95-1358. Transport Rate Structure and Pricing  

  • [Federal Register Volume 60, Number 13 (Friday, January 20, 1995)]
    [Rules and Regulations]
    [Pages 4107-4110]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 95-1358]
    
    
    
    =======================================================================
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
    
    47 CFR Parts 61 and 69
    
    [CC Docket No. 91-213; FCC 94-325]
    
    
    Transport Rate Structure and Pricing
    
    AGENCY: Federal Communications Commission.
    
    ACTION: Final rule.
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    SUMMARY: The Commission affirmed the interim transport rate structure, 
    the method used to establish initial transport rates under the interim 
    rate structure, and the price cap rules adopted to regulate future 
    changes in transport rates. The Commission also clarified certain 
    implementation procedures with respect to the interim transport rate 
    structure and pricing rules. In doing so, the Commission resolved all 
    the remaining issues raised on reconsideration in this proceeding.
    
    EFFECTIVE DATE: February 21, 1995.
    
    [[Page 4108]] FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
    Matthew J. Harthun, (202) 418-1590 or David L. Sieradzki, (202) 418-
    1576, Policy and Program Planning Division, Common Carrier Bureau.
    
    SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a synopsis of the Commission's Third 
    Memorandum Opinion and Order on Reconsideration in CC Docket No. 91-
    213, adopted December 15, 1994, and released December 22, 1994. The 
    complete text of this Third Memorandum Opinion and Order on 
    Reconsideration is available for inspection and copying during normal 
    business hours in the FCC Reference Center, 1919 M Street, N.W., Room 
    239, Washington, D.C. 20554.
    
    Synopsis of Memorandum Opinion and Order
    
    A. The Interim Rate Structure
    
        1. The interim rate structure is a significant improvement over the 
    ``equal charge'' rate structure. We believe that the interim rate 
    structure is consistent with all three of our goals in this proceeding: 
    (1) Encouraging efficient use of transport facilities by allowing 
    pricing that reflects the way costs are incurred; (2) facilitating full 
    and fair interexchange competition; and (3) avoiding interference with 
    the development of interstate access competition. Having weighed the 
    costs associated with an interim approach--namely, the effect on tandem 
    competition and the delay in implementing a full cost-based rate 
    structure--against the benefits associated with its balancing of our 
    three public interest goals, we conclude that our cautious approach of 
    adopting an interim rate structure and seeking comment on a long-term 
    rate structure was a reasonable step towards a more cost-based 
    transport rate structure.
        2. We decline to hold open this proceeding, as suggested in the 
    record. We conclude that we have had sufficient time to evaluate the 
    interim restructure. We conclude, however, that continued monitoring of 
    the effects of the interim transport rate structure would be in the 
    public interest, and we delegate authority to the Chief, Common Carrier 
    Bureau, to continue and refine the Bureau's transport monitoring 
    program. With our affirmation of the interim transport rate structure, 
    we retain our conclusions that: (1) non-Tier 1 local exchange carriers 
    (LECs) are exempt from implementing the interim transport rate 
    structure; (2) if such LECs provide entrance facilities, they must 
    provide them on a flat-rated basis; and (3) such LECs must offer flat-
    rated direct-trunked transport upon receipt of a bona fide request.
    
