00-2. Regional Transmission Organizations  

  • [Federal Register Volume 65, Number 4 (Thursday, January 6, 2000)]
    [Rules and Regulations]
    [Pages 810-959]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 00-2]
    
    
    
    [[Page 809]]
    
    
    
    Part II
    
    
    
    
    
    Department of Energy
    
    
    
    
    
    _______________________________________________________________________
    
    
    
    18 CFR Part 35
    
    
    
    Regional Transmission Organizations; Final Rule
    
    Federal Register / Vol. 65, No. 4 / Thursday, January 6, 2000 / Rules 
    and Regulations
    
    [[Page 810]]
    
    
    
    DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
    
    Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
    
    18 CFR Part 35
    
    [Docket No. RM99-2-000; Order No. 2000]
    
    
    Regional Transmission Organizations
    
    Issued December 20, 1999.
    AGENCY: Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
    
    ACTION: Final Rule.
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    SUMMARY: The Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (Commission) is 
    amending its regulations under the Federal Power Act (FPA) to advance 
    the formation of Regional Transmission Organizations (RTOs). The 
    regulations require that each public utility that owns, operates, or 
    controls facilities for the transmission of electric energy in 
    interstate commerce make certain filings with respect to forming and 
    participating in an RTO. The Commission also codifies minimum 
    characteristics and functions that a transmission entity must satisfy 
    in order to be considered an RTO. The Commission's goal is to promote 
    efficiency in wholesale electricity markets and to ensure that 
    electricity consumers pay the lowest price possible for reliable 
    service.
    
    EFFECTIVE DATE: This Final Rule will become effective March 6, 2000.
    
    FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
    
    Alan Haymes (Technical Information), Federal Energy Regulatory 
    Commission, 888 First Street, NE, Washington, DC 20426, (202) 219-2919.
    Brian R. Gish (Legal Information), Federal Energy Regulatory 
    Commission, 888 First Street, NE, Washington, DC 20426, (202) 208-0996.
    James Apperson (Collaborative Process), Federal Energy Regulatory 
    Commission, 888 First Street, NE, Washington, DC 20426, (202) 219-2962.
    
    SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: In addition to publishing the full text of 
    this document in the Federal Register, the Commission provides all 
    interested persons an opportunity to view and/or print the contents of 
    this document via the Internet through FERC's Home Page (http://
    www.ferc.fed.us) and in FERC's Public Reference Room during normal 
    business hours (8:30 a.m. to 5:00 p.m. Eastern time) at 888 First 
    Street, NE, Room 2A, Washington, DC 20426.
        From FERC's Home Page on the Internet, this information is 
    available in both the Commission Issuance Posting System (CIPS) and the 
    Records and Information Management System (RIMS).
    
    --CIPS provides access to the texts of formal documents issued by the 
    Commission since November 14, 1994.
    --CIPS can be access using the CIPS link or the Energy Information 
    Online icon. The full text of this document will be available on CIPS 
    in ASCII and WordPerfect 8.0 format for viewing, printing, and/or 
    downloading.
    --RIMS contains images of documents submitted to and issued by the 
    Commission after November 16, 1981. Documents from November 1995 to the 
    present can be viewed and printed from FERC's Home Page using the RIMS 
    link or the Energy Information Online icon. Descriptions of documents 
    back to November 16, 1981, are also available from RIMS-on-the-Web; 
    requests for copies of these and other older documents should be 
    submitted to the Public Reference Room.
    
        User assistance is available for RIMS, CIPS, and the Website during 
    normal business hours from our Help line at (202) 208-2222 (E-Mail to 
    WebMaster@ferc.fed.us) or the Public Reference at (202) 208-1371 (E-
    Mail to public.referenceroom@ferc.fed.us).
        During normal business hours, documents can also be viewed and/or 
    printed in FERC's Public Reference Room, where RIMS, CIPS, and the FERC 
    Website are available. User assistance is also available.
    
    Table of Contents
    
    I. Introduction and Summary
    II. Background
        A. The Foundation for Competitive Markets: Order Nos. 888 and 
    889
        B. Developments Since Order Nos. 888 and 889
        1. Industry Restructuring and New Stresses on the Transmission 
    Grid
        2. Successes, Failures and Haphazard Development of Regional 
    Transmission Entities
        3. The Commission's ISO and RTO Inquires; Conferences with 
    Stakeholders and State Regulators
    III. Discussion
        A. Existence of Barriers and Impediments to Achieving Fully 
    Competitive Electricity Markets
        B. Benefits That RTOs Can Offer to Address Remaining Barriers 
    and Impediments
        C. Commission's Approach to RTO Formation
        1. Voluntary Approach
        2. Organizational Form of an RTO
        3. Degree of Specificity in the Rule
        4. Legal Authority
        D. Minimum Characteristics of an RTO
        1. Independence (Characteristic 1)
        2. Scope and Regional Configuration (Characteristic 2)
        3. Operational Authority (Characteristic 3)
        4. Short-Term Reliability (Characteristic 4)
        E. Minimum Functions of an RTO
        1. Tariff Administration and Design (Function 1)
        2. Congestion Management (Function 2)
        3. Parallel Path Flow (Function 3)
        4. Ancillary Services (Function 4)
        5. OASIS and Total Transmission Capability (TTC) and Available 
    Transmission Capability (ATC) (Function 5)
        6. Market Monitoring (Function 6)
        7. Planning and Expansion (Function 7)
        8. Interregional Coordination (Function 8)
        F. Open Architecture
        G. Transmission Ratemaking Policy for RTOs
        1. Pancaked Rates
        2. Reciprocal Waiving of Access Charges Between RTOs
        3. Uniform Access Charges
        4. Congestion Pricing
        5. Service to Transmission-Owning Utilities That Do Not 
    Participate in an RTO
        6. Performance-Based Rate Regulation
        7. Other RTO Transmission Ratemaking Reforms
        8. Additional Ratemaking Issues
        9. Filing Procedures for Innovative Rate Proposals
        H. Other Issues
        1. Public Power and Cooperative Participation in RTOs
        2. Participation by Canadian and Mexican Entities
        3. Existing Transmission Contracts
        4. Power Exchanges (PXs)
        5. Effect on Retail Markets and Retail Access
        6. Effect on States with Low Cost Generation
        7. States' Roles with Regard to RTOs
        8. Accounting Issues
        9. Market Design Lessons
        I. Collaborative Process
        J. Implementation Issues
        1. Filing Requirements
        2. Deadline for RTO Operation
        3. Commission Processing Procedures
        4. Other Implementation Issues
        IV. Environmental Statement
        V. Regulatory Flexibility Act Certification
        VI. Public Reporting Burden and Information Collection Statement
        VII. Effective Date and Congressional Notification
        VIII. Document Availability
    Regulatory Text
    Appendix
    
    Before Commissioners: James J. Hoecker, Chairman; William L. Massey, 
    Linda Breathitt, and Curt Hebert, Jr.
    
    I. Introduction and Summary
    
        In 1996 the Commission put in place the foundation necessary for 
    competitive wholesale power markets in this country--open access
    
    [[Page 811]]
    
    transmission. 1 Since that time, the industry has undergone 
    sweeping restructuring activity, including a movement by many states to 
    develop retail competition, the growing divestiture of generation 
    plants by traditional electric utilities, a significant increase in the 
    number of mergers among traditional electric utilities and among 
    electric utilities and gas pipeline companies, large increases in the 
    number of power marketers and independent generation facility 
    developers entering the marketplace, and the establishment of 
    independent system operators (ISOs) as managers of large parts of the 
    transmission system. Trade in bulk power markets has continued to 
    increase significantly and the Nation's transmission grid is being used 
    more heavily and in new ways.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \1\ See Promoting Wholesale Competition Through Open Access Non-
    discriminatory Transmission Services by Public Utilities and 
    Recovery of Stranded Costs by Public Utilities and Transmitting 
    Utilities, Order No. 888, 61 FR 21,540 (May 10, 1996), FERC Stats. & 
    Regs. para. 31,036 (1996) (Order No. 888), order on reh'g, Order No. 
    888-A, 62 FR 12,274 (March 14, 1997), FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 
    31,048 (1997) (Order No. 888-A), order on reh'g, Order No. 888-B, 81 
    FERC para. 61,248 (1997), order on reh'g, Order No. 888-C, 82 FERC 
    para. 61,046 (1998), appeal docketed, Transmission Access Policy 
    Study Group, et al.  v. FERC, Nos. 97-1715 et al. (D.C. Cir.).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        On May 13, 1999, the Commission proposed a rule on Regional 
    Transmission Organizations (RTOs) that identified and discussed our 
    concerns with the traditional means of grid management.2 In 
    that Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (NOPR), the Commission reviewed 
    evidence that traditional management of the transmission grid by 
    vertically integrated electric utilities was inadequate to support the 
    efficient and reliable operation that is needed for the continued 
    development of competitive electricity markets, and that continued 
    discrimination in the provision of transmission services by vertically 
    integrated utilities may also be impeding fully competitive electricity 
    markets. These problems may be depriving the Nation of the benefits of 
    lower prices and enhanced reliability. The comments on the NOPR 
    overwhelmingly support the conclusion that independent regionally 
    operated transmissions grids will enhance the benefits of competitive 
    electricity markets. Competition in wholesale electricity markets is 
    the best way to protect the public interest and ensure that electricity 
    consumers pay the lowest price possible for reliable service.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \2\ Regional Transmission Organizations, Notice of Proposed 
    Rulemaking, 64 FR 31,390 (June 10, 1999), FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 
    32,541 at 33,683-781 (1999).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Regional institutions can address the operational and reliability 
    issues now confronting the industry, and eliminate any residual 
    discrimination in transmission services that can occur when the 
    operation of the transmission system remains in the control of a 
    vertically integrated utility. Appropriate regional transmission 
    institutions could: (1) Improve efficiencies in transmission grid 
    management; 3 (2) improve grid reliability; (3) remove 
    remaining opportunities for discriminatory transmission practices; (4) 
    improve market performance; and (5) facilitate lighter handed 
    regulation.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \3\ As discussed more fully later, appropriate regional 
    institutions could improve efficiencies in grid management through 
    improved pricing, congestion management, more accurate estimates of 
    Available Transmission Capability, improved parallel path flow 
    management, more efficient planning, and increased coordination 
    between regulatory agencies.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Thus, we believe that appropriate RTOs could successfully address 
    the existing impediments to efficient grid operation and competition 
    and could consequently benefit consumers through lower electricity 
    rates resulting from a wider choice of services and service providers. 
    In addition, substantial cost savings are likely to result from the 
    formation of RTOs.
        Based on careful consideration of the thoughtful comments submitted 
    in response to the NOPR,4 the Commission adopts a final rule 
    that generally follows the approach of the NOPR. Our objective is for 
    all transmission-owning entities in the Nation, including non-public 
    utility entities, to place their transmission facilities under the 
    control of appropriate RTOs in a timely manner. Therefore, we are 
    establishing in this rule minimum characteristics and functions for 
    appropriate RTOs; a collaborative process by which public utilities and 
    non-public utilities that own, operate or control interstate 
    transmission facilities, in consultation with state officials as 
    appropriate, will consider and develop RTOs; a proposal to consider 
    transmission ratemaking reforms on a case-specific basis; an 
    opportunity for non-monetary regulatory benefits, such as deference in 
    dispute resolution and streamlined filing and approval procedures; and 
    a time line for public utilities to make appropriate filings with the 
    Commission to initiate operation of RTOs. As a result of this voluntary 
    approach, we expect jurisdictional utilities to form RTOs. If the 
    industry fails to form RTOs under this approach, the Commission will 
    reconsider what further regulatory steps are in the public interest.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \4\ The Commission received 334 initial and reply comments in 
    response to the NOPR. The commenters, and abbreviations for them as 
    used herein, are listed in an Appendix to this Final Rule.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Pursuant to our authority under section 205 of the Federal Power 
    Act (FPA) to ensure that rates, terms and conditions of transmission 
    and sales for resale in interstate commerce by public utilities are 
    just, reasonable and not unduly discriminatory or preferential, and our 
    authority under section 202(a) of the FPA to promote and encourage 
    regional districts for the voluntary interconnection and coordination 
    of transmission facilities by public utilities and non-public utilities 
    for the purpose of assuring an abundant supply of electric energy 
    throughout the United States with the greatest possible economy, this 
    rule requires the following.
        First, the Commission establishes minimum characteristics and 
    functions that an RTO must satisfy in the following areas:
    
    Minimum Characteristics:
        1. Independence
        2. Scope and Regional Configuration
        3. Operational Authority
        4. Short-term Reliability
    Minimum Functions:
        1. Tariff Administration and Design
        2. Congestion Management
        3. Parallel Path Flow
        4. Ancillary Services
        5. OASIS and Total Transmission Capability (TTC) and Available 
    Transmission Capability (ATC)
        6. Market Monitoring
        7. Planning and Expansion
        8. Interregional Coordination
    
    Industry participants, however, retain flexibility in structuring RTOs 
    that satisfy the minimum characteristics and functions. For example, we 
    do not propose to require or prohibit any one form of organization for 
    RTOs or require or prohibit RTO ownership of transmission facilities. 
    The characteristics and functions could be satisfied by different 
    organizational forms, such as ISOs, transcos, combinations of the two, 
    or even new organizational forms not yet discussed in the industry or 
    proposed to the Commission. Likewise, the Commission is not proposing a 
    ``cookie cutter'' organizational format for regional transmission 
    institutions or the establishment of fixed or specific regional 
    boundaries under section 202(a) of the FPA.
        We also establish an ``open architecture'' policy regarding RTOs, 
    whereby all RTO proposals must allow the RTO and its members the 
    flexibility to improve their organizations in the
    
    [[Page 812]]
    
    future in terms of structure, operations, market support and geographic 
    scope to meet market needs. In turn, the Commission will provide the 
    regulatory flexibility to accommodate such improvement.
        Second, to facilitate RTO formation in all regions of the Nation, 
    the Commission will sponsor and support a collaborative process to take 
    place in the Spring of 2000. Under this process, we expect that public 
    utilities and non-public utilities, in coordination with state 
    officials, Commission staff, and all affected interest groups, will 
    actively work toward the voluntary development of RTOs.
        Third, we provide guidance on flexible transmission ratemaking that 
    may be proposed by RTOs, including ratemaking treatments that will 
    address congestion pricing and performance-based regulation. We also 
    propose to consider on a case-by-case basis incentive pricing that may 
    be appropriate for transmission facilities under RTO control.
        Finally, all public utilities (with the exception of those 
    participating in an approved regional transmission entity that conforms 
    to the Commission's ISO principles) that own, operate or control 
    interstate transmission facilities must file with the Commission by 
    October 15, 2000, a proposal for an RTO with the minimum 
    characteristics and functions to be operational by December 15, 
    2001,5 or, alternatively, a description of efforts to 
    participate in an RTO, any existing obstacles to RTO participation, and 
    any plans to work toward RTO participation. We expect that such 
    proposals would include the transmission facilities of public utilities 
    as well as transmission facilities of public power and other non-public 
    utility entities to the extent possible. Through the required filings, 
    public utilities will make known to the public any plans for RTO 
    participation and any obstacles to RTO formation.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \5\ An RTO proposal includes a basic agreement filed under 
    section 205 of the FPA setting out the rules, practices and 
    procedures under which the RTO will be governed and operated, and 
    requests by the public utility members of the RTO under section 203 
    of the FPA to transfer control of their jurisdictional transmission 
    facilities from individual public utilities to the RTO. Most RTO 
    proposals by public utilities are likely to involve one or more 
    filings under FPA sections 203 and 205, but the number and types of 
    filing may vary depending upon the type of RTO proposed and the 
    number of public utilities involved in the proposal. Under the Rule, 
    a utility may file a petition for a declaratory order asking, for 
    example, whether a proposed transmission entity would qualify as an 
    RTO or if a new or innovative method for pricing transmission 
    service would be acceptable, to be followed by appropriate filings 
    under sections 203 and 205.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A public utility that is a member of an existing transmission 
    entity that has been approved by the Commission as in conformance with 
    the eleven ISO principles set forth in Order No. 888 must make a filing 
    no later than January 15, 2001. That filing must explain the extent to 
    which the transmission entity in which it participates meets the 
    minimum characteristics and functions for an RTO, and either propose to 
    modify the existing institution to the extent necessary to become an 
    RTO, or explain the efforts, obstacles and plans with respect to 
    conforming to these characteristics and functions.
        The goal of this rulemaking is to form RTOs voluntarily and in a 
    timely manner. The alternative to a voluntary process is likely to be a 
    lengthy process that is more likely to result in greater 
    standardization of the Commission's RTO requirements among regions. 
    Although the Commission has specific authorities and responsibilities 
    under the FPA to protect against undue discrimination and remove 
    impediments to wholesale competition, we find it appropriate in this 
    instance to adopt an open collaborative process that relies on 
    voluntary regional participation to design RTOs that can be tailored to 
    specific needs of each region.
    
    II. Background
    
        In April 1996, in Order Nos. 888 6 and 889,7 
    the Commission established the foundation necessary to develop 
    competitive bulk power markets in the United States: non-discriminatory 
    open access transmission services by public utilities and stranded cost 
    recovery rules that would provide a fair transition to competitive 
    markets. Order Nos. 888 and 889 were very successful in accomplishing 
    much of what they set out to do. However, the orders were not intended 
    to address all problems that might arise in the development of 
    competitive power markets. Indeed, the nature of the emerging markets 
    and the remaining impediments to full competition that became apparent 
    in the nearly four years since the issuance of Order Nos. 888 and 889, 
    and the insightful comments and information presented to us by a wide 
    array of industry participants in this rulemaking proceeding have made 
    clear that the Commission must take further action if we are to achieve 
    the fully competitive power markets envisioned by those orders.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \6\ See supra note 1.
        \7\ Open Access Same-Time Information System (Formerly Real-Time 
    Information Networks) and Standards of Conduct, Order No. 889, 61 FR 
    21,737 (May 10, 1996), FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 31,035 (1996), 
    order on reh'g, Order No. 889-A, 62 FR 12,484 (March 14, 1997), FERC 
    Stats. & Regs. para. 31,049 (1997), order on reh'g, Order No. 889-B, 
    81 FERC para. 61,253 (1997).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    A. The Foundation for Competitive Markets: Order Nos. 888 and 889
    
        In Order Nos. 888 and 889, the Commission found that unduly 
    discriminatory and anticompetitive practices existed in the electric 
    industry, and that transmission-owning utilities had discriminated 
    against others seeking transmission access.8 The Commission 
    stated that its goal was to ensure that customers have the benefits of 
    competitively priced generation, and determined that non-discriminatory 
    open access transmission services (including access to transmission 
    information) and stranded cost recovery were the most critical 
    components of a successful transition to competitive wholesale 
    electricity markets.9
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \8\ Order No. 888, FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 31,036 at 31,682.
        \9\ Id. at 31,652.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Accordingly, Order No. 888 required all public utilities that own, 
    control or operate facilities used for transmitting electric energy in 
    interstate commerce to (1) file open access non-discriminatory 
    transmission tariffs containing, at a minimum, the non-price terms and 
    conditions set forth in the Order, and (2) functionally unbundle 
    wholesale power services. Under functional unbundling, the public 
    utility must: (1) take transmission services under the same tariff of 
    general applicability as do others; (2) state separate rates for 
    wholesale generation, transmission, and ancillary services; and (3) 
    rely on the same electronic information network that its transmission 
    customers rely on to obtain information about its transmission system 
    when buying or selling power.10 Order No. 889 required that 
    all public utilities establish or participate in an Open Access Same-
    Time Information System (OASIS) that meets certain specifications, and 
    comply with standards of conduct designed to prevent employees of a 
    public utility (or any employees of its affiliates) engaged in 
    wholesale power marketing functions from obtaining preferential access 
    to pertinent transmission system information.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \10\ Id. at 31,654-55.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        During the course of the Order No. 888 proceeding, the Commission 
    received comments urging it to require generation divestiture or 
    structural institutional arrangements such as regional independent 
    system operators (ISOs) to better assure non-discrimination. The 
    Commission responded that, while it believed that
    
    [[Page 813]]
    
    ISOs had the potential to provide significant benefits, efforts to 
    remedy undue discrimination should begin by requiring the less 
    intrusive functional unbundling approach. Subsequent to issuance of 
    Order No. 888, it has become apparent that several types of regional 
    transmission institutions, in addition to the kinds of ISOs approved to 
    date, may also be able to provide the benefits attributed to ISOs in 
    Order No. 888.
        Order No. 888 set forth 11 principles for assessing ISO proposals 
    submitted to the Commission.11 Order No. 888 also stated:
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \11\ Order No. 888, FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 31,036 at 31,730.
    
        [W]e see many benefits in ISOs, and encourage utilities to 
    consider ISOs as a tool to meet the demands of the competitive 
    marketplace. As a further precaution against discriminatory 
    behavior, we will continue to monitor electricity markets to ensure 
    that functional unbundling adequately protects transmission 
    customers. At the same time, we will analyze all alternative 
    proposals, including formation of ISOs, and, if it becomes apparent 
    that functional unbundling is inadequate or unworkable in assuring 
    non-discriminatory open access transmission, we will reevaluate our 
    position and decide whether other mechanisms, such as ISOs, should 
    be required.12
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \12\ Id. at 31,655.
    
    Below, we summarize our experiences with functional unbundling from the 
    date of issuance of Order Nos. 888 and 889.
    
    B. Developments Since Order Nos. 888 and 889
    
        In the nearly four years since Order Nos. 888 and 889 were issued, 
    numerous significant developments have occurred in the electric utility 
    industry. Some of these reflect changes in governmental policies; 
    others are strictly industry-driven. These activities have resulted in 
    a considerably different industry landscape from the one faced at the 
    time the Commission was developing Order No. 888, resulting in new 
    regulatory and industry challenges.
        Order Nos. 888 and 889 required a significant change to the way 
    many public utilities have done business for most of this century, and 
    most public utilities accepted these changes and made substantial good 
    faith efforts to comply with the new requirements. Virtually all public 
    utilities have filed tariffs stating rates, terms and conditions for 
    comparable service to third-party users of their transmission systems. 
    In addition, improved information about the transmission system is 
    available to all participants in the market at the same time that it is 
    available to the public utility's merchant function and market 
    affiliate as a result of utility compliance with the OASIS regulations.
        The availability of tariffs and information about the transmission 
    system has fostered a rapid growth in dependence on wholesale markets 
    for acquisition of generation resources. Areas that have experienced 
    generation shortages have seen rapid development of new generation 
    resources. For example, in the Northeast Power Coordinating Council 
    (NPCC) region (including New England, New York and parts of eastern 
    Canada), where there was deep concern about adequacy of generation 
    supply only three years ago, approximately 30,000 MW of generation is 
    proposed or actually under construction.13 That response 
    comes almost entirely from independent generating plants, which are 
    able to sell power into the bulk power market through open access to 
    the transmission system. Power resources are now acquired over 
    increasingly large regional areas, and interregional transfers of 
    electricity have increased. The very success of Order Nos. 888 and 889, 
    and the initiative of some utilities that have pursued voluntary 
    restructuring beyond the minimum open access requirements, have placed 
    new stresses on regional transmission systems--stresses that call for 
    regional solutions.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \13\ Based on data supplied to the Commission by Resource Data 
    International.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    1. Industry Restructuring and New Stresses on the Transmission Grid
        Open access transmission and the opening of wholesale competition 
    in the electric industry have brought an array of changes in the past 
    several years: Divestiture by many integrated utilities of some or all 
    of their generating assets; significantly increased merger activity 
    both between electric utilities and between electric and natural gas 
    utilities; increases in the number of new participants in the industry 
    in the form of both independent and affiliated power marketers and 
    generators as well as independent power exchanges; increases in the 
    volume of trade in the industry, particularly sales by marketers; state 
    efforts to introduce retail competition; and new and different uses of 
    the transmission grid.
        With respect to divestiture, since August 1997, generating 
    facilities representing approximately 50,000 MW of generating capacity 
    have been sold (or are under contract to be sold) by utilities, and an 
    additional 30,000 MW is currently for sale. In total, this represents 
    more than ten percent of U.S. generating capacity. In all, 27 utilities 
    have sold all or some of their generating assets and seven others have 
    assets for sale. Buyers of this generating capacity have included 
    traditional utilities with specified service territories as well as 
    independent power producers with no required service territory.
        Since Order No. 888 was issued, more than 40 applications have been 
    filed for Commission approval of proposed mergers involving public 
    utilities.14 Most of these merger proposals involve electric 
    utilities with contiguous service areas, although some of the proposed 
    mergers have been between utilities with non-contiguous service areas. 
    In addition, an increasing number of applications involve the 
    combination of electric and natural gas assets.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \14\ See Commission's website, www.ferc.fed.us/electric/mergers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        There has been significant growth in the volume of trading, and 
    particularly the number of marketers, in the wholesale electricity 
    market. For example, in the first quarter of 1995, according to power 
    marketer quarterly filings, marketer sales traded by only eight active 
    power marketers, totaled 1.8 million MWh. By the first quarter of 1999, 
    such sales escalated to over 400 million MWh, traded by over 100 power 
    marketers.15
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \15\ See Commission's website, www.ferc.fed.us/electric/PwrMkt. 
    The Commission recognizes that a significant portion of the sales 
    represent the retrading of power by a number of different market 
    participants, such that there may be multiple resales of the same 
    generation. Nonetheless, the volume of and intensity of trading 
    continues to increase in the wholesale electricity market.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission has granted market-based rate authority to more than 
    800 entities, of which nearly 500 are power marketers, (including over 
    100 marketers affiliated with investor-owned utilities). The remaining 
    entities include approximately equal numbers of affiliated power 
    producers, investor-owned utilities and other utilities.16
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \16\ See Commission's website, www.ferc.fed.us/electric.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        State commissions and legislatures have been active in the past few 
    years studying competitive options at the retail level, setting up 
    pilot retail access programs, and, in many states, implementing full 
    scale retail access programs. As of November 1, 1999, twenty-one states 
    had enacted electric restructuring legislation, three had issued 
    comprehensive regulatory orders, and twenty-six states plus the 
    District of Columbia had legislation or orders pending or 
    investigations underway.17 Fifteen states had implemented 
    full-
    
    [[Page 814]]
    
    scale or pilot retail competition programs that offer a choice of 
    suppliers to at least some retail customers. Eight states have 
    initiated programs to offer access to retail customers by a date 
    certain.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \17\ See the Energy Information Administration website, 
    www.eia.doe.gov/cneaf/electricity/chg__str/regmap.html.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Because of the changes in the structure of the electric industry, 
    the transmission grid is now being used more intensively and in 
    different ways than in the past. The Commission is concerned that the 
    traditional approaches to operating the grid are showing signs of 
    strain. According to the North American Electric Reliability Council 
    (NERC), ``the adequacy of the bulk transmission system has been 
    challenged to support the movement of power in unprecedented amounts 
    and in unexpected directions.'' 18 These changes in the use 
    of the transmission system ``will test the electric industry's ability 
    to maintain system security in operating the transmission system under 
    conditions for which it was not planned or designed.'' 19 It 
    should be noted that, despite the increased transmission system 
    loadings, NERC believes that the ``procedures and processes to mitigate 
    potential reliability impacts appear to be working reliably for now,'' 
    and that even though the system was particularly stressed during the 
    summer of 1998, ``the system performed reliably and firm demand was not 
    interrupted due to transmission transfer limitations.'' 20
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \18\ Reliability Assessment 1998-2007, North American Electric 
    Reliability Council (September 1998), at 26 (Reliability 
    Assessment).
        \19\ Id.
        \20\ Id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        An indication that the increased and different use of the 
    transmission system is stressing the grid is the increased use of 
    transmission line loading relief (TLR) procedures.21 And, 
    according to published reports, the incidence of TLRs is growing. While 
    in all of 1998 over 300 TLRs were called, in the first ten months of 
    1999, over 400 TLRs have been called, resulting in over 8,000 MW of 
    power curtailment in the three-month summer period beginning June 
    1999.22
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \21\ The TLR procedures are designed to remedy overloads that 
    result when a transmission line or other transmission equipment 
    carries or will carry more power than its rating, which could result 
    in either power outages or damage to property. The TLR procedures 
    are designed to bring overloaded transmission equipment to within 
    NERC's Operating Security Limits essentially by curtailing 
    transactions contributing to the overload. See North American 
    Electric Reliability Council, 85 FERC para. 61,353 (1998) (NERC).
        \22\ Power Markets Week, November 8, 1999 at 1, citing NERC 
    data.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        It appears that the planning and construction of transmission and 
    transmission-related facilities may not be keeping up with increased 
    requirements. According to NERC, ``business is increasing on the 
    transmission system, but very little is being done to increase the load 
    serving and transfer capability of the bulk transmission system.'' 
    23 The amount of new transmission capacity planned over the 
    next ten years is significantly lower than the additions that had been 
    planned five years ago, and most of the planned projects are for local 
    system support.24 NERC states that, ``The close coordination 
    of generation and transmission planning is diminishing as vertically 
    integrated utilities divest their generation assets and most new 
    generation is being proposed and developed by independent power 
    producers.'' 25
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \23\ Reliability Assessment at 26.
        \24\ Id. at 7.
        \25\ Id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The transition to new market structures has resulted in new 
    challenges and circumstances. For example, during the week of June 22-
    26, 1998, the wholesale electric market in the Midwest experienced 
    numerous events that led to unprecedented high spot market prices. Spot 
    wholesale market prices for energy briefly rose as high as $7,500 per 
    MWh, compared with an average price for the summer of approximately $40 
    per MWh in the Midwest if the pricing abnormalities are 
    excluded.26 This experience led to calls for price caps, 
    allegations of market power, and a questioning of the effectiveness of 
    transmission open access and wholesale electric competition.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \26\ See Staff Report to the Federal Energy Regulatory 
    Commission on the Causes of Wholesale Electric Pricing Abnormalities 
    in the Midwest During June 1998, (Sept. 22, 1998) (Staff Price Spike 
    Report) at 3-8 to 3-11. Unusually high spot market wholesale prices 
    also occurred during the summer of 1999. The Commission is not aware 
    that any formal evaluations of market data have been performed for 
    that occurrence of price abnormalities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission staff undertook an investigation of the pricing 
    abnormalities. Staff's report concluded that the unusually high price 
    levels were caused by a combination of factors, particularly above-
    average generation outages, unseasonably hot temperatures, storm-
    related transmission outages, transmission constraints, poor 
    communication of price signals, lowered confidence in the market due to 
    a few contract defaults, and inexperience in dealing with competitive 
    markets.27
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \27\ Id. at v.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission's staff found that the market institutions were not 
    adequately prepared to deal with such a dramatic series of events. 
    Regarding regional transmission entities, the staff report observed: 
    ``The necessity for cooperation in meeting reliability concerns and the 
    Commission's intent to foster competitive market conditions underscores 
    the importance of better regional coordination in areas such as 
    maintenance of transmission and generation systems and transmission 
    planning and operation.'' 28 Support for this view comes 
    from many sources. For example, the Public Utilities Commission of 
    Ohio, in its own report on the high spot market prices, recommended 
    that policy makers ``take unambiguous action to require coordination of 
    transmission system operations by regionwide Independent System 
    Operators.'' 29
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \28\ Id. at 5-8.
        \29\ Ohio's Electric Market, June 22-26, 1998, What Happened and 
    Why, A Report to the Ohio General Assembly, at iii.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        On September 29, 1998, the Secretary of Energy Advisory Board Task 
    Force on Electric System Reliability published its final 
    report.30 The Task Force was convened in January 1997 to 
    provide advice to the Department of Energy on critical institutional, 
    technical, and policy issues that need to be addressed in order to 
    maintain bulk power electric system reliability in a more competitive 
    industry. The Task Force found that ``the traditional reliability 
    institutions and processes that have served the Nation well in the past 
    need to be modified to ensure that reliability is maintained in a 
    competitively neutral fashion;'' that ``grid reliability depends 
    heavily on system operators who monitor and control the grid in real 
    time;'' and that ``because bulk power systems are regional in nature, 
    they can and should be operated more reliably and efficiently when 
    coordinated over large geographic areas.'' 31
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \30\ Maintaining Reliability in a Competitive U.S. Electricity 
    Industry; Final Report of the Task Force on Electric System 
    Reliability (Sept. 29, 1998) (Task Force Report). The Task Force was 
    comprised of 24 members representing all major segments of the 
    electric industry, including private and public suppliers, power 
    marketers, regulators, environmentalists, and academics.
        \31\ Task Force Report at x-xi.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The report noted that many regions of the United States are 
    developing ISOs as a way to maintain electric system reliability as 
    competitive markets develop. According to the Task Force, ISOs are 
    significant institutions to assure both electric system reliability and 
    competitive generation markets. The Task Force concluded that a large 
    ISO would: (1) Be able to identify and address reliability issues most 
    effectively; (2) internalize much of the loop flow caused by the 
    growing number of transactions; (3) facilitate transmission access 
    across a larger
    
    [[Page 815]]
    
    portion of the network, consequently improving market efficiencies and 
    promoting greater competition; and (4) eliminate ``pancaking'' of 
    transmission rates, thus allowing a greater range of economic energy 
    trades across the network.32
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \32\ Id. at 76.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    2. Successes, Failures, and Haphazard Development of Regional 
    Transmission Entities
        Since Order No. 888 was issued, there have been both successful and 
    unsuccessful efforts to establish ISOs, and other efforts to form 
    regional entities to operate the transmission facilities in various 
    parts of the country. While we are encouraged by the success of some of 
    these efforts, it is apparent that the results have been inconsistent, 
    and much of the country's transmission facilities remain outside of an 
    operational regional transmission institution.
        Proposals for the establishment of five ISOs have been submitted to 
    and approved, or conditionally approved, by the Commission. These are 
    the California ISO,33 PJM ISO,34 ISO New 
    England,35 the New York ISO,36 and the Midwest 
    ISO.37 In addition, the Texas Commission has ordered an ISO 
    for the Electric Reliability Council of Texas (ERCOT).38 
    Moreover, our international neighbors in Canada and Mexico are also 
    pursuing electric restructuring efforts that include various forms of 
    regional transmission entities.39
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \33\ Pacific Gas & Electric Company, et al., 77 FERC para. 
    61,204 (1996), order on reh'g, 81 FERC para. 61,122 (1997) (Pacific 
    Gas & Electric).
        \34\ Pennsylvania-New Jersey-Maryland Interconnection, et al., 
    81 FERC para. 61,257 (1997), order on reh'g, 82 FERC para. 61,047 
    (1998) (PJM).
        \35\ New England Power Pool, 79 FERC para. 61,374 (1997), order 
    on reh'g, 85 FERC para. 61,242 (1998) (NEPOOL).
        \36\ Central Hudson Gas & Electric Corporation, et al., 83 FERC 
    para. 61,352 (1998), order on reh'g, 87 FERC para. 61,135 (1999) 
    (Central Hudson).
        \37\ Midwest Independent Transmission System Operator, et al., 
    84 FERC para. 61,231, order on reconsideration, 85 FERC para. 
    61,250, order on reh'g, 85 FERC para. 61,372 (1998) (Midwest ISO).
        \38\ See 16 Texas Administrative Code Sec. 23.67(p). 
    Furthermore, on June 18, 1999, S.B.7 was enacted to restructure the 
    Texas electric industry allowing retail competition. The bill 
    requires retail competition to begin by January 2002. Rates will be 
    frozen for three years, and then a six percent reduction will be 
    required for residential and small commercial consumers.
        \39\ See Policy Proposal for Structural Reform of the Mexican 
    Electricity Industry, Secretary of Energy, Mexico (Feb. 1999); Third 
    Interim Report of the Ontario Market Design Committee (Oct. 1998); 
    TransAlta Enterprises Corporation, 75 FERC para. 61,268 at 61,875 
    (1996) (recognition of the restructuring in the Province of Alberta, 
    Canada to create a Grid Company of Alberta).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The PJM, New England and New York ISOs were established on the 
    platform of existing tight power pools. It appears that the principal 
    motivation for creating ISOs in these situations was the Order No. 888 
    requirement that there be a single systemwide transmission tariff for 
    tight pools. In contrast, the establishment of the California ISO and 
    the ERCOT ISO was the direct result of mandates by state governments. 
    The Midwest ISO, which is not yet operational, is unique. It was 
    neither required by government nor based on an existing institution. 
    Two states in the region subsequently required utilities in their 
    states to participate in either a Commission-approved ISO (Illinois and 
    Wisconsin), or sell their transmission assets to an independent 
    transmission company that would operate under a regional ISO 
    (Wisconsin).
        As part of general restructuring initiatives, several states now 
    require independent grid management organizations. For example, an 
    Illinois law required that its utilities become members of a FERC-
    approved regional ISO by March 31, 1999, and Wisconsin law gives its 
    utilities the option of joining an ISO or selling their transmission 
    assets to an independent transmission company by June 30, 2000. In both 
    states, the backstop is a single-state organization if regional 
    organizations are not developed. Recently, Virginia,40 
    Arkansas 41 and Ohio42 have also enacted 
    legislation requiring their electric utilities to join or establish 
    regional transmission entities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \40\ See Virginia Electric Utility Restructuring Act, S1269 
    (Mar. 25, 1999). In Virginia, electric utilities are required by 
    January 2001, to join or establish regional transmission entities.
        \41\ See The Arkansas Electric Consumer Choice Act of 1999, Act 
    1, 82nd General Assembly (Apr. 1999).
        \42\ See Amended Substitute Senate Bill No. 3, 123rd General 
    Assembly (July 6, 1999).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The approved ISOs have similarities as well as differences. All 
    five Commission-approved ISOs operate, or propose to operate, as non-
    profit organizations. All five ISOs include both public and non-public 
    utility members. However, among the five, there is considerable 
    variation in governance, operational responsibilities, geographic scope 
    and market operations. Four of the ISOs rely on a two-tier form of 
    governance with a non-stakeholder governing board on top that is 
    advised, either formally or informally, by one or more stakeholder 
    groups. In general, the final decision making authority rests with the 
    independent non-stakeholder board. One ISO, the California ISO, uses a 
    board consisting of stakeholders and non-stakeholders.
        Four of the five ISOs operate a single control area, but the large 
    Midwest ISO does not currently plan to operate a single control area. 
    Three are multi-state ISOs (New England, PJM and Midwest), while two 
    ISOs (California and New York) currently operate within a single state. 
    The current Midwest ISO members do not encompass one contiguous 
    geographic area. The ISO New England administers a separate NEPOOL 
    tariff, while the other four administer their own ISO transmission 
    tariffs.
        Three ISOs operate or propose to operate centralized power markets 
    (New England, PJM and New York), and one ISO (California) relies on a 
    separate power exchange (PX) to operate such a market.43 The 
    Midwest ISO has not proposed an ISO-related centralized market for its 
    region.44 In addition, at least one separate PX has begun to 
    do business in California apart from the PX established through the 
    restructuring legislation.45
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \43\ The California PX offers day-ahead and hour-ahead markets 
    and the ISO operates a real-time energy market. Participation in the 
    PX market is voluntary except that the three traditional investor-
    owned utilities in California must bid their generation sales and 
    purchases through the PX for the first five years. New York will 
    offer day-ahead and real-time energy markets that will be operated 
    by the ISO. PJM and New England offer only real-time energy markets, 
    although PJM has proposed to operate a day-ahead market. The ERCOT 
    ISO is the only other ISO that does not currently operate a PX.
        \44\ There are indications, however, that the Midwest ISO is 
    considering the formation of a power exchange. See Joint Committee 
    for the Development of a Midwest Independent Power Exchange, 
    ``Solicitation of Interest-Creation of an Independent Power Exchange 
    for the U.S. Midwest,'' February 5, 1999.
        \45\ See Automated Power Exchange, Inc., 82 FERC para. 61,287, 
    reh'g denied, 84 FERC para. 61,020 (1998), appeals docketed, No. 98-
    1415 (D.C. Cir. Sept. 14, 1998) and No. 98-1419 (D.C. Cir. Sept. 14, 
    1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The existing ISOs are also evolving in terms of their governance 
    structure and as a result of operating experience with the transmission 
    systems and the various markets they operate. For example, the 
    Commission rejected the original governance proposals for two ISOs: the 
    New England ISO and New York ISO. In both cases, the Commission 
    concluded that the vertically integrated utility members of the ISO 
    would have too much voting power in the various advisory committees 
    that provide advice and recommendations to the non-stakeholder Boards. 
    The ISOs resubmitted governance proposals that gave balanced 
    representation to the various sectors of stakeholders, and the 
    Commission subsequently approved both revised governance structures.
        In addition, the Commission has considered a number of significant 
    modifications of market rules proposed by the existing ISOs in the 
    seven months since issuance of the RTO
    
    [[Page 816]]
    
    NOPR. In particular, a number of rules for the California ISO and New 
    England ISO have been modified, affecting the products traded in, and 
    the timing of, the markets for energy, ancillary services, balancing 
    services and transmission.
        An additional few transmission restructuring proposals that were 
    pending as of the date of issuance of the RTO NOPR have been approved 
    by the Commission, and others have been filed since that date. In July 
    1999, the Commission granted a petition for declaratory order filed by 
    Entergy Services Inc., in which the majority concluded that passive 
    ownership of a transmission entity by a generating company or other 
    market participant could meet the ISO principles contained in Order No. 
    888. The order stated, however, that the passive ownership must be 
    properly designed, such that the transmission entity is truly 
    independent of the market participants.46 Another filing 
    that was pending when the NOPR was issued was the request by 
    FirstEnergy to sell its transmission assets to a newly-formed 
    affiliate. The Commission approved the disposition of jurisdictional 
    facilities, noting that the proposed action would not adversely affect 
    competition, rates or regulation. In addition, the Commission noted 
    that the creation of the transmission-owning affiliate would facilitate 
    the subsequent transfer of FirstEnergy's transmission facilities to an 
    RTO, which FirstEnergy pledged to do within two years of Commission 
    approval of the disposition of facilities to its 
    affiliate.47
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \46\ See Entergy Services, Inc., 88 FERC para. 61,149 (1999) 
    (Commissioner Massey dissented from this order).
        \47\ See FirstEnergy Operating Companies, et al., 89 FERC para. 
    61,090 (1999).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Since issuance of the RTO NOPR, the Alliance Companies filed a 
    proposal to create an RTO. Applicants suggest that the RTO could take 
    one of two forms, either an ISO or a transco, but note that they prefer 
    a transco configuration in which, at least initially, the five 
    transmission-owning participants could hold five percent ownership 
    stakes in the transco.48
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \48\ See Application of Alliance Companies in Docket No. ER99-
    3144-000 (filed June 3, 1999). The Commission issued an order on 
    this application concurrently with the issuance of this Final Rule. 
    See Alliance Companies, 89 FERC para.____ (1999) (Alliance 
    Companies).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Not all efforts to create ISOs have been successful. For example, 
    after more than two years of effort, the proponents of the IndeGO 
    (Independent Grid Operator) ISO in the Pacific Northwest and Rocky 
    Mountain regions ended their efforts to create an ISO.49 
    More recently, members of the Mid-American Power Pool (MAPP), an 
    existing power pool that covers six U.S. states and two Canadian 
    provinces, failed to achieve consensus for establishing a long-planned 
    ISO.50 In the Southwest, proponents of the Desert STAR ISO 
    have not been able to reach agreement to date on a formal proposal 
    after more than two years of discussion.51 In the interim 
    period, some of the participants in the Desert STAR ISO have filed at 
    the Commission a proposal to create the Mountain West Independent 
    Scheduling Administrator, which would oversee the scheduling of 
    transmission service within Nevada.52
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \49\ Recently, however, parties in the Pacific Northwest have 
    resumed RTO discussions.
        \50\ However, trade press reports suggest that while MAPP 
    members continue to try to reach consensus, the Midwest ISO is in 
    discussion with MAPP members to join the Midwest ISO. See Inside 
    FERC, July 26, 1999; The Energy Report, Nov. 1, 1999 at 931.
        \51\ Recent press reports, however, indicate that Desert STAR 
    has incorporated as a non-profit organization, a first step toward 
    the launch of an ISO. See Energy Daily, Nov. 5, 1999 at 2.
        \52\ See Application of Mountain West Independent Transmission 
    Administrator in Docket No. ER99-3719-000 (filed July 23, 1999).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Various reasons have been advanced to explain the difficulty in 
    forming a voluntary, multi-state ISO. Reasons include: ``cost 
    shifting,'' which involves increases in transmission rates for some 
    parties; disagreements about sharing of ISO transmission revenues among 
    transmission owners; difficulties in obtaining the participation of 
    publicly-owned transmission facilities; concerns about the loss of 
    transmission rights and prices embedded in existing transmission 
    agreements; and the preference of certain transmission owners to sell 
    or transfer their transmission assets to a for-profit transmission 
    company in lieu of handing over control to a non-profit ISO.
    3. The Commission's ISO and RTO Inquiries; Conferences With 
    Stakeholders and State Regulators
        In light of the various restructuring activities occurring 
    throughout the United States, the Commission has held 11 public 
    conferences in nine different cities across the country to hear the 
    views of industry, consumers, and state regulators with respect to the 
    need for RTOs and their appropriate roles and responsibilities.
        The Commission initiated an inquiry in March 1998 pertaining to its 
    policies on ISOs. A notice establishing procedures for a conference 
    gave the following rationale:
    
        In Order Nos. 888 and 889 and their progeny, the Commission 
    established the fundamental principles of non-discriminatory open 
    access transmission services. Nevertheless, many issues remain to be 
    addressed if the Nation is to fully realize the benefits of open 
    access and more competitive electric markets.
    * * * * *
        Given the dramatic changes taking place in both wholesale and 
    retail electric markets and the many proposals under consideration 
    with respect to the creation of ISOs or other transmission entities, 
    such as transmission-only utilities, it is time for the Commission 
    to take stock of its policies in order to determine whether they 
    appropriately support our dual goals of eliminating undue 
    discrimination and promoting competition in electric power 
    markets.53
    
        \53\ Inquiry Concerning the Commission's Policy on Independent 
    System Operators, Notice of Conference, Docket No. PL98-5-000, at 1-
    2 (March 13, 1998).
    
    Accordingly, the Commission held a series of eight conferences in 1998 
    to gain insight into participants' views on the formation and role of 
    ISOs in the electric utility industry. The first conference was held in 
    April 1998 at the Commission's offices in Washington, D.C. Between May 
    28 and June 8, 1998, the Commission held seven regional conferences in 
    Phoenix, Kansas City, New Orleans, Indianapolis, Portland, Richmond and 
    Orlando. As a result of these conferences, the Commission heard 
    approximately 145 oral presentations and received a large number of 
    written comments on the appropriate size, scope, organization and 
    functions of regional transmission institutions. A number of different 
    of viewpoints were expressed.54
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \54\ A summary of those views was included as Appendix A to the 
    NOPR in this docket.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        On October 1, 1998, the Secretary of Energy delegated his authority 
    under section 202(a) of the FPA to the Commission. In doing so, the 
    Secretary stated that section 202(a) ``provides DOE with sufficient 
    authority to establish boundaries for Independent System Operators 
    (ISOs) or other appropriate transmission entities.'' 55 The 
    Secretary also stated: ``FERC is also increasingly faced with 
    reliability-related issues. Providing FERC with the authority to 
    establish boundaries for ISOs or other appropriate transmission 
    entities could aid in the orderly formation of properly-sized 
    transmission institutions and in addressing reliability-related issues, 
    thereby increasing the reliability of the transmission system.''
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \55\ 63 FR 53,889 (Oct. 7, 1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        On November 24, 1998, we gave notice in this docket of our intent 
    to initiate a consultation process with State commissions pursuant to 
    section
    
    [[Page 817]]
    
    202(a).56 The purpose of the consultations was to afford 
    State commissions a reasonable opportunity to present their views with 
    respect to appropriate boundaries for regional transmission 
    institutions and other issues relating to RTOs. Conferences with State 
    commissioners were held in St. Louis, Missouri, on February 11, 1999; 
    in Las Vegas, Nevada, on February 12, 1999; and in Washington, D.C., on 
    February 17, 1999. In all, we heard oral presentations by 
    representatives of 41 state commissions during these consultations, 
    with others monitoring or providing written comments.57 
    During these sessions, we received much valuable advice. Furthermore, 
    we have had additional consultations since issuance of the RTO NOPR in 
    May 1999.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \56\ Regional Transmission Organizations, Notice of Intent to 
    Consult with State Commission, 63 FR 66,158 (Dec. 1, 1998), FERC 
    Stats & Regs. para. 35,534 (1998).
        \57\ See Appendix for a list of commenters.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    III. Discussion
    
    A. Existing Barriers and Impediments To Achieving Fully Competitive 
    Electricity Markets
    
        In the NOPR, the Commission expressed its belief that there remain 
    important transmission-related impediments to a competitive wholesale 
    electric market. The Commission grouped these remaining impediments 
    into two broad categories: (1) The engineering and economic 
    inefficiencies inherent in the current operation and expansion of the 
    transmission grid, and (2) continuing opportunities for transmission 
    owners to unduly discriminate in the operation of their transmission 
    systems so as to favor their own or their affiliates' power marketing 
    activities.58
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \58\ FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,696.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        With respect to engineering and economic inefficiencies, the NOPR 
    noted that the transmission facilities of any one utility in a region 
    are part of a larger, integrated transmission system which, from an 
    electrical engineering perspective, operates as a single 
    machine.59 Engineering and economic inefficiencies occur 
    because each separate operator usually makes independent decisions 
    about the use, limitations and expansion of its piece of the 
    interconnected grid based on incomplete information, even though any 
    action taken by one transmission provider can have major and 
    instantaneous effects on the transmission facilities of all other 
    transmission providers. The Commission noted that, while this was not a 
    new phenomenon, the demands placed on the transmission grid had changed 
    in recent years due to (1) increases in bulk power trade, (2) large 
    shifts in power flows, and (3) an increasingly de-integrated and 
    decentralized competitive power industry.60 As a consequence 
    of these changes in trade patterns and industry structure, certain 
    operational problems had become more significant and difficult to 
    resolve.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \59\ Id. at 33,697.
        \60\ See id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Engineering and Economic Inefficiencies. The NOPR identified a 
    number of specific economic and engineering inefficiencies. First, the 
    NOPR noted that the reliability of the nation's bulk power system was 
    being stressed in ways that have never been experienced before, and 
    questioned the continued feasibility of one-on-one coordination of an 
    interconnected transmission grid encompassing more than 100 
    transmission owners and 140 separate control areas.61 
    Second, the NOPR observed that there were increasing difficulties in 
    accurately computing Total Transmission Capacity (TTC) and Available 
    Transmission Capacity (ATC), assessments that require reliable and 
    timely information about load, generation, facility outages and 
    transactions on neighboring systems, as well as consistency in 
    methodologies among systems.62 Third, the NOPR noted that 
    efficient congestion management required regional actions, and that the 
    current methods for managing congestion (e.g., Transmission Line 
    Loading Relief procedures in the Eastern Interconnection), which do not 
    attempt to optimize regional congestion relief, were cumbersome, 
    inefficient and disruptive to bulk power markets.63 Fourth, 
    the NOPR expressed concern that the uncertainty associated with 
    transmission planning and expansion had increased with the increasing 
    number and distance of unbundled transactions and the wider variation 
    in generation dispatch patterns. The NOPR pointed to a noticeable 
    decline in planned transmission investments and expressed concern that, 
    without a regional approach to planning and expansion, it would be 
    difficult to address complex and controversial issues that arise when 
    the benefits of an expansion do not necessarily accrue to the 
    transmission system that must undertake the expansion.64 
    Finally, the NOPR explained that pancaked transmission rates (where a 
    separate access charge is assessed every time the transaction contract 
    path crosses the boundary of another transmission owner) restrict the 
    size of regional power markets. The Commission added that the 
    balkanization of electricity markets hurts consumers who pay higher 
    transmission rates and have access to fewer generation 
    options.65
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \61\ See id. at 33,699.
        \62\ Id. at 33,700.
        \63\ Id. at 33,701-02.
        \64\ See id. at 33,702-03.
        \65\ Id. at 33,703.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Continuing Opportunities for Undue Discrimination. With respect to 
    continuing opportunities for undue discrimination, the NOPR observed 
    that, when utilities control monopoly transmission facilities and also 
    have power marketing interests, they have poor incentives to provide 
    equal quality transmission service to their power marketing 
    competitors.66 The NOPR explained that the Commission had 
    made this point in Order No. 888:
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \66\ Id. at 33,704.
    
        It is in the economic self-interest of transmission monopolists, 
    particularly those with high-cost generation assets, to deny 
    transmission or to offer transmission on a basis that is inferior to 
    that which they provide themselves. The inherent characteristics of 
    monopolists make it inevitable that they will act in their own self-
    interest to the detriment of others by refusing transmission and/or 
    providing inferior transmission to competitors in the bulk power 
    markets to favor their own generation, and it is our duty to 
    eradicate unduly discriminatory practices.67
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \67\ Order No. 888, FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 31,036 at 31,682.
    
    In the NOPR, the Commission noted that functional unbundling does not 
    change the incentives of vertically integrated utilities to use their 
    transmission assets to favor their own generation, but instead attempt 
    to reduce the ability of utilities to act on those 
    incentives.68
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \68\ As noted in the NOPR, in Order No. 888, the Commission 
    received and considered numerous comments that functional unbundling 
    was unlikely to work, and that more drastic restructuring, such as 
    corporate unbundling, was needed. For example, the Federal Trade 
    Commission advised the Commission that a functional unbundling 
    approach ``* * * would leave in place the incentive and opportunity 
    for some utilities to exercise market power in the regulated system. 
    Preventing them from doing so by enforcing regulations to control 
    their behavior may prove difficult.'' However, the Commission 
    decided at the time to adopt the less intrusive and less costly 
    remedy of functional unbundling. FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 32,541 at 
    33,707.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The NOPR expressed concern about continuing indications that 
    transmission service problems related to discriminatory conduct remain 
    and concluded that these problems are impeding competitive wholesale 
    power markets.69 The NOPR also noted that
    
    [[Page 818]]
    
    instances of actual discrimination may be undetectable in a non-
    transparent market and, in any event, it is often hard to determine, on 
    an after-the-fact basis, whether an action was motivated by an intent 
    to favor affiliates or simply reflected the impartial application of 
    operating or technical requirement. The NOPR added that, while 
    continued discrimination may be deliberate, it could also result from 
    the failure to make sufficient efforts to change the way integrated 
    utilities have done business for many years. The Commission expressed 
    concern that the difficulty in determining whether there has been 
    compliance with our regulations raises the question as to whether 
    functional unbundling is an appropriate long-term regulatory solution.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \69\ The NOPR described specific examples of undue 
    discrimination that had been brought to its attention through formal 
    complaints, informal complaints made to the Commission's enforcement 
    hotline, oral and written comments made in conjunction with public 
    conferences held by the Commission, and pleadings filed with the 
    Commission in various dockets. The complaints generally involved: 
    (1) Calculation and posting of ATC in a manner favorable to the 
    transmission provider; (2) standards of conduct violations, (3) line 
    loading relief and congestion management, and (4) OASIS sites that 
    are difficult to use. See id. at 33,707-13.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The NOPR explained that the Commission considers allegations of 
    discrimination, even if not reduced to formal findings, to be a serious 
    concern for two reasons. First, this can be indicative of additional, 
    unreported, discriminatory actions, because there are significant 
    disincentives to filing and pursuing formal complaints that would 
    result in definitive findings.70 The NOPR expressed a 
    concern that actual problems with functional unbundling may be more 
    pervasive than formally adjudicated complaints would suggest. Second, 
    the NOPR explained that allegations of discrimination are serious 
    because, if nothing else, they represent a perception by market 
    participants that the market is not working fairly. If market 
    participants perceive that other participants have an unfair advantage 
    through their ownership or control of transmission facilities, it can 
    inhibit their willingness to participate in the market, thus thwarting 
    the development of robust competition. The NOPR added that such 
    mistrust can also harm reliability.71
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \70\ As noted in the NOPR, transmission customers are reluctant 
    to make even informal complaints because they fear retribution by 
    their transmission supplier; the complaint process is costly and 
    time-consuming; the Commission's remedies for violations do not 
    impose sufficient financial consequences on the transmission 
    provider to act as a significant deterrent; and, in the fast-paced 
    business of power marketing, there may be no adequate remedy for the 
    lost short-term sales opportunities in after-the-fact enforcement. 
    See FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,706.
        \71\ Id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The NOPR explained the potential for undue discrimination increases 
    in a competitive environment unless the market can be made structurally 
    efficient and transparent with respect to information, and equitable in 
    its treatment of competing participants. Also, a system that attempts 
    to control behavior that is motivated by economic self-interest through 
    the use of standards of conduct will require constant and extensive 
    policing and requires the Commission to regulate detailed aspects of 
    internal company policy and communication. The NOPR added that 
    functional unbundling does not necessarily promote light-handed 
    regulation and undoubtedly imposes a cost on those entities that have 
    to comply with the standards of conduct and abide by rules that limit 
    the flexibility of their internal management activities. The NOPR 
    stated that the perception that many entities that operate the 
    transmission system cannot be trusted is not a good foundation on which 
    to build a competitive power market, and it created needless 
    uncertainty and risk for new investments in generation.72
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \72\ See id. at 33,714.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments. Engineering and Economic Inefficiencies. Virtually all 
    commenters support the NOPR's premise that engineering and economic 
    inefficiencies exist in the operation, planning and expansion of the 
    regional transmission grid and that these inefficiencies hinder 
    electric system reliability and a fully competitive bulk power 
    market.73 Many commenters state further that, in the new 
    industry structure, coordinated regional transmission planning has 
    become a thing of the past and new transmission additions that will 
    benefit reliable grid operations are being delayed.74
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \73\ See, e.g., Duquesne, Entergy, Florida Power Corp., NU, 
    Kentucky Commission, NECPUC, Ohio Commission, Texas Commission, DOE, 
    American Forest, Arkansas Cities, East Texas Cooperatives, EPSA, 
    First Rochdale, FMPA, Oglethorpe, PNGC, Powerex, Public Citizen, 
    SoCal Cities, Sonat, Williams.
        \74\ See, e.g., EPRI, Florida Power Corp, Duquesne, Entergy, 
    SoCal Cities, Merrill Energy, TAPS, IPCF, Powerex.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        FMPA states that grid fragmentation harms reliability.75 
    NU and EPRI note that recent demand growth has meant new stresses on 
    grid reliability and there is less coordination of generation and 
    transmission planning. TXU Electric states that, as the shift from 
    regulation to competition accelerates, and restructuring efforts 
    proliferate, the regional transmission grid is being exposed to 
    stresses that cannot be alleviated without regional solutions.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \75\ FMPA at 24.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        WPPI describes a situation in 1997 in which the 345-kV transmission 
    facility between MAPP and MAIN was overloaded as a result of 
    transactions scheduled within MAPP, and Wisconsin operators became 
    aware of the problem only when the constrained 345-kV facility 
    automatically separated in response to the overload. WPPI explains 
    that, with the 345-kV facility shut down, other transmission facilities 
    in the region overloaded, causing the transmission system over a large 
    region to come perilously close to a blackout. WPPI adds that, because 
    transmission providers do not have information about their neighbors' 
    on-system transactions to serve native load, they are unable to predict 
    the impact of potential TLR events. WPPI says that, in the face of this 
    uncertainty, transmission providers have to make overly conservative, 
    but inaccurate assumptions which unnecessarily reduce the amount of 
    transmission capacity available to the market.
        TAPS states that, when the owners of a constrained interface 
    between MAPP and MAIN tried to remove the line for service for 
    maintenance, they found that 500 MW of flow remained on the line even 
    after all scheduled transactions were terminated. TAPS explains that 
    there were so many transactions in the region at the time that 
    transmission operators could not determine the source of this 500 MW 
    loop flow and were unable to ask other parties to cut their schedules 
    to permit the necessary maintenance.76 TAPS asserts that 
    transmission owners have engaged in ``creative'' concepts such as CBM 
    to reduce ATC and argues that price spikes are exacerbated, if not 
    caused by the failure to have regional transmission information and 
    control in one place.77
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \76\ TAPS, Appendix A, at 8
        \77\ TAPS, Appendix A at 2-5.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        TDU Systems complaint that the current system balkanizes regions 
    into a series of submarkets, each with its own dominant incumbent 
    transmission owner/generator that collects its own transmission toll.
        EPRI contends that the current off-line ATC calculations result in 
    inconsistencies of ATC values. Entergy argues that the accuracy of ATC 
    will continue to be a problem as long as contract path pricing is 
    used.78
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \78\ Entergy at 8.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Minnesota Power notes that reliability across the broader region 
    suffers simply because of different standards for ATC calculations 
    within and across NERC
    
    [[Page 819]]
    
    regions and, indeed, different terminology and operating practices. 
    Minnesota Power states that: the market currently suffers as 
    participants attempt to deal with multiple OASIS sites; existing 
    tagging and reservation practices that limit transactions due to the 
    complexity of arrangements; its transactions are subject to curtailment 
    pursuant to two different procedures, NERC TLR and MAPP LLR; and 
    congestion management alternatives to line loading relief have not 
    succeeded because they lack regional coordination. Minnesota Power 
    argues that energy price volatility will continue to increase unless 
    there is a viable process, supported by transmission rights and 
    secondary transfer markets, where a participant can secure transmission 
    daily, or as needed, to bring the least cost supply to its customers.
        EPSA asserts that one of the major impediments to robust 
    competitive bulk power markets is the current balkanization of the 
    system with dozens of individual utilities, NERC Regional Councils, and 
    security coordinators, and state laws and regulations imposing a 
    patchwork of often inconsistent and incompatible rules for the use of 
    the interstate transmission system. EPSA argues that the operational 
    and economic inefficiencies detailed in the NOPR are not unique to 
    certain region as and may be most pronounced in those regions where 
    competition has yet to take hold.79
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \79\ EPSA specifically points to the SERC as a region where 
    ``state commissions and utilities may be arguing that they don't 
    `need' RTOs to promote competitive markets,'' at a time when 
    Southeastern markets trail the rest of the nation in proposed 
    merchant plant development and power trading, ``both hallmarks of 
    robust wholesale competition and workable open access policies.'' 
    EPSA notes that SERC is the largest NERC region, both in load and 
    peak demand, yet SERC and FRCC together constitute only 5.2 percent 
    of the wholesale power trades nationwide.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        SoCal Edison states that existing transmission systems were 
    designed to serve native load customers in a defined area, in the most 
    efficient manner possible, in conjunction with the generation that it 
    owned and operated, and were not designed to function as common 
    carriers. SoCal Edison concludes that that radical changes in 
    downstream generation markets are having, and will continue to have, 
    significant and largely adverse effects of transmission systems. 
    Consumers Energy echoes this concern, noting that it should be obvious 
    that the current transmission system was designed to deliver locally 
    generated power to local markets with interfaces used primarily for 
    reliability purposes. Consumers Energy states that the system is simply 
    not engineered to move large quantities of power from many distant 
    generation sources to millions of end users.
        Williams concludes that problems with congestion management, 
    pancaked transmission rates, parallel path or loop flows, inaccurate 
    ATC postings, and transmission facilities management and expansion 
    planning continue to impede the development of robust, competitive 
    wholesale electric markets in the United States.
        PECO states that current TLR procedures allow one entity to cause 
    the curtailment of numerous third party transactions on a regular basis 
    to preserve power delivery in its single control area, regardless of 
    the impact on other control areas. PECO argues that, while physical 
    operation of the grid is maintained under these TLR procedures, 
    reliable, inter-control area power delivery is not assured and market 
    participants are denied fair access to the grid.
        Tampa Electric states that, within peninsular Florida, transmission 
    users must often go to several individual transmission providers and 
    OASIS nodes, sign multiple agreements with various providers and 
    attempt to piece together and navigate through various partial paths to 
    connect a power sale to a buyer. Tampa Electric concludes that access 
    to transmission services within this region is not as open as it could 
    be to facilitate an efficient, robust wholesale market.
        AEP states that coordination that previously existed in a fully 
    integrated electric system of the construction of new generation and 
    transmission facilities has eroded due to the separation of these 
    functions. AEP states that congestion constraints could potentially 
    inhibit the development of additional generation capacity or provide a 
    disincentive to add generating capacity where needed. AEP also notes 
    that the priorities of state regulatory agencies sometimes favor the 
    needs of native load customers that can create conflicts among 
    competing interest at the regional level. AEP also states that 
    developers of new merchant generation plants have become less willing 
    to share their long-term planning goals with transmission owners due to 
    the business strategies that accompany a more competitive power market. 
    However, AEP argues that removal of pancaking is not consistent with 
    economic efficiency and may distort future transmission expansion 
    because the cost of transmission should be based on distance and 
    location.\80\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \80\ AEP at 1, and Attachment to AEP's comments (Statement of 
    Paul Moul). As discussed in the Transmission Ratemaking section 
    (Section G), elimination of pancaked rates (multiple access charges 
    assessed only because the transaction crosses a corporate boundary) 
    does not constitute a prohibition on distance sensitive rates.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several commenters state that needed transmission expansion is not 
    taking place because of a lack of pricing incentives to build new 
    transmission.\81\ EPRI states that failure to satisfy grid expansion 
    needs is resulting in increasing frequency and duration of power 
    disturbances and outages costing $50 billion per year.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \81\ See, e.g., Transmission ISO Participants, H.Q. Energy 
    Services, Powerex.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        WPPI points out that transmission planning must be undertaken on a 
    regional, not a state basis, noting that import capability from MAPP 
    into Wisconsin is sometimes constrained by facilities located outside 
    of Wisconsin, e.g., transformers and lines located in Illinois and 
    Minnesota. On the other hand, Allegheny asserts that the industry has 
    not failed to plan and coordinate on a regional basis and cites 
    examples of study groups and planning committees, such as VEM 
    (Virginia-ECAR-MAAC) and GAPP (General Agreement on Parallel Paths).
        Most commenters assert that pancaked transmission access charges 
    prevent efficient access to regional markets and distort the generation 
    market.\82\ A few commenters, however, question the benefits associated 
    with eliminating rate pancaking. Southern Company observes that the 
    severity of pancaking effects may vary from region to region.\83\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \82\ See, e.g., FMPA, IMEA, NECPUC, Ohio Commission, Texas 
    Commission, American Forest, Arkansas Cities, East Texas 
    Cooperatives, Oglethorpe, PNGC, Powerex, Williams, WPSC.
        \83\ For illustration, Southern Company points out that a 
    customer in its service area can transmit power 500 miles away for 
    $3/MWh whereas a customer wanting to transmit power from Boston to 
    Washington, DC (also a distance of 500 miles) will have to go 
    through the three PJM, New England and NY ISOs and pay a total of 
    approximately $14/MWh.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Continuing Opportunities for Undue Discrimination. Comments dealing 
    with continuing opportunities for undue discrimination fall generally 
    into two camps. On the one side, transmission customers and some 
    transmission providers agree with the NOPR's premise that opportunities 
    for discrimination exist, that perceptions of discrimination are also a 
    serious impediment to competitive bulk power markets, and that 
    functional unbundling does not reflect the optimal long-term regulatory 
    solution.\84\ On the other side,
    
    [[Page 820]]
    
    a number of transmission providers disagree with these premises.\85\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \84\ E.g., American Forest, Los Angeles, TAPS, UAMPS, Steel 
    Dynamics, Turlock, Cinergy, Statoil, WPPI, NJBUS, MidAmerican, LG&E, 
    Clarksdale, Michigan Commission, New Smyrna Beach, Industrial 
    Consumers, IMPA, First Rochdale, East Texas Cooperatives, FMPA, TDU 
    Systems, Canada DNR, Allegheny, IMEA, Sonat, Public Citizen, EPSA, 
    CCEM/ELCON, UtiliCorp and FTC. [85]:United Illuminating, Southern 
    Company, MidAmerican, Duke, PSE&G, FP&L, Entergy, FirstEnergy, 
    Alliance Companies, Lenard and Florida Power Corp.
        \85\ United Illuminating, Southern Company, MidAmerican, Duke, 
    PSE7G, FP&L, Entergy, First Energy, Alliance Companies, Lenard and 
    Florida Power Corp.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments Asserting That Discrimination Still Exists. AMP-Ohio 
    points to an event last summer when it was unable to transmit power 
    from a generator on AEP's system to a load on the FirstEnergy system 
    and was forced to purchase power from FirstEnergy at $4000/MWh. AMP-
    Ohio contends that AEP and FirstEnergy were simultaneously reporting 
    zero ATC during the hour, i.e., an event that cannot be rationalized by 
    AMP-Ohio (i.e., an interface that is fully loaded in both directions at 
    the same time would, in AMP-Ohio's view, cancel out).
        UAMPS argues that three transmission owners that jointly own 
    segments of a single transmission line have avoided releasing the 
    capacity of this line under their open access tariffs through a series 
    of contractual arrangements that distributes transmission rights 
    directly to each of their merchant functions. As a result, only the 
    transmission owners' merchant functions have the ability the schedule 
    transmission service over the line. UAMPS contends that this example, 
    and others, confirm the Commission's perception that the remedies 
    mandated in Order No. 888 have not eliminated discrimination. UAMPS 
    states that it is intuitively obvious that when the transmission 
    function and merchant function ultimately serve the same master, 
    neither can be truly independent.
        Hogan contends that, without an efficient regional spot market and 
    its ease of access, the problems of discrimination will persist. FTC 
    concludes that several years of industry experience confirm the concern 
    that discrimination remains in the provision of transmission services 
    by utilities that continue to own both generation and transmission. FTC 
    concludes that reliance on behavioral rules have proved to be less than 
    ideal.
        Cinergy contends that reliance on CBM by some transmission 
    providers this summer provided their native load an unfair operational 
    edge over network service in the import of power through interconnects 
    that were the subject of TLR orders. Cinergy argues that the more 
    severe impact on market efficiency is caused by the lack of information 
    underlying the transmission provider's implementation of TLRs, and 
    raises significant opportunities for transmission providers to use 
    alleged reliability reasons to hide conduct actually motivated to 
    protect their own or their affiliate's own power market. Cinergy 
    concludes that market participants will never know the real answer 
    because it may be impossible to prove abuse of the TLR procedures with 
    access to information on the nature and cause of constraints and the 
    lack of consistency in implementing TLRs across the regions. Cinergy 
    adds that, even where there may be sufficient evidence to prove 
    discrimination, potential complainants may fear retribution by the 
    transmission provider, and may also be hesitant to file complaints 
    because of the litigation costs of the complaint process and the lack 
    of remedy for lost short-term market opportunities.
        Enron/APX/Coral Power state that the following types of relatively 
    overt, although difficult to detect, discrimination occur: (1) Offers 
    of attractive transmission service to a transmission owner's affiliate 
    or merchant function that are not similarly offered to others; (2) 
    advance notification to the affiliate or merchant function of the 
    availability of transmission service or the availability of a new 
    service; and (3) changes in procedures, such as scheduling deadlines, 
    for obtaining transmission service in ways that benefit the affiliate 
    or merchant function. Enron/APX/Coral Power (as well as CCEM/ELCON, 
    UtiliCorp and EPSA) also argue that a ``principal form of 
    discrimination grows out of the exemption from the pro forma OATT and 
    OASIS that is enjoyed by transmission bundled with service to captive 
    `native-load' customers.'' Enron/APX/Coral Power believes that, if the 
    Commission were to conduct an investigation of compliance with the 
    Commission's open access requirements and the uses of their own 
    transmission system during periods of extreme peak loads and volatile 
    prices during the past summer, the Commission would uncover evidence of 
    widespread abuses. According to Enron/APX/Coral Power, these abuses 
    would include instances where the transmission provider imported power 
    on a network basis, as if it were intended to service captive, native 
    load customers, only to turn around and sell that power competitively, 
    off-system; where scheduling requirements or deadlines were changed 
    without adequate notice to third parties; and where ATC amounts that 
    either were not posted or were posted in an untimely manner.
        NASUCA concludes that, despite Order No. 888, there is still reason 
    for concern that continued discrimination in the provision of 
    transmission services by vertically integrated utilities may be 
    impeding competitive electric markets.
        EPSA states that the prospect of real competition continues to be 
    threatened by (1) arbitrary and discriminatory curtailment and line 
    loading relief policies, and (2) needlessly complex and overly 
    restrictive transmission planning, expansion and interconnection 
    practices.
        TAPS argues that the anticompetitive effects of allowing a subset 
    of competitors to control essential facilities have been long 
    recognized.\86\ TAPS provides specific examples that it claims show 
    that discrimination exists: (1) The price spikes in June 1998 and 
    Summer of 1999 where the asserted ATC was inadequate to allow external 
    generation resources to meet the needs of the market; (2) failure of a 
    transmission owner to provide necessary upgrades; and (3) a 
    transmission owner taking negotiating positions contrary to a clear 
    provision of the Open Access Transmission Tariff (OATT). In its reply 
    comments, TAPS describes a recent situation where AEP, acting in its 
    role as the NERC Security Coordinator, informed IMPA that it had 
    implemented a TLR seven minutes earlier, too late for IMPA to replace 
    the curtailed schedule with another transaction at market prices, which 
    were $35/MWh. TAPS contends that IMPA had no effective choice but to 
    make up the shortfall by purchasing emergency energy from AEP at $100/
    MWh. In following hours that day, IMPA elected to purchase power from 
    AEP at $35/MWh rather than continue its other purchase options (at $17/
    MWh) and risk further curtailments. TAPS observes that AEP 
    substantially profited from delayed communication of the TLR, by 
    selling power to IMPA at nearly three times the then-market price. TAPS 
    states that, even assuming AEP was acting properly on this occasion, 
    this example illustrates the inherent conflict of interest in combining 
    security coordinator functions with that of market participant. TAPS 
    argues that this diminishes the faith in the market place and breeds 
    mistrust. Based on the examples it provides and on the evidence 
    reviewed in the NOPR, TAPS
    
    [[Page 821]]
    
    recommends that the Final Rule make formal findings that undue 
    discrimination remains widespread throughout the industry.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \86\ TAPS cites to a 1912 Supreme Court case involving the 
    control of a railway terminal by several railroads which their 
    competitors were required to use. See United States v. Terminal RR 
    Ass'n, 224 U.S. 383, 397 (1912).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Steel Dynamics states that the Commission needs to build confidence 
    that transmission customers will not be victimized when markets get 
    tight and claims the Commission's record to date has been uneven. Steel 
    Dynamics cites a case in which the Commission determined that Niagara 
    Mohawk Power Corporation had committed several violations of the OASIS 
    posting requirements and standards of conduct in order to favor its 
    marketing affiliate over a third-party user.
        Clarksdale states that it has experienced problems with the posting 
    of ATC by Entergy on the OASIS. Clarksdale states that on July 21, 
    1999, it attempted to purchase from Cajun Electric Cooperative 20 MW of 
    power for whatever length of time that Cajun would have had it 
    available up to one week. Entergy denied the transaction on the basis 
    that the ATC between Entergy and Cajun was zero. Clarksdale complained 
    and the next day the ATC for this interface was shown to be 1,700 
    megawatts; however, by that time Cajun had sold the power to another 
    entity and it was no longer available for Clarksdale. Clarksdale 
    submits that the incident, along with others Clarksdale reported, 
    compels the conclusion that the function of security coordination 
    should be entirely separate from the transmission owner and from the 
    generation owner and that participation in an absolutely independent 
    RTO should be mandated by the Commission in the final rule.
        FMPA states that, whether because of discriminatory motivations or 
    simply because of balkanized perspectives (or both), there have been 
    numerous instances of Florida's dominant transmission owners falling 
    short on the transmission planning performance. According to FMPA, 
    Florida's dominant transmission owners have failed to promptly address 
    regionally significant constraints (until addressing them became 
    advantageous for their own merchant function), and have continued to 
    impose discriminatory transmission-related construction requirements. 
    FMPA claims that relying on functional separation rules to curb the 
    self interest of market-interested transmitters when huge sums of money 
    are at stake is like ``relying on words to hold back the tide.'' \87\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \87\ FMPA at 23-24.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        WPPI states that it routinely experiences and observes subtle and 
    difficult to detect problems in the marketplace. WPPI states that, 
    because they are subtle and difficult to detect, they are not 
    susceptible to any prompt and effective regulatory remedy. WPPI adds 
    that prosecution of complaints is expensive and time consuming and 
    customers do not have the ability to prosecute each such incident.
        WPPI contends that transmission owners are able to dispatch their 
    resources in order to manipulate their exposure to TLRs, while 
    customers cannot. WPPI characterizes this tactic as a ``shell game'' 
    because it is purportedly accomplished by designating fictional sources 
    and sinks and treating one transaction as two separate transactions. 
    WPPI contends that these actions leave other transmission users to bear 
    the costs of curtailments and denials of service. WPPI argues that 
    these manipulations of TLRs are ``rampant.''
        WPPI states that during summer peak periods, when it claims power 
    prices exceeded $5,000/MWh in the Eastern Interconnection, at least one 
    Midwestern transmission-owning utility appears to have been able to 
    abuse its control-area operator authority to gain a market advantage. 
    According to WPPI, as a control-area operator, the transmission owner 
    at issue declared that power shortages had created an emergency 
    situation which allowed it to relax the transmission limitations that 
    it had imposed on other market participants, enabling the transmission 
    owner to acquire less expensive power from the MAPP region. WPPI claims 
    that the transmission owner thereby gained a market advantage, at a 
    time when market advantages were worth huge sums. WPPI claims that most 
    if not all other control-area operators in the region played by the 
    rules and did not abuse the system to access less expensive power for 
    which ATC ostensibly was not available. WPPI asserts that utilities 
    that are not control-area operators had no choice other than to buy 
    high cost, locally generated power, and that they ``lack not only the 
    right, but also the might'' \88\ to declare an emergency or to 
    recalculate ATC to help themselves. WPPI and Cinergy maintain that this 
    recent event provides a clear example of the continuing potential, 
    under present industry structure, for vertically integrated utilities 
    to abuse their transmission control to gain market advantages and for 
    that reason, among others, the Commission should mandate that entities 
    under its jurisdiction participate in RTOs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \88\ WPPI at 31.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        TDU Systems provide a number of examples which raise their concerns 
    about undue discrimination, including: (1) Failure of an incumbent IOU 
    to reduce its own out-of-region power sales during a period when the 
    system was experiencing overloads and the transactions of other 
    transmission users were jeopardized; (2) overly aggressive and 
    selective enforcement of tariff requirements on transmission customers 
    than are imposed on the transmission providers' own merchant function; 
    (3) selectively targeting generating units that are jointly owned by 
    competitors when redispatch of the transmission system is required to 
    relieve line loading; (4) self-serving ATC calculations in 
    circumstances when transmission customers have no way of knowing 
    whether access is being denied legitimately or through manipulation for 
    competitive gain; and (5) onerous and lengthy negotiations to obtain 
    system studies. TDU Systems contend that there is a fire under the 
    smoke of allegations of discrimination, and those complaining of the 
    anecdotal nature of its information haven't provided any evidence to 
    show that discrimination is not occurring.
        TXU Electric states that, if a truly successful, restructured 
    competitive electric industry is to achieve its full potential, it is 
    incumbent of all concerned, transmission providers, users and 
    regulators alike, to move beyond the impediments of the past, including 
    hidden motivations on the part of some, unfounded fears of hidden 
    motivations on the part of others, and a general environment of 
    distrust. TXU Electric adds that, transmission users and regulators 
    must have confidence that the transmission grid is truly an open, non-
    discriminatory and robust commercial highway and transmission providers 
    must inspire that confidence. TXU Electric concludes that the 
    Commission's voluntary collaborative approach is an important step in 
    the right direction.
        LG&E states that, under the current system, transmission owners' 
    operational decisions, even if well intentioned, are surrounded by a 
    cloud of suspicion that, acting in the name of reliability, the 
    transmission owner has enhanced its position in the generation market. 
    LG&E agrees that this perception that the transmission system is not 
    being operated in an even handed manner undermines confidence in the 
    non-discriminatory open access implemented under Order No. 888.
        Virginia Commission agrees that allegations of discrimination 
    represent only known problems, and there may be many unknown ones 
    remaining given that it is difficult for transmission users
    
    [[Page 822]]
    
    to identify and demonstrate instances of discrimination.
        Canada DNR states that discriminatory behavior by transmission 
    operators, identified in the NOPR as the second significant driver for 
    establishment of RTOs, is not perceived as a key impediment to the 
    evolution of efficient bulk power markets in Canada.
        Dynegy argues that transmission provides have the incentive and 
    ability to discriminate in today's markets due to the combination of 
    control over transmission with participation in power markets and the 
    existing regulatory structure that exempts transmission providers from 
    the open access rules of Order Nos. 888 and 889 for its bundled, native 
    load customers. Dynegy argues that the ``native load'' exemption can be 
    and is often manipulated to favor the transmission providers' own or 
    affiliated merchant functions.
        PECO notes that, in their capacity as vertically integrated 
    utilities, transmission providers have access to critical market 
    sensitive information with respect to each transaction (e.g., source, 
    sink), at a time when they are in direct competition in the same 
    markets and with the same transmission customers whose market 
    information they have. PECO argues that, in spite of the existence of 
    functional unbundling and codes of conduct, the serious potential for 
    conflicts of interest and abuse inherent in the current structure 
    cannot be ignored.
        Comments Asserting That Discrimination Is Not a Problem. A number 
    of commenters, mostly transmission owners, do not believe that 
    significant discrimination problems remain with respect to wholesale 
    transmission access pursuant to Order No. 888. As a general matter, 
    those transmission owners whose actions are cited in other pleadings as 
    examples of undue discrimination disagree with those characterizations 
    of the cited events and declare that they provide non-discriminatory 
    transmission service under their OATT. These transmission owners 
    contend that the disputes cited in the pleadings are not the result of 
    discriminatory practices; rather, they are the result of the priority 
    accorded native load customers under the OATT, and good faith errors on 
    the part of the transmission provider trying to administer complex 
    rules and tariff changes that have necessitated fundamental changes to 
    the structure of companies and the way they do business.
        EEI contends that many of the difficulties transmission customers 
    encounter in obtaining price, availability and transmission service 
    result in a technology gap that can be, and often is, interpreted as 
    discriminatory behavior. EEI also contends that many allegations of 
    discrimination are ``rooted at their heart'' on the scarcity of 
    transmission resources and not overt attempts to discriminate against 
    specific customers.
        PSE&G argues that supposition and anecdotal evidence of alleged 
    abuses by transmission owners does not justify a radical change in the 
    existing regulatory scheme. PSE&G contends that, while the incentive to 
    maximize shareholder value is certainly a powerful force in the 
    marketplace, the requirements of law, such as Order Nos. 888 and 889, 
    will prevail.
        Duke argues that mere anecdotes of discrimination, involving 
    unnamed parties and without reference to specific facts, are not 
    evidence of anything, let alone discrimination, and cannot form the 
    basis of a reasoned decision. Duke also lists a number of formal 
    complaint proceedings where the Commission found the transmission 
    provider to have acted properly. Entergy argues that those alleging 
    discrimination, as competitors of transmission providers, have an 
    economic incentive to make their own allegations. Entergy adds that, if 
    perceptions of discrimination were impeding competitive markets, there 
    would not be 20,000 MW of generation investment proposed in its region.
        United Illuminating complains that many of the allegations of undue 
    discrimination presuppose that all utilities are the same, i.e., 
    vertically integrated transmission, distribution and generation 
    companies, and do not recognize that a number of utilities are 
    divesting their generation business.
        Southern Company states that the goal of non-discriminatory 
    transmission service is already being satisfied in the Southeast. 
    Southern Company asserts that it has separated its transmission and 
    reliability functions from its wholesale merchant function up to the 
    level of ``very senior management.'' Southern Company submits that it 
    is unaware of any pending allegations of discrimination against it. 
    Southern Company adds that the Southeast is characterized by large 
    transmission systems such as Southern Company, Tennessee Valley 
    Authority, and Entergy and that these transmission systems are already 
    planned and operated on a regional basis. Southern Company also points 
    out that it alone covers a region as large as (if not larger than) many 
    ISOs currently in existence. Under these circumstances, Southern 
    Company believes that the Commission's open access initiatives have 
    worked in the Southeast and that additional steps are not required to 
    ensure non-discriminatory transmission service.
        MidAmerican asserts that complaints received by the Commission 
    about alleged discrimination should not be the primary basis for 
    determining if the market is successful. According to MidAmerican, if 
    it is assumed that an adequate number of parties are competing 
    successfully, it could be concluded that the complaints may be 
    indications of ill-defined problems not yet resolved, isolated market 
    flaws, or indications of a successful market with somewhat inadequate 
    tools.
        Duke believes that its transmission organization is meeting the 
    needs of its customers as evidenced by the very few and relatively 
    insignificant complaints Duke has received regarding the administration 
    of its OATT. Duke believes that Order No. 888 has been quite successful 
    and, although it agrees with the Commission that elimination of 
    balkanized transmission operations through the formation of larger, 
    regional operations is ultimately preferred, Duke does not believe 
    Order No. 888 should be abandoned hastily.
        Duke argues that disputes are primarily the result of the 
    complexity of the priority scheme in the Commission's pro forma tariff, 
    the rules for which are still being developed; the inherent tension 
    between the Commission's comparability requirement and the requirements 
    of state-regulated native load customers; and the obligation to ensure 
    reliability of the transmission grid on a real time basis. Duke asserts 
    that the vast majority of transactions occurring as a result of Order 
    No. 888 do not produce transmission disputes and, to the extent that 
    isolated instances of discrimination have occurred, the Commission has 
    adequate authority to address the problem.
        Duke also maintains that a major source of confusion involves the 
    rights of native load customers versus wholesale transmission users 
    under the pro forma tariff and that this issue remains subject to 
    disagreement and needs further clarification. Duke says its conclusion 
    is reinforced by its experience as a market participant in areas where 
    there are ISOs. Duke asserts that the establishment of ISOs in 
    California, NEPOOL and PJM has not resulted in the elimination of 
    disputes over tariff ambiguities. Duke questions the assertion that 
    disagreements between customers and individual transmission owners are 
    indicative of significant ongoing discrimination.
        Florida Power Corp. and FP&L's comments are similar to Duke's. 
    Florida
    
    [[Page 823]]
    
    Power Corp. and FP&L state that they have not received any formal 
    complaints alleging undue discrimination with regard to their OATT. 
    Florida Power Corp. and FP&L agree that the increasing number of 
    transactions has led to a concomitant increase in transmission 
    disputes; however, they characterize the disputes as legitimate 
    disagreements over policy or meaning of the pro forma tariff as opposed 
    to true allegations of discriminatory conduct. Like Duke, Florida Power 
    Corp. and FP&L believe that many of the allegations of potentially 
    discriminatory conduct are attributable to two primary areas: (1) 
    Rights of native load customers versus wholesale wheeling customers; 
    and (2) disputes arising from the complex priority scheme in the pro 
    forma tariff. According to FP&L, disputes will still occur until the 
    issues relating to priority rights are resolved. FP&L argues that the 
    Commission cannot expect that any remedy will eliminate discrimination 
    claims in light of the Eighth Circuit Court's decision in Northern 
    States Power Co. v. FERC.\89\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \89\ See Northern States Power Co. (Minnesota) and Northern 
    States Power Co. (Wisconsin), 83 FERC para. 61,098, clarified, 83 
    FERC para. 61,338, reh'g, clarification and stay denied, 84 FERC 
    para. 61,128 (1998), remanded, Northern States Power Co., et al. v. 
    FERC, 176 F.3d 1090 (8th Cir. 1999), reh'g denied (unpublished order 
    dated Sept. 1, 1999), order on remand, 89 FERC para. 61,178 (1999) 
    (request to withdraw curtailment procedures pending) (Northern 
    States).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        FPL and Florida Power Corp. argue that unsubstantiated allegations 
    do not constitute evidence of discrimination and should be 
    characterized as legitimate disputes over tariff interpretation, while 
    EEI describes some of the allegations as ``one-sided characterizations 
    of cases now being litigated.'' FPL also contends that some intervenors 
    adopt the stance that, whenever the transmission provider and customer 
    are in disagreement, it evidences discrimination. Florida Power Corp. 
    states that, if undue discrimination exists outside of Florida, it is a 
    function of the newness of the Commission's open access rules, and it 
    is far too soon to declare functional unbundling ineffective. Florida 
    Power Corp. agrees with the Commission's statement that it may be 
    impossible to distinguish an inaccurate ATC presented in good faith 
    from an inaccurate ATC posted for the purpose of favoring the 
    transmission provider's marketing interests, but concludes that, once 
    technical issues have been resolved about ATC calculations, the volume 
    of disputes will be greatly diminished. Florida Power Corp. adds that 
    there is no evidence of a pattern of industry-wide undue 
    discrimination, and concludes that mere perceptions cannot provide a 
    justification for generic remedial action.
        Entergy, FirstEnergy, Alliance Companies and Lenard argue that 
    there is no credible or substantial evidence in the record that 
    transmission owners have been engaging in discriminatory practices in 
    providing transmission services under Order Nos. 888 and 889 and, 
    therefore, the Commission should not, and lawfully cannot, rely on mere 
    allegations of discriminatory conduct. FirstEnergy states that it has 
    doubled its control area reservation and back office staff to handle 
    the five percent of its transmission business that is wholesale related 
    and still is having difficulty keeping pace with OASIS and tagging 
    administrative processes. FirstEnergy asserts that due to relatively 
    new processes associated with open access transmission, there are often 
    good faith disputes over the proper interpretation of the Commission's 
    requirements and these disputes should not be mischaracterized as 
    continued discrimination.
        Commission Conclusion. Engineering and Economic Inefficiencies. In 
    this Final Rule, we affirm our preliminary determination that the 
    engineering and economic inefficiencies identified in the NOPR 
    90 are present in the operation, planning and expansion of 
    regional transmission grids, and that they may affect electric system 
    reliability and impede the growth of fully competitive bulk power 
    markets. The sources of these inefficiencies involve: difficulty 
    determining ATC; parallel path flows; the limited scope of available 
    information and the use of non-market approaches to managing 
    transmission congestion; planning and investing in new transmission 
    facilities; pancaking of transmission access charges; the absence of 
    clear transmission rights; the absence of secondary markets in 
    transmission service; and the possible disincentives created by the 
    level and structure of transmission rates. Virtually all commenters 
    agree that at least some of these inefficiencies exist. There is 
    substantial agreement among commenters that most of the engineering and 
    economic obstacles identified by the NOPR arise from the current 
    industry structure and can be rectified through development of regional 
    transmission entities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \90\ FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,697.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As noted by Allegheny, the industry historically has done an 
    excellent job of regional coordination in implementing voluntary 
    standards to maintain the security of the transmission system through 
    various study groups and planning committees. However, virtually all 
    commenters agree that new competitive pressures are interfering with 
    the use of traditional methods of coordinated regional transmission 
    planning. As a result, new transmission additions that will benefit 
    reliable grid operations are being delayed. Some commenters state that 
    the increasing frequency and duration of power outages have cost the 
    economy billions of dollars, and they predict that unless this problem 
    is addressed now the reliability of power supply will worsen. The 
    traditional use of regional coordination through study groups and 
    planning committees is no longer effective because these entities are 
    usually not vested with the broad decisionmaking authority needed to 
    address larger issues that affect an entire region, including managing 
    congestion, planning and investing in new transmission facilities, 
    pancaking of transmission access charges, the absence of secondary 
    markets in transmission service, and the possible disincentives created 
    by the level and structure of transmission rates.
        We recognize, as some commenters point out, that the degree to 
    which these inefficiencies act as obstacles to electric competition and 
    reliability varies from system to system. However, we believe it is 
    clear that such inefficiencies exist and are sufficiently widespread 
    that they must be addressed to prevent them from interfering with 
    reliability and competitive electricity markets.
        Continuing Opportunities for Undue Discrimination. As noted, many 
    transmission customers and some transmission providers argue that there 
    are continuing opportunities for undue discrimination under the 
    existing functional unbundling approach. A number of the commenters 
    provide examples of events that, in their view, indicate that 
    transmission owners are engaging in undue discrimination. These 
    commenters also generally believe that even the perception of undue 
    discrimination is a significant impediment to the evolution of 
    competitive electricity markets. A number of transmission providers 
    challenge the relevancy of these examples, characterizing them as 
    unsubstantiated or anecdotal allegations that do not rise to the level 
    of evidence of undue discrimination necessary to support generic 
    action. These transmission providers further contend that many disputes 
    simply reflect good faith efforts of transmission providers to 
    interpret the Commission's pro forma tariff and standards of conduct. 
    These
    
    [[Page 824]]
    
    commenters also generally share the view that the Commission should not 
    base its decisions in this rule on mere perceptions that may be 
    prevalent in the industry.
        For the most part, the challenges mounted by these commenters are 
    focused against a determination by the Commission that it should 
    mandate participation in RTOs in this Rule. As noted in Section C.1 of 
    this Rule, we have also determined that a measured and appropriate 
    response to the evidence presented and concerns raised is to adopt a 
    voluntary approach to the formation of RTOs. However, as discussed 
    below, we do conclude that opportunities for undue discrimination 
    continue to exist that may not be remedied adequately by functional 
    unbundling. We further conclude that perceptions of undue 
    discrimination can also impede the development of efficient and 
    competitive electric markets. These concerns, in addition to the 
    economic and engineering impediments affecting reliability, operational 
    efficiency and competition, provide the basis for issuing this Final 
    Rule.
        At the outset, it is important to note that the conclusion that 
    there are continuing opportunities for undue discrimination should not 
    be construed as a finding that particular utilities, or individuals 
    within those utilities, are acting in bad faith or deliberately 
    violating our open access requirements or standards of conduct. 
    However, we cannot ignore the fact that the vertically integrated 
    structure reflected in the industry today was created to support the 
    business objectives of a franchised monopoly service provider that 
    owned and operated generation, transmission and distribution facilities 
    primarily to serve requirements customers at wholesale and retail in a 
    non-competitive environment. Clearly, there are aspects of this 
    vertically integrated structure that are difficult to transition into a 
    competitive market. As we noted in the NOPR and Order No. 888, 
    vertically integrated utilities have the incentive and the opportunity 
    to favor their generation interests over those of their competitors. If 
    a transmission provider's marketing interests have favorable access to 
    transmission system information or receive more favorable treatment of 
    their transmission requests, this obviously creates a disadvantage for 
    market competitors.
        While we have attempted to rely on functional unbundling to address 
    our concerns about undue discrimination, there are indications that 
    this is difficult for transmission providers to implement and difficult 
    for the market and the Commission to monitor and police. In cases in 
    which the Commission has issued formal orders, we have found serious 
    concerns with functional separation and improper information sharing 
    with respect to at least four public utilities.91 In 
    addition, our enforcement staff is receiving an increasing number of 
    telephone calls about standards of conduct issues, ranging from simple 
    questions about what is permissible conduct to more serious complaints 
    alleging actual violations of the standards of conduct. In a number of 
    cases, our staff has verified non-compliance with the standards of 
    conduct.92 The petitioners for rulemaking in Docket No. 
    RM98-5-000 allege that there are common instances of ``unauthorized 
    exchanges of competitively valuable information on reservations and 
    schedules between transmission system operators and their own or 
    affiliated merchant operation employees.'' 93 They also cite 
    OASIS data showing an instance where a transmission provider quickly 
    confirmed requests for firm transmission service by an affiliate, while 
    service requests from independent marketers took much longer to 
    approve. We believe that some of the identified standards of conduct 
    violations are transitional issues resulting from a new way of doing 
    business, and we acknowledge that many utilities are making good-faith 
    efforts to properly implement standards of conduct. However, we also 
    believe that there is great potential for standards of conduct 
    violations that will never even be reported or detected. Moreover, as 
    we stated in the NOPR,94 we are increasingly concerned about 
    the extensive regulatory oversight and administrative burdens that have 
    resulted from policing compliance with standards of conduct. The use of 
    standards of conduct is not the best way to correct vertical 
    integration problems. Their use may be unnecessary in a better 
    structured market where operational control and responsibility for the 
    transmission system is structurally separated from the merchant 
    generation function of owners of transmission.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \91\ See Wisconsin Public Power Inc. SYSTEM v. Wisconsin Public 
    Service Corporation, 83 FERC para. 61,198 at 61,855, 61,860, order 
    on reh'g, 84 FERC para. 61,120 (1998) (WPSC's actions raised 
    ``serious concerns'' as to functional separation; WP&L's actions 
    demonstrated that it provided unduly preferential treatment to its 
    merchant function); Washington Water Power Co., 83 FERC para. 61,097 
    at 61,463, further order, 83 FERC para. 61,282 (1998) (utility found 
    to have violated standards in connection with its marketing 
    affiliate); Utah Associated Municipal Power Systems v. PacifiCorp, 
    87 FERC para. 61,044 (1999) (finding that PacifiCorp had failed to 
    maintain functional separation between merchant and transmission 
    functions).
        \92\ See, e.g., Communications of Market Information Between 
    Affiliates, Docket No. IN99-2-000, 87 FERC para. 61,012 (1999) 
    (Commission issued declaratory order based on hotline complaint 
    clarifying that it is an undue preference in violation of section 
    205 of the FPA for a public utility to tell an affiliate to look for 
    a marketing offer prior to posting the offer publicly).
        \93\ Petition at 15.
        \94\ FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,711-12.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We also cannot dismiss the significance of reports of undue 
    discrimination simply because they are not reduced to formal 
    complaints. As many intervenors have asserted, the cost and time 
    required to pursue legal channels to prove discrimination will often 
    provide an inadequate remedy because, among other things, the 
    competition may have already been lost.95 The fact that 
    evidence of discrimination in the fast-paced marketplace is not 
    systematic or complete is not unexpected. The fact remains that claims 
    of undue discrimination have not diminished, and there is no evidence 
    that discrimination is becoming a non-issue.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \95\ For example, EPSA has told us: ``Furthermore, even if the 
    exercise of such discrimination could be adequately documented and 
    packaged in the form of a complaint under section 206 of the Federal 
    Power Act under a more streamlined complaint process contemplated by 
    the Commission, it would still be extremely costly and inefficient 
    to deal with such complaints on a case-by-case basis. More than 
    likely, the potential power transactions for which transmission 
    principally was sought would disappear by the time a Commission 
    ruling was obtained. Motion to Intervene and Comments of Electric 
    Power Supply Association in Support of Petition for Rulemaking, 
    Docket No. RM98-5-000 (filed Sept. 21, 1998), at 3.''
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Finally, we continue to believe that perceptions of discrimination 
    are significant impediments to competitive markets. Efficient and 
    competitive markets will develop only if market participants have 
    confidence that the system is administered fairly.96 Lack of 
    market confidence resulting from the perception of discrimination is 
    not mere rhetoric. It has real-world consequences for market 
    participants and consumers. As stated by NERC, there is a reluctance on 
    the part of market participants to share operational real-time and 
    planning data with transmission providers because of the suspicion that 
    they could be providing an advantage to their affiliated marketing 
    groups,97 and this can, in turn, impair the reliability
    
    [[Page 825]]
    
    of the nation's electric systems. Lack of market confidence may deter 
    generation expansion, leading to higher consumer prices. Fears of 
    discriminatory curtailment may deter access to existing generation or 
    deter entry by new sources of generation that would otherwise mitigate 
    price spikes of the type that have been experienced during peak periods 
    in the last two summer peak periods. Mistrust of ATC calculations will 
    cause transactions involving regional markets to be viewed as more 
    risky and will unnecessarily constrain the market area, thereby 
    reducing competition and raising prices for consumers. The perception 
    that a transmission provider's power sales are more reliable may 
    provide subtle competitive advantages in wholesale markets, e.g., 
    purchasers may favor sales by the transmission provider or its 
    affiliate, expecting greater transmission service reliability. We 
    believe that the potential for such problems increases in a competitive 
    environment unless the market can be made structurally efficient and 
    transparent with respect to information, and equitable in its treatment 
    of competing participants.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \96\ For example, a representative of Blue Ridge told us: 
    ``There simply is no shaking the notion that integrated generation 
    and transmission-owning utilities have strategic and competitive 
    interests to consider when addressing transmission constraints. 
    Functional unbundling and enforcement of [standard of] conduct 
    standards require herculean policing efforts, and they are not 
    practical.'' Regional ISO Conference (Richmond), Transcript at 20.
        \97\ NERC Reliability Assessment 1998-2007, at 39.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In summary, we affirm our conclusion in the NOPR that economic and 
    engineering inefficiencies and the continuing opportunity for undue 
    discrimination are impeding competitive markets. As noted below, we 
    conclude that RTOs will remedy these impediments and that it is 
    essential for the Commission to issue this Final Rule.
    
