97-4538. Countervailing Duties  

  • [Federal Register Volume 62, Number 38 (Wednesday, February 26, 1997)]
    [Proposed Rules]
    [Pages 8818-8856]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 97-4538]
    
    
    
    [[Page 8817]]
    
    _______________________________________________________________________
    
    Part II
    
    
    
    
    
    Department of Commerce
    
    
    
    
    
    _______________________________________________________________________
    
    
    
    International Trade Administration
    
    
    
    _______________________________________________________________________
    
    
    
    19 CFR Part 351
    
    
    
    Countervailing Duties; Proposed Rule
    
    Federal Register / Vol. 62, No. 38 / Wednesday, February 26, 1997 / 
    Proposed Rules
    
    [[Page 8818]]
    
    
    
    DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE
    
    International Trade Administration
    
    19 CFR Part 351
    
    [Docket No. 950306068-6185-03]
    RIN 0625-AA45
    
    
    Countervailing Duties
    
    AGENCY: International Trade Administration, Department of Commerce.
    
    ACTION: Notice of proposed rulemaking and request for public comments.
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    SUMMARY: The Department of Commerce (``the Department'') proposes to 
    establish regulations to conform the Department's existing 
    countervailing duty regulations to the Uruguay Round Agreements Act, 
    which implemented the results of the Uruguay Round multilateral trade 
    negotiations. In addition to conforming changes, the Department has 
    sought to issue regulations that: (1) Where appropriate and feasible, 
    translate the principles of the implementing legislation into specific 
    and predictable rules, thereby facilitating the administration of these 
    laws and providing greater predictability for private parties affected 
    by these laws; (2) simplify and streamline the Department's 
    administration of countervailing duty proceedings in a manner 
    consistent with the purpose of the statute and the President's 
    regulatory principles; and (3) codify certain administrative practices 
    determined to be appropriate under the new statute and under the 
    President's Regulatory Reform Initiative.
    
    DATES: Written comments will be due on April 28, 1997.
    
    ADDRESSES: Address written comments to Robert S. LaRussa, Acting 
    Assistant Secretary for Import Administration, Central Records Unit, 
    Room 1870, U.S. Department of Commerce, Pennsylvania Avenue and 14th 
    Street, NW, Washington, DC 20230. Comments should be addressed: 
    Attention: Proposed Regulations/Uruguay Round Agreements Act--
    Countervailing Duties. Each person submitting a comment is requested to 
    include his or her name and address, and give reasons for any 
    recommendation.
    
    FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Jennifer A. Yeske at (202) 482-0189 or 
    Penelope Naas at (202) 482-3534.
    
    SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
    
    Background
    
        This notice, which deals with countervailing duty (``CVD'') 
    methodology, constitutes part of a larger process of developing 
    regulations under the Uruguay Round Agreements Act (``URAA''). The 
    process began when the Department took the unusual step of requesting 
    advance public comments in order to ensure that, at the earliest 
    possible stage, we could consider and take into account the views of 
    the private sector entities that are affected by the antidumping 
    (``AD'') and CVD laws. Following an extension of the comment period, on 
    May 11, 1995, the Department published interim-final rules that dealt 
    with a limited number of new or revised procedures resulting from the 
    URAA. On February 8, 1996, the Department published proposed rules 
    (``APO Regulations'') that, among other things, revised procedures 
    relating to administrative protective orders in AD and CVD proceedings. 
    Finally, on February 27, 1996, the Department published proposed rules 
    dealing with AD and CVD procedures and AD methodology (``AD Proposed 
    Regulations'').\1\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \1\ The prior notices published by the Department as part of its 
    URAA rulemaking activity are: (1) Advance Notice of Proposed 
    Rulemaking and Request for Public Comments (Antidumping Duties; 
    Countervailing Duties; Article 1904 of the North American Free Trade 
    Agreement), 60 FR 80 (Jan. 3, 1995); (2) Advance Notice of Proposed 
    Rulemaking; Extension of Comment Period (Antidumping Duties; 
    Countervailing Duties; Article 1904 of the North American Free Trade 
    Agreement), 60 FR 9802 (Feb. 22, 1995); (3) Interim Regulations; 
    Request for Comments ((Antidumping and Countervailing Duties), 60 FR 
    25130 (May 11, 1995); (4) Proposed Rule; Request for Comments 
    (Antidumping and Countervailing Duty Proceedings; Administrative 
    Protective Order Procedures; Procedures for Imposing Sanctions for 
    Violation of a Protective Order), 61 FR 4826 (Feb. 8, 1996); (5) 
    Notice of Proposed Rulemaking and Request for Public Comments 
    (Antidumping Duties; Countervailing Duties), 61 FR 7308 (February 
    27, 1996); (6) Extension of Deadline to File Public Comments on 
    Proposed Antidumping and Countervailing Duty Regulations and 
    Announcement of Public Hearing (Antidumping Duties; Countervailing 
    Duties), 61 FR 18122 (April 24, 1996); and Announcement of 
    Opportunity to File Public Comments on the Public Hearing of 
    Proposed Antidumping and Countervailing Duty Regulations 
    (Antidumping Duties; Countervailing Duties), 61 FR 28821 (June 6, 
    1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In these proposed regulations, the Department has continued to be 
    guided by the objectives described in the AD Proposed Regulations. 
    Specifically, these objectives are: (1) Conformity with the statutory 
    amendments made by the URAA; (2) the elaboration through regulation of 
    certain statements contained in the Statement of Administrative Action 
    (``SAA''); \2\ and (3) consistency with President Clinton's Regulatory 
    Reform Initiative and his directive to identify and eliminate obsolete 
    and burdensome regulations.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \2\ See, Statement of Administrative Action accompanying H.R. 
    5110 (H.R. Doc. No. 316, Vol. 1, 103d Cong., 2d Sess. (1994)).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In the case of CVD methodology, the Department's existing 
    ``regulations'' consist largely of the proposed regulations published 
    in 1989 (``1989 Proposed Regulations'').\3\ Because the Department 
    never issued final rules, the 1989 Proposed Regulations were not 
    binding on the Department or private parties. Nevertheless, to some 
    extent both the Department and private parties relied on the 1989 
    Proposed Regulations as a restatement of the Department's CVD 
    methodology as it existed at the time. Thus, notwithstanding statutory 
    amendments made by the URAA and subsequent developments in the 
    Department's administrative practice, the 1989 Proposed Regulations 
    still serve as a point of departure for any new regulations dealing 
    with CVD methodology.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \3\ See Notice of Proposed Rulemaking and Request for Public 
    Comments (Countervailing Duties), 54 FR 23366 (May 31, 1989).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As described in the AD Proposed Regulations, we have consolidated 
    the AD and CVD regulations into a single part 351. For the most part, 
    the regulations contained in this notice constitute subpart E of part 
    351. We anticipate that the consolidation of the AD and CVD regulations 
    will make the regulations easier to use and, by reducing their sheer 
    size, will make the regulations more accessible to the non-expert.
    
    Comments--In General
    
        The Department wishes to emphasize that the regulations contained 
    in this notice are proposed regulations only. While they reflect our 
    best judgment at this time regarding the appropriate style and content 
    of regulations dealing with CVD methodology, we remain open-minded on 
    the various issues raised herein. Therefore, we are very interested in 
    receiving public comment on these proposed regulations. We have found 
    the dialogue that commenced with the advance notice to be extremely 
    useful, and we hope and expect that it will continue.
    
    Comments--Format and Number of Copies
    
        Each person submitting a comment should include his or her name and 
    address, and give reasons for any recommendation. To facilitate their 
    consideration by the Department, comments regarding these proposed 
    regulations should be submitted in the following format: (1) Identify 
    each comment by reference to the section and/or paragraph of these 
    proposed
    
    [[Page 8819]]
    
    regulations to which the comment pertains; \4\ (2) begin each comment 
    on a separate page; (3) concisely state the issue identified and 
    discussed in the comment; and (4) provide a brief summary of the 
    comment (a maximum of 3 sentences) and label this section ``summary of 
    the comment.''
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \4\ If a comment does not pertain to a particular proposed 
    regulation, please clearly identify the comment as ``Other,'' 
    followed by a brief description of the issue to which the comment 
    pertains; e.g., ``Other--Infrastructure.''
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        To help simplify the processing and distribution of comments, the 
    Department encourages the submission of documents in electronic form 
    accompanied by an original and two copies in paper form. We request 
    that documents filed in electronic form be on DOS formatted 3.5'' 
    diskettes and prepared in either WordPerfect format or a format that 
    the WordPerfect program can convert and import into WordPerfect. Please 
    submit comments on a separate file on the diskette and identify each 
    comment in the manner described in the preceding paragraph.
        Comments received on diskette will be made available to the public 
    on the Internet at the following address: http://www.ita.doc.gov/
    import__admin/records/.
        In addition, the Department will make comments available to the 
    public on 3.5'' diskettes, with specific instructions for accessing 
    compressed data, at cost, and paper copies will be available for 
    reading and photocopying in Room B-099 of the Central Records Unit. Any 
    questions concerning file formatting, document conversion, access on 
    the Internet, or other file requirements should be addressed to Andrew 
    Lee Beller, Director of Central Records, (202) 482-0866.
    
    Explanation of the Proposed Rules
    
    Section 351.102
    
        These proposed regulations add several definitions to Sec. 351.102. 
    Many of these definitions are identical (or virtually identical) to 
    definitions contained in Sec. 355.41 of the 1989 Proposed Regulations, 
    and some are based on definitions contained in the Illustrative List of 
    Export Subsidies (``Illustrative List'') annexed to the Agreement on 
    Subsidies and Countervailing Measures (``SCM Agreement''). However, a 
    few definitions warrant comment.
        The definition of firm is based on Sec. 355.41(a) of the 1989 
    Proposed Regulations, but an additional clause has been added to 
    clarify that the purpose of this term is to serve as a shorthand 
    expression for the recipient of an alleged subsidy. While other terms 
    could be used, the use of the term ``firm'' in this manner has become 
    an accepted part of CVD nomenclature.
        Similarly, government-provided is used as a shorthand adjective to 
    distinguish the act or practice being analyzed as a possible 
    countervailable subsidy from the act or practice being used as a 
    benchmark. As made clear in the regulation, the use of ``government-
    provided'' does not mean that a subsidy must be provided directly by a 
    government.
        Loan is defined to include forms of debt financing other than what 
    one normally considers as a ``loan,'' such as bonds, overdrafts, etc. 
    Again, this definition is intended as a shorthand expression in order 
    to avoid repetitive use of more cumbersome phrases, such as ``loans or 
    other debt instruments.''
        In this regard, the Department considered codifying its approach 
    with respect to so-called ``hybrid instruments,'' financial instruments 
    that do not readily fall into the basic categories of grant, loan, or 
    equity. In the 1993 steel determinations, see Certain Cold-Rolled 
    Carbon Steel Flat Products from Austria (General Issues Appendix), 58 
    FR 37062, 37254 (``GIA''), the Department developed a hierarchical 
    approach for categorizing hybrid instruments, an approach that was 
    sustained in Geneva Steel v. United States, 914 F. Supp. 563 (Ct. Int'l 
    Trade 1996). However, notwithstanding this judicial imprimatur, the 
    Department has relatively little experience with hybrid instruments. 
    Therefore, although the Department has no present intention of 
    deviating from the approach set forth in the GIA, the codification of 
    this approach in the form of a regulation would be premature at this 
    time.
    
    Section 351.501
    
        Section 351.501 restates very generally the subject matter of 
    subpart E. To be a bit more specific, the arrangement of subpart E is 
    as follows. After dealing with the specificity of domestic subsidies in 
    Sec. 351.502, Secs. 351.503 through 351.512 deal with the 
    identification and measurement of various general types of subsidy 
    practices. Sections 351.513 through 351.519 focus on export subsidies, 
    incorporating the appropriate standards from the Illustrative List. 
    Section 351.520 deals with general export promotion activities of 
    governments. Sections 351.521 through 351.523 deal with import 
    substitution subsidies (currently designated as ``Reserved''), certain 
    agricultural subsidies, and upstream subsidies, respectively. Section 
    351.524 sets forth rules regarding the calculation of an ad valorem 
    subsidy rate and the attribution of a subsidy to a product. Finally, 
    Secs. 351.525 through 351.527 contain rules regarding program-wide 
    changes, transnational subsidies, and the tax consequences of benefits, 
    respectively.
        The last sentence of Sec. 351.501 acknowledges that subpart E does 
    not address every possible type of subsidy practice. However, the same 
    sentence provides that in dealing with alleged subsidies that are not 
    expressly covered by these regulations, the Secretary will be guided by 
    the underlying principles of the Act and subpart E.
        In this regard, the Act and the SCM Agreement serve to eliminate 
    much of the confusion and controversy surrounding the necessary 
    elements of a countervailable subsidy. First, under section 771(5)(B) 
    of the Act and Article 1.1(a) (1) and (2) of the SCM Agreement, there 
    must be a financial contribution that a government provides either 
    directly or indirectly, or an income or price support in the sense of 
    Article XVI of GATT 1994. Although the precise parameters will have to 
    be determined on a case-by-case basis, this element provides a 
    framework for analysis that was previously missing.
        Second, under section 771(5)(B) and Article 1.1(b) of the SCM 
    Agreement, the financial contribution (or income or price support) must 
    confer a benefit. Although the concept of a ``benefit to the 
    recipient'' is not new to U.S. CVD law, in some cases the meaning of 
    this concept had become obscured. The new law clarifies this concept 
    and eliminates any possibility of confusing the ``benefit'' of a 
    subsidy with the ``effect'' of a subsidy. In particular, section 
    771(5)(E) of the Act and Article 14 of the SCM Agreement, through their 
    description of the various standards (or ``benchmarks'') used to 
    identify and measure the benefits attributable to different types of 
    subsidy practices, make clear that a benefit is conferred when a firm 
    pays less for its ``inputs'' than it otherwise would pay in the absence 
    of the government-provided input or earns more than it otherwise would 
    earn. For example, when the amount that a firm pays on a government-
    provided loan is less than what the firm ``would pay on a comparable 
    commercial loan that the (firm) could actually obtain on the market,'' 
    the firm's cost of borrowing money is reduced. See section 
    771(5)(E)(ii) of the Act. Similarly, when a firm sells its goods to the 
    government and ``such goods are purchased for more than adequate 
    remuneration,'' the firm's revenues are increased beyond what it would 
    otherwise earn. See section
    
    [[Page 8820]]
    
    771(5)(E)(iv) of the Act. In neither instance need the Department do 
    more than apply the test enumerated by the statute in order to find 
    that a benefit has been conferred.
        In this regard, when we talk about a firm paying less for its 
    inputs than it otherwise would pay (or receiving more revenues than it 
    otherwise would earn), we are referring to the lower price it pays to 
    acquire the thing provided by the government, i.e., money, a good, or a 
    service. We do not mean to suggest, as has sometimes been argued, that 
    one must consider the overall impact of government actions on a firm in 
    determining whether a particular government action confers a benefit. 
    Neither the statute nor the SCM Agreement supports such an analysis.
        For example, assume that a government puts in place new 
    environmental requirements that require a firm to purchase new 
    equipment to adapt its facilities. Assume also that the government 
    provides the firm with subsidies to purchase that new equipment, but 
    the subsidies do not fully offset the total increase in the firm's 
    costs; i.e., the net effect of the new environmental requirements and 
    the subsidies leaves the firm with costs that are higher than they 
    previously were.
        In this situation, section 771(5B)(D) of the Act, which deals with 
    one form of non-countervailable subsidy, makes clear that a subsidy 
    exists. Section 771(5B)(D) treats the imposition of new environmental 
    requirements and the subsidization of compliance with those 
    requirements as two separate actions. A subsidy that reduces a firm's 
    cost of compliance remains a subsidy (subject, of course, to the 
    statute's remaining tests for countervailability), even though the 
    overall effect of the two government actions, taken together, may leave 
    the firm with higher costs.
        Thus, if there is a financial contribution and a firm pays less for 
    an input than it otherwise would pay in the absence of that financial 
    contribution (or receives revenues beyond the amount it otherwise would 
    earn), that is the end of the inquiry insofar as the benefit element is 
    concerned. The Department need not consider how a firm's behavior is 
    altered when it receives a financial contribution that lowers its input 
    costs or increases its revenues.
        If there were any doubt on this score, section 771(5)(C) of the Act 
    eliminates it by clarifying that the ``benefit'' and the ``effect'' of 
    a subsidy are two different things. While, as stated above, there must 
    be a benefit in order for a subsidy to exist, section 771(5)(C) 
    expressly provides that the Department ``is not required to consider 
    the effect of a subsidy in determining whether a subsidy exists.'' This 
    message is driven home by the SAA at 256, which states that ``the new 
    definition of subsidy does not require that Commerce consider or 
    analyze the effect (including whether there is any effect at all) of a 
    government action on the price or output of the class or kind of 
    merchandise under investigation or review.''
        As stated above, a benefit exists where a firm pays less for an 
    input than it otherwise would pay in the absence of the financial 
    contribution (or receives revenues beyond the amount it otherwise would 
    earn). By the same token, where a firm does not pay less for an input 
    than it otherwise would pay (or its revenues are not increased) as a 
    result of a financial contribution, it would be very difficult to 
    contend that a benefit exists. However, we have not closed our minds 
    here and we would welcome comment on this issue.
        Finally, under section 771(5)(A) of the Act and Article 1.2 of the 
    SCM Agreement, a subsidy must be specific in order to be 
    countervailable. The ``specificity test'' is discussed in more detail 
    below, but we note here that by clarifying the purpose of the 
    specificity test and the manner in which it is to be applied, the URAA, 
    the SAA and the SCM Agreement should serve to reduce the volume of 
    litigation concerning this heavily litigated issue.
        Regarding the coverage of subpart E, we should note two topics that 
    are not addressed by these regulations: indirect subsidies (with the 
    exception of upstream subsidies) and privatization. The topic of 
    ``indirect subsidies'' refers generally to situations where a 
    government provides a financial contribution through a private body, 
    and involves the application of section 771(5)(B)(iii) of the Act. 
    Several comments were received on this topic, including particular 
    suggestions regarding the possible contents of a regulation. Although 
    the issues raised by the commenters are important ones, we are not 
    addressing them at this time. We note that the legislative history 
    clearly calls for the Department to proceed on a case-by-case basis. 
    See SAA at 255-56. Our decision not to address these comments serves, 
    in part, to preserve this flexibility and discretion, and allows us the 
    opportunity to request comments specifically pertaining to the factors 
    we should consider in making our case-by-case determinations.
        The topic of privatization typically involves situations where 
    ownership of a government-owned firm is transferred to a private 
    entity. Privatization raises the question of the extent to which 
    previously bestowed subsidies which are allocated over time remain 
    countervailable after the privatization, and involves the application 
    of section 771(5)(F) of the Act, the new section in the URAA addressing 
    this subject.
        In these proposed regulations, we have not included a provision 
    dealing with privatization. However, we are evaluating whether a 
    regulation on this topic is appropriate. Therefore, in the discussion 
    that follows, we describe and discuss certain issues that we believe 
    are raised by section 771(5)(F). We begin with a review of the methods 
    we have used to date for addressing prior subsidies and privatization. 
    We then turn to the new legislation.
    
    Agency Practice
    
        Although there were earlier administrative precedents, the recent 
    history of the privatization issue began in January 1993, with the 
    Department's final CVD determinations in the Lead and Bismuth cases 
    (see, in particular, Certain Hot-rolled Lead and Bismuth Carbon Steel 
    Products from the United Kingdom, 58 FR 6237). In those determinations, 
    the Department ruled that the sale of a firm (or a ``productive unit'' 
    of a firm), even if at arm's length, does not alter the 
    countervailability of previously bestowed subsidies. The Department 
    reasoned that it ``does not examine the impact of subsidies on 
    particular assets or tie the benefit level of subsidies to changes in 
    the company under investigation. Therefore, it follows that when a 
    company sells a productive unit, the sale does nothing to alter the 
    subsidies enjoyed by that productive unit.'' Id., at 6240.
        In the July 1993 final CVD determinations in the Certain Steel 
    cases, the Department modified the approach taken in the Lead and 
    Bismuth cases. The Department concluded that once a subsidy is 
    bestowed, the Act precludes a reevaluation of the amount or 
    countervailability of a subsidy based on subsequent events, such as a 
    change in the ownership of a firm. The Department stated: 
    ``Accordingly, whether subsidies convey a demonstrable competitive 
    benefit upon recipients, in the year of receipt or any subsequent year, 
    is irrelevant--the statute embodies the irrebutable presumption that 
    subsidies confer a countervailable benefit upon goods produced by their 
    recipients.'' The Department further ruled that ``a private party 
    purchasing all or part of a government-owned company (e.g., a 
    productive unit) can repay prior subsidies on behalf of the company as
    
    [[Page 8821]]
    
    part or all of the sales price.'' GIA at 37262. Put differently, a 
    portion of previously bestowed subsidies might not ``travel to a new 
    home'' depending on the price paid for a firm by the buyer.
        To determine the amount of previously bestowed subsidies that pass 
    through to the privatized firm, the Department developed a repayment 
    method. Under that method, the Department determines the amount of 
    subsidies repaid based on a ratio of the privatized firm's subsidies to 
    the firm's net worth over a period of time. Subsidies that are not 
    repaid continue to benefit the merchandise produced by the privatized 
    firm. Id., at 37263. Only non-recurring subsidies (i.e., subsidies 
    allocated over time) are included in the pass through and repayment 
    calculations.
    
    New Law
    
        In June, 1994, the U.S. Court of International Trade (``CIT'') 
    overturned the Department's determinations in the Lead and Bismuth 
    cases. In Inland Steel Bar Co. v. United States, 858 F. Supp. 179, 
    rev'd, 86 F.3d 1174 (Fed. Cir. 1996) (``Inland''), and Saarstahl AG v. 
    United States, 858 F. Supp. 187, rev'd, 78 F.3d 1539 (Fed. Cir. 1996) 
    (``Saarstahl''), the CIT declared the Department's privatization 
    methodology to be unlawful ``to the extent it states previously 
    bestowed subsidies are passed through to a successor company sold in an 
    arm's length transaction.'' This decision meant that if a firm is 
    privatized in an arm's length transaction, previously bestowed 
    subsidies are extinguished.
        When the CIT issued its decisions in Inland and Saarstahl, the 
    Administration and Congress were in the process of drafting, under 
    ``fast track'' procedures, H.R. 5110, the bill that ultimately would 
    become the URAA. As of June 1994, the draft CVD legislation did not 
    contain any provisions that dealt expressly with the issue of 
    privatization, and no such provisions were contemplated. However, 
    following the CIT's decisions, a new provision was added that became 
    section 771(5)(F) of the Act.
        As enacted, section 771(5)(F) provides as follows:
    
        Change in ownership.--A change in the ownership of all or part 
    of a foreign enterprise or the productive assets of a foreign 
    enterprise does not by itself require a determination by the 
    (Department) that a past countervailable subsidy received by the 
    enterprise no longer continues to be countervailable, even if the 
    change in ownership is accomplished through an arm's length 
    transaction.
    
        The SAA at 928 offered the following explanation of section 
    771(5)(F):
    
        Section 771(5)(F) provides that a change in the ownership of 
    ``all or part of a foreign enterprise'' (i.e., a firm or a division 
    of a firm) or the productive assets of a firm, even if accomplished 
    through an arm's-length transaction, does not by itself require 
    Commerce to find that past countervailable subsidies received by the 
    firm no longer continue to be countervailable. For purposes of 
    section 771(5)(F), the term ``arm's-length transaction'' means a 
    transaction negotiated between unrelated parties, each acting in its 
    own interest, or between related parties such that the terms of the 
    transaction are those that would exist if the transaction had been 
    negotiated between unrelated parties.
        Section 771(5)(F) is being added to clarify that the sale of a 
    firm at arm's length does not automatically, and in all cases, 
    extinguish any prior subsidies conferred. Absent this clarification, 
    some might argue that all that would be required to eliminate any 
    countervailing duty liability would be to sell subsidized productive 
    assets to an unrelated party. Consequently, it is imperative that 
    the implementing bill correct and prevent such an extreme 
    interpretation.
        The issue of the privatization of a state-owned firm can be 
    extremely complex and multifaceted. While it is the Administration's 
    intent that Commerce retain the discretion to determine whether, and 
    to what extent, the privatization of a government-owned firm 
    eliminates any previously conferred countervailable subsidies, 
    Commerce must exercise this discretion carefully through its 
    consideration of the facts of each case and its determination of the 
    appropriate methodology to be applied.
    
        In addition to this passage in the SAA, the Senate Report on the 
    URAA stated as follows:
    
        The Committee believes that this provision serves the important 
    purpose of making clear that the sale of a firm at ``arm's length'' 
    does not automatically extinguish any previously-conferred 
    subsidies. New section 771(5)(F) stands in contrast to such an 
    interpretation, which would result in an end to the 
    countervailability of prior subsidies otherwise allocable to the 
    merchandise. The sale of subsidized goods or assets to an unrelated 
    party should not in and of itself permit the avoidance of duties. 
    The Commerce Department should continue to have the discretion to 
    determine whether, and to what extent (if any), actions such as the 
    ``privatization'' of a government-owned company actually serve to 
    eliminate such subsidies. It is the Committee's expectation that 
    Commerce will exercise this discretion carefully and make its 
    determination based on the facts of each case, developing a 
    methodology consistent with the principles of the countervailing 
    duty statute.
    
    S. Rep. No. 412, 103d Cong., 2d Sess. 92 (1994).
    
    Approach Under the New Law
    
        Based on our reading of section 771(5)(F) and the legislative 
    history of that provision, we believe that the new law overturns the 
    approach adopted by the CIT in Inland and Saarstahl, i.e., that an 
    arm's length transaction, in and of itself, is sufficient to extinguish 
    prior subsidies. We would further note that in March, 1996, the Court 
    of Appeals for the Federal Circuit reversed the CIT's decision, holding 
    that ``the [CIT] erred in holding that as a matter of law a subsidy 
    cannot be passed through during an arm's length transaction'' 
    (Saarstahl, AG v. United States, 78 F.3d 1539, 1544). Hence, under the 
    pre- and post-URAA statute, the Department's position is that even if a 
    privatization is accomplished by means of an arm's length transaction, 
    previously bestowed subsidies are not automatically, and in all cases, 
    extinguished.
        By the same token, it has been suggested that the language in the 
    SAA and the Senate Report directing Commerce to consider ``the facts of 
    each case'' in determining whether and to what extent privatization of 
    a government-owned firm eliminates any previously conferred subsidies 
    may preclude an approach whereby all prior subsidies would 
    automatically, and in all cases, be passed through to the privatized 
    company.
        Instead of establishing automatic rules in determining the extent 
    to which prior subsidies pass through or are extinguished by 
    privatization, a more flexible approach would be to examine a broad 
    array of factors specific to the individual case. This may include 
    examining the circumstances surrounding the privatization transaction, 
    as well as the impact of prior subsidies on current market conditions.
        Having said this, however, we do not believe that Congress intended 
    that the Department's privatization determinations be made on an ad hoc 
    basis. As stated in the Senate Report, it was expected that the 
    Department would develop ``a methodology consistent with the principles 
    of the countervailing duty statute.'' S. Rep. No. 412, 103d Cong., 2d 
    Sess. 92 (1994). Thus, the question to which we now turn is what facts 
    would be relevant to determining the effect that a change in ownership 
    has on previously bestowed subsidies.
        One starting point for consideration of the appropriate approach 
    under the new law is the method previously adopted by the Department. 
    As discussed above, we have recognized that privatization has some 
    impact on previously bestowed subsidies and have employed a repayment 
    formula to determine the extent to which those subsidies pass through 
    to the privatized firm. We have indicated in recent cases our position
    
    [[Page 8822]]
    
    that the repayment method is permissible under the new law (see, in 
    particular, Certain Hot-rolled Lead and Bismuth Carbon Steel Products 
    from the United Kingdom; Final Results of Countervailing Duty 
    Administrative Review, 61 FR 58377, 58379. Some have questioned the 
    Department's method for calculating the amount of repayment. For 
    example, in computing the share of the sales price that repays past 
    subsidies, the Department averages several years data on subsidies and 
    the net worth of the firm.
         Should this average be weighted to give greater weight to 
    the years immediately preceding the privatization? Or, should the 
    average be abandoned and replaced with information on subsidies and net 
    worth at the time of privatization?
         Are there other ways of determining whether repayment has 
    occurred (e.g., whether repayment must be made by the firm as opposed 
    to the purchasers of the firm) and are there more accurate means of 
    calculating such repayment?
        Besides the facts that are relevant to the repayment method 
    discussed above, there may be a number of considerations that should be 
    evaluated in determining the extent to which previously bestowed 
    subsidies are extinguished or passed through by means of privatization. 
    For example, while the new statutory provision rules out the 
    possibility that an arm's length transaction, in and of itself, is 
    sufficient to extinguish past subsidies in all cases, it leaves open 
    the question of what importance (if any) we should assign to the fact 
    that a privatization does or does not occur at arm's length.
         Should the arm's length criterion alter the extent to 
    which the Department considers previously bestowed subsidies to be 
    countervailable with respect to merchandise produced by the privatized 
    firm? Under the methodology currently applied by the Department, the 
    presence or absence of an arm's length transaction does not affect our 
    repayment calculation.
         In situations where the privatization transaction is not 
    an arm's length transaction, is it more likely that prior subsidies 
    pass through to the privatized company, or that a larger amount of the 
    prior subsidies pass through? What factors would determine the extent, 
    if any, to which prior subsidies pass through?
         Is it necessary for a privatization to be an arm's length 
    transaction before the Department could even consider that previously 
    bestowed subsidies are extinguished by the privatization? Conversely, 
    if the privatization transaction is not at arm's length, should the 
    Department even consider that any previously bestowed subsidies could 
    have been extinguished?
         Under what circumstances and what privatization techniques 
    does the transaction give rise to new subsidies to the purchasers? 
    Would these new subsidies be in addition to any prior subsidies that 
    pass through to the purchaser?
        In addition to considering whether the privatization is an arm's 
    length transaction, there may be other circumstances of the 
    privatization transaction relevant to determining the extent to which 
    previously bestowed subsidies pass through to the privatized firm. For 
    example, it has been argued that when the privatization process occurs 
    in a competitive market setting, the purchasers may be paying the full 
    value of the company, including the current value of any previously 
    bestowed subsidies.
         Can a competitive market setting, in and of itself, 
    extinguish past subsidies? Under what circumstances would this occur?
         What elements might give rise to a competitive market 
    setting and what is the relevance of those elements in determining the 
    extent to which prior subsidies are passed through.
         Is it important to look at the nature of the auction, 
    public stock offering, or other type of sale of the firm, including the 
    number of bidders? Where there are few bidders, would it be important 
    to consider whether the privatizing government placed restriction on 
    who could purchase the company (e.g., whether certain classes of buyers 
    were precluded from participating)?
         Is it important that the privatization be carried out in 
    an open, transparent manner? What elements might be important to this 
    consideration?
         What role should independent valuations of the firm (e.g., 
    valuations by independent auditors) play? What if the winning bid for 
    the firm being privatized was less than the value established in 
    independent assessments?
         Given that equity markets may be more advanced in some 
    countries than in others, should the Department account for the effect 
    of the state of market development on the competitive bid process?
         Does the method of payment matter? For example, if the 
    seller accepts debt or vouchers as payment for the privatized firm, 
    should that be viewed differently than accepting cash?
        Beyond these circumstances relating to the mechanics of the 
    privatization transaction are events leading up to the privatization. 
    These might include actions taken by the government to make the firm 
    more attractive to potential purchasers. For example, the government 
    might forgive debt owed to it by the firm in order to ``clean up the 
    balance sheet.'' Or, the government may undertake the expense of 
    closing certain inefficient operations and sell off only the more 
    modern plants.
         Are these types of actions taken in anticipation of 
    privatization relevant to a determination of whether subsidies pass 
    through to the privatized firm?
         Should such actions be separated from what would otherwise 
    be considered ``prior'' subsidies in determining the extent to which 
    subsidies pass through or are extinguished?
        Similarly, the government may impose post-privatization 
    restrictions on the privatized firm. For example, the new owners may be 
    required to produce particular goods or services, to operate in 
    particular locations, to purchase particular supplies from particular 
    suppliers, to retain a certain number of workers or to undertake a 
    certain level of investment in the privatized firm. Or, government 
    restrictions on the privatized firm may take the form of a ``golden 
    share'' whereby the government retains the right to make decisions 
    about the certain specified operations of the firm, although ownership 
    and control has otherwise passed to the new owners.
         Should these types of conditions on the sale be considered 
    in determining whether, and the extent to which, prior subsidies pass 
    through?
        It has also been argued that certain government-owned companies 
    benefit from government preferences, be it through low, government-
    guaranteed input prices or preferential access to government-controlled 
    credit.
         Should the Department be concerned with whether the 
    privatized firm will continue to benefit from such preferences? Or, 
    would it be necessary for the government to eliminate the preferences 
    before privatization?
        Finally, the issue has been raised that in the privatization 
    scenarios typically encountered by the Department, excess global 
    capacity exists because one or more foreign governments have created or 
    maintained productive assets that would not exist in the absence of 
    government subsidization. Because of this, some would argue, even if 
    the buyer of a firm pays a market price, the prior subsidies to the 
    privatized company result in an unfairly low price being received for 
    the firm.
         In a situation where subsidies have led to the creation of 
    excess capacity (thereby lowering the market price for
    
    [[Page 8823]]
    
    the firm being privatized), are those facts relevant to determining 
    whether and to what extent the prior subsidies pass through to the 
    privatized firm?
         How would the Department determine that excess global 
    capacity has been created? How would excess capacity be defined and 
    measured?
         It has also been argued that if excess capacity created by 
    subsidies is relevant to the issue of privatization, then reductions to 
    capacity made possible by subsidies should also be relevant. What 
    relevance should the nature of the subsidy (i.e., whether it 
    contributes to or reduces capacity) have in determining whether and to 
    what extent prior subsidies pass through to the privatized firm?
    