    B. Initial Benchmark Level and Permanent Rate Relationships
    
        3. We affirm the benchmark used in setting the initial transport 
    rates and our use of price cap rules to govern subsequent changes in 
    the price cap LECs' transport rates.
        4. Adjusting the Benchmark or Applying It to Subsequent Rate 
    Changes. We decline to revise the benchmark used to establish initial 
    transport rates or establish rigid rate relationships based on such a 
    benchmark. We conclude that the small and medium interexchange 
    carriers' (IXCs') suggested level of the benchmark lacks adequate cost 
    justification. We continue to believe that special access rates provide 
    a rational framework for establishing the initial transport rates.
        5. Further, fixed rate relationships are not consistent with LEC 
    price cap regulation. We believe that requiring permanent rate 
    relationships between DS3, DS1, and tandem-switched transport rates 
    would interfere with the efficient functioning of the market, and could 
    retard long-distance price reductions, depress telecommunications 
    usage, and inhibit economic growth. We reject the related 
    recommendation to require the LECs to reset their tandem-switched 
    transport rates annually based on DS3 and DS1 direct-trunked transport 
    rates, weighted based on updated fiber/copper ratios. We continue to 
    believe that price cap rules, rather than required annual adjustments 
    guided by cost factors, are the most appropriate means, in an 
    increasingly competitive access market, to govern ongoing changes in 
    rates for LEC services, including tandem-switched transport.
        6. We also decline to require the LECs to place uniform overhead 
    loadings on their transport rates as a means of constraining changes to 
    the price relationships between DS3 and DS1 rates. We conclude that 
    even if it were demonstrated that different transport services are 
    ``like services,'' differences between the levels of overhead loadings 
    recovered in those rates would not necessarily constitute unreasonable 
    discrimination. (We note that allegations that specific rates of 
    individual carriers are discriminatory are not before us in this 
    proceeding.)
        7. While we continue to believe that a certain level of pricing 
    flexibility is needed to enable the LECs to meet increasing competition 
    in the local access market, we also recognize that without sufficient 
    regulatory constraints the LECs could price their transport services 
    anti-competitively. We have addressed this concern through special 
    safeguards in the price cap system: placing DS3 flat-rated transport, 
    DS1 flat-rated transport, and tandem-switched transport in separate 
    service categories and subcategories, and retaining the +2% upper 
    pricing band for tandem-switched transport services. We continue to 
    believe that this approach best balances our concerns about potential 
    anti-competitive LEC pricing and the LECs' need for some pricing 
    flexibility in the face of increased competition, and thus, best 
    promotes our public interest goals. We note, however, that this 
    decision does not limit our discretion in addressing the separate 
    record developed in our pending LEC Price Cap Review proceeding (Price 
    Cap Performance Review for Local Exchange Carriers, Notice of Proposed 
    Rulemaking, 59 FR 12888 (March 18, 1994)).
        8. Applying the Benchmark Separately to Different Transport 
    Segments. The method we used to create the benchmark was based on a 
    typical configuration of LEC transport offerings, using rates from 
    analogous special access offerings--one IXCs would likely use to 
    purchase transport services, and competitive access providers would 
    likely use to offer services that could be substituted for both 
    entrance facilities and interoffice facilities. We decline to require 
    the LECs to satisfy separate benchmark requirements for entrance 
    facilities and for direct-trunked transport.
        9. Methodology for LECs with Rate Ratios Below the Benchmark. We 
    decline to revise the method by which those LECs with September 1992 
    special access rates below the 9.6 to 1 benchmark established initial 
    transport rates.
    
    C. Price Cap Service Categories and Price Bands
    
    1. Tandem Switching
        10. We decline to place tandem switching and local switching into 
    the same price cap basket, whether that basket is the traffic sensitive 
    basket or a new ``switching'' basket. We note also that this decision 
    does not limit our discretion in addressing the separate record 
    developed in the LEC Price Cap Review proceeding. We see no reason to 
    treat tandem switching differently from tandem-switched transport 
    transmission elements, and we retain the tandem switch element in the 
    tandem-switched transport service category.
        11. We also reject SW Bell's proposal to place the interconnection 
    charge into a separate ``public policy'' basket. Until [[Page 4109]] we 
    have completed our evaluation of what underlying costs are recovered in 
    the interconnection charge and how the interconnection charge revenues 
    should be reallocated or otherwise disposed of, we conclude that the 
    interconnection charge service category should be included in the 
    trunking basket.
        12. Finally, we decline to price the tandem switching element 
    incrementally, or to eliminate that element. We conclude that such 
    measures would not be in the public interest.
    2. Price Cap Service Categories and Pricing Bands
        13. In our 1994 Second Transport Order (Transport Rate Structure 
    and Pricing, Second Report and Order, 59 FR 10300 (March 4, 1994)), we 
    specifically placed tandem-switched transport, DS1, and DS3 flat-rated 
    services into separate service categories and service subcategories in 
    order to prevent the LECs from offsetting lower rates for services 
    subject to more competition with higher rates for less competitive 
    services. We concluded in that order, and continue to believe, that 
    separate price cap service categories and pricing bands are sufficient 
    to protect against potential anti-competitive behavior. Accordingly, we 
    decline to eliminate the separate service categories and subcategories 
    that apply to transport services.
        14. We also decline to put entrance facilities and interoffice 
    facilities into separate service categories. No sufficient reason 
    exists to place entrance facilities and interoffice facilities in 
    separate service categories and to restrict the LECs' pricing 
    flexibility between these services. We decline to eliminate the limited 
    upward pricing flexibility permitted for tandem-switched transport.
    