    B. Benefits That RTOs Can Offer to Address Remaining Barriers and 
    Impediments
    
        In the NOPR the Commission explained how the use of independent 
    RTOs could help eliminate the opportunity for unduly discriminatory 
    practices by transmission providers, restore the trust among 
    competitors that all are playing by the same rules, and reduce the need 
    for overly intrusive regulatory oversight.98 The Commission 
    further identified a number of significant benefits of establishing 
    RTOs: (1) RTOs would improve efficiencies in the management of the 
    transmission grid; 99 (2) RTOs would improve grid 
    reliability; (3) RTOs would remove opportunities for discriminatory 
    transmission practices; (4) RTOs would result in improved market 
    performance; and (5) RTOs would facilitate lighter-handed governmental 
    regulation.100 The Commission requested comments on the 
    benefits of RTOs and the magnitude of these benefits.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \98\ FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,714.
        \99\ These efficiencies include, among other things, regional 
    transmission pricing, improved congestion management of the grid, 
    more accurate ATC calculations, more effective management of 
    parallel path flows, reduced transaction costs, and facilitation of 
    state retail access programs.
        \100\ FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,716-20.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments. Description of Benefits. Many commenters support the 
    establishment of RTOs throughout the United States to effectively 
    remove the remaining impediments to competition in the power 
    markets.101 Illinois Commission states that the pursuit of 
    competition as the driving force for markets in the electric industry 
    requires developing new institutions and accepting new practices, and 
    RTOs are the logical next organizational step in the electric industry 
    restructuring process. Entergy agrees that significant benefits can be 
    achieved by the creation of properly-structured, large RTOs and that 
    the Commission has accurately described many of those benefits in the 
    NOPR. Ohio Commission believes that a properly structured RTO will 
    facilitate efficient regional generation markets, while preventing 
    incumbent holding companies from improperly exercising their market 
    power.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \101\ See, e.g., PJM, DOE, Illinois Commission.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        PG&E acknowledges that the benefits of Order No. 888 have been 
    largely reaped, and still significant impediments to an efficient 
    competitive marketplace remain in place where RTOs are not yet 
    operational. Moreover, industry restructuring has led to new and 
    complex operational issues that were unanticipated at the time Order 
    No. 888 was issued. RTOs represent the most promising and efficient 
    regulatory method for the Commission to address these issues. Without 
    RTOs, it would be incumbent on the Commission to take very detailed and 
    intrusive actions because the transmission grid cannot operate reliably 
    and efficiently unless the competitive and operational issues are 
    resolved.
        Ontario Power agrees that the electric power industry should now 
    move beyond the functional unbundling approach prescribed in Order Nos. 
    888 and 889. TDU Systems asserts that wholesale electric markets will 
    benefit immensely if RTOs can simply provide transmission service on an 
    unbiased basis, treating all customers fairly, and take the lead role 
    in regional transmission planning.
        On the other hand, a number of vertically integrated utilities do 
    not support government action to form RTOs. For example, Duke 
    recognizes that there may be transmission functions performed today 
    within individual company control centers, within existing control 
    areas, or within existing reliability councils that may be better and/
    or more efficiently performed by a regional transmission organization. 
    However, Duke also believes that the industry is voluntarily working to 
    identify such functions or processes and is effecting meaningful 
    changes and improvements in a timely manner. Accordingly, Duke believes 
    that this progress should not be pre-empted by regulatory mandates, and 
    that there are insufficient data, at this time, to draw meaningful 
    conclusions regarding the magnitude of benefits that will result from 
    RTO formation.
        Similarly, MidAmerican argues that benefits of RTOs can be realized 
    without RTOs. MidAmerican claims that existing regional organizations, 
    such as MAPP, are capable of meeting the Commission's concerns about 
    eliminating existing impediments to an efficient competitive 
    marketplace. FP&L states that the NOPR does not attempt to quantify any 
    of the claimed benefits of RTOs. FP&L is unaware of any data that 
    specifically and objectively show that ISOs have saved ratepayers money 
    in those areas where ISOs have been established. Nor is it aware of any 
    specific quantification of any other actual or projected benefits of 
    ISOs.
        Some commenters contend that the costs of establishing RTOs must 
    not exceed the benefits. Cal DWR argues that significant start-up costs 
    and costs associated with duplicative efforts have been higher than the 
    NOPR appears to recognize. These costs entail not only costs of the new 
    organization itself, but also market participants' costs in travel, 
    staffing, and other expenses and investments necessary to participate 
    or operate in new structures. Other commenters suggest that each 
    proposal contained in the NOPR should be carefully evaluated for its 
    cost consequences.\102\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \102\ See, e.g., Cal DWR, California Board, Southern Company, 
    Aluminum Companies.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Seattle notes that its region has the lowest cost electricity in 
    the Nation and an already thriving wholesale market with little price 
    volatility. Assuming that an RTO is projected to result in additional 
    transmission costs, Northwest consumers will be less willing to incur 
    these costs than consumers in regions where power costs are high and 
    wholesale prices are extremely volatile. Snohomish and Aluminum 
    Companies assert that one of fatal flaws of the IndeGO proposal \103\ 
    was that its demonstrable benefits did
    
    [[Page 826]]
    
    not clearly outweigh the costs of its start-up and operation. Snohomish 
    requests that the Commission not impose an RTO with similar flaws upon 
    the Northwest. A number of commenters also urge the Commission to 
    reject any RTO filing for the Northwest or other regions that fails to 
    provide a strong demonstration that its benefits will substantially 
    outweigh its projected costs.\104\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \103\ IndeGO is an independent grid operator proposal that has 
    been discussed for the Pacific Northwest and Rocky Mountain area.
        \104\ See, e.g., Big Rivers, Chelan, California Board, 
    Industrial Customers, Arizona Commission, EEI, Idaho Commission, 
    Washington Commission.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        To ensure that RTOs are formed in a cost effective and efficient 
    manner, SRP proposes a phased approach to RTO development that would 
    allow RTOs to gradually take on new functions and responsibilities in 
    response to the needs to the market. In addition, the Commission should 
    require RTOs to establish criteria against which they will measure cost 
    effectiveness and efficient performance and to make adjustments where 
    criteria are not being met.
        Canada DNR states that structural differences between the Canadian 
    and American electric power industries mean that there may be fewer 
    potential benefits from the formation of RTOs in Canada than those 
    identified by the Commission for the United States. Consequently, it 
    believes that Canadian jurisdiction should be able to assess the costs 
    and benefits of RTO proposals. In addition, it notes that some may find 
    that, although the benefits do warrant the associated costs, they may 
    address impediments to efficient electricity markets through other 
    means.
        Comments on RTOs Improving Efficiencies in the Management of the 
    Transmission Grid.\105\ PJM agrees with the Commission that placing as 
    many grid management functions as possible under an RTO is the best 
    means of bringing the benefits of RTOs to the marketplace. A number of 
    commenters address specific RTO actions as examples of grid management 
    efficiencies, including use of regional transmission pricing, accurate 
    estimation of ATC, efficient planning for grid expansion, and 
    facilitating state retail access programs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \105\ As noted earlier, many of the principal benefits of RTOs 
    (e.g., congestion management, improved reliability, parallel path 
    flow resolution) are discussed in greater detail later as RTO 
    minimum characteristics and functions; however, some of the 
    commenters cited here mention these benefits as part of their 
    overall discussion of RTOs improving efficiencies in the management 
    of the transmission grid.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        FMPA claims that a just and reasonable RTO transmission rate, with 
    a unified regional loss factor or factors, would provide a regionally 
    rational approach, which is not provided by the existing fragmented 
    regime. Pancaking has long prevented FMPA and its members located on 
    the Florida Power Corp. transmission system from economically 
    delivering the output from their portions of the St. Lucie nuclear 
    plant to their loads. Similarly, WPSC notes that without an RTO that 
    encompasses the Midwest region, unjustified pancaked transmission rates 
    may inhibit the efficient flow of power across the region.
        PacifiCorp supports the Commission goal of eliminating transmission 
    pancaking, to the extent practical. PacifiCorp maintains that such a 
    goal could be furthered by the creation of the most geographically 
    expansive RTOs that are technically workable. The goal also could be 
    met, however, if multiple RTOs within the western United States agree 
    to reciprocally eliminate charges in connection with the ``export'' or 
    ``import'' of power from one RTO to another. In the western United 
    States, such ``reciprocity'' agreements may be preferable to the 
    creation of a single RTO that otherwise is too large to be efficient, 
    safe and reliable, or of a single RTO for which operating principles 
    must be unreasonably compromised to attract all necessary transmission 
    owners.
        Allegheny asserts that even with an RTO, grid inefficiencies such 
    as rate pancaking and congestion will continue unless an appropriate 
    pricing mechanism is adopted. The various RTO structures, regardless of 
    size and number, would still need to work cooperatively to ensure that 
    the various interfaces are sufficient to maintain the reliable 
    operation of the system. The formation of an RTO, by itself, does not 
    bring a particular benefit.
        Rochdale asserts that a properly structured independent RTO, with a 
    broad geographic scope, could eliminate incorrect calculations of ATC 
    and TTC. Furthermore, the motive for discrimination and possible 
    manipulation that exists where transmission owners with affiliated 
    power marketers are responsible for reporting ATC and TTC would become 
    moot. FMPA contends that, without an RTO, most market participants 
    would remain unable to replicate or trust the transmission owners' ATC 
    calculations. FMPA indicates that customers and regulators cannot 
    properly review transmission providers' ATC accounting without access 
    to their TTC starting points; however, existing Florida OASIS sites do 
    not provide TTC information. In addition, ATC calculations require 
    extensive application of engineering judgment. FMPA questions whether 
    market-interested transmission providers can be trusted to exercise 
    such judgment disinterestedly. Consequently, FMPA believes that an RTO 
    could provide unbiased ATC information.
        Many commenters believe that RTOs would provide more efficient 
    planning for transmission and generation investments.\106\ For example, 
    Entergy agrees that the creation of RTOs can lead to more efficient and 
    effective planning and expansion of the transmission system. However, 
    to ensure efficient investment in the transmission system, Entergy 
    proposes that the Commission encourage innovative pricing policies to 
    replace traditional cost-of-service ratemaking in certain respects. 
    Minnesota Power also agrees that an RTO would help identify the best 
    place on the grid to locate new generation. It believes that the 
    centralization of regional reliability planning is a big step forward 
    for enabling independent power producers to build projects and also is 
    a significant benefit to each transmission owner who deals with 
    requests from generation groups.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \106\ Comments are addressed in greater detail in the discussion 
    of planning and expansion as an RTO minimum function.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Illinois Commission and Texas Commission state that electricity 
    consumers in states adopting retail direct access can directly and 
    fully benefit from the operation of properly constituted RTOs and their 
    concomitant improvements in system efficiency, reliability and market 
    competition.
        Comments on RTOs Improving Grid Reliability. Many commenters agree 
    that an RTO could provide improved reliability.\107\ Minnesota Power 
    supports the formation of a single regional body that operates the 
    regional grid and enforces reliability rules for the entire region. It 
    suggests that a non-profit RTO can be expected to enforce reliability 
    rules fairly and aggressively and, thus, require minimal Commission 
    oversight. On the other hand, a for-profit RTO may be perceived as 
    biased towards making a profit at the expense of reliability and may 
    require additional scrutiny by the Commission.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \107\ Comments are addressed in greater detail in the discussion 
    of short-term reliability as an RTO minimum characteristic.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Michigan Commission strongly supports creating an RTO for the 
    Midwest that is large enough to ensure reliability. It is very 
    concerned that splitting the Midwest region into improperly sized 
    competing ISOs, RTOs, and/or Transcos will affect regional reliability 
    and delay the benefits of competition. Also, splitting a region into 
    multiple RTOs reduces
    
    [[Page 827]]
    
    access to economic generation due to increased transmission charges. 
    Michigan Commission believes competition and reliability within the 
    region will be served best if the Transmission Alliance and Midwest ISO 
    are joined.
        Comments on RTOs Removing Opportunities for Discriminatory 
    Transmission Practices. Many commenters, mostly transmission customers, 
    agree that RTOs will remedy continuing opportunities for undue 
    discrimination.\108\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \108\ See, e.g., American Forest, TDU Systems, WPPI, Sonat, 
    Illinois Commission, Arizona Commission, FMPA, Tampa Electric, 
    Advisory Committee ISO-NE. Comments are addressed in more detail 
    later in the discussion of existing discriminatory conduct.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As both a buyer and seller of wholesale electricity, Oglethorpe 
    supports the evolution of competitive markets for generation service. 
    To ensure that competitive markets evolve and perform in a workable 
    manner, market participants should be assured access to the 
    transmission system on a fair and comparable basis, without regard to 
    transmission ownership. It believes that true competition can occur 
    only with widespread, open and nondiscriminatory access to the 
    transmission system. UtiliCorp claims that removing control over access 
    to transmission from the remaining large transmission-owning utilities 
    and placing such control in properly structured RTOs will go a long way 
    toward eliminating the remaining obstructions to effective competition 
    in wholesale markets for electric power.
        Virginia Commission agrees that discrimination exists and that RTOs 
    can help facilitate competition and police non-competitive activities. 
    However, Virginia Commission believes that it is premature to conclude 
    that there is no role for rigorous governmental regulation. Virginia 
    Commission urges that the Commission not rely exclusively on RTOs to 
    detect, prevent and penalize violations of the FPA and should itself 
    provide for expedited handling of allegations regarding discrimination 
    and market power abuses.
        On the other hand, a number of commenters, mostly transmission 
    owners, do not believe that RTOs are needed to address undue 
    discrimination because they do not believe that significant 
    discrimination problems remain with respect to wholesale transmission 
    access pursuant to Order No. 888.\109\ PSE&G argues that, if a 
    misperception exists in the marketplace as to the trustworthiness or 
    incentives of transmission owners as a whole, it may signal a need for 
    an industry-wide educational campaign that discusses transmission 
    operation and system reliability. However, such a misperception does 
    not, in and of itself, warrant altering the structure of the industry.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \109\ See, e.g., United Illuminating, Southern Company, 
    MidAmerican, Duke, PSE&G, FP&L, Entergy, FirstEnergy, Alliance 
    Companies, Lenard, Florida Power Corp.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments on RTOs Resulting in Improved Market Performance. DOE 
    asserts that open and comparable transmission access can reduce both 
    concentration in generation markets (by expanding the boundaries of the 
    relevant market) and the potential to discriminate through vertical 
    control but cannot, in its view, eliminate all market power. The 
    establishment of an independent RTO can and should substantially 
    mitigate the potential exercise of market power through vertical 
    control, because dispatch and related transmission services will be 
    provided by an independent entity with no financial interest in 
    wholesale market participants. Furthermore, the expected contribution 
    of an RTO in reducing the risk of horizontal market power will be 
    realized only if RTOs have sufficient ``critical mass.'' Appropriately 
    sized RTOs are necessary to assure a transparent and fair marketplace 
    for all generation.
        EPA notes that RTOs can play an important role in the development 
    of environmentally preferred or ``green'' electricity products for use 
    by states that are implementing retail electricity competition. As the 
    operator of the transmission system, an RTO will have access to 
    detailed information on the operations of individual generators as well 
    as fuel type and air emissions, even where such information is 
    considered confidential. RTOs are uniquely situated to assemble the 
    information necessary to determine environmental attributes of specific 
    retail electricity products for purposes of consumer information 
    disclosure. EPA notes that this is already occurring in New England, 
    where ISO-NE has agreed to provide the states with information on 
    environmental attributes and resource mix for individual generators. In 
    addition to facilitating consumer information disclosure, EPA notes 
    that this information will support other state policies, such as 
    renewable portfolio standards and generation performance standards.
        Comments on RTOs Facilitating Lighter-Handed Governmental 
    Regulation. Although most commenters agree that properly-designed RTOs 
    can be self-governing to a certain extent, the vast majority of 
    commenters believe that the Commission has either overstated the 
    reliance it should place on self-governance or has reached this 
    conclusion prematurely. Most of these commenters suggest that there is 
    insufficient evidence at this time to reach the conclusion that RTO 
    formation would necessarily result in lighter-handed regulation. A 
    number of commenters also caution that the Commission should not 
    significantly reduce its oversight of RTOs until they are proven to be 
    effective. British Columbia Ministry states that the structure of 
    future RTOs should minimize additional layers of administration and 
    oversight. However, at least one commenter, Cal DWR, noting that RTOs 
    are themselves transmission monopolies subject to the FPA, argues that 
    the Commission should continue its course of regulating RTOs to ensure 
    compliance with legal and policy requirements.
        PJM generally supports the Commission's conclusion regarding light-
    handed regulation. It notes that, where ISOs' decisions are independent 
    and conducted through an extensive stakeholder processes to produce 
    collaborative solutions to market issues, the Commission can defer 
    confidently to those decisions. Under such circumstances, the 
    Commission can be assured that ISO proposals to changes market rules 
    and procedures would promote competitive markets and are not designed 
    to favor any one group of market participants.
        PJM argues further that the Commission accord greater flexibility 
    to properly structured RTOs to change market rules and procedures 
    without Commission filings. An RTO with an established stakeholder 
    process could publish some changes in market rules on its internet 
    site, without requiring prior Commission approval. In the event that a 
    market participant objected, it could file a complaint with the 
    Commission. PJM says the benefit is that the market would not be 
    hindered by delay in implementing new rules. Other rules could be 
    permitted to go into effect upon filing, rather than at the end of the 
    Commission review process.
        Some commenters suggest that the Commission be particularly 
    deferential to decisions that result from ADR processes. For example, 
    PNGC supports strong and broad dispute resolution power in an RTO. It 
    argues that many small transmission users currently have no effective 
    way to be heard regarding service complaints, outage restoration, and 
    adequacy of equipment or maintenance because of the high cost of 
    bringing such a dispute to the Commission. In addition, Desert STAR
    
    [[Page 828]]
    
    asserts that where the Commission has approved the charter governance 
    and ADR processes of an RTO as being sufficiently broad-based and 
    independent, the Commission should give some deference to decisions 
    reached through the RTO's ADR processes. However, deference in dispute 
    resolution to an RTO should not impair a transmission user's 
    fundamental rights under section 211 of the FPA. Because the RTO will 
    be a jurisdictional entity, the Commission is an appropriate appeals 
    forum. Similarly, Seattle supports the Commission proposal to defer to 
    RTOs on matters involving commercial, operating and planning practices, 
    as well as to resolve disputes, but argues that it is too early to tell 
    whether ISOs transcos or other forms of RTOs can be deferred to in lieu 
    of regulatory filings.
        MidAmerican welcomes the Commission's proposed lighter-handed 
    approach to regulation, but questions whether lighter-handed 
    regulation, in fact, will be derived from the proposed rule. 
    MidAmerican proposes that the Commission issue a policy statement to 
    provide general guidance on how it intends to give deference to RTOs. 
    For example, the policy should outline that, if a transmission owner 
    follows RTO directives, it will be presumed that the transmission owner 
    does not have transmission market power and that it is not capable of 
    transmission market discrimination. The Commission should give 
    deference to RTOs to design tariffs that include rate incentives and 
    should permit returns on equity that compensate transmission owners for 
    additional risks and for competitive market development.
        A number of commenters argue that there is as yet no evidence to 
    support the conclusion that RTO formation should lead to lighter-handed 
    regulation. Duke and Entergy argue that each of the existing ISOs has 
    been mired in significant litigation with market participants, and the 
    Commission's dockets are loaded with cases arising out of decisions 
    made by ISOs. They and NECPUC suggest that this raises the possibility 
    that RTOs represent a new layer of regulatory oversight of market 
    activities, supplementing rather than replacing federal and state 
    regulation. FP&L states that the independence and objectivity of the 
    Florida Public Service Commission make it unnecessary to create a 
    formal (and costly) separate entity to operate and oversee the Florida 
    grid as an RTO.
        Other commenters suggest that the probability that RTOs can be 
    self-regulating may be overstated. APPA argues that existing ISOs still 
    represent the interests of the transmission owners that formed these 
    ISOs. In addition, it argues that each ISO is a market participant 
    because its revenue recovery is affected by the performance of 
    transmission, ancillary services, and energy imbalance spot markets. It 
    suggests that the right to self-regulation must be earned in the 
    marketplace, not bestowed by regulators in advance.
        NECPUC argues that not only must an RTO be properly structured to 
    be self-regulating, so must the utilities involved, or the RTO will 
    constantly be involved in the business of dispute resolution. It 
    suggests that during a transition phase, a certain level of active 
    regulation may be inescapable. For example, it notes that the 
    Commission stepped in quite definitively in developing the governance 
    of the New England Power Pool. NECPUC believes that strong intervention 
    by the Commission was effective at achieving progress when the parties 
    in New England stalemated.
        PG&E claims that an RTO is uniquely situated to handle a number of 
    responsibilities, including reliability enforcement and sanctions, 
    market monitoring, and reporting non-reliability market-related 
    violations. However, a single entity, no matter how well-structured and 
    independent, cannot successfully fulfill several competing roles 
    simultaneously, i.e., serve as judge, jury and advocate. While the RTO 
    can do much to create region-specific processes that meet the needs of 
    market participants, the Commission must retain ultimate oversight. The 
    RTO is not a substitute for this function. With the tremendous volume 
    of transactions flowing through an RTO, even small errors in energy or 
    financial accounting can lead to huge cost shifts. Market participants 
    need to have a remedy at the Commission if issues are not resolved 
    adequately by the RTO.
        Other commenters believe that the Commission may have to play a 
    strong role in ADR. Arizona Commission urges the Commission to give 
    respect rather than deference to decisions reached through an RTO's ADR 
    processes. TDU Systems state that the ability of an RTO transmission 
    customer to obtain ultimate Commission review of a dispute with the RTO 
    (or another RTO customer) should not be cut off. RTO tariffs should 
    contain ADR provisions that allow for mediation or other low-cost forms 
    of ADR so disputes can, if possible, be resolved without resort to the 
    Commission. If this is not possible, the Commission should consider any 
    dispute that comes to it after the conclusion of ADR at an RTO on a de 
    novo basis.
        In dealing with disputes between RTOs and their customers, TDU 
    Systems suggests that the Commission be sensitive to the issue of 
    ``minority rights.'' The Commission should ensure that transmission 
    customers with complaints against their RTOs get due process and a full 
    and fair opportunity to air their concerns. Just because a customer may 
    take a position in a dispute not shared by many others does not mean 
    that it is automatically wrong.
        Moreover, TDU Systems believe that the Commission, in considering 
    the ADR issue, should make a distinction between ISOs or other RTOs 
    that are not-for-profit or quasi-governmental in nature and for-profit 
    RTOs. For-profit RTOs may not necessarily be well suited to be the 
    arbiters of disputes, especially where they are an involved party. It 
    would be inappropriate for the Commission simply to ``off load'' 
    dispute resolution duties to a private for-profit entity, especially if 
    the entity is an interested party in the dispute. ISOs, on the other 
    hand, are more quasi-governmental in nature, and if fully independent, 
    may be in a better position to attempt to resolve a dispute, subject to 
    Commission review.
        Duke asserts that streamlined filings and approval procedures could 
    reduce costs that would otherwise be borne by market participants. 
    Reducing regulatory burdens could constitute one form of incentive to 
    encourage RTO participation. The policy could be applied equally for 
    non-profit and for-profit RTOs. On the other hand, TDU Systems argues 
    that opportunities for streamlined RTO filings could set a very 
    dangerous precedent, especially if applied to incentive rate filings of 
    for-profit RTOs. RTOs will still be monopolies (although hopefully 
    large horizontal ones, rather than smaller, vertically integrated 
    ones). The norm for RTO filings should still be full Commission 
    scrutiny. Entergy argues that the Commission should encourage proposals 
    submitted by RTOs designed to increase regulatory efficiencies and 
    reduce regulatory burdens imposed on RTOs. The Commission should 
    specifically declare its willingness to entertain proposals to 
    streamline filing requirements. The Commission could encourage 
    innovative ways to reduce regulatory costs by authorizing performance-
    based rates that reward RTOs for reducing regulatory costs.
        Commission Conclusion. We conclude that properly structured RTOs 
    throughout the United States can provide significant benefits in the 
    operation of the transmission grid. The comments received reinforce our 
    preliminary determination in the NOPR
    
    [[Page 829]]
    
    that RTOs can effectively remove existing impediments to competition in 
    the power markets.
        Description of Benefits. We conclude that RTOs will provide the 
    benefits that we described in detail in the NOPR, and others that 
    commenters mention.110 While we acknowledge that the level 
    of RTO benefits may vary from region to region depending on the current 
    transparency and efficiency of markets, the Commission believes that 
    benefits from RTO's would be universal. These benefits will include: 
    increased efficiency through regional transmission pricing and the 
    elimination of rate pancaking; improved congestion management; more 
    accurate estimates of ATC; more effective management of parallel path 
    flows; more efficient planning for transmission and generation 
    investments; increased coordination among state regulatory agencies; 
    reduced transaction costs; facilitation of the success of state retail 
    access programs; facilitation of the development of environmentally 
    preferred generation in states with retail access programs; improved 
    grid reliability; and fewer opportunities for discriminatory 
    transmission practices.111 All of these improvements to the 
    efficiencies in the transmission grid will help improve power market 
    performance, which will ultimately result in lower prices to the 
    Nation's electricity consumers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \110\ The benefits described in this section are not intended to 
    include all benefits that RTOs could provide. Some of the principal 
    benefits of RTOs (e.g., more effective management of parallel path 
    flows, improved congestion management) are addressed in later 
    discussions of RTO minimum characteristics and functions.
        \111\ FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,716-20.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As stated in the NOPR, we expect that RTOs can reduce opportunities 
    for unduly discriminatory conduct by cleanly separating the control of 
    transmission from power market participants. An RTO would have no 
    financial interests in any power market participant, and no power 
    market participant would be able to control an RTO. This separation 
    will eliminate the economic incentive and ability for the transmission 
    provider to act in a way that favors or disfavors any market 
    participant in the provision of transmission services.
        Most commenters support the premise that RTOs can be beneficial in 
    addressing the remaining transmission-related impediments to full 
    competition in the electricity markets. Although we recognize certain 
    differences in perspective about the existence of, or potential for, 
    widespread discrimination by current transmission owners, no one 
    seriously disputes the benefits of a marketplace where service quality 
    and availability are uniform, where users of the network are treated 
    equally, and where commercially important data are readily available to 
    all. Although some commenters support the NOPR proposal only if the 
    costs of establishing RTOs do not exceed the benefits, a subject 
    discussed further below, most believe that the benefits listed in the 
    NOPR are accurate and can be achieved through an RTO.
        We recognize that some commenters believe that either RTOs alone 
    will not solve all of the identified problems, or individual benefits 
    can be achieved in ways other than creating RTOs. Both of these 
    observations may have some merit. However, we believe that the creation 
    of RTOs is one action that can address all of the identified 
    impediments to competition and provide all or most of the identified 
    benefits.
        We also recognize that there are those who worry that the costs of 
    establishing an RTO will outweigh the benefits. We believe this concern 
    fails to account for the flexibility we have built into this rule. 
    While many look at the high costs involved with respect to establishing 
    some existing ISOs and PXs, this rule does not require an RTO to follow 
    any specific approach. For example, this rule does not require the 
    consolidation of control areas nor does it require the establishment of 
    a PX. We are allowing significant flexibility with respect to how and, 
    in some cases, when the minimum characteristics and functions are 
    satisfied. Accordingly, we do not believe it will be necessary to 
    expend the same level of resources that were expended, e.g., in 
    California, to create an RTO satisfying our minimum characteristics and 
    functions. We therefore conclude that the flexibility built into the 
    Final Rule will allow RTOs to create streamlined organizational 
    structures that are not overly costly. Moreover, with five ISOs now 
    operating in the United States, there is considerable experience 
    available regarding what works and what does not with respect to 
    regional transmission entities. This experience should make it somewhat 
    easier, and more cost efficient, to create new RTOs.
        As we stated in the NOPR, by improving efficiencies in the 
    management of the grid, improving grid reliability, and removing any 
    remaining opportunities for discriminatory transmission practices, the 
    widespread development of RTOs will improve the performance of 
    electricity markets in several ways and consequently lower prices to 
    the Nation's electricity consumers. To the extent that RTOs foster 
    fully competitive wholesale markets, the incentives to operate 
    generating plants efficiently are bolstered. The evidence is clear that 
    market incentives can lead to highly efficient plant operations. The 
    incentives for more efficient plant operation can also affect existing 
    generation facilities. Especially noteworthy is the recent experience 
    that indicates improvements in the generation sector in regions with 
    ISOs. Regions that have ISOs in place are undergoing dramatic shifts in 
    the ownership of generating facilities. Large-scale divestiture and 
    high levels of new entry in California and the Northeast are changing 
    the ownership structure of these regions' generators. Access to 
    customers and the presence of competing suppliers are creating the 
    incentives for better-performing plants.
        By improving competition, RTOs also will reduce the potential for 
    market power abuse. As discussed earlier, eliminating pancaked 
    transmission prices will expand the scope of markets and bring more 
    players into the markets. By eliminating the mistrust in the current 
    grid management, entry by new generation into the market will become 
    more likely as new entrants will perceive the market as more fair and 
    attractive for investment. And with more players, the market becomes 
    deeper and more fluid, allowing for more sophisticated forms of 
    transacting and better matching of buyers and sellers.
        Estimation of Benefits. The full value of the benefits of RTOs to 
    improve market performance cannot be known with precision before their 
    development, and we do not yet have a sufficiently long track record 
    with existing institutions with which to measure. The Commission staff 
    has estimated a subset of the potential cost savings from RTOs as part 
    of its National Environmental Policy Act analysis. In the Environmental 
    Assessment (EA) for this rulemaking, three scenarios were developed to 
    estimate potential economic and environmental effects of the 
    rulemaking.112 The scenario analysis was conducted using a 
    computer simulation model of the continental U.S. electric power system 
    over the
    
    [[Page 830]]
    
    period 1997 to 2015.113 The Commission adopts staff's 
    analysis.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \112\ One of these scenarios assessed transmission effects only, 
    the second assessed generation efficiencies in addition to 
    transmission effects, and the third posited increased entry of new 
    supply and demand choices.
        \113\ The Integrated Planning Model (IPM) was developed for the 
    U.S. Environmental Protection Agency by ICF Inc. See 3.3.1 of the 
    Commission Staff's Environmental Assessment in this proceeding.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The results of the EA modeling present a range of potential cost 
    savings resulting from the changes in modeling assumptions in each 
    scenario. Although this Final Rule does not mandate RTO formation, full 
    development of RTOs as envisioned by the Commission in this rule could 
    offer substantial economic benefits. The EA scenarios modeled resulted 
    in average annual savings of up to $5.1 billion per year over the 2000-
    2015 period. Based upon review of the EA scenarios and comparison with 
    other existing analyses of competitive electric power markets, the best 
    estimate from the EA analysis of annual benefits that could result from 
    RTO formation is $2.4 billion per year. This estimate results from a 
    scenario in which the modeling assumptions for transmission and 
    generation efficiency are selected for consistency with other economic 
    analyses of competitive power markets, including the Order No. 888 
    Environmental Impact Statement analysis conducted by Commission staff 
    in 1996.114
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \114\ Order No. 888, Final Environmental Impact Statement, FERC/
    EIS-0096, FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 31,036 at 31,860-96.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        These estimates do not represent a complete economic analysis of 
    the rulemaking because the EA analysis addressed only factors that may 
    change the dispatch of power plants or future generating capacity 
    decisions. The model accounts for production costs (capital additions, 
    operations and maintenance expenses, and fuel) equal to roughly one-
    third of the annual sales revenue now passing through the industry, and 
    does not include such cost categories as existing (sunk) capital, the 
    distribution system, and end user charges such as taxes. If other cost 
    savings were realized, for example, from merger-like consolidation 
    savings in the transmission grid, these savings would be additional to 
    those estimated in the EA. Benefits from elimination of market power 
    and improved intra-regional congestion management are also not included 
    in the calculation and could represent significant additional savings.
        The costs of RTO formation are not explicitly captured in the EA 
    analysis, nor are any potential costs associated with the provision of 
    incentives for RTO formation or operation. Costs of RTO formation 
    cannot be well estimated because of the wide range of design choices 
    that the rule allows for a new RTO. For instance, the choice of 
    building a dedicated telecommunications and data infrastructure, as 
    opposed to relying on existing infrastructures, can have a large effect 
    on the initial cost of an RTO.115
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \115\ See, e.g., California ISO, Cost Performance Benchmarking 
    Study of Independent System Operators, revised version of Feb. 17, 
    1999.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Based on review of cost studies for existing ISOs, it appears 
    unlikely that the costs of RTO formation will exceed RTO cost savings 
    on an annualized basis over time. This is because most of the costs are 
    capital investments that occur at the beginning of the RTO's operation. 
    But whether the costs in the initial period are under $10 million or up 
    to several hundred million dollars (and more likely between these two 
    figures) for an RTO, they are small in comparison with the ongoing 
    annual savings that RTOs may provide.
        As discussed above, our best estimate of cost savings from RTO 
    formation is $2.4 billion annually, with potential cost savings 
    estimated to be as high as $5.1 billion annually. This represents about 
    1.1 to 2.4 percent of the current total costs of the U.S. electric 
    power industry.116 Such savings can be considered in the 
    context of recent analysis of the economic benefits of further industry 
    restructuring.117 The wholesale cost savings the Commission 
    is anticipating from the formation of RTOs are properly viewed as 
    distinct from the larger savings that may result from competitive 
    retail power markets. However, RTOs can also help achieve retail access 
    and its associated benefits by creating a robust wholesale power 
    market. In this sense the cost savings from retail access depend on the 
    Commission fulfilling its RTO objectives.118
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \116\ Defined as revenue from sales to ultimate users, which 
    were reported as $215 billion in 1997. See Energy Information 
    Administration, Annual Energy Review 1997, DOE/EIA-0384(97) (July 
    1998).
        \117\See, e.g., Department of Energy, Supporting Analysis for 
    the Comprehensive Electricity Competition Act, DOE-PO-0059 (May 
    1999).
        \118\ DOE's Economic Analysis of the Comprehensive Electricity 
    Competition Act shows an estimated cost savings from a national 
    policy of retail access to be $20 to $32 billion per year. See id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Light-Handed Regulation. One of the benefits of RTOs that we 
    identified in the NOPR was that the existence of a properly structured 
    RTO would reduce the need for Commission oversight and scrutiny, which 
    would benefit both the Commission and the industry. We stated that to 
    the extent an RTO is independent of power marketing interests, there 
    would be no need for the Commission to monitor and attempt to enforce 
    compliance with the standards of conduct designed to unbundle a 
    utility's transmission and generation functions. We also stated that an 
    independent RTO with an impartial dispute resolution mechanism could 
    resolve disputes without resort to the Commission complaint process, 
    and that it is generally more efficient for these organizations to 
    resolve many disputes internally rather than bringing every dispute to 
    the Commission. Further, we noted that the Commission has in the past 
    indicated its willingness to grant more latitude to transmission 
    pricing proposals from appropriately constituted regional groups 
    119 and, to the extent that RTOs increase market size and 
    decrease market concentration, the competitive consequences of proposed 
    mergers would become less problematic and thereby help further 
    streamline the Commission's merger decision-making process.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \119\ Inquiry Concerning the Commission's Pricing Policy for 
    Transmission Services Provided by Public Utilities Under the Federal 
    Power Act, 59 FR 55031 (Nov. 3, 1994), FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 
    31,005, at 31,140, 31,145, 31,148 (1994) (Transmission Pricing 
    Policy Statement).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We continue to believe that the types of reduced regulatory 
    scrutiny mentioned in the NOPR, and summarized above, are possible and 
    appropriate for RTOs. A number of commenters, however, have expressed 
    concern that it is premature to reduce regulation of RTOs, and that 
    RTOs will be monopolies that will require continued regulation. We 
    believe that this concern stems from a misunderstanding of our concept 
    of light-handed regulation. Admittedly, this concept is subject to 
    varying interpretations.
        We clarify that we will continue to apply the level of regulation 
    and scrutiny that is necessary to ensure that public utilities comply 
    with the FPA and our regulations. Only when we determine that a 
    different form of regulation will adequately protect the public 
    interest, we will allow a reduced oversight role for the Commission.
        Furthermore, our encouragement of the use of ADR by participants in 
    RTOs to resolve disputes without resort to formal complaint proceedings 
    is not new. In our RTG Policy Statement, we encouraged RTGs to develop 
    alternative dispute resolution procedures for resolving transmission 
    issues, particularly technical and reliability issues. We also stated 
    that we would be willing to entertain proposals for some degree of 
    deference to decisions rendered pursuant to an ADR process, pursuant to 
    procedures that are specified in an agreement and assure
    
    [[Page 831]]
    
    due process for all participants. 120 We stated there, and 
    we reaffirm here, that while the Commission cannot delegate its 
    authority, it can give deference to resolutions that meet the standards 
    of the FPA.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \120\ Policy Statement Regarding Regional Transmission Groups, 
    58 FR 41626 (Aug. 5, 1993), FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 30,976 (1993) 
    (RTG Policy Statement).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We reiterated this concept in the eleven ISO principles we set 
    forth in Order No. 888. We stated there that an ISO should provide for 
    a voluntary dispute resolution process that allows parties to resolve 
    technical, financial, and other issues without resort to filing 
    complaints at the Commission.121 We have also expressed our 
    willingness to grant some deference to changes to an open access tariff 
    by an ISO concerning a regional solution to an identified regional 
    problem based on what we understand is a broad consensus.122
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \121\ Order No. 888, FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 31,036 at 31,732.
        \122\ See PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., 84 FERC para. 61,212 
    (1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Accordingly, we believe that some degree of deference can be 
    granted on certain issues to independent RTOs that have appropriate 
    procedural mechanisms in place to ensure fair representation of 
    viewpoints. We cannot delineate here precisely the degree of deference 
    that is appropriate, or on what issues. To the extent some issues can 
    be fairly resolved within a region without formal Commission 
    procedures, a benefit accrues to both the parties and the Commission.
        In addition, we note that some of the innovative ratemaking 
    policies discussed later in this Final Rule are consistent with light-
    handed regulation, since we expect that these policies may result in 
    reduced levels of regulatory scrutiny. We emphasize, however, that we 
    will not delegate or fail to exercise our regulatory responsibilities. 
    We also recognize that the degree of deference and reduced regulatory 
    scrutiny accorded to an RTO may necessarily depend on the ability of 
    the RTO to reach consensus solutions to regional issues.
    
    C. Commission's Approach to RTO Formation
    
        The NOPR proposed an approach to RTO formation that embraces 
    several general principles: first, as a matter of policy, we should 
    strongly encourage transmission owners to participate voluntarily in 
    RTOs; second, we should be neutral as to organizational form (e.g., ISO 
    or transco) of an RTO as long as it satisfies our minimum 
    characteristics and functions; and third, we should provide maximum 
    flexibility as to the specifics of how an RTO can satisfy the minimum 
    characteristics and functions. We sought comment on these principles 
    and specifically asked whether we should generically mandate RTO 
    participation 123 or whether market-based rates or merger 
    approvals should be conditioned on RTO participation.124
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \123\ FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,762.
        \124\ Id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Based on the wide array of comments received, which we discuss 
    next, and the voluminous record compiled in this rulemaking proceeding, 
    we conclude that a voluntary approach to RTO formation represents a 
    measured and appropriate response to the technical impediments to 
    competition that have been identified as well as the lingering 
    discrimination concerns that have been raised. We believe that 
    voluntary formation of RTOs will address the fundamental economic and 
    engineering issues which confront the industry and the Commission, and 
    will help eliminate any actual or perceived discriminatory conduct by 
    entities that continue to control both generation and transmission 
    facilities.125 Further, we believe that the voluntary 
    process adopted in this rule, in conjunction with the innovative 
    transmission pricing reforms that we will permit RTOs to seek, will be 
    successful in achieving widespread formation of RTOs in a timely 
    manner. Our adoption of a voluntary approach to RTO formation in this 
    Final Rule does not in any way preclude the exercise of any of our 
    authorities under the FPA to order remedies to address undue 
    discrimination or the exercise of market power, including the remedy of 
    requiring participation in an RTO, where supported by the record.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \125\ These engineering, economic and discrimination issues are 
    discussed in Section III.A above.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    1. Voluntary Approach
        Comments. Comments as to whether the Commission should require 
    formation of and/or participation in RTOs break down into five main 
    categories: (1) The Commission should require formation of and 
    participation in RTOs; (2) formation of and participation in RTOs 
    should be voluntary; (3) the Commission should encourage voluntary 
    RTOs, but with strong enforcement mechanisms; (4) RTOs should be 
    voluntary, but if they do not form or if utilities do not participate, 
    the Commission should mandate them; and (5) RTOs should be voluntary, 
    but the requirements of the NOPR effectively create a mandate.
        Most investor-owned utilities argue that RTOs should be voluntary. 
    Most municipal utilities, customer groups, consumer advocates, and 
    marketers argue that the Commission should require RTOs. State 
    commissions and cooperatives are more evenly split. These 
    characterizations, however, are broad generalizations, and there are 
    strong exceptions to each statement.
        Comments That the Commission Should Require Formation of and 
    Participation in RTOs. The most extensive argument for mandating RTOs 
    comes from TAPS and is representative of the positions of a number of 
    public power utilities and other transmission customers. 126 
    TAPS argues that the non-mandatory approach leaves the keys to reform 
    in the hands of the wrong people--the monopolists who have market 
    power--and that the voluntary creation of RTOs will give opportunities 
    for monopolists to maintain their market power. TAPS presents extensive 
    arguments as to the Commission's authority to mandate and its 
    obligation under the FPA to do so. They state:
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \126\ E.g., APPA, Empire District, FMPA, Great River, Lincoln, 
    UAMPS, UMPA.
    
        Only by mandating that jurisdictional utilities participate in * 
    * * RTOs will the Commission protect against * * * utilities' 
    inclinations to form alternative RTOs that are structured to 
    perpetuate or enhance their competitive position. Compelling such 
    participation is also the only way for the Commission to satisfy its 
    statutory obligations to eradicate undue discrimination and protect 
    against unjust and unreasonable pricing of both transmission service 
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    and wholesale generation sales.
    
    TAPS further argues that past attempts to allow voluntary formation of 
    RTOs have not been successful. Only where states have required ISOs or 
    where the Commission has required them as part of a merger proceeding 
    have effective ISOs been formed.
        TDU Systems also presents extensive arguments for a mandate. It 
    argues that the need for a national system of RTOs is urgent; that the 
    Commission cannot rely purely on voluntary actions of transmission 
    owners; that only a mandate will create RTOs in a timely fashion; and 
    that inducements are counterproductive. WPPI states that the financial 
    incentive to protect a transmission owner's generation investment is 
    much stronger than any transmission incentive FERC can give to induce 
    RTO participation. First Rochdale argues that voluntary RTOs will 
    create too great an emphasis on forcing parties to litigation and other
    
    [[Page 832]]
    
    costly, time consuming dispute resolution.
        Some investor-owned utilities support a mandate.127 For 
    example, Cinergy presents arguments similar to those of TAPS, and 
    believes that ``all jurisdictional utilities must be required to 
    transfer control of their transmission facilities to a qualified ISO, 
    which shall integrate those facilities into an RTO approved by the 
    Commission.''
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \127\ E.g., Minnesota Power, WEPCO, PG&E, PECO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A number of marketers believe that RTOs must be mandated. Sonat is 
    not convinced that incentives alone are sufficient to persuade 
    transmission providers to follow through with RTO formation. NEMA 
    believes that participation by all transmission owners should be 
    mandatory, but that the form of the RTO should be allowed to evolve.
        Many industrial customers agree that RTOs must be required. PJM/
    NEPOOL Customers argue that the goals of the Commission cannot be 
    achieved without mandatory participation by all transmission owners in 
    RTOs. They go further to state that experience from both the Midwest 
    ISO/Alliance debate over formation of ISOs and from the natural gas 
    industry demonstrates monopolists will not act effectively to eliminate 
    discrimination without strong mandates attached to strong penalties.
        Residential consumer advocates and environmental organizations 
    concur. Public Citizen says that the Commission should order the 
    creation of three non-profit public transmission companies (one each 
    for the Eastern, Western, and ERCOT interconnections) and order each 
    public transco to purchase all of the transmission facilities needed to 
    provide customers with transmission service.
        Project Groups recommends that the final rule be strengthened to 
    require that if owners do not voluntarily transfer control of 
    facilities to an approved RTO by a date certain, the Commission will 
    either order the transfer (in the case of jurisdictional utilities) or 
    take other actions designed to minimize the opportunities for resisting 
    owners to use their facilities in anti-competitive ways.
        A number of state commissions support a mandatory RTO regime 
    imposed by the Commission. Illinois Commission does not believe that 
    the voluntary approach set out in the NOPR is likely to obtain its 
    objectives and especially not in a timely manner, noting that voluntary 
    efforts ``for more than six years'' have failed and that the 
    encouragements and incentives contained in the NOPR are unlikely to 
    change the situation. Indiana Commission points to its experience with 
    the Midwest ISO/Alliance debates as indicating that the Commission must 
    take a more assertive role. Montana Commission agrees, pointing to 
    unwillingness of transmission owners to give up control and to concerns 
    about cost-shifting. It recommends that the Commission strengthen the 
    NOPR to ensure the prompt formation of RTOs using all the tools at its 
    disposal. Pennsylvania Commission argues that in order to be stable, 
    both as to their authority and with respect to membership 
    participation, RTOs must be mandatory. Virginia Commission argues that 
    the goal of independence is in conflict with a voluntary approach.
        Wisconsin Commission argues that the Commission should move forward 
    quickly and require all transmission facilities to be placed under the 
    control of an RTO. In the absence of any action from FERC to require 
    utility membership, it states, it is unclear how any effort to resolve 
    the ``Swiss cheese'' problems already experienced in the Midwest can 
    succeed. Ohio Commission argues that it continues to believe that the 
    mandatory participation and boundary drawing approach is more 
    appropriate.
        Comments That Formation of and Participation in RTOs Should Be 
    Voluntary. The most extensive presentation of the argument that RTOs 
    should and must be voluntary comes from Indianapolis P&L and FP&L, 
    which make mostly legal arguments that are addressed below. Southern 
    Company argues that a voluntary, flexible RTO policy is consistent with 
    desires of the states as reflected in statements given at the 
    consultations with the states held by the Commission. It also avers 
    that an RTO is not required to achieve the goals of the NOPR. Alliance 
    Companies and Trans-Elect argue that voluntary formation is the key to 
    RTO success, noting that the Commission's voluntary approach of 
    encouraging regionalization of the transmission grid has been 
    successful and there is no reason to doubt its continued success.
        EEI suggests that the voluntary approach is working well, 
    indicating that five ISOs have been approved serving 46 percent of U.S. 
    customers and 38 percent of total MWh sales. They state that four other 
    regions have proposed or are about to propose RTOs which will result, 
    within three years since the issuance of Order No. 888, in nearly 63 
    percent of the nation's electricity customers being served by regional 
    transmission entities. They go on to argue that a mandate could 
    stimulate litigation that would slow this voluntary 
    development.128
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \128\ Other transmission-owning utilities supporting voluntary 
    development and opposing mandates are Detroit Edison, Duke, Entergy, 
    Florida Power Corp., SCE&G, Metropolitan, MidAmerican, NEPCO et al., 
    NU, NSP, Montana-Dakota, Tampa Electric, TXU Electric, United 
    Illuminating, CP&L, Central Maine and Virginia Power.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A number of public power entities, including municipal utilities, 
    cooperative utilities, Federal Power Marketing Administrations, and 
    others, also support a voluntary approach. TVA argues that FERC's 
    proposal to make RTO participation voluntary is a wise one, that as 
    RTOs demonstrate their effectiveness and the benefits of RTOs become 
    more evident, transmission owners likely will be persuaded to 
    participate and the holes in the RTOs should disappear. CMUA argues 
    that mandatory RTOs are not likely to be formed through collaborative 
    processes and therefore are not likely to take into account broad 
    stakeholder input. Tacoma Power supports voluntary formation because 
    some utilities may not find that the cost savings are sufficient to 
    warrant the expenditure necessary. Also, it states that public power 
    utilities may face legal obligations or restrictions that inhibit their 
    participation and that such utilities should not face penalties or 
    sanctions for not participating.129
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \129\ Other public power and cooperative entities supporting 
    voluntary formation of RTOs include Big Rivers, East Kentucky, 
    Georgia Transmission, South Carolina Authority, SMUD, Seattle, JEA, 
    LPPC, NRECA, Los Angeles, MEAG, Oglethorpe, Platte River, NPRB, 
    NPPD, RUS and Tri-State.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A number of state commissions support voluntary formation of RTOs. 
    Alabama Commission argues that the Commission does not have authority 
    to mandate RTOs. Florida Commission agrees and states that any action 
    by the Commission must be on a case-by-case basis, and the Commission 
    should defer to states in developing regional approaches. Michigan 
    Commission believes that there is a solution short of mandating RTO 
    formation, but that uses FERC's unique national perspective and 
    authority to facilitate larger RTO formation. Wyoming Commission urges 
    the Commission not to codify or mandate anything other than the general 
    framework for RTOs and thereby allow the voluntary process an 
    opportunity to work.130
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \130\ Other state commissions supporting voluntary formation 
    include South Carolina, Iowa, New York, and Washington. Other 
    entities supporting voluntary formation of RTOs include NYPP, SRP 
    and Cal ISO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments That the Commission Should Encourage Voluntary RTOs But 
    With Strong Enforcement Mechanisms. The Justice Department argues that 
    the
    
    [[Page 833]]
    
    NOPR makes a strong case for mandating RTOs. It recommends that a 
    regime of ``carrots and sticks'' be carefully designed to reasonably 
    guarantee complete voluntary compliance, rather than merely promote 
    greater voluntary compliance.
        Enron/APX/Coral Power argue that the Commission should take steps 
    to induce transmission owners to participate in RTOs.131 
    They doubt, however, that performance-based ratemaking alone will be a 
    sufficient inducement and recommend Commission procedures to prevent 
    transmission owners that fail to participate in RTOs from misusing 
    their transmission systems to favor their own or affiliated uses of 
    their systems. These could include regional proceedings to impose added 
    safeguards against violations, presumptions of ineligibility for 
    market-based rates, and presumptions that mergers are inconsistent with 
    public interest absent membership in an RTO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \131\ Concurring are H.Q. Energy Services, Midwest Energy and 
    Oregon Office.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments That RTOs Should Be Voluntary, But if They Do Not Form, 
    the Commission Should Mandate Them. PNGC argues that if a voluntary RTO 
    encompassing the Pacific Northwest does not come about in a reasonably 
    short time, the Commission should explore its authority or seek new 
    authority to mandate participation in RTOs. Fertilizer Institute 
    believes that the Commission has sufficient authority to mandate RTOs 
    but would likely be bogged down in endless litigation should it do so, 
    and so recommends that the Commission pursue a voluntary approach, but, 
    should that not work, proceed with a requirement. WPSC argues that 
    encouraging voluntary participation in RTOs is the appropriate starting 
    place. However, the Commission must be prepared to take more direct 
    action, including increased legislative authority, to ensure the 
    participation of utilities that do not voluntarily choose to join an 
    RTO.
        Comments That RTOs Should Be Voluntary, But the Requirements of the 
    NOPR Effectively Create a Mandate. Puget states that if the Final Rule 
    continues to reflect a position that nonparticipation in the RTO will 
    result in negative regulatory consequences for the nonparticipant, then 
    the RTO proposal cannot really be said to be voluntary. CP&L argues 
    that mandatory filings, coupled with threats of withholding benefits 
    and/or leveling penalties for those that do not choose to 
    ``voluntarily'' join and RTO, do not present a picture of a truly 
    voluntary process.
        Comments on Sanctions for Non-Participation. Most vertically 
    integrated public utilities oppose conditioning market-based rates and 
    merger approval on RTO participation, while most transmission customers 
    favor the Commission using conditioning authority. A number of 
    utilities express concern that the Commission may be exceeding its 
    legal authority, and that conditioning would undermine the voluntary 
    nature of the RTO initiative. Florida Power Corp. argues that the 
    Commission cannot impose penalties for failure to participate 
    voluntarily in an RTO in contravention of the FPA. Puget contends that 
    the possibility of penalties for non-participation means that no 
    provision is made for participation to be truly voluntary. Duke 
    expresses concern that potential revocation of market-based rate 
    authorization and refusal to find a merger in the public interest are 
    actions that make it legally or economically impossible for any public 
    utility not to participate in an RTO. EEI observes that such linkage 
    would change settled law requiring reasoned analysis or factual 
    findings. Similarly, Consumers Energy submits that summary withdrawal 
    of existing market-based rate authorization must be justified by 
    substantial evidence of changed circumstances. CP&L claims that the 
    Commission cannot impose RTO participation conditions on a proposed 
    merger that go beyond the consistency with the public interest standard 
    under the FPA.
        Two commenters suggest that the Commission must proceed on a case-
    by-case basis. MidAmerican contends that there is no clear indication 
    that the number of parties competing in generation markets is so small 
    to cause inadequate levels of competition. Since changes to restructure 
    the industry into RTOs will be costly and difficult for all parties, 
    mandates or sanctions should be based only on willful violations of 
    Commission policy. LG&E concurs that only where the record supports a 
    case-specific finding that a transmission owner's failure to 
    participate in an RTO will result in undue discrimination or the 
    ability to exercise market power should the Commission take remedial 
    steps to address the situation so that the Commission is on firm legal 
    grounds.
        On the other hand, a number of commenters believe the Commission 
    must require RTO participation as a condition of future market-based 
    rate transactions and authorizations. TAPS notes that this is necessary 
    for the Commission to meet its obligation to protect consumers from 
    unjust and unreasonable rates if it intends to pursue a lighter-handed 
    regulatory approach, adding that only RTOs of appropriate size and 
    structure will be able to meet fully the Commission's statutory 
    obligation to protect consumers. Oneok and New Smyrna Beach argue that 
    manipulation and undetectable anticompetitive conduct for which there 
    is no practical after-the-fact remedy are concerns that could be 
    alleviated by an RTO and that, accordingly, denial of merger approval 
    or market-based rate authorization is well within the Commission's 
    authority when anticompetitive factors have not been mitigated.
        PJM/NEPOOL Customers, Great River, East Texas Cooperatives and PNGC 
    support revoking market-based rate authorization to remedy inherent 
    discrimination resulting from non-participation and also using non-
    participation as a factor in merger analysis. APPA favors imposing the 
    merger condition in the form of an immediate requirement to participate 
    given the Commission's prior experience with conditioning mergers with 
    commitments to join an ISO. merican Forest supports conditioning all 
    future market-based rate transactions on participation. H.Q. Energy 
    Services encourages the Commission to explore the full extent of its 
    authority under the FPA to compel participation in RTOs.
        Enron/APX/Coral Power recommend that the Commission create a 
    rebuttable presumption that RTO participation is required for approval 
    of market-based pricing or a transfer of facilities under section 203 
    of the FPA. For market-based rate authorizations, the Commission should 
    establish a presumption that a decision by a transmission owner not to 
    participate in an RTO is evidence that it is misusing its transmission 
    facilities to advantage its merchant function. This presumption could 
    be rebutted through a demonstration that stand-alone operation of the 
    non-participant's grid serves the public interest as well as or better 
    than participating in an RTO. They suggest that utilities currently 
    with market-based rate authorizations should be ordered to show cause 
    by the December 15, 2001, implementation deadline why their market rate 
    authorizations should not be revoked. Enron/APX/Coral Power also 
    recommend that all sales, leases, mergers and consolidations of 
    transmission systems be conditioned on RTO participation based on a 
    presumption that it is inconsistent with the public interest to dispose 
    of transmission facilities without eliminating the incentive to
    
    [[Page 834]]
    
    discriminate by committing the operation of those facilities to an RTO.
        Industrial Consumers believes that the engineering and economic 
    efficiencies of RTO participation loom so large that the Commission is 
    justified in adopting a presumption that a decision by a transmission 
    owner not to participate in an RTO is evidence that it is misusing its 
    transmission facilities. Industrial Consumers recommends that the 
    Commission assert jurisdiction over the transmission component of 
    bundled sales, and order that the rates, terms and conditions offered 
    under the OATT apply to all eligible customers. This would deprive 
    vertically-integrated utilities of the incentive to resist RTO 
    participation.
        State commission commenters tend to favor the Commission using 
    conditioning authority, but some are not sure this will necessarily 
    encourage participation in RTOs. Oregon Commission comments that unless 
    a utility can demonstrate that it cannot manipulate the transmission 
    system to its advantage or that an RTO is impossible, the Commission 
    should revoke its ability to sell at market-based rates. Complaints of 
    unfair practices without credible reasons should be prima facie 
    evidence of market power. Pennsylvania Commission recommends that the 
    Commission revisit previously granted market-based rate authorizations. 
    Indiana Commission cautions, however, that a recalcitrant utility that 
    does not join an RTO may not perceive loss of market-based pricing 
    authorization as detrimental. Illinois Commission does not oppose 
    conditioning merger and market-based rate approvals on RTO 
    participation, but it also believes that the threat of these penalties 
    may be inadequate to induce RTO participation.
        Comments on Consequences for Failure to File, or Filing Alternative 
    Explanation. The majority of comments on this issue support the 
    Commission taking additional action if adequate RTOs do not form. PJM/
    NEPOOL Customers suggests that strict penalties must be assessed 
    against actions inconsistent with RTO formation. Oneok suggests that 
    certain benefits that are within the Commission's authority and 
    discretion to grant or deny should be withheld from utilities unwilling 
    to participate. Project Groups recommend that the Final Rule provide 
    that the Commission itself create RTOs if the stakeholders are unable 
    or unwilling voluntarily to do so by a reasonable date certain. PNGC 
    suggests that if RTOs do not form within a reasonable time, the 
    Commission should explore its authority or seek new authority to 
    mandate participation by all utilities.
        On the other hand, Duke is concerned that the Commission may not 
    accept valid reasons for nonparticipation and use the October 15, 2000, 
    alternative filings as vehicles to mandate RTO membership. Duke offers 
    that the Commission cannot consider imposing penalties for non-
    participation while simultaneously claiming that its policy on 
    participation is voluntary. Seattle cautions that the Commission should 
    exercise care not to unfairly sanction transmission-owning utilities 
    that cannot participate in an RTO (e.g., where good cause is shown that 
    participation would violate state and local legal obligation, or the 
    costs of RTO participation outweighs the benefits).
        Commission Conclusion. Based on the record before us with respect 
    to undue discrimination and market power, as well as with respect to 
    economic and engineering issues affecting reliability, operational 
    efficiency, and competition in the electric industry, it is clear that 
    RTOs are needed to resolve impediments to fully competitive markets. 
    However, we continue to believe, as we proposed in the NOPR, that at 
    this time we should pursue a voluntary approach to participation in 
    RTOs.
        We acknowledge that there are many commenters who are skeptical 
    that a voluntary approach will be able to accomplish our stated 
    objective, which, as we stated in the NOPR,132 is for all 
    transmission-owning entities to place their transmission facilities 
    under the control of RTOs in a timely manner. In general, they argue 
    that those with a market advantage will not easily give it up, and that 
    voluntary efforts to date have not been very successful in creating 
    effective regional entities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \132\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,685.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        However, we believe that a voluntary approach as we have structured 
    it, with guidance and encouragement from the Commission, is most 
    appropriate at this time. Given the rapidly evolving state of the 
    electric industry, we want to allow involved participants the 
    flexibility to develop mutually agreeable regional arrangements with 
    respect to RTO formation and coordination. Further, we want the 
    industry to focus its efforts on the potential benefits of RTO 
    formation and how best to achieve them, rather than on a non-productive 
    challenge to our legal authority to mandate RTO participation.
        We believe the voluntary approach to RTO formation can be more 
    successful now than in the past for several reasons. The pace of 
    industry restructuring is accelerating. Many formerly vertically 
    integrated utilities have recently recognized the strategic benefits to 
    them of concentrating solely in one of the traditional utility areas 
    (generation, transmission, or distribution). Moreover, the NOPR has 
    focused industry attention on RTOs and their benefits. Further, this 
    Final Rule is providing clear rules and guidance on what is necessary 
    to form an RTO. Through this Final Rule, we are also committing the 
    Commission to act as a catalyst in RTO discussions by initiating and 
    encouraging a collaborative process. Finally, we have provided in this 
    Final Rule for certain favorable ratemaking treatments for those who 
    assume the risks of the transition to a new structure, which should, at 
    a minimum, eliminate any rate disincentives to RTO formation.
        We are not adopting as a generic policy in this Final Rule either 
    that RTO participation is required in order to retain or obtain market-
    based rate authorization for wholesale power sales, or that RTO 
    participation is required for a disposition of jurisdictional 
    facilities to be in the public interest. However, in response to those 
    who argue that the Commission has a statutory responsibility to remedy 
    undue discrimination and anticompetitive effects when evaluating 
    market-based rate and merger requests, we recognize that we may have to 
    consider, in individual cases, issues that arise as to whether market 
    power has been mitigated in the absence of RTO participation or as to 
    whether a merger would be in the public interest without RTO 
    participation.
        While we have concluded on this record that it is in the public 
    interest to provide for a voluntary approach to RTO formation that 
    relies upon encouragement, guidance, and support from the Commission, 
    this does not mean that all aspects of this Rule are voluntary. The 
    filing requirements set forth in section 35.34(c) of the new 
    regulations are mandatory. In other words, public utilities must file 
    either an RTO proposal or a report on the impediments to RTO 
    participation. In addition, to qualify as an RTO, an applicant must 
    comply with the minimum characteristics and functions and other 
    specific RTO requirements set forth in the new regulations. We will 
    also expect that all transmission owners will participate in good faith 
    in the collaborative process that we are establishing herein.
    2. Organizational Form of an RTO
        Comments. A number of commenters address the proposal to allow 
    flexibility
    
    [[Page 835]]
    
    in the type of structure allowed for RTOs. Several of those commenting 
    recommend maintaining the NOPR's flexibility and that the Commission 
    not prescribe either a transco, ISO or some other 
    structure.133 FirstEnergy advocates flexibility and says 
    that no one knows today what the best structure will be for the future 
    so, therefore, the Commission should allow customization reflecting 
    regional needs. Several commenters, such as APPA, argue that the 
    Commission's flexibility on type of organization should go beyond the 
    standard ISO and transco structures and include gridcos, wirecos, not-
    for-profit and for-profit forms of each organization, and hybrid 
    organizations.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \133\ See, e.g., EEI, Lincoln, LG&E, SERC and Washington 
    Commission.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Numerous commenters state a preference in favor of for-profit 
    transcos although many of these commenters still recommend that other 
    structures be allowed at each region's option.134 In 
    favoring transcos, commenters cite the greater efficiency due to a 
    transco's profit motive.135 Commenters further argue that 
    for-profit transcos can better serve the goal of independence because 
    the transco would make all business decisions,136 can more 
    cleanly divide Commission-regulated transmission from state-regulated 
    distribution,137 and can operate more efficiently by 
    integrating investment decisions, facility design, construction and O&M 
    into a unified strategy.138 A few additional supporters of 
    transcos prefer that they be not-for-profit.139 Gainesville 
    recommends further that transcos in Florida become an instrumentality 
    of the state.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \134\ See, e.g., Allegheny, Entergy, INGAA and Trans-Elect.
        \135\ See, e.g., Sierra Pacific, H.Q. Energy Services and 
    Detroit Edison.
        \136\ MidAmerican.
        \137\ CTA.
        \138\ Duke.
        \139\ LPPC, Los Angeles, Gainesville and Public Citizen.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In contrast to the above, ISOs are preferred by a number of 
    commenters.140 PJM argues that ISOs are necessary to ensure 
    independence, provide more independent market monitoring and have a 
    fiduciary duty to the public interest. PJM also notes that ISOs can 
    meet the Commission's objectives more quickly than transcos. NASUCA 
    reports that some of its members oppose for-profit transcos because of 
    their ``natural incentive to extract monopoly rents from consumers.'' 
    141 Some of those who prefer ISOs contend that transcos 
    would favor transmission solutions over generation solutions to 
    congestion.142 This argument is contested in the reply 
    comments of Trans-Elect and others. NEPCO et al. maintains that the 
    alleged bias in favor of transmission solutions can be overcome by 
    using performance-based rates to replace standard rate base regulation.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \140\ See, e.g., NASUCA, PJM and ICUA.
        \141\ NASUCA at 20.
        \142\ See, e.g., PJM and ISO-NE.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Some commenters favor a hybrid involving an ISO with a gridco or 
    with another type of organization.143 As noted above, many 
    commenters recommend flexibility and believe that either an ISO or 
    transco would satisfy the needs of an RTO if designed properly.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \143\ See, e.g., ISO-NE.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several commenters cited problems that need to be worked out for 
    both transcos and ISOs. Professor Joskow notes that ISOs would suffer 
    efficiency losses from the separation between ownership and operation 
    of transmission assets. This separation makes it harder to apply 
    incentive regulation because it divides decisions that affect the costs 
    of transmission between two organizations. On the other hand, Professor 
    Joskow says that an ISO may be superior to a transco where transmission 
    ownership is presently so balkanized that loop flow and congestion 
    cannot be managed, but he asserts that this advantage may decline over 
    time as the industry changes. Southern Company says that while some see 
    ISOs as ineffective bureaucracies which add to transmission risk, the 
    creation of transcos presents substantial tax and financial problems.
        A few commenters contend that the NOPR's provisions produce a bias 
    in favor of ISOs even though this intent is not noted.144 
    For example, Duke argues that the NOPR provisions for stakeholder 
    participation in formation, governance and market monitoring functions 
    seem more geared toward the ISO form of organization. These commenters 
    recommend that the Final Rule not include such a bias.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \144\ See, e.g., Sierra Pacific, Duke and Enron/APX/Coral Power.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A number of commenters suggest multi-layered structural 
    alternatives. For example, ISO-NE proposes an ISO and gridco operating 
    in tandem. A non-profit ISO would direct the operation of the 
    transmission system and run day-ahead and real-time power markets 
    coupled with a grid entity that owns and maintains the transmission in 
    the area operated by the ISO. This, they claim, would require a final 
    rule that defines an RTO as an entity, or a combination of entities 
    working in collaboration, that satisfies the minimum characteristics 
    set forth in the NOPR. Under the model discussed by ISO-NE, the ISO 
    would have responsibility for assuring open transmission access, 
    operating the regional transmission assets (including provision of 
    switching orders to the gridco), monitoring power markets, serving as a 
    clearing agent and possibly serving as a clearinghouse, and maintaining 
    short-term reliability. The gridco would own and maintain transmission 
    assets, operate transmission assets in response to ISO directions 
    consistent with safety requirements, and build new transmission 
    facilities (including licensing, permitting and siting 
    responsibilities). Joint responsibilities would include planning 
    upgrades to transmission system.
        ISO-NE argues that ISOs alone would have disadvantages in the realm 
    of transmission expansion due to fragmentation of transmission 
    ownership. A gridco, however, could raise investment capital, bring 
    parallel and complementary strengths to an ISO, and should bring crisp 
    and decisive implementation of transmission planning and expansion 
    decisions. Pairing an ISO with a gridco, ISO-NE argues, would eliminate 
    the problems inherent in a transco by separating transmission ownership 
    from market administration and market monitoring.
        Midwest ISO suggests a structure that it believes could meld the 
    best of both ISOs and transcos, i.e., an ISO that would allow an 
    independent transmission company to operate under the Midwest ISO. This 
    model would not require that all transmission be owned by a single 
    gridco--transmission owners could decide whether to operate directly 
    through the ISO, or spin assets off to a gridco that would operate 
    under the ISO. Midwest ISO argues that this proposal overcomes the 
    problems encountered in expecting all transmission owners to divest 
    their transmission assets to separate companies.
        PGE points out that, ``for an RTO to achieve * * * critical mass in 
    the near term, it must be capable of managing a regional transmission 
    market in which a variety of subsidiary transmission structures will be 
    in place. Such subsidiary structures may include single-company and 
    sub-regional ITCs, integrated utilities located in states that already 
    have restructured their retail electric markets, integrated utilities 
    located in states that have not yet restructured, and publicly-owned 
    and federal utilities.'' PJM argues that ISOs
    
    [[Page 836]]
    
    should be present even in regions that form separate transmission-
    owning companies to avoid continued conflict regarding the neutrality 
    and commercial consequences of grid management decisions.
        Professor Hogan states that it is very unlikely that a pure transco 
    model is viable at all. He further indicates that, ``the advantages of 
    an independent transmission company can be pursued through the gridco 
    model with an accompanying ISO.'' He suggests that this approach is 
    already well advanced in the United States and elsewhere, and that by 
    separating ownership of the wires from control of system operations, it 
    would be easy to accommodate a complex pattern of ownership.
        ComEd says that characteristics and functions should be performed 
    by two linked organizations that make up a binary RTO: a for-profit ITC 
    under the oversight of an independent not-for-profit regional 
    transmission board.
        Michigan Commission believes that wirecos, transcos and ISOs are 
    all interim transitional organizations along the path toward very large 
    RTO-like organizations. Even if vestiges of the smaller interim 
    organizations continue to exist, they should operate under some kind of 
    RTO umbrella to assure appropriate regional control. Missouri 
    Commission proposes a zonal model in which the zones are areas where 
    generation is integrated through the transmission grid in such a way as 
    to minimize restrictions on sources of generation used in the area. In 
    the future, independent transmission companies may form with the 
    possibility that adjacent control areas will join to form larger zones. 
    In such a case, an RTO is a collection of zones for purposes of 
    administering the regional gatekeeper function and providing markets 
    for transmission congestion. Each zone would be responsible for 
    maintaining its transmission facilities and coordinating both the use 
    and expansion of those facilities with the RTO.
        WEPCO proposes that each RTO should be composed of two parallel 
    organizations to serve the same region under a common, independent 
    board: a Regional Reliability Council to develop regional reliability 
    rules and a not-for-profit ISO that operates under those regional 
    rules.
        Cal DWR suggests a three-tiered structure that builds on existing 
    organizations. Existing NERC regional councils should set broad 
    governing criteria for ISO reliability issues, parallel path flow 
    issues, and for regional planning. More than one ISO may be located in 
    each NERC region. These should control area reliability, administer 
    transmission terms and conditions, and create market mechanisms to 
    manage congestion, among other functions. Transmission owners should 
    support, but not duplicate the roles of NERC regional councils.
        Commission Conclusion. We will not limit the flexibility of 
    proposed structures or forms of organization for RTOs. We are prepared 
    to accept a transco, ISO, hybrid form, or other form as long as the RTO 
    meets our minimum characteristics and functions and other requirements.
        Some of the commenters argue that the NOPR's requirements either 
    favor one form of organization over others or make one or the other 
    forms very difficult to construct. It is not our intention to favor or 
    disfavor transcos, ISOs, or other organizational form. We acknowledge 
    that some of our minimum requirements might affect transcos and ISOs 
    differently, but there also may be different acceptable ways for an ISO 
    or transco to satisfy the minimum requirements. However, we designed 
    this Final Rule to be neutral as to organizational form, and we do not 
    believe that the requirements for forming an RTO in this Final Rule 
    favor any particular RTO structure.
        Arguments are made that an ISO is the better form of RTO because an 
    ISO has no incentive either to favor transmission solutions to solve 
    congestion constraints or to perpetuate congestion. ISOs are easier to 
    form, in most cases, because there are fewer tax and mortgage 
    consequences as there is no actual transfer of ownership.
        On the other hand, some argue that transcos are preferable because 
    they introduce a profit motive for efficient operation and expansion. 
    Performance-based rates are normally considered more effective with 
    transcos than with ISOs. Advantages are cited for having the same 
    entity both propose and carry out transmission expansion and 
    maintenance.
        The transco and ISO forms of organization each has its advantages 
    and disadvantages as do combination forms and other forms that have 
    been suggested. In many cases, the situation facing transmission owners 
    in a particular region may influence the appropriate form of 
    organization to propose. In other cases it may be a matter of 
    preference for how the participants wish to do business. Some may 
    propose to start operation in one form and transform to another form at 
    a future date. Tax consequences, public ownership, bond indentures and 
    current organization will each have an impact on the decision of what 
    form of organization a particular RTO will propose.
        This Rule does not necessarily require that a single organization 
    perform all of the functions itself. To mention but a few examples, we 
    specifically clarify in other parts of this Final Rule that the 
    security coordinator function and the OASIS function could be shared 
    with another RTO or contracted out, and that appropriate scope may be 
    achieved in creative ways. We will entertain appropriate tiered or 
    other structures. We require only that the RTO be responsible for 
    ensuring that the requirements are met in a way that satisfies our 
    Rule.
        Because of the differing conditions facing various regions, we 
    offer flexibility in form of organization. We welcome innovative 
    structures and forms that meet the needs of the market participants 
    while satisfying the minimum requirements of this Rule.
    3. Degree of Specificity in the Rule
        Comments. Many commenters believe that our proposed flexible 
    approach is either still too rigid, or that it should provide clearer 
    guidance. INGAA argues for less specificity in the Final Rule. INGAA 
    points to the success of Order No. 636, wherein the Commission required 
    open access, functional unbundling, and a new rate design, and it 
    established specific requirements for operational control and pipeline 
    capacity trading, all without having to specify the structure of the 
    conforming gas transmission entity. NU similarly points to the 
    precedent of the restructured gas industry. It states that the 
    Commission should avoid the perils of imposing a rigid system pursuant 
    to the mistaken belief that it can be easily and swiftly changed later 
    to respond to future needs of the marketplace. CP&L also cautions that 
    the principle of flexibility could prove illusory in practice and that 
    there is a danger that, if guidance from the Commission takes the form 
    of overly restrictive rules, it will stifle the development of 
    innovative proposals. PG&E submits that the Commission should simply 
    define a broad standard that provides for independence and evaluate 
    particular RTO proposals on a case-by-case basis. South Carolina 
    Commission also counsels that the Commission should not attempt to 
    mandate a particular form of RTO, or establish its size or region, 
    because this will not ensure that an efficient market will develop. It 
    posits that any RTO policy should be flexible enough and dynamic enough 
    to allow for both regional and
    
    [[Page 837]]
    
    organizational differences and for growth and changes in the future.
        SCE&G claims that the NOPR is overly prescriptive with respect to 
    both scope and timing. TXU Electric submits that the NOPR's approach to 
    reliance on minimum characteristics and functions seems to reflect a 
    significant number of fundamental policy decisions that have already 
    been made without the benefit of any of the very experimentation the 
    NOPR extols. Southern Company argues that the Commission should recast 
    the characteristics and functions as voluntary guidelines at this early 
    stage in the development of RTOs, since it is unclear what the best 
    form of RTO will be.
        ISO supporters, such as NYPP and Central Maine, recommend that the 
    Commission reject proposals to impose rigid and inflexible rules on 
    RTOs and remain flexible especially with regard to existing ISOs and 
    RTO pricing. ISO-NE counsels that tolerance for a diversity of 
    approaches is essential, as well as politically pragmatic, due to the 
    fact that different regions will have different histories, industry 
    elements, and local regulatory policies that need to be accommodated.
        FirstEnergy supports the NOPR's flexibility because there is no 
    best model to deal with regional variations. Alliance Companies and 
    Washington Commission also recommend that the Commission adhere to a 
    flexible RTO policy, open to voluntary regional experimentation in the 
    design of RTO structures. In addition, both Southern Company and Trans-
    Elect recommend that the Commission maintain flexibility toward 
    transcos. And while a transco supporter, Entergy, sees the NOPR as 
    properly flexible in regard to for-profit and not-for-profit RTOs. 
    Finally, Duke agrees that RTOs should satisfy key principles, as long 
    as they are not so prescriptive as to promote only one type of RTO.
        On the other hand, Illinois Commission submits that the NOPR's 
    minimalist approach will lead to creation of lowest common denominator 
    RTOs that minimally comply with the characteristics and functions and 
    general guidance as to geographic scope and membership. Project Groups 
    suggests that the Commission expand and strengthen the minimum 
    characteristics. TDU Systems recommends that the Commission resist 
    calls to water down its Final Rule and urges more substance. TAPS 
    claims that calls for more flexibility are really a cover for diluted, 
    ineffective RTOs that will lack the scope, independence and authority 
    to get the job done.
        Commission Conclusion. While many commenters think that our 
    proposal to rely on guidance and flexibility to promote establishment 
    of appropriate RTOs is either too rigid or too non-specific, we 
    conclude that we struck an appropriate balance in the NOPR.
        Although we and the electric industry see many problems associated 
    with the operation of the Nation's transmission systems and we see a 
    general need for regional transmission solutions, we cannot at this 
    time foresee the best organizational means to resolve every problem. 
    Given this situation, we believe that the right balance is a minimally 
    intrusive, solution-oriented approach that provides guidance and 
    specifies only the fundamental RTO characteristics and functions.
        We do not agree with those commenters who contend that the NOPR 
    approach adopted herein is either overly or insufficiently 
    prescriptive. Certainly the minimum characteristics and functions do 
    reflect a number of threshold requirements, but collectively, these 
    requirements serve to define the minimum necessary to improve the 
    operation of the Nation's transmission systems. While we agree that 
    there is no best answer and we encourage regional innovation, we cannot 
    simply define a standard of independence and nothing else. This would 
    leave the industry without direction and provides no guidance on how we 
    would evaluate the various RTO proposals.
        Finally, we do not agree with those who suggest that our electric 
    regulation must follow our natural gas pipeline industry Order No. 636 
    model, where the Commission did not attempt structural unbundling of 
    the pipeline industry but simply relied on more limited, functional 
    unbundling. The situations in the two industries are different 
    regarding the need for regional entities. Most importantly, there was 
    not in the gas industry the degree of vertical integration of 
    production, transmission, and distribution that historically existed in 
    the electric industry. In addition, the gas industry has no analog to 
    loop flow, transmission loading relief, the need for large regional 
    calculations of ATC, or the use of generation energy and reactive power 
    output to manipulate transmission flow, among other reasons.
    4. Legal Authority
        In the NOPR, we noted that sections 205 and 206 of the FPA, 16 
    U.S.C. 824d and 824e, give the Commission both the authority and 
    responsibility to ensure that the rates, charges, classifications, and 
    services of public utilities (and any rule, regulation, practice, or 
    contract affecting any of these) are just and reasonable and not unduly 
    discriminatory, and to remedy undue discrimination in the provision of 
    such services. We stated that in fulfilling its responsibilities under 
    FPA sections 205 and 206, the Commission is required to address, and 
    has the authority to remedy, undue discrimination and anticompetitive 
    effects.145 We also noted that the Commission has the 
    authority and responsibility under section 203 of the FPA to review 
    mergers and other transactions involving public utilities, including 
    dispositions of jurisdictional facilities by public utilities, and that 
    the Commission may grant an application under section 203 upon such 
    terms and conditions as it finds necessary to secure the maintenance of 
    adequate service and the coordination in the public interest of 
    jurisdictional facilities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \145\ FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,695.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Further, we noted that section 202(a) of the FPA authorizes and 
    directs the Commission ``to divide the country into regional districts 
    for the voluntary interconnection and coordination of facilities for 
    the generation, transmission, and sale of electric energy.'' The 
    purpose of this division into regional districts is for ``assuring an 
    abundant supply of electric energy throughout the United States with 
    the greatest possible economy and with regard to the proper utilization 
    and conservation of natural resources.'' Section 202(a) states that it 
    is ``the duty of the Commission to promote and encourage such 
    interconnection and coordination within each such district and between 
    such districts.''
        We solicited comments on whether the Commission should generically 
    mandate RTO participation by all public utilities to remedy undue 
    discrimination under sections 205 and 206 of the FPA, whether market-
    based rates for generation services could continue to be justified for 
    a public utility that does not participate in an RTO, whether a merger 
    involving a public utility that is not a member of an RTO would be 
    consistent with the public interest, whether non-participants that own 
    transmission facilities should be allowed to use the non-pancaked 
    transmission rates of the RTO participants in that region, whether 
    transmission services provided by a transmitting utility need to be 
    under RTO control to satisfy the discrimination standards of sections 
    211 and 212 of the FPA, and whether a public utility's lack of 
    participation
    
    [[Page 838]]
    
    would otherwise be in violation of the FPA.146
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \146\ Id. at 33,762.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments. The comments on the Commission's legal authority to 
    mandate participation in RTOs span the spectrum from those asserting 
    that we clearly have that authority to those asserting that we clearly 
    do not, with others taking a less definitive position in between.
        Supporting Commission's Authority to Mandate RTO Participation. 
    Representative of those asserting that the Commission has the authority 
    to mandate RTO participation are the joint comments filed by APPA, 
    ELCON, TAPS, and TDU Systems (``APPA et al. (WP)''). These parties 
    argue that the FPA as presently constituted gives the Commission 
    ``ample'' legal authority to require participation by public utilities 
    in properly structured and configured RTOs. APPA et al. assert that 
    section 202(a) permits the Commission to determine rational and 
    efficient regional boundaries; section 203 provides authority to 
    require RTO participation as a standardized condition to mitigate the 
    increased generation and transmission concentration brought about by 
    mergers; ``it would be fully consistent with, and indeed required by'' 
    FPA section 205 to insist on RTO participation as a condition necessary 
    to yield competition robust enough to produce just and reasonable 
    market-based rates; requiring RTO participation falls within the 
    Commission's broad discretion to fashion a remedy for undue 
    discrimination under FPA sections 205 and 206; and the Commission could 
    reasonably conclude that it is no longer just and reasonable for 
    transmission service to be planned, implemented, or priced on a less-
    than-regional basis. Other commenters echo some or all of these points 
    in asserting that the Commission currently has sufficient legal 
    authority to mandate RTO participation.147
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \147\ E.g., UAMPS, PJM/NEPOOL Customers, Illinois Commission, 
    Michigan Commission, Cinergy, Industrial Consumers, First Rochdale, 
    East Texas Cooperatives, FMPA.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Some other commenters emphasize the authority contained in 
    particular statutory sections. One commenter states that FPA section 
    202(a) is an express delegation of authority to the Commission to make 
    policy, and the stated goal of that section of assuring an abundant 
    supply of electric energy with the greatest possible economy provides 
    ample authority to support the conclusion that transmission facilities 
    should be operated by an RTO. This commenter states that it is well 
    established administrative law that there is great deference given to 
    an agency charged with policymaking responsibility.148 
    Another commenter, FMPA, argues that the Commission's interconnection 
    authority under FPA sections 202(b) and 210 provides ample basis for 
    mandating RTO participation. According to FMPA, the Commission could 
    find that RTO participation is necessary to ``make effective'' an 
    interconnection, pursuant to FPA section 210, that has been rendered 
    ineffective by fragmented and anticompetitive practices of transmission 
    owners. FMPA also asserts that the Commission could use this authority 
    through a rulemaking without following the individual procedural 
    requirements of section 212.149
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \148\ Professor Koch, citing Chevron U.S.A., Inc. v. Natural 
    Resources Defense Council Inc., 467 U.S. 837 (1984).
        \149\ Citing American Paper Institute, Inc. v. American Elec. 
    Power Serv. Corp., 461 U.S. 402, 419-20 (1983).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In addition to those commenters finding clear authority in the FPA 
    for an RTO mandate, a number of commenters support the suggestion, as 
    one commenter put it, that certain benefits and rights that are within 
    the Commission's authority and discretion to grant or deny should be 
    withheld from utilities unwilling to participate in an 
    RTO.150 PNGC states that the Commission should use ``big 
    sticks'' to obtain RTO participation, and Michigan Commission says the 
    Commission ``should use every stick, carrot, orange-colored stick and 
    tool it can.'' Some commenters assert specifically that the Commission 
    has the authority, and should use its authority, to condition mergers 
    under section 203 and condition market-based rate authority under 
    section 205 of the FPA on RTO participation.151 Some 
    commenters also favor limiting access to non-pancaked transmission 
    rates of RTOs to those who participate in RTOs.152
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \150\ Oneok.
        \151\ E.g., Oneok, TAPS, APPA, PJM/NEPOOL Customers, Illinois 
    Commission, Industrial Consumers, East Texas Cooperatives, FMPA, TDU 
    Systems and PNGC.
        \152\ E.g., TDU Systems, PNGC and PJM/NEPOOL Customers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Even some commenters that generally oppose the idea of an RTO 
    mandate acknowledge that market-based rate authority or mergers could, 
    on a case-by-case basis, be conditioned on RTO participation. For 
    example, Florida Power Corp. states that the Commission could find, 
    ``given certain factual circumstances,'' that the granting of market-
    based rate authority would not be appropriate ``unless the entity 
    agreed to commit its transmission facilities to an RTO.'' United 
    Illuminating states that whatever conditioning authority the Commission 
    may have for market-based rates or mergers could not be used as a basis 
    for a generic rulemaking.
        NECPUC cites to other sections of the FPA that the Commission might 
    rely upon to promote RTO establishment. It supports the use of the 
    complaint process under section 206 of the FPA in specific cases. It 
    also suggests the use of FPA section 207 proceedings, which can be 
    initiated by state commissions, as a vehicle for requiring RTOs where 
    the Commission finds interstate service inadequate or insufficient. 
    NECPUC also urges the use of joint boards and cooperative procedures 
    between the Commission and the states under FPA section 209 as a means 
    of resolving RTO issues.
        Opposing Commission's Authority to Mandate RTO Participation. At 
    the other end of the debate on the Commission's legal authority with 
    respect to RTOs are those that assert that the Commission's authority 
    to mandate RTOs is non-existent or very limited.153 A number 
    of commenters emphasize that FPA section 202(a) is explicitly voluntary 
    and therefore provides no support for the Commission's authority to 
    mandate RTOs.154 FP&L states that it is questionable whether 
    the Commission could use FPA section 202(a) as a tool to promote 
    competition, given that section 202(a) is for the ``coordination and 
    interconnection of facilities,'' and coordination is arguably 
    inconsistent with competition.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \153\ E.g., Southern Company, Puget, Avista, CP&L, Duke, STDUG, 
    FirstEnergy, NYPP, Indianapolis P&L, FP&L, Detroit Edison, Florida 
    Power Corp., Florida Commission, Alabama Commission.
        \154\ E.g., EEI, United Illuminating, Southern Company, Central 
    Maine, CP&L, Duke, NYPP, Florida Power Corp., Florida Commission.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Some argue that the exercise of FPA section 206 authority to remedy 
    discrimination on a generic basis by requiring RTOs would have to be 
    supported by more explicit findings of discrimination than are 
    contained in the NOPR.155 For example, Florida Power Corp. 
    and United Illuminating contend that the Commission cannot use an 
    industry-wide solution to remedy a problem that does not exist 
    industry-wide,156 and the record does not demonstrate an 
    industry-wide problem. EEI and others argue that the Commission may 
    only impose a remedy that is reasonable and appropriate in light of the 
    specific discriminatory
    
    [[Page 839]]
    
    findings made and the actual practices to be corrected, and the NOPR 
    fails to demonstrate such a nexus. Southern Company notes that the 
    Commission has not made any finding of discrimination and that the 
    ``perception'' of discrimination is an insufficient basis on which to 
    invoke FPA sections 205 and 206. CP&L asserts that section 206 may give 
    the Commission some authority with respect to requiring RTOs, but only 
    in individual cases after hearings and substantial evidence of 
    discriminatory practices. Southern Company contends that the 
    Commission's remedial authority under section 206 must be construed in 
    light of the voluntary nature of section 202(a) and the Commission 
    cannot do anything indirectly under section 206 that it cannot do 
    directly under section 202(a). Central Maine asserts that 
    discrimination findings would not apply against a ``wires only'' 
    company such as itself, and similarly, Indianapolis P&L argues that it 
    has no ability to discriminate in favor of its own wholesale generation 
    and therefore could not be forced to join an RTO as a remedy for 
    discrimination.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \155\ E.g., EEI, Central Maine, Southern Company, Duke, NYPP, 
    Dalton Utilities, Indianapolis P&L, Florida Power Corp., Entergy.
        \156\ Citing Associated Gas Distributors v. FERC, 824 F.2d 981 
    (D.C. Cir. 1987), cert. denied, 485 U.S. 1006 (1988).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Some commenters question the Commission's authority to condition 
    market-based rates or mergers on RTO participation. Central Maine 
    argues that the Commission could not conclude on a generic basis that 
    an RTO is needed in every market-based rate case, and that the 
    Commission could not change its existing policy on market-based rates 
    without substantial evidence and reasoned decisionmaking. CP&L states 
    that the Commission cannot use FPA section 205 authority to grant 
    market-based rates merely to advance preferred policies, and cannot use 
    FPA section 203 to condition mergers absent specific findings in a 
    particular case. Duke contends that the Commission has no authority to 
    issue a rule that imposes sanctions for non-participation that would 
    make non-participation practically or economically unfeasible. 
    Similarly, NYPP states that mergers, market-based rates, and access to 
    non-pancaked transmission rates are economic necessities, and using 
    them as conditions would effectively require RTO participation. 
    Indianapolis P&L asserts that it would be inequitable and unjustifiable 
    to withhold market-based rate authority from a utility that has a good 
    reason not to participate in an RTO, and further, that the Commission 
    may not pressure a utility to engage in an activity that it may not 
    require through direct regulation.157 Similarly, Puget 
    states that if the Commission is not mandating RTOs, which is beyond 
    its authority, then the rule must contain no penalties for non-
    participation.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \157\ Citing Altamont Gas Transmission Co., v. FERC, 92 F.3d 
    1239, 1246 (D.C. Cir. 1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several commenters point to the recent court decision in Northern 
    States 158 as limiting the Commission's authority with 
    respect to RTOs.159 These parties assert that Northern 
    States stands for the proposition that the Commission may not directly 
    or indirectly interfere with state regulation of retail service, and 
    that the NOPR would result in traditional utility retail 
    responsibilities being shifted to RTOs. Specifically, for example, 
    Puget alleges that redispatch and planned maintenance are reliability 
    functions that affect the utility's ability to serve native load and 
    are subject to state law. Indianapolis P&L asserts that Northern States 
    makes clear that the Commission may act only under authority given by 
    Congress.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \158\ See Northern States, supra note 89.
        \159\ E.g., Southern Company, Puget, Indianapolis P&L, FP&L, 
    Florida Commission.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A variety of other legal arguments are made in opposition to any 
    Commission efforts to mandate RTO participation. Southern Company 
    contends that since there has been no finding that Order Nos. 888 and 
    889 have failed, there has been no reasonable explanation as to why the 
    Commission should change that policy. CP&L argues that the Commission's 
    authority to enforce FPA section 205 is in the enforcement provisions 
    of FPA sections 314, 316, and 317. CP&L also states that it would be 
    discriminatory to have higher pancaked rates for non-participants in 
    RTOs while participants get the advantage of non-pancaked rates. Duke 
    and Florida Power Corp. assert that requiring involuntary wheeling and 
    imposing common carrier status is outside the Commission's 
    authority,160 and likewise, so is mandating RTOs. Florida 
    Power Corp. contends that requiring RTO participation would force a 
    utility to join an ISO or divest its transmission or generation assets, 
    and the Commission cannot compel divestiture. Florida Power Corp. and 
    Southern Company make the point that the Public Utility Holding Company 
    Act granted the SEC, not the FERC, the authority to restructure the 
    electric utility industry. Florida Power Corp. further argues that 
    requiring RTO participation would be a ``taking'' of utility property 
    for which just compensation would be owed, and that the ``taking'' 
    problem is exacerbated by utilities being liable for facilities no 
    longer under their control. Florida Commission states that the Energy 
    Policy Act of 1992 indicated that the Commission should proceed with 
    transmission access issues case-by-case, not generically.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \160\ Citing Richmond Power & Light Co. v. FERC, 574 F.2d 610 
    (D.C. Cir. 1978) and Otter Tail Power Co. v. U.S., 410 U.S. 366 
    (1973).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Other Comments On Legal Authority. DOE submitted comments strongly 
    supporting the Commission's efforts to establish RTOs. DOE states that 
    while the Commission has substantial authority to accomplish much of 
    what needs to be done, Federal legislation clarifying Commission 
    authority, especially with respect to non-jurisdictional utilities, 
    would greatly facilitate RTO formation.
        One commenter raised the issue of what authority the Commission 
    would rely upon to require the filings in proposed section 35.34(c). 
    This commenter wants the Commission to clarify that the filings would 
    be required pursuant to the information gathering authority under FPA 
    sections 304, 307, and 311, and not under authority of section 205, 
    which the commenter asserts provides no such authority.161
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \161\ Consumers Energy.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        There were only a few comments in response to the Commission's 
    inquiry about sections 211 and 212 or other FPA standards. Florida 
    Power Corp. submits that the Commission cannot rely on FPA sections 211 
    and 212 to mandate RTOs. Florida Power Corp. notes that in Order Nos. 
    888 and 888-A, the Commission recognized that it does not have the 
    authority to order wheeling pursuant to FPA sections 211 and 212 except 
    on a case-by-case basis after an evidentiary hearing resulting in 
    specific findings. Florida Power Corp. argues that because the 
    Commission is fashioning an industry-wide generic solution and not 
    acting on a case-by-case basis, the Commission cannot rely on sections 
    211 and 212 in this proceeding.
        NARUC also notes that Congress revised FPA sections 211 and 212 to 
    provide FERC with authority to address requests for non-discriminatory 
    transmission service on a case-by-case basis. NARUC argues that the 
    goal of promoting regional flexibility is more readily served by case-
    by-case consideration. In this way, NARUC believes that the Commission 
    can use FPA sections 211 and 212 to take a more tailored approach 
    rather than ``one-size-fits-all'' regulations that ignore market 
    development and local conditions.
        Commission Conclusion. Much of the discussion in the comments on 
    the Commission's legal authority with
    
    [[Page 840]]
    
    respect to RTOs focuses on whether the Commission has the statutory 
    authority to mandate that transmission owners participate in an RTO. As 
    discussed elsewhere in this Final Rule, we have decided not to mandate 
    generically that all public utility transmission owners must join an 
    RTO. We conclude that the Commission possesses both general and 
    specific authorities to advance voluntary RTO formation. We also 
    conclude that the Commission possesses the authority to order RTO 
    participation on a case-by-case basis, if necessary, to remedy undue 
    discrimination or anticompetitive effects where supported by the 
    record.162 Of course, RTO participation is not the only 
    remedy that the Commission might employ to address these problems.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \162\ We need not decide in this case the extent of the 
    Commission's authority to mandate generically RTO participation.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        FPA sections 205 and 206. As we stated in the NOPR, the Commission 
    is granted the authority and responsibility by FPA sections 205 and 
    206, 16 U.S.C. 824d and 824e, to ensure that the rates, charges, 
    classifications, and service of public utilities (and any rule, 
    regulation, practice, or contract affecting any of these) are just and 
    reasonable and not unduly discriminatory, and to remedy undue 
    discrimination in the provision of such services. In fulfilling its 
    responsibilities under FPA sections 205 and 206, the Commission is 
    required to address, and has the authority to remedy, undue 
    discrimination and anticompetitive effects. The Commission has a 
    statutory mandate under these sections to ensure that transmission in 
    interstate commerce and rates, contracts, and practices affecting 
    transmission services, do not reflect an undue preference or advantage 
    (or undue prejudice or disadvantage) and are just, reasonable, and not 
    unduly discriminatory or preferential.163 Additionally, as 
    discussed in Order No. 888,164 there is a substantial body 
    of case law that holds that the Commission's regulatory authority under 
    the FPA ``clearly carries with it the responsibility to consider, in 
    appropriate circumstances, the anticompetitive effects of regulated 
    aspects of interstate utility operations pursuant to [FPA] sections 202 
    and 203, and under like directives contained in sections 205, 206, and 
    207.'' 165
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \163\ Once such a finding is made, the Commission is required to 
    remedy it. See, e.g., Southern California Edison Company, 40 FERC 
    para. 61,371 at 62,151-52 (1987), order on reh'g, 50 FERC para. 
    61,275 at 61,873 (1990), modified sub nom., Cities of Anaheim v. 
    FERC, 941 F.2d 1234 (D.C. Cir. 1991); Delmarva Power and Light 
    Company, 24 FERC para. 61,199 at 61,466, order on reh'g, 24 FERC 
    para. 61,380 (1983).
        \164\ Order No. 888, FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 31,036 at 31,669.
        \165\ Gulf States Utilities Co. v. FPC, 411 U.S. 747, 758-59, 
    reh'g denied, 412 U.S. 944 (1973). See City of Huntingburg v. FPC, 
    498 F.2d 778, 783-84 (D.C. Cir. 1974) (Commission has a duty to 
    consider the potential anticompetitive effects of a proposed 
    Interconnection Agreement.)
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        There are two principal contexts in which the authority of FPA 
    sections 205 and 206 has been raised. One is the use of requiring 
    participation in RTOs as a remedy for undue discrimination by public 
    utilities. As discussed above, many commenters believe that the 
    evidence of undue discrimination is sufficient to justify generically 
    mandating RTO participation as a remedy, and many others argue that the 
    record on undue discrimination is insufficient to impose a generic, 
    industry-wide solution. We have concluded in our discussion elsewhere 
    in this Rule that continuing opportunities for undue discrimination 
    exist in the electric transmission industry. However, we have also 
    concluded that a voluntary approach to eliminating such opportunities 
    through RTO formation (including the filing requirements and Commission 
    supported collaboration efforts identified herein) represents a 
    measured and appropriate response to the significant undue 
    discrimination and other competitive impediments identified in this 
    record.
        The other context in which our authority under FPA sections 205 and 
    206 is raised is whether permitting a public utility to charge market-
    based rates for wholesale electricity sales can continue to be 
    justified if the seller or its affiliate owns or operates transmission 
    assets that have not been placed under the control of an RTO. The 
    Commission has a responsibility under FPA sections 205 and 206 to 
    ensure that rates for wholesale power sales are just and reasonable, 
    and has found that market-based rates can be just and reasonable where 
    the seller has no market power. The Commission has determined that to 
    show a lack of market power, the seller and its affiliates must not 
    have, or must have adequately mitigated, market power in the generation 
    and transmission of electric energy, and cannot erect other barriers to 
    entry by potential competitors.166 In the past, the 
    Commission has found that an open access transmission tariff mitigated 
    transmission market power.167
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \166\ See, e.g., Heartland Energy Services, Inc., 68 FERC para. 
    61,233 at 62,060 (1994); Louisville Gas & Electric Company, 62 FERC 
    para. 61,016 at 61,143-44 (1993) (Heartland). See also Louisiana 
    Energy and Power Authority v. FERC, 141 F.3d 364 (D.C. Cir. 1998) 
    (court upholds Commission's use of market-based rate authority).
        \167\ See, e.g., Heartland, 68 FERC at 62,061, 62,063-64.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As discussed above, some commenters believe that the Commission 
    should insist upon RTO participation as a condition necessary to yield 
    competition robust enough to support market-based rates, while others 
    argue that we cannot use market-based rate authority to advance 
    preferred policies or as a penalty. We are not adopting in this Final 
    Rule a generic policy that participation in an RTO is a necessary 
    condition to a public utility receiving, or retaining, market-based 
    rate authority, nor do we propose to use the denial of market-based 
    rate authority as a penalty for not voluntarily complying with this 
    Rule. However, we do have an obligation to ensure that rates for 
    wholesale power sales are just and reasonable, and we adhere to our 
    precedent that market-based rates can be just and reasonable only where 
    transmission market power has been mitigated and there are no other 
    barriers to entry.
        FPA section 202(a) and PURPA section 205. Section 202(a) of the 
    FPA, the authority for which has been delegated to the Commission by 
    the Secretary of Energy,168 authorizes and directs the 
    Commission ``to divide the country into regional districts for the 
    voluntary interconnection and coordination of facilities for the 
    generation, transmission, and sale of electric energy.'' The purpose of 
    this division into regional districts is for ``assuring an abundant 
    supply of electric energy throughout the United States with the 
    greatest possible economy and with regard to the proper utilization and 
    conservation of natural resources.'' Section 202(a) of the FPA states 
    that it is ``the duty of the Commission to promote and encourage such 
    interconnection and coordination within each such district and between 
    such districts.''
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \168\ 63 FR 53889 (Oct. 7, 1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Some commenters assert that FPA section 202(a) gives us broad 
    authority and discretion to promote RTOs to support an abundant supply 
    of electric energy with the greatest possible economy, while others 
    contend that the authority is limited by the ``voluntary'' nature of 
    the provision. We need not decide the precise confines of section 
    202(a) authority here. Clearly, this section gives the Commission the 
    authority, after consultation with state commissions, to establish 
    boundaries for regional districts for the voluntary interconnection and 
    coordination of
    
    [[Page 841]]
    
    facilities in order to assure an abundant supply of electric energy 
    with the greatest possible economy. We have decided in this Rule that 
    we will exercise this authority, at least in the first instance, by 
    allowing transmission owners, in consultation with other interested 
    parties and state commissions, to propose to us what they believe to be 
    appropriate regional districts. In this regard, we conclude that the 
    Commission, pursuant to FPA section 202(a), clearly has the authority 
    to direct public utilities as well as non-public utilities 
    169 to consider the regional coordination that would result 
    from joining an RTO and to participate in Commission-sanctioned RTO 
    discussions.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \169\ The legislative history, as well as the Commission's past 
    use of section 202(a), indicates that the provision applies to both 
    public utilities and non-public utilities. See S. Rep. No. 621, at 
    49 (1935) (``public as well as private plants are included''); 
    Reliability and Adequacy of Electric Service, Order No. 383, 41 FPC 
    846,47 (1969) (information on coordination requested pursuant to 
    section 202(a) from public and non-public utilities).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As we are not in this Final Rule mandating any particular 
    interconnection or coordination of facilities, we need not address 
    whether the language in FPA section 202(a) referring to ``voluntary'' 
    interconnection and coordination limits our authority. It is clearly 
    the intent and requirement of this section that the Commission 
    encourage and promote a regional approach, which is what we are doing 
    in this Final Rule.
        Section 205 of PURPA 170 also supports the Commission's 
    authority to encourage and promote regional coordination. This section, 
    which addresses power pooling, gives the Commission the authority to 
    exempt electric utilities from state laws or regulations which prohibit 
    or prevent voluntary coordination, and to recommend to electric 
    utilities to enter voluntarily into negotiations for pooling 
    arrangements where opportunities for conservation, efficiency, and 
    increased reliability exist. The Commission has previously interpreted 
    section 205 of PURPA as essentially complementing the functions under 
    section 202(a).171
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \170\ 16 U.S.C. 824a-1.
        \171\ In Public Service Company of New Mexico, 25 FERC para. 
    61,469 at 62,038 (1983), the Commission stated that, ``Our mandate 
    under PURPA to promote voluntary coordination is similar to that 
    exercised by our predecessor, the Federal Power Commission, for more 
    than 40 years under Section 202(a) of the Federal Power Act.'' 
    Accord Pacific Gas and Electric Company, 38 FERC para. 61,242 at 
    61,791 (1987) (PURPA ``reaffirms the Commission's authority to 
    promote voluntary coordination of electric utilities'').
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        FPA Section 203. The Commission has the authority and 
    responsibility under section 203 of the FPA to review mergers and other 
    transactions involving public utilities, including dispositions of 
    jurisdictional facilities by public utilities. There are two aspects of 
    this authority that relate to RTO formation. First, public utilities' 
    transfers of control of jurisdictional transmission facilities to 
    entities such as RTOs would require section 203 approval. Under section 
    203 of the FPA, the Commission must approve a proposed disposition of 
    jurisdictional facilities if it is consistent with the public interest.
        Second, the Commission may grant an application under section 203 
    upon such terms and conditions as it finds necessary to secure the 
    maintenance of adequate service and the coordination in the public 
    interest of jurisdictional facilities. FPA section 203(b) explicitly 
    gives the Commission authority to condition a public utility's proposed 
    disposition of jurisdictional assets ``upon such terms and conditions 
    as it finds necessary or appropriate to secure the maintenance of 
    adequate service and the coordination in the public interest of 
    facilities subject to the jurisdiction of the Commission.'' Thus, for 
    instance, the Commission has used section 203 conditioning authority to 
    require that all mergers be conditioned on the offer of comparable open 
    access transmission.172 In the Commission's Merger Policy 
    Statement, it was recognized that the development of fully competitive 
    generation markets is in the public interest and that turning over 
    control of transmission assets to an ISO might be an appropriate remedy 
    for anticompetitive effects of a merger.173
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \172\ El Paso Electric Company and South West Services, 68 FERC 
    para. 61,181 at 61,914-15 (1994), dismissed, 72 FERC para. 61,292 
    (1995).
        \173\ Inquiry Concerning the Commission's Merger Policy Under 
    The Federal Power Act, 61 FR 68595 (Dec. 30, 1996), FERC Stats. & 
    Regs. para. 31,044 at 30,115, 30,121, 30,137 (1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Some commenters urge the Commission to make RTO participation a 
    standardized condition to all mergers in order to mitigate increased 
    generation and transmission concentration, while others claim that RTO 
    imposition as a section 203 condition would require specific findings 
    in a particular case. We do not find as a generic matter in this 
    proceeding that no merger could be consistent with the public interest 
    in the absence of RTO participation. However, as noted in the Merger 
    Policy Statement with respect to ISOs, turning control of transmission 
    assets over to an RTO might be an appropriate remedy for the 
    anticompetitive effects of a merger. In general, our processing of 
    merger applications can be facilitated to the extent the merging 
    parties have resolved potential anticompetitive issues through means 
    such as RTO participation.
        Other Legal Issues. Commenters have suggested other statutory 
    authorities that may be relevant to our efforts to encourage RTOs. 
    These include FPA section 207, which upon state commission complaint 
    authorizes the Commission to remedy inadequate or insufficient 
    interstate service; FPA sections 202(b) and 210, which address the 
    Commission's authority to order interconnections and make effective an 
    interconnection; FPA section 209, which authorizes the Commission to 
    refer matters to joint boards composed of Commission and state 
    representatives; and FPA sections 211 and 212, which address the 
    Commission's authority to require transmission services. We agree that, 
    under appropriate circumstances, these authorities may indeed be 
    relevant to RTO formation. However, we do not, and need not, rely upon 
    them for what we are requiring in this Final Rule, so we will not 
    address here what authority they might confer.
        In response to those commenters who assert that the Northern States 
    \174\ court decision somehow limits our authority with respect to RTOs, 
    we disagree. As reflected in our recently issued order on remand \175\ 
    of the Northern States court decision, that decision addresses narrow 
    circumstances involving transmission curtailment where the third-party 
    transmission customer has redispatch options. We do not interpret the 
    decision as limiting our authority to encourage or require RTO 
    participation. Moreover, we note that formation of RTOs is likely to 
    eliminate or significantly reduce the potential for the type of 
    conflict encountered in Northern States.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \174\ See Northern States, supra note 89.
        \175\ Northern States Power Co. (Minnesota) and Northern States 
    Power Co. (Wisconsin), 89 FERC para. 61,178 (1999).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        With respect to the commenter seeking clarification of the 
    authorities we are relying upon to require the filings we are mandating 
    in this Rule, we clarify that we are relying upon the authorities 
    contained in FPA sections 202(a), 304, 307, and 309 for the filings we 
    are requiring under new sections 35.34(c) and (g). To the extent a 
    public utility proposes to participate in an RTO, we will process that 
    application pursuant to FPA sections 203, 205 or other sections as 
    appropriate.
    
