99-1393. Public Comments and Response of the United States; United States v. Enova Corporation  

  • [Federal Register Volume 64, Number 14 (Friday, January 22, 1999)]
    [Notices]
    [Pages 3551-3571]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 99-1393]
    
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE
    
    Antitrust Division
    
    
    Public Comments and Response of the United States; United States 
    v. Enova Corporation
    
        Notice is hereby given pursuant to the Antitrust Procedures and 
    Penalties Act, 15 U.S.C. 16(b)-(h), that public comments and the 
    response of the United States thereto have been filed with the United 
    States District Court for the District of Columbia in United States v. 
    Enova Corporation, Civil No. 98-CV-583 (RWR).
        On March 9, 1998, the United States filed a Complaint seeking to 
    enjoin a transaction in which Pacific Enterprises (``Pacific'') would 
    merge with Enova Corporation (``Enova''). Pacific is a California gas 
    utility company and Enova is a California electric utility company. 
    Enova sells electricity from plants that use coal, gas, nuclear power, 
    and hydropower. Pacific is virtually the sole provider of natural gas 
    transportation and storage services to plants in southern California 
    that use natural gas to produce electricity. The proposed merger would 
    have created a company with both the incentive and the ability to 
    lessen competition in the market for electricity in California. The
    
    [[Page 3552]]
    
    Complaint alleged that the proposed merger would substantially lessen 
    competition in the market for electricity in California, in violation 
    of Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 18.
        Public comment was invited within the statutory sixty-day comment 
    period. The two comments received, and the responses thereto, are 
    hereby published in the Federal Register and filed with the Court. 
    Copies of the Complaint, Stipulation and Order, Proposed Final 
    Judgment, Competitive Impact Statement, Public Comments, and 
    Plaintiff's Response to Public Comments are available for inspection in 
    Room 215 of the U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust Division, 325 
    Seventh Street, NW., Washington, DC 20530 (telephone: (202) 514-2481) 
    and at the office of the Clerk of the United States District Court for 
    the District of Columbia, 333 Constitution Avenue, NW., Washington, DC 
    20001. Copies of these materials may be obtained on request and payment 
    of a copying fee.
    Constance K. Robinson,
    Director of Operations, Antitrust Division.
    
        United States of America, U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust 
    Division, 325 Seventh Street, NW., Suite 500, Washington, DC 20530, 
    Plaintiff, v. Enova Corporation, 101 Ash Street, San Diego, CA 
    92101, Defendant.
    
    [Case Number: 98-CV-583 (RWR); Judge Richard W. Roberts]
    
    Plaintiff's Response to Public Comments
    
        Pursuant to the requirements of the Antitrust Procedures and 
    Penalties Act (``APPA''), 15 U.S.C. 16(b)-(h) (``Tunney Act''), the 
    United States hereby responds to the two public comments received 
    regarding the proposed Final Judgment in this case.
    
    I. The Complaint and Proposed Judgment
    
        The United States filed a civil antitrust Complaint on March 9, 
    1998, alleging that the proposed merger of Pacific Enterprises 
    (``Pacific''), a California natural gas utility, and Enova Corporation 
    (``Enova''), a California electric utility, would violate Section 7 of 
    the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 18. The Complaint alleges that as a result 
    of the merger, the combined company (``PE/Enova'') would have both the 
    incentive and the ability to lessen competition in the market for 
    electricity in California and that consumers would be likely to pay 
    higher prices for electricity.
        The Complaint further alleges that prior to the merger, Pacific's 
    wholly owned subsidiary, Southern California Gas Company, was virtually 
    the sole provider of natural gas transmission and storage to natural 
    gas-fueled electric generating plants in Southern California (``gas-
    fired plants''). As a consequence and without regard to the merger, it 
    had the ability to use that market power to control the supply and thus 
    the price of natural gas available to the gas-fired plants. Prior to 
    the merger, however, Pacific did not own any electric generation 
    plants, so it did not have the incentive to limit its gas 
    transportation, sales or storage or to raise the price of gas to 
    electric utilities in order to increase the price of electricity.
        The Complaint alleges that in early 1998, the California electric 
    market experienced significant changes as the result of a legislatively 
    mandated restructuring. In this new competitive electric market, gas-
    fired plants, which are the most costly electric generating plants to 
    operate, set the price that all sellers receive for electricity in 
    California in peak demand periods. Thus, if a firm could increase the 
    cost of the gas-fired plants by raising their fuel prices, it could 
    raise the price all sellers of electricity in California receive, and 
    increase the profits of owners of lower cost sources of electricity.
        Based on these facts, the Complaint alleges that the merger 
    violated Section 7 of the Clayton Act because the acquisition of 
    Enova's low-cost electric generating plants gave Pacific a means to 
    benefit from any increase in electric prices. The Complaint challenges 
    the acquisition of these specific plants:
    
        Once Pacific's pipeline is combined with Enova's low cost 
    electricity generation facilities, PE/Enova would have the ability 
    to raise the pool price of electricity either by (a) limiting the 
    availability of natural gas to competing gas-fired plants that 
    supply the most expensive units of electricity into the pool, or (b) 
    by limiting gas or gas transportation to gas-fired plants that are 
    more efficient and would otherwise have kept the pool price for 
    electricity down. PE/Enova would have the incentive to raise the 
    pool price after the merger because, through its ownerships of low 
    cost generation facilities, it could profit substantially from any 
    increase in the pool price of electricity and its incremental 
    profits would more than offset any losses of gas transportation 
    sales that would result from withholding gas from competing gas-
    fired plants. PE/Enova thus will have the incentive and ability to 
    lessen competition substantially and increase the price of 
    electricity in California during periods of high demand.
    
    (Compl. para.24 (emphasis added).)
    
        The proposed Final Judgment directly remedies this harm by 
    requiring Enova to divest its low-cost generating units to a purchaser 
    or purchasers acceptable to the United States in its sole discretion. 
    These divestiture assets are the Encina and South Bay electricity 
    generation facilities owned by Enova and located at Carlsbad and Chula 
    Vista, California, and include all rights, titles and interests related 
    to the facilities.\1\ By requiring this divestiture, the incentive that 
    was created by the merger for PE/Enova to raise electricity prices is 
    removed, providing a full remedy to the harm alleged in the 
    Complaint.\2\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \1\ The Final Judgment provides that the approvals by the United 
    States required by this decree for sale of these assets are in 
    addition to the necessary approvals by the California Public 
    Utilities Commission (``CPUC'') or any other governmental 
    authorities for the sale of such assets. Enova must submit required 
    applications to divest the assets no later than ninety days after 
    entry of the Final Judgment, and complete the divestiture as soon as 
    practicable after receipt of all necessary government approvals, in 
    accordance with the proposed Final Judgment.
        \2\ As explained in the Competitive Impact Statement (``CIS''), 
    the decree does not require the divestiture of the merged company's 
    nuclear assets, as the price of electricity from those assets will 
    be regulated during the cirtical first years of the decree, which 
    means that ownership of those assets will not give the merged firm 
    an incentive to raise prices. In 2001, if the nuclear power prices 
    become deregulated, the decree provides for safeguards to ensure 
    that any incentive to use these assets to raise price is minimized 
    or eliminated.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As part of the settlement, the United States also obtained the 
    Defendant's agreement to protection that are beyond those needed to 
    remedy directly the harm created by the acquisition. The proposed 
    decree includes limitations on PE/Enova's ability in the future to 
    acquire other low cost gas-fired generating assets that could give the 
    merged firm the same incentive and opportunity to raise electricity 
    prices that the acquisition of the divested Enova assets would have 
    presented. Recognizing that PE/Enova would have numerous acquisition 
    opportunities over the next few years as a consequence of the State of 
    California's orders that many generating assets be divested (see CIS at 
    13), the proposed decree requires PE/Enova to seek prior approval from 
    the United States before acquiring ownership or ownership-like rights 
    to other low-cost, California generating assets. The United States can, 
    at its sole discretion, disallow any acquisition of such assets, 
    without incurring the costs and risks of litigation.\3\ The types of 
    transactions
    
    [[Page 3553]]
    
    subject to this prior approval process include outright acquisition of 
    any existing California Generating Assets (Final Jmt. Sec. V.A.1); any 
    contract that allows PE/Enova to control such assets (Final Jmt. 
    Sec. V.A.2); any contract for the operation and sale of the output from 
    generating facilities owned by the Los Angeles Department of Water and 
    Power (``LADWP''), the second largest generator of electricity in 
    California and an entity owning more generation than Enova even prior 
    to the divestiture (Final Jmt. Secs. V.A.2, II.B); power management 
    contracts of California Generating Facilities with the LADWP (Final 
    Jmt. Secs. V.C.4,II.C); and future tolling arrangements of the type 
    that would most clearly mimic true ownership of the tolled facilities 
    (Final Jmt. Secs. V.A.2, V.C.3).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \3\ The Final Judgment does not prevent PE/Enova from building 
    new capacity in California, or from acquiring capacity built in 
    California after January 1, 1998. New capacity will only be built in 
    California if the output is inexpensive enough to be sold in many 
    hours. By increasing the amount of less expensive power available to 
    meet demand, new, low-cost capacity will reduce the number of hours 
    in which the most costly gas-fired capacity is needed. This in turn 
    will limit PE/Enova's ability to raise the pool price since it is 
    more costly and difficult for PE/Enova to restrict gas to more 
    numerous low-cost plants. For the same reasons, the Final Judgment 
    allows the merged company to acquire or gain control of plants that 
    are rebuilt, repowered, or activated out of dormancy after January 
    1, 1998. Output from such plants is the equivalent of output from 
    new-build capacity. CIS at 13-14.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In addition, the United States has the ability to monitor PE/
    Enova's entry into many power management contracts not subject to prior 
    approval (Final Jmt. Sec. V.C.5). The United States thus has the 
    opportunity to review these contracts, which are relatively new in the 
    deregulated California market, and determine whether they would give 
    PE/Enova the same incentive to raise electricity prices that ownership 
    of the divested Enova assets would have created. The United States can 
    then challenge any contracts that would do so.
        In sum, the decree provides two types of relief for the United 
    States. First, it achieves a direct remedy for the harm caused by 
    Pacific's acquisition of Enova's low-cost generating assets by ordering 
    divestiture of those specific assets. Second, it provides the 
    additional benefits of the prior approval and contract monitoring 
    provisions. These additional provisions are not meant to (nor can they) 
    prevent PE/Enova from entering any transaction or acquiring any asset 
    that could give it the incentive to exploit Pacific's pipeline market 
    power in the electricity market. Instead they provide the United States 
    with a check on potentially anticompetitive transactions, where the 
    acquisition of such assets would again create incentives similar to 
    these created by the assets acquired (and divested) in the transaction 
    before this Court.
        The United States and Enova have stipulated that the proposed Final 
    Judgment may be entered after compliance with the APPA.
    
    II. Response to Public Comments
    
        On June 8, 1998, the United States filed the CIS in this docket and 
    on June 18, 1998, the Complaint, Final Judgment and CIS were published 
    in the Federal Register. The Federal Register notice explained that 
    interested parties could provide comments to the Department for a 
    period of 60 days. Two parties filed comments with the Department: 
    Edison International (``Edison'') and the City of Vernon.
    A. Edison's Comments
        Edison's primary comment is that the decree does not strip PE/Enova 
    of the ability or incentive to increase electricity prices, but only 
    eliminates one opportunity to do so. Despite the decree, Edison argues, 
    PE/Enova still can use Pacific's market power over natural gas 
    transmission and still can enter into transactions that will give it 
    the incentive to exercise that power and raise electricity prices. 
    Edison enumerates and discusses particular transactions that would give 
    Pacific that incentive:
        1. Building or acquiring new or repowered generating facilities;
        2. Entering into tolling agreements;
        3. Entering into power generation management contracts; and
        4. Entering into financial contracts (derivatives) tied to prices 
    in the California Electric market.
        But Edison's criticism misses the mark, because each of the 
    potential transaction it lists is a transaction that Pacific could 
    engage in whether or not it merges with Enova. Thus, Edison's comments 
    do not focus on the harm caused by the merger, but rather on the harm 
    to competition that might result from Pacific's premerger ownership of 
    a monopoly gas pipeline. In contrast, the United States' Complaint is 
    focused only on the effects that flow from the merger.
        Edison's assertion (Edison Comments at 13) that Pacific had no 
    premerger incentive to manipulate electricity prices is simply wrong. 
    As soon as California deregulated retail electricity prices, Pacific 
    had the incentive, among other things, to build or acquire new and/or 
    repower other existing generating assets, purchase derivatives, and 
    make gas tolling agreements in order to exploit its pipeline's market 
    power over gas-fired generators. The ability and incentive of Pacific 
    to exercise its natural gas transmission market power for gain in the 
    electric market in any of these manners does not require acquisition of 
    any of Enova's generating assets or its ``electricity expertise.'' \4\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \4\ Edison's comments, which mention Enova's ``electricity 
    expertise'' in one sentence, do not define this term, identify where 
    in Enova it resides, or assert that pacific, the pipeline's parent 
    company, did not already have such expertise prior to the merger or 
    have the ability to obtain it by a number of means, including hiring 
    employees with electric experience.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Nevertheless, Edison argues that the Final Judgment is defective 
    because the United States did not also  ``understand[  ], anticipat[e], 
    and then prohibit[  ] all the various means by which the merged company 
    could seek to retain or create incentives to earn profits through 
    electricity price manipulations.'' (Edison Comments at 20.) To the 
    extent that Edison means to suggest that, once any merger transaction 
    is found to violate the Clayton Act, a merger decree should enjoin any 
    and all other means by which the defendant might violate the antitrust 
    laws in the future, the suggestion plainly is incorrect.\5\ Contrary to 
    Edison's suggestions, enforcement of the merger laws, Section 7 of the 
    Clayton Act, is aimed at remedying the competitively harmful changes in 
    market structure or other conditions that result from the merger. Here, 
    the merger takes Pacific's ability to profitably raise electric prices 
    and adds the incentive provided by Enova's low cost generating assets. 
    The proposed decree severs those assets from the merged company, 
    remedying the change in incentive and ability from the status quo ante. 
    The Final Judgment requires these assets to be sold to a party that 
    will not own the monopoly pipeline and removes the new incentive 
    provided by the acquired Enova assets for PE/Enova to use the 
    pipeline's already existent market power.\6\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \5\ See Zenith Radio Corp. v. Hazeltine Research, Inc., 395 U.S. 
    100, 133 (1969) (explaining that a court may not enjoin ``all future 
    violations of the antitrust laws, however unrelated to the violation 
    found by the court''); Hartford-Empire Co. v. United States, 323 
    U.S. 386, 409-10 & n.7 (1945) (citing NLRB v. Express Publ'g Co., 
    312 U.S. 426, 433, 435-36 (1941)).
        \6\ Edison also makes the same argument from the opposite 
    perspective--that competition is separately harmed because Enova has 
    gained an ability via the merger to raise price. (Edison Comments at 
    5.) Again, there is no additional pipeline monopoly power created by 
    the merger. The proposed remedy is effective against the harm caused 
    by the combination (the pipeline and Enova's low cost generating 
    assets), whether the Southern California Gas Company pipeline's 
    monopoly power is wielded by Enova or by Pacific.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Just as Edison's critical comments do not address the merger-
    related harms alleged in the Complaint, its comments do not address 
    whether the parties' proposed decree is adequate to remedy the harms 
    alleged in that Complaint. Instead, Edison proposes its own alternative 
    remedies that either do not
    
