which special access services 
    are not as widespread. We recognize that rates for direct-trunked 
    transport and for the transmission component of tandem-switched 
    transport, because they were established based on special access rates, 
    do not reflect the full cost of providing transport services in higher-
    cost, rural areas. Because none of our other facilities-based rate 
    elements recover costs reflecting this differential, we conclude that 
    the additional costs of rural transport currently are recovered through 
    the TIC. On the basis of the current record, however, we are unable to 
    quantify these cost differentials. Moreover, based on differences in 
    network architectures, population density variations, topography, and 
    other factors that vary among LECs, we find that transport cost 
    differentials are also likely to vary greatly among incumbent LECs and 
    among study areas served by the same incumbent LEC. We do not believe, 
    however, that we need to quantify these differences in this Order to 
    ameliorate this distortion caused by the current rate structure, 
    because the requirements set forth in the next paragraph will address 
    this issue.
        227. If an incumbent LEC deaverages its transport rates, either by 
    implementing zone-density pricing under our rules, 47 CFR Sec. 69.123, 
    or by waiver, the underlying predicate is that the costs in low-density 
    areas are higher than those in higher-density areas. The rates it sets 
    for the different areas should reveal a cost differential of at least 
    that magnitude between low-density and high-density areas served by 
    that LEC. When an incumbent LEC deaverages transport rates, therefore, 
    we require it to reallocate additional TIC amounts to facilities-based 
    transport rates, reflecting the higher costs of serving lower-density 
    areas. The reallocation we require here will permit incumbent LECs, in 
    deaveraging their transport rates, to achieve cost-based transport 
    rates while ensuring that a significant portion of costs reflecting the 
    geographic cost difference are removed from the TIC. Each incumbent LEC 
    must reallocate costs from the TIC each time it increases the 
    deaveraging differential. We find that any incumbent LEC that has 
    already deaveraged its rates must move an equivalent amount from the 
    TIC to its transport services. Under any of these scenarios, the costs 
    shall be reassigned to direct-trunked transport and tandem-switched 
    transport categories or subcategories in a manner that reflects the way 
    deaveraging is being implemented by the incumbent LEC. We do not 
    require incumbent LECs that average their transport rates to make a 
    similar reallocation at this time, because of the difficulty in 
    determining the amount to be reallocated.
        228. Price Cap Implementation issues. For purposes of phasing out 
    the TIC, we are keeping the TIC in its own service category in the 
    trunking basket. The reallocation of costs from the TIC to other access 
    elements will require price cap LECs to adjust their price cap indices 
    (PCIs) and service band indices (SBIs) to reflect the new revenue 
    streams. To accomplish these reallocations, price cap LECs shall make 
    exogenous adjustments to their PCIs and SBIs that are targeted to the 
    indices in question, rather than applying the exogenous adjustment 
    proportionately across all categories in the affected price cap basket. 
    Thus, when a reallocation occurs within a price cap basket, only the 
    affected SBIs will be adjusted. When the reallocation affects service 
    categories in more than one basket, however, the affected PCIs and SBIs 
    must be adjusted. The upward or downward adjustment to the PCIs and 
    upper SBIs shall be calculated as the percentage of the revenues being 
    added or subtracted from a basket or category, divided by the total 
    revenues recovered through the basket or category at the time of the 
    adjustment. For example, if ten percent of the revenues are being 
    reallocated from a service category, the category upper SBI will be 
    reduced by ten percent. If that revenue amount is only three percent of 
    the PCI for the basket, the PCI is reduced by three percent.
    b. Treatment of Remaining Costs Recovered by the TIC
        229. Residual TIC reduction plan. After the costs identified above 
    have been reallocated to other access services, some costs will 
    continue to be recovered by the TIC. While it is desirable to eliminate 
    the TIC as soon as possible by shifting the costs recovered by the TIC 
    to facilities-based rates, referring separations questions to a Joint 
    Board is the best means of reaching that ultimate objective, as we 
    noted earlier. Even as we make this referral, we will require incumbent 
    LECs to target to the TIC price cap reductions arising in any price cap 
    basket as a result of the application of the ``GDP-PI minus X-factor'' 
    formula until the per-minute TIC is eliminated, as many parties have 
    suggested. These parties submit that this targeting will permit 
    incumbent LECs to manage the reduction in revenues recovered by the 
    TIC, while reducing the amount at issue in the TIC. Sprint states that, 
    using a targeting approach, we would not need to address the cost 
    allocation issues raised by Part 36 and Part 69. Targeting these price 
    cap reductions to the TIC reduces the TIC over a reasonable period, 
    thereby ultimately substantially reducing what is widely recognized to 
    be an inefficient aspect of the access rate structure. We require 
    price-cap LECs to begin these targeted X-factor reductions to the TIC 
    in tariff filings to become effective July 1, 1997.
        230. Targeting PCI reductions to the per-minute TIC will not change 
    the overall revenue levels that our price cap mechanisms permit 
    incumbent LECs to receive. We have reallocated those costs that the 
    record shows are clearly related to other facilities-based elements. 
    The upcoming separations proceeding may provide additional data that 
    will permit us to reallocate more costs to facilities-based rate 
    elements, or to the intrastate jurisdiction. The approach we take is a 
    reasonable response to the D.C. Circuit's remand directive, and 
    establishes a plan that should substantially reduce the TIC within a 
    reasonable period, pending review of the jurisdictional separations 
    process.
        231. We reject ALTS' allegation that targeting the productivity 
    factor to the TIC undercuts the rationale for the ``just and 
    reasonable'' status of all price-cap rates, which ALTS contends is 
    dependant on the widespread application of the X-factor. The targeting 
    approach that we adopt will eliminate anticompetitive aspects of the 
    TIC, which promotes inefficient entry into the transport market by 
    imposing some transport costs on IXCs that do not cause the costs to be 
    incurred. In addition, by spreading current TIC revenues across all 
    price cap PCIs and SBIs, our targeting method does not offer TIC 
    revenues special insulation against the pressures of the competitive 
    marketplace, as would some proposals to bulk-bill the TIC to IXCs. We 
    also decline to adopt the approach of spreading the remaining costs 
    recovered by the TIC proportionately among all transport services, as 
    proposed by State Consumer Advocates. That approach might, because of 
    the unknown nature of the costs that will remain in the TIC, result in 
    an excessive reallocation to transport.
        232. The D.C. Circuit instructed us to revise our transport rate 
    structure rules to be more consistent with cost-causation principles. 
    There is conflicting evidence in the record concerning the nature of 
    the costs contained within the residual TIC; these costs may be traffic 
    sensitive or NTS and may be associated with common
    
    [[Page 31904]]
    
    line, transport or switching services. BA/NYNEX states, without 
    explanation, that the costs in the TIC are NTS in nature. To the extent 
    that some portion of the residual TIC has its origin in the methods 
    used to separate cable and wire facilities between the regulatory 
    jurisdictions, it seems likely that BA/NYNEX is partially correct in 
    this assertion. The evidence, however, does not clearly resolve this 
    issue.
        233. If the costs remaining in the residual TIC are NTS, as BA/
    NYNEX suggests, then traffic-sensitive recovery could artificially 
    raise per-minute rates for interstate access. These higher per-minute 
    access rates could distort the market for interstate toll services by 
    artificially suppressing demand for interstate toll services and by 
    encouraging users that efficiently could make use of the network to 
    instead seek other alternatives. Conversely, if costs remaining in the 
    residual TIC are usage-sensitive, flat-rating may also create a 
    distortion by encouraging inefficient overuse of interstate toll 
    services. Because the limited evidence in the record suggests that at 
    least some amount of the residual TIC represents NTS costs, and because 
    we wish to see that consumers enjoy the benefits of usage of the 
    network to the greatest extent possible, we find that we should err, if 
    at all, on the side of NTS recovery of these costs. For elements not 
    demonstrably reflecting usage-sensitive costs, therefore, we find, on 
    balance, compelling policy arguments in favor of flat-rated pricing 
    because usage-sensitive recovery of any NTS costs artificially 
    suppresses demand for interexchange calling by inflating per-minute 
    rates. In the absence of definitive evidence as to the nature of the 
    residual TIC amounts, we conclude that the public interest would be 
    better served by imposing these costs on IXCs on a flat per-line basis, 
    rather than on a per-minute basis.
        234. Accordingly, we seek to migrate the current usage-based 
    charges into flat-rated charges as quickly as possible consistent with 
    avoiding short-term market distortions. We do that by: (1) On July 1, 
    1997, drawing down the per-minute-of-use residual TIC charge by 
    targeting the price cap productivity (X-factor) adjustment to the 
    trunking PCI and, specifically, the TIC SBI, thus effectively spreading 
    those residual TIC revenues, which otherwise would be recovered 
    exclusively on a minute of use basis, among the universe of (both 
    traffic-sensitive and NTS) access services and moving TIC recovery 
    closer to flat-rated recovery; (2) starting in January 1998, recovering 
    remaining residual TIC revenues through PICC charges each year, subject 
    to the PICC cap; and (3) drawing down any remaining residual per-minute 
    TIC revenues each July by targeting the annual X-Factor adjustments to 
    those revenues.
        235. The targeting of price cap productivity reductions to the TIC 
    will be accomplished in the following manner. Because the price cap 
    LECs will not have reallocated facilities-based costs contained in the 
    TIC before they file tariffs to be effective July 1, 1997, we first 
    direct the price cap LECs to compute their anticipated ``residual'' TIC 
    amount by excluding revenues that are expected to be reassigned on a 
    cost-causative basis to facilities-based charges in the future, 
    pursuant to the transition plan described in this Order. To determine 
    TIC amounts so excluded, NYNEX, BellSouth, U S West, and Bell Atlantic 
    shall use the residual TIC percentage estimates contained in USTA's ex 
    parte letter filed May 2, 1997, to compute their respective anticipated 
    residual TICs. These percentages are as follows: NYNEX, 77.63 percent; 
    BellSouth, 56.93 percent; U S West, 59.14 percent; and Bell Atlantic, 
    63.96 percent. SBC Communications shall use the cost data for SWBT, 
    Pacific Bell, and Nevada Bell contained in its ex parte letter filed 
    April 24, 1997 to estimate its residual TICs. These percentages, 
    calculated from TIC data supplied, are: SWBT, 69.11 percent; Pacific 
    Bell and Nevada Bell combined, 53.52 percent. Each remaining price cap 
    LEC shall estimate a ``residual'' TIC in an amount equal to 55 percent 
    of its current TIC revenues. For these remaining price cap LECs, we 
    find that this 55 percent level represents a reasonable, but 
    conservative estimate. The 55 percent level corresponds approximately 
    to the lowest residual TIC percentage identified in the record, and 
    three of the price cap LECs that submitted data on the record are 
    within a few percentage points of this level. We therefore find that 
    residual TIC estimates at the 55 percent level for companies that have 
    not developed actual percentage estimates on the record will be 
    reasonable, but will also minimize the risk that we will eliminate 
    facilities-based TIC costs with targeted X-factor price cap reductions.
        236. The ``GDP-PI minus X'' adjustments LECs ordinarily would apply 
    to each of their price cap indices (i.e., revenues) for the July 1, 
    1997, annual filing shall be applied by LECs to reduce their calculated 
    anticipated ``residual'' TIC revenues. For tariffs to become effective 
    July 1, 1997, the price cap LECs shall calculate the annual price cap 
    reduction resulting from the application of the productivity adjustment 
    to each basket other than the interexchange basket, and shall sum the 
    dollar effects of the adjustment. If the effect is to reduce PCIs, the 
    dollar amount shall be targeted completely to the trunking basket PCI 
    and the TIC SBI, without changing the PCIs or SBIs for any other basket 
    or service category. The percentage reduction in the PCI and SBI shall 
    equal the ratio of the total dollar effect of the price cap annual 
    adjustment to the dollar value of the PCI and SBI, respectively. If the 
    effect of the productivity adjustment would increase the PCIs, the PCIs 
    shall be adjusted in their usual fashion, and no targeting to the TIC 
    shall occur. This avoids exacerbating an already inefficient aspect of 
    the access rate structure.
        237. Price cap LECs will begin reallocation of facilities-based TIC 
    components on January 1, 1998. At that time, the price cap LECs should 
    all have actual cost data reflecting the facilities-based components of 
    the TIC. If, at that time, any price cap incumbent LEC determines that 
    its use of the applicable residual TIC estimate, above, resulted in 
    more PCI reductions being targeted to the interconnection charge in its 
    tariff filing to become effective on July 1, 1997, than were required 
    to eliminate the per-minute interconnection charge, then that price cap 
    LEC shall make necessary exogenous adjustments to its PCIs and SBIs to 
    reverse the effects of the excess targeting.
        238. For tariff filings to become effective July 1, 1998, and 
    annually in July thereafter, all price cap LECs will have actual cost 
    data reflecting the facilities-based components of the TIC and will be 
    able to target reductions to actual anticipated residual per-minute TIC 
    amounts without resort to the percentage estimates prescribed above. 
    For these filings, ``GDP-PI minus X'' adjustments similar to those 
    described above shall be targeted to the trunking basket PCI and the 
    TIC SBI to reduce residual per-minute TIC amounts recovered through 
    per-minute originating and terminating access charges.
        239. To avoid the adverse effects of per-minute pricing of costs 
    that may be NTS, we require price cap LECs to recover residual TIC 
    amounts not otherwise eliminated by targeted X-factor reductions, 
    described above, through the flat-rated PICC to the extent the PICC is 
    below its ceiling. In order to ensure that primary residential and 
    single line business subscribers do not pay more than their fair share 
    of the residual TIC, however, we prohibit price cap LECs from charging 
    a PICC on primary residential or single-line
    
    [[Page 31905]]
    
    business lines that recovers TIC revenues that exceed residual TIC 
    revenues permitted under our price cap rules divided by the total 
    number of access lines. As the PICC caps increase each year, more of 
    the residual TIC charge can be included in the flat-rated PICC. Any 
    residual TIC amounts that cannot be recovered through the PICC shall be 
    recovered on a per-minute basis from originating traffic, subject to a 
    cap on per-minute originating access charges, as explained in Section 
    III.A, above. If this cap is exceeded, the residual TIC shall be 
    recovered through per-minute terminating switched access rates. 
    Although a portion of the residual TIC will be recovered through PICC 
    charges, the TIC will remain in the trunking basket. Therefore, to 
    ensure that excess headroom is not created in the trunking basket, 
    price cap LECs shall include the TIC revenues received from the flat-
    rated PICC in calculating the API for the trunking basket and the SBI 
    for the TIC.
        240. The policies adopted when the TIC was created require 
    incumbent LECs to assess the TIC on all minutes that interconnect with 
    the incumbent LEC switched access network, including minutes that 
    transit a CAP's transport network without using any incumbent LEC 
    transport facilities. As we noted in the NPRM, and as some commenters 
    assert, if the incumbent LEC's transport rates are kept artificially 
    low and the difference is recovered through the TIC, competitors of the 
    incumbent LEC pay some of the incumbent LEC's transport costs. In a 
    recent arbitration between Teleport and US West, the Colorado 
    Commission has precluded US West from imposing the TIC on competitors 
    for the portion of transport that US West does not provide. See TCG 
    Colorado Petition for Arbitration Pursuant to sec. 252(b) of the 
    Telecommunications Act of 1996 to Establish an Interconnection 
    Agreement with US West, Docket No. 96A-329T, Decision Regarding 
    Petition for Arbitration, Decision No. C96-1186 (adopted November 5, 
    1996); TCG Colorado Petition for Arbitration Pursuant to sec. 252(b) of 
    the Telecommunications Act of 1996 to Establish an Interconnection 
    Agreement with US West, Docket No. 96A-329T, Order Denying Applications 
    for Rehearing, Reargument, or Reconsideration, Decision No. C96-1344 
    (adopted December 18, 1996), at para. I.B.1.4. We find that our current 
    policy, which requires competitive entrants to pay the TIC even in 
    cases where it provides its own transport, is inconsistent with the 
    procompetitive goals of the 1996 Act. We therefore modify our rules to 
    permit incumbent LECs to assess any per-minute residual TIC charge only 
    on minutes that utilize incumbent LEC transport facilities, and not on 
    any switched minutes of CAPs that interconnect with the incumbent LEC 
    switched access network at the end office.
        241. Other Approaches. We reject alternative methods for recovering 
    the TIC that were proposed in the record. The majority of the incumbent 
    LEC parties supported recovering any remaining costs in the TIC by bulk 
    billing such amounts to IXCs based on each IXC's share of revenues, or 
    presubscribed lines. Other incumbent LECs proposed establishing 
    ``public policy'' elements to recover the residual TIC. These 
    approaches would insulate TIC costs from the pressures of the 
    competitive market and guarantee incumbent LECs the recovery of these 
    amounts, even where such costs have resulted from inefficiencies that 
    the competitive market--but not regulators--detected and otherwise 
    would eliminate. This would be inconsistent with the development of an 
    efficient competitive market. Our resolution of the TIC will allow LECs 
    a reasonable opportunity to recover their costs, without providing a 
    guarantee. We also reject the idea of spreading the remaining costs 
    recovered by the TIC proportionately over all transport services, as 
    suggested by AARP, et al. As we noted earlier, some of the remaining 
    costs in the TIC may implicate certain Commission decisions separating 
    costs between the federal and state jurisdictions and thus may be 
    related to services other than transport. We, therefore, believe that 
    awaiting further consideration by a Joint Board is a more practical 
    means of ultimately resolving the TIC issue.
        242. Some parties have requested that a portion of the costs 
    recovered by the TIC should be considered to be universal service 
    costs. We do not find this argument persuasive. Elsewhere in this 
    Order, we have reallocated the TIC's identifiable cost components. On 
    the basis of the record before us, we cannot clearly associate the 
    remaining TIC revenues with any particular facilities or services. The 
    parties arguing that these costs are related to universal service have 
    not made any clear showing as to the source of these costs or 
    demonstrated why they believe that these TIC revenues are either costs 
    of universal service that should be recovered from the universal 
    service fund or constituent costs of supported services.
        243. We have analyzed the effect of the reallocation of TIC costs 
    and the new recovery procedures on small business entities, including 
    small LECs and new entrants, and find that the changes will facilitate 
    the development of a competitive marketplace by moving incumbent LEC 
    rates toward cost-based levels and by eliminating the ability of 
    incumbent LECs to assess the TIC on switched access minutes that do not 
    use incumbent LEC transport facilities. These pricing revisions may 
    create new opportunities for small entities wishing to enter the 
    telecommunications market.
    
    E. SS7 Signalling
    
    1. Background
        244. SS7 is a network protocol used to transmit signalling 
    information over common channel signalling networks. As described in 
    greater detail in the NPRM, signalling networks like SS7 establish and 
    close transmission paths over which telephone calls are carried. 
    Signalling networks are also used to retrieve information from remote 
    data bases to enable credit card and collect calling. SS7 systems are 
    also used to transmit information needed to provide custom local area 
    signalling services like automatic call back.
        245. An SS7 network consists of several primary components--
    signalling points, signal transport links, and dedicated lines used for 
    access to an incumbent LEC's signalling network (signal links). 
    Signalling points are nodes in an SS7 network that originate, transmit, 
    or route signalling messages. There are three principal types of 
    signalling points: service switching points (SSPs), service control 
    points (SCPs), and signalling transfer points (STPs). An SSP is a 
    switch that can originate, transmit, and receive messages for call 
    setup and database transactions. An SCP serves as a database that 
    stores and provides information used in the routing of calls, such as 
    the line information database (LIDB) used to validate calling cards or 
    the database that identifies the designated long-distance carrier for 
    toll-free service. An STP is a specialized packet switch that performs 
    screening and security functions and switches SS7 messages within the 
    signalling network.
        246. Signal transport links are facilities dedicated to the 
    transport of SS7 messages within the incumbent LEC's signalling 
    network. Finally, dedicated network access lines (DNALs) consist of 
    dedicated circuits that transmit queries between the incumbent LEC's 
    signalling network and the signalling networks of other individual 
    carriers, such as IXCs. A carrier's DNAL is connected to an incumbent 
    LEC's
    
    [[Page 31906]]
    
    signalling network through a port on an incumbent LEC's STP.
        247. Under the interim transport rate structure, incumbent LECs 
    charge IXCs and other access customers a flat-rated charge (dedicated 
    signalling transport) under Part 69 for the use of dedicated facilities 
    used to connect to the incumbent LEC's signalling network. This rate 
    element has two subelements--a flat-rated signalling link charge for 
    the dedicated network access line (dedicated signalling line) and a 
    flat-rated STP port termination charge. Most other signalling costs, 
    such as costs for switching messages at the STP and transmitting 
    messages within the signalling network, are not recovered through 
    facility-based charges and thus most, if not all, of these costs are 
    embedded in the TIC or in the local switching charge and recovered 
    through per-minute-of-use charges. Retrieval of information from 
    databases for toll-free calls and LIDB databases, however, is charged 
    on a per-query basis.
        248. In the NPRM, we solicited comment on whether the Commission 
    should revise its rate structure for SS7 services to reflect the SS7 
    rate structure implemented by Ameritech. In March, 1996, the Commission 
    granted a waiver to Ameritech, allowing it to restructure its recovery 
    of SS7 costs through four unbundled charges. These charges correspond 
    to various functions performed by signalling networks: signal link, STP 
    port termination, signal transport, and signal switching.
        249. The Ameritech waiver was granted to allow Ameritech to realign 
    its charges for SS7 services more closely with the manner in which such 
    costs are incurred. Unbundling of SS7 services from transport and local 
    switching ensures that transport and local switching customers do not 
    pay for SS7 services they do not use. Unbundling also enables Ameritech 
    to offer SS7 services to competing providers of local exchange and 
    exchange access services without requiring the purchase of other 
    elements that the competitors do not need. In support of its waiver 
    petition, Ameritech noted that it had received numerous customer 
    requests for such unbundling. It also explained that it had deployed 
    equipment necessary for measuring third-party usage of its SS7 
    networks, enabling the company to bill its SS7 services separately from 
    its switched access services.
        250. The NPRM also requested comment on whether incumbent LECs 
    should be allowed to impose separate charges for ISDN User Part (ISUP) 
    messages and Transaction Capabilities Application Part (TCAP) messages. 
    ISUP messages are used to set up and take down calls. For example, ISUP 
    messages include the initial address message used to establish and 
    close the transmission path used to carry a telephone call. TCAP 
    messages, on the other hand, are used to carry information between SSPs 
    that support particular services, such as toll free services, LIDB 
    services and certain custom local area signalling services (CLASS) like 
    automatic call back. We noted that differentiation between charges for 
    ISUP and TCAP messages may be economically justified because TCAP 
    messages tend to be shorter in average length and place lower demands 
    on the signalling network that ISUP messages.
        251. The NPRM also requested comment regarding the appropriate 
    placement of SS7 signalling elements in price cap baskets. Currently, 
    STP port termination rates and charges for the signalling link, or 
    DNAL, are placed in the trunking basket. Because both services are 
    dedicated to particular SS7 customers, rates for these elements are 
    flat-rated. We requested comment on whether the STP port termination 
    charge should be placed in its own service category in the traffic-
    sensitive basket. We noted that interconnectors can provide their own 
    signalling link, exposing that service element to some measure of 
    competition. The STP port termination, on the other hand, is relatively 
    insulated from competitive pressures because it is part of the 
    incumbent LEC's STP and must be purchased from the incumbent LEC under 
    existing network architecture.
    2. Discussion
        252. As we noted in the Ameritech SS7 Waiver Order, the removal of 
    SS7 costs from the local switching and transport interconnection charge 
    rate elements would benefit access customers that pay for these 
    services but do not actually use an incumbent LEC's signalling 
    services. It would also benefit alternative local service providers by 
    enabling them to purchase separate SS7 services from incumbent LECs to 
    support their provision of competing local exchange or exchange access 
    services. Unbundling the individual SS7 components into separate 
    charges would further promote efficiency by ensuring that signalling 
    charges more accurately reflect the costs of providing such services. 
    Competitive service providers could limit their signalling costs by 
    purchasing only the signalling elements they need. Despite these 
    benefits, however, we are reluctant to impose on incumbent LECs the 
    cost burden of installing metering or other equipment needed to measure 
    third party usage of signalling facilities. In granting Ameritech a 
    waiver to implement its unbundled SS7 rate structure, we noted that 
    Ameritech had previously installed the equipment and other facilities 
    needed to meter independent signalling usage. Although we encourage 
    actions that would promote disaggregation and unbundling of SS7 
    services, we will not require incumbent LECs to implement such an 
    approach and incur the associated equipment costs of doing so. The 
    record indicates that, as a general matter, the costs of mandating the 
    installation of metering equipment may well exceed the benefits of 
    doing so.
        253. Instead, we will permit incumbent LECs to adopt unbundled 
    signalling rate structures at their discretion and acquire the 
    appropriate measuring equipment as needed to implement such a plan. 
    Specifically, incumbent LECs may implement the same unbundled rate 
    structure for SS7 services that we approved in the Ameritech SS7 Waiver 
    Order. We recognize, however, that other signalling rate structures may 
    achieve the same benefits that are available under the Ameritech rate 
    structure. Hence, an incumbent LEC may implement an unbundled 
    signalling rate structure that varies from the approach implemented in 
    the Ameritech SS7 Waiver Order by filing a petition demonstrating that 
    the establishment of new rate elements implementing such a service is 
    consistent with the public interest. We note, however, that variations 
    in signalling rate structures among incumbent LECs could impose burdens 
    on IXCs if IXCs must adapt to a diverse range of unbundled signalling 
    rate structures. We anticipate that, if incumbent LECs choose to adopt 
    unbundled rate structures for their SS7 network services, they will 
    evaluate how the implementation of these plans will affect their 
    prospective customers.
        254. With respect to rate differentiation between ISUP and TCAP 
    messages, the NPRM expressed the concern that imposing rate 
    differentiation may be inconsistent with rate structure simplicity. 
    Several commenters indicate that the costs of implementing rate 
    differentiation would exceed the benefits of such an approach. We 
    further note that commenters offered little, if any, general support 
    for the adoption of rate differentiation. Accordingly, to avoid 
    unnecessary complexity and to avoid the imposition of unnecessary 
    regulatory costs, we will not impose a rate differential between ISUP 
    and TCAP messages.
        255. With respect to the placement of SS7 rate elements in price 
    cap baskets, we have previously recognized that the
    
    [[Page 31907]]
    
    signalling link and the STP port termination are not subject to the 
    same level of competition. As noted in the Ameritech SS7 Waiver Order, 
    STP port termination is provided only by incumbents while the 
    signalling link can be provided by SS7 customers themselves or by other 
    alternative providers. Comments filed in this proceeding also 
    acknowledge this competitive disparity. Although Ameritech discounts 
    the risk that STP port termination charges would be used to offset 
    price reductions for the signal link, it nevertheless acknowledges the 
    existence of the competitive differential we suggested in the NPRM. 
    Other commenters argue that the competitive disparity is sufficient to 
    justify concerns that price cap LECs would adjust their rates to 
    account for the competitive differential. Accordingly, we will 
    establish a new STP port termination rate element in the traffic-
    sensitive basket. Placing these SS7 services in different price cap 
    baskets will ensure consistency with the Commission's general approach 
    of maintaining elements with similar competitive characteristics in the 
    same service baskets.
    
    F. Impact of New Technologies
    
        256. The NPRM requested comment regarding the rate structure 
    treatment of new technologies that enable new telecommunications 
    services and, by enhancing the productivity of telecommunications 
    facilities, lower prices for services in the future. These 
    technologies, which we describe in greater detail in the NPRM, include 
    synchronous optical networks (SONET), Asynchronous Transfer Mode (ATM) 
    switching, and advanced intelligent networks (AIN). We invited 
    commenters to recommend specific rate structure rules that would 
    reflect the manner in which incumbent LECs incur costs when providing 
    services utilizing such new technologies.
        257. As a general matter, the Commission is reluctant to adopt 
    detailed rules governing rate structures for recovering the cost of 
    deploying advanced technologies. We note that, in the Price Cap Third 
    Report and Order, we adopted rules that permit price cap LECs to 
    petition the Commission for the establishment of one or more switched 
    access rate elements to accommodate new services. Under these rules, 
    petitioners must demonstrate either of the following: (1) that the new 
    rate elements would be in the public interest; or (2) that another LEC 
    has previously obtained approval to establish identical rate elements 
    and that the original petition did not rely upon a competitive showing 
    as part of its public interest justification. Because technological 
    advancements emerge rapidly, the adoption of uniform rate structures 
    corresponding to particular technologies may slow investment in the 
    development of newer technologies or improvements in current 
    technologies. Indeed, as a general matter, incumbent LECs oppose the 
    adoption of uniform rate structures for new technologies, suggesting 
    that strict uniform rules in this regard could inhibit development of 
    such technologies. Accordingly, we will refrain from adopting in this 
    Order specific rate structures with respect to SONET, AIN, or other new 
    technologies. As noted above, however, our rules already accommodate 
    rate element adjustments that may be needed on an ad hoc basis when 
    technological advancements justify such modifications. As particular 
    new technologies become used on a widespread basis, we can always 
    consider whether there is a need for a uniform rate structure at that 
    point.
    