    Conclusion
    
        These lines of inquiry are consistent with section 771(5)(F) and 
    with the recognition in the SAA, at 928, that the privatization issue 
    ``can be extremely complex and multifaceted.''
        In addition, it is consistent with the emphasis in both the SAA and 
    the Senate Report on the importance of considering the facts of 
    individual cases. We wish to emphasize that our list is not meant to be 
    all-inclusive and we invite commenters to offer their views on other 
    factors they consider to be relevant. Also, commenters should explain 
    how these factors would be incorporated into a framework for analyzing 
    privatizations and calculating subsidies to privatized firms.
        We further invite comment on whether we should attempt to 
    promulgate a final rule on the topic of privatization and what that 
    rule might look like. Regarding the latter question, commenters are 
    invited to address whether precise formulae should be used to determine 
    the extent to which, if any, prior subsidies pass through or whether a 
    case-by-case approach integrating some or all of the considerations 
    identified in this preamble should be adopted. Commenters may want to 
    address whether a formulaic approach could be developed that would be 
    sufficiently comprehensive to account for special circumstances, or 
    whether a formulaic approach would be undesirably rigid. Commenters may 
    also want to address the consequences of the uncertainty resulting from 
    a case-by-case approach.
        In conclusion, we would like to repeat that the Department is 
    carefully considering whether to issue a final regulation on the 
    subject of privatization. To that end, the foregoing discussion is 
    intended to stimulate, rather than foreclose, further thinking on this 
    topic. We appreciate the comments that have been submitted on this 
    topic thus far, and the fact that we may not have identified a 
    particular suggestion should not be construed as an indication that we 
    have rejected the suggestion.
    
    Section 351.502
    
        Section 351.502 deals with the ``specificity'' of domestic 
    subsidies. Unlike its predecessor, Sec. 355.43 of the 1989 Proposed 
    Regulations, Sec. 351.502 does not contain a ``general'' specificity 
    test. This is due to the fact that section 771(5A) of the Act and the 
    SAA provide much more detail and clarity regarding the application of 
    the ``specificity test'' than did the prior statute and its legislative 
    history. Thus, on the subject of specificity, there are far fewer 
    interpretative gaps for the Department to fill in than there were in 
    1989, and, thus, less need for regulations. Accordingly, Sec. 351.502 
    deals with certain aspects of the specificity test that are not 
    addressed expressly in the statute or the SAA.
        Paragraph (a) is based on Sec. 355.43(b)(8) of the 1989 Proposed 
    Regulations, and continues to provide that the Secretary will not 
    consider a subsidy as being specific merely because it is limited to 
    the agricultural sector. Instead, as under prior practice, the 
    Secretary will find an agricultural subsidy to be countervailable only 
    if it is specific within the agricultural sector; e.g., a subsidy is 
    limited to livestock, or livestock receives disproportionately large 
    amounts of the subsidy. See Lamb Meat from New Zealand, 50 FR 37708, 
    37711 (1985).
        One commenter suggested that the Department should abandon the 
    special specificity rule for agricultural subsidies, citing the fact 
    that under section 771(5B)(F) of the Act and Article 13(a) of the WTO 
    Agreement on Agriculture, so-called ``green box'' agricultural 
    subsidies are non-countervailable. With respect to this comment, we 
    note that the Department's application of the specificity test to 
    agricultural subsidies was upheld in Roses, Inc. v. United States, 774 
    F. Supp. 1376 (Ct. Int'l Trade 1991). In light of this judicial 
    affirmance, and given the absence of any indication that Congress 
    intended to change the Department's practice or overturn Roses, we are 
    retaining the special specificity rule for agricultural subsidies.
        Paragraph (b) is based on Sec. 355.43(b)(7) of the 1989 Proposed 
    Regulations, and continues to provide that the Secretary will not 
    consider a subsidy as being specific merely because it is limited to 
    small or small-and medium-sized firms. Instead, as under prior 
    practice, the Secretary will find such a subsidy to be countervailable 
    if, either on a de jure or a de facto basis, the subsidy is limited to 
    certain small or small-and medium-sized firms. As in the case of the 
    special specificity rule for agricultural subsidies, there is no 
    indication that Congress intended to alter this aspect of the 
    Department's specificity practice.
        Paragraph (c) provides that the Secretary will not regard disaster 
    relief as a specific subsidy if the relief constitutes general 
    assistance available to anyone in the affected area. Although paragraph 
    (c) has no counterpart in the 1989 Proposed Regulations, the rule 
    contained in paragraph (c) has been part of the Department's 
    specificity practice since Certain Steel Products from Italy, 47 FR 
    39356, 39360 (1982), in which the Department stated that ``[d]isaster 
    relief is not selective in the same manner as other regional programs 
    since there is no predetermination of eligible areas and no part of the 
    country, and no industry, is excluded from eligibility in principle.'' 
    However, before declaring a subsidy to be non-specific under paragraph 
    (c), the Department would have to be satisfied that the subsidy in 
    question was, in fact, bona fide disaster relief. See Certain Steel 
    Products from Italy, 58 FR 37327, 37332 (1993).
        The Department received several comments regarding the issue of 
    specificity, most of which had to do with the specificity of domestic 
    subsidies. For ease of discussion, we have divided these comments up by 
    sub-issue.
    
    Purpose of the specificity test
    
        Some commenters requested that the Department restate in the 
    regulations the policy rationale behind the specificity test. According 
    to these commenters, the underlying purpose of the specificity test is 
    to identify those domestic subsidies that confer a competitive 
    advantage and thereby distort international trade. Other commenters 
    pointed out that the new statute expressly states that the Department 
    is not required to examine the effects of a subsidy or establish that 
    the subsidy has any effect at all. These commenters, citing the 
    reference to the Carlisle decision in the SAA, maintain that the sole 
    purpose of the specificity test is to ``winnow out those foreign 
    subsidies which are truly broadly available and widely used throughout 
    the economy.'' SAA at 259-260, citing Carlisle Tire & Rubber Co. versus 
    United States, 564 F. Supp. 834 (Ct. Int'l Trade 1983).
        In our view, the language from the SAA cited above makes the 
    purpose of
    
    [[Page 8824]]
    
    the specificity test abundantly clear. Given the clarity of the SAA on 
    this point, the authoritative nature of the SAA (see section 102(d) of 
    the URAA), and our general reluctance to issue regulations that merely 
    repeat the statute or the SAA, we do not consider it appropriate to 
    issue a regulation that restates the purpose of the specificity test.
    
    Use of Presumptions
    
        Two commenters suggested that in applying the specificity test, the 
    Department should employ certain presumptions. One commenter maintained 
    that the Department should presume that domestic subsidy programs are 
    specific, and that the burden should be on respondent interested 
    parties to prove otherwise. The second commenter stated that, for each 
    domestic subsidy program under investigation, the Department should 
    request information concerning applications and approvals made since 
    the inception of the program. In the absence of such information, 
    according to this commenter, the Department should presume that the 
    foreign government in question exercises discretion in the 
    administration of the program, and that the program is specific. 
    Similarly, when the Department is analyzing newly instituted programs 
    with few users, it should employ a rebuttable presumption that the 
    program is specific. Both commenters made the point that information 
    regarding the distribution of program benefits normally is not 
    available to a petitioner prior to the filing of a petition.
        Other commenters argued that there is no legal basis for making 
    such presumptions. With respect to de facto specificity, for example, 
    the SAA states that the Department is obligated to ``seek and 
    consider'' information relevant to each of the four factors listed in 
    section 771(5A)(D)(iii) of the Act. SAA at 261. One of these commenters 
    also asserted that a petitioner alleging that a subsidy is specific 
    should be required to provide a reasonable amount of information 
    supporting the allegation.
        As was true under the old law, a petitioner that includes a 
    domestic subsidy in a petition must provide reasonably available 
    information supporting the specificity allegation. See section 702(c) 
    of the Act. On the other hand, the Department recognizes that because 
    detailed information regarding the distribution of program benefits 
    usually is either not published or is not widely available, it often is 
    not reasonably available to a petitioner at the time a petition is 
    filed. Therefore, in deciding whether to include alleged domestic 
    subsidies in its investigation, the Department carefully considers the 
    information the petitioner has put forward, the reasons why more 
    information may not be available, and any arguments the petitioner 
    makes regarding the specificity of the program. Because the types of 
    allegations and information available will vary from case-to-case, it 
    is not possible to state a general rule for accepting or rejecting 
    specificity allegations. However, we believe that the threshold we have 
    used in the past for including alleged subsidies in CVD investigations 
    has been sufficient to ensure that all potentially countervailable 
    subsidies are investigated. We intend to continue employing this 
    initiation threshold.
        Where domestic subsidy programs are included in an investigation, 
    the Department will not presume the program is specific. Instead, the 
    Department will seek in its questionnaire all of the information 
    necessary to apply the specificity test according to section 771(5A)(D) 
    of the Act. Based on its analysis of the information provided in the 
    questionnaire responses, verification, and other information that may 
    be collected, the Department will make the necessary specificity 
    determination. If a respondent refuses to provide the information 
    requested by the Department to conduct its specificity analysis, the 
    Department may draw adverse inferences in the application of the 
    ``facts available.'' See section 776(b) of the Act. However, the use of 
    an adverse inference in these situations is not the same thing as 
    relying on a rebuttable presumption.
    
    Sequential Analysis
    
        Some commenters argued that the Department should codify the 
    ``sequential approach'' to specificity. Under the sequential approach, 
    as reflected in the 1989 Proposed Regulations, if a subsidy was de jure 
    specific or met any one of the enumerated de facto specificity factors, 
    further analysis was unnecessary and was not undertaken. In support of 
    their position, these commenters emphasized the language contained in 
    both section 771(5A)(D)(iii) of the Act and the SAA that a subsidy will 
    be considered specific ``if one or more'' of the factors exist. SAA at 
    261. Furthermore, these commenters noted, the SAA and the legislative 
    history of the URAA make clear that the specificity test was intended 
    to be generally consistent with the Department's previous practice, a 
    practice that included the sequential approach. SAA at 259; S. Rep. No. 
    412, 103d Cong., 2d Sess. 93-94 (1994). Finally, these commenters cited 
    the legislative history of the North American Free Trade Agreement 
    (NAFTA) as endorsing the sequential approach.
        In opposition to this view, other commenters maintained that the 
    sequential approach contradicts the SAA, because the SAA states that 
    the Department will ``seek and consider information relevant'' to all 
    four of the de facto specificity factors. SAA at 261. Moreover, these 
    commenters maintained, the language in the SCM Agreement requires that 
    all of the de facto specificity factors be considered and that any 
    specificity determination ``shall be clearly substantiated on the basis 
    of positive evidence.'' Articles 2.1(c) and 2.4 of the SCM Agreement.
        We believe that the Act and the SAA are sufficiently clear that, 
    with the exception of the government discretion factor, the Department 
    may find a domestic subsidy to be specific based on the presence of a 
    single de facto specificity factor. Therefore, while the Department 
    will continue its practice of collecting information regarding each of 
    the four de facto specificity factors, our analysis of the issue will 
    stop if the Secretary determines that a single factor justifies a 
    finding of specificity. As for the SCM Agreement, none of the 
    provisions cited precludes a finding of specificity based on the 
    presence of a single factor.
        In this regard, however, the Department does not agree that a 
    finding of specificity automatically may be based solely on the fact 
    that some measure of discretion may have been exercised in the 
    administration of a subsidy program. Indeed, such an approach would be 
    inconsistent with the purpose of the specificity test, as articulated 
    in Carlisle. If a subsidy program is broadly available and widely used 
    and there is no evidence of dominant or disproportionate use, the mere 
    fact that government officials may have exercised discretion in 
    administering the program is insufficient to justify a finding of 
    specificity. SAA at 261.
        Based on our experience in administering the CVD law, some measure 
    of administrative discretion exists in the operation of almost every 
    alleged subsidy program. At the most basic level, an administrator of a 
    program typically must exercise judgment (i.e., discretion) in 
    evaluating the facts of an application for a subsidy to determine 
    whether the applicant qualifies for the subsidy. If we were to find 
    specificity based simply on the exercise of this type of discretion, 
    the
    
    [[Page 8825]]
    
    other de facto factors would become practically meaningless, because 
    virtually every subsidy program in the world could be declared specific 
    on the basis of the discretion factor alone. This would produce the 
    very sort of absurd results warned against in Carlisle.
        As indicated in the SAA at 261, the discretion factor is generally 
    more valuable as an analytical tool that enhances the analysis of the 
    other de facto specificity factors and criteria. For example, in the 
    case of a new subsidy program for which there have been few applicants 
    and few recipients, the Department must make a judgment as to the 
    likely future distribution of benefits under the program. The manner in 
    which authorities have exercised their discretion in the early days of 
    a new program would inform the Department in making this type of 
    judgment. See SAA at 261.
    
    Purposeful Government Action
    
        Some commenters, citing such cases as Saudi Iron and Steel Co. 
    (Hadeed) v. United States, 675 F. Supp. 1362, 1367 (Ct Int'l Trade 
    1987), maintained that a finding of specificity does not require a 
    finding of targeting or some other sort of purposeful government action 
    that limits the number of subsidy program beneficiaries. In a similar 
    vein, they cited the statute and its legislative history for the 
    proposition that the fact that program usage may be limited by the 
    ``inherent characteristics'' of the thing being provided by the 
    government should be deemed irrelevant. SAA at 262; S. Rep. No. 412, 
    103d Cong., 2d Sess. 94 (1994). Finally, these same commenters argued 
    that the Department should analyze the availability and use of a 
    subsidy in the context of the economy as a whole and not in the context 
    of the universe of potential subsidy recipients.
        Other commenters insisted that the Department must look behind the 
    distribution of subsidy benefits and explore the reasons why the use of 
    a subsidy may be limited. According to these commenters, ``purposeful 
    government action'' should be critical to a finding of specificity.
        In our view, the SAA and other legislative history make it very 
    clear that the Department does not need to find ``targeting'' or 
    ``purposeful government action'' to conclude that a domestic subsidy is 
    specific. See SAA at 262 (``[E]vidence of government intent to target 
    or otherwise limit benefits would be irrelevant in a de facto 
    specificity analysis.''). Except in the special circumstances described 
    in section 771(5A), i.e., where respondents request the Department to 
    take into account the extent of economic diversification in the 
    jurisdiction of the granting authority or the length of time during 
    which the program has been in operation, the Department is not required 
    to explain why the users of a subsidy may be limited in number. Thus, 
    for example, the fact that users may be limited due to the inherent 
    characteristics of what is being offered would not be a basis for 
    finding the subsidy non-specific. SAA at 262; S. Rep. No. 412, 103d 
    Cong., 2d Sess. 94 (1994).
    
    Characteristics of a ``Group''
    
        Citing PPG Industries, Inc. v. United States, 978 F.2d 1232, 1240-
    41 (Fed. Cir. 1992) (``PPG II''), several commenters argued that to be 
    consistent with judicial precedent, the Department must examine the 
    ``actual make-up'' of a group of beneficiaries when performing a 
    specificity analysis. According to these commenters, if a group of 
    recipients does not share similar characteristics, but, instead, 
    consists of companies in a variety of industries, the Department cannot 
    conclude that the subsidy in question is limited to a ``group of 
    industries.'' Moreover, nothing in the Act or the SAA requires the 
    Department to ignore the characteristics of the group receiving the 
    benefits from an alleged subsidy program.
        Other commenters argue that the Department can identify a ``group'' 
    of subsidy recipients without regard to any shared characteristics of 
    the individual group members. According to these commenters, a proper 
    understanding of what may constitute a specific ``group of industries'' 
    flows directly from the Carlisle purpose of the specificity test; 
    namely, that subsidy recipients should be considered a specific group 
    unless the recipient industries are numerous and distributed very 
    broadly throughout the economy. Moreover, these commenters maintain 
    that the Department has on several occasions found subsidy programs 
    specific even when the ``group'' of recipients have not shared common 
    characteristics. Steel Wheels from Brazil 54 FR 15523, 15526 (1989); 
    Cold-Rolled Carbon steel Flat-Rolled Products from Korea, 49 FR 47284, 
    47287 (1984).
        We disagree with the first set of comments. In determining whether 
    a subsidy is de jure or de facto specific, the Department is not 
    required to evaluate the actual make-up of those firms that are 
    eligible for, or actually receive, a subsidy.
        With respect to PPG II, assuming arguendo that it is relevant under 
    the new law, we note that the decision upheld the Department's 
    determination of the non-specificity of a program. To put PPG II in its 
    proper context, it is necessary to understand the facts presented in 
    the underlying CVD case. In that case, there were numerous enterprises 
    that used the FICORCA program being investigated. Therefore, when 
    looked at in terms of the number of enterprises, the actual recipients 
    were not limited. However, this conclusion says nothing as to whether 
    the number of industries that received FICORCA benefits was limited. To 
    answer this question, the Department (and the court) correctly focussed 
    on the makeup of the users. If the numerous enterprises that received 
    benefits had comprised a limited number of industries, then FICORCA 
    would have been specific. However, because the users represented 
    numerous and diverse industries, FICORCA was found not to be specific. 
    We see no basis in PPG II or in the language of section 771(5A)(D) of 
    the Act for imposing a requirement that the limited users also share 
    similar characteristics. Moreover, we believe that such a requirement 
    would undermine the purpose of the specificity test as articulated in 
    the SAA.
    
    Integral Linkage
    
        Section 355.43(b)(6) of the 1989 Proposed Regulations provided 
    that, for purposes of applying the specificity test, the Department 
    would consider two or more subsidy programs as a single program if the 
    Secretary determined that the programs were ``integrally linked.'' 
    Section 355.43(b)(6) also set forth factors to be considered in making 
    this determination.
        Although the Department did not receive any comments, pro or con, 
    regarding the integral linkage test, we have decided not to incorporate 
    Sec. 355.43(b)(6) into these regulations. Questions of integral linkage 
    were relatively rare, and when they did arise, we did not find the 
    factors set forth in Sec. 355.43(b)(6) particularly helpful.
        However, the fact that we are not recodifying Sec. 355.43(b)(6) 
    does not mean that we never would consider two or more ostensibly 
    separate subsidy programs as constituting a single program for 
    specificity purposes, although we anticipate that the circumstances 
    leading to such a combination of programs will seldom arise. In 
    situations where the subsidy programs have the same particular purpose 
    (e.g., to promote technological innovation), bestow the same type of 
    benefits (e.g., long-term loans or tax credits), and confer similar 
    levels of benefits on similarly situated firms, treating the programs 
    as a single
    
    [[Page 8826]]
    
    program may be appropriate. However, when an interested party believes 
    that two or more programs should be considered in combination for 
    purposes of the Department's specificity analysis, it will have the 
    burden of identifying the relevant programs and providing information 
    and documentation regarding their purposes and types and levels of 
    benefit.
    
    Section 351.503
    
        Section 351.503 deals with the benefit attributable to the most 
    basic type of subsidy, a grant. Paragraph (a), which is based on 
    Sec. 355.44(a) of the 1989 Proposed Regulations, provides that in the 
    case of a grant, a benefit exists in the amount of a grant. Paragraph 
    (b), which is based on Sec. 355.48(b)(1) of the 1989 Proposed 
    Regulations, sets forth the rule for determining when a firm is 
    considered to have received a subsidy provided in the form of a grant.
        Paragraph (c) deals with the allocation of the benefit to a 
    particular time period. Although paragraph (c) is based on Sec. 355.49 
    of the 1989 Proposed Regulations, it also contains certain changes in 
    approach that merit comment.
    
    Which Grants Are Allocated Over Time
    
        Paragraph (c) retains the distinction between ``recurring'' and 
    ``non-recurring'' grants. See Sec. 355.49(a) of the 1989 Proposed 
    Regulations. Paragraph (c)(1) provides that the Secretary will allocate 
    a recurring grant to the year in which the subsidy is considered as 
    having been received, a practice usually referred to as ``expensing.'' 
    Paragraph (c)(2) provides that, with one exception (discussed below), 
    the Secretary will allocate non-recurring grants over time.
        Paragraph (c)(3) contains a test for distinguishing between 
    recurring and non-recurring grants, and is based on the standard 
    applied by the Department in the GIA. Under this standard, if a benefit 
    is exceptional or requires express government approval, the Department 
    will consider it as non-recurring. As explained in the GIA:
    
        Under the modified test, we are attempting to analyze the 
    frequency and ``automaticity'' with which a benefit is provided. 
    ``Exceptional'' benefits are those types of benefits which are not 
    received on a regular and predictable basis; the recipient cannot 
    expect to receive the benefits on an ongoing basis from review 
    period to review period. The element of ``government approval'' 
    relates to the issue of whether the program provides benefits 
    automatically, essentially as an entitlement, or whether it requires 
    a formal application and/or specific government approval prior to 
    the provision of each yearly benefit. The approval of benefits under 
    the latter type of program cannot be assumed and is not automatic. 
    The receipt of a benefit after merely filling out the appropriate 
    forms (e.g., tax benefits) or, after initial qualification for 
    yearly benefits under a program (e.g., some types of price support 
    programs), would meet the automaticity part of the test.
    
    Id. If a grant is not non-recurring under this standard, the Department 
    will treat it as a recurring grant.
        In these proposed regulations, we have codified the standard 
    contained in the GIA for distinguishing between recurring and non-
    recurring benefits. However, we continue to consider whether there 
    might be a better standard for distinguishing between these two types 
    of benefits. An important purpose of the recurring/non-recurring test 
    is to reduce the burden on the Department and interested parties by 
    limiting the amount of information requested on subsidies bestowed 
    prior to the period of investigation or review. However, the Department 
    is increasingly facing arguments regarding its application of the 
    standard described in the GIA. At some point, the burden of applying 
    the GIA standard may well outweigh the benefits. Therefore, we 
    particularly invite comments on this issue. We note that the Department 
    has considered other options in the past including: (1) Developing a 
    list of the types of subsidies that would be allocated and those that 
    would be expensed; (2) allocating any grant-like benefit that exceeds 
    0.50 percent (discussed below); and (3) allocating only those grant-
    like subsidies that are tied to the purchase of fixed assets. See 
    Memorandum from Staff to Joseph Spetrini, Acting Assistant Secretary 
    for Import Administrations and Barbara R. Stafford, Deputy Assistant 
    Secretary for Investigations, dated May 17, 1993, regarding 
    Countervailing Duty Investigations of Certain Steel Products, How to 
    Make the Expense vs. Allocate Decision; Investigations, C-100-004, 
    Public Document. Regarding the first option, i.e., development of a 
    list of the types of subsidies that would be allocated and those that 
    would be expensed, the Department has given examples of the two types 
    of subsidies in the preamble to Sec. 355.49(a)(2) of the 1989 Proposed 
    Regulations and in the GIA at 37226.
    
    The 0.50 Percent Test and the Expensing of Small Grants
    
        Although the Department normally will allocate non-recurring grants 
    over time, paragraph (c)(2)(ii) retains (with some stylistic changes) 
    the so-called 0.50 percent test. See Sec. 355.49(a)(3)(i) of the 1989 
    Proposed Regulations; GIA at 37226. Under this test, the Department 
    will expense non-recurring grants received under a particular subsidy 
    program to the year of receipt if the total amount of such grants is 
    less than 0.50 percent ad valorem, as calculated under Sec. 351.525.
        The Department considers this test to be an important part of its 
    efforts to simplify CVD proceedings and to reduce the burdens on all 
    parties involved. By expensing small non-recurring grants to the year 
    of receipt, the Department avoids the need to: (1) Collect, analyze, 
    and verify the data needed to allocate such grants over time; and (2) 
    keep track of the allocation calculations for minuscule subsidies from 
    year to year. If considered only in the context of a single case, the 
    burdens imposed by this activity may not appear to be particularly 
    onerous. However, when considered across all investigations and 
    administrative reviews, the cumulative burden becomes considerable.
        Certain commenters have argued that the 0.5 test should be applied 
    on an aggregated basis; i.e., that non-recurring subsidies should be 
    expensed only when the total of benefits under all programs is less 
    than 0.5 percent. In their view, this would prevent foreign governments 
    from evading countervailing duties by awarding ``small'' benefits under 
    numerous programs.
        To address this concern, we have written Sec. 351.503(c)(2)(ii) to 
    say that the Secretary will ``normally'' expense non-recurring grants 
    received under a program if the grants are less than 0.5 percent. Thus, 
    although we intend to continue to apply the 0.5 percent rule on a 
    program basis, we have given ourselves the flexibility to take a 
    different approach in situations where petitioners are able to point to 
    clear evidence that the foreign government has deliberately structured 
    its subsidy programs so as to reduce the exposure of its exporters to 
    countervailing duties.
    
    The Time Period Over Which Non-Recurring Grants Are Allocated
    
        Once the Department has determined that a grant is non-recurring, 
    it will calculate the amount of subsidy to be assigned to a particular 
    year according to the formula described in paragraph (c)(4). The 
    formula is the same one that appeared in Sec. 355.49(b)(1) of the 1989 
    Proposed Regulations. We note that comments were received recently on 
    this formula. We have not addressed those comments here, but intend to 
    do so for the final regulations.
        As described below, we have made changes in the methods used to 
    determine certain variables used in the formula. In a departure from 
    past
    
    [[Page 8827]]
    
    practice, paragraph (c)(2) provides that the Secretary will allocate a 
    non-recurring grant over the number of years corresponding to a firm's 
    AUL, a term that is defined in paragraph (c)(4)(ii) as the average 
    useful life of a firm's productive assets. Before describing how the 
    Department will calculate a firm-specific AUL, we first should discuss 
    why we are changing our practice.
    
    Selection of the AUL Method
    
        It has often been suggested that there is no single correct method 
    for determining the number of years over which a subsidy should be 
    allocated. For example, in paragraph 2 of its Guidelines on 
    Amortization and Depreciation, BISD 32S/154 (1984-85) (``Guidelines''), 
    the Tokyo Round Committee on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures 
    stated: ``Financial and accounting theory and practice do not provide 
    any single acceptable method of determining the appropriate time-period 
    over which subsidies should be allocated.'' Similarly, in the Subsidies 
    Appendix annexed to Cold-Rolled Carbon Steel Flat-Rolled Products from 
    Argentina, 49 FR 18016, 18018 (1984), the Department stated that 
    ``[t]here are no economic or financial rules that mandate the choice of 
    an allocation period.''
        In addition, there has been little guidance from Congress on this 
    issue. The legislative history of the Trade Agreements Act of 1979 
    refers to the selection of ``a reasonable period based on the 
    commercial and competitive benefit to the recipient as a result of the 
    subsidy,'' S. Rep. No. 249, 96th Cong., 1st Sess. 86-87 (1979), and 
    reliance on ``generally accepted accounting principles.'' H.R. Rep. No. 
    317, 96th Cong., 1st Sess. 74-75 (1979); H.R. Doc. No. 153, Pt. II, 
    96th Cong., 1st Sess. 433 (1979). However, this advice does not of 
    itself supply concrete answers, particularly in light of the fact that, 
    as suggested above, generally accepted accounting principles do not 
    provide rules for allocating subsidies over time.
        Against this conceptual and legal background, in the Subsidies 
    Appendix, the Department chose the so-called ``IRS tables method'' of 
    selecting an allocation period. Under this method, the Department 
    allocated a subsidy over the number of years corresponding to the 
    average useful life of a firm's renewable physical assets (equipment), 
    as set forth in the U.S. Internal Revenue Service's 1977 Class Life 
    Asset Depreciation Range System (Rev. Proc. 77-10, 1977-1, C.B. 548 
    (RR-38). Subsequently, the Department codified this method in 
    Sec. 355.49(b)(3) of the 1989 Proposed Regulations. At the time, the 
    Department believed that the IRS tables method offered ``consistency 
    and predictability,'' although the Department expressed a willingness 
    to consider other approaches. See 54 FR at 23376-77.
        The IRS tables method has not been a subject of controversy in the 
    vast majority of CVD proceedings in which the Department has used that 
    method. However, in those proceedings where one or more parties did 
    challenge the IRS tables method, the Department has been unable to 
    successfully defend that method in court. Beginning with British Steel 
    Corp. v. United States, 632 F. Supp. 59, 68 (1986), and continuing up 
    to Usinor Sacilor v. United States, 893 F. Supp. 1112 (1995), the CIT 
    repeatedly has struck down the use of the IRS tables method. In 
    addition, in United States--Imposition of Countervailing Duties on 
    Certain Hot-Rolled Lead and Bismuth Carbon Steel Products Originating 
    in France, Germany and the United Kingdom, SCM/185, Nov. 15 1994 
    (Unadopted), a panel convened pursuant to the Tokyo Round Subsidies 
    Code found fault with the IRS tables method as applied by the 
    Department. The common theme of these adverse decisions appears to be 
    that because the IRS tables method is not a company-specific approach, 
    it fails to adequately reflect the benefit of a subsidy to a particular 
    firm.
        While we do not necessarily agree with the reasoning of these 
    decisions, the inability of the IRS tables method to pass judicial 
    muster undermines the consistency and predictability that are the most 
    attractive features of that method. Pending a resolution of this issue 
    by the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit, which could be a 
    long time in coming, every determination by the Department relying on 
    the IRS tables method would be vulnerable to litigation, a process that 
    is expensive and time-consuming not only for the Department, but also 
    for the private parties that the CVD law is intended to serve.
        Accordingly, the Department has determined to abandon the IRS 
    tables method. In identifying a replacement method, one obvious 
    consideration is that the method must relate sufficiently to the 
    ``commercial and competitive benefit to the recipient as a result of 
    the subsidy,'' the phrase from the legislative history to which the 
    courts, rightly or wrongly, have assigned great significance. It is 
    also important that the method must be sufficiently administrable so as 
    not to impose undue burdens on private parties and the Department.
        With these criteria in mind, we have considered alternatives to the 
    IRS tables method that have been suggested in comments submitted as 
    part of this rulemaking, as well as in past and pending litigation. 
    See, e.g., Final Results of Redetermination Pursuant to Court Remand on 
    General Issue of Allocation in British Steel plc. v. United States, 
    Consol. Ct. No. 93-09-00550-CVD (Ct. Int'l Trade June 30, 1995) 
    (``British Steel Remand''). The principal alternatives are: (1) 
    Company-specific average useful life of productive assets; (2) company-
    specific average maturity of long-term debt; (3) company-specific 
    weighted-average use of funds; and (4) the IRS tables as a rebuttable 
    presumption.
        We have chosen the first alternative, the company-specific average 
    useful life of productive assets, or ``AUL.'' First, we believe that 
    the AUL method will be more administrable and predictable than the 
    other alternatives, because, as discussed in more detail below, it 
    should be easily calculable from a firm's accounting records. With 
    respect to the long-term debt alternative, based on our experience, 
    many of the firms that we investigate do not have access to long-term 
    debt financing (except possibly as a result of government support). 
    Therefore, as a practical matter, this alternative would frequently 
    lead us to use non-company-specific, surrogate measures of life of 
    debt. With respect to the use of funds alternative, this alternative 
    appears unduly complicated, requiring both private parties and the 
    Department to calculate multiple allocation periods, including a 
    company-specific AUL, and then take a weighted-average of those 
    figures. Finally, with respect to using the IRS tables as a rebuttable 
    presumption, this alternative likely would waste the time of private 
    parties and the Department in arguments over whether or not the 
    allocation period called for by the IRS tables had been effectively 
    ``rebutted'' by a firm's own AUL.
        Second, the AUL method has been recognized internationally as a 
    reasonable method of determining the appropriate time period over which 
    subsidies should be allocated. As stated in para. 5.1 of the 
    Guidelines, ``[w]hile the benefit of a grant (that is, elimination of 
    financial obligations the recipient company would otherwise incur) has 
    no exact correlation to the life of any assets purchased with the 
    grant, allocating the grant over the average life of renewable physical 
    assets is one generally practical, fair, and consistent method of 
    allocation.'' Although the Guidelines are no longer in effect due to 
    the termination of the Tokyo Round
    
    [[Page 8828]]
    
    Subsidies Code, we consider it significant that the United States and 
    its major trading partners went on record as endorsing the AUL method 
    as an acceptable method of determining an allocation period for 
    subsidies.
        Finally, we note that the Department's use of company-specific AUL 
    was recently affirmed in British Steel PLC v. United States, 929 F. 
    Supp. 426 (Ct. Int'l Trade 1996).
    