    [[Page 3554]]
    
    address the harm caused by the merger, or are not as effective as the 
    decree. Edison suggests that: (1) The merger be rescinded, (2) the 
    pipeline be divested, (3) the pipeline be controlled by an independent 
    system operator, or (4) the merged company be barred from trading in 
    financial instruments for Southern California electricity markets 
    (Edison Comments at 6).\7\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \7\ Edison compares its preferred options with the proposed 
    Final Judgment, calling the remedy in the proposed Final Judgment 
    ``the least attractive option'' from Edison's perspective. (Edison 
    Comments at 3 (``The last but least attractive option is to try to 
    lessen the merged firm's incentive to exercise its monopoly power in 
    order to profit from higher electric prices.'').) Edison finds this 
    course less attractive because ``it requires a complex latticework 
    of provisions * * * [that is] difficult to write and even harder to 
    administer.'' Id. The alternative it suggests, creating an 
    independent system operator for the pipeline system, has never been 
    done anywhere in the United States and, while possible, cannot be 
    assumed to be easy to write and easier to adminster.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Two of Edison's proposed remedies--the independent system operator 
    and the bar on trading--are aimed at controlling the preexisting market 
    power of the gas pipeline rather than remedying any harm created by the 
    merger. And, ironically, the Edison remedies aimed most closely at the 
    merger--rescission or divestiture of the pipeline--would not place any 
    limits on the pipeline's new owner's ability to raise the price of 
    electricity or limit the pipeline owner from acquiring assets or 
    contracts that would give it the incentive to do so, even though this 
    incentive and ability is purportedly the gravamen of Edison's concern. 
    The Proposed Final Judgment, in contrast, gives this emerging electric 
    market more protection than Edison's suggested remedies through prior 
    notice and market monitoring provisions.\8\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \8\ For example, Edison argues that the FTC's consent decree in 
    PacificCorp (PacifiCorp/The EnergyGroup, FTC File No. 9710091) 
    provides a superior remedy. It mischaracterizes the FTC decree as 
    equivalent to the divestiture of Pacific's gas pipeline assets that 
    constitute virtually all of the assets Pacific contributed to the 
    merger with Enova. Unlike this case, however, the divesture of coal 
    assets in PacifiCorp was not the equivalent of rescission of the 
    merger. PacifiCorp is a large integrated electric utility with coal 
    holdings in the western United States. It was acquiring the Energy 
    Group, an international electric company, the second largest 
    electric distribution company in the United Kingdom, which also held 
    coal reserves in both eastern and western United States. The FTC 
    decree did not requirement the Energy Group to divest its coal 
    business, much less its primary utility business, as Edison would 
    have the decree in the instant case require divestiture of Pacific's 
    utility pipeline business. Instead, the FTC decree required a 
    specific subset of the Energy Group's western coal mines to be 
    divested. The FTC's PacifiCorp decree stopped with divesture of 
    those specific assets and, unlike the Final Judgment proposed here, 
    did not go further to limit the merged company's reacquisition of 
    assets that would create the same vertical problem as the divested 
    assets.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In the end, Edison's preference for a different remedy is not 
    relevant to the Court's inquiry. Under the Tunney Act, the Court may 
    not choose or fashion a remedy that is ``better'' in someone's opinion 
    than the one negotiated and agreed to by the parties. To the contrary, 
    ``a proposed decree must be approved even if it falls short of the 
    remedy the court would impose on its own, as long as it falls within 
    the range of acceptability or is `within the reaches of the public 
    interest.' '' \9\ The proposed Final Judgment meets and exceeds this 
    legal standard.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \9\ United States v. American Tel. & Tel. Co., 552 F. Supp. 131, 
    153 n.95 (D.D.C. 1982), aff'd sub nom. Maryland v. United States, 
    460 U.S. 1001 (1983)(mem.).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    B. City of Vernon's Comments
        The City of Vernon recognizes in its comments that the Proposed 
    Final Judgment focuses entirely on the potential of PE/Enova to reduce 
    competition in the electricity market in Southern California. It 
    comments that the proposed judgment ``ignores'' the effect of the 
    merger on the natural gas transmission market in Southern California. 
    The case brought by the Department, however, involved the electricity 
    market in Southern California, and the relief addressed in the Proposed 
    Final Judgment remedies the competitive harm posed by the proposed 
    acquisition to that market. The Complaint does not allege violations in 
    the natural gas transmission market, and the City of Vernon's proposed 
    relief is thus not relevant to this proceeding.
    
    III. The Legal Standard Governing the Court's Public Interest 
    Determination
    
        Once the United States moves for entry of the proposed Final 
    Judgment, the Tunney Act directs the Court to determine whether entry 
    of the proposed Final Judgment ``is in the public interest.'' 15 U.S.C. 
    Sec. 16(e). In making that determination, ``the court's function is not 
    to determine whether the resulting array of rights and liabilities is 
    one that will best serve society, but only to confirm that the 
    resulting settlement is within the reaches of the public interest.'' 
    United States v. Western Elec. Co., 993 F.2d 1572, 1576 (D.C. Cir.) 
    (emphasis added, internal quotation and citation omitted), cert. 
    denied, 114 S. Ct. 487 (1993).
        The Court is not ``to make de novo determination of facts and 
    issues.'' Western Elec., 993 F.2d at 1577. Rather, ``[t]he balancing of 
    competing social and political interests affected by a proposed 
    antitrust decree must be left, in the first instance, to the discretion 
    of the Attorney General.'' Id. (internal quotation and citation 
    omitted). In particular, the Court must defer to the Department's 
    assessment of likely competitive consequences, which it may reject 
    ``only if it has exceptional confidence that adverse antitrust 
    consequences will result--perhaps akin to the confidence that would 
    justify a court in overturning the predictive judgments of an 
    administrative agency.'' Id. \10\ The Court may reject a decree simply 
    ``because a third party claims it could be better treated,'' United 
    States v. Microsoft, 56 F.3d 1448, 1459 (D.C. Cir. 1995), or based on 
    the belief that ``other remedies were preferable,'' id. at 1460.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \10\ The Tunney Act does not give a court authority to impose 
    different terms on the parties. See e.g., American Tel. & Tel., 552 
    F. Supp. at 153 n. 95; accord H.R. Rep. No. 93-1463, at 8 (1974). A 
    court, of course, can condition entry of a decree on the parties' 
    agreement to a different bargain, see e.g., American Tel. & Tel., 
    552 F. Supp. at 225, but if the parties do not agree to such terms, 
    the court's only choices are to enter the decree the parties 
    proposed or to leave the parties to litigate.
        United States v. Thomson Corp., 949 F. Supp. 907 (D.D.C. 1996), 
    cited by Edison (Edison Comments at 9-10), does not support Edison's 
    argument to reject the Proposed Final Judgment. That case involved 
    the Tunney Act review of a proposed final judgment that required one 
    of the merging companies to license a copyright that it claimed but 
    had not licensed prior to the merger. While there was some 
    controversy as to whether the decree's license provisions could have 
    been extracted as the result of a trial, see Thomson, 949 F. Supp. 
    at 927, the Court nevertheless considered comments on the specific 
    terms of the license proposal because of the potential 
    anticompetitive harm that could result from ``the merger of these 
    two publishing giants in conjunction with'' the asserted copyright 
    claim. Id. at 928. The Thomson Court addressed comments on the 
    license provision on that ground, and not because the decree would 
    remedy preexisting wrongs; nor did the court add or alter any 
    provisions to the Final Judgment that had not been agreed to by the 
    parties. Here, in contrast, Edison is not commenting on a specific 
    remedy agreed to by the parties as a means of addressing the harms 
    related to a merger. Instead, Edison is asking this Court to insert 
    an entirely new mechanism for relief into the decree, in order to 
    address Pacific's preexisting pipeline market power as it could be 
    exercised in relation to the acquisition of any electricity assets, 
    regardless of Pacific's merger with Enova. Edison's proposed 
    approach is completely at odds with Judge Friedman's actions in the 
    Thomson case. Judge Friedman, as Edison concedes, was careful not to 
    substitute his judgment for the government's and, further, did not 
    adopt proposed remedies that were unrelated to the merger. (See 
    Edison Comments at 10).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Further, the Tunney Act does not contemplate judicial reevaluation 
    of the wisdom of the government's determination of which violations to 
    allege in the Complaint. The government's decision not to bring a 
    particular case on the facts and law before it, like any other decision 
    not to prosecute, ``involves a complicated balancing of a number of 
    factors which are peculiarly within [the government's expertise.'' 
    Heckler v. Chaney, 470 U.S. 821, 831 (1985). Thus, the Court may
    
    [[Page 3555]]
    
    not look beyond the Complaint ``to evaluate claims that the government 
    did not make and to inquire as to why they were not made.'' Microsoft, 
    56 F.3d at 1459; see also United States v. Associated Milk Producers, 
    Inc.. 534 F.2d 113, 117-18 (8th Cir. 1976).
        The government has wide discretion within the reaches of the public 
    interest to resolve potential litigation. See e.g., Western Elec. Co., 
    993 F.2d 1572; American Tel & Tel., 552 F. Supp. at 151. The Supreme 
    Court has recognized that a government antitrust consent decree is a 
    contract between the parties to settle their disputes and differences, 
    United States v. ITT Continental Baking Co.. 420 U.S. 223, 235-38 
    (1975); United States v. Armour & Co., 402 U.S. 673, 681-82 (1971), and 
    ``normally embodies a compromise; in exchange for the saving of cost 
    and elimination of risk, the parties each give up something they might 
    have won had they proceeded with the litigation.'' Armour, 402 U.S. at 
    681. As Judge Greene has observed:
    
        If courts acting under the Tunney Act disapproved proposed 
    consent decrees merely because they did not contain the exact relief 
    which the court would have imposed after a finding of liability, 
    defendants would have no incentive to consent to judgment and this 
    element of compromise would be destroyed. The consent decree would 
    thus as a practical matter be eliminated as an antitrust enforcement 
    tool, despite Congress' directive that it be preserved.
    
    American Tel. & Tel., 552 F. Supp. at 151. This Judgment has the virtue 
    of bringing the public certain benefits and protection without the 
    uncertainty and expense of protracted litigation. See Armour, 402 U.S. 
    at 681; Microsoft, 56 F. 3d at 1459.
        Finally, the entry of a governmental antitrust decree forecloses no 
    private party from seeking and obtaining appropriate antitrust 
    remedies. Defendants will remain liable for any illegal acts, and any 
    private party may challenge such conduct if and when appropriate.
    
    IV. Conclusion
    
        After careful consideration of the public comments, the United 
    States concludes that entry of the proposed Final Judgment will provide 
    an effective and appropriate remedy for the antitrust violation alleged 
    in the Complaint and is in the public interest. The United States will 
    therefore ask the Court to enter the proposed Final Judgment after the 
    public comments and this Response have been published in the Federal 
    Register, as 15 U.S.C. 16(d) requires.
    
        Dated: January 11, 1999.
    
            Respectfully submitted,
    Jade Alice Eaton
    D.C. Bar #939629, Trial Attorney, U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust 
    Division, 325 Seventh Street, N.W., Washington, DC 20530. Phone: (202) 
    307-6316.
    
    Certificate of Service
    
        I hereby certify that I have caused a copy of the foregoing 
    Plaintiff's Response to Public Comments, as well as attached copies of 
    the public comments received from the City of Vernon, California, and 
    from Southern California Edison Company, to be served on counsel for 
    defendant and for public commentators in this matter in the manner set 
    forth below:
    
        By first class mail, postage prepaid:
    Steven C. Sunshine,
    Shearman & Sterling, 801 Pennsylvania Avenue, N.W., Washington, DC 
    2004.
    John W. Jimison,
    Brady & Berliner, 1225 Nineteenth Street, N.W., Suite 800, Washington, 
    DC.
    J.A. Bouknight, Jr.,
    David R. Roll,
    James B. Moorhead,
    Steptoe & Johnson LLP, 1330 Connecticut Ave., N.W., Washington, DC 
    20036.
    
        Dated: January 11, 1999.
    Jade Alice Eaton,
    D.C. Bar # 939629. Antitrust Division, U.S. Department of Justice, 325 
    Seventh Street, N.W., Suite 500, Washington, DC 20530, (202) 307-6456, 
    (202) 616-2441 (Fax).
    
    Brady & Berliner
    
    1225 Nineteenth Street. N.W., Suite 800, Washington, DC 20036
    
    August 17, 1998.
    Mr. Roger W. Fones,
    Chief Transportation Energy & Agriculture Section Antitrust 
    Division, U.S. Department of Justice, 325 Seventh Street, N.W., 
    Suite 500, Washington, DC 20530.
    
    Re: Comments of the City of Vernon, California, on the Proposed 
    Final Judgement, Stipulation in the Competitive Impact Statement in 
    U.S. v. Enova Corporation, Civil No. 98-CV-583
    
        Dear Mr. Fones: Pursuant to the legal notice issued by the 
    Antitrust Division on June 18, 1998 the City of Vernon, California, 
    (``Vernon'') hereby provides these comments in opposition to the 
    approval of the Proposed Final Judgement Stipulation in the 
    Competitive Impact Statement in U.S. v. Enova Corporation, Civil No. 
    98-CV-583 (``Proposed Judgement'').
        Vernon submits that the Proposed Judgement would permit a merger 
    to be consummated that will alter and damage the potential for 
    competition in the California natural gas market. The Proposed 
    Judgement focuses entirely on the potential of the merged entity to 
    reduce competition in the electricity market in southern California, 
    and orders as a remedy the divestiture of certain electricity 
    generating stations owned by the San Diego Gas & Electric Company 
    (``SDG&E''). The Proposed Judgement ignores the fact that the merger 
    will combine the two largest natural gad transmission and 
    distribution companies in southern California. The merger will thus 
    eliminate the potential for competition between them, or for support 
    by either of them for new natural gas transmission pipeline which 
    would compete with the other.
        Vernon operates a municipal electricity utility including its 
    own gas-fired power plant and will complete this year a municipal 
    natural gas utility. Vernon and other natural gas distributing 
    entities in southern California have lacked any meaningful 
    alternative to the monopoly natural gas transmission service from 
    the Southern California Gas Company (``SoCalGas''), the parent of 
    which, Pacific Enterprises, is merging with Enova. Although two 
    interstate pipelines were built into California in the first years 
    of this decade, their systems terminate in the Bakersfield, 
    California, region and do not compete with SoCalGas in its service 
    territory in the large Los Angeles metropolitan region, including 
    Vernon.
        In order for a competing pipeline to be constructed into Los 
    Angeles, the sponsor must overcome significant hurdles and expenses 
    of locating and obtaining an environmentally suitable right-of-way, 
    and must have agreements with shippers for an adequate volume of 
    natural gas to support the expensive project. Having large 
    prospective shippers under contract to use a new pipeline is a 
    prerequisite to constructing one. Despite these obstacles, there 
    have been a number of potential pipelines discussed and considered 
    that would have competed with SoCalGas' gas transmission service 
    into the Los Angeles area. However, to date, SoCalGas' actions to 
    frustrate and oppose any such competition have been successful. 
    These efforts have included special discounted contracts offered to 
    the most likely customers of a new pipeline and adopting a penalty 
    tariff that effectively forbids any customer of a new pipeline from 
    taking any service at all from SoCalGas--even at different 
    locations--without paying the full SoCalGas system tariff for 
    transmission in addition to the cost of the competing pipeline.
        The single largest potential ``anchor'' customer of a new 
    pipeline to compete with SoCalGas was SDG&E. The merger that would 
    be approved by the Proposed Judgement would eliminate SDG&E's 
    potential role as an anchor shipper on a new pipeline, and cement a 
    permanent alliance between SDG&E and SoCalGas to sustain their joint 
    monopoly on gas transmission services in southern California.
        While the divestiture of SDG&E's power plant may have reduced 
    the potential that the merged entity would use that monopoly to 
    favor its own gas-fired generators in a competitive electricity 
    market, that limited divestiture does nothing to reduce the damage 
    to competition created by this merger in the natural gas market.
        Across the United States, competition among natural gas 
    transportation companies has benefitted consumers with improved
    
    [[Page 3556]]
    
    service at lower tariffs. With the exception of those customers in 
    the Bakersfield area, and those selectively receiving discounts to 
    ensure they will not support competing pipelines, the customers in 
    southern California have not had any benefits of competition among 
    gas transmission providers. The approval of the Proposed Judgement 
    and consummation of the merger it approves will reduce their chances 
    of such benefits.
        Vernon submits that approval of the merger should have been 
    conditioned not only on actions to reduce the potential risks to 
    competition in the electricity market, but also to reduce the injury 
    to competition in the natural gas market. Such action could have 
    included a requirement that SoCalGas sell to independent entities a 
    volume of transportation capacity equivalent to that which it had 
    traditionally used to serve SDG&E, or a requirement that SoCalGas 
    offer transportation rights on its system which can be released and 
    brokered to others, creating the potential for a competitive third-
    party market among gas shippers with defined rights. No such action 
    was taken in the Proposed Judgement.
    
        For this reason, Vernon opposes the approval of the Proposed 
    Judgement.
    
            Respectfully submitted,
    John W. Jimison, Esq.,
    Attorney for The City of Vernon.
    
    Comments of Amicus Curiae Southern California Edison Company on the 
    Proposed Final Judgment
    
    Kevin J. Lipson,
    Mary Anne Mason,
    Hogan & Hartson LLP, Columbia Square, 555-Thirteenth Street, NW, 
    Washington, DC 20004-1109, (202) 637-5600.
    Stephen E. Pickett,
    Douglas Kent Porter, Southern California Edison Company, P.O. Box 800, 
    2244 Walnut Grove Avenue, Rosemead, California 91770, (626) 302-1903.
    J.A. Bouknight, Jr.,
    David R. Roll,
    Steptoe & Johnson LLP, 1330 Connecticut Avenue, NW, Washington, DC 
    20036, (202) 429-3000.
    