    D. The Interconnection Charge
    
    1. Mid-Course Adjustment to the Interconnection Charge
        15. We clarify that the period to be used in calculating the amount 
    of any mid-course adjustment to the interconnection charge is from the 
    effective date of the initial transport tariffs (December 30, 1993) 
    through December 31, 1994. This calculation will define the amount that 
    will prospectively establish the appropriate level for the 
    interconnection charge. We further clarify that the mid-course 
    adjustment to the interconnection charge permits recoupment of under-
    recovered interconnection charge revenues from December 30, 1993 to the 
    effective date of the tariff implementing the mid-course adjustment. We 
    intended that the interconnection charge yield only an initial rate 
    restructure that was revenue-neutral. We interpret ``initial'' to apply 
    to the first year after the implementation of the new rates. Subsequent 
    changes to the interconnection charge will be governed by the price cap 
    rules. LECs must file requests for mid-course adjustments to the 
    interconnection charge no later than March 31, 1995. We delegate 
    authority to the Chief, Common Carrier Bureau, to specify the format 
    and content of such filings.
        16. The mid-course adjustment to the interconnection charge, should 
    any LEC choose to avail itself of the adjustment, does not constitute 
    retroactive ratemaking. The adjustment will affect only rates in effect 
    after the date of the adjustment. It will not retroactively change the 
    interconnection charge rates that customers already paid before the 
    adjustment date. Nor will the adjustment require recoupment of revenues 
    from customers or refunds to customers without suspension and an 
    accounting order pursuant to Section 204(a) of the Communications Act, 
    47 U.S.C. 204(a).
        17. That the mid-course adjustment will take into account revenues 
    the LECs under-recovered before the date of the adjustment does not 
    convert the adjustment into retroactive ratemaking. All interested 
    parties were on notice prior to the effective date of the transport 
    tariffs that the interconnection charge was subject to adjustment and 
    that the purpose of that adjustment was to achieve more fully our 
    objective of revenue neutrality during the transition from the old to 
    the new rate structure. Therefore, any adjustment at a later date 
    merely constitutes the implementation of a prospectively established 
    obligation affecting the LECs and all access customers. The prior 
    notice that the interconnection charge would be subject to adjustment, 
    and the unique nature of the interconnection charge mid-course 
    adjustment in the context of the major, Commission-required transport 
    rate restructure, distinguish this case from cases in which a carrier 
    generally seeks to adjust its rates prospectively to recoup costs from 
    an earlier period. We do not address whether or not such cases would 
    constitute retroactive ratemaking.
    2. Burden of Proof for the Mid-Course Adjustment
        18. We decline to modify the burden of proof associated with the 
    mid-course adjustment. The LECs have the burden of demonstrating a 
    significant under-recovery of revenues that justifies an adjustment to 
    the interconnection charge. We affirm our determination that the LECs 
    must prove the extent to which they have not been able to reuse 
    facilities no longer needed after IXC reconfigurations.
        19. We clarify, however, that the burden of proving that facilities 
    could not be reused does not apply to facilities that are reused as a 
    result of the transport restructure itself. For example, if a customer 