    Calculation of a Company-Specific AUL
    
        Paragraph (c)(4)(ii) describes the manner in which the Department 
    will calculate a company-specific AUL. Normally, firms will not 
    calculate their ``actual'' AUL in the normal course of business, and 
    requiring firms to calculate this figure for purposes of a CVD 
    proceeding could pose an extremely onerous burden on firms with 
    thousands of individual assets. Therefore, what is needed is a 
    calculation method that results in reasonable reporting requirements, 
    while at the same time produces a reasonable estimate of a firm's 
    actual AUL.
        We believe that paragraph (c)(4)(ii) achieves these dual 
    objectives. Under paragraph (c)(4)(ii), a firm's AUL will be calculated 
    by dividing the firm's depreciable productive assets by the firm's 
    average annual charge to accumulated depreciation. As indicated in the 
    second sentence of paragraph (c)(4)(ii), this calculation will be based 
    on data covering a period considered appropriate by the Secretary. 
    Because this is a new method with which the Department has little 
    experience, we are reluctant to provide more detail at this time in the 
    form of a regulation. Instead, we intend to include detailed 
    instructions in our CVD questionnaires concerning the calculation of an 
    AUL. Once we have gained more experience with this method, we may add 
    additional detail to the regulation.
        We should note, however, that we currently intend to include in our 
    initial CVD questionnaires a request that a firm calculate its average 
    AUL over a period of ten years, a period that would include the period 
    of investigation and the nine preceding years. Based on the results of 
    this calculation, the firm then would provide information on its non-
    recurring subsidies for a time period corresponding to the average AUL 
    it calculated. For example, if a firm calculated that its average AUL 
    for the ten-year period described above was 15 years, the firm would 
    provide data on its subsidies for the period of investigation and the 
    14 preceding years. If the investigation results in a CVD order, the 
    AUL will be recalculated for non-recurring subsidies received after the 
    period on investigation (``POI'') based on updated information. For 
    example, if a non-recurring grant is received in the third year after 
    the original POI, the allocation period for that subsidy would be the 
    average AUL for the year that subsidy is received and the nine previous 
    years.
        As in the case of any other piece of data included in a response to 
    a CVD questionnaire, a firm's calculation of its AUL would be subject 
    to verification by the Department and comment by parties to the 
    proceeding.
        As set forth in the third sentence of paragraph (c)(4)(ii), the 
    Secretary will attempt to exclude fixed assets that are not depreciable 
    (such as land or construction in progress) and assets that have been 
    fully depreciated and that are no longer in service. However, assets 
    that are in service would be included even if they have been fully 
    depreciated.
        In addition, it may be necessary to make normalizing adjustments 
    for factors that may distort the calculation of an AUL. Again, we are 
    not in a position at this time to provide additional detail in the 
    regulation itself, because the types of adjustments necessary likely 
    will vary based on the facts of a particular case. However, certain 
    obvious normalizing adjustments that come to mind are situations in 
    which a firm may have charged an extraordinary write-down of fixed 
    assets to depreciation due, or where the economy of the country in 
    question can be characterized as hyperinflationary.
        Finally, there may be situations in which an AUL cannot be 
    calculated in the manner described above (assets divided by 
    depreciation). For example, if a firm's depreciation is not based on an 
    estimate of the actual useful life of its assets, the calculation 
    described above would not be a reasonable method of calculating AUL. 
    Similarly, AUL could not be calculated in this manner if the firm does 
    not use straightline depreciation and additions to the firm's asset 
    pool are irregular and uneven. Indeed, there may be cases where there 
    is no reasonable method of calculating a company-specific AUL. In such 
    cases, the Department will consider, among other things, any 
    alternative calculation methods for AUL offered by parties to the 
    proceeding, including the IRS table method previously used by the 
    Department. Such alternative methods will not be limited to those that 
    are company-specific.
        In addition, we should note that because petitioners may not be in 
    a position to calculate a potential respondent's AUL at the time a 
    petition is filed, petitioners may not know how many years back they 
    can go in alleging countervailable subsidies. To provide more certainty 
    to petitioners, the Department will accept the period specified in the 
    IRS tables for purposes of making subsidy allegations in a petition.
    
    Calculation of the Benefit Stream
    
        Paragraph (c)(4)(iii) deals with the selection of a discount rate. 
    Consistent with the GIA at 37227, paragraph (c)(4)(iii)(B) provides 
    that, in the case of an uncreditworthy firm, the Secretary will use as 
    a discount rate an interest rate with a ``risk premium'' included.
    
    Section 351.504
    
        Section 351.504 deals with loans and other forms of debt financing. 
    Paragraph (a) deals with the identification and measurement of the 
    benefit attributable to a loan. Paragraph (a)(1) tracks the general 
    standard set forth in section 771(5)(E)(ii) of the Act, which directs 
    the Department to use a ``comparable commercial loan that the recipient 
    could actually obtain on the market'' as the benchmark for determining 
    whether a government-provided loan confers a benefit. Additionally, 
    paragraph (a)(1) restates the Department's current practice, as 
    reflected in Sec. 355.44(b)(8) of the 1989 Proposed Regulations, that 
    in making this comparison the Secretary normally will seek to compare 
    effective interest rates rather than nominal rates. ``Effective 
    interest rates'' are intended to take account of the actual cost of the 
    loan, including the amount of any fees, commissions, compensating 
    balances, government charges (such as stamp taxes) or penalties paid in 
    addition to the ``nominal'' interest. However, the Department intends 
    that, if effective rates are not available, the Secretary will compare 
    nominal rates or, as a last resort, nominal to effective rates, as 
    under current practice. If the ``loan'' is a bond (see definition of 
    ``loan'' in Sec. 351.102), the Department normally will treat the yield 
    on the bond as the effective interest rate.
        Paragraphs (a)(2) and (a)(3) elaborate on the criteria for 
    selecting the benchmark. As the reader quickly will ascertain, the 
    criteria contained in paragraphs (a)(2) and (a)(3) are much more 
    general (and, thus, much more flexible) than the detailed hierarchies 
    contained in Sec. 355.44(b) of the 1989 Proposed Regulations. The 
    Department seldom used these hierarchies, because, in practice, the 
    required information was seldom available.
        Paragraph (a)(2) sets out the criteria the Department will normally 
    consider
    
    [[Page 8829]]
    
    in selecting a comparable commercial loan. We received the following 
    comments relating to this issue: (1) If the Department modifies its 
    current benchmark hierarchies, any new hierarchies or benchmark 
    selection criteria should take account of the maturity and 
    corresponding level of risk associated with the government-provided 
    loan being analyzed; (2) requiring identical financing is impractical 
    and undermines the Department's discretion; (3) in the case of foreign 
    currency loans, which typically are long-term in nature, the 
    Department's selection of a comparable loan should be based explicitly 
    on the comparable currency, and should only be based on the domestic 
    currency in certain unique situations; and (4) the Department should 
    make clear its policy of selecting as its benchmark a loan that was 
    taken out (or could have been taken out) at the same point in time as 
    the government-provided loan.
        With respect to these comments, we agree that a comparable 
    commercial loan used as a benchmark should represent a financial 
    instrument that is similar to the government-provided loan and that was 
    taken out (or could have been taken out) at the same point in time. We 
    believe that this type of approach will ensure a reasonable comparison, 
    because the comparable loan will exhibit the same basic characteristics 
    of maturity, risk, and currency denomination that are embodied in the 
    allegedly subsidized financing. In addition, we agree with the 
    commenter that recommended that the Department specify the time period 
    from which it will select comparable financing. See paragraphs 
    (a)(2)(iii) and (a)(2)(iv). With respect to those comments suggesting 
    refinements to the benchmark hierarchies contained in the 1989 Proposed 
    Regulations, as explained above, we have discarded those hierarchies in 
    favor of a more flexible approach. However, we believe that our new 
    approach is consistent with the objectives underlying the comments.
        Several commenters suggested that loans under a government program, 
    even if the program is not specific, should not be considered 
    ``commercial'' loans. We agree with these commenters, and have 
    incorporated their suggestion into paragraph (a)(2)(ii). We note, 
    however, that we do not equate a ``loan provided under a government 
    program'' with a ``loan from a government-owned bank.'' Consistent with 
    Sec. 355.44(b)(9) of the 1989 Proposed Regulations, which is discussed 
    further below in connection with paragraph(a)(6)(ii), the Secretary 
    normally will consider loans from government-owned banks as commercial 
    loans.
        The commenters disagreed over the selection of a comparable 
    commercial loan in the case of a suspension agreement, some commenters 
    arguing that special rules should be used in the case of a suspension 
    agreement, because: (1) a suspension agreement is forward-looking, and 
    (2) the use of a retrospective benchmark undermines the utility of a 
    suspension agreement.
        We agree that a suspension agreement is forward-looking, but we do 
    not believe that this fact requires special rules governing the 
    selection of comparable commercial loans. Typically, in its 
    administration of a suspended investigation, the Department will 
    monitor developments in commercial benchmarks outside of the normal 
    administrative review process. This monitoring activity ensures that 
    the commercial benchmarks used are timely. See Roses and Other Cut 
    Flowers From Colombia; Miniature Carnations From Colombia, 61 FR 9429 
    (March 8, 1996).
        Paragraph (a)(3) addresses the requirement that the comparable loan 
    be one that the firm ``could actually obtain on the market,'' and 
    reflects a change in practice for short-term loans. As described in 
    Sec. 355.44(b)(3) of the 1989 Proposed Regulations, the Department has 
    used national average interest rates to determine the benefit from 
    government-provided short-term loans. However, at the time the 1989 
    Proposed Regulations were promulgated, the Department announced that it 
    would consider using company-specific benchmarks for short-term loans. 
    Based upon our experience in the interim, and especially because of the 
    ability to computerize our loan calculations, we have concluded that we 
    have the capability to use company-specific benchmarks. Moreover, we 
    believe that company-specific benchmarks provide a more accurate 
    measure of the benefit, if any, to a recipient of a government-provided 
    short-term loan. Therefore, paragraph (a)(3)(i) states a preference for 
    using company-specific benchmarks for both short-and long-term loans. 
    Under paragraph (a)(3)(ii), we normally would use national averages 
    only in the event that the firm did not take out any comparable 
    commercial loans during the relevant period.
        One commenter argued that a benchmark hierarchy for short-term 
    loans should emphasize company-specific rates and should rely on 
    country-wide rates only as a last resort. In response to these 
    comments, another commenter argued that mandating the use of company-
    specific rates has no basis in the statute and may be inappropriate in 
    cases involving a large number of companies.
        We disagree that there is no basis in the statute for using 
    company-specific benchmarks for short-term loans. To the contrary, we 
    see the use of company-specific benchmarks as being more consistent 
    with the requirement that the benefit be determined by looking at a 
    loan (or loans) the firm actually could obtain. In large cases, e.g., 
    cases with numerous respondents, it may become necessary to use a 
    national average rate. If so, paragraph (a)(3)(i) provides sufficient 
    flexibility to do so.
        Paragraph (a)(3)(iii) deals with the long-term loans to firms 
    considered to be uncreditworthy. In a change from the practice 
    described in Sec. 355.44(b)(6)(iv) of the 1989 Proposed Regulations, 
    paragraph (a)(3)(iii) describes a new method for calculating the 
    benchmark the Department will use in identifying and measuring the 
    benefit attributable to a government-provided long-term loan received 
    by an uncreditworthy firm.
        The new method is based explicitly on the notion that when a lender 
    makes a loan to a company that is considered to be uncreditworthy (as 
    opposed to a safer, creditworthy company) the lender faces a higher 
    probability that the borrower will default on repayment of the loan. As 
    a consequence of this higher probability of default, the lender will 
    charge a higher interest rate. The calculation described in paragraph 
    (a)(3)(iii) captures the increased probability of default by adjusting 
    upward the rate of interest a creditworthy company would pay in the 
    country in question.
        In making this adjustment, the Department is not proposing to 
    calculate the probability that a particular uncreditworthy firm will 
    default on a particular loan. Such a calculation would require 
    extensive data and analysis, and any conclusion would be highly 
    speculative. Instead, similar to the method the Department has used 
    since 1984, we are proposing to rely on information regarding the U.S. 
    debt market. In particular, we have used the weighted average one-year 
    default rate for speculative grade bonds between 1970 and 1994, as 
    reported by Moody's Investor Service. This average default rate is 4.3 
    percent. This rate is reflected indirectly in the formula, which is 
    based on the probability that these risky loans will be repaid (i.e., 
    1--.043 = .957).
        Although the uncreditworthy benchmark we adopted in 1984 and 
    included in the 1989 Proposed Regulations has not been controversial, 
    we believe that the method we are
    
    [[Page 8830]]
    
    proposing here offers a more accurate measure of risk involved in 
    lending to firms with little or no access to commercial bank loans. By 
    adjusting the interest rate that a healthy, low-risk company would pay 
    in the country in question upward to account for the greater likelihood 
    of default by an uncreditworthy borrower, we capture more precisely the 
    speculative nature of loans to uncreditworthy companies and the premium 
    they would have to pay the lender to assume that risk.
        Paragraph (a)(4) sets forth the standard for determining when a 
    firm is uncreditworthy. Paragraph (a)(4)(i) is based on 
    Sec. 355.44(b)(6)(i) of the 1989 Proposed Regulations, but has been 
    modified to clarify the analysis the Department intends to undertake in 
    determining whether a company is creditworthy. In Sec. 355.44(b)(6)(i) 
    of the 1989 Proposed Regulations we stated that the Secretary would 
    deem a firm uncreditworthy if that ``firm did not have sufficient 
    revenues or resources to meet its costs and fixed financial obligations 
    in the three years prior to the year in which the firm and the 
    government agreed upon the terms of the loan.'' We have replaced this 
    statement with an explanation of what we mean by 
    ``uncreditworthiness.'' Specifically, we will find a company to be 
    uncreditworthy if information available at the time the government-
    provided loan is made indicates that the firm could not have obtained 
    long-term financing from conventional commercial sources. In this 
    context, ``conventional commercial sources'' is meant to refer to bank 
    loans and non-speculative grade bond issues. Hence, uncreditworthy 
    companies are those that would be forced to resort to other sources, 
    such as junk bonds, to raise funds. The Department will make its 
    creditworthiness finding based on the information described in 
    paragraphs (a)(5)(ii) (A), (B), (C), and (D), which are unchanged from 
    the comparable paragraphs in Sec. 355.44(b)(6) of the 1989 Proposed 
    Regulations.
        Paragraph (a)(4)(ii) is based on the last sentence of 
    Sec. 355.44(b)(6)(i) of the 1989 Proposed Regulations. However, the 
    word ``normally'' has been replaced by the phrase ``In the case of 
    firms not owned by the government * * * .'' Also, the term 
    ``government-provided guarantee'' replaces ``explicit government 
    guarantee.'' With respect to the first change, the deletion of ``normal 
    ly'' reflects the Department's consistent practice considering 
    commercial financing to a firm to be dispositive evidence of a firm's 
    creditworthiness only if the firm is privately-owned. With respect to 
    the second change, this is intended to indicate that the Department 
    will consider the circumstances surrounding the financing as a whole, 
    instead of relying on one factor in determining whether the financing 
    shows that the firm is creditworthy.
        Paragraphs (a)(4)(iii) and (a)(6)(i) are based on 
    Secs. 355.44(b)(6) (ii) and (iii) of the 1989 Proposed Regulations. 
    Paragraph (a)(4)(iii) states that the Secretary will ignore current and 
    prior countervailable subsidies in determining whether a firm is 
    uncreditworthy. In other words, the Secretary will not attempt to 
    adjust a firm's financial data for current and prior subsidies in 
    making a creditworthiness determination. Paragraph (a)(6)(i) continues 
    to require a specific allegation before the Secretary will consider the 
    uncreditworthiness of a firm.
        Paragraph (a)(5) deals with long-term variable rate loans, and 
    codifies a methodology set forth in the GIA. Under paragraph (a)(5)(i), 
    the year in which the terms of the government-provided loan are set 
    establishes the reference point for comparing the government-provided 
    variable-rate loan with the comparable commercial variable-rate loan. 
    If the interest rate on the government-provided loan is lower than the 
    interest rate on the comparable commercial loan, a benefit exists. If 
    the interest rate on the government-provided loan is the same or 
    higher, no benefit exists. The rationale for basing the decision on the 
    first-year interest rate differential is that the interest rate spread, 
    if any, in that year generally will apply throughout the life of the 
    loan. Paragraph (a)(5)(ii) recognizes that there may be situations 
    where the method described in paragraph (a)(5)(i) is not appropriate 
    and provides the Department with the discretion to modify that method. 
    For example, there may be no comparable commercial variable-rate loan 
    to use for comparison purposes or the repayment structure of the 
    government-provided variable-rate loan may be such that the simple 
    interest rate comparison described in paragraph (a)(5)(i) would not 
    yield an accurate measure of the benefit.
        Paragraph (a)(6)(ii) establishes an evidentiary standard for 
    investigations of loans extended by government-owned banks, and is 
    based on Sec. 355.44(b)(9) of the 1989 Proposed Regulations. See also 
    paragraph (a)(2)(ii), discussed above. In this regard, some commenters 
    argued that the Department should investigate all loans from 
    government-owned, or government-supported, banks, and that the 
    Department should abandon its requirement that evidence be presented 
    that such loans were provided under a specific government program. 
    According to the commenters, because this type of information is not 
    reasonably available to petitioners, the burden of proving that a 
    company has not received subsidized loans from a government-owned bank 
    should be shifted to respondent interested parties. In addition, these 
    commenters argued that the Department should consider financing 
    provided by a bank that is partially funded by the government to be 
    countervailable even in the absence of a particular government program.
        In response, one commenter argued that the Department should 
    continue to require reasonable evidence that loans from government-
    owned banks are provided at government direction or from government 
    funds and on subsidized terms. According to this commenter, the 
    adoption of a looser approach would create a per se rule that the 
    lending practices of government-owned banks are in and of themselves 
    suspect. Additionally, shifting the burden of proof to respondents to 
    show that such loans are not countervailable would be a violation of 
    the ``positive evidence'' approach outlined in Article 2.4 of the SCM 
    Agreement and the ``substantial evidence'' requirement of section 
    516A(b)(1)(B) of the Act.
        Under our past practice, we have distinguished between government-
    owned banks that are operated to meet special financing needs and 
    commercial banks that are government-owned. For the former (i.e., 
    special purpose banks such as national development banks), petitioners 
    are asked to provide information reasonably available to them to show 
    that loans being provided by such banks are specific and that the 
    interest being charged is not at commercial rates. For the latter 
    (i.e., commercial banks that are government-owned), we have 
    additionally requested that petitioners provide reasonably available 
    information that the loans in question are something more than mere 
    commercial loans. In particular, we request information suggesting that 
    such loans are being provided at the direction of the government or 
    with funds provided by the government.
        We believe this approach is appropriate because we have no basis to 
    presume that loans given under the commercial operations of government-
    owned banks confer a subsidy. Moreover, we do not believe that our 
    request for this additional information places an unreasonable burden 
    on petitioners; they need only provide reasonably available information 
    that the government-owned bank, for example, administers government 
    loan
    
    [[Page 8831]]
    
    programs that could be the source of the loan in question.
        Thus, with the exception of special purpose banks (as discussed 
    above), we agree with the commenters who argued that the Department 
    should investigate loans from a government-owned bank only when a 
    petitioner provides information suggesting that such loans are being 
    provided at the direction of the government or with funds provided by 
    the government. Accordingly, paragraph (a)(6)(ii) reaffirms the 
    Department's prior approach with respect to government-owned banks.
        Paragraph (b) sets forth a rule regarding the point in time at 
    which the benefit from a loan arises, and is based on Sec. 355.48(b)(3) 
    of the 1989 Proposed Regulations. The second sentence of paragraph (b) 
    addresses loans with special characteristics, such as loans with 
    preferential grace periods. In the case of these types of loans, we do 
    not believe that it is appropriate to wait until the end of the grace 
    period to begin assigning subsidy amounts, because the longer the grace 
    period, the greater the subsidy benefit and the greater the time before 
    countervailing duties can be assessed.
        Paragraph (c) deals with the allocation of the benefits of a 
    government-provided loan to a particular time period. While paragraph 
    (c) is based, in part, on Sec. 355.49 of the 1989 Proposed Regulations, 
    it contains several changes.
        Paragraph (c)(1) provides that the benefit of a short-term loan 
    will be allocated (expensed) to the year(s) in which the firm is due to 
    make interest payments on the loan. This approach, which essentially 
    treats short-term loans as recurring subsidies, is consistent with 
    longstanding Department practice.
        Paragraph (c)(2) deals with situations in which the benefit of a 
    government-provided loan stems solely from the concessionary interest 
    rate of the loan, not from any differences in repayment terms. Where 
    this is the case, there is no need to engage in the complicated 
    calculations called for by Sec. 355.49(c) of the 1989 Proposed 
    Regulations. Instead, as paragraph (c)(2) provides, the annual benefit 
    can be determined by simply calculating, for each year in which the 
    loan is outstanding, the difference in interest payments between the 
    government-provided loan and the comparison loan. The last sentence of 
    paragraph (c)(2) restates the principle reflected in Sec. 355.49(c)(2) 
    of the 1989 Proposed Regulations that the amount of the subsidy 
    conferred by a government-provided loan never can exceed the amount 
    that would have been calculated if the loan had been given as a grant.
        Paragraph (c)(3) deals with situations where both the government-
    provided loan and the comparison loan are long-term, fixed-interest 
    loans, but where the two loans have dissimilar grace periods or 
    maturities, or where the repayment schedules have different shapes 
    (e.g., declining balance versus annuity style). Because a firm may 
    derive a benefit from special repayment terms, in addition to any 
    benefit derived from a concessional interest rate, for these loans we 
    will continue to calculate what was described as the ``grant 
    equivalent'' in Sec. 355.49(c) of the 1989 Proposed Regulations. 
    However, instead of adopting the loan allocation formula from the 1989 
    Proposed Regulations, we intend to use the grant allocation formula 
    described in Sec. 351.503(c) (except that the allocation period will be 
    the life of the government-provided loan). The elimination of the old 
    loan formula reflects our desire to streamline methodologies, where 
    possible. Moreover, by timing the receipt of the benefit from these 
    types of loans to the year in which the government-provided loan was 
    received (see Sec. 351.504(b)), the old loan formula becomes 
    unnecessary, because its primary purpose was to begin assigning annual 
    subsidy amounts in the year after the receipt of the loan.
        Paragraph (c)(4) sets forth the method of calculating an annual 
    benefit for government-provided variable-rate loans, and is little 
    changed from Sec. 355.49(d) of the 1989 Proposed Regulations.
        Several commenters suggested that instead of using the life of the 
    loan as the allocation period for long-term loans, the Department 
    should use the same allocation period as used for other types of non-
    recurring subsidies. Given that, as discussed above, the Department has 
    adopted the AUL method for non-recurring grants, if the Department were 
    to adopt this suggestion it would mean allocating the benefit of a 
    long-term loan over the average useful life of a firm's renewable 
    assets.
        For the following reasons, we have not adopted this suggestion. 
    First, as part of our streamlining effort, we are not, as a general 
    matter, calculating grant equivalents. Therefore, our new methodology 
    does not lend itself to allocating loan subsidies over any period other 
    than the life of the loan. Moreover, while para. 4.2 of the Guidelines 
    recognizes that the allocation of the benefit of a long-term loan over 
    the life of assets is a reasonable method, para. 4.1 recognizes that 
    allocation over the life of the loan is also a reasonable method. In 
    addition, the life-of-the-loan method imposes less of a burden on 
    private parties and Department staff than other alternatives, because 
    it is a comparatively easy matter to determine the life of a loan. The 
    Department's longstanding practice of allocating a long-term loan 
    benefit over the life of the loan has been relatively non-controversial 
    and litigation-free, and we are reluctant to change this practice 
    absent a persuasive demonstration that an alternative method is 
    superior to existing practice. In this instance, we do not believe that 
    such a demonstration has been made.
        Paragraph (d) sets forth a method for calculating the annual 
    benefit attributable to a long-term interest-free loan, the obligation 
    for repayment of which is contingent upon subsequent events, such as 
    the achievement of a particular profit level by the firm. Paragraph (d) 
    is based on Sec. 355.49(f) of the 1989 Proposed Regulations, and 
    continues to provide that the Secretary will treat any outstanding 
    balance on one of these types of loans as an interest-free, short-term 
    loan (using a short-term loan benchmark), and will expense any 
    benefit(s) to the year(s) in which interest would have been paid on the 
    short-term loan.
    
    Section 351.505
    
        Section 351.505 deals with loan guarantees. Paragraph (a)(1) sets 
    forth the general rule for identifying and measuring the benefit 
    attributable to a government-provided loan guarantee, and conforms to 
    the new standard contained in section 771(5)(E)(iii) of the Act.
        One commenter argued that in choosing a comparable commercial loan 
    by which to identify and measure the benefit attributable to a 
    government-provided loan guarantee, the Department should use a loan 
    with a comparable commercial guarantee. This same commenter also 
    recommended that the Department continue the approach described in 
    Sec. 355.44(c)(2) of the 1989 Proposed Regulations. Under this 
    practice, if the government was the owner of the firm and it was normal 
    commercial practice in the country for owners or shareholders to 
    provide loan guarantees comparable to the government-provided 
    guarantee, the Department did not consider the government-provided 
    guarantee as giving rise to a benefit. In response, one commenter 
    argued that the Department's practice in this regard is inconsistent 
    with the government's involvement in the transaction in that, unless a 
    subsidy was being provided, the firm would have obtained the loan 
    through a commercial guarantor.
        We agree that in determining whether a government-provided loan 
    guarantee
    
    [[Page 8832]]
    
    confers a benefit, the Department should determine whether it is a 
    normal commercial practice in the country in question for a private 
    owner, or parent company, to guarantee a loan. We have drafted 
    paragraph (a)(2) accordingly. A government-provided guarantee should 
    not be considered countervailable if it is given by the government in 
    its capacity as owner (i.e., not under a government guarantee program 
    used by government-owned and privately-owned companies) and if private 
    owners normally provide guarantees in the same circumstances. For 
    example, if the government directly guaranteed the debt of a company it 
    owned, it would fall upon the respondent to demonstrate that private 
    shareholders in that country also would normally guarantee the debt of 
    the companies in which they own shares. Where a government-owned 
    holding company guarantees the debt of its subsidiaries, the respondent 
    would need to show that it is normal commercial practice for non-
    government-owned corporations to guarantee the debt of their 
    subsidiaries. In addition, the respondent would need to demonstrate 
    sufficient internally-generated resources to serve as guarantor of the 
    debt. Where the government or a government-owned holding company 
    guaranteed the debt of an ``uncreditworthy'' company it owned (see 
    Sec. 351.504(a)(4) regarding uncreditworthy companies), the respondent 
    would need to provide evidence that private owners would also guarantee 
    the debt of uncreditworthy companies they own.
        The Department normally will not consider whether the behavior of a 
    government owner/guarantor represents normal commercial practice unless 
    a respondent provides adequate supporting information. Such information 
    can include statements by independent sources such as financial or 
    banking experts, tax experts or academics in the field of business. 
    Absent such a demonstration, the Department will identify and measure 
    the benefit from a government-provided loan guarantee by comparing the 
    guaranteed loan to a comparable commercial loan in the same manner as 
    under Sec. 351.504. In addition, to conform to new section 
    771(5)(E)(iii) of the Act, paragraph (a)(1) provides that the 
    Department will adjust for any difference in the guarantee fees. 
    Therefore, we do not agree with the first comment that we should decide 
    which loans are comparable on the basis of the comparability of the 
    loan guarantees.
        Paragraphs (b) and (c) deal, respectively, with the time at which 
    the benefit from a loan guarantee is considered to have been received 
    and the allocation of the benefit to a particular time period. Both 
    paragraphs essentially apply the methodology for loans set forth in 
    paragraphs (b) and (c) of Sec. 351.504.
    
    Section 351.506
    
        Section 351.506 deals with equity infusions. Paragraph (a) deals 
    with the identification and measurement of the benefit attributable to 
    a government-provided equity infusion. Like Sec. 355.44(e) of the 1989 
    Proposed Regulations, paragraph (a) is divided into two methodological 
    tracks, the choice of methodology depending on whether or not there are 
    actual private investor prices to serve as a benchmark for shares of a 
    firm purchased by a government. However, paragraph (a)(1) retains the 
    existing preference for private investor prices as a benchmark.
    