        Dated: August 17, 1998.
    
    Comments of Amicus Curiae Southern California Edison Company on the 
    Proposed Final Judgment
    
        Southern California Edison Company (``SCE'') respectfully submits 
    the following comments on the proposed Final Judgment in the above 
    referenced matter.\1\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \1\ As a part of these Comments, SCE is attaching the Affidavit 
    of Paul R. Carpenter, an economist who has extensive experience in 
    analyzing energy markets.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Introduction and Summary
    
        This is a case about an electric utility. Like any company in our 
    capitalistic system, this utility would like to raise its prices in 
    order to increase profits for its shareholders. Finding that 
    competition constrains its ability to increase electricity prices, the 
    utility decides to buy the only company in the world that will give it 
    that ability to raise electricity prices in the area where the utility 
    competes. Not surprisingly, the Department of Justice (``DOJ'') finds 
    the merge to be an obvious violation of the antitrust laws. DOJ then 
    files a complaint and proposes a Final Judgment that permits the merger 
    without eliminating the competitive problem identified in the 
    complaint.
        The violation alleged in DOJ's complaint is straight-forward. Enova 
    Corporation (``Enova''), the owner of one of California's three major 
    electric utilities, has acquired Pacific Enterprises (``Pacific''), 
    which owns and operates the intrastate gas pipeline system that 
    provides virtually all of the natural gas consumed in southern 
    California. As DOJ's complaint alleges, control of this pipeline system 
    will provide Enova with monopoly control of natural gas in the southern 
    California market. This in turn will permit Enova to control the price 
    of electricity in southern California much of the time, because natural 
    gas is used to generate electricity ``on the margin'' during most hours 
    of the year in southern California.
        In competitive markets, the cost characteristics of a producer on 
    the margin are likely to set the market-clearing price. In southern 
    California, as of April 1, 1998, this is necessarily true, because 
    California has created a power exchange (``PX'')--the first such market 
    in the United States--in which generators of electric power bids for 
    each hour and all successful bidders are paid a price determined by the 
    highest bid that is accepted. Thus, where gas-fueled generation is on 
    the margin, as it is most of the time, an increase in the price of 
    natural gas leads directly to an increase in the price for every 
    kilowatt hour of electricity consumed in southern California.
        Prior to the merger, Enova had every incentive to raise electricity 
    prices but it lacked the ability to do so because it has no control 
    over natural gas prices. On the other hand, before the merger, Pacific 
    had the ability to control natural gas prices but had not succeeded in 
    entering the electricity marketing business.\2\ Thus, Enova has the 
    incentive but not the ability to manipulate electricity prices; Pacific 
    had the ability but lacked the incentive.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \2\ Before the merger, Pacific had established a subsidiary for 
    gas and electricity marketing and tried to enter the electricity 
    marketing business. However, as Enova explained to the Federal 
    Energy Regulatory Commission (``FERC''), this subsidiary had not 
    succeeded in securing any contracts to sell electricity at the time 
    of the proposed merger. See Ensource, 78 FERC para. 61,064, at 
    61.231 (1997) (``Since Ensource never has engaged in marketing 
    activity* * *'').
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        DOJ correctly concluded that a merger of these two firms, which 
    combines the ability and incentive to raise electricity prices in the 
    southern California market, violates the antitrust laws. In the face of 
    this violation, what is the remedy? The most obvious remedy, of course, 
    is to stop the merger from happening. Short of that, the next most 
    effective and logical remedy is to remove the source of the merged 
    firm's monopoly power, either by requiring divestiture of the natural 
    gas pipeline system or by creating an independent system operator 
    (``ISO'') to operate that system. The last but least attractive option 
    is to try to lessen the merged firm's incentive to exercise its 
    monopoly power in order to profit from higher electricity prices. This 
    is the least attractive option because curbing incentives to profit 
    from higher electricity prices requires a complex latticework of 
    provisions designed to prevent the merged firm from retaining and 
    acquiring contractual rights and other types of economic interests in 
    electric power. Such a remedy is difficult to write and even harder to 
    administer.
        Rather than stopping the merger in its tracks or adopting a 
    structural remedy to remove the source of the monopoly power. DOJ asks 
    this Court to approve a remedy that will have little or no impact on 
    the merged company's incentive to raise electricity prices. The 
    proposed Final Judgment should be rejected because the merged entity 
    still has the unfettered ability to enter into a variety of electric 
    power transactions, which will enable it to profit from higher 
    electricity prices. Specifically:
    
         While the proposed Final Judgment requires Enova to 
    divest two of its gas-fueled electric generating plants, totaling 
    some 1650 megawatts, it allows the merged company to acquire an 
    unlimited amount of generating facilities built after January 1, 
    1998, or any repowered/rebuilt facilities, whatever the fuel-type. 
    Thus, the 1650 MW divestiture requirement can be undone with a 
    single purchase of a large new facility.
         There is no prohibition on the merged company 
    contracting, the day after divestiture, to purchase the electrical 
    output of those same divested generating facilities (or other 
    facilities).
         The proposed Final Judgment explicitly permits the 
    merged firm to enter into ``tolling'' arrangements by which it can 
    in essence rent electric generating plants to convert gas into 
    electricity.
         There is no prohibition on the merged company entering 
    into financial contracts (derivatives such as options and futures) 
    that
    
    [[Page 3557]]
    
    would enable it to prohibit from changes in southern California 
    electricity prices.
    
        Under the proposed decree, the merged firm can acquire both new and 
    repowered/rebuilt electric generation assets. It can acquire by 
    contract the economic attributes of ownership of electric generation. 
    It can rent generating units to produce electric power. And it can 
    trade in electricity financial contracts for the southern California 
    market. If it can do all this, then it obviously can benefit from 
    increases in the price of electricity just as it could if it still 
    owned the divested electric generating facilities. Consequently, the 
    proposed Final Judgment does not eliminate the merged firm's incentive 
    to exercise market power in order to increase electricity prices. And 
    it does not even purport to address market power. Therefore, the 
    proposed Final Judgment does not even come close to solving the 
    fundamental competitive problem articulated in DOJ's complaint.
        One rationale that DOJ has put forward for having accepted the 
    ineffective remedial measures in the proposed Final Judgment is that 
    more effective remedies would involve relief that extends beyond the 
    effect of the merger, as Pacific could theoretically have engaged in 
    theses activities without a merger. But this is an unlawful merger. 
    Without the acquisition, Enova's incentive to raise electricity prices 
    is not backed by any ability to do so. The merger dramatically and 
    unlawfully changes the landscape by immediately coupling Enova's 
    incentive and electricity-expertise with Pacific's natural gas muscle. 
    The argument that a substantial link between the gas pipeline system 
    and electricity markets could easily have been established without the 
    merger ignores the fact that this merger creates that substantial link.
        If, for whatever reason, DOJ prefers not to stop the merger and not 
    to address the upstream source of the market power, but instead chooses 
    to focus on the incentives to exercise its market power in the 
    downstream electricity market, then the public interest requires that 
    it craft remedies designed to curb the incentives that are sufficiently 
    effective to cure the antitrust violation. Because DOJ failed in that 
    task, this Court is faced with a proposed Final Judgment that falls far 
    short of being within the reaches of the public interest.\3\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \3\ As a diversionary tactic, Enova can be expected to urge the 
    Court to disregard SCE's comments, no matter how persuasive they may 
    otherwise be, because SCE is merely a self-interested competitor of 
    the merged firm. While it is true that SCE is a competitor for 
    electricity sales, SCE's principal interest in this matter is at the 
    largest purchaser of electricity in the southern California market, 
    one that will be directly and significantly harmed by electricity 
    price increases resulting from this merger. Under the California 
    restructuring legislation, the legislature ``froze'' electricity 
    rates at levels in effect as of June 1996. See Cal. Pub. Util. Code 
    Sec. 368(a). During the rate freeze period which will end December 
    31, 2001, SCE must purchase all the energy that it sells to its 
    utility service customers from the PX. SCE's rates include separate 
    components for transmission, distribution, etc. The sum of these 
    separate components is less than the frozen rate levels, with that 
    residual difference being used by SCE to recover costs associated 
    with generation-related assets that would not otherwise be recouped 
    if cost recovery were determined solely by selling energy purchased 
    from these assets at the prevailing market price. As a consequence, 
    SCE's shareholders are at risk and will be directly harmed if PX 
    electricity prices rise to a level that would cause SCE's costs to 
    exceed the frozen rate levels.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In summary, SCE urges that the proposed Final Judgment be rejected. 
    If DOJ nevertheless concludes that a salvage effort is appropriate, DOJ 
    and Enova can be sent back to the bargaining table to produce a Final 
    Judgment that remedies the competitive problem described in the 
    complaint. Such remedies would include one of the following:
        (1) Rescission of the merger;
        (2) Divestiture of the gas pipeline system or, alternatively, 
    establishment of an independent system operator to operate it 
    independently of the merged company; or
        (3) Adoption of measures that will eliminate the merged company's 
    incentive to participate directly, and indirectly through financial 
    instruments, in the southern California electricity market in any 
    manner that would allow it to profit from increased electricity prices.
    
    Argument
    
    I. The Tunney Act Standard of Review Requires This Court To Determine 
    Whether the Proposed Final Judgment Is in the Public Interest
    
        On March 9, 1998, the Antitrust Division of DOJ filed a complaint 
    against Enova alleging that the merger of Enova and Pacific will 
    violate Section 7 of the Clayton Act. Along with the complaint, DOJ 
    filed a Stipulation and Order pursuant to which the parties consented 
    to entry of a proposed Final Judgment and Enova agreed to abide by its 
    terms pending its entry by the court.
        The filing of the proposed Final Judgment triggered a proceeding 
    under the Antitrust Procedures and Penalties Act, commonly known as the 
    Tunney Act.\4\ The purpose of the Tunney Act is to provide notice to 
    the public, an opportunity to comment, and judicial scrutiny of consent 
    decrees in antitrust cases to determine whether they are in the 
    ``public interest.'' The Tunney Act requires DOJ to publish the 
    proposed Final Judgment and to file and publish a competitive impact 
    statement (``CIS'') explaining the case, the anti-competitive conduct 
    involved, the proposed remedy, and any alternative remedies considered 
    by it. DOJ must also furnish to the Court any comments that it receives 
    from the public during a 60-day period commencing with the noticing of 
    the CIS, its response to these comments, and any documents it 
    ``considered determinative in formulating'' the decree.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \4\ 15 U.S.C. Sec. 16(b)-(h).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Before a court may approve a proposed Final Judgment, the Tunney 
    Act requires the court to ``determine that the entry of such judgment 
    is in the public interest''.\5\ The Act provides that in making its 
    public interest determination, the court may consider:
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \5\ 15 U.S.C. Sec. 16(e).
    
        (1) the competitive impact of such judgment, including 
    termination of alleged violations, provisions for enforcement and 
    modification, duration or relief sought, anticipated effects of 
    alternative remedies actually considered, and any other 
    considerations bearing upon the adequacy of such judgment;
        (2) the impact of entry of such judgment upon the pubic 
    generally and individuals alleging specific injury from the 
    violations set forth in the complaint including consideration of the 
    public benefit, if any, to be derived from a determination of the 
    issues at trial.\6\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \6\ Id.
    
        The scope of Tunney Act review was articulated in a 1995 decision 
    of the Court of Appeals for the D.C. Circuit in Microsoft.\7\ In that 
    case, District Judge Sporkin had declined to enter a proposed consent 
    decree settling an action by DOJ alleging monopolization and various 
    exclusionary practices. Although the Court of Appeals reversed and 
    ordered entry of the proposed decree without revision, it set forth 
    certain guidelines, among others, that are relevant to the Court's 
    public interest determination in this case:
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \7\ United States v. Microsoft, 56 F.3d 1448 (D.C. Cir. 1995).
    
         ``[T]he court's function is not to determine whether 
    the resulting array of rights and liabilities is the one that will 
    best serve society, but only to confirm that the resulting 
    settlement is within the reaches of the public interest.'' \8\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \8\ Id. at 1460 (emphasis in original, internal citations and 
    quotation marks omitted).
    
         ``[I]f third parties contend that they would be 
    positively injured by the decree, a district judge might well 
    hesitate before assuming that the decree is appropriate.'' \9\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \9\ Id. at 1462.
    
    
    [[Page 3558]]
    
    
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
         ``A district judge * * * would and should pay special 
    attention to the decree's clarity [and may] insist on that degree of 
    precision concerning the resolution of known issues as to make this 
    task, in resolving subsequent disputes, reasonably manageable * * * 
    . If the decree is ambiguous, or the district judge can foresee 
    difficulties in implementation, we would expect the court to insist 
    that these matters be attended to.'' \10\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \10\ Id. at 1461-62.
    
        Under Microsoft, it is now clear that a court may not reject a 
    remedy simply because it is not the ``best'' remedy that could have 
    been selected. On the other hand, it is equally clear under Microsoft 
    that a court has discretion to reject a negotiated remedy which is 
    ineffective because it does not seek to address and resolve the core 
    competitive problem identified in DOJ's complaint.
        Following Microsoft, courts have continued to scrutinize proposed 
    consent decrees to determine whether they effectively address and 
    resolve the fundamental competitive problems articulated by DOJ. For 
    instance, in Thomson, District Judge Friedman examined concerns about 
    several aspects of a proposed consent decree as expressed in briefs 
    submitted amicus curiae by two competitors of the merging parties, in 
    public comments submitted to DOJ, and at an extended public 
    hearing.\11\ Judge Friedman carefully examined arguments concerning 
    each of the four separate areas of concern, noting proposed 
    supplemental commitments \12\ and modifications to the initially filed 
    proposed consent decree to resolve some of these concerns.\13\ He was 
    careful not to substitute his own judgment for DOJ's as to what could 
    be the best remedy \14\ and he declined to suggest relief for conduct 
    unrelated to the merger.\15\ Nonetheless, Judge Friedman refused to 
    enter even the revised decree, because neither the original nor the 
    proposed revision resolved substantial concerns that the decree would 
    maintain, by court order, a dubious copyright claim that DOJ's 
    complaint and commentators had identified as a substantial barrier for 
    new competitors seeking to enter the relevant market.\16\ Only after 
    the parties submitted a further amendment addressing these concerns did 
    Judge Friedman order entry of the consent decree.\17\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \11\ United States v. The Thomson Corp., 949 F. Supp. 907, 909, 
    912 (D.D.C. 1996), aff'd per curiam 1998 U.S. App. LEXIS 12921 (May 
    29, 1998).
        \12\ See, e.g., id. at 916 (noting that ``Thomson confirmed in 
    writing that it will continue'' a practice that commentators and 
    amicus curiae thought might cease after the merger).
        \13\ See, e.g., id. at 916 (noting adoption of new consent 
    decree provision barring Thomson from taking certain actions to 
    undermine viability of products to be divested under the decree); 
    id. at 924 (noting proposal to add language to proposed decree to 
    ensure that licenses to one of the products to be divested may be 
    sublicensed); id. at 925 (noting further change to proposed consent 
    decree after Tunney Act hearing to ensure that divestiture will not 
    affect pre-existing rights under a particular contract). See also 
    id. at 926 nn. 19-20 (noting changes to initial proposed decree in 
    response to concerns expressed in comments and at the hearing).
        \14\ See id. at 919.
        \15\ See, e.g., id. at 920 (refusing to consider requests to 
    reopen bidding on past contracts, because not related to competition 
    among the parties to the merger).
        \16\ See id. at 927-930 (discussing complaint's allegations and 
    decree's proposed remedy regarding copyright claim).
        \17\ See United States v. The Thomson Corp., 1997-1 Trade Cas. 
    (CCH) para. 71,735, 1997 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 1893 (Feb. 27, 1997).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    II. The Proposed Final Judgment is Not in the Public Interest
    
        Under standards laid down in Microsoft and implemented in Thomson, 
    the proposed Final Judgment is not within the ``reaches of the public 
    interest'' because it does not remedy the core competitive problem 
    identified in DOJ's complaint--namely, that the merged entity will have 
    the ability and incentive to increase electricity prices. Unless and 
    until DOJ and Enova agree to a remedy which addresses and resolves this 
    problem, the Court must reject the proposed decree.
    A. The Complaint Correctly Identifies the Root of the Competitive 
    Problem: Pacific's Control of Natural Gas Transportation and Storage in 
    California
        As a result of its monopoly over intrastate transmission and 
    storage of natural gas, Pacific (via its subsidiary, SoCal Gas), has 
    the power and ability to increase the price of natural gas to gas-fired 
    electric generators which in turn will increase the price of 
    electricity in California. In its complaint, DOJ found that, 
    notwithstanding regulatory oversight, Pacific has the ability to use 
    its control over those assets to manipulate the price of gas to 
    consumers, including gas-fueled electric generators:
    
         Pacific has ``a monopoly of transportation of natural 
    gas within southern California [and] a monopoly of all natural gas 
    storage services throughout California.'' \1\\8\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \1\\8\ Complaint para.15.96 percent of gas-fueled generators in 
    southern California buy gas transportation services from Pacific. 
    Proposed Final Judgment and Competitive Impact Statement; United 
    States v. Enova Corp. (``CIS''), 63 FR 33393, at 33403 (June 18, 
    1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
         ``[A]lthough regulated by the California Public 
    Utilities Commission (`CPUC'), Pacific has the ability to restrict 
    the availability of gas transportation and storage to consumers, by 
    limiting their supply or cutting them off entirely, which has the 
    effect of raising the price they pay for natural gas.'' \19\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \19\ Complaint para.16; see also Complaint para.20.
    