    IV. Baseline Rate Levels
    
    A. Primary Reliance on a Market-Based Approach With a Prescriptive 
    Backdrop and the Adoption of Several Initial Prescriptive Measures
    
    1. Background
        258. In the NPRM, we established a goal of encouraging efficient 
    competitors to enter local exchange access markets so that incumbent 
    LECs would face substantial competition for the entire array of 
    interstate access services. As a particular service becomes subject to 
    substantial competition from new providers, we proposed to remove that 
    service from price cap and tariff regulation. We sought comment on two 
    general approaches for a transition to reliance on substantial 
    competition to ensure that interstate access charges are closely 
    related to forward-looking economic costs: a ``market-based'' approach 
    and a ``prescriptive'' approach. Under a market-based approach, we 
    would permit market forces to operate as competition emerges, allowing 
    an incumbent to change its prices in response to competitive entry. To 
    that end, we proposed a two-phase approach in which incumbent LECs 
    would be permitted certain pricing flexibility upon a showing that 
    meaningful competitive entry is possible within a particular local 
    exchange and exchange access market, followed by a further relaxation 
    of price cap regulation when meaningful actual competition developed 
    within the market. We did not propose, however, to abandon the 
    possibility of using the prescriptive tools at our disposal in the 
    event that competition does not develop in some places.
        259. As an alternative to the proposed market-based approach, we 
    also sought comment on a prescriptive approach, under which incumbent 
    LECs would be required to change their prices for some or all exchange 
    access services using specific measures adopted by the Commission to 
    more accurately ensure that access charges are closely related to the 
    economic costs of providing interstate access services. We also invited 
    comment on whether the two approaches could be merged in some fashion. 
    We emphasized that our ultimate goal under any approach, whether 
    market-based, prescriptive or combined, is to remove from price cap 
    regulation LEC services that are subject to substantial competition. 
    Instead of price cap regulation, we expect eventually to rely on the 
    operation of competitive local markets to prevent incumbent LECs from 
    exercising market power, and thereby to protect consumers.
        260. In this section, we endorse the use of a market-based approach 
    generally. Our market-based approach will retain the protection 
    afforded by price cap regulation, while relaxing particular 
    restrictions on incumbent LEC pricing as competition emerges, thereby 
    permitting the development and operation of competitive markets, which 
    will maximize the efficient allocation of telecommunications services 
    and promote consumer welfare. This section also explains how, if 
    competition fails to emerge over time for certain access services in 
    particular geographic areas, we will ensure that the rates for those 
    services reflect the forward-looking economic costs of providing the 
    services. In the NPRM, we sought comment on a number of specific issues 
    concerning the timing and degrees of pricing flexibility and ultimate 
    deregulation. We recognize that we must attend carefully to this task 
    of granting incumbent LECs increased pricing flexibility commensurate 
    with competitive developments, and we will resolve these issues of 
    timing and degree in detail in a subsequent report and order in this 
    docket, where we can more fully discuss these matters.
        261. Elsewhere in this Order, we adopt or propose several measures 
    that work within our current price cap structure to lower baseline 
    access charge rate levels consistent with evidence that the revised 
    rate levels better reflect the underlying costs of providing interstate 
    access services. In Section IV.C below,
    
    [[Page 31908]]
    
    we order an exogenous cost reduction to reflect the completion of the 
    amortization of equal access costs. In Section IV.D, we order 
    reallocation of certain marketing and retail expenses and discuss the 
    reallocation of GSF costs. We issue a further notice on GSF costs in 
    Section VII. In the companion Price Cap Performance Review for Local 
    Exchange Carriers and Transport Rate Structure and Pricing, Fourth 
    Report and Order, CC Docket Nos. 94-1 and 91-213, FCC 97-159, ______ FR 
    ______ (released May 8, 1997) (Price Cap Fourth Report and Order), 
    which we also adopt today, we modify our current price cap plan by 
    adopting a single productivity offset (X-Factor) of 6.5 percent and 
    eliminating sharing while maintaining the low-end adjustment.
    2. Discussion
        262. The Commission's objective is the one set forth in the 1996 
    Act--``opening all telecommunications markets to competition.'' 
    Therefore, we must ensure that our own regulations do not unduly 
    interfere with the development and operation of these markets as 
    competition develops. If we successfully reform our access charge rules 
    to promote the operation of competitive markets, interstate access 
    charges will ultimately reflect the forward-looking economic costs of 
    providing interstate access services. This is so, in part, because 
    Congress established in the 1996 Act a cost-based pricing requirement 
    for incumbent LECs' rates for interconnection and unbundled network 
    elements, which are sold by carriers to other carriers. As we have 
    recognized, interstate access services can be replaced with some 
    interconnection services or with functionality offered by unbundled 
    elements. Because these policies will greatly facilitate competitive 
    entry into the provision of all telecommunications services, we expect 
    that interstate access services will ultimately be priced at 
    competitive levels even without direct regulation of those service 
    prices.
        263. We decide that adopting a primarily market-based approach to 
    reforming access charges will better serve the public interest than 
    attempting immediately to prescribe new rates for all interstate access 
    services based on the long-run incremental cost or forward-looking 
    economic cost of interstate access services. Competitive markets are 
    superior mechanisms for protecting consumers by ensuring that goods and 
    services are provided to consumers in the most efficient manner 
    possible and at prices that reflect the cost of production. 
    Accordingly, where competition develops, it should be relied upon as 
    much as possible to protect consumers and the public interest. In 
    addition, using a market-based approach should minimize the potential 
    that regulation will create and maintain distortions in the investment 
    decisions of competitors as they enter local telecommunications 
    markets. Finally, under section 254 of the 1996 Act, implicit universal 
    service subsidies, wherever possible, are to be made explicit and 
    supported by all carriers on an equitable and non-discriminatory basis. 
    To the extent that any implicit subsidies remain in interstate access 
    charges because it was not feasible to identify them or make them 
    explicit, our market-based approach will have the effect of making 
    those implicit subsidies subject to being competed away as competitors 
    offer comparable services at prices that do not include the subsidies. 
    In addition, we note that the rate structure changes we adopt today go 
    a long way towards achieving such ends because the inefficiency 
    produced by distortions in markets ``rises as a quadratic function of 
    the relative price distortion [Scherer & Ross, supra., at 662].'' 
    Therefore, the first steps made toward removing distortions caused by 
    our regulations will produce the greatest benefits.
        264. The market-based approach to access charge reform that we 
    adopt will not, as some parties assert, expose customers of interstate 
    access services to the unfettered exercise of market power. We will 
    continue to maintain the current mechanisms upon which we rely to 
    ensure that rates for these services are ``just and reasonable [as 
    required by section 201 of the Communications Act],'' and not unjustly 
    or unreasonably discriminatory [as required by section 202 of the 
    Communications Act]. Instead of exposing customers to harm, we expect 
    that permitting incumbent LECs certain kinds of pricing flexibility in 
    response to the development of competition will allow prices for 
    interstate access services to adjust in ways that reflect the 
    underlying economic costs of providing those services without moving 
    outside the range of rates that are just and reasonable. This process 
    of relaxing regulation as competition develops, and ultimately 
    deregulating services subject to effective competition, is well 
    established. For example, many of the types of pricing flexibility 
    discussed in the NPRM are similar to forms of pricing flexibility we 
    have in the past accorded incumbent LECs and IXCs facing increased 
    competition in markets for particular services.
        265. Economic teaching also leads to the conclusion that rates for 
    interstate access services will generally move toward the forward-
    looking economic cost of providing such services in response to 
    increased competition in local exchange and exchange access markets. In 
    addition, competition will do a better job of determining the true 
    economic cost of providing such services. As competitive entry becomes 
    increasingly possible, IXCs that now purchase interstate switched 
    access services from incumbent LECs will be able to bypass those 
    services where the prices (interstate access charges) do not reflect 
    the economic costs of providing the underlying services. Those IXCs can 
    do this by entering the local markets themselves as local exchange 
    service providers, thereby self-providing interstate access services 
    for their new local exchange service customers. They can also seek out 
    competitive providers of comparable services. As customers choose 
    providers other than incumbent LECs as their local providers, 
    interstate access services will come to be priced competitively. 
    Incumbent LECs will have to respond to competitors' offerings with 
    lower-priced access services of their own in order to retain customers 
    that would otherwise switch to competitors' networks, further 
    increasing the effect of competition on overall access charge payments.
        266. The 1996 Act has created an unprecedented opportunity for 
    competition to develop in local telephone markets. It also has provided 
    this Commission with tools for opening markets to competition, and for 
    implementing our market-based relaxation of regulation so that 
    interstate access charges reflect forward-looking economic costs. We 
    recognize, however, that competition is unlikely to develop at the same 
    rate in different locations, and that some services will be subject to 
    increasing competition more rapidly than others. The observation that 
    competitive entry will occur in some places, and for some services, 
    more rapidly than others is a corollary to the rule that firms in 
    competitive markets seek to maximize their profits. To maximize 
    profits, firms naturally seek out those customers and services on which 
    they can generate the most profits. Therefore, some customers are 
    naturally more desirable than others at any given point in time. As 
    competitors attempt to gain the patronage of the customers offering the 
    greatest profit opportunities, they offer lower-priced or more 
    desirable services. These actions have the effect of reducing over time 
    the profitability of serving those particular customers and, as this 
    occurs, the relative profitability of serving other
    
    [[Page 31909]]
    
    customers or offering other services increases. Therefore, competitors 
    begin seeking to serve these other customers, and entry occurs in new 
    places, or for new services. Accordingly, we anticipate that 
    competition will drive rates for some interstate access services toward 
    more economically efficient levels more rapidly in some areas than 
    rates for other services or in other areas. Where competition develops, 
    we will provide incumbent LECs with additional flexibility, culminating 
    in the removal of incumbent LECs' interstate access services from price 
    regulation where they are subject to sufficient competition to ensure 
    that the rates for those services are just and reasonable, and are not 
    unjustly or unreasonably discriminatory.
        267. We also recognize, however, that there will be areas and 
    services for which competition may not develop. Therefore, we shall 
    retain many of the existing safeguards afforded by our price cap 
    regulation, including the productivity offset (X-Factor), which 
    requires incumbent LECs to adjust their access charges to reflect 
    changes in the economic cost of providing service. In addition, we also 
    adopt a prescriptive ``backstop'' to our market-based approach that 
    will serve to ensure that all interstate access customers receive the 
    benefits of more efficient prices, even in those places and for those 
    services where competition does not develop quickly. To implement our 
    backstop to market-based access charge reform, we require each 
    incumbent price cap LEC to file a cost study no later than February 8, 
    2001, demonstrating the cost of providing those interstate access 
    services that remain subject to price cap regulation because they do 
    not face substantial competition. The Commission will require 
    submission of such studies before that date if competition is not 
    developing sufficiently for our market-based approach to work. Studies 
    should identify and quantify forward-looking costs, short-run and long-
    run, that are incremental to providing each such service, and also 
    costs that are common as between various services. These studies are 
    required only for non-competitive services; as stated above, we do not 
    intend to regulate prices of services that are subject to substantial 
    competition.
        268. We have chosen this date in order to give competition 
    sufficient time to develop substantially in the various markets for 
    interstate exchange access services. We have also chosen this date to 
    permit us and all interested parties to take into account the effects 
    of implementing the substantial changes that we adopt in this Order and 
    that we will be adopting elsewhere to satisfy the universal service 
    goals in section 254. By this date, we also expect to have additional 
    regulatory tools by which to assess the reasonableness of access 
    charges. We may, for example, be able to establish benchmarks based on 
    prices for the interstate access services for which competition has 
    emerged, and use the prices actually charged in competitive markets to 
    set rates for non-competitive services and markets. Carriers could be 
    required either to set their rates in accordance with the benchmarks or 
    to justify their rates using their cost studies.
        269. We anticipate that the pro-competitive regime created by the 
    1996 Act, and implemented in the Local Competition Order and numerous 
    state commission decisions, will generate competition over the next few 
    years. Further, it would be imprudent to prejudge the effectiveness of 
    those measures at creating competitive local markets. Rather than 
    ignore or interfere with the effects of this developing competition on 
    prices for interstate access services, we find that the public interest 
    is best served by permitting emerging competition to affect access 
    charge rate levels. In addition, the experience we gain from observing 
    the effects of emerging competition on interstate access services will 
    permit us more effectively and efficiently to implement any 
    prescriptive measures that may be needed in the future to ensure that 
    interstate access services remaining subject to regulation are priced 
    in accordance with the forward-looking economic cost of providing those 
    services.
        270. Economic logic holds that giving incumbent LECs increased 
    pricing flexibility will permit them to respond to competitive entry, 
    which will allow prices to move in a way that they would not have moved 
    were the pricing restrictions maintained. This can lead to better 
    operating markets and produce more efficient outcomes. Deregulation 
    before competition has established itself, however, can expose 
    consumers to the unfettered exercise of monopoly power and, in some 
    cases, even stifle the development of competition, leaving a 
    monopolistic environment that adversely affects the interests of 
    consumers. Therefore, it is important that we design our market-based 
    approach carefully. We must, among other things, decide which, if any, 
    of the rules setting forth specific competitive triggers and 
    corresponding flexibility as proposed in the NPRM we should adopt. We 
    will resolve these issues in the subsequent report and order in this 
    docket.
        271. As set forth in the summary of comments appended to this 
    order, AT&T cites to Farmers Union Central Exchange, Inc. v. FERC, 734 
    F.2d 1486, 1508 (D.C. Cir.) (Farmers Union), cert. denied, Williams 
    Pipe Line Co. v. Farmers Union Central Exchange, Inc., 469 U.S. 1034 
    (1984), for the proposition that ``[r]eliance on competitive forces to 
    constrain exchange access rates, particularly in the presence of strong 
    indications that market forces will not produce the intended results, 
    would be arbitrary and capricious and contravene the Commission's 
    statutory duty to ensure just, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory 
    rates.'' We disagree with AT&T's assertion. In Farmers Union, FERC had 
    stated in its relevant order that ratemaking for oil pipelines should 
    be used solely to prevent price gouging, and had interpreted the 
    Congressional mandate of ``just and reasonable'' rates as requiring 
    that rates be kept within the zone of commercial reasonableness, not 
    public utility reasonableness. Under this interpretation, FERC had 
    concluded that it would rely primarily on market forces to keep rates 
    reasonable.
        272. The court in Farmers Union recognized that ``[m]oving from 
    heavy to lighthanded regulation * * * can be justified by a showing 
    that * * * the goals and purposes of the statute will be accomplished 
    through substantially less regulatory oversight,'' but objected to 
    FERC's failure to establish that its new approach would satisfy the 
    ``just and reasonable'' standard. The court rejected FERC's position 
    that oil pipeline ratemaking should protect only against ``egregious 
    exploitation and gross abuse'' as being inconsistent with the mandate 
    that Congress had established for FERC. The court concluded that FERC 
    had not shown that market forces were sufficient to rely upon in 
    setting reasonable rates.
        273. We reject AT&T's argument that our market-based approach to 
    access charge reform is analogous to FERC's conduct at issue in 
    Farmer's Union. Our access charge and price cap rules are designed to 
    ensure that access charges remain within the ``zone of reasonableness'' 
    defining rates that are ``just and reasonable,'' and our market-based 
    approach will also be designed to implement this statutory requirement. 
    It will not remove incumbent LECs from regulation immediately, but will 
    implement deregulation in steps, as competitive conditions warrant. 
    Throughout the transition to deregulation in the face of substantial 
    competition, we will maintain many
    
    [[Page 31910]]
    
    safeguards against unjust or unreasonable rates, such as the price cap 
    indices. We will deregulate incumbent LEC services only when it is 
    reasonable to conclude that competition has developed to such an extent 
    that the market will ensure just and reasonable rates.
        274. Second, our market-based approach is an eminently reasonable 
    method for pursuing our goal of promoting competition and ensuring the 
    economically efficient pricing of interstate access services. As 
    competition emerges, the market-based approach will permit access 
    charges to move towards the levels that will prevail in competitive 
    markets. During the transition to competitive markets, access services 
    not subject to competition will remain subject to price cap regulation, 
    and we will eventually prescribe rates for those services at forward-
    looking economic cost levels, to ensure that all consumers reap the 
    benefits of economically-efficient prices. Unlike the FERC regulation 
    at issue in Farmers Union, our market-based approach to promoting the 
    development of competitive markets and economically-efficient pricing 
    will not be based on ``largely undocumented reliance on market forces * 
    * *.'' Instead, we will design our approach so that deregulation occurs 
    only when the reliability of market forces can be fully determined with 
    respect to a particular service. Finally, we observe that FERC's 
    mandate in Farmers Union was one of rate regulation due to market 
    failure and concern over monopoly power. In light of the 1996 Act, our 
    mandate is no longer strictly or solely one of rate regulation. 
    Congress has stated its desire to establish ``a pro-competitive, 
    deregulatory national policy framework.'' Our market-based approach 
    will be designed to coincide with and promote this objective.
        275. Price Squeeze Concerns Are Adequately Addressed. Several 
    parties have argued that current access charge rate levels create the 
    conditions for an anticompetitive price squeeze when a LEC affiliate 
    offers interexchange services in competition with IXCs. A price 
    squeeze, as the term is used by these parties, refers to a particular, 
    well-defined strategy of predation that would involve the incumbent LEC 
    setting ``high'' prices for interstate exchange access services, over 
    which the LEC has monopoly power (albeit constrained by regulation), 
    while its affiliate is offering ``low'' prices for long-distance 
    services in competition with the other long-distance carriers. Because 
    interstate exchange access services are a necessary input for long-
    distance services, these parties argue that an incumbent LEC can create 
    a situation where the relationship between the LEC's ``high'' exchange 
    access prices and its affiliate's ``low'' prices for long-distance 
    services forces competing long-distance carriers either to lose money 
    or to lose customers even if they are more efficient than the LEC's 
    affiliate at providing long-distance services. It is this 
    nonremunerative relationship between the input prices and the 
    affiliate's prices, and not the absolute levels of those prices, that 
    defines a price squeeze. In the most extreme case, a price squeeze 
    involves a monopolist setting input prices that are actually higher 
    than its prices in the output market.
        276. Price cap regulation of access prices limits the ability of 
    LECs to raise the prices of the input services. Commenters raising 
    price squeeze concerns argue, however, that a LEC's interexchange 
    affiliate will still be in a position to implement a price squeeze by 
    setting long-distance rates close to the rates for access services, 
    thereby forcing IXCs to charge below-cost rates to retain customers. 
    They argue that LECs' interexchange affiliates have lower costs of 
    providing interexchange services because of their affiliation with 
    monopoly providers of interstate access services, and not as a result 
    of being more efficient. According to these commenters, the relevant 
    economic costs of providing interstate interexchange services will be 
    lower for the LEC affiliate offering interexchange services than for 
    competing IXCs because it only has to recover the true economic cost of 
    providing the interstate access services (since the owners of the LEC 
    and its interexchange affiliate will want the two entities to maximize 
    their joint profits), whereas the IXCs will be forced to pay interstate 
    access charges that are above the true economic cost of providing the 
    underlying services.
        277. Absent appropriate regulation, an incumbent LEC and its 
    interexchange affiliate could potentially implement a price squeeze 
    once the incumbent LEC began offering in-region, interexchange toll 
    services. Although no BOC affiliate may offer such services at this 
    time, GTE, SNET, Sprint and other incumbent LECs do have affiliates 
    offering such services. The incumbent LEC could do this by raising the 
    price of interstate access services to all interexchange carriers, 
    which would cause competing in-region carriers to either raise their 
    retail rates to maintain their profit margins or to attempt to maintain 
    their market share by not raising their prices to reflect the increase 
    in access charges, thereby reducing their profit margins. If the 
    competing in-region, interexchange providers raised their prices to 
    recover the increased access charges, the incumbent LEC's interexchange 
    affiliate could seek to expand its market share by not matching the 
    price increase. The incumbent LEC affiliate could also set its in-
    region, interexchange prices at or below its access prices. Its 
    competitors would then be faced with the choice of lowering their 
    retail rates for interexchange services, thereby reducing their profit 
    margins, or maintaining their retail rates at the higher price and risk 
    losing market share.
        278. We conclude that, although an incumbent LEC's control of 
    exchange and exchange access facilities may give it the incentive and 
    ability to engage in a price squeeze, we have in place adequate 
    safeguards against such conduct. The Policy and Rules Concerning Rates 
    for Competitive Common Carrier Services and Facilities Authorizations 
    Therefor, CC Docket No. 79-252, Fifth Report & Order, 49 FR 34824 
    (September 4, 1984) (Fifth Competitive Carrier Report and Order), 
    requirements aid in the prevention and detection of such 
    anticompetitive conduct. In our recent Regulatory Treatment of LEC 
    Provision of Interexchange Services Originating in the LEC's Local 
    Exchange Area and Policy and Rules Concerning the Interstate, 
    Interexchange Marketplace, Second Report and Order in CC Docket No. 96-
    149 and Third Report and Order in CC Docket No. 96-61, 62 FR ______ 
    (released April 18, 1997) (Dom/Nondom R&O), we decided to retain the 
    Fifth Competitive Carrier Report and Order separation requirements for 
    incumbent LEC provision of in-region interLATA services. These 
    requirements apply both to BOCs and to other incumbent LECs. In 
    addition, as discussed in that order, BOC interexchange affiliates are 
    subject to the safeguards set forth in section 272 of the Act.
        279. The Fifth Competitive Carrier Report and Order separation 
    requirements have been in place for over ten years, and independent 
    (non-BOC) incumbent LECs have been providing in-region, interexchange 
    services on a separated basis with no substantiated complaints of a 
    price squeeze. Under these separation requirements, incumbent LECs are 
    required to maintain separate books of account, permitting us to trace 
    and document improper allocation of costs and/or assets between a LEC 
    and its long-distance affiliate, as well as to detect discriminatory 
    conduct. In addition, we prohibit joint ownership of facilities, which 
    further reduces the risk
    
    [[Page 31911]]
    
    of improper allocations of the costs of common facilities between the 
    incumbent LEC and its interexchange affiliate, as discussed at length 
    in the Dom/Nondom R&O and the Implementation of the Non-Accounting 
    Safeguards of Sections 271 and 272 of the Communications Act of 1934, 
    as amended, First Report and Order and Further NPRM, FCC 96-489 Paras.  
    159-62 (December 24, 1996) (Non-Accounting Safeguards Order), on 
    recon., FCC 97-52 (February 19, 1997), recon. pending, CC Docket No. 
    96-149, petition for summary review in part denied and motion for 
    voluntary remand granted sub nom., Bell Atlantic v. FCC, No. 97-1067 
    (D.C. Cir. filed March 31, 1997), petition for review pending sub nom., 
    SBC Communications v. FCC, No. 97-1118 (D.C. Cir. filed March 6, 1997) 
    (held in abeyance pursuant to court order filed May 7, 1997), 62 FR 
    2991 (January 21, 1997) (addressing the Act's prohibition of BOC joint 
    ownership with its interexchange affiliate pursuant to section 272). As 
    we also discussed at length in those orders, the prohibition on 
    jointly-owned facilities also helps to deter any discrimination in 
    access to the LEC's transmission and switching facilities by requiring 
    the affiliates to follow the same procedures as competing interexchange 
    carriers to obtain access to those facilities. Finally, our requirement 
    that incumbent LECs offer services at tariffed rates, or on the same 
    basis as requesting carriers that have negotiated interconnection 
    agreements pursuant to section 251 reduces the risk of a price squeeze 
    to the extent that an affiliate's long-distance prices would have to 
    exceed their costs for tariffed services.
        280. Current conditions in markets for interexchange services give 
    us comfort that an anticompetitive price squeeze is unlikely to occur 
    as a result of our decision not to prescribe immediately access charge 
    rates at forward-looking economic cost levels. If an incumbent LEC does 
    attempt to engage in an anticompetitive price squeeze against rival 
    long-distance providers, the provisions of the Act should permit new 
    entrants or other competitors to seek out or provide competitive 
    alternatives to tariffed incumbent LEC access services. For example, 
    under the provisions of section 251, a competitor will be able to 
    purchase unbundled network elements to compete with the incumbent LEC's 
    offering of local exchange access. Therefore, so long as an incumbent 
    LEC is required to provide unbundled network elements quickly, at 
    economic cost, and in adequate quantities, an attempted price squeeze 
    seems likely to induce substantial additional entry in local markets. 
    Accordingly, there should be a reduced likelihood that an incumbent LEC 
    could successfully employ such a strategy to obtain the power to raise 
    long-distance prices to the detriment of consumers.
        281. Furthermore, even if a LEC were able to allocate improperly 
    the costs of its affiliate's interexchange services, we conclude that 
    it is unlikely that the LEC's interexchange affiliate could engage 
    successfully in predation. At least four interexchange carriers--AT&T, 
    MCI, Sprint, and LDDS WorldCom--have nationwide, or near-nationwide, 
    network facilities that cover every LEC's region. These are large, 
    well-established companies with millions of customers throughout the 
    nation. It is unlikely, therefore, that one or more of these national 
    companies can be driven from the market with a price squeeze, even if 
    effectuated by several LECs simultaneously, whether acting together or 
    independently. Even if it could be done, it is doubtful that the LECs' 
    interexchange affiliates would later be able to raise, and profitably 
    sustain, prices above competitive levels. As Professor Spulber has 
    observed, ``[e]ven in the unlikely event that [LECs'' interexchange 
    affiliates] could drive one of the three large interexchange carriers 
    into bankruptcy, the fiber-optic transmission capacity of that carrier 
    would remain intact, ready for another firm to buy the capacity at 
    distress sale and immediately undercut the [affiliates'] noncompetitive 
    prices.'' Daniel F. Spulber, Deregulating Telecommunications, 12 Yale 
    J. Reg. 25, 60 (1995).
        282. Finally, in addition to our regulations and the provisions of 
    section 251 of the Act, the antitrust laws also offer a measure of 
    protection against a possible price squeeze. Beginning with Judge 
    Learned Hand's opinion in United States v. Aluminum Co. of America 
    (Alcoa), 148 F.2d 416, 437-38 (2d Cir. 1945), a specific body of 
    precedent has developed under federal antitrust law defining situations 
    where a price squeeze can be actionable as a form of monopolization or 
    attempted monopolization under Section 2 of the Sherman Act. 15 U.S.C. 
    sec. 2. Under this precedent, a price squeeze can violate the antitrust 
    laws where (1) a firm has monopoly power with respect to an 
    ``upstream'' product; (2) it sells that product at ``higher than a 
    `fair price,' ''; (3) the product is a necessary input for the product 
    being sold by other firms in competition with the monopoly or its 
    affiliate in a ``downstream'' market; and (4) the monopolist offers the 
    ``downstream'' product at a price so low that (equally-efficient) 
    competitors cannot match the price and still earn a ``living profit.'' 
    Alcoa, 148 F.2d at 437-38. Over time, courts have developed several 
    tests for determining when the relationship between the two prices is 
    sufficiently adverse to competitors that it constitutes an 
    anticompetitive price squeeze. Although we believe it would not serve 
    the public interest for us knowingly to permit a price squeeze to 
    occur, and to rely entirely on the adequacy of antitrust law remedies 
    to protect the public, we take comfort in the fact that such remedies 
    exist should an anticompetitive price squeeze occur in spite of the 
    safeguards we have adopted. In particular, although a price squeeze 
    engaged in by several LECs, particularly if it involved more than one 
    of the BOCs or GTE, could have a significant impact on interexchange 
    competitors, we believe that the antitrust laws will act as a strong 
    backstop to our own enforcement process so that the risk of such 
    concerted activity is sufficiently limited. Because the rates charged 
    by LEC interexchange affiliates will not be regulated, we do not 
    believe that a court would reject a price squeeze claim under the 
    antitrust laws on the grounds that `` `normally' a price squeeze will 
    not constitute an exclusionary practice in the context of a fully 
    regulated monopoly.'' Town of Concord v. Boston Edison Co., 915 F.2d 17 
    (1st Cir. 1990) (J. Breyer), cert. denied, ______ U.S. ______, 111 S. 
    Ct. 1337 (1991). Indeed, the court in that case explicitly declined to 
    address the ``special problem'' posed by a price squeeze allegation 
    against a firm regulated in the input market and undercutting rivals' 
    prices in the unregulated market where inputs are used.
        283. Other Concerns Raised by Commenters. Several commenters raised 
    concerns that our market-based approach to access charge reform might 
    permit incumbent LECs to engage in cross subsidization, either between 
    competitive and non-competitive services, or between interstate access 
    services and other services such as video distribution. No evidence has 
    been presented, however, indicating any likelihood that current price 
    cap regulation, which is designed, in part, to prevent cross 
    subsidization, might become less effective under a market-based 
    approach to access charge reform. Those price cap regulations will 
    remain in place until there is sufficient competition to prevent an 
    incumbent LEC from charging rates that are not just and reasonable. 
    Therefore, we find that the record does not contain substantial
    
    [[Page 31912]]
    
    evidence that a market-based approach to access charge reform is any 
    less likely than current regulation to permit incumbent LECs to engage 
    in unreasonable cross subsidization with their interstate access 
    charges.
        284. Finally, several commenters based their support for a market-
    based approach, in part, on arguments that it would reduce, or 
    minimize, administrative burdens. Other commenters, on the other hand, 
    opposed a market-based approach on the grounds that it would increase 
    administrative burdens. Based on the record before us, however, we 
    cannot reach a conclusion as to the relative administrative burdens of 
    the two approaches. Some parts of our proposed market-based approach, 
    such as grants of increased pricing flexibility as competitive 
    conditions warranted, were modeled on waivers that we have granted 
    within the context of our current price cap plan and would likely be 
    necessary even if we had adopted a primarily prescriptive approach to 
    access charge rate level reform. Similarly, some parts of a 
    prescriptive approach, such as annual changes in price cap 
    calculations, will necessarily be a part of our market-based approach. 
    Accordingly, we can see no basis in this record for concluding that a 
    market-based approach to access charge reform will be any more or less 
    burdensome than any other alternative.
    