    Actual Private Investor Prices Available
    
        Paragraph (a)(2) contains rules for analyzing equity infusions when 
    actual private investor prices are available, the first methodological 
    track, and is largely based on Sec. 355.44(e)(1) of the 1989 Proposed 
    Regulations. Under Sec. 355.44(e)(1), the first question in analyzing 
    an equity infusion was whether, at the time of the infusion, there was 
    a market price for newly-issued equity. If so, and if the shares 
    purchased on the market were in the same form as the shares purchased 
    by the government, the Department determined the amount of the benefit 
    by comparing the price paid by government for its shares with the 
    market price. In an exceptional situation, however, the Department 
    could find the volume of a firm's traded shares to be so low as to 
    preclude the use of those shares as a benchmark.
        Paragraph (a)(2) is not intended to alter any of these basic 
    principles. It does, however, elaborate on them in two respects. First, 
    it addresses the use of prices of shares that are not in the same form 
    as the shares provided to the government as benchmarks. Second, it 
    permits the Department to use as a benchmark the market price of 
    publicly-traded shares that the firm had previously issued.
        The Department considered these last two issues in the 1993 steel 
    determinations. With regard to the use of shares that are not identical 
    to the shares being purchased by the government, the Department 
    determined that in appropriate circumstances, shares with similar 
    characteristics can be compared. See GIA at 37252. The CIT subsequently 
    upheld the principle of relying on a similar form of equity where the 
    same form of equity does not exist. Geneva Steel v. United States, 914 
    F. Supp. at 580 (1996).
        With respect to secondary market shares, in the GIA at 37250, the 
    Department explained that its practice was to ``resort to the use of 
    secondary market share prices in instances where private investors did 
    not purchase new shares from the firm at the same time they were issued 
    to the government.'' The Department reaffirmed this practice, holding 
    that, ``(a)s long as the market price benchmark at the time of the 
    infusion has not been shown to be deficient or tainted * * * a 
    government equity infusion must be determined to be made on an 
    equityworthy basis whenever the government purchases shares at (the 
    secondary market) price.'' Id. at 37251. This practice, too, has been 
    sustained by the courts. Geneva Steel v. United States, 914 F. Supp. at 
    581 (1996).
        The URAA did not modify these general principles. Section 
    771(5)(E)(i) states that a benefit shall normally be treated as 
    conferred if, in the case of an equity infusion, ``the investment 
    decision is inconsistent with the usual investment practice of private 
    investors, including the practice regarding the provision of risk 
    capital, in the country in which the equity infusion is made.'' Market-
    determined share prices, when available and useable, provide the best 
    gauge as to the usual investment practice of private investors, 
    including practices regarding the provision of risk capital.
        Therefore, under paragraph (a)(2)(i)(A), an equity infusion confers 
    a benefit if the price paid by the government for newly-issued equity 
    is more than the price paid by private investors for newly-issued 
    equity of the same (or similar) form. For example, if a government pays 
    $10 per share for newly-issued shares in a firm, and private investors 
    pay $5 per share for the same shares, a benefit exists in the amount of 
    $5 per share ($10 - $5 = $5).
        If there is no private investor price for newly-issued equity, 
    under paragraph (a)(2)(i)(B), an equity infusion confers a benefit if 
    the price paid by the government for newly-issued equity is less than 
    the market-determined price, at such time as permits a reasonable 
    comparison, of previously issued publicly-traded shares of the same (or 
    similar) form. We continue to believe that market prices should be 
    preferred as benchmarks, because such prices incorporate private 
    investors' perceptions of a firm's future earning potential and worth.
        In this regard, however, we intend that in applying this private 
    investor standard, the amount of shares
    
    [[Page 8833]]
    
    purchased by private investors must be sufficiently significant so as 
    to provide an appropriate benchmark. See paragraph (a)(2)(iii). For an 
    example of a situation where the Department found sufficient private 
    participation to warrant use of the prices paid by private investors as 
    the benchmark, see Small Diameter Circular Seamless Carbon and Alloy 
    Steel Standard, Line and Pressure Pipe from Italy, 60 FR 31922, 31994 
    (1995). Also, the use of a ``similar'' share as the basis of the 
    benchmark neither precludes nor requires a price adjustment for 
    differences in the types of shares. However, under paragraph 
    (a)(2)(iv), the Department intends to make the adjustment when it is 
    appropriate and reasonably quantifiable. For an example of an 
    adjustment to account for differences in the types of shares, see 
    Certain Atlantic Groundfish from Canada, 51 FR 10047 (1986).
        Two commenters, citing AIMCOR v. United States, 871 F. Supp. 447 
    (Ct. Int'l Trade 1994) (``AIMCOR I''), stated that the Department 
    should ``clarify'' its equity methodology so as to preclude the use of 
    previously issued, publicly-traded shares as benchmarks. These 
    commenters claim that merely because a company has previously issued 
    publicly-traded shares does not imply that the company could obtain 
    fresh equity capital on the same terms from reasonable private 
    investors. They claim that the Department's use of the price of 
    outstanding shares is flawed because it recognizes neither the concept 
    of earnings dilution (i.e., the fact that newly-issued shares dilute 
    the claims attributable to previously issued shares) nor the difference 
    between replacement cost and market value. Finally, they argue that the 
    Department's current methodology does not take into account differences 
    between ``hybrid'' equity-like instruments issued to the government and 
    previously issued equity instruments that do not have ``hybrid'' 
    features.
        With respect to these comments, paragraph (a)(2)(i) reflects a 
    distinction between the AIMCOR I problem, where the ownership rights 
    conferred upon the private shareholders differed from the ownership 
    rights conferred upon the government, and the question of whether the 
    publicly-traded price of previously issued shares is an adequate proxy 
    for the price of newly-issued shares. Paragraph (a)(2)(i) recognizes 
    the AIMCOR I problem by requiring that the Department use the same or 
    ``similar'' shares for its benchmark, and by permitting the Department 
    to make an adjustment for differences between the shares used as the 
    benchmark and the government-provided equity.
        As for the use of secondary market prices, the Department believes 
    that it can improve the accuracy of the secondary market price 
    benchmark by altering the timing of the calculation. In particular, we 
    are proposing to use secondary market prices in the period immediately 
    following a government equity infusion. We believe use of these prices 
    will allow us to capture private investors' perceptions as to what the 
    newly infused capital will allow the firm to achieve, and also will 
    enable us to measure any dilution of ownership. In our view, paragraph 
    (a)(2)(iv) is sufficiently flexible so as to permit the Department to 
    calculate a benchmark based on prices paid during a time period that 
    will permit a reasonable comparison with the government equity 
    infusion. However, we are particularly interested in public comments on 
    this issue.
    
    Actual Private Investor Price Not Available
    
        One of the most difficult methodological problems confronted by the 
    Department in its administration of the CVD law involves the analysis 
    of government-provided equity infusions in situations where there is no 
    market benchmark price. This problem typically arises in the case of 
    firms that are wholly owned by the government. Since 1982, the 
    Department has dealt with this problem by categorizing firms as either 
    ``equityworthy'' or ``unequityworthy.'' As set forth in 
    Sec. 355.44(e)(2) of the 1989 Proposed Regulations, an equityworthy 
    firm was one that showed ``an ability to generate a reasonable rate of 
    return within a reasonable period of time.'' An unequityworthy firm did 
    not show such an ability. If the Department found that a firm was 
    equityworthy, the Department would declare a government-provided equity 
    infusion in the firm to be not countervailable. The Department would 
    not consider whether, notwithstanding the general financial health of a 
    firm, an excessive price was paid for government-provided equity. 
    Conversely, if the Department found a firm to be unequityworthy, the 
    Department would declare a government-provided equity infusion in the 
    firm to be countervailable without further analysis.
        In these regulations, we have retained the equityworthy/
    unequityworthy distinction. Thus, under paragraph (a)(3), if actual 
    private investor prices are not available under paragraph (a)(2), the 
    Secretary will determine whether the firm in question was equityworthy. 
    Paragraph (a)(4) sets forth the standard the Secretary will apply in 
    determining equityworthiness, and is virtually identical to 
    Sec. 355.44(e)(2) of the 1989 Proposed Regulations.
        This distinction between equityworthy and unequityworthy firms has 
    certain administrative advantages. However, as applied by the 
    Department in the past, it was, to some extent, a rather simplistic 
    approach to a complex problem. This point was driven home by the 
    decision in AIMCOR, Alabama Silicon, Inc. v. United States, 912 F. 
    Supp. 549 (Ct. Int'l Trade 1995) (``AIMCOR II''), in which the court 
    ruled that, because of restrictions imposed on certain ``Class E'' 
    shares, the government's purchase of those shares was inconsistent with 
    commercial considerations, notwithstanding the fact that the firm in 
    question was equityworthy. As stated previously by the court in AIMCOR 
    I, ``[w]here a company is equity-worthy, as here, it does not 
    necessarily follow that the purchase of stock from that company will be 
    consistent with commercial considerations.'' 871 F. Supp. at 454.
        While we do not necessarily agree with the court's resolution of 
    the factual issue in AIMCOR II (i.e., whether the purchase of Class E 
    shares was inconsistent with commercial considerations), we do agree 
    with the basic principle articulated by the court. Put in terms of the 
    new statute, where a company is equityworthy, it does not necessarily 
    follow that the purchase of stock from that company will be consistent 
    with the usual investment practice of private investors. Accordingly, 
    paragraph (a)(5) provides that if the Secretary finds a firm to be 
    equityworthy, the Secretary will conduct a further examination to 
    determine whether the particular investment was consistent with usual 
    investment practice. Our intent here is not to conduct a further 
    analysis if the government has purchased common shares in a firm. 
    Instead, we will conduct a further analysis in situations, like AIMCOR 
    I, in which the government has purchased shares to which special 
    conditions or restrictions are attached.
        Thus far, we have been discussing firms determined by the 
    Department to be equityworthy. However, unequityworthy firms present 
    the same problem: just as the Department's practice has oversimplified 
    government-provided equity to equityworthy companies, it has also 
    oversimplified government-provided equity to unequityworthy companies 
    because it assumes that the shares purchased by the government are 
    worthless. We have reconsidered this practice, adopted in the 1993 
    steel determinations, and have
    
    [[Page 8834]]
    
    proposed in these regulations an approach that is consistent with our 
    general rule for equity which directs that consistency with the usual 
    investment practice will normally be determined by reference to the 
    price a private investor would pay for the shares.
        This new approach, reflected in paragraph (a)(6)(i), provides that 
    if the Secretary determines that a firm is unequity-worthy, the 
    Secretary normally will measure the benefit conferred by a government 
    equity infusion by estimating the price that a reasonable private 
    investor would have paid for the shares purchased by the government. If 
    the price paid by the government exceeds this estimated price, the 
    amount of the benefit will be the difference between the two prices. In 
    estimating the price that a reasonable private investor would have 
    paid, the Secretary will rely only on information and analysis that 
    existed at the time of the equity infusion, because this is the 
    information that would have been available to a reasonable private 
    investor.
        At this time, we have not been able to develop a method for 
    calculating the price that a reasonable private investor would have 
    paid for the shares purchased by the government. Among the methods we 
    have considered is an options pricing model, in which possible future 
    returns would be valued using a standard pricing formula for equity 
    call options. To use such a model, we would need to develop estimates 
    for the underlying value of the option and the volatility of expected 
    returns. We would especially welcome comments on the use of such a 
    model for estimating share prices or any alternative methods.
        It has long been recognized that the ideal approach to equity 
    infusions in unequityworthy firms would be to estimate the price that a 
    private investor would have paid for shares purchased by the 
    government. See Holmer et al., Identifying and Measuring Subsidies 
    Under the Countervailing Duty Law: An Attempt at Synthesis, in The 
    Commerce Department Speaks on Import Administration and Export 
    Administration 1984 (Practising Law Institute 1984), at 444. This 
    approach, which we will refer to as the ``constructed private investor 
    price'' method (``CPIP'), corresponds most closely to the preferred 
    methodology. However, in the past, the CPIP method has been rejected as 
    impractical. Id.
        Upon further consideration, we have concluded that before rejecting 
    the CPIP method as impractical, we first should attempt to use it in 
    actual cases. Our conclusion is reinforced by the fact that while our 
    prior practice may not be unreasonable as a legal matter, it is even 
    more reasonable to rely on a methodology that recognizes that, at least 
    in some cases, shares of an unequityworthy firm may have some value.
        We recognize that there may be instances in which the information 
    necessary to estimate what a reasonable private investor would have 
    paid simply does not exist or does not provide an appropriate basis for 
    making such an estimate. Therefore, paragraph (a)(6)(ii) provides an 
    alternative method for measuring the benefit conferred by an equity 
    infusion in an unequityworthy firm. Under this alternative method, the 
    Secretary would allocate the equity infusion to two or more years in 
    accordance with paragraph (c)(2) (discussed below), and would adjust 
    the amount allocated to a particular year by the amount of subsequent 
    after-tax returns achieved in that year by the firm in question. The 
    reason for accounting for subsequent returns is that under our 
    preferred methodology, we are attempting to account for the reasonable 
    private investor's expectations, at the time of the equity infusion in 
    question, regarding a firm's future returns. If available information 
    does not allow us to estimate those expected returns, the best proxy is 
    the actual return earned on the investment. While this approach lacks 
    the conceptual purity of the CPIP method, we believe it is preferable 
    to the grant methodology, which treats all equity infusions in all 
    unequityworthy firms as automatically worthless.
        Although several comments were filed on our methodology for 
    government-provided equity in unequityworthy companies, they fell into 
    one of two camps. One group called for the Department to codify the 
    grant methodology adopted in the 1993 steel cases. These commenters 
    pointed to the fact that the grant methodology has been upheld by the 
    CIT in British Steel plc v. United States, 879 F.Supp. 1254, 1309 (Ct. 
    Int'l Trade 1995). See also, Usinor Sacilor v. United States, 893 
    F.Supp. 1112, 1125-26 (Ct. Int'l Trade 1995). They further maintained 
    that this practice is consistent with the new law.
        The other group of commenters urged the Department to return to the 
    methodology it employed prior to the 1993 steel investigations, the so-
    called ``rate of return shortfall'' (``RORS'') methodology. In their 
    view, the RORS methodology offers the best proxy for determining the 
    amount by which the government overpaid for its shares. These 
    commenters also cited to a GATT Panel Report that, in their view, 
    squarely rejected the grant methodology. (See United States--Imposition 
    of Countervailing Duties on Certain Hot-rolled Lead and Bismuth Carbon 
    Steel Products Originating in France, Germany and the United Kingdom, 
    SCM/185 (Nov.15, 1994) (unadopted).
        Although the CIT has upheld the grant methodology for government-
    provided equity to unequityworthy firms, AIMCOR I led us to review our 
    equity methodology in its entirety. We concluded that a finding of 
    ``equityworthiness'' or ``unequityworthiness'' is not by itself a 
    sufficient basis for measuring the benefit conferred by government-
    provided equity. Specifically, a finding that a firm is equityworthy 
    does not mean that the government paid the price a private investor 
    would have paid for the particular shares in question. Similarly, a 
    finding that a firm is unequityworthy does not mean that a private 
    investor would have paid nothing for the shares purchased by the 
    government. Merely because the government could not expect a reasonable 
    rate of return given the price it paid for its shares, it does not 
    follow that the expected return on the investment is zero. In this 
    respect, we believe that the grant methodology, like the RORS 
    methodology it replaced, does not adequately account for the 
    expectation held by the reasonable private investor, at the time of the 
    infusion, of the company's future rate of return.
        The methodology we have proposed in these regulations for both 
    equityworthy and unequityworthy firms reflects our goal of determining 
    the price a private investor would have paid in either an equityworthy 
    or unequityworthy situation. We believe this approach is preferable to 
    RORS because it attempts to use information available at the time of 
    the government's equity purchase regarding the firm's expected return 
    to calculate the price the government should have paid for the shares 
    it purchased. Moreover, where a CPIP cannot be determined, we believe 
    that the alternative methodology proposed in paragraph (a)(6)(ii) is a 
    better reflection of the benefit conferred on an unhealthy (i.e., 
    unequityworthy) firm receiving government-provided equity than the RORS 
    methodology. This is because, given our finding that the firm is 
    unequityworthy, the best prediction we can make is that the value of 
    the shares is zero. Our prediction may be wrong, and paragraph 
    (a)(6)(ii) allows us to take into account the return we were not able 
    to predict, but the prediction we make of a zero-share price is the 
    best estimate we can make based on information that would have been
    
    [[Page 8835]]
    
    available to investors at the time the government made its equity 
    purchase. Moreover, we believe that our willingness to take into 
    account the return actually earned by the government addresses the 
    concern raised by the GATT Panel.
        Paragraph (a)(7) deals with allegations regarding equity infusions, 
    and is based on Sec. 355.44(e)(3) of the 1989 Proposed Regulations. In 
    our view, Sec. 355.44(e)(3) has not posed an undue burden on 
    petitioners nor prevented the filing of meritorious allegations. 
    However, it does ensure that allegations will consist of something more 
    than a mere statement that a government owns a firm in whole or in 
    part.
        Paragraph (b) provides that the Secretary normally will consider 
    the benefit from an equity infusion to have been received as of the 
    date on which the firm received the infusion.
        Paragraph (c) deals with the allocation of the benefit to 
    particular years and provides in (c)(1) a general rule that the 
    Secretary will normally allocate the benefit of an equity infusion over 
    the same allocation period that would be used for a non-recurring 
    grant. Paragraph (c)(2) provides that where the Secretary has measured 
    the benefit by reference to actual or constructed private investor 
    prices (and, thus, has calculated a premium that can be viewed as a 
    grant), the Secretary will allocate the benefit as if it were a non-
    recurring grant, using the methodology set forth for such grants in 
    Sec. 351.503(c)(2). This approach is consistent with 
    Sec. 355.49(a)(3)(i) of the 1989 Proposed Regulations, which also 
    required that equity infusions be treated as grants if a market-
    determined price was used to identify and measure the benefit.
        Paragraph (c)(3) applies to equity infusions in unequityworthy 
    firms in situations where the Secretary cannot use the CPIP method 
    under paragraph (a)(6)(i). Paragraph (c)(2) also provides for the 
    allocation of the equity infusion as if it were a non-recurring grant, 
    but references the fact that the Secretary will adjust the allocated 
    amount in accordance with paragraph (a)(6)(ii).
    
    Section 351.507
    
        Section 351.507 deals with assumptions or forgiveness of debt. 
    Paragraph (a), which deals with the identification and measurement of 
    the benefit attributable to government-provided debt assumptions or 
    forgiveness, is little changed from Sec. 355.44(k) of the 1989 Proposed 
    Regulations. Paragraph (b) describes when the benefit from debt 
    assumption or forgiveness will be deemed to have been received. 
    Paragraph (c) provides that the Secretary will normally treat the 
    benefit from debt assumption or forgiveness as a non-recurring grant 
    for allocation purposes. However, where the government is assuming 
    interest under certain narrowly-drawn circumstances, the interest 
    assumption will be treated as a reduced-interest loan and allocated 
    according to the loan allocation rules. Although it has undergone some 
    refinement, this exception is consistent with the policy articulated by 
    the Department in the 1993 steel determinations.
    
    Section 351.508
    
        Section 351.508 deals with subsidy programs that provide a benefit 
    in the form of relief from direct taxes. (``Direct tax'' is defined in 
    Sec. 351.102.) The most common form of a direct tax is an income tax, 
    and the subsidy programs most frequently encountered are those that 
    provide special income tax exemptions, deductions or credits. With 
    respect to the benefit provided by these types of programs, paragraph 
    (a)(1) of Sec. 351.509 retains the standard set forth in 
    Sec. 355.44(i)(1) of the 1989 Proposed Regulations; i.e., a benefit 
    exists to the extent that the taxes paid by a firm as the result of a 
    program are less than the taxes the firm would have paid in the absence 
    of the program. See 1989 Proposed Regulations, 54 FR at 23372, and 
    cases cited therein.
        Another type of direct tax program is the deferral of direct taxes 
    owed. Although Sec. 355.44(i)(1) included tax deferrals with exemptions 
    and remissions of direct taxes, the Department has consistently used a 
    different methodology for identifying and measuring the benefits of 
    deferrals, treating deferrals as government-provided loans. Therefore, 
    consistent with our practice, paragraph (a)(2) directs that the loan 
    methodology described in Sec. 351.504 will be applied to direct tax 
    deferrals. Normally, deferrals of one year or less will be treated as 
    short-term loans, while multi-year deferrals will be treated as short-
    term loans rolled over on the anniversary date(s) of the deferral.
        Although the Department did not receive any private sector comments 
    regarding direct tax subsidy programs, the Department has identified 
    one aspect of its practice that might warrant modification. In the case 
    of special accelerated depreciation allowances, a firm typically 
    experiences tax savings in the early years of an asset's life and tax 
    increases in the latter years of the asset's life. In the past, the 
    Department has focused on the tax savings, but has not acknowledged the 
    later tax increases. The Department is considering adopting a 
    methodology that accounts for both the early tax savings and the later 
    tax increases by calculating the net present value of the expected tax 
    savings at the outset of the accelerated depreciation period. Before 
    doing so, however, the Department would like to obtain the views of the 
    private sector. We are also seeking private sector views on how the 
    direct tax methodology should address losses, including loss 
    carryforwards and treatment of losses under accelerated depreciation. 
    Therefore, on these matters in particular, we encourage public comment.
        Paragraph (b) of Sec. 351.508 deals with the question of when the 
    benefit from a direct tax subsidy is considered to have been received 
    by a firm, and is based on Sec. 355.48(b)(4) of the 1989 Proposed 
    Regulations. As under current practice, the Secretary will consider the 
    benefit from a tax exemption, deduction, or credit to have been 
    received as of the date when the recipient firm can calculate the 
    amount of the benefit, which normally will be when the firm files its 
    tax return. In the case of a tax deferral of one year or less, the 
    Secretary normally will consider the benefit to have been received when 
    the deferred tax becomes due. For a multi-year deferral, the benefit is 
    received on the anniversary date(s) of the deferral.
        Paragraph (c) deals with the allocation of the benefits of direct 
    tax subsidies to particular time periods. As under current practice, 
    the Department normally will allocate such benefits to the year in 
    which the benefits are considered to have been received under paragraph 
    (b).
    
    Section 351.509
    
        Section 351.509 deals with programs that provide full or partial 
    exemptions from, and deferrals of, indirect taxes or import charges. 
    (``Indirect tax'' and ``Import charge'' are defined in Sec. 351.102). 
    However, Sec. 351.509 deals only with programs that potentially would 
    be considered import substitution subsidies or domestic subsidies under 
    section 771(5A)(C) or section 771(5A)(D) of the Act, respectively. 
    Sections 351.516-518 deal with programs that potentially would be 
    considered export subsidies under section 771(5A)(B) of the Act because 
    they provide for an exemption or rebate of indirect taxes or import 
    charges when a product is exported.
        Paragraph (a)(1) of Sec. 351.509 is based on Sec. 355.44(i)(2) of 
    the 1989 Proposed Regulations, and continues to provide that a benefit 
    exists to the extent that the taxes or import charges paid by a firm as 
    the result of a program are less than
    
    [[Page 8836]]
    
    the taxes the firm would have paid in the absence of the program. As in 
    the case of direct taxes under Sec. 351.508, deferrals of indirect 
    taxes and import charges will be treated under paragraph (a)(2) as 
    government-provided loans. Normally, deferrals of one year or less will 
    be treated as short-term loans, while multi-year deferrals will be 
    treated as short-term loans rolled over on the anniversary date(s) of 
    the deferral.
        Paragraph (b) of Sec. 351.509 is based on Sec. 355.48(b)(6) of the 
    1989 Proposed Regulations, and continues to provide that the Secretary 
    will consider the benefit from a full or partial exemption of indirect 
    taxes or import charges to have been received as of the date when the 
    recipient firm otherwise would have had to pay the tax or charge. In 
    the case of deferrals of one year or less, the Secretary normally will 
    consider the benefit to have been received when the deferred amount 
    becomes due. For multi-year deferrals, the benefit is received on the 
    anniversary date(s) of the deferral.
        Paragraph (c) deals with allocation to a particular time period, 
    and provides that the Secretary normally will allocate (expense) to the 
    year of receipt the benefits attributable to the types of subsidy 
    programs covered by Sec. 351.509.
    
    Section 351.510
    
        Section 351.510 deals with the provision of goods and services. As 
    explained below, we have designated paragraph (a) as ``[Reserved]'' in 
    order to first acquire some experience with the relevant statutory 
    provision before codifying our methodology in the form of regulations. 
    Paragraph (b) is based on Sec. 355.48(b)(2) of the 1989 Proposed 
    Regulations, and continues to provide that the benefit from a 
    government-provided good or service is considered to be received when 
    the firm pays, or is due to pay, for the good or service. Paragraph 
    (c), which also is consistent with existing practice, provides that the 
    Secretary will expense the benefit of a government-provided good or 
    service to the year of receipt.
    
    Adequate Remuneration
    
        Prior to the URAA, section 771(5)(A)(ii)(II) of the Act provided 
    that the provision of goods or services constituted a subsidy if such 
    provision was ``at preferential rates.'' Now, under section 
    771(5)(E)(iv) of the Act, a subsidy exists if such provision is ``for 
    less than adequate remuneration.'' Under section 771(5)(E) of the Act, 
    the adequacy of remuneration is to be determined
    
        * * * in relation to prevailing market conditions for the good 
    or service being provided * * * in the country which is subject to 
    the investigation or review. Prevailing market conditions include 
    price, quality, availability, marketability, transportation, and 
    other conditions of purchase or sale.
    
        One commenter suggested that we provide guidance in the regulations 
    concerning how the Department intends to identify and measure adequate 
    remuneration. Other commenters debated whether the Department is 
    required to define adequate remuneration as the price that would exist 
    absent government intervention in the marketplace. At this time, 
    however, we are reluctant to go beyond the terms of the statute and the 
    SAA. Instead, we intend to apply this new standard on a case-by-case 
    basis. Once we have gained sufficient experience in actual cases, a 
    codification of methodology may be appropriate. However, for the time 
    being, we have designated paragraph (a) as ``[Reserved].''
        We should note, however, that while ``adequate remuneration'' has 
    replaced ``preferential'' as the standard, we do not believe this 
    precludes us from continuing to apply certain preferentiality-based 
    analyses we have used in the past. See Pure Magnesium and Alloy 
    Magnesium from Canada, 57 FR 30946, 30949 (1992); and Certain Fresh Cut 
    Flowers from the Netherlands, 52 FR 3301, 3302 (1987). There is no 
    indication that Congress intended to change our practice with respect 
    to government-provided goods and services such as electricity, water, 
    or natural gas; i.e., goods and services provided to a wide variety of 
    users by a government-owned company that is usually the sole provider 
    of the good or service.
        We note further that where adequate remuneration is being 
    ascertained by reference to the prices of goods (or services) imported 
    into the country in question, we would propose to use the amount 
    actually paid for the import. Hence, if the price of the imported good 
    included antidumping or countervailing duties imposed by the country in 
    question, we would use the price inclusive of those duties for 
    comparison purposes. Absent the imposition of antidumping/
    countervailing duties by the country in question, however, we would not 
    adjust the import prices to reflect alleged subsidies or dumping.
    
    Infrastructure
    
        We received several comments regarding the special specificity test 
    for government-provided infrastructure set forth in Sec. 355.43(b)(4) 
    of the 1989 Proposed Regulations. Although the commenters suggested 
    different modifications to this test, they all used Sec. 355.43(b)(4) 
    as a starting point.
        Unlike the prior statute, section 771(5) of the Act, as amended by 
    the URAA, expressly mentions government-provided infrastructure. 
    However, it does so not in the context of specificity, but in the 
    context of ``financial contribution,'' one of the prerequisites for a 
    subsidy. Specifically, section 771(5)(D)(iii) of the Act, which 
    implements Article 1.1(a)(1)(iii) of the SCM Agreement, provides that 
    the term ``financial contribution'' includes the provision of ``goods 
    or services, other than general infrastructure.'' In other words, the 
    provision of ``general infrastructure'' does not constitute a 
    ``financial contribution,'' and, thus, does not constitute a subsidy.
        In light of the change in the statute, the countervailability of 
    infrastructure depends on the definition of ``general infrastructure.'' 
    However, we have no experience in applying this definition, and we are 
    uncertain regarding the extent to which the principles reflected in 
    Sec. 355.43(b)(4) remain useful analytical tools for distinguishing 
    potentially countervailable ``infrastructure'' from non-countervailable 
    ``general infrastructure.'' Therefore, we are not issuing regulations 
    on infrastructure at this time. Instead, we will apply the statutory 
    definition on a case-by-case basis.
    
    Section 351.511
    
        Section 351.511 deals with the purchase of goods. Section 
    771(5)(E)(iv) of the Act provides that the purchase of goods by a 
    government can confer a benefit if the goods are purchased ``for more 
    than adequate remuneration.'' As discussed above in connection with the 
    provisions of goods or services, the Department does not have any 
    experience in applying an adequate remuneration standard. In addition, 
    while government procurement was potentially a countervailable subsidy 
    prior to the URAA, allegations of procurement subsidies were extremely 
    rare. Thus, we do not even have experience on such matters as the 
    ``timing'' of procurement subsidies or the allocation of such subsidies 
    to a particular time period.
        Therefore, given our lack of experience with procurement subsidies 
    in general, and the adequate remuneration standard in particular, we 
    are not issuing regulations concerning the government purchase of 
    goods. Instead, we have designated Section 351.511 as ``[Reserved].''
    
    [[Page 8837]]
    
        In this regard, however, one commenter that suggested a regulation 
    regarding government procurement stated that any such regulation should 
    cover the government procurement of services. Although, for the reasons 
    stated above, we are not promulgating a regulation on government 
    procurement at this time, we should note that under section 
    771(5)(D)(iv) of the Act and Article 1.1(a)(1)(iii) of the SCM 
    Agreement, only government procurement of goods is identified as a 
    financial contribution.
    
    Section 351.512
    
        Section 351.512 deals with worker-related subsidies. Under 
    paragraph (a), which is based on Sec. 355.44(j) of the 1989 Proposed 
    Regulations, the Department will continue to identify and measure the 
    benefit of government-provided assistance to workers based on the 
    extent to which such assistance relieves a firm of an obligation it 
    otherwise normally would incur.
        One commenter argued that the Department should clarify that worker 
    assistance is countervailable only when the assistance relieves a firm 
    of an existing contractual or statutory obligation. Such a 
    clarification would prevent what this commenter considered to be an 
    erroneous determination in Certain Steel Products from Germany, 58 FR 
    38318 (1993); GIA at 37256-57. In that case, the Department 
    countervailed the Member State-funded portion of Article 56(2)(b) early 
    retirement aid based on its conclusion that the government's 
    contribution was likely to have an effect on the outcome of labor 
    negotiations between steel producers and their workers. A different 
    commenter, however, endorsed the Department's determination and the 
    method used by the Department to measure the amount of the subsidy.
        The Department disagrees with the proposal of the first commenter, 
    because, in certain circumstances, the relief from an obligation that 
    is not ``binding'' in a contractual or statutory sense nonetheless may 
    provide a benefit to a firm that is readily identifiable and 
    measurable. On the other hand, the Department is not prepared to codify 
    the particular approach used in Certain Steel Products from Germany. 
    Given the limited alternatives available in that case, we consider the 
    approach used therein to be reasonable. At the same time, we 
    acknowledged in the determination that the approach used was somewhat 
    speculative, and we stated that we would consider further refinements 
    in the future, particularly as part of any administrative review 
    requested. However, because no such review was requested, we have not 
    had the benefit of private sector comments, other than the two comments 
    described above. Moreover, the determination remains the subject of 
    litigation.
        Nevertheless, we may deal with this issue in more detail in the 
    final regulations. Therefore, we invite public comment on this issue in 
    particular.
        Paragraph (b) deals with the timing of worker-related subsidies. 
    Most subsidies of this type are provided in the form of cash payments 
    (grants), and paragraph (b) provides that the Secretary will consider 
    the subsidy to have been received by the firm as of the date on which 
    the payment is made that relieves the firm of the obligation it 
    normally would incur. Paragraph (c) deals with the allocation of 
    worker-related subsidies to a particular time period, and essentially 
    treats these types of subsidies as recurring grants to be allocated 
    (expensed) to the year of receipt.
    