        The attached Affidavit of Dr. Paul Carpenter describes the numerous 
    means by which Pacific (via SoCalGas) can exercise its monopoly power, 
    as charged by DOJ, to restrict the availability of gas transportation 
    and gas storage capacity in southern California. These means include 
    SoCalGas' ability to (a) control and deny access to its intrastate 
    transmission and storage assets, (b) manipulate the price of intrastate 
    services, such as short-term balancing or emergency supply services, 
    (c) withhold the quantity of interstate capacity it makes available in 
    secondary markets in order to raise price, (d) determine the volume of 
    flowing supplies on a day-to-day basis through its core-related storage 
    injection and withdrawal decisions, and (e) manipulate prices and 
    access through its possession of valuable operational 
    information.\2\\0\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \2\\0\ Aff. at para.8.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The ability of Pacific to restrict the availability of gas 
    transportation and storage to consumers, including gas-fueled 
    generators, is the key to its power to increase electricity prices in 
    southern California for two related reasons. First, as explained by 
    DOJ, most electricity generated in California is bought and sold 
    through the California PX, which is a computerized bidding system that 
    matches electricity supply and demand every hour.\21\ The price of 
    electricity for all units sold is determined by the most expensive unit 
    sold in that hour, regardless of the cost or bidding price of less 
    expensive units.\22\ Stated differently, all sellers receive the PX's 
    marginal price, regardless of their bid, and all buyers pay the 
    marginal price.\23\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \21\ CIS at 33403. The CIS states that the matches occur every 
    half-hour; in fact, the matches are hourly.
        \22\ CIS at 33403.
        \23\ Aff. at para.9. This is true with one exception involving 
    nuclear-powered generators, which are covered by a different pricing 
    scheme.
    
        Second, ``gas-fired plants are in general the most costly to 
    operate.'' \24\ In other words, gas-fueled plants are usually on the 
    margin. Because of the California PX, an increase in the price of 
    natural gas to these gas-fired plants will translate in an increase in 
    the price of all electricity sold in California through the PX. DOJ 
    made this point in its CIS as follows:
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \24\ CIS at 33403.
    
        [d]uring these periods [of high electricity demand], the gas-
    fired plants, as the most costly to operate and thus the highest 
    bidders
    
    [[Page 3559]]
    
    into the [PX], are able to set the price for all electricity sold 
    through the [PX].\25\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \25\ Id. DOJ is certainly correct in this critical finding. 
    Attachment B to Dr. Carpenter's affidavit depicts the electricity 
    supply curve for all generating resources in the western United 
    States. As shown, actual demand for electricity (which varies by 
    time of day and by season) falls within a certain band (70,500 
    megawatts to 93,500 megawatts) about two-thirds of the time. Within 
    that band, 90 percent of the megawatts that can be generated come 
    from gas-fired generators. And, 69 percent of those megawatts come 
    from California gas-fired generators. Aff. at Attach. B.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In short, what this all means is that as a consequence of its 
    monopoly over gas transportation and storage, Pacific has the 
    unquestioned ability to directly and materially affect the price of 
    electricity in southern California. As summarized by DOJ:
    
        By virtue of its monopoly over natural gas transportation and 
    storage, Pacific currently has the ability to increase the price of 
    electricity, when during high demand periods, electricity from 
    California gas-fired generators is needed to supplement less costly 
    electricity. Pacific can restrict gas-fired generators' access to 
    gas, which has the effect of raising the cost of gas-filed 
    generators in general. Alternatively, Pacific can cut off or impede 
    the more efficient gas generators' access to gas, leaving the 
    higher-cost generators to meet consumer demand for electricity. In 
    either case, Pacific is able to increase the cost of electricity 
    from gas-fired plants, thereby increasing the prices they bid into 
    the [PX] and ultimately the price of electricity sold through the 
    [PX].\26\
    
        \26\ CIS at 33404 (emphasis added).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        To be sure, Pacific's ability to increase electricity prices 
    existed absent the merger. Without the merger, however, Pacific had no 
    incentive to use its market power because it was not in the electricity 
    business, and it had no economic interest in electricity sales.\27\ It 
    is surely no coincidence that Enova--one of California's ``big three'' 
    electric utilities and one which every incentive to raise electricity 
    prices--sought out Pacific, the one company in the world that could 
    raise prices in the soon-to-be deregulated California electricity 
    market (the PX). It is also no coincidence that the timing of the 
    merger was to coincide almost precisely with the commencement of 
    operation of that deregulated market.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \27\ A Pacific affiliate did have paper authority from the 
    FERC--the federal overseer of wholesale electricity sales--to make 
    electricity sales but it never made any such sales and, in fact, 
    voluntarily terminated its marketing certificate once the Enova-
    Pacific merger was announced. See Ensource, 78 FERC para. 61,064 
    (1997).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        To take the position, as apparently DOJ does, that Pacific's 
    ability to raise gas prices and hence, electricity prices is not merger 
    related, and therefore should not be subject to any merger-related 
    remedy is to ignore reality. But for this merger, Enova would not be 
    able to affect electricity prices. It is the merger that transforms 
    Pacific's previously benign ability to affect electricity prices into a 
    serious, immediate threat to stifle competition in a nascent but 
    vitally important market.
    B. The Competitive Problem Attendant to This Merger Calls for a 
    Structural Remedy Directed at the Natural Gas Transportation and 
    Storage Assets
        Having identified the source of the competitive problem, and having 
    concluded that the merger was unlawful, DOJ then had to fashion an 
    appropriate remedy. Logic, traditional antitrust policy and precedent, 
    and one of the very terms of the proposed Final Judgment, all point to 
    a structural remedy aimed directly at the source of the market power--
    Pacific's natural gas transportation and storage assets.\28\ Such a 
    remedy would separate Pacific's gas transportation and storage assets 
    from the merged company's other assets, either by divestiture or by 
    creation of an ISO to operate those assets. But, for unexplained 
    reasons, the proposed Final Judgment does no such thing; indeed, this 
    remedy apparently was not even seriously considered. In a section of 
    the CIS entitled ``Alternatives to the Proposed Final Judgment'', the 
    only alternative DOJ stated that it considered was a full trial on the 
    merits.\29\ The remedies that the DOJ did adopt are all aimed at 
    curtailing the incentive of the merged company to carry out it proven 
    ability to manipulate gas and, hence, electricity prices. The 
    ineffectiveness of these remedies is discussed in the following 
    section.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \28\ Of course the most obvious and most effective remedy--
    preventing this unlawful merger from being consummated--was 
    apparently rejected by DOJ. No explanation was given for eschewing 
    this proven, simple method of remedying the effects of this unlawful 
    merger.
        \29\ See CIS at 33407.
    
        Ironically, a provision in the proposed Final Judgment itself makes 
    clear that the only completely effective remedy is a structural remedy 
    aimed at the source of the market power; the same provision undermines 
    the effectiveness of the remedies actually proposed by DOJ and Enova, 
    which focus only on incentives. Article XIII. A of the proposed Final 
    Judgment provides that all of the complex provisions of the decree will 
    abruptly terminate in the event ``an Independent System Operator has 
    assumed control of Pacific's gas pipelines within California in a 
    manner satisfactory to the United States.\30\ Termination under these 
    circumstances would be appropriate in DOJ's view, because
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \30\ Proposed Final Judgment at 33402.
    
    [i]n that event, PE/Enova will lose the ability to control access to 
    gas transportation and storage. Without these tools, the merged 
    company will not be able to raise the price for electricity sold 
    through the [PX] by reducing its gas sales, and the basis for the 
    Final Judgment would be removed.\31\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \31\ CIS at 33406 (emphasis added).
    
    Thus, DOJ's own reasoning supports the position that the only way to 
    completely eliminate the merged company's ability to increase 
    electricity prices is to eliminate Pacific's control over its gas 
    transportation and storage assets. This structural remedy serves the 
    public interest because it addresses the core competitive problem and 
    is certain to be effective over the long term. No policing is 
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    necessary.
    
        The staff of the Bureau of Economics of the Federal Trade 
    Commission (``FTC'') recently expressed its view that structural 
    remedies aimed directly at the source of market power are the most 
    effective remedies because such structural remedies alter incentives 
    (by eliminating the ability to exercise market power) while behavioral 
    remedies do not:
    
        As a general proposition, we have found that structural 
    remedies, such as divestiture in merger cases, are the most 
    effective and require the least amount of subsequent monitoring by 
    government agencies. The effectiveness of structural remedies lies 
    in the fact that they directly alter incentives. Behavioral 
    remedies, in contrast, leave incentives for discriminatory behavior 
    in place and impose a substantial burden on government agencies to 
    monitor subsequent conduct.
        In 1995, with regard to competition in electric generation and 
    transmission, we suggested that FERC [the Federal Energy Regulatory 
    Commission] promote independent system operators (ISOs) to control 
    the regional electric transmission grids, as an alternative to 
    ordering divestiture of transmission lines or relying solely on open 
    access rules to promote competition in electric generation 
    markets.\32\
    
        \32\ Comments of the Staff of the Bureau of Economics of the 
    Federal Trade Commission Before the Public Utilities Commission of 
    Texas, at 2 (June 19, 1998). See Aff. at para. 13. Adoption of a 
    structural remedy aimed at the source of the market power would be 
    consistent with traditional antitrust policy and precedent. See, 
    e.g., California v. American Stores Cos., 495 U.S. 271, 294 n.28 
    (1990) (citing 2 P. Areeda & D. Turner, Antitrust Law Sec. 328b 
    (1978) (``[D]ivestiture is the normal and usual remedy against an 
    unlawful merger''.); United States v. American Cyanamid Co., 719 
    F.2d 558, 565 (2d Cir. 1983) (citing Ford Motor Co. v. US, 405 U.S. 
    562,573 (1972) (``[D]ivestiture is not uncommonly the appropriate 
    relief when a Section 7 violation is proven''). See also United 
    States v. Merc & Co., Inc., Proposed Final Judgment and Competitive 
    Impact Statement, 45 F.R. 60044 (1980) (ordering divestiture of 
    assets that would give the defendant the ability to exercise market 
    power in violation of Section 7 of the Clayton Act and Sections 1 
    and 2 of the Sherman Act).
    
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [[Page 3560]]
    
    Thus, as explained by Dr. Carpenter, in a merger of electricity 
    transmission and generation companies, the FTC would focus its relief 
    on the source of the market power--the transmission facilities--rather 
    than the generation facilities that provide the incentive to engage in 
    the anti-competitive activity.\33\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \33\ Aff. at para. 13.
    
        Earlier this year in an analogous situation, the FTC entered into a 
    consent order settling a challenge to a proposed acquisition by an 
    electric power company of a coal supplier.\34\ Like the merger in the 
    present case involving electricity and natural gas pipelines, the FTC 
    found that a merger involving electricity and coal posed a direct 
    threat to competition in western U.S. electricity markets. In so 
    concluding, the FTC made findings remarkably similar to DOJ's findings 
    in this case:
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \34\ PacifiCorp/The Energy Group, File No. 971 0091. PacifiCorp, 
    headquartered in Portland, Oregon, makes electricity sales 
    throughout the western United States. The Energy Group PLC 
    (``TEG''), headquartered in London, England, is a diversified energy 
    company that owns, among other things, Peabody Coal Company, which 
    produces roughly 15 percent of the coal mined in the United States. 
    See FTC Restructures Electric/Coal Combination to Ensure that All 
    Consumers Reap Low Prices From Electricity Deregulation, FTC News 
    Release, Feb. 18, 1998.
    
         ``PacifiCorp's acquisition of Peabody, which is the 
    exclusive supplier of coal to certain power plants that compete with 
    PacifiCorp's own power plants, raises antitrust concerns.'' \35\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \35\ Analysis of Proposed Consent Order to Aid Public Comment 
    (``Analysis'') at 4.
    
         During off-peak periods in the western United States, 
    ``coal-fired plants frequently are the price-setting, marginal 
    plants.'' \36\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \36\ Analysis at 3.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
         PacifiCorp's acquisition ``would give PacifiCorp the 
    power to raise the price (or otherwise diminish the availability) of 
    coal, a necessary input for any firm seeking to compete with 
    PacifiCorp in electricity generation.'' \37\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \37\ Statement of The Federal Trade Commission Upon Withdrawal 
    From Consent Agreement, In the Matter of PacifiCorp, File No. 971 
    0091, (``Statement'') at 1 (emphasis added).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
         ``PacifiCorp would have an incentive to increase fuel 
    costs at Navajo and Mohave in order to drive up the market price of 
    electricity in the western United States.'' \38\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \38\ Analysis at 4 (emphasis added).
    
    Prior to the acquisition, the coal supplier (Peabody) had the ability 
    to raise coal prices to competing electric generators, but it had no 
    incentive to do so. On the other hand, before the acquisition, the 
    electricity company (PacifiCorp.) had the incentive to increase 
    electricity prices but lacked the ability. It was the merger of the 
    two, bringing together that ability and that incentive, that gave rise 
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    to the FTC's concerns.
    
        In stark contrast to DOJ's remedy in the present proceeding, the 
    FTC in PacifiCorp/The Energy Group did not hesitate to adopt a remedy 
    which went to the heart of the market power problem identified in the 
    FTC's complaint. The FTC proposed a remedy that required PacifiCorp to 
    divest Peabody Western Coal Company--the owner of the coal mines that 
    conferred market power on the merged firm and enabled it to increase 
    fuel prices at competing generating facilities (Navajo and Mohave). 
    And, the FTC directly addressed and rejected the proposals of several 
    commenters who had recommended conduct/behavioral remedies to resolve 
    the antitrust problem:
    
         ``Public comments on the consent agreement recommended 
    that we substitute conduct provisions for the order's divestiture 
    requirement, but we were not persuaded that the suggested course of 
    action would be preferable.'' \39\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \39\ Statement at 1 n.1.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
         ``The divestiture remedy is consistent with 
    longstanding Commission policy which favors the structural approach 
    to remedies, rather than the behavioral approach which seeks to 
    govern conduct through the use of rules.'' \40\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \40\ Analysis at 8. The merger never was consummated because 
    PacifiCorp subsequently withdrew its bid in the face of a competing 
    offer. In closing the investigation, the FTC stated: ``Absent this 
    turn of events, the Commission would have been inclined to issue the 
    final order against PacifiCorp without modification.'' Statement at 
    1.
    
        In both PacifiCorp and this case, the fuel supply assets are the 
    source of the competitive problem identified by the federal enforcement 
    authorities. The simple, direct way to remedy that problem is to cut 
    out and divest those assets or require that they be controlled by an 
    independent system operator.
    C. The Remedies Adopted in the Proposed Final Judgment Fail To 
    Effectively Curb the Merged Company's Incentive To Manipulate 
    Electricity Prices
        As explained above, DOJ made no pretext of selecting a remedy 
    designed to address the gas market power problem. Rather, DOJ focused 
    all of its attention on the electricity side of the merged company's 
    business and proposed a complicated set of conditions that are supposed 
    to curb the incentive of the merged company to manipulate electricity 
    prices. DOJ's theory is that if there is no financial gain to be made 
    from electricity price manipulations, then the merged company likely 
    would not engage in such conduct even if it possessed the power and 
    ability to do so. There is nothing wrong with this theory from an 
    analytical point of view. But having chosen this least attractive 
    remedial approach, DOJ needed to `'get it right'' by understanding, 
    anticipating, and then prohibiting all the various means by which the 
    merged company could seek to retain or create incentives to earn 
    profits through electricity price manipulations. DOJ, however, did not 
    do so.
        The proposed Final Judgment requires and allows the following:
         Enova is required to sell its Encina and South Bay 
    electricity generation facilities, totaling some 1650 megawatts, to 
    a purchaser acceptable to DOJ.\41\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \41\ Proposed Final Judgment art. IV(A) at 33398 (requiring 
    divestiture) & (D)(3) at 33398 (specifying DOJ's right to prior 
    approval of purchaser) & (I) at 33399 (specifying the criteria for 
    DOJ approval). The divestiture is to occur within eighteen months, 
    subject to extension by DOJ, or a trustee will be appointed. 
    Proposed Final Judgment art. IV(E) at 33399.
    