    B. Prescriptive Approaches
    
    1. Prescription of a New X-Factor
    a. Background
        285. In the NPRM, we observed that the Commission had initiated a 
    rulemaking proceeding in the Price Cap Fourth Further NPRM to examine a 
    number of proposals for revising the productivity offset component of 
    the X-Factor, and to consider related issues such as eliminating 
    sharing obligations and the low-end adjustment mechanism. We invited 
    parties to discuss in this proceeding whether the record developed 
    pursuant to the Price Cap Fourth Further NPRM justified increasing the 
    productivity offset, and specifically invited comment on the effects of 
    a forward-looking cost of capital and economic depreciation on total 
    factor productivity (TFP) measurement.
    b. Discussion
        286. The commenters generally repeat arguments made in the Price 
    Cap Fourth Further NPRM proceeding. For reasons explained in detail in 
    our companion Price Cap Fourth Report and Order, we conclude that we 
    should prescribe an X-Factor on the basis of total factor productivity 
    studies, the difference between LEC input price changes and input price 
    changes in the economy as a whole, and the 0.5 percent consumer 
    productivity dividend (CPD). In the companion order we find that this 
    results in an X-Factor prescription of 6.5 percent.
    2. Other Prescriptive Approaches
    a. Background
        287. In the NPRM, we sought comment on four options for a 
    prescriptive approach: reinitializing price cap indices (PCIs) to 
    economic cost-based levels; reinitializing PCIs to levels targeted to 
    yield no more than an 11.25 percent rate of return, or some other rate 
    of return; adding a policy-based mechanism similar to the CPD to the X-
    Factor; or prescribing economic cost-based rates. We have decided above 
    to rely primarily on a market-based approach, and impose prescriptive 
    requirements only when market forces are inadequate to ensure just and 
    reasonable rates for particular services or areas. We will determine 
    the details of our market-based approach in a future Order. In that 
    Order, we will also discuss in more detail what prescriptive 
    requirements we will use as a backstop to our market-based access 
    charge reform. In this section, we explain why we have decided not to 
    adopt any specific prescriptive mechanism in this Order.
    b. Rate Prescription
        288. Background. We sought comment on prescribing new interstate 
    access rates because simply reinitializing PCIs would not necessarily 
    compel incumbent LECs to establish reasonable rate structures. We also 
    noted, however, that prescribing access rates on a TSLRIC basis could 
    raise common cost allocation issues to a much greater extent than did 
    TELRIC pricing for unbundled network elements.
        289. Discussion. In Section IV.A, above, we explain why we can and 
    should rely primarily on market forces to cause interstate access rates 
    to move toward economic cost levels over the next several years. 
    Prescribing TSLRIC-based access rates would be the most direct, uniform 
    way of moving those rates to cost. But, precisely because of its 
    directness and uniformity, rate regulation can only be, at best, an 
    imperfect substitute for market forces. Regulation cannot replicate the 
    complex and dynamic ways in which competition will affect the prices, 
    service offerings, and investment decisions of both incumbent LECs and 
    their competitors. A market-based approach to rate regulation should 
    produce, for consumers of telecommunications services, a better 
    combination of prices, choices, and innovation than can be achieved 
    through rate prescription. A market-based approach, with continued 
    price cap regulation of services not subject to substantial competition 
    and with the prescriptive backstop described in Section IV.A, is thus 
    consistent both with the pro-competitive, deregulatory goals of the 
    1996 Act and with our responsibility under Title II, Part I of the 
    Communications Act to ensure just and reasonable rates.
        290. Furthermore, immediate prescription of TSLRIC-based rates 
    would not necessarily move rates to those levels faster than the 
    market-based approach and prescriptive backstop developed in Section 
    IV.A. Some parties that favor a prescriptive approach have asserted 
    that setting access rates immediately at TSLRIC levels would reduce 
    incumbent LEC revenues by $10 billion or more. Were we to make such a 
    rate prescription, we would consider phasing in rate reductions of that 
    magnitude over a period of years, in order to avoid the rate shock that 
    would accompany such a great rate reduction at one time. Finally, 
    because we have adopted a more efficient rate structure for interstate 
    switched access services, it is not necessary to prescribe new rates in 
    order to achieve efficient rate structures, as TRA and TCI recommend. 
    Accordingly, we will not prescribe TSLRIC-based access rates at this 
    time.
    c. Reinitialization of PCIs on a Rate-of-Return Basis
        291. Discussion. We reject reinitialization on the basis of any 
    rate of return at this time. As a general matter, the parties 
    advocating a rate-of-return based reinitialization do not provide any 
    persuasive reason for adopting that particular approach. They favor 
    reinitialization largely because they believe interstate access charges 
    should be lower than they are now. As explained above, however, we are 
    adopting a primarily market-based approach to rate level adjustments. 
    The prescriptive backstop to that approach will be based on TSLRIC cost 
    studies and, most likely, applied to geographically deaveraged rates. 
    That approach is more likely to result in rates that are aligned with 
    economic costs than would reinitialization to a particular rate of 
    return on an embedded cost rate base.
        292. Moreover, because the basic theory of our existing price cap 
    regime
    
    [[Page 31913]]
    
    is that the prospect of retaining higher earnings gives carriers an 
    incentive to become more efficient, we believe that rate of return-
    based reinitialization would have substantial pernicious effects on the 
    efficiency objectives of our current policies. In this regard, we have 
    often expressed concern in past price cap orders that maintaining links 
    between rate levels and a carrier's achieved rate of return would 
    undercut the efficiency incentives price cap regulation was designed to 
    encourage. In the LEC Price Cap Order, we rejected a so-called 
    ``automatic stabilizer'' adjustment to the price cap index that--like 
    reinitialization--would have permanently adjusted index levels downward 
    in the event that carriers achieved earnings above a certain rate of 
    return. Similarly, in our 1995 LEC Price Cap Performance Review Order, 
    we cited as a disadvantage of AT&T's ``Direct Model'' method of 
    determining the PCI formula's ``X-Factor'' the fact that ``a target 
    rate of return is a critical factor in measuring productivity.'' And 
    although we sought comment in the Access Reform NPRM on the question of 
    rate of return-based reinitialization of the price cap indices, we once 
    again expressed concern that such action ``could have a negative effect 
    on the productivity incentives of the LEC price cap plan.'' We, of 
    course, have authority to change our methods and theories of regulating 
    LEC rates when we believe the purposes of the Communications Act would 
    be better served by doing so. However, we find that, given our 
    consistently critical past statements about rate of return-based 
    adjustments to price caps, a decision now to reinitialize PCIs to any 
    specified rate of return would further undermine future efficiency 
    incentives by making carriers less confident in the constancy of our 
    regulatory policies.
        293. In declining to reinitialize PCIs on the basis of carriers' 
    rates of return, we reject GSA/DOD's suggestion that access rates have 
    been excessive merely because the earnings of most price cap carriers 
    have exceeded 11.25 percent, and, in some cases, by substantial 
    amounts. When the Commission adopted price cap regulation, it 
    specifically permitted price cap carriers to earn in excess of 11.25 
    percent in order to encourage them to become more productive. The 
    Commission also concluded that complaints alleging excessive earnings 
    relative to costs will not lie as long as the carrier is in compliance 
    with the sharing mechanism. In addition, we found in the LEC Price Cap 
    Performance Review Order that access rates declined substantially under 
    price cap regulation from 1991 to 1994, in spite of the increases in 
    earnings to which GSA/DOD alluded. Furthermore, the vastly different 
    results among companies show that the incentive plan we have for cost 
    reduction (price caps) largely is working as predicted, whereas a rate-
    of-return-based scheme would have cost much in terms of inefficiency.
    d. Reinitialization of PCIs on a TSLRIC Basis
    i. Background
        294. In the NPRM, we sought comment on reducing price cap PCIs by 
    an amount equal to the difference between the incumbent LECs' PCIs and 
    the revenues that would be produced by rates set at TSLRIC levels. We 
    noted that a TSLRIC-based PCI reinitialization might be preferable to a 
    TSLRIC-based rate prescription because it would not require us to 
    prescribe common cost allocations. We also sought comment on whether or 
    to what extent we could rely on TELRIC studies developed for pricing 
    unbundled network elements, and whether we should initiate joint board 
    proceedings to rely on state commissions to evaluate the incumbent 
    LECs' TELRIC studies.
    ii. Discussion
        295. We have decided not to require incumbent LECs to reinitialize 
    PCIs on a TSLRIC basis at this time. As we discuss in Section IV.A 
    above, we expect market forces to develop as a result of the 1996 Act 
    and to drive access rate levels to forward-looking economic costs. 
    Furthermore, the record in this proceeding is unclear on whether there 
    is an accurate and convenient method for determining TSLRIC for 
    purposes of reinitializing PCIs at this time. Specifically, it is 
    unclear whether the TELRIC studies used to develop unbundled network 
    element prices can be used for access services.
    e. Policy-Based X-Factor Increase
        296. Background. In the NPRM, we observed that we adopted a 
    consumer productivity dividend (CPD) to assure that some portion of the 
    benefits of the incumbent LECs' increased productivity growth under 
    price cap regulation would flow to ratepayers in the form of reduced 
    rates. We sought comment on establishing a policy-based mechanism 
    similar to the CPD to force access rates to cost-based levels.
        297. Discussion. We do not require a policy-based X-Factor increase 
    at this time for the same reason we do not require a TSLRIC-based PCI 
    reinitialization; we expect market forces to control access charges 
    effectively in a less intrusive manner.
        298. BellSouth and GTE oppose increasing the CPD as an arbitrary 
    and confiscatory measure. SNET claims that increasing the X-Factor 
    merely because the price cap LECs have earned too much, or simply to 
    drive rates down, is essentially an abandonment of price cap 
    regulation, because it would punish incumbent LECs for their efficiency 
    gains made under the price cap regime. BA/NYNEX and GTE contend that 
    the X-Factor should be chosen to reflect reasonably expected incumbent 
    LEC productivity growth rather than to achieve a specific rate 
    reduction. We emphasize that we have done nothing in this Order to 
    increase the X-Factor. In our companion Price Cap Fourth Report and 
    Order, we prescribe a new X-Factor of 6.5 percent, but this 
    prescription is based on detailed studies of LEC productivity growth 
    and input price changes. We decline to increase the CPD, and we reject 
    a proposal to set the X-Factor to target an industry average rate of 
    return of 11.25 percent. Thus, none of our actions in either this Order 
    or our companion Order can properly be characterized as an abandonment 
    of price cap regulation, or as motivated merely by a desire to drive 
    rates down.
    
    C. Equal Access Costs
    
    1. Background
        299. In the NPRM, we solicited comment on whether to require 
    incumbent price cap LECs to make an exogenous cost decrease to one or 
    more of their PCIs to account for the completion of the amortization of 
    equal access costs on December 31, 1993. We note that through the 
    years, this issue has been referred to as ``equal access network 
    reconfiguration'' or EANR costs. This is a misnomer, which we correct 
    today. ``Equal access'' is the provision of exchange access to all 
    interexchange carriers on an unbundled, tariffed basis that is equal in 
    type, quality, and price to that provided to AT&T and its affiliates. 
    Equal Access and Network Reconfiguration Costs, Memorandum Opinion and 
    Order, 50 FR 50910 ( December 9, 1985) at para. 18 (Equal Access Cost 
    Order). ``Network Reconfiguration'' costs are those investments and 
    expenses incurred in connection with structurally conforming the pre-
    divestiture AT&T network with the LATA boundaries mandated by the MFJ. 
    Issues underlying network reconfiguration costs were resolved in the 
    Equal Access Cost Order and have not been raised since.
        300. Under court order, the BOCs and GTE were required to provide 
    equal
    
    [[Page 31914]]
    
    access. See United States v. AT&T, 552 F. Supp. 131, 233 (D.D.C. 1982); 
    United States v. GTE Corp., 603 F. Supp. 730, 745 (D.D.C. 1984). This 
    conversion, estimated at more than $2.6 billion, was largely completed 
    by 1990, and involved both capital and non-capital expenditures. Under 
    the Equal Access Cost Order, incumbent LECs were required to identify 
    separately the incremental capital investments and the incremental non-
    capital-related expenses associated with the implementation of equal 
    access. The Equal Access Cost Order directed that the capital 
    investments, which it estimated to comprise approximately 55 percent of 
    the $2.6 billion, be treated pursuant to ordinary accounting and 
    ratemaking principles. The Commission determined that the remaining 45 
    percent of the expenditures--which were non-capitalized equal access 
    expenses--required special treatment:
    
        [W]e are concerned that these expenditures will cause irregular 
    and substantial fluctuations in revenue requirements associated with 
    equal access. Because they are extraordinary, are for the greatest 
    part expected to be incurred over the next few years, and, 
    therefore, are likely to be distortive of financial results and rate 
    requirements, we find that these equal access expenses should be 
    deferred and amortized.
    
    Equal Access Cost Order, 50 FR at 50914-15, para. 33. The Commission 
    ordered that these equal access expenses be separately identified and 
    recorded, and that they be written off over a period of eight years, 
    ending December 31, 1993. See Equal Access and Network Reconfiguration 
    Costs, Reconsideration, FCC No. 86-470 (released November 5, 1986) at 
    para. 25 (Equal Access Cost Reconsideration Order). In the 
    reconsideration of the Equal Access Cost Order, the Commission found 
    that the specific termination date of the eight year amortization of 
    these expenses would ``shorten the period during which the unamortized 
    balances are entitled to earn a rate of return.'' Id. It is clear that 
    the LECs' rate-of-return (ROR) rates included revenue recovery for both 
    capitalized expenditures (recovered through the ordinary depreciation 
    process) and non-capitalized expenses (recovered through the special 
    amortization process). It is also clear that at the time the 
    amortization was imposed, the Commission envisioned an end to the 
    recovery for the amortized expenses and a subsequent decrease in ROR 
    rates.
        301. In converting to price cap regulation, the Commission found 
    that equal access conversion was, in large part, completed and that the 
    associated costs, which included both the capitalized expenditures and 
    the amortized expenses, were embedded in the existing rates. As such, 
    the Commission refused to grant LECs an exogenous increase for equal 
    access costs, finding that these costs were already accounted for in 
    the existing rates. The Commission also based its decision to deny an 
    exogenous increase on its concern that exogenous treatment of equal 
    access expenditures would create inappropriate incentives for the LECs 
    to inflate the amounts spent on equal access. The Commission noted the 
    difficulty of reviewing equal access costs, as well as the risk that 
    incumbent LECs might willfully or inadvertently shift switched access 
    costs into the proposed equal access category in order to benefit from 
    the requested exogenous increase.
    2. Discussion
        302. We find that an exogenous cost decrease to account for 
    completion of the amortization of equal access non-capitalized expenses 
    is necessary and appropriate. Although we have addressed this issue in 
    the past and declined to act, we now find that an exogenous decrease is 
    merited. We recognize our decision departs from our past decisions that 
    have declined to impose an exogenous decrease for the completed 
    recovery of these costs. As discussed below, our decision today 
    reverses those decisions and is based on an extensive record from this, 
    and prior proceedings. Our decision today aligns our treatment of the 
    completion of the amortization of equal access costs with two other 
    similar amortizations that were ordered under ROR regulation and 
    carried over into price cap regulation, namely, the exogenous decrease 
    imposed for the completion of the amortization of depreciation reserve 
    deficiencies, and the exogenous decrease imposed for the completion of 
    the amortization of inside wire costs. We are convinced that this 
    treatment is the proper method to ensure that ratepayers are not paying 
    for costs that have already been completely recovered.
        303. The need for an exogenous adjustment to account for the 
    expiration of the equal access expense amortization stems from the 
    different ways in which rates are established under ROR regulation, on 
    the one hand, and price cap regulation, on the other hand, and from the 
    Commission's decision to establish initial price cap levels at the 
    outset of price cap regulation on the basis of existing ROR-derived 
    rates. When converting from ROR regulation to price cap on regulation 
    January 1, 1991, the Commission needed to select a set of ``baseline'' 
    rate levels to which the price cap index of incremental cost changes 
    would be tied. For that purpose, we chose the ROR-developed rates that 
    were in effect on July 1, 1990. The Commission found that, in general, 
    those rates served as an appropriate starting point for measuring 
    subsequent incremental cost changes under price cap regulation, because 
    they ``reflect[ed] the reasonable operation of ROR regulation.''
        304. In two respects, however, the Commission recognized that 
    existing rates did not reflect equilibrium ROR-derived rates, but 
    rather reflected special corrective adjustments that we had ordered 
    previously. In particular, the Commission noted that existing rates had 
    embedded within them costs associated with Commission-ordered ``one-
    time'' amortizations of depreciation reserve deficiencies and inside 
    wiring costs. Had ROR regulation continued, the rates subject to these 
    amortizations would have been reduced when the amortizations were 
    completed. To ensure that ratepayers under price caps would not be 
    required permanently to bear these temporary Commission-ordered, ROR-
    derived rate adjustments, we directed LECs to make downward exogenous 
    cost adjustments to their price cap indices upon the expiration of 
    those amortizations.
        305. Similarly, the Commission ordered amortization of equal access 
    expenses, which also were reflected in baseline rates at the outset of 
    price cap regulation. Under normal ROR ratemaking principles, those 
    expenses--which, for the most part, already had been incurred before 
    price cap regulation was initiated--would have been recovered in the 
    BOCs' rates the same year they were incurred and would no longer have 
    been reflected in rates at the time price caps were instituted. 
    However, as explained supra, the Commission required the carriers to 
    amortize these extraordinary expenses over eight years because of the 
    potential fluctuations in revenue requirements associated with equal 
    access. Thus these expenses remained embedded within BOC rates at the 
    outset of price caps even though, for the most part, the extraordinary 
    expenses themselves were no longer being incurred.
        306. The specific question of whether the completely amortized 
    equal access expenses should be treated exogenously has been presented 
    to the Commission on a number of occasions. In the past, procedural 
    impediments arising from our rules, as well as the lack of an adequate 
    record, convinced us to decline to impose such treatment at that time. 
    For example, when AT&T raised
    
    [[Page 31915]]
    
    the issue of downward adjustment for completed amortization of equal 
    access expenses in an annual access charge tariff proceeding, the 
    Common Carrier Bureau found that the issue was beyond the scope of the 
    proceeding because it would require a substantive change to the price 
    cap rules. Similarly, in response to AT&T's and MCI's revisiting the 
    question in both the First 1994 Annual Access Charge Order and the 
    Second 1994 Annual Access Charge Order, the Commission found that 
    exogenous treatment would require a rule change to section 61.45(d) of 
    the Commission's rules. Because no LEC had filed for a waiver of 
    section 61.45(d), the Common Carrier Bureau found that the issue was 
    not properly presented for investigation.
        307. In denying the requests for procedural reasons, the Commission 
    supported its decisions with various rationales. In some instances, 
    these rationales appear now not to have been considered to a sufficient 
    degree. In addressing equal access costs in the orders adopting price 
    cap regulation, the Commission focused primarily on the question of 
    whether future equal access investments and expenses should be treated 
    exogenously because equal access had been compelled by regulatory (or 
    judicial) order. We concluded, subject to consideration of waiver 
    requests, that we should not accord exogenous cost treatment to such 
    future equal access conversion costs, because of concerns that 
    exogenous cost treatment would create disincentives to implement equal 
    access in an efficient manner. We did not focus in detail on the 
    logically distinct question of whether equal access expenses that were 
    already embedded within baseline BOC rates pursuant to the temporary 
    ``one-time'' amortizations (and thus raised no question with respect to 
    future incentives) should be removed through exogenous adjustments when 
    the amortizations expired. Instead, we relegated that issue to a 
    footnote, which denied exogenous cost treatment on the basis of a 
    skeletal analysis that makes no reference to our treatment of the 
    depreciation reserve deficiency and inside wiring amortizations. In the 
    footnote, it is clear that the Commission was not distinguishing 
    between capitalized costs, which were properly treated as depreciated 
    expenses, and non-capitalized expenses, which were actually amortized 
    per the Commission's own requirement. The Commission framed the issue 
    of a downward adjustment in terms of whether the completion of 
    depreciation required a downward adjustment, querying ``whether the 
    BOCs will experience any cost change in 1994 [at the completion of the 
    amortization] that stems from factors beyond their control.'' In 
    support of its implicitly negative answer, the Commission analogized to 
    the absence of a price cap index change when a piece of equipment is 
    fully depreciated, or when a carrier increased or decreased the speed 
    with which it recovered investments. The Commission found that, 
    ``[b]ased on a meager factual record presented on the issue of equal 
    access expense, we are reluctant to depart from our practice of not 
    adjusting PCI levels to reflect levels of cost recovery.''
        308. The Commission's analysis at that time was incomplete. The 
    Equal Access Cost Order and the Equal Access Cost Reconsideration Order 
    explicitly recognized two components of equal access costs--
    capitalized, which were to be depreciated, and non-capitalized, which 
    were extraordinary and were to be amortized over a set period. The 
    Commission established different treatment for these two sets of costs 
    based on policy reasons, and ordered an amortization schedule for the 
    non-capitalized costs. The Commission's establishment of this schedule 
    was beyond the incumbent LECs' control. The Commission's analogy to the 
    lack of exogenous treatment for equipment depreciation and changes in 
    the tempo of recovery should have only applied to the capitalized 
    portion of the equal access costs.
        309. The Commission explicitly stated in the LEC Price Cap Order 
    that completed amortizations of depreciation reserve deficiencies 
    require an exogenous downward adjustment. The Commission found that 
    such an adjustment was necessary to ensure that ratepayers were not 
    paying for a cost that no longer existed. Analytically, the amortized 
    portion of equal access expenses should have been treated in the same 
    fashion as the amortized depreciation reserve deficiency costs. The 
    Commission's imposition of a downward exogenous adjustment for the 
    completion of inside wire amortizations further supports our finding 
    today that an exogenous decrease is appropriate and necessary for the 
    completion of the amortization of equal access non-capitalized 
    expenses.
        310. We reject our prior analysis of amortized equal access costs 
    and accord the expiration of equal access cost amortizations the same 
    exogenous cost treatment given to the amortizations of the depreciation 
    reserve deficiencies and inside wiring costs. Both of those 
    amortizations were given exogenous cost treatment when they expired 
    because they reflected temporary, one-time treatment of costs under ROR 
    regulation that, due to the mid-stream switch to price cap regulation, 
    would have become permanent (even though the costs already had been 
    recovered) absent an exogenous cost adjustment. The same is true for 
    equal access cost amortizations.
        311. Because this is a rulemaking, we do not face the same 
    procedural impediments as in some of our prior decisions, as explained 
    supra. We determine that the record from this proceeding allows us to 
    make a reasoned decision on this issue. We find that an exogenous 
    decrease is necessary in order to adjust the price caps for the 
    completed recovery of the specified equal access non-capitalized 
    expenses that we required be amortized over an eight-year period. 
    Because the current price cap index includes an expense that has now 
    been completely recovered, the price cap should be adjusted downward to 
    account its recovery. Simply stated, we find that ratepayers should not 
    be forced to pay for a cost that, were it not for the way price cap 
    regulation occurred in this instance, they would no longer be paying. 
    By imposing a downward exogenous adjustment to adjust the PCI for the 
    complete recovery of specific equal access expenses through 
    amortization, we will avoid unfairly imposing a subsidy burden on 
    ratepayers. Our decision in this matter will align charges more closely 
    to costs.
        312. Several commenters have argued that they continue to incur 
    costs as a part of the provision of equal access. These ongoing costs 
    are not at issue in the present proceeding. As explained above, the 
    costs at issue were a set of costs that the Commission determined 
    should be amortized for policy reasons. These costs were extraordinary 
    and, if allowed to be imposed in the normal fashion, would have 
    resulted in huge rate fluctuations. We consider the ongoing costs of 
    providing equal access as part of the normal costs of providing 
    telephone service. Exogenous treatment of these costs is unnecessary. 
    In response to BellSouth's contention that the record is inadequate for 
    us to make a decision about an exogenous decrease, we find that the 
    current record provides a sufficient basis for our decision. 
    Furthermore, we note that in the past, the record may have been 
    sufficient, but, as explained above, the Commission's analysis was 
    incorrect.
        313. TCA and GCI are concerned about how the Commission will treat 
    cost recovery for LECs that convert to equal access in the future. As 
    we stated in the very first LEC Price Cap report
    
    [[Page 31916]]
    
    and order, LECs that have not received a bona fide request for equal 
    access at the time they become subject to price cap regulation may 
    request a waiver for special treatment of those special conversion 
    costs when the time arises. See Policies and Rules Concerning Rates for 
    Dominant Carriers, CC Docket No. 87-313, First Report and Order, 54 FR 
    19836 (May 8, 1989).
        314. We hereby direct price cap LECs to make a downward exogenous 
    adjustment to the traffic sensitive basket in the Annual Access Tariff 
    filing that takes effect on July 1, 1997 to account for the completed 
    amortization of equal access expenses.
    