    reconfigures its LEC entrance facility from 25 DS1 circuits to a lower-
    priced DS3 circuit running over the same physical facility, the 
    ``reuse'' of that facility in providing DS3 service instead of DS1 
    service is not excluded from the computation of the interconnection 
    charge. In such a case, the interconnection charge may reasonably 
    include recovery of the difference between the price of the 25 DS1 
    circuits and the price of the DS3 circuit. The requirement that LECs 
    show that they have been unable to reuse facilities applies to 
    situations in which facilities are no longer used for interstate 
    switched transport, and the LECs have not been able to put the 
    facilities to any alternative uses. For example, if the customer 
    terminates its use of the 25 DS1 circuits because, due to the transport 
    restructure, it has decided to consolidate its points of presence, and 
    the LEC is unable to put the entrance facility to any alternative uses 
    in its network, then the LEC may reasonably include recovery of the 
    lost DS1 revenues in the interconnection charge.
        20. We also affirm our determination that the LECs should have the 
    burden of proving that demand losses result from the transport rate 
    restructure rather than competition. While we intend that the transport 
    rate restructure be revenue-neutral to the LECs, competition in the 
    provision of switched transport is likely to result in revenue losses 
    to the LECs. The interconnection charge should not be used to shield 
    LECs from the risks of revenue loss associated with growing 
    competition.
    3. Waiver of Non-Recurring Charges
        21. We decline to modify the scope of the NRC waiver. As a general 
    matter, we conclude that to broaden the scope of the NRC waiver to 
    include network reconfigurations not related to the rate restructure 
    would be unfair to the LECs and beyond the scope of this proceeding. 
    Specifically, we conclude that six months was ample time for the 
    mandated waiver to be held open, especially since IXCs had more than 
    one year to plan any network reconfigurations before the new rate 
    structure became effective. We reject [[Page 4110]] CompTel's 
    recommendation that we require waiver of termination penalties in 
    contracts for entrance facilities because we conclude that such a 
    waiver would deny the LECs recovery of capital expenditures made 
    specifically for a particular IXC. We also decline to adopt AT&T's 
    proposal to require LECs to waive NRCs for all IXC consolidations 
    because it is moot and beyond the scope of this proceeding. Moreover, 
    we decline to restrict the NRC waiver to once per trunk, as USTA 
    suggests, because, in light of the limited time period for which the 
    waiver was available, we have no reason to believe that the significant 
    churn envisioned by USTA occurred.
        22. Finally, we conclude that, in their mid-course adjustment of 
    the interconnection charge, the LECs are entitled, upon a proper 
    showing, to take into account NRCs waived pursuant to the Commission's 
    requirement. Therefore, if a LEC can demonstrate that, as a result of 
    the Commission-mandated waiver of NRCs, the transport restructure 
    yielded revenues significantly less than the amount it realized 
    previously, in part, because the number of NRCs charged during the year 
    fell short of the demand level used in calculating the initial 
    interconnection charge, the LEC may seek a mid-course adjustment on 
    this basis. We conclude that the Commission has statutory authority to 
    allow this type of recovery through the interconnection charge because 
    it is necessary to maintain revenue neutrality and because carrying out 
    such an adjustment does not constitute retroactive ratemaking.
    