    D. Minimum Characteristics of an RTO
    
        In the NOPR, we proposed minimum characteristics and functions for 
    a transmission entity to qualify as an
    
    [[Page 842]]
    
    RTO. These characteristics and functions are designed to ensure that 
    any RTO will be independent and able to provide reliable, non-
    discriminatory and efficiently priced transmission service to support 
    competitive regional bulk power markets. In the section that follows, 
    we discuss the four minimum characteristics for an RTO, which are:
        (1) Independence from market participants;
        (2) Appropriate scope and regional configuration;
        (3) Possession of operational authority for all transmission 
    facilities under the RTO's control; and
        (4) Exclusive authority to maintain short-term reliability.
        In our discussion below, we clarify and revise to some extent our 
    discussion in the NOPR, but we affirm these as the minimum 
    characteristics of an RTO.
    1. Independence (Characteristic 1)
        As a first required characteristic, the Commission stated that all 
    RTOs must be independent of market participants. To achieve 
    independence, we proposed that RTOs must satisfy three conditions. 
    First, the RTO, its employees, and any non-stakeholder directors must 
    not have any financial interests in any market participants.\176\ 
    Second, the RTO must have a decision-making process that is independent 
    of control by any market participant or class of participants.\177\ The 
    NOPR defined market participant as any entity or its affiliate that 
    buys or sells electric energy in the RTO's region or in any neighboring 
    region that might be affected by the RTO's actions. We said that this 
    second condition would be judged on a case-by-case basis. However, the 
    Commission also proposed, by way of example, that an RTO could satisfy 
    this second condition with (a) a non-stakeholder governing board and 
    (b) a prohibition on market participants having more than a de minimis 
    (one percent) ownership interest in the RTO. Third, the RTO must have 
    exclusive and independent authority to file changes to its transmission 
    tariff with the Commission under section 205 of the FPA.\178\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \176\ FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,726.
        \177\ Id. at 33,727.
        \178\Id. at 33,729.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments. A large number of commenters address different facets of 
    the independence characteristic. To make the summary of comments more 
    manageable, we grouped the comments by key sub-issues: the basic 
    principle; who is a market participant; RTO economic interests in 
    market participants and energy markets; voting interests of one market 
    participant and affiliates; voting interests of classes of market 
    participants; passive ownership interests; RTO governing boards; role 
    of state agencies; and section 205 filing rights.
        The Basic Independence Principle. In the NOPR, the Commission 
    reiterated its earlier statement that ``the principle of independence 
    is the bedrock upon which the ISO must be built'' and that this 
    standard should apply to all RTOs, whether they are ISOs, transcos or 
    variants of the two.\179\ Virtually all commenters agree with this 
    principle. For example, EEI states that ``[a] decisionmaking process 
    independent of the control of any market participant or class of market 
    participants should be an important aspect of the independence 
    principle.'' \180\ The TDU Systems say that ``[f]ull independence is 
    vitally important to the success of RTOs * * * and cannot be safely 
    compromised.'' \181\ The Nine Commissions urge that RTOs must be 
    ``truly independent of market participants in word, deed and 
    appearance.'' \182\ Despite the almost unanimous acceptance of the 
    principle, there are fundamental disagreements (discussed in later 
    sections) among commenters as to how the principle should be 
    implemented, especially for RTOs that would operate as stand alone, 
    for-profit transcos.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \179\ Id. at 33,726.
        \180\ EEI at 25.
        \181\ TDU Systems at 41.
        \182\ Nine Commissions at 8.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Some commenters question whether complete independence comes at too 
    high a cost. For example, FP&L recommends that the Commission ``not 
    consider independence in a vacuum.'' It contends that ``it would make 
    little sense to trade off the greatest degree of independence for the 
    highest cost structure.'' \183\ Salomon Smith Barney makes a similar 
    point. It contends that strict application of the independence standard 
    could thwart the development of for-profit RTOs. Therefore, it urges 
    the Commission ``not to promulgate rules that maintain absolute purity 
    but also throttle the * * * voluntary formation of RTOs.'' \184\ 
    Konoglie/Ford/Fleishman, three individuals from the financial 
    community, express concern that independence will usually be 
    interpreted to mean a separation between ownership and control as 
    currently practiced in ISOs. They argue that, if the ISO model becomes 
    the norm, it could lead to higher capital costs because those who own 
    the transmission assets would not be able to make basic investment and 
    operating decisions. They point out that ownership usually imparts 
    control in most U.S. industries and that transmission operating and 
    investment efficiencies are unlikely to be achieved unless this becomes 
    the norm in a restructured U.S. electricity industry.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \183\ FP&L at 32.
        \184\ Salomon Smith Barney at 5.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        PJM and WEPCO contend that a for-profit transmission company can 
    never be independent because it will always be biased in its operating 
    and investment decisions. Specifically, they assert that a for-profit 
    transco will always be biased toward transmission solutions over other 
    solutions (such as generation redispatch) and its own transmission 
    assets over transmission assets owned by others. WEPCO, therefore, 
    concludes that independence can be achieved only if there is an ISO 
    operating over a for-profit transmission company.\185\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \185\ WEPCO at 9.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Other commenters argue that it would be naive to believe that 
    independence, by itself, will lead to an effective RTO. They argue that 
    an RTO may be completely independent but it must also have sufficient 
    operational and decisionmaking authority if it is to be effective. For 
    example, the TDU Systems assert that independence will not be 
    sufficient if transmission owners attempt to reserve certain decisions 
    for themselves. It points to the transco proposals of the Entergy and 
    the Alliance Companies as examples of a proposed RTO having 
    insufficient decisionmaking authority. NECPUC, representing six New 
    England commissions, argues that an RTO must have independent funding 
    and urges the Commission to include this as an explicit requirement in 
    the final rule. NCPA states that an RTO will not be truly independent 
    unless it is able to make and implement independent procurement 
    decisions.
        Who Is a Market Participant? There is substantial disagreement 
    among commenters about the proposed definition of market participant. 
    Some commenters argue that it should be expanded; others contend that 
    it should be narrowed. In the first group, Illinois Commission urges us 
    to expand the definition of a stakeholder because ``[a] market interest 
    can arise through functions and activities other than just buying or 
    selling electricity.'' \186\ Enron/APX/Coral Power echo this point and 
    contend that an RTO should ``not be subject to control by, and has no 
    interest in the success of any vendor or buyer in the competitive 
    functions of the
    
    [[Page 843]]
    
    industry.'' \187\ Duke recommends expanding the definition to include 
    ``any distribution company or neighboring transmission company and/or 
    any buyer or seller of ancillary services.'' \188\ PJM urges that the 
    definition of a market participant include any entity that owns 
    transmission facilities or provides or buys transmission service.\189\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \186\ Illinois Commission at 29.
        \187\ Enron/APX/Coral Power at 8.
        \188\ See Duke Power at 27. See also Midwest Municipals, Avista 
    and American Forest.
        \189\ United Illuminating disagrees. It asserts that 
    ``transmission owners without power marketing interests'' should not 
    be considered as market participants. United Illuminating at 37.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        TAPS, representing an informal group of transmission dependent 
    utilities in 24 states, also urges us to adopt a broad definition of 
    market participant to ensure RTO neutrality. It argues that millions of 
    dollars of investments and operating costs will be affected by RTO 
    decisions. It gives several examples of how RTO decisions can have 
    major economic impacts. As a transmission planner, an RTO will have 
    substantial responsibility for routing new transmission lines. 
    Depending on its decisions, it can help or hurt one gas pipeline or 
    another or one generator or another. As a transmission tariff 
    administrator, it will have significant discretion in choosing how to 
    price congestion. Any decision that it makes (e.g., zonal versus nodal 
    pricing) could have significant impacts on the profitability of 
    particular generators. As the supplier of last resort for ancillary 
    services, it will have considerable discretion in defining the types 
    and quantities of ancillary services that are needed. Depending on its 
    decisions, some generators ``will win, and others will lose.'' \190\ 
    Finally, as the ``transmission-request gatekeeper,'' it will have 
    substantial influence on who gets service and on what terms. To ensure 
    both the appearance and reality of neutrality in these various 
    decisions, TAPS urges us to adopt a broad definition of market 
    participant.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \190\ TAPS at 63.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In contrast, others contend that the proposed definition is too 
    broad. CP&L states that a literal application of the proposed 
    definition ``would make every single residential, commercial, 
    industrial and wholesale electric customer (and all of their 
    affiliates) market participants.'' \191\ It recommends that the 
    definition be narrowed by changing it to ``those entities that are 
    active in wholesale and non-regulated retail power markets using 
    transmission of the RTO.'' \192\ LPPC asks that the Commission define 
    the term ``affiliate'' because it is not defined anywhere in the NOPR. 
    It also suggests that the definition of affiliate be limited to 
    ``common control'' rather than using the five-percent ownership 
    interest standard of PUHCA.\193\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \191\ CP&L at 23-24. American Forest believes that ``the 
    Commission did not intend such a broad exclusion, and seeks 
    clarification on this point.'' American Forest at 4.
        \192\ CP&L at 23-24.
        \193\ LPPC points out that the term ``affiliate'' is used in 
    defining market participant but is not defined anywhere in the 
    proposed rule.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A number of commenters focus specifically on the question of 
    whether a ``distribution only'' entity (i.e., an entity that performs 
    the sole function of transporting electricity at distribution voltages) 
    should be considered a market participant. Montana Power urges us 
    against expanding the definition to include an entity that operates 
    ``distribution-only facilities.'' It argues that an RTO and a 
    distribution entity are both ``delivery entities'' and efficiencies can 
    be gained by having one entity provide ``total delivery service'' from 
    high to low voltages. These efficiencies of vertical integration could 
    include the savings that would result from having maintenance performed 
    on both transmission and distribution facilities by the same crews, the 
    sharing of shop and warehouse space and the sharing of various 
    administrative support functions. Sierra Pacific generally supports 
    this view and asserts that it does not believe that a ``transmission 
    owner could so operate its facilities to materially assist affiliated 
    transmission and distribution interests to the disadvantage of 
    unaffiliated entities.'' 194
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \194\ Sierra Pacific at 17.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Salomon Smith Barney takes a more cautious view. It states that an 
    RTO owned by distribution entities ``could manipulate the grid to favor 
    their customers over the customers of other distributors.'' 
    195 Trans-Elect argues that the Commission's recent attempt 
    to impose non-discriminatory curtailment procedures on all users of the 
    grid in the NSP service territory demonstrates that this problem 
    already exists.196 Arguing that it would be undesirable to 
    lose distribution entities as potential investors in RTOs, Salomon 
    Smith Barney recommends that the Commission require RTOs to follow 
    market-based priority rules in curtailment situations to reduce the 
    likelihood that an RTO would favor affiliated distribution entities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \195\ Salomon Smith Barney at 5.
        \196\ Trans-Elect at 5 citing Northern States Power Co. v. FERC, 
    176 F.3d 1090 (8th Cir. 1999).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Both Sierra Pacific and NEPCO et al. raise concerns about the 
    interaction of the market participant definition and ``state-mandated 
    backstop power supply obligations.'' NEPCO et al. asserts that all 23 
    states that have opted for retail competition to date have usually 
    imposed a default supplier obligation (which also is referred to as a 
    ``standard offer supplier'' or a `` provider of last resort'' 
    obligation) on one party which is usually the incumbent provider. 
    Sierra Pacific notes that the nature and duration of this mandated 
    obligation varies from state-to-state ``but at least some of the 
    programs are structured so that the POLR [provider of last resort] does 
    not compete for new customers and has no incentive to retain existing 
    POLR customers.'' 197 Both commenters argue that providers 
    of last resort should not automatically be considered as market 
    participants, even though they buy and sell electricity, because this 
    would reduce the pool of potential transco investors. Sierra Pacific 
    states that the Commission should ``leave the door open to consider the 
    POLR issue on a case-by-case basis'' and that the final regulations 
    should explicitly say that a provider of last resort would not be 
    deemed a market participant if its state mandated obligation gives it 
    no incentive to make such sales.198
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \197\ Sierra Pacific at 16.
        \198\ Id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Finally, NEPCO et al. raises the issue of incumbent utilities that 
    have tried to divest themselves of their generating assets but have not 
    yet succeeded. It points to its difficulties in divesting its minority 
    ownership interests in nuclear plants. It requests that an entity not 
    be automatically deemed a market participant because of these minority 
    ownership interests especially if it has taken actions to eliminate its 
    control over the retained ownership interest (e.g., through a long-term 
    contract that would give marketing rights to a non-affiliated entity).
        RTO Economic Interests in Market Participants and Energy Markets. 
    Many commenters, representing a wide range of industry constituencies, 
    agree with the NOPR's proposal that the RTO, its employees and any non-
    stakeholder directors must not have any financial interests in 
    electricity market participants.199 Duke recommends that, 
    where divestment is required, the Commission should continue its past 
    practice of allowing employees to divest personal investments in a 
    manner that
    
    [[Page 844]]
    
    does not cause them significant financial harm.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \199\ One exception is Salomon Smith Barney. It argues that this 
    requirement is ``altogether unreasonable, in that it could require 
    the most qualified directors and employees to dispose of mutual 
    funds, pension plans and old investments whose tax base makes 
    disposition unreasonable.'' Salomon Smith Barney at 3.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Most commenters agree that the focus should be on current financial 
    interests.200 Several commenters point out that it would be 
    virtually impossible for an RTO to hire knowledgeable and experienced 
    employees if the Commission were to require no past financial 
    connections to market participants. They assert that some of the most 
    knowledgeable candidates for RTO positions, at least in an RTO's early 
    years of operation, are likely to be individuals who have retired from 
    companies that are market participants and it is likely that these 
    individuals will be receiving pensions from their former employers. In 
    situations like this, NASUCA urges the Commission to ``exclude from 
    this prohibition * * * employee pension plans and other post-employment 
    benefits received while a former employee of a market participant.'' 
    201 Others urge that the Commission follow the precedent 
    that was established in the Midwest ISO decision.202 
    Individuals would not be automatically excluded from RTO employment or 
    directorships if their pension does not directly depend on the economic 
    performance of their former employers (e.g., a defined benefit pension 
    plan). TDU Systems suggests that reasonable exceptions should be made 
    ``in the case of defined benefit pension plans, general mutual funds 
    (as opposed to utility/energy sector funds) that hold stock or bonds of 
    market participants, or other similar financial holdings where the 
    holder cannot direct specific investments or benefit directly from 
    stock performance.'' 203
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \200\ With respect to future financial interests, Salomon Smith 
    Barney states that ``[p]rivate enterprises do not normally, control 
    the lives of their ex-employees.'' Salomon Smith Barney at 3.
        \201\ NASUCA at 17.
        \202\ See Midwest Independent System Operator, 85 FERC para. 
    61,250 (1998). See also Southern Company, Duke, TDU Systems and 
    Avista.
        \203\ TDU Systems at 39.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In the NOPR, we asked whether there was a need to ``define the 
    financial independence requirement in more specific terms.'' 
    204 The answer from almost all respondents was ``no.'' For 
    example, TDU Systems recommend that we issue a general rule with a set 
    of guidelines and then allow for its application on a case-by-case 
    basis. Avista agrees and states that any financial independence 
    standard ``require[s] case-by-case consideration as well as the common 
    sense application of the rule of reason.'' 205 PJM/NEPOOL 
    Customers states that RTOs will have the benefit of the conflict of 
    interest standards that have been drafted for each of the functioning 
    ISOs. They also recommend that the Commission commence a separate 
    rulemaking on this issue.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \204\ FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,727.
        \205\ Avista at 11.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Some commenters contend that the NOPR's treatment of financial 
    independence is too narrowly drawn. For example, Dynegy argues that 
    while ISOs ``may ostensibly be independent of market participants--they 
    are not independent of the market itself.'' 206 As evidence 
    of this phenomenon, it points to instances when the California ISO has 
    tried to impose price caps on energy prices. EPSA expresses a similar 
    view and points to the price caps proposed by ISO New England and 
    approved by this Commission during the June 1999 heat wave, when energy 
    prices reached $1,600 a megawatt-hour, as another example of 
    undesirable and inappropriate intervention by a transmission provider 
    in energy markets. In crafting a definition of independence, EPSA urges 
    the Commission to require that RTOs ``should be indifferent to the 
    price at which the commodity they transport clears the market.'' 
    207
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \206\ Dynegy at 35.
        \207\ EPSA Reply Comments at 12.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Others argue that this conflict is unavoidable as long as the 
    Commission imposes a requirement that RTOs be the supplier of last 
    resort for certain ancillary services.208 According to these 
    commenters, this obligation will often require that the RTO be a buyer 
    in certain ancillary service markets. If the supplier of last resort 
    obligation is also combined with a requirement that the RTO buy 
    efficiently, then it is inevitable that the RTO will be interested in 
    whether the prices are high or low (i.e., it is no longer simply a 
    disinterested market operator).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \208\ See NEMA at 19. See also EPSA Reply Comments.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Active (Voting) Ownership Interests in the RTO. a. By Individual 
    Market Participants and Their Affiliates. A number of commenters oppose 
    a one-percent cap on allowed voting interests of market participants in 
    RTOs as a necessary requirement for achieving 
    independence.209 EEI states that such a cap is not 
    ``necessary, rational or supportable'' for achieving the goal of 
    independence.210 It recommends that the Commission allow 
    market participants or their affiliates to own up to ten-percent voting 
    interests in RTOs. EEI also asks for a clarification of whether an 
    ownership restriction would ``apply only to ownership in the RTO itself 
    or does it also apply to ownership interests in the transmission 
    facilities under the operational control of the RTO.'' 211 
    PJM, which is organized as a non-profit limited liability corporation 
    (LLC), asks the Commission to clarify whether its ``members'' would be 
    considered owners.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \209\ See, e.g., EEI, Duke, CP&L and PacifiCorp.
        \210\ EEI notes that the NOPR mentions the one percent cap on 
    voting interests by market participants in the National Grid Company 
    in England and Wales but observes that there was no obvious 
    justification given at the time the decision was made.
        \211\ EEI at 26.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        CTA also argues for a higher cap. It states that the NOPR's 
    emphasis on ownership is misplaced. Instead, the Commission should be 
    concerned with the ``actual control over the day-to-day affairs of the 
    system, not some arbitrary percent ownership test.'' 212 The 
    Alliance Companies express the concern that, even though the one 
    percent cap appears to have been proposed as a ``safe harbor,'' it 
    could quickly become ``the only port of entry to Commission approval.'' 
    213
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \212\ CTA at 4.
        \213\ Alliance Companies at 18.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        EEI observes that other government agencies allow five or ten 
    percent ownership in voting shares before assuming that these ownership 
    interests conveyed control.214 For example, it notes that 
    the SEC definition of an ``affiliate'' under PUHCA is limited to 
    entities that own or control more than five percent of the voting stock 
    of a public utility. It also observes that this Commission, in 
    determining whether a company is an affiliate of a natural gas pipeline 
    or an electric utility, applies a rebuttable presumption of control 
    only when a utility owns ten percent or more of a company's voting 
    stock. Entergy states that ``there do not appear to be instances under 
    U.S. law where one-percent ownership is considered to give rise to a 
    risk of control.'' 215
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \214\ Most investor-owned utilities agree with EEI. An exception 
    is Cinergy which urges the Commission to incorporate the one-percent 
    ownership standard in the final regulations ``exactly as proposed'' 
    because such a prohibition ``is vital to preserving a RTO's 
    financial independence characteristic.'' Cinergy at 17.
        \215\ Entergy at 28.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several commenters question why there should be any limits on the 
    amount of voting shares that can be held by a market participant. For 
    example, Allegheny asserts that ``[t]he desire to maintain or obtain 
    ownership of transmission assets by market participants should not be 
    regarded as an evil to be avoided at all costs.'' 216 FP&L 
    states that there is no need to
    
    [[Page 845]]
    
    prohibit affiliated transcos.217 It argues that the 
    Commission should allow 100-percent ownership of voting equity and 
    ensure non-discriminatory transmission access through codes of conduct 
    and state commission oversight, in the case of a single state RTO. It 
    observes that ``in the natural gas industry there are numerous transcos 
    (pipelines) that are affiliated with gas producers, marketers and/or 
    distribution companies and there is no basis to conclude that this 
    structure would be less likely to succeed in the electric power 
    industry.'' 218
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \216\ Allegheny Reply Comments at 10.
        \217\ In contrast, APPA states that affiliated transcos should 
    be allowed ``only where such private companies operate under the 
    direct, ongoing supervision of a strong, fully functional regional 
    Independent System Operator.'' APPA at 28.
        \218\ FP&L at 26.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Other commenters disagree and urge the Commission to adopt even 
    stricter standards on ownership than those presented in the 
    NOPR.219 For example, APPA recommends that the final rule 
    prohibit any ownership interests in RTOs by market 
    participants.220 APPA states that even a one-percent 
    ownership would represent an unjustifiable and unnecessary exception to 
    the independence standard. South Carolina Authority agrees with APPA 
    and argues that the NOPR failed to present a ``public policy benefit'' 
    for allowing even a de minimis ownership interest.221 NASUCA 
    also shares this view. In addition, it asserts that as soon as the 
    Commission allows any ownership by market participants it will be 
    forced to continually track the share of each market participant, 
    including affiliates. NASUCA argues that this would be ``time-
    consuming, difficult and expensive'' and would represent the very 
    antithesis of the independent, lightly regulated structure that the 
    Commission wished to foster.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \219\ See, e.g., Midwest Municipals, APPA, TDU Systems and 
    Industrial Consumers.
        \220\ APPA clarifies that it does not oppose market participants 
    owning ``for-profit'' transcos if the transcos come under the 
    supervision of strong fully functional ISOs. Industrial Consumers 
    recommend that a one-percent cap should be adopted in the final rule 
    as a general requirement rather than as a possible safe harbor. In 
    addition, it recommends that the cap be calculated on a corporate-
    wide basis to avoid the situation of multiple affiliates each with a 
    one-percent interest. See Industrial Consumers at 30.
        \221\ See South Carolina Authority at 18.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        TDU Systems concurs and observes that any ownership by market 
    participants will trigger the ``chasing after conduct'' regulation that 
    the Commission said it hoped to avoid.222
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \222\ TDU Systems at 41 citing FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 
    32,541 at 31,145.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In addition, TDU Systems criticizes EEI's ten percent proposal. TDU 
    Systems asserts that EEI fails to understand the rationale for the 
    ``safe harbor'' proposal in the NOPR. TDU Systems argues that the 
    regulatory purpose of a ``safe harbor'' is to ensure that ``no case-by-
    case review of the regulatory agency is required.'' 223 
    Therefore, TDU Systems contends that it would be inappropriate to adopt 
    EEI's proposed ten percent because this percentage is not in the ``safe 
    harbor'' but, as recognized by other regulatory agencies, raises a 
    clear risk of control. Consumer Groups supports this view and points to 
    one case in which a court decided that a three-percent ownership 
    interest of a company's common stock was found to be ``sufficient to 
    assert control over the corporation because the ownership of the other 
    common shares was widely dispersed.'' 224
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \223\ TDU Systems Reply Comments at 14 (italicized in the 
    original).
        \224\ Consumer Groups Reply Comments at 8.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Alliance Companies, who support a ceiling of five percent 
    ownership in voting interests by market participants, state that they 
    ``are aware of no practical means of tracking who has an ownership 
    interest at a threshold of less than five percent `` because SEC 
    regulations require reporting of ownership in publicly traded companies 
    only at five-percent ownership and above. In contrast, Cinergy asserts 
    that enforcing a lower ownership limit should not be a problem. It 
    states that the Commission could keep track of ownership interests 
    ``through transmission owners'' representations and subsequent audits 
    if the need arises.'' 225
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \225\ Cinergy at 18.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        APPA, which argues for absolute and total prohibition on voting 
    ownership by market participants, asserts that even with access to SEC 
    data it will be difficult for the Commission to keep track of who 
    really owns voting shares since they are often registered in ``street'' 
    names. Therefore, it urges the Commission to impose a total prohibition 
    on ownership by market participants. South Carolina Authority agrees 
    and further argues that anything less would fail to achieve the 
    Commission's characterization of an RTO as entity in which ``the 
    control of transmission operation is cleanly separated from power 
    market participants.'' 226 It concludes that ``[t]here is 
    nothing `clean' about permitting incumbent transmission owners to 
    indefinitely maintain an ownership interest, voting or otherwise, in 
    the newly created RTO.'' 227
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \226\ South Carolina Authority at 8 (quoting from FERC Stats. & 
    Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,718 (emphasis added by the quoter)).
        \227\ South Carolina Authority at 14.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        EPSA suggests a compromise that would allow greater flexibility 
    with respect to initial ownership interests. It proposes that the 
    Commission establish time limits on voting ownership. TDU Systems makes 
    a similar recommendation with respect to passive ownership. While TDU 
    Systems states that it would prefer an absolute prohibition on market 
    participants owning voting shares, it suggests that the Commission 
    might consider allowing transmission owners to ``hold passive, non-
    voting ownership interests in excess of one percent as an extraordinary 
    transition measure.'' 228 However, TDU Systems recommends 
    that such interests be reduced to one percent or below in a 
    ``relatively short period of time.''
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \228\ TDU Systems at 42.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        b. By Classes of Market Participants. SRP asserts that the NOPR is 
    flawed because it is not sufficient to place a limitation on the 
    ownership interests that can be held by a single participant and its 
    affiliates while ignoring the possibility that other owners may have 
    similar interests. SRP urges the Commission to recognize that ``[a]n 
    interest that may be considered de minimis, when viewed in isolation, 
    could still result in effective control when aggregated for a group 
    with common interests.'' \229\ Therefore, it recommends that limits be 
    placed not only on the ownership interests of an individual market 
    participant but also on the ownership interests by other market 
    participants with similar economic interests. SRP does not recommend a 
    specific percentage for a group cap, but Industrial Consumers urge the 
    Commission to cap the voting interests of any group at five percent.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \229\ Salt River at 11. United Illuminating agrees and states 
    that if the Commission ``were to adopt a higher de minimis standard, 
    such as five or ten percent ownership interest, it would be 
    relatively easy for five or six market participants owning such 
    percentages to control the operations of an RTO.'' United 
    Illuminating at 39-40.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        FP&L contends that there is no need for ownership caps for a group 
    of market participants because they will often have conflicting 
    economic interests. It gives the example of a group of transmission 
    owners with ownership interests in an RTO who also own affiliated power 
    marketers. FP&L argues these marketing affiliates will compete against 
    each other and this rivalry will mitigate the potential for collusion 
    among the parent companies that jointly own the RTO. Alliance Companies 
    agree with this view. They assert that ``[i]n today's competitive power 
    markets, all market participants, including those traditionally 
    classified within the same
    
    [[Page 846]]
    
    stakeholder group are likely to be competitors'' and, therefore, that 
    it is unlikely that there will be a ``nexus of interest.'' \230\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \230\ Alliance Companies at 21-22.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        EEI argues that ownership caps on groups of market participants 
    would be ``impractical and extremely burdensome on Commission 
    resources'' because the Commission would have to keep track of 
    ownership levels by every market participant and also align market 
    participants into specific groups with ``alleged common interests.'' 
    \231\ In addition, it contends that this task would be difficult to do 
    because markets are evolving and the business objectives of individual 
    firms will change as they buy or sell assets. Moreover, while accepting 
    that ``some market participants may have common interests at certain 
    times'' EEI believes that such ``coalitions'' would be ``fragile, 
    short-lived and unlikely to result in a serious threat to the 
    independence of the RTO.'' \232\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \231\ EEI Reply Comments at 21.
        \232\ Id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A number of commenters assert that a cap on voting interests will 
    thwart capital formation in new and existing transmission facilities. 
    For example, UtiliCorp contends that such a cap ``may potentially choke 
    off significant sources of capital'' for the formation of for-profit 
    transcos.\233\ Various commenters from the financial community argue 
    that such a cap would make it difficult to create RTOs that function as 
    for-profit transcos. Salomon Smith Barney states that current owners of 
    transmission assets need to retain a larger ownership interest, at 
    least for a transition period, in order to avoid heavy capital gains 
    taxes. It estimates that many current transmission owners would have to 
    pay capital gains taxes on about 35 to 50 percent of the current book 
    value of their transmission assets if they were to sell these assets.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \233\ UtiliCorp at 7.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Alliance Companies asserts that restrictions on ownership would 
    reduce the potential pool of investors (i.e., buyers of transmission 
    assets) and therefore reduce the price that current owners could 
    receive for their assets. They contend that this would be especially 
    damaging because it would place limits on ownership by ``those entities 
    that are most likely to understand the potential value of the business 
    model.'' \234\ Alliance Companies states that the Commission should 
    allow five-percent individual ownership interests by industry 
    participants because this will provide confidence to other, non-energy 
    industry investors that the transco will be a financial success.\235\ 
    In general, the Alliance Companies and other commenters that share this 
    view take the position that a one-percent cap for market participants 
    will be a major impediment to the creation of for-profit transcos and 
    that the de facto effect of such a cap will be to limit the industry to 
    the ISO model.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \234\ Alliance Companies at 19.
        \235\ In contrast, APPA asserts that ``if the underlying 
    business model is sound, investors will come.'' APPA at 36.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Passive (Non-Voting) Ownership Interests in the RTO. A number of 
    privately-owned utilities stress that the final rule must distinguish 
    between passive and voting interests in RTOs.\236\ For example, while 
    EEI is willing to accept a ten-percent cap on ownership of voting 
    interests by individual market participants, it states that ``[t]here 
    should be no limit on the amount of passive ownership interest'' 
    because ``[p]assive owners who lack voting rights have no ability to 
    control the firm.'' \237\ Enron/APX/Coral Power also support this 
    position. They urge the Commission to ``explicitly and unambiguously 
    allow incumbent utilities and other power industry participants to 
    possess passive but not controlling ownership interests in an RTO.'' 
    \238\ Southern Company states that ``[p]assive ownership of 
    transmission facilities--even up to 100 percent--should not be a 
    concern.'' \239\ United Illuminating, while recommending that the 
    Commission allow passive ownership, recommends that we should not issue 
    generic rules because passive ownership is a ``complex matter that must 
    be reviewed on a case-by-case basis.'' \240\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \236\ See, e.g., EEI, Enron/APX/Coral Power and UtiliCorp.
        \237\ EEI at 26. EEI relies on a legal memorandum that concludes 
    that passive ownership interests are ``necessarily permissible, no 
    matter how large and no matter what other interests they are 
    combined with.'' EEI Appendix H at 17.
        \238\ Enron/APX/Coral Power at 14.
        \239\ Southern Company at 42.
        \240\ United Illuminating at 7.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        EEI contends that some of the opposition to passive ownership by 
    market participants may simply reflect a misunderstanding of the 
    fiduciary responsibilities that the board of a for-profit transco has 
    to its passive owners. EEI asserts that, under Delaware law and various 
    model statutes, the fiduciary responsibilities of a for-profit transco 
    board, its managers and owners that hold voting rights to a passive 
    owner are limited to maximizing the value of the transmission assets 
    and ``not the value of any other assets that may be held by the passive 
    owner.'' \241\ According to EEI, a transco board has no fiduciary 
    obligation to take actions to produce economic benefits for other 
    assets such as generating units that happen to be owned by its passive 
    owners. Entergy states that if there are any lingering doubts about the 
    fiduciary obligation of the board and its voting members, a provision 
    could be inserted in the ``transco's limited liability agreement that 
    specifically directed that managers would have no fiduciary duty to 
    consider the private interests of members'' and that such a provision 
    would be enforceable under Delaware law.\242\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \241\ EEI at 26.
        \242\ Entergy at 29.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Consumer Groups, however, questions the legal feasibility of this 
    approach. It cites to several law review articles which it argues raise 
    doubts as to whether fiduciary duties assigned by a state law to the 
    directors of a subsidiary corporation can be removed by private 
    agreement. It also cautions the Commission not to get lost in ``a 
    lawyer's duel over conflicting citations about the treatment of passive 
    and affiliated ownership interests'' when the fundamental issue is the 
    need to safeguard independence and ``avoid any appearance of 
    partiality.'' \243\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \243\ Consumer Groups Reply Comments at 9.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        EEI points to our recent decision in Entergy Services, Inc., as 
    demonstrating that the Commission recognizes that passive ownership is 
    not inconsistent with the independence principle under the ISO 
    principles of Order No. 888.\244\ It asks that the Commission reach the 
    same policy conclusion for any similar independence requirement in the 
    final RTO rule. In contrast, the South Carolina Authority observes that 
    while the Entergy decision could be read to imply that the Commission 
    has ``prejudged this issue,'' the Commission should now use the 
    opportunity of this NOPR to take another look at the issue.\245\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \244\ EEI at 26 citing Entergy Services, Inc., 88 FERC para. 
    61,149 (1999).
        \245\ South Carolina Authority at 22.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        EEI also points to actions or policies taken by other federal 
    regulatory agencies that it argues support its contention that passive 
    ownership does not necessarily convey control. It observes that the 
    definitions of ``holding company,'' ``affiliate'' and ``subsidiary 
    company'' in PUHCA are all tied to ownership of voting rather than non-
    voting shares. Similarly, EEI states that the FCC ``attribution rules'' 
    used to determine when broadcasters and cable companies own or control 
    another
    
    [[Page 847]]
    
    broadcaster or cable company are keyed to voting rather than passive 
    ownership interests. According to EEI, these policies demonstrate that 
    other federal regulatory agencies do not believe that passive ownership 
    conveys control and that the Commission should adopt a similar policy.
        EEI also contends that the Commission has already allowed a 
    ``passive economic interest'' in all of the ISOs that have been 
    approved to date. Sierra Pacific makes a similar argument. Sierra 
    Pacific contends that ``profits'' made by an ISO go back to the 
    transmission owners even though they may have relinquished operational 
    and decisionmaking control. It argues that ``this arrangement [in ISOs] 
    is the essence of a passive ownership interest.'' \246\ The principal 
    difference is that ``the passive ownership interest in a Transco 
    involves ownership in the transco itself rather than the assets 
    operated by the Transco.'' \247\ However, it argues that in substance 
    both types of interests are the same since they allow the owner to 
    share in the profits derived from operating their transmission 
    facilities without having any influence over that operation. Sierra 
    Pacific concludes by urging the Commission to allow passive ownership 
    in both types of institutions to avoid creating ``an artificial 
    incentive in favor of ISOs instead of Transcos.'' \248\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \246\ Sierra Pacific at 11.
        \247\ Id.
        \248\ Sierra Pacific at 12.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Enron/APX/Coral Power point to the example of National Grid Company 
    (NGC) in England and Wales as a real world example of passive ownership 
    of a for-profit transco by market participants. For several years after 
    privatization in 1990, the regional electricity companies (RECs) were 
    allowed to own NGC but were ``expressly barred from participating in 
    day-to-day management or interfering with the ability of NGC to fulfill 
    the purpose of privatization.'' \249\ However, in reply comments TDU 
    Systems contends that Enron/APX/Coral Power fails to mention that this 
    passive ownership arrangement was terminated after several years. 
    Citing to a recent interview with Callum McCarthy, Great Britain's 
    Director of Gas and Electricity Supply, TDU Systems points out that the 
    RECs were ``told to divest these interests, and did so.'' \250\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \249\ Enron/APX/Coral Power at 14.
        \250\ TDU Systems Reply Comments at 22.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In contrast, TDU Systems and others ask the Commission not to allow 
    passive ownership in the final rule.\251\ TDU Systems say that ``the 
    line between passive and active ownership is often not a bright line.'' 
    \252\ As an example, it states that in the recent Alliance transco 
    filing, the divesting transmission owners ``hold supposedly passive 
    ownership interests in the Transco, but retain the right to pass on a 
    number of different business transactions.'' \253\ TDU Systems assert 
    that if the Commission opens the door to ownership of RTOs by market 
    participants, it will be forced to engage in substantial ``conduct 
    policing.'' Salomon Smith Barney concurs and states that passive 
    ownership ``will prove troublesome for both the utilities and FERC'' 
    because it creates a ``need to constantly police supposedly passive 
    ownership positions to make sure that they remain passive in all 
    respects.'' \254\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \251\ See, e.g., APPA, Industrial Consumers and South Carolina 
    Authority.
        \252\ TDU Systems at 41.
        \253\ Entergy at 42.
        \254\ Salomon Smith Barney Reply Comments at 15.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        South Carolina Authority echoes this point. It argues that by 
    allowing passive ownership the Commission would be put in the difficult 
    job of determining ``how `passive' a particular `passive interest' 
    really is.'' \255\ It urges the Commission not to compromise its 
    ``bedrock position on independence'' because it will lead to ``an 
    endless series of extensive battles over ownership structure, corporate 
    bylaws and rules, layered on top of continuing allegations of 
    discrimination in the marketplace.'' \256\ It asks ``why * * * risk 
    compromising the independence principle?'' \257\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \255\ South Carolina Authority at 21.
        \256\ Id. at 24.
        \257\ Id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Just as several commenters raise capital formation arguments in 
    support of the need to allow some voting interests by market 
    participants, many of these commenters also raise similar arguments in 
    support of allowing passive ownership.\258\ In general, they contend 
    that current owners are not likely to sell transmission assets 
    voluntarily to others if selling leads to a large capital gains tax 
    payment. They contend that passive ownership provides a creative way to 
    allow transfer of grid operations to an independent party while 
    reducing the tax burden on current transmission owners.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \258\ See, e.g., Entergy and Southern Company.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In contrast, Consumer Groups asserts that there are mechanisms 
    other than passive ownership that would ``permit `divestiture' without 
    tax consequences'' and that an important advantage of these other 
    mechanisms is that they would ``better assure independence.'' \259\ As 
    one example, Consumer Groups asserts that a vertically integrated 
    utility could spin off its transmission assets to its shareholders. 
    While recognizing that the IRS Code seems to eliminate the favorable 
    tax treatment if the spun-off corporation is sold within two years of 
    the original distribution, Consumer Groups states that this is a 
    rebuttable, not an absolute, prohibition and that a recent IRS proposed 
    rule seems to suggest that favorable tax treatment could be retained if 
    the spin-off of transmission assets is done in response to regulatory 
    mandates. South Carolina Authority raises a different argument against 
    regulatory policies to accommodate passive ownership. It asks why the 
    Commission should feel obligated to minimize the federal corporate 
    income tax responsibilities of privately owned utilities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \259\ Consumer Groups Reply Comments at 11.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several commenters recommend that we accept passive ownership at 
    least as a necessary transition device. For example, Enron/APX/Coral 
    Power state that ``there will likely need to be some years of passive 
    ownership by industry participants before the RTOs will have 
    demonstrated their viability as stand-alone transmission businesses 
    that can successfully be taken public.'' \260\ ISO-NE, which favors a 
    single grid company for all of New England, observes that because of 
    ``tax and other considerations, current owners of transmission assets 
    may wish to avoid immediate divestiture, and may wish to retain 
    indirect ownership.'' \261\ Salomon Smith Barney predicts that most 
    utilities will want to dispose of passive and minority interests over 
    time. NECPUC, representing the six New England commissions, echoes this 
    point. It states that the Commission may have to accept 
    ``[t]ransitional periods in which the ownership interests of market 
    participants are phased out over time.'' If such transitions are 
    allowed, NECPUC urges us to ensure that they are ``carefully 
    monitored.'' \262\ TDU Systems, as noted earlier, recommends that 
    passive ownership should be used only as an ``extraordinary transition 
    measure'' and should be allowed only for a short period of time.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \260\ Enron/APX/Coral Power at 14.
        \261\ ISO-NE at 20.
        \262\ NECPUC at 11.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        RTO Governing Boards. Many commenters recommend that membership on 
    RTO governing (i.e., decisional) boards be limited to non-
    stakeholders.\263\ For example, the Justice
    
    [[Page 848]]
    
    Department urges the Commission to consider barring all market 
    participants from any decision-making role. It says that this approach 
    assures ``a clean structural break.'' \264\ If stakeholders are allowed 
    on the governing board, the Justice Department recommends that 
    independents (i.e., non-stakeholders) should constitute a majority of 
    the board's voting members and that the board's voting rules not allow 
    vetoes by any one class of stakeholders. Most commenters who support an 
    independent board recommend that the maximum size of the board not be 
    specified in the final rule but instead be left to the discretion of 
    the participants. Two exceptions are the South Carolina Authority, 
    which recommends that board size be limited to seven to nine directors, 
    and the Midwest Municipals, which suggests that the Commission question 
    any non-stakeholder board that has more than 10 to 15 members.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \263\ See, e.g., Advisory Committee ISO-NE, APX, Avista, Desert 
    STAR, Industrial Consumers, PJM, Reliant, South Carolina Authority 
    and UtiliCorp. In general, these commenters adopt the convention 
    used in the NOPR that a non-stakeholder is synonymous with a non-
    market participant. See note 187 in FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 
    32,541 at 33,726.
        \264\ Justice Department at 4. The Southern Company states that 
    if the Commission requires non-stakeholders boards RTOs that are 
    ISOs, then it must allow transmission owners the right to establish 
    ``performance standards'' for the RTO and the right to withdraw if 
    the RTO fails to meet these standards. Southern Company at 40-41.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Other commenters state that a danger of non-stakeholder boards, 
    such as those already approved by the Commission for several ISOs, is 
    that they become isolated and sometimes unresponsive to stakeholder 
    concerns. UtiliCorp, for example, asserts that ``one of the most 
    frequently heard criticisms of the ISOs currently in existence is their 
    unresponsiveness and lack of accountability.'' 265 Several 
    other commenters echo this concern and recommend that an independent 
    board be required to consult formally and informally with advisory 
    committees of stakeholders (i.e., a two-tier form of governance). For 
    example, the Midwest Municipals recommend that RTOs with non-
    stakeholder boards ``be required to have a senior management or 
    advisory committee made up of market participants from each relevant 
    market sector and subordinate, issue oriented committees'' similar to 
    those that exist in the PJM, New York and New England 
    ISOs.266 STDUG recommends that if a non-stakeholder board is 
    formed ``it must be accompanied by some action forming mechanism that 
    forces the board to listen and consider the concerns of all members or 
    stakeholders in the RTO.'' 267
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \265\ UtiliCorp at 11.
        \266\ Midwest Municipals at 19.
        \267\ STDUG at 7-8.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        EPSA urges the Commission to pay close attention to the composition 
    and functions of any committee structure that operates underneath a 
    governing board because independent governance ``does not stop at the 
    ISO board.'' 268 It contends that this is necessary for 
    independence because advisory committees of stakeholders will often 
    have de facto decisionmaking power. Dynegy makes specific 
    recommendations for any stakeholder committees that operate below and 
    report to an RTO board. It recommends that such committees be governed 
    by ``segment voting''--each industry segment would have a proportional 
    vote; each market participant would have to choose to participate in 
    one market segment; and the votes within a segment would be split among 
    however many entities choose to participate in that segment. It 
    observes that this approach has been adopted or proposed in the PJM, 
    NEPOOL and New York ISOs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \268\ EPSA at 15.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Other commenters urge us not to prohibit stakeholder or hybrid 
    boards consisting of stakeholders and non-stakeholders such as the one 
    that exists in California. Cal ISO, noting that it is the only FERC-
    jurisdictional ISO with a stakeholder board, states that ``[t]he Cal-
    ISO stakeholder board has worked'' and urges us to confirm the 
    acceptability of a stakeholder board in the final rule if the board is 
    structured to ensure that no market participant or class of market 
    participants can control the decisions of the RTO.269 
    Dairyland points out that the Commission has encouraged and approved 
    stakeholder boards under the independence principle for ISOs in Order 
    No. 888.270 Dynegy recommends a hybrid governing board with 
    ``disinterested'' (i.e., non-stakeholder) members comprising one-third 
    of the board and stakeholder members comprising the remaining two-
    thirds.271 However, it observes that mandated stakeholder 
    representation would be ``inappropriate'' for an RTO that is a for-
    profit transco. California Board urges us to allow a variety of 
    governance forms including stakeholder boards ``until and unless 
    experience shows that one form'' is clearly superior to other forms of 
    governance.272 TXU Electric states that ``stakeholder 
    representation is a legitimate form of governance for a regional 
    transmission organization'' and, in fact, is the required form of 
    governance under the recently enacted Texas electric restructuring 
    statute.273
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \269\ Cal ISO at 15. Cal ISO points out that this has been 
    achieved through a board of governors in which (1) no one voting 
    class is able to block or veto an action, and (2) no two classes 
    together are able to form a sufficient majority to make decisions, 
    and (3) no entity (including its affiliates and subsidiaries) is 
    able to participate in more than one voting class. See Attachment A-
    1 of Cal ISO.
        \270\ ``A governance structure that includes fair representation 
    of all types of users would help to ensure that the ISO formulates 
    policies, operates the system, and resolves disputes in a fair and 
    non-discriminatory manner.'' Order 888, FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 
    31,036 at 31,730-731
        \271 \ Dynegy recommends that five ``segments'' for the 
    stakeholder representatives: transmission owners, transmission-
    dependent utilities, marketers, end-users and independent power 
    producers. Dynegy at 42.
        \272 \ California Board at 6.
        \273 \ TXU Electric at 9.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Role of State Agencies. Commenters express a wide range of opinions 
    on the appropriate role of state agencies. The comments fall generally 
    into two categories: the role of state agencies during the 
    developmental stage and the role of state agencies after an RTO begins 
    operating.
        Many commenters believe that state commissions and other state 
    agencies should have a major role in RTO development. NARUC argues that 
    state commissions ``should fully participate in RTO formation and 
    development.'' 274 State commissions generally take the 
    position that their involvement is important because the size, scope 
    and functions of an RTO will be critical for the success of their 
    state-by-state retail choice programs.275 NECPUC notes that 
    it had an important role in shaping the design of the ISO-NE before any 
    formal filing was made at the Commission. Nine Commissions, 
    representing state commissions from the East-Central, Midwest and 
    Southwest regions, gives a specific example of how the Commission 
    should defer to state commissions. They state that if a critical mass 
    of state commissions in their region reach agreement on the appropriate 
    boundaries for an RTO, then FERC ``should provide deference to that 
    collective state determination.'' 276
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \274\ NARUC at 11.
        \275\ See, e.g., Illinois Commission.
        \276\ Nine Commissions at 6.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Other commenters outside of the state regulatory community also 
    address the issue of the appropriate role for state commissions. For 
    example, Enron/APX/Coral Power say that state regulators and 
    politicians should play a role in encouraging local transmission owners 
    to join RTOs but ``[t]he role of states * * * should extend no 
    further.'' 277
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \277 Enron/APX/Coral Power at A-3.\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Once an RTO becomes operational, Enron/APX/Coral Power argue that 
    state commissions should have no special
    
    [[Page 849]]
    
    role and, in fact, the RTO ``should be protected from local 
    interference.'' Their argument for minimizing the role of state 
    agencies is that ``no other commercial activity (with the possible 
    exception of telecommunications) is more intrinsically in interstate 
    commerce.'' Conlon, the former President of the California Public 
    Utilities Commission, expresses a similar view (``local control, 
    although desirable from a states' rights standpoint, should be 
    sacrificed to get interstate control of the entire interconnection.'') 
    278
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \278\ Conlon states that these are his views and are not 
    necessarily the views of any present or former Commissioners or 
    staff of the California PUC.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        On the issue of voting rights for state commissions, Enron/APX/
    Coral Power argues that it would be inappropriate for any state 
    commission to be a voting member of an RTO. Their rationale is that the 
    state commission would lose its ability to monitor the relationship 
    between the RTO and any entity that may be serving the state's domestic 
    load if it is also a voting member of the RTO board. NECPUC expresses a 
    similar view. While recommending that state commissions have extensive 
    communication with the RTO and its participants, it concludes that 
    state commissions ``should not have a vote in the governance of the ISO 
    New England.'' 279 Arizona Commission says that states 
    should have the right of ex officio membership but that ``FERC should 
    not force the states to be voting members.'' 280 ISO-NE also 
    shares this view. It contends that it would be ``awkward'' for a state 
    official to serve as a voting director of an RTO for several reasons. 
    First, it could create a conflict between the state official's duties 
    as an RTO board member and his or her regulatory or administrative 
    duties at the state level. ISO-NE argues that many state conflict of 
    interest laws may expressly prohibit such service because of the 
    conflicts it would create.281 Second, in the case of a 
    multistate RTO, it may difficult for an official from one state to vote 
    for decisions that are good for the residents of all the states served 
    by the RTO. Third, the solution of having a board member from each 
    state ``could create gridlock or unwieldy boards.'' 282
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \279\ NECPUC at 9.
        \280\ Arizona Commission at 5.
        \281\ In contrast, Reliant recommends that ``state officials 
    should serve as board members in order to avoid conflicts in future 
    decisions.'' It appears that Reliant is referring to future 
    decisions of the state agencies. Reliant at 5.
        \282\ ISO-NE at 3.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Florida Commission makes a distinction between for-profit and non-
    profit RTOs. It says that it would be inappropriate for members of a 
    state regulatory body or other state officials to serve on the board of 
    a for-profit transco. However, Florida Commission believes that it may 
    be appropriate for a state commissioner to serve on the board of a non-
    profit RTO if disputes involving the RTO and other parties do not come 
    before the state commission.
        Washington Commission expresses a different view. In its opinion, 
    the role of state commissions should vary depending on the type of 
    board. It recommends that state involvement could be limited to the 
    selection of the non-affiliated board members for a non-stakeholder or 
    hybrid board. In contrast, if there is a stakeholder board, Washington 
    Commission urges that states be granted ``voting member status.'' In 
    the case of a for-profit transco, it urges the Commission to require a 
    formal advisory role for the states.
        Section 205 Filing Rights. Many IOUs and public systems oppose the 
    NOPR's proposal to require that RTOs have ``exclusive and independent 
    authority to file changes to its transmission tariff with the 
    Commission under section 205 of the Federal Power Act.'' 283 
    In contrast, those who support the proposal assert that it is a 
    necessary and logical implication of the Commission's previously stated 
    policy that the ``[a]uthority to act unilaterally * * * is a crucial 
    element of a truly independent ISO.'' 284 SRP recommends 
    that ``the need for an RTO to independently administer its own tariff 
    must be balanced against the need for individual transmission owners to 
    maintain control over their ability to recover their revenue 
    requirements and meet their debt service obligations.'' 285
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \283\ See, e.g., AEP, Alliance Companies, CMUA, Duke, Florida 
    Power Corp., LPPC, Metropolitan, Midwest Municipals, Montana-Dakota 
    and Southern Company.
        \284\ Citing NEPOOL, 79 FERC para. 61,974 at 62,585 (1997). See, 
    e.g., PJM, Cal ISO, Industrial Consumers, Montana Commission, NECPUC 
    and NASUCA.
        \285\ SRP Reply Comments at 12.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Those who oppose the proposal focus on the case of an RTO that is 
    an ISO. Transmission ISO Participants argues that the proposal is bad 
    law and bad policy. Citing the Supreme Court decision in United Gas 
    Pipe Line Co. v. Mobile Gas Service Corp.,286 it asserts 
    that the Commission does not have the legal authority to grant section 
    205 filing rights to an ISO. It contends that the FPA grants this 
    fundamental right to transmission owners that are public utilities. 
    While a transmission owner may ``voluntarily cede'' this right to an 
    ISO, the Commission cannot compel a transmission owner, either directly 
    or indirectly, to give up this legal right. Puget Sound argues that the 
    proposal would have the effect of reducing the transmission-owning 
    utility to little more than a ``bystander'' and could constitute an 
    illegal ``taking'' under the Fifth Amendment of the U.S. Constitution.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \286\ 350 U.S. 332 (1956).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Transmission ISO Participants also claims that the Commission's 
    previous decisions in this area have not been consistent. It asserts 
    that the Commission ``required transmission owners to cede their 
    section 205 rights to the ISO in our order approving the PJM ISO.'' 
    287 But it points to the fact in a 1997 California ISO order 
    that the Commission seemed to establish a much smaller role for the ISO 
    (``the ISO is responsible for only collecting the revenue 
    requirement.'') 288 Furthermore, it notes that in this same 
    order the Commission decided to set all rate design and rate 
    methodology issues in the dockets established for the filings made by 
    the transmission owners, and not in a docket for the transmission 
    tariff filing made by the ISO.289
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \287\ Transmission ISO Participants at 20.
        \288\ Quoting 81 FERC para. 61,122 at 61,506 (1997).
        \289\ However, the California ISO asserts that it has 
    ``exclusive and independent'' authority ``to modify the design of 
    rates for transmission and ancillary services.'' See Cal ISO at 18.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Many commenters also address whether it would be practical to give 
    RTOs FPA section 205 filing rights for transmission rate design and 
    terms and conditions that directly affect access while transmission 
    owners would retain section 205 rights for overall revenue 
    requirements. A number of commenters say that this distinction is 
    unworkable because the two are inextricably connected (i.e., changes in 
    rate design can have major impacts on revenue 
    collections).290
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \290\ See, e.g., EEI, Transmission ISO Participants and Southern 
    Company.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        However, other commenters argue that the Commission cannot 
    realistically expect an RTO to be a neutral and unbiased transmission 
    provider unless the RTO has full legal authority to propose changes in 
    its own transmission tariff.291 PJM states that ``its 
    ability to function would be severely hindered'' unless it has the 
    ability to unilaterally make tariff filings. It points to several 
    recent instances of emergency filings with us as examples of why it 
    must have its own independent filing authority without getting the 
    prior approval of
    
    [[Page 850]]
    
    transmission owners or any other group. It argues that it will not be 
    able to satisfy its responsibility to ``provide for safe and reliable 
    operation of the transmission grid and operation of a robust, 
    competitive, and non-discriminatory electricity market'' without such 
    authority.292 However, PJM does state that transmission 
    owners, rather than the RTO, should have the unilateral right to seek 
    changes in the RTO's tariff to address changes in the transmission 
    owners revenue requirements with respect to transmission 
    facilities.293
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \291\ See, e.g., Cal ISO, PJM ISO, Industrial Customers, Montana 
    Commission, NECPUC and NASUCA.
        \292\ PJM at 53.
        \293\ PJM at 54. The California, New York and New England ISOs 
    agree with PJM on this point.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Oneok, a power marketer, states that an RTO needs its own section 
    205 filing authority because it would not be able to reach a consensus 
    and act quickly if it must get the prior approval of all stakeholders. 
    However, Oneok suggests an alternative to what was proposed in the 
    NOPR. It recommends a two-tier approach to transmission tariff filings. 
    Under this proposal, ``transmission-owning utilities would be free to 
    file changes to their rates (or rate structures) at any time'' to their 
    single customer, the RTO.294 The RTO would then be free to 
    ``repackage'' the transmission capacity and services that it purchased 
    under these separate transmission owner tariffs in its own RTO 
    transmission tariff filed under section 205. Oneok states that there 
    are precedents for this approach in prior Commission practices.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \294\ Oneok at 8.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commission Conclusion. The Basic Independence Principle. In the 
    NOPR, we repeated our earlier statement that ``the principle of 
    independence is the bedrock upon which the ISO must be built ``and 
    emphasized that this principle must apply to all RTOs, whether they are 
    ISOs, transcos or variants of the two. We also stated that ``[a]n RTO 
    needs to be independent in both reality and perception.'' We reaffirm 
    both principles in the Final Rule.
        In applying these principles in the context of ISOs, we have 
    stressed the importance of a decisionmaking process that is independent 
    of control by any market participant or class of participants. This, in 
    turn, required that we pay considerable attention to governance (e.g., 
    voting shares and voting rules). Because ISOs are typically non-profit 
    and non-share corporations, we generally did not have to consider the 
    effect of ownership interests on the independence of the ISO. This will 
    change with the emergence of for-profit RTOs, such as transcos, that 
    have ownership interests. For these types of RTOs, we will have to 
    examine how ownership of the RTO by market participants could affect 
    the independence of its decisionmaking process.
        Who Is a Market Participant? The overall purpose of the 
    independence standard in the Final Rule is to ensure that an RTO will 
    provide transmission service and operate the grid in a non-
    discriminatory manner. Equal access requires RTOs to be independent. 
    Implementation of this standard then requires answering the question: 
    independence from whom? Our logic in the NOPR, which we have adopted in 
    the Final Rule, is to define a group of entities, referred to as market 
    participants, whose economic or commercial interests are likely to be 
    affected by an RTO's decisions and actions.
        Commenters provided many helpful comments on the definition of 
    market participant that was proposed in the NOPR. As noted in the 
    summary, the commenters generally fall into two broad categories: those 
    who argue that the NOPR definition is too broad and those that argue 
    that it is too narrow. We find that these views were not always 
    inconsistent since the commenters were often discussing different 
    aspects of the definition. After a careful review of the comments, we 
    conclude that it is necessary to change the definition of a market 
    participant that was proposed in the NOPR. The revised definition at 
    section 35.34(b) is:
    
        (2) Market participant means:
        (i) Any entity that, either directly or through an affiliate, 
    sells or brokers electric energy, or provides transmission or 
    ancillary services to the Regional Transmission Organization, unless 
    the Commission finds that the entity does not have economic or 
    commercial interests that would be significantly affected by the 
    Regional Transmission Organization's actions or decisions; and
        (ii) Any other entity that the Commission finds has economic or 
    commercial interests that would be significantly affected by the 
    Regional Transmission Organization's actions or decisions.
        (3) Affiliate means the definition given in section 2(a)(11) of 
    the Public Utility Holding Company Act (15 U.S.C. 79b(a)(11)).
    
        Before discussing how this definition is different from the NOPR 
    definition, it is useful to consider why a definition of market 
    participant is needed in the first place. It is the Commission's view 
    that an RTO must be independent of any entity whose economic or 
    commercial interests could be significantly affected by the RTO's 
    actions or decisions. Without such independence, it will be difficult 
    for an RTO to act in a non-discriminatory manner. Therefore, the 
    definition focuses on those entities whose economic and commercial 
    interests can be significantly affected by the RTO's behavior. However, 
    it should be emphasized that the definition of a market participant is 
    simply a starting point for implementing the independence standard. The 
    definition is used as a reference point for establishing limits on 
    ownership (i.e., an RTO's ownership of market participants and market 
    participants' ownership of an RTO) and standards for independent 
    decisionmaking or governance. As discussed below, the fact that a 
    particular participant is defined as a market participant does not 
    preclude it from having any active or passive ownership interest in an 
    RTO.
        We agree with many commenters that the NOPR definition was too 
    broad in defining a market participant to be ``any entity that buys or 
    sells electric energy in the RTO's region or in any neighboring region 
    that might also be affected by the RTO's actions.'' As several 
    commenters pointed out, a literal reading of this definition would make 
    market participants of every residential, commercial, industrial and 
    wholesale electric customer in the RTO region and some neighboring 
    regions. This is clearly too encompassing and was not our intent. We 
    therefore are narrowing the definition of a market participant in the 
    Final Rule to include those who sell or broker electric energy but not 
    those who buy electric energy.
        We recognize, however, that there may be circumstances where buyers 
    of electric energy could buy a controlling interest in a for-profit RTO 
    and manipulate its access and curtailment decisions to their advantage. 
    Such an outcome would clearly be inconsistent with the independence 
    standard. Therefore, as a backstop, we are adding paragraph (b) to the 
    definition (``any other entity that the Commission finds has economic 
    or commercial interests that would be significantly affected by the 
    RTO's actions or decisions''). The addition of this paragraph allows 
    us, on a case-by-case basis, to consider whether particular buyers of 
    electric energy (or any other entity) could manipulate an RTO's 
    decisions to the disadvantage of other RTO customers.
        We are also dropping the phrase ``in the RTO's region or in any 
    neighboring region that might also be affected by the RTO's actions.'' 
    Given the high degree of integration within the Eastern and Western 
    Interconnections, the growth of transactions involving buyers and 
    sellers separated by hundreds of miles and the participation of energy 
    concerns
    
    [[Page 851]]
    
    in multiple markets, we conclude that it would be virtually impossible 
    to apply a geographically delineated standard. However, we will 
    consider requests for waivers from entities in other Interconnections 
    who can demonstrate that their economic or commercial interests would 
    not be significantly affected by the RTO's actions or decisions.
        We are also making one other change to the NOPR definition to 
    expand its scope. Paragraph (a) expands the NOPR definition by 
    including entities that provide transmission or ancillary services to 
    an RTO. We believe that it would compromise an RTO's independence if 
    one or more transmission owners could influence the RTO's decisions to 
    the detriment of other market participants. Therefore, it is 
    appropriate to include providers of transmission service as market 
    participants.295 With regard to the creation of RTOs that 
    are transcos, we have developed policies on the level of ownership that 
    market participants may possess, as discussed below, in order to ensure 
    that the operating decisions of the RTO are truly independent and non-
    discriminatory.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \295\ It is conceivable that RTO A might provide transmission 
    service to a neighboring RTO B. In such a situation, RTO A would be 
    considered a market participant. RTO A might also acquire ownership 
    interests in RTO B as a first step towards consolidation of the two 
    RTOs. We would anticipate granting a waiver to RTO A from a market 
    participant definition and any associated ownership restrictions if 
    we had reason to believe that the waiver could lead to a larger and 
    more effective RTO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We believe that it is necessary to include ancillary service 
    providers as market participants since the RTO is the supplier of last 
    resort for ancillary services. As a consequence, the RTO is likely to 
    have considerable discretion in defining the types and quantities of 
    ancillary services needed and how they will be procured (e.g., market 
    design). An RTO's decisions in any of these dimensions can have major 
    economic effect on one or more providers of such services. Therefore, 
    we define these entities as market participants to ensure that they are 
    not in a position to influence the RTO's decisions to their own 
    advantage.
        Several other commenters urged us to include distribution entities 
    as market participants. At present, most distribution entities provide 
    a bundled service. The bundled service includes the sale of electric 
    energy as well as the delivery of this electric energy over local 
    distribution facilities. Since these traditional distribution entities 
    are selling electric energy, they would be considered market 
    participants under the definition.
        However, several commenters pointed out that a new type of 
    distribution entity is likely to emerge with the spread of retail 
    competition. This type of distribution entity would simply transmit 
    electric energy over distribution facilities for others and would not 
    sell electricity.
        The issue is whether this type of pure distribution entity should 
    be considered a market participant. Several commenters pointed to the 
    danger of allowing one or two distribution entities to control an RTO. 
    Their concern is that these distribution entities could use their 
    control over the RTO to favor their distribution facilities over the 
    facilities of non-affiliated distribution entities when the RTO has to 
    choose among competing requests for transmission service or alternative 
    curtailment actions. Other commenters minimize this risk and argue that 
    distribution entities should be allowed to own RTOs because there are 
    economies in having a single entity provide total delivery service 
    (i.e., transmit electric energy at high and low voltages). The 
    Commission does not wish to create impediments to the efficient 
    integration of transmission and distribution facilities. Therefore, we 
    will not include pure distribution entities in paragraph (a) of the 
    market participant definition. However, if we are presented with 
    evidence that a distribution entity is able to influence an RTO's 
    actions or decisions to the disadvantage of other users, we may find 
    such a distribution entity to be a market participant under paragraph 
    (b) of the definition. Paragraph (a) of the revised definition defines 
    all sellers of electric energy, whether retail or wholesale, as market 
    participants. Several commenters urge us to exclude retail providers of 
    last resort from the definition. These are entities that are required 
    by state commissions or state law to be backup suppliers to retail 
    customers who choose not to switch suppliers in a state-mandated retail 
    competition program. We have decided to include such entities in the 
    market participant definition because they are sellers of electric 
    energy. However, the obligations and responsibilities of such entities 
    are still being developed on a state-by-state basis. As a consequence, 
    even though such entities may be generically referred to as ``suppliers 
    of last resort,'' their responsibilities and incentives may vary 
    widely. The Commission believes that certain factors, (e.g., an 
    entity's sole electric sales are made to satisfy a state requirement 
    and it does not compete for retail load) would support a finding that 
    the entity is not a market participant.
        NEPCO et al. point to the problem of incumbent utilities that have 
    tried to divest themselves of generating assets but have not yet 
    succeeded. They say that this is likely to be a particular problem for 
    utilities that own minority interests in nuclear plants since it is 
    currently difficult to sell such interests. NEPCO et al. request that 
    they not be automatically deemed a market participant because of these 
    ownership interests. Once again, we will entertain requests for 
    exemption. For example, we would be willing to give an exemption if the 
    current owner could clearly demonstrate that it has transferred to non-
    affiliated entities both the marketing rights and any profits resulting 
    from the sale of electric energy associated with its ownership 
    interest. Any compensation that the market participant receives from 
    the non-affiliated entity should not be tied to profits on specific 
    sales made by this entity.
        RTO Economic Interests in Market Participants and Energy Markets. 
    We reaffirm the NOPR proposal that the RTO, its employees and any non-
    stakeholder directors must not have any financial interests in market 
    participants. As noted in the NOPR, our focus will be on current 
    financial interests. Since this principle raises a number of specific 
    issues, especially with respect to pension rights and benefits, we will 
    continue our current policy of implementing this principle on a case-
    by-case basis.
        Several commenters argued that the NOPR's treatment of financial 
    independence was too narrowly drawn. For example, Dynegy, pointing to 
    the example of ISOs, argues that while ISOs ``may ostensibly be 
    independent of market participants--they are not independent of the 
    market itself.'' 296 The participation of RTOs in the market 
    stems from certain obligations that we require of any RTO: it is the 
    supplier of last resort for required ancillary services and it must 
    attempt to procure such services efficiently in competitive markets. 
    These two requirements mean that most RTOs will be operators of 
    bilateral and spot markets in ancillary services as well as buyers in 
    these same markets. In addition, they will be resellers of any 
    ancillary services that they purchase.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \296\ Dynegy at 35.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        It is our intention that RTOs perform functions that make the 
    transmission infrastructure operate efficiently, not that they take 
    actions in ways that skew competitive outcomes in the market.
    
    [[Page 852]]
    
    Nevertheless we acknowledge that RTO operations may have that effect. 
    Moreover, the two requirements may lead to an outcome that an RTO is 
    not indifferent to whether the prices are high or low. Given this 
    possible conflict, we will require that all RTOs must propose an 
    objective monitoring plan to assess whether the RTOs involvement in 
    these markets favors its own economic interests over those of its 
    customers or members.297
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        297 This is discussed more fully under Market Monitoring. 
    See infra section III.E.6.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Passive Ownership Interests in the RTO. As we have emphasized, the 
    Commission wishes to give industry participants every reasonable 
    opportunity to create RTOs through their own voluntary actions. 
    However, we also recognize that mere exhortations that the industry 
    participants should volunteer to create independent transmission 
    entities will not ensure a truly open and reliable grid in the 
    reasonably foreseeable future. The Commission must take actions to 
    ensure that the stand-alone transmission business is financially 
    attractive and viable. We must also provide a high degree of regulatory 
    certainty and not foreclose viable options for creating and developing 
    RTOs. To provide more certainty, the Final Rule provides guidance on 
    our future policies for establishing revenues, incentives and 
    performance-based regulation for proposed RTOs.298
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \298\ See infra section 111.G.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We also recognize that the voluntary creation of RTOs requires that 
    current owners of transmission assets must be willing to transfer 
    operational control of these assets to RTOs or to divest their 
    interests in their entirety. Therefore, it is important that we provide 
    current transmission owners with flexibility in deciding how they will 
    relinquish ownership or control of their transmission facilities to an 
    RTO. Numerous commenters, ranging from IOUs to state commissions to 
    marketers, urge the Commission not to make RTO policy in a vacuum. In 
    particular, they stress that the Commission needs to understand that 
    there are many existing legal and tax disincentives to the outright 
    sale of such assets to an RTO.299
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \299\ See EEI, Southern Company, United Illuminating, Enron/APX/
    Coral Power, ISO-NE, NECPUC, Salomon Smith Barney and Konoglie/Ford/
    Fleishman.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Among these potential impediments, commenters identify the federal 
    capital gains tax most frequently. There was agreement among many 
    commenters that it would be unrealistic for the Commission to expect 
    current transmission owners to sell their transmission facilities to an 
    RTO if the sale becomes a taxable event that triggers a large capital 
    gains tax. Therefore, they urge the Commission to accommodate financing 
    and ownership arrangements that facilitate the creation of for-profit 
    RTOs while minimizing the tax burden on current transmission owners who 
    are willing to take actions that would promote the Commission's RTO 
    policies. Many commenters argue that the Commission could significantly 
    accelerate RTO development if we were to allow current transmission 
    owners to retain a passive ownership interest in new RTOs. Several 
    commenters contend that if the Commission fails to accommodate such 
    arrangements, this initiative will be unproductive because our policies 
    would be effectively biased against the creation of for-profit 
    transmission companies that seek RTO status. They assert that such an 
    outcome would be inconsistent with the statement in the NOPR that the 
    Commission wishes to encourage all types of RTOs, whether they are 
    transcos, ISOs or combinations of the two.300
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \300\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,726.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In response to these comments, we reaffirm that it is the 
    Commission's policy to encourage all types of RTOs. In light of our 
    evolving experience with the workability of certain RTO models, it 
    would be inappropriate for us to mandate a single RTO model of 
    ownership and operation. While the dominant approach to date has been 
    ISOs, we are receptive to alternative approaches that can provide 
    evidence of the legitimacy of various models of ownership and 
    operation. Because the institutions which we propose to sanction 
    pursuant to this Final Rule will be so influential in operating the 
    Nation's nfrastructure over a period of time, the Commission resolves 
    to implement its independence criteria with an open mind and, to the 
    extent practicable, with flexibility. At this juncture, we therefore 
    propose to remove unnecessary impediments to the creation of 
    transmission companies by allowing market participants to maintain 
    passive ownership interests in RTOs.
        We reaffirm our belief that ``[a]n RTO must be independent in both 
    reality and perception.'' 301 This same conclusion was also 
    reached by the DOE Reliability Task Force and the NERC Reliability 
    Panel, two widely respected industry groups comprised of 
    representatives from all sectors of the industry. The DOE Reliability 
    Task Force concluded that regional reliability entities must be ``truly 
    independent of commercial interests so that their reliability actions 
    are--and are seen to be--unbiased and untainted.'' The Electric 
    Reliability Panel concluded that ``[t]o dispel suspicions that the 
    system operator favors one participant over another * * * the operator 
    must be independent of market participants.'' 302
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \301\ As discussed below, this overriding consideration is also 
    relevant to active voting interests.
        \302\ See U.S. Department of Energy, Maintaining Reliability in 
    a Competitive U.S. Electricity Industry: Final Report of the Task 
    Force on Electric System Reliability, at xv (September 29, 1998); 
    North American Reliability Council, Electric Reliability Panel, 
    Reliable Power: Renewing the North American Electric Reliability 
    Oversight System at 17 (Dec. 22, 1997)
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission concludes that an RTO will not be successful unless 
    all market participants believe that the RTO will operate the grid and 
    provide transmission service to all grid users on a non-discriminatory 
    basis. It is clear that the perception of a broad cross-section of 
    commenters is that passive ownership may interfere with the independent 
    operation of RTOs.303 In the view of many commenters, 
    passive ownership is only a subtle mechanism to allow existing 
    transmission owners to continue to control use of transmission assets 
    and ultimately deny equal access to competitors. Therefore, we must 
    provide assurances to all market participants that any passive 
    ownership interest is truly passive and will in no way interfere with 
    the independent operation and decisionmaking of the RTO. It is 
    important to require a system of independent compliance auditing to 
    ensure that passive ownership arrangements remain passive over time and 
    to provide assurances to other market participants that the RTO is 
    truly independent.304
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \303\ See, e.g., Consumer Groups, South Carolina Authority, TDU 
    Systems, Industrial Customers, APPA, Los Angeles, NASUCA, Arkansas 
    Cities and Wolverine Cooperative.
        \304\ The auditing requirements of this Rule represent one 
    approach to addressing our concern that it may otherwise be 
    difficult to assess the ongoing independence of passive ownership 
    arrangements. We expect that parties will include in any rehearing 
    requests their views on this approach, in general, and the 
    particular auditing requirements that we have adopted.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Those who support the policy of allowing market participants to 
    have passive ownership in RTOs point to the fact that the Commission 
    has accepted many instances of passive ownership in the past. 
    Typically, these arrangements have involved the sale and leaseback of 
    generating units in which a jurisdictional public utility will sell a 
    generating unit to a bank, insurance company or other financial 
    institution. The financial institution will then lease
    
    [[Page 853]]
    
    back the generating unit to the jurisdictional utility. Even though the 
    financial institution is the owner of record, we have generally 
    concluded that it is a passive owner without any real operational 
    control and, therefore, is not a jurisdictional public utility under 
    the FPA.305
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \305\ See Pacific Power and Light Co., 3 FERC para. 61,119 
    (1978); Baltimore Refuse Energy Systems Co., Wheelabrator Millbury, 
    Inc., 40 FERC para. 61,366 (1987).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        There are, however, several considerations that distinguish these 
    earlier passive arrangements from the ones that are being contemplated 
    for RTOs. First, the passive ownership arrangements for RTOs (e.g., 
    two-tier LLCs, synthetic leases and leveraged partnerships) may be 
    complicated and multi-layered. Even those commenters who urge that we 
    accept passive ownership as a necessary transition mechanism admit that 
    such arrangements ``will prove troublesome for both utilities and 
    FERC'' because they create the ``need to constantly police supposedly 
    passive ownership positions to make sure that they remain passive in 
    all respects.'' 306
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \306\ Salomon Smith Barney Reply Comments at 15.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Second, unlike financial institutions, the passive owners will 
    typically own other assets (e.g., generating assets) that could reap 
    major economic benefits if an RTO's decisions can be influenced to 
    their advantage. Therefore, unlike financial institutions, the passive 
    owners in RTOs may have a direct economic incentive to influence the 
    RTO's operating and investment decisions to favor other economic 
    interests.
        In response to a request for a declaratory order from Entergy 
    Services, Inc., the Commission found that passive ownership of a 
    transmission entity by a generating entity or other market participant 
    could meet the Commission's ISO standards relating to governance and 
    independence if it were properly designed. Because Entergy's proposal 
    was incomplete, the Commission provided some limited guidance related 
    to: board selection and removal, potential issues about the board's 
    fiduciary duties, attraction of capital and issues about the 
    transmission entity contracting with member companies. In this rule we 
    provide further guidance which we believe will help RTO applicants who 
    may be considering some form of passive ownership structure.
        Based on these considerations, the Commission's policy on proposals 
    for passive ownership of RTOs by market participants will have three 
    key elements:
        (1) Passive ownership proposals will be reviewed on a case-by-case 
    basis. The Commission will approve a proposal only if we are satisfied 
    that the passive owners have relinquished control over operational, 
    investment and other decisions to ensure that the RTO will treat all 
    users of the grid--passive owners and others--on an equal basis in all 
    matters. The burden of proof is on the RTO to demonstrate that control 
    of the RTO is ``truly independent'' and that the RTO has a 
    decisionmaking process that is independent of control by the passive 
    owners.
        (2) The Commission requires any RTO with passive ownership 
    interests approved by the Commission to undertake an obligation and 
    propose processes for an independent compliance audit to ensure the 
    independence of its decisionmaking process from the passive owners. The 
    first independence audit will be required two years after initial 
    approval of the RTO and every three years thereafter. The independence 
    compliance audit must be submitted to the Commission in a public 
    document without any requirement for approval by the RTO 
    board.307
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \307\ See supra note 304.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        (3) The Commission will take appropriate action if it finds 
    evidence of abuses.
        We will now discuss implementation of these elements. The first 
    element of our policy is that any RTO that wishes approval for passive 
    ownership above the limits set for active ownership must demonstrate in 
    its application that the passive owners will relinquish effective 
    control over operational and investment decisions. Specifically, the 
    RTO must demonstrate that the proposed arrangement has been designed to 
    ensure that it can treat all users of the grid--passive owners and 
    others--on an equal basis in the provision of non-discriminatory 
    transmission service.
        It will be difficult for the Commission to make an assessment of 
    whether a particular passive arrangement achieves true independence in 
    decisionmaking for the RTO board and its management unless an RTO 
    provides complete information about the rights that passive owners have 
    reserved for themselves both as owners of the RTO and as providers of 
    facilities and services to the RTO. In judging any proposal, our 
    overriding concern is that the arrangements provide a high degree of 
    assurance that those who are not passive owners will have equal access 
    to the services provided by the RTO.
        To assure ourselves that this standard is satisfied, the Commission 
    will need information on the following issues: fiduciary 
    responsibilities of the RTO board and management to passive owners; 
    ability of the RTO to raise capital independently of its passive 
    owners; ability of the RTO to make investment and financing decisions 
    independently of its passive owners; the extent of control by passive 
    owners over board selection and removal; the extent of control by 
    passive owners over transmission rates, terms and conditions; control 
    of passive owners over issuance of new membership interests and/or 
    equity; services that will be provided by the passive owners or their 
    employees to the RTO; and the extent of access of passive owners to 
    information not available to other market participants.308 
    An RTO application seeking approval for passive ownership should 
    provide any other relevant information that will allow the Commission 
    to assess whether passive owners have reserved rights for themselves 
    that are superior to those of other market participants and if such 
    rights constitute control over the RTO.309
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        308 For example, this could include information on the market 
    behavior of one or more non-affiliate market participants acquired 
    through a market monitoring program and information on the RTO's 
    proposed investment and operational plans, except where the 
    Commission has approved it as necessary to protect the passive 
    owner's capital investment.
        \309\ We note that many of these same concerns also apply to 
    RTOs that allow market participants to have ownership interests in 
    voting securities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The second element requires a mechanism for assuring ourselves and 
    market participants that any passive ownership arrangement remains 
    passive over time. The Commission will require the RTO to notify us 
    immediately of any changes in the underlying agreements or facts that 
    occur after the initial filing. The Commission has relied on a similar 
    system of self-monitoring in cases in which we have approved market-
    based rates. Specifically, we have required that any public utility 
    that receives market-based pricing must notify us of any factual 
    changes that call into question whether it should be allowed to 
    continue to charge market-based rates.310
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \310\ When there is a change in the factual circumstances that 
    were the basis for the Commission's approval of market-based 
    pricing, we require that a public utility notify us immediately of 
    this change or at the next update of their market power analysis. 
    This update occurs once every three years. With respect to passive 
    ownership, we will require that the passive owner must notify us 
    immediately of any change in governance in ownership or governance 
    that takes place after our initial approval.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We will also require a system of independent compliance auditing. 
    The auditing must be performed by individuals or organizations that are 
    not
    
    [[Page 854]]
    
    affiliated with the RTO or its owners. The purpose of the auditing 
    would be to ensure that what is passive on paper is passive in reality 
    throughout the transition period. In particular, auditors would assess 
    whether the passive owners have retained rights or privileges in their 
    role as owners or providers of services that would put non-owner 
    participants at a competitive disadvantage. The audits would cover the 
    RTO's actions and decisions with respect to operations and investments. 
    In order for this to be a credible auditing system, the auditors should 
    have clear authority to obtain any information or data necessary to 
    perform their audits and they should have the right to report any 
    findings and recommendations to the Commission without prior approval 
    of the RTO or any of its owners/members. An initial audit must be 
    performed two years after our approval of the passive ownership 
    arrangements and every three years thereafter.311 If there 
    is evidence of abuse or we are unable to determine if the ownership 
    interests continue to be passive, the Commission will not hesitate to 
    order appropriate remedial action, including possible termination of 
    passive ownership interests.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \311\ See supra note 304.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We understand that passive ownership arrangements are likely to 
    take many forms and that the Commission has not had much experience in 
    examining these types of arrangements in the context of RTOs. We 
    encourage market participants to investigate the options available for 
    passive ownership to identify those types of arrangements that will 
    provide the greatest assurance of independence. For example, we note 
    that the SEC's Rule 250.7(d) establishes criteria under which entities 
    may have ownership interests that do not trigger SEC jurisdiction under 
    PUHCA. The criteria under Rule 250.7(d) are that: (1) The entity owns 
    the facility as a company, a trustee or holder of a beneficial interest 
    under a trust; (2) the facility is leased under a net lease directly to 
    a public utility company and such facility is to be employed by the 
    lessee in its operations; (3) the company is otherwise primarily 
    engaged in business other than that of a public utility; (4) the terms 
    of the lease have been approved by the regulatory authority having 
    jurisdiction over the lessee; (5) the lease extends for an initial term 
    of not less than 15 years; and (6) the rent reserved under the lease 
    shall not include any amount based, directly or indirectly, on revenues 
    or income of the lessee public utility. While it is unclear whether 
    these exact criteria can be applied to the passive ownership 
    arrangements that may be involved in the formation of an RTO or whether 
    they would address the particular independence issues raised in this 
    Rule, we believe that it would be acceptable for market participants to 
    develop passive ownership arrangements that are purely financial. A 
    passive ownership arrangement that is demonstrated to be purely 
    financial could be relieved of the auditing requirement in this Rule.
        Active Ownership Interests in the RTO. We now turn to a discussion 
    of active as opposed to passive ownership. Most commenters used the 
    term ``active'' ownership interests to refer to ownership of voting 
    securities that give the owner the ability to influence or control an 
    RTO's operating and investment decisions. We adopt this definition for 
    purposes of our discussion and will use the terms ``active'' and 
    ``voting'' interchangeably.
        Several commenters who were strong proponents of allowing high or 
    unlimited voting interests by market participants argue that in the 
    NOPR the Commission was wrong to focus on any particular ownership 
    percentage. Instead, they contend that what really matters is ``actual 
    control over the day to day affairs of the system, not some arbitrary 
    ownership percent ownership test.'' 312 We agree that the 
    independence of an RTO ultimately depends on who makes the 
    decisions.313 But control of decisionmaking ultimately 
    depends on who votes and how many votes each party has.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \312\ CTA at 4.
        \313\ However, independence does not automatically guarantee 
    that an RTO will be effective in providing non-discriminatory access 
    to the grid. Independence must also be combined with adequate 
    operational and legal authority in order for the RTO to provide non-
    discriminatory access.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Consequently, we do not think that the Commission can ignore market 
    participants' ownership of voting interests in the RTO.314 
    To do so would require us to presume that even though a market 
    participant has the legal right to vote for its own commercial 
    interests, it will choose to vote for the public interest (or the 
    general interests of all market participants). Therefore, we conclude 
    that ownership of voting interests does matter and we cannot remain 
    agnostic about the ownership of voting interests in an RTO by 
    individual market participants, their affiliates or classes of market 
    participants.315
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \314\ In response to EEI's request for a clarification, we 
    clarify that we are referring only to corporate or shareholder 
    ownership in the RTO itself and not to ownership of transmission 
    facilities under the RTO's operational control. The fact that such 
    facilities are owned by market participants would not be a concern 
    unless the owners retain legal rights and operational 
    responsibilities that make it difficult for an RTO to provide non-
    discriminatory transmission service to other market participants.
        \315\ This is not the first time that we have emphasized the 
    importance of voting rights. In various cases dealing with voting 
    shares and voting rules for ISOs, we required that proposed 
    arrangements be reformed to assure that no individual market 
    participant or class of market participants could dominate the 
    decisions of stakeholder committees that advised the ISO's board. 
    See New England Power Pool, 88 FERC para. 61,079 (1999); Central 
    Hudson Gas and Electric Corp., et al., 88 FERC para. 61,229 (1999).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        a. Active Ownership by Individual Market Participants and 
    Affiliates. A number of transmission customers argue that the cleanest 
    solution would be an ``absolute prohibition'' on ownership of voting 
    interests by any market participant 316 We agree that this 
    would produce a high level of certainty that an RTO is truly 
    independent and anything less than an absolute prohibition introduces 
    some risk. However, if our goal is to encourage the voluntary creation 
    of RTOs, we have to accept that current owners may not relinquish 
    ownership or control of their transmission assets unless it is in their 
    economic interests to do so. In order to create a viable, for-profit, 
    regional transco, at least some current transmission owners must be 
    willing to sell their transmission assets to a new transmission 
    company. Many commenters point out that this voluntary action is not 
    likely to happen if the current owners anticipate large capital gains 
    taxes as a consequence of the sale. The solution, according to many 
    commenters, is to allow current owners to retain some voting interests, 
    some non-voting (i.e., passive) interests or both.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \316\ See, e.g., APPA, Consumer Groups and South Carolina 
    Authority.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As with passive ownership, the Commission must balance two 
    conflicting goals: the need to assure that any RTO will be truly 
    independent; and of not creating disincentives for transmission owners 
    to voluntarily relinquish ownership or control of their transmission 
    assets. Against the backdrop of these two goals, the specific question 
    that confronts us is how much ownership of active voting interests in 
    RTOs should be allowed for market participants.
        Several investor-owned utilities urged us to allow current 
    transmission owners to retain as much as 100 percent voting interest in 
    new for-profit transcos. They argue that we allow 100 percent ownership 
    combined with codes of conduct in the natural gas industry and there is 
    no reason why this model should not also apply to a restructured 
    electricity industry. We disagree with
    
    [[Page 855]]
    
    this recommendation. The two industries, while similar in some 
    respects, also differ significantly in the degree of vertical 
    integration. The electricity industry is starting with a much higher 
    level of vertical integration. As we noted in our NOPR discussion of 
    the complaints filed since the issuance of Order No. 888, it is 
    difficult to monitor compliance with codes of conduct when there is 
    substantial vertical integration (i.e., those who own generation and 
    also own transmission). 317
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \317\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,704-14.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Moreover, it is a very intrusive form of regulation and ultimately 
    requires us to be ``chasing after conduct.'' If such regulation is to 
    be effective, we have to be concerned with internal corporate 
    organization and ``who spoke to whom in the company cafeteria.'' 
    318 This is not light-handed regulation. Therefore, we see 
    little value in replicating this model in the new world of RTOs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \318\ Id. at 33,714.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        It would be equally unworkable to adopt the recommendations of some 
    transmission customers that we should allow no ownership of RTOs by 
    market participants from the outset. While this is a clean solution and 
    greatly reduces the need to monitor for discriminatory behavior, it 
    also reduces the likelihood that many current transmission owners will 
    voluntarily relinquish ownership or control of their transmission 
    facilities. As a consequence, it is likely to produce significant 
    delays in the creation of RTOs that can support more competitive 
    markets that would benefit consumers. Therefore, the Commission has 
    concluded that it is in the public interest to permit some ownership of 
    RTOs by market participants for a transition period. Within five years 
    of RTO approval, however, active ownership by market participants must 
    end unless the RTO seeks, and the Commission approves, an extension. 
    Any request for extension, including a request occasioned by changed 
    circumstances, must demonstrate that the extension is consistent with 
    the independence standard of this rule and is otherwise in the public 
    interest.
        For the transition period, the Commission will establish a safe 
    harbor of five percent for active ownership interests by market 
    participants. We will allow any market participant to own up to five 
    percent of an RTO's outstanding voting securities without the need for 
    case-by-case review by the Commission. An active ownership interest at 
    five percent or lower will be construed as not providing the owner with 
    control.
        The Commission will carefully evaluate, on a case-by-case basis, 
    proposals that involve an ownership percentage higher than five 
    percent. In deciding whether to allow active ownership interests that 
    exceed five percent, we will look at various factors including the 
    voting interests held by other class members (i.e., other market 
    participants with similar economic interests), the amount of passive 
    ownership held by market participants, the degree of dispersion of 
    voting interests among other market participants and the general 
    public, and the rights retained by the owners as suppliers of 
    facilities and services to the RTO. While there is no prohibition on 
    RTO proposals that involve higher ownership percentages, it would 
    heighten the concerns identified above and would require justification 
    by the applicants to overcome these concerns.
        We note that other Federal regulatory agencies have chosen to use a 
    five percent value in similar situations. The SEC employs a five 
    percent value in deciding when one entity is an affiliate of another 
    under PUHCA.319 The SEC also requires that any person who 
    becomes a direct or indirect owner of more than five percent of any 
    class of stock of a company must file a public statement with the SEC. 
    In commenting on this latter requirement, the FCC observed that its 
    purpose is ``to ensure that investors are alerted to potential changes 
    in control * * * which confer on their holders the potential for 
    influence or control.'' 320 Less than two months ago, the 
    FCC established a five-percent ``voting share benchmark'' for assessing 
    ownership interests in companies that are cable TV operators. In 
    justifying its decision to stay with a five-percent value, the FCC 
    noted that ``[t]here is a body of more recent academic evidence that 
    tends to confirm our earlier conclusions, demonstrating that interest 
    holders of [five percent] can likely exert considerable influence on a 
    company's management and operational decisions.'' 321 The 
    FCC concluded that ``ownership percentages starting at [five] percent 
    can influence management polices.'' 322
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \319\ See 15 U.S.C. 79b(a)(11).
        \320\ Federal Communications Commission, In the Matter of 
    Implementation of the Cable Television Consumer Protection and 
    Competition Act 1999; Implementation of Cable Act Reform Provisions 
    of the Telecommunications Act of 1996; Review of the Commission's 
    Cable Attribution Rules, FCC LEXIS 5243, *53 (October 20, 1999) 
    citing Securities and Exchange Commission v. Savoy Industries, Inc., 
    587 F.2d 1149 (D.C. Cir. 1978), cert. denied, 440 U.S. 913 (1979).
        \321\ Id.
        \322\ Id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We recognize that this Commission has used higher percentages in 
    other contexts. For example, in determining whether a company is an 
    affiliate of a natural gas pipeline or an electric utility, we have 
    applied a rebuttable presumption of control only when a utility or 
    pipeline owns ten percent or more of the company's voting stock. As a 
    general matter, since the success of RTOs will depend on both the 
    perception and reality of independence, the Commission believes that 
    caution requires us to allow only very limited voting interests by 
    market participants. The Commission believes that a lower percentage is 
    necessary in this instance because we allow other market participants 
    with similar economic interests (i.e., members of the same class) to 
    have voting interests. Therefore, we believe that it is appropriate to 
    impose a lower cap to reduce the risk that owners with similar outside 
    economic interests may create a voting bloc. If, after our initial 
    approval, we find evidence that control over the RTO is being exercised 
    by an individual market participant or a class of market participants, 
    we will not hesitate to take appropriate action, including ordering one 
    or more entities to divest their ownership interests in the RTO.
        The Commission recognizes that there are risks associated with 
    allowing market participants to have any active ownership interests in 
    an RTO. Even with a five percent active ownership interest, there is a 
    risk that one or more market participants will be able to influence the 
    RTO's decisionmaking process to the disadvantage of other market 
    participants. Consequently, the RTO may fail to be an entity in which 
    ``the control of transmission operation is cleanly separated from power 
    market participants.'' 323 Accordingly, we will require that 
    all market participants divest themselves of any active ownership 
    interests no later than five years after our approval of the RTO. We 
    will consider requests for extensions to this ``sunsetting'' 
    requirement on a case-by-case basis. Any request for extension, 
    including a request occasioned by changed circumstances, will be 
    granted if the requester demonstrates that the extension is consistent 
    with the independence standard of this Rule and is otherwise in the 
    public interest. We will also require that any RTO that proposes active 
    ownership by a market participant must adopt a system of independent 
    compliance auditing to ensure that the active voting interests held by 
    an individual market participant or classes of market
    
    [[Page 856]]
    
    participants do not convey decisionmaking control.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \323\ FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,718.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        b. Active Ownership by Classes of Market Participants. In the NOPR, 
    we stated that ``[a]n RTO must have a decisionmaking process that is 
    independent of control of any market participant or class of 
    participants.'' 324 While we suggested a safe harbor of one 
    percent ownership in voting securities by an individual market 
    participant and its affiliates, we did not propose any specific cap on 
    ownership of voting securities by a class of participants. Based on a 
    review of the comments received, we have concluded that a policy on 
    ownership by classes of market participants is necessary to ensure the 
    independence of the RTO. Thus, we will review RTO proposals with 
    respect to class ownership, considering potentially relevant factors 
    such as voting interests held by other market participants or classes 
    of market participants, the degree of passive ownership by market 
    participants, the degree of dispersion of voting interests, and the 
    rights retained by the owners as suppliers of facilities and services 
    to the RTO. We recognize that this is a fact-specific determination 
    that will require the Commission to evaluate, on a case-by-case basis, 
    proposals that involve ownership by more than one market participant. 
    We will adopt a benchmark of 15 percent class ownership. Our 
    willingness to allow ownership by a class of participants that exceeds 
    fifteen percent will depend on the particular circumstances of the 
    filing (e.g., the presence of offsetting voting interests by another 
    class of market participants with competing economic or commercial 
    interests or proposals to sunset active ownership).325 
    Moreover, intervenors may also advance arguments that a 15 percent 
    class ownership is inappropriate under certain factual circumstances.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \324\ Id. at 33,727.
        \325\ See Alliance Companies, supra note 48.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments on this issue reflect widely divergent views. SRP 
    criticizes the NOPR for failing to recognize that ``[a]n interest may 
    be considered de minimis when viewed in isolation, could still result 
    in effective control when aggregated for a group with common 
    interests.'' SRP contends that while the Commission explicitly 
    recognized the importance of classes in the NOPR, we failed to do 
    anything about it. In contrast, FP&L and others argue that there is no 
    need for any ownership caps for a group of market participants since 
    they will often have conflicting interests. EEI echoes this point by 
    observing that any ``coalitions'' are likely to be ``fragile, short-
    lived and unlikely to result in a serious threat to the independence of 
    the RTO.'' 326 It also contends that it will be difficult to 
    keep track of ownership interests and to categorize market participants 
    into specific groups with ``alleged common interests.'' Therefore, 
    while EEI proposes a ten-percent cap on ownership interests in voting 
    securities by individual market participants, it recommends that there 
    be no cap on the ownership interests of any group of participants.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \326\ EEI Reply Comments at 21.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In several ISO orders, we rejected proposed governance arrangements 
    because we concluded that the voting weights and rules given to classes 
    or sectors of participants would allow transmission owners to dominate 
    the decisionmaking process.327 We believe that the concerns 
    that motivated these orders also hold true with respect to ownership of 
    RTOs. It would make little sense to establish a policy on ownership by 
    individual market participants and their affiliates while allowing five 
    or six generators or marketers to group together to force an RTO to 
    adopt a policy that favors their interests.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \327\ See New England Power Pool, 88 FERC para. 61,079 (1999); 
    Central Hudson Gas and Electric Corp., et al., 88 FERC para. 61,229 
    (1999).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission is unpersuaded by the assertions that similarly 
    situated market participants will not have a ``nexus of interests.'' 
    While we recognize, for example, that individual generators may 
    actively compete against each other for specific sales, this does not 
    imply that there is a total absence of common economic interests among 
    generators relative to marketers or distributors. If we were to accept 
    this argument, it would require us to ignore the fact that the 
    Commission routinely receives joint pleadings from non-affiliated 
    parties with similar economic interests. Similarly, over the last two 
    years, we have frequently observed various non-affiliated entities 
    within ISOs voting as a bloc on issues where they have similar economic 
    interests (e.g., existing generators voting against new generators who 
    seek lower interconnection charges when they connect to the grid).
        There is a second reason why we believe it is necessary to review 
    class or sector ownership of voting securities in RTOs. With ISOs, we 
    have allowed sector or class representation on the advisory and 
    technical committees that are charged with giving advice or making 
    recommendations to non-stakeholder governing boards. We have accepted 
    these arrangements even though the votes of some classes exceed 20 
    percent because all other classes are represented and have roughly 
    equal voting power. Thus, independence is achieved through a diffusion 
    of voting power among all the affected classes. While this arrangement 
    may work for ISOs that are typically non-profit and non-share 
    corporations, we do not think it is viable option for RTOs that have 
    ownership shares that must be purchased. In particular, we cannot 
    assume that all affected classes of market participants will have the 
    financial resources to purchase ownership interests that would 
    guarantee them a vote at the table. Therefore, we cannot presume that 
    there will be a balance of voting power as was the case for the ISOs. 
    In the absence of such countervailing voting blocs, we believe that it 
    is necessary to establish lower limits on the amount of voting shares 
    that can be owned by members of any one class of market participants.
        Based on our experience to date, we do not think it is impractical 
    to define classes of market participants with similar economic 
    interests. This has been routinely done as part of the governance 
    design in every one of the ISOs that we have approved. The Commission 
    will not establish categories of classes in this Final Rule. Instead, 
    we will allow each RTO to propose the classes that it believes are 
    relevant to its region. However, we are inclined to define such classes 
    broadly to avoid bypassing the class cap through narrowly defined 
    classes.
        In addition, we will require independent compliance auditing to 
    ensure that market participants that have ownership interests will not 
    use these ownership interests to put other non-owner market 
    participants at a competitive disadvantage.328
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \328\ See supra note 304.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The auditing should be performed by individuals or organizations 
    that are not affiliated with the owners or RTO. The auditors would have 
    clear authority to obtain any information or data necessary to perform 
    their audits, and they would have the right to report any findings and 
    recommendations to the Commission without prior approval of the RTO or 
    any of its owners/members. An initial audit should be performed two 
    years after our approval of the RTO. This will be the only audit 
    required for active ownership unless the RTO or the active owners 
    request and receive approval for an extension of active ownership 
    interests beyond five years. If such an extension is granted, then 
    follow-up compliance audits must be performed at three year intervals,
    
    [[Page 857]]
    
    beginning with a three-year audit filed along with any request for 
    extension.
        As we discussed above with respect to passive ownership, applicants 
    will have a continuing obligation to inform the Commission of any 
    changed circumstances regarding active ownership. Moreover, the 
    Commission would expect auditing for compliance with the individual and 
    class caps established at the time of RTO approval. Where feasible, the 
    auditors would rely on publicly available information on ownership 
    interests (e.g., SEC data sources). Where such information is not 
    publicly available (e.g., individual ownership interests of less than 
    five percent), the auditors should have the authority to obtain this 
    information from market participants and their affiliates. Any market 
    participant that wishes to have an ownership interest in an RTO must 
    agree to provide this information to the auditor or the Commission upon 
    request. We would expect that market participants will comply with both 
    the individual and class caps at all times. If the auditor finds that 
    either cap has been violated, it must notify the Commission and the 
    affected owners immediately and also recommend a remedy.
        Since the caps do not guarantee a lack of control, the Commission 
    expects that the auditors will also look for evidence of control over 
    RTO decisionmaking at lower levels of ownership. These audit reports 
    would be closely reviewed by the Commission and if there is evidence of 
    abuse or unwillingness to cooperate with the auditors, the Commission 
    will not hesitate to order owners to divest themselves of their active 
    ownership interests.
        RTO Governing Boards. Many commenters urge us to impose specific, 
    detailed requirements on RTO governance. Commenters make 
    recommendations on many different aspects of governance: the 
    desirability of stakeholder, non-stakeholder or hybrid boards, the size 
    of boards, the relationship between non-stakeholder boards and 
    stakeholder advisory groups, the number of classes for stakeholder 
    boards, the appropriate voting entitlements for individual classes on a 
    stakeholder board; and optimal voting rules. Most of the 
    recommendations seemed to be targeted for RTOs that are ISOs. In the 
    Final Rule, we have decided not to impose any specific requirements on 
    RTO governing boards other than the general requirement that they must 
    satisfy the overall principle that their decisionmaking process should 
    be independent of any market participant or class of participants. We 
    have opted not to impose more detailed governance requirements for 
    three reasons.
        First, we anticipate that RTOs will take many different forms that 
    reflect the needs and different starting points of each region. We 
    expect to see proposals from ISOs, transcos and hybrids. It is unlikely 
    that a single approach to governance will work for the different types 
    of RTOs that are likely to emerge. At this early stage, it would be 
    counterproductive to impose a ``one size fits all'' approach to 
    governance when RTOs may differ significantly in structure and patterns 
    of ownership.
        Second, our experience to date has been largely limited to 
    reviewing governance proposals of ISOs that operate but do not own 
    transmission facilities. A governance model that works for an ISO may 
    not be appropriate for transcos or other types of for-profit 
    transmission enterprises.
        Third, even among the ISOs, there are different models of 
    governance. As we noted in the NOPR, the dominant governance model 
    (PJM, New England, New York and the Midwest) for ISOs is a two-tier 
    form of governance. The top tier consists of a non-stakeholder board, 
    while the lower tier consists of advisory committees of stakeholders 
    that may recommend options to the non-stakeholder board. Generally, the 
    top tier has the final decisionmaking authority.329 In 
    contrast, California, employs a decisionmaking board for its ISO that 
    consists of both stakeholders and non-stakeholders representatives. And 
    we note that the recently passed Texas restructuring law would require 
    a pure stakeholder governing board for the ERCOT ISO. Given the variety 
    of governance forms that exist or are proposed for ISOs and the limited 
    experience with these different approaches, the Commission believes 
    that it is premature to conclude that one form of governance is clearly 
    superior to all other forms in every situation.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \329\ One exception is the New York ISO where decisionmaking is 
    explicitly shared by a non-stakeholder Board of Directors and 
    stakeholder Management Committee. Modification of the ISO tariffs 
    under the FPA requires approval of the ISO Board and the Management 
    Committee. If they fail to agree on a modification, either the Board 
    or the Management Committee may make a filing under FPA section 206. 
    See Central Hudson Gas & Electric Corp., et al., 88 FERC para. 
    61,138 (1999).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Therefore, we will not mandate detailed governance requirements for 
    RTO boards. Instead, the approach that we adopt in the Final Rule is 
    that any RTO governance proposals, whether from an ISO, transco or a 
    hybrid arrangement, will be judged on a case-by-case basis against the 
    overarching standard that its decisionmaking process must be 
    independent of individual market participants and classes of market 
    participants.330
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \330\ We will require every ISO to submit an audit of the 
    independence of its governance process two years after its approval 
    as an RTO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        While we are not imposing any other specific requirements, the 
    Commission believes that it is appropriate to give some general 
    guidance based on the governance arrangements that we have reviewed to 
    date. Where there is a governing board with classes of market 
    participants, we would expect that no one class would be allowed to 
    veto a decision reached by the rest of the board and that no two 
    classes could force through a decision that is opposed by the rest of 
    the board. Where there is a non-stakeholder board, we believe that it 
    is important that this board not become isolated. Both formal and 
    informal mechanisms must exist to ensure that stakeholders can convey 
    their concerns to the non-stakeholder board. Where there are 
    stakeholder committees that advise or share authority with a non-
    stakeholder board, it is important that there be balanced 
    representation on the stakeholder committees so no one class dominates 
    its recommendations or its decisions.
        We note that this general guidance is based on our experience with 
    governance proposals of ISOs. The Commission recognizes that these 
    observations may not be completely relevant for an RTO that intends to 
    operate as a for-profit transmission company. Nevertheless, we 
    emphasize that the common element for all types of RTOs must be that 
    they satisfy the threshold principle that their decisionmaking should 
    be independent of market participants.
        Role of State Agencies. We do not impose any specific requirements 
    on the role of state agencies in RTOs. Such specificity would be 
    counterproductive in light of the variation in the legal 
    responsibilities of state commissions and RTO design across regions. 
    However, we agree with NARUC that state commissions ``should fully 
    participate in RTO formation and development.'' When we undertake our 
    collaborative efforts with the industry after issuance of the Final 
    Rule, we encourage state commissions and other state agencies to play a 
    key role in this effort. State involvement is important for several 
    reasons, especially where RTOs are a critical element of the retail 
    choice programs of many states. State commissions are in a unique 
    position to assess whether a particular RTO design will help or hinder 
    their efforts to promote retail competition.
    
    [[Page 858]]
    
        Once an RTO becomes operational, it appears that most states 
    believe that it would be inappropriate for a state official, whether a 
    state commission representative or some other state employee, to serve 
    as a voting member of an RTO board. We note that NECPUC, representing 
    the six New England state commissions, was joined by most other state 
    commissions and commenters from other sectors of the industry in 
    recommending that state officials should not be voting members of any 
    RTO governing body. ISO-NE presents three reasons why it would be 
    problematic for a state official to serve as a voting member of an RTO 
    governing board. First, it would create a conflict between the state 
    official's duties as an RTO board member and his or her regulatory or 
    legal responsibilities at the state level. Second, in the case of a 
    multi-state RTO, it would be difficult for an official of one state to 
    represent the interests of others states if the state interests are in 
    conflict. Third, the solution of allowing each state to have its own 
    voting member on the RTO board could lead to large and unwieldy boards 
    for multi-state RTOs.
        While most commenters agreed that state officials should not serve 
    as voting members of RTO boards, most of these same commenters were 
    comfortable with allowing state officials to serve as ex officio 
    members. It was thought that state officials would be better informed 
    in making their own decisions if they could closely observe the 
    considerations and constraints that were weighed by the RTO in making 
    its decisions. It was thought that the ability of state officials to 
    observe the RTO's decisionmaking process would be especially useful if 
    the RTO had to recommend one or more expansions to the existing grid.
        While we see considerable merit in the arguments that state 
    officials should not be voting members of an RTO governing board (and 
    note that most state commissions share this view), the Commission is 
    not imposing such a prohibition. Since RTOs do not yet exist, it would 
    be premature to conclude that state officials should not participate as 
    voting members of RTO boards. There may be special circumstances in 
    some regions that would make it in the public interest to give voting 
    rights to one or more state government representatives. Therefore, we 
    will be willing to entertain such proposals and perhaps revisit the 
    issue after we gain more experience.
        Section 205 Filing Rights. In the NOPR, we proposed that the RTO 
    must have exclusive and independent authority to file changes in its 
    transmission tariff under section 205 of the Federal Power Act. This 
    proposal triggered hundreds of pages of comments. Upon consideration of 
    the comments received, as discussed below, we will modify our proposal, 
    in part, to make clear that transmission owners who do not also operate 
    their transmission facilities retain certain section 205 rights.
        Most commenters on this issue fall into two categories. Those who 
    oppose the proposal in the NOPR argue that it is bad law and bad 
    policy. They contend that the Commission does not have the legal 
    authority to grant section 205 rights over their transmission 
    facilities to some other entity. While a transmission owner may 
    voluntarily cede this right to an RTO, they argue that the Commission 
    cannot compel a transmission owner, either directly or indirectly, to 
    give up this legal right. Many transmission owners, representing IOUs, 
    public and cooperative systems, argue that the transfer of this right 
    to an RTO would increase their risk of recovering revenues to which 
    they are lawfully entitled. On the other hand, those who support the 
    proposal argue that it is a necessary and logical implication of our 
    previously stated policy that the ``[a]uthority to act unilaterally * * 
    * is a crucial element of a truly independent transmission provider.'' 
    331 They contend that an RTO will not be able to function as 
    an independent and neutral transmission provider if it has to seek the 
    approval of transmission owners or other market participants every time 
    it wishes to modify its tariff. They point to numerous tariff changes 
    that the various ISOs have had to make as real world evidence of their 
    need to move quickly and make filings at the Commission when they 
    encounter a tariff problem that needs to be corrected.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \331\ New England Power Pool, 70 FERC para. 61,374 at 62,585 
    (1997).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Based on the comments received, we reaffirm our determination that 
    RTOs, in order to ensure their independence from market participants, 
    must have the independent and exclusive right to make section 205 
    filings that apply to the rates, terms and conditions of transmission 
    services over the facilities operated by the RTO. This determination, 
    however, is subject to several important clarifications discussed 
    below.
        We recognize that for some RTOs (in particular, ISOs), both the 
    transmission owners and the RTO will be public utilities with respect 
    to the same transmission facilities,332 i.e., one or more 
    entities will own the facilities and a different entity will operate 
    the facilities and actually sell the transmission provided by the 
    facilities, and that this presents a somewhat unusual situation insofar 
    as sections 205 and 206 of the FPA are concerned. The FPA does not 
    explicitly address who has filing authority or responsibility in this 
    circumstance. We conclude that while the RTO must have independent and 
    exclusive authority to propose changes in the rates, terms and 
    conditions of transmission service provided over the facilities it 
    operates, it also is reasonable for the transmission owners to retain 
    certain independent section 205 filing rights with respect to the level 
    of the revenue requirement that the transmission owners receive from 
    the RTO and that the RTO, in turn, will collect from the transmission 
    customers through its rates. We therefore clarify that a transmission 
    owner must have independent authority to set the level of its portion 
    of the revenue requirement to be collected by the RTO.333
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \332\ Under FPA section 201(e), a public utility is any person 
    who owns or operates jurisdictional facilities.
        \333\ Of course, a transmission owner may voluntarily agree to 
    relinquish this right during the RTO negotiation process or 
    subsequently.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Importantly, we further clarify that we expect the authorities of 
    the transmission owners and the RTO to be exercised as follows. The 
    transmission owners may make section 205 filings to establish the 
    payments that the RTO will make to the transmission owners for the use 
    of the transmission facilities that are under the control of the RTO; 
    the RTO, in turn, will make section 205 filings to recover from 
    transmission customers the cost of the payments it makes to 
    transmission owners as well as its own costs, and propose any other 
    changes in the rates, terms and conditions of service to transmission 
    customers. Thus, the transmission owners may have on file a tariff that 
    assures their recovery of transmission revenues from the RTO and, while 
    they may be affecting the level of the RTO's revenue requirement, they 
    will not be permitted to make section 205 filings for RTO services to 
    transmission customers and will not interfere with the independence of 
    the RTO to file proposed changes to the open access 
    tariff.334
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \334\ We note that some existing ISOs have adopted an approach 
    where the transmission owners' revenue requirement is filed with the 
    Commission in a separate transmission rate filing (e.g., California 
    ISO), while others incorporate the revenue requirement of the 
    transmission owners, as changed from time to time, in the ISO's 
    tariff. In either case, only the ISO is authorized to make filings 
    that change the tariff sheets in the ISO's tariff.
    
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [[Page 859]]
    
        We believe this division of filing rights reflects a reasonable 
    interpretation of the FPA as applied to these circumstances, and that 
    it appropriately balances the need to ensure the independence of the 
    RTO with the need to provide transmission owners the opportunity to 
    recover revenues. To avoid unnecessary disputes and coordinate the 
    interaction of these independent section 205 filings, we will require 
    the RTO and the transmission owners to give prior notice to each other 
    of any planned section 205 filings. Further, we strongly encourage 
    transmission owners and RTOs to resolve rate issues prior to the filing 
    of proposed rate changes.
        We recognize that the division of filing rights described above may 
    not be the only way to accommodate the concerns raised. Accordingly, 
    the Commission will entertain other approaches as long as they ensure 
    the independent authority of the RTO to seek changes in rates, terms or 
    conditions of transmission service and the ability of transmission 
    owners to protect the level of the revenue needed to recover the costs 
    of their transmission facilities. The Commission will require RTOs to 
    provide a detailed description of the process to allow us to assess its 
    fairness and workability.
    2. Scope and Regional Configuration (Characteristic 2)
        The NOPR proposed as the second minimum characteristic of an RTO 
    that the RTO must serve an appropriate region--a region of sufficient 
    scope and configuration to permit the RTO to effectively perform its 
    required functions and to support efficient and nondiscriminatory power 
    markets.353 The NOPR noted that there is likely no one 
    ``right'' configuration of regions and proposed to establish a set of 
    factors that encourage appropriate regional configuration without 
    prescribing boundaries. The NOPR suggested that a region that is large 
    in scope would facilitate the effective performance of many of the 
    RTO's functions, but also recognized that there may be factors that 
    might limit how large an RTO should be.336 The NOPR also 
    proposed a set of factors that may affect the location of regional 
    boundaries. These factors indicate that boundaries should facilitate 
    essential RTO functions and goals, recognize trading patterns, mitigate 
    the exercise of market power, do not unnecessarily split existing 
    control areas or existing regional transmission entities, encompass 
    contiguous geographic areas and highly interconnected portions of the 
    grid, and take into account useful existing regional boundaries (such 
    as NERC regions) and international boundaries. The NOPR put forth for 
    discussion the appropriateness of existing configurations, such as the 
    three electric interconnections within the continental United States, 
    the ten NERC reliability councils, and the 23 NERC security coordinator 
    areas.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \335\ FERC Stats. and Regs. at 33,729.
        \336\ Id. at 33,730.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The NOPR also requested comments on what portion of the 
    transmission facilities within an appropriate region the RTO must 
    control in order to be approved as an RTO. The Commission recognized 
    that it might be difficult to obtain 100 percent participation of all 
    transmission owners within a region, but that, on the other hand, it 
    would not be appropriate to approve an RTO proposal that included only 
    a small portion of the facilities of the region. The Commission also 
    requested comments on how much deference the Commission should give to 
    regions proposed to us, and to what extent state commission approval or 
    disapproval should be taken into account.
        a. How Should Initial Boundaries be Established? Comments. Most 
    commenters agree with the Commission's proposal not to initially 
    prescribe the boundaries for appropriate regions.337 Among 
    the rationales asserted by these commenters is that this is a matter 
    best left in the first instance to the stakeholders in the various 
    regions,338 there should be deference to proposals by 
    transmission owners and market participants,339 FERC should 
    give deference to state commissions on scope and 
    configuration,340 boundaries should be determined naturally 
    in a way that facilitates market transactions,341 and size 
    and configuration must be determined on a case-by-case 
    basis.342
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \337\ See, e.g., South Carolina Authority, Cleco, SRP, LG&E, 
    Detroit Edison, Wyoming Commission, Entergy, UtiliCorp, NECPUC, 
    MidAmerican, Enron/APX/Coral Power, Duke, NASUCA, Industrial 
    Consumers, Connectiv, Massachusetts Division, Iowa Board.
        \338\See, e.g., South Carolina Authority, NASUCA, Florida Power 
    Corp.
        \339\ See, e.g., Entergy, MidAmerican.
        \340\ See, e.g., Southern Company, NECPUC, Nine Commissions, 
    Florida Commission.
        \341\ See, e.g., Duke, FirstEnergy, Allegheny, Iowa Board.
        \342\ See, e.g., NYPP.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        However, some commenters argue that the Commission should prescribe 
    regional boundaries. APPA, East Texas Cooperatives, TDU Systems and the 
    Michigan Commission urge that the Commission use section 202(a) 
    authority to establish initial boundaries. APPA asserts that the 
    Commission should establish a rebuttable presumption in favor of 
    specific regional district boundaries based on the topology of the 
    transmission network to enhance system security. East Texas 
    Cooperatives argues that after the Commission established regional 
    districts, the burden would be on those proposing different regions to 
    show that they provide at least the benefits of the prescribed 
    districts. Michigan Commission states that the electricity market is 
    currently too immature to determine by itself the size of the markets, 
    and that firm guidance is needed rather than allowing the RTO 
    boundaries to be set by participants.
        Several other commenters do not go as far in asserting that the 
    Commission should initially set boundaries, but argue that the 
    Commission should take a strong role in assuring proper boundaries. For 
    example, Cinergy urges that the Commission be aggressive in 
    establishing boundaries consistent with the proposed criteria, noting 
    that the willingness of the Commission to exercise its authority over 
    boundaries will determine the success of the Commission's restructuring 
    efforts. Coalition of Alliance Users maintains that the Commission 
    should take a direct and active role in formulating RTO boundaries. 
    WEPCO believes that the role of the Commission should be to set 
    criteria that encourage the establishment of sensible RTO boundaries. 
    Project Groups assert that if the stakeholders in a region do not 
    determine boundaries by the end of 2000, the Commission should make the 
    determinations. LG&E states that while the Commission should show 
    deference to voluntary RTOs, it should not hesitate to disapprove 
    proposals with geographic shortcomings.
        Commenters express a variety of views regarding whether particular 
    regional configurations would be appropriate. Some commenters support 
    interconnection-wide RTOs as a desirable goal,343 while 
    others regard either an Eastern or Western interconnection RTO as 
    unworkably large. 344
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \343\ See, e.g., South Carolina Authority, Conlon, Industrial 
    Consumers, First Rochdale, Los Angeles, PG&E, Sonat.
        \344\ See, e.g., South Carolina Authority, Desert STAR, 
    MidAmerican, TDU Systems, CREDA, SNWA, CRC, Platte River, PSNM, SRP, 
    Metropolitan.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commenters offer specific ideas about the number and placement of 
    RTOs. PG&E states that the long-term goal should be four or five RTOs 
    nationwide.
    