    D. Correction of Improper Cost Allocations
    
    1. Marketing Expenses
    a. Background
        315. Prior to 1987, incumbent LEC marketing expenses were allocated 
    between the interstate and intrastate jurisdictions on the basis of 
    local and toll revenues. In 1987, a Federal-State Joint Board 
    recommended that interstate access revenues be excluded from the 
    allocation factor used to apportion marketing expenses between the 
    interstate and intrastate jurisdictions because marketing expenses are 
    not incurred in the provision of interstate access services. Amendment 
    of Part 67 (New Part 36) of the Commission's Rules and Establishment of 
    a Federal-State Joint Board, CC Docket No. 86-297, Recommended Decision 
    and Order, 52 FR 15355 (April 28, 1987) (Marketing Expense Recommended 
    Decision). The Commission agreed with the Joint Board's recommendation 
    and adopted new procedures that allocated marketing expenses in Account 
    6610 on the basis of revenues excluding access revenues. MTS and WATS 
    Market Structure, Amendment of Part 67 (New Part 36) of the 
    Commission's Rules and Establishment of a Federal-State Joint Board, CC 
    Docket Nos. 78-72, 80-286, and 86-297, Report and Order, 52 FR 17228 
    (May 6, 1987). In petitions for reconsideration of the Commission's 
    order, several incumbent LECs argued that the revised separations 
    treatment of marketing expenses would result in a significant, 
    nationwide shift of $475 million in revenue requirements to the 
    intrastate jurisdiction. MTS and WATS Market Structure, Amendment of 
    Part 67 (New Part 36) of the Commission's Rules and Establishment of a 
    Joint Board, CC Docket No. 78-72, 80-286, and 86-297, Memorandum 
    Opinion and Order on Reconsideration and Supplemental Notice of 
    Proposed Rulemaking, 52 FR 32922 (September 1, 1987) (Marketing Expense 
    Reconsideration Order). On reconsideration, the Commission adopted for 
    marketing expenses an interim allocation factor that includes access 
    revenues, pending the outcome of a further inquiry by the Joint Board.
        316. In the NPRM, we stated that some of the difference between the 
    price cap LECs' interstate allocated costs and forward-looking costs 
    may be traced to past regulatory practices that were designed to shift 
    some costs from the intrastate jurisdiction to the interstate 
    jurisdiction in order to further universal service goals. We observed 
    that the Commission's decision in the Marketing Expense Reconsideration 
    Order to allocate intrastate marketing costs to the interstate 
    jurisdiction was an example of such past regulatory practices. We asked 
    parties to comment on the extent to which the difference between price 
    cap LECs' interstate allocated costs and forward-looking costs is a 
    result of such decisions.
    b. Discussion
        317. Under current separations procedures, approximately 25 percent 
    of price cap LECs' total marketing expenses are allocated to the 
    interstate jurisdiction. We agree with parties that contend that, 
    because marketing expenses generally are incurred in connection with 
    promoting the sale of retail services, those expenses for the most part 
    should be recovered from incumbent LEC retail services, which are found 
    predominantly in the intrastate jurisdiction. Pursuant to section 
    410(c) of the Act, however, the Commission must refer any rulemaking 
    proceeding regarding the jurisdictional separation of common carrier 
    property and expenses between interstate and intrastate operations to a 
    Federal-State Joint Board. We intend to initiate a proceeding to review 
    comprehensively our Part 36 jurisdictional separations procedures in 
    the near future. We will refer this issue to the Federal-State Joint 
    Board in CC Docket No. 80-286 for resolution as part of that 
    comprehensive review. We therefore do not reallocate these costs 
    between the interstate and intrastate jurisdictions at this time.
        318. In the Marketing Expense Recommended Decision, the Joint Board 
    stated that the inclusion of access revenues in the allocation factor 
    for marketing expenses is unreasonable because incumbent LECs do not 
    actively market or advertise access services. Although parties 
    contested the accuracy of this statement on reconsideration, the 
    Commission did not assess incumbent LEC claims that the decision to 
    exclude access revenues in the allocator for marketing expenses was 
    based on an inaccurate perception of the extent to which LECs actively 
    market or advertise exchange access services. The Commission instead 
    referred marketing expense issues back to the Joint Board, with 
    specific instruction to the parties to identify any Account 6610 
    marketing activities that are related to access services and any such 
    activities that are related to a specific jurisdiction. We continue to 
    recognize that some expenses recorded in Account 6610 may indeed be 
    incurred in the provision of interstate access service, and that this 
    is an issue that must be addressed by the Joint Board when it examines 
    the appropriate allocation factor for marketing expenses. We note, 
    however, that the Commission did not find in the Marketing Expense 
    Reconsideration Order that the Joint Board's initial conclusion in the 
    Marketing Expense Recommended Decision that incumbent LECs do not 
    market or advertise access services to be inaccurate.
        319. We conclude that price cap LECs' marketing costs that are not 
    related to the sale or advertising of interstate switched access 
    services are not appropriately recovered from IXCs through per-minute 
    interstate switched access charges. Pending a recommendation by the 
    Joint Board on a new method of apportioning marketing costs between the 
    intrastate and interstate jurisdictions, we direct price cap LECs to 
    recover marketing expenses allocated to the interstate jurisdiction 
    from end users on a per-line basis, for the reasons we discuss below.
        320. Recovering these expenses from end users instead of from IXCs 
    is consistent with principles of cost-causation to the extent that 
    price cap LEC sales and advertising activities are aimed at selling 
    retail services to end users, and not at selling switched access 
    services to IXCs. Recovery on a per-line basis, while perhaps not 
    precisely reflective of the manner in which marketing costs are 
    incurred, is preferable to the current rule requiring price cap LECs to 
    recover their marketing expenses through per-minute access charges. A 
    price cap LEC's retail marketing costs are not caused by usage of 
    switched access services, and its efforts to sell additional lines, 
    vertical features, and other retail services would only indirectly 
    cause an increase in switched access usage. Per-minute recovery of 
    retail marketing costs thus distorts prices in the long distance and 
    local markets in the same way as does per-minute recovery of other NTS 
    costs.
        321. In the past, price cap LEC retail marketing may have focused 
    on the sale of optional vertical features such as call
    
    [[Page 31917]]
    
    waiting and caller ID, and on features and services designed for 
    business customers. As local competition develops, we would expect that 
    sales expenses would be driven by the price cap LEC's need to respond 
    to competition. In any case, it is beyond our jurisdiction to reassign 
    retail marketing costs to retail services on a truly cost-causative 
    basis. There is probably a relationship, however, between the number of 
    lines purchased by an end user, particularly a business user, and the 
    amount of effort a price cap LEC expends to sell services and features 
    to that end user. Furthermore, as parties have observed in the record 
    in this proceeding, price cap LECs actively market second lines to 
    residential customers. We conclude, therefore, that the most efficient 
    and cost-causative method legally available to this Commission at this 
    time for recovery of price cap LEC retail marketing costs allocated to 
    the interstate jurisdiction is to charge those end users to whom the 
    price cap LECs' marketing is directed--multi-line business and non-
    primary residential line end users. We further note that by not 
    permitting price cap LECs to recover these costs from primary 
    residential and single-line business customers, we avoid potential 
    universal service concerns that weigh against increasing charges on 
    these end users.
        322. Moreover, continued recovery of interstate-allocated marketing 
    expenses in per-minute switched access charges would raise competitive 
    concerns. Increasingly, IXCs will be competing with incumbent, price 
    cap LECs in the provision of local exchange and exchange access 
    services. By permitting incumbent, price cap LECs to recover from IXCs 
    through interstate switched access charges their costs of marketing 
    retail services, these potential competitors are forced to bear the 
    incumbent, price cap LECs' costs of competing with the IXCs. Assigning 
    recovery of marketing costs to end users, on the other hand, subjects 
    these costs to the competitive pressures of the market.
        323. Marketing expenses are currently recovered through all 
    interstate access rate elements and the interexchange category in 
    proportion to the investment originally assigned to these elements and 
    categories by the Part 69 cost allocation rules. Special access and 
    interexchange services are purchased by, and marketed to, retail 
    customers. It is therefore appropriate to allow rates for those 
    services to continue to include recovery of marketing expenses. 
    Marketing expenses must be removed from all other rate elements by 
    means of downward exogenous adjustments to the PCIs for the common 
    line, traffic sensitive, and trunking baskets. With respect to the 
    trunking basket, the exogenous adjustment shall not reflect the amount 
    of any Account 6610 marketing expenses allocated to special access 
    services. The service band indices (SBIs) within the trunking basket 
    shall be decreased based on the amount of Account 6610 marketing 
    expenses allocated to switched services included in each service 
    category to reflect the exogenous adjustment to the PCI for the 
    trunking basket.
        324. After performing the appropriate downward exogenous 
    adjustments described above to the PCIs in the common line, traffic 
    sensitive, and trunking baskets, price cap LECs may recover the 
    revenues related to the Account 6610 marketing expenses removed from 
    these baskets by increasing the SLCs for multi-line business and non-
    primary residential lines. To prevent end-user charges from exceeding 
    levels we have established earlier in this Order, the amount of 
    marketing expenses to be recovered from multi-line business and non-
    primary residential lines in their SLCs shall be limited by the 
    ceilings we establish for these SLCs in this Order. To the extent these 
    ceilings prevent full recovery of these amounts, price cap LECs may 
    recover these costs by increasing equally both the non-primary 
    residential line PICC and the multi-line business PICC, not to exceed 
    the ceilings on the PICC for non-primary residential and multi-line 
    business lines. In the event the PICC ceilings prevent full recovery of 
    these expenses, any residual may be recovered through per-minute 
    charges on originating access service, subject to its ceiling. Finally, 
    to the extent price cap LECs cannot recover their remaining marketing 
    expenses through per-minute charges on originating access, any residual 
    may be recovered through per-minute charges on terminating access 
    service. Although these marketing expenses will be recovered through 
    the SLC, they shall not be included in the base factor or considered 
    common line revenues. To prevent price cap LECs from recovering these 
    expenses from access services, we are establishing a separate basket 
    for these marketing expenses.
        325. We reject, however, AT&T's assertion that recovery of 
    interstate-allocated marketing expenses through interstate access 
    charges violates the wholesale pricing provisions contained in section 
    252(d)(3) of the Act. AT&T identifies and quantifies inappropriate 
    retail expenses embedded in current interstate switched access rates 
    based on the requirements of section 252(d)(3) and the criteria for 
    wholesale rate cost studies outlined in the Local Competition Order. 
    Section 252(d)(3) establishes a pricing standard for the wholesale 
    provision of retail offerings to other carriers that resell the LEC 
    retail services. Section 252(d)(3) does not apply to the pricing of 
    interstate access, which is not a retail service.
    2. General Support Facilities
    a. Background
        326. In the NPRM, we sought comment on other possible cost 
    misallocations that may contribute to the difference between embedded 
    costs and forward-looking costs allocated to the interstate 
    jurisdiction. AT&T suggests that the allocation of embedded general 
    support facilities (GSF) costs, including general purpose computer 
    expenses, among access categories is one such misallocation. This 
    allocation, AT&T contends, results in the inappropriate support of 
    LECs' billing and collection service, which is a nonregulated, 
    interstate service, through regulated access charges. AT&T estimates 
    that $124 million of expenses recovered in interstate access support 
    the nonregulated billing and collection category. Of the $124 million, 
    $60.1 million is included in interstate switched carrier access, and 
    $20.5 million is in interstate special access, with the remainder 
    recovered by the SLC.
        327. The GSF investment category in Part 36 includes assets that 
    support other operations, such as land, buildings, vehicles, as well as 
    general purpose computer investment accounted for in USOA Account 2124. 
    Some incumbent LECs use general purpose computers to provide 
    nonregulated billing and collection services to IXCs. Part 69 allocates 
    GSF investment among the billing and collection category, interexchange 
    category, and the access elements based on the amount of Central Office 
    Equipment (COE), Cable and Wire Facilities (CWF), and Information 
    Origination/Termination Equipment (IO/T) investment allocated to each 
    Part 69 category. Because no COE, CWF, or IO/T investment is allocated 
    to the billing and collection category, no investment in general 
    support facilities, and thus no portion of general purpose computer 
    investment, is allocated to the billing and collection category. 
    Likewise, because expenses related to GSF investment are allocated in 
    the same manner as GSF investment, no GSF expenses, including expenses
    
    [[Page 31918]]
    
    related to general purpose computers, are allocated to the billing and 
    collection category. To the extent that costs are underallocated to the 
    billing and collection category, incumbent LECs' regulated services 
    recover through interstate access charges costs associated with 
    nonregulated provision of billing and collection services.
    b. Discussion
        328. We agree with AT&T and WorldCom that the current allocation of 
    GSF costs enables incumbent LECs to recover through regulated 
    interstate access charges costs caused by the LECs' nonregulated 
    billing and collection functions. By shifting some costs from 
    interstate access services to the nonregulated billing and collection 
    category, we would move interstate access rates closer to cost. The 
    NPRM, however, may not have provided sufficient notice to interested 
    parties that we would change in the allocation of LEC interstate costs 
    between regulated interstate services and nonregulated billing and 
    collection activities. We therefore seek comment on this issue in 
    Section VII.B below.
    
    V. Access Reform for Incumbent Rate-of-Return Local Exchange 
    Carriers
    
    A. Background
    
        329. In the NPRM we concluded that, with limited exceptions, the 
    scope of this proceeding should be limited to incumbent price cap LECs 
    because these carriers face the potential of significant competition in 
    the interstate exchange access market due to the new duties and 
    obligations imposed upon them by the 1996 Act. We proposed limited 
    exceptions that would subject all incumbent LECs to the rules 
    addressing allocation of universal service support to the interstate 
    revenue requirement, discussed in Section VI.D, below, and to the 
    reforms to the transport rate structure, including the TIC, discussed 
    in sections III.D., above. We invited comment on these tentative 
    conclusions on the scope of this proceeding. We also sought comment on 
    whether we should apply our proposed changes to the common line rate 
    structure to rate-of-return incumbent LECs and whether we should update 
    Part 69 access rules in light of various developments. We further 
    invited comment on the effect of these proposals and tentative 
    conclusions on small business entities, including small incumbent LECs 
    and new entrants. We also noted that we would address access reform for 
    rate-of-return carriers in a separate proceeding in 1997.
    
    B. Discussion
    
        330. We conclude that, with the limited exceptions discussed in 
    Sections III.D and VI.D, the scope of this proceeding should be limited 
    to price cap incumbent LECs. Price cap regulation governs almost 91 
    percent of interstate access charge revenues and more than 92 percent 
    of total incumbent LEC access lines. Currently, all ten of the 
    incumbent LECs with more than two million access lines and 13 of the 17 
    non-NECA incumbent LECS with more than 50,000 access lines are subject 
    to price cap regulation. Therefore, even though this proceeding applies 
    only to price cap incumbent LECs, it will nonetheless affect the vast 
    majority of all access lines and interstate access revenues.
        331. Small and rural LECs will most likely not experience 
    competition as fast as incumbent price cap LECs. We do not expect small 
    and rural LECs generally to face significant competition in the 
    immediate future because, for the most part, the high cost/low-margin 
    areas served by these LECs are unlikely to be the immediate targets of 
    new entrants or competitors. Moreover, as we noted in the NPRM, all 
    non-price cap incumbent LECs may be exempt from, or eligible for a 
    modification or suspension of, the interconnection and unbundling 
    requirements of the 1996 Act. By contrast, all incumbent LECs that are 
    ineligible for section 251(f) exemption, suspensions, or modifications 
    are incumbent price cap LECs. Because the latter incumbent LECs must 
    fulfill the section 251 (b) and (c) duties to provide interconnection 
    and unbundled elements to new entrants, they are likely to face 
    significant competition in the interstate exchange access market before 
    the small and mid-sized rate-of-return incumbent LECs face such 
    competition.
        332. We recognize that small and rural rate-of-return LECs face 
    unique circumstances and that a few of these carriers may now have, or 
    may soon receive, bona fide requests for interconnection. Although all 
    rate-of-return carriers may not be completely insulated from 
    competitive pressures, we are not persuaded by arguments that delaying 
    the initiation of an access reform proceeding for these carriers until 
    later this year will have a detrimental impact on their viability. A 
    separate proceeding for small and rural rate-of-return LECs will 
    provide us with the opportunity to conduct a comprehensive review of 
    the circumstances and issues unique to these carriers.
        333. We do not agree that Citizens Utilities should be exempt from 
    some of the rules we adopt in this order for price cap companies. The 
    decisions we reach here accommodate many of the concerns that Citizens 
    Utilities, as well as a number of other price cap LECs that serve rural 
    areas, voices in its pleadings. Although Citizens Utilities arguably 
    may face different circumstances than other price cap LECs that serve 
    larger urban and suburban populations, Citizens has indicated, by 
    electing price cap regulation, that it believes it can achieve a higher 
    rate of productivity than smaller rate-of-return LECs and that price 
    cap regulation is more beneficial to it than rate-of-return regulation. 
    Citizens Utilities has not demonstrated that the modifications we are 
    adopting in this proceeding would necessarily affect it differently 
    than other price cap LECs. If Citizens Utilities believes that it 
    cannot remain financially viable as a price cap carrier under the 
    revised access charge regime, it may petition for a waiver of the rule 
    that makes its decision to elect price cap regulation irreversible.
        334. We reject Centennial's suggestion that we adopt access reform 
    modifications for all incumbent LECs but then grant waivers for small, 
    rural LECs whose special circumstances warrant different 
    accommodations. For the most part, rate-of-return LECs face a common 
    set of complex issues, different than those faced by price cap LECs, 
    that are better addressed in a separate proceeding. In that proceeding, 
    we will address any differences that may exist between large and small 
    rate-of-return carriers.
        335. We therefore limit application of the rules we adopt in this 
    proceeding to the incumbent price cap LECs, with limited exceptions. 
    Because rate-of-return LECs will collect revenues from the new 
    universal service support mechanisms, we address allocation of 
    universal service support to the interstate revenue requirement for all 
    incumbent LECs in Section VI.D. In addition, because rate-of-return 
    incumbent LECs' transport rates were subject to the rules that were 
    remanded by the court in CompTel v. FCC, the changes to the TIC that we 
    adopt in Section III.D. pursuant to the court's remand, except for 
    changes that require reallocation of costs to newly-created rate 
    elements, will also apply to rate-of-return incumbent LECs. Finally, in 
    order to prevent double recovery of the costs associated with providing 
    access services to new entrants through the sale of unbundled network 
    elements, we conclude in Section VI.A, below, that our exclusion of 
    unbundled network elements from Part 69 access charges applies to all 
    incumbent LECs.
    
    [[Page 31919]]
    
    VI. Other Issues
    
    A. Applicability of Part 69 to Unbundled Elements
    
    1. Background
        336. In the NPRM, we requested comment regarding the potential 
    application of Part 69 access charges to unbundled network elements 
    purchased by carriers to provide local exchange services or exchange 
    access services. We tentatively concluded that unbundled network 
    elements should be excluded from such access charges. We noted that the 
    1996 Act allows telecommunications carriers to purchase access to 
    unbundled network elements and to use those elements to provide all 
    telecommunications services, including originating and terminating 
    access of interstate calls. We further noted that the 1996 Act requires 
    purchasing carriers to pay cost-based rates to incumbent LECs to 
    compensate them for use of the unbundled network elements. Accordingly, 
    we tentatively concluded that the requesting carrier paying cost-based 
    rates to the incumbent LEC would have already compensated the incumbent 
    LEC for the ability to deploy unbundled network elements to provide 
    originating and terminating access.
    2. Discussion
        337. We will adhere to our tentative conclusion to exclude 
    unbundled network elements from Part 69 access charges. This conclusion 
    applies to all incumbent LECs. As we noted in the Local Competition 
    Order, payment of cost-based rates represents full compensation to the 
    incumbent LEC for use of the network elements that carriers purchase. 
    We further noted that sections 251(c)(3) and 252(d)(1), the statutory 
    provisions establishing the unbundling obligation and the determination 
    of network element charges, do not compel telecommunications carriers 
    using unbundled network elements to pay access charges. Moreover, these 
    provisions do not restrict the ability of carriers to use network 
    elements to provide originating and terminating access. Allowing 
    incumbent LECs to recover access charges in addition to the reasonable 
    cost of such facilities would constitute double recovery because the 
    ability to provide access services is already included in the cost of 
    the access facilities themselves. Excluding access charges from 
    unbundled elements ensures that unbundled elements can be used to 
    provide services at competitive levels, promoting the underlying 
    purpose of the 1996 Act. If incumbent LECs added access charges to the 
    sale of unbundled elements, the added cost to competitive LECs would 
    impair, if not foreclose, their ability to offer competitive access 
    services. The availability of access services at competitive levels is 
    vital to the general approach we adopt in this Order, which relies on 
    the growth of competition, including from competitors using unbundled 
    network elements, to move overall access rate levels toward forward-
    looking economic cost. In addition, we note that excluding unbundled 
    network elements from access charges benefits small entities seeking to 
    enter the local service market by ensuring that they can acquire 
    unbundled elements at competitive prices.
        338. We disagree with suggestions offered by some commenters that 
    access charges should be imposed on unbundled elements because cost-
    based rates for such elements would not recover universal service 
    support subsidies built into the access charge regime. Although our 
    plan to implement comprehensive universal service reform is not fully 
    implemented, we believe excluding access charges from the sale of 
    unbundled elements will not dramatically affect the ability of price 
    cap LECs to fulfill their universal service obligations. First, 
    competitors using unbundled network elements to provide interstate 
    services will contribute to universal service requirements pursuant to 
    section 254. Carriers receive no exemption from their obligation to 
    contribute to universal service by using unbundled network elements. 
    Second, rate structure modifications adopted in this Order--including 
    reallocation of TIC costs, adoption of a mechanism to phase out the 
    TIC, and raising multi-line SLCs--should reduce the impact on price cap 
    LECs of excluding the recovery of TIC costs in the sale of unbundled 
    network elements. Third, if unbundled network element prices are 
    geographically deaveraged, LECs will receive higher prices when they 
    sell unbundled network elements that embody higher costs. Fourth, 
    because the difference between the level of access charges and the 
    forward-looking economic costs of network elements may include more 
    than universal service support, imposing access charges on the sale of 
    unbundled network elements could recover from market entrants 
    substantially more than amounts used to support universal service. 
    Accordingly, we are not persuaded by suggestions that the universal 
    service obligations of price cap LECs compel the imposition of access 
    charges on the purchase of unbundled network elements by requesting 
    carriers.
        339. Although, in the Local Competition Order, we allowed 
    application of certain non-cost-based access charges (the CCLC and a 
    portion of the TIC) to unbundled elements, we limited the duration of 
    such application to a transition period ending June 30, 1997 even if 
    access and universal service reform were not completed by the end of 
    the transition period. The transition period was limited in order to 
    minimize the burden on competitive local service providers seeking to 
    use unbundled network elements to offer the competitive services that 
    the 1996 Act sought to promote. The interim application of certain 
    access charges was also limited to non-cost-based charges because such 
    charges, unlike facilities-based charges, were more likely to include 
    subsidies for universal service. All facilities-based charges were 
    completely excluded from unbundled network elements to prevent double 
    recovery by incumbent LECs of the costs of these facilities when they 
    are purchased by competitive carriers.
        340. We are also unpersuaded by suggestions that access charges 
    should be imposed on unbundled elements because provision of 
    competitive service by rebundling the same network elements used by the 
    incumbent LEC to provide access is equivalent to resale of a retail 
    service. First, in the Local Competition Order, we recognized major 
    differences between competition through the use of unbundled network 
    elements and competition through resale of an existing retail service 
    offered by an incumbent LEC. We explained, for example, that an entrant 
    relying on unbundled elements rather than resale has the flexibility to 
    offer all telecommunications services made possible by using network 
    elements but also assumes the risk that end users will not generate 
    sufficient demand to justify the investment. The entrant using a resale 
    strategy, however, is limited to offering the retail service itself 
    without the attendant investment risk. Thus, we reject the notion that 
    the rebundling of network elements is equivalent to resale. Second, 
    although we concluded in the Local Competition Order that IXCs must 
    continue to pay access charges to incumbent LECs for access services 
    when the end user is served by a competitive carrier reselling the 
    incumbent LEC's retail services, our conclusion was based on the resale 
    provisions of the 1996 Act which limit resale to retail services 
    offered to subscribers or other customers who are not 
    telecommunications carriers. The resale provision does not apply to 
    non-
    
    [[Page 31920]]
    
    retail services, including access services, that may be offered using 
    the same facilities. Unlike the provision of local exchange services, 
    access services are not services that LECs provide directly to end 
    users on a retail basis. To impose access charges on the sale of 
    unbundled elements would contravene the terms of the resale provision 
    by effectively treating exchange access as a service provided on a 
    retail basis.
    
    B. Treatment of Interstate Information Services
    
    1. Background
        341. In the 1983 Access Charge Reconsideration Order, the 
    Commission decided that, although information service providers (ISPs) 
    may use incumbent LEC facilities to originate and terminate interstate 
    calls, ISPs should not be required to pay interstate access charges. 
    (For purposes of this Order, providers of enhanced services and 
    providers of information services are referred to as ISPs.) MTS and 
    WATS Market Structure, CC Docket No. 78-72, Memorandum Opinion and 
    Order, 48 FR 42984 (September 21, 1983) (Access Charge Reconsideration 
    Order). In recent years, usage of interstate information services, and 
    in particular the Internet and other interactive computer networks, has 
    increased significantly. Although the United States has the greatest 
    amount of Internet users and Internet traffic, more than 175 countries 
    are now connected to the Internet. Network Wizards Internet Domain 
    Survey, January 1997, available on the World Wide Web at http://
    www.nw.com/zoneWWW/top.html>. As usage continues to grow, information 
    services may have an increasingly significant effect on the public 
    switched network.
        342. As a result of the decisions the Commission made in the Access 
    Charge Reconsideration Order, ISPs may purchase services from incumbent 
    LECs under the same intrastate tariffs available to end users. ISPs may 
    pay business line rates and the appropriate subscriber line charge, 
    rather than interstate access rates, even for calls that appear to 
    traverse state boundaries. The business line rates are significantly 
    lower than the equivalent interstate access charges, given the ISPs' 
    high volumes of usage. ISPs typically pay incumbent LECs a flat monthly 
    rate for their connections regardless of the amount of usage they 
    generate, because business line rates typically include usage charges 
    only for outgoing traffic.
        343. In the NPRM, we tentatively concluded that ISPs should not be 
    required to pay interstate access charges as currently constituted. We 
    explained that the existing access charge system includes non-cost-
    based rates and inefficient rate structures. We stated that there is no 
    reason to extend such a system to an additional class of customers, 
    especially considering the potentially detrimental effects on the 
    growth of the still-evolving information services industry. We 
    explained that ISPs should not be subjected to an interstate regulatory 
    system designed for circuit-switched interexchange voice telephony 
    solely because ISPs use incumbent LEC networks to receive calls from 
    their customers. We solicited comment on the narrow issue of whether to 
    permit incumbent LECs to assess interstate access charges on ISPs. In 
    the companion Notice of Inquiry (NOI), we sought comment on broader 
    issues concerning the development of information services and Internet 
    access. See In the Matter of Usage of the Public Switched Network by 
    Information Service and Internet Access Providers, CC Docket No. 96-
    263, Notice of Inquiry, 62 FR 4657 (January 31, 1997) (NOI).
    2. Discussion
        344. We conclude that the existing pricing structure for ISPs 
    should remain in place, and incumbent LECs will not be permitted to 
    assess interstate per-minute access charges on ISPs. We think it 
    possible that had access rates applied to ISPs over the last 14 years, 
    the pace of development of the Internet and other services may not have 
    been so rapid. Maintaining the existing pricing structure for these 
    services avoids disrupting the still-evolving information services 
    industry and advances the goals of the 1996 Act to ``preserve the 
    vibrant and competitive free market that presently exists for the 
    Internet and other interactive computer services, unfettered by Federal 
    or State regulation.'' 47 U.S.C. sec. 230(b)(2).
        345. We decide here that ISPs should not be subject to interstate 
    access charges. The access charge system contains non-cost-based rates 
    and inefficient rate structures, and this Order goes only part of the 
    way to remove rate inefficiencies. Moreover, given the evolution in ISP 
    technologies and markets since we first established access charges in 
    the early 1980s, it is not clear that ISPs use the public switched 
    network in a manner analogous to IXCs. Commercial Internet access, for 
    example, did not even exist when access charges were established. As 
    commenters point out, many of the characteristics of ISP traffic (such 
    as large numbers of incoming calls to Internet service providers) may 
    be shared by other classes of business customers.
        346. We also are not convinced that the nonassessment of access 
    charges results in ISPs imposing uncompensated costs on incumbent LECs. 
    ISPs do pay for their connections to incumbent LEC networks by 
    purchasing services under state tariffs. Incumbent LECs also receive 
    incremental revenue from Internet usage through higher demand for 
    second lines by consumers, usage of dedicated data lines by ISPs, and 
    subscriptions to incumbent LEC Internet access services. To the extent 
    that some intrastate rate structures fail to compensate incumbent LECs 
    adequately for providing service to customers with high volumes of 
    incoming calls, incumbent LECs may address their concerns to state 
    regulators.
        347. Finally, we do not believe that incumbent LEC allegations 
    about network congestion warrant imposition of interstate access 
    charges on ISPs. The Network Reliability and Interoperability Council 
    has not identified any service outages above its reporting threshold 
    attributable to Internet usage, and even incumbent LEC commenters 
    acknowledge that they can respond to instances of congestion to 
    maintain service quality standards. Internet access does generate 
    different usage patterns and longer call holding times than average 
    voice usage. However, the extent to which this usage creates congestion 
    depends on the ways in which incumbent LECs provision their networks, 
    and ISPs use those networks. Incumbent LECs and ISPs agree that 
    technologies exist to reduce or eliminate whatever congestion exists; 
    they disagree on what pricing structure would provide incentives for 
    deployment of the most efficient technologies. The public interest 
    would best be served by policies that foster such technological 
    evolution of the network. The access charge system was designed for 
    basic voice telephony provided over a circuit-switched network, and 
    even when stripped of its current inefficiencies it may not be the most 
    appropriate pricing structure for Internet access and other information 
    services.
        348. Thus, in our review of the record filed in response to the 
    NOI, we will consider solutions to network congestion arguments other 
    than the incumbent LECs' recommendation that we apply access charges to 
    ISPs' use of circuit-switched network technology. We intend rather to 
    focus on new approaches to encourage the efficient offering of services 
    based on new network configurations and technologies, resulting in more
    
    [[Page 31921]]
    
    innovative and dynamic services than exist today. In the NOI, we will 
    address a range of fundamental issues about the Internet and other 
    information services, including ISP usage of the public switched 
    network. The NOI will give us an opportunity to consider the 
    implications of information services more broadly, and to craft 
    proposals for a subsequent NPRM that are sensitive to the complex 
    economic, technical, and legal questions raised in this area. We 
    therefore conclude that ISPs should remain classified as end users for 
    purposes of the access charge system.
    