         Enova is enjoined from acquiring ``California 
    Generation Facilities'' without prior notice and approval of DOJ. 
    \42\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \42\ Proposed Final Judgment art. V(A)(1). The term ``California 
    Generation Facilities'' is defined to mean electricity generation 
    facilities in California in existence on January 1, 1998, and any 
    contract to operate and sell output from generating assets of the 
    Los Angeles Department of Water and Power (``LADWP''). Proposed 
    Final Judgment art. II(B) at 33397. ``Acquire'' is defined to mean 
    ``obtaining any interest in any electricity generating facilities or 
    capacity, including but not limited to, all real property * * * 
    capital equipment * * * or contracts related to the generation 
    facility, and including all generation, tolling, reverse tolling, 
    and other contractual rights.'' Proposed Final Judgment art II(A).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
         Enova is enjoined from entering any contracts that 
    allow it to ``control any California Generation Facilities'' without 
    prior notice and approval of DOJ.\43\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \43\ Proposed Final Judgment art. V(A)(2) at 33399. ``Control'' 
    means to have the ability to set the level of output of an 
    electricity generation facility.'' Proposed Final Judgment art. 
    II(E) at 33398.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
         In general, Enova is allowed to acquire or control up 
    to 500 MW of capacity of California Generation Facilities without 
    prior DOJ approval.\44\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \44\ Proposed Final Judgment art. V(B)(1) at 33399. The cap may 
    be increased to 800 MW upon Enova's sale of all of its existing 
    nuclear generating capacity, but only up to 10% of its total retail 
    electricity sales. Proposed Final Judgment art. XIII(D) at 33402.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
         Enova is allowed to ``own, operate, control, or acquire 
    any electricity generation facilities other than California 
    Generation Facilities [and] any cogeneration or renewable generation 
    facilities in California.'' \45\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \45\ Proposed Final Judgment art. V(C)(1) and (2) at 33399.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
         Enova is also allowed to ``enter into tolling and 
    reverse tolling agreements with any electricity generation 
    facilities in
    
    [[Page 3561]]
    
    California,'' provided it does not ``control'' them.\46\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \46\ Proposed Final Judgment art. (V)(C)(3) at 33399.
    
        As explained by Dr. Carpenter, these remedies are ineffective 
    because they are incomplete.\47\ While their aim is to curb the merged 
    company's incentives to harm competition by restricting its 
    participation in certain activities, they also allow other activities 
    that can completely undo what DOJ seeks to achieve. It is as if DOJ 
    closed one door to anti-competitive activity but left wide open several 
    other doors.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \47\ Aff. at Paras. 19, 21.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The rationale underlying DOJ's required divestiture of the 1650 of 
    the 1650 MW of Enova generating facilities is that infra-marginal 
    assets (assets that are low-cost relative to the market price of 
    electricity) create incentives through the price-clearing mechanism in 
    the PX for the merged company to manipulate gas prices. As stated by 
    DOJ:
        The Final Judgment requires Defendant to sell all generation 
    assets that would likely give PE/Enova the inventive to raise 
    electricity prices. [footnote excluded] To that end, the Final 
    Judgment requires Defendant to divest all of its low-cost gas 
    generators * * *. Because these generators operate in almost all 
    hours of the year and are relatively low-cost, if PE/Enova were to 
    own them, it could earn substantial profits (revenues exceeding its 
    costs) by restricting the supply of natural gas which, as explained 
    above, would increase the overall price for electricity in the pool 
    and thus the prive PE/Enova would receive for electricity.\48\
    
        \48\ CIS at 33404.
    
        But, what DOJ overlooked is that many other arrangements and 
    transactions that are not prohibited by the proposed Final Judgment 
    will allow the merged entity to directly, or indirectly through 
    financial instruments, collect the earnings from infra-marginal 
    generating facilities. Specifically, the proposed Final Judgmebnt has 
    left in place significant anti-competitive incentives by permitting the 
    merged company to:
         Build or acquire new or repowered generating facilities;
         Enter into tolling agreements;
         Enter into power generation management contracts;
         Enter into financial contracts tied to prices in the 
    California electricity market
    
    1. Acquisition of New or Repowered Generating Facilities
    
        While the merged company would generally be prohibited from owning 
    or controlling existing California generating facilities over and above 
    the 500 MW cap, the proposed Final Judgment allows it to build or 
    acquire new generating facilities and to acquire plants that are 
    rebuilt, repowered or activated out of dormancy after January 1, 1998. 
    While adding new facilities is generally procompetitive, here that is 
    not the case. Acquisition of new (or rebuilt/repowered/reactivated) 
    generating facilities will create incentives to manipulate gas prices 
    that the merged company does not have, easily undoing via vertical 
    market power the otherwise positive horizontal effect of adding new 
    generation facilities.\49\ DOJ required the divestiture of Enova's two 
    generation plants because, as low-cost facilities, they could ``earn 
    substantial profits'' under the PX pricing mechanism (see supra at p. 
    22). That same rationale holds equally true for the types of generating 
    facilities that the proposed Final Judgment permits the merged company 
    to acquire.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \49\ Aff. at para. 22.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        By way of example, consider two scenarios. In scenario one, the 
    merged company divests 1650 MW of Enova's generating facilities, and 
    then builds a 1650 MW facility to replace the lost output. Because of 
    technology improvements, the new facility can be brought on-line with 
    costs roughly equal to those of the old facilities. In scenario two, 
    the merged company retains its 1650 MW of existing facilities and a 
    disinterested third party builds a 1650 MW facility. In both scenarios, 
    the market has the same amount of megawatts available for consumption 
    and the merged company has roughly the same incentive to raise gas 
    prices.\50\ The proposed Final Judgment permits scenario one but 
    prohibits scenario two. A provision such as that can hardly be said to 
    be within the reaches of the public interest.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \50\ See Aff. at para. 23.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    2. Tolling Agreements
    
        The proposed Final Judgment permits the merged company to enter 
    into tolling or reverse tolling agreements so long as it does not 
    control the level of the plant's output. Under a tolling agreement, a 
    party who owns natural gas enters into a contract with the owner of the 
    generating facility to use (``rent'') that facility, thereby allowing 
    the gas-owning party to produce electricity for a set fee. The gas-
    owning party can then sell the electricity at the market price, which 
    may be higher or lower than the set fee.\51\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \51\ Aff at para. 24.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The problem is that tolling agreements are akin to virtual 
    ownership because they provide the merged company with the same 
    incentive to increase electricity prices as does physical ownership. 
    And, the agreement need not provide for control of the plant's output 
    for that incentive to exist. For example, the merged company could 
    enter into tolling agreements with the two Enova generating facilities 
    that it has agreed to divest. The facilities' operator, whoever that 
    is, would bid into the PX at the facilities' marginal cost and the 
    facilities would operate whenever the bids are successful. To the 
    extent that the agreement provides the merged company with electricity 
    at a fixed price, the company has an incentive to increase the PX price 
    by increasing gas prices--it will simply pocket the additional 
    revenue.\52\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \52\ Aff. at para. 25.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The failure of the proposed Final Judgment to close this gap is 
    another reason to find it not in the public interest.
    
    3. Power Generation Management Contracts
    
        A further reason to reject the proposed Final Judgment is due to 
    its failure to prohibit the merged company from entering into 
    management contracts under which it would operate a generation facility 
    owned by a third party. Such arrangements are similar to tolling 
    agreements in that they permit a sharing in a facility's profits.\53\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \53\ Aff. at para. 26. A management contract may be structured 
    to be more complex than a tolling agreement (e.g., clauses with 
    operating cost incentives) but, in essence, both arrangements have a 
    built-in incentive to make the facility as profitable as possible. 
    Id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Importantly, the proposed Final Judgment recognizes the potential 
    harm to competition that such contracts can cause. It requires the 
    merged company to notify and/or obtain approval from DOJ for management 
    contracts entered into with the Los Angeles Department of Water and 
    Power and with the California Public Power Providers. These 
    restrictions go part way to reducing incentives but apparently they do 
    not apply to contracts relating to all other California generating 
    facilities.\54\ Permitting such contracts for certain but not all 
    California generating facilities is inconsistent and not in the public 
    interest.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \54\ There is some ambiguity due to the definition of 
    ``acquisition'' in the proposed Final Judgment. ``Acquire'' could be 
    interpreted to prohibit any financial interest, or it could be 
    interpreted to prohibit any ownership interest. The latter 
    interpretation leaves open the possibility of entering into 
    management contracts. See proposed Final Judgment at art. II(A); see 
    also Aff. at para. 28.
    
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [[Page 3562]]
    
    4. Financial Market Contracts
    
        Finally, the proposed Final Judgment fails to place any 
    restrictions whatsoever on the merged company's ability to enter into 
    financial contracts (e.g., forwards, futures, options and other 
    derivatives) that provide the same incentive to increase electricity 
    prices.\55\ Financial contracts can be used to approximate the same 
    financial position the merged company would have by virtue of owning 
    generation facilities.\56\ The merged company, for example, could 
    contract for a one-year call option for 1000 MW of output at a certain 
    ``strike price.'' The higher the electricity market price is above the 
    strike price, the greater the profit when the option is exercised.\57\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \55\ A forward contract is a non-standardized bilateral contract 
    for future delivery of electricity at a pre-specified price. A 
    futures contracts is a standardized forward contract that is traded 
    on an organized exchange. California-Oregon border and Palo Verde 
    electricity futures contracts, both of which are traded on the New 
    York Mercantile Exchange, are accessible to the California market. 
    Option contracts, which can be either traded on an exchange or done 
    bilaterally, include additional flexibility for the buyer or the 
    seller. For example, a call option gives the buyer the right but not 
    the obligation to purchase electricity in the future at a specified 
    price. Aff. at para.29 fn.9.
        \56\ Aff. at para.29.
        \57\ Aff. at para.29.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As explained by Dr. Carpenter, financial contracts have the 
    potential to foster more anti-competitive creativity than ownership of 
    generation facilities because they are more flexible. While it is 
    difficult to change ownership, it is simple to contract for electricity 
    in varying amounts over differing time horizons and to change positions 
    quickly and frequently. This flexibility allows the merged company to 
    tailor its electricity market position to most advantage itself.\58\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \58\ Aff. at para.29.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Both individually and collectively, the shortcomings of the 
    proposed Final Judgment are significant because they completely 
    undermine DOJ's effort to curb the merged entity's incentive to 
    increase electricity prices. DOJ's failure to eliminate this incentive 
    renders the proposed Final Judgment ineffective and thus outside the 
    reaches of the public interest. This Court should reject it as 
    presently written.
    
            Respectfully submitted,
    Kevin J. Lipson,
    Mary Anne Mason,
    Hogan & Hartson LLP, Columbia Square, 555--Thirteenth Street, NW, 
    Washington, DC 20004-1109. (202) 637-5600.
    Stephen E. Pickett,
    Douglas Kent Porter,
    Southern California Edison Company, P.O. Box 800, 2244 Walnut Grove 
    Avenue, Rosemead, California 91770. (626) 302-1903.
    J.A. Bouknight, Jr.,
    David R. Roll,
    Steptoe & Johnson LLP, 1330 Connecticut Avenue, NW, Washington, DC 
    20036. (202) 429-3000.
    
    Affidavit of Paul R. Carpenter
    
    Kevin J. Lipson,
    Mary Anne Mason,
    Hogan & Hartson LLP, Columbia Square, 555--Thirteenth Street, NW, 
    Washington, DC 20004-1109. (202) 637-5600.
    Stephen E. Pickett,
    Douglas Kent Porter,
    Southern California Edison Company, P.O. Box 800, 2244 Walnut Grove 
    Avenue, Rosemead, California 91770. (626) 302-1903.
    J.A. Bouknight, Jr.,
    David R. Roll,
    Steptoe & Johnson LLP, 1330 Connecticut Avenue, NW, Washington, DC 
    20036. (202) 429-3000.
        Dated: August 17, 1998.
    
        1. My name is Paul Carpenter. I am a Principal of The Brattle 
    Group, an economic and management consulting firm with offices at 44 
    Brattle Street, Cambridge, Massachusetts 02138, in Washington D.C., and 
    London, England.
        2. I am an economist specializing in the fields of industrial 
    organization, finance, and regulatory economics. I received a Ph.D. in 
    Applied Economics and an M.S. in Management from the Massachusetts 
    Institute of Technology, and a B.A. in Economics from Stanford 
    University. Since the early 1980s, I have been involved in research and 
    consulting regarding the economics and regulation of the natural gas, 
    oil, and electric power industries in North America, the United 
    Kingdom, and Australia. I have testified frequently before the Federal 
    Energy Regulatory Commission (``FERC''), the Public Utilities 
    Commission of the State of California (``CPUC''), other state and 
    Canadian regulatory commissions, federal courts, the U.S. Congress, the 
    British Monopolies and Mergers Commission, and the Australian 
    Competition Tribunal on issues of pricing, competition and regulatory 
    policy in the natural gas and electric power industries. For at least 
    ten years I have been extensively involved in the evaluation of the 
    economics and structure of the natural gas industry in California, 
    including the interstate pipelines that serve the state, appearing as 
    an expert witness in many CPUC, FERC and Canadian regulatory 
    proceedings regarding the certification and pricing of interstate 
    pipeline capacity to California. Further details of my professional and 
    educational background and a listing of my publications are provided in 
    my curriculum vitae appended as Attachment A.
    
    Introduction and Summary of Opinion
    
        3. I have been asked by Southern California Edison Company 
    (``Edison'') to prepare this affidavit. Its purpose is to evaluate 
    whether the U.S. Department of Justice (``DOJ'') Final Judgment in this 
    proceeding (as further explained in its accompanying Competitive Impact 
    Statement (``CIS'')) remedies the competitive problem identified in 
    DOJ's Complaint--namely, that as a result of their merger, Pacific 
    Enterprises (``Pacific'') and Enova Corporation (``Enova'') will have 
    the incentive and ability to lessen competition in the market for 
    electricity in California.
        4. The DOJ observed correctly in its Complaint and CIS that the 
    merger will give the combined company (``the Merged Entity'') both the 
    incentive and the ability to harm competition in the California 
    electricity market by limiting the supply and/or raising the price of 
    natural gas supplied to gas-fired electric generating plants in 
    southern California.
        5. In my opinion, the Proposed Final Judgment does not remedy the 
    serious competitive problem identified by the DOJ in its complaint. The 
    bases for my opinion are summarized here and elaborated upon in the 
    remainder of this affidavit:
         The DOJ correctly concluded that the merger will give the 
    Merged Entity both the ability and incentive to raise electricity 
    prices in southern California.
         The DOJ could have remedied this competitive problem by 
    eliminating the ability of the Merged Entity to exercise market power 
    by requiring either:
         The divestiture of Pacific's intrastate natural gas and 
    storage assets to a third party; or
         The creation of an Independent System Operator to hold and 
    operate Pacific's natural gas assets.
         This type of structural remedy is favored by antitrust 
    authorities because it is aimed directly at the source of the 
    competitive problem--market power--and it is clean and easy to enforce, 
    requiring no ongoing administrative involvement in reviewing the 
    conduct and performance of the suspect market.
    
    [[Page 3563]]
    
         The remedy chosen by the DOJ is to leave the Merged 
    Entity's market power intact, and instead to try to curb the Merged 
    Entity's incentives to harm competition by requiring the sale of two 
    generating plants and by restricting its participation in certain 
    activities. This remedy is ineffective. Not only does it leave market 
    power intact, it fails to eliminate significant anticompetitive 
    incentives that are equivalent financially to the ownership of the two 
    power plants.
         The Proposed Final Judgment has left in place significant 
    anti-competitive incentives by permitting the Merged Entity to:
         Build or acquire new or repowered generating capacity.
         Enter into tolling agreements or management contracts.
         Enter into financial contracts (e.g., forwards, futures, 
    options and other derivatives) for electricity.
         These overlooked capabilities are a very real part of the 
    incentives of the Merged Entity, are a standard part of the package of 
    services of any major energy marketer, and they are consistent with the 
    avowed strategic business plans of the Merged Entity.
    