    [[Page 860]]
    
    Williams argues for 3 to 10 RTO nationwide, while Project Groups 
    advocates 3 to 12 RTO nationwide. WEPCO proposes the formation of five 
    RTOs: (1) three in the Eastern interconnection (one covering MAPP, 
    MAIN, ECAR and portions of SPP; one covering SERC, Florida and the rest 
    of SPP; and one covering NPCC and MAAC); (2) one for WSCC; and (3) one 
    for ERCOT. APPA, supported by East Texas Cooperatives, suggests: (1) no 
    more than three RTOs in the West; (2) the combination of PJM, NY ISO 
    and ISO-NE into one RTO with the possible participation of Ontario; (3) 
    the combination of the Alliance RTO, Midwest ISO, and MAPP into one 
    RTO; (4) Kansas to the Carolinas under one RTO; and (5) separate RTOs 
    for Florida, ERCOT and Hydro-Quebec.
        With respect to specific regions, ISO-NE contends that it already 
    operates a region of appropriate size and configuration. Mass Companies 
    agrees that ISO-NE is an appropriate region. NYC argues that the 
    formation of a northeastern RTO with a broader geographic scope than 
    the NY ISO would help remove existing institutional impediments to the 
    construction of new transmission lines. American Forest argues that PJM 
    is too small, while NASUCA and Mid-Atlantic Commissions believe that 
    PJM satisfies the size criteria. Some commenters object to a split 
    between the area represented by the proposed Alliance RTO and the 
    Midwest ISO.\345\ Most of the Florida commenters assert that peninsular 
    Florida represents an appropriate region.\346\ For example, Florida 
    Commission claims that peninsular Florida is a large and efficient 
    marketplace that does not share parallel flows with other electrical 
    regions; however, it states that the Florida panhandle could be in a 
    region with all of SERC or a subregion of SERC.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \345\ See, e.g., Michigan Commission, South Carolina Authority, 
    Midwest ISO, Midwest ISO Participants, NASUCA.
        \346\ See, e.g., Florida Commission, JEA, FP&L, Florida Power 
    Corp., Tallahassee, Gainesville.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Although some commenters encourage a Western interconnection-wide 
    RTO, the majority of commenters support three or four RTOs for the 
    Western interconnection, noting that the interests in the WSCC are too 
    diverse and the area too large for control by a single entity.\347\ Cal 
    ISO contends that California satisfies the minimum size criteria, but 
    does not represent the maximum feasible area. Commenters from the 
    Pacific Northwest generally agree that a region including Washington, 
    Oregon, and all or portions of Idaho and Montana is distinct enough to 
    warrant an RTO limited to that area.\348\ CREDA and Platte River 
    envision one RTO for the Pacific Northwest, one for California and one 
    for the Rocky Mountain/Desert Southwest area; CRC suggests a similar 
    alignment, with the exception of the Rocky Mountain and Southwest areas 
    as separate RTOs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \347\ See, e.g., SRP, Metropolitan.
        \348\ See, e.g., Seattle, PGE, Industrial Customers, BC Hydro, 
    Powerex, Tacoma Power, PNGC.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A number of commenters make the point that, regardless of where RTO 
    boundaries are drawn, it is important that there be integration and 
    coordination among RTOs.\349\ NERC believes that there are two seams 
    issues: reliability practices across seams and market practices across 
    seams. TDU Systems suggests that there be a set of regions for 
    reliability/operations purposes within a larger region for rates and 
    scheduling. Industrial Consumers state that, if multiple RTOs are 
    formed within an interconnection, RTOs should be required to coordinate 
    their operations to collectively ``simulate'' an interconnection-wide 
    RTO. Cinergy suggests that, if there were more than one RTO in a large 
    interconnection, a ``super'' RTO could be established to operate and 
    coordinate inter-RTO activities. Montana Commission states that RTO 
    boundaries are less important than ensuring that seams do not interfere 
    with the market, and proposes, as do others such as Ontario Power and 
    CMUA, that the Commission require adjacent RTOs to embody consistent 
    methods of access, pricing, and congestion management to encourage 
    seamless trading. PacifiCorp asserts that reciprocity agreements among 
    RTOs may be easier to achieve than having all parties in a large region 
    agree to one RTO. Allegheny suggests that appropriate transmission 
    pricing could provide some of the same benefits as a large RTO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \349\ See, e.g., South Carolina Authority, SPP.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several commenters express concern that multiple RTO proposals for 
    the same region will be submitted. Indiana Commission contends that the 
    NOPR leaves the door open for more than one RTO proposal for 
    approximately the same wholesale power market region and this could 
    limit the operational efficiency and increase the cost of transmission 
    in the region. It suggests that the Commission consider requiring 
    formal mediation or play an assertive role in such circumstances. 
    Snohomish suggests favoring the RTO proposal that is negotiated 
    pursuant to the most open process that included consumers, transmission 
    dependent utilities and others with a vital interest in the effective 
    and efficient operation of the transmission grid. Midwest ISO 
    Participants submit that the proponents of multiple RTOs meet a heavy 
    burden and demonstrate the need for more than one RTO. In particular, 
    it would require demonstration that the proposals: do not balkanize the 
    market; allow for effective congestion relief; maintain reliability; 
    facilitate construction of new transmission facilities; and allow for 
    effective tariff administration and unbiased ATC determination 
    throughout the region.
        Commission Conclusion. We adopt the NOPR proposal on this 
    characteristic. All RTO proposals filed with us must identify a region 
    of appropriate scope and configuration. The scope and configuration of 
    the regions in which RTOs are to operate will significantly affect how 
    well they will be able to achieve the necessary regulatory, 
    reliability, operational, and competitive benefits.
        As proposed in the NOPR, we will not at this time prescribe initial 
    boundaries for RTOs. Section 202(a) of the FPA does give us the 
    authority, after consultation with state commissions, to fix and modify 
    boundaries for regional districts for the voluntary interconnection and 
    coordination of facilities. We acknowledge those commenters who believe 
    that it may be more efficient for the Commission to establish at least 
    a rebuttable presumption that particular boundaries are appropriate 
    starting points. However, we conclude, as a matter of policy, that we 
    should not attempt to draw boundaries at this time. We are convinced 
    that the transmission owners, market participants, and regulators in a 
    particular region have a better understanding of the dynamics of the 
    transmission system in that region, and that they should, at least in 
    the first instance, propose the appropriate scope and regional 
    configuration of an RTO. There are many technical considerations 
    involved in discerning the appropriate scope and regional configuration 
    of an RTO, and we believe that those most familiar with such 
    considerations in a region are in a better position to propose a 
    workable solution.
        As noted above, some commenters advocate that the NERC regions be 
    starting points; others advocate that the Interconnections be the goal; 
    and still others propose specific configurations that would divide the 
    Nation as many as three to 12 RTOs. Consistent with our decision to let 
    the parties take the initiative to propose what is appropriate for 
    their region, we will not specifically
    
    [[Page 861]]
    
    endorse any particular scheme for RTO configuration.
        This is not to say, however, that we will deem appropriate any 
    regional configuration proposed. As stated in the regulatory text for 
    this characteristic, an appropriate region is one of sufficient scope 
    and configuration to permit the RTO to effectively perform its required 
    functions and to support efficient and nondiscriminatory power markets. 
    A proposed RTO could simply be too limited to satisfy several of the 
    necessary functions. Further, we are aware that transmission owners 
    could seek to gain strategic advantage by the way an RTO is formed. For 
    example, an RTO could be placed to act as a toll collector on a 
    critical corridor.\350\ An RTO could propose a configuration that 
    interferes with the formation of a larger, more appropriately 
    configured RTO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \350\ See Statement of Ohio Commission Chairman Craig Glazer, 
    RTO Conference (St. Louis), transcript at 85-87.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As we review a proposal by a regional transmission entity for its 
    scope and regional configuration, if we determine that the scope is 
    inappropriate, that entity will not be deemed to be an RTO, and its 
    participants will not be deemed to be RTO participants.\351\ In 
    response to the commenters questioning what the Commission would do if 
    it received multiple RTO proposals for a region, we note that we hope 
    the collaborative process we are encouraging in this Final Rule would 
    foreclose that circumstance. However, if we are faced with multiple 
    proposals, we would have to determine which RTO proposal best meets the 
    objectives of this Rule.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \351\ The proposal could be accepted, however, as something less 
    than an RTO that represents an improvement over the status quo.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As we stated in the NOPR, we are aware that there is likely no one 
    ``right'' configuration of regions. One particular boundary may satisfy 
    one desirable RTO objective and conflict with another. We recognize 
    here, and elsewhere in this Final Rule,\352\ that the industry will 
    continue to evolve, and the appropriate regional configurations will 
    likely change over time with technological and market developments. The 
    Commission is also mindful of the interests of individual states 
    regarding RTO boundaries. Given all these considerations, the 
    Commission believes that the public interest will best be served if we 
    provide guidance in this Final Rule, in the form of factors that affect 
    appropriate regional configuration, without actually prescribing 
    boundaries.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \352\ See section F on Open Architecture.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        b. Scope and Configuration Factors. Comments. A large number of 
    commenters agree that the factors listed in the NOPR for determining a 
    proper scope and configuration for an RTO are generally 
    appropriate.\353\ Industrial Consumers propose that the factors be 
    codified as part of our regulations. Florida Commission, on the other 
    hand, argues that the factors should not be mandated as part of the 
    Commission's regulations.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \353\ See, e.g., UtiliCorp, Desert STAR, Midwest ISO 
    Participants, Metropolitan, NECPUC, LG&E, PJM/NEPOOL Customers, 
    Midwest Municipals, Industrial Consumers, Dairyland, TDU Systems, 
    ISO-NE, Midwest Energy, APX, APPA, Cal ISO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Many commenters argue that the RTO region should be as large as 
    possible, i.e., bigger is better.\354\ Several commenters suggest the 
    minimum size should be the NERC regions.\355\ Conlon suggests a minimum 
    area should be one containing a load of 50,000 MW. PJM states that its 
    organization demonstrates that a very large RTOs is feasible, in that 
    it manages a grid serving more than 57,000 MW of generation and 
    containing more than 8,000 miles of high voltage transmission lines. 
    PJM states that even larger control areas are possible as technology 
    advances. PJM/NEPOOL Customers, claiming that all potential factors 
    that might limit size can be overcome, argue that the Commission should 
    not conclude that there are factors that limit size. As discussed below 
    with respect to the congestion management function, some commenters 
    make a particular point of emphasizing the importance of large scope to 
    effective congestion management.\356\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \354\ See, e.g., Cinergy, American Forest, EPSA, UtiliCorp, 
    PG&E, NSP, Pennsylvania Commission, NJBUS, LG&E, Enron/APX/Coral 
    Power, NASUCA, PJM/NEPOOL Customers, Cal ISO, Texas Commission, 
    Conlon, Dynegy, Nine Commissions, Michigan Commission, Lincoln, 
    WPSC, First Rochdale, East Texas Cooperatives, Los Angeles, Ohio 
    Commission, EME, Ontario Power, H.Q. Energy Services, Ogelthorpe, 
    UMPA, PG&E, Indiana Commission.
        \355\ See, e.g., Cinergy, WPSC, Lincoln, Ohio Commission, PG&E.
        \356\ See, e.g., LG&E, ComEd, Midwest ISO Participants, Midwest 
    ISO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Other commenters argue that bigger is not necessarily better and 
    that there are factors that limit size.\357\ CMUA argues that the role 
    of security coordinator and operational characteristics of a region may 
    limit geographic scope. STDUG claims that size breeds inefficiency. 
    Several commenters claim that requiring maximum scope upon creation may 
    discourage RTO formation or make it more costly and take longer to 
    achieve.\358\ NYPP expresses concern that, if an RTO is too large, it 
    may not be able to handle local reliability issues. Other commenters 
    believe that the ability to plan new transmission facilities may limit 
    scope.\359\ AEPCO expresses concern that the voice of smaller 
    participants could be lost in a larger RTO. Florida Power Corp. claims 
    that there may be a security risk associated with concentrating control 
    of too large an area into a single facility, and that large areas of 
    non-pancaked rates may eliminate incentives for proper generator siting 
    decisions. A number of commenters believe that either the Eastern 
    interconnection or the Western interconnection is too large an area to 
    be controlled by one RTO.\360\ New York Commission argues that the 
    Commission should recognize that experience must be gained in stages 
    before an RTO encompassing an entire interconnection can be 
    implemented. Several commenters in the Pacific Northwest cite the 
    failed attempt to create IndeGo as evidence that trying to create too 
    large an RTO is unworkable, and at some point ``bigger'' creates more 
    problems than it solves.\361\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \357\ See, e.g., AEPCO, Tallahassee.
        \358\ See, e.g., Enron/APX/Coral Power, FirstEnergy, Tri-State.
        \359\ See, e.g., Dairyland, Minnesota Power.
        \360\ See, e.g., South Carolina Authority, Desert STAR, 
    MidAmerican, TDU Systems, CREDA, SNWA, CRC, Platte River, PSNM, SRP, 
    Metropolitan.
        \361\ See, e.g., Industrial Customers, Powerex, Tacoma Power.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Some commenters offer subjective parameters for the scope of an 
    RTO. For example, SNWA proposes that the RTO be large enough to 
    accommodate as many market participants as possible, but not so large 
    as to be overly burdensome to manage. SRP argues that a balance must be 
    struck between an RTO that is too small to cover a meaningful wholesale 
    power market and one that is too large to form and operate effectively. 
    TDU Systems argue that RTOs should comprise the largest regions that 
    could operate in a coordinated fashion within a short period of time 
    with reasonable investments of funds.
        A number of commenters emphasize particular factors that they 
    consider important in determining scope and configuration. Some 
    commenters assert that reliability and system security should be the 
    primary determinant of scope and configuration.\362\ Others place prime 
    importance on trading patterns and facilitating market 
    transactions.\363\ EEI states that the most efficient size and 
    configuration of an RTO should be left to the market to determine. 
    Other commenters propose electrical
    
    [[Page 862]]
    
    configuration and physical power flows as important factors.\364\ CREDA 
    and Desert STAR argue that the preservation of a Federal Power 
    Marketing Administration project marketing area is an important 
    consideration. Chelan argues that cost shifts need to be considered in 
    determining scope. Platte River contends that established security 
    coordinators should be a factor. Southern Company argues that joint 
    ownership agreements should be a factor. Tacoma Power claims that 
    traditional business relationships and social and political commonality 
    are factors that affect scope.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \362\ See, e.g., CMUA, APPA, Florida Commission, Minnesota 
    Commission.
        \363\ See, e.g., UtiliCorp, Reliant, Duke, South Carolina 
    Commission, NU, Florida Power Corp., Detroit Edison.
        \364\ See, e.g., South Carolina Authority, Williams, NSP, 
    Dynegy.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commenters are divided on whether points where transmission 
    facilities are constrained should be used as an RTO boundary or 
    internalized within an RTO. Some commenters claim that constraints 
    should be internalized to the extent possible and not constitute 
    boundaries between regions.365 NERC states that boundaries 
    should not be placed at weak interconnections because a single entity 
    is better able to strengthen them. On the other hand, other commenters 
    believe that constrained facilities should constitute the boundaries, 
    either because they may form a natural boundary between robust systems 
    or because it makes more sense to internalize markets than to 
    internalize constraints.366 APPA states that, because it is 
    not possible to internalize all constraints, the goal should be to 
    alleviate or mitigate the effects of interregional constraints through 
    additional construction and RTO operating rules and pricing policies. 
    NECPUC argues that it does not matter where constraints are if 
    compatible methods of locational pricing are adopted by contiguous 
    RTOs. MidAmerican and Duke assert that constraints are not natural 
    boundaries between regions because the location of points of constraint 
    change over time as market conditions change. Several commenters, such 
    as Dairyland and Desert STAR, take the position that the issue whether 
    to design RTO boundaries at constrained interfaces cannot be stated 
    generically, and must be decided on a case-by-case basis.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \365\ See, e.g., Industrial Consumers, First Rochdale, Minnesota 
    Power, STDUG, NARUC.
        \366\ See, e.g., Ohio Commission, EAL, Florida Power Corp.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commission Conclusion. The factors we believe should be used to 
    develop appropriate regions are set out here and called regional 
    configuration factors. These cover such considerations as how large a 
    region should be and how boundaries should be evaluated. We do not see 
    a benefit to placing them in regulatory text, as suggested by one 
    commenter, and we will not do so. The factors are intended as guidance 
    and, as such, must necessarily be applied flexibly.
        Regional Configuration Factors. As stated above, the principal 
    consideration in evaluating the appropriate scope of an RTO is that 
    such scope must permit the RTO to perform its functions effectively. As 
    we stated in the NOPR, many of the characteristics and functions for an 
    RTO proposed in this section suggest that the regional configuration of 
    a proposed RTO should be large in scope.367 For example:
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \367\ This reiterates the conclusion we reached in the eleven 
    ISO principles in Order No. 888, where we stated that ``[t]he 
    portion of the transmission grid operated by a single ISO should be 
    as large as possible.'' Order No. 888, FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 
    31,036 at 31,731.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
         Making accurate and reliable ATC determinations: An RTO of 
    sufficient regional scope can make more accurate determinations of ATC 
    across a larger portion of the grid using consistent assumptions and 
    criteria.
         Resolving loop flow issues: An RTO of sufficient regional 
    scope would internalize loop flow and address loop flow problems over a 
    larger region.
         Managing transmission congestion: A single transmission 
    operator over a large area can more effectively prevent and manage 
    transmission congestion.
         Offering transmission service at non-pancaked rates: 
    Competitive benefits result from eliminating pancaked transmission 
    rates within the broadest possible energy trading area.
         Improving Operations: A single OASIS operator over an area 
    of sufficient regional scope will better allocate scarcity as regional 
    transmission demand is assessed; promote simplicity and ``one-stop 
    shopping'' by reserving and scheduling transmission use over a larger 
    area; and lower costs by reducing the number of OASIS sites.
         Planning and coordinating transmission expansion: 
    Necessary transmission expansion would be more efficient if planned and 
    coordinated over a larger region.
        We note that the comments on this issue express a range of views. 
    Many commenters assert that the bigger the RTO is the better, and that 
    there really are no serious limitations to RTOs representing loads as 
    large as several hundred thousand megawatts. Other commenters suggest a 
    number of considerations that may militate against RTOs that are too 
    large, including the role of security coordinator, operational 
    characteristics, costs of formation, local reliability issues, and the 
    effect on smaller participants. In the NOPR, we recognized that there 
    may be a limitation on how many facilities or transactions can be 
    overseen reliably by a single operator, imposed either by hardware 
    design or costs, or imposed by human limitations to process the 
    required amount of information. We further recognized that the 
    difficulty and cost of transferring operational control over many 
    transmission systems to one RTO may affect regional configuration. We 
    also noted that, as regions get larger and involve more existing owners 
    of transmission, reaching consensus on an appropriate transmission rate 
    design for the region may prove challenging.
        We note that a number of commenters make the point that, at least 
    for some purposes and functions, the scope of an individual RTO is less 
    important if it is part of a group of RTOs that have adequately 
    eliminated the negative effects of ``seams'' between itself and the 
    other RTOs. NERC identifies two seams issues: reliability practices 
    across seams and market practices across seams. We further note that 
    other commenters suggest that large RTOs could be ``simulated'' through 
    coordinated operations and consistent methods of access, pricing, and 
    congestion management, and that there may be different acceptable 
    scopes for reliability and operations purposes on one hand, and rates 
    and scheduling on the other.368 We also detect a common 
    theme that runs through a number of comments: large geographic size is 
    most important for trading areas. Thus, the concept of large ``seamless 
    trading areas'' for power emerges as a ``scope'' issue that is distinct 
    from the scope of the region for organizing the transmission functions 
    of an RTO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \368\ In a recent conference to address interregional ISO 
    coordination in the northeast, the three northeast ISOs (ISO New 
    England, New York ISO, and PJM ISO) and other market participants 
    discussed current and future coordination efforts among the ISOs 
    intended to simplify market transactions and enhance reliability in 
    the northeast. See http//www.dps.state.ny.us/isoconf.htm.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We conclude that a large scope is important for an RTO to 
    effectively perform its required functions and to support efficient and 
    nondiscriminatory power markets. Adequate scope is not necessarily 
    determined by geographic distance alone; other factors include the 
    numbers of buyers and sellers covered by the RTO, the amount of load 
    served, and the number of miles of transmission lines under operational 
    control. The scope must be large enough to achieve
    
    [[Page 863]]
    
    the regulatory, reliability, operational and competitive objectives of 
    this Rule.
        We are receptive to flexible and innovative ways for an RTO to 
    achieve sufficient scope. Where a proposed regional transmission entity 
    may be of sufficient scope for some RTO purposes, but not others, an 
    RTO may be able to achieve sufficient ``effective scope'' by 
    coordination and agreements with neighboring entities, or by 
    participating in a group of RTOs with either hierarchical control or a 
    system of very close coordination. We do not foreclose the possibility 
    that an RTO may satisfy some of the minimum characteristics and 
    functions by itself, while satisfying others through a strong 
    cooperative agreement with neighboring RTOs to create a ``seamless 
    trading area.'' The functions of a large RTO may be met by eliminating 
    the effect of seams separating smaller RTOs through a contract or other 
    coordination arrangement. One of our concerns about an RTO's scope is 
    that the existing impediments to trade, reliability, and operational 
    efficiency be eliminated to the greatest extent possible. However, an 
    RTO application that proposes to rely on ``effective scope'' to satisfy 
    Characteristic 2 must demonstrate that the arrangement it proposes to 
    eliminate the effect of seams is the practical equivalent of 
    eliminating the seams by forming a larger RTO.
        Factors for Evaluating Boundaries. In addition to the factors 
    affecting the size of a region, other factors may affect the 
    delineation of regional boundaries. As stated in the NOPR, the 
    Commission proposed that RTO boundaries be drawn so as to facilitate 
    and optimize the competitive, reliability, efficiency and other 
    benefits that RTOs are intended to achieve, as well as to avoid 
    unnecessary disruption to existing institutions. The Commission 
    proposed in the NOPR a list of factors it would consider in evaluating 
    the configuration for a proposed RTO. Nearly all of the comments agree 
    that these factors are generally appropriate.
        We recognize that different factors may suggest different 
    configurations and that assessing the appropriateness of a region's 
    configuration will require balancing factors and a flexible approach. 
    Given this qualification, the Commission, in evaluating an RTO's 
    boundaries, will consider the extent to which the proposed boundaries:
        Facilitate performing essential RTO functions and achieving RTO 
    goals: The regions should be configured so that an RTO operating 
    therein can ensure non-discrimination and enhance efficiency in the 
    provision of transmission and ancillary services, maintain and enhance 
    reliability, encourage competitive energy markets, promote overall 
    operating efficiency, and facilitate efficient expansion of the 
    transmission grid. For example, we understand that there have been 
    instances where transmission system reliability was jeopardized due to 
    the lack of adequate real-time communication between separate 
    transmission operators in times of system emergencies. To the extent 
    possible, RTO boundaries should encompass areas for which real-time 
    communication is critical, and unified operation is preferred.
        Encompass one contiguous geographic area: The competitive, 
    efficiency, reliability, and other benefits of RTOs can be best 
    achieved if there is one transmission operator in a region. To be most 
    effective, that operator should have control over all transmission 
    facilities within a large geographic area, including the transmission 
    facilities of non-public utility entities. This consideration could 
    preclude a noncontiguous region, or a region with ``holes.'' However, 
    as we discuss below, we will not automatically deny RTO status where 
    the RTO is not able to obtain full participation in its region.
        Encompass a highly interconnected portion of the grid: To promote 
    reliability and efficiency, portions of the transmission grid that are 
    highly integrated and interdependent should not be divided into 
    separate RTOs. One RTO operating the integrated facilities can better 
    manage the grid. This is not to say, however, that every weak 
    interconnection belongs on a regional boundary. Where a weak interface 
    is frequently constrained and acts as a barrier to trade, it may be 
    appropriate to place that interface within an RTO region. It may be 
    more difficult to expand a weak interface on the boundary between two 
    regions; this may act as a barrier to trade between the two 
    regions.369
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \369\ Commenters are also divided on whether weak interfaces 
    should be encompassed within an RTO or act as a natural boundary. 
    After consideration, we conclude that there is not a universal 
    answer applicable to all situations. Consequently, we will address 
    this issue as it arises in RTO proposals on a case-by-case basis.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Deter the exercise of market power: While the industry should work 
    toward a goal of virtually seamless trade between RTOs, it may be that 
    initially a significant amount of trade may be contained within an RTO, 
    especially if the RTO or the market establishes a power exchange that 
    covers the same area as the RTO. Thus, to have a competitive market, it 
    is important to create an RTO region that is not dominated by a few 
    buyers or sellers of energy. Also, the RTO configuration should not be 
    one where the RTO participants can exercise transmission market power 
    by collecting congestion fees on a critical corridor.
        Recognize trading patterns: Given that a goal of this initiative is 
    to promote competition in electricity markets, regions should be 
    configured so as to recognize trading patterns, and be capable of 
    supporting trade over a large area, and not perpetuate unnecessary 
    barriers between energy buyers and sellers. There may exist today some 
    infrastructure or institutional barriers unnecessarily inhibiting trade 
    between regions that could be economically reduced. RTO boundaries 
    should not perpetuate these unnecessary and uneconomic barriers.
        Take into account existing regional boundaries (e.g., NERC regions) 
    to the extent consistent with the Commission's goals for RTOs: An RTO's 
    configuration should, to the extent possible, not disrupt existing 
    useful institutions. The Commission recognizes that utilities have been 
    working together regionally in different contexts for some time, and 
    that there is value in preserving historical institutions and 
    relationships; but we also recognize that in the evolving market, 
    efficiencies may call for new configurations.
        Encompass existing regional transmission entities: Because existing 
    ISOs, and any other regional transmission entities we may hereafter 
    approve, already integrate transmission systems, it may not be 
    efficient to divide them into different regions. This is not to say, 
    however, that RTO boundaries must coincide with existing regional 
    transmission entities. An appropriate region may well be larger, and 
    there may be circumstances that support combining or reconfiguring 
    existing entities.
        Encompass existing control areas: Many existing control areas are 
    relatively small. It may be advisable not to divide them further. 
    However, parties would not be precluded from proposing to divide a 
    control area if they show this to be beneficial.
        Take into account international boundaries: The Commission 
    recognizes that natural transmission boundaries do not necessarily 
    coincide with international boundaries. Indeed, a large part of 
    Canada's transmission system, and a small part of Mexico's transmission 
    grid, is interconnected on a synchronous basis with that of the U.S. 
    Accordingly, an appropriate region need not stop at the international 
    boundary. However, this Commission
    
    [[Page 864]]
    
    does not have, and is not intending by this rule to seek, jurisdiction 
    over the facilities in a foreign country. We will ask our international 
    neighbors to participate in discussion of these issues. Perhaps what 
    may be thought of as a ``dotted line'' boundary at the international 
    border could be used to indicate that a natural transmission region 
    does not necessarily stop at the border, while this Commission's 
    jurisdiction does.
        Although most commenters generally support these factors, other 
    considerations are proposed as factors. For example, some commenters 
    claim that we should make reliability and system security the dominant 
    factor, while other commenters propose that we make trading patterns 
    and market transactions the dominant factor. After consideration, we do 
    not think it appropriate to identify one factor as the most important. 
    Although it is essential that reliability not be jeopardized by RTO 
    formation, and it is important to promote competition, we do not 
    believe that one goal needs to be sacrificed to achieve the other.
        Other commenters suggest additional factors that they deemed 
    important to RTO boundaries, including, for example, established 
    security coordinators, joint ownership arrangements, and Federal power 
    marketing administration project marketing areas. We do not intend the 
    factors we have listed to be exclusive: other factors may have merit 
    for a particular region. We encourage parties to identify additional 
    factors they believe relevant as we consider specific RTO proposals.
        c. Control of Facilities Within a Region. We proposed in the NOPR 
    to accept as RTOs only those proposals for which a region of 
    appropriate scope and configuration is identified and the proponents 
    represent a large majority of the transmission facilities within the 
    identified region. We solicited comments on how best to balance our 
    goal of having RTOs in place that operate all transmission facilities 
    within an appropriately sized and configured region against the reality 
    that there may be difficulties in obtaining 100-percent participation 
    in all regions in the near term. We asked if we should deny RTO status 
    for any proposal that does not include all transmission facilities 
    within an appropriate region, or if we should require that the RTO at 
    least negotiate certain agreements with any non-participants within its 
    region to ensure maximum coordination.
        Comments. Almost all commenters argue that RTO status should not be 
    withheld if the RTO participants are unable to obtain participation by 
    all transmission owners in the region.370 Several 
    commenters, such as Desert STAR and Minnesota Power, note that, if the 
    Commission does not mandate 100 percent participation, it does not make 
    sense to make it a condition of RTO approval. Other commenters propose 
    standards to consider in determining when a proposed RTO represents 
    sufficient facilities in the region. For example, Desert STAR suggests 
    that the RTO have more than a majority of transmission owners and has 
    not restricted membership. Southern Company proposes a standard that 
    sufficient facilities include most of the major transmission facilities 
    and the RTO can show benefits. MidAmerican proposes that the RTO be 
    able to demonstrate that it would improve the wholesale market of any 
    subregion of the country without hindering the wholesale market of any 
    other region of the country. Enron/APX/Coral Power argues that an RTO 
    should be approved if it provides an improvement even with ``gaps.'' 
    Midwest Municipals believe that an RTO should be accepted if the 
    Commission can make the judgment that the proposal with ``gaps'' is 
    likely to encourage others to join through the strength of its 
    operations and the facilities support the development of a competitive 
    generation market. CRC suggests a standard that the proponents make a 
    showing that they have diligently tried to accommodate the concerns and 
    needs of the nonparticipating transmission owners.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \370\ See, e.g., Desert STAR, Southern Company, Metropolitan, 
    MidAmerican, Nevada Commission, Avista, Enron/APX/Coral Power, Duke, 
    PJM/NEPOOL Customers, Cal ISO, Midwest Municipals, CRC, NPRB, 
    Minnesota Power, Tri-State, TVA.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Some commenters, such as NJBUS and Cal ISO, believe that an RTO 
    should include the participation of all jurisdictional transmission 
    owners in the region. Duke, however, opposes any attempt by the 
    Commission to determine the appropriate level of participation, stating 
    that the market should determine the participation level. Some 
    commenters, such as Metropolitan, support having the RTO develop 
    coordinated operations agreements with non-participants, while other 
    commenters, such as Avista and Duke, caution that requiring such 
    agreements would be contrary to market principles and would give the 
    non-participating party too much bargaining power.
        Seattle contends that the Commission should guard against utilities 
    that would add to the RTO some facilities that are not necessary for 
    RTO operations merely to obtain incentives. It argues that small 
    municipal control areas should have some latitude to determine which of 
    their facilities are regional for RTO purposes. Seattle also questions 
    what ``participation'' entails for a utility that has limited 
    transmission facilities.
        Commission Conclusion. To satisfy the scope and configuration 
    characteristic of this Final Rule, all or most of the transmission 
    facilities in a region must be included in the RTO. Any RTO proposal 
    filed with us should intend to operate all transmission facilities 
    within its proposed region.
        We recognize, however, that the proponents of an RTO may not be 
    able to obtain agreement by all transmission owners in a region of 
    appropriate scope and configuration to transfer operating control of 
    their facilities to the RTO. This may occur, for example, because 
    certain facilities may be owned by governmental entities that have 
    restrictions on transfer of control that may require time to resolve. 
    We do not believe that it would be desirable to deny RTO status or 
    delay RTO start-up where the transmission owners representing a large 
    majority of the facilities within a region are ready to move forward, 
    while a few others are not. On the other hand, we do not believe it 
    would be desirable to approve an RTO proposal for a region if the 
    proponents represent only a small portion of the facilities in an 
    otherwise satisfactory region.
        Not knowing the full extent of difficulties that may be involved to 
    achieve participation by all transmission facilities, we will not 
    decide generically to automatically deny RTO status for lack of full 
    participation. If an RTO proposal does not cover all the transmission 
    facilities within its proposed region, it should identify the reasons 
    for this, any continuing efforts to include all facilities, and any 
    interim arrangements with the non-represented facility owners to 
    coordinate transmission functions within the region. The Commission may 
    at a future time determine whether the use of its authorities under FPA 
    sections 202(a) and 206 is appropriate to rationalize proposed regions 
    in order to accomplish the objectives of those sections, as discussed 
    elsewhere in this Final Rule.
    3. Operational Authority (Characteristic 3)
        In the NOPR, the Commission proposed that the RTO have operational 
    authority for all transmission facilities under its 
    control.371 We stated that this
    
    [[Page 865]]
    
    requirement raised two questions: Which functions must an RTO perform? 
    How should an RTO perform the functions that it has reserved for 
    itself? With respect to the question of which functions an RTO should 
    perform, the Commission proposed that, at a minimum, the RTO must have 
    operational authority over all transmission facilities transferred to 
    the RTO and must be the security coordinator for its 
    region.372 As security coordinator, the RTO would be 
    responsible for real-time monitoring of system conditions (including 
    voltage, frequency, transmission and generation availability, and power 
    flows) in order to anticipate potential reliability problems, and for 
    directing and coordinating relief procedures to respond to transmission 
    loading problems (such as assisting the control area in alleviating the 
    loading, halting additional interchange transactions, reallocating the 
    use of the transmission system, selecting the transmission loading 
    relief procedure, and implementing emergency procedures, including 
    directing that the control area immediately redispatch generation, 
    reconfigure transmission or reduce load). Those proposing an RTO may 
    also decide to have their RTO perform other traditional control area 
    functions (such as maintaining the energy balance, interchange 
    schedules and system frequency). The Commission proposed, however, that 
    an RTO would not be required to be a single control area because of 
    concerns over potentially high costs and technical limitations. Instead 
    those proposing an RTO would be given flexibility in determining the 
    best division of functions between the RTO and any providers of other 
    control area functions if there are no other grid operators in its 
    region. However, the Commission insisted that an RTO must be ultimately 
    responsible for providing reliable and non-discriminatory transmission 
    service.373
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \371\ FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,734 and proposed 
    Sec. 35.34(i)(3). In the NOPR, we used the terms ``operational 
    authority'' and ``operational responsibility'' interchangeably. For 
    purposes of clarity and consistency, we will use only the term 
    ``operational authority'' to describe this function and have revised 
    the proposed regulatory text accordingly.
        \372\ FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,734 and proposed 
    Sec. 35.34(i)(3)(ii).
        \373\ Id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        With respect to the second question of how an RTO will perform its 
    functions, the Commission proposed that an RTO be given considerable 
    flexibility in determining whether it will control facilities directly, 
    delegate functions, or use a combination of these 
    methods.374 For example, we stated that an RTO proposal 
    could have the RTO operate a single control area, or establish a 
    master-satellite hierarchical control structure with one central and 
    multiple distributed control centers (in either case it could propose 
    to lease equipment and convert employees from existing control 
    centers).375 The Commission also proposed that the RTO must 
    submit a public report assessing its operational arrangements no later 
    than two years after it begins operations.376
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \374\ Id. and proposed Sec. 35.34(i)(3)(i).
        \375\ Id.
        \376\ Id. at 33,735.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments. Comments on the Functions an RTO Must Perform. Most 
    commenters agree that the RTO must have operational authority 
    377 for the transmission facilities under its 
    control.378 Some commenters claim that this authority is 
    necessary to prevent anticompetitive behavior by transmission 
    owners.379 Some commenters further contend that this 
    authority must extend to all facilities involved in wholesale 
    transactions so that the transmission owner does not retain control of 
    ``access ramps'' that happen to be at low (34kV or 69kV) voltage 
    levels.380 In contrast, some utilities express concern that 
    RTO authority over low voltage facilities will unnecessarily complicate 
    operations.381
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \377\ Operational authority refers to the authority to control 
    transmission facilities, either directly or through contractual 
    agreements with the entities that do have direct control. In 
    contrast, security coordination refers to real-time monitoring of 
    system conditions in order to anticipate potential reliability 
    problems, and directing and coordinating relief procedures to 
    respond to transmission loading problems.
        \378\ See, e.g., APPA, Cal ISO, Duke, East Texas Cooperatives, 
    Entergy, EPSA, First Rochdale, Georgia Transmission, Illinois 
    Commission, IMEA, ISO-NE, Michigan Commission, Minnesota Power, 
    Montana-Dakota, NASUCA, NECPUC, Nevada Commission, Mid-Atlantic 
    Commissions, PacifiCorp, PJM, PJM/NEPOOL Customers, SNWA, Southern 
    Company, SRP, SPRA, Tri-State, UtiliCorp, WPSC.
        \379\ See, e.g., Illinois Commission, IMEA, NASUCA, PJM/NEPOOL 
    Customers.
        \380\ See, e.g., First Rochdale, IMEA, UMPA.
        \381\ See, e.g., Montana-Dakota, Tacoma Power.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several commenters oppose operational authority over the 
    transmission system by the RTO. Some commenters claim that the 
    Commission does not have the legal authority to require transmission 
    owners to transfer control to any other entity.382 Midwest 
    Energy and SPP believe a transfer of authority would be too costly to 
    implement. Other commenters maintain that the owner and operator of the 
    transmission system must be the same entity in order to avoid liability 
    disputes.383 Mass Companies suggests that transmission 
    owners retain authority to ensure the safe and prudent management of 
    their facilities. ComEd suggests that transmission owners retain 
    operational authority with the RTO having oversight responsibility.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \382\ See, e.g., Florida Commission, Puget. It appears that the 
    Florida Commission interprets a transfer of operational control as a 
    transfer of retail dispatch authority. Although other commenters 
    such as WPSC support the RTO having operational authority, they 
    believe that the Commission may need legislative action to obtain 
    the authority to require such a transfer.
        \383\ See, e.g., Florida Power Corp., Georgia Transmission, JEA, 
    MidAmerican, Southern Company, Enron/APX/Coral Power.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commenters are divided whether the RTO should be required to be a 
    control area operator. The existing ISOs in California, New England and 
    PJM, which are all control area operators, report that this structure 
    is working in their regions. Some commenters express concern over 
    potential harm to competitive markets if control area authority is not 
    transferred to an independent entity.384 ICUA recommends 
    that the RTO be the sole control area operator. Many other commenters 
    support a single control area as the ultimate goal, but suggest that 
    the RTO be allowed to evolve to this structure and not be required to 
    consolidate control areas immediately.385 Other commenters 
    express concern about potential costs associated with control area 
    consolidation, but agree that such action would be acceptable if and 
    when the RTO decides it is necessary for reliability or other 
    reasons.386
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \384\ See, e.g., APPA, APS, Arkansas Consumers, NASUCA, NJBUS, 
    TDU Systems.
        \385\ See, e.g., Conlon, Illinois Commission, Los Angeles, First 
    Energy, Minnesota Power, SRP, TDU Systems.
        \386\ See, e.g., CP&L, ECAR, EEI, Entergy, EPSA, Southern 
    Company.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commenters that oppose requiring control area consolidation provide 
    a variety of reasons.387 Enron/APX/Coral Power state that 
    only an RTO that is a transco should perform control area functions. 
    The Florida Commission is concerned that control area consolidation may 
    result in a security risk. Tri-State and WEPCO believe that there are 
    higher priorities in RTO development (such as eliminating pancaking, 
    and promoting regional system planning) and that emphasizing control 
    area consolidation may inhibit RTO formation.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \387\ It appears that the Florida Commission and JEA believe 
    that such a transfer would involve RTO control of retail dispatch. 
    It also appears that Dynegy believes that the basic control area 
    function of frequency control is identical to dynamic scheduling, 
    which they believe should not be centralized or consolidated.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        With respect to specific control area functions, numerous 
    commenters discuss the need for an RTO to have some control of 
    generation in order to ensure system reliability, especially
    
    [[Page 866]]
    
    during emergency situations.388 Minnesota Power suggests 
    that the Commission include ``control generation as required to ensure 
    reliability'' as an additional minimum function in the final rule. It 
    also recommends that responsibility for area control error (ACE) and 
    automatic generation control (AGC) be transferred to the RTO as control 
    area functions because separating these functions from transmission 
    operations can lead to reliability problems. Other commenters request 
    that the balancing function be transferred to the RTO to prevent 
    discriminatory behavior by transmission owners.389
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \388\ See, e.g., NASUCA, First Energy, Otter Tail, PJM, PJM/
    NEPOOL Customers, Professor Hogan, Project Groups, SPRA, UtiliCorp, 
    Williams, WPPI. We also discuss below in more detail the issue of 
    congestion management as an RTO minimum function.
        \389\ See, e.g., East Texas Cooperatives, WPPI, Project Groups.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        There is widespread agreement among commenters that the RTO must be 
    the security coordinator. Marketers, utilities, existing ISOs and 
    customers all agree that coordination and reliability will be enhanced 
    if a regional organization is responsible for maintaining grid 
    security.390 Some commenters state that the authority of a 
    security coordinator to receive commercially sensitive information to 
    order the curtailment of transactions and the shedding of firm load 
    also grants it the ability to favor its own merchant functions. 
    Confidence in comparable and non-discriminatory transmission service, 
    therefore, will be improved if these functions are performed by an 
    entity that is independent of all market participants.391 
    Though essentially in support of our proposal, NERC and MidAmerican 
    assert that is not necessary to link each RTO to a single security 
    center, but rather it is possible to allow a single security 
    coordinator to assume responsibility for more than one RTO. NERC points 
    out that if an RTO performs all the characteristics and functions 
    specified in the NOPR, it will necessarily be a security coordinator.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \390\ See, e.g., Allegheny, APPA, APX, Cal ISO, ComEd, Dynegy, 
    East Texas Cooperatives, Enron/APX/Coral Power, Entergy, EPSA, LG&E, 
    Mass Companies, MidAmerican, Midwest Energy, Montana-Dakota, NASUCA, 
    NECPUC, NERC, NJBUS, PJM/NEPOOL Customers, PPC, Professor Hogan, 
    Seattle, South Carolina Authority, SPP, SRP, Tri-State, UtiliCorp, 
    Williams.
        \391\ See, e.g., LG&E, PJM/NEPOOL Customers, SPP, UtiliCorp. See 
    also supra section III.D.1 for a more detailed discussion of 
    independence as an RTO minimum characteristic.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A number of parties state that the RTO must have access to real-
    time system information in order to perform its functions as security 
    coordinator.392 Montana-Dakota explains further that 
    security centers, by definition, will be equipped with the hardware and 
    software required to assume basic operational control of the system, 
    which are beyond that required strictly for security functions.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \392\ See, e.g., Montana-Dakota, PJM/NEPOOL Customers, South 
    Carolina Authority, Williams.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Only two commenters express concern over the need for the RTO to be 
    the security coordinator. ComEd, though supporting some security 
    functions for the RTO, asserts that the RTO's role can be limited 
    simply to one of oversight. ComEd does not believe that the RTO needs 
    access to real-time data, and instead would allow the individual 
    control areas to perform the bulk of the security functions. The only 
    commenter that argues against making the RTO a security coordinator is 
    Avista, which states that the security coordinator in the Pacific 
    Northwest is already an independent body and has the authority 
    necessary for ensuring reliability; therefore, no changes are required.
        Comments on How an RTO Should Perform Its Functions. Overall, 
    commenters strongly agree with the Commission's proposal to permit 
    those proposing an RTO the authority to decide the type of control they 
    require: direct, functional or a combination. Some commenters believe 
    direct control is the best approach to prevent abuse of sensitive 
    information and better ensure reliability.393 However, 
    Manitoba Board and Canada DNR express concern that continued 
    coordination between U.S. and Canadian utilities might be undermined if 
    highly centralized systems are developed and controlled by U.S. 
    entities. A few commenters contend that it is best for the RTO to 
    delegate control authority.394 The majority of commenters 
    support some form of hierarchical control structure, where the RTO 
    would establish a master control center and direct the operations in 
    the existing geographically distributed control centers, which would 
    become satellite centers.395 PJM and ISO-NE indicate that 
    they both currently operate with a hierarchical control structure, 
    where the ISO control center is the master control room that directs 
    the actions of the satellite control centers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \393\ See, e.g., East Texas Cooperatives, First Rochdale, 
    Illinois Commission, PJM/NEPOOL Customers.
        \394\ See, e.g., MidAmerican, Seattle, South Carolina Authority.
        \395\ See, e.g., ECAR, Enron/APX/Coral Power, EPSA, East Texas 
    Cooperatives, First Rochdale, Industrial Consumers, ISO-NE, LG&E, 
    Los Angeles, Lincoln, MidAmerican, Montana-Dakota, NECPUC, NASUCA, 
    Otter Tail, PJM, PJM/NEPOOL Customers, Project Groups, Seattle, 
    South Carolina Authority, Tri-State. Many of these commenters 
    support eventual consolidation when any cost and technical barriers 
    are overcome and if the RTO decides it is necessary.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A number of supporters of the hierarchical structure specifically 
    request that the Commission ensure that the RTO has the authority to 
    direct all actions at the satellite control centers and that the 
    satellite centers will be independent in order to prevent 
    discriminatory transmission service and the transfer of commercially 
    valuable information to market participants.396 Montana-
    Dakota and Otter Tail believe a major benefit of the hierarchical 
    structure is improved emergency response and system security in a large 
    region if the RTO is coordinating and directing the actions of all 
    operators in the region. Finally, Enron/APX/Coral Power believe the 
    standardization of balancing practices for a large region is an 
    important benefit of a hierarchical system.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \396\ See, e.g., EAL, East Texas Cooperatives, ISO-NE, 
    Industrial Consumers, LG&E, NASUCA, PJM, PJM/NEPOOL Customers, 
    Powerex, Project Groups, Tri-State.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commission Conclusion. Which Functions Must an RTO Perform? We 
    reaffirm the determination proposed in the NOPR that an RTO must have 
    operational authority for all transmission facilities under its control 
    and also must be the security coordinator for its region. We recognize 
    that it is difficult to draw a precise line between transmission 
    control and generation control,397 and we also recognize 
    that given the changing nature of the industry, terminology such as 
    ``control area operator'' is undergoing definitional 
    changes.398 Accordingly, it is difficult to state precisely 
    what functions an RTO must have in order to have full operational 
    authority for transmission facilities. Moreover, our desire to allow 
    RTOs flexibility dissuades us from trying to be too precise. However, 
    certain concepts are basic and generally understood in the industry.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \397\ See NERC Operating Manual Policy 2 which can be found at 
    www.nerc.com. As we have stated before, the dividing line ``between 
    transmission control and generation control is not always clear 
    because both sets of functions are ultimately required for reliable 
    operation of the overall system.'' Midwest ISO, 84 FERC at 62,151. 
    The idea that the entity that controls the transmission system must 
    have some degree of control over some generation seems to be 
    generally recognized. See Docket No. ER98-1438-000 Applicants' 
    Response at 3.
        \398\ We note that the definition of a control area, and 
    consequently the functions that must be performed by a control area, 
    is currently being reexamined by the NERC Control Area Criteria Task 
    Force in an open forum. See NERC web page at www.nerc.com.
    
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [[Page 867]]
    
        One necessary aspect of operational authority as used here refers 
    to the authority to control transmission facilities. This includes, but 
    is not limited to, switching transmission elements into and out of 
    operation in the transmission system (e.g., transmission lines and 
    transformers), monitoring and controlling real and reactive power 
    flows, monitoring and controlling voltage levels, and scheduling and 
    operating reactive resources. Functions such as these must be included 
    within the operational authority of an RTO.
        We conclude, as proposed in the NOPR, that the RTO is also required 
    to be the NERC security coordinator for its region. The role of a 
    security coordinator is to ensure reliability in real-time operations 
    of the power system. As security coordinator, the RTO will assume 
    responsibility for: (1) performing load-flow and stability studies to 
    anticipate, identify and address security problems; (2) exchanging 
    security information with local and regional entities; (3) monitoring 
    real-time operating characteristics such as the availability of 
    reserves, actual power flows, interchange schedules, system frequency 
    and generation adequacy; and (4) directing actions to maintain 
    reliability, including firm load shedding.
        We believe that the RTO must be security coordinator for several 
    reasons. The functions of the security coordinator are enhanced when 
    they are performed over large regions. In addition, the independence of 
    the security coordinator is important for ensuring non-discriminatory 
    transmission service, and the RTO will have that independence. As we 
    stated in Midwest ISO:
    
        This role [the role of a security coordinator] is central to 
    maintaining grid reliability and non-discriminatory access. Under 
    proposed NERC policies, security coordinators would be required to 
    anticipate problems that could jeopardize the reliability of the 
    interconnected grid. In the course of performing these reliability 
    functions, the Security Coordinator would receive considerable 
    information which is commercially sensitive. Therefore, it is 
    important that the proposed Midwest ISO Security Coordinator be 
    performed by an entity that is independent of market 
    participants.\399\
    
        \399\ 84 FERC at 62,158.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        However, we will allow flexibility in how the RTO performs its 
    security coordinator functions. For example, an RTO may contract these 
    responsibilities out to an independent security coordinator if this is 
    justified. Also, this requirement does not prevent more than one RTO 
    from sharing a single security coordinator as suggested by NERC.
        As proposed in the NOPR, we will not at this time require the RTO 
    to operate what traditionally has been thought of as a single control 
    area for its region. However, the RTO must perform the control 
    functions required to satisfy the minimum characteristics and functions 
    in this Final Rule, including the transmission control and security 
    coordinator functions discussed above,\400\ in a non-discriminatory 
    manner for all market participants.\401\ We will permit those 
    developing an RTO proposal flexibility in deciding on the particular 
    division of operational responsibilities with existing control areas.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \400\ For example, several commenters state that an RTO must 
    have some authority over generation to ensure system reliability. 
    The RTO is required to have some authority as a minimum 
    characteristic, as discussed with respect to short-term reliability.
        \401\ In our order approving the Midwest ISO, we stated that our 
    approval of the ISO was based on the applicants' commitment that the 
    ISO would be able to ``take all actions necessary to provide 
    nondiscriminatory transmission service, promote and maintain 
    reliability.'' Midwest ISO, 84 FERC at 62,159.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We recognize that the feasibility of consolidating existing control 
    areas into a single such area may be limited by cost and technical 
    considerations. However, we note that physical consolidation may be 
    unnecessary when a hierarchical control structure is used to define a 
    single control area by making existing control areas subject to RTO 
    direction (and so avoiding the high costs and technical uncertainty 
    associated with centralization of physical control for a very large RTO 
    region). Hierarchical control is a form of power system control that 
    relies on a master-satellite control structure, which establishes a 
    single controlling authority without requiring the construction of a 
    single, consolidated control room. Existing control centers are not 
    replaced, but continue to operate, independent from market 
    participants, as satellite control centers reporting to the RTO master 
    control center. The RTO security center assumes the dual role of the 
    master control center and security center, with clear authority to 
    direct all actions at the satellite centers.\402\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \402\ See, e.g., Marija Ilic and Shell Liu, Hierarchical Power 
    System Control: Its Value in a Changing Industry, Springer-Verlag, 
    1996.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We conclude that each region should be free to decide if and when 
    the region will transition to a hierarchical control structure, 
    consolidate the control areas in its region, or adopt a different 
    control structure that best meets the region's needs.
        How Should the RTO Perform Its Functions? We conclude that those 
    designing the RTO should have flexibility to decide how it would 
    exercise its operational control authority. The RTO operate the 
    transmission system through direct physical operation by RTO employees, 
    contractual agreements with other entities (e.g., transmission owners 
    and control area operators) or implement a hierarchical control 
    structure involving a combination of direct and functional control. 
    Under these arrangements, the personnel of existing control centers 
    might become employees of the RTO or remain as employees of the control 
    center owner, while being supervised by RTO personnel. We will leave it 
    to the discretion of the region to decide on the combination of direct 
    and functional control that works best for its circumstances.\403\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \403\ This issue is also addressed in greater detail in our 
    discussion of the RTO's role as a provider of ancillary services as 
    an RTO minimum function.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        However, regardless of the method of control chosen, the RTO must 
    have clear authority to direct all actions that affect the facilities 
    under its control, including the decisions and actions taken at any 
    satellite control centers. The system of operational control chosen 
    must ensure reliable operation of the grid and non-discriminatory 
    access to the grid by all market participants. In addition, to ensure 
    that the RTO does not become locked into an operational system that is 
    unsatisfactory, the Commission will require the RTO to prepare a public 
    report that assesses the efficacy of its operational arrangements no 
    later than two years after it begins operations.
    4. Short-Term Reliability (Characteristic 4)
        The fourth proposed characteristic of an RTO is that it must have 
    exclusive authority for maintaining the short-term reliability of the 
    transmission grid under its control. In the NOPR we identified four 
    basic short-term reliability responsibilities of an RTO: (1) the RTO 
    must have exclusive authority for receiving, confirming and 
    implementing all interchange schedules; (2) the RTO must have the right 
    to order redispatch of any generator connected to transmission 
    facilities it operates if necessary for the reliable operation of these 
    facilities; (3) when the RTO operates transmission facilities owned by 
    other entities, the RTO must have authority to approve and disapprove 
    all requests for scheduled outages of transmission facilities to ensure 
    that the outages can be accommodated within established reliability 
    standards; and (4)
    
    [[Page 868]]
    
    if the RTO operates under reliability standards established by another 
    entity (e.g., a regional reliability council), the RTO must report to 
    the Commission if these standards hinder its ability to provide 
    reliable, non-discriminatory and efficiently priced transmission 
    service.\404\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \404\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,735.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments. General Comments. Commenters address both general 
    concerns about reliability as well as the four basic proposed short-
    term reliability responsibilities of an RTO. Most commenters generally 
    agree that the RTO should have the responsibility for short term-
    reliability.\405\ Several commenters raise questions regarding 
    definition and scope of ``short-term'' reliability. TEP requests that 
    the Commission further define the time period involved. It suggests 
    that designating a specific time period (whether one month, six months 
    or a year) would be beneficial to evaluating this characteristic. 
    Enron/APX/Coral Power requests that the Commission make clear that 
    ``short-term'' is intended to mean ``real-time.''
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \405\ See, e.g., American Forest, Cal ISO, California Board, 
    Cinergy, CMUA, CSU, EAL, Enron/APX/Coral Power, Entergy, EPSA, 
    Industrial Customers, NASUCA, NECPUC, PJM, PNGC, SMUD, UtiliCorp, 
    H.Q. Energy Services, Mass Companies, Mid-Atlantic Commissions, 
    MidWest Energy, Minnesota Commission, NY ISO, PacifiCorp, PG&E, 
    Williams, WPSC.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        While agreeing that the RTO should be given ultimate control over 
    facilities necessary to preserve reliability, SMUD expresses concern 
    that the RTO should not be encumbered with responsibility for 
    facilities that do not serve a regional transmission function. TANC 
    requests that the RTO's responsibility over reliability not infringe on 
    the management responsibilities of local regulatory authorities or 
    interfere with the management and operation of the local system 
    facilities of a utility distribution company.
        PG&E requests that the Commission require that the RTO rely 
    primarily on market mechanisms to maintain reliability. However, PJM/
    NEPOOL Customers urge the Commission to ensure that the RTO's actions 
    in maintaining the short-term reliability of the grid do not 
    unreasonably impinge on the freedom of business decisions inherent in a 
    competitive supply market. Several commenters, such as San Francisco 
    and Minnesota Commission, state that because the primary function of a 
    RTO is ensuring short-term reliability, it should be more clearly 
    defined and should not be compromised by any other RTO market 
    functions.
        PJM suggests that the Commission grant additional authorities to 
    the RTO to ensure reliability, including the authority to (1) collect 
    information, (2) direct operations in the control area, (3) assure that 
    those it directs will respond in a predictable manner (which the RTO 
    can achieve through training and drills) and (4) declare an emergency, 
    direct emergency operations, and determine when emergency conditions 
    have ended.
        Southern Company notes that the industry has little, if any, 
    experience in granting a new entity control over the operations of a 
    transmission system that encompasses a broad, multi-state region.\406\ 
    It claims that transmission owners and State commissions must be 
    assured that the RTO is capable of operating a regional transmission 
    system reliably before an RTO is formed. New York Commission indicates 
    that the authority of States to require the maintenance of electric 
    system reliability should be recognized in establishing 
    responsibilities. Iowa Board believes that there is a need for greater 
    regional development of reliability standards to reflect regional needs 
    and conditions. It requests that State commissions be involved in the 
    decisionmaking process of an RTO to ensure that electric facilities are 
    properly sized and located and that additions are not detrimental to 
    the reliability of the grid.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \406\ Southern Company notes that the California and ERCOT ISOs 
    operate within the boundaries of a single state. In PJM, New York 
    and New England, the control of the grid remains remarkably 
    unchanged because the ISOs in those regions were already operating 
    the system on behalf of the transmission owners and adopted the 
    institutions and infrastructures of an ISO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments on Interchange Scheduling. The Commission proposed that, 
    in the context of the RTO's role as the recipient and evaluator of all 
    requests for transmission service under its own FERC-approved tariff, 
    an RTO that is a control area operator must also receive, confirm, and 
    implement all interchange schedules between adjacent control 
    areas.\407\ The Commission expressed concern that non-RTO control area 
    operators would receive commercially sensitive information involving 
    its competitors in implementing interchange schedules and questioned 
    whether there is any Commission action, other than its current code of 
    conduct standards, and short of requiring consolidation of all control 
    areas within a region, which could address this concern.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \407\ FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,735-36.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several commenters agree that the RTO should have authority over 
    receiving, confirming and implementing all interchange schedules.\408\ 
    PJM believes that an independent ISO is in the best position to 
    exercise the scheduling authority of an RTO. It suggests that an RTO 
    that is independent of commercial interests in the market does not face 
    the commercial information problem because it does not compete with 
    market participants and consequently would make scheduling decisions in 
    an unbiased and fair manner.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \408\ See, e.g., Cal ISO, CMUA, Entergy, Mass Companies, NECPUC, 
    Nevada Commission, PJM/NEPOOL Customers, PJM, SMUD, Southern 
    Company, WPSC, PG&E.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        PJM/NEPOOL Customers claims that interchange scheduling oversight 
    must be performed by an independent entity because it would be neither 
    possible nor desirable for a non-RTO control area operator to perform 
    this function without access to commercially sensitive information. It 
    suggests that the RTO maintain direct control over interchange 
    scheduling either by using RTO employees or a master satellite 
    arrangement where ultimate responsibility remains in the RTO master 
    control area operating room. APX suggests that requiring a contractor 
    (acceptable to the RTO and the control area operator) to operate the 
    control area operator facility could help address this concern.
        Enron/APX/Coral Power believes that the risk is eliminated if 
    transmission operations, including control-area operations, are 
    operationally separated from the load and generation of vertically-
    integrated utilities. Barring such complete separation, this risk could 
    nevertheless be substantially obviated if the RTO provided control area 
    operators with information only about scheduled net interchanges 
    between control areas without disclosing the individual transactions 
    making up the new schedules.\409\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \409\ See also Southern Company.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        However, other commenters contend that control area operators will 
    continue to need information on individual transactions in order to 
    implement interchange schedules and to ensure real-time 
    reliability.\410\ Desert STAR believes that work should be done in this 
    area to determine what information is required by control area 
    operators and when they must receive it in order to carry out their 
    reliability responsibilities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \410\ See, e.g., Duke, Florida Power Corp.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Florida Commission states that this issue has already been resolved 
    within the Florida Reliability Coordinating Council (FRCC) by requiring 
    all entities who operate control areas within the
    
    [[Page 869]]
    
    region that require access to commercially sensitive information to 
    sign agreements that separate reliability personnel and the relevant 
    information from their wholesale merchant personnel.
        Several commenters, such as Duke and Florida Power Corp., state 
    that no additional Commission action is necessary. These commenters 
    believe that the existing code of conduct standards are working and the 
    reciprocity provisions of Order No. 888 provide for compliance with the 
    code of conduct standards by all non-public utility control area 
    operators. Florida Power Corp. also notes that within the FRCC, all 
    entities operating control areas are required to sign agreements 
    verifying functional separation.
        Comments on Generation Redispatch. In the NOPR, the Commission 
    proposed that the RTO's reliability authority include the ability to 
    order redispatch of any generator connected to the transmission grid 
    when necessary for the reliability of the grid. However, the RTO would 
    have no authority over initial unit commitment and normal dispatch 
    decisions.\411\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \411\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,736.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several commenters agree that the RTO have some authority to order 
    redispatch when necessary to maintain the reliability of the grid.\412\ 
    Sithe, however, believes that, in the evolving competitive marketplace, 
    redispatch authority alone is insufficient. It argues that the RTO 
    should also provide appropriate incentives to the owners of assets that 
    are needed for reliability to maintain those assets and make them 
    available for operation in constrained areas. Sithe urges the 
    Commission to consider adopting a final rule that provides RTOs with 
    sufficient commercial authority, ``including the necessary financial 
    resources'' to enter into market-rate business arrangements, that 
    assure availability of assets needed for reliability. Sithe states that 
    without this authority, the RTO may not have sufficient tools to fully 
    ensure reliability, because must-run generators would have little 
    incentive to continue to operate in constrained areas.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \412\ See, e.g., Cal ISO, Cinergy, CMUA, NECPUC, PJM, UtiliCorp, 
    Entergy, Allegheny, LG&E, Lincoln, Metropolitan, Minnesota Power, 
    Nevada Commission, Otter Tail, Southern Company, TDU Systems, 
    NASUCA, Reliant, Mass Companies, TAPS.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        CMUA maintains that it is insufficient to vest authority in the RTO 
    to maintain short-term reliability without also vesting enforcement 
    powers to ensure compliance with RTO dispatch instructions. Allegheny 
    and other commenters agree that RTOs should be able to direct 
    redispatch, particularly if the redispatch is accomplished under a 
    market-based compensation scheme as a part of transmission service 
    pricing methodology that uses the redispatch costs to set marginal 
    system use costs. However, they argue that in no case should the RTO be 
    able to direct generation redispatch unless the generator is 
    compensated at market value (unless market power issues are 
    involved).413
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \413\ See, e.g., Cinergy, Chelan, Southern Company, LG&E, 
    Reliant.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Avista expresses serious concern with the breadth of a redispatch 
    requirement. It believes that the right to order redispatch of 
    generation should be negotiated among the parties in the region without 
    a presumption that the RTO must have broad redispatch authority, except 
    in emergency circumstances. Avista and others note that a negotiated 
    approach is particularly important to operators of hydroelectric 
    resources which are subject to numerous environmental and operating 
    restrictions that limit their ability to redispatch.414 
    Avista and SMUD request that the Commission clarify that the RTO's 
    authority to redispatch is limited to emergency circumstances affecting 
    reliability.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \414\ See, e.g., CMUA.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Chelan believes that RTOs should be required to enter into arm's-
    length agreements with those generators that are willing to service 
    redispatch requests, and compensate those generators for supplying this 
    service. RTOs should not be allowed to unilaterally redispatch a 
    generating unit without the generator's consent, and without 
    compensation.
        Commenters, such as Cal ISO and Nevada Commission, suggest that the 
    Commission require reliability-related services (i.e. redispatch) be 
    provided to RTOs under a set of uniform rates, terms and conditions. 
    Such a requirement would reduce the Commission's administrative burden 
    of contracts governed by different sets of terms and conditions.
        EME believes that the RTO's control over dispatch of generation 
    should be carefully circumscribed. It recommends that reliability 
    functions be internalized into explicit procedures for congestion 
    pricing. It states that in most cases proper pricing signals can 
    provide sufficient incentives for generators to schedule operation of 
    their facilities to ensure system reliability.
        Industrial Consumers states that the RTO's redispatch decisions 
    regarding ``any generator'' must be qualified to excuse on-site 
    generators that serve an industrial load, especially those that serve a 
    critical steam host. For environmental, safety and economic reasons, 
    these units should not be forced to redispatch except as a last resort 
    option.
        Metropolitan supports an RTO having authority to order redispatch 
    of any generating unit when necessary for the reliability of the grid. 
    However, ``reliability'' must be carefully defined to avoid RTO 
    interference with normal market operations by redispatching generation 
    for its own convenience, or to alleviate adverse market 
    conditions.415
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \415\ Metropolitan believes the Cal ISO's definition of system 
    emergency appropriately describes the circumstances in which 
    redispatch may be appropriate. A ``system emergency'' is described 
    as ``any abnormal system condition which requires immediate manual 
    or automatic action to prevent loss of load, equipment damage or 
    tripping of system elements which might result in cascading outages 
    or to restore system operation to meet the minimum operating 
    reliability criteria.''
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several commenters oppose the proposal to allow the RTO to 
    redispatch generation.416 PG&E believes that the proposal 
    would give too much latitude to RTOs and create an incentive to impose 
    centrally determined fixes on market operations, rather than allowing 
    market mechanisms to self-correct. Therefore, PG&E argues that RTOs 
    should be allowed to redispatch generation facilities only when there 
    is a true reliability emergency as specified in the RTO tariff. 
    Moreover, RTOs should be able to redispatch only those units that have 
    actually participated in the market.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \416\ See, e.g., PG&E, Southern Company, Reliant, SMUD.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        PJM/NEPOOL Customers believes that the authority as proposed in the 
    NOPR is too broad and must be further defined. It requests that the 
    Commission ensure that this authority is exercised only during only the 
    most serious circumstances when grid reliability is truly in danger. It 
    suggests that the Commission promulgate or pre-approve reliability 
    standards for determining when the RTO can order redispatch of 
    generators, the amount of generation assets that the RTO will have 
    authority over and standards for the redispatch order. Southern Company 
    recommends that the Commission provide only general guidance concerning 
    redispatch and allow the regions to develop more specific procedures.
        When considering allowing an RTO to redispatch a Federal 
    hydroelectric generator, SPRA emphasizes that the Commission must 
    recognize that individual Federal hydroelectric generators are under 
    the control of either the Corps, the Bureau of
    
    [[Page 870]]
    
    Reclamation or the International Boundary Waters Commission, not the 
    PMA. While a PMA may belong to an RTO, it is unlikely that other 
    Federal agencies will. The Commission must give careful consideration 
    to determine that RTO redispatch authority does not prohibit or limit a 
    PMA's ability to fulfill its statutory obligations.
        Comments on Transmission Maintenance Scheduling. In the NOPR, the 
    Commission proposed that an RTO which operates transmission facilities 
    owned by other entities be authorized to approve or disapprove all 
    requests for scheduled outages of transmission facilities in order to 
    ensure that maintenance outage schedules meet applicable reliability 
    standards.417
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \417\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,736-37.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission requested comments on a number of issues related to 
    this proposed requirement: Does it cede too much or too little 
    authority to the RTO? If the RTO requires a transmission owner to 
    reschedule its planned maintenance, should the transmission owner be 
    compensated for any costs created by the required rescheduling? Would 
    it be feasible to create a market mechanism to induce transmission 
    owners to plan their maintenance so as to minimize reliability effects? 
    Should an RTO that is an ISO have any authority to require rescheduling 
    of maintenance if it anticipates that the planned maintenance schedule 
    will adversely affect power markets? If the RTO is a transco, can it 
    manipulate its transmission maintenance schedules in a manner that 
    harms competition?
        The Commission stated that the RTO's regional perspective will 
    allow it to coordinate individual maintenance schedules with each other 
    as well as with expected seasonal system demand variations. Because the 
    RTO will have access to extensive information, it will see the ``big 
    picture'' and be able to make more accurate assessments of the 
    reliability effect of proposed maintenance schedules than individual, 
    sub-regional transmission owners.
        Commenters address essentially three issues related to transmission 
    maintenance scheduling: the RTO's authority; appropriate compensation; 
    and use of market mechanisms.
        RTO Authority to Schedule Transmission Maintenance. Many commenters 
    support giving an RTO authority over transmission maintenance 
    scheduling.418 Duke, however, believes that an enforcement 
    mechanism may also be needed. First Rochdale recommends that 
    transmission owners be given the right to protest an RTO's actions to 
    the Commission. Reliant, however, opposes RTO authority over 
    maintenance scheduling, arguing that transmission maintenance decisions 
    must reside with transmission facility owners.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \418\ See, e.g., Cal ISO, NECPUC, PJM, Desert STAR, Entergy, 
    PGE, Allegheny, Avista, LG&E, Lincoln, Tri-State, WPSC, CRC, Duke, 
    EAL, First Rochdale, Industrial Consumers, ISO-NE, Metropolitan, 
    Montana-Dakota, NASUCA, New Smyrna Beach, NYPP, Oneok, PG&E, 
    Southern Company, SRP, Turlock, WPPI, Florida Power Corp., Nevada 
    Commission.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Seattle and NYPP suggest that the Commission define an RTO role 
    only for scheduling facility outages that are clearly associated with 
    the regional transmission network because internal subtransmission and 
    radial transmission facilities do not have regional significance. 
    Turlock supports restricting the RTO's authority to the grid it manages 
    to prevent its outage scheduling authority extending beyond the grid 
    for which it is responsible. On the other hand, TDU Systems claims that 
    an RTO should also coordinate maintenance of interconnected 
    distribution facilities that are not under its control, if maintenance 
    on those facilities would adversely affect RTO operations.
        Duke suggests that with the creation of an RTO that is not a 
    transco, a set of governing principles for outage coordination should 
    be established. The parties should agree on the timing of requests for 
    planned maintenance and the timing of responses to those requests. If 
    for any reason, other than the gross negligence of the transmission 
    owner, a scheduled maintenance outage was determined to be a problem 
    after an agreement is reached, rescheduling the outage would require 
    the mutual consent of the transmission owner and the RTO.
        EAL recommends that appropriate contracts with existing 
    transmission facility owners that ensure the continued reliable 
    operation of the grid are required. Principal elements of such 
    contracts would include standards of service, provisions for 
    information sharing and reporting, maintenance scheduling, transmission 
    facility ratings, testing and performance expectations. Maintenance 
    scheduling should include provisions for maintenance deferral under 
    instructions from the RTO if required for system security reasons only.
        NYPP states that arrangements for outages should be made well in 
    advance of the outage start date because RTO approval of proposed 
    schedules could become the critical path. If approval is delayed, or 
    subsequently revoked, the transmission owner will incur significant 
    expenses that should be reimbursed.
        Montana-Dakota suggests that the effects of rescheduling can be 
    decreased by having the RTO review and approve all transmission 
    maintenance schedules on a weekly, monthly and quarterly basis. After 
    reviewing the transfer capability and market effects of the proposed 
    outage, the RTO should communicate the need to reschedule to the 
    transmission owner far enough in advance of the planned outage to allow 
    the owner to reschedule, possibly to avoid any cost impact. Montana-
    Dakota notes, however, that the closer the date of the outage, the 
    higher the probability of an economic impact.
        Southern Company requests that the Commission clarify that once an 
    RTO approves a scheduled outage, it should be allowed to change that 
    schedule only if implementing the plan would compromise system 
    integrity or reliability.
        Seattle believes that the NOPR fails to provide adequate assurances 
    to transmission owners that a timely maintenance schedule will be 
    adopted by the RTO. The RTO must establish timely dates certain for 
    maintenance outage requests from operating entities. To do this the RTO 
    must adequately balance safety considerations, and the cost of 
    deferring maintenance with commercial impact. For these reasons, an RTO 
    should not be permitted to arbitrarily postpone required maintenance.
        Compensation. Nearly all of the commenters believe that 
    transmission owners should be compensated in some form if they are 
    required by an RTO to reschedule maintenance.419 Avista 
    argues that the transmission owners' shareholders should not bear the 
    burden of decisions made by an independent body that result in reduced 
    revenues or increased costs for the transmission owner.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \419\ See, e.g., PJM, TANC, WPSC, Avista, Lincoln, CRC, Duke, 
    Metropolitan, Minnesota Power, Montana-Dakota, NASUCA, NPRB, NYPP, 
    PJM/NEPOOL Customers, Reliant, TDU Systems, Turlock, Florida Power 
    Corp., Reliant, Desert STAR, Southern Company.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Metropolitan states that if an RTO requests a transmission owner to 
    reschedule planned maintenance for reliability concerns, a transmission 
    owner should be compensated only for its direct costs necessarily and 
    reasonably incurred in complying with the RTO's request. Direct costs 
    may include, for example, increased labor or equipment expenses arising 
    from the rescheduled maintenance. However, Metropolitan does not 
    believe a transmission owner should recover lost
    
    [[Page 871]]
    
    opportunity costs arising from the rescheduled maintenance because 
    opportunity costs are uncertain and speculative.
        Southern Company argues that, if an RTO requires a transmission 
    owner to reschedule a previously approved outage, the RTO should 
    compensate the transmission owner for any additional costs caused by 
    the rescheduling.
        NASUCA believes that the RTO should compensate transmission or 
    generation owners only to the extent that incremental costs are 
    incurred due to the rescheduling of outages. NASUCA argues that it is 
    unlikely that owners would incur significant incremental costs, 
    especially for transmission outages.
        Some commenters such as PGE and Minnesota Power state that if an 
    RTO requires a transmission owner to reschedule its planned maintenance 
    for reliability reasons in an emergency situation, the RTO should not 
    be required to compensate the transmission owner. However, if an RTO 
    requires a transmission owner to reschedule its planned maintenance for 
    economic reasons, the RTO should be required to compensate the 
    transmission owner for liquidated damages.
        Other commenters such as Tri-State and Cal ISO oppose transmission 
    owners being compensated for the rescheduling of maintenance work. Cal 
    ISO states that, where an RTO properly exercises such authority by 
    requiring a transmission owner to reschedule a maintenance outage, that 
    transmission owner is not entitled to compensation for the costs 
    associated with rescheduling. Tri-State recommends factoring any 
    additional expense into the revenue requirement that the transmission 
    owner receives from the RTO.
        Market Mechanisms. PJM/NEPOOL Customers suggests that the RTO enact 
    a compensation mechanism in transmission outage rescheduling situations 
    or propose to use a market mechanism to encourage transmission owners 
    to plan maintenance so as to minimize reliability effects. Minnesota 
    Power, however, argues that maintenance rescheduling to benefit power 
    markets is analogous to generation redispatch and should be paid for by 
    the benefitting market participants.
        Montana-Dakota believes that an RTO should have the authority to 
    reschedule maintenance for market effects if there is an incremental 
    cost reimbursement mechanism in place that would provide an incentive 
    to the transmission owner to change maintenance schedules to benefit 
    the market.
        Metropolitan argues that an RTO with authority to unilaterally 
    reschedule transmission maintenance for market considerations could 
    have a destabilizing effect on the power market. Emerging markets 
    require predictability to thrive, and therefore RTOs should interfere 
    in market operations only when necessary to address reliability 
    concerns.
        Florida Power Corp. suggests that, while it may be feasible to 
    develop a market mechanism to induce transmission owners to plan their 
    maintenance to minimize reliability effects, it would be far simpler to 
    retain the existing structure in which a single entity both owns and 
    operates the transmission system. When ownership and operation are 
    combined, a single entity is responsible for both reliability and 
    maintenance, and thus has a natural incentive to seek an optimal 
    balance between these activities. Thus, Florida Power Corp. opposes 
    RTOs having authority to reschedule maintenance to manage the 
    performance of the market.
        Turlock also does not believe an RTO should have authority to make 
    transmission outage decisions based on market considerations. Turlock, 
    as well as Desert STAR and CRC, believe instead that consideration 
    should be given to motivating transmission owners to appropriately 
    schedule their maintenance outages, to minimize impacts on competitive 
    markets.
        Comments Generation Maintenance Scheduling. The short-term 
    reliability characteristic, as proposed in the NOPR, would not give an 
    RTO authority over proposed generation maintenance outage schedules. 
    However, the Commission noted that some generation control is necessary 
    for reliable operation of a transmission system. The Commission asked 
    whether an RTO should have some authority over generation maintenance 
    schedules and, if so, how much.420
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \420\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,737.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The majority of commenters support an RTO having at least some 
    authority over generation maintenance schedules.\421\ However, most 
    commenters suggest limiting the RTO's authority. Some commenters 
    suggest that an RTO have authority only for generating units that are 
    ``must-run'' or that the RTO has under contract due to the requirement 
    to maintain system reliability.\422\ Desert STAR believes that an RTO 
    should not attempt to manipulate the commercial power market when 
    reliability is not affected.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \421\ See, e.g., Cinergy, NECPUC, PJM, Desert STAR, WPSC, Cal 
    ISO, EAL, Industrial Consumers, ISO-NE, Turlock, Florida Power 
    Corp., Metropolitan, Minnesota Power, Montana-Dakota, NASUCA, Nevada 
    Commission, NYPP, PSNM, TDU Systems.
        \422\ See, e.g., Desert STAR, Metropolitan, Turlock, Florida 
    Power Corp., PSNM, NYPP.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Cinergy supports an RTO having the ability to request changes to a 
    schedule to serve reliability needs, coordinate transmission outages, 
    and maximize grid efficiency to increase ATC for transmission 
    customers' use, so long as generators receive compensation at market-
    based prices for missed market opportunities. Other commenters agree 
    that an RTO should compensate the generation owner if a schedule change 
    is necessary.\423\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \423\ See, e.g., WPSC, LG&E, Montana-Dakota.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A few commenters claim that the RTO should not have any authority 
    over generation maintenance schedules.\424\ SPRA states that requiring 
    such authority would discourage or prevent participation by PMAs 
    because other Federal agencies own the hydroelectric plants that 
    generate the power marketed by the PMAs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \424\ See, e.g., Duke, PJM/NEPOOL Customers, SPRA, Tri-State, 
    Empire District.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Tri-State does not believe that an RTO should have approval 
    authority over generation maintenance outages because these outages are 
    driven by the cost considerations associated with generation plant 
    equipment replacement or rehabilitation. However, Tri-State agrees that 
    an RTO must have advance knowledge of the scheduled generation outages 
    in order to assure transmission system reliability and adequacy of 
    reserves. Other commenters concur with a notification requirement.\425\ 
    Cinergy notes, however, that while it believes a generator may be 
    required to submit its maintenance schedule to an RTO, the RTO should 
    be prohibited from sharing that information with any other market 
    participants, or affiliates of market participants.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \425\ See, e.g., Enron/APX/Coral Power, FirstEnergy, Mass 
    Companies, Metropolitan.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments on Performance Standards. In the NOPR, the Commission 
    discussed the establishment of performance standards by an RTO for 
    transmission facilities under its direct or contractual control.\426\ 
    For example, an RTO could establish a standard that identifies specific 
    performance targets for planned and unplanned outages of facilities. 
    The Commission requested comments on whether a non-profit ISO could 
    establish incentive schemes for the transmission owners whose 
    facilities it operates.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \426\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,737.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        PJM believes that an RTO will be capable of developing performance
    
    [[Page 872]]
    
    standards and incentives to encourage transmission owners and 
    generators to operate and maintain reliable facilities. It states that 
    market participants cooperatively can create market-oriented incentives 
    to maintain their transmission and generation facilities 
    effectively.\427\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \427\ See also LG&E.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Duke also believes that incentive schemes can be developed. It 
    suggests that the revenues collected from users by the RTO could be 
    returned to transmission owners according to a prearranged formula that 
    incorporates quality standards for reliability. Thus, the revenue 
    allocation would reflect transmission owner performance in providing a 
    reliable system.
        PSE&G believes that RTOs will, and should, be able to offer 
    incentives to participants to ensure that reliability standards are not 
    only met but exceeded. It states that a mechanism of linking payment 
    with performance, measured against accepted benchmarks, has worked well 
    for many years in PJM.
        EAL states that appropriate contracts with existing transmission 
    facility owners that ensure the continued reliable operation of the 
    grid are required. It suggests that these contracts include standards 
    of service, provisions for information sharing and reporting, 
    maintenance scheduling, transmission facility ratings, testing and 
    performance expectations.
        Industrial Consumers believes that an RTO could establish 
    performance standards for transmission facilities that takes into 
    account the ``reliability'' of each facility. It argues that a facility 
    that has frequent unplanned outages should not receive the same 
    compensation as a facility whose availability is more reliable. It 
    suggests that a transmission owner be precluded from recovering fixed 
    costs during periods of unplanned outages that exceed some minimum 
    threshold based on superior performance.
        Cal ISO indicates that its tariff provides for the implementation 
    of maintenance standards, and penalties under those standards, to 
    ensure both adequate maintenance and system reliability. These 
    provisions act in concert with the California ISO's authority to 
    coordinate and approve maintenance outages.
        Southern Company believes that the establishment of performance 
    standards for transmission facilities controlled by an RTO is 
    misplaced. Transmission owners plan and operate their transmission 
    systems according to NERC and regional reliability standards, as well 
    as State legal and regulatory requirements. Thus, while Southern 
    Company doesn't claim that performance-based incentives are 
    inappropriate, it points out that there already are existing standards 
    to ensure reliable system operations.
        Comments on Facility Ratings and Operating Ranges. Reliable 
    operation of the transmission system in the short-term requires both 
    continuous monitoring of equipment availability and loading, and 
    actions to maintain loading levels within the established operating 
    ranges and equipment ratings. The NOPR suggested that RTOs are best 
    situated to establish ratings and operating ranges for two reasons. 
    First, they will have the most complete information about expected and 
    real-time operating conditions. Second, RTOs will be trusted because 
    they will not have any economic interests in electricity market 
    outcomes and they will not be owned or controlled by any market 
    participants. The Commission proposed to let RTO established equipment 
    ratings prevail in a dispute with a transmission owner pending the 
    outcome of a dispute resolution process.\428\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \428\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,737-38.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Nearly all commenters that address this issue oppose the NOPR 
    proposal. South Carolina Authority urges the Commission to proceed with 
    caution to prevent avoidable damage to persons or property. SRP argues 
    that ratings and operating ranges influence the useful life and 
    maintenance cost of equipment, as well as the level of service to the 
    end-use customer, and notes that each transmission owner has a 
    legitimate interest in the ratings. SRP believes that the ideal 
    situation would be to establish ratings by mutual consent of the 
    transmission owner and RTO. If they cannot agree, the issue should go 
    to dispute resolution.
        NYPP and Mass Companies oppose this proposal because transmission 
    owners have the fiduciary responsibility to protect their assets. 
    Furthermore, they state that the rating of equipment necessarily 
    requires a particularized knowledge of the equipment and related 
    facilities that is unlikely to be possessed by the RTO.
        Metropolitan believes that a well-established reliability 
    organization is best suited for establishing maximum transmission line 
    ratings that can be sustained over most of the hours in a year because 
    it will include the cooperation of technical groups representing all 
    systems, not just those under RTO control. It sees no benefit from 
    moving this responsibility to RTOs when the reliability councils have 
    historically performed this function with a minimum of controversy. EAL 
    suggests that since the owner of the transmission facility assumes the 
    equipment, personnel and public risks for the operation of its 
    equipment, the RTO could fulfill an audit role to ensure that facility 
    ratings by the owners follow industry norms.
        Seattle suggests that the Commission instruct RTOs to work 
    cooperatively with facility owners, since ratings on most power 
    transmission equipment are a function of age and past usage, and a new 
    entity will not have such historical information.
        Southern Company states that transmission owners have 
    responsibilities to their shareholders and State commissions to operate 
    their equipment safely and reliably. SPRA believes that this proposal 
    has the potential to create significant liability risks for the United 
    States.
        Entergy believes that a transco has an advantage at performing this 
    function because it will have the natural incentive to maintain the 
    highest and safest ratings for the transmission facilities since it 
    will be solely and directly responsible for the risks and rewards of 
    equipment ratings.
        Comments on Liability for Actions. Given that an RTO has 
    responsibility for system reliability, the NOPR requested comments on 
    the appropriate extent of an RTO's liability for its actions, and 
    whether RTO facility ownership changes this determination.\429\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \429\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,738.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Most commenters believe that liability must be linked to the entity 
    operating and controlling the transmission assets. Several commenters 
    recommend that all RTO governing documents and operating agreements 
    clearly establish the RTO's liability for any facilities that it 
    operates but does not own.\430\ SRP recommends that the Commission not 
    set a hard and fast rule, but rather give deference to assignments of 
    liability worked out between the RTO and the transmission owner in the 
    course of negotiating an operating agreement.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \430\ See, e.g., Seattle, PGE, Desert STAR, PSNM, South Carolina 
    Authority.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Salomon Smith Barney believes that an RTO should be paid to run the 
    network, and should suffer the consequences if it is not run well. 
    Given this reasoning, it believes that an RTO requires sufficient 
    capital to bear the risk, and that it operates under a regulatory 
    scheme that acknowledges that higher risk taking requires a higher 
    return.
        Other commenters focus on how to apportion liability. Several 
    commenters
    
    [[Page 873]]
    
    suggest that the governing standard for liability for a particular 
    activity should be the same standard that the Commission has approved 
    for comparable ISO conduct. Thus, for example, the RTO would be subject 
    to liability only on account of its reliability activities when damage 
    caused by its actions is found to be the result of gross negligence or 
    intentional misconduct.\431\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \431\ See, e.g., NY ISO, Cal ISO, Nevada Commission, New York 
    Commission.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Other commenters believe that, if the RTO assumes authority to 
    ensure proper maintenance and reliability of the system, it should 
    assume that role fully (i.e., assume liability for its decisions) and 
    it should hold transmission owners harmless for any increased cost 
    responsibility.\432\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \432\ See, e.g., Avista, Minnesota Power, SPRA, MidAmerican, 
    Florida Power Corp.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Tri-State believes that an RTO should not be held liable for the 
    inevitable errors and omissions that will occur during transmission 
    system operations except in the instance of gross negligence. It 
    believes that without some form of indemnification, the RTO could be 
    the target of numerous lawsuits alleging financial harm as a result of 
    RTO actions.
        TANC believes that the RTO should be held liable for the 
    consequential damages resulting from the RTO's instructions, if damage 
    is caused to the transmission owners facilities as a result of the RTO 
    requiring a transmission owner to operate its facilities in a manner 
    that is inconsistent with prudent utility practice.
        Comments on Reliability Standards. In the NOPR, the Commission 
    expressed a potential concern regarding an RTO's implementation of 
    reliability standards that are established by another entity. The 
    Commission identified two specific concerns: (1) regional or sub-
    regional reliability groups may not be as independent from market 
    participants as RTOs; and (2) almost every reliability standard will 
    have a commercial consequence. The NOPR proposed to require an RTO to 
    notify the Commission immediately if implementation of externally 
    established reliability standards will prevent it from meeting its 
    obligation to provide reliable, non-discriminatory transmission 
    service.\433\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \433\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,738-39.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Most commenters generally support the proposal in the NOPR, 
    although a few commenters believe that the NOPR proposal does not go 
    far enough. On the other hand, some commenters seek clarification or 
    oppose the NOPR proposal; most commenters that oppose the NOPR proposal 
    believe that RTOs must be subordinate to national or regional 
    reliability groups.
        PJM/NEPOOL Customers and other commenters agree that the RTO is an 
    appropriate institution to evaluate whether other rules and 
    requirements are impacting its ability to perform its function and to 
    inform the Commission of this fact.\434\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \434\ See, e.g., Entergy, NECPUC, NASUCA.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        PSE&G requests that the Commission clarify in its Final Rule that 
    RTOs, not reliability trade associations, will have primary 
    responsibility for resolving reliability issues in the future. It 
    suggests that reliability trade associations can continue to play a 
    role in developing reliability standards to be incorporated into RTO 
    tariffs; these standards would then be implemented by the RTOs and 
    ultimately enforced by the FERC. The standards, however, must be 
    developed through a fair and open consensus process, such as the 
    American National Standards Institute (ANSI) process.
        EPSA believes that reliability standards should be uniform 
    throughout the United States. Reliability standards should be 
    established at the national level through an industrywide 
    representative organization, subject to review and approval by the 
    Commission. Reliability rules should deviate regionally only if 
    necessary to reflect specific operating conditions that are unique to a 
    particular region. EPSA requests that existing reliability rules be 
    considered carefully by the RTO, and reviewed by the Commission, as to 
    their function and importance. EPSA and other commenters suggest that 
    RTOs replace existing regional reliability councils as the entity 
    responsible for maintaining compliance with nationally established 
    reliability standards.\435\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \435\ See, e.g., Cal ISO, Duquesne, Nevada Commission, Statoil.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Conlon claims that the RTO must have the ability to establish 
    various reliability standards that every participant. He suggests that 
    the RTO, or the Commission with delegated authority to the RTO, set 
    mandatory standards and impose sanctions or fines for violations.
        Cal ISO believes that RTOs are the appropriate entities to 
    establish reliability standards. Regional organizations (not a single 
    national standard-setter) should have the flexibility to develop 
    standards that reflect regional priorities as well as individual issues 
    related to particular areas or configurations in the transmission grid. 
    It recommends that RTOs have the authority and responsibility to 
    develop regional reliability standards, subject to general oversight by 
    an appropriate independent national reliability organization such as 
    NAERO.
        Similarly, Entergy believes that the RTO should have the primary 
    role, authority and responsibility to adopt, implement and enforce 
    regional reliability standards. Entergy further argues that this 
    authority must be subject to regional oversight, especially as to 
    reliability issues between and among interconnected RTOs.
        Some commenters argue that the Commission should provide additional 
    authority to RTOs. For example, PJM believes that an RTO should have 
    exclusive authority for administering the regional reliability of the 
    bulk power system. It argues that no entity external to an RTO's region 
    should have authority to dictate reliability rules that adversely 
    affect the reliability in a region served by an RTO. Thus, PJM believes 
    the Commission should extend this proposal beyond the proposed 
    reporting requirement. In its opinion, RTOs that are responsible for a 
    particular area of the bulk power market system best can develop tools 
    that are designed to meet the needs of their individual areas. PJM 
    requests that the Commission insist in its rule that RTOs play a 
    significant role in setting any national reliability standards. Sithe 
    suggests that RTOs should also have independent authority to modify 
    existing rules, and/or to place new rules before the Commission for its 
    review and approval in order to promote rules that intrude less into 
    the markets and that promote efficiency goals, as well as system 
    reliability.
        Illinois Commission argues that the proposal is not adequate and 
    that the Commission must more directly address the concern over lack of 
    independence between reliability standards development, enforcement 
    organizations and commercial market interests. Illinois Commission 
    suggests some possibilities: (1) require NERC/regional reliability 
    council reform so that the process of establishing and enforcing 
    reliability guidelines, standards, and policies is independent of 
    discriminatory generation/transmission owner influence; (2) require 
    that all NERC/regional reliability council guidelines, standards, and 
    policies be approved by FERC prior to their adoption; or (3) reform 
    NERC so that it is independent of generation/transmission owners, then 
    eliminate MAIN and ECAR and require the Midwest ISO to act as the 
    regional standards setting entity and as the
    
    [[Page 874]]
    
    reliability enforcement entity for the Midwest Region.
        A few commenters seek clarification.\436\ British Columbia Ministry 
    requests that the Commission clarify how the RTO roles and 
    responsibilities overlap with duties outlined for the Self Regulating 
    Reliability Organization in the North American Electric Reliability 
    Council's draft legislation. New York Commission and Iowa Board request 
    that the Commission recognize the authority of the states to require 
    the maintenance of electric system reliability.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \436\ See, e.g., Canada DNR, Manitoba Board, Cal DWR, Entergy, 
    Minnesota Commission, PSE&G.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        NERC and several other commenters generally oppose the proposal. 
    NERC urges the Commission to include an obligation that the RTO adhere 
    to the reliability rules adopted by NERC and the relevant regional 
    reliability council as a condition of becoming an RTO. NERC states that 
    RTOs must be designed, implemented and operated consistent with NERC 
    operating and planning policies. NERC notes it will revise its 
    operating and planning policies to recognize and accommodate these 
    emerging institutions, as necessary.
        Several commenters such as Duke and SERC supports the work of NERC 
    to establish consistently applied reliability standards and supports 
    NERC's authority to enforce these standards. Duke also supports NERC 
    and the regional reliability councils continuing to play a vital role 
    in setting reliability standards. NERC oversight of reliability should 
    prevent different RTOs from applying different standards and will 
    ensure that inter-RTO reliability matters will be dealt with 
    effectively. CEA suggests that the reliability responsibilities 
    authorized for RTO's be respectful of the carefully balanced design of 
    the evolving NERC/NAERO.
        SRP requests that each RTO be required to join NERC, or NAERO when 
    formed. In addition, other commenters such as SRP and Los Angeles 
    propose that RTOs be required to use planning and design criteria that 
    comply with the criteria established by the appropriate NERC (or NAERO 
    when established) regional reliability council.
        NYPP believes that properly constituted local and regional 
    reliability councils authorized by FERC should have the authority to 
    establish criteria necessary to maintain the reliability of the 
    transmission system including the reliability of discrete locations 
    (e.g., the supply of reactive power to support voltage in load 
    pockets).\437\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \437\ The Commission has authorized the establishment of the New 
    York State Reliability Council and has accepted the relationship 
    between it and the NY ISO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        FirstEnergy requests that the role of the regional reliability 
    councils be clarified with respect to regional RTOs. Also it would have 
    us identify the need boundaries so that each RTO reports only to one 
    regional reliability council. In addition, the regional reliability 
    councils may need to undergo a transformation similar to NERC/NAERO to 
    expand the role of the various industry segments.
        Commission Conclusion. The Commission adopts the proposal in the 
    NOPR that the RTO must have exclusive authority for maintaining the 
    short-term reliability of the grid that it operates. Although many 
    commenters support this requirement, some pose additional questions 
    regarding how this function will be performed by the RTO. Some 
    commenters request that the Commission define better the time period 
    associated with ``short-term'' reliability. We clarify that the term 
    ``short-term'' is intended to cover transmission reliability 
    responsibilities short of grid capacity enhancement. It includes all 
    time periods, including but not limited to ``real-time,'' necessary for 
    the RTO to satisfy its reliability responsibilities, up to the planning 
    horizon. There is no time gap between what is included within short-
    term reliability and the RTO's planning responsibilities.
        Commenters also request more specificity in describing the RTO's 
    functions. The facilities that will be under RTO control, the specific 
    functions that the RTO must perform, and how the RTO will execute its 
    responsibilities and direct operations, are all defined above in the 
    section on operational authority. PJM's additional request that the RTO 
    have authority to collect information is discussed in both the 
    operational authority and the market monitoring sections.
        PG&E requests that the RTO rely on market mechanisms to maintain 
    short-term reliability. PJM/NEPOOL Customers requests that reliability 
    and commercial activities be kept separate. We will not require the RTO 
    to rely on market mechanisms in every instance to maintain short-term 
    reliability. The Commission believes that some reliability functions 
    may not be conducive to supply through competitive market mechanisms 
    since a reliable power system provided to one customer cannot be 
    withheld from other customers, viz., many reliability functions are, in 
    economic terms, ``public goods.'' In Order No. 888, we identified some 
    functions necessary to maintain grid reliability as ancillary services 
    and required them to be provided as separate products. These services 
    and their potential inclusion in emerging markets is discussed in the 
    section on ancillary services below. We cannot conclude at this time 
    that it is appropriate to rely solely on market mechanisms to supply 
    the reliability functions that the transmission system operator must 
    perform, but we expect that over time most of the generation services 
    that perform these functions will be competitively procured.
        Interchange Scheduling. We conclude that the RTO must have 
    exclusive authority for receiving, confirming and implementing all 
    interchange schedules, which are often coincident with schedules for 
    unbundled transmission service. This function will automatically be 
    assumed by RTOs that operate a single control area. If the RTO 
    structure includes control area operators who are market participants 
    or affiliated with market participants, the RTO will have the authority 
    to direct the implementation of all interchange schedules. As stated in 
    the NOPR, a remaining concern is that non-RTO control area operators, 
    who are also competitors in energy markets, have unequal access to 
    commercially sensitive information and could use this knowledge of 
    their competitors' schedules and transactions to gain an unfair 
    competitive advantage in the energy markets. In the event that the RTO 
    filing includes a structure in which non-RTO control area operators 
    receive sensitive information, we will require the RTO to monitor for 
    any unfair competitive advantage, and report to the Commission 
    immediately if problems are detected. In addition, to address concerns 
    about protecting commercially sensitive information, we will require 
    the RTO or any entities who operate control areas within the RTO's 
    region that require access to commercially sensitive information to 
    sign agreements that separate reliability personnel and the relevant 
    information they receive from their wholesale merchant personnel.
        Redispatch Authority. We conclude that the RTO must have the right 
    to order the redispatch of any generator connected to the transmission 
    facilities it operates, if necessary for the reliable operation of the 
    transmission system.\438\
    
    [[Page 875]]
    
    We also require each RTO to develop procedures for generators to offer 
    their services and to compensate generators that are redispatched for 
    reliability. In order to maintain the reliability of the transmission 
    system, the entity that controls transmission must also have some 
    control over some generation. In general, we believe this control 
    should be through a market where the generators offer their services 
    and the RTO chooses the least cost options. This authority does not 
    extend to initial unit commitment and dispatch decisions for 
    generators. However, for reliability purposes, the RTO should have full 
    authority to order the redispatch of any generator, subject to existing 
    environmental and operating restrictions that may limit a generator's 
    ability to change its dispatch.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \438\ Redispatch for congestion management is addressed under 
    different rules, as discussed in the section on congestion 
    management.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Some commenters request that we define what is meant by redispatch 
    for reliability. We clarify that we intend the authority for generator 
    redispatch to be used by the RTO to prevent or manage emergency 
    situations, such as abnormal system conditions that require automatic 
    or immediate manual action to prevent or limit equipment damage or the 
    loss of facilities or supply that could adversely affect the 
    reliability of the electric system, or to restore the system to a 
    normal operating state.\439\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \439\ In general, a power system can be in one of three states: 
    normal, emergency and restorative. When all constraints and loads 
    are satisfied, the system is in its normal state; when one or more 
    physical limits are violated, the system is in an emergency state; 
    and when part of the system is operating in a normal state yet one 
    or more of the loads is not met (partial or total blackout), the 
    system is in a restorative state.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Transmission Maintenance Approval. We conclude that, when the RTO 
    operates transmission facilities owned by other entities, the RTO must 
    have authority to approve and disapprove all requests for scheduled 
    outages of transmission facilities to ensure that the outages can be 
    accommodated within established reliability standards. Control over 
    transmission maintenance is a necessary RTO function because outages of 
    transmission facilities affect the overall transfer capability of the 
    grid. If a facility is removed from service for any reason, the power 
    flows on all regional facilities are affected. These shifting power 
    flows may cause other facilities to become overloaded and, 
    consequently, adversely affect system reliability.
        The RTO is expected to base its approval on a determination of 
    whether the proposed maintenance of transmission facilities can be 
    accommodated within established state, regional and national 
    reliability standards. The RTO's regional perspective will allow it to 
    coordinate individual maintenance schedules with other RTOs as well as 
    with expected seasonal system demand variations. Since the RTO will 
    have access to extensive information, it will be able to make more 
    accurate assessments of the reliability effect of proposed maintenance 
    schedules than individual, sub-regional transmission owners.
        If the RTO is a transmission company that owns and operates 
    transmission facilities, these assessments will be an internal company 
    matter. However, if there are several transmission owners in the RTO 
    region, the RTO will need to review transmission requests made by the 
    various transmission owners.\440\ In this latter case, we expect the 
    RTO to: receive requests for authorization of preferred maintenance 
    outage schedules; review and test these schedules against reliability 
    criteria; approve specific requests for scheduled outages; require 
    changes to maintenance schedules when they fail to meet reliability 
    standards; and update and publish maintenance schedules as needed.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \440\ Since some of these transmission owners may also own 
    generation, they may have an incentive to schedule transmission 
    maintenance at times that would increase the prices received from 
    their power sales. A transmission company, not affiliated with any 
    generators, would not have these same incentives.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We conclude that, if the RTO requires a transmission owner to 
    reschedule planned maintenance, the transmission owners should be 
    compensated for any costs created by the required rescheduling only if 
    the previously scheduled outage had already been approved by the RTO.
        We encourage the RTO to establish performance standards for 
    transmission facilities under its direct or contractual control. Such 
    standards could take the form of targets for planned and unplanned 
    outages. The rationale for this requirement is that two transmission 
    owners should not receive equal compensation if one owner operates a 
    reliable transmission facility while the other operates an unreliable 
    facility. For RTOs that are transcos, we will require that such quality 
    standards be made explicit in any rate proposal.
        Generation Maintenance Approval. We conclude that the RTO is not 
    required to have authority over proposed generation maintenance 
    schedules. However, we acknowledge that there are reliability 
    advantages to the RTO having this authority, and we would accept RTO 
    proposals where the participants choose to grant the RTO such 
    authority. In our order approving the Midwest ISO, we observed that 
    ``the dividing line between transmission control and generation control 
    is not always clear because both sets of functions are ultimately 
    required for reliable operation of the overall system.'' 441 
    Because of this close connection between generation and maintenance of 
    system reliability, it is essential for generator owners and operators 
    to provide the RTO with advance knowledge of planned generation outage 
    schedules so that the RTO can incorporate this information into its 
    reliability studies and operations plan. However, although a generator 
    may be required to submit its maintenance schedule to an RTO, the RTO 
    should be prohibited from sharing that information with any other 
    market participants, or affiliates of market participants.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \44\ Midwest ISO, 84 FERC at 62,180.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Facility Ratings. After consideration of the comments, we conclude 
    that it is inappropriate here to require RTOs to establish transmission 
    facility ratings. We encourage, however, such ratings to be determined, 
    to the extent practical, by mutual consent of the transmission owner 
    and the RTO, taking into account local codes, age and past usage of the 
    facilities.
        The Commission acknowledges the concern that changes in existing 
    equipment ratings may lead to problems of equipment safety and possible 
    damage. We further recognize that the RTO may initially need to rely 
    upon existing values for equipment ratings and operating ranges so as 
    not to disrupt reliable system operation. However, as an RTO gains 
    experience operating or directing the operation of the transmission 
    facilities in its region, we expect this responsibility to migrate to 
    the RTO, as facility ratings have at least an indirect effect on the 
    ability of the RTO to perform other RTO minimum functions (e.g., 
    planning and expansion, ATC and TTC). If there is a dispute over 
    equipment ratings, the parties should pursue resolution through an ADR 
    process approved by the Commission.
        Liability. After consideration, we will determine the extent of RTO 
    liability relating to its reliability activities on a case-by-case 
    basis.
        Reliability Standards. We conclude that the RTO must perform its 
    functions consistent with established NERC (or its successor) 
    reliability standards, and notify the Commission immediately if 
    implementation of these or any other externally established reliability 
    standards will prevent it from meeting its obligation to provide 
    reliable, non-discriminatory transmission service.
    
    [[Page 876]]
    
    E. Minimum Functions of an RTO
    
        In the NOPR, we proposed seven minimum functions that an RTO must 
    perform. In general, we proposed that an RTO must:
        (1) administer its own tariff and employ a transmission pricing 
    system that will promote efficient use and expansion of transmission 
    and generation facilities;
        (2) create market mechanisms to manage transmission congestion;
        (3) develop and implement procedures to address parallel path flow 
    issues;
        (4) serve as a supplier of last resort for all ancillary services 
    required in Order No. 888 and subsequent orders;
        (5) operate a single OASIS site for all transmission facilities 
    under its control with responsibility for independently calculating TTC 
    and ATC;
        (6) monitor markets to identify design flaws and market power; and
        (7) plan and coordinate necessary transmission additions and 
    upgrades.
        We basically affirm these seven functions with the clarifications 
    and revisions as noted below. In addition, we have added interregional 
    coordination as an eighth minimum function, as discussed below.
    1. Tariff Administration and Design (Function 1) Sole Administrator of 
    Tariff
        In order to ensure non-discriminatory service within the region, 
    the NOPR proposed that the RTO be the sole administrator of its own 
    transmission tariff.442 The RTO would thus be the sole 
    authority making decisions on the provision of transmission service 
    including decisions relating to new interconnections. The NOPR 
    requested comments on several aspects of this standard, including how 
    the authority over interconnections would work for ISOs that do not own 
    transmission and would not be performing the construction. The NOPR 
    also sought comment on whether authority over interconnection should 
    apply to all new interconnections, including those for reliability and 
    connections to other regions.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \442\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,739-740. The 
    authority to file changes in the RTO tariff is discussed above under 
    the Independence Characteristic.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments. The vast majority of commenters addressing these issues 
    agree with the proposal that the RTO be the sole administrator of its 
    own tariff.443 Commenters noted many of the benefits of an 
    RTO being the sole tariff administrator: it will eliminate confusion; 
    reduce transactions costs; assure that access decisions are 
    independent; 444 reduce reliability concerns; 445 
    and ensure consistent ratemaking across the RTO.446 Some 
    commenters suggest that their respective organizations already meet 
    this requirement, including ISO-NE and NY ISO, which ask whether 
    sharing authority with transmission owners for non-discriminatory 
    access meets the standard.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \443\ See, e.g., Allegheny, APX, SMUD, NASUCA, NY ISO, East 
    Kentucky, Utilicorp, JEA, LG&E, Enron/APX/Coral Power, EPSA, South 
    Carolina Authority, First Energy, Cal DWR, California Board, 
    PacifiCorp and NSP.
        \444\ PJM.
        \445\ PJM/NEPOOL Customers.
        \446\ UAMPS.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        But some of the commenters that support the proposal had specific 
    concerns and suggestions: the Commission should adopt specific pricing 
    regulations and expressly permit expedited declaratory orders on 
    pricing; 447 the Commission should take a more active 
    approach in developing innovative rates; 448 there may be a 
    problem for an RTO located in both the United States and Canada if 
    there is disagreement over the tariff by the respective authorities; 
    449 and quicker decisions are likely if a stakeholder board 
    is not involved.450
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \447\ Entergy.
        \448\ Illinois Commission.
        \449\ Canada DNR.
        \450\ New Smyrna Beach.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A number of commenters also supported the proposal with respect to 
    the RTO's authority over interconnections.451 Some of these 
    commenters expressed concerns and recommendations about the 
    Commission's proposal, e.g., transmission owners should be a part of 
    the decision process; 452 transcos will be better able to 
    integrate interconnection decisions into a unified strategy covering 
    investment, operations, maintenance and facility design; 453 
    RTOs should not have the authority to deny a generator that is not 
    optimally located on the grid; 454 interconnection policy 
    should rely more heavily on market mechanisms; 455 the 
    transmission owner should develop the actual interconnection agreement 
    to insure adequate protections for its equipment; 456 
    national fees and technical standards should be established for 
    interconnections; 457 authority over interconnections should 
    involve coordinated planning and construction, not ``autonomous, 
    unilateral authority''; 458 RTOs need to develop procedures 
    and guidelines so that there are no adverse impacts of interconnection 
    on existing facilities; 459 RTOs should have authority to 
    assess the impact of a new interconnection on regional facilities but 
    should only have authority over interconnections involving RTO 
    facilities, not all regional facilities; 460 and an RTO must 
    be required to show harm to deny an interconnection 
    request.461
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \451\ See, e.g., Entergy, PJM, South Carolina Authority, 
    Southern Company, Tri-State, Desert STAR, East Texas Cooperatives, 
    Enron/APX/Coral Power, Sithe and PG&E.
        \452\ Cal ISO.
        \453\ Duke.
        \454\ Minnesota Power.
        \455\ PG&E.
        \456\ Southern Company.
        \457\ Distributed Power and EAL.
        \458\ SPRA.
        \459\ TANC.
        \460\ Metropolitan.
        \461\ Williams.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A few commenters opposed the Commission's proposal or suggested 
    making significant modifications. With respect to tariff 
    administration, Seattle opposes the Commission giving RTOs with small 
    control areas blanket authority to approve new interconnections and 
    also argues that the RTO should not be given authority over the 
    interconnection of customer based backup and load shaving generators, 
    QFs, or subtransmission and radial transmission facilities (used to 
    reinforce municipal grids). TXU Electric argues that the Commission 
    should be more flexible and allow RTOs to choose whether to administer 
    the tariff of other entities. TXU Electric notes that in ERCOT, each 
    owner has its own tariff with its own revenue requirement but with 
    uniform terms and conditions of access and that this approach can 
    protect the owner better than an RTO tariff. Florida Commission 
    recommends that the question of tariff administration be determined on 
    a regional basis with endorsement by state regulators.
        With respect to RTO authority over interconnections, Mass Companies 
    argues that the RTO should not have the authority over interconnections 
    because such authority is unlawful, impairs reliability, and because 
    the transmission owner is in a better position to perform this 
    function. SRP suggests that an RTO's exclusive right to administer its 
    own tariff and the right to control interconnections may establish a 
    property right that would jeopardize a public power's tax free status 
    by being declared a private business use. This would be a potential 
    problem if the RTO were not a governmental entity or a 501(c)(3) non-
    profit organization. To prevent this, SRP says that the RTO would have 
    to be structured carefully with these concerns in mind. DOE indicates 
    that the authority over interconnection is a concern for PMAs
    
    [[Page 877]]
    
    because of the NEPA requirements which must be accommodated. Industrial 
    Consumers would amend the proposed Regulatory Text on tariff 
    administration to add ``throughout the interconnection within which the 
    Regional Transmission Organization resides'' to the requirement to 
    promote efficient use and expansion. Industrial Consumers also propose 
    that the Regulatory Text on interconnection be amended to add the 
    responsibility to coordinate transmission needs across the 
    interconnection. Finally, Industrial Consumers would amend the 
    provision that RTOs review and approve requests for new 
    interconnections to add ``by new loads that take service at 
    transmission voltages and by any new generation resource regardless of 
    the nominal voltage at the generator's point of interconnection. Any 
    proposal to increase the nameplate-rated capacity at an existing 
    generating site shall be treated as a new request for interconnection'' 
    to clarify that the RTO is to authorize such interconnections and 
    minimize entry barriers to new sources of generation.
        Commission Conclusion. We note the strong support for this standard 
    in the comments and we adopt the NOPR's requirement that the RTO be the 
    sole provider of transmission service and sole administrator of its own 
    open access tariff. Included in this is the requirement that the RTO 
    have the sole authority for the evaluation and approval of all requests 
    for transmission service including requests for new 
    interconnections.462
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \462\ Of course, eligible applicants always have the right to 
    seek interconnections from the Commission pursuant to sections 
    202(b) and 210 of the FPA.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        With the RTO the sole provider of transmission service, 
    transmission customers have a nondiscriminatory and uniform access to 
    regional transmission facilities. This type of access cannot be assured 
    if customers are required to deal with several transmission owners with 
    differing tariff terms and conditions. As noted in the NOPR, the RTO 
    must be the provider of transmission service in the strong sense of the 
    term. Mere monitoring and dispute resolution are insufficient to meet 
    the requirements of this standard.
        The requirement that the RTO administer its own tariff and not the 
    tariff or tariffs of other entities received little objection in the 
    comments, even from ISOs where this requirement is not currently being 
    met.463 One commenter, SCE&G proposes that the RTO's tariff 
    only cover its own costs and wheeling. The transmission owners would 
    maintain standard open access tariffs which would be administered by 
    the RTO. We reject this proposal. To provide truly independent and 
    nondiscriminatory transmission service, the RTO must administer its own 
    tariff and have the independent authority to file tariff changes.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \463\ See, e.g., ISO-NE at 9.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Mass Companies argues that the RTO is not in as good a position as 
    transmission owners to judge requests for new interconnections. SPRA 
    and Metropolitan suggest that an RTO's authority over new 
    interconnections should be limited. Because the ability for customers 
    to obtain nondiscriminatory access to the regional transmission system, 
    whether over existing facilities or over new facilities, is integral to 
    a competitive market for generation, we reject these proposals to 
    modify our original position on new interconnections.
        Other commenters, as noted above, support this standard but have 
    specific concerns they would like to see the Commission address. The 
    concerns listed do not cause us to change our original proposal. These 
    concerns, to the extent they apply, should be voiced at the time RTO 
    proposals are filed and they will be considered on a case-by-case 
    basis.
        Multiple Access Charges. The NOPR proposed that the RTO's tariff 
    must not result in transmission customers paying multiple access 
    charges. We affirm that proposal in this Final Rule. Because the issue 
    of multiple access charges is a rate issue, we discuss in detail the 
    comments we received on this issue, the reasons for our conclusion, and 
    the concepts of pancaked rates, license plate rates, and uniform access 
    charges in Section III.G of this Final Rule addressing transmission 
    ratemaking policy for RTOs.
    2. Congestion Management (Function 2)
        In the NOPR, we proposed to include congestion management as a 
    minimum function that an RTO must perform.464 Specifically, 
    we proposed to require the RTO to ensure the development and operation 
    of market mechanisms to manage transmission congestion. We proposed 
    that the RTO must either operate such markets itself or ensure that the 
    task is performed by another entity that is not affiliated with any 
    market participant. In carrying out this function, we stated that the 
    RTO must satisfy certain standards or demonstrate that an alternative 
    proposal is consistent with or superior to satisfying the standard. We 
    further proposed that the market mechanisms must accommodate broad 
    participation by all market participants, and must provide all 
    transmission customers with efficient price signals regarding the 
    consequences of their transmission usage decisions. We proposed to 
    allow RTOs considerable flexibility in experimenting with different 
    market approaches to managing congestion through pricing. However, we 
    stated that proposals should ensure that (1) the generators that are 
    dispatched in the presence of transmission constraints are those that 
    can serve system loads at least cost, and (2) limited transmission 
    capacity is used by market participants that value that use most 
    highly. We asked for comments as to what specific requirements, if any, 
    may best suit these goals.465
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \464\ FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,741-43.
        \465\ Id. at 33,754-55.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We stated in the NOPR that traditional approaches to congestion 
    management such as those that rely exclusively on the use of 
    administrative curtailment procedures may no longer be acceptable in a 
    competitive, vertically de-integrated industry. We thus concluded that 
    efficient congestion management requires a greater reliance on market 
    mechanisms, and stated our belief that a large regional organization 
    like an RTO will be able to create a workable and effective congestion 
    management market. We stated that while it is our intent to give RTOs 
    considerable flexibility in experimenting with different market 
    approaches to managing congestion, we believe that a workable market 
    approach should establish clear and tradeable rights for transmission 
    usage, promote efficient regional dispatch, support the emergence of 
    secondary markets for transmission rights, and provide market 
    participants with the opportunity to hedge locational differences in 
    energy prices.
        The Commission invited comments on the requirement that RTOs must 
    be responsible for managing congestion with a market mechanism, and 
    posed the following questions. Can decentralized markets for congestion 
    management be made to work effectively and quickly? Can the RTO's role 
    be limited to that of a facilitator that simply brings together market 
    participants for the purpose of engaging in bilateral transactions to 
    relieve congestion? If not, will these markets require centralized 
    operation by the RTO or some other independent entity? How can an RTO 
    ensure that enough generators will participate in the congestion 
    management market to make possible a least-cost dispatch? Are there any 
    special considerations in evaluating
    
    [[Page 878]]
    
    market power in a congestion market operated or facilitated by an RTO? 
    In addition, we proposed to allow up to one year after start-up for 
    this function to be implemented. We noted that market approaches to 
    congestion management may take additional time to work out, and asked 
    for comments on whether this additional implementation time period is 
    warranted, and whether one year is an appropriate additional time 
    period.
        Comments. Using Market Mechanisms to Manage Congestion. Although 
    opinions vary as to the proper role of the RTO in managing congestion, 
    many commenters believe that efficient congestion management requires 
    greater reliance on market mechanisms.466 CSU believes that 
    congestion management is uniquely amenable to a market solution. CSU 
    states that there will be a continuing need for some type of market 
    mechanism to address constraints and this mechanism is best established 
    at the regional level and best placed with an entity independent of 
    wholesale power market participants.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \466\ See, e.g., United Illuminating, CSU, Duke, NASUCA, Los 
    Angeles, NYPP, DOE, SMUD, Otter Tail, PG&E, FirstEnergy, Mass 
    Companies, Enron/APX/Coral Power, Nevada Commission.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Some commenters emphasize that it is better to use market 
    mechanisms to manage congestion than to rely on the physical 
    interruption of power flows.467 NERC contends that if the 
    industry had in place more market-oriented mechanisms that dealt 
    effectively with constraints, then the frequency of transmission 
    loading relief (TLR) procedures would decrease. Professor Hogan claims 
    that with efficient pricing, users have the incentive to respond to the 
    requirements of reliable operation. He asserts that, absent such price 
    incentives, market choices would need to be curtailed in order to give 
    the system operator enough control to counteract the perverse 
    incentives that would be created by prices that did not reflect the 
    marginal costs of dispatch. PJM/NEPOOL Customers argues that, when 
    faced with a transmission congestion circumstance, the RTO should 
    redispatch generators to the extent possible.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \467\ See, e.g., NERC, Sithe, NASUCA, Cinergy, Professor Hogan, 
    PJM, Dr. Ilic.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Also, Statoil claims that the use of TLR procedures is inherently 
    discriminatory. Statoil claims that most transmission owners serving 
    retail load do not engage in interchange transactions or use the pro 
    forma tariff at the same level as new competitive market entrants 
    attempting to enter historically captive markets. Statoil thus argues 
    that, even if TLR is applied in a comparable manner, it will still 
    disproportionately and adversely affect new competitive market 
    entrants.
        Role of the RTO in Congestion Management. Commenters offer a 
    variety of views concerning the proper role of the RTO in congestion 
    management. Some advocate an active role for the RTO in operating an 
    energy market that is highly centralized.468 Others envision 
    the RTO's role as being much smaller, perhaps limited to that of a 
    facilitator that brings together market participants for the purpose of 
    engaging in voluntary transactions to relieve congestion.469 
    Still others, such as Southern Company and EEI, believe that RTOs are 
    not necessary to make congestion management work. EEI argues that while 
    congestion management does require a coordinated regional or 
    interconnection-wide solution, it does not require the extensive 
    infrastructure and responsibilities associated with what the Commission 
    has proposed to define as RTOs. EEI notes that NERC's Congestion 
    Management Working Group is exploring available options for congestion 
    management, independently of whether RTOs exist.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \468\ See, e.g., PJM, Professor Hogan, CSU, Sithe, NERA, Duke, 
    PJM/NEPOOL Customers, H.Q. Energy Services, Minnesota Power, FTC.
        \469\ See, e.g., APX, SPP, South Carolina Authority, Alliant 
    Energy, WPSC, NSP, TANC, Williams.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        PJM/NEPOOL Customers believes that an independent entity must 
    operate any congestion management market. It believes also that that 
    entity must have sufficient power and centralization to address 
    congestion problems effectively and quickly. Consequently, it urges the 
    Commission not to consider proposals that include a decentralized 
    market for congestion management or that limit the RTO role to that of 
    a facilitator of bilateral transactions to relieve congestion. In 
    addition, it contends that the RTO must retain sufficient authority 
    over generators that choose to make themselves available to ensure that 
    those generators will participate in the congestion management market. 
    Duke states that, eventually, decentralized markets may organize in a 
    manner to accomplish effective congestion management, but at this time, 
    the congestion management function should be centrally managed.
        PJM claims that RTOs can facilitate efficient, broad-scale 
    congestion management. PJM states that by combining multiple 
    transmission systems over a large geographic region, an RTO can have an 
    effective pricing system to price efficiently actual transmission flows 
    in a region. PJM argues that not only should the Commission require 
    that RTOs be responsible for managing congestion with market 
    mechanisms, the Commission also should prohibit any other entity from 
    acting in a manner that detracts from the RTO's ability to employ its 
    market mechanisms.
        Cleveland believes that an effective way to manage congestion may 
    be to combine a market-based mechanism with a power exchange. It states 
    that the RTO's redispatch function and the bidding process available 
    through a power exchange should jointly operate to minimize the 
    congestion.
        H.Q. Energy Services contends that control over the management of 
    congestion goes hand-in-hand with control over reliability. It believes 
    that, ideally, an RTO should establish a congestion pricing system that 
    manages congestion with minimal operator intervention. However, H.Q. 
    Energy Services argues that, without control over reliability, an RTO 
    will not be in the position to accurately and fairly allocate available 
    transmission capacity because it cannot send the correct congestion 
    pricing signals.
        Sithe contends that the Commission should not allow overly 
    decentralized systems whereby individual utilities in a region continue 
    to manage congestion relief, especially if those utilities continue to 
    own generation. Arkansas Consumers believe that the RTO's congestion 
    management function helps provide a remedy for any anti-competitive 
    activity on the part of generators or transmission owners. First 
    Rochdale contends that only fully independent operation of an RTO is 
    likely to lead to open markets in which all entities can compete 
    freely. Duke asserts that there are no special considerations in 
    evaluating market power in a congestion market operated or facilitated 
    by an RTO.
        Other commenters stress that the RTO's role in managing congestion 
    using market mechanisms should be strictly limited. Indeed, the South 
    Carolina Authority opposes a centralized arrangement for managing 
    congestion as being unduly restrictive and perhaps anti-competitive. 
    WPSC argues that the role of the RTO should be limited to acting as a 
    clearinghouse so that market participants are aware of the range of 
    alternatives available for dealing with congestion. WPSC contends that 
    the market will then dictate which mechanisms are used in any 
    particular instance. SPP suggests that the RTO can be a facilitator of 
    congestion relief and that there is no need for the Commission to 
    require that the RTO adopt a centralized approach,
    
    [[Page 879]]
    
    such as locational marginal pricing, for managing congestion. SPP 
    states that it is a facilitator of congestion relief and intends to 
    continue in that role under its new proposal. SPP states that it will 
    identify which generators can relieve a constraint and the relative 
    impact of redispatching those generators. It will then be the 
    customer's responsibility to contract with the owner of these 
    generators for redispatch services. SPP notes that this method relies 
    on the market and bilateral contracts for the redispatch solutions. SPP 
    claims that the market can also provide for price assurance and for 
    long-term redispatch obligations. PG&E claims that with the proper 
    information, bilateral market-based redispatch could be used within an 
    hour of the occurrence of congestion on any part of the controlled 
    system.
        APX argues that the RTO should not conduct the trading process 
    because it will impede the adaptation of trading to market conditions, 
    which is essential for market development. APX claims that all 
    competitive industries use decentralized trading through forward 
    contracts, and no competitive industry uses a central bidding agent to 
    create its market. Consequently, APX believes that the Commission 
    should limit the RTO's role in congestion management to that of a 
    provider of last resort. PG&E argues that although the RTO may 
    administer certain market mechanisms such as congestion management, it 
    is important that the RTO not view itself as responsible for energy 
    pricing and other aspects of supply and demand interactions, all of 
    which, PG&E contends, can be most effectively managed by the market 
    unless material and lasting market flaws are present.
        Similarly, Cinergy argues that the mechanism for price transparency 
    in the commodity market should be developed and implemented by the 
    market, not the RTO. Cinergy recognizes, however, that an economic 
    congestion management system depends on a power market mechanism that 
    provides price transparency for determining economic dispatch of 
    generation. Consequently, Cinergy notes, RTOs will be confronted with 
    issues of applying an economic dispatch valuation mechanism. Cinergy 
    argues that such mechanism should evolve from the marketplace, not 
    directly from the RTO. Cinergy proposes that the RTO would administer 
    the congestion management system, but would not be involved in the 
    commodity market infrastructure unless its involvement was mutually 
    agreeable among all stakeholders.
        Williams claims that decentralized markets for congestion 
    management, operating under the auspices of RTOs, can work effectively 
    and quickly in an environment in which market participants have the 
    correct incentives. Williams states that depending upon the geographic 
    size of RTOs and the extent of congestion within each, zones for 
    congestion management may have to be developed. Williams provides a 
    detailed description of how a zonal approach to congestion management 
    can be implemented.
        Both CP&L and Enron/APX/Coral Power believe that the role of the 
    RTO in congestion management should depend on the time frame in which 
    the decisions are being made. These commenters prescribe different 
    roles for the RTO in each of three different time frames.
        The Direct Dispatch Authority of the RTO. While supporting the use 
    of pricing and other market mechanisms to manage congestion, a number 
    of commenters state that an RTO must have authority to direct 
    redispatch if necessary to ensure grid reliability.\470\ For example, 
    Otter Tail contends that the RTO should have direct authority to order 
    redispatch of generation for purposes of relieving congestion and 
    during system emergencies. Otter Tail states that this dispatch should 
    be directed for the generating units that can most economically reduce 
    the congestion. Otter Tail states that because there is a need for 
    immediate, real-time response to system contingencies and to relieve 
    transmission congestion, the RTO should have control of generating 
    units. East Kentucky contends that to effectively manage congestion, 
    the RTO must have absolute authority to order redispatch of all 
    generators on the RTO transmission system. However, for this to work, 
    East Kentucky states that the RTO will have to compensate the generator 
    with firm transmission service for the additional out-of-pocket costs 
    incurred due to the redispatch, plus an amount for lost margins on lost 
    revenue. It suggests that generators with non-firm transmission service 
    would have to redispatch as directed by the RTO but would have to bear 
    their own costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \470\ See, e.g., Otter Tail, NERC, Allegheny, EME, NASUCA, East 
    Kentucky, Williams, Minnesota Power, CSU. See also supra section 
    III.D.3, which addresses the appropriate scope of the RTO's 
    operational authority.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        NERC notes that market mechanisms may offer better ways of dealing 
    with congestion management than does physical interruption of power 
    flows, but asserts that it will always be necessary to have a non-
    market mechanism such as transmission loading relief in place to ensure 
    that the stability of the grid is always maintained. However, EME 
    believes that the extent of RTO control over dispatch of generation 
    should be carefully circumscribed to ensure maximum development of 
    competitive markets in wholesale power and ancillary services. Seattle 
    contends that where transparent power supply markets exist, price 
    differences are widely known to the market and congestion can be 
    resolved bilaterally with no intervention by an RTO. PJM notes that 
    since implementing LMP, it rarely has needed to take emergency actions 
    to alleviate transmission congestion.
        Minnesota Power believes that RTOs must have the authority to 
    require that all generators, existing and new, agree to redispatch as a 
    condition of grid connection. Minnesota Power also believes that the 
    RTO must have the authority to penalize generators who subsequently 
    refuse a redispatch order, or claim a false unplanned outage. CSU 
    asserts that generation redispatch is essential in Front Range 
    Colorado, which can be expected to have an increasing population of 
    gas-fired generation within the boundaries of the constraints. It 
    contends that the inability to redispatch these units for any reason 
    other than reliability would severely hinder the ability of an RTO to 
    address capacity constraints.
        MidAmerican states that, although congestion must be managed using 
    pricing signals from the market, circumstances may occur where 
    immediate actions are required and time does not permit normal bidding 
    to allow the marketplace to respond. It contends that during such 
    events, the RTO must be required to follow previously established 
    procedures.
        However, Seattle argues that the RTO should not have authority to 
    redispatch generation to accomplish congestion management without 
    unanimous consent of the stakeholders. Seattle notes that many 
    Northwest generating plant operators are subject to fishery-related 
    hydroelectric dispatch constraints. Seattle states that because these 
    constraints are particular to the owners of the generating facilities, 
    these resources are not well suited to third party dispatch.
        Managing Congestion by Eliminating It. Some commenters contend that 
    the ultimate goal of RTOs should be the elimination of congestion 
    within their respective areas of control.\471\ Powerex believes that it 
    is better to eliminate congestion at its source through facilities 
    upgrades, if economically and environmentally feasible, rather than
    
    [[Page 880]]
    
    attempting to manage congestion on a long-term basis through congestion 
    pricing schemes. Salomon Smith Barney believes that the Commission has 
    overemphasized congestion pricing as a vehicle to price the existing 
    network rather than as a vehicle to induce investment when such 
    investment is an economical alternative.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \471\ See, e.g., Williams, Powerex, Manitoba Board, Salomon 
    Smith Barney.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        TDU Systems state that they do not want management of significant 
    transmission congestion to become a long-term function of RTOs. They 
    claim that minor congestion (i.e., congestion that is economically 
    dealt with through redispatch of generators) will always be a feature 
    of wholesale transmission markets, and an RTO should properly manage 
    it. However, they argue that an RTO should deal with significant 
    persistent transmission congestion by constructing (or having 
    constructed) the appropriate transmission or generation facilities.
        Desirable Attributes of Market Mechanisms. Many commenters offer 
    their views on the desirable attributes of any market mechanisms that 
    are used to manage congestion.\472\ For example, PJM/NEPOOL Customers 
    urges the Commission to employ three general criteria to evaluate any 
    proposal: simplicity, visibility and predictability. They state that 
    the proposed approach to relieve the congestion should be simple to 
    administer, both for customers and for the RTO. They believe that 
    market participants should be able to examine the operation of the 
    congestion management mechanism on a real-time basis and verify that 
    transmission access is being appropriately accorded to entities that 
    most desire transmission service. They state that such visibility will 
    engender confidence by market participants in the congestion management 
    mechanism. In addition, they believe that the congestion management 
    mechanism must be predictable to all transmission users to determine 
    the anticipated price that will be necessary to ensure the continuation 
    of transmission service if congestion occurs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \472\ See, e.g., NASUCA, CMUA, NSP, PG&E, Statoil, SMUD, 
    UtiliCorp, PacificCorp, PJM/NEPOOL Customers, Metropolitan, Cal DWR.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Cinergy states that an economically efficient congestion management 
    system must begin with properly defining information posting 
    requirements. Accordingly, Cinergy argues that the Final Rule should 
    ensure that requisite information on congestion is posted on the OASIS. 
    Similarly, Williams and Industrial Consumers believe that RTO access to 
    region-wide information on network conditions and power transactions, 
    coupled with efficient congestion management and well specified 
    transmission rights, could help RTOs in taking preemptive actions 
    against potential curtailment incidents. Statoil and EPSA believe that, 
    ideally, economic rationing schemes should be uniform across RTOs and 
    should be implemented as an ancillary service under a regional 
    transmission tariff. Montana Commission asserts that congestion 
    management must be efficient. CMUA believes that congestion management 
    mechanisms must do their job, but not unreasonably interfere with 
    choices by market participants.
        Some commenters believe that efficient congestion management 
    requires a transparent commodity market. Cinergy states that market 
    mechanisms that include locational pricing and financial rights for 
    firm transmission have been successfully implemented where they are 
    supported by a power exchange or pool pricing mechanism that provides 
    market-clearing prices and price transparency. CalPX emphasizes the 
    value of a separate power exchange and argues that the bifurcation of 
    the exchange and transmission operator functions does not add to the 
    market cost of congestion management, as some have suggested. Also, 
    Otter Tail believes that the development of an hour-ahead power 
    exchange within the RTO would improve grid reliability.
        Many commenters support the NOPR's requirement that market 
    mechanisms be used to manage congestion and note the particular value 
    of using price as a tool to manage congestion.\473\ Some commenters 
    specifically endorsed the proposed requirement that congestion pricing 
    proposals must meet the two efficiency objectives set forth in the 
    NOPR.\474\ PJM/NEPOOL Customers state that these two objectives are 
    fundamental to the operation of a market and to the ultimate goals of 
    electricity supply competition.\475\ SMUD believes that a well-designed 
    congestion management policy, that provides proper locational price 
    signals without creating opportunities for gaming or cost shifting, 
    will attract market participation. SMUD agrees that market participants 
    must be given efficient price signals concerning their use of the 
    transmission system, but claims that this is difficult because the 
    existing transmission grid was not designed with the capability to 
    operate as a common carrier or to serve customers in an open access 
    manner. Also, a few commenters expressed doubts about the overall value 
    of using pricing mechanisms to manage congestion,\476\ and others cited 
    reasons to move cautiously.\477\ Tri-State is skeptical that market 
    mechanisms for managing congestion will lead to a least-cost dispatch. 
    Tri-State states that entities with firm transmission rights on the 
    congested path may be reluctant to participate voluntarily in 
    generation redispatch that will jeopardize the economics of long-term 
    power supply contracts or firm resources, even if the result would 
    lower costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \473\ See, e.g., PJM/NEPOOL Customers, United Illuminating, 
    Allegheny, EPSA, SMUD, Los Angeles, NASUCA, Duke, NERC, Professor 
    Hogan, EME, PJM, DOE, CSU.
        \474\ See, e.g., PJM/NEPOOL Customers.
        \475\ However, Montana Commission asks the Commission to specify 
    more precisely the nature of the pricing and congestion management 
    methods that will satisfy the NOPR's efficiency objectives.
        \476\ See, e.g., LIPA, Transmission ISO Participants.
        \477\ See, e.g., EPSA, Tri-State.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several commenters suggest principles to guide the design of 
    congestion pricing mechanisms.\478\ NASUCA states that any mechanism 
    for using congestion prices for managing transmission system flows 
    should be easy to implement; designed to minimize cost shifts; designed 
    to support an economically efficient dispatch; and coordinated with the 
    underlying transmission rate design. PacifiCorp states that key 
    components of a good market-based congestion clearing methodology are: 
    (1) Tradable transmission capacity reservations; (2) a system in which 
    all parties who can clear congestion can bid to do so; (3) the 
    establishment of congestion costs far enough in advance to facilitate 
    reasoned decision-making; and (4) the avoidance of any RTO rules that 
    substantially reduce liquidity in power markets. UtiliCorp believes 
    that a congestion management system should establish tradeable rights 
    for transmission usage, promote efficient regional dispatch, support 
    the emergence of secondary market for transmission rights, and give 
    market participants the opportunity to hedge locational differences in 
    energy prices. However, Enron/APX/Coral Power disagrees on the latter 
    feature. It contends that the monopoly wires business should not be 
    allowed to encroach on what they see as the highly competitive and 
    innovative business of providing hedges against locational price 
    differences of energy or capacity or against price volatility of these 
    or any other competitive products.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \478\ See, e.g., NASUCA, NJBUS, PJM/NEPOOL Customers, EPSA, 
    Enron/APX/Coral Power.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Cal DWR and Metropolitan urge the Commission to adopt RTO 
    ratemaking principles that include off-peak rates.
    