    C. Terminating Access
    
        349. In the NPRM, we requested comment regarding the regulation of 
    terminating access. We noted that, unlike originating access, the 
    choice of an access provider for terminating access is made by the 
    recipient of the call. The call recipient generally does not pay for 
    the call and, therefore, is not likely to be concerned about the rates 
    charged for terminating access. We suggested that neither the 
    originating caller nor its long-distance service provider can exert 
    substantial influence over the called party's choice of terminating 
    access provider. Thus, even if competitive pressures develop at the 
    originating end as new entrants offer alternatives, the terminating end 
    of a long-distance call may remain a bottleneck, controlled by the LEC 
    providing access for a particular customer. We also recognized, 
    however, that excessive terminating access charges could furnish an 
    incentive for IXCs to enter the access market in order to avoid paying 
    excessive terminating access charges.
    1. Price Cap Incumbent LECs
    a. Background
        350. We requested comment on various alternative special methods 
    for regulating the terminating access rates of price cap LECs. For 
    instance, we sought comment on whether to establish a ceiling on the 
    terminating access rates of price cap LECs equal to the forward-looking 
    economic cost of providing the service. We suggested alternative 
    methods for measuring forward-looking economic cost, including 
    reference to prices in reciprocal compensation arrangements for the 
    transport and termination charges of telecommunications under sections 
    251(b)(5) and 252(d)(2) or a requirement that terminating rates be 
    based on a TSLRIC study or other acceptable forward-looking cost-based 
    model.
    b. Discussion
        351. We believe that new entrants, by purchasing unbundled network 
    elements or providing facilities-based competition, will eventually 
    exert downward pressure on originating access rates assessed by 
    incumbent LECs. We agree that excessive terminating access rates could 
    encourage long-distance companies to avoid the payment of such charges 
    by seeking to become the local exchange and exchange access provider 
    for end user customers. These market developments, however, would not 
    fully address the concerns expressed in the NPRM and reflected in 
    comments with respect to the ability of incumbent LECs to charge 
    unreasonable rates for terminating access.
        352. We are also not convinced that a significant competitive 
    impact would result from changes in calling patterns between pairs of 
    callers. Commenters have not described any realistic way that users, by 
    changing their calling patterns, could experience savings attributable 
    to differing levels of terminating access charges paid by IXCs. 
    Although one commenter points to high termination charges in foreign 
    countries as affecting the market for overseas calls originating in the 
    United States, such results are less likely to occur for domestic 
    calls, which are much less expensive than international calls and are 
    subject to geographic rate averaging and rate integration requirements. 
    Thus, we are reluctant to base our approach on the expectation that a 
    significant proportion of callers will implement such a strategy.
        353. Accordingly, we are establishing regulatory requirements that 
    will address the potential that incumbent LECs could charge 
    unreasonable rates for terminating access. Specifically, we are 
    adopting rules in this Order that, for price cap LECs, will limit 
    recovery of TIC and common line costs from terminating access rates for 
    a limited period, and then eliminate any recovery of common line and 
    TIC costs from terminating access. Under this approach, beginning 
    January 1, 1998, price cap LECs will recover common line and residual 
    TIC revenues through a new flat charge, subject to a ceiling. Remaining 
    common line and residual TIC revenues will then be first recovered 
    through originating access rates, subject to a ceiling. Any remaining 
    common line and residual TIC revenues may then be recovered through 
    terminating rates. As the caps on SLCs applicable to non-primary 
    residential lines and the PICC are raised, none of these residual 
    revenues will be recovered through terminating access charges. When the 
    increased SLCs and PICCs are fully implemented, recovery of these costs 
    will be more susceptible to competitive forces because IXCs could seek 
    to influence the end user's choice of its provider of local service, 
    and the end user's choice of service provider will determine whether 
    the incumbent LEC is able to recover these costs from the end user.
        354. In addition, pending full recovery of all common line and 
    residual TIC costs in flat rate SLCs and PICCs, this approach will put 
    downward pressure on terminating access rates by lowering the overall 
    service revenues derived from terminating access charges. Because 
    competitive pressure is more likely to develop on the originating end 
    of a long-distance call, we can rely to a greater extent on competitive 
    forces to ensure just and reasonable rates under this approach by 
    moving recovery of certain revenues from terminating access to 
    originating access. By stripping terminating access rates of CCL and 
    residual TIC charges and, pending full implementation of the new flat 
    charges, placing more of the burden of TIC recovery on originating 
    access rates, we reduce potential excesses in terminating access 
    charges while exposing the CCL and residual TIC recovery to competitive 
    pressures in the originating access market.
        355. The NPRM described proposals linking terminating rates to 
    originating rate levels or shifting costs from terminating to 
    originating access charges. Some commenters support limiting price cap 
    LEC terminating access rates to the level of the LEC originating access 
    rates. If originating access charges are lowered because of 
    competition, the ceiling on terminating access rates would be lowered 
    as well, placing downward pressure on terminating rates. This approach, 
    however, would not substantially affect terminating access rates where 
    originating access rates have not responded to competitive inroads. 
    Moreover, linking an incumbent LEC's terminating access rate to its own 
    originating rate could reduce the incumbent LEC's incentive to lower 
    its originating access rates. Thus, we decline to adopt this method of 
    regulating terminating access rates.
        356. The NPRM requested comment on the possibility of eliminating 
    all charges for terminating access by shifting the burden of recovering 
    all costs currently recovered in terminating access rates to 
    originating access charges. We decline to adopt this approach because a 
    complete shift of
    
    [[Page 31922]]
    
    terminating access costs to originating access conflicts with one of 
    the basic objectives of this proceeding--to ensure that charges for 
    access services reflect the manner in which the costs of providing 
    those services are incurred. Switching costs, for example, should 
    continue to be recovered in part from terminating access charges 
    because those costs are traffic sensitive and are related to the 
    volumes of both originating and terminating traffic. Moreover, we 
    emphasize that, as discussed in Section III.A, the rate structure we 
    are adopting, which will replace per-minute recovery of the CCL charge 
    and the TIC with flat rate charges, helps to achieve our goal of 
    ensuring that charges for access services reflect the manner in which 
    costs are incurred. Our requirement that incumbent LECs recover a 
    greater portion of common line and TIC costs in originating access 
    rates pending full implementation of flat-rated charges will address 
    concerns about the reasonableness of terminating access charges while 
    providing price cap LECs sufficient latitude to recover the reasonable 
    costs of deploying their facilities to provide terminating access 
    services.
        357. The NPRM also discussed the alternative of requiring price cap 
    LECs to establish end user charges for terminating access. This 
    approach would place direct responsibility for the cost of terminating 
    access on the recipient of terminating access services and would expose 
    terminating access to competitive pressures. We noted that wireless 
    companies already charge called parties for receiving calls and 
    requested comment on how we might implement a system of end user 
    charges in the context of access reform and whether its implementation 
    would increase the number of uncompleted calls due to a reluctance by 
    called parties to accept the charges. We agree with commenters that 
    such a change could prove disruptive to consumers of wireline services. 
    After review of the record, which produced few, if any, advocates of 
    such an approach, we conclude that we should not mandate at this time 
    this change in current pricing practices for wireline service.
    2. Non-Incumbent LECs
    a. Background
        358. In the NPRM, we requested comment about whether to impose 
    ceilings on the terminating access rates of non-incumbent LECs. We 
    stated in the NPRM that our policy since the Competitive Carrier 
    Proceeding has consistently been that a carrier is non-dominant unless 
    the Commission makes or has made a finding that it is dominant. We 
    noted that, since the Competitive Carrier Proceeding, new entrants into 
    the exchange access market have been presumptively classified as non-
    dominant because they have not been shown to exercise significant 
    market power in their service areas. Policy and Rules Concerning Rates 
    for Competitive Common Carrier Services and Facilities Authorizations 
    Therefor, CC Docket No. 79-252, First Report and Order, 45 FR 76148 
    (November 18, 1980), Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 46 FR 10924 
    (February 5, 1981), Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 47 FR 
    17308 (April 22, 1982), Second Report and Order, 47 FR 37889 (August 
    27, 1982). At the same time, we stated that competitive LECs may 
    possess market power over IXCs needing to terminate calls because the 
    LEC controlling the terminating local loop is the only access provider 
    available to the IXC seeking to terminate a long-distance call on that 
    particular loop. We solicited comment on several alternatives, 
    including whether we should use incumbent LEC terminating access rates 
    as a benchmark to determine the reasonableness of competitive LEC 
    terminating rates. We invited commenters to offer other approaches 
    including, for example, whether we should establish a presumption of 
    reasonableness if the competitive LEC's terminating access rate is no 
    higher than the incumbent LEC's rate in the same geographic market.
    b. Discussion
        359. We recently noted that the test in deciding whether to apply 
    dominant carrier regulation to a class of carriers is whether those 
    carriers have market power. Regulatory Treatment of LEC Provision of 
    Interexchange Services Originating in the LEC's Local Exchange Area and 
    Policy and Rules Concerning the Interstate, Interexchange Marketplace, 
    CC Docket Nos. 96-149 and 96-61, Second Report and Order in CC Docket 
    No. 96-149 and Third Report and Order in CC Docket No. 96-61, FCC 97-
    142 (April 18, 1997) (Dominant-Non-Dominant Order). As we discussed in 
    the Dominant/Nondominant Order, in determining whether a firm possesses 
    market power, the Commission has previously focused on certain well-
    established market features, including market share, supply and demand 
    substitutability, the cost structure, size or resources of the firm, 
    and control of bottleneck facilities. Competitive LECs currently have a 
    relatively small market share in the provision of local exchange and 
    exchange access service. Nonetheless, at first blush, there is a 
    concern that a competitive LEC may have market power over an IXC that 
    needs to terminate a long-distance call to a customer of that 
    particular competitive LEC. Therefore, we sought comment on whether and 
    to what extent we should regulate the terminating access charges of 
    competitive LECs.
        360. We conclude, based on the record before us, that non-incumbent 
    LECs should be treated as nondominant in the provision of terminating 
    access. Although an IXC must use the competitive LEC serving an end 
    user to terminate a call, the record does not indicate that competitive 
    LECs have previously charged excessive terminating access rates. Nor 
    have commenters provided evidence demonstrating that competitive LECs 
    are, in fact, charging excessive terminating rates. Indeed, the record 
    suggests that the terminating rates of competitive LECs are equal to or 
    below the tariffed rates of incumbent LECs. In addition, the record 
    does not show that competitive LECs distinguish between originating and 
    terminating access in their offers of service. Therefore, it does not 
    appear that competitive LECs have structured their service offerings in 
    ways designed to exercise any market power over terminating access. 
    Accordingly, the concerns expressed in the NPRM about the ability of 
    competitive LECs to exercise market power in the provision of 
    terminating access are not substantiated in the record.
        361. Further, as competitive LECs, which have a small share of the 
    interstate access market, attempt to expand their market presence, the 
    rates of incumbent LECs or other potential competitors will constrain 
    the terminating access rates of competitive LECs. Specifically, 
    competitive LECs compete with incumbent LECs whose rates are regulated. 
    The record indicates that long-distance carriers have established 
    relationships with incumbent LECs for the provision of access services, 
    and new market entrants are not likely to risk damaging their 
    developing relationships with IXCs by charging unreasonable terminating 
    access rates. This is especially true with respect to competitive 
    access providers seeking to maintain or expand their access transport, 
    special access, or other services apart from switched access.
        362. In addition, we believe that overcharges for terminating 
    access could encourage access customers to take competitive steps to 
    avoid paying unreasonable terminating access charges. If, for example, 
    a competitive
    
    [[Page 31923]]
    
    LEC consistently overcharged an IXC for terminating access, the IXC 
    would have an incentive to enter a marketing alliance with another 
    competitive LEC in the same market or in other geographic markets where 
    the overcharging competitive LEC seeks to expand. Although high 
    terminating access charges may not create a disincentive for the call 
    recipient to retain its local carrier (because the call recipient does 
    not pay the long distance charge), the call recipient may nevertheless 
    respond to incentives offered by an IXC with an economic interest in 
    encouraging the end user to switch to another local carrier. Such an 
    approach could have particular impact when the IXC has significant 
    brand recognition among consumers. Moreover, as noted in the NPRM, 
    excessive terminating access charges could encourage IXCs to enter the 
    access market in an effort to win the local customer. We believe that 
    the possibility of competitive responses by IXCs will have a 
    constraining effect on non-incumbent LEC pricing.
        363. Thus, we will not adopt at this time any regulations governing 
    the provision of terminating access provided by competitive LECs. 
    Because competitive LECs have not charged unreasonable terminating 
    access rates, and because they are not likely to do so in the future, 
    competitive LECs do not appear to possess market power. Thus, the 
    imposition of regulatory requirements with respect to competitive LEC 
    terminating access is unnecessary. We similarly find no reason to adopt 
    a presumption of reasonableness where a competitive LEC's terminating 
    access rates are less than its rates for originating access or less 
    than the incumbent LEC's terminating access rates. Instead, if we need 
    to examine the reasonableness of competitive LEC terminating access 
    rates in an individual instance, we can do so taking into account all 
    relevant factors including relationships to other rates. Thus, if an 
    access provider's service offerings violate section 201 or section 202 
    of the Act, we can address any issue of unlawful rates through the 
    exercise of our authority to investigate and adjudicate complaints 
    under section 208. On the basis of the current record, we conclude that 
    reliance on the complaint process will be sufficient to assure that 
    non-incumbent LEC rates are reasonable. We emphasize that we will not 
    hesitate to use our authority under section 208 to take corrective 
    action where appropriate.
        364. We will be sensitive to indications that the terminating 
    access rates of competitive LECs are unreasonable. The charging of 
    terminating access rates above originating rates in the same market, 
    for example, may suggest the need to revisit our regulatory approach. 
    Similarly, terminating rates that exceed those charged by the incumbent 
    LEC serving the same market may suggest that a competitive LEC's 
    terminating access rates are excessive. If there is sufficient 
    indication that competitive LECs are imposing unreasonable terminating 
    access charges, we will revisit the issue of whether to adopt 
    regulations governing competitive LEC rates for terminating access.
    3. ``Open End'' Services
        365. In some cases, an IXC is unable to influence the end user's 
    choice of access provider for originating access services because the 
    end user on the terminating end is paying for the call. For example, 
    charges for the ``open end'' originating access minutes for 800 or 888 
    services are paid by the recipient of the call. Consequently, the 
    Commission has treated incumbent LEC originating ``open end'' minutes 
    as terminating minutes for access charge purposes. The NPRM solicited 
    comment on whether such regulatory treatment should be retained for 
    ``open end'' services under which terminating access rates serve as 
    originating access rates, and whether this approach should be extended 
    to competitive LECs.
        366. We continue to believe that ``open end'' originating minutes 
    should be treated as terminating minutes for access charge purposes. 
    Although few comments were filed regarding this issue, commenters 
    addressing this matter advocate retention of the current regulatory 
    approach. By continuing to treat ``open end'' originating minutes as 
    terminating minutes for access charge purposes, we recognize that 
    access customers have limited ability to influence the calling party's 
    choice of access provider. Accordingly, access charges for these ``open 
    end'' minutes will be governed by the requirements we adopt in this 
    Order applicable to terminating access provided by incumbent LECs. 
    Thus, residual common line charges and the per-minute TIC will not be 
    recovered through ``open end'' originating minutes except to the extent 
    such recovery is permitted under the rules described in Section III.A 
    of this Order.
    
    D. Universal Service-Related Part 69 Changes
    
        367. In the NPRM, we recognized that, because of the role that 
    access charges have played in funding and maintaining universal 
    service, it is critical to implement changes in the access charge 
    system together with complementary changes in the universal service 
    system. In this section, we address the manner in which incumbent LECs 
    must adjust their interstate access charges to reflect the universal 
    service support mechanisms adopted in the Universal Service Order.
    1. Background
        368. In November 1996, pursuant to section 254 of the Act, the 
    Federal-State Universal Service Joint Board issued its recommendations 
    to the Commission for reforming our system of universal service so that 
    universal service is preserved and advanced, but in a manner that 
    permits the local exchange and exchange access markets to move from 
    monopoly to competition. In our Universal Service Order, we are 
    adopting most of the Joint Board's recommendations relating to the 
    support of rural and high cost areas.
        369. Section 254 of the Act requires that any federal universal 
    service support provided to eligible carriers be ``explicit'' and 
    recovered on an ``equitable and nondiscriminatory basis'' from all 
    telecommunications carriers providing interstate telecommunications 
    service. In our companion Universal Service Order, we agree with the 
    Joint Board that these programs must be replaced with universal service 
    support mechanisms that satisfy section 254.
        370. Currently, there are three mechanisms designed expressly to 
    provide support for high cost and small telephone companies: the 
    Universal Service Fund (high cost assistance fund), the Dial Equipment 
    Minutes (DEM) weighting program, and Long Term Support (LTS). An 
    incumbent LEC is eligible for high cost assistance from the current 
    Universal Service Fund if its embedded loop costs exceed 115 percent of 
    the national average loop cost. This program is funded entirely by 
    IXCs. DEM weighting assistance is an implicit support mechanism that 
    permits LECs with fewer than 50,000 access lines to apportion a greater 
    proportion of these local switching costs to the interstate 
    jurisdiction than larger LECs may allocate. Finally, the existing LTS 
    program supports carriers with higher-than average subscriber line 
    costs by providing carriers that are members of the NECA pool with 
    enough support to enable them to charge IXCs only a nationwide average 
    CCL interstate access rate. LTS payments reduce the access charges of 
    smaller, rural incumbent LECs participating in the loop-cost pool by 
    raising the access
    
    [[Page 31924]]
    
    charges of non-participating incumbent LECs.
        371. In the NPRM, we sought comment on whether incumbent LECs' 
    access charges must be adjusted to reflect elimination of LTS 
    contribution requirements and receipt of explicit universal service 
    funds in order to prevent incumbent LECs from being compensated twice 
    for providing universal service. We proposed a downward exogenous cost 
    adjustment for price cap incumbent LECs to reflect elimination of LTS 
    contribution requirements and any revenues received from any new 
    universal service support mechanisms, and sought comment on how 
    interstate costs must also be reduced to account for explicit universal 
    service support.
    2. Discussion
        372. In our companion Universal Service Order, we conclude that a 
    carrier will continue to receive universal service support based upon 
    the existing LTS, high cost, DEM weighting mechanisms, until the 
    carrier begins to receive support based upon forward-looking economic 
    cost. In the following sections, we will discuss the manner in which 
    incumbent LECs must reduce their interstate access charges to reflect 
    the elimination of the obligation to contribute to LTS, increase their 
    interstate access charges to permit recovery of the new universal 
    service obligation, and, to the extent necessary, adjust their 
    interstate access charges to account for any additional universal 
    service funds received under the modified universal service mechanisms.
    a. Removal of LTS Obligation From Interstate Access Rates
        373. In our companion Universal Service Order, we agree with the 
    Joint Board that LTS payments constitute a universal service support 
    mechanism that is inconsistent with the Act's requirement that support 
    be collected from all providers of interstate telecommunications 
    services on an equitable and non-discriminatory basis and be available 
    to all eligible telecommunications carriers. In that order, we conclude 
    that LTS should be removed from the interstate access charge system. We 
    provide, instead, for recovery of comparable payments from the new 
    federal universal service support mechanisms.
        374. Currently, only incumbent LECs that do not participate in the 
    NECA CCL tariff (non-pooling incumbent LECs) make LTS payments and only 
    incumbent LECs participating in the NECA CCL tariff receive LTS 
    support. Non-pooling incumbent LECs' contributions to the common line 
    pool are set annually based on the total projected amount of LTS, 
    converted to a monthly payment amount. Non-pooling incumbent LECs 
    recover the revenue necessary for their LTS contributions through their 
    CCL charges. We agree with commenters that argue that, to the extent we 
    do not reduce interstate access revenues by the amount of LTS 
    contribution currently recovered in the rates, incumbent LECs will 
    double recover. We therefore conclude that incumbent LEC interstate 
    access charges must be reduced to reflect elimination of the obligation 
    to contribute to LTS.
        375. Because payments from the existing LTS mechanism will cease on 
    January 1, 1998, incumbent LECs should no longer contribute to the 
    existing LTS fund after that date. For price cap LECs, which were 
    requested to stop participating in the NECA Common Line tariff before 
    coming under price cap regulation, LTS contributions were included in 
    the common line revenue requirement when the PCI for the common line 
    basket was established. We conclude that price cap LECs must make a 
    one-time downward exogenous adjustment to the PCI for the common line 
    basket to account fully for the elimination of their LTS obligations. 
    This exogenous adjustment shall be made in a manner consistent with 
    section 61.45 and other relevant provisions of the Commission's rules.
        376. Non-pooling, rate-of-return LECs recover their LTS 
    contributions in the common line revenue requirement. Because current 
    LTS contributors will no longer be making such contributions after 
    January 1, 1998, their CCL charges should be adjusted to account for 
    this change. Rate-of-return LECs that formerly made LTS contributions 
    should recompute their common line revenue requirements based on the 
    elimination of their LTS obligations, and adjust their CCL charges 
    accordingly.
        377. We note that the replacement of LTS with comparable support 
    from the new universal service support mechanisms requires us to amend 
    the NECA Common Line tariff rules, which establish the CCL for pooling 
    members at the average of price cap LECs' CCL charges. Under the 
    current LTS support system, NECA annually projects the common line 
    revenue requirement, including an 11.25 percent return on investment, 
    for incumbent LECs that participate in the common line pool. NECA then 
    computes the total amount of LTS support needed by subtracting the 
    amount pooling carriers will receive in CCL revenues and SLCs from the 
    pool's projected revenue requirement, after removing pay telephone 
    costs and revenues. Our rules currently provide that the NECA CCL 
    tariff be set to recover the average of price cap LECs' CCL charges. If 
    we were to retain this rule, our decision eliminating LTS obligations 
    for price cap LECs and requiring them to reduce their CCL charges 
    accordingly would automatically reduce the CCL revenues of NECA pool 
    members. Further, reductions would occur as price cap LECs implemented 
    our decisions in Section III of this Order, which restructures the 
    common line rate structure for price cap LECs to recover common line 
    costs through flat-rated charges instead of the per-minute CCL charge. 
    Because we have deferred consideration of access reform for non-price 
    cap LECs and did not seek comment on this issue in the NPRM, we must 
    address this issue in a future proceeding that undertakes access reform 
    for small, non-price cap LECs.
    b. Recovery of New Universal Service Obligations
        378. In the Universal Service Order, we conclude that assessment of 
    contributions for the interstate portion of the high cost and low-
    income support mechanisms shall be based solely on end-user interstate 
    revenues, and that assessment of universal support for eligible 
    schools, libraries, and rural health care providers shall be based on 
    interstate and intrastate total end-user revenues. As to the manner in 
    which carriers may recover their contributions to the universal service 
    fund, in our Universal Service Order we conclude that carriers may 
    recover universal service contributions via interstate mechanisms. In 
    this Section, we address the manner in which incumbent price cap LECs 
    may recover their universal service contributions. We address non-price 
    cap LECs' recovery of universal service contributions in Section XIII.F 
    of the Universal Service Order.
        379. Price cap LECs may treat their contributions to the new 
    universal service mechanisms, including high cost and low-income 
    support and support for eligible schools, libraries, and health care, 
    as exogenous changes to their price cap indices (PCIs). Because the 
    only interstate revenues that will serve as the basis for assessing 
    universal service contributions in 1998 will be end-user revenues, we 
    find that price cap LECs recovering their universal service obligation 
    through interstate access charges must recover those contributions in 
    the baskets for services that generate end-user interstate revenues. 
    Because price cap LECs do
    
    [[Page 31925]]
    
    not recover revenues from end users of services in all baskets, the 
    exogenous adjustment should not be across-the-board. The baskets 
    containing end-user interstate services are the common line, 
    interexchange, and trunking baskets. The end-user charges assessed on 
    services in the common line basket are recovered through the SLC; in 
    the interexchange basket, end-user charges are recovered through per-
    minute toll charges; and in the trunking basket, end user charges are 
    recovered through special access service provided directly to end 
    users. Price cap LECs electing to recover their universal service 
    obligation through interstate access charges must therefore apply the 
    full amount of the exogenous adjustment among these three baskets on 
    the basis of relative size of end-user revenues. We note, however, that 
    the tandem-switched transport, interconnection charge, and tandem 
    switch signalling service categories in the trunking basket do not 
    recover end-user interstate revenues. In order to prevent recovery from 
    customers of these services, the service band indices (SBI) for these 
    service categories should not be increased to reflect the exogenous 
    adjustment to the PCI for the trunking basket. To reflect the exogenous 
    adjustment to the trunking basket PCI, price cap LECs should, instead, 
    increase the SBIs for the remaining service categories in the trunking 
    basket based on the relative end-user interstate revenues generated in 
    each service category. The four remaining service categories in the 
    trunking basket are as follows: (1) voice grade entrance facilities, 
    voice grade direct-trunked transport, voice grade dedicated signalling 
    transport, voice grade special access, WATS special access, metallic 
    special access, and telegraph special access services; (2) audio and 
    video service; (3) high capacity flat-rated transport, high capacity 
    special access, and DDS services; and (4) wideband data and wideband 
    analog services.
        380. In 1999, the percentage of price cap LECs' revenues that will 
    be assessed for universal service support may increase as a result of 
    the anticipated increases in high cost, low-income support and support 
    for schools, libraries, and health care in 1999. Price cap LECs shall 
    therefore perform an upward exogenous adjustment to the PCIs for the 
    common line, interexchange, and trunking baskets in the same manner as 
    the exogenous adjustment performed in 1998, to reflect any change in 
    the assessment rate in 1999.
    c. Adjustments to Interstate Access Charges to Reflect Additional 
    Support From the Modified Universal Service Mechanisms
        381. In our Universal Service Order, we conclude that the federal 
    universal service mechanism should support 25 percent of the difference 
    between the forward-looking economic cost of serving the customer and 
    the appropriate revenue benchmark. We further conclude in that order 
    that 25 percent approximates the portion of the cost of providing the 
    supported network facilities that would be assigned to the interstate 
    jurisdiction, and that, by funding these interstate costs, we will 
    ensure that federal implicit universal service support is made 
    explicit. Consistent with our decision in the Universal Service Order 
    to fund only interstate costs through the federal universal service 
    fund, we direct incumbent LECs to use any universal service support 
    received from the new universal service mechanisms to reduce or satisfy 
    the interstate revenue requirement otherwise collected through 
    interstate access charges.
        382. Non-Rural Carriers. In our Universal Service Order, we 
    conclude that, until a forward-looking economic cost methodology takes 
    effect on January 1, 1999, non-rural carriers will continue to receive 
    high cost assistance and LTS amounts based on the existing universal 
    service mechanisms. As there will be no change until January 1, 1999 to 
    the support non-rural incumbent LECs currently receive as high cost and 
    LTS support, we conclude that it is not necessary at this time to 
    determine the manner in which non-rural carriers should adjust their 
    interstate access charges to reflect a difference in universal service 
    support. We will address this issue prior to the January 1, 1999, 
    effective date of the forward-looking cost mechanisms for non-rural 
    carriers.
        383. Rural Carriers. In our Universal Service Order, we conclude 
    that rural carriers, as defined in section 153(37) of the Act, shall 
    continue to receive support based on embedded costs for at least three 
    years. Beginning on January 1, 1998, rural carriers shall receive high 
    cost loop support, DEM weighting assistance, and LTS benefits on the 
    basis of the modified support mechanisms.
        384. In our Universal Service Order, we adopt modified per-line 
    support mechanisms for providing support comparable to the LTS support 
    received under the existing mechanisms. Beginning on January 1, 1998, 
    we will allow a rural carrier's annual LTS support to increase from its 
    support for the preceding calendar year based on the percentage of 
    increase of the nationwide average loop cost. Rural, non-price cap LECs 
    should continue to apply any revenues received from the modified 
    universal service support mechanisms that replace current LTS amounts 
    to the accounts to which they are currently applying LTS support.
        385. We also decide in the Universal Service Order that, from 
    January 1, 1998 through December 31, 1999, rural carriers shall 
    calculate their high cost support using the current high cost formulas. 
    We conclude that no adjustment to rural incumbent LECs' interstate 
    access charges is necessary at this time because incumbent LECs will 
    continue to use the existing high cost formulas to determine high cost 
    support. As we determine in that order, however, beginning January 1, 
    2000, rural carriers shall receive high cost loop support for their 
    average loop costs that exceed 115 percent of an inflation-adjusted 
    nationwide average loop cost. The inflation adjusted nationwide average 
    cost per loop shall be calculated by multiplying the 1997 nationwide 
    average cost per loop by the percentage in change in Gross Domestic 
    Product Chained Price Index (GDP-CPI) from 1997-1998. We conclude that 
    rural, non-price cap LECs should continue to apply any revenues 
    received from the modified universal service support mechanism that 
    replace amounts received under the current high cost support system to 
    the accounts to which they are currently applying high cost support.
        386. Finally, in our Universal Service Order, we adopt the Joint 
    Board's recommendation that a subsidy corresponding in amount to that 
    generated formerly by DEM weighting be recovered from the new universal 
    service support mechanisms. Beginning on January 1, 1998 and continuing 
    until permanent mechanisms for them become effective, rural carriers 
    will receive DEM weighting assistance calculated as follows: assistance 
    will equal the difference between the 1996 weighted DEM factor and the 
    unweighted DEM factor multiplied by the annual unseparated local 
    switching revenue requirement. As with comparable LTS and high cost 
    support, rural, non-price cap LECs should continue to apply any support 
    received from the modified universal service support mechanisms that 
    replaces existing DEM weighting amounts to the accounts to which they 
    are currently applying DEM weighting assistance.
        387. Currently, the high cost and DEM weighting support mechanisms 
    shift a portion of the intrastate revenue
    
    [[Page 31926]]
    
    requirement to the interstate jurisdiction in order to permit LECs to 
    recover a greater percentage of their costs from the interstate 
    jurisdiction. Some non-price cap LECs are concerned that, to the extent 
    that support from the modified universal service mechanisms is not 
    applied to the intrastate jurisdiction, an intrastate revenue shortfall 
    will occur. In the Universal Service Order, we conclude that, until 
    universal service support is based on forward-looking economic cost, 
    carriers should continue to receive amounts from the new universal 
    service mechanisms comparable to existing high cost and DEM weighting 
    support. In that order, we do not alter the existing revenue-shifting 
    mechanisms in place for the current high cost support and DEM weighting 
    at this time. Thus, no intrastate revenue shortfall will occur, because 
    no revenue requirement is being shifted back to the intrastate 
    jurisdiction.
    