    E. Miscellaneous
    
    1. Pricing Flexibility
        23. We reaffirm that the LECs may offer term and volume discounts 
    for switched transport services and may implement density zone pricing 
    of switched transport, as set forth in the Switched Transport Expanded 
    Interconnection Order (Expanded Interconnection with Local Telephone 
    Company Facilities, Second Report and Order and Third Notice of 
    Proposed Rulemaking, 58 FR 48756 (September 17, 1993)), and as 
    reaffirmed and slightly modified by the Expanded Interconnection Remand 
    Order, (Expanded Interconnection with Local Telephone Company 
    Facilities, Memorandum Opinion and Order, 59 FR 38922 (August 1, 
    1994)). We decided these issues in the expanded interconnection 
    proceeding, based on a separate and complete record. The present 
    record, however, does not refute the need for this additional pricing 
    flexibility in an increasingly competitive access market.
        24. With respect to volume and term discounts, we clarify that the 
    rules we adopted in the expanded interconnection proceeding regarding 
    discounted transport offerings (47 U.S.C. 69.110(f)-(h), 69.111(i)-(k), 
    and 69.112(f)-(h)) contemplate only volume discounts (reduced per-unit 
    prices for a particular number of units of service) and term discounts 
    (reduced per-unit prices for a specified service for a particular 
    period of time). These rules do not provide for percentage or growth 
    discounts--reduced per-unit prices for customers that commit to 
    purchase a certain percentage of their past usage from a LEC, or 
    reduced prices based on growth in traffic placed over a LEC's network. 
    With respect to density zone pricing, we reaffirm our requirement that 
    the price subindexes (i.e., the upper and lower pricing bands--not the 
    rate levels) be the same in each zone when a LEC introduces density 
    zone pricing in a study area.
    2. Intermediate Hubbing and Tandem-Switched Transport
        25. We decline to adopt Sprint's proposal to modify the definition 
    of ``tandem-switched transport'' to include service between any 
    customer-designated telephone company office and an end office, thus 
    permitting IXCs to purchase (1) dedicated facilities to an intermediate 
    hub that is not collocated at the serving wire center or at the tandem 
    office; and (2) tandem-switched transport from that intermediate hub to 
    an end office, rated based on the distance between the hub and the end 
    offices without regard for the actual location of the intervening 
    tandem office. We have already adopted rules that enable tandem-
    switched transport users to obtain efficiencies through intermediate 
    hubbing. Sprint's proposal would substantially change the transport 
    rate structure, and would lead to the pricing of more services in a 
    manner that does not reflect the way facilities are deployed. Given our 
    doubts about the efficiency benefits of Sprint's request and the fact 
    that the existing rules already provide reasonable opportunities for 
    tandem-switched transport users to compete with direct-trunked 
    transport users, we decline to amend our prior decisions.
    3. Meet Point Billing
        26. We conclude that specific methods for assessing, and avoiding 
    double billing for, the tandem charge and the interconnection charge 
    under meet point billing arrangements are better left to the individual 
    parties involved, given the wide variety and diversity of such 
    arrangements. If such issues cannot be settled among the parties, we 
    can address them in the future in the tariff process or pursuant to 
    specific complaints filed with the Commission.
    4. Prohibition on Ratcheting
        27. We continue to believe that ratcheting by interconnectors 
    benefits access customers and competition, and therefore, decline to 
    modify our rules with respect to ratcheting.
    
    Ordering Clauses
    
        28. Accordingly, it is ordered, pursuant to Sections 1, 4(i) and 
    (j), 201-205, 218, 220, 403, and 405 of the Communications Act of 1934, 
    as amended, 47 U.S.C. 151, 154(i) and (j), 201-205, 218, 220, 403, and 
    405, that the petitions for reconsideration and clarification 
    concerning the rate structure and pricing of local transport are 
    denied, except to the extent indicated herein.
        29. It is further ordered that the decisions and policies adopted 
    herein shall be effective thirty days after the date of publication in 
    the Federal Register.
        30. It is further ordered that WilTel's Motion for Acceptance of 
    Late-Filed Opposition to Petition for Reconsideration is granted.
        31. It is further ordered that authority is delegated to the Chief, 
    Common Carrier Bureau, as set forth herein.
    
    List of Subjects in 47 CFR Part 61 and 69
    
        Communications common carriers, Reporting and recordkeeping 
    requirements, Telephone.
    
    Federal Communications Commission.
    William F. Caton,
    Acting Secretary.
    [FR Doc. 95-1358 Filed 1-19-95; 8:45 am]
    BILLING CODE 6712-01-M
    
    

Document Information

Effective Date:
2/21/1995
Published:
01/20/1995
Department:
Federal Communications Commission
Entry Type:
Rule
Action:
Final rule.
Document Number:
95-1358
Dates:
February 21, 1995.
Pages:
4107-4110 (4 pages)
Docket Numbers:
CC Docket No. 91-213, FCC 94-325
PDF File:
95-1358.pdf
CFR: (2)
47 CFR 61
47 CFR 69