    [[Page 881]]
    
    Cal DWR believes that customers should face accurate transmission price 
    signals and, therefore, transmission prices should be lower in periods 
    of off-peak demand for transmission. Cal DWR believes that off-peak 
    pricing provides an accurate price signal over the longer term, 
    promoting investment necessary to shift transmission usage to off-peak 
    periods. In addition, Metropolitan believes that off-peak pricing can 
    help to resolve problems of cost-shifting.
        A number of commenters emphasize certain benefits of a well 
    designed congestion pricing policy, claiming that price signals can 
    assist RTOs and market participants in determining the efficient size 
    and location of both new generation and new grid expansions.\479\ Los 
    Angeles argues that ensuring accurate market signals through the 
    creation of a congestion pricing mechanism will be the keystone to 
    future system planning. Los Angeles states that these signals should 
    alert generators to the advantages of siting in congested areas, 
    motivate marketers and distribution companies to develop demand-side 
    management options, and generally foster marketplace innovation. Los 
    Angeles also believes that congestion price signals should help in 
    determining the proper size of transmission upgrades that the RTO might 
    build to relieve congestion. Otter Tail believes there exists a great 
    need for new transmission capacity and, indeed, argues that the overall 
    focus of the NOPR and FERC transmission policy should be on providing 
    the appropriate financial incentives to assure investment in and 
    expansion of the system.\480\ To ensure that price signals translate 
    into appropriate expansion of the grid, SMUD believes that the RTO must 
    be sufficiently independent and strong to require the expansion of the 
    grid. NASUCA notes that, while congestion cost pricing may help to 
    signal where new generation and transmission lines are needed, it may 
    not be necessary for the efficient daily operation of the transmission 
    grid.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \479\ See, e.g., Allegheny, EME, United Illuminating, EPSA, 
    SMUD, Los Angeles, NASUCA, CSU.
        \480\ Other commenters emphasize the need for significant 
    investments to expand transmission capacity. See, e.g., EPRI, 
    Salomon Smith Barney.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Other commenters believe that it may be difficult to design market 
    mechanisms to provide incentives for the efficient expansion of the 
    grid.\481\ H.Q. Energy Services states that currently, the rules for 
    congestion management do not act as a sufficient incentive to 
    transmission owners to upgrade facilities. NWCC states that it is 
    unclear whether congestion charges can act as a means of driving 
    transmission expansion, since adding transmission is, by nature, 
    capacity-based. NWCC also states that it is unclear whether congestion 
    costs will be an adequate incentive for market participants to finance 
    transmission expansion on their own, given the extensive permitting and 
    regulatory requirements that are involved. LIPA states that, while new 
    location-based pricing mechanisms have not been in place long enough to 
    determine if they will provide empirical evidence that is helpful in 
    identifying efficient transmission expansions, it believes that the 
    mechanisms do not provide sufficient incentives for development of 
    transmission. Also, LIPA claims that they do not provide a useful 
    signal when reliability, as opposed to economic efficiency, drives the 
    need for transmission enhancements.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \481\ See, e.g., Transmission ISO Participants, SoCal Edison, 
    H.Q. Energy Services, LIPA, NWCC.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        SoCal Edison criticizes the congestion management policies 
    implemented by the Cal ISO, stating that procedures intended to 
    encourage the voluntary mitigation of congestion through investment in 
    new transmission may not provide a sufficient incentive. SoCal Edison 
    contends that, while correct congestion price signals will assist in 
    the identification of transmission investment needs, they will not 
    eliminate fundamental disputes among affected market participants over 
    the responsibility for the costs of new transmission or eliminate the 
    risks associated with attempting to construct new transmission 
    projects. It asserts that the Commission cannot simply assume that the 
    market will respond to congestion signals if, at the same time, it is 
    creating a regulatory climate that discourages investment in new 
    transmission. SoCal Edison believes that impediments to grid expansion 
    can be overcome only if the Commission adopts transmission pricing 
    policies that more accurately reflect the value that new transmission 
    investments bring to electric consumers. Similarly, FirstEnergy argues 
    that if the Commission desires an efficient generation market that 
    optimizes the public good, then a mechanism that allows transmission 
    owners to capitalize on increases in the transmission capacity at fair 
    market value must be found. FirstEnergy contends that the interaction 
    of these free market forces will drive the proper allocation of 
    resources between transmission and generation over the long term.
        Locational Marginal Pricing. A number of commenters advocate the 
    use of locational marginal pricing (LMP) for congestion 
    management.\482\ Professor Hogan states that, with LMP, the security-
    constrained economic dispatch process would produce prices for energy 
    at each location, incorporating the combined effect of generation, 
    losses and congestion. He states that the corresponding transmission 
    price between the location where power is supplied and where it is used 
    would be determined as the difference between the energy prices at the 
    two locations. Professor Hogan therefore contends that this same 
    framework is easily extended to include bilateral transactions. 
    Professor Hogan states that, with LMP, the system operator coordinates 
    the dispatch and provides the information for settlement payments, with 
    regulatory oversight to guarantee comparable service through open 
    access to the pool run by the system operator through a bid-based 
    economic dispatch. He claims that PJM implemented LMP after 
    experimenting with an alternative market model and pricing approach 
    that proved to be fundamentally inconsistent with a competitive market 
    and user flexibility. He states that the earlier pricing system allowed 
    market participants the flexibility to choose between bilateral 
    transactions and spot purchases, but did not simultaneously present 
    market participants with the costs of their choices. He states that 
    this created perverse incentives. Professor Hogan argues that LMP is 
    the only workable system that can support a non-discriminatory 
    competitive market that allows for participant choice and flexibility.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \482\ See, e.g., Professor Hogan, PJM, NERA, Sithe, Allegheny, 
    Mid-Atlantic Commissions, DOE, Duke, United Illuminating, EME.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        PJM states that the Commission correctly concludes that LMP will 
    ``encourage efficient use of the transmission system, and facilitate 
    the development of competitive electricity markets.'' PJM notes that, 
    under LMP, transmission customers are assessed congestion charges 
    consistent with their actual use of the system and the actual 
    redispatch that their transactions cause. It claims that this provides 
    an economic choice to non-firm transmission customers to self-curtail 
    their use of the transmission system or pay congestion charges 
    determined by the market. PJM believes that by basing congestion 
    charges on the true redispatch cost, parties behave in a rational and 
    efficient manner. It states that the market determines the clearing 
    price for transmission congestion and which customers ultimately 
    utilize the transmission system. PJM states that the use of fixed 
    transmission rights (FTRs)
    
    [[Page 882]]
    
    enables market participants to pay known, fixed transmission rates and 
    to hedge against congestion charges.
        The FTC believes that accurate LMP signals for investment to reduce 
    congestion may become even more important as distributed generation 
    presents opportunities for small-scale, fine-tuned (with respect to 
    both size and location) generation investments to relieve transmission 
    congestion, in place of large-scale transmission or generation 
    investments. EME endorses the LMP pricing approach adopted by PJM and 
    the New York ISO, and states that the Midwest ISO and the Alliance RTO 
    should be encouraged to adopt similar approaches. The CalPX notes that 
    the separation of the CalPX and the ISO in California does not prevent 
    the use of a locational pricing model that incorporates the individual 
    buses and transmission lines in the network.
        Allegheny believes that ``[c]onsistent locational marginal price 
    dislocations readily identify system expansion, or other congestion 
    relief, requirements as well as serve as an indicator of the most 
    economic fix to congestion patterns over time.'' It claims that there 
    would be no incentives for the RTO or transmission owners to maintain 
    congestion, since there is no financial impact on them from LMP because 
    any excess payments received by the RTO during congestion are returned 
    to holders of FTRs. Allegheny recommends that the Commission remain 
    flexible in considering other pricing innovations for congestion 
    management, but believes that a simplified locational marginal pricing 
    methodology should be established as a default market mechanism against 
    which other pricing innovations are evaluated.
        Some commenters, however, criticize the locational marginal pricing 
    approach to congestion management.\483\ APX argues that, because LMP 
    requires the RTO to implement a centrally optimized dispatch, it will 
    discourage, if not eliminate, the commitment of forward contracts in 
    the energy market and replace the price discovery of forward markets 
    with ex post pricing. APX contends that because LMP price calculations 
    occur only periodically and in a single iteration, price visibility is 
    restricted compared to a continuous forward market. APX claims that 
    this diminished visibility can make the result less efficient and more 
    vulnerable to an exercise of market power. APX contends that, for most 
    industries, a process of continuous trading creates efficiency in a 
    competitive market, while the LMP optimization process has no role for 
    trading. APX asserts that no competitive industry uses optimization to 
    simulate and substitute for market outcomes. APX contends that under 
    LMP, the system operator, not the market, will specify the structure of 
    the optimization problem. APX claims that markets process information 
    much more flexibly and comprehensively through the self-interested 
    trading behavior of buyers and sellers. APX asserts that this is the 
    strength of markets and the critical shortcoming of LMP.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \483\ See, e.g., APX, LIPA, TDU Systems, CP&L, Virginia 
    Commission, Tri-State, Dynegy.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Dynegy claims that markets for FTRs have yet to fulfill their 
    promise to provide market participants with critically important price 
    certainty for their transmission transactions. For example, Dynegy 
    states that allocation problems still exist, in that only a small 
    portion of available FTRs is being auctioned off in certain markets 
    while a large number are being withheld for incumbents' use. Dynegy 
    argues that in order for FTRs to provide a truly effective hedge 
    against transmission price increases resulting from LMP in the hourly 
    market, hourly FTRs would have to be available in a liquid market at a 
    moment's notice, but nothing close to such a market exists. Dynegy 
    suggests that, because the LMP model has yet to be implemented 
    successfully due to the lack of a liquid FTR market, the time is ripe 
    to look at other models, such as a physical rights model.
        LIPA claims that neither the opportunity to obtain fixed 
    transmission rights nor the prospect of locational price reductions are 
    sufficient to encourage efficient generation and transmission 
    expansions. For example, LIPA notes that awarding a transmission 
    expander transmission rights that entitle it to collect congestion 
    rents on the expanded capacity creates an incentive that runs counter 
    to the purpose of the expansion; i.e., the more successful the 
    expansion is in eliminating congestion, the less value the incentive 
    has for the expander. Also, LIPA believes that locational pricing 
    systems are biased toward using generation to solve congestion problems 
    on the transmission grid and, as a result, could lead to market power 
    abuse by an operator that sites a new generator in a load pocket and 
    then takes advantage of transmission limitations to manipulate the 
    operation of other generators that it owns.
        The Virginia Commission claims that pricing mechanisms 
    incorporating locational marginal prices tend to produce intense 
    signals over short time frames, particularly when constraints are 
    seasonal and driven by extraordinary events such as extreme weather. 
    The Virginia Commission therefore believes that, at least initially, 
    locational marginal prices may provide incentives for short-term 
    actions for congestion relief, rather than longer term solutions such 
    as the construction of additional transmission or generating facilities 
    in a particular location.\484\ The Virginia Commission also states that 
    the use of locational marginal pricing is heavily dependent on the 
    existence of transparent short-term competitive power markets. It urges 
    the Commission to evaluate carefully proposals that place greater 
    reliance on market mechanisms through the use of price signals, and to 
    condition the use of such mechanisms on the existence of such things as 
    fully functioning power exchanges, the establishment of fixed 
    transmission rights and the existence of secondary markets for such 
    rights.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \484\ The Brattle Group believes that, in addition to locational 
    congestion pricing, some form of regulatory incentives may be needed 
    to bring about efficient investment in the transmission grid.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        CP&L argues that while the proposed congestion management rule 
    appears to permit only PJM-redispatch types of arrangements, CP&L does 
    not believe that the PJM model is the only workable congestion 
    management process. Rather, CP&L believes that congestion is best 
    managed through the coordinated reservation and scheduling of 
    transactions on the grid rather than post-congestion fixes. Also, TDU 
    Systems states that it may be difficult to transplant the PJM model to 
    regions that do not have a centrally dispatched, tight power pool to 
    use as an RTO platform.
        Some commenters claim that LMP is more complex than necessary,\485\ 
    although Allegheny believes that today's technology mitigates these 
    concerns. The FTC states that, despite the apparent virtues of LMP, it 
    may be reasonable to back away from a full application of an LMP 
    approach if doing so provides benefits to consumers from increased 
    competition in generation markets. For example, the FTC states that, in 
    light of its alleged complexity and the difficulty that financial 
    markets may have in anticipating congestion charges, LMP may inhibit 
    the formation of efficiency-enhancing futures markets in electricity 
    generation and trading because congestion prices are more uncertain 
    under LMP than under other pricing approaches (such as zonal 
    transmission congestion pricing). The FTC thus suggests that the 
    Commission may want to continue to entertain alternatives to LMP if a 
    reasonable case is made that benefits to consumers are
    
    [[Page 883]]
    
    greater under the alternatives than under LMP.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \485\ See, e.g., PG&E, PJM/NEPOOL Customers, FTC, Tri-State, 
    Dynegy.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Managing Congestion with Tradable Transmission Rights. Several 
    commenters emphasize the importance of including explicit transmission 
    rights in any congestion management plan that relies on market 
    mechanisms.\486\ EPSA believes that when transmission rights are 
    clearly defined and allocated, ATC calculations can be made more 
    accurately and congestion management simplified. DOE notes that 
    financial transmission rights will provide a hedge against long-term 
    fluctuations in spot prices, will encourage the development of 
    competitive markets and will likely contribute to efficient generation 
    and transmission resource planning. SMUD emphasizes that, without the 
    pricing hedge provided by such rights, it cannot guarantee its 
    customer-owners low cost or reliable transmission service.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \486\ See, e.g., PJM, SMUD, DOE, Enron/APX/Coral Power, EPSA, 
    NSP, Seattle, Professor Hogan, EME.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A number of commenters emphasize that transmission rights must be 
    tradeable in a secondary market.\487\ Indeed, some commenters believe 
    that the use of firm (physical) transmission rights along with a robust 
    secondary market in these rights is the most workable solution for 
    efficient congestion management.\488\ Seattle notes that with an 
    effective market for transmission rights, market participants may be 
    afforded transmission-based options for resolving congestion. It states 
    that market participants that invest in transmission facilities that 
    increase capacity can receive the right to use or sell that capacity. 
    Enron/APX/Coral Power believes that the RTO should be charged with 
    developing a workable market approach to congestion and parallel-path 
    management based on clear and tradeable rights for transmission usage 
    that promote efficient regional dispatch, and support the emergence of 
    secondary markets for transmission rights. Enron/APX/Coral Power 
    contends that this will require that RTO systems be operated as they 
    are in the Western Interconnection based on physical rights. It 
    suggests that, in order to ensure a firm right to schedule service over 
    an interface when it is constrained, a customer would have to 
    demonstrate ownership of sufficient property rights in the interface. 
    Enron/APX/Coral Power suggests three options for obtaining rights: (1) 
    From the RTO in the primary auction or other primary form of 
    allocation; (2) from holders of rights in the secondary market; and (3) 
    from the RTO in the form of short-term released rights not scheduled by 
    their holders. Enron/APX/Coral Power states that by defining and 
    enhancing physical property rights, the market for those rights will 
    provide ex ante transmission prices that include the cost of purchasing 
    rights in constrained interfaces. It claims that this will permit 
    dispatch decisions to be made on the basis of delivered energy prices. 
    Enron/APX/Coral Power states that to ensure that no market participant 
    can exercise market power by hoarding property rights, the rights 
    should be designed as use-or-lose so that if a right is not scheduled 
    it can be used by others on a non-firm basis.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \487\ See, e.g., DOE, NSP, Enron/APX/Coral Power, Seattle, 
    Nevada Commission.
        \488\ See, e.g., APX, Enron/APX/Coral Power, Tri-State, Desert 
    STAR.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Similarly, Dynegy proposes a physical rights model in which a 
    limited amount of firm physical rights would be sold and only those 
    holding physical rights would be allowed to schedule when capacity is 
    constrained. Under Dynegy's proposal, only those with preassigned FTRs 
    would be allowed to schedule on a firm basis at a set price. Dynegy 
    states that others could submit non-firm schedules, subject to 
    curtailment, or, if the party is willing, redispatch. Dynegy adds that 
    the proponents of rights that are financial only argue that it is 
    impossible to define physical rights as ``100 percent firm'' from a 
    given source to a given sink. Dynegy states that, while such arguments 
    are convincing, the capacity between a source and sink may actually be 
    available for a significant percentage of the time to a reasonable 
    degree of certainty and, accordingly, could be sold as firm.
        APX states that the definition of transmission property rights 
    requires the calculation of stable power distribution factors that show 
    the proportion of a power transaction that flows over each path on the 
    grid connecting the source-sink pair. It states that after defining the 
    property rights, the RTO can conduct an auction to allocate them. APX 
    states that, following the auction, holders of transmission rights can 
    retain them or trade them in a secondary forward market. APX believes 
    that FTR trading will provide a more direct and comprehensive valuation 
    of rights than LMP. Desert STAR states that it plans to rely on firm 
    transmission rights markets as the primary vehicle for managing 
    commercially significant congestion, and the use of incremental/
    decremental generation bids to manage other congestion.
        Other commenters, however, doubt that a system of physical 
    transmission rights can be used effectively to manage congestion.\489\ 
    NERA states that most commodity markets operate according to a process 
    based on physical contracts or rights traded in decentralized markets 
    separated from physical operations. NERA adds, however, that most 
    commodities do not flow on an integrated grid where network 
    externalities are so strong and complex that a monopoly system operator 
    is needed. NERA argues that network externalities on any complex 
    electricity grid make it virtually impossible to define physical 
    transmission rights that will use the system fully and yet can be 
    traded in decentralized markets. Also, Professor Joskow believes that 
    on complex electric power networks with loop flow, a financial rights 
    system can be designed more easily and can work more smoothly and 
    efficiently than can a physical rights system.\490\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \489\ See, e.g., NERA, Professor Joskow, Allegheny.
        \490\ Professor Joskow notes that Enron/APX/Coral Power claims 
    that two unpublished papers he has co-authored with Jean Tirole 
    conclude that physical rights designed on a use-it-or-lose-it basis 
    (so that they cannot be hoarded) more effectively prevent the 
    exercise of market power than financial rights, which can always be 
    hoarded. He states that this is not what the papers conclude.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Some commenters offer additional notes of caution regarding the use 
    of transmission rights. For example, APPA states that one must guard 
    against market participants using transmission rights to act 
    strategically. APPA argues that if a generator can adversely affect 
    transfer capability, it may seek to purchase and resell transmission 
    rights in the secondary market after manipulating its internal 
    operations to create congestion on the grid. RECA considers proposals 
    that allow customers to purchase long-term rights to mitigate the risk 
    of congestion pricing to be unacceptable because such proposals result 
    in long-term firm customers having to pay a premium for price 
    stability. Also, CSU contends that no party should hold any entitlement 
    over a constrained path due to transmission ownership which predates 
    the formation of the RTO. CSU argues that, because all parties 
    dedicating bulk transmission assets to the RTO will be fully 
    compensated for their embedded costs, there should exist no reserved 
    rights of use other than those purchased from the RTO. In addition, 
    Great River is concerned that the NOPR's proposal regarding the 
    establishment of clear and tradable transmission rights is not 
    consistent with the flexibility that transmission customers currently 
    have under network service. Great River urges the Commission to 
    carefully consider congestion management proposals that preserve 
    network-like
    
    [[Page 884]]
    
    service, even if such proposals do not result in the identification of 
    asset-based transmission rights.
        Other Mechanisms for Managing Congestion. Some commenters support 
    yet other market mechanisms for managing congestion.491 EPSA 
    notes that other pricing approaches that deserve consideration include 
    the RTO's use of supply-side bids to relieve congestion in load 
    pockets, as well as the use of bilateral arrangements to solve 
    congestion problems. Also, NSP recommends that the RTO offer a 
    ``firming'' service, at posted rates, that would provide customers with 
    the assurance that their transaction will occur under most curtailment 
    conditions. In addition, NSP proposes that the RTO offer a real-time 
    redispatch service that will allow transmission customers to buy 
    through congestion at real-time prices. Cal ISO notes that the 
    Commission has accepted its zonal approach to congestion management, 
    which relies on market mechanisms to manage inter-zonal congestion. 
    PG&E claims, however, that while providing a more understandable 
    picture of congestion, such a system must still solve the problem of 
    intra-zonal congestion. Also, the Montana Commission recommends that 
    the congestion management regime that was developed as a part of the 
    IndeGO proposal serve as a model for how to manage congestion on the 
    transmission system. However, Avista claims that the IndeGo proposal 
    proved to be too complicated to solve a problem that exists only on a 
    few select transmission paths in the Pacific Northwest.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \491\ See, e.g., Cal ISO, Montana Commission.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Costs and Revenues in Congestion Management. A number of commenters 
    urge the Commission to pay close attention to issues related to the 
    distribution of the costs and revenues of congestion management among 
    market participants.492 In particular, several commenters 
    caution that congestion pricing mechanisms should ensure that 
    congestion costs are fairly allocated and should not result in 
    excessive revenues or monopoly profits for transmission 
    owners.493 APPA states that only after we have a nationwide 
    framework of truly independent RTOs should the Commission consider a 
    new approach to transmission pricing that would allow the RTO to price 
    transmission capacity rights and usage on congested paths above 
    embedded costs while discounting uncongested paths below embedded 
    costs, subject to a balancing account to ensure that the total 
    transmission revenue requirement is not over-recovered.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \492\ See, e.g., TDU Systems, NCPA, Los Angeles, Wyoming 
    Commission, SMUD, South Carolina Authority.
        \493\ See, e.g., APPA, RECA, TDU Systems, Los Angeles, EPSA.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Similarly, TDU Systems believe that while the formation of RTOs is 
    a unique opportunity to experiment with new forms of transmission 
    pricing, the Commission should be mindful that an RTO will be a large 
    regional transmission monopoly. TDU Systems question the wisdom of 
    designing congestion pricing mechanisms to ensure that limited 
    transmission capacity is used by market participants who value that use 
    most highly. It states that such an auction-to-the-highest-bidder 
    approach could reap monopoly rents for transmission providers, at the 
    expense of consumers. TDU Systems thus argues that over-reliance on 
    economic self-interest and market mechanisms in transmission pricing 
    may become a recipe for new forms of undue discrimination. It suggests 
    that an incentive to avoid expanding the system in order to collect 
    monopoly rents can be removed by placing any excess revenues from 
    congestion pricing in a fund earmarked for transmission system 
    expansion.
        TDU Systems also recommends that the Commission encourage 
    congestion management plans that distinguish between congestion caused 
    by the RTO's obligation to provide service to firm transmission 
    customers, and congestion caused for economic reasons. It argues that, 
    in the case of the former, the costs of relieving the congestion should 
    be averaged over the firm RTO transmission customers that are using its 
    system. However, it claims that economic congestion occurs because 
    market participants wish to take advantage of short-term production 
    cost economies to minimize their power costs. In this case, TDU Systems 
    argues that the specific loads purchasing the generation should pay the 
    associated congestion costs. Also, RECA states that long-term firm 
    transmission customers are the ones that use and pay to support the 
    system throughout the year, but the auction approach allows a short 
    term trader to outbid these customers at the very times they need it 
    most. Enron/APX/Coral Power notes that, if the RTO's regulated rates 
    for transmission service, including congestion management, are properly 
    designed to reward the RTO for cutting operating costs and maximizing 
    throughput, then it would not have to assign the grid expansion costs 
    to new generators that interconnect. Instead, the RTO would charge the 
    new generator only the cost of local interconnection with the grid.
        Dynegy claims that, with respect to each transmission provider's 
    system, there is a predictable level of constraints and, similarly, 
    some representative level of costs associated with relieving those 
    constraints. Dynegy believes that such costs should be rolled into firm 
    transmission rates that can be quoted up front and with certainty. 
    Dynegy argues that transmission providers would have an economic 
    incentive to operate their transmission systems efficiently if they are 
    given an uplift cost target, and are rewarded for beating the target 
    and penalized for exceeding the target. EPSA states that some 
    congestion pricing mechanisms can impose potentially huge costs on 
    individual transactions, which can be detrimental to the goal of 
    fostering wholesale competition. EPSA thus urges the Commission to 
    consider whether these pricing mechanisms provide greater benefits than 
    a system that internalizes more of the congestion costs. Indeed, EPSA 
    argues that it is still appropriate to spread many of those costs to 
    all system users because redispatch generally benefits all users of the 
    transmission system.
        NCPA asserts that, in order to prevent large increases in the cost 
    of generation for customers in congested areas, some non-discriminatory 
    way must be found to return the extra revenues collected to those 
    customers. NCPA believes that this will require restructuring of 
    tariffs, but failure to address the problem is likely to keep utilities 
    with customers in congested areas out of the California ISO. Similarly, 
    the South Carolina Authority is concerned that certain centralized 
    market mechanisms would cause cost shifts for those participating in an 
    RTO, and if so, potential participants opt out. Also, the Wyoming 
    Commission is concerned that, by offering rewards for transmission 
    investment such as a higher return on equity, the Commission would 
    effectively be discouraging a more market-oriented review of 
    alternatives to building transmission to solve congestion problems.
        Some commenters emphasize the importance of ensuring full cost 
    recovery for generators that are redispatched by an RTO to alleviate 
    transmission constraints or to provide other support 
    services.494 NERC contends there must not be disincentives, 
    in the form of unrecovered costs, to having generators perform these 
    vital functions. MidAmerican asserts that optimal dispatch will occur 
    during congestion management as long as all power suppliers are fully 
    compensated at
    
    [[Page 885]]
    
    market prices. Cinergy claims that, unless generators have the ability 
    to recover lost revenues for reducing generation in response to 
    congestion management needs, generators have no incentive to follow 
    dispatch orders. SMUD contends that the Commission needs to develop 
    congestion management principles that ensure that market participants 
    will receive fair market value for facilities that they have owned and 
    operated for many years.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \494\ See, e.g., Allegheny, Platte River, NERC.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Importance of Scale in Congestion Management. A number of 
    commenters argue that the achievement of an appropriate scale by an RTO 
    will be important to the effective management of 
    congestion.495 LG&E states that the Commission should 
    require RTOs to be of sufficient size to be capable of meaningfully 
    addressing congestion. It believes that if a proposed RTO's ability to 
    address congestion would be impaired by its size or configuration, then 
    the Commission should either refuse the RTO's application or should 
    condition approval on attaining the necessary size and configuration to 
    manage regional congestion issues. Industrial Consumers state that, 
    although congestion management can be addressed with non-market 
    solutions such as transmission loading relief procedures, it is far 
    better to internalize the problem within an RTO with an appropriate 
    scope and configuration. Minnesota Power notes that, currently, it can 
    have transactions curtailed by two different procedures, NERC 
    Transmission Loading Relief and MAPP Line Loading Relief. It claims 
    that an RTO will provide transmission users with region-wide, standard, 
    congestion management.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \495\ See, e.g., LG&E, ComEd, Midwest ISO Participants, Midwest 
    ISO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Midwest ISO states that an appropriately sized RTO will be able 
    to relieve congestion on a broad scale. However, it claims that its own 
    redispatch options will be limited by the failure of border companies, 
    such as FirstEnergy and AEP, to join it. Also, it notes that longer 
    term congestion relief involves the construction of transmission 
    facilities. It claims that, if border companies are not members, the 
    Midwest ISO will not have the ability to coordinate required 
    transmission construction by those entities. Also, the Midwest ISO 
    Participants state that new transmission facilities required to relieve 
    constraints may involve both the companies of the Alliance RTO and the 
    Midwest ISO Participants. The Midwest ISO Participants believe that, 
    with planning and authority split between these two regional entities, 
    these facilities may not be optimally constructed or located.
        Ontario Power, however, takes a different view. It claims that many 
    of the advantages that would flow from expanding U.S. markets to 
    include Ontario can be realized without requiring the Independent 
    Electricity Market Operator (IMO) in Ontario to join a larger RTO at 
    this time. Ontario Power believes that these advantages could be 
    achieved by negotiating agreements between the IMO and other RTOs. 
    Also, Central Maine states that if transmission line loading relief is 
    performed on a market basis, many of the benefits that might result 
    from merging existing ISOs could be realized without actually requiring 
    those ISOs to merge.
        Tri-State argues that the Commission should provide an incentive 
    for non-participating transmission owners to join an RTO by allowing 
    the RTO to use a pricing and congestion management structure that 
    withholds the benefits of the RTO from entities that refuse to turn 
    control of their transmission assets over to the RTO. Also, Vernon 
    claims that non-participants can take unfair advantage of ISO-
    controlled facilities by scheduling their own loads over ISO grid 
    facilities that parallel the non-participant paths, instead of 
    scheduling them over their own wires. Vernon contends that having thus 
    freed up their own wires, the non-participants can then put their 
    facilities to various uses, such as to avoid the increased ISO grid 
    congestion.
        Congestion Management Between RTOs. Many commenters believe that 
    effective congestion management must take into account effects that 
    extend beyond the RTO's boundaries.496 NERC states that 
    congestion management approaches that work within a particular region 
    may not adequately deal with transactions that originate or terminate 
    outside the region. NERC believes that as RTOs develop congestion 
    management approaches, the Commission must require that they be 
    compatible with what is happening elsewhere.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \496\ See, e.g., NERC, Mass Companies, Industrial Consumers, 
    Montana Commission, Indiana Commission, AEP.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Industrial Consumers believe that congestion management, especially 
    during emergency conditions, is an interconnection-wide responsibility. 
    It asserts that, if multiple RTOs are allowed within an 
    interconnection, congestion management must be coordinated across RTO 
    boundaries. Industrial Consumers argues that an RTO can accomplish this 
    only by sharing data on system conditions (e.g., ATC calculations) with 
    neighboring RTOs, agreeing to protocols for cross-boundary actions to 
    mitigate congestion, and cooperating in a process to ensure fair 
    compensation to generators that are redispatched.
        UAMPS believes that if a state is involved in the consideration of 
    various potential solutions to regional congestion, it will likely be 
    more willing to accept that a particular proposal to construct new 
    transmission within its borders is indeed the most efficient solution 
    to a genuine problem, and to provide the necessary approvals for that 
    construction.
        Transcos and Congestion Management. Some commenters are concerned 
    that, if a for-profit company owns transmission (e.g., a transco), it 
    may not have the correct incentives to manage congestion 
    efficiently.497 ISO-NE argues that if such a company seeks 
    to operate transmission and markets as an RTO, it will have competing 
    responsibilities and economic interests. ISO-NE believes that, given 
    the company's economic motivations, market participants may have 
    insufficient confidence in such a company's determinations of whether a 
    transmission-expansion solution to congestion is preferable to a 
    generation-based solution. EAL believes that compensating a wire-owning 
    RTO on the basis of invested capital could lead to over-building of 
    transmission. New Smyrna Beach is concerned that a for-profit 
    transmission company will exhibit a bias toward transmission 
    construction when other, more economical alternatives might exist. New 
    Smyrna Beach states that the Commission should consider requiring the 
    RTO to conduct a competitive bidding process when it determines that 
    transmission construction, or an alternative, is needed to relieve 
    transmission constraints.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \497\ See, e.g., ISO-NE, EAL, New Smyrna Beach, Industrial 
    Consumers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Industrial Consumers asserts that transcos would compete head-on 
    with generation companies wherever there is congestion. It thus 
    believes that transcos-as-RTOs would have a serious conflict of 
    interest if they have the authority over congestion management and over 
    the decision whether to eliminate congestion with new generation or 
    transmission facilities. Industrial Consumers believes that where new 
    generation is a more cost-effective option than construction of new 
    transmission facilities, the cheaper option should be built, and 
    markets should be given the opportunity to make
    
    [[Page 886]]
    
    the choice. Industrial Consumers believes, however, that this will 
    require that the markets have access to redispatch costs, congestion 
    valuations (from a secondary market for capacity reservations), and 
    other data on grid conditions. This is information that is better 
    disclosed by a disinterested independent RTO than a self-interested 
    transco or generation company.
        Cal DWR questions whether either ISOs or transcos have an incentive 
    to use transmission alternatives (such as demand-side management, load 
    shedding, distributed generation, or generation) to reduce the overall 
    cost of transmission. However, it believes that this problem may be 
    more acute for a transco, for which revenues and return are directly 
    tied to the use of their transmission assets.
        However, other commenters claim that there is no basis for concerns 
    that a transco will favor a transmission solution to 
    constraints.498 Entergy contends that, if a generation 
    solution is the most efficient way to resolve congestion, a new 
    generator will likely realize that and try to locate in the appropriate 
    area. Entergy states that an RTO's obligations as an open access 
    transmission provider leave it with no choice but to interconnect with 
    the new generator. Also, Entergy argues that an RTO will not have the 
    unfettered ability to propose and build inefficient transmission 
    solutions. It believes that review by state regulators with siting 
    authority, and prudence review by the Commission, will make it 
    difficult for an RTO to build inefficient and unnecessary transmission 
    additions. Enron/APX/Coral Power and JEA believe that a transco may, in 
    fact, be well suited for congestion management. Enron/APX/Coral Power 
    states that placing responsibility for managing congestion in the RTO's 
    hands complements their view that an RTO-Transco must be obligated to 
    assume delivery risk (i.e., deliver physically firm power) in exchange 
    for being rewarded for cutting costs and increasing system throughput.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \498\ See, e.g., Trans-Elect, FirstEnergy, Entergy.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Need for Flexibility in the Design of Market Mechanisms. 
    Commenters in general showed considerable support for the NOPR's 
    proposal to give RTOs considerable flexibility in experimenting with 
    different market approaches to managing congestion.499 Mass 
    Companies state that the NOPR's willingness to allow RTOs latitude to 
    develop local approaches to congestion management is particularly 
    appropriate, given the difference in conditions in different parts of 
    the country. CP&L believes that congestion management is an area where 
    a one-size-fits-all solution would miss the mark and unnecessarily 
    increase the cost of forming and operating an RTO. SRP believes that a 
    flexible approach is needed because the use of market mechanisms for 
    congestion management is in its infancy, and poorly designed market 
    mechanisms can exacerbate problems and adversely impact reliability.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \499\See, e.g., Mass Companies, SRP, CP&L, Southern Comany, PJM/
    NEPOOL Customers, United Illuminating, Georgia Commission, JEA, 
    Florida Commission, NYPP, Cinergy.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Florida Commission states that the details of proposals for 
    managing congestion using a market mechanism should be determined on a 
    regional basis with endorsement by the state regulatory body. The 
    Florida Commission recommends that the Commission continue to monitor 
    discussions of these issues within NERC and not duplicate or foreclose 
    their development and resolution at NERC.
        Montana-Dakota recommends that the Commission not limit the 
    experimentation with market mechanisms to the provision of firm 
    transmission service. Montana-Dakota believes that there is potential 
    to further improve transmission services by allowing RTOs the ability 
    to implement congestion management methods for non-firm services rather 
    than relying only on the use of TLR to curtail such services.
        Many commenters express support for the proposal to allow RTOs 
    flexibility in developing approaches to congestion 
    pricing.500 Some, such as Florida Power Corp. and Desert 
    STAR, believe that allowing flexibility in pricing may provide 
    incentives for transmission owners to join or form an RTO. Florida 
    Power Corp. argues that such flexibility allows transmission owners to 
    deal with issues such as cost shifting, and believes that providing 
    more specific guidance will only limit possible options.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \500\ See, e.g., PJM/NEPOOL Customers, United Illuminating, 
    Florida Power Corp., Desert STAR, Oregon Commission, NERC.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        However, the FTC cautions that the Commission should not allow its 
    policy of flexibility to continue indefinitely. The FTC states that 
    although experimentation with transmission congestion pricing 
    alternatives to LMP may be appropriate at present, it does not believe 
    that great uncertainty about the most effective approach to 
    transmission congestion management need exist indefinitely. It suggests 
    that the Commission may wish to establish a date in the not-too-distant 
    future when it will undertake a comparative analysis of the consumer 
    costs and benefits of alternative transmission pricing regimes. The FTC 
    states that if one or more approaches provide substantially superior 
    results for consumers, the Commission may wish to initiate a rulemaking 
    on policies to encourage RTOs to adopt these approaches. The Oregon 
    Commission recommends that the Commission evaluate the effectiveness 
    and efficiency of various congestion pricing experiments, and based on 
    its evaluation, require RTOs to use the better methods. However, the 
    Oregon Commission estimates that the process of refining congestion 
    pricing methods may take a decade or more.
        NERC states that there are strongly held, differing opinions 
    throughout the industry on how congestion prices should be designed. 
    NERC states that, while flexibility is one important consideration, the 
    various regional solutions must be able to work together. It believes 
    that the Commission can provide the leadership needed to bring the 
    industry to closure on these issues. NERC notes that this may require 
    the Commission to be more proscriptive, and it should not hesitate to 
    do so. In this regard, Minnesota Power suggests that the Commission 
    encourage neighboring RTOs with constrained interfaces to jointly 
    develop constraint relief procedures including common constraint 
    pricing where appropriate.
        Timing of Implementation.With regard to the NOPR's proposal to 
    allow RTO's up to one year after start-up to implement the congestion 
    management function, commenters express a variety of opinions. Some 
    indicate that one year is an appropriate additional time 
    period.501 Others, however, believe that it is essential 
    that the RTO have some form of congestion management system in place 
    when it begins operation.502 SMUD and CMUA state that a 
    significant deterrent to participating in the Cal ISO has been the fact 
    that, in California, Cal ISO transmission is strictly a short-term 
    transaction given that Cal ISO has not yet fully implemented FTRs. SMUD 
    emphasizes that, without the hedge provided by FTRs, it cannot 
    guarantee its customer-owners low cost or reliable transmission 
    service. TANC believes that allowing an RTO to begin operations without 
    a congestion management procedure in place greatly increases the 
    opportunity for market power abuses as well as market inefficiency.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \501\ See, e.g., Industrial Consumers, Allegheny, PGE, Entergy.
        \502\ See, e.g., SMUD, Tri-State, CMUA, TANC, Desert STAR, 
    Cinergy.
    
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [[Page 887]]
    
        Duke states that, ideally, the permanent congestion management 
    function should be in place on the first day of RTO operation. Then, 
    Duke notes, it would not be necessary to incur the cost of 
    implementing, and developing strategies and behavior appropriate to an 
    initial system, only to have to incur additional costs and changes in 
    behavior to adapt to a permanent system. However, Duke states that 
    congestion management issues are complex and substantial information 
    management systems must be put in place. Consequently, Duke believes 
    one year from the time the RTO becomes operational may not be a 
    sufficient length of time to implement the congestion management 
    function.
        Desert STAR states that the new approaches to congestion management 
    called for by newly competitive markets will take additional time to 
    work out and, therefore, the Commission should be willing to consider 
    additional time on a case-by-case basis. However, in order to ensure 
    reliable operation, Desert STAR believes some congestion management 
    system must be in place when the RTO begins operation.
        Some commenters believe that more than one year of additional time 
    may be needed for the RTO to implement the congestion management 
    function. NSP states that if the RTO has a state-estimator model with 
    the necessary properties, it is possible that a congestion management 
    system, of the type preferred by NSP, could be implemented within about 
    18 months from the time of project initiation. However, for regions 
    without the necessary models, NSP expects the time-line would likely be 
    three years from time of project initiation.
        Montana Power believes that there will be many ``growing pains'' 
    associated with implementation of RTOs that will take time to work out, 
    especially in areas like the Pacific Northwest, which have no history 
    of tight pool operation. Montana Power believes that allowing one-year 
    for implementing a market mechanism for congestion management is a very 
    aggressive schedule. Montana Power thus encourages the Commission to 
    allow up to three years. Similarly, Avista states that, with the IndeGo 
    experience in mind, it encourages the Commission to allow two to three 
    years for implementation of this function, especially where it is 
    demonstrated that the RTO will comply immediately with other 
    characteristics and functions identified in the Commission's Final 
    Rule.
        The Florida Commission believes that the Commission should not 
    impose any arbitrary time period for implementation of congestion 
    management. It states that NERC is working with the regions on this 
    issue and FERC should monitor those activities before setting any 
    deadlines, if at all. Also, JEA believes that requiring the congestion 
    management function to be in place within one year from the start-up of 
    RTO operation may be feasible only for those RTOs structured as 
    transcos from the beginning.
        Commission Conclusion. As we proposed in the NOPR, we conclude that 
    an RTO must ensure the development and operation of market mechanisms 
    to manage congestion. Furthermore, as we proposed, we will require that 
    responsibility for operating these market mechanisms reside either with 
    the RTO itself or with an another entity that is not affiliated with 
    any market participant.
        We agree with the large number of commenters that believe that the 
    use of market mechanisms to manage congestion is superior to the use of 
    administrative curtailment procedures or other approaches that do not 
    take into account the relative value of transactions that are curtailed 
    and those that are allowed to go forward. In addition, we conclude that 
    the RTO or an independent entity must assume an active role in 
    developing and implementing any congestion market mechanisms, because 
    the use of such mechanisms must necessarily be closely coordinated with 
    the operational activities that the RTO performs on a day-to-day and, 
    in many cases, moment-to-moment basis.
        Some commenters argue that an RTO should not be allowed to operate 
    a centralized market for congestion management. The commenters contend 
    that, if such a market is operated by an RTO or other entity that is 
    independent of the market, a robust market in forward contracts for 
    energy will not develop. As a result, these commenters claim, society 
    will never obtain the efficiency benefits that would otherwise flow 
    from a marketplace in which buyers and sellers are able to trade 
    actively among themselves. These commenters also argue that the price 
    certainty provided by forward markets will be replaced with the 
    uncertainty of prices that are determined after the fact.
        We disagree with these commenters and see no reason why the RTO's 
    operation of a market for congestion management should inhibit the 
    ability of others to offer forward contracts for energy, or other 
    market instruments that provide price certainty. We recognize that some 
    of the market redispatch programs undertaken to date are experimenting 
    with various ways to manage congestion efficiently-including relying 
    upon decentralized markets to effect the necessary 
    redispatch.503 It is too early to tell if these 
    decentralized markets will work efficiently. But given the short time 
    frame in which system operators often must react to congestion 
    situations, experience may ultimately show that markets for congestion 
    management can achieve more efficient and effective results if they are 
    centrally operated. Therefore, we will not deny here the RTO, or other 
    independent entity, the opportunity to operate a market--either 
    centralized or de-centralized--for congestion management.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \503\ See, e.g., the market redispatch experiment of NERC 
    (Docket No. ER99-2012-000).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As we proposed in the NOPR, we will require the RTO to implement a 
    market mechanism that provides all transmission customers with 
    efficient price signals regarding the consequences of their 
    transmission use decisions. We are convinced that efficient congestion 
    management requires that transmission customers be made aware of the 
    cost consequences of their actions in an accurate and timely manner, 
    and we believe that this is best accomplished through such a market 
    mechanism. Also, as we proposed in the NOPR, we believe that congestion 
    pricing proposals should seek to ensure that (1) the generators that 
    are dispatched in the presence of transmission constraints are those 
    that can serve system loads at least cost, and (2) limited transmission 
    capacity is used by market participants that value that use most 
    highly. Although we agree with some commenters that price signals can 
    also assist in determining the efficient size and location of new 
    generation and grid expansions, we share the view of LIPA and others 
    that price signals alone cannot be relied upon to identify all needed 
    enhancements.
        While we will not prescribe a specific congestion pricing 
    mechanism, we note that some approaches appear to offer more promise 
    than others. As we stated in our order approving the PJM ISO and 
    reiterated in the NOPR, markets that are based on locational marginal 
    pricing and financial rights for firm transmission service appear to 
    provide a sound framework for efficient congestion 
    management.504 A number of commenters express strong support 
    for the LMP approach. As PJM notes in its comments, LMP assesses 
    congestion charges directly to transmission customers in a manner 
    consistent with
    
    [[Page 888]]
    
    each customer's actual use of the system and the actual dispatch that 
    its transactions cause. In addition, LMP facilitates the creation of 
    financial transmission rights, which enable customers to pay known 
    transmission rates and to hedge against congestion charges. We further 
    note that, where financial rights holders are entitled to receive a 
    share of congestion revenues, the availability of such rights helps to 
    address the concerns of commenters who fear that congestion pricing can 
    lead to the over-recovery of transmission costs. The Commission 
    recognizes, however, that LMP can be costly and difficult to implement, 
    particularly by entities that have not previously operated as tight 
    power pools.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \504\ See PJM, 81 FERC at 62,252-53.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The principal alternative to LMP advocated by commenters is an 
    approach that manages congestion by means of physical transmission 
    rights that are tradable in a secondary market. Under this approach, 
    the RTO may be required to issue the transmission rights initially 
    through an auction or allocation process. Market participants would 
    then generally have to demonstrate ownership of sufficient rights in a 
    constrained interface before they would be allowed to schedule firm 
    service over the interface. Such an approach greatly reduces the role 
    of the RTO in congestion management. While the approach of trading 
    physical transmission rights in a secondary market may prove to be 
    workable in regions where congestion is minor or infrequent, in other 
    regions where congestion is more of a chronic problem, it may not be 
    workable. Also, commenters such as NERA and Professor Hogan claim that 
    the network interactions on complex electricity grids make it difficult 
    to define physical transmission rights that will use the system fully 
    and yet can be traded in decentralized markets. We expect RTOs and any 
    affected stakeholders to consider carefully such issues as they 
    formulate specific pricing proposals.
        While our experience has shown that, in specific situations, some 
    approaches to congestion pricing appear to have advantages over others, 
    we have not yet identified one approach as being clearly superior to 
    all others. Furthermore, the Commission recognizes that an RTO's choice 
    of a congestion pricing method will depend on a variety of factors, 
    many of which may be unique to that RTO. Therefore, we will allow RTOs 
    considerable flexibility to propose a congestion pricing method that is 
    best suited to each RTO's individual circumstances.
        Some commenters appear to confuse the need to redispatch generators 
    to maintain reliability with the need to take specific actions to 
    relieve congestion. Commenters generally agree that the RTO should have 
    clear authority to order redispatch for reliability purposes. However, 
    for congestion management, we conclude here that the RTO should attempt 
    to rely on market mechanisms to the maximum extent practicable. We 
    recognize, of course, that there may be times when even well-
    functioning markets will fail to provide the RTO with the options it 
    needs to alleviate a specific instance of congestion. In those cases, 
    the RTO must have the authority to curtail one or more transmission 
    service transactions that are contributing to the congestion. Although 
    the act of curtailing a transaction may sometimes require the 
    redispatch of generation, we clarify that we are not requiring the RTO 
    to redispatch any generators exclusively for the purpose of managing 
    congestion.
        In the NOPR, we stated that a workable market approach to 
    congestion management should establish clear and tradeable rights for 
    transmission usage, promote efficient regional dispatch, support the 
    emergence of secondary markets for transmission rights, and provide 
    market participants with the opportunity to hedge locational 
    differences in energy prices. Most commenters agree that these are 
    reasonable features of any congestion management proposal. However, 
    Enron/APX/Coral Power believes that the RTO should not be allowed to 
    provide a hedging instrument. It contends that the ``monopoly wires 
    business'' should not be allowed to encroach on what it views as the 
    highly competitive and innovative business of providing hedges against 
    locational price differences of energy or capacity, or against price 
    volatility of these or any other competitive products. In response, we 
    note that, while decentralized markets may ultimately prove to be 
    capable of providing such products, as these commenters claim, we do 
    not yet have evidence to that effect. Therefore, in the interest of 
    allowing RTOs flexibility to experiment with different market 
    approaches, we will not prohibit the RTO from offering such products 
    through markets that it may operate.
        Finally, with regard to the timing of implementation of the 
    congestion management function, we will adopt our proposal to allow the 
    RTO to take up to one year after start-up to implement market 
    mechanisms for managing congestion. Most commenters agree that some 
    period of time is needed for implementation. However, a number of them 
    indicate that the RTO must have some form of congestion management 
    system in place when it begins operation. We agree, and clarify that, 
    upon start-up, the RTO must have in place effective protocols for 
    managing congestion while preserving reliability. Because the NOPR did 
    not make this point explicitly, we do so here.
    3. Parallel Path Flow (Function 3)
        In the NOPR, the Commission proposed to require that an RTO develop 
    and implement procedures to address parallel path flow issues within 
    its region and with other regions.\505\ The Commission noted that 
    measures to address parallel path flow between regions may not 
    necessarily be in place on the first day of RTO operation, and proposed 
    to allow up to three years after start-up for this function to be 
    implemented.\506\ The Commission sought comments on whether such an 
    additional implementation time period is warranted, and whether three 
    years is an appropriate additional time period.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \505\ The terms ``parallel path flow'' and ``loop flow'' are 
    sometimes used interchangeably to refer to the unscheduled 
    transmission flows that occur on adjoining transmission systems when 
    power is transferred in an interconnected electrical system.
        \506\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,743-44.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments. Virtually all commenters support the NOPR's proposal to 
    require that an RTO develop and implement procedures to address 
    parallel path flow issues as a separate function.\507\ Industrial 
    Consumers states that parallel path flow-related disputes will diminish 
    as a result of RTOs addressing this issue.\508\ But PGE notes that 
    grandfathering existing transmission contracts may impede the RTO's 
    ability to address loop flow.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \507\ See, e.g., ComEd, East Texas Cooperatives, EPSA, 
    Industrial Consumers, LG&E, NASUCA, NSP, PJM, Southern Company and 
    Williams. However, Cinergy argues that parallel path flows should 
    not be considered as a separate function but should be considered as 
    a characteristic under the scope and regional configuration because 
    that will allow an RTO to address congestion management issues along 
    with parallel path issues.
        \508\ Industrial Consumers also notes that the first sentence in 
    the proposed regulation should be modified to read as ``RTO must 
    develop and implement procedures to address parallel path flow 
    issues within its region and with other regions in the 
    interconnection within which it resides.'' (Suggested change 
    underlined)
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Many commenters assert that parallel path flow and congestion 
    management issues are closely related to one another since both the 
    issues involve identification of power flows resulting from a specific 
    transaction.\509\ Therefore, they argue that any solution to parallel 
    path flow should recognize
    
    [[Page 889]]
    
    this close relationship. For example, Industrial Consumers believes 
    that an RTO can take preemptive actions against potential curtailment 
    situations to manage congestion resulting from loading of chronically 
    constrained transmission interfaces due to loop flow. PJM suggests that 
    the use of redispatch solutions like LMP not only is more efficient and 
    beneficial to a competitive market, but is preferable to curtailing 
    transactions under TLR to address congestion due to loop flow. South 
    Carolina Authority is convinced that over the long run the problem of 
    parallel path flow needs to be addressed as a planning issue, focusing 
    on appropriate reinforcements to constrained transmission lines.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \509\ See, e.g., EPSA, Florida Power Corp., FTC, Georgia 
    Transmission, LG&E, Mass Companies, NSP and PJM.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Many commenters recommend that an RTO should encompass as large a 
    region as possible so that it can ``internalize'' most of the loop flow 
    within its region.\510\ However, others argue that the loop flow issue 
    can be solved satisfactorily only if it is addressed at the 
    interconnection level.\511\ They believe that while a large RTO will 
    ``internalize'' most of the parallel path flows within its region, 
    parallel path flows between RTOs will remain. Some other commenters are 
    convinced that cooperative efforts among regional entities works best 
    when it comes to resolving issues such as parallel path flow 
    issue.\512\ NERC notes that it is in the process of developing the 
    needed information system to address the parallel path flow issue on an 
    interconnection basis and urges the Commission to direct the RTOs to 
    work closely with it to coordinate efforts to resolve this issue. 
    Southern Company and Industrial Consumers support NERC's initiative in 
    solving the loop flow issue. Cleveland states that the national grid 
    should be viewed as a single electrical system which calls for a 
    universal approach rather than a regional approach to resolve the loop 
    flow issue. The universal approach, Cleveland argues, will not only 
    improve the integrity and reliability of the national grid but also 
    eliminate the need for any policy shift in the future.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \510\ See, e.g., LG&E, Michigan Commission, NASUCA, New Smyrna 
    Beach, NSP, PJM and South Carolina Authority.
        \511\ See, e.g., Cleveland, East Texas Cooperatives, Georgia 
    Transmission, Industrial Consumers, NY ISO, Southern Company, TEP. 
    Industrial Consumers note that several other issues need to be 
    addressed at the interconnection level and not at the regional 
    level. They are ATC calculation, inadvertent flows and congestion 
    management.
        \512\ Central Maine Reply at 9; NYPP Reply at 10.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commenters from Western System Coordinating Council (WSCC) assert 
    that the loop flow issue in their region was solved by the adoption of 
    WSCC Flow Mitigation Plan (Plan) that provides for controlling 
    unscheduled flows through the use of phase shifting transformers.\513\ 
    SRP suggests loop flow in WSCC should continue to be addressed at the 
    WSCC level and not at the RTO level because WSCC may end up with four 
    or more RTOs. PG&E recommends that the establishment of property rights 
    such as FTRs be explored as a means to solve loop flow issues, on the 
    basis that developing property rights will ensure the most efficient 
    use of the transmission lines. Enron/APX/Coral Power urges RTOs in the 
    Eastern Interconnection to move toward the Western model. NASUCA 
    believes that RTOs should perform a cost-benefit analysis of 
    controlling loop flows with phase shifting transformers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \513\ See, e.g., PG&E, Seattle, SRP and TEP.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Most commenters support the NOPR's proposal for an additional 
    implementation time period of three years for coordination among 
    RTOs.\514\ They argue that the proper resolution of loop flow presents 
    a number of complex issues that may require negotiations and agreements 
    among neighboring RTOs and that the additional time period will give 
    them an opportunity to coordinate their efforts. Allegheny supports an 
    additional time period for implementation of this function but urges 
    the contract path methodology be replaced at a faster pace than three 
    years. Industrial Consumers notes that an additional time period of 
    three years is necessary for NERC to solve the loop flow issue at the 
    interconnection level. However, Florida Power Corp. and Florida 
    Commission observe that the severity of parallel path flow varies from 
    region to region and therefore opposes setting an arbitrary time limit 
    for the implementation of this function. Duke likewise believes that 
    the deadline for the implementation of this function should be 
    determined by the Commission on a case-by-case basis.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \514\ See, e.g., Cal ISO, Desert STAR, Entergy, Industrial 
    Consumers, NECPUC, NERC, NY ISO, PGE, SRP, Tri-State, TVA, UtiliCorp 
    and WPSC. Cleveland also argues that a similar grace period should 
    be given for the implementation of function # 5. (TTC and ATC 
    Calculation). Cleveland at 14.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commission Conclusion. We reaffirm our preliminary determination 
    that an RTO should develop and implement procedures to address parallel 
    path flow issues within its region and with other regions. Most 
    commenters agree that the formation of RTOs, with their widened 
    geographic scope of transmission scheduling and expanded coverage of 
    uniform transmission pricing structures, provide an opportunity to 
    ``internalize'' most, if not all, of the effect of parallel path flow 
    in their scheduling and pricing process within a region. NERC notes 
    that it is in the process of developing the needed information system 
    to address parallel path issues on an interconnection basis, and we 
    will direct RTOs to work closely with NERC, or its successor 
    organization, to resolve this issue. As noted by Industrial Consumers, 
    parallel path flow-related disputes will diminish as a result of RTOs 
    addressing this issue.
        Commenters from Western System Coordinating Council (WSCC) state 
    that they adopted the WSCC Flow Mitigation Plan (Plan) to address 
    parallel path flow issue in their region. SRP suggests that parallel 
    path flow in WSCC continue to be addressed at the WSCC level and not at 
    the RTO level because WSCC may end up with more than one RTO. We will 
    not here make any judgments on the merits of WSCC's Plan as a solution 
    for parallel path flow issues. However, we clarify that this rule does 
    not prevent addressing parallel path flow issues on a larger-than-
    single-RTO basis. In fact, we require RTOs to develop and implement 
    procedures for addressing parallel flow issues with other regions.
        In the NOPR we proposed that the RTO have measures in place on the 
    date of initial operation to address parallel path flow issues within 
    its own region. We also noted that measures to address parallel path 
    flow issues between RTO regions may not necessarily be in place on the 
    first day of RTO operation. We proposed to allow up to three years 
    after start-up for this function to be implemented. Most commenters 
    support the NOPR's proposal for an additional time period of three 
    years. A few commenters \515\ prefer a case-by-case approach. Since 
    severity of the parallel path flow varies from region to region, some 
    parts of the Nation may choose to resolve inter-regional parallel path 
    flow issues sooner than the required three years. Consequently, we will 
    adopt our proposal in the NOPR that the RTO have measures in place to 
    address parallel path flow issues in its region on the date of initial 
    operation. We also adopt three years as an adequate time period for 
    implementation of measures to address parallel path flow issues between 
    regions.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \515\ Florida Power Corp., Florida Commission and Duke.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We recognize that these measures to address parallel path flows 
    combined with the requirement that the RTO be the sole provider of 
    transmission services over facilities that it owns or controls will 
    eliminate or diminish the ability of transmission users to choose among 
    different contract paths owned by different service providers within 
    the
    
    [[Page 890]]
    
    RTO region. However, these users will have the ability to move power 
    anywhere within the RTO at a single rate and under a single set of 
    terms and conditions. We believe this is pro-competitive and represents 
    one of the fundamental benefits that is envisioned by the Rule. As we 
    noted in the NOPR, the creation of large RTOs that can internalize 
    most, if not all, of the effect of parallel path problems through their 
    scheduling and pricing actions provides a unique opportunity to resolve 
    a major operating concern that has caused problems on both the Eastern 
    and Western Interconnections and which is a significant impediment to 
    promoting efficient competition in generation markets.\516\ Therefore, 
    in reviewing the competitive implications of a proposed RTO application 
    under section 203, we believe that any inability of transmission 
    customers to choose among different contract path suppliers within an 
    RTO will be outweighed by their enhanced ability to reach numerous 
    buyers and sellers of electricity throughout the region.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \516\ See FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,744.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    4. Ancillary Services (Function 4)
        The fourth proposed minimum function is that the RTO must serve as 
    the supplier of last resort for all ancillary services required by 
    Order No. 888.\517\ This supply obligation for the RTO is necessary 
    because only the single grid operator will be able to provide certain 
    ancillary services, not all transmission customers may be able to self-
    supply (some own generation, others do not), and because it typically 
    is more efficient for the RTO to provide some ancillary services for 
    all transmission users on an aggregated basis.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \517\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,744.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In carrying out this function, the Commission proposed that all 
    market participants would have the option of self-supplying or 
    acquiring ancillary services from third parties. In addition, the RTO 
    must have the authority to decide the minimum required amounts of each 
    ancillary service and, if necessary, the locations at which these 
    services must be provided; must be able to exercise direct or indirect 
    operational control over all ancillary service providers; must promote 
    the development of competitive markets for ancillary services whenever 
    feasible; and must ensure that its transmission customers have access 
    to a real-time balancing market.
        Comments. Supplier of Last Resort. Comments on whether an RTO 
    should serve as a supplier of last resort are mixed. A large number of 
    commenters support the Commission's proposal, as written.\518\ Detroit 
    Edison believes that the RTO should serve as the sole supplier of 
    ancillary services to transmission customers and that the RTO should be 
    permitted either to purchase services directly from generation 
    suppliers or to purchase generation resources for this purpose. First 
    Energy believes that the RTO's obligation as the supplier of last 
    resort for ancillary services cannot be eliminated, since it is the 
    basis of reliability.\519\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \518\ See, e.g., Entergy, Industrial Consumers, NECPUC, Cal ISO, 
    EPSA, FirstEnergy, LG&E, PacifiCorp, Empire District, EME, Southern 
    Company, UtiliCorp, PGE, PNGC, PSNM, TDU Systems, Nevada Commission.
        \519\ See also Florida Power Corp.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        On the other hand, a few commenters suggest that the Commission 
    allow flexibility. Duke believes that an RTO should always have the 
    responsibility for ensuring that transmission customers have arranged 
    adequate ancillary service and that those services are delivered. They 
    suggest that where a competitive market for ancillary services exists, 
    the RTO should not be required to provide such ancillary services as a 
    supplier of last resort.\520\ And a number of commenters take issue 
    with one or more aspects of the proposed requirements, although many of 
    these commenters generally support the proposal.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \520\ See, e.g., NASUCA, Seattle, CalPX, Mass Companies.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        For example, some commenters suggest that more information is 
    needed. Southern Company suggests that the Commission allow NERC to 
    finalize an ancillary services policy before mandating changes to 
    ancillary service requirements.\521\ Professor Hogan suggests further 
    investigation into developments in ancillary services.\522\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \521\ Southern Company notes that NERC's Interconnected 
    Operations Services Working Group is currently addressing the 
    ancillary services that should be required in a competitive 
    environment and has issued a proposed policy for public comment and 
    review.
        \522\ NWCC recommends that additional research regarding the 
    application of ancillary services to wind and other intermittent 
    generation technologies be conducted.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Other commenters believe that the focus of the proposal should be 
    narrowed. Los Angeles suggests that an RTO should be the ``safety net'' 
    of last resort for providing generation-based ancillary services. As 
    such, the RTO would not play a significant role in the energy market 
    and can remain essentially indifferent to energy market issues. PG&E 
    believes that an RTO could set appropriate rules for ancillary services 
    but would not itself procure such services from the marketplace absent 
    clearly defined emergency situations or in its role as provider of last 
    resort. Avista states that while a transitional ``supplier of last 
    resort'' role may be appropriate, an RTO should generally not become 
    deeply involved in any of the markets for generation services.
        A number of commenters suggest that the obligation to provide 
    ancillary services should be expanded to include more or different 
    sellers. MidAmerican believes that each control area should retain 
    responsibility for the provision of ancillary services and should be 
    allowed to self-provide or acquire necessary ancillary services in the 
    most economical means it sees fit to meet performance compliance 
    standards. East Texas Cooperatives suggests that the Commission require 
    both transmission owners and the RTO to offer ancillary services at 
    cost-based rates unless a seller can demonstrate a competitive market 
    in a particular ancillary service. PPC and Desert STAR also believe 
    that the role of provider of last resort of ancillary services would 
    better rest with local control areas or independent generators that can 
    supply ancillary services. Steel Dynamics requests that the final rule 
    require generation-owning members of RTOs to maintain Commission 
    approved cost-based tariff schedules for ancillary services. Georgia 
    Transmission believes that any RTO members that are capable of 
    providing ancillary services should be the providers of ``first 
    resort,'' and the ability to acquire such services from different 
    providers would enhance competition in these markets.
        While not specifically objecting to the RTO being the supplier of 
    last resort for ancillary services, some parties suggest that the 
    Commission should allow other mechanisms to work.\523\ California Board 
    urges the Commission to allow consideration of other means for ensuring 
    that the need for ancillary services is addressed. It recommends that 
    the final rule reflect a requirement that the RTO filings must indicate 
    how default provision of ancillary services will be accomplished 
    without necessarily requiring the RTO to be the provider of last 
    resort. Enron/APX/Coral Power advocates a form of performance-based 
    ratemaking in which the RTO would have an incentive to perform its 
    ancillary service function as efficiently and economically as possible. 
    Florida Commission recommends that an RTO only be responsible for 
    providing non-competitive ancillary services and
    
    [[Page 891]]
    
    should require users to purchase or self-provide the other competitive 
    services.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \523\ See, e.g., CMUA, LPPC, California Board, San Francisco, 
    Oneok, SMUD, Avista, Sithe, Seattle.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Similarly, FTC suggests that the Commission consider arrangements 
    in which the RTO's primary role is to provide a market mechanism for 
    transmission customers to acquire ancillary services for themselves. It 
    argues that this method may reduce costs by allowing customers to 
    customize their purchases of ancillary services to better fit their 
    specific needs.\524\ Some commenters suggest that final RTO regulations 
    expressly recognize the administration of an ancillary service exchange 
    as an alternative to the provider-of-last-resort obligation that is 
    imposed on a RTO under the proposed regulations.\525\ For example, ISO-
    NE believes that a competitive market for ancillary services is a 
    superior supply mechanism, and ISO-NE suggests that the text of 
    proposed Sec. 35.34(j)(4) be amended to read:
    
        \524\ See also Empire District.
        \525\ See, e.g., Cinergy, APX, EAL, NY ISO, JEA.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        An RTO must develop and maintain a market or other contractual 
    arrangements for the supply of all ancillary services required by 
    Order No. 888, FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 31,036 (Final Rule on Open 
    Access and Stranded Costs), and subsequent orders.
    
        Comments were also sought on the circumstances under which an RTO's 
    obligation as supplier of last resort could be eliminated.\526\ Several 
    commenters believe that the supplier of last resort obligation can be 
    eliminated once a viable competitive market develops within the RTO 
    region.\527\ For example, WPSC suggests that an RTO must continue to 
    fulfill the role of supplier of last resort for these services or a 
    power exchange must be available to supply these services. WPSC 
    believes that it would be difficult to predict the circumstances under 
    which the market for ancillary services is sufficiently robust that the 
    RTO's role as supplier of last resort may be eliminated. WPSC believes 
    that it would be a mistake to eliminate that role in any market where 
    the generation market concentration levels as measured by the 
    Herfindahl-Hirschman Index exceed 1,800. TDU Systems states that it is 
    not aware of a market in any of the ancillary services that is now 
    sufficiently competitive to warrant elimination of an ancillary service 
    from this obligation. However, TDU Systems acknowledges that there may 
    never be a competitive market for certain ancillary services and that 
    an alternative mechanism must be created.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \526\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,745.
        \527\ See, e.g., WPSC, APS, Florida Commission, Duke.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The NOPR also asked for comments on whether a different set of 
    ancillary services requirement for RTOs is needed because RTOs will not 
    own generating resources. Comments on this issue were mixed.
        Sithe and several other commenters 528 generally believe 
    the Commission's initial set of guidelines on ancillary services is 
    reasonable, and that a new set of ancillary services requirements for 
    RTOs is unnecessary. LG&E adds that, as already is the case under the 
    open access tariff, an RTO should be allowed to choose to add to the 
    list of ancillary services in recognition of local or regional 
    conditions. MidAmerican believes that while no additional or revised 
    ancillary services are required, an RTO must ensure that sufficient 
    transmission capacity is available to allow delivery of backup supply, 
    planning reserves and the existing six ancillary services.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \52\ See, e.g., PGE, TDU Systems, Cal ISO, Duke, Tri-State.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        On the other hand, Los Angeles believes that a different set of 
    ancillary services requirements than those required currently from a 
    vertically integrated utility should apply to an RTO which does not own 
    generation resources. They envision an ultimate industry structure of 
    complete desegregation of generation and transmission assets so that 
    any incentive (either real or perceived) for the transmission provider 
    to act in a discriminatory manner is eliminated.
        NSP requests that the Commission refer to the draft NERC policy 
    that discusses the role of an operating authority as an unbundled 
    procurement agent for community ancillary services. They describe this 
    document as a good ``guidepost'' for the Commission to follow in the 
    RTO NOPR, and for the establishment of additional ancillary services 
    such as system blackstart and frequency responsive reserve.\529\ Desert 
    STAR and Cal ISO agree that additional blackstart ancillary service may 
    be required. TDU Systems believes that RTOs should be required to offer 
    backup service and an additional load following service. It describes 
    backup service as required to meet contingencies during periods 
    following those covered by the OATT's reserve services, and load 
    following service as required to complement the OATT's minute-to-minute 
    regulation service with a service matching hour-to-hour variations in 
    load. Industrial Consumers recommends that the Commission remove 
    Schedule 4 (energy imbalance service) from any tariff administered by 
    an RTO. They suggest that this service be provided by the real-time 
    balancing market as proposed in the NOPR.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \529\ See also Eric Hirst.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Self-Supply Option. Nearly all who commented on the self supply 
    option generally agree that, where feasible, all market participants 
    should have the option of self-supplying or acquiring ancillary 
    services from third parties. \530\ Some commenters strongly endorse the 
    self-supply model. For example, APS believes that it should be the aim 
    of the RTO to have each transmission customer self-supply its 
    generation-related ancillary service requirements to the fullest extend 
    practical. Los Angeles suggests that the role of the RTO should be 
    limited to ensuring that the transmission customer has adequately 
    provided for the necessary ancillary services for each transaction, and 
    the RTO provide such services only in the event of non-compliance. It 
    believes that the RTO should develop specific rules and protocols that 
    would support the self-provision of ancillary services. Some 
    commenters, including PJM/NEPOOL Customers and LG&E, suggest that it is 
    important for the development of a competitive market in ancillary 
    services that RTO customers not be required to purchase them from the 
    RTO, and that an RTO must not prohibit or interfere with the ability of 
    all market participants to have the option of acquiring competitive 
    ancillary services or providing such services through buy/sell 
    transactions from customer-owned generation.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \530\ See, e.g., CMUA, Cal ISO, LG&E, PG&E, PJM/NEPOOL 
    Customers, PPC, APX, Metropolitan, MidAmerican, NSP, Seattle, SMUD, 
    Desert STAR, TDU Systems, Tri-State.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        On the other hand, FirstEnergy states that the Commission should be 
    very cautious that policies that encourage self-supply of ancillary 
    services do not compromise the very ability of the RTO to ensure 
    reliable and secure network operation. It maintains that the provision 
    of ``self-supplying'' ancillary services is untested, the 
    infrastructure needed is as yet undeveloped, and the process of 
    providing them could potentially lead to abuses. FirstEnergy identifies 
    this issue as one of the reasons that NERC is pushing for mandatory 
    compliance requirements.\531\ It believes that an RTO must have the 
    ability to evaluate and accept/approve those NERC-certified sources 
    that reliably contribute to support the grid.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \531\ FirstEnergy notes that NERC is developing certification 
    and verification criteria for ancillary service providers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Authority to Determine Amounts and Location of Ancillary Services. 
    Most commenters generally support the proposal that the RTO have the
    
    [[Page 892]]
    
    authority to determine the quantities and, where appropriate, the 
    location at which ancillary services must be provided.\532\ In 
    addition, CMUA suggests that the RTO be responsible for enforcing 
    compliance with established standards.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \532\ See, e.g., Industrial Consumers, PJM, Turlock, Cal ISO, 
    Florida Power Corp., PJM/NEPOOL Customers, LPPC, PGE, SMUD, TDU 
    Systems, NYPP, Tri-State, Nevada Commission.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        PJM/NEPOOL Customers requests that RTO decisions regarding the 
    amounts and locations of ancillary services consider both stakeholder 
    input and NERC standards. It believes that this requirement would 
    ensure that the RTO does not impose unnecessarily high ancillary 
    service obligations that will inhibit the operation of the competitive 
    market. In addition, PJM/NEPOOL Customers asks that the Commission 
    ensure that the RTO exercises this authority only to the extent 
    necessary for reliability purposes, since decisions regarding ancillary 
    services could impact the competitive electricity supply market.
        NYPP requests that the RTO's authority not be exclusive. It 
    suggests that properly constituted local and regional reliability 
    councils authorized by FERC should have the authority to establish 
    criteria necessary to maintain the reliability of the transmission 
    system including the reliability of discrete locations.
        Duke notes that the Commission has previously recognized NERC's 
    leadership role in developing concepts in the area of ancillary 
    services.\533\ It encourages the Commission to recognize and adopt 
    NERC's development of ancillary service definitions and reliability 
    standards.\534\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \533\ Citing FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 31,036 at 31,705 (1996).
        \534\ See also Eric Hirst.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Industrial Consumers and Steel Dynamics request that the Commission 
    first approve the standards by which the RTO determines the 
    requirements. They requests that these standards include the 
    development of ``metrics,'' i.e., standardized units of measurement 
    such that the performance of each service can be verified. In addition, 
    Industrial Consumers recommends modifying the requirement to ensure 
    seamless application between multiple RTOs and for transactions that 
    only go through an RTO. It suggests adding an additional requirement to 
    Sec. 35.34(j)(4)(ii):
    
        The Regional Transmission Organization must support the minimum 
    required amounts of each ancillary service for transactions between 
    itself and other Regional Transmission Organizations in the 
    interconnection and through itself.
    
        Control Over Ancillary Services Providers. All commenters that 
    commented on this subject believe that the RTO should be able to 
    exercise some operational control, either directly or indirectly, over 
    any supplier of ancillary services.535 SMUD supports the RTO 
    establishing well documented and specific operating criteria and the 
    ability to require compliance with such operating criteria, including 
    monetary penalties and commission-approved sanctions. JEA believes that 
    this control should be exerted only where pre-existing contractual 
    rights are established.536
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \535\ See, e.g., PJM, Cal ISO, Florida Power Corp., Cinergy, Los 
    Angeles, PSNM, SMUD, Duke.
        \536\ See also Cinergy.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Some commenters would broaden the requirement. For example, 
    FirstEnergy is concerned that limiting the RTO's control to ancillary 
    services providers rather than all generation located within the RTO 
    may compromise the RTO's ability to operate the transmission system 
    reliably. It suggests that the Commission allow a greater flexibility 
    for the RTO and all generation owners located within the RTO to develop 
    an agreement for provision of ancillary services through the RTO that 
    provides for the necessary requirements for voluntary generation 
    participation in the ancillary services market including operational 
    control if appropriate, and the necessary requirements for calling on 
    ancillary services from connected generation necessary for the reliable 
    operation of the transmission system.
        On the other hand, PJM/NEPOOL Customers suggest that the RTO 
    control be limited to those providers that the RTO will rely on to 
    fulfill its obligation as supplier of last resort for ancillary 
    services. It claims that control over additional generators is 
    unnecessary and may affect the operation of the competitive market.
        Metropolitan recommends that the Commission allow RTO indirect 
    control of existing large hydroelectric plants to protect and 
    facilitate use of existing systems that have been operational for a 
    substantial period of time and to preserve the integrity of the FERC 
    hydro license. It states that allowing indirect control would eliminate 
    the need for costly installation of software and 
    infrastructure.537
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \537\ See also NYPP, PSNM.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Promote Competitive Markets for Ancillary Services.Most commenters 
    support the proposal in the NOPR that RTOs promote competitive markets 
    for ancillary services.538 Seattle suggests that the RTO 
    provide incentives to ensure a robust, transparent market with many 
    buyers and sellers of ancillary services. PJM/NEPOOL Customers states 
    that it is important that the RTO not impede the development of 
    competitive markets for ancillary services and that the RTO actually 
    facilitate the development of these markets. However, it stresses that 
    the RTO and incumbent transmission owners should not be permitted to 
    have market-based rates for ancillary services until a viable 
    competitive market for such services develops.539
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \538\ See, e.g., FTC, LPPC, Avista, APX, PJM/NEPOOL Customers, 
    Seattle.
        \539\ See also TDU Systems.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Sithe advocates that the final rule grant RTOs the authority to 
    administer spot markets for ancillary services and establish rules 
    obligating all participants to meet uniform requirements. PG&E believes 
    that the RTO should not be the sole purchaser of ancillary services. 
    Instead, it should facilitate the development of bilateral markets for 
    as many of the ancillary services as possible, thereby allowing market 
    participants to self-provide those ancillary services.
        Access to Real-Time Balancing Markets. In the NOPR, the Commission 
    proposed that an RTO must ensure that its transmission customers have 
    access to a real-time balancing market. We proposed that the RTO must 
    either develop and operate such markets itself or ensure that this task 
    is performed by another entity that is not affiliated with any market 
    participant. The Commission noted that although system-wide balancing 
    is a critical element of reliable short-term grid operation, this does 
    not necessarily require that there be a moment-to-moment balance 
    between the individual loads and resources of bilateral traders and 
    load-serving entities and the schedules and actual production of 
    individual generators. We also noted that unequal access to balancing 
    options for individual customers can lead to unequal access in the 
    quality of transmission service available to different customers, and 
    that this could be a significant problem for RTOs that serve some 
    customers who operate control areas and other customers who do not. The 
    Commission proposed to give RTOs considerable discretion in how a real-
    time balancing market would be operated.
        We invited comments on the use of market mechanisms to support 
    overall system balancing and imbalances of individual transmission 
    users. In addition, we invited responses to the following questions. Is 
    it feasible to rely on markets to support a function that is so time-
    sensitive? Can such markets be
    
    [[Page 893]]
    
    made to function efficiently if the RTO is not a control area operator? 
    For the imbalances of individual transmission customers, should a 
    distinction be made between loads and generators? Should customers have 
    the option of paying for all imbalances in such a market or only 
    imbalances within a specified band?
        Several commenters hold the view that it is indeed feasible to rely 
    on markets to support a balancing function that is time-
    sensitive,540 and many agree that access to a real-time 
    balancing market would be of considerable benefit to market 
    participants.541 NERA claims that technical logic dictates 
    that an electricity system have a central process to co-ordinate real-
    time physical operations. NERA argues that to the extent that this 
    process is not based on markets, it must be based on less efficient 
    command-and-control methods. NERA also claims that economic and 
    commercial logic requires that a commodity market have short-term 
    trading arrangements to bring market positions into agreement with 
    physical reality, and argues that to the extent that market trading 
    does not reflect physical reality, some non-market process must close 
    the gap between the market and reality. NERA asserts that these two 
    propositions imply that the best way to maximize the role of the market 
    and minimize the role of non-market processes is to base real-time 
    physical operations on a spot market and to allow market participants 
    to use this market for commercial purposes to the extent they find this 
    useful.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \540\ See, e.g., Duke, PJM, Illinois Commission, Cal ISO, NERA.
        \541\ See, e.g., Enron/APX/Coral Power, Eric Hirst, NYPP, 
    Powerex, East Texas Cooperatives, Industrial Consumers, Professor 
    Hogan.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Enron/APX/Coral Power states that access to a real-time energy 
    balancing market is central to assuring comparability in open access, 
    and Industrial Consumers believes that this proposal is the beginning 
    of a much needed ``paradigm shift'' in the manner in which ancillary 
    services are defined and provided in the marketplace. Eric Hirst states 
    that implementation of a real-time balancing market would permit FERC 
    to eliminate the Order No. 888 requirement that transmission providers 
    offer an energy imbalance service to transmission customers. He argues 
    that elimination of energy imbalance service, with its awkward and 
    arbitrary deadband and penalty payments, would be a pro-competitive 
    change. Professor Hogan claims that without an efficient spot market 
    and the associated transparent spot prices, it will be much more 
    expensive and difficult to arrange balancing and settlement for the 
    increasing number of retail access programs in the states. East Texas 
    Cooperatives agrees that real-time balancing markets are desirable but 
    believe that simply commanding RTOs to promote the development of 
    competitive markets for ancillary services provides no incentive for 
    the RTO and its members to do so.
        Also, two commenters argue that access to real-time balancing 
    markets would eliminate some significant barriers to entry for non-
    traditional resources such as renewable and distributed 
    energy.542 In particular, EPA notes that providing such 
    access would eliminate arbitrary energy imbalance penalties that are a 
    major barrier to intermittent resources such as wind and solar energy.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \542\ See EPA and Project Groups.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Some commenters believe that the RTO itself should develop and 
    operate a real-time balancing market.543 PJM/NEPOOL 
    Customers believe that the development of such a market is an essential 
    function of the RTO that will facilitate the further development of 
    retail competitive supply markets. PJM states that a real-time 
    balancing market can best be provided through a power exchange operated 
    by an RTO. Commenters are divided as to whether the development of a 
    real-time balancing market requires that the RTO be a control area 
    operator. Several believe that such markets are possible whether or not 
    the RTO operates a control area.544 Indeed, MidAmerican 
    believes that, to function efficiently, these markets normally must 
    operate in a region that is larger than a typical control area. 
    However, others take an opposite view.545 FirstEnergy, for 
    example, argues that the timing, dispatch and telecommunications 
    infrastructure needed to operate a real-time balancing market today can 
    only be done by a control area operator and then only for a combined 
    load within a control area with ample generation resources under 
    automatic generation control.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \543\ See, e.g., PJM, PJM/NEPOOL Customers, Professor Hogan, 
    NERA.
        \544\ See, e.g., Tri-State, Illinois Commission, MidAmerican, 
    Duke.
        \545\ See, e.g., PJM/NEPOOL Customers, Southern Company, 
    FirstEnergy.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Some commenters provide detailed recommendations regarding the 
    rules that should govern the RTO's operation of real-time balancing 
    markets.546 Professor Hogan notes that the complex network 
    interactions in an electric grid require that there be an entity that 
    can provide certain critical coordinating services, and that the most 
    obvious example of such services is energy balancing. He states that 
    the operator should offer an energy balancing redispatch service where 
    market participants can make offers to buy and sell energy.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \546\ See, e.g., Professor Hogan, Allegheny.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        He believes that the best approach would be to run the balancing 
    market as a ``bid-based, security-constrained economic dispatch'' with 
    voluntary participation by generators and loads. Professor Hogan 
    emphasizes that the RTO must not reject voluntary bids, stating that 
    the natural extension of open access and the principles of choice would 
    suggest that participation in the coordinated balancing market offered 
    by the operator should be voluntary. He states that market participants 
    can evaluate their own economic situation and make their own choice 
    about participating in the operator's economic dispatch or finding 
    similar services elsewhere. He believes that any other rule would 
    require some form of discrimination, and adds that there should be a 
    strong burden of proof for those who argue that it is necessary to 
    restrict voluntary bids, or discard consideration of some bids. 
    Professor Hogan claims that experience in PJM and elsewhere shows that 
    his suggested approach can work.
        However, several commenters take a very different view, claiming 
    that the development of a real-time balancing market is not a viable 
    option.547 For example, FirstEnergy is concerned that a 
    real-time balancing market is not practical to implement. It claims 
    that transmission customers do not yet have the real-time metering and 
    associated communication needed to dispatch and match fluctuating loads 
    to generation. FirstEnergy argues that it would be much better to tie 
    this service to the NERC effort of certifying ancillary service 
    providers for control of generation, and activate the service when the 
    technology and installation can be accommodated. Seattle states that it 
    performs its own real-time energy balancing and expects to continue to 
    do so. Seattle opposes adding this function to an RTO because Seattle 
    believes it will increase the overhead costs of the organization. 
    Seattle believes that market participants that require this service 
    should contract with third parties that stand ready to provide it. 
    Florida Power Corp. states that, given the complexity of implementing 
    short term transmission service in general, it is difficult to imagine 
    that a market for
    
    [[Page 894]]
    
    energy imbalance service could be developed. It argues that if the 
    market is limited to the generators needed for control, the development 
    of market mechanisms will depend on resolving issues such as the 
    mitigation of potential market power. Florida Power Corp. suggests that 
    an RTO could contract with generators to perform this balancing 
    function using a mechanism that is market-like in that generators would 
    be selected based on their bids to perform the function over some 
    designated period of time, albeit not on an hourly basis.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \547\ See, e.g., Seattle, FirstEnergy, Florida Power Corp.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several commenters believe that control areas or RTOs should not be 
    the sole provider of energy imbalance services,548 while 
    others argue that the role of RTOs should be limited to that of a 
    supplier of last resort. 549 UtiliCorp states that, in 
    addition to serving as a supplier of last resort, the RTO must ensure 
    public access to real-time balancing information. SMUD argues that any 
    burden on the RTO that falls outside of the core function of ensuring 
    regional transmission reliability will add cost and complexity to an 
    already costly and complex endeavor. SMUD recommends that the 
    Commission should limit its focus on generation to the role that 
    generation-related service plays in promoting reliable transmission. 
    Desert STAR and FirstEnergy believe that the Commission should give 
    deference to RTOs regarding the development of markets for real-time 
    balancing.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \548\ See, e.g., Southern Company, Tri-State.
        \549\ See, e.g., UtiliCorp, Avista, APX.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        FirstEnergy believes that, ultimately, ancillary service provision 
    must be based on a free-market pricing mechanism, and Southern Company 
    believes that if a real-time balancing market is desired in a region, 
    it will develop without a mandate. FirstEnergy asserts that the 
    detrimental effects of regulated and capped ancillary service markets 
    have been observed in the California and PJM markets. Also, APX 
    believes that the Commission should let the market, not the RTO, 
    provide the trading arrangements in the power industry. APX asserts 
    that efficiency in the competitive market comes from the de-centralized 
    trading activity of self-interested buyers and sellers, and that 
    competition will develop further when market participants self-provide 
    their ancillary services which they acquire in forward contract 
    markets. In APX's view, the RTO should not provide a centrally 
    optimized dispatch because a central dispatch will discourage, if not 
    eliminate, the commitment of forward contracts in the energy market and 
    replace the price discovery of forward markets with ex post pricing. To 
    the extent that the RTO must acquire ancillary services, including 
    balancing services, APX believes that the RTO should acquire them from 
    a market created by market participants, and not create its own 
    markets. NERA, however, states that this argument ignores the fact that 
    preventing the ISO from operating balancing markets does not eliminate 
    the network interactions and real-time events that are inherent in any 
    electricity network. Rather, according to NERA, it merely forces the 
    ISO to manage these interactions and events by less efficient and more 
    intrusive non-market means. NERA contends that if the objective really 
    is to maximize the role of competitive market forces and minimize the 
    extent to which the monopoly ISO determines the outcome, the ISO should 
    operate market-clearing mechanisms that reflect network interactions 
    and real-time events as accurately as possible. Similarly, ISO-NE 
    claims that it does not understand how operating a market in which (as 
    in New England, currently) an RTO does not buy and sell the pertinent 
    commodities can constitute ``taking a position'' in those markets such 
    that its operation is perceived as biased. ISO-NE believes that because 
    it does not own market assets or commodities, an ISO-type RTO is 
    exceptionally well situated to run a fair and non-discriminatory 
    market. ISO-NE states that the linkages among transmission operation/
    dispatch, generation commitment/dispatch, and economic and market 
    forces strongly support the integration of a physical market with an 
    RTO's operations. Nevertheless, ISO-NE states that other financial 
    power markets are welcome and can co-exist in the same region with an 
    RTO market.
        Several commenters offered their views as to whether unequal access 
    to balancing options leads to unequal access in the quality of 
    transmission service available to different customers, and whether this 
    is a significant problem when RTOs serve some customers that operate 
    control areas and other customers that do not.\550\ A number of 
    commenters believe that the present system does lead to undue 
    discrimination.\551\ Enron/APX/Coral Power states that both the NERC 
    and pro forma tariff rules are inequitable and discriminatory in that 
    large customers rarely will be significantly out of balance due to the 
    law of large numbers. Enron/APX/Coral Power states that such customers 
    are given great flexibility to balance their scheduled deliveries and 
    load, while smaller customers are much more likely to exceed the 1.5 
    percent deviation band, making them immediately subject to penalties. 
    Enron/APX/Coral Power believes that by offering real-time balancing to 
    all transmission customers, the NOPR promises to redress this inequity. 
    TDU Systems recommends that, pending the development of competitive 
    balancing markets, the existing inequity between control area operators 
    and other users be partially redressed by enlarging the deadband for 
    imbalances to be repaid or received in kind to no less than five 
    percent of scheduled amounts. It also recommends that the penal 
    character of these charges should be reduced to a ten percent premium, 
    except in cases of abuse.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \550\ See, e.g., Enron/APX/Coral Power, LG&E, PJM/NEPOOL 
    Customers, FirstEnergy, TDU Systems, Florida Power Corp.
        \551\ See, e.g., Enron/APX/Coral Power, PJM/NEPOOL Customers, 
    TDU Systems.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        PJM/NEPOOL Customers argue that, to the extent current control area 
    operators wish to maintain access to inadvertent energy accounts to pay 
    back imbalances and avoid penalties, other transmission customers must 
    have the same opportunity. In the alternative, it recommends that all 
    users be required to cash-out through the RTO balancing process. 
    Utility Engineers recommends implementing a pricing plan for 
    inadvertent interchange by participants of the RTO, where the price for 
    inadvertent interchange is geographically differentiated to reflect 
    losses and constrained transmission paths. They claim that such a 
    pricing plan would need a continuous auction, which could be achieved 
    through establishing a pricing formula.
        With regard to providing access to inadvertent energy accounts, 
    other commenters argue that there are valid reasons for distinguishing 
    between customers that are control areas and those that are not. 
    FirstEnergy argues that no other entity, other than control areas, can 
    or should have that access to inadvertent accounts. It claims that, if 
    market participants are provided with the authority to ``go 
    inadvertent'' as control area operators currently have, the strain on 
    the grid would drastically degrade system reliability, requiring much 
    higher reserve capacity requirements. FirstEnergy believes that 
    marketers would ``borrow'' from the grid during high price time periods 
    and make whole on their borrowing during low price time periods, thus 
    distorting the true price signal. Florida Power Corp. notes that in 
    addition to balancing generation against load, control area balancing 
    also includes a requirement for contributing to the maintenance of
    
    [[Page 895]]
    
    system frequency. In contrast, it notes that the non-control area 
    transmission customer's balancing requirement is limited to the 
    directly measured load it serves. Florida Power Corp. also claims that, 
    if a system of payments was substituted for the inadvertent payback 
    system presently used, control area operators would simply be 
    circulating large sums of dollars between themselves to accomplish the 
    same result at a higher administrative cost. LG&E suggests that the 
    Commission treat such technical issues separate from the RTO NOPR and 
    work in conjunction with NERC's parallel efforts in this area. Also, 
    Florida Commission believes that inadvertent energy accounting between 
    control areas should continue to be allowed within the operating 
    standards of NERC.
        With regard to any requirement that loads and resources must be in 
    balance from moment-to-moment, Professor Hogan and Eric Hirst believe 
    there is no need for individual loads and generation to balance their 
    schedules separately, and PJM/NEPOOL Customers states that balancing 
    should be required only to ensure that generators deliver the amount 
    scheduled and committed. Professor Hogan argues that individual 
    balancing requirements both complicate the task for the RTO and provide 
    a device to reinforce market power. Eric Hirst states that the RTO's 
    costs of providing or absorbing imbalance energy should be charged 
    equitably to those that under-generate and over-consume, with 
    compensation to those that over-generate and under-consume. He states 
    that this will result in charges and payments netting roughly to zero 
    in each hour. However, Enron/APX/Coral Power believes that any RTO 
    proposal should include development of an ex post energy balancing 
    market in which buyers and sellers are given a finite amount of time 
    after the market has closed to find others with offsetting positions.
        Regarding the imbalances of individual transmission customers, 
    commenters disagree as to whether a distinction should be made between 
    loads and generators. MidAmerican and Florida Power Corp. believe that 
    loads and generators should be treated differently. MidAmerican 
    contends that it is much easier to control generators than it is to 
    control load, and in the future managing imbalances will become more 
    complex in that control from the load-side will involve the response of 
    potentially thousands of entities that may or may not respond as 
    quickly as central generation. MidAmerican states that a distinction 
    exists between loads and generators both in magnitude and response 
    time. Florida Power Corp. claims that load and generators are not 
    always similarly situated. It states that the nature of energy 
    imbalance service depends on whether a generator and the load that it 
    serves are in the same control area or are in different control areas. 
    Eric Hirst, TDU Systems, and Duke believe that, in general, the market 
    rules and principles should be the same or comparable for generators 
    and loads, although TDU Systems believes that loads may be less likely 
    than generators to abuse the system by leaning on it. Eric Hirst states 
    that the use of imbalance markets would eliminate the asymmetry between 
    generation and load in FERC's definition of energy imbalance.
        Finally, the NOPR also asked whether customers should be able to 
    pay for all imbalances in a market or only imbalances within a 
    specified band. Duke believes that it is appropriate to let the market 
    participants determine how imbalances will be determined and paid. PJM/
    NEPOOL Customers believes that the RTO should provide transmission 
    users with as many service offerings as possible, including the ability 
    to opt for different balancing pricing proposals. Florida Power Corp., 
    however, believes that there should only be one method of settling the 
    imbalance market. It claims that complexity and opportunities for 
    gaming increase with options for settlement.
        MidAmerican believes that transmission customers should pay for all 
    energy imbalances caused by the mismatch of scheduled energy and actual 
    load. It recommends that imbalance charges be based on market prices at 
    the time the imbalance occurred, and should include a penalty, in 
    appropriate circumstances, to deter future imbalances. MidAmerican 
    contends that if transmission customers are allowed to avoid payment 
    within a specified bandwidth, gaming of the transmission system will 
    occur.
        PJM/NEPOOL Customers and Professor Hogan, however, argue that the 
    RTO should not be allowed to impose balancing penalties on transmission 
    users. Eric Hirst states that RTOs should maximize the use of price 
    signals rather than penalties to encourage appropriate behavior on the 
    part of generators and loads, and Professor Hogan states that such 
    prices should reflect the marginal cost for power. Eric Hirst believes 
    that penalties should be imposed only to counter the perverse 
    incentives that are created when metering or billing procedures require 
    prices to be calculated over time intervals that do not correspond to 
    those used to measure generation and consumption quantities. Using the 
    example of the California ISO, he states that mismatches between ten 
    minute prices and hourly quantities provide unintended incentives to 
    generators to ignore ISO dispatch instructions or to ignore their 
    schedules. He claims that aligning the time periods for price 
    determination and billing would eliminate these perverse incentives. He 
    adds that, where penalties are needed, they should be closely tied to 
    the costs incurred by the ISO.
        TDU Systems argues that if markets for balancing services are fully 
    competitive, transmission users should be able to use them to deal with 
    any amount of imbalance. TDU Systems recommends that until such markets 
    are fully competitive, it may be necessary to restrict such purchases 
    to a deadband to prevent abuse. It believes that any such deadband 
    should be less restrictive than that of the pro forma tariff. In that 
    regard, it recommends that the minimum within-band allowance should be 
    no less than the greater of two megawatts or five percent for loads or 
    capacities up to 200 MW, with declining percentage tolerances as loads 
    and capacities increase in size.
        Commission Conclusion. We conclude that an RTO must serve as the 
    provider of last resort of all ancillary services required by Order No. 
    888 and subsequent orders.
        Since some commenters interpreted the ``supplier'' of last resort 
    obligation as proposed in the NOPR to require that the RTO be the 
    direct supplier of ancillary services,552 we have made a 
    minor change to the requirement by substituting the term ``provider'' 
    for ``supplier.'' We clarify that this obligation requires that the RTO 
    have adequate arrangements in place for the provision of ancillary 
    services.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \552\ See, e.g., LPPC, Los Angeles, Georgia Transmission, JEA, 
    PPC. A direct supplier of ancillary services either owns or operates 
    generation.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The ancillary services adopted in Order No. 888 were defined using 
    the control area and its operator as the basis because a majority of 
    transmission service was provided by control area operators and they 
    controlled the generation facilities that supplied ancillary services. 
    We note that since we are not requiring the RTO to be a single control 
    area operator, we can not require an RTO that owns no generation to be 
    the direct supplier of ancillary services. Therefore we will give the 
    RTO and its participants flexibility in developing adequate 
    arrangements for the provision of ancillary services to all 
    transmission
    
    [[Page 896]]
    
    customers that request service over the facilities under RTO control.
        The RTO could fulfill its ancillary services obligations through a 
    variety of mechanisms, including contractual arrangements, indirect or 
    direct control of specified generation facilities, or market 
    mechanisms. However, regardless of the method of provision, the 
    ancillary services must be included in the RTO administered tariff so 
    that transmission customers will have access to one-stop shopping for 
    transmission service.
        We conclude that all market participants must continue to have the 
    option of self-supplying or acquiring ancillary services from third 
    parties subject to any general restrictions imposed by the Commission's 
    ancillary services regulations in Order No. 888 and subsequent orders. 
    In such instances, the RTO must determine if the transmission customer 
    has adequately obtained these services. The Commission believes that 
    allowing self-supply provides a possible competitive check on the RTO 
    to ensure that to the extent it does provide the services, it acquires 
    them at lowest cost.
        In the NOPR we asked whether additional or revised ancillary 
    services are needed. While a completely unbundled and competitive 
    environment may require a modification to the ancillary services 
    required by Order No. 888, comments suggest that an immediate change is 
    unnecessary. We will not, at this time, make changes to the ancillary 
    services described in Order No. 888. However, we will allow an RTO to 
    propose other services in recognition of local or regional conditions.
        We conclude that the RTO must have the authority to decide the 
    minimum required amounts of each ancillary service and, if necessary, 
    the locations at which these services must be provided. All generators 
    or other facilities that provide ancillary services must be subject to 
    direct or indirect operational control by the RTO. The RTO must promote 
    the development of competitive markets for ancillary services whenever 
    feasible. To ensure the reliable operation of the system, an RTO must 
    have authority to determine quantities and locations for ancillary 
    services. The RTO should consider stakeholder input as well as 
    established industry standards in determining these requirements. The 
    Commission anticipates that some of the generation-based ancillary 
    services could be acquired in short-term markets. This has been the 
    approach taken by most of the ISOs that we have approved, and we see no 
    reason that this would be different for transcos or other types of RTO 
    entities. Apart from establishing the general requirement to use 
    competitive markets, the Commission will allow the RTO considerable 
    flexibility in determining many of the detailed market design 
    questions, with case-by-case review by us.
        As we proposed in the NOPR, we conclude that an RTO must ensure 
    that its transmission customers have access to a real-time balancing 
    market that is developed and operated by either the RTO itself or 
    another entity that is not affiliated with any market participant. We 
    have determined that real-time balancing markets are necessary to 
    ensure non-discriminatory access to the grid and to support emerging 
    competitive energy markets. Furthermore, we believe that such markets 
    will become extremely important as states move to broad-based retail 
    access, and as generation markets move toward non-traditional 
    resources, such as wind and solar energy, that may operate only 
    intermittently.
        Some commenters believe that implementation of real-time balancing 
    markets presents technical problems that may prevent RTOs in some areas 
    of the country from making such markets available to market 
    participants. For example, some argue that it is difficult if not 
    impossible for an RTO that is not a control area operator to operate an 
    efficient real-time balancing market. These commenters suggest that to 
    the extent such markets are feasible and desirable in a particular 
    region, the RTO, its stakeholders and market participants should be 
    given the flexibility to develop markets in accordance with their needs 
    and capabilities.
        We are not convinced that, at this time, technical considerations 
    preclude the development of a real-time balancing market for any 
    potential RTO. As discussed elsewhere in this Final Rule, we are 
    requiring each RTO to be the security coordinator for its region and to 
    have, at a minimum, the authority to exercise a combination of direct 
    and functional control over facilities within its region. Thus, even if 
    an RTO is not a control area operator, it should have sufficient 
    operational authority to ensure that a real-time balancing market can 
    be implemented. With regard to the issue of flexibility, we believe 
    that real-time balancing markets are essential for development of 
    competitive power markets. Therefore, although we will give RTOs 
    considerable discretion in how they operate real-time balancing 
    markets, we will not allow implementation of such markets to be 
    discretionary.
        Our conclusions regarding provision of real-time balancing markets 
    are similar to our conclusions regarding markets for congestion 
    management; that is, we will not prevent an entity other than an RTO 
    that is unaffiliated with market participants, from seeking to offer 
    transmission customers a real-time balancing market. However, because 
    this function is so time-sensitive and requires such close coordination 
    with the actual dispatch, experience may ultimately show that it cannot 
    be performed to a high degree of efficiency unless it is made a part of 
    the RTO's central or hierarchical dispatch activities. Also, we do not 
    agree that an RTO's operation of a real-time balancing market will 
    interfere unduly with the efforts of others to establish markets in 
    forward contracts for energy.
        We asked in the NOPR whether customers should have the option of 
    paying for all imbalances in a real-time balancing market or only 
    imbalances within a specified band. Based on the comments received, we 
    decline to give a generic solution for all RTOs in this rule. An RTO 
    may propose one approach or the other but should explain how it 
    proposes to overcome any disadvantages of the approach selected.
        In the NOPR, we noted that unequal access to balancing options can 
    lead to unequal access in the quality of transmission service, and that 
    this could be a significant problem for RTOs that serve some customers 
    who operate control areas and other customers who do not. We conclude 
    that control area operators should face the same costs and price 
    signals as other transmission customers and, therefore, also should be 
    required to clear system imbalances through a real-time balancing 
    market. We believe that providing options for clearing imbalances that 
    differ among customers would be unduly discriminatory.
        Finally, we asked in the NOPR whether, for the imbalances of 
    individual transmission customers, a distinction should be made between 
    loads and generators. We conclude that, for the purpose of determining 
    cost responsibility for imbalances, no distinction needs to be made. 
    The system-wide balance between load and generation is affected 
    comparably by changes in load and changes in generation. Therefore, the 
    cost of an imbalance is unaffected whether the imbalance is determined 
    ultimately to be the responsibility of load or of generation. However, 
    commenters point out certain differences between loads and generators 
    (such as in the time needed to respond to an operator's
    