    E. Part 69 Allocation Rules
    
    1. Background
        388. In the NPRM, we solicited comment on whether it would be 
    appropriate for incumbent price cap LECs to be relieved of complying 
    with subparts D and E of part 69 of our rules, which address the 
    allocation of investments and expenses to the access rate elements.
    2. Discussion
        389. We conclude that at this time we should maintain our part 69 
    cost allocation rules. In this Report and Order, we have instituted a 
    phasing out of the CCL charge. Until the per-minute CCL charge is 
    phased out completely and multi-line PICCs do not recover any common 
    line revenues, price cap LECs will need to use these rules to calculate 
    the SLC. Therefore, we decline to eliminate the cost allocation rules 
    at this time. We note that we may revisit this issue when these rules 
    are no longer needed to calculate the SLC.
    
    F. Other Proposed Part 69 Changes
    
    1. Background
        390. In the NPRM, we sought comment on revisions necessary to 
    update part 69 and conform it to the 1996 Act. In the NPRM, we made 
    several proposals that we thought necessary to bring Part 69 current, 
    including: eliminating the rules that provide for a ``contribution 
    charge'' that may be assessed on special access and expanded 
    interconnection; removing the rule and sections referencing the rule 
    that establishes the equal access rate element; and removing the rule 
    and sections referencing the rule that establishes a rate element for 
    costs associated with lines terminating at ``limited pay telephones''; 
    and changing the definition of ``Telephone Company'' to mean incumbent 
    LEC. We also sought comment on whether rate elements and subelements 
    established pursuant to waiver should be incorporated into Part 69.
    2. Discussion
        391. The passage of the 1996 Act and the subsequent enactment of 
    implementing regulations requires that we update and revise various 
    sections of Part 69. Sections 69.4(f) and 69.122 of our rules provide 
    for a ``contribution charge'' that may be assessed on special access 
    and expanded interconnection. These sections are inconsistent with 
    section 254 as amended by the 1996 Act, which requires, inter alia, 
    that such carrier contributions be equitable and nondiscriminatory. 
    Furthermore, our rules governing the contribution charge merely allow a 
    LEC to try to justify this charge in the expanded interconnection 
    context. No party has even attempted to justify such a charge in more 
    than four years. Given this and the relevant amendments in the 1996 
    Act, we find that there is no need for this rate element. We conclude 
    that Secs. 69.4(f) and 69.122 of our rules, which provide for a 
    ``contribution charge'' that may be assessed on special access and 
    expanded interconnection, should be deleted.
        392. Under Sec. 69.4(d), we required carriers to eliminate any 
    separate equal access charge by January 1, 1994. We conclude, 
    therefore, that Sec. 69.4(d), which established the equal access rate 
    element for a limited duration, should be deleted because of the 
    expiration of the designated time period. Similarly, we conclude that 
    Sec. 69.107, which governs the computation of the equal access rate 
    element charges, and Secs. 69.308 and 69.410, which concern allocation 
    of costs to that rate element, should be deleted because the designated 
    time period for separate equal access rate elements has expired. We 
    conclude that references to these deleted sections should also be 
    removed from part 69. Section 69.309 refers to Sec. 69.308 and 
    Sec. 69.411 refers to Sec. 69.410. To ensure consistency, a new 
    section, designated as Sec. 69.3(3)(12), should be added and should 
    read as follows: ``Such a tariff shall not contain any separate 
    carrier's carrier tariff charges for an Equal Access element.'' 
    Similarly, we conclude that Sec. 69.205, which concerns transitional 
    premium charges for IXCs and others should be deleted because the 
    designated transition period for these charges has expired.
        393. Section 69.103 requires incumbent LECs to establish a separate 
    rate element for costs associated with lines terminating at ``limited 
    pay telephones.'' We note that few, if any, payphone service providers 
    offer this type of service today. Sections 69.303(a), 69.304(c), 
    69.307(c), and 69.406(a)(9) concern the allocation of costs to this 
    rate element. Section 276 of the Act and the implementing regulations 
    require a new per call compensation plan, which requires, inter alia, 
    that incumbent LECs remove all payphone costs from access charges. 
    Implementation of the Pay Telephone Reclassification and Compensation 
    Provisions of the Telecommunications Act of 1996, Report and Order, CC 
    Docket No. 96-128, FCC 96-388, 61 FR 39397 (July 29, 1996) (Payphone 
    Order), recon., FCC 96-439, 61 FR 65341 (December 12, 1996) (Payphone 
    Reconsideration Order), appeal docketed sub nom., Illinois Public 
    Telecommunications Ass'n v. FCC and United States, Case No. 96-1394 
    (D.C. Cir., filed October 17, 1996). This new compensation plan, as 
    well as the payphone dialing parity requirements, have eliminated the 
    need for Secs. 69.103, 69.303(a), 69.304(c), 69.307(c), and 
    69.406(a)(9). We conclude that these sections should be deleted.
        394. We conclude that codifying previously-granted Part 69 waivers 
    is not necessary at this time. Under the Price Cap Performance Review 
    Third Report and Order, a party seeking to introduce a new service may 
    do so by filing a petition showing that the new service is in the 
    public interest. Once that petition for a new service has been granted, 
    carriers seeking to introduce the same service with the same rate 
    structure may do so under expedited procedures. This streamlined 
    alternative for introducing new services should resolve past 
    difficulties encountered with the Part 69 waiver process. The proposed 
    codification of previously-granted waivers is thus unnecessary. We 
    therefore decline to codify previously-granted Part 69 waivers into our 
    rules.
        395. NECA and TCA have requested that the Commission extend to all 
    rate-of-return companies, the right to offer new services based on an 
    expedited process, which requires, inter alia, a showing that the new 
    service is in the public interest. In the Third Report and Order, we 
    granted to incumbent price cap LECs the right to introduce new services 
    under a streamlined procedure. We will address the request of NECA and 
    TCA when we take up access
    
    [[Page 31927]]
    
    reform for rate-of-return companies in the near future.
        396. In the NPRM, we solicited comment on whether we should adopt 
    regulatory requirements to govern rates for terminating access offered 
    by competitive LECs. In Section VI.C., supra, we conclude that we will 
    not adopt such regulatory requirement at this time. For the same 
    reasons, we find it unnecessary to apply any of our Part 69 regulations 
    to competitive LECs. We therefore conclude that Sec. 69.2(hh), which 
    currently defines ``Telephone Company'' by reference to Section 3(r) of 
    the 1934 Act, should be changed to read as follows: `` `Telephone 
    Company' or `local exchange carrier' as used in this Part means an 
    incumbent local exchange carrier as defined in section 251(h)(1) of the 
    1934 Act as amended by the 1996 Act.'' There is no indication in the 
    record that competitive LECs have exercised any degree of market power 
    in provision of terminating access or other access services. By 
    definition, non-dominant carriers do not exercise market power. 
    Further, non-dominant carriers possess a negligible share of the 
    current access market and they will be competing with incumbent LECs 
    whose rates are subject to regulation. As a practical matter, the rates 
    of the incumbent LECs will serve as a constraint to some degree on the 
    pricing and practices of non-dominant LECs. We therefore find on this 
    record that it is sufficient to rely on the Section 208 complaint 
    process to assure compliance with the Act by competitive LECs, and that 
    we should not apply Part 69 to them. To the extent that our definitions 
    or our application of Part 69 needs in the future to be expanded to 
    encompass LECs other than incumbent LECs, we can revisit this issue.
    
    VIII. Final Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
    
        397. As required by the Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA), an 
    Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis (IRFA) was incorporated in the 
    NPRM in this proceeding. The Commission sought written public comments 
    on the proposals in the NPRM, including the IRFA. The Commission's 
    Final Regulatory Flexibility Analysis (FRFA) in this Order (the First 
    Report and Order in this Access Charge Reform proceeding) conforms to 
    the RFA, as amended. We provide this summary analysis to provide 
    context for our analysis in this FRFA. To the extent that any statement 
    contained in this FRFA is perceived as creating ambiguity with respect 
    to our rules or statements made in preceding sections of this Order, 
    the rules and statements set forth in those preceding sections shall be 
    controlling.
    
    A. Need for and Objectives of This First Report and Order
    
        398. The Telecommunications Act of 1996 requires incumbent LECs to 
    offer interconnection and unbundled elements on an unbundled basis, and 
    imposes a duty to establish reciprocal compensation arrangements for 
    the transport and termination of calls. The Commission's access charge 
    rules were adopted at a time when interstate access and local exchange 
    services were offered on a monopoly basis, and in many cases are 
    inconsistent with the competitive market envisioned by the 1996 Act. 
    This proceeding is being conducted to revise the Commission's access 
    charge rules to make them consistent with the Telecommunications Act of 
    1996.
    
    B. Summary of Significant Issues Raised by the Public Comments in 
    Response to the IRFA
    
        399. Only one party, Rural Tel. Coalition, commented on the IRFA 
    contained in the NPRM. Rural Tel. Coalition disagrees with our 
    conclusion that rules applying only to price cap LECs will not affect 
    non-price cap LECs in a way that requires analysis under the RFA. 
    According to Rural Tel. Coalition, the decisions made in this Order 
    will ``prejudge and prejudice'' a later rulemaking addressing access 
    charge reform for non-price cap LECs. In addition, Rural Tel. Coalition 
    argues that non-price cap LECs, which include small incumbent LECs, 
    will be injured if the access reform issues addressed in this Order are 
    not implemented for them as well as price-cap LECs. Finally, Rural Tel. 
    Coalition argues that the Commission impermissibly determined that 
    small incumbent LECs are not small businesses within the meaning of the 
    RFA.
        400. Rather than attempt to enact ``one size fits all'' access 
    charge reform that would risk not fully accounting for the special 
    circumstances of rate-of-return and other non-price cap LECs, we have 
    chosen to address those LECs separately in a proceeding in which we may 
    better focus on their needs. We do not agree with Rural Tel. Coalition 
    that our decisions in this Order will ``prejudge and prejudice'' our 
    consideration of the issues in a subsequent rulemaking. Although we may 
    often find that the public interest concerns are similar for large and 
    small carriers, our analysis will begin anew, and will address all 
    relevant factors. Moreover, where the special circumstances faced by 
    small incumbent LECs justify different treatment than is accorded price 
    cap LECs in this Order, we will be better able to explain and address 
    those concerns in a separate proceeding. For the reasons set forth in 
    Section V above, we also disagree with Rural Tel. Coalition that small 
    incumbent LECs may be injured by the delay involved in conducting 
    separate rulemakings. Finally, although we are not persuaded on the 
    basis of this record that our prior practice of finding incumbent LECs 
    not subject to regulatory flexibility analysis (because they are not 
    small businesses) has been incorrect, we have fully performed an RFA 
    analysis for small incumbent LECs in this Order, including 
    consideration of any adverse impact of the rules we adopt and 
    consideration of alternatives that may reduce adverse impacts on such 
    entities.
    
    C. Description and Estimate of the Number of Small Entities to Which 
    the Rules Will Apply
    
        401. The RFA generally defines ``small entity'' as having the same 
    meaning as the terms ``small business,'' ``small organization,'' and 
    ``small governmental jurisdiction.'' In addition, the term ``small 
    business'' has the same meaning as the term ``small business concern'' 
    under the Small Business Act unless the Commission has developed one or 
    more definitions that are appropriate for its activities. A small 
    business concern is one which: (1) Is independently owned and operated; 
    (2) is not dominant in its field of operation; and (3) satisfies any 
    additional criteria established by the Small Business Administration 
    (SBA).
        402. Pursuant to 5 U.S.C. sec. 601(3), the statutory definition of 
    a small business applies ``unless an agency after consultation with the 
    Office of Advocacy of the Small Business Administration and after 
    opportunity for public comment, establishes one or more definitions of 
    such term which are appropriate to the activities of the agency and 
    publishes such definition(s) in the Federal Register.'' SBA has 
    developed a definition of small business for Standard Industrial 
    Classification (SIC) category 4813 (Telephone Communications, Except 
    Radiotelephone). We first discuss the number of small businesses 
    falling within this category, and then we attempt to refine further our 
    estimate to correspond with the categories of telephone companies that 
    are commonly used under our rules.
        403. Consistent with our prior practice, our use of the terms 
    ``small entities'' and ``small businesses'' does not encompass ``small 
    incumbent
    
    [[Page 31928]]
    
    LECs.'' We use the term ``small incumbent LECs'' to refer to any 
    incumbent LECs that arguably might be defined by SBA as ``small 
    business concerns.'' Because the small incumbent LECs subject to these 
    rules are either dominant in their field of operations or are not 
    independently owned and operated, they are, consistent with our prior 
    practice, excluded from the definition of ``small entity'' and ``small 
    business concerns.'' Out of an abundance of caution, however, for 
    regulatory flexibility analysis purposes, we will consider small 
    incumbent LECs within this analysis and use the term ``small incumbent 
    LECs'' to refer to any incumbent LECs that arguably might be defined by 
    the SBA as ``small business concerns.''
    1. Telephone Companies, Except Radiotelephone Companies (SIC 4813)
        404. Total Number of Telephone Companies Affected. The United 
    States Bureau of the Census (``the Census Bureau'') reports that, at 
    the end of 1992, there were 3,497 firms engaged in providing telephone 
    services, as defined therein, for at least one year. This number 
    contains a variety of different categories of carriers, including local 
    exchange carriers, interexchange carriers, competitive access 
    providers, cellular carriers, mobile service carriers, operator service 
    providers, pay telephone operators, personal communications services 
    providers, covered specialized mobile radio providers, and resellers. 
    It seems certain that some of those 3,497 telephone service firms may 
    not qualify as small entities or small incumbent LECs because they are 
    not ``independently owned and operated.'' For example, a PCS provider 
    that is affiliated with an interexchange carrier having more than 1,500 
    employees would not meet the definition of a small business. It seems 
    reasonable to conclude that fewer than 3,497 telephone service firms 
    are small entity telephone service firms or small incumbent local 
    exchange carriers.
        405. According to the Telecommunications Industry Revenue: 
    Telecommunications Relay Service Fund Worksheet Data (TRS Worksheet), 
    there are 2,847 interstate carriers. These carriers include, inter 
    alia, local exchange carriers, wireline carriers and service providers, 
    interexchange carriers, competitive access providers, operator service 
    providers, pay telephone operators, providers of telephone toll 
    service, providers of telephone exchange service, and resellers.
        406. Wireline Carriers and Service Providers. The SBA has developed 
    a definition of small entities for telephone communications companies 
    other than radiotelephone (wireless) companies. According to the SBA's 
    definition, a small business telephone company other than a 
    radiotelephone company is one employing no more than 1,500 persons. The 
    Census Bureau reports that, there were 2,321 such telephone companies 
    in operation for at least one year at the end of 1992. All but 26 of 
    the 2,321 non-radiotelephone companies listed by the Census Bureau were 
    reported to have fewer than 1,000 employees. Thus, even if all 26 of 
    those companies had more than 1,500 employees, there would still be 
    2,295 nonradiotelephone companies that might qualify as small entities 
    or small incumbent LECs. We do not have information on the number of 
    carriers that are not independently owned and operated, and thus are 
    unable at this time to estimate with greater precision the number of 
    wireline carriers and service providers that would qualify as small 
    business concerns under the SBA's definition. Consequently, we estimate 
    that there are fewer than 2,295 small telephone communications 
    companies other than radiotelephone companies.
        407. Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers. Neither the Commission nor 
    the SBA has developed a definition for small incumbent providers of 
    local exchange services (LECs). The closest applicable definition under 
    the SBA rules is for telephone communications companies other than 
    radiotelephone (wireless) companies. The most reliable source of 
    information regarding the number of LECs nationwide is the data that we 
    collect annually in connection with the TRS Worksheet. According to our 
    most recent data, 1,347 companies reported that they were engaged in 
    the provision of local exchange services. We do not have information on 
    the number of carriers that are not independently owned and operated, 
    nor what carriers have more than 1,500 employees, and thus are unable 
    at this time to estimate with greater precision the number of incumbent 
    LECs that would qualify as small business concerns under SBA's 
    definition. Consequently, we estimate that there are fewer than 1,347 
    small incumbent LECs.
    2. Information Service Providers and Competitive LECs Are Not Affected
        408. In Section VIII.B of the NPRM, we sought comment on whether to 
    continue to exempt enhanced service providers (which we now refer to as 
    information service providers, or ISPs) from any requirement to pay 
    access charges. Because we decide to retain the ISP exemption, and do 
    not permit LECs to impose access charges on ISPs at this time, we 
    conclude that the RFA does not require us to consider the effects of 
    any proposed rules on ISPs that fall within the definition of a small 
    entity. Instead, as set forth in Section VI.B above, we find that the 
    proceeding commenced with the Notice of Inquiry issued 
    contemporaneously with the NPRM is the appropriate forum to address the 
    fundamental questions about ISP usage of the public switched network. 
    In the Notice of Inquiry, we sought comment on broader issues 
    concerning the development of information services and Internet access. 
    The information provided will give us the data we need to make further 
    reasonable and informed decisions regarding Internet access and other 
    information services, and, if necessary, to craft proposals for a 
    subsequent Notice of Proposed Rulemaking that are sensitive to the 
    complex economic, technical, and legal questions raised in this area. 
    Similarly, we sought comment in Section VIII.A of the NPRM on whether 
    the public interest would be served by regulating interstate 
    terminating access services offered by competitive (non-incumbent) 
    LECs. Because we conclude that the public interest would not be served 
    by imposing any regulations on competitive LECs' interstate terminating 
    access offerings at this time, we conclude that the RFA does not 
    require us to consider the effects of any proposed rules on competitive 
    LECs that fall within the definition of a small entity.
    
    D. Summary Analysis of the Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping, and 
    Other Compliance Requirements
    
        409. In Section V.A above, we adopt changes to transport 
    interconnection charge (TIC) rate structures and transport rate 
    structures to comply with the court order in CompTel v. FCC. These 
    changes will affect all incumbent LECs, including small incumbent LECs, 
    and will require small incumbent LECs to make one or more tariff 
    filings reflecting the new rate structures, which will involve the use 
    of legal skills, and possibly accounting, economic, and financial 
    skills.
        410. As set forth in Section VI.D above, incumbent LECs, including 
    small incumbent LECs, must reduce their interstate access charges to 
    reflect the elimination of those former universal service obligations 
    that are being replaced with new universal service obligations, 
    increase their interstate access charges to reflect their new universal 
    service obligations, and, to the
    
    [[Page 31929]]
    
    extent necessary, adjust their interstate access charges to account for 
    any additional universal service funds received under the modified 
    universal service mechanisms. This will require small incumbent LECs to 
    make one or more tariff filings, which will involve the use of legal 
    skills.
    
    E. Burdens on Small Entities, and Significant Alternatives Considered 
    and Rejected
    
        411. Sections III.C-D: Transport/TIC Rate Structure Changes. As set 
    forth in Sections III.C-D above, we adopt a new tandem-switched 
    transport rate structure and rate levels that replace the interim rate 
    structure in place prior to today. In addition, we adjust the TIC to 
    reflect the changes made by the new tandem-switched transport rate 
    structure and rate levels. Unlike before, we adopt for the first time a 
    final, cost-based rate structure, which should reduce and minimize 
    uncertainty for those small businesses and small incumbent LECs whose 
    businesses involve these services. Moreover, the new rate structure and 
    rate levels are more closely related to the costs of providing the 
    underlying services, which should minimize the economic impact of these 
    rules on small businesses and small incumbent LECs by minimizing the 
    adverse impacts that can accompany non-cost based regulation.
        412. We also adopt a transition plan that will have the effect of 
    giving small businesses and small incumbent LECs the opportunity to 
    plan, adjust, and develop their networks with a minimum of disruption 
    for them and their customers. Finally, as set forth in Section III.C-D 
    above, we find that the reallocation of TIC costs and the new recovery 
    procedures will facilitate the development of competitive markets. This 
    is because incumbent LEC rates will move toward cost-based levels and 
    incumbent LECs will no longer have the ability to assess TICs on 
    switched access minutes that do not use their transport facilities. 
    These pricing revisions may create new opportunities for small 
    entities, including small business and small incumbent LECs wishing to 
    enter local telecommunications markets.
        413. Section V: Access Reform for Incumbent Rate-of-Return Local 
    Exchange Carriers. Our decision to limit access charge reform, with 
    certain specified exceptions, to price cap LECs, which do not include 
    small businesses or small incumbent LECs, should mitigate the potential 
    that access charge reform could have a significant economic impact on 
    any small incumbent LECs. This is because the Commission will address 
    in a separate proceeding the common set of complex issues faced by non-
    price cap LECs, which are different than those faced by price cap LECs. 
    Moreover, as discussed above in Section V, we find that small incumbent 
    LECs are unlikely to face imminent harm as a result of the continued 
    application of our current access charge rules because all non-price 
    cap incumbent LECs may be exempt from, or eligible for a modification 
    or suspension of, the interconnection and unbundling requirements of 
    the 1996 Act.
        414. Section VI.A: Applicability of Part 69 to Unbundled Elements. 
    As a result of the exclusion of unbundled elements from Part 69 access 
    charges, described in Section VI.A above, incumbent LECs, including 
    small incumbent LECs, may receive reduced overall levels of interstate 
    access charges as competitors enter local markets using unbundled 
    network elements. They will, however, receive payment for those 
    unbundled network elements pursuant to interconnection agreements under 
    Section 251 of the Act. Moreover, to the extent that small incumbent 
    LECs receive universal service support through interstate access 
    charges, such funding will continue to be received without regard to 
    any loss of revenue from interstate access charges. This is because all 
    universal service support received by small incumbent LECs will be 
    received from the new Universal Service Fund, established in a separate 
    order released today. Finally, we note that section 251 of the Act 
    contains provisions expressly designed to take into account the special 
    circumstances of small incumbent LECs, including those that qualify as 
    rural LECs, with respect to interconnection obligations.
        415. Our decisions in Section VI.A above to exclude unbundled 
    elements from the application of Part 69 access charges is likely to 
    facilitate the development of competitive markets. This is because 
    prices for unbundled elements will reflect the costs of those elements, 
    and will not impose on competitors additional charges unrelated to the 
    costs of elements being purchased. Accordingly, as set forth in Section 
    VI.A above, competitors using unbundled elements will contribute to 
    universal service on an equitable and non discriminatory basis instead 
    of paying implicit subsidies to incumbent LECs (whether in addition to, 
    or in place of, explicit universal service mechanisms). These decisions 
    may create new opportunities for small entities, including small 
    businesses and small incumbent LECs, wishing to enter local 
    telecommunications markets.
        416. Section VI.C: Terminating Access Services Offered by Non-
    Incumbent LECs. As set forth in Section VI.C above, we find that 
    treating new entrants as dominant carriers subject to regulation of 
    their terminating access services until we find otherwise would impose 
    unnecessary regulation, including potentially increased regulatory 
    burdens on small businesses. Instead of imposing such burdens, we find 
    that the imposition of regulatory requirements with respect to 
    competitive LEC terminating access is unnecessary in the absence of 
    some stronger record evidence that competitive LECs have in the past 
    charged unreasonable terminating access rates, or are likely to do so 
    in the future. If there is sufficient indication that competitive LECs 
    are imposing unreasonable terminating access charges, we will revisit 
    this issue.
        417. Section VI.D: Universal Service Related Part 69 Changes. As 
    set forth in Section VI.D.2.a above, we require that LECs that 
    contribute to the Long Term Support (LTS) program and LECs that receive 
    LTS payments revise their tariffs to reflect the fact that the LTS 
    program is being replaced with explicit support from the new Universal 
    Service Fund implemented pursuant to the Universal Service Order 
    adopted today. This will require small incumbent LECs to make one or 
    more tariff filings. The new Universal Service Fund will facilitate the 
    transition to competitive markets while maintaining specific, 
    predictable and sufficient support for universal service as required 
    under section 254 of the Act. Accordingly, the required changes in 
    LECs' tariff filings, including those in tariffs filed by small 
    incumbent LECs, are part of an overall mechanism designed to minimize 
    the economic impact of the 1996 Act on small businesses and small 
    incumbent LECs. The other universal service related changes that we 
    adopt in this Order affect only price-cap LECs, which do not include 
    any small businesses or small incumbent LECs.
    
    F. Report to Congress
    
        418. The Commission shall include a copy of this FRFA, along with 
    this Order, in a report to be sent to Congress pursuant to SBREFA.
    
    X. Ordering Clauses
    
        419. Accordingly, it is ordered, pursuant to Sections 1-4, 10, 201-
    205, 251, 254, 303(r), and 410(a) of the Communications Act of 1934, as 
    amended, and Section 601 of the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 47 
    U.S.C. secs. 151-154, 160, 201-205, 251,
    
    [[Page 31930]]
    
    254, 303(r), 410(a), and 601, that the order is adopted.
        420. It is further ordered that the provisions in this Order will 
    be effective June 15, 1997. We anticipate this date will be at least 
    thirty days after publication of the rules in the Federal Register. If 
    publication of this Order is delayed, however, we find good cause under 
    5 U.S.C. sec. 553(d)(3) to make this Order effective less than thirty 
    days after publication, because the local exchange carriers subject to 
    price cap regulation must file tariffs by June 16, in order for them to 
    be effective on July 1, 1997, as required by Section 69.3 of the 
    Commission's rules, 47 CFR Sec. 69.3. In addition, to ensure that the 
    local exchange carriers subject to price cap regulation have actual 
    notice of this Order immediately following its release, we are serving 
    those entities by certified first class mail. The collections of 
    information contained within are contingent upon approval by the Office 
    of Management and Budget.
        421. It is further ordered that the following rules or amendments 
    thereto, which impose new or modified information or collection 
    requirements, shall become effective upon approval by the Office of 
    Management and Budget (OMB), but no sooner than June 15, 1997: 47 CFR 
    Secs. 61.45, 61.47, 69.104, 69.126, 69.151, and 69.152. The following 
    rules, or amendments thereto, in this Report and Order shall be 
    effective January 1, 1998: 47 CFR Secs. 61.3, 61.46, 69.1, 69.2, 
    69.105, 69.123, 69.124, 69.125, 69.154, 69.155, 69.157, 69.305, 69.306, 
    69.309, 69.401, 69.411, and 69.502. The following rules, which impose 
    new or modified information or collection requirements, shall become 
    effective upon approval by the Office of Management and Budget (OMB), 
    but no sooner than January 1, 1998: 47 CFR Secs. 61.42, 61.48, 69.4, 
    69.106, 69.111, 69.153, 69.156. Unless otherwise stated herein, all 
    remaining provisions of this Order are effective June 15, 1997.
        422. It is further ordered that the waiver petitions of Bell 
    Atlantic, Pacific Bell, GTE, Cincinnati Bell, U S West, and BellSouth 
    discussed in Section III.A.5., regarding Section 69.104 as applied to 
    ISDN service are dismissed.
        423. It is further ordered that the rulemaking proceeding in CC 
    Docket No. 95-72 is terminated.
        424. It is further ordered, pursuant to Sections 1-4, 10, 201-205, 
    251, 254, 303(r), and 701 of the Communications Act of 1934, as 
    amended, 47 U.S.C. secs. 151-154, 160, 201-205, 251, 254, 303(r), and 
    601, that notice is hereby given of the rulemaking described above and 
    that comment is sought on these issues.
    
    List of Subjects
    
    47 CFR Part 61
    
        Communications common carriers, Tariffs.
    
    47 CFR Part 69
    
        Access charges, Communications common carriers.
    
    Federal Communications Commission.
    William F. Caton,
    Acting Secretary.
    
    Rule Changes
    
        Parts 61 and 69 of title 47 of the Code of Federal Regulations are 
    amended as follows:
    
    PART 61--TARIFFS
    
        1. The authority citation for Part 61 continues to read as follows:
    
        Authority: Secs. 1, 4(i), 4(j), 201-205, and 403 of the 
    Communications Act of 1934, as amended; 47 U.S.C. 151, 154(i), 
    154(j), 201-205, and 403, unless otherwise noted.
    
        2. Section 61.3 is amended by revising the introductory text of 
    paragraph (f) to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 61.3  Definitions
    
    * * * * *
        (f) Basket. Any class or category of tariffed service or charge:
    * * * * *
        3. Section 61.42 is amended by revising paragraphs (d)(1), (d)(2), 
    and (d)(3), adding paragraph (d)(6), and revising paragraphs (e)(1) and 
    (e)(2)(vi) to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 61.42  Price cap baskets and service categories.
    
    * * * * *
        (d) * * *
        (1) A basket for the common line interstate access elements as 
    described in Secs. 69.115, 69.152, 69.154, and 69.157 of this chapter, 
    and that portion of the interstate access element described in 
    Sec. 69.153 of this chapter that recovers common line interstate access 
    revenues;
        (2) A basket for traffic sensitive switched interstate access 
    elements;
        (3) A basket for trunking services as described in Secs. 69.110, 
    69.111, 69.112, 69.114, 69.125(b), and 69.155 of this chapter, and that 
    portion of the interstate access element described in Sec. 69.153 of 
    this chapter that recovers residual interconnection charge revenues;
    * * * * *
        (6) A basket for the marketing expenses described in Sec. 69.156 of 
    this chapter, including those recovered through End User Common Line 
    charges and Presubscribed Interexchange Carrier charges.
        (e)(1) The traffic sensitive switched interstate access basket 
    shall contain such services as the Commission shall permit or require, 
    including the following service categories:
        (i) Local switching as described in Sec. 69.106(f) of this chapter;
        (ii) Information, as described in Sec. 69.109 of this chapter;
        (iii) Data base access services;
        (iv) Billing name and address, as described in Sec. 69.128 of this 
    chapter;
        (v) Local switching trunk ports, as described in Sec. 69.106(f)(1) 
    of this chapter; and
        (vi) Signalling transfer point port termination, as described in 
    Sec. 69.125(c) of this chapter.
        (2) * * *
        (vi) Interconnection charge, as recovered in Secs. 69.153 and 
    69.155 of this chapter.
    * * * * *
        4. Section 61.45 is amended by revising the introductory text of 
    paragraph (b) and (b)(1), redesignating the introductory text of 
    paragraph (c) as the introductory text of paragraph (c)(1) and revising 
    it, and adding new paragraphs (c)(2), (d)(1)(ix), (i), (j), (k), and 
    (l) to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 61.45  Adjustments to the PCI for local exchange carriers.
    