    Section 351.513
    
        Section 351.513 contains a standard for determining when a subsidy 
    is an export subsidy, as opposed to a domestic or import substitution 
    subsidy. Consistent with section 771(5A)(B) of the Act, Sec. 351.513 
    expands the definition of an export subsidy.
        In particular, Sec. 351.513 would overturn the practice described 
    in Extruded Rubber Thread from Malaysia, 57 FR 38472 (1992). In that 
    case, the Malaysian Government considered 12 criteria in evaluating 
    whether a particular company should receive ``pioneer'' status. Two of 
    these criteria addressed the export potential of a product or activity. 
    In addition, in certain situations, companies had to agree to export 
    commitments. In analyzing this program, the Department examined the 
    number of criteria being applied with respect to a particular company. 
    If one or more of the criteria applied by the Government included 
    favorable prospects for export, but the export criteria did not carry 
    preponderant weight, the Department did not consider the award of 
    pioneer status to constitute an export subsidy. However, under the new 
    standard contained in Sec. 351.513, if exportation or anticipated 
    exportation was either the sole or one of several criteria for granting 
    pioneer status to a firm, we would consider any benefits provided under 
    the program to the firm to be export subsidies.
        This expanded definition of export subsidy is not intended to 
    include situations where exportation or anticipated exportation is one 
    of many criteria for awarding benefits under a program, but the firm in 
    question has qualified to receive the benefits under non-export-related 
    criteria. In these circumstances, the Department would not treat the 
    subsidy to that firm as an export subsidy.
    
    Section 351.514
    
        Section 351.514 corresponds to paragraph (c) of the Illustrative 
    List, and deals with preferential internal transport and freight 
    charges on export shipments. Paragraph (a)(1) restates the general 
    principle that a benefit exists to the extent that a firm pays less for 
    the transport of goods destined for export than it would for the 
    transport of goods destined for domestic consumption. In addition, 
    paragraph (a)(2), which is based on Sec. 355.44(g)(2) of the 1989 
    Proposed Regulations, provides that the Secretary will not consider a 
    benefit to exist if differences in charges are the result of an arm's 
    length transaction or are commercially justified.
        Paragraph (b) provides that the Secretary will consider the benefit 
    to have been received as of the date on which the firm pays or, in the 
    absence of payment, was due to pay the transport or freight charges. 
    Paragraph (c) provides that the Secretary will allocate (expense) the 
    benefit to the year in which the benefit is received.
    
    Section 351.515
    
        Section 351.515 deals with the government provision of goods or 
    services on favorable terms or conditions to exporters. Like its 
    predecessor, Sec. 355.44(h) of the 1989 Proposed Regulations, 
    Sec. 351.515 is based on paragraph (d) of the Illustrative List, and 
    reflects the changes to paragraph (d) made as part of the Uruguay 
    Round. Paragraph (a) contains the standard for determining the 
    existence and amount of the benefit attributable to these types of 
    subsidy programs. As paragraph (a)(2) makes clear, in determining 
    whether the domestically sourced input is being provided on more 
    favorable terms than are commercially available on world markets, the 
    Department will add to the world market price delivery charges to the 
    country in question. In our view, delivered prices offer the best 
    measure of prices that are commercially available to exporters in that 
    country. Furthermore, it has been suggested that commercially available 
    prices in world markets may include dumped or subsidized prices and we 
    invite comment on this issue. Paragraphs (b) and (c) contain rules 
    regarding the timing of benefit receipt and the
    
    [[Page 8838]]
    
    allocation of the benefit to a particular time period, respectively.
        One commenter argued that the Department should provide that all 
    export subsidy payments are prohibited per se under the SCM Agreement 
    and U.S. law, and that nothing in paragraph (d) permits them. According 
    to this commenter, in the past, foreign governments have claimed an 
    exception to paragraph (d) for practices that protect domestic markets 
    while promoting subsidized exports of agricultural and manufactured 
    goods. The example cited was the European Community (``EC'') program 
    providing ``export restitution'' payments or ``export refunds'' on 
    durum wheat, the primary agricultural product used in the production of 
    pasta. The commenter stated that these refunds were prohibited because 
    paragraph (d) applied only to the ``provision'' of goods and/or 
    services, not export payments, and that the Department's regulations 
    should clearly prohibit export ``payments.''
        This argument is identical to one put forth by petitioners in the 
    1985 administrative review on Iron Construction Castings from India, 55 
    FR 50747, 50748 (1990). In that case, India's International Price 
    Reimbursement Scheme (``IPRS'') provided payments to castings 
    exporters, refunding the difference between the price of raw materials 
    purchased domestically and the price exporters otherwise would have 
    paid on the world market. The Department refused to examine whether the 
    IPRS met the criteria for non-countervailability under the exception in 
    item (d) and countervailed the IPRS payments in their entirety.
        Exporters and importers challenged the Department's determination, 
    and, in its decision in Creswell Trading Co. v. United States, 783 F. 
    Supp. 1418 (1992), the CIT remanded the case to the Department with 
    instructions to analyze the consistency of the IPRS with item (d). The 
    Federal Circuit discussed this decision with approval in connection 
    with an appeal from a second CIT decision in this same case. See 
    Creswell Trading Co. v. United States, 15 F. 3d 1054 (1994). Therefore, 
    based on the above judicial precedent, we must disagree with the 
    commenter that paragraph (d) does not apply to programs where a 
    government reimburses an exporter for the difference between a higher 
    domestic price for an input and a lower price that the exporter would 
    have paid on the world market, as opposed to providing the input 
    itself.
        Also consistent with the Federal Circuit's decision in Creswell, 
    where a program exists that provides inputs for exported goods at a 
    lower price than is available for inputs for use in the production of 
    goods for domestic consumption, the burden will be on respondents to 
    provide evidence that the lower price reflects the price that is 
    commercially available on world markets.
    
    Section 351.516
    
        Section 351.516 deals with the remission or rebate upon export of 
    indirect taxes. (``Indirect tax'' is defined in Sec. 351.102.) Section 
    351.516 is consistent with longstanding U.S. practice, see Zenith Radio 
    Corp. v. United States, 437 U.S. 443 (1978), and is based on paragraph 
    (g) of the Illustrative List. Paragraph (g) deals with indirect taxes, 
    such as value added taxes, and provides that the remission or rebate of 
    such taxes constitutes an export subsidy only if the amount of the 
    remittance or rebate is excessive; i.e., if it exceeds the amount of 
    indirect taxes levied on like products sold for domestic consumption. 
    For example, if a government imposes a $5 tax on a widget sold for 
    domestic consumption and provides a $10 rebate if the same type of 
    widget is exported, an export subsidy exists in the amount of $5. 
    However, a corollary of paragraph (g) is that the exemption or non-
    excessive remission upon export of indirect taxes does not constitute a 
    subsidy. See note 1 of the SCM Agreement.
        Paragraph (b) provides that the benefit from an excessive rebate of 
    indirect taxes is deemed to be received on the date of exportation. 
    Paragraph (c) provides that the Secretary will expense these types of 
    subsidies to the year of receipt.
    
    Section 351.517
    
        While Sec. 351.516 deals with the exemption or remission of 
    indirect taxes in general, Sec. 351.517 deals with the exemption, 
    remission, or deferral of prior-stage cumulative indirect taxes. 
    (``Prior-stage indirect tax'' and ``cumulative indirect tax'' are 
    defined in Sec. 351.102.) Section 351.517 is based on paragraph (h) of 
    the Illustrative List, and reflects certain changes made to paragraph 
    (h) as part of the Uruguay Round negotiations. Section 351.517 is 
    intended to be consistent with paragraph (h) and the Guidelines on 
    Consumption of Inputs in the Production Process (Annex II to the SCM 
    Agreement).
        Section 351.17 is drafted to address separately exemptions, 
    remissions and deferrals of prior stage cumulative indirect taxes. 
    Paragraph (a)(1) deals with exemptions and states that where inputs are 
    exempt from prior stage cumulative indirect taxes, a benefit exists to 
    the extent that the exemption extends to inputs not consumed in the 
    production of the exported product, making normal allowance for waste. 
    (``Consumed in the production process'' is defined in Sec. 351.102.) 
    Where a benefit exists, it is equal to the amount of the taxes the firm 
    would otherwise pay on inputs not consumed in the production of the 
    exported product.
        Paragraph (a)(2) addresses remissions of indirect taxes and states 
    that a benefit exists to the extent that the amount remitted exceeds 
    the amount of prior stage cumulative indirect taxes paid on inputs that 
    are consumed in the production of the exported product, making normal 
    allowance for waste. Where a benefit exists, paragraph (a)(2) sets 
    forth a general rule to the effect that the amount of the benefit 
    normally will equal the difference between the amount remitted and the 
    amount of prior stage cumulative indirect taxes on inputs that are 
    consumed in the production of the exported product. However, paragraph 
    (a)(2) further directs, based on Annex II to the SCM Agreement, that 
    the Secretary may consider the entire amount of a remission of prior-
    stage cumulative taxes to be a benefit if the Secretary determines that 
    the foreign government has not examined the actual inputs in order to 
    confirm which inputs are consumed in the production of exported 
    products and in what amounts, and the taxes that are imposed and paid 
    on those inputs. This qualification is essentially a modified version 
    of the Department's ``linkage test,'' a test upheld in Industrial 
    Fasteners Group, American Importers Ass'n v. United States, 710 F.2d 
    1576 (Fed. Cir. 1983).
        Paragraph (a)(3) deals with the amount of the benefit attributable 
    to a deferral of prior-stage cumulative indirect taxes. Consistent with 
    footnote 59 to the SCM Agreement, the first sentence of paragraph 
    (a)(3) provides that a deferral does not give rise to a benefit if the 
    government charges appropriate interest on the taxes deferred. 
    Otherwise, the second sentence of paragraph (a)(3) provides that the 
    Secretary will determine the amount of benefit by treating the tax 
    deferral as if it were a government-provided loan in the amount of the 
    taxes deferred. Normally, deferrals of one year or less will be treated 
    as short-term loans, while multi-year deferrals will be treated as 
    short-term loans rolled over on the anniversary date(s) of the 
    deferral.
    
    [[Page 8839]]
    
        Paragraph (b) deals with the time of receipt of the benefit. 
    Paragraph (b)(1) provides that in the case of a tax exemption, the 
    benefit is received as of the date on which the tax otherwise would 
    have been due. Paragraph (b)(2) provides that in the case of a tax 
    remission, the benefit arises as of the date of exportation. Paragraphs 
    (b)(3) and (b)(4) address deferrals, stating that the Secretary will 
    normally treat the benefit as having been received when the tax would 
    otherwise be due, for a deferral of one year or less, or on the 
    anniversary date(s) of the deferral for multi-year deferrals. Paragraph 
    (c) deals with the allocation of the benefit to a particular time 
    period, and provides that the Secretary will allocate (expense) the 
    benefit from an exemption, remission, or deferral of prior-stage 
    cumulative indirect taxes to the year of receipt.
    
    Section 351.518
    
        Section 351.518 deals with the remission or drawback of import 
    charges. Section 351.518 generally is consistent with prior Department 
    practice, but contains some revisions to reflect changes made to 
    paragraph (i) of the Illustrative List during the Uruguay Round 
    negotiations. Section 351.518 is intended to be consistent with 
    paragraph (i), the Guidelines on Consumption of Inputs in the 
    Production Process, and the Guidelines in the Determination of 
    Substitution Drawback Systems as Export Subsidies (Annex III to the SCM 
    Agreement).
        Paragraph (a)(1) reflects the longstanding principle that 
    governments may remit or drawback import charges levied on imported 
    inputs when the finished product is exported. However, if the amount 
    remitted or drawnback exceeds the amount of import charges levied, a 
    benefit exists.
        Paragraph (a)(2) deals with so-called ``substitution drawback.'' 
    Under a substitution drawback system, a firm may substitute domestic 
    inputs for imported inputs without losing its eligibility for drawback. 
    However, a benefit exists if the amount drawnback exceeds the amount of 
    import charges levied on imported inputs, or if the export of the 
    finished product does not occur within a reasonable time (not to exceed 
    two years) of the import of the inputs.
        Paragraph (a)(3) deals with the calculation of the amount of 
    benefit attributable to an excessive remission or drawback of import 
    charges. Paragraph (a)(3)(i) sets forth the general rule that the 
    amount of the benefit equals the difference between the amount remitted 
    or drawnback and the amount of import charges levied initially on the 
    imported inputs for which the remission or drawback is claimed. For 
    example, assume that a firm imports widgets to produce gizmos, and pays 
    $2 in import duties per widget. If, when the firm exports finished 
    gizmos, the firm receives $5 in drawback, the benefit equals $3 
    ($5-$2=$3).
        However, paragraph (a)(3)(ii) provides that in certain 
    circumstances, the Secretary may consider the amount of the benefit to 
    equal the amount of the remission or drawback. Paragraph (a)(3)(ii) 
    provides for a ``linkage'' test, and is essentially identical to 
    Sec. 351.517(a)(2)(ii). See discussion of Sec. 351.517(a)(2)(ii), 
    above.
        Paragraph (b) provides that the Secretary normally will consider 
    the benefit to have been received as of the date of exportation. 
    Paragraph (c) provides that the Secretary normally will allocate this 
    benefit to the year in which it is received.
    
    Section 351.519
    
        Section 351.519 deals with export insurance. Paragraph (a), which 
    deals with the benefit attributable to export insurance, is based on 
    paragraph (j) of the Illustrative List. Paragraph (a) differs from the 
    section of the 1989 Proposed Regulations dealing with export insurance, 
    Sec. 355.44(d). First, to reflect changes made to the Illustrative List 
    during the Uruguay Round, the word ``manifestly'' has been deleted.
        Second, Sec. 355.44(d) required that an export insurance program 
    must have exhibited losses for a five-year period before the Secretary 
    would consider the program a countervailable subsidy. We have not 
    included the five-year loss requirement in these regulations, because, 
    depending on how an export insurance program is structured, it may be 
    evident earlier than five years that premiums will be inadequate to 
    cover the long-term operating costs and losses of the program. On the 
    other hand, where the program is structured in such a way that expected 
    premiums can cover expected long-term operating costs and losses, we 
    anticipate that we will continue to apply the five-year rule. For 
    example, we would continue to apply the five-year rule to programs like 
    the Israeli Exchange Insurance Scheme. With respect to this program, we 
    originally determined that it was structured so as to be self-balancing 
    in the sense that it could reasonably be expected to break even over 
    the long term. See Potassium Chloride from Israel, 49 FR 36122, 36214 
    (1984). Therefore, we did not find a countervailable subsidy despite 
    losses in the early years of the program. However, after observing 
    losses for five years, we concluded that the premiums charges were 
    inadequate, and we determined that the scheme conferred a 
    countervailable benefit.
        Finally, Sec. 355.44(d)(1) stated that the Department would take 
    into account income from other insurance programs operated by the 
    entity in question. We have reconsidered this policy, and, although we 
    do not have much experience in this regard, have concluded that this 
    requirement may be overly restrictive. For example, there may be 
    instances where the insuring entity operates on a commercial basis, 
    except for the export insurance function that may be specifically 
    underwritten by the government. In such a situation, it would be 
    inappropriate to take into account the insuring company's income from 
    other insurance programs.
    
    Section 351.520
    
        Section 351.520 continues and codifies the Department's practice 
    with respect to certain types of government export promotion 
    activities. As the Department has observed in the past, most countries, 
    including the United States, maintain general export promotion 
    programs. As long as these programs provide only general information 
    services, such as information concerning export opportunities or 
    government advocacy efforts on behalf of a country's exporters, they do 
    not confer a benefit for purposes of the CVD law. However, if, for 
    example, such activities promoted a specific product or provided 
    financial assistance to a firm, a benefit could exist under one of the 
    other provisions of subpart E.
    
    Section 351.521
    
        Section 771(5A)(C) of the Act defines an ``import substitution 
    subsidy'' as ``a subsidy that is contingent upon the use of domestic 
    goods over imported goods, alone or as 1 of 2 or more conditions.'' As 
    stated in the Senate Report, ``the category of import substitution 
    subsidies is a new one that is neither part of the 1979 Subsidies Code 
    nor included in current law.'' S. Rep. No. 412, 103rd Cong., 2d Sess. 
    93 (1994). Under the new law, import substitution subsidies are 
    automatically considered to be specific.
        Two domestic parties commented that the Department should state in 
    its regulations that import substitution subsidies include subsidies 
    that are contingent ``in law or in fact'' upon the use of domestic over 
    imported goods. The quoted language is included in the export subsidy 
    definition in section 771(5A)(B) of the Act, but does not
    
    [[Page 8840]]
    
    appear in the import substitution subsidy definition in section 
    771(5A)(C) of the Act. One of the parties argued that similar language 
    should be included in a regulatory definition of import substitution 
    subsidy to avoid a ``potential loophole'' for de facto import 
    substitution subsidies.
        We agree with these commenters that the statute does not expressly 
    state that import substitution subsidies include those that are 
    contingent ``in law or in fact'' upon the use of domestic over imported 
    goods. On the other hand, however, the plain language of section 
    771(5A)(C) does not limit the definition of import substitution 
    subsidies to only those subsidies that are contingent ``in law'' upon 
    the use of domestic goods.
        Because of the Department's lack of experience in dealing with this 
    new category of subsidies, we are not issuing a regulation at this time 
    on this particular point. Instead, we intend to develop our practice 
    regarding import substitution subsidies on a case-by-case basis. 
    However, the omission at this time of explicit ``in law or in fact'' 
    language from these regulations should not be construed as an 
    indication that the Department believes that section 771(5A)(C) applies 
    only to de jure import substitution measures.
    
    Section 351.522
    
    Certain Agricultural Subsidies
        Section 771(5B)(F) of the Act implements provisions of the WTO 
    Agreement on Agriculture regarding the noncountervailable status of 
    certain ``domestic support measures.'' Under Annex 2 of the Agreement 
    on Agriculture, domestic support measures that meet the policy-specific 
    criteria and conditions of Annex 2 are exempt from Member countries' 
    commitments to reduce subsidies. In addition, Article 13(a) of the 
    Agreement on Agriculture directs that these subsidies, commonly 
    referred to as ``green box'' subsidies, will be noncountervailable 
    during the nine-year implementation period described in Article 1(f) of 
    the Agreement on Agriculture.
        In accordance with section 13(a) of the Agreement, section 
    771(5B)(F) of the Act provides that the Secretary will treat as 
    noncountervailable domestic support measures that (1) are provided with 
    respect to products listed in Annex 1 of the Agreement on Agriculture, 
    and (2) that the Secretary ``determines conform fully to the provisions 
    of Annex 2'' of that Agreement. To implement section 771(5B)(F), 
    Sec. 351.522 sets out the criteria the Secretary will consider in 
    determining whether a particular domestic support measure conforms 
    fully to the provisions of Annex 2.
        One commenter argued that the regulations should require the 
    Secretary to consider whether or not an alleged green box subsidy has 
    trade distorting effects. Further, the commenter noted that the SAA 
    enumerates certain U.S. programs that meet the green box criteria. 
    According to the commenter, the regulations should explicitly treat as 
    noncountervailable a foreign program that is similar to an enumerated 
    U.S. program. This same commenter also argued that the list of eight 
    types of direct payments to producers included in Annex 2 is 
    illustrative, not exclusive. The commenter stated that the regulations 
    should provide ``precise, objective and even-handed'' criteria for 
    determining whether a particular subsidy is a green box subsidy. A 
    second commenter disputed the suggestion that the regulations should 
    include a list of agricultural programs that the Secretary 
    automatically would consider as noncountervailable. According to this 
    commenter, there is no basis in the statute for automatically exempting 
    particular programs from the CVD law. Instead, this commenter argued, 
    the Department should assess whether particular programs meet the green 
    box criteria on a case-by-case basis.
        The Department believes there is little to be gained from 
    enumerating in the regulations specific types of programs that would 
    qualify automatically as green box subsidies. Annex 2 of the Agreement 
    provides explicit criteria that a program must meet to receive green 
    box status, and Sec. 351.522 reflects the plain language of these 
    criteria. Consistent with section 771(5B)(F) of the Act and the 
    Agreement on Agriculture, paragraph (a) of Sec. 351.522 provides that 
    the Secretary will treat as noncountervailable a subsidy provided to an 
    agricultural product listed in Annex 1 of the Agreement if the subsidy 
    fully conforms to both the basic criteria of subparagraphs (a) and (b) 
    of paragraph 1 of Annex 2 and the relevant policy-specific criteria and 
    conditions set out in paragraphs 2 through 13 of that Annex.
        In this regard, we received two comments concerning the so-called 
    ``peace clause'' in the Agreement on Agriculture. Specifically, 
    Articles 13 (b) and (c) of that Agreement require WTO Member countries 
    to exercise ``due restraint'' in initiating CVD proceedings on 
    agricultural subsidies provided by a Member whose total non-green box 
    agricultural subsidies (both domestic and export) are within that 
    Member's reduction commitments. See SAA at 67-69. The obligation to 
    exercise ``due restraint'' exists only during the ``implementation 
    period,'' defined in Article 1(f) of the Agreement on Agriculture.
        One commenter argued that the Department's regulations should 
    ensure that the Department exercises due restraint by not self-
    initiating CVD investigations on products that benefit from subsidies 
    described in Articles 13 (b) and (c). A second commenter argued that 
    the Department should interpret the due restraint clause narrowly.
        We do not believe that a regulation is necessary on this particular 
    point. The Department understands the due restraint requirement to 
    entail a commitment to refrain from self-initiating CVD investigations, 
    and the Department will administer the statute accordingly.
    Green Light Subsidies in General
        Under section 771(5B), which implements Article 8 of the SCM 
    Agreement, certain domestic subsidies and domestic subsidy programs are 
    treated as noncountervailable, notwithstanding the fact that they are 
    specific under section 771(5A)(D) of the Act. There are three 
    categories of these so-called ``Green Light'' subsidies: (1) Research 
    subsidies (see section 771(5B)(B) of the Act); (2) subsidies to 
    disadvantaged regions (see section 771(5B)(C) of the Act); and (3) 
    subsidies for adaptation of existing facilities to new environmental 
    requirements (see section 771(5B)(D) of the Act). Although at this time 
    we are not promulgating regulations regarding Green Light subsidies, we 
    received many comments concerning this category of subsidies, and we 
    address those comments here.
        The noncountervailable status of these Green Light subsidies can be 
    established in two ways. First, a WTO Member country can notify a 
    subsidy program to the WTO SCM Committee in accordance with Article 8.3 
    of the SCM Agreement. Once notified, section 771(5B)(E) provides that a 
    Green Light subsidy program ``shall not be subject to investigation or 
    review'' by the Department. However, an exception to this rule exists 
    in situations where a member country has successfully challenged in the 
    WTO a claim for Green Light status. In the event of a successful 
    challenge, section 751(g) and section 775 of the Act establish 
    mechanisms for promptly including the subsidy or subsidy program in an 
    existing CVD proceeding should there be reason to believe that 
    merchandise subject to the proceeding may be benefiting from the 
    subsidy or subsidy program.
    
    [[Page 8841]]
    
        The second method for obtaining Green Light status involves 
    situations where a subsidy program has not been notified to the SCM 
    Committee. In the case of a subsidy given under a non-notified program, 
    the subsidy is noncountervailable if the Secretary determines in a CVD 
    investigation or review that the subsidy satisfies the relevant Green 
    Light criteria contained in subparagraphs (B), (C) or (D) of section 
    771(5B). However, the Secretary must determine that the subsidy 
    satisfies all of the relevant criteria before a given subsidy will be 
    treated as noncountervailable. See section 771(5B)(A) of the Act; SAA 
    at 266. Moreover, as discussed in the SAA, in investigations and 
    reviews of non-notified subsidies, the burden will be on the party 
    claiming Green Light status to present evidence demonstrating that a 
    particular subsidy meets all of the relevant criteria. SAA at 266. In 
    addition, under section 771(5B)(A) of the Act, Green Light status may 
    be claimed only in proceedings involving merchandise imported from a 
    WTO Member country.
        In accordance with the Administration's commitment in the SAA, the 
    Department intends to strictly construe the various Green Light 
    provisions to ``limit the scope of the provision(s) to only those 
    situations which clearly warrant non-countervailable treatment.'' SAA 
    at 265. Thus, the Department ``will not limit its analysis * * * to a 
    narrow review of the technical criteria of Article 8 of the SCM 
    Agreement, but will analyze all aspects of the subsidy program and its 
    implementation to ensure that the purposes and terms of Article 8 have 
    been respected.'' SAA at 267.
        Under the transition rules set forth in section 291 of the URAA, 
    the new law applies to investigations and administrative reviews 
    initiated on the basis of post-January 1, 1995 requests. As with other 
    issues that arise in such investigations and reviews, the Department 
    will consider claims for Green Light treatment as parties present such 
    claims to the Department. A Department determination that a particular 
    subsidy received by a firm is a Green Light subsidy would not 
    necessarily mean that the Department would find the entire program 
    under which the subsidy is provided satisfies all of the applicable 
    Green Light criteria in all cases.
        Certain commenters suggested that the Department ``incorporate 
    fully'' in the regulations the discussion of Green Light subsidies 
    contained in the SAA. We do not believe this is necessary. As discussed 
    above, our general approach to the drafting of these regulations has 
    been to avoid simply repeating the language of the statute and/or the 
    SAA.
    Investigation of Notified Subsidies
        One commenter, noting the text of section 771(5B)(E), suggested 
    that the Department should refrain from investigating notified subsidy 
    programs. According to the commenter, a failure to ``screen out'' 
    notified subsidies prior to the initiation of an investigation would 
    result in a waste of Departmental resources and unnecessary burdens on 
    foreign governments.
        In response, several commenters argued that if there is any 
    ambiguity regarding whether a subsidy alleged by a petitioner does, in 
    fact, qualify as a notified Green Light subsidy, the Department should 
    include the subsidy in its CVD investigation or review to determine 
    whether it qualifies for a Green Light exemption. One example given by 
    these commenters is a situation where a petitioner presents evidence 
    that a subsidy program has been modified subsequent to its notification 
    to the SCM Committee. These commenters also suggested that it may 
    simply be unclear whether an alleged subsidy is the same as the 
    notified subsidy, in which case the Department should include the 
    alleged subsidy in the investigation to make this determination.
        In replying to these comments, we note that section 771(5B)(E) of 
    the Act and the SAA make clear that if a subsidy program has been 
    notified under Article 8.3 of the SCM Agreement, any challenge 
    regarding its eligibility for Green Light treatment, whether due to 
    later modification or otherwise, must be made through the review 
    procedures under the WTO rather than in the context of a CVD 
    proceeding. As described above, Commerce may not initiate a CVD 
    investigation or review of a notified subsidy program (which appears to 
    benefit subject merchandise) unless informed by USTR that a violation 
    has been determined under the procedures of Article 8.
        However, the identity of a subsidy is a different matter. If there 
    is a legitimate question as to whether a subsidy alleged in a petition 
    is, in fact, a subsidy that has been notified under Article 8.3, the 
    Department will include the subsidy in a CVD investigation or review in 
    order to resolve the identity of the subsidy in question. If a party 
    claiming Green Light status demonstrated that the alleged subsidy had 
    been notified, that would be the end of the analysis, and the 
    Department would not inquire further as to the subsidy's conformance 
    with the applicable Green Light criteria. If the party failed to 
    establish that the alleged subsidy program had been notified, then the 
    Department would analyze the subsidy's eligibility for Green Light 
    status in the same manner as for any other non-notified subsidy.
        Nevertheless, the Department is not promulgating a regulation 
    concerning this issue at this time. While the manner in which the 
    Department would proceed in the situation described appears fairly 
    straightforward, our lack of experience in administering the new Green 
    Light provisions leaves open the possibility that questions of 
    interpretation will arise that cannot be foreseen at this time.
    Policy for Investigating Non-Notified Subsidies
        One commenter argued that the Department should adopt a regulation 
    providing that, whenever a petition includes a potential Green Light 
    subsidy that has not been notified under Article 8.3, the Department 
    will conduct a full investigation to determine whether the subsidy 
    meets the relevant requirements of section 771(5B). This commenter and 
    others emphasized that the regulations also should include the SAA's 
    express requirement that the party claiming Green Light status has the 
    burden of presenting evidence demonstrating compliance with all of the 
    relevant criteria for any particular subsidy category. See SAA at 266.
        While we do not disagree with the policy espoused, we do not 
    believe that this policy must be codified in the regulations. As 
    discussed above, the statute and the SAA are clear that in 
    investigations and reviews of subsidies that have not been notified 
    under Article 8.3 of the SCM Agreement, the party claiming Green Light 
    status has the burden of presenting evidence demonstrating that a 
    particular subsidy meets all of the relevant criteria for 
    noncountervailable status.
    Alleged Green Light Subsidies not Used During the Period of 
    Investigation or Review
        Although this issue was not raised by any of the commenters, the 
    Department believes that, in an investigation or a review of a CVD 
    order or suspended investigation, the Department should not consider 
    claims for Green Light status if the subject merchandise did not 
    benefit from the subsidy during the period of investigation or review. 
    Instead, consistent with the Department's existing practice, the Green 
    Light status of a subsidy should be considered only in an investigation 
    or review of a time period where the
    