    [[Page 897]]
    
    instructions) that are important from the standpoint of system 
    operation. These differences can be relevant to the determination of 
    the appropriate penalties to assess to loads and generators that fail 
    to submit accurate schedules. Thus, for purposes of assessing penalties 
    for inaccurate schedules, we conclude that a penalty mechanism that 
    treats loads and generators differently may be appropriate.
    5. OASIS and Total Transmission Capability (TTC) and Available 
    Transmission Capability (ATC)
        In the NOPR, the Commission proposed that an RTO must be the single 
    OASIS site administrator for all transmission facilities under its 
    control and independently calculate TTC and ATC. The Commission stated 
    that the most controversial aspect of OASIS operation is the 
    calculation and posting of ATC \553\ and noted that there is widespread 
    dissatisfaction with the reliability of posted ATC numbers. To 
    alleviate this problem, the Commission proposed that the RTO become the 
    administrator of a single OASIS site for all transmission facilities 
    over which it is the transmission provider.\554\ The NOPR outlined 
    three levels at which an RTO could be involved in ATC calculations. At 
    Level 1, the RTO would post ATC values received from transmission 
    owners. At Level 2, the RTO would receive raw data from transmission 
    owners and itself calculate ATC values. At Level 3, the RTO would 
    itself calculate ATC values based on data developed partially or 
    totally by the RTO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \553\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,747.
        \554\ Id. at 33,748.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In the NOPR, the Commission envisioned that RTOs would operate at 
    Level 3 to ensure that ATC values are based on accurate information and 
    to minimize the opportunities for manipulation.\555\ The Commission 
    also proposed that: (1) An RTO must formulate a validation system to 
    check any ATC data supplied by others; (2) in the event of a dispute 
    over ATC values, the RTO's data should be used pending the outcome of 
    the dispute resolution process; and (3) the RTO must formulate the 
    operating standards (subject to regional and national reliability 
    requirements) underlying ATC calculations.\556\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \555\ See id.
        \556\ Id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments. Most commenters who address the subject agree with the 
    Commission's observations regarding dissatisfaction with ATC/TTC data. 
    Moreover, most commenters on the subject endorse the proposal that an 
    RTO must be the single OASIS site administrator for all transmission 
    facilities under its control.\557\ Some commenters, however, are 
    opposed to mandating the RTO as the OASIS site administrator. For 
    example, Central Maine argues that it should not be precluded from 
    operating its own site because as a ``wires-only company'' it has an 
    incentive to operate an efficient site in order to maximize use of 
    transmission capacity. EEI asserts that OASIS operation can occur 
    independently of formation of an RTO and that the tasks and problems of 
    OASIS operation will not become naturally easier to solve with the 
    creation of an RTO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \557\ See, e.g., NASUCA, WPSC, EAL, NERC, Industrial Consumers, 
    Entergy, Mass Companies, JEA, LG&E, NY ISO, NJBUS, Sithe, TAPS, How 
    Group, Southern Company, PG&E, PJM, UtiliCorp, Williams, Cinergy, 
    Oneok, East Texas Cooperatives, Cal DWR, Tri-State, Seattle, New 
    Smyrna Beach, RUS, Cinergy, Nevada Commission, and Enron/APX/Coral 
    Power.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Most commenters also support the Commission's proposal to have the 
    RTO independently calculate ATC and TTC.\558\ In addition, a number of 
    commenters emphasize that independent and disinterested RTOs could be 
    trusted and empowered to maintain reliable ATC data and calculate 
    accurate values.\559\ Moreover, several commenters are concerned with 
    consistency across RTOs and contend that RTOs must also coordinate ATC 
    values with adjacent regions and with the NERC regional reliability 
    councils.\560\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \558\ See, e.g., Sithe, RUS, TAPS, PG&E, SMUD, Cal DWR, New 
    Smyrna Beach, East Texas Cooperatives, WPSC, EAL, NERC, NASUCA, 
    Seattle, Georgia Transmission, First Rochdale, Tri-State, Industrial 
    Consumers, Enron/APX/Coral Power, Cinergy, Oneok, PJM, Williams, 
    Empire District, PJM/NEPOOL Industrial Customers, Entergy, Mass 
    Companies, Nevada Commission, NJBUS, and LG&E.
        \559\ E.g., FMPA, East Texas Cooperatives, NJBUS, Empire 
    District, Entergy, Oneok, First Rochdale, Seattle, EAL, Sithe, WPSC, 
    Sithe, PG&E, SMUD, New Smyrna Beach, and PJM/NEPOOL Customers.
        \560\ See, e.g., Industrial Consumers, Seattle and WPSC.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Many commenters concur with the Commission's conclusions about the 
    different levels of RTO involvement in ATC calculations. These 
    commenters believe that Level 1 is insufficient for reliable and 
    trustworthy data and that an RTO should independently calculate ATC 
    values. Several commenters, however, disagree about the appropriate 
    timing for Level 3 compliance. Some commenters, such as Cinergy, argue 
    that upon commencement of operation, an RTO should be required to 
    perform all studies and analysis needed for accurate ATC values 
    consistent with Level 3. APX supports each RTO reaching Level 3 as 
    quickly as possible. Enron/APX/Coral Power asserts that upon 
    commencement of operation, an RTO should operate at Level 2 and, as it 
    gains operational experience, migrate to Level 3. SMUD supports RTO 
    operation at Level 3 but is concerned about the significant costs 
    associated with developing data.
        JEA is opposed to any RTO structure that gives an RTO complete 
    authority over ATC calculations for transmission that JEA will continue 
    to own. JEA asserts that transmission owners are in the best position 
    to assess the capabilities of their own transmission system. Therefore, 
    absent formation of a transco, JEA does not support relying on an RTO 
    for ATC and TTC calculations because JEA argues that ownership and 
    control of the assets would be split between two or more entities whose 
    interests are not always the same.
        Both Cal ISO and NY ISO argue that the final rule should provide 
    flexibility in the OASIS requirements to accommodate network systems 
    like the Cal ISO and the NY ISO in which transmission service is not 
    explicitly reserved. In addition, numerous commenters argue that the 
    Commission should expand the minimum requirements to have every RTO 
    employ a single set of OASIS practices and terminology.\561\ They note 
    that consistency in OASIS procedures will allow seamless trades across 
    RTOs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \561\ See, e.g., Williams, EPSA, Cinergy, Empire District and 
    PJM/NEPOOL Customers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        How Group also focuses its comments on the standardization of 
    transmission transactions. It notes that without some level of 
    standardization only a limited number of market participants who learn 
    all of the differences between RTOs can perform transactions that span 
    multiple RTOs. How Group proposes that each RTO establish a 
    coordinating committee with neighboring RTOs and transmission customers 
    in order to: (1) Coordinate the naming of interconnected facilities, 
    sources, sinks, paths, points of receipt and/or delivery between the 
    RTO and its neighbors; (2) coordinate the sharing of necessary data for 
    the calculation of transmission capability on interconnected paths; and 
    (3) foster coordination with neighbors in adopting standardized 
    business practices. It also suggests that continued industry-wide 
    coordination is necessary to formulate common definitions for types of 
    transmission and ancillary services, curtailment priorities, and timing
    
    [[Page 898]]
    
    requirements for arrangement of transmission services.
        Only one commenter expressed concern about the proposal to use the 
    RTO's ATC values in the event of a dispute. Southern Company contends 
    that the existing transmission owner's data are preferable to the RTO's 
    data. Southern Company argues that existing transmission owners have 
    experience in operating the regional transmission facilities and, 
    therefore, are best qualified to determine ATC values.
        Some commenters raise other OASIS-related issues that were not 
    addressed in the NOPR. For example, commenters argue that: (1) All 
    reservations and scheduling, including that for network service, should 
    occur on the OASIS; (2) sanctions should be levied against transmission 
    providers that skew their ATC values; and (3) the power flow 
    methodology rather than the contract path model should be used for 
    scheduling.\562\ A few commenters address issues relating to Capacity 
    Benefit Margin (CBM). NASUCA argues that administration of CBM should 
    be a required function of RTOs and that a uniform methodology for 
    calculating CBM is needed. Similarly, Idaho Commission asserts that 
    requiring the posting of CBM on OASIS with a narrative explanation of 
    its derivation would be beneficial. Empire District states that the 
    Commission should provide better guidance about how to calculate CBM.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \562\ See, e.g., Ontario Power, Williams, NERC and EPSA.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commission Conclusion. After considering the comments, we continue 
    to believe that an RTO must be the single OASIS site administrator for 
    all transmission facilities under its control. As numerous commenters 
    note, independent RTOs can be trusted to maintain an OASIS site with 
    reliable and current data that is easy to use. In addition, a single 
    OASIS site for each region instead of multiple sites will enable 
    transactions to be carried out more efficiently.
        However, in response to those who argue for flexibility in OASIS 
    requirements, we clarify that this requirement does not mean that each 
    RTO must itself operate the OASIS for its region. Our concern is that 
    there be no more than one OASIS site for the facilities under the RTO's 
    control, and that the RTO ensure that the OASIS site operator have the 
    same attributes of independence we require for an RTO. Thus, we will 
    allow an RTO the flexibility to contract out OASIS responsibilities to 
    another independent entity, if justified. More specifically, we do not 
    intend to keep an RTO from participating in a ``super-OASIS'' jointly 
    with other RTOs.
        We reaffirm that an RTO should operate at what the NOPR 
    characterizes as Level 3 for ATC/TTC calculations, which requires the 
    RTO itself to calculate ATC values based on data developed partially or 
    totally by the RTO. Most commenters believe that Levels 1 and 2, where 
    the RTO would accept the transmission owners' ATC calculations or data, 
    are insufficient for reliable and trustworthy ATC values. Level 3 
    ensures that ATC values are based on accurate information and 
    consistent assumptions. When data are supplied by others, the RTO must 
    create a system for tests and checks that ensure customers of 
    coordinated and unbiased data. We also agree with commenters who 
    recommend that RTOs coordinate ATC values with adjacent regions.
        We recognize that the NOPR was silent on the appropriate timing for 
    Level 3 compliance. Commenters suggested that: (1) An RTO should reach 
    Level 3 compliance upon commencement of operation; (2) an RTO should 
    reach Level 3 as quickly as possible; or (3) an RTO should operate at 
    either Level 1 or 2 upon commencement of operation and as it gains 
    operational experience, migrate to Level 3. We conclude that an RTO 
    OASIS site, including ATC calculations, must be fully operational at 
    Level 3 upon commencement of service. All parties to a transmission 
    transaction need precise ATC values to make scheduling decisions.
        We affirm that in the event of a dispute over ATC values, the RTO's 
    values should be used pending the outcome of a dispute resolution 
    process. Only one commenter, Southern Company, disagreed with this 
    proposal and we are not persuaded by its arguments. Each RTO must 
    develop procedures to validate its ATC values.
        How Group and other commenters address issues relating to the 
    standardization of transmission transactions. Standardization of 
    transactions involves two separate concerns: (1) Many transactions will 
    cross RTO boundaries; and (2) numerous customers will do business with 
    multiple RTOs. Without standardized communications protocols and 
    business practices, the costs of doing business will be increased as 
    market participants will be required to install additional software and 
    add personnel to transact with different RTOs and regions. Therefore, 
    to promote interregional trade, standardized methods of moving power 
    into, out of, and across RTO territories will be needed.
        We believe that standards for communications between customers and 
    RTOs must be developed to permit customers to acquire expeditiously 
    common services among RTOs. For example, we envision the creation of 
    standardized communications protocols to schedule power movements and 
    to acquire auction rights. These protocols would not standardize what 
    the rights are, or the nature of the auctions. Instead, the focus of 
    the communications protocols would be on how customers communicate 
    their intentions to an RTO and how customers receive an RTO's 
    responses.
        We agree with How Group and others that certain business and 
    communication standards \563\ are necessary, and we believe that these 
    standards will facilitate the development of efficient markets. We 
    believe, however, that these issues need further examination based on a 
    complete record.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \563\ We believe that the communications standards and protocols 
    would, like the current OASIS, make use of: (1) The Internet for 
    communications; (2) interactive displays using World Wide Web 
    browsers; (3) file uploads and downloads for computer-to-computer 
    communication; and (4) templates defining the file uploads and 
    downloads.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A few other commenters discussed issues that were not addressed in 
    the NOPR. For example, commenters argue that: (1) All transmission 
    transactions (reservations and scheduling) should occur on the OASIS; 
    (2) sanctions should be levied against transmission providers that skew 
    their ATC values; and (3) the power flow methodology for scheduling, 
    rather than the contract path model, should be utilized. In addition, 
    NASUCA, Empire District and the Idaho Commission raise issues relating 
    to CBM. These issues are too detailed for this proceeding and we will 
    not address them at this time. Commenters will have the opportunity to 
    bring up these issues in response to specific RTO filings, as well as 
    during OASIS Phase II proceedings and in the CBM docket (Docket No. 
    EL99-46-000).
    6. Market Monitoring (Function 6)
        In the NOPR, the Commission proposed that RTOs perform a market 
    monitoring function. Specifically, RTOs would be required to: (1) 
    Monitor markets for transmission service and the behavior of 
    transmission owners and propose appropriate action; (2) monitor 
    ancillary services and bulk power markets that the RTO operates; (3) 
    periodically assess how behavior in markets operated by others affects 
    RTO operations and how RTO operations
    
    [[Page 899]]
    
    affect those markets; and (4) provide reports on market power abuses 
    and market design flaws to the Commission and affected regulatory 
    authorities, including specific recommendations. In addition, the 
    Commission asked a number of questions regarding the role of RTOs in 
    market monitoring, the tools RTOs should use, and similar issues.
        Comments. Commenters address a number of issues regarding the 
    market monitoring function. The issues can be grouped into three 
    general areas: (1) The need for and scope of a market monitoring 
    function; (2) who should perform the market monitoring function and how 
    it should be performed; and (3) what are the specific components or 
    procedures of a market monitoring plan.
        Need For and Scope of Market Monitoring. As a general proposition, 
    a variety of commenters favor having RTOs serve as market 
    monitors.\564\ Commenters, such as Blue Ridge, argue that RTOs should 
    conduct market monitoring because they will be in the best position to 
    deal with the growing volume of multiparty transactions and discern any 
    manipulation or preferential treatment. Several commenters, such as the 
    Florida Commission, note that the appropriate role for RTOs in market 
    monitoring and the various aspects of the function will depend upon the 
    nature of the RTO that is ultimately established. TEP claims that RTO 
    market monitoring needs to be flexible given the costs involved in such 
    a function. PP&L Companies believes that RTO market monitoring should 
    focus on properly structuring business rules to foster efficient 
    transactions and gathering statistical information to make available to 
    the Commission or other enforcement agencies. EEI and Allegheny 
    recommend that RTO market monitoring identify market design flaws and 
    propose solutions that lead to greater efficiency, competitiveness and 
    reliability.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \564\ See, e.g., New York Commission, South Carolina Authority, 
    Mass Companies, LG&E, ISO-NE, TAPS, SMUD, NECPUC, WPSC, Project 
    Groups and Tri-State.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A number of commenters support having the RTO should serve as the 
    ``first line of defense'' for detecting design flaws and market power 
    abuses.\565\ Cal ISO suggests that the RTO serve as a first line of 
    defense in conjunction with state commissions and local regulatory 
    authorities in the region, particularly in the operation of hourly and 
    real-time markets where potential buyers may not have the ability to 
    decline electric service, and where transmission and ancillary services 
    markets tend to have high concentrations. PJM believes that market 
    monitoring by RTOs provides a continual check on market activities and 
    accordingly, RTOs should have clear authority to investigate potential 
    market power abuses or flaws and to compel market participants to 
    produce relevant information. SMUD contends that although RTO 
    monitoring should be the first line of defense, an independent RTO 
    monitoring unit must not be a substitute for review by the Commission 
    and other regulatory agencies.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \565\ See, e.g., Metropolitan, DOE, CMUA, NASUCA and Project 
    Groups.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In contrast, some commenters, such as Cinergy, argue that, if 
    transmission markets realize the efficiencies envisioned in the NOPR, 
    the commodity market should be able to regulate itself, with the 
    Commission and the courts serving as backstops. SNWA cautions that RTOs 
    may be too focused on safe and reliable operations to be a first line 
    of defense. Some commenters, such as Metropolitan and Southern Company, 
    claim that there is no benefit in having RTO monitoring replicate the 
    costly regulatory responsibility that already exists in state and 
    Federal agencies.
        Several commenters propose an expansive RTO market monitoring role. 
    NECPUC proposes that monitoring include mitigation of both market flaws 
    and market power. East Texas Cooperatives and SMUD believe that RTO 
    market monitoring should include remedying market abuse. Project Groups 
    believes that an RTO should monitor energy and ancillary services 
    markets and their interplay, and develop indices and criteria to 
    evaluate activities and behaviors that may reflect market power abuse. 
    Advisory Committee ISO-NE suggests that the RTO monitor transmission 
    and ancillary services markets to identify design flaws and market 
    power, and to administer or propose remedial actions. Dynergy claims 
    that monitoring should include oversight of transmission owners' 
    behavior. EPSA proposes that the RTO also document any significant 
    market impacts attributable to application of reliability rules.
        Some commenters support limits on market monitoring by the RTO. 
    Commenters, such as Southern Company and Entergy, argue that RTO 
    monitoring should not reach to any market the RTO does not operate, nor 
    should it encompass market power abuse and the effect of existing 
    structural conditions on the competitiveness of electricity markets. 
    Entergy adds that the RTO will not be in a good position to monitor 
    markets it does not operate. Several commenters claim that the purpose 
    of monitoring should be to look for market flaws, not act as policeman 
    looking for bad behavior.\566\ Desert STAR recommends that any proposed 
    remedy be restricted to market flaws within the RTO's area of 
    operation. Enron/APX/Coral Power argues that evaluation of the 
    structure of power markets and policing market power lies outside of an 
    RTO's core competencies as the operator of the transmission system. 
    Tri-State opposes RTO monitoring of power markets because it would add 
    to the complexity and cost of RTOs and impermissibly involve the RTO in 
    issues about generation market power. NY ISO opposes monitoring to the 
    extent that it encompasses the RTO playing an investigative and 
    enforcement role. Nonetheless, in its view, the RTO could mitigate 
    evident market power problems on a prospective basis by applying pre-
    approved remedies.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \566\ See, e.g., Desert STAR, CRC and Tri-State.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Sithe recommends that RTOs not have the authority to compel the 
    provision of commercially sensitive data and should instead rely on 
    nonproprietary information to monitor markets. PG&E contends that 
    commercially sensitive information should not be released to anyone 
    except in accordance with Commission-approved rules. PP&L raises 
    concerns regarding the ability of the RTO market monitoring 
    organization to guarantee confidentiality of commercially sensitive 
    information supplied to it. Seattle argues that any claims of 
    commercial sensitivity must be tempered by the need to create an 
    efficient, self-policing, transparent market for nondiscriminatory 
    transmission services.
        Various commenters would limit the RTO market monitoring function 
    to information gathering.\567\ They argue that the NOPR proposal is 
    overly broad, too extensive and open-ended, and a potentially 
    burdensome requirement. Sithe argues that the application of mitigation 
    measures by the RTO could have real commercial impacts on market 
    participants that often cannot easily be measured or repaid after the 
    fact; therefore, market participants should have an opportunity to 
    review and comment on monitoring procedures prior to their 
    implementation. Seattle claims that the Commission should take a 
    minimalist approach by facilitating market monitoring through greater 
    public information disclosure. PG&E believes that the RTO should not 
    regulate the functioning of the energy market. Duke supports RTO 
    identification and description of alleged market abuses to appropriate 
    authorities
    
    [[Page 900]]
    
    through the regulatory framework that exists today.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \567\ See, e.g., CP&L, TDU Systems, PP&L and PG&E.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Other commenters question the need for or otherwise oppose an RTO 
    market monitoring function, in general, as a form of back door 
    regulation.\568\ They contend that RTO monitoring will be unduly 
    burdensome, overtaxing and costly to the ratepayers. Los Angeles and 
    Salomon Smith Barney argue that RTO monitoring may interfere with the 
    proper relationship between the RTO and its customers, which they claim 
    should be focused solely on providing nondiscriminatory open access 
    transmission services. UtiliCorp argues that the assignment of market 
    monitoring functions to a commercial entity such as a transco (other 
    than those functions concerned strictly with transmission pricing) may 
    raise antitrust concerns both for the transco and its customers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \568\ See, e.g., Industrial Consumers, Williams, Southern 
    Company, PSE&G, Arizona Commission, Georgia Transmission and East 
    Kentucky.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commenters differ on whether market monitoring should continue 
    indefinitely. East Texas Cooperatives believes that continuous RTO 
    market monitoring is necessary because, in its view, antitrust laws and 
    complaints to the Commission provide only a slow, after-the-fact 
    remedy. Entergy recommends that any RTO self-monitoring be allowed to 
    terminate after a fixed period, subject to Commission approval. 
    Industrial Consumers suggests that market monitoring be limited to the 
    period when the risk of discriminatory conduct is greatest. Los Angeles 
    claims that, once the Commission determines that generation markets are 
    workably competitive, market forces should be allowed to discipline the 
    markets. If an RTO market monitoring function is required, PSE&G 
    suggests a five-year sunset provision.
        Who Should Perform Market Monitoring and How Should it Be 
    Performed. Many commenters address the issue of whether the RTO should 
    perform market monitoring depending on the form of the RTO (i.e., 
    whether the RTO is a for-profit or a not-for-profit organization). Most 
    commenters raise concerns about and generally oppose a for-profit RTO 
    monitoring markets.\569\ The commenters generally argue that, due to 
    its economic and business interests, a for-profit RTO cannot 
    objectively monitor itself. CP&L submits that a for-profit RTO may be a 
    competitor of other market participants in the provision of congestion 
    relief and ancillary services, which would make unbiased monitoring of 
    those markets difficult. TDU Systems would limit a for-profit RTO's 
    role to data collection. Other commenters recommend that for-profit 
    RTOs employ a fully independent organization to monitor market 
    conditions.\570\ A few commenters, however, support for-profit RTOs 
    serving as market monitors.\571\ Entergy claims that market monitoring 
    conducted by a transco could be as effective as for any other type of 
    RTO as long as procedures are in place that ensure its independence.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \569\ See, e.g., Dynegy, South Carolina Authority, Industrial 
    Consumers and East Texas Cooperatives.
        \570\ See, e.g., PJM/NEPOOL Customers, Cal ISO, Tri-State and 
    Metropolitan.
        \571\ See, e.g., Entergy and Duke.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commenters also address whether an RTO that is an ISO needs to 
    insulate its market monitoring function from other RTO functions to 
    ensure independence and objectivity. A number of commenters generally 
    believe it is appropriate for ISOs to internally monitor market 
    activities either through staff devoted to the function or through a 
    committee of ISO members assigned to the function.\572\ They argue that 
    an ISO, which would be free of commercial interests, can be trusted by 
    market participants, and therefore should not have to undertake costly 
    establishment of autonomous monitoring units. Mid-Atlantic Commissions 
    note that PJM ISO's monitoring unit is a neutral body that has access 
    to and maintains confidentiality of market sensitive data in accordance 
    with sharing arrangements with each of the states in the region. 
    California Board contends that, if the internal unit is independent and 
    has the ability to report and/or consult with state and Federal 
    authorities without needing additional approval, those regulators are 
    likely to respect the opinions and recommendations of the market 
    monitoring unit. CalPX suggests that RTOs and separate power exchanges 
    coordinate their market monitoring functions and jointly conduct 
    research to lower costs. EPSA suggests that the information and market 
    data, if collected by an independent and unbiased RTO, could be relied 
    upon by market participants in formulating business strategies, and by 
    regulators for purposes of reviewing and approving modifications to 
    regulated aspects of RTO structures and operations.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \572\ See, e.g., PJM, ISO-NE, NY ISO, WPSC and East
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Most commenters, however, would require an ISO (i.e., a not-for-
    profit RTO) to make its market monitoring function more independent. 
    Pennsylvania Commission contends that an independent ISO is absolutely 
    necessary to perform market monitoring functions. EEI points out that 
    while an RTO's independence may ensure that its recommendations do not 
    favor particular market participants, this does not ensure that it will 
    monitor its own performance objectively. In its view, an ISO should use 
    outside experts within the monitoring committee or on an ad hoc basis 
    to address concerns about objectivity. Similarly, PG&E contends that 
    experience has shown that an ISO's rules and actions may interfere with 
    the proper functioning of the market. Industrial Consumers contend that 
    an RTO's operations must be sufficiently transparent that it is the 
    market participants that do the real monitoring. FTC suggests that 
    internal RTO monitoring could be problematic if the internal monitoring 
    unit is given enforcement powers, because this could both devolve into 
    re-regulation and raise conflict of interest issues. FTC recommends 
    that the Commission's RTO rules explicitly make clear that self-
    monitoring controlled by an RTO does not create an antitrust exemption 
    for the RTO and its participants.
        Los Angeles believes that market monitoring should be conducted by 
    an independent body. CP&L, however, believes that delegation to a 
    private party is questionable, where its objectivity may also be 
    challenged on grounds of conflict of interest, particularly, if the 
    delegated authority includes the ability to impose sanctions and 
    penalties. Oregon Commission believes that RTOs should appoint a local 
    committee to use RTO data to monitor the market for ancillary services 
    because RTOs, as major buyers and sellers of such services, will want 
    to protect their market shares. The Commission should consider 
    establishing its own regulatory advisory bodies to monitor markets. DOE 
    also claims that the Commission should avoid reliance upon RTO 
    monitoring to the exclusion of the Commission's own monitoring efforts. 
    Alliant believes that moving responsibility for monitoring market power 
    to another organization would allow the RTO to focus on the many 
    technical demands that will be placed on it. Metropolitan believes 
    market monitoring should occur on two levels: an internal group 
    responsible for data gathering and publication and frequent preliminary 
    analysis of anomalous conduct; and formal analyses performed by a group 
    or committee independent of RTO management whose results and 
    recommendations would not require RTO approval.
        LG&E proposes that the RTO make its monitoring findings public and 
    refer
    
    [[Page 901]]
    
    them to an appropriate regulatory body. Industrial Consumers opposes 
    giving deference to the RTO's recommendations for correcting such 
    market power abuses and flaws. Instead, it believes that stakeholders 
    and market participants should use the RTO reports to make their own 
    recommendations.
        NYPP believes that structural solutions are matters for 
    legislators, courts or regulatory agencies. In contrast, PJM believes 
    that, if the market issue is a structural one, the RTO should be able 
    to propose structural remedies to the Commission.
        In the case of localized market power, MidAmerican submits that it 
    would be inappropriate for the RTO to take corrective competitive 
    actions in the case of localized must run generating unit market power. 
    Similarly, PG&E contends that RTOs should allow temporary supply and 
    price issues to be resolved by the competitive forces of the market, 
    unless there is a threat to the physical supply of power or a 
    Commission determination that markets are not workably competitive.
        CalPX believes that monitoring and reporting should be simplified 
    in order to reduce costs and to rationalize staff and committee work 
    loads. Also, the RTO and power exchange compliance related staffs 
    should jointly conduct research that is beneficial both to increase 
    coordination and reduce costs. NY ISO submits that RTOs that are ISOs 
    should not be required to establish costly and otherwise burdensome 
    autonomous market monitoring units.
        Many commenters address the issue of the appropriate role for the 
    Commission and the state commissions in market monitoring. Commenters 
    overwhelmingly believe that the Commission and state commissions have 
    an important role to play, whether it is a primary role as market 
    monitors, or a secondary role providing oversight of market monitoring 
    activities by RTOs.
        Some commenters believe that market monitoring is better handled by 
    the existing statutory and regulatory agency frameworks than by 
    RTOs.\573\ They suggest a continuing, if not mandatory, role for the 
    Commission and other Federal and state authorities in conjunction with 
    any market monitoring undertaken by RTOs.\574\ PP&L Companies argues 
    that, in Gulf States Utilities Co. v. FPC,\575\ the Supreme Court made 
    it clear that the Commission is charged with serving as the first line 
    of defense to protect and preserve competition in wholesale power 
    markets.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \573\ See, e.g., Salomon Smith Barney, South Carolina 
    Commission, PG&E, Enron/APX/Coral Power and Duke.
        \574\ See, e.g., SMUD, Tri-State, Cinergy, TDU Systems, EPSA, 
    Industrial Consumers, CMUA, PJM/NEPOOL Customers, NY ISO, ISO-NE and 
    DOE.
        \575\ 411 U.S. 747 (1973).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        TDU Systems and Sithe contend that regulatory commissions cannot 
    abdicate to RTOs the responsibility to ensure that wholesale electric 
    markets are free of market power. Many commenters see RTOs serving to 
    forward any claims of market abuse and market power to the various 
    federal and local regulatory agencies consistent with their respective 
    jurisdictions. PJM and LG&E see the Commission reviewing remedies and 
    approving penalties and sanctions. Desert STAR and CRC see the 
    Commission acting as a backstop to an RTO's ADR process or mitigation 
    plan. EEI suggests that RTOs regularly inform the Commission about 
    monitoring results, which will enable it to respond quickly to problems 
    not resolved by the RTO. SoCal Cities suggest that RTOs share 
    responsibility to remedy structural defects in the market or impose 
    general sanctions for market power abuse with appropriate state and 
    federal agencies, but not duplicate their responsibilities such as 
    implementation of the FPA. CalPX believes that there is a decreasing 
    role for regulatory oversight as a result of a progression toward 
    greater RTO self-regulation.
        Florida Power Corp. and Nevada Commission suggest close 
    coordination of RTO market monitoring with state regulators. Nevada 
    Commission also suggests that RTOs collaborate their monitoring efforts 
    with neighboring RTOs, as well as audit the records of those parties 
    who violate the RTO's rules. Project Groups recommends adding an eighth 
    minimum function under which RTOs provide data support for states' 
    policies, monitoring the competitive impacts of emissions regulations, 
    verifying compliance with state generation portfolio standards.
        NARUC claims that the states need to be heavily involved in RTO 
    market monitoring and that the Commission should work with the states 
    to make utility codes of conduct more effective. In its view, such 
    collaboration is the most effective means of monitoring market power in 
    generation, since the RTO would have information for the region on 
    transmission planning, generation expansion and transmission 
    constraints, and state commissions would have utility specific data and 
    information on local operations. NARUC argues that such collaboration 
    is critical because state commissions are responsible for both 
    evaluating local markets to assure competitiveness and for licensing 
    electric supplies, and abusers of market power can inhibit competition 
    and distort the prices of locally regulated services. NASUCA similarly 
    claims that market participants, state and federal regulatory agencies, 
    and state consumer advocates periodically review the indices and 
    screens to be used for RTO market monitoring. The RTO should 
    periodically issue confidential reports to federal and state regulatory 
    authorities and state consumer advocate offices, that describe the 
    state of the markets and the results of matters under investigation.
        A number of state commissions suggest a continuing oversight role 
    over RTO monitoring by the Commission and the states.\576\ Oregon 
    Commission recommends that the Commission establish its own regulatory 
    advisory bodies to monitor ancillary services markets. For a for-profit 
    RTO, it recommends that a regional oversight committee perform this 
    function with the Commission reviewing any oversight committee reports.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \576\ See, e.g., Florida Commission, New York Commission and 
    Michigan Commission.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commenters also address a number of issues related to the ability 
    of RTOs to perform self-assessments. A number of commenters believe 
    that RTOs are capable of objective analysis. NY ISO contends that an 
    ISO will have no incentive to distort the results of its analysis. 
    Cinergy recommends that RTOs be limited to monitoring the behavior of 
    the markets they administer because of the ready access to relevant 
    information. Los Angeles comments that, if the RTO is not primarily 
    responsible for providing ancillary services, it should not be burdened 
    with surveying that market.
        Other commenters oppose RTOs monitoring the markets that they 
    operate because of conflict of interest concerns.\577\ EEI argues that 
    independence from market participants does not ensure that the RTO will 
    be able to monitor its own performance objectively, e.g., a non-profit 
    RTO may not have sufficient incentives to minimize the costs under its 
    control. Oregon Commission comments that RTOs cannot be entrusted to 
    monitor ancillary services markets, where they will be providing 
    services and have incentives to protect market share. Industrial 
    Consumers contends that market participants must perform monitoring 
    and, accordingly, an RTO's operations should be fully transparent. SNWA 
    and PG&E claim that the RTO
    
    [[Page 902]]
    
    should establish an independent body to monitor and evaluate its 
    performance.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \577\ See, e.g., Florida Power Corp., CMUA and DOE.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Some commenters, such as Salomon Smith Barney and Michigan 
    Commission, oppose the RTO monitoring markets where the RTO takes a 
    market position because the RTO plays the dual role of seller of 
    services and policeman. Alliant contends that an RTO will be competing 
    with generation providers in congestion management and have an 
    incentive to build transmission facilities. Similarly, CP&L contends 
    that a for-profit RTO may compete with others in providing ancillary 
    services, and therefore any proposal by the RTO monitor for remedial 
    action raises serious conflict of interest concerns. Industrial 
    Consumers suggests that, even in markets where the RTO is the supplier 
    of last resort, the RTO should not have quasi-regulatory powers.
        Commenters also address the issue of whether RTOs should be 
    required to provide periodic assessments of markets they do not 
    participate in or operate, thereby assessing the effect of existing 
    structural conditions on the competitiveness of their region's 
    electricity markets. Some commenters oppose this proposal. Tri-State 
    opposes an RTO monitoring of power markets because it would not only 
    violate the Commission's goal of separation between transmission and 
    power sales, it would also add a level of complexity and cost to the 
    operation of the RTO. Justice Department believes that the RTO cannot 
    reasonably be expected to monitor activities with which it has no 
    involvement. Justice Department therefore recommends that the 
    Commission consider requiring each separate electric power trading 
    institution to monitor any market that it operates.
        On the other hand, a number of commenters favor extending RTO 
    monitoring responsibility to markets they do not operate. PJM/NEPOOL 
    Customers argues that the independence of the RTO would enable market 
    participants and the Commission to have confidence in the RTO's 
    assessments. ISO-NE favors RTOs monitoring power markets. NASUCA 
    recommends that RTOs monitor bulk power markets, capacity markets, 
    transmission rights markets, ancillary services markets and any other 
    potentially competitive markets. FTC suggests that, where an RTO is 
    smaller than one of the major interconnects, the Commission may wish to 
    encourage all the RTOs within each of the interconnects to coordinate 
    their efforts to examine the effects of market rules or variations 
    between RTOs in market rules on the volume and price of inter-RTO 
    transactions. Cal ISO also sees collaborative market monitoring and 
    assessment by neighboring RTOs and at the national level.
        Florida Power Corp. recommends that an RTO that is an ISO be 
    required to make regular assessments as to whether it has sufficient 
    operational authority to ensure its ongoing ability to provide 
    reliable, open access transmission service on a comparable basis to all 
    customers--nonetheless, the RTO should not be self-regulating.
        For those regions where the real-time balancing function is 
    performed by an ISO, Advisory Committee believes that the ISO should 
    monitor market power in generation markets. SoCal Edison claims that, 
    where markets are not yet workably competitive, the RTO, with 
    Commission approval, should ensure that prices are just and reasonable 
    through appropriate temporary mechanisms such as price caps. PG&E 
    counters that, in no case, should RTOs be permitted to use control of a 
    power exchange for unilaterally capping prices set by the market.
        Many commenters address the issue of how the RTO should report, if 
    at all, its monitoring activities. The Commission did not propose to 
    establish detailed standards on the format and content of monitoring 
    reports, noting that such matters are best left to the RTO. We asked 
    commenters to address whether reporting should be limited to when a 
    specific problem is encountered, or whether periodic reporting on the 
    state of competition and transmission access would be more appropriate.
        Commenters express mixed views on reporting requirements. CRC 
    supports the concept of RTOs reporting to the Commission regarding RTO 
    design flaws, and New York Commission suggests that RTOs report on 
    market power abuse as well. Florida Power Corp. submits that, if market 
    monitoring is necessary, it should be performed by the RTO reporting 
    and filing appropriate information with state and Federal regulators. 
    Project Groups wants the provision of data to support state programs 
    pertaining to the monitoring of the competitive impacts of emissions 
    regulations. Project Groups argue that RTOs would be uniquely 
    positioned to support data collection for verification of green 
    marketing claims and compliance with information disclosure 
    requirements and portfolio standards. EEI opposes a Commission mandate 
    for RTOs to track generation source and emissions data. EEI recommends 
    the RTO voluntarily undertake this task to meet specific state 
    compliance requirements provided appropriate safeguards protect 
    competitively sensitive information. EEI expresses concern regarding 
    the possibility that the RTO would have authority to collect and 
    disclose information from a generation source where the state has not 
    imposed such a requirement.
        Several commenters favor issuance of monitoring reports at regular 
    intervals. Project Groups believes that RTO monitoring units should 
    issue public reports on their activities and findings, including annual 
    reports on the general state of the market. Metropolitan supports 
    reporting at regular intervals from an external monitoring source; 
    however, during initial startup, more frequent reporting is advisable 
    to assist participants' understanding of the market operation. East 
    Texas Cooperatives believes that RTOs should prepare periodic reports 
    to the Commission with the precise form left to the discretion of the 
    RTO.
        California Board contends that regular reports on market 
    performance should issue at least on a yearly basis, and include all 
    relevant data that can be made publicly available. NASUCA contends 
    that, to further create trust in the RTOs' ability to effectively and 
    objectively monitor the market, RTOs should periodically issue reports 
    describing the state of the markets that it is monitoring, items under 
    investigation by the RTO, and any results from completed 
    investigations. In its view, market participants, state and federal 
    regulatory agencies and state consumer advocates should participate in 
    the development and periodic review of the indices and screens the RTO 
    will use to monitor the operation of the markets. Reports should be 
    provided to state and federal regulatory authorities as well as state 
    consumer advocate offices, on a confidential basis, to enable them to 
    independently assess whether additional investigation is merited. Cal 
    ISO submits that the Commission should specify regular reporting 
    requirements for the RTO's monitoring unit. PJM believes that RTOs 
    should periodically report results of monitoring activities to the 
    Commission and state agencies.
        Components of a Market Monitoring Plan. Commenters address various 
    issues regarding particular elements of a market monitoring plan. Many 
    commenters address the issue of whether RTOs should be allowed to 
    impose penalties and sanctions. Most commenters would limit the RTO's 
    ability to impose penalties or sanctions. Many of them argue that such 
    authority should remain the province of the
    
    [[Page 903]]
    
    regulatory and antitrust agencies.\578\ Justice Department claims that 
    RTOs lack experience either in detecting exercises of market power or 
    in making recommendations on correcting market power problems. SPRA 
    questions whether the imposition of sanctions by the RTO may conflict 
    with the Supremacy Clause of the Constitution and whether affected 
    public power bodies could only consent to such sanctions if they do not 
    create indefinite or uncertain liabilities. PP&L argues that, because 
    it will be judge and jury, the RTO must demonstrate competitive harm 
    before taking any market action. Some commenters, such as CP&L, note 
    that a for-profit RTO may not be objective in imposing sanctions 
    because it competes with other market participants. Other commenters, 
    such as Salomon Smith Barney, claim that RTOs should be limited to 
    extracting ordinary commercial penalties when market participants fail 
    to follow the market's rules. EPSA claims that RTOs should be empowered 
    to intervene in a market within the strict confines of the Commission's 
    oversight only when a situation has the potential to become 
    catastrophic. Mass Companies opposes allowing a private RTO or one that 
    is operated by a non-stakeholder board to enforce violations of market 
    standards and impose sanctions and penalties.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \578\ See, e.g., Entergy, Duke, PG&E, PSE&G, PJM/NEPOOL 
    Customers and Williams.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Canada DNR claims that it will be problematic for Canadian entities 
    subject to the jurisdiction of Canadian provincial and Federal energy 
    regulators also to be subject to an RTO that has its disciplinary 
    authority backstopped by the Commission. In its view, the issue will 
    not be resolved by simply having the appropriate Canadian regulator 
    serve as the regulatory backstop to the RTO for each Canadian entity 
    because the Canadian regulator may take a different position than the 
    Commission.
        A few commenters support authority for RTOs to impose penalties and 
    sanctions. Among them, CalPX believes that RTO governing boards and 
    power exchange market monitoring committees must be able to take 
    appropriate action either by referral to regulatory agencies or 
    directly through applicable sanctioning authority. It views this as 
    critical for self-policing and providing prompt remedies before 
    problems detrimentally affect market results. ISO-NE believes that an 
    RTO should have the ability to impose penalties and sanctions, but 
    suggests that the RTO not act as an antitrust agency, in order to 
    increase the acceptability of sanctions among participants.
        The Commission specifically sought comment on whether penalties 
    should be limited to violations of RTO rules and procedures, or whether 
    the RTO should be allowed to impose penalties for the exercise of 
    market power. More commenters oppose than support RTOs imposing 
    sanctions and penalties for market power abuse. Among them, Allegheny 
    and Metropolitan claim that this is a proper function of regulatory or 
    antitrust authorities. Central Maine argues that the Commission cannot 
    grant RTOs the authority to impose corrective actions without affording 
    the affected public utilities with procedural due process. EEI believes 
    that the RTO tariff may include RTO authority to impose fines or 
    sanctions to ensure compliance with RTO rules in accordance with the 
    costs imposed by their actions. Pointing to similar positions taken by 
    Justice Department and FTC, EEI contends, however, that the RTO should 
    not attempt to define or prosecute alleged exercise of market power 
    because it is not a regulatory body or an antitrust agency authorized 
    to take such actions. It also suggests that limited additional 
    authority might be granted during the transition to restructured 
    markets to permit the RTO to deal effectively and timely with 
    identified market design flaws, software errors, or other unanticipated 
    situations that could be costly if no action is taken.
        Cinergy also argues that the RTO should not be allowed to take 
    corrective action against individual market participants. It believes 
    that claims of market abuse and the exercise of market power should be 
    forwarded to the Commission to address consistent with its 
    jurisdiction. Similarly, MidAmerican recommends that RTO penalties be 
    limited to (1) willful violations of material RTO directives related to 
    the operation of regional transmission facilities, Commission approved 
    RTO standards for transmission facility operations, and material 
    provisions of RTO agreements that conflict with the RTO transmission 
    tariff, and (2) violations of RTO transmission tariff provisions 
    relating to operating reserves and energy imbalances. NASUCA recommends 
    that compliance with RTO rules be enforced with penalties and sanctions 
    imposed through a collaborative process involving all market 
    participants, regulatory agencies and consumer advocates. However, the 
    Final Rule should specify that any actions taken by the RTO cannot 
    substitute for penalties or other remedies which may stem from 
    independent investigations by governmental authorities. Similarly, ISO-
    NE and SNWA generally would impose sanctions based on a participant's 
    engaging in patterns of conduct defined in the RTO's rules or its 
    tariff.
        NYPP, DOE, and LG&E generally concur that RTO sanctions and 
    penalties should only be levied for violations of RTO rules and 
    procedures, whereas penalties and sanctions for market power abuses are 
    matters for the regulatory and antitrust agencies, legislators, or the 
    courts. Florida Power Corp. argues that, since an RTO does not have 
    authority to grant or terminate market-based rate authorizations 
    premised respectively on the absence or presence of market power, the 
    RTO should therefore have no role in passing judgement or imposing 
    penalties for the exercise of market power.
        On the other hand, some commenters, such as East Texas 
    Cooperatives, are more comfortable with RTO imposition of penalties and 
    sanctions for market power abuse. PJM recommends that RTOs be able to 
    take corrective action to ameliorate market abuses or flaws and to seek 
    Commission approval to add penalties and sanctions to its market 
    monitoring plan. NECPUC recommends that market monitoring be expanded 
    to include formalized mitigation and sanction rules in connection with 
    market design, implementation flaws and market power. NY ISO claims 
    that RTOs should mitigate evident market power problems, on a 
    prospective basis, by applying pre-approved remedies. CRC submits that 
    RTOs investigate whether market power abuse results from a design flaw 
    and report the results to the Commission for approval of its mitigation 
    plan. WPSC sees RTOs being effective because they will have access to 
    real-time data on system conditions and should be given authority to 
    take appropriate corrective action immediately to respond to market 
    abuses.
        Some commenters also want sanctions against market participants for 
    reliability rule violations. PSNM claims that RTOs should defer to 
    existing mechanisms where they exist (such as the WSSC's Reliability 
    Management System RMS, and NERC Reliability Standards and Measures) for 
    sanctions against market participants for poor performance, rather than 
    create new monitoring and sanction systems for RTOs. Similarly, Desert 
    STAR submits that any RTO should be allowed to pass the reliability 
    performance standards sanctions on to participants who do not comply. 
    SMUD concurs that an important aspect of enforcing reliability 
    standards is ensuring that the RTO has sufficient authority to police 
    and
    
    [[Page 904]]
    
    investigate the markets they administer, and assess fines and other 
    appropriate penalties, or resolve disputes amongst market participants 
    as to any alleged market abuse.
        A few commenters also address the Commission's questions about how 
    much discretion the RTO should have in setting penalties (e.g., should 
    the RTO's penalty authority be limited to collecting liquidated 
    damages). Nevada Commission submits that RTOs should be allowed to 
    impose specific penalties and sanctions for non-compliance with RTO 
    rules based on liquidated damages and not punitive damages. Cal ISO and 
    Metropolitan believe that penalties should be limited to liquidated 
    damages. Cal ISO argues that for cases of repeated or intentional 
    violations or serious abuses of market power, the RTO should seek 
    relief, including imposition of punitive damages, from the Commission 
    or other appropriate agencies such as the Justice Department. 
    Metropolitan argues that liquidated damages sought by an RTO should be 
    approved by the Commission. And Duke opposes the RTO assuming the role 
    of market monitor and enforcer; therefore, it recommends that terms and 
    conditions for any penalties the RTO might impose should be agreed upon 
    by contract during the RTO development process.
        On the other hand, WPSC claims that the RTO should have the 
    discretion to determine the amounts of adequate sanctions and penalties 
    to discourage anti-competitive conduct. Whether the RTO has acted 
    properly can always be reviewed after the fact through a dispute 
    resolution procedure either through the Commission or the Justice 
    Department. NASUCA contends that sanctions and other penalties should 
    be large enough to be an effective deterrent. It suggests that a for-
    profit RTO may have incentives to impose unjustified penalties and 
    should be required to allocate all revenue derived from sanctions and 
    penalties in a way that benefits customers. SMUD offers that, since 
    liquidated damages are a mere proxy designed to make a victim whole for 
    a transgression, they do not really serve as a deterrent to market 
    abusive conduct.
        Several commenters address whether the SEC model of regulating 
    stock exchanges, i.e., requiring extensive and sophisticated market 
    monitoring of stock exchanges, should applicable to RTO market 
    monitoring. Some commenters, such as EEI and PP&L, do not believe the 
    model is applicable. EEI claims that monitoring scheme in the 
    securities industry is an exception because in most industries the 
    market participants bring competitive problems to the attention of 
    antitrust authorities. Sithe also opposes any emulation of the NASD or 
    NYMEX model of self-regulation at this time because of the limited 
    amount of market experience to date.
        PJM/NEPOOL Customers and Cal ISO, however, contend that the RTO 
    monitoring function should be similar to that of a stock exchange 
    because the RTO is designed to ensure that the exchange of electricity 
    can occur readily and easily in a competitive marketplace.
        Commission Conclusion. In the NOPR, the Commission proposed that 
    RTOs perform a market monitoring function. Many commenters raise a 
    number of issues regarding market monitoring. The issues largely 
    encompass the following concerns: the need for and scope of a market 
    monitoring function; who should perform this function and how it should 
    be performed; and what are the specific components or procedures of a 
    market monitoring plan.
        The Commission recognizes that the market monitoring concept is new 
    and not yet well-refined, either at the Commission or within existing 
    ISOs. We also acknowledge the apprehensions of some parties that market 
    monitoring by an RTO could intrude into markets and affect their 
    behaviors. The Commission, however, is engaged in finding ways to 
    understand market operations in real-time, so that it can identify and 
    react to any problems that are preventing the most efficient 
    operations. It also has a responsibility to protect against 
    anticompetitive effects in electricity markets. \579\ If we are to 
    satisfy this goal, we must systematically assess whether our policies 
    and decisions are consistent with this responsibility. Market 
    monitoring is an important tool for ensuring that markets within the 
    region covered by an RTO do not result in wholesale transactions or 
    operations that are unduly discriminatory or preferential or provide 
    opportunity for the exercise of market power. In addition, market 
    monitoring will provide information regarding opportunities for 
    efficiency improvements.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \579\ See Gulf States Utilities v. FPC, 411 U.S. 747, 758-59 
    (1973).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        However, in light of the different forms of RTOs that could be 
    developed by market participants and the varying types of markets an 
    RTO may be operating within its region, different market monitoring 
    plans are likely to be appropriate for different RTOs. Consequently, 
    after careful consideration of the comments, the Commission will 
    require that RTO proposals contain a market monitoring plan that 
    identifies what the RTO participants believe are the appropriate 
    monitoring activities the RTO, or an independent monitor, if 
    appropriate, will perform. We believe that such approach will provide 
    those proposing an RTO sufficient flexibility to design a monitoring 
    plan that fits the corporate form of the RTO as well as the types of 
    markets the RTO will operate or administer. We have revised the 
    regulatory text for the RTO market monitoring function to reflect our 
    decision to allow this flexible approach.
        Although we decline at this time to prescribe a particular market 
    monitoring plan or the specific elements of such a plan, the RTO must 
    propose a monitoring plan that contains certain standards. The 
    monitoring plan must be designed to ensure that there is objective 
    information about the markets that the RTO operates or administers and 
    a vehicle to propose appropriate action regarding any opportunities for 
    efficiency improvement, market design flaws, or market power identified 
    by that information. The monitoring plan also must evaluate the 
    behavior of market participants, including transmission owners, if any, 
    in the region to determine whether their behavior adversely affects the 
    ability of the RTO to provide reliable, efficient and nondiscriminatory 
    transmission service. Because not all market operations in a region may 
    be operated or administered by the RTO (e.g., there may be markets 
    operated by unaffiliated power exchanges), the monitoring plan must 
    periodically assess whether behavior in other markets in the RTO's 
    region affect RTO operations and, conversely, how RTO operations affect 
    the efficiency of markets operated by others. Reports on opportunities 
    for efficiency improvement, market design flaws and market power abuses 
    in the markets the RTO operates and administers also must be filed with 
    the Commission and affected regulatory authorities.
        In developing its market monitoring plan, the RTO should identify 
    the markets that will be monitored, i.e., transmission, ancillary 
    services or any other market it may develop (e.g., congestion 
    management). With regard to those markets, the monitoring plan should 
    examine the structure of the market, compliance with market rules, 
    behavior of individual market participants and the market as a whole, 
    and market power and market power abuses. The monitoring plan should 
    also address how information will be used and reported. The monitoring 
    plan
    
    [[Page 905]]
    
    should indicate whether the RTO will only identify problems and/or 
    abuses or whether it also will propose solutions to such problems. We 
    note that sanctions and penalties may be appropriate for certain 
    actions such as noncompliance with RTO rules. However, the monitoring 
    plan should clearly identify any proposed sanctions or penalties and 
    the specific conduct to which they would be applied, provide the 
    rationale to support any sanctions, penalties or remedies (financial or 
    otherwise) and explain how they would be implemented. With regard to 
    the reporting of market monitoring information, the monitoring plan 
    should indicate the types and frequency of reports that will be made 
    and to whom the reports will be sent. Under the FPA, the Commission has 
    the primary responsibility to ensure that regional wholesale 
    electricity markets served by RTOs operate without market power. An 
    appropriate market monitoring plan must provide an objective basis to 
    observe markets and, if appropriate, provide reports and/or market 
    analyses. Market monitoring also will be a useful tool to provide 
    information that can be used to assess market performance. This 
    information will be beneficial to many parties in government as well as 
    to power market participants. This includes state commissions that 
    protect the interests of retail consumers, especially where they are 
    overseeing the development of a competitive electric retail market. We 
    note, however, that the market monitoring function for the RTO does not 
    limit the ability of each state within the RTO's region or other 
    authorities to decide the nature and extent of its own market 
    monitoring activities.
        We are not requiring a plan that necessarily involves the 
    collection of data the RTO would not collect in its ordinary course of 
    business. We believe that the information collected through the RTO 
    market monitoring plan will reflect data that the RTO will collect or 
    have access to in the normal course of business (e.g., bid data, 
    operational information). In light of our requirements that the RTO 
    have operational control over the transmission facilities transferred 
    to it and the RTO be the security coordinator for its region, the RTO 
    will be in the best position to perform (or provide information to 
    another entity, if appropriate, for it to perform) objective monitoring 
    functions for the markets that the RTO operates or administers in the 
    region.
        In response to commenters' arguments that RTO market monitoring 
    results in an impermissible shift of Commission authority to other 
    entities, we emphasize that performance of market monitoring by RTOs is 
    not intended to supplant Commission authority. Rather it will provide 
    the Commission with an additional means of detecting market power 
    abuses, market design flaws and opportunities for improvements in 
    market efficiency. Further, because market monitoring plans will be 
    required to be filed with and approved by the Commission as part of an 
    RTO proposal, we will retain the ability to determine what, how and by 
    whom activities will be performed in the first instance.
        Because we believe market monitoring is essential, we decline to 
    set any sunset date for monitoring at this time. However, as bulk power 
    markets evolve and become more competitive, we may revisit the need for 
    the type of monitoring the Rule requires.
    7. Planning and Expansion (Function 7)
        In the NOPR, the Commission proposed that the RTO planning and 
    expansion process must satisfy certain standards. Specifically, RTOs 
    would be required to: (1) Encourage market-motivated operating and 
    investment actions for preventing and relieving congestion; and (2) 
    accommodate efforts by state regulatory commission to create multi-
    state agreements to review and approve new transmission facilities, 
    coordinated with programs of existing Regional Transmission Groups 
    (RTGs) where necessary. We suggested that RTOs be designed to promote 
    efficient use, which requires efficient price signals such as 
    congestion pricing, and efficient expansion of their regional grid, 
    which requires control over planning and expansion. We specifically 
    proposed that the RTO have ultimate responsibility for both 
    transmission planning and expansion within its region. If the RTO is 
    unable to satisfy the planning and expansion requirement when it 
    commences operation, we proposed that the RTO must file a plan with 
    specified milestones that will ensure that it meets this requirement no 
    later than three years after initial operation. In addition, the 
    Commission sought comment on whether three years is an appropriate 
    amount of time for implementation of this function.\580\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \580\ FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,751-53.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments. Encourage Market-Motivated Operating and Investment 
    Actions for Preventing and Relieving Congestion. Many commenters 
    support the Commission's proposal to require that an RTO must ensure 
    the development and operation of market mechanisms to plan and 
    refinance transmission system expansion. As part of this an RTO should 
    provide all transmission customers with efficient price signals that 
    show the consequences for their transmission use decisions.\581\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \581\ See, e.g., United Illuminating, Wyoming Commission, 
    Industrial Consumers, Champion, NSP, PG&E, Williams, LG&E, FTC and 
    APX.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Some commenters, such as JEA and Williams believe that this role is 
    best performed by for-profit entities because system expansion 
    decisions must be driven by economic considerations. Entergy also 
    contends that a transco will not create any bias in the method of grid 
    expansion.
        Los Angeles agrees that an RTO should rely upon market signals and 
    market solutions in assessing all feasible options (e.g., construction 
    of new generation, redispatch of existing generation, grid expansion) 
    to assure the least-cost option is pursued. NASUCA also argues that the 
    Commission should mandate that RTOs use least-cost planning on a 
    region-wide basis for transmission system expansions and upgrades. It 
    notes that the larger the region over which least-cost planning is 
    conducted, the more economically efficient the outcome is likely to be. 
    If market solutions do not develop or are not timely, Los Angeles 
    believes that the RTO must have the power to resolve the transmission 
    problem. LG&E proposes that RTOs be permitted to use competitive 
    bidding as a means to meet new transmission investment needs.
        EPA believes that RTOs should adopt a resource planning process 
    with sufficient flexibility to consider non-traditional resources and 
    to assign appropriate values to their unique benefits. EPA further 
    believes that RTOs should be encouraged to take into account 
    environmental costs and benefits that are not reflected in resource 
    prices.
        Puget suggest that the Commission should recognize that the concept 
    of RTOs may contain some elements that do not enhance the reliable 
    operation of the transmission grid. Puget requests that the Commission 
    should address more fully how it will mitigate the effects of the 
    severance of generation and transmission planning and operation and how 
    it plans to ensure maximum reliability at the lowest integrated costs.
        NASUCA recommends that the Commission require RTOs to develop a 
    baseline regional transmission expansion plan that would identify the 
    regional system's ability to meet essential NERC reliability criteria 
    and
    
    [[Page 906]]
    
    isolate potential constraint areas of the existing system where 
    upgrades may be necessary or additional generation desirable. Such a 
    baseline plan could provide a valuable tool to market participants in 
    signaling the best locations for new generation projects. Entergy 
    proposes the use of a regional transmission plan that includes a 
    regional transmission planning summit process involving all 
    stakeholders.
        TAPS, however, questions whether market-based mechanisms to expand 
    the transmission grid will emerge readily from an efficient short-term 
    transmission pricing regime that accounts properly for the costs of 
    congestion. TAPS asserts that, while efficient congestion pricing is an 
    important component of a well-designed transmission regime, it is not 
    the answer to the concerns that have been raised regarding the lack of 
    economic and regulatory incentives to expand the transmission grid.
        Many commenters agree that RTOs should be responsible for 
    conducting the studies necessary to assess the need for new 
    transmission system enhancement.\582\ However, some commenters argue 
    that the role of the RTO should be to facilitate market investment by 
    others in new transmission and generation, not to lead the market by 
    making its own plans for new facilities. For example, Seattle suggests 
    that the RTO should generate information on the locations, frequencies 
    and costs of congested paths to guide capital investment. It believes 
    that the RTO need not make capital investments directly; rather it 
    should seek market mechanisms, such as requesting bids for needed 
    capacity, to encourage investments. EME states that performance of this 
    role requires accurate accounting for the impact of congestion and new 
    generation, and proper allocation of costs to those that require such 
    costs to be incurred.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \582\ See, e.g., EME and Seattle.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        To ensure that transmission expansion decisions are not biased, 
    ComEd proposes that RTO functions be performed by two linked 
    organizations that together make up a ``Binary RTO.'' ComEd envisions 
    that the Binary RTO would consist of for-profit independent 
    transmission companies (ITCs), each operating a large aggregation of 
    existing transmission systems, under the oversight of an independent, 
    not-for-profit Regional Transmission Board (RTB). The ITCs will 
    identify transmission additions, upgrade opportunities, and prepare 
    long-range plans which would be reviewed by the RTB and subsequently 
    integrated in an RTB-wide planning system.
        Powerex believes that it is better to eliminate congestion at its 
    source through facilities upgrades, if economically and environmentally 
    feasible, than to attempt to manage congestion on a long-term basis 
    through congestion pricing schemes.
        Many commenters support the concept that RTOs must be responsible 
    for transmission planning and that single-system planning should be the 
    objective of the RTO planning process.\583\ Commenters differ, however, 
    on the extent of the RTO's role in the planning process. Some 
    commenters, such as Powerex, argue that the RTO must have control over 
    transmission service, planning, system impact studies and facilities 
    studies, and the authority to determine the need for, and require the 
    implementation of, transmission upgrades by member utilities. Other 
    commenters, such as LIPA and H.Q. Energy Services, propose that, in the 
    absence of transmission expansion proposals from current or proposed 
    market participants, the RTO should have the responsibility for 
    assessing whether transmission improvements are needed and, if a need 
    is found, the RTO should have the authority to order such expansion.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \583\ See, e.g., PNGC, Wisconsin Commission, EAL, Entergy, PJM, 
    Minnesota Power and Montana-Dakota.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Some commenters such as NY ISO, on the other hand, express concern 
    that exclusive authority by the RTO over transmission planning is 
    overly restrictive. NY ISO claims that entities which are responsible 
    for coordinating transmission expansion, but which lack authority to 
    make enforceable planning decisions, can nevertheless achieve the 
    Commission's primary transmission expansion-related goal, i.e., 
    ensuring that investments in new transmission facilities are 
    coordinated to ensure a least-cost outcome that maintains or improves 
    existing reliability levels.
        H.Q. Energy Services objects to NY ISO's arguments as being merely 
    concerned with preserving its so-called ``two-tier'' governance system 
    which provides NY ISO transmission owners with significant authority, 
    or veto power, over interconnections with generating facilities and 
    over decisions related to transmission system planning and expansion. 
    H.Q. Energy Services does not believe that the two-tier approach is 
    appropriate unless the RTO has ultimate decision-making authority.
        Many commenters agree with the proposal that an RTO must be 
    ultimately responsible for all transmission expansions and 
    upgrades.\584\ These commenters claim that transmission operations must 
    be conducted on an independent and fair basis and must be undertaken by 
    an impartial entity if transmission services are to be offered on a 
    truly non-discriminatory basis. They argue that vesting the RTO with 
    the ultimate responsibility for expanding transmission systems 
    eliminates the conflict that is inherent in vesting these 
    responsibilities with an entity that also has commercial interests that 
    are competing with users of the system.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \584\ See, e.g., San Francisco, SoCal Cities and CMUA.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Although SMUD supports having the RTO be responsible for 
    transmission planning and expansion, it cautions that, in such a 
    paradigm, people that have no responsibility to the ratepayers will be 
    deciding planning and expansion issues. Therefore, SMUD argues that the 
    Commission needs to scrutinize the recovery of the costs of such 
    expansion to ensure that such expansion decisions and costs are 
    prudent, just and reasonable.
        Several commenters agree that the RTOs can and should play a 
    significant role in the transmission planning and expansion 
    process.\585\ Some of these commenters, such as NYPP and Mass 
    Companies, however, do not believe that the Commission should require 
    that RTOs have authority to order a transmission owner to modify or 
    expand its transmission system. Nevada Commission believes that 
    transmission owners should be allowed to assist an RTO in the 
    development of grid planning criteria and could take the lead in such 
    grid planning with RTOs performing more of an overview role. Professor 
    Joskow states that the transmission owners, operating through a sound 
    RTO/ISO transmission planning process should be expected to be the 
    primary, but not necessarily the exclusive, source of network 
    enhancement initiatives. WEPCO argues that transmission owners should 
    be integrated into the RTO regional transmission plans where they can 
    be improved and expanded to meet regional needs most efficiently. 
    Turlock contends that the RTO's authority over the transmission system 
    it operates must be limited to that system. Turlock argues that the RTO 
    should not have the ability to force expansion of lower voltage or 
    tangentially related facilities which are beyond the area of its 
    responsibility, even if those other facilities might have a small but
    
    [[Page 907]]
    
    theoretically possible impact on the RTO's facilities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \585\ See, e.g., NYPP, Industrial Customers, Mass Companies and 
    Nevada Commission.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        CP&L supports a coordinated planning approach which would be 
    similar to the planning approaches identified in the Midwest ISO and 
    the Alliance RTO filings, where the RTO would have responsibility for 
    review of the transmission plan, but the individual transmission-owning 
    entities would provide the necessary input to facilitate the 
    development of the comprehensive RTO transmission plan. East Kentucky 
    argues, however, that an individual transmission owner should be able 
    either to require or to veto the building of a particular RTO facility.
        MidAmerican disagrees with the proposal that the RTO have the 
    ultimate responsibility for both transmission planning and expansion in 
    the region. MidAmerican claims that existing regional transmission 
    groups (RTGs) have clear and prominent roles in transmission expansion 
    decisions in which planning for transmission improvements are 
    coordinated through collaborative processes that already involve many 
    interested stakeholders in the widest fashion possible. MidAmerican 
    states that throughout the MAPP region there is broad support for 
    continuing transmission planning and expansion decisionmaking as a 
    collaborative function and that the existing collaborative processes 
    adequately accommodate RTO participation.
        Central Maine believes that RTOs/ISOs can and should play a 
    significant role in the transmission planning and expansion process, 
    but disagrees with the Commission's proposal to give ISOs ultimate 
    responsibility for transmission planning and expansion. Central Maine 
    does not object to ISOs having oversight responsibility in these area, 
    but Central Maine believes that the planning and engineering functions 
    should be a shared responsibility between utilities and RTO, i.e., the 
    Commission should consider utility planners as a satellite to the ISO/
    RTO similar to satellite function served by utility control centers in 
    monitoring, switching and dispatching. Central Maine states that the 
    Commission should grant individual transmission owning utilities an 
    equal voice in determining the technical aspects of transmission 
    planning and expansion.
        Although Big Rivers believes that, as proposed in the NOPR, the RTO 
    should be the default provider of transmission planning and expansion, 
    it agrees with NRECA that incumbent transmission owners should have the 
    first opportunity to build required transmission system expansion with 
    RTO ability to facilitate needed construction by others.
        Some commenters suggest specific tasks and functions that the RTO 
    should perform or have the ability to require as part of the 
    transmission planning and expansion function.\586\ For example, SRP 
    proposes that at a minimum, each RTO should have the authority to: (1) 
    Direct transmission owners to study and evaluate system performance and 
    to develop plans to solve known reliability or adequacy problems; (2) 
    revise or combine elements of transmission owners' plans to achieve the 
    most efficient and reliable transmission expansion plan; (3) approve or 
    reject any component of the RTO transmission plan developed by a 
    transmission owner; and (4) approve facility additions by third 
    parties.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \586\ See, e.g., Project Groups, LIPA and SRP.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Accommodate Efforts by State Regulatory Commission to Create Multi-
    State Agreements to Review and Approve New Transmission Facilities. 
    Many comments concur that multi-state agreements are to be encouraged 
    and that the RTO should be designed to work within that structure.\587\ 
    Commenters, including NSP and Nevada Commission, encourage the 
    Commission to provide an active role for RTOs to participate with state 
    and local government in the siting and licensing of new facilities. PJM 
    states that a cooperative relationship between RTOs and the states is 
    essential to effective transmission expansion planning. In PJM's view, 
    states are more likely to trust the planning decisions of RTOs that 
    have no commercial interest in transmission and generation expansion 
    than decisions made by transmission-owning entities, which have 
    commercial interests.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \587\ See, e.g., Illinois Commission, DOE and New Smyrna Beach.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Cinergy recommends that the final rule include a Commission 
    commitment to proceed aggressively to establish a forum to encourage 
    coordination of RTO planning and expansion among states through multi-
    state certification agreements and multi-state regional planning 
    boards. Cinergy notes, however, that the creation of a forum or agency 
    to review grid planning and expansion that would consider the public 
    interest beyond the constraints of state boundaries may require federal 
    legislation. If so, the Commission should be aggressive in its dialogue 
    with Congress to obtain the requisite legislative relief.
        The Kentucky Commission suggests creating a voluntary ``Joint Board 
    on Regional Transmission Siting'' to develop and review standards for 
    transmission expansion. The Joint Board would include participation 
    from the Commission, state commissions, RTOs, and other interested 
    parties. The Joint Board would also convene ad hoc committees to review 
    specific transmission expansion proposals. Pennsylvania Commission also 
    prefers a joint Federal-state approach towards regulating RTO site 
    approvals, expansion, innovation and customer service. It notes that a 
    joint Federal-state approach has been used with success in other areas, 
    such as the Susquehanna River Basin Commission, the Delaware River 
    Basin Commission and the Joint Pipeline Office which regulates the 
    Trans-Alaska Pipeline System.
        Illinois Commission recommends that accommodation of multi-state 
    efforts be expanded to include the possibility of multi-state regional 
    regulatory oversight organizations. Such organizations could be 
    instrumental in coordinating regional solutions to regulatory and 
    policy issues.
        Otter Tail expresses concern that multi-state agreements may not 
    actually add to the efficient use and expansion of the interstate 
    transmission system due to a danger that these types of agreements 
    could be mired in state-versus-state political conflict and become 
    unworkable, to the detriment of transmission owners, generators, and 
    ultimately customers. Industrial Consumers also does not believe that 
    requiring an accommodation with ``multi-state agreements'' is 
    necessarily productive. It states that nothing now prevents such 
    coordination among states, yet there is no obvious evidence that this 
    will work. Industrial Customers believes that states will always 
    reserve the right to veto a project that may be partially situated 
    within their jurisdiction, regardless of the benefits elsewhere.
        East Texas Cooperatives believes that retention of state public 
    utility commission authority over siting (and other necessary 
    approvals) is necessary to control the risk of overbuilding because 
    RTOs will have no real incentive to limit facility construction.
        Commenters generally express support for the proposal that the RTO 
    build on existing RTG processes.\588\ For example, Industrial Consumers 
    urges that the Commission require existing RTGs to merge their 
    functions with the RTOs because RTGs should not be allowed to develop 
    an institutional
    
    [[Page 908]]
    
    culture that diverges from the goals and objectives of RTOs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \588\ See, e.g., Wisconsin Commission, Industrial Customers and 
    SRP.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        New Smyrna Beach and Oneok claim that market participants will 
    undoubtedly benefit from a multi-state siting process for transmission 
    because it may make siting of new generation easier if there is more 
    certainty that related transmission siting decisions will be made on a 
    timely basis with one-stop shopping.
        Several commenters address the role of the Commission in the RTO 
    planning and expansion process. Detroit Edison and Wolverine 
    Cooperative support the establishment of the Commission as the primary 
    channel of certification for transmission siting, construction, and 
    expansion. Detroit Edison states that regional reliability 
    organizations and the RTOs in each reliability region should be 
    permitted to determine necessary changes and additions in transmission 
    with input from transmission owners, control area operators, and other 
    interested parties. It is vital, it states, that a single 
    administrative agency resolve issues related to the siting of 
    transmission facilities on a regional basis and have the authority to 
    approve transmission expansion plans on a timely basis. Detroit Edison 
    believes that the Commission should fill the important role of sole 
    regulator over transmission siting and construction, just as it 
    currently does in approving the siting and construction of natural gas 
    pipelines, and it urges the Commission to work to gain such authority.
        Pennsylvania Commission recommends that, if an RTO determines that 
    transmission expansion is necessary, it should file with the Commission 
    to demonstrate that need. Once the Commission determines a need exists 
    within the RTO, the RTO should then file with the appropriate states 
    for a determination of the siting issues. Pennsylvania Commission 
    believes that vesting authority for determining the need for 
    transmission expansion with the Commission solves several problems that 
    are certain to arise in state forums. Federal determination of the need 
    for transmission expansion obviates the burden of filing with multiple 
    jurisdictions and possibly receiving conflicting determinations.
        Otter Tail states that Commission should seriously consider whether 
    the public interest would be better served through adoption of a 
    transmission siting policy that is similar to review of interstate 
    natural gas pipelines.
        NY ISO claims that in many cases transmission expansion is delayed 
    or blocked entirely by environmental and other transmission siting 
    regulations. Nevertheless, NY ISO supports the NOPR's proposal that 
    RTOs participate in efforts to create multi-state transmission 
    expansion agreements.
        East Kentucky believes that there needs to be some regulatory 
    oversight authority for facilities that are deemed necessary by an RTO 
    planning staff. East Kentucky proposes that this regulatory authority 
    be the Commission or a regional regulatory authority.
        Conlon recommends that the Commission have the necessary authority 
    to enforce reasonable siting request, or critically needed future 
    transmission lines could be delayed causing a reliability risk. 
    Granting the right of eminent domain to transcos or ISOs in Federal 
    legislation would be another approach. This could be accomplished by 
    the Commission recommending to Congress that it have the right of 
    eminent domain.
        LG&E believes that it is important that state authority over system 
    expansion not impede necessary improvements that enhance the efficiency 
    of the regional grid that is, or will be, subject to RTO control. 
    Ultimately there may be a need for a congressional solution to the 
    current balkanized system for authorizing grid expansion. In its 
    comments, the East Central Area Reliability Council explicitly calls 
    for such legislative action based on its concern that transmission 
    facility expansion requests will fail as they become bogged down in 
    multiple state reviews. LG&E shares this concern. Still, until such 
    time as the statutory framework for transmission expansion is amended, 
    LG&E believes that RTOs represent an opportunity for coordinating 
    regional transmission expansion needs among transmission owners and 
    state authorities.
        Project Groups maintains that RTOs should be required to coordinate 
    and lead in the development of comprehensive least cost regional plans 
    for assuring short-and long-term system reliability, and they must 
    coordinate the actions necessary for implementing timely system 
    upgrades and additions pursuant to those plans. For example, RTOs must 
    be given the authority to petition state and local regulators for 
    necessary siting authorizations, including certificates of need or 
    public necessity and environmental permits, as well as the authority to 
    order construction of facilities sited and permitted under state 
    regulatory authorities. The Commission should encourage state reliance 
    on RTO-approved plans as the primary basis for the exercise of eminent 
    domain powers under state law.
        Puget notes that state condemnation powers granted to utilities are 
    usually limited for the benefit of the citizens of the state in which 
    the utility operates. It is not clear that a state utility can delegate 
    its state condemnation power to a regional RTO. Therefore, the final 
    rule should expressly address how state condemnation authority can be 
    legally exercised by a regional RTO.
        NASUCA maintains that the RTO regional planning efforts must not 
    displace state government siting authority. NASUCA states that the 
    final rule should specifically recognize state statutory authority to 
    regulate siting of transmission facilities. For other planning and 
    expansion matters, the Commission should require RTOs to establish a 
    process to ensure that the RTO obtains input from state government 
    agencies with respect to the regional transmission plan. Nevada 
    Commission states that it is imperative that the RTO coordinate 
    transmission siting and planning with state agencies. Tri State 
    believes that states should continue to fulfill their traditional roles 
    in siting transmission facilities. However, it notes that it may be 
    necessary for the states to consult with the RTO on transmission 
    facility certification since the RTO will be charged with overall 
    responsibility for transmission planning and will be required to work 
    cooperatively with states and other regional groups.
        CP&L supports state and local governments retaining the authority 
    for certification and siting of new transmission facilities. These 
    government agencies are closer to the local residents who will be 
    affected and can best evaluate the great number of factors that must be 
    considered in approving transmission routes.
        Several commenters address the issue of eminent domain authority as 
    a component of the transmission planning and expansion function. East 
    Kentucky believes that the issue of eminent domain needs to be 
    addressed for not only RTOs, but also for the entire open access 
    transmission network. East Kentucky questions whether an entity, if 
    required by an RTO or the Commission to construct a transmission 
    facility, has eminent domain authority that is sufficient to allow the 
    entity to acquire all property rights necessary to construct the 
    required facility. Consequently, East Kentucky argues that, as a 
    general proposition, Congress needs to grant federal eminent domain 
    authority to any entity that is required by the Commission or any form 
    of RTO to build a facility so that such entity can acquire private 
    property rights under Federal law. Because it believes that siting of 
    transmission has become the principal impediment to transmission
    
    [[Page 909]]
    
    expansion, EPSA also advocates that the RTO should be delegated 
    sufficient authority to direct transmission owners or others to excise 
    their eminent domain authority, as necessary, to implement transmission 
    system expansion plans independent of the source of funds or the 
    beneficiary of the project. Under current law, this authority must come 
    from the states. Thus, EPSA also advocates the passage of Federal 
    legislation that vests the Commission with primary jurisdiction over 
    major transmission planning and siting decisions, perhaps subject to a 
    requirement that the Commission consult with a regional siting 
    authority or a consortium of affected state siting boards.
        Central Maine disagrees and recommends that the Commission should 
    reject EPSA's comments. Central Maine notes that, if a state government 
    intends that an RTO have the power of eminent domain, the state 
    legislature will grant it. Central Maine argues that RTOs should not be 
    granted the power to do something indirectly that they may not do 
    directly. Consequently, it believes that EPSA must pursue its proposal 
    through the enactment of state legislation.
        Whether Three Years Is an Appropriate Amount of Time for 
    Implementation of This Function. Several commenters support the 
    Commission's proposal to allow up to three years to implement the 
    planning and expansion function.\589\ Some commenters, however, believe 
    that three years is too short.\590\ South Carolina Authority suggests a 
    five-year period. Florida Commission believes that it is premature to 
    set any time limit for implementation of the planning and expansion 
    function.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \589\ See, e.g., Tri State, SoCal Edison and PNM.
        \590\ See, e.g., NECPUC, Duke and South Carolina Authority.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        On the other hand, several commenters believe that three years is 
    too long a period.\591\ Most of these commenters believe that the 
    planning and expansion is such an important function that its 
    implementation should not be delayed at all. NYC suggests that 
    implementation should not be delayed more than a year. SRP argues that 
    the uncertainty that currently exists about who ultimately will be 
    responsible for building and paying for new transmission facilities is 
    causing delays in upgrades. According to SRP, requiring the RTO to 
    perform this function upon commercial operation will eliminate this 
    uncertainty. Industrial Customers also argues that any delay should not 
    be used as an excuse to stall the construction of any facility for 
    which the need has been established. SRP suggests that, if a delay in 
    implementation is permitted, the RTO should be required to identify the 
    entity responsible for financing and building transmission expansion 
    prior to the RTO assuming such responsibility.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \591\ See, e.g., Champion, NYC, Turlock, SRP, TDU Systems and 
    Industrial Customers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commission Conclusion. We reaffirm the NOPR proposal that the RTO 
    must have ultimate responsibility for both transmission planning and 
    expansion within its region that will enable it to provide efficient, 
    reliable and non-discriminatory service and coordinate such efforts 
    with the appropriate state authorities. In carrying out this overall 
    responsibility, the Commission has concluded that the NOPR's three 
    separate requirements for RTO planning and expansion must also be 
    satisfied or, in the alternative, the RTO must demonstrate that an 
    alternative proposal is consistent with or superior to these three 
    requirements. Specifically, an RTO must satisfy the requirement to: (1) 
    Encourage market-motivated operating and investment actions for 
    preventing and relieving congestion; (2) accommodate efforts by state 
    regulatory commissions to create multi-state agreements to review and 
    approve new transmission facilities, coordinated with programs of 
    existing Regional Transmission Groups (RTGs) where necessary; and (3) 
    file a plan with the Commission with specified milestones that will 
    ensure that it meets the overall planning and expansion requirement no 
    later than three years after initial operation, if the RTO is unable to 
    satisfy this requirement when it commences operation.
        As noted above, the RTO should have ultimate responsibility for 
    both transmission planning and expansion within its region. The 
    rationale for this requirement is that a single entity must coordinate 
    these actions to ensure a least cost outcome that maintains or improves 
    existing reliability levels. In the absence of a single entity 
    performing these functions, there is a danger that separate 
    transmission investments will work at cross-purposes and possibly even 
    hurt reliability. We also recognize that the RTO's implementation of 
    this general standard requires addressing many specific design 
    questions, including who decides which projects should be built and how 
    the costs and benefits of the project should be allocated.\592\ As with 
    other requirements of the Final Rule, we propose to give RTOs 
    considerable flexibility in designing a planning and expansion process 
    that works best for its region. It is both inevitable and desirable 
    that the specific features of this process ``should take account of and 
    accommodate existing institutions and physical characteristics of the 
    region.'' \593\ We emphasize that, as the transmission provider in the 
    region, the RTO is required to provide service under a tariff that is 
    consistent with or superior to the Commission's pro forma tariff, and 
    that tariff obligates the transmission provider to expand and modify 
    its system to provide the services requested under the pro forma 
    tariff.\594\ Because an RTO may not own all of the facilities it 
    operates, we clarify that nothing in this Rule relieves any public 
    utility of its existing obligation under the pro forma transmission 
    tariff to expand or upgrade its transmission system upon request. 
    Accordingly, we shall evaluate each RTO proposal to ensure that the RTO 
    can direct or arrange for the construction of expansion projects that 
    are needed to ensure reliable transmission services.\595\ However, the 
    Commission reiterates, as discussed below, its strong preference for 
    market-motivated operating and investment actions.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \592\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,751-52.
        \593\ Id. at 33,752.
        \594\ See, e.g., Section 15.4 of the pro forma tariff which 
    requires the transmission provider to use due diligence to expand or 
    modify its transmission system to provide requested services. Also, 
    Section 28.2 of the pro forma tariff requires the transmission 
    provider to plan, construct, operate and maintain its transmission 
    system in order to provide network service, and to endeavor to 
    construct and place into service sufficient transmission capacity to 
    deliver network resources to network customers on a basis comparable 
    to its own use of the transmission system.
        \595\ We note that existing ISOs have addressed similar issues 
    successfully. For example, the PJM ISO is responsible for expansion 
    planning, but the transmission owners remain obligated to undertake 
    upgrades necessitated by the plan, 81 FERC para. 61,257 at 62,275 
    (1997).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We further note that the pricing mechanisms and actions used by the 
    RTO as part of its transmission planning and expansion program should 
    be compatible with the pricing signals for shorter-term solutions to 
    transmission constraints (i.e., congestion management) so that market 
    participants can choose the least-cost response. Otherwise, their 
    choices may reflect less efficient outcomes for the marketplace. For 
    example, if the price of expansion overstates its cost (or the price of 
    congestion management understates actual congestion cost), market 
    participants likely will continue congestion management solutions to a 
    transmission constraint when
    
    [[Page 910]]
    
    expanding the system to relieve congestion is more efficient.
        Market-Motivated Actions. Planning new generation or new 
    transmission requires a coordinated approach to ensure reliability and 
    efficient congestion management. However, this does not necessarily 
    imply that all transmission expansions must be centrally planned by the 
    RTO. Where feasible, an RTO should encourage market approaches to 
    relieving congestion. A market approach will require providing all 
    transmission customers with access to well-defined transmission rights 
    and efficient price signals that show the consequences of their 
    transmission usage decision. If the RTO's market approach is 
    successful, the decisions of where, when and how to relieve congestion 
    will be driven by economic considerations.
        Most commenters agree with the NOPR proposal that RTOs should rely 
    upon market signals and market solutions in assessing all feasible 
    options (e.g., construction of new generation, redispatch of existing 
    generation, as well as expansion of the transmission grid) to assure 
    that the least costly option is pursued. If an RTO can facilitate 
    market-motivated decisions, several commenters point out that its 
    planning role may largely be limited to extreme circumstances where 
    continuing congestion in an area threatens reliability. However, we 
    also recognize that different market approaches to relieving congestion 
    are still in the early stages of development. Similarly, while market 
    approaches to expansion are the subject of much discussion, they are 
    also in the early stages of development.\596\ It is not the intent of 
    the Commission either to mandate a market approach to the exclusion of 
    an executive decision by the RTO or to mandate any particular market 
    approach.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \596\ For example, TDU Systems and other commenters suggest 
    that, by promoting competition for new construction, the RTO can 
    minimize construction cost and also reduce its own risk profile. For 
    example, an ISO in Victoria, Australia (VPX), which operates, but 
    does not own transmission assets, uses competitive bidding for new 
    transmission facilities. At the Regional ISO Conference in Richmond, 
    Virginia on June 8, 1998, Raymond Coxe described how VPX's strategy 
    resulted in a number of bidders competing for the right to build, 
    own and operate new facilities. He concluded that the ``result of 
    this competition was a lower price to the consumers of Victoria than 
    would have resulted from regulated transmission service by the 
    largest incumbent provider.'' Transcript at 86, Docket PL98-5-006.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Nevertheless, if any market-driven approach is to be successful, 
    there must be accurate price signals that reflect the costs of 
    congestion and expansion costs. As we stated in the NOPR, accurate 
    price signals are the link between current usage and future expansion. 
    Therefore, as discussed in more detail in Section III.E.2 Congestion 
    Management, every RTO must establish a system of congestion management 
    that establishes clear rights to transmission facilities and provides 
    market participants with price signals that reflect congestion and 
    expansion costs. In implementing its planning and expansion 
    responsibility, an RTO must ensure that its decisions are not unduly 
    discriminatory and produce efficient outcomes.
        The Commission reaffirms its statement in the NOPR that independent 
    governance of the RTO is a necessary condition for nondiscriminatory 
    and efficient planning and expansion. While accurate price signals can 
    signal the need for expansion, such expansion may not be achieved if an 
    RTO operates under a faulty governance system (e.g., a governance 
    system that allows market participants to block expansions that will 
    harm their commercial interests).
        Multi-State Agreements and RTGs. The final rule fully recognizes 
    the statutory authority of the states to regulate siting of 
    transmission facilities. Currently, state and local governments and 
    regulatory agencies have exclusive authority over the siting process. 
    Therefore, an RTO's planning and expansion process must be designed to 
    be consistent with these state and local responsibilities.
        RTOs must accommodate efforts by state regulatory commissions to 
    create multi-state agreements to review and approve new transmission 
    facilities. The Commission encourages the development of multi-state 
    agreements or compacts to review and approve new transmission 
    facilities. This would expedite transmission construction and eliminate 
    duplicative (and possibly conflicting) reviews by multiple states. To 
    facilitate any voluntary actions taken by our state colleagues, we will 
    require that the RTO planning and coordination system must be able to 
    accommodate the possible emergence of new regional regulatory systems.
        Existing RTGs have clear and prominent roles in transmission 
    expansion decisions in which planning for transmission improvements are 
    coordinated through collaborative processes. To avoid duplicative 
    efforts, the RTO process must build on existing RTG planning processes. 
    Over time, since the RTO will have ultimate responsibility for planning 
    the entire transmission system within its region, we expect that the 
    functions of an RTG will be assumed by an RTO to avoid unnecessary 
    duplication of effort.
        Three-Year Implementation. If the RTO is unable to satisfy the 
    planning and expansion function when it commences operation, it must 
    file a plan with the Commission with specified milestones that will 
    ensure that it meets this requirement no later than three years after 
    initial operation. Recognizing that the planning and expansion function 
    may require coordination among multiple parties and regulatory 
    jurisdictions, we do not require this function to be in place at the 
    initial operation of the RTO. We continue to believe that three years 
    is a reasonable deadline for creating an operational planning and 
    expansion system. Therefore, we will not extend this deadline or the 
    requirement to file a plan with the Commission with an implementation 
    timetable. This time period could be affected by the RTO's scope, the 
    number of states and market participants, and implementation costs; 
    however, the urgent needs of the electricity markets make us 
    disinclined to extend these deadlines.
        However, the delay should not stall the construction of new or 
    enhanced facilities for which needs have been established, unless the 
    RTO makes a positive decision that the facility is not in the best 
    interests of the region. Delaying transmission expansion could result 
    in significant market inefficiencies as well as unacceptable risks to 
    reliability given the long regulatory and construction lead times 
    required to build new facilities.
    8. Interregional Coordination (Function 8)
        In Order No. 888, the Commission identified eleven principles it 
    would use to assess Independent System Operator (ISO) proposals 
    submitted to the Commission.\597\ One of these principles required that 
    the ISO develop mechanisms to coordinate with neighboring control areas 
    to ensure reliability and the provision of transmission services that 
    cross system boundaries. The RTO NOPR encouraged transmission entities 
    to consider ways to reduce impediments to transactions among 
    themselves,\598\ but a coordination requirement was not included 
    explicitly in the RTO NOPR. Several commenters pointed out that there 
    was no explicit coordination requirement proposed in the RTO NOPR and 
    recommended including a function for RTOs similar to the coordination 
    principle in Order No. 888.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \597\ Order No. 888, FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 31,036 at 
    31,730-32.
        \598\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,758.
    
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [[Page 911]]
    
        Comments. Several commenters identify coordination with other 
    regions as a necessary element that should be added more explicitly to 
    the RTO functions.\599\ These commenters express this need as either 
    required to ensure reliability or necessary for bulk power markets to 
    operate over sufficiently large areas. For example, NERC states that 
    the need for such coordination effort has increased as the management 
    of short-term reliability of the interconnected bulk power system and 
    the operation of increasingly competitive bulk power markets have 
    become inseparable. Accordingly, NERC recommends that an additional 
    function be added to the final rule that requires RTOs to integrate 
    their market interface practices and reliability practices. It 
    identifies OASIS standards, information sharing with neighboring RTOs, 
    ancillary services requirements, parallel path flows, transmission 
    loading relief, and interregional congestion management, as practices 
    and standards that need to be integrated.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \599\ Many parties supported this requirement including NERC, 
    Justice Department, NARUC, NASUCA, Oneok, PJM, Duquesne and 
    Industrial Consumers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Duquesne states that efficiencies can be realized from coordinating 
    and developing a seamless marketplace. It recommends that the 
    Commission require RTOs to coordinate and plan for seamless and uniform 
    transmission rules, scheduling systems and procedures, and reliability 
    standards. In addition, Oneok suggests that the Commission encourage 
    neighboring RTOs to form reliability compacts under which loop flow and 
    other issues involving interregional reliability impacts can be 
    resolved.\600\ Also, Wyoming Commission believes that the Commission 
    should be flexible with respect to inter-RTO interaction and that it 
    may be appropriate to address these issues later rather than in initial 
    RTO filings.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \600\ ISO-NE, NY ISO and PJM recently signed a memorandum of 
    understanding concerning interregional coordination activities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commission Conclusion. Coordination of activities among regions is 
    a significant element in maintaining a reliable bulk transmission 
    system and for the development of competitive markets. In the NOPR, we 
    discussed several region-to-region coordination activities in 
    connection with the parallel path, congestion management, and expansion 
    planning functions. However, the comments persuade us to add a more 
    general interregional coordination requirement as one of the minimum 
    RTO functions.
    
        We will require an RTO to develop mechanisms to coordinate its 
    activities with other regions whether or not an RTO yet exists in these 
    other regions.\601\ If it is not possible to set forth the coordination 
    mechanisms at the time an RTO application is filed, the RTO applicant 
    must propose reporting requirements, including a schedule, for itself 
    to provide follow-up details as to how it is meeting the coordination 
    requirements of this function. We expect the RTO to work closely with 
    other regions to address interregional problems and problems at the 
    ``seams'' between the RTOs. Therefore, as recommended by NERC and 
    others, we will add the following regulatory text to our RTO Final Rule 
    functions:
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \601\ This is similar to the existing ISO Principle #10 in Order 
    No. 888 for single control area ISOs: ``An ISO should develop 
    mechanisms to coordinate with neighboring control areas.''
    
        (8) Interregional Coordination: The Regional Transmission 
    Organization must ensure the integration of reliability practices 
    within an interconnection and market interface practices among 
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    regions.
    
        An RTO proposal must explain how the RTO will ensure the 
    integration of reliability and market interface practices. An RTO may 
    ensure the integration of these practices either by developing 
    integration practices itself or by cooperating in the development of 
    integrated practices with an independent entity that covers all regions 
    or, for reliability practices, covers an entire interconnection. The 
    term, interconnection,\602\ refers here to any one of three large U.S. 
    transmission systems. The Eastern Interconnection covers most of the 
    area east of the Rocky Mountains in the United States and Canada. The 
    Western Interconnection covers an area that is mostly west of the Rocky 
    Mountains in the United States and Canada, as well as a small portion 
    of Mexico. The Electric Reliability Council of Texas (ERCOT) 
    Interconnection covers much of Texas.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \602\ ``Interconnection'' is a term used by the North American 
    Electric Reliability Council and others to refer to an 
    interconnected alternating current transmission system. Engineering 
    considerations require all generators connected to any one 
    interconnection to operate in a coordinated manner, that is, 
    synchronously.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        This provision does not mean that all RTOs necessarily must have a 
    uniform practice, but that RTO reliability and market interface 
    practices must be compatible with each other, especially at the 
    ``seams.'' RTOs must coordinate their practices with neighboring 
    regions to ensure that market activity is not limited because of 
    different regional practices.
        We understand, as NERC pointed out in its comments, that the 
    reliability and market interface practices are becoming highly 
    interrelated. The reliability practices affect how markets interface 
    with each other, and the market interface practices affect reliability. 
    For example, TLR and congestion management are both used to unload an 
    overloaded transmission interface, and these two practices must work 
    together. We consider congestion management and TLR are best used as 
    sequential steps to unload a line, with congestion management used 
    first to unload a line in a market-oriented manner, and TLR used to 
    unload a line in a fair manner when either congestion management is 
    unavailable or an emergency condition requires immediate action. We 
    therefore list below TLR as a reliability practice and congestion 
    management as a market interface practice, understanding that these and 
    other practices listed affect both reliability and markets.
        The integration of reliability practices involves procedures for 
    coordination of reliability practices and sharing of reliability data 
    among regions in an interconnection, including procedures that address 
    parallel path flows, ancillary service standards, transmission loading 
    relief procedures, among other reliability-related coordination 
    requirements in this Final Rule.
        The integration of market interface practices involves developing 
    some level of standardization of inter-regional market standards and 
    practices, including the coordination and sharing of data necessary for 
    calculation of TTC and ATC, transmission reservation practices, 
    scheduling practices, and congestion management procedures, as well as 
    other market coordination requirements covered elsewhere in this Final 
    Rule.
    
    F. Open Architecture
    
        In the NOPR, the Commission stated its commitment to a policy of 
    ``open architecture'' and proposed to require that RTOs be designed so 
    that they can evolve over time. The Commission noted that there should 
    be no provision in any RTO proposal that precludes the RTO and its 
    members from improving their organization to meet market needs.\603\ 
    The Commission sought comments regarding the open architecture policy 
    in general and the flexibility needs of RTOs in particular.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \603\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,753.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments. Virtually all commenters support the NOPR's open 
    architecture concept and recommend that an RTO have the ability to 
    evolve over time as
    
    [[Page 912]]
    
    it gains operating experience.\604\ They endorse the principle of 
    flexibility to accommodate the changing needs of the market.\605\ WEPCO 
    notes that open architecture should permit flexibility and urges the 
    Commission not to require an RTO to be the only control area operator 
    in the region.\606\ Ontario Power states that the open architecture 
    policy should enable RTOs to accommodate Canadian entities in the 
    future. Oglethorpe observes that open architecture policy would allow 
    RTOs to utilize existing infrastructure and avoid high transition 
    costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \604\ See, e.g., APX, Arizona Commission, Cal ISO, Central 
    Maine, Consumers Energy, CP&L, Conectiv, Desert STAR, DOE, Duke, 
    Entergy, EPSA, FirstEnergy, Florida Commission, Georgia 
    Transmission, Illinois Commission, Industrial Consumers, LG&E, NERC, 
    NPCC, NSP, NU, NY ISO, Oglethorpe, PJM, Seattle, Southern Company, 
    SMUD, SRP, TDU Systems, TEP, Tri-State and WEPCO.
        \605\ NSP states that the configuration of electric markets will 
    be much different five or ten years from now.
        \606\ WEPCO notes that costs savings associated with creating 
    large, efficient electricity markets will dwarf the savings attained 
    by reducing the number of operators through control area 
    consolidation.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        However, Central Maine and Southern Company argue that the 
    flexibility implied by open architecture should not be used carte 
    blanche. For example, there should be limits to an RTO's evolution 
    process because transmission owners have some fundamental rights, such 
    as: (1) The right to terminate their participation in the RTO; (2) the 
    right to switch to another RTO; (3) the right to merge RTOs; (4) the 
    right to recover their costs and a return on investment; and (5) the 
    right to protect their assets and employees from damages and injuries.
        LG&E states that the flexibility inherent in the open architecture 
    concept should be applied fairly to all market participants, including 
    those transmission owners that have already committed to existing or 
    proposed ISOs. For example, a member of an existing ISO should be 
    allowed to move to another RTO.
        Industrial Consumers perceives a potential downside to the open 
    architecture policy in that it may give existing IOUs a license to 
    continue their opportunistic behavior rather than facilitating true 
    market transformation. Therefore, Industrial Consumers argues that it 
    supports the notion of flexibility inherent in the open architecture 
    policy only in the absence of market power. Illinois Commission argues 
    that the pace of evolutionary improvement of RTOs should not remain in 
    the hands of vertically integrated utilities because their interest in 
    structural change may not be consistent with the public interest.
        Cinergy, EPSA and Georgia Transmission state that the flexibility 
    implied by open architecture should not be used to support deviations 
    from minimum characteristics and functions. However, CP&L believes that 
    the proposed minimum characteristics and functions are too stringent 
    and do not allow for much flexibility that a changing market 
    needs.\607\ Georgia Transmission supports the Commission's commitment 
    to providing regulatory flexibility to allow RTOs to evolve.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \607\ CP&L and Southern Company state that the Commission should 
    establish basic RTO guidelines through a policy statement rather 
    than by a rule. They contend that the rules under the NOPR are too 
    prescriptive, and will stifle the development of new RTOs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Many commenters state that the open architecture concept is so 
    broad that it will prevent stakeholders from developing meaningful RTO 
    proposals. To bring some certainty to the negotiating parties to an RTO 
    proposal, CP&L recommends that the Commission find that some necessary 
    and reasonable limitations on modifications to RTOs are permissible, 
    and these can be overridden only by unanimous consent or a 
    supermajority vote.\608\ MidAmerican states that the Commission should 
    accept RTO proposals that contain stated limitations, such as a 
    transmission owner's right to withdraw from an RTO. MidAmerican argues 
    that such limitations are consistent with the Commission's open 
    architecture policy and would prevent transmission owners from being 
    discouraged to join RTOs. To promote certainty, Entergy notes that the 
    Commission should establish a general policy of grandfathering 
    previously approved RTOs and not altering their requirements except in 
    extraordinary circumstances.\609\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \608\ CP&L notes that participants in Midwest ISO identified 
    certain conditions that could be altered only by the transmission 
    owners, including revenue distribution, pricing methodology and 
    withdrawal rights.
        \609\ Entergy at 42.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Southern Company is concerned that RTOs could evolve in ways that 
    are undesirable to the participants that initiated its formation. 
    Therefore, it argues that the parties should have some assurance that 
    certain key provisions of an RTO would not change in the name of RTO 
    evolution. For example, functions, boundaries, transmission rate 
    design, and allocation of transmission revenues should not be amended 
    by the RTO except by vote of the transmission owners, at least for the 
    duration of a specified transition period. Southern Company contends 
    that the transmission owners will then know what they are ``getting 
    into'' when they join an RTO.
        Many commenters recommend that the Commission should not mandate 
    the ultimate organizational form of the RTO given the electric 
    industry's current state of structural flux and the uncertainty of the 
    future. These commenters argue that the Commission's open architecture 
    policy should encourage market participants to develop transmission 
    institutions that are effective in meeting the needs of the 
    marketplace. FirstEnergy and NU state that there is a range of 
    organizational and functional forms--power pool (tight and loose): 
    gridco, transco, marketco--which can accomplish the Commission's goal 
    of improving the efficiency of the transmission grid, and only time and 
    market forces should determine which form is best suited for a specific 
    region of the country. Southern Company believes that there should be 
    no requirement that would prohibit an RTO with no transmission 
    ownership to transform into one that owns transmission (i.e., change 
    from an ISO to a transco).
        PJM urges the Commission to clarify that RTOs can propose 
    improvements to the RTO independently of its members to meet changing 
    market needs. PSE&G is opposed to giving such authority to RTOs because 
    it believes that the market participants rather than RTOs should drive 
    changes in the structure and operation of electric markets.\610\ Cal 
    ISO recommends that the Commission's open architecture policy should 
    support the creation of a structure that facilitates the addition of 
    new participants, both within and outside of the existing RTO 
    boundaries. Illinois Commission urges the Commission to modify the 
    proposed paragraph 35.34(k) of proposed regulations to include an 
    affirmative expectation that RTOs will change to meet new competitive 
    market needs and to improve over time.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \610\ PSE&G Reply Comments at 6-7.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commission Conclusion. As proposed in the NOPR, we adopt the 
    principle of open architecture in order that the RTO and its members 
    have the flexibility to improve their organizations in the future in 
    terms of structure, geographic scope, market support and operations to 
    meet market needs. We will require that the RTO design have the ability 
    to evolve over time. In addition, we will provide flexibility to allow 
    RTOs to propose changes to their enabling agreements to meet changing 
    market, organization and policy needs.
    
    [[Page 913]]
    
        Open architecture will permit RTOs to evolve in several ways, as 
    long as proposed changes continue to satisfy RTO minimum 
    characteristics and functions. As a first example, open architecture 
    will allow basic changes in the organizational form of the RTO to 
    reflect changes in facility ownership and revised corporate strategies. 
    As noted by Southern Company, an RTO that initially does not own any 
    transmission facilities might acquire ownership of some or all of those 
    facilities. With an open architecture design, the RTO's enabling 
    agreements should anticipate and facilitate changes of this nature.
        Second, open architecture design accommodates change in the 
    geographical scope of RTOs. Electric markets are evolving quickly and 
    future market trading patterns cannot be foreseen at the time of RTO 
    organization. An open architecture design will enable an RTO to grow 
    geographically and possibly merge with another RTO as changes in 
    markets suggest a realignment of organizations to meet evolving market 
    needs.
        Third, market support is another area that benefits from open 
    architecture design. For example, an RTO may not initially operate a PX 
    to support a regional spot market, but later determine that the 
    establishment of a PX would provide additional benefit in its region. 
    With open architecture, the RTO can propose to add a PX function (or a 
    PX monitoring function) to its design. Open architecture design ensures 
    that such future developments that are beneficial to the marketplace 
    are not foreclosed.
        Fourth, open architecture design accommodates changing operational 
    needs. Most commenters agree that, as RTOs gain operating experience, 
    some changes will become necessary. Cal ISO acknowledges that it had to 
    make significant changes to its tariff and operational practices as it 
    gained operating experience, and it believes further modifications are 
    likely to be identified as additional experience is gained regarding 
    evolving competitive markets.
        Finally, as noted in the NOPR, technological change make changes in 
    RTO design inevitable and desirable. Accommodating that change will 
    require flexibility and adaptability in the RTO organization; open 
    architecture will permit design modification to keep pace with 
    technology.
        Some commenters argue that the flexibility implied by open 
    architecture design should not be interpreted to mean unfettered 
    ability on the part of the RTO to modify its structure or processes. We 
    agree. Although under our open architecture policy the RTO will have 
    the ability to propose whatever changes it believes are appropriate to 
    meet the evolving needs of the RTO and the region, any such proposals 
    or changes to existing agreements, which will be changes to the RTO's 
    jurisdictional rate schedule(s) and contracts, will be subject to 
    Commission review and approval under the FPA. The Commission will 
    consider the merits of any changes to an approved RTO on a case-by-case 
    basis. Interested parties will have the opportunity to comment on any 
    such proposal. This process will enable all parties and the Commission 
    to guard against proposed changes that are likely to stifle 
    competition.
    
    G. Transmission Ratemaking Policy for RTOs
    
        We have concluded that the success of the Commission's efforts to 
    have effective and efficient RTOs is dependent in large measure on the 
    feasibility and vitality of the stand-alone transmission business. For 
    that reason, and to promote economic efficiency, the RTO transmission 
    ratemaking policies of the Commission are an important factor of RTO 
    success. In light of the restructuring of markets and market 
    institutions that is taking place, we now believe that it will be 
    helpful to inform the industry about what we consider to be appropriate 
    and inappropriate transmission pricing practices for RTOs, and about a 
    framework for RTOs to propose efficient and fair pricing reform. 
    Accordingly, we provide guidance below on a number of fundamental 
    ratemaking issues.
        We believe that it is critically important for RTOs to develop 
    ratemaking practices that: eliminate regional rate pancaking; manage 
    congestion; internalize parallel path flows; deal effectively and 
    fairly with transmission owning utilities that choose not to 
    participate in RTOs; and provide incentives for transmission owning 
    utilities to efficiently operate and invest in their systems. In 
    particular, the Commission encourages RTOs to develop and propose 
    innovative ratemaking practices, particularly with respect to 
    efficiency incentives. We therefore devote a significant portion of the 
    discussion in this section of the Final Rule to performance-based 
    regulation (PBR) and other RTO transmission ratemaking reforms.
        In addition to the guidance offered here, we have added regulatory 
    text (section 35.34(e)) with regard to PBR and other RTO transmission 
    ratemaking reforms,\611\ which now identifies a select list of 
    innovative transmission rate treatments. The Commission will consider 
    such innovative rate treatments for entities that file proposals under 
    the new section 35.34 and that meet the minimum characteristics and 
    functions required in the Final Rule. The Applicant must explain how 
    the proposed rate treatment would help achieve the goals of RTOs, 
    including efficient use of and investment in the transmission system 
    and reliability benefits to consumers; provide a cost-benefit analysis, 
    including rate impacts; and explain why the proposed rate treatment is 
    appropriate for the RTO proposed by the Applicant. This means that 
    filings under section 35.34(e) must be complete and fully explained; 
    must demonstrate that the resulting rates are just, reasonable, and not 
    unduly discriminatory or preferential; must identify how the rate 
    treatment promotes efficiency and what benefits result; and must 
    demonstrate that the rate treatment does not impede the RTO from 
    meeting the minimum characteristics and functions required under this 
    Final Rule. The Commission encourages properly developed transmission 
    pricing proposals from RTOs that comply with the guidance set forth 
    below and the amended regulatory text.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \611\ We have adopted and expanded the regulatory text proposed 
    by Edison Electric Institute in its comments (see EEI, Appendix E).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We agree with those commenters that urge the Commission to reform 
    its transmission pricing policies to reflect new realities of the 
    industry. For example, a number of commenters point to the unbundling 
    requirements of Order Nos. 888 and 889, the vertical de-integration of 
    generation and transmission for some utilities, the advent of wholesale 
    and retail competition in energy markets, entry into markets of a range 
    of new players, including independent generators and marketers, and 
    other developments as a signal that the Commission's traditional cost-
    of-service ratemaking practices for transmission assets should be 
    reevaluated. Some commenters suggest that the advent of competitive 
    power markets necessitates a more robust transmission network as well 
    as enhanced operating capabilities of the network, compared to the 
    previous era of vertically integrated utilities providing service in 
    monopoly franchise areas. They argue that the Commission's traditional 
    transmission ratemaking practices are unlikely to support such a robust 
    transmission network and enhanced operating capabilities.
    