    * * * * *
        (b) Adjustments to local exchange carrier PCIs for the baskets 
    designated in Sec. 61.42(d) (2), (3), (4), (5), and (6) shall be made 
    pursuant to the formula set forth in Sec. 61.44(b), and as further 
    explained in Secs. 61.44 (e), (f), (g), and (h).
        (1) Notwithstanding the value of X defined in Sec. 61.44(b), the X 
    value applicable to the baskets specified in Sec. 61.42(d) (2), (3), 
    and (6) shall be 4.0%, or 4.7%, or 5.3%, as the carrier elects.
    * * * * *
        (c)(1) Subject to paragraphs (c)(2) and (e) of this section, 
    adjustments to local exchange carrier PCIs for the basket designated in 
    Sec. 61.42(d)(1) shall be made pursuant to the following formula:
    * * * * *
        (2) The formula set forth in paragraph (c)(1) of this section shall 
    be used by a local exchange carrier subject to price cap regulation 
    only if that carrier is imposing a carrier common line charge pursuant 
    to Sec. 69.154 of this chapter. Otherwise, adjustments to local 
    exchange carrier PCIs for the basket designated in Sec. 61.42(d)(1) 
    shall be made pursuant to the formula set forth in Sec. 61.44(b), and 
    paragraphs (i) and (j) of this section, and as further explained in 
    Sec. 61.44 (e), (f), (g), and (h). For the purposes of this paragraph, 
    and notwithstanding the value of X defined
    
    [[Page 31931]]
    
    in Sec. 61.44(b), the X value applicable to the basket specified in 
    Sec. 61.42(d)(1) shall be 4.0%, or 4.7%, or 5.3%, as the carrier 
    elects.
        (d) * * *
        (1) * * *
        (ix) The completion of amortization of equal access expenses.
    * * * * *
        (i)(1) Notwithstanding the provisions of paragraphs (b) and (c) of 
    this section, and subject to the limitations of paragraph (j) of this 
    section, price cap local exchange carriers that are recovering 
    interconnection charge revenues through per-minute rates pursuant to 
    Sec. 69.124 or Sec. 69.155 of this chapter shall target, to the extent 
    necessary to eliminate the recovery of any residual interconnection 
    charge revenues through per-minute rates, any PCI reductions associated 
    with the baskets designated in Sec. 61.42(d) (1) and (2) that result 
    from the application of the formula in Sec. 61.44(b), as further 
    explained in Sec. 61.44 (e), (f), (g), and (h), to the PCI for the 
    basket designated in Sec. 61.42(d)(3), with no adjustment being made to 
    the PCIs for the baskets designated in Sec. 61.42(d) (1) and (2) as a 
    result of the application of the formula in Sec. 61.44(b). These 
    reductions are to be made after the adjustment is made to the PCI for 
    the basket designated in Sec. 61.42(d)(3) resulting from the 
    application of the formula in Sec. 61.44(b), as further explained in 
    Sec. 61.44 (e), (f), (g), and (h).
        (2) Notwithstanding the provisions of paragraphs (b) and (c) of 
    this section, and subject to the limitations of paragraph (j) of this 
    section, price cap local exchange carriers that are recovering 
    interconnection charge revenues through per-minute rates pursuant to 
    Sec. 69.155 of this chapter shall target, to the extent necessary to 
    eliminate the recovery of any residual interconnection charge revenues 
    through per-minute rates, any PCI reductions associated with the basket 
    designated in Sec. 61.42(d)(6) that result from the application of the 
    formula in Sec. 61.44(b), as further explained in Sec. 61.44 (e), (f), 
    (g), and (h), to the PCI for the basket designated in Sec. 61.42(d)(3), 
    with no adjustment being made to the PCIs for the basket designated in 
    Sec. 61.42(d)(6) as a result of the application of the formula in 
    Sec. 61.44(b). This reduction is to be made after any adjustment made 
    pursuant to paragraph (i)(1) of this section.
        (3) Through December 31, 1997, the reduction in the PCI for the 
    basket designated in Sec. 61.42(d)(3) that results from paragraph 
    (i)(1) of this section shall be determined by dividing the sum of the 
    dollar effects of the PCI reductions that would have applied to the 
    baskets designated in Sec. 61.42(d)(1) and (d)(2) except for the 
    provisions of paragraph (i)(1) of this section by the dollar amount 
    associated with the PCI for the basket designated in Sec. 61.42(d)(3), 
    and multiplying the PCI for the basket designated in Sec. 61.42(d)(3) 
    by one minus the resulting ratio.
        (4) Effective January 1, 1998, the reduction in the PCI for the 
    basket designated in Sec. 61.42(d)(3) that results from paragraphs 
    (i)(1) and (i)(2) of this section shall be determined by dividing the 
    sum of the dollar effects of the PCI reductions that would have applied 
    to the baskets designated in Sec. 61.42(d)(1), (d)(2), and (d)(6), 
    except for the provisions of paragraphs (i)(1) and (i)(2) of this 
    section, by the dollar amount associated with the PCI for the basket 
    designated in Sec. 61.42(d)(3), and multiplying the PCI for the basket 
    designated in Sec. 61.42(d)(3) by one minus the resulting ratio.
        (j) In determining the extent of the targeting that shall occur 
    pursuant to paragraphs (i)(1) and (i)(2) of this section, local 
    exchange carriers shall compute their anticipated residual 
    interconnection charge amount by excluding revenues that are expected 
    to be reallocated to cost-causative facilities-based charges in the 
    future. To determine interconnection charge amounts so excluded in 
    connection with the July 1, 1997 tariff filings, the following local 
    exchange carriers shall use as an estimate of the residual 
    interconnection charge revenues the specified residual interconnection 
    charge percentage: NYNEX, 77.63 percent; BellSouth, 56.93 percent; U S 
    West, 59.14 percent; Bell Atlantic, 63.96 percent; Southwestern Bell 
    Telephone, 69.11 percent; and Pacific Bell and Nevada Bell, 53.52 
    percent. Each remaining price cap local exchange carrier shall estimate 
    a residual interconnection charge in an amount equal to 55 percent of 
    its current interconnection charge revenues. For subsequent tariff 
    filings in which the PCI reductions are to be targeted to the 
    interconnection charge, these initial estimates shall be adjusted to 
    reflect the actual amounts that have or will be reallocated. If the use 
    of these estimates results in more PCI reductions being targeted to the 
    interconnection charge than required to eliminate the per-minute 
    interconnection charge, the local exchange carrier shall make the 
    necessary exogenous adjustments to reverse the effects of the excess 
    targeting.
        (k) The calculation of the PCI for the basket designated in 
    Sec. 61.42(d)(3) shall include any residual interconnection charge 
    revenues recovered pursuant to Secs. 69.153 and 69.155 of this chapter.
        (l) The calculation of the PCI for the basket designated in 
    Sec. 61.42(d)(6) shall include any marketing expense revenues recovered 
    pursuant to Secs. 69.153 and 69.156 of this chapter.
        5. Section 61.46 is amended by revising paragraphs (d) and (e) and 
    adding new paragraphs (g) and (h) to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 61.46  Adjustments to the API.
    
    * * * * *
        (d)(1) Subject to paragraph (d)(2) of this section, and in 
    connection with any price cap tariff proposing changes to rates for 
    services in the basket designated in Sec. 61.42(d)(1), the maximum 
    allowable carrier common line (CCL) charges shall be computed pursuant 
    to the following methodology:
    
    CCLMOU=CLMOU * (1+% change in CL 
    PCI)-(EUCLMOU+PICCMOU)* 1/(1+(g/2))
    
    Where:
    
    CCLMOU=the sum of each of the proposed Carrier Common Line 
    rates multiplied by its corresponding base period Carrier Common Line 
    minutes of use, divided by the sum of all types of base period Carrier 
    Common Line minutes of use,
    CLMOU=the sum of each of the existing maximum allowable 
    Carrier Common Line rates multiplied by its corresponding base period 
    Carrier Common Line minutes of use, plus each existing maximum 
    allowable End User Common Line (EUCL) rate multiplied by its 
    corresponding base period lines, plus the common line portion of each 
    existing maximum allowable Presubscribed Interexchange Carrier Charge 
    (PICC) multiplied by its corresponding base period lines, divided by 
    the sum of all types of base period Carrier Common Line minutes of use,
    EUCLMOU=maximum allowable End User Common Line rates 
    multiplied by base period lines, and divided by the sum of all types of 
    base period Carrier Common Line minutes of use,
    PICCMOU=the common line portion of maximum allowable 
    Presubscribed Interexchange Carrier charge rates multiplied by base 
    period lines, and divided by the sum of all types of base period 
    Carrier Common Line minutes of use, and
    g=the ratio of minutes of use per access line during the base period to 
    minutes of use per access line
    
    [[Page 31932]]
    
    during the previous base period, minus 1.
    
        (2) The formula set forth in paragraph (d)(1) of this section shall 
    be used by a local exchange carrier subject to price cap regulation 
    only if that carrier is imposing a per-minute carrier common line 
    charge pursuant to Sec. 69.154 of this chapter. Otherwise, adjustments 
    to local exchange carrier APIs for the basket designated in 
    Sec. 61.42(d)(1) shall be made pursuant to the formula set forth in 
    paragraph (a) of this section.
        (e)(1) In addition, for the purposes of paragraph (d) of this 
    section, ``Existing Carrier Common Line Rates'' shall include existing 
    originating premium, originating non-premium, terminating premium and 
    terminating non-premium rates; and ``End User Common Line Rates'' used 
    to calculate the CLMOU and the EUCLMOU factors 
    shall include, but not be limited to, Residential and Single Line 
    Business rates, Centrex rates, and the Special Access surcharge.
        (2) For purposes of paragraph (d) of this section, ``each existing 
    Presubscribed Interexchange Carrier Charge'' shall include all the 
    charges specified in Sec. 69.153 of this chapter.
    * * * * *
        (g) The calculation of the API for the basket designated in 
    Sec. 61.42(d)(3) shall include any residual interconnection charge 
    revenues recovered pursuant to Secs. 69.153 and 69.155 of this chapter.
        (h) The calculation of the API for the basket designated in 
    Sec. 61.42(d)(6) shall include any marketing expense revenues recovered 
    pursuant to Secs. 69.153 and 69.156 of this chapter.
        6. Section 61.47 is amended by adding paragraphs (g)(7), (i) and 
    (j) to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 61.47  Adjustments to the SBI; pricing bands.
    
    * * * * *
        (g)(1) * * *
        (7) The initial level of the local switch trunk ports service 
    category designated in Sec. 61.42(e)(1)(v) shall be established to 
    include those costs identified pursuant to Sec. 69.106(f)(1) of this 
    chapter. This level shall be assigned a value of 100, and thereafter 
    must be adjusted as provided in paragraph (a) of this section, subject 
    to the banding restrictions of paragraph (e) of this section.
    * * * * *
        (i)(1) Through December 31, 1997, notwithstanding the requirements 
    of paragraph (a) of this section, if a local exchange carrier is 
    recovering interconnection charge revenues through per-minute rates 
    pursuant to Sec. 69.124 or Sec. 69.155 of this chapter, any reductions 
    to the PCI for the basket designated in Sec. 61.42(d)(3) resulting from 
    the application of the provisions of Sec. 61.45 (b) and (i)(1) shall be 
    directed to the SBI of the service category designated in 
    Sec. 61.42(e)(2)(vi).
        (2) Effective January 1, 1998, notwithstanding the requirements of 
    paragraph (a) of this section, if a local exchange carrier is 
    recovering interconnection charge revenues through per-minute rates 
    pursuant to Sec. 69.155 of this chapter, any reductions to the PCI for 
    the basket designated in Sec. 61.42(d)(3) resulting from the 
    application of the provisions of Sec. 61.45(b), (i)(1), and (i)(2) 
    shall be directed to the SBI of the service category designated in 
    Sec. 61.42(e)(2)(vi).
        (3) Through December 31, 1997, the SBI reduction required by 
    paragraph (i)(1) of this section shall be determined by dividing the 
    sum of the dollar amount of any PCI reduction required by 
    Sec. 61.45(i)(1) and from the application of Sec. 61.45(b) to the 
    basket described in Sec. 61.42(d)(3) by the dollar amount associated 
    with the SBI for the service category designated in 
    Sec. 61.42(e)(2)(vi), and multiplying the SBI for the service category 
    designated in Sec. 61.42(e)(2)(vi) by one minus the resulting ratio.
        (4) Effective January 1, 1998, the SBI reduction required by 
    paragraph (i)(2) of this section shall be determined by dividing the 
    sum of the dollar amount of any PCI reduction required by Sec. 61.45 
    (i)(1) and (i)(2), and from the application of Sec. 61.45(b) to the 
    basket described in Sec. 61.42(d)(3) by the dollar amount associated 
    with the SBI for the service category designated in 
    Sec. 61.42(e)(2)(vi), and multiplying the SBI for the service category 
    designated in Sec. 61.42(e)(2)(vi) by one minus the resulting ratio.
        (j) The calculation of the SBI for the service category designated 
    in Sec. 61.42(e)(2)(vi) shall include any residual interconnection 
    charge revenues recovered pursuant to Secs. 69.153 and 69.155 of this 
    chapter.
        7. Section 61.48 is amended by adding paragraph (k) to read as 
    follows:
    
    
    Sec. 61.48  Transition rules for price cap formula calculations.
    
    * * * * *
        (k) Marketing expenses. In the January 1, 1998 price cap tariff 
    filing, local exchange carriers shall establish the marketing expense 
    basket designated in Sec. 61.42(d)(6) with an initial PCI and API level 
    of 100. The initial value of 100 for the PCI and API for marketing 
    expenses shall correspond to the marketing expenses described in 
    Sec. 69.156(a) of this chapter.
    
    PART 69--ACCESS CHARGES
    
        8. The authority citation for part 69 continues to read as follows:
    
        Authority: 47 U.S.C. 154 (i) and (j), 201, 202, 203, 205, 218, 
    254, and 403.
    
        9. Section 69.1(c) is revised to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 69.1  Application of access charges.
    
    * * * * *
        (c) The following provisions of this part shall apply to telephone 
    companies subject to price cap regulation only to the extent that 
    application of such provisions is necessary to develop the nationwide 
    average carrier common line charge, for purposes of reporting pursuant 
    to Secs. 43.21 and 43.22 of this chapter, and for computing initial 
    charges for new rate elements: Secs. 69.3(f), 69.106(b), 69.106(f), 
    69.106(g), 69.109(b), 69.110(d), 69.111(c), 69.111(g)(1), 69.111(l), 
    69.112(d), 69.114(b), 69.114(d), 69.125(b)(2), 69.301 through 69.310, 
    and 69.401 through 69.412. The computation of rates pursuant to these 
    provisions by telephone companies subject to price cap regulation shall 
    be governed by the price cap rules set forth in part 61 of this chapter 
    and other applicable Commission Rules and orders.
        10. Section 69.2 is amended by revising paragraph (hh) to read as 
    follows:
    
    
    Sec. 69.2  Definitions.
    
    * * * * *
        (hh) ``Telephone company'' or ``local exchange carrier'' as used in 
    this part means an incumbent local exchange carrier as defined in 
    section 251(h)(1) of the 1934 Act as amended by the 1996 Act.
    * * * * *
        11. Section 69.4 is amended by removing and reserving paragraphs 
    (b)(1), (d) and (f), revising the introductory text of paragraph (b), 
    and adding paragraph (h) to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 69.4  Charges to be filed.
    
    * * * * *
        (b) Except as provided in paragraphs (c), (e), and (h) of this 
    section, and in Sec. 69.118, the carrier's carrier charges for access 
    service filed with this Commission shall include charges for each of 
    the following elements:
    * * * * *
        (h) In addition to the charges specified in paragraph (b) of this 
    section, the carrier's carrier charges for access service filed with 
    this Commission by price cap local exchange carriers shall include 
    charges for each of the following elements:
    
    [[Page 31933]]
    
        (1) Presubscribed interexchange carrier;
        (2) Per-minute residual interconnection;
        (3) Dedicated local switching trunk port;
        (4) Shared local switching trunk port;
        (5) Dedicated tandem switching trunk port;
        (6) Line port costs in excess of basic, analog service; and
        (7) Multiplexers associated with tandem switching.
    
    
    Sec. 69.103  [Removed]
    
        12. Section 69.103 is removed.
        13. Section 69.104 is amended by revising the section heading and 
    paragraphs (a) and (e) to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 69.104  End user common line for non-price cap incumbent local 
    exchange carriers.
    
        (a) This section is applicable only to incumbent local exchange 
    carriers that are not subject to price cap regulation as that term is 
    defined in Sec. 61.3(x) of this chapter. A charge that is expressed in 
    dollars and cents per line per month shall be assessed upon end users 
    that subscribe to local exchange telephone service or Centrex service 
    to the extent they do not pay carrier common line charges. A charge 
    that is expressed in dollars and cents per line per month shall be 
    assessed upon providers of public telephones. Such charge shall be 
    assessed for each line between the premises of an end user, or public 
    telephone location, and a Class 5 office that is or may be used for 
    local exchange service transmissions.
    * * * * *
        (e) The monthly charge for each residential and single line 
    business local exchange service subscriber shall be the charge computed 
    in accordance with paragraph (c) of this section, or $3.50, whichever 
    is lower.
    * * * * *
        14. Section 69.105 is amended by revising the section heading and 
    paragraph (a), and removing paragraphs (b)(7) and (b)(8), to read as 
    follows:
    
    
    Sec. 69.105  Carrier common line for non-price cap local exchange 
    carriers.
    
        (a) This section is applicable only to local exchange carriers that 
    are not subject to price cap regulation as that term is defined in 
    Sec. 61.3(x) of this chapter. A charge that is expressed in dollars and 
    cents per line per access minute of use shall be assessed upon all 
    interexchange carriers that use local exchange common line facilities 
    for the provision of interstate or foreign telecommunications services, 
    except that the charge shall not be assessed upon interexchange 
    carriers to the extent they resell MTS or MTS-type services of other 
    common carriers (OCCs).
    * * * * *
        15. Section 69.106 is amended by revising paragraphs (a) and (b), 
    and by adding paragraphs (f) and (g) to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 69.106  Local switching.
    
        (a) Except as provided in Sec. 69.118, charges that are expressed 
    in dollars and cents per access minute of use shall be assessed by 
    local exchange carriers that are not subject to price cap regulation 
    upon all interexchange carriers that use local exchange switching 
    facilities for the provision of interstate or foreign services.
        (b) The per minute charge described in paragraph (a) of this 
    section shall be computed by dividing the projected annual revenue 
    requirement for the Local Switching element by the projected annual 
    access minutes of use for all interstate or foreign services that use 
    local exchange switching facilities.
    * * * * *
        (f) Except as provided in Sec. 69.118, price cap local exchange 
    carriers shall establish rate elements for local switching as follows:
        (1) Price cap local exchange carriers shall separate from the 
    projected annual revenues for the Local Switching element those costs 
    projected to be incurred for ports (including cards and DS1/voice-grade 
    multiplexers required to access end offices equipped with analog 
    switches) on the trunk side of the local switch. Price cap local 
    exchange carriers shall further identify costs incurred for dedicated 
    trunk ports separately from costs incurred for shared trunk ports.
        (i) Price cap local exchange carriers shall recover dedicated trunk 
    port costs identified pursuant to paragraph (f)(1) of this section 
    through flat-rated charges expressed in dollars and cents per trunk 
    port and assessed upon the purchaser of the dedicated trunk terminating 
    at the port.
        (ii) Price cap local exchange carriers shall recover shared trunk 
    port costs identified pursuant to paragraph (f)(1) of this section 
    through charges assessed upon purchasers of shared transport. This 
    charge shall be expressed in dollars and cents per access minute of 
    use. The charge shall be computed by dividing the projected costs of 
    the shared ports by the historical annual access minutes of use 
    calculated for purposes of recovery of common transport costs in 
    Sec. 69.111(c).
        (2) Price cap local exchange carriers shall recover the projected 
    annual revenues for the Local Switching element that are not recovered 
    in paragraph (f)(1) of this section through charges that are expressed 
    in dollars and cents per access minute of use and assessed upon all 
    interexchange carriers that use local exchange switching facilities for 
    the provision of interstate or foreign services. The maximum charge 
    shall be computed by dividing the projected remainder of the annual 
    revenues for the Local Switching element by the historical annual 
    access minutes of use for all interstate or foreign services that use 
    local exchange switching facilities.
        (g) On or after July 1, 1998, a price cap local exchange carrier 
    may recover signalling costs associated with call setup through a call 
    setup charge imposed upon all interstate interexchange carriers that 
    use that local exchange carrier's facilities to originate or terminate 
    interstate interexchange or foreign services. This charge must be 
    expressed as dollars and cents per call attempt and may be assessed on 
    originating calls handed off to the interexchange carrier's point of 
    presence and on terminating calls received from an interexchange 
    carrier's point of presence, whether or not that call is completed at 
    the called location. Price cap local exchange carriers may not recover 
    through this charge any costs recovered through other rate elements.
    
    
    Sec. 69.107  [Removed]
    
        16. Section 69.107 is removed.
        17. Section 69.111 is amended by removing and reserving paragraphs 
    (b) and (f), revising paragraphs (a), (c), (d), (e), and (g), and 
    adding paragraph (l) to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 69.111  Tandem-switched transport and tandem charge.
    
        (a)(1) Through June 30, 1998, except as provided in paragraph (l) 
    of this section, tandem-switched transport shall consist of two rate 
    elements, a transmission charge and a tandem switching charge.
        (2) Beginning July 1, 1998, except as provided in paragraph (l) of 
    this section, tandem-switched transport shall consist of three rate 
    elements as follows:
        (i) A per-minute charge for transport of traffic over common 
    transport facilities between the incumbent local exchange carrier's end 
    office and the tandem switching office. This charge shall be expressed 
    in dollars and cents per access minute of use and shall be assessed 
    upon all purchasers of common transport facilities between the local 
    exchange carrier's end office and the tandem switching office.
        (ii) A per-minute tandem switching charge. This tandem switching 
    charge shall be set in accordance with
    
    [[Page 31934]]
    
    paragraph (g) of this section, excluding multiplexer and dedicated port 
    costs recovered in accordance with paragraph (l) of this section, and 
    shall be assessed upon all interexchange carriers and other persons 
    that use incumbent local exchange carrier tandem switching facilities.
        (iii) A flat-rated charge for transport of traffic over dedicated 
    transport facilities between the serving wire center and the tandem 
    switching office. This charge shall be assessed as a charge for 
    dedicated transport facilities provisioned between the serving wire 
    center and the tandem switching office in accordance with Sec. 69.112.
        (b) [Reserved]
        (c)(1) Through June 30, 1998, tandem-switched transport 
    transmission charges generally shall be presumed reasonable if the 
    telephone company bases the charges on a weighted per-minute equivalent 
    of direct-trunked transport DS1 and DS3 rates that reflects the 
    relative number of DS1 and DS3 circuits used in the tandem to end 
    office links (or a surrogate based on the proportion of copper and 
    fiber facilities in the interoffice network), calculated using the 
    total actual voice-grade minutes of use, geographically averaged on a 
    study-area-wide basis, that the incumbent local exchange carrier 
    experiences based on the prior year's annual use. Tandem-switched 
    transport transmission charges that are not presumed reasonable 
    generally shall be suspended and investigated absent a substantial 
    cause showing by the telephone company.
        (2) Beginning July 1, 1998:
        (i) Except in study areas where the incumbent local exchange 
    carrier has implemented density pricing zones as described in section 
    69.124, per-minute common transport charges described in paragraph 
    (a)(2)(i) of this section shall be presumed reasonable if the incumbent 
    local exchange carrier bases the charges on a weighted per-minute 
    equivalent of direct-trunked transport DS1 and DS3 rates that reflects 
    the relative number of DS1 and DS3 circuits used in the tandem to end 
    office links (or a surrogate based on the proportion of copper and 
    fiber facilities in the interoffice network), calculated using the 
    total actual voice-grade minutes of use, geographically averaged on a 
    study-area-wide basis, that the incumbent local exchange carrier 
    experiences based on the prior year's annual use. Tandem-switched 
    transport transmission charges that are not presumed reasonable shall 
    be suspended and investigated absent a substantial cause showing by the 
    incumbent local exchange carrier.
        (ii) In study areas where the incumbent local exchange carrier has 
    implemented density pricing zones as described in Sec. 69.124, per-
    minute common transport charges described in paragraph (a)(2)(i) of 
    this section shall be presumed reasonable if the incumbent local 
    exchange carrier bases the charges on a weighted per-minute equivalent 
    of direct-trunked transport DS1 and DS3 rates that reflects the 
    relative number of DS1 and DS3 circuits used in the tandem to end 
    office links (or a surrogate based on the proportion of copper and 
    fiber facilities in the interoffice network), calculated using the 
    total actual voice-grade minutes of use, averaged on a zone-wide basis, 
    that the incumbent local exchange carrier experiences based on the 
    prior year's annual use. Tandem-switched transport transmission charges 
    that are not presumed reasonable shall be suspended and investigated 
    absent a substantial cause showing by the incumbent local exchange 
    carrier.
        (d)(1) Through June 30, 1998, the tandem-switched transport 
    transmission charges may be distance-sensitive. Distance shall be 
    measured as airline distance between the serving wire center and the 
    end office, unless the customer has ordered tandem-switched transport 
    between the tandem office and the end office, in which case distance 
    shall be measured as airline distance between the tandem office and the 
    end office.
        (2) Beginning July 1, 1998, the per-minute charge for transport of 
    traffic over common transport facilities described in paragraph 
    (a)(2)(i) of this section may be distance-sensitive. Distance shall be 
    measured as airline distance between the tandem switching office and 
    the end office.
        (e)(1) Through June 30, 1998, if the telephone company employs 
    distance-sensitive rates:
        (i) A distance-sensitive component shall be assessed for use of the 
    transmission facilities, including intermediate transmission circuit 
    equipment between the end points of the interoffice circuit; and
        (ii) A non-distance-sensitive component shall be assessed for use 
    of the circuit equipment at the ends of the interoffice transmission 
    links.
        (2) Beginning July 1, 1998, if the telephone company employs 
    distance-sensitive rates for transport of traffic over common transport 
    facilities, as described in paragraph (a)(2)(i) of this section:
        (i) A distance-sensitive component shall be assessed for use of the 
    common transport facilities, including intermediate transmission 
    circuit equipment between the end office and tandem switching office; 
    and
        (ii) A non-distance-sensitive component shall be assessed for use 
    of the circuit equipment at the ends of the interoffice transmission 
    links.
        (f) [Reserved]
        (g)(1) The tandem switching charge imposed pursuant to paragraphs 
    (a)(1) or (a)(2)(ii) of this section, as applicable, shall be set to 
    recover twenty percent of the annual part 69 interstate tandem revenue 
    requirement plus one third of the portion of the tandem switching 
    revenue requirement being recovered through the interconnection charge 
    recovered by Secs. 69.124, 69.153, and 69.155, excluding multiplexer 
    and dedicated port costs recovered in accordance with paragraph (l) of 
    this section.
        (2) Beginning January 1, 1999, the tandem switching charge imposed 
    pursuant to paragraph (a)(2)(ii) of this section shall be set to 
    recover the amount prescribed in paragraph (g)(1) of this section plus 
    one half of the remaining portion of the tandem switching revenue 
    requirement then being recovered through the interconnection charge 
    recovered by Secs. 69.124, 69.153, and 69.155, excluding multiplexer 
    and dedicated port costs recovered in accordance with paragraph (l) of 
    this section.
        (3) Beginning January 1, 2000, the tandem switching charge imposed 
    pursuant to paragraph (a)(2)(ii) of this section shall be set to 
    recover the entire interstate tandem switching revenue requirement, 
    including that portion formerly recovered through the interconnection 
    charge recovered in Secs. 69.124, 69.153, and 69.155, and excluding 
    multiplexer and dedicated port costs recovered in accordance with 
    paragraph (l) of this section.
        (4) A local exchange carrier that is subject to price cap 
    regulation as that term is defined in Sec. 61.3(x) of this chapter 
    shall calculate its tandem switching revenue requirement as used in 
    this paragraph by dividing the tandem switching revenue requirement 
    that was included in the original interconnection charge by the 
    original interconnection charge, and then multiplying this result by 
    the annual revenues recovered through the interconnection charge, 
    described in Sec. 69.124, as of June 30, 1997.
    * * * * *
        (l) In addition to the charges described in this section, price cap 
    local exchange carriers shall establish separate charges for 
    multiplexers and dedicated trunk ports used in conjunction with the 
    tandem switch as follows:
        (1) Local exchange carriers must establish a traffic-sensitive 
    charge for
    
    [[Page 31935]]
    
    DS3/DS1 multiplexers used on the end office side of the tandem switch, 
    assessed on purchasers of common transport to the tandem switch. This 
    charge must be expressed in dollars and cents per access minute of use. 
    The maximum charge shall be calculated by dividing the total costs of 
    the multiplexers on the end office-side of the tandem switch by the 
    serving wire center side of the tandem switch by the projected annual 
    access minutes of use calculated for purposes of recovery of common 
    transport costs in paragraph (c) of this section. A similar charge 
    shall be assessed for DS1/voice-grade multiplexing provided on the end-
    office side of analog tandem switches.
        (2)(i) Local exchange carriers must establish a flat-rated charge 
    for dedicated DS3/DS1 multiplexing on the serving wire center side of 
    the tandem switch provided in conjunction with dedicated DS3 transport 
    service from the serving wire center to the tandem switch. This charge 
    shall be assessed on interexchange carriers purchasing tandem-switched 
    transport in proportion to the number of DS3 trunks provisioned for 
    that interexchange carrier between the serving wire center and the 
    tandem-switch.
        (ii) Local exchange carriers must establish a flat-rated charge for 
    dedicated DS1/voice-grade multiplexing provided on the serving wire 
    center side of analog tandem switches. This charge may be assessed on 
    interexchange carriers purchasing tandem-switched transport in 
    proportion to the interexchange carrier's transport capacity on the 
    serving wire center side of the tandem.
        (3) Price cap local exchange carriers may recover the costs of 
    dedicated trunk ports on the serving wire center side of the tandem 
    switch only through flat-rated charges expressed in dollars and cents 
    per trunk port and assessed upon the purchaser of the dedicated trunk 
    terminating at the port.
    