    [[Page 8842]]
    
    subject merchandise did receive a benefit from the subsidy. However, 
    the Department does not believe that a regulation is needed to clarify 
    this issue.
    Research Subsidies
        Prior to the enactment of the URAA, the Department treated 
    assistance provided by a government to finance research and development 
    (``R&D'') as noncountervailable if the R&D results were (or would be) 
    made available to the public, including the U.S. competitors of the 
    recipient of the assistance. This policy, sometimes referred to as the 
    public availability test, was described by Commerce in Sec. 355.44(l) 
    of the 1989 Proposed Regulations. One commenter argued that the 
    Department should reaffirm the public availability test.
        The Department has not retained the public availability test in 
    these regulations. We believe that the objectives served by the public 
    availability test are better met by applying the criteria listed in 
    section 771(5B)(B) of the Act and Article 8.2(a) of the SCM Agreement.
        Another commenter argued that, in determining whether a given 
    research subsidy falls within the 75 and 50 percent maximum allowed 
    under section 771(5B)(B), the Department should base its analysis on 
    the total costs incurred over the duration of the project in question. 
    Under this reasoning, the Department would not countervail a subsidy if 
    the 75 or 50 percent maximum was exceeded during the year under 
    investigation or review, provided that the applicable threshold ``is 
    not exceeded over the life of the project.'' This commenter further 
    argued that, if the Department determined that the applicable threshold 
    was exceeded over the life of the project, only the amount of subsidy 
    in excess of the relevant ``maximum'' should be countervailed.
        Several commenters challenged these arguments. First, they argued 
    that the Department should evaluate the 75 and 50 percent maxima based 
    on the costs already incurred at the time of the relevant investigation 
    or administrative review, and not on the basis of expected costs over 
    the lifetime of the project. Second, these commenters argued that, if 
    the Department determined that the applicable threshold had been 
    exceeded, the entire benefit--not just the excess over the relevant 
    threshold--should be countervailed. According to these commenters, the 
    SAA states clearly that all of the relevant criteria must be met for a 
    given program to receive Green Light status, and that a failure to meet 
    all relevant criteria would result in the ``entire subsidy'' being 
    countervailable in full. See SAA at 266.
        The Department agrees in part with the first commenter, and in part 
    with the latter commenters. With respect to the proper frame of 
    reference for determining whether a given research subsidy has exceeded 
    the 75 or 50 percent maximum, section 771(5B)(B)(iii)(II) of the Act 
    instructs the Department to base its analysis on ``the total eligible 
    costs incurred over the duration of a particular project.'' Thus, it 
    would be improper for the Department to limit its analysis to only 
    those costs incurred as of the time period covered by an investigation 
    or administrative review. The Department agrees, however, that if, over 
    the duration of a project, the subsidy exceeds the 75 or 50 percent 
    threshold, the entire amount of the subsidy is countervailable, not 
    merely the excess. Also, if it is indisputable at the outset of the 
    project that the relevant threshold will be exceeded, the entire amount 
    of the subsidy is countervailable.
    Subsidies to Disadvantaged Regions
        One commenter suggested that the Department should clarify that the 
    Green Light category regarding subsidies to disadvantaged regions is 
    not limited to subsidies provided by national governments, but also 
    includes subsidies granted by subnational levels of government, such as 
    states or provinces. This commenter further argued that, in determining 
    whether a subsidy provided by a state or province to a disadvantaged 
    region meets the criteria of section 771(5B)(C) of the Act, the 
    Department should assess the criteria within the framework of the 
    subnational government's jurisdiction.
        In response, other commenters argued that the Department should 
    assess the Green Light criteria in relation to the investigated country 
    as a whole, not just in relation to the jurisdiction of the subsidizing 
    government if that government is at the subnational level. According to 
    these commenters, the statute and the SAA instruct the Department to 
    evaluate the relevant Green Light criteria in relation to the ``average 
    for the country subject to investigation or review.''
        We agree with the first commenter that the Green Light categories 
    include subsidies granted by governments at the subnational level, and 
    that, in the case of the regional category, the Department should 
    assess the relevant criteria in relation to the jurisdiction of the 
    granting authority. In discussing the language in section 
    771(5B)(C)(ii) of the Act regarding the ``average for the country 
    subject to investigation or review,'' the SAA explains that, where a 
    CVD proceeding involves a member of a customs union, the term 
    ``country'' shall be defined in accordance with the structure of the 
    regional assistance program. SAA at 264. For example, if the Department 
    were to investigate a product from Luxembourg, the term ``country'' 
    would refer to the EC as a whole if the subsidy being investigated was 
    received under an EC regional assistance program. Thus, the SAA 
    indicates that the Department should make its determinations based on 
    averages for the jurisdiction granting the regional assistance subsidy. 
    Although the Department is not promulgating a regulation on this point, 
    the Department intends to adopt this approach as a matter of practice.
    Subsidies for Adaptation of Existing Facilities to New Environmental 
    Requirements
        One commenter argued that, with respect to the Department's 
    criteria for Green Light environmental subsidies described in section 
    771(5B)(D) of the Act, the Department should treat as 
    noncountervailable those subsidies given to upgrade existing facilities 
    to environmental standards that are higher than the minimum standards 
    imposed by law or regulation. According to this commenter, 
    ``[g]overnments should be allowed the flexibility to encourage higher 
    environmental standards than the minimum required by law when 
    government shares the additional costs of achieving the higher 
    environmental standards.''
        Several commenters dispute this suggestion, claiming that section 
    771(5B)(D)(i) specifically limits Green Light status for environmental 
    subsidies to those that are ``provided to promote the adaptation of 
    existing facilities to new environmental requirements * * * .'' 
    According to these commenters, the Department has no authority to 
    broaden the scope of environmental subsidies eligible for Green Light 
    treatment.
        Although we acknowledge that governments should have the 
    flexibility to encourage higher environmental standards, the Department 
    agrees with the latter commenters. As noted above, section 
    771(5B)(D)(i) provides that noncountervailable environmental subsidies 
    are those that are ``provided to promote the adaptation of existing 
    facilities to new environmental requirements that are imposed by 
    statute or by regulation * * * .'' According to the SAA, ``strict 
    application of these requirements is essential in order to limit the 
    scope of the provision to only those situations
    
    [[Page 8843]]
    
    which clearly warrant non-countervailable treatment.'' SAA at 267. 
    Given the clear language of the statute and the SAA, the Department 
    believes that subsidies given to upgrade existing facilities to 
    environmental standards in excess of legal requirements are 
    countervailable.
    
    Section 351.523
    
        Section 351.523 deals with the identification and measurement of 
    upstream subsidies. Because the URAA did not significantly amend the 
    corresponding statutory provision, section 771A of the Act, 
    Sec. 351.523 is based largely on Sec. 355.45 of the 1989 Proposed 
    Regulations, except for the deletion of language that merely repeats 
    the statute. However, we have made one change that reflects a change in 
    practice regarding the identification and measurement of the 
    competitive benefit bestowed by an upstream subsidy. Before turning to 
    that change, we note that we have adopted certain new terminology in 
    Sec. 351.523(a). Specifically, we have replaced ``control'' with 
    ``cross ownership.'' See Sec. 351.524(b)(6) for an explanation of 
    ``cross ownership.''
        Regarding ``competitive benefit'' and upstream subsidies, 
    Sec. 351.523 sets forth the standard for determining whether a 
    competitive benefit exists. In this regard, section 771A(b)(1) of the 
    Act provides that a competitive benefit exists when
    
        * * * the price for the (subsidized) input product is lower than 
    the price that the manufacturer or producer of merchandise which is 
    the subject of a countervailing duty proceeding would otherwise pay 
    for the product in obtaining it from another seller in an arms-
    length transaction.
    
    In addition, section 771A(b)(2) of the Act provides that when the 
    Secretary has determined in a previous proceeding that a 
    countervailable subsidy is paid or bestowed on the comparison input 
    product, the Department ``may (A) where appropriate, adjust the price 
    that the manufacturer or producer of merchandise which is the subject 
    of such proceeding would otherwise pay for the product to reflect the 
    effects of the countervailable subsidy, or (B) select in lieu of that 
    price a price from another source.''
        In the past, as reflected in Sec. 355.45(d) of the 1989 Proposed 
    Regulations, the Department preferred to base its comparisons upon the 
    price charged for unsubsidized inputs produced by other producers in 
    the same country as the producer of the subject merchandise. If the 
    Department had determined in a prior CVD proceeding that a 
    countervailable subsidy had been bestowed in the subject country on the 
    comparison input, the Department's next preferred alternative was to 
    adjust the price of the input product to reflect the subsidy. As a 
    final alternative, the Department could select a ``world market price 
    for the input product.'' The Department interpreted the phrase ``world 
    market price'' broadly to include (1) actual prices charged for the 
    input product by producers located in other countries, and (2) average 
    import prices. Additionally, because the statute did not preclude, for 
    comparison purposes, the use of prices of subsidized, imported inputs, 
    the Department had determined that it would be ``inappropriate to 
    exclude all subsidized producers, even assuming that we could identify 
    them.'' Circular Welded Non-Alloy Steel Pipe From Venezuela; Final 
    Determination, 57 FR 42964, 42967-68 (1992).
        We have revised our approach regarding ``competitive benefit'' in 
    the following manner. Under paragraph (c)(1)(i), we will rely first 
    upon the actual price charged or offered for an unsubsidized input 
    product, regardless of whether the producer of that input is located in 
    the same country as the producer of the subject merchandise. Upon 
    further reflection, we see no justification for distinguishing between 
    input products based on the country of production. Section 771A(b)(1) 
    of the Act merely requires the Department to compare the price paid for 
    the subsidized input product to the price that the producer ``would 
    otherwise pay for the product in obtaining it from another seller in an 
    arms-length transaction.'' The price that the producer ``would 
    otherwise pay'' could include the actual price paid by the producer of 
    subject merchandise to an unrelated supplier or a bid offered by an 
    unrelated supplier, regardless of the location of that supplier.
        If actual prices or offers for unsubsidized inputs are not 
    available, we have concluded that it is preferable to rely upon an 
    average of publicly available prices for unsubsidized inputs from 
    different countries or some other surrogate price deemed appropriate by 
    the Department. See paragraph (c)(1)(ii). Only if there are no prices 
    for unsubsidized inputs available from any source will we adjust the 
    price of the comparison input product to reflect a countervailable 
    subsidy. In such a case, under paragraph (c)(1)(iii), we first will 
    rely upon the actual price that the producer of the subject merchandise 
    otherwise would pay for the input product adjusted to reflect the 
    subsidy, regardless of the country in which the input product is 
    produced. If such a price is not available, under paragraph (c)(1)(iv), 
    the Department would use an average price for the input product from 
    different countries adjusted to reflect the subsidy or some other 
    adjusted surrogate price. Only when no adjustable price is available 
    (e.g., the only available price is a published price reflecting an 
    average of both subsidized and non-subsidized prices), would we rely 
    upon the price of a subsidized input. See paragraph (c)(1)(v).
        We believe that the approach described in the preceding paragraph 
    better reflects the overall purpose of the upstream subsidies 
    provision, which is to account, when appropriate, for upstream 
    subsidies provided on input products used in the production or 
    manufacture of subject merchandise. The language of section 771A itself 
    does not express a preference regarding the selection of a comparison 
    input price, and grants the Department wide latitude in determining 
    when to adjust the price of the comparison product to reflect known 
    countervailable subsidies. However, parts of the legislative history 
    underlying the Trade and Tariff Act of 1984, which added section 771A 
    to the Act, support a preference for using the price of an unsubsidized 
    input, and that the Department should make adjustments for subsidies 
    only when there is no price for unsubsidized inputs. See, e.g., 130 
    Cong. Rec. S13970 (daily ed. Oct. 9, 1984) (statement of Sen. Dole). 
    Although, as described above, we are revising our practice regarding 
    the identification and measurement of a competitive benefit, the 
    preference for using the price of unsubsidized inputs also was 
    reflected in the Department's earlier practice. See, e.g., Agricultural 
    Tillage Tools from Brazil, 50 FR 24270, 24273 (1985).
        In the hierarchy described above for selecting the price that the 
    producer otherwise would pay for the input, we intend to use subsidized 
    prices only when unsubsidized prices are not available. In determining 
    whether a price is subsidized, we will rely primarily on CVD findings 
    made by the United States or the investigating authorities of other 
    countries in the recent past (i.e., within the past five years).
        One other clarification in paragraph (c) is that in determining 
    whether there is a competitive benefit, the Department will adjust 
    prices upward to account for delivery charges (i.e., c.i.f.). Although 
    the statute does not specify the precise basis for calculating a 
    benchmark price for the input product, section 771A(b)(1) does require 
    the use of the price that the manufacturer or producer of the subject 
    merchandise ``would otherwise pay.'' In
    
    [[Page 8844]]
    
    our view, this requires the use of a price that represents a commercial 
    alternative to the producer of the subject merchandise, and f.o.b. 
    prices do not provide a measurement of the commercial alternative to 
    the downstream producer. See Non-Alloy Steel Pipe from Venezuela, 57 FR 
    at 42967 (1992).
        Several outside parties commented on the upstream subsidies 
    provision. One commenter argued that when using a world market price as 
    a benchmark, the Department should rely upon an average of all publicly 
    available export prices, including U.S. export prices. In response, 
    several domestic parties argued that the world market price should 
    equal the weighted-average landed price of the input product within the 
    country under investigation. These commenters added that the price 
    should also include all delivery expenses. Finally, other domestic 
    parties suggested a hierarchy that would apparently not include any 
    averaged prices from the world market, but instead would be limited to 
    (1) actual prices paid by the producer of the subject merchandise to 
    domestic or third-country suppliers, or (2) information regarding 
    prices from such suppliers. We believe the above explanation adequately 
    addresses the concerns raised by these comments.
    
    Section 351.524
    
        Section 351.524 deals with the calculation of the ad valorem 
    subsidy rate and the attribution of a subsidy to a particular product. 
    While Sec. 351.524 is based roughly on Sec. 355.47 of the 1989 Proposed 
    Regulations, it contains changes that reflect further refinements in 
    the Department's practice since 1989.
        Paragraph (a) deals with the calculation of the ad valorem subsidy 
    rate, and continues to provide that the Secretary will calculate the 
    rate by dividing the amount of the subsidy benefit by the sales value 
    of the product or products to which the subsidy is attributed. For 
    example, if a firm receives an untied domestic subsidy for which the 
    benefit is $100 and the firm's total sales were $1,000, the ad valorem 
    subsidy rate would be 10 percent ($100  $1,000 = 10 percent).
        The second and third sentences of paragraph (a) deal with the basis 
    on which the Secretary will determine the sales value of a product. The 
    Department's longstanding practice has been to determine sales value 
    for products that are exported on an F.O.B. (port) basis in order to 
    correspond to the basis on which the Customs Service assesses duties. 
    However, in the GIA, the Department announced that it would begin using 
    sales values as recorded in a firm's financial statements. The 
    Department did so in the belief that this approach would be more 
    accurate, would reduce the burden on the firms involved, and would 
    allow the Department to account for the fact that shipping expenses 
    might be subsidized. However, in order to ensure that the Customs 
    Service collected the correct amount of duties based on an F.O.B. 
    (port) basis, the Department found it necessary to adjust the 
    calculated ad valorem subsidy rate based on a ratio of the invoice 
    value of exports to the United States to the F.O.B. value of exports to 
    the United States. In the end, only one of the respondents in the 1993 
    steel investigations had the information needed to calculate this 
    ratio. Therefore, for all other firms in those cases, the Department 
    wound up using its traditional F.O.B. (port) methodology.
        Because the Department's experiment with a different basis was not 
    successful, in the second sentence of paragraph (a) we have reverted to 
    our standard practice of determining sales value on an F.O.B. (port) 
    basis in the case of products that are exported. In the case of 
    products that are sold for domestic consumption, we would determine 
    sales value on an F.O.B. factory basis. While this method imposes a bit 
    more work on firms than does a method that relies on booked values, we 
    believe that the burden can be mitigated by relying on aggregate 
    figures and reasonable allocations of those figures across markets 
    (e.g., subtracting total freight and insurance expenses, expenses that 
    usually are maintained in ledgers that are separate from sales 
    information).
        In addition, there is no compelling reason for allocating subsidy 
    benefits over sales values that include freight and other shipping 
    costs. Although there may be rare instances where the ``shipping'' 
    component of a transaction is subsidized, the Department can deal with 
    those instances on a case-by-case basis. Accordingly, the third 
    sentence of paragraph (a) provides that the Secretary may make 
    appropriate adjustments to the ad valorem subsidy rate to account for 
    ``shipping'' subsidies.
        Paragraph (b) deals with the attribution of a subsidy to a 
    particular product. Paragraphs (b)(2) through (b)(7) set forth general 
    rules of attribution that the Secretary will apply to a given factual 
    situation. We have taken this approach because, depending on the facts, 
    several of the different rules may come into play at the same time. If 
    we tried to account for all the possible permutations in advance, we 
    would wind up with an extremely lengthy set of rules that might prove 
    to be unduly rigid.
        On the other hand, we appreciate that there needs to be a certain 
    degree of predictability as to how the Department will attribute 
    subsidies. We believe that the rules set forth in paragraph (b) are 
    sufficiently precise so that parties can predict with a reasonable 
    degree of certainty how the Department will attribute subsidies to 
    particular products in a given factual scenario. In this regard, the 
    Department's intent is to apply these rules in an harmonious manner.
        With respect to the attribution rules themselves, they are 
    consistent with the concept of ``benefit'' described in Sec. 351.501, 
    i.e., that a benefit is conferred when a firm pays less than it 
    otherwise would pay in the absence of the government-provided input or 
    when a firm receives more revenue than it otherwise would earn. In 
    light of this, subsidies should be attributed, to the extent possible, 
    to those products for which costs are reduced (or revenues increased). 
    See, e.g., H.R. Rep. No. 317, 96th Cong., 1st Sess. 74-75 (1979) 
    (``[W]ith regard to subsidies which provide an enterprise with capital 
    equipment or a plant * * * the net amount of the subsidy should be * * 
    * assessed in relation to the products produced with such equipment or 
    plant. * * *.'').
        This principle of attributing a subsidy to an affected cost (or 
    revenue) center is embodied in the Department's longstanding practice 
    concerning the ``tying'' of subsidies. See, e.g., Sec. 355.47 of the 
    1989 Proposed Regulations. As discussed below, there are various ways 
    in which a subsidy can be tied. However, regardless of the method, the 
    Department attributes a subsidy to the product or products to which it 
    is tied. In this regard, one can view an ``untied'' subsidy as a 
    subsidy that is tied to all products produced by a firm.
        Paragraphs (b)(2) through (b)(7) set forth rules that the 
    Department will apply to different types of tying situations. For 
    example, paragraph (b)(2) contains an attribution rule regarding export 
    subsidies. Because an export subsidy is, by definition, tied to the 
    exportation, paragraph (b)(2) provides that the Secretary will 
    attribute an export subsidy only to products exported by a firm.
        As noted above, the Department intends to apply paragraphs (b)(2) 
    through (b)(7) consistently with each other. As an example, assume that 
    a government provides an export subsidy on exports of widgets to 
    Country X. Here, three attribution rules come into
    
    [[Page 8845]]
    
    play. Under paragraph (b)(2), the subsidy would be attributed to 
    products exported by a firm. Under paragraph (b)(4), the subsidy would 
    be attributed to products sold by a firm to Country X. Under paragraph 
    (b)(5), the subsidy would be attributed to widgets sold by a firm. 
    Putting the three rules together, the subsidy in this example would be 
    attributed to a firm's exports of widgets to Country X.
        The rules set forth in paragraphs (b)(5) and (b)(6) warrant 
    additional explanation because of the special nomenclature that is 
    being used. In all other sections of these regulations, the term 
    ``firm'' is used to describe the recipient of the subsidy. See 
    Sec. 351.102. However, for purposes of certain attribution rules, where 
    we are describing how subsidies will be attributed within firms, 
    ``firm'' is too broad. Therefore, for purposes of paragraphs (b)(5) and 
    (b)(6), we are using the term ``corporation.'' In so doing, we are not 
    intending to limit the application of these rules to firms that are 
    organized as corporations. However, based on our experience, most of 
    the firms we investigate are organized as corporations. Therefore, our 
    use of the term ``corporation'' makes these attribution rules as clear 
    as possible. If a respondent is not organized as a corporation, we will 
    address any attribution issues covered by the rules in paragraphs 
    (b)(5) and (b)(6) based on the facts of that case.
        Paragraph (b)(5) sets out our rules regarding product tying. 
    Paragraph (b)(5)(i) states our longstanding general rule that where a 
    subsidy is tied to production of a particular product, the subsidy will 
    be attributed to that product. Paragraph (b)(5)(ii) provides an 
    exception to this general rule, which is also consistent with our past 
    practice. Under this exception, if an input product is produced within 
    the same corporation, subsidies tied to the input product will be 
    attributed to sales of both the input and the downstream products. It 
    is important to note that the Department intends to limit this 
    exception to situations where production of the input and downstream 
    product occur within the same corporation. If they are produced by 
    companies that are separately incorporated--even if there is ``cross 
    ownership'' between those separately incorporated companies (as 
    discussed further below)--the Department will follow the general tying 
    rule in paragraph (b)(5)(i). Consequently, petitioners alleging that 
    subsidies to a separately incorporated input producer also benefit the 
    downstream product should file their allegation in accordance with 
    Sec. 351.523(a) (upstream subsidies).
        Paragraph (b)(6) deals with situations where cross ownership exists 
    between corporations. For example, cross ownership exists where 
    corporation A owns corporation B (or vice versa), or where A and B are 
    both owned by corporation C. Cross ownership does not require one 
    corporation to own 100 percent of the other corporation. Normally, 
    cross ownership will exist where there is a controlling ownership 
    interest (i.e., majority voting ownership) between two corporations or 
    through common ownership of two (or more) corporations. In certain 
    circumstances, a large minority voting interest (for example, 40 
    percent) may also result in cross ownership. Specifically, if the 
    remaining shares are widely held, then a large minority voting interest 
    interest would be sufficient to find cross ownership. (Situations where 
    cross ownership exists by virtue of common government ownership are 
    addressed further below.)
        The term ``cross ownership'' as it is used here clearly differs 
    from ``affiliation,'' as that term is defined in section 771(33) of the 
    Act. ``Affiliation'' describes a wide range of business relationships, 
    while cross ownership describes a much narrower range of relationships. 
    In limiting our attribution rules to situations where there is cross 
    ownership, we are not reading ``affiliated'' out of the CVD law. 
    Indeed, we intend to include in our questionnaires a request for 
    respondents to identify all affiliated parties. Also, persons 
    affiliated with companies that shipped during the period of 
    investigation will not be entitled to request a new shipper review 
    under section 751(a)(2)(B) of the Act. However, we do not believe that 
    affiliation alone provides a sufficient basis for attributing subsidies 
    received by one corporation to products produced and sold by another 
    affiliated corporation. Instead, we have chosen to focus on cross 
    ownership, as described above, because where cross ownership exists one 
    corporation can use or direct the individual assets of the other 
    corporation in essentially the same ways it can use its own assets. 
    Where the interests of the two parties have merged to this degree, we 
    believe it is reasonable to presume that subsidies to one corporation 
    may also benefit another corporation. Paragraph (b)(6) reflects this. 
    However, where cross ownership does not exist, we will not make this 
    presumption. Nor do we intend to investigate subsidies to affiliated 
    parties unless cross ownership exists or other information indicates 
    that such subsidies may indeed benefit the merchandise being produced 
    by the corporation being investigated.
        Paragraph (b)(6) begins by stating a general rule, which is 
    followed by three exceptions to that rule deriving from the presumption 
    described above. Paragraph (b)(6)(i) states that the Secretary will 
    normally attribute a subsidy received by a corporation to the products 
    produced by that corporation. Hence, for example, if corporation A 
    receives a subsidy, then that subsidy will normally be attributed to 
    the production of corporation A.
        However, under paragraph (b)(6)(ii), if two (or more) corporations 
    with cross ownership produce the same merchandise, then subsidies 
    received by either or both of those corporations will be attributed to 
    the combined sales of the two corporations. Thus, for example, if 
    corporation A and corporation B are both owned by corporation C and 
    both A and B produce widgets, benefits to A and B will be combined to 
    determine the subsidy and the subsidy will be attributed to the 
    combined production of A and B.
        Paragraph (b)(6)(iii) addresses a second instance where subsidies 
    received by one corporation are attributed to sales of another 
    corporation with cross ownership. This is where the subsidy is received 
    by a holding company. Under paragraph (b)(6)(iii), such subsidies will 
    normally be attributed to the consolidated sales of the holding 
    company. However, if the Department determines that the holding company 
    is merely serving as a conduit for government-provided funds to one (or 
    more) of the holding company's subsidiaries, then the subsidy will be 
    attributed to the production of that subsidiary. Analogous to this 
    situation is the situation where a government provides a subsidy to a 
    non-producing subsidiary (e.g., a financial subsidiary) and there are 
    no conditions on how the money is to be used. Consistent with our 
    treatment of subsidies to holding companies, we would attribute a 
    subsidy to a non-producing subsidiary to the consolidated sales of the 
    corporate group that includes the non-producing subsidiary. See Certain 
    Steel from Belgium, 58 FR 37273, 37282 (1993).
        Finally, paragraph (b)(6)(iv) addresses situations where a 
    corporation producing another product receives subsidies. In this 
    instance, the Department will determine whether the corporation 
    receiving the subsidy transfers it to the corporation producing the 
    subject merchandise. For example, subsidies may be transferred between 
    corporations with cross ownership through loans or other financial
    
    [[Page 8846]]
    
    transactions. However, as discussed above, where the subsidies are 
    allegedly transferred through the purchase of inputs from an input 
    supplier with cross ownership, that situation will be addressed under 
    Sec. 351.523 (upstream subsidies).
        Although cross ownership is broadly defined, permitting us to 
    include corporations under common government ownership, we expect that 
    common government ownership will not normally be viewed as cross 
    ownership. Instead, we intend to continue our longstanding practice of 
    treating most government-owned corporations as the government itself, 
    and not as corporations that transfer subsidies received from the 
    government to other government-owned corporations through loans or 
    other financial transactions. For example, where a government-owned 
    corporation producing the product under investigation purchases 
    electricity from a government-owned utility, a subsidy is conferred if 
    the utility does not receive adequate remuneration. Nothing in 
    paragraph (b)(6)(iv) is meant to require the Department to determine 
    that the government-owned utility is receiving subsidies which it then 
    transfers to the producer of the product under investigation. The 
    situations where we would normally expect to treat common government 
    ownership as cross ownership are: (1) Upstream subsidy allegations (see 
    Sec. 351.523(a)(1)(ii)(A)); (2) government-owned corporations producing 
    the same product (see Sec. 351.524(b)(6)(ii)); and (3) government-owned 
    corporations producing different products (see Sec. 351.524(b)(6)(iv)) 
    where the corporations are under the control of the same ministry or 
    within a corporate group containing producers of similar products.
        Although the rules described in paragraphs (b)(2)-(b)(7) of 
    Sec. 351.524 deal with tying, Sec. 351.524 does not contain a 
    definition of ``tied.'' In the past, the Department has described this 
    concept in a variety of ways. For example, in Appendix 2 to Certain 
    Steel Products from Belgium, 47 FR 39304, 39317 (1982), the Department 
    stated that ``a grant is `tied' when the intended use is known to the 
    subsidy giver and so acknowledged prior to or concurrent with the 
    bestowal of the subsidy.'' In the preamble to the 1989 Proposed 
    Regulations, 54 FR at 23374, the Department stated that a ``tied'' 
    subsidy benefit is ``e.g., a benefit bestowed specifically to promote 
    the production of a particular product.''
        Given the wide variety of factual scenarios that the Department has 
    encountered in the past, and is likely to encounter in the future, we 
    are reluctant to promulgate an all-encompassing definition of ``tied.'' 
    Moreover, the absence of a definition of ``tied'' has not proven to be 
    a problem in practice, and Annex IV to the SCM Agreement, which refers 
    to ``tied'' subsidies in paragraph 3, also lacks a definition of this 
    term. Therefore, for the present time, we intend to apply the term 
    ``tied'' on a case-by-case basis. We would, however, welcome comments 
    regarding what factors are relevant to the Department's determination 
    of whether benefits are tied.
        Virtually every comment submitted on attribution-related issues 
    included a reference to the fungibility of money. Certain commenters 
    argued that because money is fungible, the Department should not allow 
    subsidies to be tied to particular products or to particular export 
    markets. In their view, the only distinction that should be made is 
    between export and domestic subsidies. Other commenters invoked the 
    fungibility principle in support of their position that untied capital 
    infusions to companies with multinational production should be 
    attributed to worldwide sales of the firm.
        While we agree with these commenters that money is fungible, we do 
    not believe that the fungibility principle is useful for purposes of 
    attributing subsidies. For example, according to the fungibility 
    principle, there should be no distinction between export and domestic 
    subsidies. Yet, this agency's consistent and non-controversial practice 
    over the past 16 years has been to attribute export subsidies to 
    exported products and domestic subsidies to all products sold. Over 
    time, we also have adopted the practices of attributing: (1) Subsidies 
    that can be tied to particular markets to products sold to those 
    markets; (2) subsidies that can be tied to particular products to those 
    products; (3) subsidies to companies with multinational production to 
    production occurring in the jurisdiction of the subsidizing government; 
    and (4) subsidies to corporate entities to the specific entities that 
    receive the subsidies, absent a showing that the subsidies are 
    transferred elsewhere within the corporate family. While we have 
    characterized these as exceptions to the principle of the fungibility 
    of money, the exceptions have become more prevalent than the rule 
    insofar as attribution of subsidies is concerned. Therefore, while we 
    do not reject fungibility, we do not believe that it should guide our 
    attribution decisions.
        This having been said, we would note that the rules we have 
    proposed are entirely consistent with the court ruling most often cited 
    in connection with the fungibility principle, British Steel Corp. v. 
    U.S., 605 F. Supp. 286, 293-96 (Ct. Int'l Trade 1985) (``British 
    Steel''). In British Steel, the issue being addressed by the court was 
    whether funds provided by the government to cover redundancy and 
    closure costs of British Steel Corporation conferred a benefit on the 
    company's ongoing production:
    
        In plaintiffs' view, funds provided to shut down excess capacity 
    and eliminate unnecessary jobs are for purposes that are the very 
    antithesis of ``manufacture, production or export,'' and thus are 
    not countervailable under any circumstances.
    
    Id. Commerce had taken a position contrary to this view, stating that 
    the government's payments made ``the recipient more efficient and 
    relieve[d] it of significant financial burdens.''
        Presented with the same facts and arguments today, we would take 
    the same position. The fact that the funds were given for the purpose 
    of closing down facilities would not render the funds non-
    countervailable. This is because the costs that are affected when the 
    government provides funds to close down facilities are the input costs 
    of the ongoing operation, the operation that would bear those costs in 
    the absence of the government payments. Hence, consistent with the 
    attribution principles described above, those subsidies would properly 
    be attributed to the ongoing production and sales of the recipient and 
    not to the activities that had been closed down.
        The court also addressed the Department's practice of attributing 
    the benefit of untied subsidies (i.e., the same redundancy and closure 
    payments) to all merchandise produced by the recipient. Plaintiffs had 
    characterized this practice as being based on the fungibility 
    principle, and argued that application of the fungibility principle did 
    not yield an accurate measure of the subsidy conferred on the subject 
    merchandise. The court upheld Commerce's practice that untied subsidies 
    benefit all products on a pro rata basis. This same practice is 
    reflected in Sec. 351.524(b)(3) of these regulations.
        Therefore, we see the attribution rules we have proposed as being 
    consistent with past practice, even where fungibility has been at 
    issue. Moreover, we believe that these rules provide the best measure 
    of the level of countervailable subsidies being conferred on the 
    subject merchandise, because they match the subsidy with the
    
    [[Page 8847]]
    
    activity or cost center experiencing the cost saving (or revenue 
    increase).
        Regarding the attribution of capital infusions received by 
    companies with multinational production, certain commenters urged the 
    Department to return to its pre-1993 policy of treating such subsidies 
    as benefitting all of the recipient's sales. Other commenters sought 
    codification of the 1993 policy, which established a rebuttable 
    presumption that domestic subsidies are tied to domestic production.
        Section 351.524(b)(7) reflects our continued position, based upon 
    our past administrative experience, that
    
        * * * the government of a country normally provides subsidies 
    for the general purpose of promoting the economic and social health 
    of that country and its people, and for the specific purposes of 
    supporting, assisting or encouraging domestic manufacturing or 
    production and related activities (including, for example, social 
    policy activities such as the employment of its people).
    