    The Competitive Problem Associated With the Merger
    
        6. Pacific, through its wholly owned subsidiary Southern California 
    Gas Company (``SoCalGas''), is effectively the sole provider of 
    intrastate natural gas transmission and storage services to almost all 
    of the gas-fired electric generating plants in southern California. As 
    a consequence of this market power, SoCalGas has the ability to limit 
    the supply and/or raise the price of natural gas to gas-fired plants. 
    Prior to the merger, however, it had no strong incentive to do so 
    because it had no position in or control over electricity markets.
        7. The DOJ has recognized Pacific's ability to restrict the 
    availability of gas transportation and storage to gas-fired generators, 
    and to raise the price of delivered gas to such generators:
        Gas-fired power plants cannot and do not switch to other fuels in 
    response to price increases in natural gas transportation or storage 
    services, and in California Pacific controls almost all gas-fired 
    generators' access to gas supply because the state of California has 
    granted Pacific a monopoly on transportation of natural gas within 
    southern California. Consequently, 96% of gas-fired generators in 
    southern California buy gas transportation services from it. Pacific 
    also has a monopoly on all natural gas storage services throughout 
    California. Although regulated by the California Public Utilities 
    Commission (``CPUC''), Pacific has the ability to restrict the 
    availability of gas transportation and storage to consumers, including 
    gas-fired generators, by limiting their supply or cutting them off 
    entirely. Limiting or cutting off gas supply raises the price gas-fired 
    plants pay for delivered natural gas and in turn raises the cost of 
    electricity they produce.\1\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \1\ Competitive Impact Statement (Case 98-CV-583), at 5-7. See 
    also Complaint, at 6.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        8. The Merged Entity has numerous means to raise prices or limit 
    supply to gas-fired generators in the southern California market. These 
    means are derived primarily from SoCalGas' control of the intrastate 
    transmission, distribution and storage system in southern California, 
    its role as gas buyer for ``core'' residential and small commercial 
    customers, and its holding of excess interstate pipeline capacity under 
    long-term contract.
         Intrastate transmission and storage access. As operator of 
    the intrastate transmission, distribution and storage system. SoCalGas 
    has considerable authority and autonomy to determine which gas will 
    flow and under what conditions. It decides on the amount of intrastate 
    capacity available at each interstate pipeline interconnect, based on 
    subjective procedures that are not articulated in any tariff or 
    internal procedural manual. It also has discretion in determining 
    storage availability.
         Pricing of intrastate services. As the provider of hub and 
    storage services, SoCalGas is allowed under California regulation to 
    exercise pricing discretion with regard to certain negotiated services. 
    These services include short-term balancing or emergency supply 
    services.
         Interstate access and pricing.  SoCalGas has discretion in 
    determining the price and quantity of capacity it makes available in 
    secondary (``capacity release'') markets. This discretion presents the 
    Merged Entity with one more means by which to influence the delivered 
    price of gas to its electricity market rivals.
         Core procurement behavior. SoCalGas has substantial 
    flexibility in its core-related storage injection and withdrawal 
    decisions that allows it to determine the volume of flowing supplies on 
    a day-to-day basis, notwithstanding customer demand.
         Use of operational information. As the operator of the 
    intrastate natural gas transportation and storage system. SoCalGas 
    possesses considerable operational information that is extremely 
    valuable in the restructured natural gas and electricity markets. For 
    example, as system operator. SoCalGas will receive regular nomination 
    information from all of its shippers. Because SoCalGas has considerable 
    discretion in operating its system, it can do so in a manner that can 
    result in the manipulation of prices and access, and thus the cost of 
    rivals of using its system. Such manipulations would be almost 
    impossible to detect, difficult to prove, and not readily subject to 
    cure.
        Each one of these advantages is sufficiently potent to enable to 
    the Merged Entity to manipulate the price of gas and/or the quality of 
    service to electricity generators.
        9. As of March 31, 1998, California launched the Power Exchange 
    (PX), through which much of the electricity is now bought and sold in 
    California. The PX's price per unit of electricity for any given hour 
    is determined by the bid of the marginal generator--the most expensive 
    generator required to meet load in that hour. All sellers receive the 
    marginal price, regardless of their bid, and all buyers pay the 
    marginal price. As DOJ has acknowledged, because of California's mix of 
    generating capacity, gas-fired generators usually are the marginal 
    suppliers, and the marginal-cost pricing instituted by the PX means 
    that the price bid by gas-fired generators will set electricity prices 
    in the California market the majority of the time.\2\ The marginal bid 
    price setting mechanism of the PX means that California gas-fired 
    capacity will have a dominant effect on electricity prices.\3\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \2\ To illustrate, Attachment B to this affidavit depicts the 
    electricity supply curve for both utility and non-utility generating 
    resources for the entire Western Systems Coordinating Council 
    (WSCC). This supply curve distinguishes gas-fired capacity and 
    California gas-fired capacity from other generation capacity. As 
    illustrated, actual load (which varies by time of day and 
    seasonally) falls within a band of 70,500 MW to 93,500 MW 
    approximately two-thirds of the time. Within this same band of the 
    supply curve, 90% of the capacity is gas-fired capacity, and 69% is 
    California gas-fired capacity.
        \3\ While not all California gas-fired capacity is served by 
    SoCalGas, the majority of it is, and it has been found that the 
    prices paid in northern California for gas delivered by Pacific Gas 
    & Electric Co. (PG&E) are determined by the gas supply alternatives 
    available at the southern California border. See CPUC Decision 97-
    08-055. August 1, 1997, at p.10.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        10. Enova, through its wholly owned subsidiary, San Diego Gas & 
    Electric (SDG&E), owns gas-fired electric generating stations and 
    controls over 2,600 MW of electric generating capacity. DOJ recognized 
    that SDG&E's control of substantial quantities of electricity sold into 
    the PX gives SDG&E and incentive to raise the PX's electricity price, 
    making sales of its own
    
    [[Page 3564]]
    
    electricity more profitable. To this existing incentive, the merger 
    with Pacific adds the ability to increase the price of electricity. The 
    Merged Entity can accomplish this by increasing the price of natural 
    gas to gas-fired generating plants in southern California, which in 
    turn will raise their cost of producing electricity. Because California 
    gas-fired capacity dominates the electric margin, this will increase 
    the PX's price per unit of electricity to all sellers.\4\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \4\ Much of the gas-fired generating capacity in California is 
    currently under temporary ``must-run'' contracts for reliability, 
    which when invoked will prevent these units from setting, or 
    profiting from, the PX price. However, this will have no effect when 
    must-run conditions are not declared, and the arrangement is 
    scheduled to expire in three years.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Failure of the Proposed Final Judgment To Impose a Structural Remedy 
    Aimed at Market Power
    
        11. The proposed Final Judgment fails to eliminate the competitive 
    harm caused by the PE/Enova merger because: (1) it does not contain any 
    provisions designed to curb the Merged Entity's ability to harm 
    competition through its monopoly over natural gas transportation and 
    supply, and (2) while it requires SDG&E to divest ownership of two gas-
    fired electric generating plants, it permits the Merged Entity to 
    replicate ownership by entering into contractual arrangements which 
    offer the same incentives to engage in anti-competitive activity.
        12. The proposed Final Judgment fails to impose the obvious, 
    traditional, and assuredly effective remedy to a market power problem 
    in a merger proceeding. It could have eliminated the ability of the 
    Merged Entity to harm competition by eliminating its ability to 
    exercise market power. It could have done this by requiring the 
    divestiture of Pacific's intrastate natural gas transmission and 
    storage assets, or by requiring the creation of an Independent System 
    Operator (``ISO'') for those assets.
        13. The staff of the Bureau of Economics of the Federal Trade 
    Commission has recently expressed its view that structural remedies 
    (such as ISOs) aimed directly at the source of market power are the 
    most effective remedies because such structural remedies alter 
    incentives (by eliminating the ability to exercise market power) while 
    behavioral remedies do not:
    
        As a general proposition, we have found that structural 
    remedies, such as divestiture in merger cases, are the most 
    effective and require the least amount of subsequent monitoring by 
    government agencies. The effectiveness of structural remedies lies 
    in the fact that they directly alter incentives. Behavioral 
    remedies, in contrast, leave incentives for discriminatory behavior 
    in place and impose a substantial burden on government agencies to 
    monitor subsequent conduct.
        * * * In 1995, with regard to competition in electric generation 
    and transmission, we suggested that FERC [the Federal Energy 
    Regulatory Commission] promote independent system operators (ISOs) 
    to control the regional electric transmission grids, as an 
    alternative to ordering divestiture of transmission lines or relying 
    solely on open access rules to promote competition in electric 
    generation markets.\5\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \5\ Comments of the Staff of the Bureau of Economics of the 
    Federal Trade Commission Before the Public Utilities Commission of 
    Texas, at 2 (June 19, 1998).
    
        I agree with this view. Thus, for example, in a merger of 
    electricity transmission and generation companies, the FTC would focus 
    its relief on the source of the market power--the transmission 
    facilities--rather than the generation facilities that provide the 
    incentive to engage in anti-competitive activity. As stated above, the 
    FTC would place the transmission facilities in the hands of an 
    independent entity, an ISO, and would prevent those facilities, which 
    confer market power, from being controlled by the merged entity.
        14. In remedying the anti-competitive effects of vertical mergers 
    like the present one, the antitrust authorities have opted, and should 
    continue to opt, for structural remedies that eliminate the source of 
    the market power. Recently, in addressing the anti-competitive effects 
    of a proposed merger between an electric utility and a coal company, 
    the FTC insisted on divestiture of the coal supply assets that were the 
    source of the market power which in turn led to anti-competitive 
    control over electricity prices. I agree with this approach and this 
    remedy. A copy of the FTC's reasoning in that case is appended as 
    Attachment C.
        15. A structural remedy in this case, requiring intrastate gas 
    transmission and storage divestiture or the creation of an ISO, would 
    eliminate cleanly the Merged Entity's ability to control the price of 
    electricity in California, and it would eliminate the enforcement 
    difficulties associated with behavioral remedies that attempt to 
    control anti-competitive incentives after the fact.\6\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \6\ Nowhere in its CIS does DOJ explain why it has failed to 
    impose a remedy that eliminates the ability of the merged entity to 
    raise prices.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    The Proposed Final Judgment Does Not Remedy the Competitive Problem 
    Identified by DOJ
    
        16. The proposed Final Judgment does not attempt to eliminate the 
    Merged Entity's market power over natural gas transportation and 
    storage which gives it the ability to harm competition and raise prices 
    in electricity markets. Instead, DOJ has chosen to attempt to curb the 
    Merged Entity's incentive to harm competition by requiring Enova to 
    divest itself of 1,644 MW of generation assets, namely, the Encina and 
    South Bay gas-fired electricity generating plants. In addition, the 
    Final Judgment caps the Merged Entity's ownership of California 
    electricity generation assets at 500 MW.\7\ The Final Judgment also 
    enjoins the Merged Entity from acquiring electricity generation 
    facilities in California which were in existence on January 1, 1998 
    (except facilities that are rebuilt, repowered, or activated out of 
    dormancy after January 1, 1998) and/or entering into any contract for 
    operation and sale of output from generating assets of Los Angeles 
    Department of Water and Power (``LADWP''), without prior notice to, and 
    approval of, the United States. Finally, the Final Judgment enjoins the 
    Merged Entity from entering into any contracts that allow it to control 
    the output of electricity generation facilities in California in 
    existence on January 1, 1998 without prior notice to and approval of 
    the United States.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \7\ Since nuclear plants in California will remain price 
    regulated (i.e., will not receive the PX price) until 2001, Enova's 
    20% (430 MW) interest in the San Onofre Nuclear Generating Station 
    (``SONGS'') will not be included in the 500 MW cap. If nuclear power 
    prices become deregulated after 2001, SONGS capacity will be 
    included in the cap and the period of the final judgment will be 
    extended from five to ten years. A 75 MW contract with Portland 
    General Electric will be included in the cap, unless the contract is 
    terminated or divested. Finally, the capacity of the Encina and 
    South Bay generation facilities will be included in the cap for as 
    long as Enova owns these assets.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        17. Importantly, this merger involves much more than an effort to 
    combine SDG&E's electricity generation assets with SoCalGas' natural 
    gas transmission and distribution assets. The problem with the merger 
    is that it combines SDG&E's expertise in profiting through the 
    acquisition and sale of electric power with SoCalGas' ability to 
    control the price of natural gas in California through its monopoly 
    over natural gas transportation and storage services in California.\8\ 
    As explained further below, this combination of electricity expertise 
    and natural gas control creates a serious competitive problem that is 
    not remedied by the divestiture of assets and other conditions set 
    forth in the Final Judgment. Specifically, such
    
    [[Page 3565]]
    
    electricity expertise could be used to enter into tolling agreements, 
    management contracts and forward and futures contracts that perpetuate 
    the Merged Entity's incentive to manipulate gas prices for anti-
    competitive ends, notwithstanding the Final Judgment's generation 
    ownership restrictions.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \8\ The California Commission noted in its merger decision that 
    ``* * * each company sees unregulated energy services (particularly 
    electricity marketing) as a way to increase earnings. But each feels 
    that it lacks critical skills and physical assets.'' See D. 98-03-
    073, at 24.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        18. As a general matter, it is extremely difficult to eliminate all 
    of the anti-competitive incentives facing a utility in a restructured, 
    partially deregulated wholesale electricity market. Those incentives 
    manifest themselves in many different ways--only one of which is 
    through ownership of existing gas-fired plants. Yet to be confident 
    that the harm is competition is eliminated (when the ability to 
    exercise market power remains), the antitrust authority or regulator 
    must identify all of the potential incentives to profit from market 
    manipulation and then design remedies that will curb each and every 
    incentive. As explained below, the Final Judgment fails to curb very 
    significant incentives.
        19. The Competitive Impact Statement (CIS) correctly defines the 
    Merged Entity's incentive but misconstrues the relationship between the 
    kinds of transactions the Merged Entity might pursue and the incentives 
    that would be created. As a result, the behavioral remedies put forward 
    in the Final Judgment eliminate only part of the Merged Entity's 
    incentives to raise prices.
        20. The CIS recognizes that infra-marginal assets (assets that are 
    low-cost relative to the market price of electricity) create incentives 
    through the price-clearing mechanism in the California PX for the 
    Merged Entity to manipulate gas prices. For example, the CIS states (at 
    page 9):
    
        The Final Judgment requires Defendant to sell all generation 
    assets that would likely give PE/Enova the incentive to raise 
    electricity prices [footnote excluded] To that end, the Final 
    Judgment requires Defendant to divest all of its low-cost gas 
    generators * * *. Because these generators operate in almost all 
    hours of the year and are relatively low-cost, if PE/Enova were to 
    own them, it could earn substantial profits (revenues exceedings its 
    costs) by restricting the supply of natural gas which, as explained 
    above, would increase the overall price for electricity in the pool 
    [PX] and thus the price PE/Enova would receive for electricity.
    
        21. In making this finding, the DOJ overlooks the fact that many 
    other arrangements and transactions that are not prohibited by the 
    proposed Final Judgment create financial positions equivalent to, and 
    potentially even more profitable than, the physical ownership of an 
    infra-marginal generating unit. Any arrangement that allows the Merged 
    Entity to collect or share in the earnings of an infra-marginal 
    generator will give it the incentive to manipulate the spot price of 
    power by increasing gas prices. The Final Judgment does not prohibit, 
    and in fact explicitly allows, several such arrangements. Under the 
    Final Judgment, the Merged Entity is allowed to (1) acquire new, 
    rebuilt or repowered generation, (2) enter into tolling agreements with 
    third-party generation owners, (3) enter into power generation 
    management contracts, and (4) take forward contractual positions in the 
    electricity market. All of these permitted transactions allow the 
    Merged Entity to profit by manipulating the price of electric power, 
    and will risk the abuse of market power as long as the Merged Entity 
    has the continuing ability to influence gas prices that the CIS has 
    acknowledged. As I explain below, in each of these situations the Final 
    Judgment's restrictions simply do not eliminate the Merged Entity's 
    incentives to exercise market power.
    