    
    Sec. 69.122   [Removed]
    
        18. Section 69.122 is removed.
        19. Section 69.123 is amended by adding paragraph (f) to read as 
    follows:
    
    
    Sec. 69.123  Density pricing zones for special access and switched 
    transport.
    
    * * * * *
        (f)(1) An incumbent local exchange carrier that establishes density 
    pricing zones under this section must reallocate additional amounts 
    recovered under the interconnection charge prescribed in Sec. 69.124 to 
    facilities-based transport rates, reflecting the higher costs of 
    serving lower-density areas. Each incumbent local exchange carrier must 
    reallocate costs from the interconnection charge each time it increases 
    the differential between prices in density zones two and one or between 
    three and one.
        (2) Any incumbent local exchange carrier that has already 
    deaveraged its rates on January 1, 1998 must reallocate an amount 
    equivalent to that described in paragraph (f)(1) of this section from 
    the interconnection charge prescribed in Sec. 69.124 to its transport 
    services.
        (3) Price cap local exchange carriers shall reassign to direct-
    trunked transport and tandem-switched transport categories or 
    subcategories interconnection charge amounts reallocated under 
    paragraph (f)(1) or (f)(2) of this section in a manner that reflects 
    the way density pricing zones are being implemented by the incumbent 
    local exchange carrier.
        20. Section 69.124 is revised to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 69.124  Interconnection charge.
    
        (a) For telephone companies not subject to price cap regulation, an 
    interconnection charge expressed in dollars and cents per access minute 
    shall be assessed upon all interexchange carriers and upon all other 
    persons using the telephone company local transport network.
        (b) For telephone companies not subject to price cap regulation, 
    the interconnection charge shall be computed by subtracting entrance 
    facilities, tandem-switched transport, direct-trunked transport, and 
    dedicated signalling transport revenues from the part 69 transport 
    revenue requirement, and dividing by the total interstate local 
    transport minutes.
        21. Section 69.125 is amended by revising paragraph (a) to read as 
    follows:
    
    
    Sec. 69.125  Dedicated signalling transport.
    
        (a) Dedicated signalling transport shall consist of two elements, a 
    signalling link charge and a signalling transfer point (STP) port 
    termination charge.
    * * * * *
        22. Section 69.126 is revised to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 69.126  Nonrecurring charges.
    
        Incumbent local exchange carriers shall not assess any nonrecurring 
    charges for service connection when an interexchange carrier converts 
    trunks from tandem-switched transport to direct-trunked transport or 
    when an interexchange carrier orders the disconnection of 
    overprovisioned trunks, until six months after the effective date of 
    the tariffs eliminating the unitary pricing option for tandem-switched 
    transport.
        23. Subpart C is revised to read as follows:
    
    Subpart C--Computation of Charges for Price Cap Local Exchange Carriers
    
    Sec.
    69.151  Applicability.
    69.152  End user common line for price cap local exchange carriers.
    69.153  Presubscribed interexchange carrier charge (PICC).
    69.154  Per-minute carrier common line charge.
    69.155  Per-minute residual interconnection charge.
    69.156  Marketing expenses.
    69.157  Line port costs in excess of basic, analog service.
    
    Subpart C--Computation of Charges for Price Cap Local Exchange 
    Carriers
    
    
    Sec. 69.151  Applicability.
    
        This subpart shall apply only to telephone companies subject to the 
    price cap regulations set forth in part 61 of this chapter.
    
    
    Sec. 69.152  End user common line for price cap local exchange 
    carriers.
    
        (a) A charge that is expressed in dollars and cents per line per 
    month shall be assessed upon end users that subscribe to local exchange 
    telephone service or Centrex service to the extent they do not pay 
    carrier common line charges. A charge that is expressed in dollars and 
    cents per line per month shall be assessed upon providers of public 
    telephones. Such charge shall be assessed for each line between the 
    premises of an end user, or public telephone location, and a Class 5 
    office that is or may be used for local exchange service transmissions.
        (b) Except as provided in paragraphs (d) through (i) of this 
    section, the maximum single line rate or charge shall be computed:
        (1) By dividing one-twelfth of the projected annual revenue 
    requirement for the End User Common Line element by the projected 
    average number of local exchange service subscriber lines in use during 
    such annual period, only so long as a per-minute carrier common line 
    charge is assessed or the multi-line PICC defined in Sec. 69.153 
    recovers common line revenues.
        (2) By dividing one-twelfth of the projected annual revenues 
    permitted for the common line basket under the Commission's price cap 
    rules, as set forth in part 61 of this chapter, by the projected 
    average number of local exchange service subscriber lines in use during 
    such annual period, if no per-minute carrier common line charge is 
    assessed and the multi-line PICC
    
    [[Page 31936]]
    
    defined in Sec. 69.153 does not recover any common line revenues.
        (3) Provided, however, that the charge for each local exchange 
    service subscriber line shall not exceed $9.00 as adjusted by the 
    inflation factor computed under paragraph (k) of this section.
        (c) The charge for each subscriber line associated with a public 
    telephone shall be equal to the monthly charge computed in accordance 
    with paragraph (b) of this section.
        (d)(1) Through December 31, 1997, the monthly charge for each 
    primary residential or single line business local exchange service 
    subscriber line shall be the charge computed in accordance with 
    paragraph (b) of this section, or $3.50, whichever is lower.
        (2) Beginning January 1, 1998, the maximum monthly charge for each 
    primary residential or single line business local exchange service 
    subscriber line shall be the charge computed in accordance with 
    paragraph (b) of this section, or $3.50, whichever is lower.
        (e)(1) Through December 31, 1997, the monthly charge for each non-
    primary residential local exchange service subscriber line shall be the 
    charge computed in accordance with paragraph (b) of this section, or 
    $3.50, whichever is lower.
        (2) Beginning January 1, 1998, the maximum monthly charge for each 
    non-primary residential local exchange service subscriber line shall be 
    the lower of:
        (i) The maximum charge computed in accordance with paragraph (b) of 
    this section; or
        (ii) $5.00. On January 1, 1999, this amount shall be adjusted by 
    the inflation factor computed under paragraph (k) of this section, and 
    increased by $1.00. On July 1, 2000, and in each subsequent year, this 
    amount shall be adjusted by the inflation factor computed under 
    paragraph (k) of this section, and increased by $1.00.
        (3) Where the local exchange carrier provides a residential line to 
    another carrier so that the other carrier may resell that residential 
    line to a residence that already receives a primary residential line, 
    the local exchange carrier may collect the non-primary residential 
    charge described in paragraph (e) of this section from the other 
    carrier.
        (f) Except as provided in paragraphs (n) and (o) of this section, 
    the charge for each primary residential local exchange service 
    subscriber line shall be the same as the charge for each single line 
    business local exchange service subscriber line.
        (g) A line shall be deemed to be a residential subscriber line if 
    the subscriber pays a rate for such line that is described as a 
    residential rate in the local exchange service tariff.
        (h) [Reserved]
        (i) A line shall be deemed to be a single line business subscriber 
    line if the subscriber pays a rate that is not described as a 
    residential rate in the local exchange service tariff and does not 
    obtain more than one such line from a particular telephone company.
        (j) No charge shall be assessed for any WATS access line.
        (k)(1) On January 1, 1999:
        (i) The ceiling for multi-line business subscriber lines under 
    paragraph (b)(3) of this section will be adjusted to reflect inflation 
    as measured by the change in GDP-PI for the 18 months ending September 
    30, 1998.
        (ii) The ceiling for non-primary residential subscriber lines under 
    paragraph (e)(2)(ii) of this section will be adjusted to reflect 
    inflation as measured by the change in GDP-PI for the 12 months ending 
    September 30, 1998.
        (2) On July 1, 2000, the ceiling for multi-line business subscriber 
    lines and non-primary residential subscriber lines will be adjusted to 
    reflect inflation as measured by the change in GDP-PI for the 18 months 
    ending on March 31, 2000.
        (3) On July 1 of each subsequent year, the ceiling for multi-line 
    business subscriber lines and non-primary residential subscriber lines 
    will be adjusted to reflect inflation as measured by the change in GDP-
    PI for the 12 months ending on March 31 of the year the adjustment is 
    made.
        (l)(1) Beginning January 1, 1998, local exchange carriers shall 
    assess no more than one end user common line charge as calculated under 
    the applicable method under paragraph (e) of this section for Basic 
    Rate Interface integrated services digital network (ISDN) service.
        (2) Local exchange carriers shall assess no more than five end user 
    common line charges as calculated under paragraph (b) of this section 
    for Primary Rate Interface ISDN service.
        (m) In the event the local exchange carrier charges less than the 
    maximum end user common line charge for any subscriber lines, the local 
    exchange carrier may not recover the difference between the amount 
    collected and the maximum from carrier common line charges or PICCs.
        (n) Through December 31, 1997, the End User Common Line charge for 
    a residential subscriber shall be 50% of the charge specified in 
    paragraphs (b) and (d) of this section if the residential local 
    exchange service rate for such subscribers is reduced by an equivalent 
    amount, provided that such local exchange service rate reduction is 
    based upon a means test that is subject to verification.
        (o) Paragraphs (o)(1) and (o)(2) of this section are effective 
    through December 31, 1997.
        (1) The End User Common Line charge for residential subscribers 
    shall be reduced to the extent of the state assistance as calculated in 
    paragraph (o)(2) of this section, or waived in full if the state 
    assistance equals or exceeds the residential End User Common Line 
    charge under the circumstances described in this paragraph. In order to 
    qualify for this waiver, the subscriber must be eligible for and 
    receive assistance or benefits provided pursuant to a narrowly targeted 
    telephone company lifeline assistance program, requiring verification 
    of eligibility, implemented by the state or local telephone company. A 
    state or local telephone company wishing to implement this End User 
    Common Line reduction or waiver for its subscribers shall file 
    information with the Commission Secretary demonstrating that its plan 
    meets the criteria set out in this section and showing the amount of 
    state assistance per subscriber as described in paragraph (o)(2) of 
    this section. The reduction or waiver of the End User Common Line 
    charge shall be available as soon as the Commission certifies that the 
    state or local telephone plan satisfies the criteria set out in this 
    paragraph and the relevant tariff provisions become effective.
        (2)(i) The state assistance per subscriber shall be equal to the 
    difference between the charges to be paid by the participating 
    subscribers and those to be paid by other subscribers for comparable 
    monthly local exchange service, service connections and customer 
    deposits, except that benefits or assistance for connection charges and 
    deposit requirements may only be counted once annually. In order to be 
    included in calculating the state assistance, such benefits must be a 
    single telephone line to the household's principal residence.
        (ii) The monthly state assistance per participating subscriber 
    shall be calculated by adding the amounts calculated in paragraphs 
    (o)(2)(ii)(A) and (o)(2)(ii)(B) of this section.
        (A) The amount of the monthly state assistance per participating 
    subscriber for local exchange service shall be calculated by dividing 
    the annual difference between charges paid by all participating 
    subscribers for residential
    
    [[Page 31937]]
    
    local exchange service and the amount which would have been charged to 
    non-qualifying subscribers for comparable service by twelve times the 
    number of subscribers participating in the state assistance program. 
    Estimates may be used when historic data are not available.
        (B) The amount of the monthly state assistance for service 
    connections and customer deposits per participating subscriber shall be 
    calculated by determining the annual amount of the reductions in these 
    charges for participating subscribers each year and dividing this 
    amount by twelve times the number of participating subscribers. 
    Estimates may be used when historic data are not available.
        (p) Through December 31, 1997, in connection with the filing of 
    access tariffs pursuant to Sec. 69.3(a), telephone companies shall 
    calculate for the association their projected revenue requirement 
    attributable to the operation of Sec. 69.104 (n) through (o). The 
    projected amount will be adjusted by the association to reflect the 
    actual lifeline assistance benefits paid in the previous period. If the 
    actual benefits exceeded the projected amount for that period, the 
    differential will be added to the projection for the ensuing period. If 
    the actual benefits were less than the projected amount for that 
    period, the differential will be subtracted from the projection for the 
    ensuing period. Through December 31, 1997, the association shall so 
    adjust amounts to the Lifeline Assistance revenue requirement, bill and 
    collect such amounts from interexchange carriers pursuant to 
    Sec. 69.117 and distribute the funds to qualifying telephone companies 
    pursuant to Sec. 69.603(d).
    
    
    Sec. 69.153  Presubscribed interexchange carrier charge (PICC).
    
        (a) A charge expressed in dollars and cents per line may be 
    assessed upon the subscriber's presubscribed interexchange carrier to 
    recover the common line revenues permitted under the price cap rules in 
    part 61 of this chapter that cannot be recovered through the end user 
    common line charge established under Sec. 69.152, residual 
    interconnection charge revenues, and certain marketing expenses 
    described in Sec. 69.156(a). In the event the ceilings on the PICC 
    prevent the PICC from recovering all the residual common line, residual 
    interconnection charge revenues, and marketing expenses, the PICC shall 
    recover all residual common line revenues before it recovers residual 
    interconnection charge revenues, and all residual interconnection 
    charge revenues before it recovers marketing expenses.
        (b) If an end-user customer does not have a presubscribed 
    interexchange carrier, the local exchange carrier may collect the PICC 
    directly from the end user.
        (c) The maximum monthly PICC for primary residential subscriber 
    lines and single-line business subscriber lines shall be the lower of:
        (1) One twelfth of the sum of annual common line revenues and 
    residual interconnection charge revenues permitted under our price cap 
    rules divided by the projected average number of local exchange service 
    subscriber lines in use during such annual period, minus $3.50; or
        (2) $0.53. On January 1, 1999, this amount shall be adjusted by the 
    inflation factor computed under paragraph (e) of this section, and 
    increased by $0.50. On July 1, 2000, and in each subsequent year, this 
    amount shall be adjusted by the inflation factor computed under 
    paragraph (e) of this section, and increased by $0.50.
        (d) To the extent that a local exchange carrier cannot recover its 
    full common line revenues, residual interconnection charge revenues, 
    and those marketing expense revenues described in Sec. 69.156(a) 
    permitted under price cap regulation through the recovery mechanisms 
    established in Sec. 69.152, paragraph (c) of this section, and 
    Sec. 69.156 (b) and (c), the local exchange carrier may assess a PICC 
    on multi-line business subscriber lines and non-primary residential 
    subscriber lines.
        (1) The maximum monthly PICC for non-primary residential subscriber 
    lines shall be the lower of:
        (i) One twelfth of the annual common line, residual interconnection 
    charge, and Sec. 69.156(a) marketing expense revenues permitted under 
    the price cap rules set forth in part 61 of this chapter, less the 
    maximum amounts permitted to be recovered through the recovery 
    mechanisms under Sec. 69.152, paragraph (c) of this section, and 
    Sec. 69.156 (b) and (c), divided by the total number of projected non-
    primary residential and multi-line business subscriber lines in use 
    during such annual period; or
        (ii) $1.50. On January 1, 1999, this amount shall be adjusted by 
    the inflation factor computed under paragraph (e) of this section, and 
    increased by $1.00. On July 1, 2000, and in each subsequent year, this 
    amount shall be adjusted by the inflation factor computed under 
    paragraph (e) of this section, and increased by $1.00.
        (2) If the maximum monthly PICC for non-primary residential 
    subscriber lines is determined using paragraph (d)(1)(i) of this 
    section, the maximum monthly PICC for multi-line business subscriber 
    lines shall equal the maximum monthly PICC of non-primary residential 
    subscriber lines. Otherwise, the maximum monthly PICC for multi-line 
    business lines shall be the lower of:
        (i) One twelfth of the annual common line, residual interconnection 
    charge, and Sec. 69.156(a) marketing expense revenues permitted under 
    this part and part 61 of this chapter, less the maximum amounts 
    permitted to be recovered through the recovery mechanisms under 
    Sec. 69.152, paragraphs (c) and (d)(1)(i) of this section, and 
    Sec. 69.156 (b) and (c), divided by the total number of projected 
    multi-line business subscriber lines in use during such annual period; 
    or
        (ii) $2.75. On January 1, 1999, this amount shall be adjusted by 
    the inflation factor computed under paragraph (e) of this section, and 
    increased by $1.50. On July 1, 2000, and in each subsequent year, this 
    amount shall be adjusted by the inflation factor computed under 
    paragraph (e) of this section, and increased by $1.50.
        (e) For the PICC ceiling for primary residential subscriber lines 
    and single-line business subscriber lines under paragraph (c)(2) of 
    this section, non-primary residential subscriber lines under paragraph 
    (d)(1)(ii) of this section, and multi-line business subscriber lines 
    under paragraph (d)(2)(ii) of this section:
        (1) On January 1, 1999, the ceiling will be adjusted to reflect 
    inflation as measured by the change in GDP-PI for the 12 months ending 
    September 30, 1998.
        (2) On July 1, 2000, the ceiling will be adjusted to reflect 
    inflation as measured by the change in GDP-PI for the 18 months ending 
    on March 31, 2000.
        (3) On July 1 of each subsequent year, the ceiling will be adjusted 
    to reflect inflation as measured by the change in GDP-PI for the 12 
    months ending on March 31 of the year the adjustment is made.
        (f)(1) Local exchange carriers shall assess no more than one PICC 
    as calculated under the applicable method under paragraph (d)(1) of 
    this section for Basic Rate Interface integrated services digital 
    network (ISDN) service.
        (2) Local exchange carriers shall assess no more than five PICCs as 
    calculated under paragraph (d)(2) of this section for Primary Rate 
    Interface ISDN service.
    
    
    Sec. 69.154  Per-minute carrier common line charge.
    
        (a) Local exchange carriers may recover a per-minute carrier common
    
    [[Page 31938]]
    
    line charge from interexchange carriers, collected on originating 
    access minutes and calculated using the weighting method set forth in 
    paragraph (c) of this section. The maximum such charge shall be the 
    lower of:
        (1) The per-minute rate that would recover annual common line 
    revenues permitted less the maximum amounts allowed to be recovered 
    under Secs. 69.152 and 69.153; or
        (2) The sum of the local switching, carrier common line and 
    interconnection charge charges assessed on originating minutes on 
    December 31, 1997, minus the local switching charges assessed on 
    originating minutes.
        (b) To the extent that paragraph (a) of this section does not 
    recover from interexchange carriers all permitted carrier common line 
    revenue, the excess may be collected through a per-minute charge on 
    terminating access calculated using the weighting method set forth in 
    paragraph (c) of this section.
        (c) For each Carrier Common Line access element tariff, the premium 
    originating Carrier Common Line charge shall be set at a level that 
    recovers revenues allowed under paragraphs (a) and (b) of this section. 
    The non-premium charges shall be equal to .45 multiplied by the premium 
    charges.
    
    
    Sec. 69.155  Per-minute residual interconnection charge.
    
        (a) Local exchange carriers may recover a per-minute residual 
    interconnection charge on originating access. The maximum such charge 
    shall be the lower of:
        (1) The per-minute rate that would recover the total annual 
    residual interconnection charge revenues permitted less the portion of 
    the residual interconnection charge allowed to be recovered under 
    Sec. 69.153; or
        (2) The sum of the local switching, carrier common line and 
    residual interconnection charges assessed on originating minutes on 
    December 31, 1997, minus the local switching charges assessed on 
    originating minutes, less the maximum amount allowed to be recovered 
    under Sec. 69.154(a).
        (b) To the extent that paragraph (a) of this section prohibits a 
    local exchange carrier from recovering all of the residual 
    interconnection charge revenues permitted, the residual may be 
    collected through a per-minute charge on terminating access.
        (c) Any charge assessed pursuant to paragraph (a) or (b) of this 
    section shall be assessed only upon minutes utilizing the local 
    exchange carrier's local transport service.
    
    
    Sec. 69.156  Marketing expenses.
    
        (a) Local exchange carriers shall recover marketing expenses that 
    are allocated to the common line and traffic sensitive baskets, and the 
    switched services within the trunking basket pursuant to Secs. 32.6610 
    of this chapter and 69.403.
        (b) The expenses described in paragraph (a) of this section may be 
    recovered from non-primary residential subscriber lines, by increasing 
    the end user common line charge described in Sec. 69.152(e). The amount 
    of marketing expenses permitted to be recovered in this manner shall be 
    the total marketing expenses described in paragraph (a) of this section 
    divided by the sum of non-primary residential lines and multi-line 
    business lines. In no event shall the end user common line charge for 
    these lines exceed the lower of the ceilings established in Sec. 69.152 
    (b)(3) and (e)(2)(ii).
        (c) The expenses described in paragraph (a) of this section may be 
    recovered from multi-line business subscriber lines, by increasing the 
    end user common line charge described in Sec. 69.152(b). The amount 
    permitted to be recovered in this manner shall be the total marketing 
    expenses described in paragraph (a) of this section divided by the sum 
    of non-primary residential lines and multi-line business lines. In no 
    event shall the end user common line charge for these lines exceed the 
    ceiling established in Sec. 69.152(b)(3).
        (d) In the event that the ceilings set forth in paragraphs (b) and 
    (c) of this section, and Sec. 69.153(d) prevent a local exchange 
    carrier from recovering fully the marketing expenses described in 
    paragraph (a) of this section, the local exchange carrier may recover 
    the remainder through a per-minute assessment on originating access 
    minutes, so long as the charge for originating access does not exceed 
    the amount defined in Sec. 69.155(a)(2) less the maximum permitted to 
    be recovered under Sec. 69.155(a).
        (e) In the event that the ceilings set forth in paragraphs (b), (c) 
    and (d) of this section, and Sec. 69.153(d) prevent a local exchange 
    carrier from recovering fully the marketing expenses described in 
    paragraph (a) of this section, the local exchange carrier may recover 
    the remainder through a per-minute assessment on terminating access 
    minutes.
        (f) The amount of marketing expenses that may be recovered each 
    year shall be adjusted in accordance with the price cap rules set forth 
    in part 61 of this chapter.
    
    
    Sec. 69.157  Line port costs in excess of basic, analog service.
    
        To the extent that the costs of ISDN line ports, and line ports 
    associated with other services, exceed the costs of a line port used 
    for basic, analog service, local exchange carriers may recover the 
    difference through a separate monthly end user charge.
    
    
    Sec. 69.303  [Amended]
    
        24. Section 69.303 is amended by removing paragraph (a) and the 
    paragraph designation ``(b)''.
    
    
    Sec. 69.304  [Amended]
    
        25. Section 69.304 is amended by removing paragraph (c).
        26. Section 69.305 is amended by revising paragraphs (b) and (d), 
    and adding paragraph (e) to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 69.305  Carrier cable and wire facilities (C&WF).
    
    * * * * *
        (b) Carrier C&WF, other than WATS access lines, not assigned 
    pursuant to paragraph (a), (c), or (e) of this section that is used for 
    interexchange services that use switching facilities for origination 
    and termination that are also used for local exchange telephone service 
    shall be apportioned to the local Transport elements.
    * * * * *
        (d) All Carrier C&WF that is not apportioned pursuant to paragraphs 
    (a), (b), (c), and (e) of this section shall be assigned to the Special 
    Access element.
        (e) Carrier C&WF that is used to provide transmission between the 
    local exchange carrier's signalling transfer point and the local switch 
    shall be assigned to the local switching category.
        27-28. Section 69.306 is amended by revising paragraphs (c), (d), 
    and (e) to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 69.306  Central office equipment (COE).
    
    * * * * *
        (c) COE Category 2 (Tandem Switching Equipment) that is deemed to 
    be exchange equipment for purposes of the Modification of Final 
    Judgment in United States v. Western Electric Co. shall be assigned to 
    the tandem switching charge subelement and the interconnection charge 
    element. COE Category 2 which is associated with the signal transfer 
    point function shall be assigned to the local switching category. COE 
    Category 2 which is used to provide transmission facilities between the 
    local exchange carrier's signalling transfer point and the database 
    shall be assigned to the Line Information Database subelement at 
    Sec. 69.120(a). All other COE Category 2 shall be assigned to the 
    interexchange category.
        (d) COE Category 3 (Local Switching Equipment) shall be assigned to 
    the Local Switching element except as provided in paragraph (a) of this
    
    [[Page 31939]]
    
    section; and that, for telephone companies subject to price cap 
    regulation set forth in part 61 of this chapter, line-side port costs 
    shall be assigned to the Common Line rate element.
        (e) COE Category 4 (Circuit Equipment) shall be apportioned among 
    the interexchange category and the Common Line, Transport, and Special 
    Access elements. COE Category 4 shall be apportioned in the same 
    proportions as the associated Cable and Wireless Facilities; except 
    that any DS1/voice-grade multiplexer investment associated with analog 
    local switches and assigned to the local transport category by this 
    section shall be reallocated to the local switching category.
    
    
    Sec. 69.307  [Amended]
    
        29. Section 69.307 is amended by removing paragraph (c).
    
    
    Sec. 69.308  [Removed]
    
        30. Section 69.308 is removed.
        31. Section 69.309 is revised to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 69.309  Other investment.
    
        Investment that is not apportioned pursuant to Secs. 69.302 through 
    69.307 shall be apportioned among the interexchange category, the 
    billing and collection category and access elements in the same 
    proportions as the combined investment that is apportioned pursuant to 
    Secs. 69.303 through 69.307.
        32. Section 69.401 is amended by revising paragraph (b) to read as 
    follows:
    
    
    Sec. 69.401  Direct expenses.
    
    * * * * *
        (b) Plant Specific Operations Expenses in Accounts 6210, 6220, and 
    6230, shall be apportioned among the interexchange category and access 
    elements on the basis of the apportionment of the investment in 
    Accounts 2210, 2220, and 2230, respectively; provided that any expenses 
    associated with DS1/voice-grade multiplexers, to the extent that they 
    are not associated with an analog tandem switch, assigned to the local 
    transport category by this paragraph shall be reallocated to the local 
    switching category; provided further that any expenses associated with 
    common channel signalling included in Account 6210 shall be assigned to 
    the local transport category.
    * * * * *
    
    
    Sec. 69.406  [Amended]
    
        33. Section 69.406 is amended by removing paragraph (a)(9).
    
    
    Sec. 69.410  [Removed]
    
        34. Section 69.410 is removed.
        35. Section 69.411 is revised to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 69.411  Other expenses.
    
        Except as provided in Secs. 69.412, 69.413, and 69.414, expenses 
    that are not apportioned pursuant to Secs. 69.401 through 69.409 shall 
    be apportioned among the interexchange category and all access elements 
    in the same manner as Sec. 69.309 Other investment.
    
    
    Sec. 69.501  [Amended]
    
        36. Section 69.501 is amended by removing and reserving paragraph 
    (a).
        37. Section 69.502 is revised to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 69.502  Base factor allocation.
    
        Projected revenues from the following shall be deducted from the 
    base factor portion to determine the amount that is assigned to the 
    Carrier Common Line element:
        (a) End User Common Line charges, less any marketing expense 
    revenues recovered through end user common line charges pursuant to 
    Sec. 69.156;
        (b) Special Access surcharges; and
        (c) The portion of frozen per-line support that carriers receive 
    pursuant to Sec. 54.303 that is attributable to LTS payments received 
    prior to January 1, 1998.
    
    
    Sec. 69.611  [Removed]
    
        38. Section 69.611 is removed.
    
    [FR Doc. 97-14628 Filed 6-10-97; 8:45 am]
    BILLING CODE 6712-01-P