    GIA at 37231. Moreover, a government normally will not provide 
    subsidies to firms that refuse to use them as the government wants, and 
    firms receiving subsidies will not use them in a way that would 
    contravene the government's purposes, as they otherwise risk losing 
    future subsidies. Consistent with this, Sec. 351.524(b)(7) states that 
    we normally will attribute subsidies to merchandise produced within the 
    jurisdiction of the granting authority. However, where a respondent can 
    demonstrate that the subsidy is tied to foreign production, the subsidy 
    will be attributed to merchandise produced by the foreign facility.
        Although the proposed rule is similar to the practice the 
    Department adopted in 1993, there are some differences. First, the rule 
    is not stated as a rebuttable presumption. Instead of showing that 
    subsidies are not tied to domestic production, respondents will instead 
    have to demonstrate that the subsidies are tied to foreign production. 
    We believe that this shift in emphasis will bring our practice with 
    respect to multinational companies more in line with the other 
    attribution rules that require evidence of tying, as opposed to 
    evidence that a subsidy is not tied. Second, where a respondent can 
    demonstrate that a subsidy is tied to foreign-produced merchandise, the 
    subsidy will not be countervailable. See Sec. 351.526 (transnational 
    subsidies). This result is similar to the result under the practice 
    adopted in 1993; i.e., subsidies that were found not tied to domestic 
    production were attributed to worldwide sales. By using worldwide 
    sales, the CVD rate was reduced just as it will be reduced when 
    subsidies are tied to foreign production and foreign production is not 
    included in the denominator used to calculate the ad valorem CVD rate.
        Finally, we note that nothing in paragraph (b)(7) is intended to 
    imply that the Department is considering calculating regional subsidy 
    rates; i.e., different CVD rates for imports originating in different 
    subnational jurisdictions.
    
    Section 351.525
    
        Section 351.525 deals with program-wide changes, and is almost 
    identical to Sec. 355.50 of the 1989 Proposed Regulations.
    
    Section 351.526
    
        Section 351.526 is based on Sec. 355.44(o) of the 1989 Proposed 
    Regulations, and provides that so-called ``transnational subsidies'' 
    are not countervailable. Subsidies of this type include situations 
    where (1) The government of one country provides foreign aid that 
    ultimately is received by a firm located in the donee country, or (2) 
    funds are provided by an international lending or development 
    institution, such as the World Bank.
        Section 355.44(o) contained a paragraph (o)(2) which essentially 
    duplicated what is now section 701(d) of the Act, a provision that 
    deals with subsidies to international consortia. In light of our 
    decision to avoid regulations that merely repeat the statute, 
    Sec. 351.526 merely references, but does not repeat, section 701(d).
    
    Section 351.527
    
        Section 351.527 is based on Sec. 355.46(b) of the 1989 Proposed 
    Regulations, and provides that the Secretary will ignore the secondary 
    tax consequences of a subsidy. For example, the Secretary would not 
    reduce the benefit of a countervailable grant because the grant is 
    treated as revenue for income tax purposes.
    
    Classification
    
    E.O. 12866
    
        This proposed rule has been determined to be significant under E.O. 
    12866.
    
    Regulatory Flexibility Act
    
        The Assistant General Counsel for Legislation and Regulation of the 
    Department of Commerce certified to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of 
    the Small Business Administration that this proposed rule, if 
    promulgated as final, would not have a significant economic impact on a 
    substantial number of small entities. The Department does not believe 
    that there will be any substantive effect on the outcome of AD and CVD 
    proceedings as a result of the streamlining and simplification of their 
    administration. With respect to the substantive amendments implementing 
    the Uruguay Round Agreements Act, the Department believes that these 
    regulations benefit both petitioners and respondents without favoring 
    either, and, therefore, would not have a significant economic effects. 
    As such, an initial regulatory flexibility analysis was not prepared.
    
    Paperwork Reduction Act
    
        Notwithstanding any other provision of law, no person is required 
    to respond to nor shall a person be subject to a penalty for failure to 
    comply with a collection of information subject to the requirements of 
    the Paperwork Reduction Act unless that collection of information 
    displays a currently valid OMB Control Number. This proposed rule does 
    not contain any new reporting or recording requirements subject to the 
    Paperwork Reduction Act.
        There are three separate collections of information contained in 
    this rule. Each is currently approved by the Office of Management and 
    Budget. The Petition Format for Requesting Relief Under U.S. 
    Antidumping Laws, OMB Control No. 0625-0105, is estimated to impose an 
    average public reporting burden of 40 hours. The information submitted 
    is used to assess the petitioner's allegations of unfair trade 
    practices and to determine whether an investigation is warranted. The 
    information requested relates to the existence of sales at less than 
    fair value and injury to the affected U.S. industry. Second, the Format 
    for Petition Requesting Relief Under the Countervailing Duty Law is 
    approved under OMB Control No. 0625-0148. This format is used to elicit 
    the information required by the Tariff Act of 1930, as amended, and its 
    implementing regulations, for the initiation of a countervailing duty 
    investigation. Specifically, the Format requests information about the 
    imported product, a description of the alleged subsidies to the 
    imported product, and the extent to which the domestic industry is 
    being injured by the imported product. Finally, OMB Control No. 0625-
    0200, Antidumping and Countervailing Duties, Procedures for Initiation 
    of Downstream Product Monitoring, provides for the filing of a petition 
    requesting the review of a ``downstream'' product. A downstream product 
    is one that has incorporated as a component part, a part that is 
    covered by a U.S. antidumping or countervailing duty finding. To be 
    eligible to file a
    
    [[Page 8848]]
    
    petition, the petitioner must produce a product like the component part 
    or the downstream product. It is estimated to require 15 hours per 
    petition.
        These estimates include the time for reviewing instructions, 
    searching existing data sources, gathering and maintaining the data 
    needed, and completing and reviewing the collections of information. 
    Send comments regarding these burden estimates or any other aspect of 
    these collections of information, including suggestions for reducing 
    the burden, to the Department of Commerce (see ADDRESSES) or to OMB 
    Desk Officer, New Executive Office Building, Washington, DC. 20503.
    
    E.O. 12612
    
        This proposed rule does not contain federalism implications 
    warranting the preparation of a Federalism Assessment.
    
    List of Subjects in 19 CFR Part 351
    
        Administrative practice and procedure, Antidumping, Business and 
    industry, Cheese, Confidential business information, Countervailing 
    duties, Investigations, Reporting and recordkeeping requirements.
    
        Dated: February 18, 1997.
    Robert S. LaRussa
    Acting Assistant Secretary for Import Administration.
        For the reasons stated, it is proposed that the proposed rule 
    published at 61 FR 7308 on February 27, 1996, adding a new 19 CFR part 
    351, is further amended as follows:
    
    PART 351--COUNTERVAILING AND ANTIDUMPING DUTIES
    
        1. The authority citation for part 351 is proposed to continue to 
    read as follows:
    
        Authority: 5 U.S.C. 301; 19 U.S.C. 1202 note, 1303 note, 1671 
    et. seq., and 3538.
    
    
    Sec. 351.102  [Amended]
    
        2. Section 351.102 (Definitions) is amended by adding the following 
    definitions in alphabetical order to read as follows:
    * * * * *
        Consumed in the production process. Inputs ``consumed in the 
    production process'' are inputs physically incorporated, energy, fuels 
    and oil used in the production process and catalysts which are consumed 
    in the course of their use to obtain the product.
        Cumulative indirect tax. ``Cumulative indirect tax'' means a multi-
    staged tax levied where there is no mechanism for subsequent crediting 
    of the tax if the goods or services subject to tax at one stage of 
    production are used in a succeeding stage of production.
    * * * * *
        Direct tax. ``Direct tax'' means a tax on wages, profits, 
    interests, rents, royalties, and all other forms of income, a tax on 
    the ownership of real property, or a social welfare charge.
    * * * * *
        Export insurance. ``Export insurance'' includes, but is not limited 
    to, insurance against increases in the cost of exported products, 
    nonpayment by the customer, inflation, or exchange rate risks.
        Firm. For purposes of subpart E (Identification and Measurement of 
    Countervailable Subsidies), ``firm'' means any individual, partnership, 
    corporation, association, organization, or other entity, and is used to 
    refer to the recipient of an alleged countervailable subsidy.
        Government-provided. ``Government-provided'' is used as a shorthand 
    expression to refer to an act or practice that is alleged to be a 
    countervailable subsidy. The use of the term ``government-provided'' is 
    not intended to preclude the possibility that a government may provide 
    a countervailable subsidy indirectly in a manner described in section 
    771(5)(B)(iii) of the Act (indirect financial contribution).
        Import charge. ``Import charge'' means a tariff, duty, or other 
    fiscal charge that is levied on imports, other than an indirect tax.
    * * * * *
        Indirect tax. ``Indirect tax'' means a sales, excise, turnover, 
    value added, franchise, stamp, transfer, inventory, or equipment tax, a 
    border tax, or any other tax other than a direct tax or an import 
    charge.
        Loan. ``Loan'' means a loan or other form of debt financing, such 
    as a bond.
        Long-term loan. ``Long-term loan'' means a loan, the terms of 
    repayment for which are greater than one year.
    * * * * *
        Prior-stage indirect tax. ``Prior-stage indirect tax'' means an 
    indirect tax levied on goods or services used directly or indirectly in 
    making a product.
    * * * * *
        Short-term loan. ``Short-term loan'' means a loan, the terms of 
    repayment for which are one year or less.
        3. A new subpart E is added to 19 CFR part 351, to read as follows:
    
    Subpart E--Identification and Measurement of Countervailable 
    Subsidies
    
    Sec.
    351.501  Scope.
    351.502  Specificity of domestic subsidies.
    351.503  Grants.
    351.504  Loans.
    351.505  Loan guarantees.
    351.506  Equity.
    351.507  Debt forgiveness.
    351.508  Direct taxes.
    351.509  Indirect taxes and import charges (other than export 
    programs).
    351.510  Provision of goods or services.
    351.511  Purchase of goods. [Reserved]
    351.512  Worker-related subsidies.
    351.513  Export subsidies.
    351.514  Internal transport and freight charges for export shipments
    351.515  Price preferences for inputs used in the production of 
    goods for export.
    351.516  Remission upon export of indirect taxes.
    351.517  Exemption, remission or deferral upon export of prior-stage 
    cumulative indirect taxes.
    351.518  Remission or drawback of import charges upon export.
    351.519  Export insurance.
    351.520  General export promotion.
    351.521  Import substitution subsidies. [Reserved]
    351.522  Certain agricultural subsidies.
    351.523  Upstream subsidies.
    351.524  Calculation of ad valorem subsidy rate and attribution of 
    subsidy to a product.
    351.525  Program-wide changes.
    351.526  Transnational subsidies.
    351.527  Tax consequences of benefits.
    
    Subpart E--Identification and Measurement of Countervailable 
    Subsidies
    
    
    Sec. 351.501  Scope.
    
        The provisions of this subpart E set forth rules regarding the 
    identification and measurement of countervailable subsidies. Where this 
    subpart E does not expressly deal with a particular type of alleged 
    subsidy, the Secretary will identify and measure the subsidy, if any, 
    in accordance with the underlying principles of the Act and this 
    subpart E.
    
    
    Sec. 351.502  Specificity of domestic subsidies.
    
        (a) Agricultural subsidies. The Secretary will not regard a subsidy 
    as being specific under section 771(5A)(D) of the Act solely because 
    the subsidy is limited to the agricultural sector (domestic subsidy).
        (b) Subsidies to small- and medium-sized businesses. The Secretary 
    will not regard a subsidy as being specific under section 771(5A)(D) of 
    the Act solely because the subsidy is limited to small firms or small- 
    and medium-sized firms.
        (c) Disaster relief. The Secretary will not regard disaster relief 
    as being specific under section 771(5A)(D) of the Act if such relief 
    constitutes general assistance available to anyone in the area affected 
    by the disaster.
    
    [[Page 8849]]
    
    Sec. 351.503  Grants.
    
        (a) Benefit. In the case of a grant, a benefit exists in the amount 
    of the grant.
        (b) Time of receipt of benefit. In the case of a grant, the 
    Secretary will consider a benefit as having been received as of the 
    date on which the firm received the grant.
        (c) Allocation of benefit to a particular time period.--(1) 
    Recurring grants. The Secretary will allocate (expense) a recurring 
    grant to the year in which the subsidy is received (see paragraph (b) 
    of this section).
        (2) Non-recurring grants.--(i) In general. The Secretary will 
    allocate a non-recurring grant over the number of years corresponding 
    to a firm's AUL (see paragraph (c)(4) of this section).
        (ii) Exception. The Secretary will normally allocate (expense) non-
    recurring grants received under a particular subsidy program to the 
    year in which the subsidies are received if the total amount of such 
    grants is less than 0.50 percent of all sales of the firm in question 
    during the same year, or, in the case of an export subsidy program, 
    0.50 percent of the export sales of the firm in question during the 
    same year.
        (3) ``Recurring'' versus ``non-recurring.'' The Secretary will 
    consider a grant as ``non-recurring'' if the grant is exceptional in 
    the sense that the recipient of the grant cannot expect to receive 
    additional grants under the same subsidy program on an ongoing basis 
    from year to year; or the government must approve the provision of the 
    grant each year. If a grant does not satisfy the standard for a non-
    recurring grant under the preceding sentence, the Secretary will 
    consider the grant as ``recurring.'
        (4) Process for allocating non-recurring grants over time.--(i) In 
    general. For purposes of allocating a non-recurring grant over time and 
    determining the annual subsidy amount that should be assigned to a 
    particular year, the Secretary will use the following formula:
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP26FE97.000
    
    Where
    Ak=the amount of the benefit allocated to year k,
    y=the face value of the grant (see paragraph (a) of this section,
    n=the AUL (see paragraph (c)(4)(ii) of this section),
    d=the discount rate (see paragraph (c)(4)(iii) of this section, and
    k=the year of allocation, where the year of receipt=1 and 1 < k="">< n.="" (ii)="" aul.="" the="" term="" ``aul''="" means="" the="" average="" useful="" life="" of="" a="" firm's="" productive="" assets.="" normally,="" the="" secretary="" will="" calculate="" a="" firm's="" aul="" by="" dividing="" the="" average="" gross="" book="" value="" of="" the="" firm's="" depreciable="" productive="" fixed="" assets="" (for="" a="" period="" considered="" appropriate="" by="" the="" secretary)="" by="" the="" firm's="" average="" annual="" charge="" to="" accumulated="" depreciation.="" in="" calculating="" a="" firm's="" aul,="" the="" secretary="" will="" attempt="" to="" exclude="" fixed="" assets="" that="" are="" not="" depreciable="" (e.g.,="" land="" or="" construction="" in="" progress)="" and="" assets="" that="" have="" been="" fully="" depreciated="" and="" are="" no="" longer="" in="" service.="" in="" addition,="" the="" secretary="" may="" make="" a="" normalizing="" adjustment="" to="" account="" for="" such="" factors="" as="" an="" extraordinary="" write-down="" in="" the="" value="" of="" fixed="" assets="" or="" hyperinflation.="" (iii)="" selection="" of="" a="" discount="" rate.--(a)="" in="" general.="" the="" secretary="" will="" select="" a="" discount="" rate="" based="" upon="" data="" for="" the="" year="" in="" which="" the="" government="" and="" the="" firm="" agreed="" on="" the="" terms="" for="" receiving="" the="" grant.="" the="" secretary="" will="" use="" as="" a="" discount="" rate="" the="" following,="" in="" order="" of="" preference:="" (1)="" the="" cost="" of="" long-term,="" fixed-rate="" loans="" of="" the="" firm="" in="" question,="" excluding="" any="" loans="" that="" the="" secretary="" has="" determined="" to="" be="" countervailable="" subsidies;="" (2)="" the="" average="" cost="" of="" long-term,="" fixed-rate="" loans="" in="" the="" country="" in="" question;="" or="" (3)="" a="" rate="" that="" the="" secretary="" considers="" to="" be="" most="" appropriate.="" (b)="" exception="" for="" uncreditworthy="" firms.="" in="" the="" case="" of="" a="" firm="" considered="" by="" the="" secretary="" to="" be="" uncreditworthy="" (see="" sec.="" 351.504(a)(4)),="" the="" secretary="" will="" use="" as="" a="" discount="" rate="" the="" interest="" rate="" described="" in="" sec.="" 351.504(a)(3)(iii).="" sec.="" 351.504="" loans.="" (a)="" benefit.--(1)="" in="" general.="" in="" the="" case="" of="" a="" loan,="" a="" benefit="" exists="" to="" the="" extent="" that="" the="" amount="" a="" firm="" pays="" on="" the="" government-="" provided="" loan="" is="" less="" than="" the="" amount="" the="" firm="" would="" pay="" on="" a="" comparable="" commercial="" loan(s)="" that="" the="" firm="" could="" actually="" obtain="" on="" the="" market.="" see="" section="" 771(5)(e)(ii)="" of="" the="" act.="" in="" making="" the="" comparison="" called="" for="" in="" the="" preceding="" sentence,="" the="" secretary="" normally="" will="" rely="" on="" effective="" interest="" rates.="" (2)="" ``comparable="" commercial="" loan''="" defined.--(i)="" ``comparable''="" defined.="" in="" selecting="" a="" loan="" that="" is="" ``comparable''="" to="" the="" government-="" provided="" loan,="" the="" secretary="" normally="" will="" place="" primary="" emphasis="" on="" similarities="" in="" the="" structures="" of="" the="" loans="" (e.g.,="" fixed="" interest="" rate="" v.="" variable="" interest="" rate),="" the="" maturities="" of="" the="" loans="" (e.g.,="" short-="" term="" v.="" long-term),="" and="" the="" currencies="" in="" which="" the="" loans="" are="" denominated.="" (ii)="" ``commercial''="" defined.="" in="" selecting="" a="" ``commercial''="" loan,="" the="" secretary="" normally="" will="" use="" a="" loan="" taken="" out="" by="" the="" firm="" from="" a="" commercial="" lending="" institution="" or="" a="" debt="" instrument="" issued="" by="" the="" firm="" in="" a="" commercial="" market.="" also,="" the="" secretary="" will="" treat="" a="" loan="" from="" a="" government-owned="" bank="" as="" a="" commercial="" loan,="" unless="" there="" is="" evidence="" that="" the="" loan="" from="" a="" government-owned="" bank="" is="" provided="" at="" the="" direction="" of="" the="" government="" or="" with="" funds="" provided="" by="" the="" government.="" however,="" the="" secretary="" normally="" will="" not="" consider="" a="" loan="" provided="" under="" a="" government="" program="" to="" be="" a="" commercial="" loan="" for="" purposes="" of="" selecting="" a="" loan="" to="" compare="" to="" a="" government-provided="" loan.="" (iii)="" long-term="" loans.="" in="" selecting="" a="" comparable="" loan,="" if="" the="" government-provided="" loan="" is="" a="" long-term="" loan,="" the="" secretary="" normally="" will="" use="" a="" loan="" the="" terms="" of="" which="" were="" established="" during,="" or="" immediately="" before,="" the="" year="" in="" which="" the="" terms="" of="" the="" government-="" provided="" loan="" were="" established.="" (iv)="" short-term="" loans.="" in="" making="" the="" comparison="" required="" under="" paragraph="" (a)(1)="" of="" this="" section,="" if="" the="" government-provided="" loan="" is="" a="" short-term="" loan,="" the="" secretary="" normally="" will="" use="" an="" annual="" average="" of="" the="" interest="" rates="" on="" comparable="" commercial="" loans="" during="" the="" period="" of="" investigation="" or="" review.="" however,="" if="" the="" secretary="" finds="" that="" interest="" rates="" fluctuated="" significantly="" during="" the="" period="" of="" investigation="" or="" review,="" the="" secretary="" will="" use="" the="" most="" appropriate="" interest="" rate="" based="" on="" the="" circumstances="" presented.="" (3)="" ``could="" actually="" obtain="" on="" the="" market''="" defined.--(i)="" in="" general.="" in="" selecting="" a="" comparable="" commercial="" loan="" that="" the="" recipient="" ``could="" otherwise="" obtain="" on="" the="" market,''="" the="" secretary="" normally="" will="" rely="" on="" the="" actual="" experience="" of="" the="" firm="" in="" question="" in="" obtaining="" comparable="" commercial="" loans.="" (ii)="" where="" the="" firm="" has="" no="" comparable="" commercial="" loans.="" if="" the="" firm="" did="" not="" take="" out="" any="" comparable="" commercial="" loans="" during="" the="" period="" referred="" to="" in="" paragraph="" (a)(2)(iii)="" or="" (a)(2)(iv)="" of="" this="" section,="" the="" secretary="" may="" use="" a="" national="" average="" interest="" rate="" for="" comparable="" commercial="" loans.="" (iii)="" exception="" for="" uncreditworthy="" companies.="" if="" the="" secretary="" finds="" that="" a="" firm="" that="" received="" a="" government-provided="" long-term="" loan="" was="" uncreditworthy,="" as="" defined="" in="" paragraph="" (a)(4)="" of="" this="" section,="" the="" secretary="" will="" calculate="" the="" interest="" rate="" to="" be="" used="" in="" making="" the="" comparison="" called="" for="" by="" paragraph="" (a)(1)="" of="" this="" section="" according="" to="" the="" following="" formula:="">b=[(1+if)/0.957]-1
    
        Where
    ib=the benchmark interest rate for uncreditworthy companies;
    if=the long-term interest rate that would be paid by creditworthy 
    companies.
    
    
    [[Page 8850]]
    
    
        (4) Uncreditworthiness defined.--(i) In general. The Secretary will 
    consider a firm to be uncreditworthy if the Secretary determines that, 
    based on information available at the time of the government-provided 
    loan, the firm could not have obtained long-term loans from 
    conventional commercial sources. The Secretary will determine 
    uncreditworthiness on a case-by-case basis, and may examine, among 
    other factors, the following:
        (A) The receipt by the firm of comparable commercial long-term 
    loans;
        (B) The present and past financial health of the firm, as reflected 
    in various financial indicators calculated from the firm's financial 
    statements and accounts;
        (C) The firm's recent past and present ability to meet its costs 
    and fixed financial obligations with its cash flow; and
        (D) Evidence of the firm's future financial position, such as 
    market studies, country and industry economic forecasts, and project 
    and loan appraisals prepared prior to the agreement between the lender 
    and the firm on the terms of the loan.
        (ii) Significance of long-term commercial loans. In the case of 
    firms not owned by the government, the receipt by the firm of long-term 
    commercial loans, unaccompanied by a government-provided guarantee, 
    will constitute dispositive evidence that the firm is not 
    uncreditworthy.
        (iii) Significance of prior subsidies. In determining whether a 
    firm is uncreditworthy, the Secretary will ignore current and prior 
    subsidies received by the firm.
        (iv) Discount Rate. When the creditworthiness of a firm is being 
    considered in connection with the allocation of non-recurring grants 
    (or benefits treated as non-recurring grants (e.g., equity)), the 
    Secretary will rely on information available in the year in which the 
    government agrees to provide the grant.
        (5) Long-term variable rate loans.--(i) In general. In the case of 
    a long-term variable rate loan, the Secretary normally will make the 
    comparison called for by paragraph (a)(1) of this section by relying on 
    a comparable commercial loan with a variable interest rate. The 
    Secretary then will compare the variable interest rates on the 
    comparable commercial loan and the government-provided loan for the 
    year in which the terms of the government-provided loan were 
    established. If the comparison shows that the interest rate on the 
    government-provided loan was equal to or higher than the interest rate 
    on the comparable commercial loan, the Secretary will not consider the 
    government-provided loan as having conferred a benefit. If the 
    comparison shows that the interest rate on the government-provided loan 
    was lower, the Secretary will consider the government-provided loan as 
    having conferred a benefit, and, if the other criteria for a 
    countervailable subsidy are satisfied, will calculate the amount of the 
    benefit in accordance with paragraph (c)(4) of this section.
        (ii) Exception. If the Secretary is unable to make the comparison 
    described in paragraph (a)(5)(i) of this section, the Secretary may 
    modify the method described in that paragraph.
        (6) Allegations.--(i) Allegation of uncreditworthiness required. 
    Normally, the Secretary will not consider the uncreditworthiness of a 
    firm absent a specific allegation by the petitioner that is supported 
    by information establishing a reasonable basis to believe or suspect 
    that the firm is uncreditworthy.
        (ii) Government-owned banks. The Secretary will not investigate a 
    loan provided by a government-owned commercial bank absent a specific 
    allegation that is supported by information establishing a reasonable 
    basis to believe or suspect that:
        (A) The government-owned bank provided the loan at the direction of 
    the government or with funds provided by the government; and
        (B) A benefit exists within the meaning of paragraph (a)(1) of this 
    section.
        (b) Time of receipt of benefit. In the case of loans described in 
    paragraphs (c)(1), (c)(2), and (c)(4) of this section, the Secretary 
    normally will consider a benefit as having been received as of the date 
    on which the firm is due to make a payment on the government-provided 
    loan. In the case of a loan described in paragraph (c)(3) of this 
    section, the Secretary normally will consider the benefit as having 
    been received in the year in which the firm receives the proceeds of 
    the loan.
        (c) Allocation of benefit to a particular time period.--(1) Short-
    term loans. The Secretary will allocate (expense) the benefit from a 
    short-term loan to the year(s) in which the firm is due to make 
    interest payments on the loan.
        (2) Long-term fixed-rate loans with concessionary interest rates. 
    Except as provided in paragraph (c)(3) of this section, the Secretary 
    normally will calculate the subsidy amount to be assigned to a 
    particular year by calculating the difference in interest payments for 
    that year; i.e., the difference between the interest paid by the firm 
    in that year on the government-provided loan and the interest the firm 
    would have paid on the comparison loan. However, in no event may the 
    present value (in the year of receipt of the loan) of the amounts 
    calculated under the preceding sentence exceed the principal of the 
    loan.
        (3) Long-term fixed-rate loans with different repayment 
    schedules.--(i) Calculation of present value of benefit. Where the 
    government-provided loan and the loan to which it is compared under 
    paragraph (a) of this section are both long-term, fixed-interest rate 
    loans, but have different grace periods or maturities, or where the 
    shapes of the repayment schedules differ, the Secretary will determine 
    the total benefit by calculating the present value, in the year in 
    which the loan was received, of the difference between the amount that 
    the firm is to pay on the government-provided loan and the amount that 
    the firm would have paid on the comparison loan. In no event may the 
    total benefit calculated under the preceding sentence exceed the 
    principal of the loan.
        (ii) Calculation of annual benefit. With respect to the benefit 
    calculated under paragraph (c)(3)(i) of this section, the Secretary 
    will determine the portion of that benefit to be assigned to a 
    particular year by using the formula set forth in Sec. 351.503(c)(4)(i) 
    (grants) and the following parameters:
    
    Ak=the amount countervailed in year k,
    y=the present value of the benefit (see paragraph (c)(3)(i) of this 
    section),
    n=the number of years in the life of the loan,
    d=the interest rate on the comparison loan selected under paragraph (a) 
    of this section, and
    k=the year of allocation, where the year of receipt=1.
        (4) Long-term variable interest rate loans. In the case of a 
    government-provided long-term variable-rate loan, the Secretary 
    normally will determine the amount of the benefit attributable to a 
    particular year by calculating the difference in payments for that 
    year; i.e., the difference between the amount paid by the firm in that 
    year on the government-provided loan and the amount the firm would have 
    paid on the comparison loan. However, in no event may the present value 
    (in the year of receipt of the loan) of the amounts calculated under 
    the preceding sentence exceed the principal of the loan.
        (d) Contingent liability interest-free loans. In the case of a 
    long-term, interest-free loan, the obligation for repayment of which is 
    contingent upon subsequent events, the Secretary
    
    [[Page 8851]]
    
    normally will treat any balance on the loan outstanding during a year 
    as an interest-free, short-term loan in accordance with paragraphs 
    (a)(4), (b), and (c)(1) of this section.
    
    
    Sec. 351.505  Loan guarantees.
    
        (a) Benefit.--(1) In general. In the case of a loan guarantee, a 
    benefit exists to the extent that the amount a firm pays on the loan 
    with the government-provided guarantee is less than the amount the firm 
    would pay on a comparable commercial loan absent the government-
    provided guarantee, after adjusting for any difference in guarantee 
    fees. See section 771(5)(E)(iii) of the Act. The Secretary will select 
    a comparable commercial loan in accordance with Sec. 351.504(a) 
    (loans).
        (2) Government acting as owner. In situations where a government, 
    acting as the owner of a firm, provides a loan guarantee to that firm, 
    the guarantee does not confer a benefit if the Secretary finds that it 
    is a normal commercial practice in the country in question for 
    shareholders to provide guarantees to their firms under similar 
    circumstances and on comparable terms.
        (b) Time of receipt of benefit. In the case of a loan guarantee, 
    the Secretary normally will consider a benefit as having been received 
    as of the date on which the firm is due to make a payment on the loan 
    subject to the government-provided loan guarantee.
        (c) Allocation of benefit to a particular time period. In 
    allocating the benefit from a government-provided loan guarantee to a 
    particular time period, the Secretary will use the methods set forth in 
    Sec. 351.504(c) regarding loans.
    
    
    Sec. 351.506  Equity.
    