    New or Repowered Generation Capacity
    
        22. Under the proposed Final Judgment, the Merged Entity would be 
    prohibited from owning or controlling existing generating facilities, 
    but it is permitted to built or acquire new generating capacity and to 
    gain control of plants that are rebuilt, repowered or activated out of 
    dormancy after January 1, 1998. However, the addition of new generation 
    by the Merged Entity is not necessarily benign. All else equal, adding 
    generating capacity is usually procompetitive. However, in this case, 
    all else is decidedly unequal. Allowing the Merged Entity to acquire 
    new generation (or to rebuild, repower or reactivate generation) will 
    give it incentives to manipulate gas prices which it would not 
    otherwise have, easily undoing via vertical market power the otherwise 
    positive horizontal effect of adding capacity. By giving the Merged 
    Entity an incentive to raise gas prices, ownership of new or repowered 
    generation could lead to an across-the-board increase in the cost of 
    most of the margin-setting capacity in the market. Thus, the Final 
    Judgment should prohibit the acquisition of new generating capacity for 
    the same reason it requires divestiture of existing capacity. Holding 
    any sort of interest in generating capacity eligible for the PX price 
    gives the Merged Entity an incentive to exercise its market power in 
    the gas market, to the detriment of the electricity market.
        23. Another way to view this is by considering two scenarios: (A) 
    the Merged Entity divests its existing generation to a third party, and 
    builds a new generator, or (B) the Merged Entity keeps its existing 
    generation and a disinterested third party builds the new generator. In 
    both scenarios, the market has the same amount of generation, and the 
    Merged Entity has essentially the same incentive to raise gas prices. 
    However, while the CIS correctly recognizes (B) as problematic, the 
    Final Judgment explicitly (though incorrectly) allows (A), the 
    acquisition of new or repowered capacity.
    
    Tolling Agreements
    
        24. In a ``tolling'' agreement, one party contracts for the use of 
    another party's generating capacity, allowing the first party to 
    convert its own gas into electricity for a set fee. The first party can 
    then sell the electricity at the market price, and will be able to 
    collect the associated profit (or loss) as if it owned the generator. 
    The proposed Final Judgment explicitly allows the Merged Entity to 
    enter into tolling agreements, so long as it does not control the 
    plant's output level in the process.
        25. Tolling agreements create virtual ownership positions in power 
    plants, and provide the Merged Entity with the same incentives to 
    increase electricity prices as does physical plant ownership. A tolling 
    agreement would allow the Merged Entity to receive all or most of the 
    generator's infra-marginal net revenues, whether or not it controls the 
    plant's output level. The proposed Final Judgment's restriction against 
    controlling plant output displays a misconception of how the Merged 
    Entity could exercise market power. It is not by withholding generating 
    capacity from the market that the Merged Entity would manipulate 
    electricity prices. Withholding capacity is an issue in horizontal 
    market power, but not in the vertical market power that is of concern 
    in this instance. Vertical market power arises here because the Merged 
    Entity has the ability to raise the price of electricity by raising the 
    price of gas--the dominant margin-setting fuel, and a vertical input to 
    electricity. The Merged Entity can profit from gas market manipulation 
    if it holds a claim on the net revenues of any infra-marginal plant 
    that is operating when gas-fired generation is setting the PX price, 
    regardless of whether it controls the plant's output. The plant 
    operator, whoever it is, would simply bid into the PX at the plant's 
    marginal cost, so that the plant would dispatch when economical. Thus, 
    for example, if the Merged Entity enters into a tolling agreement with 
    the owners of the two plants it has agreed to divest, its
    
    [[Page 3566]]
    
    financial stake will be essentially identical to what it would have 
    been under direct ownership. While physical plant ownership is rightly 
    prohibited, the Final Judgment fails to curb the Merged Entity's 
    incentives because it allows tolling agreements that give the Merged 
    Entity the same profit-making potential.
    
    Management Contracts
    
        26. The same issues arise with ``management contracts,'' under 
    which the Merged Entity would operate a plant owned by a third party, 
    typically for a share of the plant's profits. Such arrangements are 
    similar to tolling agreements in that they allow the Merged Entity to 
    share in a plant's net revenues.
        27. The problem with the proposed Final Judgment is that it does 
    not clearly prohibit the Merged Entity from entering into management 
    contracts with existing California generating facilities (e.g. its own 
    divested generators or those of others). Thus, the Merged Entity could 
    sign a management contract for one or more of the plants divested by 
    itself or others and enjoy essentially the same financial incentives it 
    could have had by retaining its own plants. Moreover, these units under 
    management contract need not be gas-fired for them to create price 
    manipulation incentives. To perpetuate such incentives, all that is 
    required is that the plant(s) under contract be infra-marginal (i.e., 
    lower cost than the marginal gas-fired plant that is setting the PX 
    price.) To eliminate the anti-competitive incentives associated with 
    management contracts, the Merged Entity would have to be explicitly 
    prevented from entering into a management contract with any entity 
    owning or building generation in California.
        28. The proposed Final Judgement recognizes the problems with 
    management contracts when it requires that the Merged Entity notify 
    and/or obtain approval from DOJ for management contracts with assets 
    owned by California Public Power Providers (``CPPP'') and the Los 
    Angeles Department of Water and Power (``LADWP''). These restrictions 
    go part way in reducing the Merged Entity's incentives. But since 
    similar restrictions are not applied to management contracts involving 
    other assets, the Final Judgment gives the appearance of endorsing such 
    contracts. Relatedly, the Final Judgment prohibits the ``acquisition'' 
    of California Generation Facilities without prior approval. However, by 
    carving out exceptions for management contracts, the meaning of 
    ``acquire'' becomes ambiguous, despite being defined as ``obtaining any 
    interest in any electricity generating facilities or capacity''. 
    ``Acquire'' could be interpreted to prohibit any financial interest 
    (which it must do to be effective), or could it be interpreted more 
    narrowly to prohibit only ownership interest--which leaves open the 
    possibility of management contracts. By explicitly restricting 
    management contracts with respect to LADWP and CPPP assets only, the 
    proposed Final Judgment appears to endorse a narrow interpretation of 
    ``acquire'', and threatens to leave the Merged Entity with significant 
    incentives to exercise its market power. Such debates concerning 
    interpretation mean that at a minimum, in order to enforce the Final 
    Judgment the DOJ will have to put itself in a significant oversight 
    position to ensure consistency of interpretation and compliance. The 
    need for such continuing regulatory activity by the antitrust authority 
    would have been eliminated had the Final Judgment imposed a structural 
    solution to the market power problem.
    
     Financial Markets
    
        29. It is apparent from the proposed Final Judgement that the DOJ 
    fails to recognize that financial market contracts (derivatives such as 
    forwards, futures, and options) which the Merged Entity may acquire 
    could also provide it with incentives to act anti-competitively.\9\ In 
    fact, financial contracts can be used to essentially recreate the same 
    financial position one would have by virtue of power plant ownership. 
    For example, holding a one-year call option for 1,000 MW is financially 
    akin to a year's ownership of a 1,000 MW power plant with variable cost 
    equal to the ``strike price'' of the call (the contract price paid for 
    power if the option is exercised. Such financial market contracts are, 
    in effect, ``virtual generation assets.'' \10\ The equivalence between 
    financial and physical assets is such that it is now common for 
    electric industry planners to treat power plant ownership as equivalent 
    to holding a series of call options and/or forward contracts to serve 
    future spot markets for power.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \9\ A forward contract for power is simply a non-stardized 
    bilateral contact for future delivery at a pre-specified price. 
    Futures are standardized forward contracts traded on an organized 
    exchange, such as the California-Oregon Border (COB) and Palo Verde 
    (PV) electricity futures contracts which are traded on the New York 
    Mercantile Exchange (NYMEX) and which are accessible to the 
    California market. Options contracts are also derivatives that 
    include additional flexibility for either the buyer or seller. For 
    example, a call option, a common type of derivative, gives the buyer 
    the right but not he obligation to purchase power in the future at a 
    specified price.
        \10\ Financial contracts can foster even more anti-competitive 
    creativity than power plant ownership, because they are far more 
    flexible. For instance, while it is difficult to change one's 
    ownership of generating capacity, it is simple to contract for power 
    in varying amounts over differing time horizons (a year, a month, a 
    week, a day), and to change one's position quickly and frequently. 
    This would allow the Merged Entity to tailor its electricity market 
    position to make it most advantageous.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        30. Consequently, to the extent power plant ownership creates anti-
    competitive incentives, so would an equivalent bundle of forward or 
    derivative contracts. While the Final Judgment does attempt to restrict 
    the future acquisition of existing generating capacity in order to 
    prevent anti-competitive behavior, it fails to restrict financial 
    market participation, which creates the same incentives to abuse market 
    power.
    
    Conclusion
    
        31. In its Complaint in this matter, the DOJ found that the 
    proposed merger of Pacific Enterprises and Enova results in the 
    creation of an entity that has the ability and incentive to harm 
    competition in the market for wholesale electric power in California. 
    The proposed Final Judgment, however, fails to rectify the problem 
    because it preserves the ability of the Merged Entity to harm 
    competition while imposing remedies that fail to eliminate the 
    incentives. In particular, the Final Judgment fails entirely to deal 
    with the incentives which the Merged Entity could create through 
    ownership of new or repowered generation or contracting for power via 
    tolling agreements, management contracts or financial contracts. The 
    CIS provides no justification for distinguishing between the 
    acquisition of physical assets and financial assets in creating anti-
    competitive incentives. The limited restrictions that the proposed 
    Final Judgment does place on the future activities of the Merged Entity 
    in the areas of new capacity, tolling and energy management contracts 
    will not eliminate or even substantially curb the Merged Entity's 
    incentives to harm competition.
        32. The proposed Final Judgment does not remedy the serious 
    competitive problem identified by the DOJ in its Complaint.
    
    Attachment A--Paul R. Carpenter, Principal
    
        Dr. Carpenter holds a Ph.D. in applied economics and an M.S. in 
    management from the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, and a 
    B.A. in economics from Stanford University. He specializes in the 
    economics of the natural gas, oil and electric utility
    
    [[Page 3567]]
    
    industries. Dr. Carpenter was a co-founder of Incentives Research, 
    Inc. in 1983. Prior to that he was employed by the NASA/Caltech Jet 
    Propulsion Laboratory and Putnam, Hayes & Bartlett, and he was a 
    post-doctoral fellow at the MIT Center for Energy Policy Research. 
    He is currently a Principal of The Brattle Group.
    
    Areas of Expertise
    
        Dr. Carpenter's areas of expertise include the fields of energy 
    economics, regulation, corporate planning, pricing policy, and 
    antitrust. His recent engagements have involved:
         Natural Gas and Electric Utility Industries: consulting 
    and testimony on nearly all of the economic and regulatory issues 
    surrounding the transition of the natural gas and electric power 
    industries from strict regulation to greater competition. These 
    issues have included stranded investments and contracts, design and 
    pricing of unbundled and ancillary services, evaluation of supply, 
    demand and price forecasting models, the competitive effects of 
    pipeline expansions and performance-based ratemaking. He has 
    consulted on the regulatory and competitive structures of the gas 
    and electric power industries in the U.S., Canada, the United 
    Kingdom, Australia and New Zealand.
         Antiturst: expert testimony in several of the seminal 
    cases involving the alleged denial of access to regulated 
    facilities; analysis of relevant market and market power issues, 
    business justification defenses, and damages.
         Regulation: studies and consultation on alternative 
    rate making methodologies for oil and gas pipelines, on ``bypass'' 
    of regulated facilities before the U.S. Congress; advice and 
    testimony before several state utility commissions and the National 
    Energy Board of Canada on new facility certification policy.
         Finance: research on business and financial risks in 
    the regulated industries and testimony on risk, cost of capital, and 
    capital structure for natural gas pipeline companies in the U.S. and 
    Canada.
    
    Professional Affiliations
    
    International Association of Energy Economists
    American Bar Association (Antitrust Section)
    American Economic Association.
    
    Academic Honors and Fellowships
    
    Stewart Fellowship, 1983
    MIT Fellowships, 1981, 1982, 1983
    Brooks Master's Thesis Prize (Runner-up), MIT, 1978.
    
    Publications
    
    ``Pipeline Pricing to Encourage Efficient Capacity Editions,'' (with 
    Frank C. Graves and Matthew P. O'Loughlin), prepared for Columbia 
    Gas Transmission Corporation and Columbia Gulf Transmission Company, 
    February 1998.
    ``The Outlook for Imported Natural Gas,'' (with Matthew P. 
    O'Loughlin and Gao-Wen Shao), prepared for The INGAA Foundation, 
    Inc., July 1997.
    ``Basic and Enhanced Services for Recourse and Negotiated Rates in 
    the Natural Gas Pipeline Industry'' (with Frank C. Graves, Carlos 
    Lapuerta, and Matthew P. O'Loughlin), May 29, 1996, prepared for 
    Columbia Gas Transmission Corporation, Columbia Gulf Transmission 
    Company.
    ``Estimating the Social Costs of PUHCA Regulation'' (with Frank C. 
    Graves), submitted on behalf of Central and South West Corp. to the 
    U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission in its Request for Comments 
    on the Modernization of Regulation of Public Utility Holding 
    Companies, File No. S7-32-94, February 6, 1995.
    ``Review of the Model Developer's Report, Natural Gas Transmission 
    and Distribution Model (NGTDM) of the National Energy Modeling 
    System'', December 1994, prepared for U.S. Department of Energy, 
    Energy Information Administration and Oak Ridge National Laboratory 
    under Subcontract No. 80X-SL220V.
    ``Pricing of Electricity Network Services to Preserve Network 
    Security and Quality of Frequency Under Transmission Access'' (with 
    Frank C. Graves, Marija Ilic, and Asef Zobian), response to the 
    Federal Energy Regulatory Commission's Request for Comments in its 
    Notice of Technical Conference Docket No. RM93-19-000, November 
    1993.
    ``Creating a Secondary Market in Natural Gas Pipeline Capacity 
    Rights Under FERC Order No. 636'' (with Frank C. Graves), draft 
    December 1992, Incentives Research, Inc.
    ``Review of the Component Design Report, Natural Gas Annual Flow 
    Module, National Energy Modeling System,'' August 1992, prepared for 
    the U.S. Department of Energy, Energy Information Administration.
    ``Unbundling, Pricing, and Comparability of Service on Natural Gas 
    Pipeline Networks'' (with Frank C. Graves), November 1991, prepared 
    for the Interstate Natural Gas Association of America.
    ``Review of the Gas Analysis Modeling System (GAMS): Final Report of 
    Findings and Recommendations,'' August, 1991, prepared for the U.S. 
    Dept. of Energy, Energy Information Administration.
    ``Estimating the Cost of Switching Rights on Natural Gas Pipelines'' 
    (with F.C. Graves and J.A. Read), The Energy Journal, October 1989.
    ``Demand-Charge GICs Differ from Deficiency-Charge GICs'' (with F.C. 
    Graves), Natural Gas, Vol. 6, No. 1, August 1989.
    ``What Price Unbundling?'' (with F.C. Graves), Natural Gas, Vol. 5 
    No. 10, May 1989.
    Book Review of Drawing the line on Natural Gas Regulation: The 
    Harvard Study on the Future of Natural Gas, Joseph Kalt and Frank 
    Schuller eds., in The Energy Journal, April 1988.
    ``Adapting to Change in Natural Gas Markets'' (with Henry D. Jacoby 
    and Arthur W. Wright), in Energy, Markets and Regulation: What Have 
    We Learned?, Cambridge: MIT Press, 1987.
    Evaluation of the Commercial Potential in Earth and Ocean 
    Observation Missions from the Space Station Polar Platform, Prepared 
    by Incentives Research for the NASA Jet Propulsion Laboratory under 
    Contract No. 957324, May 1986.
    An Economic Comparison of Alternative Methods of Regulating Oil 
    Pipelines (with Gerald A. Taylor), Prepared by Incentives Research 
    for the U.S. Department of Energy, Office of Competition, July 1985.
    ``The Natural Gas Policy Drama: A Tragedy in Three Acts'' (with 
    Arthur W. Wright), MIT Center for Energy Policy Research Working 
    Paper No. 84-012WP, October 1984.
    Oil Pipeline Rates and Profitability under Williams Opinion 154 
    (with Gerald A. Taylor), Prepared by Incentives Research for the 
    U.S. Department of Energy, Office of Competition, September 1984.
    Natural Gas Pipelines After Field Price Decontrol: A Study of Risk, 
    Return and Regulation, Ph.D. Dissertation, Massachusetts Institute 
    of Technology, March 1984. Published as a Report to the U.S.
    Department of Energy, Office of Oil and Gas Policy, MIT Center for 
    Energy Policy Research Technical Report No. 84-004.
    The Competitive Origins and Economic Benefits of Kern River Gas 
    Transmission, Prepared by Incentives Research, Inc., for Kern River 
    Gas Transmission Company, February 1994.
    ``Field Price Decontrol of Natural Gas, Pipeline Risk and Regulatory 
    Policy,'' in Government and Energy Policy Richard L. Itteilag, ed., 
    Washington, D.C., June 1983.
    ``Risk Allocation and Institutional Arrangements in Natural Gas'' 
    (with Arthur W. Wright), invited paper presented to the American 
    Economic Association Meetings, San Francisco, December 1983.
    ``Vertical Market Arrangements, Risk-shifting and Natural Gas 
    Pipeline Regulations,'' Sloan School of Management Working Paper no. 
    1369-82, September 1982 (Revised April 1983).
    Natural Gas Pipeline Regulation After Field Price Decontrol (with 
    Henry Dr. Jacoby and Arthur W. Wright), prepared for U.S. Department 
    of Energy, Office of Oil and Gas Policy, MIT Energy Lab Report No. 
    83-013, March 1983.
    Book Review of An Economic Analysis of World Energy Problems, by 
    Richard L. Gordon, Sloan Management Review, Spring 1982.
    ``Perspectives on the Government Role in New Technology Development 
    and Diffusion'' (with Drew Bottaro), MIT Energy Lab Report No. 81-
    041, November 1981.
    