    [[Page 914]]
    
        To put our concerns about transmission pricing in perspective, the 
    NOPR said that ``the Commission expects RTOs to reform transmission 
    pricing, and in return we propose to allow RTOs greater flexibility in 
    designing pricing proposals.'' \612\ The NOPR also said that our 
    willingness to provide flexibility in reviewing pricing proposals dates 
    back to the Transmission Pricing Policy Statement, issued by the 
    Commission in 1994. In the Policy Statement, we identified five 
    principles that transmission pricing proposals should conform to, 
    including the principle that pricing proposals should meet the 
    traditional revenue requirement. In order that this principle not 
    undermine innovative pricing proposals, the Policy Statement noted that 
    non-conforming pricing proposals would be considered, but that such 
    proposals would have to satisfy additional factors, i.e., promote 
    competitive markets and produce greater overall consumer benefits. In 
    the five years since the Policy Statement was issued, we have approved 
    five ISOs with innovative transmission pricing, but otherwise have 
    received few innovative transmission pricing proposals. We believe 
    that, as a general matter, sensible pricing reform that could promote 
    competition and efficiency in other contexts will achieve maximum 
    benefits only when applied on a regional, rather than a single-system 
    basis. This is true because of the inability of single systems to 
    capture such efficiencies, but sensible pricing reform is one of the 
    efficiencies that will likely flow from RTOs. And while we do not think 
    the Policy Statement has been an impediment to transmission pricing 
    innovation, we now believe, based on the myriad comments we received, 
    that the Commission should now provide greater specificity on 
    appropriate transmission pricing reforms by RTOs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \612\ FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,754.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The rationale for providing greater specificity on transmission 
    pricing for RTOs and amending the regulatory text at this time is 
    three-fold. First, we recognize that transmission pricing issues are 
    some of the most complex issues facing the industry. Second, a 
    potential barrier to the development of RTOs, at least RTOs that span 
    multiple transmission systems, is the difficulty that stakeholders have 
    had reaching consensus on transmission pricing. This is not surprising, 
    given that transmission pricing reform to accommodate regional needs 
    and usage patterns can affect what customers pay for transmission 
    service and how transmission revenues are allocated among multiple 
    owners of transmission within a region. Third, we are concerned that as 
    we move to greater reliance on market forces, the incentives that 
    market participants have to make efficient operating and investment 
    decisions for both generation and transmission facilities are based in 
    part on the price signals that flow from transmission pricing. That is, 
    transmission pricing is a key determinant of the efficient operation of 
    energy, ancillary service and balancing markets, and congestion 
    management.
        At the outset, we want to make clear that, contrary to the 
    apprehensions of some commenters, the Commission is not proposing to 
    ``bribe'' transmission-owning utilities to join an RTO. Rather, the 
    Commission stated in the NOPR that it would consider innovative pricing 
    proposals because we believed then, and now believe more strongly, that 
    a reassessment of transmission pricing policy is warranted, given the 
    fundamental changes in industry structure that have already occurred as 
    well as those which may flow from the RTO Final Rule. In addition, as 
    pointed out by Professor Joskow, delays in RTO formation occasion costs 
    because of more limited competition in generation markets, and these 
    costs may be avoided to the extent that the Commission considers 
    transmission pricing reforms. Furthermore, as discussed below, since 
    the costs of transmission are a small portion of total electric costs, 
    getting transmission pricing right means that the industry will be able 
    to capture significant net benefits from promoting competitive 
    generation markets.
        While the NOPR did not propose specific rules on transmission 
    pricing reform, we believe it is now critical to provide further 
    specificity to the industry. We recognize the need to establish clear 
    and specific requirements for RTO development, provide certainty and 
    clarity about our willingness to entertain transmission pricing reforms 
    that are appropriate for RTOs, and assure utilities that they will not 
    be penalized for RTO participation. To the extent consistent with 
    ensuring that transmission rates are just, reasonable, and not unduly 
    discriminatory, we believe transmission pricing disincentives to 
    joining an RTO should be eliminated so that transmission-owning 
    utilities will find RTO participation to be a dynamic business 
    opportunity. Utilities that join RTOs should be accorded transmission 
    pricing that reflects the financial risks of turning facilities over to 
    an RTO and that reflects other changes in the structure of the 
    industry. Those risks may increase or decrease in particular instances. 
    At the same time, we wish to make clear that the Commission is very 
    concerned about potential impacts of market restructuring on the 
    customers in ``low-cost'' states, and the Commission therefore intends 
    to monitor the effects of RTO formation on such customers, specifically 
    the potential for cost-shifting effects of RTO pricing proposals.
        Traditional transmission pricing approaches reflect the industry 
    structure as it existed when Order No. 888 was issued: a vertically 
    integrated industry where transmission systems were designed primarily 
    to meet the needs of local loads. Our primary focus, both in terms of 
    access and pricing was comparability; that is, all transmission users 
    should receive access under rates, terms and conditions comparable to 
    those the transmitting utility applies to itself to serve its own 
    customers. RTOs reflect a somewhat different approach, in which the 
    transmission system must also be designed and operated to meet the 
    needs of regional markets. It is not unreasonable to expect that, as 
    the transmission system is restructured to meet these changing needs, 
    significant pricing reform may be needed as well. Indeed, since a 
    properly developed RTO will be designing methods to support regional 
    congestion management and regional expansion, transmission pricing 
    reform is inevitable.
        We caution that we do not view transmission pricing reform as a 
    program designed for the sole purpose of enhancing the revenues of 
    transmission owners at the expense of transmission customers. Nor are 
    we abandoning the fundamental underpinnings of our traditional 
    transmission pricing policies, i.e., that transmission prices must 
    reflect the costs of providing the service.\613\ While many aspects of 
    transmission pricing reform are labeled incentive pricing, many are 
    aimed at eliminating disincentives to the efficient use and expansion 
    of regional transmission grids to support emerging competition in 
    generating markets.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \613\ See, e.g., Federal Power Commission v. Hope Natural Gas 
    Co., 320 U.S. 591 (1944); Bluefield Water Works & Improvement Co. v. 
    Public Service Commission of West Virginia, 262 U.S. 679 (1923).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We view transmission pricing reform, not only as an important 
    component of how stand-alone transmission companies can become viable 
    and efficient network businesses, but also as an important means for 
    transmission-owning utilities which maintain ownership but cede control 
    of their transmission assets to an RTO to capture
    
    [[Page 915]]
    
    the benefits of more efficient system operation and additional grid 
    investment. We believe that the opportunities for pricing reform 
    identified in this Rule should have no effect on an RTO's decision 
    about how it will be structured. All RTOs, regardless of ownership 
    structure, are therefore eligible to propose transmission pricing 
    reforms that suit their strategic and economic objectives to the extent 
    consistent with this Final Rule.
        We also believe that the potential for any increase in 
    transmission-related revenues available to transmission providers that 
    are efficient and responsive in meeting the needs of their customers 
    must be balanced by the potential for a decrease in profits if the 
    transmission provider does not meet those needs. Moreover, a properly 
    developed RTO can be expected to produce significant efficiencies, and 
    we would expect that transmission owners, transmission customers and 
    generation market participants will share in the economic benefits 
    resulting from the efficient design and operation of the RTO.
        As the industry begins the collaborative process of establishing 
    RTOs, it is important that the Commission provide some certainty and 
    specificity about the preferred types of transmission pricing reforms, 
    and some certainty and specificity about the types of proposed 
    transmission pricing reforms that appear more problematic. Accordingly, 
    the remainder of this section discusses eight specific transmission 
    ratemaking topics: pancaked rates; reciprocal waiving of access charges 
    between RTOs; use of single system access charges; congestion pricing; 
    service to transmission-owning utilities that do not participate in an 
    RTO; performance-based regulation; other RTO transmission ratemaking 
    reforms; and additional ratemaking issues.
    1. Pancaked Rates
        As described in the NOPR, the elimination of rate pancaking for 
    large regions is a central goal of the Commission's RTO policy, and has 
    been a feature of all five ISOs the Commission had approved. Rate 
    pancaking occurs when a transmission customer is charged separate 
    access charges for each utility service territory the customer's 
    contract path crosses. The NOPR proposed that RTO tariffs not result in 
    transmission customers paying multiple access charges to recover 
    capital costs over facilities that it controls. The NOPR sought 
    comments on the impact of the non-pancaked rate requirement on 
    voluntary RTO formation because of abrupt rate changes. It also sought 
    comments on how the regional configuration may relate to these 
    potential rate changes.
        Comments. The overwhelming majority of the comments favor the 
    proposed prohibition on pancaked rates,\614\ although some commenters 
    express concern over cost shifting. Some commenters, such as Minnesota 
    Power, suggest that the cost shifting effect of non-pancaked rates 
    would discourage voluntary RTO formation.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \614\ See, e.g., NASUCA, PJM, LG&E, Industrial Consumers and 
    WEPCO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Some commenters suggest alternative approaches to the strict non-
    pancaked rate described in the NOPR. For example, WPSC advocates the 
    use of flow-based, distance-sensitive rates as a replacement for 
    pancaked rates. Allegheny argues that removing rate pancaking can cause 
    disruptive shifts in rates and revenue requirements which are solved 
    only temporarily with transitional rates. Allegheny proposes its form 
    of locational marginal pricing method to solve this problem. NSP favors 
    non-pancaked rates but notes that rates for the high-voltage system 
    that differ from those for the low-voltage system may be an effective 
    long-term rate strategy. MidAmerican recommends that the prohibition 
    against rate pancaking be changed to allow transmission owners to 
    charge a home-zone rate based on local cost determination and a wide-
    area charge outside the home area. MidAmerican argues that this 
    approach would minimize cost shifting. The pancaked rate prohibition 
    would change to: ``promote wide-area transmission rates with due 
    consideration to shifting of costs among transmission service providers 
    and between state and federal delivery rates. Finally, Williams 
    recommends that the Commission also consider other pricing methods such 
    as those based on mileage or network usage and market-based rates, 
    where possible, because it considers cost of service rates inefficient 
    and unresponsive to the market.
        A few commenters question an absolute prohibition against pancaked 
    rates. AEP and Florida Power Corp. warn that a strict prohibition 
    against pancaked rates may, at times, work against efficient solutions. 
    There should not be a strict prohibition without regard to size or 
    locational factors. Florida Power Corp. argues that this approach is 
    consistent with the Commission's Transmission Pricing Policy Statement. 
    Customers of both AEP and Florida Power Corp. dispute this view.\615\ 
    Southern Company notes that an absolute prohibition against pancaked 
    rates may hurt retail customers whose rates are supported by 
    transmission revenue. Transmission owners should be assured in the 
    final rule that they will be able to recover their full revenue 
    requirement in the face of any pancaked rate prohibition. The 
    Commission should, according to Southern Company, also clarify that a 
    prohibition against pancaked rates does not prevent the use of zonal or 
    other distance-sensitive rates. Desert STAR argues that a single 
    region-wide rate may not be appropriate in a large region with 
    legitimate cost differences among companies, and suggests that license 
    plate rates may mitigate cost shifting but will not always eliminate 
    it.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \615\ See New Smyrna Beach and Coalition of Alliance Users.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commission Conclusion. In the NOPR, we described the elimination of 
    rate pancaking as a central goal of our RTO policy. After receiving 
    comments on the subject, mostly in favor of the proposed prohibition, 
    we affirm that the RTO tariff must not result in transmission customers 
    paying multiple access charges to recover capital costs.\616\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \616\ Section 35.34(k)(1)(ii). However, see the discussion below 
    regarding service to transmission-owning utilities that do not 
    participate in an RTO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Except for transactions within the ISOs now in place, transmission 
    customers are faced with additional access charges for every utility 
    border they cross. The distances need not be great to be assessed two, 
    three or more access charges for a single transaction. This duplication 
    can severely restrict the area in which generation can economically be 
    secured. A main reason that an RTO can expand the marketplace for 
    generation to a large region is that an RTO can implement non-pancaked 
    rates for each transaction. A wider area served by a single rate means 
    more generation is economically available to any customer which means 
    greater competition for energy.
        Some commenters warn that a blind adherence to non-pancaked rates 
    can produce inefficiencies in some circumstances. Some argue that large 
    distances and special conditions can add to transmission costs in a way 
    not reflected in single system rates. They would leave open the option 
    for distance-sensitive rates or completely new rate innovations that 
    may not fit the strict definition of a non-pancaked rate. We are 
    sensitive to some of these concerns, but we do not view a policy 
    requiring non-pancaked rates as posing the problems that some 
    commenters
    
    [[Page 916]]
    
    describe. We take this opportunity to reaffirm that we will continue to 
    be receptive to distance-sensitive rates and other rate features that 
    can be supported.
    2. Reciprocal Waiving of Access Charges Between RTOs
        The elimination of pancaked rates within an RTO was intended to 
    increase the efficiency of trade in that region. The NOPR furthered 
    that concept by encouraging RTOs to agree among themselves to waive 
    access charges on a reciprocal basis for transactions that cross RTO 
    borders. If accomplished, this would have the effect of increasing 
    effective trading areas. The NOPR sought comments on how the Commission 
    could facilitate reciprocal waivers of access charges, and whether 
    there are other impediments to inter-regional trade.
        Comments. A majority of the commenters support the concept of a 
    reciprocal waiver of access charges to encourage inter-regional 
    trade.\617\ Of those who support waivers, some, including Duke and SRP, 
    specifically recommend that waivers be voluntary. Some supporters of 
    waiving access charges note that it is not just the pancaked charges 
    that inhibit inter-regional trade but also variations in business 
    practices and procedures between RTOs. These commenters \618\ recommend 
    that the Commission ensure that such incompatibilities not be allowed 
    to hamper trade between RTO regions.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \617\ See, e.g., Sithe, WPSC, Minnesota Power, Ohio Commission, 
    and Midwest ISO Participants.
        \618\ See, e.g., Ontario Power and Oregon Office.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several commenters, both supporting and opposed to waiver of access 
    charges, warn that the waivers proposed in the NOPR can cause cost 
    shifting. Duke argues that cost shifting can be remedied by the 
    structure of the rate. DOE and First Energy also express concerns about 
    cost shifting. Southern Company generally opposes waivers of access 
    charges unless transmission owners' revenues are protected.
        Some commenters oppose waiving access charges between RTOs for 
    reasons other than cost shifting concerns. South Carolina Authority 
    claims that reciprocal agreements between RTOs waiving access charges 
    are discriminatory and that independent monitoring groups would be 
    needed to prevent gaming of reciprocity agreements. CP&L argues that 
    waivers create a bias to sell outside of the RTO. Tri-State proposes 
    the use of distance-sensitive export pricing mechanisms instead of 
    waivers.
        PP&L Companies claim that inter-regional trade solutions should be 
    arrived at through a collaborative effort of stakeholders. NECPUC and 
    Desert STAR argue that the Commission should grant deference to 
    participants' solutions for inter-regional trade. Florida Commission 
    argues that the Commission should wait until intra-regional trade 
    barriers are dismantled before dealing with inter-regional trade.
        Commission Conclusion. We asked in the NOPR for comments on the 
    policy of allowing RTOs to reach reciprocal agreements to waive access 
    charges for transmission that crosses an RTO border. Most commenters 
    supported the approval of such waivers and some asked the Commission to 
    further support inter-regional trade by requiring uniform practices and 
    procedures among RTOs. Some commenters maintain that incompatible or 
    varying procedures between RTOs can be as dampening to inter-regional 
    trade as multiple rates.
        We will continue to encourage reciprocal waivers of access charges 
    between RTOs as long as they are reasonable in terms of cost recovery, 
    cost shifting, efficiency, and discrimination. We also encourage terms 
    and procedures that are compatible from region to region to the extent 
    appropriate. Accordingly, we have added an RTO function to integrate 
    reliability and market interface practices with other regions, as 
    discussed above.
    3. Uniform Access Charges
        Each ISO approved by the Commission has struggled with the problem 
    of cost shifting among the various individual transmission owners that 
    make up the ISO. A single access rate would mean that the customers of 
    low-cost transmission providers would see a rate increase and high-cost 
    transmission providers would be concerned about not meeting their 
    revenue requirements. The potential for cost shifting has been a 
    stumbling block for several regions seeking to establish regional 
    transmission organizations.
        The Commission has allowed a flexible approach to this problem, and 
    in each ISO approved by the Commission to date the solution has been to 
    adopt a ``license plate'' rate for a transitional period of five to ten 
    years before moving to a single uniform access charge. A license plate 
    rate provides access to the regional transmission system at a single 
    rate although that rate may vary based on where the customer is 
    located.\619\ The NOPR proposed to continue to employ a flexible 
    approach, including the use of license plate rates. The NOPR requested 
    comments on whether the license plate approach is appropriate for the 
    long term.\620\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \619\ Consider that registering a car in one state, paying that 
    state's fees, and obtaining a license plate from that state, allows 
    that car to be driven on the roads and highways of all other states.
        \620\ FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,754.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments. A clear majority of commenters favors the use of license 
    plate rates in general, with a nearly even split between those that 
    would allow license plate rates only for a transitional period \621\ 
    and those that would allow them as a permanent feature.\622\ Of the 
    approximately 64 commenters who addressed this subject, only about nine 
    were clearly opposed to license plate rates for either the long term or 
    for a transitional period. And several commenters advocate the use of 
    license plate rates as a general concept but did not address directly 
    the NOPR's question concerning their long-term use.\623\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \621\ See, e.g., Montana Commission, Oglethorpe, Tri-State, 
    FirstEnergy, Alliance Companies, AEP and DOE.
        \622\ See, e.g., Allegheny, Industrial Consumers, Northwest 
    Council, APS, Desert STAR and SPP.
        \623\ See, e.g., Kentucky Commission, Gainesville, Big Rivers, 
    Puget and Ontario Power.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several commenters argued that the use of license plate rates 
    should be for a transition period roughly coincident with the phase-in 
    of retail competition. For example, Duke argues that license plate 
    rates avoid cost-shifting, and will therefore make it easier for 
    companies to collect their retail revenue requirements in jurisdictions 
    without retail competition, where state regulators may disallow higher 
    transmission rates.
        Commenters that support license plate rates as a long-term solution 
    argue that license plate rates are an aid to RTO formation.\624\ SoCal 
    Edison claims that license plate rates avoid cost shifts, are 
    administratively more efficient, provide a basis for efficient 
    transmission operation, and provide incentives for system expansion. 
    SoCal Edison favors their use in the long term.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \624\ See eg., East Kentucky and PJM.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Of those opposed to license plate rates in general, some suggest a 
    different pricing methodology. CMUA prefers an integrated, two-part 
    rate. The first part of the rate reflects the revenue requirement of 
    the overall RTO (principally above 200 kV) and the second part reflects 
    the local systems to the extent used. CMUA argues that license plate 
    rates do not follow the rules of cost causation, do not promote needed 
    enhancements and do not promote comparability in rates. Minnesota Power 
    recommends a two-part rate with a demand component to
    
    [[Page 917]]
    
    collect fixed costs and a variable component for losses. WPSC advocates 
    the use of flow-based, distance-sensitive rates rather than license 
    plate rates. APPA claims that license plate rates do not go far enough. 
    A four part approach is suggested in their place: assure recovery of 
    revenue requirement; honor existing contracts and phase in regional 
    rates; sub-functionalize the grid by voltage; and, once trusted RTOs 
    are in place, allow congestion rates above embedded costs and non-
    congestion rates below, all subject to a revenue requirement true-up. 
    RECA recommends that zones for transmission access charges be formed 
    based on cost and other differences, not on existing service areas. 
    SMUD claims that Cal ISO's license plate rate encourages inefficient 
    operation.
        Some commenters provide more general reactions to the cost shifting 
    problem. Wyoming Commission recommends that the Commission not codify a 
    specific approach to license plate rates and other measures with cost-
    shifting ramifications but rather defer to regional and state processes 
    to establish guidelines within a region. PSNM is concerned about the 
    impact of the loss of existing contracts on its license plate rate 
    calculation. Manitoba Board is concerned about shifting costs to low-
    cost, transmission-dependent areas. Platte River does not want its low 
    costs averaged with higher cost systems. United Illuminating encourages 
    the Commission to continue its flexibility in permitting different 
    approaches in the recovery of sunk costs. Aluminum Companies argues 
    that the Commission needs to offer more guidance on cost shifting and 
    that rate increases due to cost shifting should be constrained to the 
    benefits involved. Further, cost shifts should not be allowed unless 
    competition is fostered.
        Commission Conclusion. We conclude that the Commission should 
    continue to provide flexibility with respect to RTO proposals for 
    allocation of fixed transmission cost recovery. The Commission will 
    permit RTO proposals to use license plate rates, as defined above, for 
    several reasons. First, commenters overwhelmingly support the use of 
    license plate rates, and demonstrated convincingly that problems 
    associated with cost-shifting are not easily resolved by means other 
    than the use of license plate rates. Second, the Commission is 
    concerned that the potential for cost-shifting could act as an 
    impediment to RTO formation, thereby denying all stakeholders the 
    benefits that come from RTO membership.
        Moreover, although license plate rates are not necessarily an ideal 
    method for fixed cost recovery, we note that all ISOs have sought 
    approval from the Commission for license plate rates, at least during 
    their startup phase. No commenter has provided convincing evidence that 
    the use of license plate rates by existing ISOs produces significant 
    harms, although several commenters suggest various rate designs, 
    including multi-part rates, as alternatives to license plate rates.
        Although commenters overwhelmingly support the use of license plate 
    rates, they are split on whether such rates should be used only for a 
    transitional period, or whether the Commission should allow them as a 
    permanent feature. This is a difficult issue. On the one hand, we are 
    reluctant to require RTOs to suspend use of license plate rates after 
    some arbitrary date certain at which time they will be required to 
    transition to single system access rates; on the other hand, we are 
    reluctant to announce generically that license plate rates may be a 
    permanent feature of an RTO. Furthermore, the use of license plate 
    rates could depend on idiosyncratic facts, e.g., the geographic makeup 
    of the RTO, or the transmission cost differences in various subregions 
    of the RTO.
        We therefore believe that it is appropriate to allow RTOs to 
    propose the use of license plate rates for a fixed term of the RTO's 
    choosing. However, RTOs that propose the use of license plate rates 
    must make clear how transmission expansion will be priced, that is, 
    whether license plate rates or some other mechanism will be applied to 
    the cost of new transmission facilities, and how such pricing affects 
    incentives for efficient expansion. In addition, we will require that 
    before the end of the fixed term, the RTO must complete an evaluation 
    of fixed cost recovery policies based on the factual situation of the 
    particular RTO, and file with the Commission its recommendations on any 
    changes that should be instituted. We emphasize that we are not 
    requiring that the RTO continue or abandon the use of license plate 
    rates at that time, but we will require the RTO to justify its choice 
    to continue or discontinue using license plate rates, or otherwise 
    change the method for fixed cost recovery. We believe that this 
    approach provides participants in RTOs significant flexibility, and is 
    consistent with the principles articulated in the open architecture 
    requirement for RTOs.
    4. Congestion Pricing
        Congestion pricing and congestion management are closely related. 
    Comments on these issues have been treated jointly, and are summarized 
    above in the discussion of congestion management.
        Commission Conclusion. With respect to congestion pricing, the 
    Commission emphasized that it intends to be flexible in reviewing 
    pricing innovations, and sought comments on what specific requirements, 
    if any, best suited the Commission's RTO goals. A number of commenters 
    agreed with the Commission's conclusion in the NOPR that ``markets that 
    are based on locational marginal pricing and financial rights for 
    transmission provide a sound framework for efficient congestion 
    management.'' \625\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \625\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,742.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We reemphasize the basic principles for congestion pricing 
    articulated in the NOPR, i.e., that proposals should ``ensure that the 
    generators that are dispatched in the presence of transmission 
    constraints must be those that can serve system loads at least cost, 
    and limited transmission capacity should be used by market participants 
    that value that use most highly.'' \626\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \626\ Id. at 33,754-55.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We recognize that congestion pricing, especially when complex 
    problems associated with parallel path flows are addressed, is in its 
    infancy. Rather than prescribe a specific method, we encourage 
    experimentation with reasonable congestion management techniques. We 
    would expect that such experiments be consistent with the open 
    architecture requirements of the rule, and that information from such 
    experiments be made widely available to all interested parties, so that 
    other RTOs can learn from each others' experience.
    5. Service to Transmission-Owning Utilities That Do Not Participate in 
    an RTO
        The Commission asked commenters to discuss the treatment by an RTO 
    of a non-participating transmission owner in a region if the 
    transmission owner does not participate in its region's RTO.\627\ For 
    example, we asked whether it would be appropriate to allow RTO members 
    to provide transmission service at individual system rates to non-
    participating transmission owners located in the RTO region thereby 
    denying non-participants the benefits of non-pancaked transmission 
    rates.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \627\ Id. at 33,759.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments. Of those commenters that generally support the proposed 
    strategy,
    
    [[Page 918]]
    
    most argue that non-participants should not enjoy the benefits of non-
    pancaked rates.\628\ PG&E submits that the reasoning the Commission 
    applied in Order No. 888 applies here (i.e., in Order No. 888, the 
    Commission rejected the claim that a reciprocity requirement required 
    explicit Commission jurisdiction over the transmission customer finding 
    that, as a matter of fairness, a public utility providing open access 
    through a non-discriminatory tariff deserved the right to obtain 
    comparable access over the transmission systems of its customers). 
    Empire District is particularly concerned that utilities on the border 
    of an RTO may receive many advantages of the RTO without accepting any 
    of the burdens of participation, yet at the same time make it more 
    difficult for competitors to service its load by staying out of the 
    RTO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \628\ Montana-Dakota, Allegheny, PG&E, Tri-State, PNGC and 
    Empire District.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Other commenters are conditional in their support. For example, 
    Oneok wants the Commission to draw a hard line on non-participation and 
    be willing to employ negative incentives; however, Oneok points out 
    that denial of non-pancaked rates will be more costly to marketers and 
    consumers. South Carolina Authority suggests that the Commission 
    consider the extent to which the transmission owner is actually able to 
    participate in an RTO before permitting denial of RTO service under 
    non-pancaked rates. In the case of publicly owned utilities, there may 
    be restrictions in the enabling act or charter, the applicable state 
    constitution or the utility's bond covenant that effectively prohibit 
    it from participating in a particular RTO. This would also apply if the 
    RTO is not the product of the ``region's RTO'' involving all 
    stakeholders in the designated region but is a business entity designed 
    to advance the financial objectives of particular sponsors. Similarly, 
    SPRA argues that, in the event that it is unable to immediately join an 
    RTO, the RTO should recognize that SPRA has an OATT that provides for 
    comparable treatment to the RTO. And New Smyrna Beach states that, 
    although denial of non-pancaked rates to nonparticipants has merit, it 
    may be a moot issue in Florida where FP&L's transmission is so 
    extensive that pancaked rates would be a more costly alternative for 
    marketers and consumers of electricity.
        Other commenters believe the proposal is a flawed concept or 
    otherwise oppose it. Avista and PPC argue that it is not appropriate to 
    allow an RTO to provide transmission service at individual system rates 
    to non-participating transmission owners as such a policy would deny 
    them the benefits of non-pancaked rates and defeat the central goal of 
    its proposal. Metropolitan concurs that non-participating transmission 
    owners should share in the benefits of non-pancaked rates. Southern 
    Company and CP&L claim that the Commission cannot punish utilities that 
    find it in the best interests of their stakeholders not to join an RTO. 
    SMUD believes that RTOs must provide nondiscriminatory access to 
    transmission it controls at cost-based rates to all customers, since 
    they contribute to the RTO's cost recovery. SMUD argues that the 
    Commission, through its NOPR has, in essence, found that pancaked rates 
    are not just and reasonable and that they should be corrected; thus, 
    the Commission cannot allow an RTO to charge pancaked rates in 
    violation of the FPA section 205 prohibition on unjust or unreasonable 
    rates.
        Snohomish, Turlock, Big Rivers and Dairyland all make similar 
    arguments--charging higher pancaked rates to utilities that do not 
    participate in the RTO is patently unfair, violates the Commission's 
    duty to eliminate discriminatory rates, and would penalize consumers of 
    customer-owned utilities who have no practicable choice about whether 
    to participate in the RTO. Dairyland says that this could open the door 
    to creation of RTOs that purposely do not accommodate non-public 
    utilities. SRP posits that imposition of pancaked rates on non-
    participants in an RTO would effectively turn the Commission's stated 
    policy goal of voluntary participation into an RTO mandate inviting 
    years of litigation.
        Two state commissions question the effectiveness of pancaked rate 
    sanctions against non-participants. Indiana Commission contends that a 
    recalcitrant utility may not perceive pancaked rates as detrimental and 
    may not feel compelled to join an RTO. Illinois Commission feels that 
    imposition of penalties involving restricted access to RTO transmission 
    rates would either be self-defeating for the Commission or detrimental 
    to the electricity consumers of the affected utility. In its view, the 
    solution to this conundrum is for the Commission to abandon its 
    unworkable voluntary approach to RTO participation, and utilize its 
    authority under FPA sections 205 and 206 and examine its authority 
    under FPA sections 202(a), 211 and 212 to mandate participation. 
    However, Nevada Commission submits that the Commission must ensure that 
    a transmission-owning utility that refuses to join an RTO should not be 
    allowed to derive any economic benefit from the existence of RTOs.
        ISO commenters have diverse views on this issue. Desert STAR argues 
    that a blanket ban on prohibiting a party that does not join an RTO 
    from deriving any benefit from the RTO whatsoever may be too broad an 
    approach. NYPP, citing Associated Gas Distributors v. FERC \629\ and 
    Richmond Power & Light v. FERC \630\ for the proposition that the 
    Commission cannot achieve indirectly what it cannot do directly, submit 
    that the Commission cannot impose any coercive measure on or deny 
    benefits to utilities that do not participate in an RTO. In addition, 
    NY ISO argues that previously approved ISO's transmission-owning 
    members should be eligible for whatever RTO participation incentives 
    and benefits are ultimately adopted in this proceeding. On the other 
    hand, PJM/NEPOOL Customers support denial of non-pancaked transmission 
    rates to nonparticipants.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \629\ 824 F.2d 981, 1024 (D.C. Cir. 1987).
        \630\ 574 F.2d 610, 620 (D.C. Cir. 1978).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Canadian entities generally oppose imposition of pancaked rates 
    against non-participants. Canada DNR contends that a decision not to 
    participate in an international RTO by a Canadian jurisdiction should 
    not place entities in that jurisdiction engaged in trade with the U.S. 
    at a disadvantage relative to U.S. RTO participants. BC Hydro concurs 
    that the decision to join an RTO should not be made a prerequisite for 
    participation of Canadian provincial utilities or their affiliates to 
    participate in the U.S. electricity market. CEA observes, however, that 
    Canadian utilities see access to the U.S. market as a significant 
    business opportunity that requires a transparent and open bulk 
    transmission system operating in both directions. Grand Council et al. 
    submits, however, that applying no penalties or incentives to Canadian 
    utilities, while giving them unfettered access to U.S. markets without 
    being subject to corresponding obligations, is inconsistent with the 
    RTO concept. And H.Q. Energy Services submits that, if the Commission 
    decides not to require RTO participation, it should strongly encourage 
    voluntary participation by denying certain benefits such as the use of 
    the system-wide tariff to nonparticipants.
        Commission Conclusion. Regarding the question raised in the NOPR 
    about whether a non-participating transmission owner in an RTO region 
    should receive all the benefits of the RTO in its region, we share the 
    concerns
    
    [[Page 919]]
    
    of most commenters that transmitting utilities may receive the benefits 
    of an RTO in its region without accepting any of the burdens of 
    participation in the RTO. Accordingly, where a transmission customer of 
    an RTO or the customer's affiliate owns, controls or operates 
    transmission in the RTO's region, and is not participating in that 
    particular RTO, we intend to permit that RTO to propose rates, terms, 
    and conditions of transmission service that recognize the participatory 
    status of the customer.
        We do not intend that every such proposal will necessarily be 
    accepted by the Commission. Each RTO must justify any proposal on a 
    case-by-case basis. The proposal should recognize the various 
    situations of non-participating transmission owners. As pointed out by 
    commenters, some transmission owners may face legal obstacles to 
    participation that may need to be taken into account in the proposal.
        It is not our intent to permit an RTO to apply such a proposal to a 
    non-participating transmission owner in another region. As discussed 
    above, Empire District expressed concern about whether this provision 
    would apply to a non-participating owner ``on the border'' of an RTO. 
    We would permit an RTO to argue that the non-participant should be part 
    of its RTO region based on engineering or other objective criteria.
        An RTO will provide several benefits for parties in the region, 
    including elimination of individual system rates. We asked in the NOPR 
    whether it would ``be appropriate to allow RTO members to provide 
    transmission service at individual system rates to non-participating 
    transmission owners located in the RTO region.'' (emphasis added) \631\ 
    SMUD argues that the Commission in its NOPR has found, in effect, that 
    individual system rates are not just and reasonable and so cannot allow 
    transmission-owning utilities in an RTO to charge individual system 
    rates.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \631\ FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,759.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        SMUD is incorrect. We have not made a generic determination that 
    individual system rates are not just and reasonable in an RTO region. A 
    non-participating public utility transmission owner in an RTO region 
    may itself file a single company rate and argue that it is just and 
    reasonable for use by its neighbors who join the RTO.
        Instead of making a generic determination about these matters, we 
    will permit an RTO and its transmission-owning public utility members 
    to make the case that it is just and reasonable to charge individual 
    system rates to a transmission customer who is a non-participating 
    transmission owner in its RTO region. We will decide each RTO proposal 
    on its merits.
    6. Performance-Based Rate Regulation
        The NOPR suggested that, once RTOs are formed, performance based 
    regulation (PBR) can facilitate good grid operation.\632\ We noted that 
    PBR can incorporate price/revenue caps, price incentives, or 
    performance standards. The NOPR sought comments on how PBR should be 
    applied to an RTO and whether it should be voluntary.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \632\ Id., at 33,755.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments. The vast majority of commenters favor PBR of some form to 
    promote efficient operations by RTOs.\633\ And most commenters that 
    favor PBR specifically state that PBR should be voluntary for RTO 
    participants.\634\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \633\ See, e.g.,  EPSA, PJM, Los Angeles, Georgia Transmission, 
    Illinois Commission, Pacific Corp and Desert STAR.
        \634\ See, e.g., Florida Power Corp., MidAmerican, Tri-State, 
    FirstEnergy, Alliance Companies, Duke and PGE.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Professor Joskow recommends that the Commission promote the view 
    that PBR will eventually be required. He suggests that there is 
    sufficient experience with PBR, such as in England and Wales. He argues 
    that PBR should be based on a standard price cap that focuses not only 
    on direct transmission service costs, but also focuses on the cost of 
    congestion management, losses, ancillary services, reactive power, and 
    connection of new generators. EEI notes that a price cap, based on a 
    reasonable ROE revenue requirement, is the most widely used method. EEI 
    argues that price caps reduce rate cases, give an incentive to improve 
    productivity, and share productivity savings with customers. Brattle 
    Group does not propose a specific PBR scheme but says that, at this 
    point, approval should be case-by-case. Care should be taken that a PBR 
    is not based on a single element, causing distortions elsewhere.
        Other supporters have specific comments regarding the 
    implementation of PBR. Entergy recommends that the Commission provide 
    more specific guidance on the use of PBR. DOE warns that PBR should not 
    be allowed to prevent a PMA that is a part of an RTO to under-recover 
    its revenue requirement. New Smyrna Beach and Oneok only support PBR if 
    there is a downside as well as an upside potential associated with 
    transmission performance. Allegheny states that the Commission must 
    settle on a definition of performance, the performance criterion should 
    be economic reliability, the owner must have an opportunity to recover 
    investment, the Commission should recognize that some aspects of 
    performance will be outside of the control of the RTO, and the 
    particular PBR rate calculation should be considered on a case-by-case 
    basis.
        A number of commenters recommend that PBR not be instituted 
    immediately upon the formation of the RTO. California Board, Trans-
    Elect, and WPSC maintain that time is needed to establish base year 
    benchmarks. PG&E and APPA say that PBR should be set aside until the 
    RTO is up and functioning and Arkansas Consumers and Wyoming Commission 
    argue that the RTO should first demonstrate that it can and will 
    provide reliable and non-discriminatory service before PBR is 
    established.
        At least eight commenters were opposed to PBR for RTOs as a 
    Commission policy. Industrial Consumers, Williams, and CMUA do not 
    think that PBR can be effective in promoting efficiency in the 
    operation of RTOs. Salomon Smith Barney and East Texas Cooperatives 
    believe that RTOs will be able to game the system and take advantage of 
    PBR. PJM/NEPOOL Customers, Lincoln, and NASUCA argue that PBR should 
    not be allowed for RTOs because they are unnecessary. NASUCA is also 
    skeptical of PBR for RTOs because some areas where performance is 
    important are not under the RTO's control. NJBUS argues that PBR will 
    not put a stop to transmission discrimination.
        NEPCO et al. disagree with those commenters who oppose PBR.\635\ 
    PBR is effective, as shown in the United Kingdom, and they are not 
    ``bribes'' given freely to transmission owners. Enron/APX/Coral Power 
    does not agree with NASUCA and California Board that there is not 
    enough experience on which to base PBR. According to Enron/APX/Coral 
    Power, there is a large amount of experience in regulating transmission 
    plus a lot of experience with the ramifications of EPAct.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \635\ See, e.g., APPA, Minnesota Power and CMUA.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A few additional commenters neither strongly support nor oppose 
    PBR, but offer specific comments about PBR use. Project Groups 
    recommends that the Commission construct a way to de-couple revenues 
    from transmission rates so that efficient transmission service rather 
    than total throughput determines revenue. Florida Commission states 
    that questions as to the advisability and particulars of a PBR 
    mechanism should be left to regional solutions that have the 
    endorsement of the state regulatory
    
    [[Page 920]]
    
    bodies. Big Rivers states that PBR is inappropriate for cooperatives 
    and public power utilities. WEPCO believes that RTOs should be not-for-
    profit and that PBR should be available only to the for-profit 
    transmission owner. Metropolitan is concerned that PBR might cause RTOs 
    to neglect needed expansions and upgrades and jeopardize reliability.
        Commission Conclusion. At the outset, we think it is important to 
    emphasize that PBR is far from a new concept. Over the last 10 to 20 
    years, a significant amount of research, primarily by economists, has 
    been done regarding the conceptual basis of, and efficient designs for, 
    PBR.\636\ This research addresses its use in the electric utility 
    industry as well as other regulated industries. It is also important to 
    note that the Commission has been receptive to PBR proposals, at least 
    since issuance of the Policy Statement on Incentive Regulation in 
    October 1992. In that Policy Statement, we provided guidance to public 
    utilities as well as natural gas and oil pipelines considering 
    proposing some form of PBR.\637\ Although the Policy Statement invited 
    public utilities to develop and file incentive regulation proposals, 
    the Commission has not received any proposals from public 
    utilities.\638\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \636\ See, e.g., Paul Joskow and Richard Schmalensee, Incentive 
    Regulation for Electric Utilities, Yale Journal of Regulation, Vol. 
    4 at 1-49 (1986); Sanford Berg and Rajiv Sharma, Techniques for 
    Assessing Firm Efficiency, University of Florida Public Utilities 
    Research Center Working Paper (June 1999); Peter Navarro, Seven 
    Basic Rules for the PBR Regulator, Electricity Journal at 24-30 
    (April 1996); G. Alan Comnes, Steven Stoft, et al., Six Useful 
    Observations for Designers of PBR Plans, Electricity Journal at 16-
    23 (April 1996); Lorenzo Brown and Ingo Vogelsang, Incentive 
    Regulation: a Research Report, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 
    Office of Economic Policy, Technical Report 89-3 (1989); and Jean-
    Jacques Laffont and Jean Tirole, A Theory of Incentives in 
    Procurement and Regulation, MIT Press (1993).
        \637\ The Policy Statement articulated five regulatory 
    standards: (1) incentive ratemaking must be prospective; (2) 
    participation must be voluntary; (3) incentive mechanisms must be 
    understood by all parties; (4) benefits to consumers must be 
    quantifiable; and (5) quality of service must be maintained.
        \638\ We note that PBR mechanisms have been widely used by state 
    regulators and the FCC as applied to the U.S. telecommunications 
    industry. See, e.g., John Kwoka, Implementing Price Caps in 
    Telecommunications, Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, Vol 
    12, No 4 at 726-52 (1993).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission's current interest in PBR stems from the proposition 
    that PBR will allow the Commission to rely on market-like forces, to 
    the maximum extent possible, to create incentives for RTOs to 
    efficiently operate and invest in the transmission system. This does 
    not mean that we expect that transmission services will be provided in 
    competitive markets any time soon, or at all. We recognize that 
    transmission service will retain most or perhaps all of the 
    characteristics of a natural monopoly for the foreseeable future, and 
    that some type of explicit price regulation will therefore be required 
    to prevent monopoly abuse. But we believe that PBR, especially if 
    accompanied by explicit and well-designed incentives, may provide 
    significant benefits over traditional forms of cost-of-service 
    regulation. We believe this view of PBR is entirely consistent with 
    other initiatives taken by the Commission, such as Order Nos. 888 and 
    889, to promote competitive power markets, and given the impracticality 
    of competitive transmission markets, to rely on market-like forces to 
    the maximum extent possible.
        Before providing further specificity on PBR, it is useful to 
    restate the overarching concerns of commenters. A large number of 
    commenters support the use of PBR, and many of them, as discussed 
    above, believe that PBR and other forms of incentive regulation will 
    significantly enhance the incentives RTOs have to make efficient 
    operating and investment decisions. For example, Professor Joskow 
    notes:
    
        It is very important for the Commission to adopt regulatory 
    mechanisms that provide transmission owners and operators with 
    powerful economic incentives to operate transmission networks 
    efficiently and to invest the resources necessary to expand their 
    capabilities efficiently. These incentives should be an integral 
    component of a performance-based regulatory (PBR) framework for the 
    regulation of transmission rates that rewards transmission owners 
    for achieving these objectives and penalizes them for failing to do 
    so.\639\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \639\ Professor Joskow at ES-iv.
    
        On the other hand, a somewhat smaller group of commenters, mostly 
    transmission customers, oppose the use of PBR. They express doubts 
    about whether PBR will provide good incentives for RTOs to operate and 
    invest efficiently. They are also concerned that PBR design is so 
    difficult that RTOs will easily game the system, which will likely 
    result in higher revenues for RTOs and therefore higher prices for 
    transmission services for all transmission customers.
        Commenters describe a wide array of PBR mechanisms, including some 
    relatively unsophisticated proposals and others which are analytically 
    complex. For example, a number of commenters have proposed that the 
    Commission entertain transmission rate moratoriums, e.g., where 
    transmission rates are locked into their current levels for a limited 
    period of years. To the extent the transmission provider can achieve 
    any transmission costs savings, these would be retained by the 
    transmission provider. In this sense, it falls within the concept of 
    PBR.
        It is argued that this rate treatment may promote the establishment 
    of independent transmission companies because it provides the certain 
    revenue stream that is needed to obtain financing for the purchase of 
    transmission systems from existing owners. It is also argued that this 
    approach is analogous to a hold harmless commitment for existing 
    customers which may simplify the efforts of those state regulators who 
    value transmission rate certainty during their conversion to retail 
    choice. This approach would also reduce litigation at the Commission 
    during the moratorium.
        Finally, if the rate level selected takes into account the existing 
    transmission component of bundled retail power rates, it addresses the 
    concern expressed by many that one deterrent to participation in RTOs 
    is the fear and uncertainty that transferring retail transmission 
    services from state to Commission jurisdiction leads to reduced 
    revenues.
        Other commenters suggest that the essence of PBR is to set cost and 
    performance benchmarks and then reward or penalize an RTO based on 
    performance relative to those targets. Clearly, such an approach 
    presents significant analytical challenges. Ideally, an RTO's cost and 
    operating performance can be compared with other, similar entities. One 
    benefit of setting such targets is that it overcomes the asymmetric 
    information problem, i.e., a transmission service provider will usually 
    have better knowledge of the potential efficiency gains than will 
    regulators. Benchmarking performance helps reduce the information 
    imbalance.\640\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \640\ We note that there have been some early attempts to 
    compare the relative cost and performance of ISOs in the U.S. See, 
    e.g., California ISO, ``A Comparative Analysis of Operating ISOs in 
    the United States'' (Oct. 15, 1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We have carefully considered all of the comments about PBR. We 
    conclude that the Commission should encourage RTOs to consider use of 
    PBR, although we recognize the difficult analytical challenges that 
    RTOs will face. To facilitate such consideration, we are providing 
    additional specificity on PBR. We address several threshold procedural 
    issues, and articulate additional design principles that should provide 
    a framework for RTO consideration of PBR.
    
    [[Page 921]]
    
        A first threshold issue is whether the Commission should require 
    that RTOs use PBR or whether it should be voluntary. There is almost no 
    support for making PBR mandatory, and we therefore will not require RTO 
    filings to include PBR proposals, although we encourage such proposals.
        A second threshold issue is what types of RTOs are eligible for 
    PBR. As discussed above, some commenters argue that PBR is not 
    appropriate for cooperatively-owned and publicly-owned transmission 
    owning utilities. Similarly, other commenters argue that PBR is 
    appropriate only for profit-making RTOs. We conclude that, although the 
    application of PBR may vary according to the type of RTO, there is no 
    reason to limit the applicability of PBR to certain members or types of 
    RTOs. The Commission welcomes RTO filings with PBR proposals from any 
    source. For example, in the context of an ISO or a tiered ISO/transco 
    that has been described by some commenters, the activities that 
    contribute to performance may be shared between the RTO and the 
    transmission owners. This does not invalidate the use of PBRs; however, 
    the RTO design would simply ensure that the rewards and penalties 
    associated with activities performed by transmission owners flow 
    through to the owners to achieve the desired result.\641\ In addition, 
    we see no impediment to the use of PBR to provide incentives for 
    efficient behavior by non-profit RTOs. We note that some existing ISOs 
    have in place performance incentives for some of their managers, and 
    such an incentive scheme may have application for RTOs which do not own 
    the transmission assets they control.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \641\ For example, PJM states that it can facilitate the 
    application of PBRs to its transmission owners by using the 
    stakeholder process to set the performance parameters and, once the 
    parameters are in place, to independently evaluate the transmission 
    owners' performance and apply the PBR.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A third threshold issue is how PBR proposals will be formulated and 
    when they will be filed. The Commission recognizes that PBR design 
    involves highly complicated issues, and that there is the possibility 
    that a bad PBR proposal can result in lower quality transmission 
    service, at higher costs, compared with service that might prevail 
    under traditional ratemaking practices. One key element in the process 
    of designing a PBR proposal would be to ensure adequate input from all 
    stakeholders. We believe that the best PBR designs will emerge when all 
    stakeholders have an opportunity for input, even if a filed PBR design 
    does not represent full consensus. We therefore conclude that RTOs that 
    wish to implement PBR need not necessarily file the PBR proposal at the 
    time the RTO makes its compliance filing if more time is needed to 
    negotiate among stakeholders the details of a well-designed PBR. Some 
    commenters suggest that an additional consideration in allowing delayed 
    filings of PBR is the need to evaluate operating experience of the RTO 
    before appropriate benchmark measures for PBR can be developed.
        The Commission also believes it is appropriate to provide 
    additional specificity on what constitutes good PBR design. We continue 
    to endorse the regulatory standards included in the Incentive 
    Regulation Policy Statement, described above. And we note that in some 
    regions, certain types of PBR mechanisms may be better suited than 
    others. For example, where there are already state-imposed rate 
    moratoriums, continuation of such programs after RTO formation may be 
    an appropriate PBR approach. Alternatively, a transmission rate 
    moratorium based on the existing rate level may be appropriate for a 
    transitional period during RTO formation.\642\ Similarly, in an area 
    that has experience with a particular performance-based mechanism, 
    extension and perhaps refinement of such a program after RTO formation 
    may be the most appropriate policy.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \642\ As noted infra, this is one of the pricing reforms that 
    will be available for a defined transition period during which RTOs 
    are being established.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We encourage RTOs to file fully documented PBR proposals that are 
    consistent with the amended regulatory text. PBR proposals should 
    include a detailed explanation of how the PBR mechanism will work, as 
    well as all of the information necessary for the Commission and all 
    market participants to evaluate the benefits and costs of implementing 
    the PBR mechanism.
        Based on the comments we received in this docket, as well as our 
    understanding of international \643\ and state experience with 
    incentive regulation, we expand on the considerations for PBR addressed 
    in the amended regulatory text by offering the following additional 
    principles for RTOs to consider in designing PBR proposals.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \643\ We note that a PBR system that uses a variant of price cap 
    regulation of the National Grid Company has been in use for nine 
    years in England and Wales. More recently, the price cap has been 
    combined with a separate incentive mechanism that focused on 
    reducing congestion on the grid. Since this is the longest-running 
    PBR targeted to grid operations, we encourage any RTO that intends 
    to propose PBR to examine the strengths and weaknesses of the 
    British approach.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        PBR should not be applied piecemeal. To the extent possible, PBR 
    programs should focus on the entire operation of the RTO, rather than 
    smaller parts of the operation. Commenters caution that PBR programs 
    that focus narrowly, e.g., only on the cost aspects of RTO operations, 
    may result in inattention by the RTO to the quality of service offered. 
    Similarly, a focus on only one aspect of costs, e.g., short-run costs, 
    may result in reduced costs for that single aspect, but higher total 
    costs for the RTO.
        PBR should encompass both rewards and penalties. Although some PBR 
    designs employ either rewards or penalties, but not both, most 
    commenters suggest, and the Commission agrees, that the most effective 
    and most fair designs will likely encompass both. One rationale for 
    this is that it is not always clear what incentives an RTO will respond 
    to, and therefore the prospect of higher revenues as well as the threat 
    of lower revenues may induce an RTO to provide the best possible 
    performance. An additional rationale is that under the FPA, the 
    Commission is required to set rates for transmission service at just 
    and reasonable levels. To the extent that rates may vary within a 
    range--both up and down--as a function of RTO performance, this 
    statutory requirement may be better satisfied.
        PBR rewards and penalties should create incentives for an RTO to 
    make efficient operating and investment decisions, and should not 
    compromise system reliability. A significant concern in any PBR 
    application is the possibility that incentives will distort RTO 
    decisionmaking. For example, commenters caution that an RTO may manage 
    congestion through a combination of generation redispatch and 
    investment in transmission infrastructure, and that poorly designed PBR 
    mechanisms could distort RTO decisionmaking toward the most profitable, 
    rather than the least-cost, solution, or toward an approach that 
    inappropriately reduces system reliability. An additional concern is 
    that PBR mechanisms may create bias with respect to the trade-off 
    between investment in generation and transmission, or in siting 
    generation and transmission facilities in the most efficient places on 
    the grid.
        The benefits of PBR should be shared between the RTO and its 
    customers. The Commission believes that as a matter of fairness, the 
    efficiency gains occasioned by PBR should be shared. This will involve 
    difficult analytical issues, including identifying efficiency gains,
    
    [[Page 922]]
    
    measuring them, and determining the effect of sharing such gains on the 
    strength of the incentives faced by the RTO. The Commission does not 
    believe it would be appropriate to specify the exact distribution of 
    such gains, as such a decision is better left to negotiation by all 
    stakeholders.
        To the extent possible, the rewards and penalties should be 
    prescribed in advance based on known and measurable benchmarks. PBR 
    designs involve an inevitable trade-off between simplicity and 
    administrative ease on the one hand, and the potential benefits of the 
    program. Although relatively simple designs such as rate freezes 
    provide significant incentives for an RTO to reduce its costs, they 
    produce relatively limited incentives to maintain reliability, promote 
    service quality, or manage congestion. PBR mechanisms that benchmark an 
    RTO's performance, either to its own historical performance, to 
    industry performance indices, to some normative goal, or to a 
    combination of these, may be designed to provide incentives for more 
    efficient operation and investment decisionmaking. The Commission 
    recognizes that designing sophisticated PBR mechanisms will be a 
    significant challenge for RTOs already grappling with other development 
    issues. The Commission, therefore, will make its staff available 
    through our pre-filing process to work with RTOs to help identify and 
    resolve issues on an informal basis prior to their filing a PBR 
    proposal.\644\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \644\ Alternatively, the RTO could seek guidance in a more 
    formal proceeding, e.g., if an RTO files a petition for a 
    declaratory order seeking approval of its PBR proposal.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    7. Other RTO Transmission Ratemaking Reforms
        The Commission proposed in the NOPR to consider innovative pricing 
    proposals for transmission owners who turn over control of their 
    transmission facilities to an RTO.\645\ The types of pricing that the 
    Commission proposed to consider include: a higher ROE on transmission 
    plant; allowing the transmission owner to retain the benefits of cost 
    saving attributable to RTO formation; acceleration of transmission cost 
    recovery in rates; non-traditional valuation of transmission assets 
    such as an estimate of replacement costs for assets purchased at higher 
    than net original cost; and liberalized allowance of levelized or non-
    levelized rate methods. The Commission proposed that transmission 
    owners meet all of the requirements to become an RTO before an 
    innovative pricing proposal is accepted.\646\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \645\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,755.
        \646\ Id. at 33,756.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments. A large number of commenters addressed the Commission's 
    proposals to consider transmission pricing reforms for RTOs. About 30 
    commenters expressed support, and about 30 commenters expressed 
    opposition. There were also a number of comments which did not 
    explicitly support or oppose this aspect of the NOPR.
        Supporting Innovative Pricing.\647\ Of the commenters that support 
    innovative pricing, a common theme is that if RTO formation is to be 
    voluntary, incentives are required to encourage participation.\648\ For 
    example, Justice Department recommends that the positive and negative 
    incentives be designed to secure universal compliance rather than have 
    some utilities not participate because the advantage of continuing 
    outside of the RTO is greater than the incentive to join. EEI supports 
    incentives since RTO formation will probably not generate increased 
    earnings for transmission owners since most of the efficiencies will be 
    a benefit to others. EEI suggests that an application for RTO formation 
    and incentives should include some assessment of the benefits from 
    which the incentives are generated but a precise calculation of 
    benefits should not be required because of the extreme difficulty in 
    making such an estimate. PacifiCorp is in favor of incentives but is 
    concerned that a ``case by case'' consideration of incentives may 
    jeopardize their realization because customers will call for lower 
    transmission rates in the short term once the RTO has been formed. 
    PacifiCorp argues that a more detailed uniform policy on incentives 
    ``up front'' is preferred.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \647\ While we used the term incentive pricing in the NOPR, this 
    term is an imprecise description of the various transmission pricing 
    reforms that will be addressed in this Rule, and we now describe 
    these pricing reforms as innovative rate proposals. However, the 
    comments sections that follow continue to use the term incentive 
    because the parties used this term in their comments.
        \648\ See, e.g., Avista, TEP, Duquesne, APS, NEPCO et al., 
    Florida Power Corp.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        On the other hand, several commenters suggest that the Commission 
    should consider incentives only on a case-by-case basis. Desert STAR 
    says that different RTOs may need different sets of incentives as will 
    public power transmission owners. MidAmerican supports case-by-case 
    consideration of incentives to join an RTO, and favors a higher ROE 
    reflecting the fact that transmission is not limited to selling to a 
    captive customer base in a bundled context but is serving a wholesale 
    marketplace at greater risk. Duke is in favor of incentives for 
    transmission expansion, but cautions that incentives should not bias 
    investment and other decisions, should be considered on a case-by-case 
    basis, and may not be very effective where operation is separated from 
    ownership. Oregon Office is in favor of incentives for meeting all of 
    the RTO characteristics and functions faster than the industry average, 
    but not for average speed in accomplishing RTO formation.
        A number of commenters favor offering incentives to public 
    utilities that are already members of an ISO as well as to provide 
    incentives for public utilities to join an RTO. For example, PJM says 
    that incentive rates should be offered to new and existing RTO members 
    to reflect the benefits generated and to prevent inefficient 
    consequences such as transmission owners moving from an existing ISO to 
    a new RTO to receive incentive rates. PSE&G favors a correspondingly 
    higher ROE and faster depreciation of transmission assets for 
    transmission owners who participate in RTOs, including those who have 
    already joined an existing organization. LG&E says that incentive plans 
    can be useful in promoting RTO participation and that existing members 
    of RTOs should be allowed to propose incentive rates as well. LG&E 
    stresses that it is just as important not to enact policies on rates 
    that might jeopardize revenue requirement recovery and thus act as a 
    disincentive. An additional consideration is offered by PP&L Companies 
    which argues that existing participants in RTOs should be allowed the 
    same incentive rates as those which are just forming because the 
    benefits of an existing RTO are greater than those of a start-up RTO 
    not yet in operation.
        The proposed incentive addressed most frequently by commenters is 
    allowing a higher rate of return on transmission assets. Georgia 
    Transmission believes that higher ROEs as an incentive to voluntarily 
    join an RTO is appropriate because of the benefits that participation 
    would bring. NSP and others argue that ROE must be sufficient to 
    attract capital and compensate utilities for the risks involved. 
    Conectiv and EEI argue that the current rate of return policy should be 
    modified, arguing that the DCF method gives results that are too low to 
    provide adequate returns to transmission owners causing a reduction in 
    building at a time when more transmission is critically needed. 
    According to Conectiv, the DCF method should be abandoned or its 
    application
    
    [[Page 923]]
    
    should be modified to account for the current industry situation and be 
    more reflective of conditions in the general economy and reflect 
    reasonable transmission asset lives. Cinergy, in reply comments 
    contends that the record in this proceeding is sufficient to establish 
    a presumption of reasonableness for higher ROEs.
        SoCal Edison does not believe that pure incentives in the form of 
    ROE ``awards'' are necessary for encouraging participation in RTO but 
    it does argue that higher returns may be justified on transmission 
    assets controlled by an RTO because the original owner no longer has 
    control over planning and expansion decisions. In addition, distributed 
    generation and bypass may be found to increase risk. SoCal Edison says 
    that it is very important to prevent the move to RTO control from being 
    a financial loss due to Commission rate setting or because of greater 
    risk and higher costs. SoCal Edison does agree with the proposal to 
    allow accelerated depreciation of transmission assets to encourage 
    participation.
        TXU Electric is in favor of consideration of higher ROEs for RTO 
    participants and thinks it is more important to take a more global look 
    at transmission ROEs in a new and uncertain industry environment where 
    transmission investment is important. TXU Electric warns that it would 
    be inappropriate to penalize RTO participation with reduced earning 
    potential because unbundled transmission ROEs are lower than ROEs 
    allowed in bundled rates. Conlon suggests that the Commission could 
    allow a higher return on assets of a transco or ISO to serve as an 
    incentive for IOUs to transfer ownership. Southern Company explains 
    that there are major tax consequences to the sale of transmission 
    assets to form a transco and recommends that the Commission find ways 
    to accommodate such a transition. As to rate incentives, Southern 
    Company advocates a change in the Commission's ratemaking policy in 
    order to increase returns to be more commensurate with non-regulated 
    businesses. Southern claims that recent court rulings support higher 
    returns on transmission service.
        A number of commenters argue that participation in an RTO increases 
    financial risk, and that incentives are therefore required to encourage 
    RTO participation. For example, Empire District says that turning over 
    control of transmission assets to an RTO increases the risk because 
    someone else will control their operation, justifying higher ROEs for 
    participation. PSE&G argues that a stand-alone transmission company or 
    an RTO is more risky than an integrated electric utility where 
    transmission was a strategic asset. FirstEnergy justifies higher ROEs 
    by noting a number of sources of risk, including emergence of 
    distributed generation, vulnerability of firms that are less 
    diversified than integrated utilities, and quicker phase out of older 
    generation plants which may result in stranding some transmission 
    plants. Midwest ISO argues that RTO membership may cause a loss in 
    earnings due to reduced transmission revenues, higher costs, and 
    operational risks. United Illuminating believes that risk for 
    transmission investment is higher for assets controlled by an RTO and 
    that accelerated depreciation is warranted because transmission 
    companies can no longer count on captive customers, and industry 
    changes have the possibility to abandon transmission plant before its 
    physical life is over. WPSC is in favor of higher ROEs for transmission 
    owners who join RTOs but not as a pure incentive. WPSC's justification 
    for higher ROEs would be the greater risk due to removal of pancaked 
    rates, new generation options, loss of higher state returns, and new 
    technologies. WPSC supports the other rate incentives as long as the 
    benefits exceed the costs based on careful examination.
        Some commenters address the broad range of proposed incentives. For 
    example:
         Trans-Elect argues in favor of incentives to include: 
    acquisition premiums, hypothetical capital structures, higher ROE, 
    accelerated recovery of costs, rate moratoriums, and expedited FPA 
    section 205 and 203 approvals. Trans-Elect would limit incentives to 
    those that do not harm transmission customers. It notes that PBRs would 
    allow transmission owners to share in cost savings but some operating 
    history may be needed before they are put in place. It argues that 
    acquisition premiums may assist in the formation of independent 
    transcos, and suggests that if there is a rate moratorium in place, 
    RTOs should be allowed to recover acquisition premiums after the 
    moratorium.
         FirstEnergy advocates flow through of cost savings to 
    owners, non-traditional valuation of assets, flexibility in the use of 
    levelized rate methodology, retention of hourly non-firm revenues, 
    deference to management in dispute resolution, elimination of codes of 
    conduct where there is structural separation, and simplification of 
    filing requirements. Some of these measures should be offered on a 
    limited basis to RTOs not yet meeting all of the characteristics and 
    functions. Incentive plans should weigh costs versus benefits. Cal DWR 
    goes further, saying that incentives should not be allowed until 
    benefits are actually proven.
         Los Angeles recommends that the Commission consider 
    several options for the valuation of assets transferred to an RTO in 
    order to reflect the true value of the assets to native load customers. 
    Selected options to explore include: an up-front acquisition premium 
    used to moderate rates to native load customers, provide native load 
    customers a congestion premium, or grant native load customers an 
    exemption to congestion charges.
         NYPP is in favor of sufficient ROE to provide for 
    expansion and accelerated depreciation to compensate for increased 
    risks as opposed to a ``bonus'' type incentive to join an RTO. Its 
    members contend that this type of incentive should be available to all 
    transmission owners, not just the ones who meet the NOPR's 
    characteristics and functions.
        A number of commenters note that incentives are needed to 
    facilitate efficient expansion of transmission assets.\649\ 
    Transmission ISO Participants view the incentive needed to induce new 
    transmission construction as more important than incentives to 
    encourage RTO formation. IPCF suggests that FERC should offer 
    transmission owners incentives to expand their networks without meeting 
    all of the requirements of becoming an RTO in order to reverse the 
    trend against building caused by Order No. 888. Williams says that 
    decisions to expand transmission facilities must be made by for-profit 
    entities, must be driven by economic considerations, and the returns 
    allowed must be commensurate with the greater risks today, Williams 
    cautions that returns for RTO participants certainly should not be at a 
    rate that results in a penalty.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \649\ See, e.g., AEP, United Illuminating, PP&L Companies, NU, 
    Otter Tail, NYPP, FirstEnergy, Transmission ISO Participants, 
    Allegheny and Salomon Smith Barney.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Opposing Innovative Pricing. Many commenters oppose the use of 
    incentives for many different reasons. One common theme is that 
    incentives are inappropriate because RTO participation should be 
    mandatory.\650\ PJM/NEPOOL Customers argues that the Commission should 
    mandate RTO formation because of the transmission owners' duty to 
    operate in an efficient manner, and because transmission customers will 
    likely pay the costs of the incentives. Ohio Commission
    
    [[Page 924]]
    
    prefers mandatory participation and questions whether the proposed 
    incentives will be effective. If incentives are used, Ohio Commission 
    recommends that the Commission consider evaluating which incentives 
    will be effective, balancing incentives with disincentives, and 
    recognize regional differences especially in arriving at a solution for 
    the Midwest.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \650\ PJM/NEPOOL Customers, Lincoln, TDU Systems, APPA, WEPCO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Another common theme is that the costs of incentives may well 
    outweigh the benefits of RTO participation. Illinois Commission argues 
    that if the Commission finds that there are benefits in RTO creation, 
    they should be mandatory. According to Illinois Commission, the 
    examples of incentives proposed in the NOPR, i.e., ROE enhancement, 
    revaluation of transmission facilities at replacement cost, accelerated 
    depreciation, and flexibility in use of levelized cost, would consist 
    of money transfers to transmission owners without contributing to cost 
    control or efficiency. South Carolina Authority is opposed to 
    incentives or disincentives to promote RTO participation unless a 
    factual determination is made that they are absolutely necessary. 
    Similarly, RECA is generally opposed to incentives but would recommend 
    their consideration if savings to the public are well established. RECA 
    finds the rate freeze proposal the least objectionable.
        APPA advocates mandatory participation in RTOs and strongly objects 
    to the use of incentives to achieve participation. It argues incentives 
    would be ineffective because of the small proportion that Commission-
    regulated transmission makes up of the total utility revenue compared 
    to the value of transmission in maximizing generation and merchant 
    revenue. To be effective, APPA argues that the cost would be so large 
    that it would not be offset by the benefits of the RTO. Also, APPA 
    raises the participation issue of whether to give incentives to 
    existing ISO members. Seattle warns against transmission owners 
    ``dumping'' transmission facilities into an RTO to receive incentives 
    when those particular facilities are of no benefit to the RTO being 
    formed.
        Some commenters argue that it is inappropriate for the Commission 
    to provide incentives for the provision of a monopoly service. 
    Metropolitan argues that incentives should not be offered because many 
    of the customers who pay for the incentives are the same customers who 
    paid for the original transmission facilities. TDU Systems argues that 
    ROEs for transmission service in an RTO is less risky because of the 
    concentration of monopoly business and the lack of any regulatory gap 
    since all transmission under an RTO will be regulated by the 
    Commission. TDU Systems notes that transmission entities, since they 
    are monopolies, should not earn the same return as firms in other 
    industries. TDU Systems argues that other NOPR proposals, including 
    rate freezes, accelerated recovery of costs and investment, and 
    revaluation of assets, are also an inappropriate enrichment of 
    transmission owners and are unneeded to attract investors. And TDU 
    Systems argues that the proposal for an acquisition premium is 
    troublesome because customers have already been paying for these assets 
    for years. TDU Systems also suggests it will be difficult to calculate 
    what level of incentives would be required to persuade a transmission 
    owner to participate in an RTO and the likelihood of offering a greater 
    incentive than is needed.
        Some commenters suggest that providing incentives would violate the 
    Commission's statutory requirement to set rates at just and reasonable 
    levels. NRECA believes that transmission owners should not be rewarded 
    for unjust conduct with incentives and that the Commission should rely 
    on standard cost-of-service based rates. TAPS, which favors mandatory 
    RTO formation, argues that incentives are unnecessary and could nullify 
    the benefits of electric industry restructuring. TAPS argues that 
    incentive rates, including each of the examples suggested in the NOPR, 
    would violate FPA's requirement for just and reasonable rates because 
    they do not reflect the cost of providing transmission service. TAPS 
    does recommend that the Commission remedy unintended disincentives such 
    as utilities' fear of the unknown. UAMPS also favors mandatory 
    participation, and argues that incentives would unfairly raise 
    transmission costs to the benefit of monopoly transmission owners. 
    UAMPS also argues that it is not feasible to divide the benefit of RTO 
    participation before these benefits are even known. In response to the 
    comments of several IOUs, UAMPS argues that the claim that stand-alone 
    transmission companies are more risky is unsubstantiated and should be 
    heard in another proceeding. NASUCA argues that EEI and others are 
    incorrect in saying that the DCF method does not produce reasonable 
    results. According to NASUCA, the DCF method takes explicit account of 
    the transmission owners' risk and the realities of the current 
    regulatory climate.
        Some commenters suggest that incentives will not necessarily 
    increase RTO participation, or will not necessarily produce the 
    benefits which the NOPR describes. For example, ICUA notes that 
    incentives cannot be relied upon to achieve participation by all 
    necessary utilities. WPPI opposes incentives to participate in RTOs 
    citing the RTO activity that has already taken place without incentives 
    and the contention that the Commission should designate boundaries and 
    require participation within one year.
        Wyoming Commission does not agree that increasing the ROE will be 
    sufficient to encourage more transmission building. According to 
    Wyoming Commission, low building activity may be attributable to 
    difficulty in meeting siting requirements, uncertainty related to 
    retail access and native load, and competition for more localized 
    generation. Wyoming Commission does not think that the Commission 
    should rush too quickly into some innovative ratemaking before the 
    industry has committed to making RTOs work as planned. And the Wyoming 
    Commission suggests that a higher ROE for transmission investment may 
    discourage a balanced consideration of options.
        A number of commenters generally opposed incentives, believing that 
    sanctions or penalties against public utilities which do not join RTOs 
    is superior to providing incentives. NASUCA argues that mandates or 
    disincentives for not joining at the time of merger or market-based 
    rate requests should be used rather than incentives. Incentives would 
    not be cost based and would therefore make rates unjust and 
    unreasonable. As to specific incentive proposals, NASUCA says that 
    using replacement cost for transferred assets would allow higher rates 
    than necessary as an incentive and would charge customers for assets 
    they have already paid for. Such incentives could set off a 
    transmission sell-off in anticipation of an adjustment and some 
    companies may refuse to form transcos until they were granted the same 
    adjustment as any other company. NASUCA is opposed to accelerated 
    depreciation of assets for similar reasons. NASUCA also states that 
    incentive rates could harm electric competition by increasing 
    transmission costs. And Big Rivers states that the incentives proposed 
    in the NOPR are inappropriate for rural electric cooperatives.
        Other Comments. A few commenters did not take an explicit position 
    on the use of incentives, but made general comments on the Commission's 
    proposals. For example:
         Cal ISO is more concerned that there not be disincentives 
    to RTO
    
    [[Page 925]]
    
    participation than offering incentives. In particular, Cal ISO points 
    out the disincentive created by the Commission's annual fee policy, 
    from which temporary relief was granted \651\ but a permanent solution 
    is needed.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \651\ PJM Interconnection L.L.C., 88 FERC para.61,109 (1999).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
         New Century recommends against the use of ``remedial 
    measures'' to encourage participation such as the suspension of market-
    based rate authority, denial of merger authority, and denial of non-
    pancaked rate access to RTO facilities.
         Entergy says that the NOPR's statements on incentives are 
    vague and would cause too much regulatory uncertainty. Entergy asks the 
    Commission to provide more explicit provisions as to what incentives 
    would be approved.
         Canada DNR is concerned that Canadian transmission owners 
    not be placed at a disadvantage for non-participation in an RTO in 
    terms of incentives and disincentive.
         SRP supports incentives as long as they are applied to 
    both public power entities and investor owned companies equitably.
         Metropolitan contends that it would not receive much 
    benefit from any incentives offered to RTOs because it is a public 
    entity and because its asset base is so heavily depreciated. However, 
    replacement cost methodology could be of use in mitigating cost shifts 
    from rolling in higher costs of other utilities.
        Commission Conclusion. As noted earlier, the NOPR and the comments 
    use the term incentive pricing as a label for the transmission pricing 
    reforms that we raised for discussion. Certainly, good pricing affects 
    behavior. But good pricing also achieves a valuable goal, in terms of 
    competition, system expansion, or efficient practices that benefit more 
    than the transmission owners or the RTO. In this section we provide 
    greater specificity with respect to certain transmission pricing 
    mechanisms that may be appropriate for RTOs. These mechanisms were 
    described in the NOPR or otherwise proposed by commenters, and are 
    included in the amended regulatory text.\652\ We emphasize that we do 
    not intend this policy guidance to be interpreted as a Commission 
    regulatory requirement for a specific transmission pricing method, nor 
    should it be interpreted as a guarantee that the Commission will 
    approve any particular innovative pricing proposal. We emphasize that 
    all innovative pricing proposals filed by RTOs must be fully and 
    adequately supported in accordance with this Final Rule and the 
    regulatory text. We believe that we are providing sufficient guidance 
    for RTOs to make critical decisions with respect to transmission 
    pricing policies. If industry participants believe that further 
    guidance from the Commission is needed to resolve transmission pricing 
    issues, they may request such guidance through requests for declaratory 
    orders or further rulemakings.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \652\ Note that these mechanisms are discussed below on a 
    thematic basis, although the regulatory text lists them on an 
    individual basis.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As discussed earlier, transmission pricing reform is needed as a 
    result of the rapid restructuring of the industry that is underway, 
    particularly with respect to changes in the ownership and control of 
    transmission assets, and changes in the transmission services being 
    provided in competitive generating markets. As a result of these 
    changes, and consistent with a number of commenters' arguments, we have 
    concluded that the Commission, at a minimum, needs to mitigate various 
    ``disincentives'' that may prevent transmission owners from efficiently 
    operating their systems. Commenters cite to the potential that 
    transmission owners will earn lower returns for providing unbundled 
    transmission service than they earned for providing bundled service, 
    even though risks associated with transmission ownership have 
    increased. Commenters suggest a number of sources of increased risk. 
    One source is the potential for bypass of transmission assets due to 
    distributed generation and the phasing out of older generators from 
    service. Other sources are directly related to RTO formation. For 
    example, some commenters assert that stand-alone transmission companies 
    (e.g., transcos) are riskier because they have a less-diversified 
    portfolio of assets than a vertically integrated utility. Other 
    commenters argue that participation in an RTO that is an ISO is 
    inherently riskier, suggesting that increased risk comes from ownership 
    of transmission assets that are ceded for purposes of operational 
    control to another, non-affiliated entity.
        Other commenters argue that a reevaluation of transmission pricing 
    is needed because it is absolutely critical that the transmission grid 
    support competitive generating markets, and the only way that the 
    Commission can ensure this will happen is to pursue pricing policies 
    that encourage it. Some commenters suggest that because the 
    contribution of transmission to total costs of energy is relatively 
    small\653\ overinvestment in transmission will not significantly affect 
    delivered electricity prices. Further, the Commission should be much 
    more concerned about underinvestment, not overinvestment, in the 
    transmission grid.\654\ Stated another way, an efficient transmission 
    grid is a prerequisite to achieving competitive generating markets, and 
    the potential benefits for consumers far exceed any limited 
    overinvestment that may occur on transmission service. A related 
    argument is that efficiency benefits of improved transmission service 
    will be captured by producers and customers of generation, not 
    transmission providers; therefore, greater incentives for RTOs to 
    provide good transmission operations and efficient investments in the 
    grid are warranted.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \653\ For example, Salomon Smith Barney, citing to an article by 
    Leonard Hyman notes that the direct, total osts of transmission 
    service represents about six to seven percent of the average 
    customer's bill, and raising transmission prices even as high as 25 
    percent in order to attract capital adds only two percent to the 
    overall electric bill.
        \254\ Professor Joskow points out that the external factors, 
    such as licensing requirements, the need for rights of way, and 
    NIMBY (i.e., ``not in my backyard'') opposition to transmission 
    expansion already places significant constraints on overinvestment 
    in major new transmission projects.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The NOPR sought comments on several procedural issues related to 
    transmission pricing reform and incentives. One issue was whether these 
    pricing reforms should be available to participants of existing ISOs, 
    or be available only to transmission owners that join RTOs as a result 
    of the Commission's RTO initiative. We have concluded that members of 
    an existing ISO organization that satisfy the minimum RTO requirements 
    in the regulatory text should be allowed to seek transmission pricing 
    reform as newly formed RTOs, so that they can avail themselves of the 
    same incentives for efficient operation of and investment in the 
    transmission grid. Furthermore, we believe that the Commission's 
    approach to evaluating innovative transmission reforms should be 
    neutral with respect to the organizational structure of the Applicant, 
    so that RTOs that own transmission assets as well as RTOs that do not 
    own transmission assets would be equally eligible for such ratemaking 
    treatments.
        Another issue is whether the Commission would prescribe which 
    transmission pricing reforms it would accept and which it would not 
    accept, or whether the Commission would consider such proposals on a 
    case-by-case basis. We conclude that a case-by-case evaluation of 
    transmission pricing
    
    [[Page 926]]
    
    reform proposals is appropriate, given that such proposals are not 
    generic in nature, and a proposal may be appropriate in some RTO 
    circumstances but not in others. However, the Commission believes some 
    further specificity on transmission pricing reform is warranted to 
    provide industry participants with the Commission's evolving views, as 
    RTOs consider the appropriateness of various reform measures.
        Therefore, we provide greater specificity on three transmission 
    pricing reform measures: (1) ROE; (2) levelized rates; and (3) 
    accelerated depreciation and incremental pricing for new transmission 
    investments. We note that some of these measures may be useful only as 
    transitional devices that may be necessary to spur the prompt creation 
    of RTOs and, therefore, we intend to offer these pricing options only 
    for a defined period of time, as detailed later in this Final Rule. On 
    the other hand, other pricing reforms may be useful as permanent 
    features, and will not be limited only to the period during which RTOs 
    are forming. Finally, while certain of these innovative pricing 
    proposals may be more helpful to one RTO structure than another (e.g., 
    ISO vs transco), we do not believe that any of these pricing proposals 
    would be incompatible with any particular structure adopted by RTOs.
        a. Return on Equity (ROE). More commenters focused on ROE-based 
    proposals than any other type of transmission pricing reform. These 
    commenters make two main points. One argument is that higher ROEs will 
    be demanded by the market as a matter of course as the industry 
    restructures and the risk of transmission business increases, and the 
    Commission must allow higher ROE to reflect participation in RTOs. A 
    second argument is that joining an RTO adds another level of risk that 
    warrants a specific adjustment to ROE (e.g., going to the high end in 
    the range of reasonable ROE, or a specific basis point 
    adjustment).\655\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \655\ Some commenters recommend abandoning the DCF method of 
    calculating ROE entirely. We are not adopting that recommendation.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As discussed above, commenters urge the Commission to provide 
    flexibility in allowing ROE-based programs for RTOs. Many of these 
    commenters specifically urge the Commission to ensure that there are 
    sufficient incentives for an RTO to make needed investments in 
    transmission infrastructure. On the other hand, a number of commenters 
    oppose ROE-based programs on the grounds that they constitute a 
    ``bribe'' for utilities to provide service that they are statutorily 
    required to provide.
        We believe that there are a number of issues surrounding ROE that 
    must be addressed by the Commission. For example, we believe that 
    allowing an RTO to propose a formula rate for determining return on 
    equity is consistent with our view that risks and rewards for 
    transmission owners should reflect market-like forces to the extent 
    possible. Allowing a formula rate of return would decouple a 
    transmission owner's earnings from its own equity valuation, and would 
    tie it more to external standards such as industry-wide performance. 
    Such an approach is also consistent with the benchmarking that may 
    occur under PBR.
        We also agree that the risk profile of the transmission business is 
    changing as the industry restructures, and that it may vary as a 
    function of the structure each transmission company elects. For 
    example, the risk associated with owning facilities that are leased for 
    a sum certain to another entity operating an RTO may be different from 
    the risk associated with operating a stand-alone transco that is facing 
    a significant expansion program. We therefore conclude that ROE-based 
    initiatives--as well as other ratemaking reforms discussed below--may 
    be applicable to all types of RTOs, without regard to organizational 
    structure.
        We further recognize that historical data typically used to 
    evaluate ROEs may not be reliable since it reflects a different 
    industry structure from the one that exists recently. And we believe 
    that as patterns of transmission ownership and control evolve, new 
    approaches to compensating transmission owners for different capital 
    structure mixes may be warranted, including allowing a transmission 
    owner to seek a return on invested capital, independent of its exact 
    capital mix.\656\ As noted above, we are willing to consider 
    moratoriums tied to the rates the transmission provider earns on 
    transmission assets with respect to bundled retail power sales, and the 
    moratorium option may be tied to the existing transmission rate level, 
    or to the existing return on equity.\657\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \656\ As noted infra, this is one of the pricing reforms that 
    will be available only for a defined transition period during which 
    RTOs are being established.
        \657\ As noted infra, moratoriums are among the pricing reforms 
    that will be available for a defined transition period during which 
    TROs are being established.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Finally, we agree that the uncertainty associated with the 
    transition of the industry, and in particular participation in RTOs, 
    may increase risks in the short-run. Certainly, our goals have not 
    changed, which are to ensure that customers have access to 
    nondiscriminatory service at just and reasonable rates, and that 
    transmission owners have an opportunity to earn a reasonable rate of 
    return on their investment. We recognize that in this era of rapid 
    change, new approaches to setting ROE may be needed to implement that 
    standard. We therefore invite RTOs to submit proposals for ROE-based 
    programs that are in conformance with these new approaches.
        We note that pricing reforms involving ROE would clearly be 
    compatible with all types of RTO structures that involve a 
    determination of return on equity on transmission rate base, e.g., 
    transcos, ISOs, or tiered organizational structures.
        b. Levelized Rates. A number of commenters argue that the 
    Commission should allow RTOs to adopt levelized rates. A levelized rate 
    is designed to recover all capital costs through a uniform, nonvarying 
    payment over the life of the asset, just as a traditional home mortgage 
    payment does. The Commission, has held in a number of recent 
    proceedings that both levelized and nonlevelized rates can produce 
    reasonable results, depending on the circumstances.\658\ The Commission 
    stated in these cases that where a utility proposes to switch from a 
    nonlevelized net plant rate design method, ``[i]n supporting such a 
    switch, a utility must prove that its proposed method is reasonable in 
    light of its past recovery of capital costs using a different method.'' 
    \659\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \658\ See, e.g., American Electric Power Service Corp., Opinion 
    440, 88 FERC para. 61,141 at 61,441-42 (1999) (AEP); Allegheny Power 
    Service Corp., Opinion 433, 85 FERC para. 61,275 at 62,117 (1998); 
    Kentucky Utilities Co., Opinion 432, 85 FERC para. 61,274 at 62,100-
    03 (1998) (KU).
        \659\ See AEP, 88 FERC at 61,441-42.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission believes that levelized rates are preferable in an 
    RTO environment because all customers, regardless of when they take 
    service, face the same price. Also, given a depreciated investment 
    base, levelized rates based on existing investments will be higher than 
    non-levelized rates and will address concerns that RTO formation will 
    decrease revenues.
        The principal objection to allowing levelized rates for RTOs is 
    that it may raise RTO transmission rates in the short-run. The 
    Commission has been reluctant outside the RTO context to approve 
    switches from or to levelized rates proposed by public utilities under 
    traditional cost-of-service ratemaking because of the opportunities 
    that switching may provide for utilities to
    
    [[Page 927]]
    
    over recover transmission costs. However, consistent with our 
    discussion above of how market restructuring may require innovation in 
    transmission pricing, we believe that levelized rates may be 
    appropriate in circumstances, as here, where an RTO reflects a fresh 
    start with respect to the provision of transmission services, and 
    potentially the customers for those services. This is especially true 
    in cases where RTO formation occurs coincident with market 
    restructuring, such that the transmission customers of the RTO may be 
    significantly different than the traditional, captive customers, that 
    formerly took transmission service. We therefore conclude that the 
    Commission should allow increased flexibility for RTO proposals that 
    include ratemaking practices based on levelized rates. Clearly, this 
    pricing reform, which relates to the method used to compute the 
    transmission revenue requirement in the first instance, is compatible 
    with any type of RTO structure, e.g., transco, ISO, or tiered 
    structure.
        c. Accelerated Depreciation and Incremental Pricing for New 
    Transmission Investments. While a number of commenters have suggested 
    accelerated depreciation as a transmission pricing reform that should 
    be considered, these arguments are premised on the possibility that 
    transmission costs will be stranded by changes in the industry, such as 
    bypass of portions of the transmission system. We think that these 
    concerns are speculative at this point in the industry's restructuring. 
    For example, we are not convinced that the problem of stranded 
    transmission assets is anywhere near the level of concern that stranded 
    generating assets represents.\660\ In any event, should certain limited 
    transmission facilities become stranded, nothing prevents proposals to 
    recover prudent costs under traditional ratemaking policies.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \660\ See Order No. 888, wherein the Commission allows recovery 
    of stranded costs (primarily generation related) only when they are 
    unrecoverable from customers that depart the system, and only upon a 
    definitive showing that the utility had a reasonable expectation of 
    continuing to serve the customer after the customer's departure.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We will, however, make a distinction between accelerated 
    depreciation for existing transmission assets, and accelerated 
    depreciation for new transmission facilities. While we will not bar 
    proposals of this type for existing assets, we cannot give any 
    encouragement to them in the Final Rule. On the other hand, we believe 
    that it is appropriate for the Commission to provide those willing to 
    make new transmission investments with the flexibility to propose that 
    such assets follow non-traditional depreciation schedules. The purpose 
    of providing such flexibility is to remove disincentives for the 
    construction of new facilities. We think such flexibility is warranted 
    because the fundamental nature of transmission investment may be 
    changing with respect to the entities that will make investments in the 
    transmission system in the future and who pays for the new transmission 
    facilities. Furthermore, given the rapid changes in market structure 
    and dynamics that have occurred and will likely continue, we are not 
    certain that traditional determinations of the economic life of new 
    transmission facilities remain appropriate.
        In addition, we believe it is appropriate for the Commission to 
    provide flexibility for pricing of new facilities, such that proposals 
    for pricing of new facilities that combine elements of incremental 
    prices with embedded-cost access fees will be considered. Although we 
    are concerned that such ratemaking practices have the potential to lead 
    to higher prices for new transmission services, and also potential to 
    lead to overinvestment in transmission facilities, e.g., where 
    generation redispatch could accomplish the same objective at lower 
    cost, we believe that such practices, if carefully constructed, will 
    create appropriate incentives for efficient investment in new 
    transmission facilities. We also believe that this pricing reform will 
    be attractive to all types of RTO structure, e.g., transcos, ISOs, or 
    tiered structures. It may also be used by any RTO that chooses to rely 
    on third parties to construct new facilities.
        d. Acquisition Adjustments. A number of commenters suggest that the 
    Commission adopt new policies for acquisition adjustments that would 
    provide assurances to purchasers of transmission facilities that 
    acquisition premiums would be recoverable through transmission rates. 
    We do not adopt this suggestion in this Final Rule.\661\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \661\ See Minnesota Power & Light Company and Northern States 
    Power Company, 43 FERC para. 61,104 at 61,342 (1988), for a 
    discussion of the Commission's existing policies with respect to the 
    ratemaking treatment for acquisition premiums. See also Duke Energy 
    Moss Landing LLC, et al. 83 FERC para. 61,318 (1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    8. Additional Ratemaking Issues
        A number of comments on ratemaking issues address topics not 
    specifically enumerated in the NOPR.
    Comments
         Williams, CSU, Alliance Companies and WPSC encourage the 
    Commission to consider rate designs based on mileage or network usage.
         Great River, NCPA and IMPA raise the concern that 
    cooperatives and public power entities need assurance that they will 
    receive full customer credit and compensation as was explicitly stated 
    in Order No. 888. SoCal Edison claims that full compensation will be 
    forthcoming and will not be a problem.
         Ohio Commission recommends that a tariff for border 
    transactions (between RTOs) be implemented that makes the market over 
    the combined regions seamless to persuade some regional organizations 
    to combine.
         PPC notes that IndeGO ran into a problem with developing 
    rates for combined systems with very different levels of quality and 
    cost, and that systems at a position of lower quality should be 
    required to meet combined system standards at their own cost.
         Puget argues that RTO rates must provide for the 
    collection of stranded costs.
         PSNM sees a problem with load-side generation customers 
    who do not have to pay their fair share of total system transmission 
    costs.
         Powerex objects to the proposal to segment companies' 
    service areas into sub-zones for pricing purposes.
         Alliance Companies and AEP favor the flexibility in RTO 
    rate filings that would allow companies to make proposals that reflect 
    market forces.
         Alliant Energy is concerned that RTO structures promote 
    workable markets and that transmission rates be permitted to include a 
    fair accounting of RTO start-up costs.
         East Texas Cooperatives recommends that RTO pricing 
    structures adequately compensate small transmission owners who join the 
    RTO, creating an incentive to join and be a more equitable system.
         Georgia Transmission says that ratemaking for RUS 
    borrowers must take into account the requirements of any RUS loans. In 
    addition, Georgia Transmission recommends that the cost of RTO 
    formation be allowed in RTO rates.
         Metropolitan, Cal DWR, and SoCal Cities favor the use of 
    time-of-use pricing or off-peak rates for transmission.
         Oregon Office recommends load-based fees for transmission 
    rather than volume based charges.
         IMEA argues that the RTO start-up and administrative costs 
    should be
    
    [[Page 928]]
    
    allocated to all customers including bundled native retail load. In 
    contrast, LG&E notes that if native load is assigned RTO administrative 
    costs there may be under recovery because of retail rate freezes.
         Industrial Customers argue that assets used for remote 
    generation should be excluded from the RTO.
         Merrill Energy says that the incremental pricing of new 
    transmission upgrades prevents expansion because customers are 
    unwilling to pay.
         NERC is concerned about the recovery of costs related to 
    reliability-related generators.
         NRECA is concerned about compensation by an RTO for low-
    use transmission facilities owned by cooperatives, because large 
    transmission owners are opposed to revenue sharing. NRECA notes that if 
    a cooperative joins an RTO, transactions for all will increase and 
    there is more to share. Also, there should be protection for joint use 
    agreement income.
         Project Groups says that pricing must facilitate entry and 
    usage by efficient, environmentally benign resources. Grid access 
    barriers to these resources need to be eliminated. NMA/WFA/CEED respond 
    by saying that the policies that Project Group objects to are equitable 
    overall.
         Seattle argues that hub and spoke pricing should be used 
    and discrete inter-regional tariffs are needed.
         NWCC notes that the characteristics of wind-produced power 
    presents problems fitting into an RTO pricing arrangement and says that 
    wind power works best with energy-based pricing systems.
         Detroit Edison advocates a two-part pricing structure 
    similar to that proposed by the Alliance RTO. It includes a local rate 
    and a regional rate. To encourage participation, Detroit Edison 
    proposes that the Commission allow RTOs to develop market-based 
    transmission pricing methodologies.
        Commission Conclusion. Commenters raise a number of important 
    ratemaking issues that must be considered in the establishment of RTOs. 
    We clarify that the reasonable costs of developing an RTO may be 
    included in transmission rates. Other issues are at a level of detail 
    and specificity that we do not believe should be resolved in this Final 
    Rule. Therefore, these issues will be considered as they apply to 
    individual RTO proposals on a case-by-case basis.
    9. Filing Procedures for Innovative Rate Proposals
        We shall evaluate all RTO proposals including any innovative rate 
    treatment based on the applicant's demonstration of how the proposed 
    rate treatment would help achieve the goals of regional transmission 
    organizations, including efficient use of and investment in the 
    transmission system and reliability benefits. We shall also require 
    applicants to provide a cost-benefit analysis, including rate impacts, 
    and demonstrate that the proposed rate treatment is appropriate for the 
    proposed RTO and that the rate proposal is just, reasonable, and not 
    unduly discriminatory.
        In addition, pricing proposals involving moratoriums and returns on 
    equity that do not vary according to capital structure may not be 
    included in RTO rates after January 1, 2005. Thus, if the Commission 
    approves an RTO rate proposal involving, e.g., a rate moratorium, 
    unless otherwise ordered, the moratorium would end on or before January 
    1, 2005. We are limiting these rate proposals for a defined period 
    during the formative stage of RTOs because, while either may be 
    appropriate as transitional rate mechanisms, they do not promote long-
    term efficiency through rate design. In addition, the limited duration 
    for these rate treatments will encourage the earliest possible filings, 
    while at the same time giving some flexibility to those filings that 
    may be delayed.
    
    H. Other Issues
    
    1. Public Power and Cooperative Participation in RTOs
        In the NOPR, the Commission stated its objective of encouraging all 
    transmission owning entities including transmission owned or controlled 
    by public power entities and cooperatives, including Federal Power 
    Marketing Agencies (PMAs), Tennessee Valley Authority (TVA), and other 
    state and local entities to place their transmission facilities under 
    the control of an RTO.\662\ To this end, we expressed an expectation 
    that public power entities would fully participate in the collaborative 
    process for forming RTOs.\663\ In addition, we noted that some public 
    power entities filed open access tariffs with the Commission and others 
    are participating in ISOs and other regional institutions. The 
    Commission, however, is aware and concerned that public power entities 
    face several difficult issues regarding RTO formation and 
    participation.\664\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \662\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,756-57.
        \663\ Id. at 33,757.
        \664\ See id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The first issue is the Internal Revenue Service (IRS) Code 
    ``private use'' restrictions on the transmission facilities of public 
    power entities financed by tax-exempt bonds. We noted that IRS 
    temporary regulations may allow facilities financed by outstanding tax-
    exempt bonds to be used to wheel power in accordance with Order No. 
    888, but that these temporary regulations may not allow the issuance of 
    additional tax-exempt bonds for expanded transmission or permit 
    transfer of operational control of existing transmission facilities 
    financed by tax-exempt bonds to a for-profit transco.\665\ The 
    Commission asked for comments on the extent to which IRS Code 
    restrictions may limit the transfer of operational control or other 
    forms of control, or ownership of public power transmission facilities 
    to a for-profit transco or other forms of an RTO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \665\ Id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission also requested comments on state and local charter 
    limitations, prohibitions on participating in stock-owning entities, 
    the current policies of various local regulatory entities that affect 
    or impede full public power participation in RTOs and legal 
    restrictions or other considerations regarding PMAs that prevent their 
    participation in RTOs. We questioned whether the Commission should 
    consider some forms of associate membership or participation and other 
    special accommodations in order for public power entities to overcome 
    obstacles to RTO participation.\666\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \666\See id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments. Most commenters support the Commission's position that a 
    properly formed RTO should include all transmission owners, including 
    cooperatives and public power, in a specific region.\667\ As EEI notes, 
    public power participation will enhance the reliability and economic 
    benefits of an RTO. Furthermore, some commenters argue that in some 
    areas of the country, especially in the Northwest and Southeast, RTO 
    formation may be impractical without public power participation.\668\ 
    Virtually all commenters recognize that regulatory and legal 
    restrictions exist that may impede public power and cooperative 
    participation in RTOs. EEI, SERC and Metropolitan argue that the best 
    way to
    
    [[Page 929]]
    
    facilitate non-jurisdictional utility participation in RTOs is for the 
    Commission to avoid a ``one-size-fits-all approach'' and to provide 
    flexible rules in order to accommodate the unique needs of public power 
    entities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \667\ See, e.g., Oglethorpe, Allegheny, Montana Power, CREDA, 
    Tallahassee, Arkansas Cities, PPC, California Board, Industrial 
    Customers, Entergy, BC Hyrdo, Powerex, Aluminum Companies, MEAG, 
    Arizona Commission, Nevada Commission, East Texas Cooperatives, 
    Lincoln, NPPD, Wyoming Commission, Georgia Transmission, WPSC, PGE, 
    Montana Commission, SMUD, Cal ISO, MLGW, Loveland Customers, NASUCA, 
    Duke, LG&E, CP&L, South Carolina Authority, STDUG, NCPA, PP&L 
    Companies, Desert STAR, PG&E and EEI.
        \668\ See, e.g., EEI, Snohomish, MLGW, Loveland Customers, 
    Montana Commission, Wyoming Commission, Aluminum Companies, 
    Industrial Customers and Powerex.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Section 141 of the IRS code imposes limitations on the use of non-
    governmental entities of public power facilities financed with tax 
    exempt bonds. These private use limitations restrain the form and 
    extent of participation by public power systems in RTOs. The key 
    private use limitation that is material to RTO participation is a bar 
    on the sale of the output of facilities financed with tax exempt debt 
    to non-governmental entities on terms not available to the general 
    public. Commenters note that in January 1998, the IRS issued temporary 
    regulations relating to the application of the private use rules to 
    public power entities that provide some relief for transmission 
    facilities. These temporary regulations permit issuers of outstanding 
    tax exempt bonds to offer open access transmission services and 
    competitive access to distribution systems, and to join RTOs, provided 
    that certain conditions are met, particularly that the facilities 
    continue to be owned by the municipal entity. The temporary 
    regulations, however, do not provide the same relief to issuers of new 
    tax exempt bonds. Many commenters assert that the temporary regulations 
    will expire in January 2001 and that these regulations are incomplete 
    and not permanent.\669\ LPPC notes that the ability of issuers to 
    continue to rely on the temporary regulations after expiration is 
    unclear and therefore, issuers taking actions permitted under the 
    temporary regulations risk having tainted the tax-exempt status of 
    their bonds on the expiration of the regulations.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \669\ E.g., Los Angeles, SoCal Cities, LPPC, APPA, Tacoma, NCPA, 
    SRP, TAPS, EEI, NPPD and East Texas Cooperatives.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commenters offer varying solutions to the ``private use'' 
    restriction problem. Many commenters urge the Commission to actively 
    attempt to influence the IRS and Congress to remove and/or mitigate the 
    tax impediment.\670\ SRP also recommends that the Commission require 
    all RTOs to demonstrate that they have made a good faith effort to 
    reduce barriers to participation and to accommodate legal restrictions 
    faced by potential participants. Arkansas Cities proposes a 
    transitional grandfathering of existing tax-exempt bonds. Arkansas 
    Cities notes that such legislation is pending in Congress and is 
    identified as the Bond Fairness and Protection Act (BFPA). Arkansas 
    Cities states ``that if enacted, the BFPA would clarify tax laws and 
    regulations governing tax exempt bonds so that publicly owned utilities 
    would be able to participate in the development of competitive electric 
    utility markets.'' \671\ Duke asserts that the leasing of transmission 
    facilities to an RTO is a viable option. Moreover, LPPC states that 
    public power entities have to be allowed to participate in a way that 
    permits them to retain sufficient operational control of their 
    transmission systems to stay within the private use limitations. In 
    addition, LPPC, Snohomish, Arkansas Cities and East Texas Cooperatives 
    argue that public power entities need an opt-out provision if their tax 
    exempt status is threatened. TEP recommends that the final rule contain 
    a template for addressing how transactions can be administered if they 
    involve the use of tax exempt facilities. TEP proposes that (1) an RTO 
    should operate in a manner that either preserves the tax exempt status 
    of such facilities or provides compensation to the facilities' owner to 
    the extent it incurs economic harm; and (2) that an RTO should develop 
    specific rules governing the operation and administration of tax-
    exempted financed facilities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \670\ See, e.g., EEI, TAPS, SRP, Georgia Transmission, Arkansas 
    Cities, Nevada Commission, PP&L Companies, TANC, Desert STAR, NCPA, 
    Montana-Dakota Enron/APX/Coral Power and Tallahassee.
        \671\ See Reply Comments of Arkansas Cities at 6.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        NRECA details the obstacles confronting cooperatives including the 
    requirement that in order to maintain tax exempt status under Section 
    501(c)(12) of the IRS Code, at least 85 percent of a cooperative's 
    income must come from the cooperative's members. If such member-derived 
    revenue does not equal at least 85 percent of total revenue, then a 
    cooperative would lose its tax-exempt status. Georgia Transmission 
    argues that there is a real risk that participation in an RTO could 
    result in a cooperative losing its tax exempt status if the revenue 
    received from the RTO (assuming the RTO is not a member of a 
    cooperative) exceeds 15 percent of the cooperative's total income. The 
    revenue received from the RTO would stem from revenue attributed to use 
    of the cooperative's transmission facilities controlled by the RTO.
        One remedy to this problem, suggested by AEPCO and Wolverine 
    Cooperative, is to increase an RTO's compensation to the cooperative to 
    include a gross-up of net margins to cover the income tax expense. 
    Under this approach, the RTO would pay the cooperative the full revenue 
    requirement for the transmission facilities, including any other taxes. 
    East Kentucky proposes that a conduit or a pass-through relationship 
    between the RTO and the cooperative would satisfy the IRS restrictions 
    and allow a cooperative to maintain its member-derived character. 
    According to East Kentucky, the RTO would act as an agent for the 
    cooperative by collecting the transmission revenues and holding these 
    revenues in a trust on behalf of the cooperative. Furthermore, Georgia 
    Transmission suggests that the Commission allow a cooperative to leave 
    an RTO if it appears that it may lose its tax exempt status because of 
    the level of RTO and other non-member revenue it expects to receive in 
    a given year.
        Another impediment to public power participation in RTOs is 
    mortgage restrictions. AEPCO notes that under the terms of a typical 
    RUS mortgage, either transfer of control of transmission assets to an 
    RTO or a sale, unless authorized by RUS, would be an event of default. 
    East Texas Cooperatives argues that the Commission should require all 
    RTOs to accommodate mortgage restrictions by allowing cooperatives to 
    retain control of their facilities until the mortgage restriction is 
    lifted or a creditor or RUS approves the transfer. In its comments, RUS 
    recognizes that development of RTOs may offer considerable benefits to 
    RUS borrowers, and RUS states that it is exploring means to facilitate 
    borrower participation consistent with the Rural Electrification Act 
    and RUS's fiduciary duties to the U.S. Treasury and taxpayers.
        According to several commenters,\672\ many public power entities 
    operate under explicit state constitutional restraints with respect to 
    their ability to participate in the ownership of a privately-owned 
    RTO.\673\ Further, some state constitutions include restrictions on the 
    use of public funds.\674\ Several states, however, expressly authorize 
    public power entities to join with other
    
    [[Page 930]]
    
    public entities in the ownership and operation of electric transmission 
    facilities.\675\ In addition, state and local laws impose additional 
    restrictions on the activities and operations of public power entities 
    that could affect the operations of any RTO in which they hold an 
    ownership interest. For example, some laws prohibit the sale or lease 
    of transmission facilities to a for-profit entity.\676\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \672\ See, e.g., LPPC, NPRB, Snohomish, Clarksdale, MEAG and 
    CAMU.
        \673\ For example, the Nebraska Constitution provides: ``No 
    city, county, town, precinct, municipality or other sub-division of 
    the state, shall ever become a subscriber to the capital stock, or 
    owner of such stock, or any portion or interest therein of any * * * 
    private corporation or association.''
        \674\ For example, the Colorado Constitution states: ``Neither 
    the state, nor any county, city, town, or township shall lend or 
    pledge credit or faith thereof, directly or indirectly, in any 
    manner to, or in aid of, any person, company or corporation, public 
    or private, for any amount, or for any purpose whatever; or become 
    responsible for any debt, contract or liability of any person, 
    company or corporation, public or private, in or out of the state.''
        \675\ For example, Washington law provides: ``Any two or more 
    [Washington] cities or public utility districts or combinations 
    thereof may form an operating agency * * * for the purpose of 
    acquiring, constructing, operating, and owning plants, systems and 
    other facilities and extensions thereof, for the generation and 
    transmission of electric energy and power.''
        \676\ Nebraska law provides that: ``[T]he plant, property, or 
    equipment of a public power district shall never * * * by outright 
    sale, or lease, become the property or come under the control of any 
    private person, firm, or corporation engaged in the business of 
    generating, transmitting, or distributing electricity for profit.'' 
    Nebraska Rev. Stat. Sec. 70-646.01.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In states in which laws allow a public utility district to sell or 
    lease its transmission facilities to an RTO, the laws impose 
    requirements on such sale or lease. For instance, Washington law would 
    require the property to be offered in a competitive bidding process, 
    and no sale could occur without voter approval.\677\ Furthermore, LPPC 
    notes that state and local laws in California, Florida, Nebraska, and 
    Texas would require the approval of the City Council, the public 
    utility commission, the governing board, or other governmental 
    authority before a transfer of facilities could occur. CAMU and NPPD 
    also state that many municipals and power authorities have statutory 
    authority to condemn property and that it is unlikely that this eminent 
    domain authority can be delegated to an RTO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \677\ See LPPC at 17.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Enron/APX/Coral Power notes that an unwillingness to participate in 
    an RTO for commercial reasons should render non-jurisdictional 
    transmission owners ineligible for RTO services and savings. Moreover, 
    Duke argues that public power must take the lead in resolving these 
    issues for themselves. Duke notes that investor-owned utilities have 
    overcome numerous obstacles to become RTO participants. Furthermore, 
    Enron/APX/Coral Power argues that public power and other non-
    jurisdictional transmission owners that elect to share in the benefits 
    of an RTO must be held to the same characteristics and functions as 
    jurisdictional transmission owners. Cinergy suggests that the 
    Commission commence regional technical conferences to address legal 
    obstacles to public power entities' participation in RTOs and to 
    explore possible alternatives to operational and functional integration 
    of public power systems into RTOs.
        Commenters also address issues relating specifically to PMAs. Many 
    commenters support the expansion of the FPA to give the Commission 
    jurisdiction over all transmission owners.\678\ CREDA points out that 
    PMAs are restricted by: (1) enabling statutes; (2) congressional 
    appropriations; (3) the inability to grant indemnification without 
    congressional approval; (4) the sovereign immunity doctrine; and (5) 
    their load serving responsibilities. MLGW notes that other PMA 
    restrictions include the TVA ``fence restriction,'' whereby, TVA's 
    organic statute prohibits TVA from performing any transmission service 
    that would result in the delivery of power generated by TVA outside the 
    specified TVA service area. MLGW further notes that existing long-term 
    contracts between TVA and its distributors are another barrier to RTO 
    participation by PMAs. To remedy these problems, TVA and others \679\ 
    argue that the Final Rule should provide enough flexibility to ensure 
    that public power obstacles can be addressed and mitigated.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \678\ See, e.g., LG&E, Otter Tail, WPSC, Alabama Commission, 
    Montana Commission, and DOE.
        \679\ See, e.g., CAMU, CMUA, STDUG, CREDA, NY ISO, Powerex, PP&L 
    Companies, Desert STAR, CP&L, LPPC, MEAG and Tennessee Authority.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        On the issue of whether the Commission should consider special 
    accommodation, commenters disagree over whether the Commission should 
    provide incentives to public power entities in order to make RTO 
    membership financially attractive. EEI and APPA urge the Commission to 
    adopt an RTO policy that makes membership attractive to public power 
    entities in terms of efficiency and benefits.
        SoCal Edison is strongly opposed to the Commission providing 
    incentives in the form of uniform grid-wide rates or transmission 
    credits. SoCal Edison argues that these incentives are nothing more 
    than inequitable cost shifts to retail ratepayers. Likewise, Duke 
    argues that public power entities should not be provided with 
    competitive advantages in order to encourage voluntary RTO 
    participation.
        In contrast, IMPA and SoCal Cities urge the adoption of a final 
    rule that provides proper credits or compensation for facilities 
    contributed to an RTO, including customer-owned facilities. 
    Furthermore, East Kentucky states that return on equity can be 
    mitigated by allowing cooperatives to earn a rate of return similar to 
    investor-owned utilities. Vernon argues that the entitlement for 
    transmission facilities contributed to the RTO grid and the appropriate 
    level of compensation are matters that should not be determined 
    nationally on a generic basis, but rather, should be decided in the 
    context of each RTO. SRP supports PBRs and other incentives as long as 
    they are applied to both public power entities and investor owned 
    companies equitably. Metropolitan contends that it would not receive 
    much benefit from any ROE incentives offered to RTOs because it is a 
    public entity and because its asset base is so heavily depreciated. 
    However, a replacement cost methodology could be of use in mitigating 
    cost shifts for Metropolitan due to rolling in higher costs of other 
    utilities. Oregon Office recommends that public power entities be 
    eligible for the same incentives as offered others to the extent that 
    the Commission regulates their rates.
        A few commenters discuss issues relating to public power and the 
    filing requirements. South Carolina Authority states that any RTO 
    proposal should contain a detailed description of the efforts made by 
    petitioners to accommodate the transmission facilities of publicly 
    owned utilities. Similarly, SRP, APPA and LPPC recommend that the 
    Commission require each RTO proposal to demonstrate: (1) how a good 
    faith effort was made to accommodate public power participants, 
    particularly deciding ownership structure; and (2) where public power 
    entities are not included, why there are no reasonable terms and 
    conditions under which the RTO could accommodate its participation. 
    Lincoln and Cinergy essentially concur.
        Commission Conclusion. We reaffirm our preliminary determination 
    that a properly formed RTO should include all transmission owners in a 
    specific region, including municipals, cooperatives, Federal Power 
    Marketing Agencies (PMAs), Tennessee Valley Authority and other state 
    and local entities. As noted by some commenters, public power and 
    cooperative participation in RTOs will enhance the reliability and 
    economic benefits of an RTO. Furthermore, participation by public power 
    entities and cooperatives is vital to ensure that each RTO is 
    appropriate in size and scope.
        Virtually all commenters note that public power entities and 
    cooperatives face numerous regulatory and legal obstacles regarding RTO 
    participation. Commenters assert that these obstructions include: (1) 
    IRS ``private use'' restrictions and the temporary regulations enacted 
    to mitigate the ``private use'' restrictions; (2) the
    
    [[Page 931]]
    
    requirement that at least 85 percent of a cooperative's income must 
    come from the cooperative's members (IRS Code Section 501(c)(12)); (3) 
    RUS mortgage restrictions; (4) state constitutional restraints; (5) 
    state and local laws; and (6) specific legal restrictions applicable to 
    PMAs. In addition, commenters offer a variety of solutions to mitigate 
    or eliminate these obstacles to public power participation in RTO 
    formation and operation.
        We acknowledge that public power entities face several difficult 
    issues regarding RTO participation and we appreciate the potential 
    solutions offered by numerous commenters. At this time, however, we 
    will not analyze each of the specific resolutions proposed by the 
    various commenters. Instead, on an RTO-by-RTO basis, we will examine 
    submitted proposals that provide public power and cooperatives with the 
    flexibility to join an RTO without jeopardizing their tax or mortgage 
    status. We note, however, that the offered solutions must be consistent 
    with the minimum functions and characteristics outlined in the Final 
    Rule.
        We are aware that some public power entities and cooperatives have 
    found ways to participate in existing ISOs. For example, we approved 
    the formation of the NY ISO contingent upon a ruling of the Internal 
    Revenue Service that the formation and operation of the NY ISO would 
    not jeopardize the tax-exempt status of the New York Power 
    Authority.\680\ Furthermore, we are encouraged by the recent efforts of 
    the Member Systems of the New York Power Pool (NYPP) to include and 
    accommodate the participation of Long Island Power Authority (LIPA) in 
    the NY ISO. NYPP proposed language in their OATT that provides LIPA 
    will not be required to provide transmission service where the 
    provision of such service would result in the loss of its tax-exempt 
    status for its bonds. NYPP also proposed additional scheduling 
    protocols and procedures to ensure the continued tax-exempt status of 
    LIPA. The Commission accepted the proposed language as described 
    above.\681\ We also note that there are two cooperatives Hoosier Energy 
    Rural Electric Cooperative, Inc. and Wabash Valley Power Association 
    that are members of the Midwest ISO.\682\ We are hopeful that similar 
    agreements between RTOs and public power entities and cooperatives can 
    be reached to provide flexibility and achieve broad regional RTO 
    participation by all entities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \680\ See Central Hudson Gas & Electric Corp., et al., 83 FERC 
    para. 61,352 at 62,405 (1998).
        \681\ See Central Hudson Gas & Electric Corp., et al., 88 FERC 
    para. 61,138 at 61,402-03 (1999).
        \682\ See Midwest Independent Transmission System Operator, 
    Inc., et al., 84 FERC para. 61,231 (1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We expect public power entities and cooperatives to participate 
    fully in the collaborative process for forming RTOs. During the 
    collaborative process, the Commission hopes that the parties will 
    explore, in detail, the impediments and various solutions to public 
    power and cooperative participation in RTOs. As discussed below with 
    respect to the collaborative process, we will make staff resources 
    available to assist in facilitating communication between all entities 
    and in designing regional solutions to full RTO formation and 
    participation. Moreover, in all filings under this Rule, we require a 
    description of efforts made to accommodate participation by public 
    power entities and cooperatives in RTOs.
        We recognize that there is uncertainty regarding what may happen 
    after the IRS temporary ``private use'' regulations expire on January 
    22, 2001. Accordingly, we intend to continue to support efforts to 
    mitigate the ``private use'' and other tax restrictions. Furthermore, 
    in its comments, RUS recognizes that the development of RTOs may offer 
    considerable benefits to RUS borrowers. RUS states that it is exploring 
    means to facilitate borrower participation in RTOs. The Commission 
    welcomes the efforts of RUS to facilitate borrower participation in 
    RTOs, and also encourages RTOs to seek ways to accommodate mortgage 
    restrictions. It would be unfortunate if public power entities and 
    cooperatives were not able to participate in RTOs and share in the 
    benefits available in a regional organization because of tax rules and 
    other government restrictions.
    2. Participation by Canadian and Mexican Entities
        In the NOPR, the Commission noted that currently, electricity 
    trading regions exist across national borders and therefore, Mexican 
    and Canadian involvement in RTO formation would be beneficial to both 
    countries, as well as to the United States.\683\ The Commission 
    asserted that regional institutions should include all market 
    participants in order to provide direct access to information and the 
    benefits of non-pancaked rates. The NOPR also proposed that in order to 
    prevent wasteful duplication of grid facilities, reliability standards 
    implemented by RTOs must be acceptable to the affected nations.\684\ 
    The Commission also emphasized that Canadian and Mexican authorities 
    would be responsible for approving prices and other terms and 
    conditions of transmission service provided over any RTO transmission 
    facilities located in their country.\685\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \683\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,758.
        \684\ Id. at 33,758-59.
        \685\ Id. at 33,759.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments. The U.S. entities that submitted comments on this issue 
    support the efforts by the Commission to encourage participation in 
    RTOs by Canadian and Mexican entities.\686\ For example, PG&E states 
    that given the high degree of operational interconnection between our 
    national grid and components of their systems, participation by these 
    entities is beneficial.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \686\ See PG&E, Desert STAR, Michigan Commission and Industrial 
    Consumers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Similarly, some Canadian entities believe that significant benefits 
    can be achieved by trading over ``natural'' or ``appropriate'' 
    transmission regions that do not necessarily stop at the border.\687\ 
    Other Canadian entities welcome the opportunity to participate in the 
    RTO proceedings and support the Commission's efforts to encourage 
    international collaboration.\688\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \687\ See, e.g., Ontario Power, H.Q. Energy Services, BC Hydro 
    and Canada DNR.
        \688\ See, e.g., Powerex, CEA, Manitoba Board, British Columbia 
    Ministry, Alberta, Canada DNR, BC Hydro and Ontario IMO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Canadian entities are concerned with sovereignty issues and urge 
    the Commission to adopt flexible RTO rules that allow voluntary 
    participation by Canadian utilities.\689\ According to the Manitoba 
    Board and Ontario IMO, one option in this regard would be to allow 
    members of an RTO the freedom to conduct transactions--through a 
    contractual relationship--at the international border with foreign 
    utilities that do not join a cross-border RTO. Furthermore, Canada DNR 
    asserts that a decision not to participate in an international RTO by a 
    Canadian jurisdiction should not place entities in Canada engaged in 
    trade with United States at a disadvantage. Grand Council et al. 
    proposes that the Commission sever the Canadian issues from this 
    proceeding and open a separate docket to examine the international 
    issues raised by the restructuring of electricity markets. Grand 
    Council et al. urges the Commission to cooperate with Canada and Mexico 
    to establish a genuine tri-national consultative process in order to 
    resolve international issues based on an adequate record. Alberta notes 
    that each
    
    [[Page 932]]
    
    individual Province has jurisdictional responsibility for the 
    development of the electrical industry within each Providence and 
    accordingly, only the Province has the jurisdiction to pass legislation 
    to develop a competitive electricity market.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \689\ E.g., Manitoba Board, British Columbia Ministry, BC Hydro, 
    Canada DNR, CEA and Ontario Power.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commission Conclusion. After reviewing the comments, we continue to 
    believe that Canadian and Mexican involvement in RTO formation and 
    operation would be beneficial to both countries, as well as to the 
    United States. As we stated in the NOPR, expansion of electricity trade 
    in the North American bulk power market requires that regional 
    institutions include all market participants so that everyone may enjoy 
    direct access to market information and the benefits of non-pancaked 
    transmission rates. Commenters from the United States and Canada agree 
    that significant benefits can be achieved by trading over ``natural'' 
    or ``appropriate'' transmission regions that do not necessarily stop at 
    the border.
        We note first that we are pleased with the level of participation 
    in our proceedings by Canadian parties, and we encourage their 
    continued participation as RTO formation progresses. We especially 
    appreciate the RTO Consultation Conference sponsored by Natural 
    Resources Canada in Ottawa in November 1999.
        In response to Canadian comments, we point out that the Final Rule 
    makes participation in an RTO voluntary for U.S. transmission owners, 
    and participation is certainly voluntary for Canadian transmission 
    owners. Further, we emphasize that our RTO Rule does not in any way 
    require competition in retail electricity markets, whether they are 
    located in the United States under state regulation or in Canada under 
    provincial regulation. For those Canadian entities that want to join an 
    RTO, the Final Rule is flexible: they may propose a cross-border RTO or 
    a Canadian-only RTO that is compatible with the Rule. The Final Rule is 
    not exclusionary: Canadian entities are not precluded from joining a 
    cross-border RTO.
        Several parties were concerned that a cross-border RTO would have 
    its rates, terms, and conditions subject to the rate jurisdiction of at 
    least two regulators. If a cross-border RTO forms, we will be open to 
    proposals for innovative approaches for jointly overseeing a cross-
    border RTO with domestic and foreign utilities. For example, one 
    approach might be for the cross-border RTO to try to develop a proposal 
    acceptable to both regulators, with the understanding that any 
    regulatory difficulty would normally be referred back to the RTO for 
    resolution and resubmission to both regulators. Another approach might 
    be to have different but complementary rate designs in the two 
    countries.
        In the case of a Canada-only RTO, some Canadian transmission 
    providers believe that having contractual and other agreements for 
    coordination between separate RTOs aross the border is better than 
    having a cross-border RTO. However, some Canadian transmission 
    customers are concerned that this would maintain a lack of 
    standardization of market rules across the border. The RTO Rule is 
    intended to permit a U.S. RTO on the Canadian border to develop 
    contractual and other agreements for coordination with its Canadian RTO 
    neighbor. Further, we have added a new minimum RTO function that an RTO 
    must ensure the integration of reliability practices with other regions 
    in the same interconnection and market interface practices with other 
    regions. We clarify here that this provision applies to integration 
    with interconnected regions in Canada and Mexico.
        For either a cross-border or a Canada-only RTO, we acknowledge the 
    sovereign authority of Canadian governments over Canadian entities and 
    transactions that take place in Canada. Moreover, we re-emphasize that 
    our Rule does not affect the authorities of Canadian government 
    entities to approve prices and other terms and conditions of 
    transmission service provided over any transmission facilities located 
    in Canada. These conclusions apply equally to Mexico.
        We encourage Canadian and Mexican entities to participate in 
    continued RTO consultations and, if appropriate, formation and filings 
    for cross-border RTOs. In particular, we urge Canadian and Mexican 
    entities to attend the appropriate regional workshops to be held in the 
    spring of 2000. These workshops will provide a forum for initial 
    discussion of the issues associated with a cross-border RTOs.
        Regarding the suggestion to establish a tri-national consultative 
    process with Canadian and Mexican authorities to resolve international 
    electric industry issues, we note that there are existing institutions 
    and processes for resolving international disputes. The RTO process is 
    just getting underway, and it is not clear that significant 
    international disputes will develop or, if they should develop, that 
    they would require a non-traditional method of resolution. Indeed, the 
    RTO itself through its dispute resolution process may provide a new and 
    quicker way to resolve some disputes.
    3. Existing Transmission Contracts
        In the NOPR, the Commission asked for comments addressing what the 
    appropriate treatment should be for existing transmission agreements 
    when an RTO is formed. We noted that in Order Nos. 888 and 888-A, the 
    Commission specifically chose not to abrogate existing requirements 
    contracts and transmission contracts when the utility filed an open 
    access transmission tariff.\690\ We stated, however, that an RTO 
    represents an entirely different context. In the NOPR, the Commission 
    recognized the importance of balancing a uniform approach for 
    transmission pricing with the equities inherent in existing 
    transmission contracts.\691\ Furthermore, we noted that the potential 
    financial impact of giving up an advantageous transmission arrangement 
    may serve as a disincentive to joining an RTO. In the NOPR, we proposed 
    to address the issue of existing transmission contracts on an RTO-by-
    RTO basis, rather than resolve the issue generically.\692\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \690\ FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 32,541 at 33,757.
        \691\ See id. at 33,757-58.
        \692\ Id. at 33,758.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments. Many commenters argue that the Commission should preserve 
    and protect existing transmission contracts.\693\ These commenters note 
    that existing contracts represent negotiated rights and obligations 
    achieved through mutual negotiation. SRP believes that the Commission 
    should grandfather existing transmission contracts in order to protect 
    customers from cost shifts and prevent uncertainty in the marketplace. 
    Turlock argues that the preservation of existing contracts, while 
    cumbersome, is the bedrock of predictability and reliability and a key 
    element of contract law. NPRB states that existing contracts should be 
    honored until the contract expires or until the parties come to a new 
    agreement. STDUG asserts that in order to be properly inclusive, an RTO 
    must take members as it finds them, existing contracts, warts, and all. 
    In contrast, CP&L asserts that the elimination of grandfathered 
    agreements to the greatest extent possible ensures the most level 
    playing field for all market participants.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \693\ E.g., TANC, Turlock, UAMPS, Desert STAR, CMUA, Sithe, 
    Georgia Transmission, Lincoln, PG&E, NPRB, NCPA, Great River, NRECA, 
    Loveland Customers, San Francisco, Platte River, Florida Commission, 
    Nevada Commission, DOE, Wolverine Cooperative, Tri-State, CREDA, 
    EPSA, Big Rivers, SPP, SoCal Cities, TEP, PJM/NEPOOL Customers, 
    Metropolitan, STDUG and PacifiCorp.
    