        (a) Benefit.--(1) In general. In the case of a government-provided 
    equity infusion, a benefit exists to the extent that the investment 
    decision is inconsistent with the usual investment practice of private 
    investors, including the practice regarding the provision of risk 
    capital, in the country in which the equity infusion is made. See 
    section 771(5)(E)(i) of the Act. In determining whether an investment 
    decision is inconsistent with usual investment practice, the Secretary 
    normally will compare the price paid by the government for the equity 
    it purchased to the price that a private investor in the country would 
    pay for the same (or similar) form of equity.
        (2) Private investor prices available. (i) In general. The 
    Secretary will consider an equity infusion as being inconsistent with 
    usual investment practice (see paragraph (a)(1) of this section) if the 
    price paid by the government for newly-issued equity is greater than, 
    in order of preference:
        (A) The price paid by private investors for the same (or similar) 
    form of newly-issued equity; or
        (B) The publicly-traded market price for previously issued equity 
    of the same (or similar) form as the newly-issued equity.
        (ii) Timing of private investor prices. In selecting a private 
    investor price under paragraph (a)(2)(i) of this section, the Secretary 
    will rely on sales of equity made at such time as, in the Secretary's 
    judgment, permits a reasonable comparison to the newly-issued equity 
    purchased by the government.
        (iii) Significant private sector participation required. The 
    Secretary will not use private investor prices under paragraph 
    (a)(2)(i) of this section if the Secretary concludes that private 
    investor purchases of newly-issued equity, or private investor trading 
    in previously issued equity, is not significant.
        (iv) Adjustments for ``similar'' form of equity. Where the 
    Secretary uses private investor prices for a form of equity that is 
    similar to the newly-issued equity purchased by the government (see 
    paragraph (a)(2)(i) of this section), the Secretary, where appropriate, 
    will adjust the prices to reflect the differences in the forms of 
    equity.
        (3) Private investor prices unavailable. If private investor prices 
    are not available under paragraph (a)(2) of this section, the Secretary 
    will determine whether the firm that received the government-provided 
    equity was equityworthy or unequityworthy at the time of the equity 
    infusion (see paragraph (a)(4) of this section). If the Secretary 
    determines that the firm was equityworthy, the Secretary will apply 
    paragraph (a)(5) of this section to determine whether the equity 
    infusion was inconsistent with the usual investment practice of private 
    investors. A determination by the Secretary that the firm was 
    unequityworthy will constitute a determination that the equity infusion 
    was inconsistent with usual investment practice of private investors, 
    and the Secretary will apply paragraph (a)(6) of this section to 
    measure the benefit, if any, attributable to the equity infusion.
        (4) Equityworthiness.--(i) In general. The Secretary will consider 
    a firm to have been equityworthy if the Secretary determines that, from 
    the perspective of a reasonable private investor examining the firm at 
    the time the government-provided equity infusion was made, the firm 
    showed an ability to generate a reasonable rate of return within a 
    reasonable period of time. In making this determination, the Secretary 
    may examine the following factors, among others:
        (A) Current and past indicators of the firm's financial health 
    calculated from the firm's statements and accounts, adjusted, if 
    appropriate, to conform to generally accepted accounting principles;
        (B) Future financial prospects of the firm, including market 
    studies, economic forecasts, and project or loan appraisals prepared at 
    the time of, or prior to, the government-provided equity infusion in 
    question;
        (C) Rates of return on equity in the three years prior to the 
    government equity infusion; and
        (D) Equity investment in the firm by private investors.
        (ii) Significance of prior subsidies. In determining whether a firm 
    was equityworthy, the Secretary will ignore current and prior subsidies 
    received by the firm.
        (5) Benefit to equityworthy firm. If the Secretary determines that 
    a firm was equityworthy, the Secretary will examine the details of the 
    particular equity infusion in question to determine whether the 
    investment was inconsistent with usual investment practice of private 
    investors. If the Secretary determines that the investment was 
    inconsistent with usual investment practice, the Secretary will 
    determine the amount of the benefit conferred on a case-by-case basis.
        (6) Benefit to unequityworthy firm.--(i) Constructed private 
    investor price. If the Secretary determines that a firm was 
    unequityworthy, the Secretary normally will measure the benefit 
    conferred by a government-provided equity infusion by estimating, based 
    on information and analysis available at the time of the equity 
    infusion, the price that a reasonable private investor would have paid 
    for the equity purchased by the government. If the price paid by the 
    government for newly-issued equity was greater than this price, the 
    benefit will be based on the difference between the two prices.
        (ii) Constructed private investor price unavailable. If the 
    Secretary determines that information is not available, or does not 
    provide an appropriate basis, for calculating the price that a 
    reasonable private investor would have paid (see paragraph (a)(6)(i) of 
    this section), the Secretary will measure the benefit conferred by an 
    equity infusion in an unequityworthy firm by adjusting the amount of 
    the infusion allocated to a particular year under paragraph (c)(3) of 
    this section by the amount of
    
    [[Page 8852]]
    
    subsequent after-tax returns achieved in that year.
        (7) Allegations. The Secretary will not investigate an equity 
    infusion in a firm absent a specific allegation by the petitioner which 
    is supported by information establishing a reasonable basis to believe 
    or suspect that the firm received an equity infusion that provides a 
    countervailable benefit within the meaning of paragraph (a) of this 
    section.
        (b) Time of receipt of benefit. In the case of a government-
    provided equity infusion, the Secretary normally will consider the 
    benefit to have been received as of the date on which the firm received 
    the equity infusion.
        (c) Allocation of benefit to a particular time period.--(1) In 
    general. The benefit conferred by an equity infusion shall be allocated 
    over the same time period as a non-recurring grant. See 
    Sec. 351.503(c)(2).
        (2) Allocation where private investor prices used. Where the 
    Secretary determines the amount of the benefit conferred by an equity 
    infusion by using private investor prices (see paragraph (a)(2) of this 
    section) or the price that a reasonable private investor would have 
    paid (see paragraph (a)(6)(i) of this section), the Secretary will 
    allocate the benefit as if it were a non-recurring grant (see 
    Sec. 351.503(c)(2)).
        (3) Allocation where private investor prices not used. Where the 
    Secretary is unable to use private investor prices (see paragraph 
    (a)(2) of this section) or the price that a reasonable private investor 
    would have paid (see paragraph (a)(6)(i) of this section), the 
    Secretary will allocate the full amount of the equity infusion as if it 
    were a non-recurring grant (see Sec. 351.503(c)(2)). The amount so 
    allocated to a particular year will be subject to adjustment under 
    paragraph (a)(6)(ii) of this section.
    
    
    Sec. 351.507  Debt forgiveness.
    
        (a) Benefit. In the case of an assumption or forgiveness of a 
    firm's debt obligation, a benefit exists equal to the amount of the 
    principal and/or interest (including accrued, unpaid interest) that the 
    government has assumed or forgiven. In situations where the entity 
    assuming or forgiving the debt receives shares in a firm in return 
    eliminating or reducing the firm's debt obligation, the Secretary will 
    determine the existence of a benefit under Sec. 351.506 (equity 
    infusions).
        (b) Time of receipt of benefit. In the case of a debt or interest 
    assumption or forgiveness, the Secretary normally will consider the 
    benefit as having been received as of the date on which the debt or 
    interest was assumed or forgiven.
        (c) Allocation of benefit to a particular time period.--(i) In 
    general. The Secretary will treat the benefit determined under 
    paragraph (a) of this section as a non-recurring grant, and will 
    allocate the benefit to a particular year in accordance with 
    Sec. 351.503(c)(2)(grants).
        (ii) Exception. Where an interest assumption is tied to a 
    particular loan and where a firm can reasonably expect to receive the 
    interest assumption at the time it applies for the loan, the Secretary 
    will normally treat the interest assumption as a reduced-interest loan 
    and allocate the benefit to a particular year in accordance with 
    Sec. 351.504(c)(loans).
    
    
    Sec. 351.508  Direct taxes.
    
        (a) Benefit.--(1) Exemption or remission of taxes. In the case of a 
    program that provides for a full or partial exemption or remission of a 
    direct tax (e.g., an income tax), or a reduction in the base used to 
    calculate a direct tax, a benefit exists to the extent that the tax 
    paid by a firm as a result of the program is less than the tax the firm 
    would have paid in the absence of the program.
        (2) Deferral of taxes. In the case of a program that provides for a 
    deferral of direct taxes, a benefit exists to the extent that 
    appropriate interest charges are not collected. Normally, a deferral of 
    direct taxes will be treated as a government-provided loan in the 
    amount of the tax deferred, according to the methodology described in 
    Sec. 351.504.
        (b) Time of receipt of benefit. In the case of a full or partial 
    exemption or remission of a direct tax, the Secretary normally will 
    consider the benefit as having been received as of the date on which 
    the recipient firm became capable of calculating the amount of the 
    benefit. Normally, this date will be the date on which the firm filed 
    its tax return. In the case of a tax deferral of one year or less, the 
    Secretary normally will consider the benefit as having been received as 
    of the date on which the deferred tax becomes due. In the case of a 
    multi-year deferral, the Secretary normally will consider the benefit 
    as having been received on the anniversary date(s) of the deferral.
        (c) Allocation of benefit to a particular time period. The 
    Secretary normally will allocate (expense) the benefit of a full or 
    partial exemption, remission, or deferral of a direct tax to the year 
    in which the benefit is considered to have been received under 
    paragraph (b) of this section.
    
    
    Sec. 351.509  Indirect taxes and import charges (other than export 
    programs).
    
        (a) Benefit.--(1) Exemption or remission of taxes. In the case of a 
    program, other than an export program, that provides for the full or 
    partial exemption or remission of an indirect tax or an import charge, 
    a benefit exists to the extent that the taxes or import charges paid by 
    a firm as a result of the program are less than the taxes the firm 
    would have paid in the absence of the program.
        (2) Deferral of taxes. In the case of a program, other than an 
    export program, that provides for a deferral of indirect taxes or 
    import charges, a benefit exists to the extent that appropriate 
    interest charges are not collected. Normally, a deferral of indirect 
    taxes or import charges will be treated as a government-provided loan 
    in the amount of the taxes deferred, according to the methodology 
    described in Sec. 351.504.
        (b) Time of receipt of benefit. In the case of a full or partial 
    exemption or remission of an indirect tax or import charge, the 
    Secretary normally will consider the benefit as having been received at 
    the time the recipient firm otherwise would be required to pay the 
    indirect tax or import charge. In the case of the deferral of an 
    indirect tax or import charge of one year or less, the Secretary 
    normally will consider the benefit as having been received as of the 
    date the deferred tax becomes due. In the case of a multi-year 
    deferral, the Secretary normally will consider the benefit as having 
    been received on the anniversary date(s) of the deferral.
        (c) Allocation of benefit to a particular time period. The 
    Secretary normally will allocate (expense) the benefit of a full or 
    partial exemption, remission, or deferral described in paragraph (a) of 
    this section to the year in which the benefit is considered to have 
    been received under paragraph (b) of this section.
    
    
    Sec. 351.510  Provision of goods or services.
    
        (a) Benefit. [Reserved]
        (b) Time of receipt of benefit. In the case of the provision of a 
    good or service, the Secretary normally will consider a benefit as 
    having been received as of the date on which the firm pays, or in the 
    absence of payment was due to pay, for the government-provided good or 
    service.
        (c) Allocation of benefit to a particular time period. In the case 
    of the provision of a good or service, the Secretary will allocate 
    (expense) the benefit to the year in which the benefit is considered to 
    have been received under paragraph (b) of this section.
    
    [[Page 8853]]
    
    Sec. 351.511 Purchase of goods.  [Reserved]
    
    
    Sec. 351.512  Worker-related subsidies.
    
        (a) Benefit. In the case of a program that provides assistance to 
    workers, a benefit exists to the extent that the assistance relieves a 
    firm of an obligation that it normally would incur.
        (b) Time of receipt of benefit. In the case of assistance provided 
    to workers, the Secretary normally will consider the benefit as having 
    been received by the firm as of the date on which the payment is made 
    that relieves the firm of the relevant obligation.
        (c) Allocation of benefit to a particular time period. Normally, 
    the Secretary will allocate (expense) the benefit from assistance 
    provided to workers to the year in which the benefit is considered to 
    have been received under paragraph (b) of this section.
    
    
    Sec. 351.513  Export subsidies.
    
        The Secretary will consider a subsidy to be an export subsidy if 
    the Secretary determines that eligibility for, approval of, or the 
    amount of, a subsidy is contingent upon actual or anticipated 
    exportation or export earnings. In applying this section, the Secretary 
    will consider a subsidy to be contingent upon actual or anticipated 
    exportation or export earnings if receipt of the subsidy is, in law or 
    in fact, tied to actual or anticipated export performance, alone or as 
    one of two or more factors.
    
    
    Sec. 351.514  Internal transport and freight charges for export 
    shipments.
    
        (a) Benefit.--(1) In general. In the case of internal transport and 
    freight charges on export shipments, a benefit exists to the extent 
    that the charges paid by a firm for transport or freight with respect 
    to goods destined for export are less than what the firm would have 
    paid if the goods were destined for domestic consumption. The Secretary 
    will consider the amount of the benefit to equal the difference in 
    amounts paid.
        (2) Exception. For purposes of paragraph (a)(1) of this section, a 
    benefit does not exist if the Secretary determines that:
        (i) Any difference in charges is the result of an arm's length 
    transaction between the supplier and the user of the transport or 
    freight service; or
        (ii) The difference in charges is commercially justified.
        (b) Time of receipt of benefit. In the case of internal transport 
    and freight charges for export shipments, the Secretary normally will 
    consider the benefit as having been received by the firm as of the date 
    on which the firm paid, or in the absence of payment was due to pay, 
    the charges.
        (c) Allocation of benefit to a particular time period. Normally, 
    the Secretary will allocate (expense) the benefit from internal 
    transport and freight charges for export shipments to the year in which 
    the benefit is considered to have been received under paragraph (b) of 
    this section.
    
    
    Sec. 351.515  Price preferences for inputs used in the production of 
    goods for export.
    
        (a) Benefit. (1) In general. In the case of the provision by 
    governments or their agencies, either directly or indirectly through 
    government-mandated schemes, of imported or domestic products for use 
    in the production of exported goods, a benefit exists to the extent 
    that the Secretary determines that the terms or conditions on which the 
    products are provided are more favorable than the terms or conditions 
    applicable to the provision of like or directly competitive products 
    for use in the production of goods for domestic consumption. The amount 
    of the benefit will equal the difference between the amount that a firm 
    paid for inputs used in the production of export products and the 
    amount the firm would have paid for like or directly competitive 
    products for use in the production of goods for domestic consumption.
        (2) Exception. A benefit will not exist under paragraph (a)(1) of 
    this section if the Secretary determines that the terms or conditions 
    relating to the provision of products for use in the production of 
    exported goods are not more favorable than those commercially available 
    on world markets to exporters in the country in question. For purposes 
    of the preceding sentence, the Secretary normally will compare the 
    price charged for the domestically sourced input to the delivered price 
    of the imported input in order to determine whether the domestically 
    sourced input is being provided on more favorable terms or conditions 
    than those available on world markets.
        (3) Commercially available. For purposes of paragraph (a)(2) of 
    this section, ``commercially available'' means that the choice between 
    domestic and imported products is unrestricted and depends only on 
    commercial considerations.
        (b) Time of receipt of benefit. In the case of a benefit described 
    in paragraph (a)(1) of this section, the Secretary normally will 
    consider the benefit to have been received as of the date on which the 
    firm paid, or in the absence of payment was due to pay, for the 
    product.
        (c) Allocation of benefit to a particular time period. Normally, 
    the Secretary will allocate (expense) benefits described in paragraph 
    (a)(1) of this section to the year in which the benefit is considered 
    to have been received under paragraph (b) of this section.
    
    
    Sec. 351.516  Remission upon export of indirect taxes.
    
        (a) Benefit. In the case of the remission upon export of indirect 
    taxes, a benefit exists to the extent that the Secretary determines 
    that the amount remitted exceeds the amount levied with respect to the 
    production and distribution of like products when sold for domestic 
    consumption.
        (b) Time of receipt of benefit. In the case of the remission upon 
    export of an indirect tax, the Secretary will consider the benefit as 
    having been received as of the date of exportation.
        (c) Allocation of benefit to a particular time period. Normally, 
    the Secretary will allocate (expense) the benefit from the remission 
    upon export of indirect taxes to the year in which the benefit is 
    considered to have been received under paragraph (b) of this section.
    
    
    Sec. 351.517  Exemption, remission or deferral upon export of prior-
    stage cumulative indirect taxes.
    
        (a) Benefit.--(1) Exemption of prior-stage cumulative indirect 
    taxes. In the case of a program that provides for the exemption of 
    prior-stage cumulative indirect taxes on inputs used in the production 
    of an exported product, a benefit exists to the extent that the 
    exemption extends to inputs that are not consumed in the production of 
    the exported product, making normal allowance for waste. If the 
    Secretary determines that the exemption of prior-stage cumulative 
    indirect taxes confers a benefit, the Secretary normally will consider 
    the amount of the benefit to be the prior-stage cumulative indirect 
    taxes that otherwise would have been paid on the inputs not consumed in 
    the production of the exported product, making normal allowance for 
    waste.
        (2) Remission of prior-stage cumulative indirect taxes. In the case 
    of a program that provides for the remission of prior-stage cumulative 
    indirect taxes on inputs used in the production of an exported product, 
    a benefit exists to the extent that the amount remitted exceeds the 
    amount of prior-stage cumulative indirect taxes paid on inputs that are 
    consumed in the production of the exported product, making normal 
    allowance for waste. If the Secretary determines that the remission of 
    prior-stage cumulative indirect taxes confers a benefit, the Secretary 
    normally will consider the
    
    [[Page 8854]]
    
    amount of the benefit to be the difference between the amount remitted 
    and the amount of the prior-stage cumulative indirect taxes on inputs 
    that are consumed in the production of the export product, making 
    normal allowance for waste. Notwithstanding the preceding sentence, the 
    Secretary will consider the entire amount of the remittance to confer a 
    benefit, unless the Secretary determines that:
        (i) The government in question has in place and applies a system or 
    procedure to confirm which inputs are consumed in the production of the 
    exported products and in what amounts, and the system or procedure is 
    reasonable, effective for the purposes intended, and is based on 
    generally accepted commercial practices in the country of export; or
        (ii) If the government in question does not have a system or 
    procedure in place, where the system or procedure is not reasonable, or 
    where the system or procedure is instituted and considered reasonable, 
    but is found not to be applied or not to be applied effectively, the 
    government in question has carried out an examination of actual inputs 
    involved to confirm which inputs are consumed in the production of the 
    exported product.
        (3) Deferral of prior-stage cumulative indirect taxes. In the case 
    of a program that provides for a deferral of prior-stage cumulative 
    indirect taxes on an exported product, a benefit does not exist if the 
    government charges appropriate interest on the taxes deferred. If the 
    Secretary determines that a benefit exists, the Secretary normally will 
    treat the deferral as if it were a government-provided loan in the 
    amount of the tax deferred, according to the methodology described in 
    Sec. 351.504.
        (b) Time of receipt of benefit. In the case of the exemption, 
    remission, or deferral of prior-stage cumulative indirect taxes, the 
    Secretary normally will consider the benefit as having been received:
        (1) In the case of an exemption, as of the date of exportation;
        (2) In the case of a remission, as of the date of exportation;
        (3) In the case of a deferral of one year or less, as of the date 
    on which the deferred tax was due; and
        (4) In the case of a multi-year deferral, as of the anniversary 
    date(s) of the deferral.
        (c) Allocation of benefit to a particular time period. The 
    Secretary normally will allocate (expense) the benefit of the 
    exemption, remission, or deferral of prior-stage cumulative indirect 
    taxes to the year in which the benefit is considered to have been 
    received under paragraph (b) of this section.
    
    
    Sec. 351.518  Remission or drawback of import charges upon export.
    
        (a) Benefit.--(1) In general. In the case of the remission or 
    drawback of import charges upon export, a benefit exists to the extent 
    that the Secretary determines that the amount of the remission or 
    drawback exceeds the amount of import charges on imported inputs 
    consumed in the production of the exported product, making normal 
    allowances for waste.
        (2) Substitution drawback. ``Substitution drawback'' involves a 
    situation in which a firm uses a quantity of home market inputs equal 
    to, and having the same quality and characteristics as, the imported 
    inputs as a substitute for them. Substitution drawback does not 
    necessarily result in the conferral of a benefit. However, a benefit 
    exists if the Secretary determines that:
        (i) The import and the corresponding export operations both did not 
    occur within a reasonable time period, not to exceed two years; or
        (ii) The amount drawnback exceeds the amount of the import charges 
    levied initially on the imported inputs for which drawback is claimed.
        (3) Amount of the benefit from remission or drawback--(i) In 
    general. If the Secretary determines that the remission or drawback, 
    including substitution drawback, of import charges confers a benefit 
    under paragraph (a)(1) or (a)(2) of this section, the Secretary 
    normally will consider the amount of the benefit to be the difference 
    between the amount of import charges remitted or drawnback and the 
    amount levied initially on the imported inputs for which remission or 
    drawback was claimed.
        (ii) Exception. Notwithstanding paragraph (a)(3)(i) of this 
    section, the Secretary will consider the entire amount of a remission 
    or drawback to confer a benefit, unless the Secretary determines that:
        (A) The government in question has in place and applies a system or 
    procedure to confirm which inputs are consumed in the production of the 
    exported products and in what amounts, and the system or procedure is 
    reasonable, effective for the purposes intended, and is based on 
    generally accepted commercial practices in the country of export; or
        (B) If the government in question does not have a system or 
    procedure in place, where the system or procedure is not reasonable, or 
    where the system or procedure is instituted and considered reasonable, 
    but is found not to be applied or not to be applied effectively, the 
    government in question has carried out an examination of actual inputs 
    involved to confirm which inputs are consumed in the production of the 
    exported product.
        (b) Time of receipt of benefit. In the case of the remission or 
    drawback of import charges, the Secretary normally will consider the 
    benefit as having been received as of the date of exportation.
        (c) Allocation of benefit to a particular time period. The 
    Secretary normally will allocate (expense) the benefit of the remission 
    or drawback of import charges to the year in which the benefit is 
    considered to have been received under paragraph (b) of this section.
    
    
    Sec. 351.519  Export insurance.
    
        (a) Benefit--(1) In general. In the case of export insurance, a 
    benefit exists if the premium rates charged are inadequate to cover the 
    long-term operating costs and losses of the program.
        (2) Amount of the benefit. If the Secretary determines under 
    paragraph (a)(1) of this section that premium rates are inadequate, the 
    Secretary normally will calculate the amount of the benefit as the 
    difference between the amount of premiums paid by the firm and the 
    amount received by the firm under the insurance program during the 
    period of investigation or review.
        (b) Time of receipt of benefit. In the case of export insurance, 
    the Secretary normally will consider the benefit as having been 
    received in the year in which the difference described in paragraph 
    (a)(2) of this section occurs.
        (c) Allocation of benefit to a particular time period. The 
    Secretary normally will allocate (expense) the benefit from export 
    insurance to the year in which the benefit is considered to have been 
    received under paragraph (b) of this section.
    
    
    Sec. 351.520  General export promotion.
    
        In the case of export promotion activities of a government, a 
    benefit does not exist if the Secretary determines that the activities 
    consist of general informational activities that do not promote 
    particular products over others.
    
    
    Sec. 351.521  Import substitution subsidies. [Reserved]
    
    
    Sec. 351.522  Certain agricultural subsidies.
    
        The Secretary will treat as noncountervailable domestic support 
    measures that are provided to certain agricultural products (i.e., 
    products listed in Annex 1 of the WTO
    
    [[Page 8855]]
    
    Agreement on Agriculture) and that the Secretary determines conform to 
    the criteria of Annex 2 of the WTO Agreement on Agriculture. See 
    section 771(5B)(F) of the Act. The Secretary will determine that a 
    particular domestic support measure conforms fully to the provisions of 
    Annex 2 if the Secretary finds that the measure:
        (a) Is provided through a publicly-funded government program 
    (including government revenue foregone) not involving transfers from 
    consumers;
        (b) Does not have the effect of providing price support to 
    producers; and
        (c) Meets the relevant policy-specific criteria and conditions set 
    out in paragraphs 2 through 13 of Annex 2.
    
    
    Sec. 351.523  Upstream subsidies.
    
        (a) Investigation of upstream subsidies--(1) In general. Before 
    investigating the existence of an upstream subsidy (see section 771A of 
    the Act), the Secretary must have a reasonable basis to believe or 
    suspect that all of the following elements exist:
        (i) A countervailable subsidy, other than an export subsidy, is 
    provided with respect to an input product;
        (ii) One of the following conditions exist:
        (A) There is cross ownership between the supplier of the input 
    product and the producer of the subject merchandise;
        (B) The price for the subsidized input product is lower than the 
    price that the producer of the subject merchandise otherwise would pay 
    another seller in an arm's length transaction for an unsubsidized input 
    product; or
        (C) The government sets the price of the input product so as to 
    guarantee that the benefit provided with respect to the input product 
    is passed through to producers of the subject merchandise; and
        (iii) The ad valorem countervailable subsidy rate on the input 
    product, multiplied by the proportion of the total production costs of 
    the subject merchandise accounted for by the input product, is equal 
    to, or greater than, one percent.
        (b) Input product. For purposes of this section, ``input product'' 
    means any product used in the production of the subject merchandise.
        (c) Competitive benefit--(1) In general. In evaluating whether a 
    competitive benefit exists under section 771A(b) of the Act, the 
    Secretary will determine whether the price for the subsidized input 
    product is lower than the benchmark input price. For purposes of this 
    section, the Secretary will use as a benchmark input price the 
    following, in order of preference:
        (i) The actual price paid by, or offered to, the producer of the 
    subject merchandise for an unsubsidized input product, including an 
    imported input product;
        (ii) An average price for an unsubsidized input product, including 
    an imported input product, based upon publicly available data;
        (iii) The actual price paid by, or offered to, the producer of the 
    subject merchandise for a subsidized input product, including an 
    imported input product, that is adjusted to account for the 
    countervailable subsidy;
        (iv) An average price for a subsidized input product, including an 
    imported input product, based upon publicly available data, that is 
    adjusted to account for the countervailable subsidy; or
        (v) An unadjusted price for a subsidized input product.
        (2) Use of delivered prices. The Secretary will use a delivered 
    (e.g., c.i.f.) price whenever the Secretary uses the price of an 
    imported input product under paragraph (c)(1) of this section.
        (d) Significant effect--(1) Presumptions. In evaluating whether an 
    upstream subsidy has a significant effect on the cost of manufacturing 
    or producing the subject merchandise (see section 771A(a)(3) of the 
    Act), the Secretary will multiply the ad valorem countervailable 
    subsidy rate on the input product by the proportion of the total 
    production cost of the subject merchandise that is accounted for by the 
    input product. If the product of that multiplication exceeds five 
    percent, the Secretary will presume the existence of a significant 
    effect. If the product is less than one percent, the Secretary will 
    presume the absence of a significant effect. If the product is between 
    one and five percent, there will be no presumption.
        (2) Rebuttal of presumptions. A party to the proceeding may present 
    information to rebut these presumptions. In evaluating such 
    information, the Secretary will consider the extent to which factors 
    other than price, such as quality differences, are important 
    determinants of demand for the subject merchandise.
    
    
    Sec. 351.524  Calculation of ad valorem subsidy rate and attribution of 
    subsidy to a product.
    
        (a) Calculation of ad valorem subsidy rate. The Secretary will 
    calculate an ad valorem subsidy rate by dividing the amount of the 
    benefit allocated to the period of investigation or review by the sales 
    value during the same period of the product to which the Secretary 
    attributes the subsidy under paragraph (b) of this section. Normally, 
    the Secretary will determine the sales value of a product on an F.O.B. 
    (port) basis (if the product is exported) or on an F.O.B. (factory) 
    basis (if the product is sold for domestic consumption). However, if 
    the Secretary determines that countervailable subsidies are provided 
    with respect to the movement of a product from the port or factory to 
    the place of destination (e.g., freight or insurance costs are 
    subsidized), the Secretary may make appropriate adjustments to the ad 
    valorem subsidy rate to account for such subsidies.
        (b) Attribution of a subsidy to a product--(1) In general. In 
    attributing a subsidy to one or more products, the Secretary will apply 
    the rules set forth in paragraphs (b)(2) through (b)(7) of this 
    section.
        (2) Export subsidies. The Secretary will attribute an export 
    subsidy only to products exported by a firm.
        (3) Domestic subsidies and import substitution subsidies. The 
    Secretary will attribute a domestic subsidy or an import substitution 
    subsidy to all products sold by a firm, including products that are 
    exported.
        (4) Subsidies tied to a particular market. If a subsidy is tied to 
    sales to a particular market, the Secretary will attribute the subsidy 
    only to products sold by the firm to that market.
        (5) Subsidies tied to a particular product.--(i) In general. If a 
    subsidy is tied to the production or sale of a particular product, the 
    Secretary will attribute the subsidy only to that product.
        (ii) Exception. If a subsidy is tied to the production or sale of 
    an input product produced within the same corporation that produces the 
    downstream product, then a subsidy which is tied to the input product 
    will be attributed to the input and downstream products produced by 
    that corporation.
        (6) Corporations with Cross Ownership.--(i) In general. The 
    Secretary normally will attribute a subsidy to the products produced by 
    the corporation that received the subsidy.
        (ii) Corporations producing the same product. If two (or more) 
    corporations with cross ownership produce the same product, the 
    Secretary will attribute the subsidies received by either or both 
    corporations to the products produced by both corporations.
        (iii) Holding companies. If the firm that received a subsidy is a 
    holding company, the Secretary will attribute the subsidy to the 
    consolidated sales of the holding company. However, if the
    
    [[Page 8856]]
    
    Secretary finds that the holding company merely served as a conduit for 
    the transfer of the subsidy from the government to a subsidiary of the 
    holding company, the Secretary will attribute the subsidy to products 
    sold by the subsidiary.
        (iv) Transfer of subsidy between corporations with cross ownership 
    producing different products. If a corporation producing non-subject 
    merchandise received a subsidy and transferred the subsidy to a 
    corporation with cross ownership, the Secretary will attribute the 
    subsidy to products sold by the recipient of the transferred subsidy.
        (7) Multinational firms. If the firm that received a subsidy has 
    production facilities in two or more countries, the Secretary will 
    attribute the subsidy to products produced by the firm within the 
    jurisdiction of the government that granted the subsidy. However, if 
    the subsidy is tied to production by a facility outside of that 
    jurisdiction, the Secretary will attribute the subsidy to products 
    produced by that facility.
    
    
    Sec. 351.525  Program-wide changes.
    
        (a) In general. The Secretary may take a program-wide change into 
    account in establishing the estimated countervailing duty cash deposit 
    rate if:
        (1) The Secretary determines that subsequent to the period of 
    investigation or review, but before a preliminary determination in an 
    investigation (see Sec. 351.205) or a preliminary results of an 
    administrative review or a new shipper review (see Secs. 351.213 and 
    351.214), a program-wide change has occurred; and
        (2) The Secretary is able to measure the change in the amount of 
    countervailable subsidies provided under the program in question.
        (b) Definition of program-wide change. For purposes of this 
    section, ``program-wide change'' means a change that:
        (1) Is not limited to an individual firm or firms; and
        (2) Is effectuated by an official act, such as the enactment of a 
    statute, regulation, or decree, or contained in the schedule of an 
    existing statute, regulation, or decree.
        (c) Effect limited to cash deposit rate.--(1) In general. The 
    application of paragraph (a) of this section will not result in 
    changing an affirmative determination to a negative determination or a 
    negative determination to an affirmative determination.
        (2) Example. In a countervailing duty investigation, the Secretary 
    determines that during the period of investigation a countervailable 
    subsidy existed in the amount of 10 percent ad valorem. Subsequent to 
    the period of investigation, but before the preliminary determination, 
    the foreign government in question enacts a change to the program that 
    reduces the amount of the subsidy to a de minimis level. In a final 
    determination, the Secretary would issue an affirmative determination, 
    but would establish a cash deposit rate of zero.
        (d) Terminated programs. The Secretary will not adjust the cash 
    deposit rate under paragraph (a) of this section if the program-wide 
    change consists of the termination of a program and:
        (1) The Secretary determines that residual benefits may continue to 
    be bestowed under the terminated program; or
        (2) The Secretary determines that a substitute program for the 
    terminated program has been introduced and the Secretary is not able to 
    measure the amount of countervailable subsidies provided under the 
    substitute program.
    
    
    Sec. 351.526  Transnational subsidies.
    
        Except as otherwise provided in section 701(d) of the Act 
    (subsidies provided to international consortia), a subsidy does not 
    exist if the Secretary determines that the funding for the subsidy is 
    provided:
        (a) By a government of a country other than the country in which 
    the recipient firm is located, or
        (b) By an international lending or development institution.
    
    
    Sec. 351.527  Tax consequences of benefits.
    
        In calculating the amount of a benefit, the Secretary will not 
    consider the secondary tax consequences of the benefit.
    
    [FR Doc. 97-4538 Filed 2-25-97; 8:45 am]
    BILLING CODE 3510-25-P
    
    
    

Document Information

Published:
02/26/1997
Department:
International Trade Administration
Entry Type:
Proposed Rule
Action:
Notice of proposed rulemaking and request for public comments.
Document Number:
97-4538
Dates:
Written comments will be due on April 28, 1997.
Pages:
8818-8856 (39 pages)
Docket Numbers:
Docket No. 950306068-6185-03
RINs:
0625-AA45: Antidumping Duties; Countervailing Duties
RIN Links:
https://www.federalregister.gov/regulations/0625-AA45/antidumping-duties-countervailing-duties
PDF File:
97-4538.pdf
CFR: (60)
19 CFR 351.102.)
19 CFR 351.214)
19 CFR 351.523(a)
19 CFR 351.504(a)(4))
19 CFR 355.44(a)
More ...