    [[Page 3568]]
    
    International Plan for Photovoltaic Power Systems (co-author), Solar 
    Energy Research Institute with the Jet Propulsion Laboratory 
    Prepared for the U.S. Department of Energy, August 1979.
    Federal Policies for the Widespread Use of Photovoltaic Power 
    Systems (contributor), Jet Propulsion Laboratory Report to the U.S. 
    Congress DOE/CS-0114, March 24, 1980.
    ``An Economic Analysis of Residential, Grid-connected Solar 
    Photovoltaic Power Systems'' (with Gerald A. Taylor), MIT Energy 
    Laboratory Technical Report No. 78-007, May 1978.
    
    Speeches/Presentations
    
    ``Opening Remarks from the Chair: Rates, Regulations and Operational 
    Realities in the Capacity Market of the Future,'' AIC conference on 
    ``Gas Pipeline Capacity `97,'' Houston, Texas June 17, 1997.
    ``Lessons from North America for the British Gas TransCo Pricing 
    Regime,'' prepared for AIC conference on: Gas Transportation and 
    Transmission Pricing, London, England, October 17, 1996.
    ``GICs and the Pricing of Gas Supply Reliability,'' California 
    Energy Commission Conference on Emerging Competition in California 
    Gas Markets, San Diego, Ca. November 9, 1990.
    ``The New Effects of Regulation and Natural Gas Field Markets: Spot 
    Markets, Contracting and Reliability,'' American Economic 
    Association Annual Meeting, New York City, December 29, 1988.
    ``Appropriate Regulation in the Local Marketplace,'' Interregional 
    Natural Gas Symposium, Center for Public Policy, University of 
    Houston, November 30, 1988.
    ``Market Forces, Antitrust, and the Future of Regulation of the Gas 
    Industry,'' Symposium of the Future of Natural Gas Regulation, 
    American Bar Association, Washington D.C., April 21, 1988.
    ``Valuation of Standby Tariffs for Natural Gas Pipelines,'' Workshop 
    on New Methods for Project and Contract Evaluation, MIT Center for 
    Energy Policy Research, Cambridge, March 3, 1988.
    ``Long-term Structure of the Natural Gas Industry,'' National 
    Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners Meeting, Washington 
    D.C., March 1, 1988.
    ``How the U.S. Gas Market Works--or Doesn't Work,'' Ontario Ministry 
    of Energy Symposium on Understanding the United States Natural Gas 
    Market, Toronto, March 18, 1986.
    ``The New U.S. Natural Gas Policy: Implications for the Pipeline 
    Industry,'' Conference on Mergers and Acquisitions in the Gas 
    Pipeline Industry, Executive Enterprises, Houston, February 26-27, 
    1986.
    Various lectures and seminars on U.S. natural gas industry and 
    regulation for graduate energy economics courses at Massachusetts 
    Institute of Technology, 1984-96.
    Panelist in University of Colorado Law School workshop on state 
    regulations of natural gas production, June 1985. (Transcript 
    published in University of Colorado Law Review.) ``Oil Pipeline 
    Rates after the Williams 154 Decision,'' Executive Enterprises, 
    Conference on Oil Pipeline Ratemaking, Houston, June 19-20, 1984.
    ``Issues in the Regulation of Natural Gas Pipelines,'' California 
    Public Utilities Commission Hearings on Natural Gas, San Francisco, 
    May 21, 1984.
    ``The Natural Gas Pipelines in Transition: Evidence From Capital 
    Markets'', Pittsburgh Conference on Modeling and Simulation, 
    Pittsburgh, April 20, 1984.
    ``Financial Aspects of Gas Pipeline Regulation,'' Pittsburgh 
    Conference on Modeling and Simulation, Pittsburgh, April 19-20, 
    1984.
    ``Natural Gas Pipelines After Field Price Decontrol,'' Presentations 
    before Conferences of the International Association of Energy 
    Economists, Washington D.C., June 1983, and Denver, November 1982.
    ``Spot Markets for Natural Gas,'' MIT Center for Energy Policy 
    Research Semi-annual Associates Conference, March 1983.
    ``Pricing Solar Energy Using a System of Planning and Assessment 
    Models,'' Presentations to the XXIV International Conference, The 
    Institute of Management Science, Honolulu, June 20, 1979.
    
    Testimonial Experience
    
    Antitrust/Federal Court/Arbitration
    
    In the matter of the Arbitration between Western Power Corp. and 
    Woodside Petroleum Corp., et al., Perth, Western Australia, May-July 
    1998.
    In the United States District Court for the District of Montana, 
    Butte Division, Paladin Associates, Inc. v. Montana Power Company, 
    November-December 1997.
    In the United States District Court for the District of Colorado, 
    Atlantic Richfield Co. v. Darwin H. Smallwood, Sr., et al., July 
    1997.
    In the Australian Competition Tribunal, Review of the Trade 
    Practices Act Authorizations for the AGL Cooper Basin Natural Gas 
    Supply Arrangements, on behalf of the Australian Competition and 
    Consumer Commission, February 1997.
    In the Southwest Queensland Gas Price Review Arbitration, Adelaide, 
    South Australia, May 1996.
    In the matter of the Arbitration between Amerada Hess Corp. v. 
    Pacific Gas & Electric Co., May 1995.
    In re Columbia Gas Transmission Corp., Claims Quantification 
    Proceeding in the U.S. Bankruptcy Court for the District of 
    Delaware, Before the Claims Mediator, July and November 1993.
    Deposition Testimony in Fina Oil & Gas v. Northwest Pipeline Corp. 
    and Williams Gas Supply (New Mexico) 1992.
    Testimony by Affidavit in James River Corp. v. Northwest Pipeline 
    Corp. (Fed. Ct. for Oregon) 1989.
    Deposition and Testimony by Affidavit in Merrion Oil and Gas Col, et 
    al., v. Northwest Pipeline Corp. (Fed. Ct. for New Mexico) 1989.
    Deposition Testimony in Martin Exploration Management Co., et al. v. 
    Panhandle Eastern Pipeline Co. (Fed. Ct. for Colorado) 1988 and 
    1992.
    Trial Testimony in City of Chanute, et al. v. Williams Natural Gas 
    (Fed. Ct. for Kansas) 1988.
    Deposition Testimony in Sinclair Oil Co. v. Northwest Pipeline Co. 
    (Fed. Ct. for Wyoming) 1987.
    Deposition and Trial Testimony in State of Illinois v. Panhandle 
    Eastern Pipeline Co. (Fed. Ct. for C.D. Ill) 1984-87.
    
    Economic/Regulatory Testimony
    
    Before the National Energy Board of Canada, Application of Alliance 
    Pipeline Ltd., Hearing Order GH-3-97, December 1997, April 1998.
    Before the California Public Utilities Commission, Pacific 
    Enterprises, Enova Corporation, et al. Merger Proceedings, Docket 
    A.96-10-038, on behalf of Southern California Edison, August 1997.
    In the Superior Court of the State of California for the County of 
    Los Angeles, Pacific Pipeline System Inc. v. City of Los Angeles, on 
    behalf of Pacific Pipeline System Inc., January 1997.
    Before the U.K. Monopolies and Mergers Commission, British Gas 
    Transportation and Storage Price Control Review, on behalf of Enron 
    Capital and Trade Resources Limited, January 1997.
    Northern Border Pipeline Company, Federal Energy Regulatory 
    Commission (FERC) Docket No. RP96-45-000, July 1996.
    Wisconsin Electric Power Co., Northern States Power Co. Merger 
    Proceedings. FERC Docket No. EC 95-16-000, on behalf of Madison Gas 
    & Electric Co., Wisconsin Citizens Utility Board and the Wisconsin 
    Electric Cooperative Association, May 1996.
    Before the California Public Utilities Commission, Application of 
    PG&E for Amortization of Interstate Transition Cost Surcharge, 
    Application 94-06-044, on behalf of El Paso Natural Gas, December 
    1995.
    Tennessee Gas Pipeline Company, FERC Docket No. RP95-112-000, on 
    behalf of JMC Power Projects, September 1995.
    Before the National Energy Board of Canada, Drawdown of Balance of 
    Deferred Income Taxes Proceeding, RH-1-95, on behalf of Foothills 
    Pipe Lines Ltd., September 1995.
    Pacific Gas Transmission, FERC Docket No. RP94-149-000, on behalf of 
    El Paso Natural Gas, May 1995.
    Before the California Public Utilities Commission, Application of 
    Pacific Pipeline System, Inc., A.91-10-013, on behalf of PPSI, April 
    1995.
    Before the National Energy Board of Canada, Multipipeline Cost of 
    Capital Proceeding, RH-2-94, on behalf of Foothills Pipe Lines Ltd., 
    November 1994.
    
    [[Page 3569]]
    
    Before the California Public Utilities Commission, Pacific Gas & 
    Electric 1992 Operations Reasonableness Review, Application 93-04-
    011, on behalf of El Paso Natural Gas, November 1994.
    Before the National Energy Board of Canada, Foothills Pipe Lines 
    (Alta.) Ltd., Wild Horse Pipeline Project, Order No. GH-4-94, 
    October 1994.
    Iroquois Gas Transmission System, L.P., FERC Docket No. RP94-72-000, 
    on behalf of Masspower and Selkirk Cogen Partners, September 1994.
    Tennessee Gas Pipeline Co., FERC Docket No. RP91-203-000, on behalf 
    of JMC Power Projects and New England Power Company, February, May 
    1994.
    Before the California Public Utilities Commission, on the 
    Application of Pacific Gas & Electric Company to Establish Interim 
    Rates for the PG&E Expansion Project, July 1993.
    Before the Florida Public Service Commission, Petition of Florida 
    Power Corporation for Order Authorizing A Return on Equity for 
    Florida Power's Investment in the SunShine Intrastate and the 
    SunShine Interstate Pipelines, FPSC Docket No. 930281-EI, June 4, 
    1993.
    Before the Florida Public Service Commission, Application for 
    Determination of Need for an Intrastate Natural Gas Pipeline by 
    SunShine Pipeline Partners, FPSC Docket No. 920807-GP, April-May 
    1993.
    Northwest Pipeline Corp., et al., FERC Docket No. IN90-1-001, 
    February 1993.
    City of Long Beach, Calif., vs. Unocal California Pipeline Co., 
    before the California Public Utilities Commission, Case No. 91-12-
    028, February 1993.
    Alberta Energy Resources Conservation Board, on Applications of NOVA 
    Corporation of Canada to Construct Facilities, January 1993.
    Before the California Public Utilities Commission, on the 
    Application of Pacific Gas & Electric Co. to guarantee certain 
    financing arrangements of Pacific Gas Transmission Co. not to exceed 
    $751 million, 1992.
    Mississippi River Transmission Co., FERC Docket No. RP93-4-000, 
    October 1992, September 1993.
    Unocal California Pipeline Co., FERC Docket No. IS92-18-000, August 
    1992.
    Before the California Public Utilities Commission, in the Rulemaking 
    into natural gas procurement and system reliability issues, R.88-08-
    018, June 1992.
    Alberta Energy Resources Conservation Board, Altamont & PGT Pipeline 
    Projects, Proceeding 911586, March 1992.
    Before the California Utilities Commission, on the Application of 
    Southern California Gas Company for approval of capital investment 
    in facilities to permit interconnection with the Kern River/Mojave 
    pipeline, A.90-11-035, May 1992.
    Northern Natural Gas, FERC Docket No. RP92-1-000, October 1991.
    Florida Gas Transmission, FERC Docket No. RP91-1-187-000 and CP91-
    2448-000, July 1991.
    Tarpon Transmission, FERC Docket No. RP84-82-004, January 1991.
    Before the California Public Utilities Commission, on the 
    Application of Pacific Gas & Electric Co. to Expand its Natural Gas 
    Pipeline System, A. 89-04-033, May 1990 and October 1991.
    CNG Transmission, FERC Docket No. RP88-211, March 1990.
    Panhandle Eastern Pipeline, FERC Docket No. RP88-262, March 1990.
    Mississippi River Transmission, FERC Docket No. RP89-249, October 
    1989, September 1990.
    Tennessee Gas Pipeline, FERC Docket No. CP89-470, June 1989.
    Empire State Pipeline, Case No. 88-T-132 before the New York Public 
    Service Commission, May 1989.
    Before the U.S. Congress, House of Representatives, Committee on 
    Energy and Commerce, Subcommittee on Energy and Power, Hearings on 
    ``Bypass'' Legislation, May 1988.
    Tennessee Gas Pipeline, FERC Docket No. RP86-119, 1986-87.
    Mojave Pipeline Co., FERC Docket No. CP85-437, 1987-88.
    Consolidated Gas Transmission Corp., FERC Docket No. RP88-10, 1988.
    Panhandle Eastern, FERC Docket No. RP85-194, 1985.
    On behalf of the Natural Gas Supply Association in FERC Rulemaking 
    Docket No. RM85-1, 1985-86.
    On behalf of the Panhandle Eastern Pipeline Co. in FERC Rulemaking 
    Docket No. RM85-1, 1985.
    
    BILLING CODE 7515-01--P
    
    [[Page 3570]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN22JA99.002
    
    
    
    BILLING CODE 4410-11-C
    
    [[Page 3571]]
    
    Attachment B--1996 WSCC Electric Supply Curve (Notes and Sources)
    
    Sources
    
        Electric Supply and Demand Database (NERC); RDI 1996 Fuel Price 
    Forecast.
    
    Notes
    
        For graphical clarity, units with dispatch cost above $60/MWh 
    are excluded (30 oil-fired turbines, 740 MW total capacity). 
    Nameplate capacity has been derated to reflect approximate average 
    annual availability; hydro derated to reflect available energy.
        The WSCC is the electric reliability council consisting of 11 
    western states and portions of Canada and Mexico; it contains 
    162,000 MW of generating capacity from over 1,400 generating units.
        The annual average WSCC load is approximately 82,000 MW, and one 
    standard deviation of coincident load is approximately 11,500 MW, so 
    a one-standard deviation band around average load encompasses the 
    range from 70,500 MW to 93,500 MW. Actual values fall within one 
    standard-deviation of the average approximately two-thirds of the 
    time.
        Note that this is an ``average annual'' supply curve, in that 
    nameplace capacity of units has been derated to reflect average 
    annual availability (annual energy limits for hydro). Some care must 
    be taken in interpreting this curve, because at any particular point 
    in time, the actual supply curve will differ somewhat, depending on 
    which particular units are actually available at that time. However, 
    it clearly demonstrates that gas, and particularly California gas, 
    is the dominant fuel of the price-setting marginal units in the 
    entire WSCC. Of course, the effect of California gas-fired capacity 
    on just the California market is even greater.
    
    Affidavit of Paul R. Carpenter, Ph.D.
    
    Commonwealth of Massachusetts, County of Middlesex
    ss
    
        I, Paul R. Carpenter, being first duly sworn on oath depose and 
    say as follows:
        I make this affidavit for the purpose of adopting as my sworn 
    testimony in this proceeding the attached material entitled 
    ``Affidavit of Paul R. Carpenter, Ph.D.'' The statements contained 
    therein were prepared by me or under my direction and are true and 
    correct to the best of my knowledge, information, and belief.
        Further affiant saith not.
    Paul R. Carpenter
    
        Subscribed and sworn to before me, a notary public in and for 
    the Commonwealth of Massachusetts, County of Middlesex, this 4th day 
    of August, 1998.
    [SIGNATURE ILLEGIBLE].
    
    [FR Doc. 99-1393 Filed 1-21-99; 8:45 am]
    BILLING CODE 4410-11-M
    
    
    

Document Information

Published:
01/22/1999
Department:
Antitrust Division
Entry Type:
Notice
Document Number:
99-1393
Pages:
3551-3571 (21 pages)
PDF File:
99-1393.pdf