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [[Page 933]]
    
        A few commenters propose a reasonable transition period to allow 
    parties to existing contracts to conform their arrangements to an RTO 
    tariff.\694\ EPSA notes that the transition period should be of 
    sufficient length to reduce the financial and other burdens on the 
    customer and on the original transmission provider. PSNM argues that at 
    a minimum, a transition period of as long as ten years is needed to 
    move the existing transmission contracts to RTO service. Furthermore, 
    TAPS proposes that the Commission provide entities with an open season 
    for transmission customers to choose to terminate or switch service 
    under the terms of an RTO tariff. Alternatively, TAPS suggests that the 
    Commission apply a just and reasonable standard to all transmission 
    customers who seek contract modifications. Regarding contract 
    modification, Southern Company asserts that in order to promote 
    fairness, both parties to a contract must have an equal opportunity to 
    modify the existing agreement. In addition, Entergy argues that the 
    Commission should encourage all entities to re-negotiate existing 
    contracts.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \694\ See, e.g., Williams, EPSA, First Energy, Duke, PSNM, LG&E, 
    PGE and MidAmerican.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several commenters support the Commission's preference that issues 
    relating to the continued validity of existing transmission contracts 
    be addressed on an RTO-by-RTO basis.\695\ WPSC argues that treatment of 
    existing transmission contracts within a particular RTO should be 
    consistent. Turlock urges the Commission to proceed with caution when 
    addressing existing contracts. On the other hand, PSE&G asserts that 
    the Commission should not address the treatment of existing contracts 
    on a case-by-case basis because this leads to arbitrary and 
    inconsistent results. Instead, PSE&G and Dalton Utilities argue that 
    the Commission should address the issue of existing transmission 
    contracts on a generic basis consistent with Order No. 888 and the 
    Mobile-Sierra doctrine (recognizing the need to preserve the sanctity 
    of contracts where possible).\696\ Sithe and NRECA concur that a 
    generic policy is appropriate.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \695\ See, e.g., WPSC, Great River, DOE, ICUA, Entergy, TDU 
    Systems, TEP, South Carolina Authority, MidAmerican, SNWA, UAMPS and 
    TAPS.
        \696\ See United Gas Pipe Line Co. v. Mobile Gas Serv. Corp., 
    350 U.S. 332, 338 (1956); FPC v. Sierra Pacific Power Co., 350 U.S. 
    348, 353 (1956).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Cal ISO argues that the Commission's policies on existing contracts 
    deserve revisiting, at a minimum for the limited purpose of conforming 
    scheduling and metering rules to those of the RTO/control area 
    operator. Cal ISO states that it has experienced the challenges of 
    workability when the ISO was required to honor existing contracts, but 
    not permitted to interpret them or conform their scheduling rules to 
    those of the regional organization. Cal ISO notes that it has 
    experienced the most significant market inefficiencies associated with 
    existing contracts in the area of scheduling and information gathering.
        A few commenters note that not honoring existing contracts would 
    create disincentives for both transmission customers and owners to join 
    an RTO.\697\ For example, CMUA and Georgia Transmission argue that the 
    financial impact of giving up an advantageous transmission arrangement 
    would be a significant disincentive to RTO membership.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \697\ E.g., CMUA, Desert STAR, Georgia Transmission, Wolverine 
    Cooperative, Cal ISO, Entergy, Tri-State, SNWA, Metropolitan and 
    TEP.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commission Conclusion. At this time, we continue to believe that it 
    is not appropriate to order generic abrogation of existing transmission 
    contracts. We recognize that existing contracts represent negotiated 
    rights and obligations achieved through mutual negotiation. However, in 
    PJM \698\ and the Midwest ISO \699\ we adopted the rationale that it 
    was unreasonable and discriminatory to maintain the pancaked rates in 
    existing contracts for others when transmission-owning utilities had 
    designed a non-pancaked rate approach for their own transactions. In 
    our examination of existing contracts, we intend to balance the 
    preference for preservation of existing contracts with the importance 
    of consistency in transmission pricing and the elimination of pancaked 
    rates.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \698\ See PJM, 81 FERC para. 61,257 at 62,280-81 (1997).
        \699\ See Midwest Independent Transmission System Operator, 
    Inc., et al., 84 FERC para. 61,231 at 62,169-70, order on reh'g, 85 
    FERC para. 61,372 at 62,418-20 (1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As the above comments demonstrate, there is no consensus on how the 
    Commission should manage the transition from existing transmission 
    contacts to RTO service. In fact, parties offer diverse and conflicting 
    views as to what the Commission should do regarding existing 
    transmission contracts. Some commenters would have us let all contracts 
    run their course with no opportunity to modify or terminate. Others 
    advocate an elimination of existing agreements to the greatest extent 
    possible. Yet others argue for a transition period ranging in duration 
    for up to ten years to move existing transmission contracts to RTO 
    service.
        Rather than adopting one extreme position or the other, we will 
    take a measured approach with regard to the treatment of existing 
    transmission contracts. We intend to address the issue of existing 
    transmission contracts on an RTO-by-RTO basis, rather than resolve the 
    issue generically. Accordingly, each RTO can propose whatever contract 
    reform is necessary, including the limited changes suggested by the Cal 
    ISO for the limited purpose of conforming scheduling, information 
    gathering, and metering rules to those of the RTO. To this end, we 
    encourage each RTO to address how and when it might convert existing 
    contracts and submit a contract transition plan that contains specific 
    details about the procedures to be utilized involving the conversion 
    from existing contracts to RTO service. Again, our goal in reviewing 
    existing transmission contracts and contract transition plans is to 
    balance the desire to honor existing contractual arrangements with the 
    need for a uniform approach for transmission pricing and the 
    elimination of pancaked rates.
    4. Power Exchanges (PXs)
        The NOPR described the apparent advantages and disadvantages of 
    having a power exchange coincident with an RTO. As further described in 
    the NOPR, supporters state that PXs can reduce price volatility by 
    providing price transparency, reduce the impact of defaults by 
    spreading transaction risks among all participants through credit 
    standards and reserve fund requirements, facilitate risk hedging by 
    providing a basis for a futures market, and help facilitate retail 
    access programs. Detractors argue that the principal functions of a PX 
    are not natural monopoly functions. They contend that PXs, compared 
    with bilateral markets, force participants to buy and sell electricity 
    using standardized contracts, which may not suit their particular 
    needs. They further argue that competition within the electricity 
    market and its full benefits can only be achieved if there is 
    competition for the PX market.
        The NOPR left it to each region to determine whether there is a 
    need for a power exchange and whether the RTO should operate it.\700\ 
    The NOPR said that the Commission will accept any RTO proposal that 
    includes a power exchange in its design as long as its operation of the 
    power exchange does not compromise its independence as a
    
    [[Page 934]]
    
    transmission service provider. The Commission sought comments on a 
    number of questions related to power exchanges, including whether 
    regional flexibility is appropriate and how RTOs should deal with an 
    independent power exchange.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \700\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,760.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments. Commenters' views on power exchanges are mixed. The 
    largest group of commenters basically agree with the NOPR.\701\ A 
    smaller group of commenters recommend that the Commission require that 
    RTO applications include provisions for a power exchange,\702\ with 
    some recommending that the power exchange be internal to the RTO \703\ 
    and some recommending that the PX be independent of the RTO.\704\ CalPX 
    argues strongly that a power exchange should be separate from the RTO, 
    given the continuing need to separate market and transmission 
    functions; the need for market transparency to facilitate determination 
    of whether congestion is being exploited; the need to provide a 
    credible reference price for new retail choice market entrants; and the 
    potential need for the RTO and power exchange to serve differing 
    geographic areas. CalPX also submits that there is no concrete evidence 
    that an RTO-operated power exchange will be more efficient and 
    economical than an unrelated power exchange. NYMEX agrees that an RTO 
    should be permitted to operate a power exchange, as long as a proper 
    code of conduct is in place. PJM points to its success with a combined 
    ISO/power exchange.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \701\ See, e.g., Entergy, NJBUS, NY ISO, TDU Systems, Wisconsin 
    Commission and UtilitCorp.
        \702\ See, e.g., Pennsylvania Commission, Duke and California 
    Board.
        \703\ See, e.g., PJM, ISO-NE and TAPS.
        \704\ See, e.g., EPSA and MidAmerican.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Another group of commenters argue that power exchanges should not 
    be included in RTOs, but should be allowed to occur naturally as 
    needed.\705\ Elaborating on this point of view, Salomon Smith Barney 
    advises that the power exchange should not be in the RTO because it 
    could throttle innovation and that the Commission should let the market 
    decide. If there are really advantages to be gained, as some claim, 
    from the operation of a single power exchange associated with the RTO, 
    then such a power exchange will naturally develop. Florida Power Corp. 
    argues that, while a region may prefer that its RTO closely coordinate 
    with the power exchange, the two should not be part of the same 
    organization because there is a fundamental difference in the business 
    objectives of the two . Similarly, EPSA contends that the Commission's 
    vision of an RTO being an entity independent from all generation and 
    power marketing interests is fundamentally incompatible with an RTO-run 
    power exchange. Nevada Commission offers that a power exchange is not 
    necessary to the formation of an RTO. And while PG&E sees every region 
    needing a real-time balancing market regardless of whether it is run 
    in-house by the RTO, PG&E also prefers that markets should otherwise be 
    left to develop on their own accord.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \705\ See, e.g., APX, SMUD, Southern Company, Tri-State and 
    Lincoln.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments were received on additional aspects of the power exchange 
    concept. PG&E argues that an RTO should not be allowed to use control 
    of a power exchange to alter or cap prices set by the market. LG&E 
    submits that the RTO should be required to be the provider of last 
    resort for ancillary services, although market participants should not 
    be required to purchase from the RTO. NASUCA notes that the NOPR does 
    not cover some important power exchange issues such as exactly which 
    markets would be included. NASUCA recommends that a NOI on power 
    exchanges and related power market issues be initiated soon after the 
    final rule.
        Several commenters state that multiple power exchanges in a region 
    should have equal standing before the RTO.\706\ FTC, however, 
    recommends that the Commission assess whether competition is feasible 
    in power exchange services. Similarly, CalPX notes that multiple power 
    exchanges may hurt the market's function because each power exchange 
    would be small, and therefore would not offer high levels of depth, 
    liquidity and efficiency. NYMEX counters that there should be no 
    credence given to the idea that one power exchange should enjoy any 
    form of artificial franchise vis-a-vis others.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \706\ See, e.g., Duke, Florida Power Corp. and Desert STAR.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commission Conclusion. The NOPR proposed leaving it to each region 
    to determine whether there is a need for a power exchange and whether 
    the RTO should operate the power exchange. We have Decided to adopt the 
    NOPR proposal. As the commenters have pointed out, there are advantages 
    and disadvantages to the inclusion of a PX in the RTO structure. We do 
    not believe that including a PX as part of the RTO structure would 
    necessarily preclude the market benefits associated with bilateral 
    transactions. We believe an RTO can accommodate both a bilateral market 
    and a PX market. As the individual structures of the various RTOs 
    supported by the regions are likely to be quite varied, we think that 
    it is best to let market preferences dictate the form of any one or 
    more regional power exchanges and whether the RTO should operate a 
    power exchange.
    5. Effect on Retail Markets and Retail Access
        The NOPR addressed the impact of RTOs and any associated PXs on 
    retail competition and the states' jurisdiction over retail 
    competition. For example, the Commission found that RTOs will enhance 
    the effectiveness of retail competition:
    
        We believe that the likelihood of success for existing and 
    planned retail choice initiatives is significantly enhanced if the 
    Commission can ensure fair and efficient access to a regional market 
    without pancaked transmission access charges, and that we need to 
    take steps beyond Order No. 888 to accomplish this.\707\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \707\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,704.
    
        In addition, the Commission found that an RTO does nothing to 
    interfere with the state's authority to decide retail access policy, 
    but asked whether a PX is necessary for successful retail competition.
        Comments. Several commenters state that RTOs were either essential 
    or of great benefit in the implementation of retail competition.\708\ 
    Mid-Atlantic Commissions notes that PJM has worked closely with the 
    Pennsylvania, New Jersey and Delaware Commissions to assist with the 
    implementation of their retail choice legislation in an organized 
    fashion, while maintaining that the grid will be operated in a reliable 
    fashion without any major economic or operational changes. According to 
    Mid-Atlantic Commissions, this has also further provided those states 
    in the region that have not implemented retail choice with a stable 
    organization that continues to maintain reliability.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \708\ See, e.g., TXU Electric, DOE, First Rochdale, Illinois 
    Commission and Williams.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A few commenters express concern that the Commission's RTO policy 
    could threaten the states' ability to control the pace of retail access 
    and retail competition.\709\ South Carolina Commission counsels that 
    the Commission should try to avoid affecting retail restructuring 
    through its efforts to establish an RTO process. Central Maine raises 
    the concern that retail choice programs already developed in concert 
    with existing ISOs may be adversely impacted by any changes to such 
    ISOs that are found to be necessary for them to conform to the RTO 
    requirements (e.g., energy service
    
    [[Page 935]]
    
    company and other load serving entity contracts entered into in 
    reliance upon the existing ISO market structures).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \709\ See, e.g., Iowa Board and Puget.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Puget views allowing RTOs to make FPA section 205 filings that 
    unilaterally propose changes to the RTO tariff as conflicting with the 
    Commission's commitment to respect the retail access efforts of the 
    individual states. Puget argues that a unilateral decision by an RTO to 
    provide transmission service to a retail customer and make that 
    customer an eligible customer under the pro forma tariff would force 
    states without retail access to accept such access as a fait accompli. 
    Puget also fears that the term ``market participant'' as ultimately 
    defined may include any entity that buys or sells electric energy in 
    the RTO's region or in any neighboring region that might be affected by 
    the RTO's actions. If so, since market participants must also have the 
    option of self-supplying or acquiring ancillary services from third 
    parties, this further suggests that retail customers may have the 
    ability to acquire transmission service regardless of whether the 
    affected state has yet decided retail choice and stranded cost recovery 
    issues. Industrial Customers, however, question the legal basis for 
    Puget's apparent suggestion that utilities be allowed to decide which 
    retail customers may access RTO transmission.
        EPSA contends that, while states tout each state's rights to 
    protect its retail native load customers, some actions taken under this 
    banner to limit exports of power actually disadvantage adjoining 
    state's retail customers or participants in the bulk power markets. 
    Therefore, the Commission should move forward with a rulemaking to 
    assure full transmission comparability for retail customers of all 
    states, and to prevent individual states from continuing to 
    disadvantage each other and to prevent individual utilities from 
    continuing to disadvantage other market participants. New York 
    Commission also submits that this proceeding is not the place to 
    address the issue of preemption of state jurisdiction over bundled 
    retail electric sales.
        TAPS raises the question of jurisdictional conflict as to which 
    facilities need to be regulated at the federal or state level, and 
    whether the policies of the Commission toward open access will be 
    undercut by transmission owners using the seven factor transmission/
    distribution classification test to place new generation at a 
    disadvantage relative to existing generation owned by the transmission 
    provider. TAPS contends that the Commission must take steps to ensure 
    that RTOs contain the appropriate facilities and that 
    refunctionalization of transmission to distribution does not interfere 
    with competition by creating RTOs that control little or no 
    transmission.
        Another concern expressed is that RTOs may cause cost shifting to 
    retail customers that could interfere with restructuring.\710\ As to 
    the impact of the power exchange on retail competition, both CalPX and 
    MidAmerican argue that power exchanges assist in the effectiveness of 
    retail competition programs by providing transparent and credible 
    reference prices.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \710\ See, e.g., LG&E and Southern Company.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commission Conclusion. We continue to be persuaded that RTOs can 
    positively affect each state's implementation of its retail choice 
    program, without interfering with those states that have not yet 
    adopted such programs. As noted by commenters, existing ISOs have 
    already successfully facilitated retail choice programs in areas where 
    only some of the states have adopted such programs, and the ISOs were 
    able to do so without clashing with or frustrating the other states 
    that have not undertaken such programs. We do not believe that an RTO 
    could interfere with a state's decisions on whether or how fast to 
    implement retail choice within its borders, either through the RTO's 
    Section 205 filing authority or otherwise through the RTO's 
    jurisdictional obligation to provide non-discriminatory and non-
    preferential transmission service.
        Commenters pointed to potentially extensive reclassification of 
    transmission facilities to local distribution as part of the unbundling 
    of retail rate schedules to implement retail choice programs, and how 
    this might lead to RTOs that are ``empty vessels'' with little 
    significant transmission under their control. We agree that RTOs must 
    control all transmission facilities that are necessary to support 
    competitive wholesale power markets. For this reason, we specified the 
    scope, configuration and operational control requirements adopted in 
    this Final Rule. We will judge any proposed reclassification on a case-
    by-case basis. We note that any reclassification of transmission 
    facilities to local distribution will require Commission approval and 
    will not remove from the Commission's jurisdiction any facilities used 
    to deliver power to wholesale customers. Furthermore, under the 
    principle of open architecture (discussed supra in section III.F), the 
    Commission expects RTOs to remain flexible such that, if over time 
    circumstances should change and certain facilities need to be 
    reclassified as transmission, procedures will be in place to do so.
        With regard to RTO pricing causing transmission cost shifting that 
    adversely affects retail choice customers, this issue is discussed in 
    the Transmission Ratemaking section of this Final Rule.\711\ The 
    Commission will continue to review transmission rate proposals to 
    ensure that they are just and reasonable, and not unduly 
    discriminatory.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \711\ See supra section III.G.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Finally, on the matter of whether a power exchange is needed to 
    facilitate states' retail choice programs, it is our view that, to the 
    extent that a region forming an RTO chooses to voluntarily establish an 
    RTO-affiliated power market, we anticipate that any such power exchange 
    would provide retail choice customers with transparent and credible 
    reference prices for power and other information that otherwise might 
    not be available.\712\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \712\ For a further discussion of PXs, see supra section 
    III.H.4.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    6. Effect on States with Low Cost Generation
        In the NOPR, we recognized that states with relatively low cost 
    power are concerned that an RTO would result in local utilities selling 
    their low cost power to other states.\713\ However, we noted that a 
    state that is low cost today may not be low cost tomorrow without an 
    RTO in its area.\714\ In addition, we stated that utilities that now 
    have low cost generation will help assure access to future low cost 
    generating plants by participating in an RTO and that new low cost 
    generation plants are more likely to be attracted to regions with a 
    well-functioning regional market governed by an RTO. We sought comment 
    from state commissions regarding how an RTO in their state would affect 
    power costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \713\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,722.
        \714\ See id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments.--A number of commenters raise concerns about the effect 
    of RTOs on states with low cost electricity. These concerns center 
    around one issue--that the costs of creating an RTO may outweigh the 
    benefits.
        South Carolina Commission argues that customers in South Carolina 
    enjoy very high quality service and pay some of the lowest rates. Duke 
    power concurs, noting that, it is not necessarily true that North 
    Carolina and South Carolina will conclude that sufficient long-term 
    benefits exist for these states to justify costs of RTO membership. 
    Duke argues
    
    [[Page 936]]
    
    that any proposed RTO should be shown to provide tangible benefits to 
    the relevant region.
        Alabama Commission believes that RTOs will cause states to lose the 
    efficiency of integrated systems and lead to retail competition, 
    whether it is in the interest of customers or not. Southern Company 
    agrees, noting that due in large part to the low cost status of 
    southeastern states, they are proceeding cautiously with retail 
    competition and restructuring initiatives. This does not mean that 
    these states are ignoring the potential benefits of restructuring. 
    Indeed, Southern Company notes that states in its service territory are 
    actively studying the potential advantages and disadvantages of retail 
    competition but have not yet concluded that the potential benefits 
    outweigh the costs and risks associated with changing the current 
    industry structure.
        SMUD points out that it has not joined the Cal ISO over similar 
    concerns. It indicates that its customers already enjoy low cost 
    electricity and that participation in the Cal ISO could not ensure that 
    SMUD's retail rates would be any lower, and on the contrary, the cost 
    of participation would cause rate increases.
        Kentucky Commission indicates that inefficiencies may occur for a 
    variety of reasons and examples of inefficiencies include: multiple 
    RTOs in a small region; several layers of governance within one RTO; 
    and too many tasks shifted from the RTO members to the RTO itself. 
    Kentucky Commission argues that if the proposed transmission 
    organizations are not operated at levels of maximum efficiencies and 
    minimum reasonable costs, the Commission will have failed to promote 
    one of its primary objectives, the growth and success of the wholesale 
    power market. Kentucky Commission further argues that the Commission 
    must be mindful of these costs in developing rules for the 
    establishment of RTOs.
        Commission Conclusion. We are mindful of the potential costs of 
    setting up and running an RTO, but we anticipate that the collaborative 
    process will result in an RTO proposal that incorporates a design that, 
    overall, increases the existing level of transmission system and market 
    efficiency for each region. As we discuss more fully in the Scope, 
    Implementation and Benefits sections of this Final Rule, we are taking 
    a results-oriented, practical approach to establishment, organization, 
    implementation and operation of RTOs. We do not expect that regions 
    with no existing institutions will necessarily invest in new, high-cost 
    RTO infrastructure. Instead, such a region may propose an RTO that 
    relies on existing infrastructure to accomplish its mission. However, 
    we expect the RTO to satisfy the minimum characteristics and functions 
    and to improve the efficiency of regional transmission service.
        In response to the concern of low cost states that RTOs could 
    result in exports of their low cost power to other states, we do not 
    believe that an RTO will cause utilities to sell their lowest cost 
    power out of state. While retail choice arguably might lead to low cost 
    power being sold out of state because incumbent utilities no longer 
    have an obligation to serve local in-state loads, this would occur with 
    or without an RTO in the region. Where there is no retail choice, our 
    Final Rule does not affect a state commission's authority to require a 
    utility to sell its lowest cost power to native load, as it always has. 
    We point out that, if the utility's transmission is operated by an RTO 
    and its higher cost power can be sold more readily to new, more distant 
    customers, this will lead to recovery of more capital costs and lower 
    retail rates. In the long term, low cost states may benefit from an RTO 
    that facilitates expanded access to wholesale electricity markets, 
    increasing the choice of low cost resources available to utilities as 
    they acquire new power resources.
    7. States' Roles with Regard to RTOs
        In the NOPR, we noted that states want a role in the governance of 
    any RTOs for their states, and we proposed to be flexible in 
    accommodating the states' needs.\715\ The NOPR encouraged RTO design to 
    accommodate appropriate state oversight, especially with regard to 
    planning and siting new multi-state transmission facilities. We sought 
    comments on the appropriate state role in RTOs on these and other RTO 
    matters.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \715\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,724.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments. Comments on the states' roles in RTO development and 
    governance were fairly extensive, with by far the greater percentage of 
    comments supporting a strong and clearly defined state role. Comments 
    can be grouped into four primary categories: (1) governance; (2) 
    formation; (3) siting and planning authority; (4) regional regulation.
        Governance. Almost all commenters on this issue expressed support 
    for a clear state role in governance; however, there were differences 
    as to exactly what that role should be. Some commenters believe that 
    states should be allowed to determine their own role in governance, 
    either as members of advisory panels to the board of directors, as 
    voting members of the board, as non-voting members of the board, or 
    having authority to appoint board members. Some commenters, however, 
    feel strongly that states should not be permitted to be voting members 
    of boards.
        Commenters argue that the appropriate state role in an RTO is a 
    matter of local control. For example, Northwest Council states that the 
    Commission should not set restrictive rules on the type of state 
    participation in RTO governance, but should allow the states to propose 
    to the Commission the kind of roles they view as appropriate, e.g., 
    voting members of a stakeholder board, ex officio status on an 
    independent board, and so forth.
        The California Board suggested that state officials should be 
    allowed as either voting or non-voting members. Los Angeles has no 
    objection to state board membership, either voting or non-voting, if a 
    state has determined that a government official can best represent that 
    state's interests. The Washington Commission agrees that states should 
    be able to define their own role. Mid-Atlantic Commissions note that 
    they have a Memorandum of Understanding with the PJM ISO Board of 
    Managers to facilitate communication and promote a cooperative 
    relationship.
        Some commenters, however, think that state officials should not 
    have voting membership on boards of directors since that could raise 
    conflict of interest problems where the state official would have to 
    approve decisions of the board while sitting as a regulator. For 
    example, Minnesota Power believes that state cooperation will be 
    enhanced if state officials participate as members of an RTO advisory 
    board, but they should not participate as voting members of an RTO 
    because the RTO process could be compromised by parochial state 
    politics. ISO-NE agrees, pointing out that some states' conflict of 
    interest laws may expressly prohibit such service, and that it might be 
    difficult for an official from one state to make decisions as a board 
    member that are good for residents of all states encompassed by the 
    RTO.\716\ WEPCO believes the appropriate role of the states in RTO 
    governance includes active participation in regional planning efforts 
    and continued oversight of siting of new transmission facilities. In 
    addition, many commenters supported
    
    [[Page 937]]
    
    an advisory role for state officials, through advisory boards.\717\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \716\ See also MidAmerican, Montana-Dakota, PSNM, East Kentucky 
    and NPRB.
        \717\ E.g., ISO-NE, PJM, Midwest ISO, MidAmerican, Project 
    Groups, PSNM, Iowa Board, Arizona Commission and UAMPS.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Formation. Numerous commenters supported a role for states in the 
    formation of RTOs. ISO-NE points out that the states in its region had 
    a significant role in the development of the ISO. In addition, the 
    California Board argues that states should have a role in determining 
    the structure of the RTO and any other market institutions that are 
    formed to serve the citizens of their respective states. California 
    Board further notes that mechanisms to ensure that states' interests 
    are protected might include statutory or regulatory reliability 
    criteria; independent market monitoring by the states or requiring 
    market monitoring reports to be provided to the state; and 
    accountability to the states to ensure adequacy of transmission and 
    generation planning.
        The Michigan Commission notes that most states have ittle direct 
    authority to order the development of an RTO, especially when the RTO 
    encompasses several states. According to the Michigan Commission, at 
    best state commissions should serve in an advisory role as the 
    utilities develop the structure and guidelines of the RTO proposal. The 
    Michigan Commission, however, joins a few other states in urging the 
    Commission to defer to state recommendations once the basic RTO 
    characteristic and functional guidelines have been met.
        NARUC comments extensively on the potential collaborative process 
    and the importance of state participation in this process and other 
    steps in the formation of RTOs. To achieve the public policy goal of 
    assuring reliable service at an affordable cost, NARUC argues that 
    states should fully participate in RTO development and formation, 
    particularly in matters for end-use native load customers. NARUC notes 
    that based on some states' retail choice or ISO experiences, state 
    oversight can play a significant role in assuring a well-functioning 
    ISO and competitive wholesale and retail markets.
        NARUC further suggests that once RTOs are formed, continuing 
    interaction is necessary, and market development and evolution will be 
    continuous. NARUC believes that RTO formation must continue to be a 
    dynamic process requiring continuing dialogue between FERC and the 
    states. NARUC further believes that once organizations are formed and 
    approved, some type of formal reporting to FERC and the states by the 
    organizations on an annual basis would be appropriate.
        Nine Commissions suggests that state commissions are well 
    positioned to balance the competitive motivations of utilities in the 
    RTO formation process with the interests of all other stakeholders in 
    defining markets in their respective regions and conforming the RTO 
    boundaries to those markets. According to Nine Commissions, the state 
    commissions' continued cooperation with FERC will ensure that the 
    mutual public interests of providing reliable electric service will be 
    met, and that market participants in every region of the country will 
    be treated comparably.
        Siting, Planning and Reliability. A number of commenters, many 
    state commissions, and quite a few other parties, argue strongly that 
    the Commission should be careful not to preempt traditional state 
    regulatory authority in promulgating its rule. In particular, 
    commenters suggest that the Commission should not usurp state 
    authorities over siting, planning, and reliability of the transmission 
    system. Some commenters proposed solutions to state/Federal 
    jurisdiction issues in the RTO context, such as joint state/Federal 
    review bodies. The Alabama Commission suggests that FERC should not 
    take any action that would infringe on state jurisdiction.
        South Carolina Commission asserts that transmission siting should 
    remain in the hands of the states and local governments. South Carolina 
    Commission further asserts that states must continue to have a 
    significant role with regard to matters of reliability for end-use 
    native load customers. The Iowa Board concurs and suggests that the 
    Commission's RTO policies cannot alter states' continued interest in 
    local matters such as transmission and generation siting, local 
    transmission and distribution interface issues, adequacy of generation 
    and transmission, service quality, and retail rates.
        The Montana Commission notes that in roughly half the states with 
    siting laws the function is not vested in the regulatory commission, 
    but rather in a separate energy policy, environmental or commerce 
    agency. They recommend that the Commission amend the language in the 
    Final Rule to make it clear that the Commission does not intend to 
    preempt state siting authority as part of this NOPR.
        UAMPS warns that RTOs may create a separation between generation 
    planning and transmission planning that endangers reliability. UAMPS 
    argues that states must be left with authority to assure reliability 
    and that retail competition issues should also be left to the states. 
    UAMPS suggests that because state cooperation and participation will be 
    so critical to an RTO's effectiveness, in addition to the four minimum 
    characteristics the Commission has proposed, RTOs should be required to 
    provide specifically for significant state involvement in their 
    development and operation. Allegheny, on the contrary, states that 
    system operations in an RTO will be pursued for the good of the RTO 
    service area, not of any one state. Allegheny notes that if that fact 
    yields a dilution of state authority it must be the price paid for RTO 
    benefits.
        Regional Regulation. A number of commenters propose or support 
    regional regulatory cooperation or joint state/Federal sharing of 
    jurisdiction. The Kentucky Commission proposes the creation of a 
    Federal/state ``joint board,'' that is styled similarly to the 
    Universal Service Joint Board currently used by the Federal 
    Communications Commission, state utility commissions, and other 
    parties. The Kentucky Commission suggests creating this voluntary Board 
    to develop and review standards for transmission expansion. The Joint 
    Board would include participation from FERC, state commissions, RTOs, 
    and other interested parties. The Joint Board would also convene ad hoc 
    committees to review specific transmission expansion proposals. These 
    committees would include the participants described above, and would 
    include representatives from regulatory commissions in states where the 
    expansion is proposed. The RTO would present the ad hoc committee with 
    a plan for transmission expansion with appropriate documentation for 
    need, cost effectiveness, and alternatives. The committee would in turn 
    pass on its recommendation or refusal of support for the plan to the 
    specific state commissions for their official approval. The Kentucky 
    Commission believes that such an arrangement could avoid Federal/state 
    conflict while allowing both levels of government to exercise 
    appropriate jurisdiction. In addition, ISO-NE points to existing 
    regional regulatory groups such as NECPUC that could continue to 
    provide valuable assistance to the Commission in the collaborative 
    process to encourage RTO formation envisioned in the NOPR.
        Nine Commissions argues that an appropriate regional oversight 
    venue will lead to more consistent treatment of issues and parties 
    between state and Federal regulatory forums. With appropriate deference 
    by both FERC and the states, such a regional venue could
    
    [[Page 938]]
    
    obviate the need for many parties to expend redundant resources to 
    participate in multiple state and Federal regulatory processes for 
    matters relating to transmission and RTOs.
        Nine Commissions notes that one possible mechanism to effectuate 
    such a regional venue is interstate compacts, which are provided for in 
    the Administration's proposed electric industry restructuring 
    legislation. Nine Commissions argues that regional regulatory 
    organizations have the advantage of being able to coordinate state 
    interests for providing regional recommendations to FERC. State 
    oversight functions (e.g. siting, local outages, customer complaints) 
    would not change. According to Nine Commissions, such regional 
    regulatory organizations would provide greater coordination among 
    states within the region, allowing for ADR processes that could satisfy 
    multiple state jurisdictional requirements, and such organizations 
    would monitor markets that have evolved beyond state borders and 
    facilitate joint FERC and multi-state facilities siting.
        Pennsylvania Commission prefers a joint Federal/state approach 
    toward regulating RTO siting approvals, expansion, innovation and 
    customer service. Pennsylvania Commission notes that a joint approach 
    would resolve the vexing problem of Federal/state jurisdictional 
    uncertainty and a joint Federal/state approach would avoid the 
    potential for creative forum shopping by individual stakeholders, who 
    will always seek to cast a dispute in jurisdictional terms so as to 
    dictate a jurisdictional resolution to the perceived favorable outcome. 
    A joint Federal/state approach has been used with success in other 
    areas, such as the Susquehanna River Basin Commission, the Delaware 
    River Basin Commission and the Joint Pipeline Office for the Trans-
    Alaska Pipeline System. Likewise, the Virginia Commission believes that 
    there is no conflict between state goals and Commission goals and that 
    the two levels of government should be able to work together and avoid 
    conflict as long as both parties recognize that the common goal is the 
    public interest.
        Commission Conclusion. We continue to believe that states have 
    important roles to play in RTO matters. For example, most states must 
    approve a utility joining an RTO, and several states have required 
    their utilities to turn over their transmission facilities to an 
    independent transmission operator. Also, states must approve the siting 
    of transmission facilities that are called for in an RTO expansion 
    plan.
        We believe, however, that it is not appropriate to try to set out a 
    full set of states' roles in this Rule. It is difficult, and not 
    necessary, to reach generic conclusions about states' roles given the 
    diversity of possible RTO forms and state authorities. For example, a 
    state's role may be different for an ISO, transco, and other 
    organizational form, and it may be different for a multistate RTO and a 
    single-state RTO, if any. States differ regarding the authorities they 
    have vested in their regulatory and siting agencies. Further, states 
    differ regarding their jurisdiction over municipal and cooperative 
    utility owners of transmission facilities.
        Regional interests forming an RTO should consult with the states 
    about what state roles best fit the agencies' authorities and 
    preferences and the organizational form of the RTO. This role could 
    vary from state to state within an RTO. Therefore, this Rule takes a 
    flexible approach that allows states to play appropriate roles in RTO 
    matters, consistent with this Commission's exclusive responsibilities 
    and authorities under the FPA.
        We note that we have discussed the role of states for particular 
    RTO functions elsewhere in this Final Rule. Regarding RTO formation, 
    the Background discussion above discusses the role that several states 
    played in creating many of the existing ISOs. It also describes our 
    initial consultations with state regulators on RTO formation and our 
    roles in FPA section 202(a) implementation; in those consultations we 
    offered to continue the RTO dialogue with states in the future. The 
    form of consultation to be used should be decided based on the issues 
    and the region so we will not endorse or reject here any particular 
    form of collaboration. However, in the Collaborative Process discussion 
    below, we set out our plans to invite states and others to work with us 
    to foster RTO formation beginning early next year.
        In our discussion above of the Independence characteristic, we 
    discuss the role of state agencies in governance, making the point that 
    states will play a key role in RTO formation and development but 
    declining to specify generically a state's role in governance. Also, in 
    our discussion above of the RTO Planning and Expansion function we 
    recognize the exclusive authority of state and local governments and 
    regulatory agencies over the siting of transmission facilities, and we 
    include in our regulations the standard that an RTO must accommodate 
    efforts by state regulatory commissions to create multi-state 
    agreements to review and approve new transmission facilities.
    8. Accounting Issues
        Although not discussed in the NOPR, EEI commented on some 
    accounting aspects of RTOs. It urges the Commission to address two 
    primary accounting issues for RTOs: (1) The need to revise the Uniform 
    System of Accounts (USofA) and related reports to reflect new RTO and 
    other unbundled rate structures; and (2) the ability of RTOs to use 
    regulatory accounting.
    a. Revision of the Uniform System of Accounts
        Comments. EEI contends that because the Commission's USofA was 
    developed when utilities' products were bundled and fully regulated, it 
    needs to be revised to support the Commission's adopted policies and 
    this proposed rule. EEI believes that with unbundling of rates, the 
    USofA will need to be revised to reflect, among other things,\718\ cost 
    functionalization (e.g., by generation, transmission, distribution, 
    etc.). EEI also believes that the Commission should specifically 
    address the accounting to be used for RTO reporting purposes, as the 
    current USofA was not designed for use by RTOs. EEI states that it is 
    very willing to work with the Commission's staff to address the 
    specific changes that should be made to the USofA.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \718\ Another significant area cited is whether the Commission 
    should modify its original cost accounting requirements for property 
    acquisitions to conform with the evolving fair value requirements of 
    the Financial Accounting Standards Board (FASB). See Appendix I to 
    EEI Comments at 11.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commission Conclusion. The Final Rule permits the various regions 
    to select different organizational forms for RTOs. Our open 
    architecture structure for RTOs permits applicants to select the 
    business organization best suited to the needs of its members and RTO 
    participants. It would therefore be difficult to prescribe in this 
    proceeding specific changes to our existing USofA that would 
    accommodate the needs of all RTOs.
        We believe a better course at this juncture would be to require 
    RTOs to conform their accounting to our USofA (as have ISOs) and to 
    submit questions of doubtful interpretation to the Commission for 
    individual or generic rulings on particular transactions, events and 
    circumstances.
        However, we agree with EEI's observation that unbundling of utility 
    services, and other changes in the industry require the Commission to 
    re-examine its existing accounting and related reporting requirements. 
    This is true not only for the new types of utilities that have emerged 
    in the industry such as ISOs, PXs and RTOs,
    
    [[Page 939]]
    
    but also for traditional public utilities. The Commission staff has 
    been and will continue to meet with EEI and others, and will continue 
    its efforts to address the specific changes that may be needed as the 
    industry restructures.
    b. Ability to Use Special Accounting
        Comments. EEI asks the Commission to consider the impact of its 
    actions on the ability of RTOs to use the special accounting rules 
    applicable to cost-based rate-regulated entities.\719\ EEI believes 
    that the ability to use regulated accounting would be advantageous to 
    RTOs and viewed favorably by the investment community.\720\ EEI urges 
    the Commission to structure alternative ratemaking methods (e.g., price 
    and revenue caps, incentive-based rates and price indexing) to allow 
    RTOs to continue to use the special accounting of SFAS 71. In this 
    regard, EEI believes that if the Commission decides it is advantageous 
    to stimulate the establishment of RTOs by ensuring that all start-up 
    costs are ultimately recovered through FERC jurisdictional rates, it 
    could issue ratemaking orders that defer expense recognition of these 
    costs, and allow for future ratemaking recovery. Similarly, EEI urges 
    the Commission to address the time frame over which software 
    development costs could be recovered through rates and to allow 
    utilities to defer expense recognition of such costs. To enhance cash 
    flows from operations, EEI suggests that the Commission accelerate the 
    amortization of all capitalized software costs. These actions, 
    according to EEI, would likely be viewed favorably by the investment 
    community.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \719\ The special accounting rules are primarily contained in 
    Statement of Financial Accounting Standards No. 71, Accounting for 
    the Effects of Certain Types of Regulation (SFAS 71). One of the 
    primary accounting differences is the ability to defer expense 
    recognition of an incurred cost if it is probable that the utility 
    will recover that cost in future cost-based regulated rates.
        \720\ Conversely, according to EEI, the inability of an entity 
    to use SFAS 71 accounting could have an adverse effect on earnings, 
    which may be viewed unfavorably by investors. According to EEI, one 
    example would be where the Commission approves a rate levelization 
    plan (e.g., under capital lease transactions) under which rate 
    recovery of certain costs would be deferred until future years. If a 
    utility could not defer expense recognition of such costs, earnings 
    would be depressed in the early years of the levelization plan.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commission Conclusion. RTOs may propose and we are willing to 
    consider alternative ratemaking methods including proposals to delay 
    rate recovery of certain expenses. We will not prescribe any specific 
    requirements at this time but allow RTOs to propose those methods which 
    are appropriate for each RTO's facts and circumstances. In this regard, 
    we intend to take a flexible regulatory approach toward approving RTO 
    rate design proposals and strive to include adequate information in our 
    rate orders on the appropriate accounting treatments.
    9. Market Design Lessons
        We expect that bid-based markets will be a central feature in many 
    RTO proposals. To date, the Commission has analyzed and approved, with 
    various modifications, bid-based market designs for four ISOs. The 
    purpose of this section is to summarize the lessons learned from these 
    real-world market experiments. The summary provided below is not 
    intended to favor one market design over another, but is intended to 
    assist RTOs in evaluating existing market designs and meeting the 
    deadlines set forth in this rule.\721\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \721\ The Commission has already given considerable guidance on 
    numerous market design issues in a number of orders. See 
    Pennsylvania-New Jersey-Maryland Interconnection, L.L.C., 81 FERC 
    para. 61,257 (1997); Central Hudson Gas & Electric Corp., et al. 86 
    FERC para. 61,062 (1999); New England Power Pool, et al. 87 FERC 
    para. 61,045 (1999); AES Redondo Beach, et al., 87 FERC ] 61,208 
    (1999).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Cal ISO, PJM and ISO-NE have had operational experience with their 
    respective market designs. For the most part the markets operated by 
    these ISOs have functioned well, and they have not experienced many of 
    the problems encountered in the bilateral markets in the Midwest and 
    the Southeast.\722\ However, each of the operational ISOs has 
    encountered some market design problems that have resulted in 
    unexpected or undesirable market outcomes.\723\ These outcomes have led 
    some ISOs to file many market design changes and requests for temporary 
    remedies or protections until permanent design changes can be 
    implemented.\724\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \722\ See Staff Report to the Federal Energy Regulatory 
    Commission on the Causes of Wholesale Electric Pricing Abnormalities 
    in the Midwest During June 1998 (September 28, 1998).
        \723\ The NY ISO has had little operational experience with the 
    particulars of its markets design.
        \724\ See New England Power Pool, et al., 87 FERC para. 61,055 
    (1999); AES Redondo Beach, et al., 87 FERC 61,208 (1999); New York 
    Independent System Operator, Inc. et al., 88 FERC para. 61,228 
    (1999).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    a. Multiple Product Markets
        The bid-based markets that we have approved to date are premised on 
    the assumption that acceptance of voluntary supply and demand bids 
    which maximize overall net benefits will also maximize efficiency. Each 
    approved ISO design employs some bid-based mechanism to ramp resources 
    up and down to balance the system, manage congestion, and to supply 
    some ancillary services. Employing bids that indicate a generator's 
    willingness to be ramped down, ramped up, or placed in reserve is an 
    economic way to balance the system, manage congestion and maintain 
    appropriate reserves, both in real time and in any day-ahead markets. 
    However, if more than one product is being sold in the same temporal 
    market,\725\ efficiency is maximized when arbitrage opportunities 
    reflected in the bids are exhausted (i.e., after the RTO's markets have 
    cleared, no technically qualified market participant would have 
    preferred to be in another of the RTO's markets). In addition, 
    efficient bid-based markets elicit prices that are consistent with 
    technical and cost requirements.\726\ For example, a situation where 
    generating units are paid more for not generating than for generating 
    as has happened in ISO-NE and the Cal ISO may be an indication of an 
    inefficient market.\727\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \725\ For example, energy and operating reserve products may be 
    offered in real-time.
        \726\ One would expect that services with more stringent 
    technical requirements ordinarily have higher costs for providing 
    those services. The prices of these services should reflect the 
    costs. For example, spinning reserves have more stringent 
    requirements and would be expected to command a higher price than 
    non-spinning reserves.
        \727\ See Report of the Market Surveillance Committee of the 
    California Independent System Operator, October 18, 1999 (MSC 
    October Report). Both ISOs have seen prices for services such as 
    non-spinning reserve products, which do not require a unit to be 
    running, higher than the energy price. Also, according to the Market 
    Surveillance Committee (MSC) of the Cal ISO, market participants 
    have an incentive to submit schedules that will cause congestion so 
    that their units can be called upon to relieve the congestion and 
    receive payments for not generating that are greater than payments 
    received for generating.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    b. Physical Feasibility
        Proper design of the market clearing procedures ensures that prices 
    balance the supply and demand for energy, and all transactions, in the 
    aggregate, are physically feasible with appropriate levels of reserves. 
    Some market designs have allowed ISOs to accept schedules that have not 
    been physically feasible (e.g., Cal ISO), while other ISO market 
    designs include mechanisms to ensure the physical feasibility of 
    transactions (e.g., the NY ISO and PJM). Some ISOs have encountered 
    instances where transmission constraints have prevented the use of 
    needed reserves,\728\ and this is inconsistent with the operator's 
    obligation to make certain that reserve requirements are met and that 
    reserves, along with necessary transmission, are available to respond 
    appropriately to contingencies.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \728\ See MSC October Report, at 67, 74-75.
    
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [[Page 940]]
    
    c. Access to Real-Time Balancing Market
        Real-time balancing refers to the moment-to-moment matching of 
    loads and generation on a system-wide basis. Real-time balancing is 
    usually achieved through the direct control of select generators (and, 
    in some cases, loads) that increase or decrease their output (or 
    consumption in the case of loads) in response to instructions from the 
    system operator. Over the last several years, the Commission has seen 
    an increasing use by system operators of market mechanisms that rely on 
    bids from generators to achieve, overall, real-time balancing. In order 
    to maintain system balance, the operator also manages congestion while 
    maintaining the appropriate level of reserves. It is expected that any 
    RTO balancing markets will be available to all grid users, i.e., 
    including individual grid users that engage in bilateral transactions. 
    The fact that the overall system must be in balance moment-to-moment 
    does not mean that there must be a moment-to-moment balance between the 
    specific load and resources involved in individual bilateral 
    transactions. Making a real-time balancing market available to all grid 
    users ensures that all users are treated equally for purposes of 
    settling their individual imbalances. The four operating ISOs approved 
    by the Commission already operate such markets.
    d. Market Participation
        Markets are most efficient when generators and loads, whether 
    internal or external to the RTO, are allowed full and flexible 
    participation in the markets. While generators and loads have the 
    option to choose between participating in any RTO-facilitated markets 
    or other markets, the RTO must have generation and ancillary service 
    quantity information, and any necessary technical information, from 
    self-schedulers in order to balance the system and ensure reliability. 
    This allows bilateral and forward financial markets and independent PX 
    markets to co-exist and complement RTO physical markets. Participants 
    that self-schedule would be expected to pay for the costs that they 
    impose on the physical system at market prices and be paid for the 
    benefits that they supply to the physical system at market prices.\729\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \729\ Costs and benefits associated with self-schedules are 
    congestion costs created by the transaction or congestion relief 
    that the transaction makes possible.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Unnecessary constraints on the imports of services can lead to 
    increases in price volatility due to thin markets.\730\ Allowing 
    exports will give generators flexibility to take advantage of 
    opportunities outside of the RTO boundaries, while allowing load 
    serving entities external to the RTO a chance to purchase services. 
    Broadening market participation deepens the market and enhances overall 
    efficiency.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \730\ Thin markets refers to a situation in which the amount bid 
    into the market is either not enough to match demand, or just enough 
    to match demand.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    e. Demand-Side Bidding
        Existing ISO markets offer generators flexible participation, but 
    they often do not offer customers demand-side bidding options. Demand-
    side bidding is desirable to the extent it is technically feasible, 
    because without it, demand response decreases and market power is 
    easier to exercise.\731\ The availability of price responsive demand 
    also reduces price volatility in the markets.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \731\ The flexibility of demand-side bidding may be limited 
    unless real-time meters are installed. Otherwise, demand-side 
    bidding can simply take the form of interruptible load.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    f. Bidding Rules
        A market that provides the flexibility for all generators to bid a 
    reasonable approximation of the costs they incur including start-up, 
    minimum load, energy, and ramping costs will be efficient. Whether it 
    is cost-effective to start up a generator and make it available for 
    dispatch depends on the prices and scheduled quantities over the 
    multiple hours and services for which the generator is committed, not 
    on the prices in any single hour or for any single service. Allowing 
    participants to bid these costs helps provide for a more efficient 
    dispatch of generating units to meet load and other services, because 
    it allows the start-up decisions underlying the dispatch schedules to 
    be based on prices and quantities for a period greater than a single 
    hour. Not permitting start-up and minimum load bids can reduce 
    efficiency because the decision to start up and dispatch generators is 
    made separately for each hour, resulting in start up decisions that can 
    cause losses for generators. Also, when the start-up and minimum load 
    bids are submitted along with minimum run and down times, generators 
    are ensured that they will not be dispatched in a way that is 
    physically damaging to the unit.
    g. Transaction Costs and Risk
        Transaction costs associated with participation in well functioning 
    RTO markets should be low, and market participation should involve no 
    unnecessary risks. For example, in sequentially clearing markets, 
    bidders are exposed to the risk that they may be chosen in one of the 
    markets that clears first, yet would have preferred to have been chosen 
    in a market that cleared later. In order to hedge against such risks, 
    bidders may undertake expensive and time consuming bid preparation 
    strategies to decrease the likelihood that such profitable 
    opportunities would be missed.
    h. Price Recalculations
        In some instances, it may be necessary to post prices on a 
    preliminary basis while the final price calculations are verified. For 
    example, in ISO-NE, the computer algorithms generate new dispatch 
    points every five minutes, and preliminary market clearing prices are 
    based on these dispatch algorithms. However, the actual dispatch 
    instructions are issued manually. In circumstances where time does not 
    permit all changes in dispatch to be communicated and effected through 
    manual processes in a timely manner, the market clearing price 
    resulting from the computer algorithm must be adjusted to reflect the 
    actual dispatch in the hour.\732\ While an RTO must ensure that the 
    final market clearing prices are correct, market clearing procedures 
    should minimize price recalculations. Also, any price recalculation 
    should be done quickly. Otherwise, market participants could incur 
    large transaction costs in attempts to hedge against such risk. Risk 
    exposure can be further reduced if market participants can engage in 
    bilateral transactions, or participate in other markets, to lock in 
    prices prior to participating in the RTO-facilitated markets.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \732\ See ISO New England, Internal Review of Operations, June 
    7-8, 1999, Report issued August 20, 1999. Electronic dispatch is 
    under consideration in ISO-NE.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    i. Multi-Settlement Markets
        Multi-settlement markets may involve a day-ahead and real-time 
    market. For real-time markets, prices are determined by real-time 
    dispatch quantities, and deviations from day-ahead schedules are priced 
    at the real-time price. When day-ahead schedules are financially 
    binding, they are financial commitments subject to payments for 
    deviations at the real-time price. If market participants adhere to 
    day-ahead schedules, they need not participate in the real-time 
    markets. If needed for reliability, bids need to be physically binding 
    and may be subject to Commission-approved penalties for failure to 
    adhere to the bid. Without financially binding commitments in the day-
    ahead market, the riskiness of market participation
    
    [[Page 941]]
    
    increases since the day-ahead bids could be changed before real-time 
    dispatch. If bids for ancillary services are accepted, the accepted 
    capacity must be physically ready to meet reliability commitments when 
    called upon. The lack of a physical capacity commitment has been a 
    problem in some ISOs.
    j. Preventing Abusive Market Power
        An efficient market design does not favor market participants that 
    have the potential to exercise market power and minimizes the 
    incentives for market participants to engage in abuse of market power. 
    For example, since large players are more likely to cause market power 
    problems, a market design that favors large players (e.g., portfolio 
    bidding \733\) may create an incentive for consolidation and resulting 
    market power problems. Fewer restrictions on imports of services will 
    help guard against thin markets, which in turn will help mitigate 
    market power. ISO's have experienced problems with thin markets, and 
    easing restrictions on imports should help.\734\ Also, artificially 
    segmenting a product market into separate geographic markets for the 
    same product can also create additional price volatility and 
    opportunities for the exercise of market power.\735\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \733\ Portfolio bidding refers to bids that aggregate all 
    generating units under the same ownership. This is in contrast to 
    generation owners bidding in each unit separately.
        \734\ Report of the Market Surveillance Committee of the 
    California Independent System Operator, August 19, 1998 at 35-36 
    (MSC August Report).
        \735\ The Cal ISO at one time segmented their product markets 
    into separate geographic markets that corresponded to the defined 
    congestion zones even when no congestion existed. It has since 
    reformed this practice. See MSC August Report, at 32-33.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        If market participants are allowed to submit bids which can then be 
    changed before financial settlements are completed, these non-binding 
    bids can be used as a signaling device to facilitate collusive 
    behavior.
    k. Market Information and Market Monitoring
        One property of an efficient market has market clearing prices and 
    quantities being made available immediately. This information enables 
    market participants and potential future market participants to assess 
    the market and plan their businesses efficiently. It will also allow 
    market participants to spot errors in the market clearing process and 
    get them corrected.
        Disclosure of individual bids could be made eventually, but not 
    immediately. Such disclosures will allow detection of market design and 
    implementation flaws, and allow study of the market by independent 
    analysts and market participants. It may lead to the exposure of the 
    exercise of market power. To detect the withholding of capacity, a 
    simple screen is to provide the output, reserve quantities, and maximum 
    capacity of each generator. Immediate disclosure of individual bids is 
    undesirable because it might facilitate collusion by the market 
    participants. It also might affect the bids of market participants who 
    wish to keep their costs confidential. However, after six months or a 
    year, the information on individual bids has essentially no value for 
    collusion and discloses little new information about any bidder's 
    current costs. Nonetheless, the information's value for market 
    monitoring remains high.\736\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \736\ The Commission approved the disclosure of bid information 
    in the following orders. See PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., 86 FERC 
    para. 61,247 at 61,890, order on reh'g, 88 FERC para. 61,274 (1999); 
    Central Hudson Gas & Electric Corp. et al. 86 FERC para. 61,062 at 
    61,204, order on reh'g, 88 FERC para. 61,138 (1999).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    l. Prices and Cost Averaging
        Market designs that base prices on the averaging or socialization 
    of costs,\737\ may distort consumption, production, and investment 
    decisions and ultimately lead to economically inefficient outcomes. 
    Where possible and cost effective, cost causality principles can be 
    used to price services and eliminate averaging.\738\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \737\ Socialization of costs means that costs that could be 
    assigned to a particular market participant(s) are instead spread 
    over all participants regardless of whether or not they caused the 
    costs.
        \738\ While it is desirable from an efficiency standpoint to 
    eliminate the averaging of costs, the costs associated with 
    calculating cost causation in some instances could be shown to 
    outweigh the benefits of eliminating averaging.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        For example, in some congestion management mechanisms, the cost of 
    alleviating congestion is spread over all loads. This scheme could have 
    some generators creating monetary benefits for other generators. In 
    addition, it could lead to over-consumption of power by some loads and 
    under-consumption by other loads. Moreover, such averaging mechanisms 
    for congestion management do not send the correct price signals for the 
    location of new generation, thus leading to problems with long-term 
    implications.\739\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \739\ MSC October Report, at 112.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Moreover, if pass-throughs or uplift charges are paid by all load 
    to ensure bid-cost recovery, as in some approved ISO market designs, it 
    may be appropriate to couple these pricing mechanisms with incentive 
    mechanisms for the RTO to control them.
    
    I. Collaborative Process
    
        The Commission proposed a regional collaborative process to 
    facilitate the creation of RTOs. State commissions had encouraged the 
    Commission to sponsor activities in each region of the country that 
    will bring together representatives of public and private electric 
    utilities, state regulators, consumer groups, representatives from 
    Canada or Mexico, as appropriate, and any other interested parties that 
    need to be part of such a process. The Commission proposed that 
    regional workshops be held after the Final Rule is issued to determine 
    what, if any, impediments exist to the formation of RTOs in a 
    particular region and how the Commission staff could help to overcome 
    those impediments. Staff resources that will be available for the 
    collaborative process include technical staff, dispute resolution 
    staff, and any other staff assistance that would be beneficial.
        Comments. Almost all commenters support the Commission's 
    collaborative proposal. Of the 49 comments that addressed this issue, 
    47 are generally supportive. These commenters include a number of state 
    commissions.\740\ In addition, NARUC supports the continuation of a 
    ``dynamic process requiring continuing dialogue between FERC and the 
    states.'' A number of public power entities also support the 
    process.\741\ Numerous Canadian entities also filed comments regarding 
    the usefulness of a collaborative process for the international aspects 
    of RTO formation.\742\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \740\ See, e.g., Nine Commissions, Illinois Commission, Indiana 
    Commission, Michigan Commission, Montana Commission, Nevada 
    Commission, South Carolina Commission, Wisconsin Commission and 
    Wyoming Commission.
        \741\ See, e.g., APPA, NRECA, CMUA, SRP, Snohomish, Seattle, 
    RUS, East Texas Cooperatives, IMEA, and Arkansas Cities.
        \742\ See, e.g., Powerex, BC Hydro and Canada DNR.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Only Florida Commission and CP&L are not fully supportive. Florida 
    Commission suggests that FERC collaboration will not work in Florida 
    but may work in other regions of the country. CP&L is not supportive 
    because the collaborative process could be used by the Commission ``as 
    a means of forcing utilities to develop RTO proposals on the 
    Commission's timetable'' which results in the Commission ``being 
    disingenuous when it describes its RTO policy as `voluntary'.'' 
    Otherwise, CP&L believes the conferences will only serve as an 
    opportunity for participants to ``posture'' and that limited Commission 
    resources should not be used for
    
    [[Page 942]]
    
    meetings that ``are not likely to produce positive results.''
        Specific comments about the collaborative process address three 
    basic issues: inclusiveness, process and procedures, and outcomes.
        Inclusiveness. The NOPR stated that ``the Commission expects public 
    utilities and non-public utilities, in coordination with appropriate 
    state officials, and affected interest groups in a region to fully 
    participate in working to develop an RTO.'' It further stated that the 
    regional public workshops will be convened in cooperation with the 
    affected state officials and that transmission owners and operators 
    will be invited.
        Many commenters advocate an open collaborative process that would 
    include a full complement of participants. They suggest that the 
    regional meetings include representatives of all stakeholders, for-
    profit transmission companies, not-for-profit transmission entities, 
    state regulators, state legislators, state Governors, state energy 
    officials, state and non-state consumer advocates, state economic and 
    environmental regulators, environmental action interests and public 
    power/municipals. Some commenters indicate that in certain regional 
    efforts to form an RTO, the deliberations have excluded key interests 
    and, as a result, the outcomes were not widely supported. For example, 
    PJM/NEPOOL Customers note with respect to the PJM formation process 
    that ``[O]nly after all stakeholders were included in organizational 
    discussions was true progress made toward implementing an ISO that 
    adequately addresses all parties' needs.'' PNGC states that ``[I]f 
    other users do not have a seat at the table while merchant functions 
    do, obviously a level playing field is not created.'' New Orleans cites 
    Entergy's ``failure to even attempt to build a regional consensus 
    concerning its transco as a reason that inclusive regional conferences 
    are needed.''
        Process and Procedures. Commenters raise a number of questions 
    regarding the collaborative process and specifically with respect to 
    the regional public workshops. Many commenters support the use/
    availability of the Commission's Dispute Resolution Service (DRS) staff 
    or the use of outside facilitators. Some commenters request that the 
    Commission clarify that the meetings will be open meetings that can be 
    attended by any person. Several commenters urge the Commission to take 
    the cost and travel time to attend meetings into account in planning 
    the regional public workshops. Some specific locations are suggested 
    for sites for the regional workshops: New Orleans, Minneapolis/St. 
    Paul, and Seattle or Portland.
        Several commenters suggest that the collaborative process begin 
    prior to spring 2000 in at least one region of the country--the Upper 
    Midwest. Commenters suggest that there is no need to wait and that the 
    region would benefit by immediate assistance from Commission staff as 
    described in the NOPR.
        Some commenters ask the Commission to be mindful that the number of 
    regional meetings scheduled may not only be costly but unproductive as 
    well. Two commenters specifically say that we must not allow the 
    ``death by meetings'' syndrome to be realized. Some interests may want 
    to stall RTO formation by promoting an ``endless'' series of meetings 
    that are not productive but are designed to ``preserve the status 
    quo.'' A few commenters suggest that the role of Commission staff at 
    the regional events should not be that of meeting referee but primarily 
    to provide policy guidance on key RTO issues and proposals. NRECA 
    proposes the creation of several Commission staff teams to ``facilitate 
    and informally monitor each RTO formation process'' and provide 
    ``neutral guidance'' in the regions. Some commenters ask that the 
    Commission establish procedural rules in writing in advance of the 
    regional workshops so that all parties will know and understand the 
    rules prior to the meetings. Some commenters also request that all 
    reports, information and data produced for the meetings be readily 
    available to all participants.
        Outcomes. The Project Groups suggest that the Commission should 
    ``clearly delineate the substantive results expected'' from the 
    collaborative process. They suggest that collaboration progress reports 
    be filed with the Commission and that ``work products'' be required, 
    including: (1) Identification of RTO boundaries; (2) a list of all 
    transmission owners and facilities in the region; (3) a draft operating 
    agreement; (4) a draft governance structure and bylaws; (5) proposed 
    operating protocols; (6) a proposed budget/financial structure; (7) a 
    draft tariff; and (8) how the proposals meet the Commission's 
    guidelines, including a timetable.
        Commission Conclusion. A key element of this Final Rule is our 
    commitment to the use of the collaborative process to assist in the 
    voluntary formation of RTOs. By collaborative process, we mean a 
    process whereby transmission owners, market participants, interest 
    groups, and governmental officials can attempt to reach mutual 
    agreement on how best to establish RTOs in their respective regions. We 
    reiterate our commitment of Commission staff resources, to the extent 
    possible, to assist parties in developing RTO proposals.
        We are encouraged that state Commissions, public utilities, public 
    power entities and cooperative utilities, power marketing interests, 
    and consumer and environmental groups support the use of a 
    collaborative process. We are further encouraged that efforts to 
    develop RTOs continue in the West and Midwest, and that other areas are 
    reviewing the potential benefits of RTOs in their respective areas. We 
    believe that this represents a growing recognition throughout the 
    nation that RTOs will improve competition in electric markets and 
    enhance the reliability of the nation's electric grid.
        We welcome participation in the RTO collaborative process by our 
    sovereign neighbors, Canada and Mexico. We believe that it is in our 
    mutual best interest to have electricity flow efficiently and 
    economically across our international boundaries. We pledge to continue 
    to work cooperatively with officials from Canada and Mexico to 
    encourage the operation and improvement of an international electric 
    system that benefits all consumers.
        The Commission believes that the collaborative process must 
    accommodate the fact that different regions of the country are in 
    different stages of RTO formation and must be flexible enough to allow 
    for these differences. Therefore, we will initiate the collaborative 
    process with a series of five workshops in the Spring of 2000. The 
    primary objective of each workshop will be to develop a consensus 
    agreement by regional participants establishing a strategic process and 
    a schedule for any further collaboration. The appropriate collaboration 
    process will depend on whether the region is considering formation of 
    an ISO, transco, or other form of RTO. To achieve this objective, 
    participants will share information about the status of RTOs or RTO 
    proposals in the region, identify impediments to RTO formation in the 
    area, explore which process(es) could most expeditiously advance 
    agreements on RTO formation, and determine what role(s), if any, 
    Commission staff should play in advancing discussions in each region. 
    One result of these discussions may be regional decisions that more 
    than one RTO would be appropriate in the area encompassed by 
    participants at the workshop. Therefore, the collaborative
    
    [[Page 943]]
    
    processes that follow the various workshops may differ significantly. 
    This includes possible variations in the role that will be played by 
    Commission staff in each RTO formation effort.
        The Commission believes that regional workshops in the Spring of 
    2000 will expedite the RTO formation process. In selecting locations 
    for the initial Spring 2000 workshops, we recognize trends in the 
    broader regionalization of the nation's electric system. We also 
    consider the evolving electric markets as well as the configuration of 
    the regional grid. We emphasize that the selection of locations for 
    initial workshops is not to indicate a preference for specific RTO 
    boundaries, but to provide convenient workshop locations. With these 
    considerations in mind, we designate the following workshop locations. 
    Parties may attend more than one regional workshop. We expect all 
    transmission owners to attend at least one workshop.
        Workshops will be held in the following cities in February, March 
    or April, 2000:
    
    1. Philadelphia, Pennsylvania
    2. Cincinnati, Ohio
    3. Atlanta, Georgia
    4. Kansas City, Missouri
    5. Las Vegas, Nevada
    
        Workshops are expected to last for two days. Additional information 
    about the regional workshops will be provided in January 2000.
        At the request of parties, the Commission staff may play a role in 
    the formation of RTOs. Commission staff will convene the regional RTO 
    workshops and provide policy and technical guidance consistent with 
    this rule. The Commission will supply meeting space for the five 
    initial Spring 2000 workshops. Regional participants are expected to 
    bear the costs of collaborative meetings after the initial five 
    workshops. Commission staff time and staff travel expenses will be 
    provided as resources allow.
        We believe that it is critical to make the Spring 2000 Workshop 
    phase of the collaborative process open to all interested parties. In 
    order to promote an open process, we will provide public notice of 
    Spring 2000 Workshop events to allow all interested parties to attend. 
    We shall also make available agendas and procedural rules to all 
    parties in advance of the regional workshops. Agendas may vary from one 
    workshop to another.
        The Spring 2000 Workshops represent the initial step of the 
    collaborative process. We expect that other meetings will be convened 
    following the workshops by parties in each region to bring the parties 
    together to form an RTO in each region. Commission staff may also 
    convene additional meetings if this would help RTO formation. The post-
    workshop meetings of parties in regions may be held with or without 
    Commission staff participation. We will make available the Commission's 
    Alternative Dispute Resolution staff upon the request of an RTO group 
    in formation. At the request of such a group, independent private 
    professional facilitation services may be arranged by Commission staff 
    and must be sponsored by the parties within the region. As needed and 
    requested by parties forming an RTO in a region, Commission staff 
    members will be available to act as settlement judges, mediators, 
    facilitators or observers.
        We believe that the best interests of the nation's electric 
    consumers will be served by the formation of RTOs. Therefore, we 
    encourage parties to establish strategic schedules at the Spring 2000 
    Workshops and to convene subsequent meetings with the goal of forming 
    an RTO expeditiously. Commission staff will monitor progress with 
    respect to the results or outcomes in each region.
        We expect that, following the initial Commission-sponsored 
    workshops, parties in each region will work collaboratively to identify 
    the appropriate RTO regions, identify all transmission owners and 
    facilities in each region, and develop a timely application in 
    accordance with the Final Rule.
        We have designated James Apperson of the Commission Staff to serve 
    as the collaborative process contact. He may be contacted at (202) 219-
    2962 with any questions or comments about the RTO collaborative 
    process.
    
    J. Implementation Issues
    
    1. Filing Requirements
        In the NOPR, the Commission proposed that all public utilities that 
    own, operate or control interstate transmission facilities (except 
    those already participating in a regional transmission entity in 
    conformance with the eleven ISO principles enumerated in Order No. 888) 
    must file with the Commission by October 15, 2000 either (1) a proposal 
    to participate in an RTO that will be operational no later than 
    December 15, 2001, or (2) an alternative filing describing efforts to 
    participate in an RTO, obstacles to RTO participation, and any plans 
    and timetable for future efforts.\743\ For those public utilities that 
    file an RTO proposal on or before October 15, 2000, we proposed to 
    permit them to file a petition for a declaratory order asking whether a 
    proposed transmission entity that would be operational by December 15, 
    2001, would qualify as an RTO, with a description of the organization 
    and operational structure, a list of the intended participants of the 
    institution, an explanation of how the institution would satisfy each 
    of the RTO minimum characteristics and functions, and a commitment to 
    submit necessary FPA section 203, 205 and 206 filings promptly after 
    receiving the Commission's determination on the declaratory order 
    petition. Finally, we proposed that the requirements not apply to a 
    public utility that owns, operates or controls transmission that also 
    is a member of an existing transmission entity that the Commission has 
    found to be in conformance with the Order No. 888 eleven ISO 
    principles; instead, each such public utility would be required to make 
    a filing no later than January 15, 2001, that (1) explains the extent 
    to which the transmission entity in which it participates meets the 
    minimum characteristics and functions of an RTO; (2) proposes to modify 
    the existing institution to become an RTO; or (3) explain efforts, 
    obstacles and plans with respect to conforming to these characteristics 
    and functions.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \743\ FERC Stats. & Regs para. 32,541 at 33,761-63.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments. Most commenters responding on this issue oppose one or 
    more aspects of the proposed filing requirements. For example, a number 
    of public utilities and two state commissions argue that the October 
    15, 2000, filing requirement does not provide enough time. Southern 
    Company contends that the proposed filing deadline requirement is 
    likely to be counterproductive because it imposes an artificial 
    deadline that may interfere with regional discussions. Moreover, once 
    established, a prematurely formed RTO may itself prove to be an 
    obstacle to more effective transmission organizations. Southern Company 
    also claims that the proposed mandatory filing requirements are 
    inconsistent with a truly voluntary approach. If the requirement is 
    retained, Southern Company suggests that the Commission clarify that 
    the alternative filings will be treated as status reports and not be 
    subject to deficiency orders or otherwise lead to proceedings in which 
    punitive measures might be taken, because any consideration or use of 
    penalties seriously undermines the Commission commitment to the 
    voluntary nature of RTOs.
        Wyoming Commission recommends that the deadlines not be made
    
    [[Page 944]]
    
    mandatory in any way in the Final Rule because RTO formation is 
    supposed to be voluntary. Since it is unclear as to what happens to 
    those entities who file an explanation as to why they did not join an 
    RTO, Wyoming Commission urges the Commission to defer to each region's 
    process and timetable in developing an RTO and acknowledge that not all 
    regions are processing at the same pace. It recommends that the 
    Commission convert the October 15, 2000, deadline into a milepost for 
    reporting RTO development.
        CP&L submits that the time frame is unrealistic because it 
    contemplates that new RTOs can be developed, approved by the 
    Commission, set up, and begin operation in less than two years. 
    Experience has shown that almost every RTO to date has taken at least 
    four years to go through that process. Therefore, the Commission should 
    modify the filing requirements to simply require informational filings 
    on the status of RTO development.
        Sierra Pacific is concerned about insufficient time being allowed 
    for transcos to form. It points out that the precedent regarding ISOs 
    is much more well-developed than that regarding transcos. The certainty 
    surrounding ISOs makes them more attractive particularly when a 
    decision to form the entity must be made relatively quickly to meet the 
    proposed October 15, 2000, filing date. To lessen the incentive to rush 
    to join an ISO, Sierra Pacific suggests that: (1) The date for filing 
    an RTO proposal should be extended to June 15, 2002; (2) the Commission 
    permit transition mechanisms that will allow transmission owners to 
    eventually join transcos; and (3) the Commission not require 
    participation in an ISO to become a trap from which a transmission 
    owner cannot extricate itself. ComEd provides supporting arguments, 
    noting that where divestiture of transmission assets is involved to 
    form transcos, the necessary transition period will largely be dictated 
    by the sheer complexity--legal, financial (bonds and mortgage), real 
    estate (titles/easements), taxation--of separating a designated portion 
    of any electric utility that has historically been a vertically 
    integrated utility.
        Based on its experience with the Midwest ISO formation process, 
    Kentucky Commission also argues that the proposed date to join an RTO 
    or respond with reasons for not joining is too short. It points out 
    that, if the Commission completes the Final Rule by the end of 1999, 
    transmission owners will have less than one year to make a final 
    decision on participation. Kentucky Commission urges the Commission to 
    give transmission owning utilities additional time to look into joining 
    an RTO, so that RTOs are not pushed so quickly that the best model 
    fails to materialize as a result of market evolution that remains 
    underway. South Carolina Commission and Big Rivers share the concern 
    that the proposed timeframe is too ambitious, given the complexity of 
    RTO related matters and the need to reach some level of consensus among 
    those with vested interests.
        Several commenters noted that meeting the October 15, 2000, filing 
    requirement will depend on the Commission's standard of review of those 
    filings. For example, TDU Systems observes that the proposed filing 
    requirements have no teeth. TDU Systems contends that a public utility 
    that decides not to participate in an RTO can make an alternative 
    filing setting out the reasons why it is not doing so and what plans it 
    has to work towards participation. In TDU Systems' view, while the 
    proposed regulations are consistent with voluntary participation, they 
    are inconsistent with full and effective participation in RTOs. TDU 
    Systems counsels that the Commission should resist calls to water down 
    the RTO regulations even more, so as to treat alternative filings as 
    mere status reports that allow transmission monopolists to hold on to 
    their monopolies.
        Duke submits that if the Commission is willing to accept valid, 
    well-justified explanations as to why a utility has not become an RTO 
    member, the October 15, 2000, filing requirement is reasonable, noting 
    that until state commission review of restructuring and RTOs is 
    completed, it may be premature for a utility to commit resources to RTO 
    membership. Similarly, Iowa Board suggests that, where transmission 
    providers are making legitimate progress, a report to that effect 
    should not be received with automatic disfavor. Alternative filings and 
    legitimate progress reports should be given equal validity with 
    definitive proposal filings.
        A few commenters explicitly support the October 15, 2000, filing 
    requirements. For example, SRP believes it to be an acceptable balance 
    between mandated participation and the status quo. PJM/NEPOOL Customers 
    also support the filing by a date certain because this would expedite 
    the collaborative process and ensure that no entity can effectively 
    block RTO formation by engaging in inappropriate negotiation tactics. 
    And Oglethorpe views the October 15, 2000, time frame as necessary to 
    assure the timely development of RTOs and help develop fully 
    competitive efficient wholesale markets. Cinergy, noting that only 
    after the Commission has had opportunity to review the October 15, 
    2000, filings will it be able to determine whether it should order 
    participation in or reconfiguration of particular RTOs, suggests that 
    by April 15, 2000, all public utilities be required to file a statement 
    of position in which each utility identifies each state in which it 
    owns transmission, and the RTO in which it is considering membership 
    and its potential scope and configuration to the best of its knowledge.
        A number of commenters address issues and treatments relating to 
    existing ISOs. Virtually all of the existing ISOs assert that the 
    Commission should allow the previously Approved ISOs to continue to 
    develop without undue interference in order to foster experimentation 
    and testing of proposals.\744\ Cal ISO argues that the Commission 
    should find that existing regional entities generally meet the RTO 
    criteria and that the Commission should confirm its determination not 
    to require substantial changes in approved ISOs that would undermine 
    difficult to reach consensus on critical issues. Similarly, the 
    Pennsylvania and New York Commissions recommend that FERC grandfather 
    the existing ISOs that meet the RTO characteristics and functions. The 
    Pennsylvania Commission states that it does not want to tinker with the 
    inner workings of PJM, nor constantly revisit and revise operations and 
    functions. The New York Commission is concerned that the New York ISO 
    tariff may have to incorporate the ``ordinary negligence'' liability 
    and indemnification provisions set forth in the pro forma tariff if the 
    ISO becomes qualified as an RTO, and that this will increase the ISO's 
    exposure to litigation. The South Carolina Commission supports NARUC's 
    position urging the Commission to grandfather existing ISO boundaries 
    that are satisfactory to the states. Similarly American Forest, CalPX 
    and Mid-Atlantic Commissions want the Commission to respect existing 
    ISOs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \744\ See, e.g., NY ISO, Cal ISO, NYPP and ISO-NE.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Furthermore, PJM/NEPOOL Customers contend that their ISOs are in 
    basic conformance with the minimum functions and characteristics. To 
    the extent that any deficiencies are found, the ISOs should be allowed 
    to engage in continued experimentation without interference from the 
    Commission. The Wyoming Commission also fails to see why existing ISOs, 
    already having gone through a rigorous approval process, should have to 
    re-certify as RTOs.
    
    [[Page 945]]
    
    Moreover, EEI notes that the Commission should weigh the incremental 
    gains achieved through economies of scale, efficiency, and additional 
    savings against the potential incremental costs of reorganization, new 
    computer programming, infrastructure changes, and changes required to 
    achieve effective communication and coordination. NYPP proposes that 
    ISOs be allowed to evaluate the costs and benefits of forming an RTO 
    after some years of market experience; hence, they oppose putting 
    members of existing ISOs on the same time frame for compliance as non-
    members of ISOs/RTOs. United Illuminating recommends that the 
    Commission continue to honor and not abrogate pricing arrangements of 
    existing ISOs. United Illuminating also contends that, since existing 
    ISO members have no opportunity to discriminate because they have 
    turned control of their transmission over to their respective ISO, the 
    Commission cannot generically abrogate existing ISO pricing 
    arrangements pursuant to its FPA section 206 authority in this 
    rulemaking. Central Maine offers that consolidating the PJM, New 
    England and New York ISOs into a super-ISO will require costly 
    expansion of telemetry, communication, and computer equipment, that it 
    could result in a decrease in reliability, and that simple 
    interregional coordination could accomplish the Commission's goals 
    without consolidation.
        A few non-ISO entities oppose any grandfathering of existing 
    regional transmission organizations.\745\ For example, New Orleans 
    argues that the Commission should not exempt existing regional 
    transmission entities from requirements of RTO formation because only 
    through universal application will all regions of the country receive 
    the benefits of open and competitive electric markets. H.Q. Energy 
    Services suggests that a larger territory, such as the combined 
    territory served by the existing New York, PJM and New England ISOs, 
    would be more effective than the NY ISO standing alone. PG&E counsels 
    that freezing the existing ISO structures in place would not serve 
    reliability or the marketplace and would be inconsistent with the open 
    architecture requirement. It believes that the Commission has struck an 
    appropriate balance imposing a reporting requirement on existing ISOs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \745\ E.g., Illinois Commission, New Orleans, SMUD and Turlock.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Most commenters agree that existing operational transmission 
    entities should gradually evolve toward RTOs during a transition 
    period, rather than making immediate and drastic changes.\746\ 
    According to SMUD, a transition period will enable customers to avoid 
    bearing unnecessary costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \746\ See, e.g., SMUD, PJM/NEPOOL Customers, NYPP, Cal DWR, 
    MEAG, American Forest and Central Maine.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A few commenters address the specific filing requirements outlined 
    in the NOPR. The New York Commission asserts that the NY ISO should not 
    have to make a filing because it possesses the requirements of an RTO. 
    In addition, the Cal ISO argues that existing entities, rather than 
    individual public utilities, should be responsible for the RTO filing 
    requirements. Likewise, PJM suggests that existing ISOs report to the 
    Commission prior to any report by its public utility members, as the 
    existing ISO is in a better position to provide the Commission with the 
    most accurate information by which to evaluate whether the ISO 
    satisfies the minimum characteristics and functions for RTOs. PJM 
    suggests that existing ISOs and existing transmission entities file 
    reports no later than December 31, 2000, explaining whether they 
    satisfy the Commission's requirements for RTOs and identifying any 
    additional authority they may require for this purpose. On the other 
    hand, EPSA welcomes the proposal requiring a showing of how the 
    existing transmission institutions meet the minimum characteristics and 
    functions by January 15, 2001, as a way to help address and solve 
    continuing discrimination within current ISOs and address whether these 
    institutions should be combined into larger groupings. Similarly, NYC 
    wants the NY ISO's January 15, 2001, filing to demonstrate how its 
    efforts to improve regional cooperation will overcome the institutional 
    impediments that have contributed to the city's load pocket condition.
        Finally, commenters raise a number of miscellaneous issues: Puget 
    questions whether there will be negative implications for any entity 
    the choose to cease participation in an RTO; DOE points out that RTOs 
    may need to fund pensions for transferred employees, and existing 
    transmission providers may need to fund early retirements or other 
    compensation for displaced employees; UMPA recommends that recourse to 
    the Commission in a de novo capacity must be part of all RTO dispute 
    resolution procedures; and Indiana Commission, Snohomish and Midwest 
    ISO express concern about how the Commission intends to handle multiple 
    RTO proposals covering approximately the same region.
        Commission Conclusion. The Commission will adopt the NOPR proposal 
    requiring that all public utilities that own, operate or control 
    interstate transmission facilities (except those already participating 
    in an approved regional transmission entity) file by October 15, 2000, 
    either a proposal to participate in an RTO or an alternative filing 
    describing efforts and plans to participate in an RTO. As proposed 
    initially, we will consider a petition for declaratory order setting 
    forth the items listed in section 35.34(d)(3) as a proposal to 
    participate in an RTO.
        We believe that the October 15, 2000, date for filing proposals is 
    realistic. It is not overly aggressive, given the amount of guidance we 
    have provided in this Rule and the amount of flexibility we are 
    permitting in how to satisfy the minimum characteristics and functions. 
    In addition, the collaborative process that we are promoting in this 
    Rule will provide an opportunity for all interested parties with their 
    varied interests to resolve many of their differences, in advance, and 
    reach consensus on the RTO solution that best fits the overall needs of 
    their respective region. The October 15, 2000, filing date should help 
    keep the parties focused and accelerate their efforts toward selecting 
    an appropriate RTO model.
        The October 15, 2000, date for filing is also reasonable because, 
    even if a public utility is unable to file an RTO proposal at that 
    time, we are permitting the public utility to make an alternative 
    filing reporting on the status of pertinent RTO formation and 
    development, the obstacles that have prevented the filing of an 
    appropriate RTO proposal, and any of the public utility's plans and 
    timetable for future efforts directed toward RTO formation and 
    participation.\747\ Given the importance that the Commission places on 
    RTO development, it is important for us to understand no later than 
    October 15, 2000 just how much progress the industry is making on 
    forming RTOs. If the October 15, 2000, filings reveal obstacles that 
    prevent serious progress toward RTO formation are reported for a given 
    region, we will be able to act early enough to provide guidance on what 
    steps we think are appropriate to help address the obstacles (e.g., 
    further collaborative efforts). And where serious regional progress is 
    reported, but more time is requested in connection with meeting a 
    particular RTO requirement, we will be able to act early enough to try 
    to accommodate the local needs,
    
    [[Page 946]]
    
    complications and complexities that the particular region faces.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \747\ Of course, these reports may be filed prior to October 15, 
    2000.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Some concern has been expressed that the October 15, 2000, filing 
    date is too short to allow transcos to form because of the inherent 
    legal, financial, real estate and taxation complexities associated with 
    the transfer of ownership of the affected transmission assets. We are 
    not proposing that the restructuring be completed by October 15, only 
    that a proposal be filed, or an alternative filing as described in this 
    Rule. Moreover, we take note of the fact that other forms of major 
    corporate restructuring, including mergers, have proceeded from initial 
    idea to formal proposal in a shorter time when the motivation is 
    sufficient. Therefore, we do not think the time allowed is too short 
    for transco proposals.
        We also reaffirm the proposed January 15, 2001, filing date for 
    transmitting public utility members of an existing approved 
    transmission entity to address the extent to which that entity conforms 
    to the minimum characteristics and functions of an RTO, any plans to 
    make it conform, and any obstacles to full conformance with our Final 
    Rule. We note that RTOs will not be ``starting from scratch.'' There is 
    significant information available about both the good and bad 
    experiences with ISOs, and this information should help RTOs meet this 
    filing deadline.
        While we are allowing a later filing date for existing transmission 
    institutions to file (January 15, 2001, versus October 15, 2000), we do 
    this because, in general, the transmission owners in those regions have 
    already made substantial progress in establishing regional entities. 
    Nonetheless, the Commission needs to know, for all regions, including 
    those covered by existing approved transmission institutions, the 
    extent of progress toward formation of fully functional RTOs. To the 
    extent that an existing ISO, for example, is less than adequate with 
    regard to one of the necessary characteristics or functions, we would 
    expect the existing institution to be working on a plan of action to 
    make the remedial improvements that are required to bring it into 
    conformance with the Final Rule.
        In sum, we continue to believe that the October 15, 2000, and 
    January 15, 2001, filing dates represent an acceptable balance between 
    the need to move toward RTOs as soon at possible and the need for 
    sufficient time for transmission owners and market participants to 
    develop proposals.
    2. Deadline for RTO Operation
        The Commission proposed that all public utilities participate in an 
    RTO that will be operational by December 15, 2001. In addition, we 
    contemplated implementation of the congestion management function 
    within one year after startup (by December 15, 2002), and 
    implementation of inter-regional parallel path flow coordination and 
    transmission planning and expansion functions within three years after 
    startup (by December 15, 2004).
        Comments. Most commenters suggest the December 15, 2001, deadline 
    should be changed to a later date or that the Commission provide 
    greater flexibility in meeting the deadline. On the other hand, Oregon 
    Commission explicitly favors the December 15, 2001, deadline, arguing 
    that the time line is designed in stages so that the easiest 
    requirements come earliest. EPSA fears that further delay of any of the 
    operational deadlines for any of the required RTO functions (i.e., for 
    initial startup, congestion management, parallel path flow 
    coordination, or transmission planning and expansion) will only 
    encourage further debate and dialogue without driving the industry 
    towards acceptable resolutions, and prolong the problems of residual 
    discrimination and remaining market inefficiencies.
        Two commenters propose an earlier deadline. PG&E contends that the 
    transition period for RTOs to meet all requirements must be as short as 
    possible--no more than one or two years to fully operational RTOs may 
    be reasonable. Sithe similarly argues that, while the negotiations and 
    proceedings associated with voluntarily RTOs can take years to 
    complete, the California experience suggests that an RTO can be 
    established quickly if a deadline exists. Sithe recommends that the 
    Commission reconsider its time frame and do everything it can to hasten 
    the process of putting in place RTOs with all minimum characteristics 
    and functions. It observes that, as proposed in the NOPR, an RTO could 
    defer for up to three years the filing of a plan for transmission 
    planning and grid expansion. The details may not be finally approved by 
    the Commission for at least another year such that a delay of over five 
    years could result.
        SRP and American Forest express concern about who will be 
    responsible for building and paying for new transmission facilities 
    until the RTO takes on this responsibility. In particular, SRP suggests 
    that the Commission require each RTO filing to describe who will be 
    responsible for financing and building transmission expansions during 
    the interim.
        Most commenters, however, view the proposed deadline as too 
    aggressive, and recommend that it be eliminated or extended. CP&L views 
    the operating deadline as arbitrary and capricious, and argues that the 
    deadline will impose higher implementation costs and inefficiency that 
    will not benefit the public or the industry. South Carolina Authority 
    believes that to assume that a large group of stakeholders with diverse 
    interests can somehow come together and agree on a particular RTO model 
    and configuration by October 15, 2000 that is up and running by 
    December 31, 2001, is unrealistic. East Kentucky suggests that the 
    timetable be extended approximately two years. Montana Power encourages 
    extension by one year because areas like the Pacific Northwest will 
    probably need significant infrastructure to be developed or re-deployed 
    and the 14 month time frame contemplated after RTO proposals are due on 
    October 15, 2000, is not sufficient time.
        A number of commenters favor a flexible approach and allowing 
    provisional RTO status. Cinergy offers that, to overcome obstacles such 
    as legal impediments to public power participation, alternative means 
    of RTO participation be considered such as joint operations without the 
    functional integration of public systems' facilities to allow them to 
    control the private use of their systems. SERC generally concurs. 
    Williams contends that not all RTOs will be able to develop at the same 
    pace, and supports provisional RTO status with dates certain respecting 
    those functions not able to be performed at startup.\748\ SNWA 
    recommends that, if necessary, a phase-in approach should be used in 
    the implementation of an RTO to smooth the implementation process. 
    Project Groups contends that, given the California experience, the cost 
    of attempting to do everything at once is significant. Transmission ISO 
    Participants urges flexibility for transmission owning members of 
    exiting ISOs since the current structure represents an imperfect and 
    probably unfinished agenda. EEI contends that the Commission should 
    allow flexible timetables to establish RTOs that are transcos, 
    contending that a vertically integrated utility that selects the option 
    of moving transmission assets to a transco faces complex financial and 
    tax issues. Nevada Commission urges the
    
    [[Page 947]]
    
    Commission to clarify that there is no prohibition against forming 
    interim organizations such as an independent system administrator until 
    such time as a viable RTO for the region is formed. South Carolina 
    Commission claims that each RTO proposal should be reviewed on a case-
    by-case basis for general adherence to the Commission's overall policy 
    goals.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \748\ Note that a number of comments opposing deadlines are 
    based on the difficulty of attaining specific RTO functions. These 
    comments are also addressed in the sections regarding the specific 
    functions.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Indiana Commission cautions, however, that careful consideration 
    should be given to what will be lost by the acceptance of an RTO 
    ``lite.'' It argues that existing transmission entities may see little 
    value in maintaining relatively high standards and could view the 
    Commission acceptance of lower standards as an incentive to gravitate 
    to lower standards. PG&E recommends the Commission grant waivers from 
    its requirements only in limited cases and only for short durations. 
    AEPCO, contends that there should be a reasonable basis for granting 
    waivers, particularly for non-jurisdictional entities. In particular, a 
    request for waiver should consider: (1) How much additional RTO 
    transmission would result from inclusion of the facilities in an RTO; 
    and (2) whether the RTO would be functional without inclusion of the 
    entity's facilities. Sithe argues that care should be taken when 
    considering whether to permit RTOs to go into effect without meeting 
    functions and in granting waivers, and suggests that the Commission 
    establish clear requirements for RTO approval, strictly scrutinize 
    proposals, and not hesitate to reject inadequate proposals.
        Commission Conclusion. We have decided to retain the originally 
    proposed startup and other functional implementation deadlines (RTO 
    startup by December 15, 2001, implementation of congestion management 
    by December 15, 2002, and implementation of the parallel path flow 
    coordination and transmission planning and expansion functions by 
    December 15, 2004).
        As a general proposition, we believe that, given the urgent needs 
    of electricity markets as discussed elsewhere in our Final Rule, we 
    have an obligation to promote RTO operation at the earliest feasible 
    date. Even where a market may already be served by an ISO or other 
    approved transmission entity, we are concerned that such market may 
    remain hampered to the extent that the approved entity has yet to fully 
    conform with our Final Rule.
        In response to those who contend that December 15, 2001, is too 
    ambitious for RTO start-up, we note several points. First, we, and the 
    industry, now have had the benefit of the experience of the formation 
    of five ISOs under Commission jurisdiction, an ISO in ERCOT, some 
    international experience with regional transmission entities, and 
    substantial discussion of the subject of regional transmission entities 
    within the industry. While the timeframe we are suggesting for RTO 
    formation may have been unrealistic several years ago, much has been 
    learned since then which should facilitate more rapid formation.
        Second, our Final Rule is providing substantial flexibility that 
    should permit an RTO to satisfy the minimum characteristics and 
    functions in a cost efficient manner. For example, we are not requiring 
    control area consolidation; we are not requiring the establishment of a 
    PX; we are allowing an RTO to meet its operational control obligation 
    through indirect or hierarchical control arrangements via contractual 
    agreements with the existing infrastructure such as transmission owners 
    and control area operators; and we are allowing an RTO to satisfy its 
    security coordinator functions through contractual arrangements with an 
    external security coordinator, as long as it is independent. An 
    acceptable RTO structure need not be a monolithic organization that 
    requires an extended period of time to become fully set up so that it 
    can directly ``push all of the buttons.'' Moreover, we are allowing a 
    longer phase-in period for functions that may be more difficult to 
    establish, such as congestion management, parallel path flow measures, 
    and transmission planning and expansion.
        With respect to the comments that question the December 15, 2002, 
    deadline for implementing the congestion management function, we 
    believe that lack of effective and market-oriented congestion 
    management is a critical issue in the industry, and that it needs 
    attention soon. We acknowledge that developing a sophisticated 
    congestion management program can be an extremely complex and time 
    consuming matter. However, implementation of economic approaches to 
    congestion management by some of the approved ISOs shows the 
    feasibility of these concepts where there is an institution to 
    undertake the organization of this function over a large area.
        Some say that transmission congestion is not a serious problem in 
    their regions, and that they therefore should not be required to 
    develop a complex congestion management plan within a short time-frame. 
    We agree that an RTO should not have to expend large resources to 
    address a problem that does not exist. However, we are concerned that 
    an RTO fully analyze the extent to which transmission congestion does 
    or could interfere with electricity sales in its region, and that it be 
    prepared to address congestion if it becomes a more serious problem 
    through changing markets. As markets become more competitive and the 
    volume of discrete transaction increases, transmission congestion may 
    become serious unless action is undertaken beforehand. Where 
    transmission congestion is infrequent, this Rule does not preclude the 
    establishment of relatively less complex forms of market-compatible 
    congestion management such as generation redispatch protocols.
        In sum, we think that the phased startup and other functional 
    implementation deadlines are reasonable.
    3. Commission Processing Procedures
        The Commission recognized that RTO formation would be complicated 
    by the requirements for Commission approval of transfer of control of 
    jurisdictional facilities under FPA section 203 and Commission approval 
    of RTO transmission rates, terms and conditions under FPA section 205. 
    In the NOPR, the Commission requested comments on whether the 
    Commission should provide expedited or streamlined processing 
    procedures for RTO filings and asked for suggestions regarding how the 
    Commission can further expedite and streamline procedures.\749\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \749\ FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 32,541 at 33,759.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Comments. Views on streamlined and expedited processing of RTO 
    filings are mixed. Commenters that generally favor streamlining include 
    Desert STAR and TEP, which suggests that filing requirements be kept 
    simple and flexible.
        A number of commenters offer specific suggestions for streamlining 
    and expediting the process, including:
         Florida Commission believes that once an RTO or other 
    structure has been agreed upon by a group of entities, the Commission 
    should expedite all required processes in order to allow the 
    participants to start implementing the agreed upon changes.
         Tallahassee recommends that the Commission should clarify 
    that it is not revisiting the functional test for distinguishing 
    transmission and distribution facilities addressed in Order No. 888.
         Entergy asserts that significant delay in obtaining 
    Commission approvals will make it difficult for Entergy to institute a 
    transco within the time-lines established by state restructuring laws 
    in Arkansas and Texas. Providing clear rules on the
    
    [[Page 948]]
    
    required and permissible features of RTOs as the Commission did in its 
    July 30, 1999 Declaratory Order for Entergy and providing clear 
    standards on pricing policies will help. Entergy argues that the 
    Commission should make explicit its willingness to consider requests 
    for expedited approval when a showing is made that expedition is 
    necessary, as it has done for California ISO.
         Trans-Elect notes that if a transfer of facilities cannot 
    close under Section 203 until the related FPA section 205 proceeding is 
    concluded, an expedited Section 205 filing must also take place. One 
    way to do this is to waive an Initial Decision and set a date certain 
    for the Commission's section 205 decision.
         PJM/NEPOOL Customers recommend that a standard RTO 
    governance structure be adopted that allows participation by all 
    stakeholder groups. It would expedite processing by requiring that any 
    RTO filing demonstrate that all stakeholders were included in the 
    formation process.
         SMUD recommends that the Final Rule require that RTOs be 
    designed, developed and implemented in a manner that does not require 
    numerous tariff amendments to remedy market ills that could be 
    addressed prospectively or at a speed that does not dramatically 
    increase RTO development costs.
        On the other hand, some commenters urged the Commission to exercise 
    caution regarding streamlining and expediting:
         East Texas Cooperatives observes that a poorly configured 
    RTO can potentially be more harmful to the industry than the status 
    quo, by allowing large transmission owners to dominate regional grid 
    management, maintain pancaked rates and discriminate in allocating 
    transmission revenue.
         Indiana Commission recommends that state commissions and 
    other interested parties have full opportunity to thoroughly review, 
    comment, and have an impact on the RTO proposals once they are filed 
    with the Commission.
         Puget indicates that a negative implication of allowing 
    streamlined filing and approval procedures for RTO participants is that 
    regulatory burdens will be leveled against nonparticipants while those 
    who join an RTO will be freed from what the Commission implicitly 
    recognizes are unnecessary requirements. A truly voluntary system would 
    not continue to impose unnecessary regulatory requirements on 
    nonparticipants and there is no reason for the Commission to delay 
    implementing these regulatory reforms now before a final decision is 
    made regarding the wisdom or efficacy of RTOs, or to condition the 
    implementation of such reforms on an entity's participation in an RTO.
         Duke contends that, given the size and complexity of the 
    typical section 203 and 205 of the FPA filings, it is not clear that 
    reducing the time that parties are granted to review such filings and 
    provide initial comments may be appropriate. Nonetheless, the 
    Commission should work to dismiss irrelevant issues used as leverage to 
    extract concessions unrelated to RTO formation, it should consider use 
    of less formal hearing procedures for issues that do not require 
    discovery, and the Commission should limit the time period allowed for 
    evidentiary hearings. Duke acknowledges that the effect of streamlined 
    filing and approval procedures could be to reduce costs that would 
    otherwise be born by market participants.
        Commission Conclusion. While there is broad-based consensus for 
    simplifying the Commission's RTO filing process and responding to RTO 
    proposals expeditiously, we must maintain an appropriate balance 
    between streamlining and expediting the filing and processing of RTO 
    proposals and ensuring due process and the development of an adequate 
    record. Given the amount of flexibility we have built into the Rule as 
    to organizational structure, it is difficult to predict what issues 
    will be raised by the RTO proposals and the degree of complexity raised 
    by such issues. Accordingly, while the Commission has the goal of 
    ensuring the rapid formation of RTOs, and will attempt to process each 
    RTO proposal as expeditiously as possible, certain RTO proposals will 
    take longer to analyze and review depending upon the complexity of the 
    issues and the level of support among the affected parties. Therefore, 
    in addition to the specific guidance provided elsewhere in this Rule, 
    we provide further guidance and note the following factors which are 
    intended to assist public utilities in streamlining their required 
    filings and help expedite the processing of the RTO proposals.
        One factor that should facilitate faster processing is that the 
    Final Rule permits delayed implementation dates for various highly 
    complex FPA section 205 related RTO provisions (congestion management 
    by December 15, 2002, and parallel path flow coordination and 
    transmission planning and expansion each by December 15, 2003). 
    Therefore, initial RTO proposals need not contain the details for these 
    provisions, but need only contain a commitment to complete the 
    provision and a timetable for submitting appropriate future filings. 
    Likewise, we need not act on those matters initially in our RTO orders.
        Expeditious processing of an RTO submittal is more likely to occur 
    if the RTO proposal is the result of a comprehensive and open 
    collaborative process with widespread support from transmission owners, 
    market participants, and affected state commissions. While we cannot 
    pre-approve unopposed proposals, many of our potential concerns could 
    be minimized to the extent the proposal has broad support.
        Another potential streamlining measure is that public utilities are 
    permitted to file RTO proposals jointly with other entities. For 
    example, in the case of existing ISOs and other approved regional 
    transmission entities, the regional entity may file on behalf of the 
    individual public utilities. This will reduce the volume of submittals 
    that must be developed by public utilities and be reviewed by the 
    Commission.
        We note that, with the exception of governance, experience gained 
    from past ISO proceedings, will be directly transferable whether the 
    form of RTO is an ISO or a transco. For transcos, as discussed 
    elsewhere in the Final Rule, restrictions on ownership of transcos that 
    we have adopted are designed to work in tandem with restrictions on 
    governance in order to ensure adequate levels of independence.
        We believe that RTO proposals that reflect the above factors, 
    should allow the Commission to minimize the amount of time necessary to 
    analyze and process the submittal. While the Commission cannot 
    guarantee that we will be able to respond to every proposal within a 
    pre-set period of time, we will make every reasonable effort to issue 
    an initial order on an RTO proposal within 60 days,\750\ after the 
    comment period closes.\751\ With respect to RTO proposals that present 
    contested issues or problematic RTO provisions, we will make every 
    effort to expedite
    
    [[Page 949]]
    
    consideration of the proposed RTO and we will continue to consider 
    alternatives to formal procedures (e.g., ADR procedures), where 
    warranted, to avoid initiating a hearing.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \750\ We recognize that, while there is no statutory deadline to 
    act on section 203 filings, there is a 60-day statutory clock 
    requiring action on section 205 related filings within 60 days from 
    the date of filing, in the absence of a proposed effective date 
    extending beyond the 60-day time frame. However, in most instances, 
    we expect that the RTO submittals will typically propose FPA section 
    205 effective dates that will be beyond the 60-day nominal clock.
        \751\ This proposed time frame refers to applications that are 
    consistent with the guidance provided in this Rule and that provide 
    all the necessary information. We further note that the Commission's 
    review process will restart in the event that applicants modify 
    their proposal or supplement the supporting information in their 
    application.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        What the Commission has approved for ISO forms of governance can be 
    used as models for governance of RTOs that are ISOs. Nothing in this 
    Rule prohibits the types of independent governance structures we have 
    approved to date. All of the ISOs approved to date, except one, have a 
    two-tier form of governance wherein a non-stakeholder board at the top 
    generally has final decision-making authority on most issues. Below 
    this board are advisory groups or committees comprised of stakeholders 
    that provide advice and may share some decision-making authority. With 
    regard to the second-tier, the Commission has required that no one 
    constituency in any group or committee be allowed to dominate the 
    recommendation or decision-making process over the objection of the 
    other classes, and that no one class holds veto power over the will of 
    the remaining classes. The California ISO's governance structure is 
    different. It has a single-tier hybrid decision-making board comprised 
    of both stakeholders and non-stakeholders. No two classes can push 
    through a decision over the objection of other classes, and no one 
    class has veto power over the will of the remaining classes.
    4. Other Implementation Issues
        Commission Conclusion. An additional issue some commenters raised 
    in connection with implementation concerns how the Commission intends 
    to handle multiple RTO proposals that pertain to the same or 
    overlapping regions. We expect that proper adherence to the 
    collaborative process and the RTO scope and configuration factors we 
    have identified, in the first instance, will bring order to the 
    formation of RTOs such that the Commission will not need to step in and 
    decide the matter of competing RTOs at the filing stage.
        Several miscellaneous RTO implementation issues that were raised by 
    some commenters concern the terms of withdrawal for members from an 
    RTO, the RTO's funding of staff compensation in connection with 
    transfers of personnel from other entities, and the Commission serving 
    as a backstop for RTO's ADR processes. These matters, however, are best 
    left to case-specific determinations in response to particular RTO 
    proposals.
        In response to those who argue for or against rejection or waiver 
    in connection with less-than-fully-conforming RTO submittals, we 
    believe the concepts of rejection and waiver are not appropriate. We 
    have provided a significant degree of flexibility in the minimum 
    characteristics and functions, and in many instances specifically allow 
    for alternative ways to satisfy those characteristics and functions. 
    Proposals that do not satisfy the minimum characteristics and functions 
    will not be approved as RTOs. That does not mean that such a proposal 
    would be summarily rejected; in fact, it may still be an improvement 
    over the status quo as long as it is consistent with the FPA 
    requirements. However, it may be questioned the extent to which 
    entities that are not participating in RTOs have acted to eliminate the 
    impediments to competition we have identified in this Final Rule.
    
    IV. Environmental Statement
    
        This section reviews and adopts the Environmental Assessment (EA) 
    prepared by the Commission staff in connection with this Final Rule. It 
    identifies the alternatives considered by the agency in reaching its 
    decision; analyzes and considers whether and to what extent, if any, 
    the chosen alternative--adoption of this Final Rule--affects the 
    quality of the human environment; and states the Commission's decision.
    
    Summary
    
        The analysis compares generation and emission trends under the 
    Final Rule to baseline trends without the Final Rule. The analysis 
    indicates that the Final Rule will result in little generation change 
    on a net national basis, but there may be shifts in regional 
    generation. Economic benefits of the Final Rule can be realized with no 
    significant, adverse environmental impacts. Further, the potential 
    exists for environmental benefits to be realized, through the 
    encouragement of newer, cleaner resources.
    
    Discussion
    
    A. Background
        To further the policies and goals of the National Environmental 
    Policy Act of 1969 (NEPA), Commission staff prepared an EA in order to 
    examine potential impacts that could result from implementing the 
    Commission's Rule, and to serve as the basis for considering whether 
    the Final Rule will have significant impacts on the quality of the 
    human environment. On May 14, 1999, the Commission issued a notice of 
    intent to prepare an EA, and a request for comments on the scope of the 
    issues that should be addressed in the EA. On July 8, 1999, a public 
    scoping meeting was held at the Commission. On October 22, 1999, the 
    Commission issued an EA, and invited interested parties to comment on 
    the EA. Comments were due on November 22, 1999.
        The Commission received two filed comments on the EA (NMA/WFA/CEED 
    and Project Groups on behalf of multiple public interest groups). 
    Specific comments are addressed in the relevant sections below.\752\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \752\ As noted in the EA, a number of comments filed during 
    scoping relate to matters outside the scope of the EA, and for the 
    most part deal with policy issues that are addressed in the Rule.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    B. Scope of the Analysis
        The EA examines potential environmental impacts that could result 
    from implementing the Commission's Final Rule. The impacts are 
    necessarily uncertain because they would be the product of changes in 
    economic regulation that may alter the future behavior and perhaps the 
    future structure of electricity supply markets. In turn, these 
    behavioral and structural changes could lead to a different set of 
    environmental conditions than would otherwise be the case. The analysis 
    recognizes the uncertainty of the Rule's potential effects on future 
    markets. It presents a systematic view of possible future market 
    changes and assesses a range of possible responses to market changes, 
    but should not be seen as predictive of specific market or 
    environmental outcomes.
        The EA addresses a broad range of potential economic changes that 
    could result from the Rule. These impacts include changes in the mix of 
    electric generating plants built in the future, shifts in the 
    utilization of existing plants, and increases in interregional 
    transmission. The analysis, therefore, includes major air pollutants: 
    sulfur dioxide (SO2), nitrogen oxides (NOX), 
    mercury, and carbon dioxide associated with various types of generating 
    plants and fuels. The EA addresses potential environmental impacts at 
    national and regional levels.
        Project Groups expressed concern that the EA does not 
    retrospectively analyze the impacts of open access policies to date. As 
    stated in 1.3.2 of the EA, we believe it is neither possible nor 
    desirable to analyze such changes. Data collection lags, and the short 
    period of time that has elapsed since the issuance of Order No. 888, 
    would preclude us from drawing meaningful conclusions.
        Project Groups also stated that economic impacts are not 
    specifically reported in the EA, making it more difficult to evaluate 
    the impacts of the
    
    [[Page 950]]
    
    Rule. We note, however, that the modeling and analysis conducted for 
    the EA are the basis for the economic discussion contained in the Final 
    Rule. These economic results do not provide a complete analysis of the 
    potential economic impacts because the analysis considers only economic 
    effects which may relate to operating decisions or new capacity, and 
    thus may lead to environmental consequences. However, there are other 
    economic benefits from competitive wholesale electric power markets 
    which have little or no effect on the environment.
    C. Analytic Approach
        Because the impacts that could result from the rulemaking are 
    uncertain, an analytic approach known as scenario analysis was used. In 
    this approach, alternative views of the future are postulated and 
    analyzed with and without the Final Rule. Potential environmental 
    impacts are evaluated by comparing the analytic results of the 
    scenarios. First, an analytic base case was developed. This base case 
    relies on the assumption that the Commission would pursue current 
    policy with respect to wholesale electric competition using existing 
    rules and procedures, including case-by-case implementation of regional 
    market arrangements.
        Having established an appropriate base case, the EA analyzed future 
    impacts assuming that the Rule is in effect. Staff adopted the 
    assumption that the Final Rule, although voluntary, would result in the 
    establishment of RTOs throughout the study area with the 
    characteristics and functions set forth in the Final Rule. Three 
    scenarios were developed to reflect a range of possible economic and 
    environmental outcomes: Transmission Efficiency Scenario; Transmission/
    Generation Efficiency Scenario; New Entry Scenario.
    D. Alternatives to the Rule
        The primary alternative to the Final Rule is for the Commission to 
    maintain the status quo, that is, to continue its existing open access 
    policies. The result of this no-action alternative, without 
    implementing the Final Rule, is that the Commission would effectuate an 
    open transmission grid, but not address changes in the industry that 
    have occurred since Order No. 888 was adopted. However, the no-action 
    alternative describes what is likely to happen if the Commission takes 
    no action over and beyond implementation of existing policies. Once 
    this baseline is established to portray what is likely to happen in the 
    electric industry during the study period, the projected impacts of the 
    Final Rule can then be determined against this backdrop.
        In addition to the Final Rule and the no-action alternative, 
    several alternative approaches were considered and ultimately rejected. 
    The alternative of analyzing mandatory RTOs, as compared with voluntary 
    RTOs as set forth in the Final Rule, was rejected as moot, since the EA 
    assumes that voluntary RTO formation proceeds with little delay and is 
    successful in creating RTOs with the functions and characteristics 
    contained in the Rule. Hence, assumptions for voluntary RTOs and 
    mandatory RTOs are analytically indistinguishable in terms of their 
    effects on the transmission grid and on the electric sector generally.
        The other major alternative considered was the analysis of 
    alternative fuel price assumptions. Project for Sustainable FERC Energy 
    Policy suggested that we prepare such an analysis. However, as we noted 
    in the EA, this alternative was ultimately rejected for two reasons. 
    First, as reflected in scenarios analyzed in the EIS for Order No. 888, 
    plausible variation in gas prices relative to coal prices is unlikely 
    to have a major impact on the environmental effects of the Final Rule. 
    Therefore, a gas price scenario was selected that had the general 
    characteristics of other forecasts, namely, that gas prices will rise 
    relative to coal prices. The selection of this gas price scenario does 
    not represent an endorsement of this particular gas price path. 
    Although we believe it to be a reasonable projection, it is a merely a 
    representative projection of gas prices for purposes of the EA. Second, 
    there is no need to consider an alternative where competition favors 
    gas over coal because such a scenario would have little adverse impact, 
    especially when compared with scenarios that tend to favor increased 
    coal use relative to gas use. In the rule scenario we selected, we 
    included, therefore, a number of improvements in coal technology as a 
    result of the RTO Rule, to ensure that the potential impacts of any 
    increased coal use relative to the base case would be considered in 
    assessing the environmental consequences of the rule.
    E. Analytic Framework and Assumptions
        It is expected that the impacts of the Final Rule will result 
    primarily from changes in the types and locations of power plants and 
    transmission facilities constructed in the future and changes in the 
    operating patterns of existing power plants, including changes in the 
    fuel mix. To examine the impacts thoroughly, the modeling approach 
    chosen includes detailed representations of electric power plants and 
    the electric transmission grid, and allows for an economic (least-cost) 
    compliance with existing and future environmental regulatory 
    requirements.
        Computer modeling capable of simulating regional electric utility 
    dispatch and capacity expansion over time was used to characterize 
    electric power markets in the base case and rule scenarios. We used a 
    large supply optimization model of the U.S. electricity supply sector, 
    which emphasizes pollution estimation and pollution control. It has 
    been used for Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) regulatory analysis 
    in publicly accessible proceedings since 1996.
        Analytic assumptions are a critical part of the modeling. Because 
    the model cannot tell us directly what the RTO-related changes will be, 
    it must assess how a set of assumed changes in the cost and/or physical 
    properties or the electricity system could lead to changes in the use 
    of the system, and hence to changes in emissions.
        A series of specific assumptions were developed to model the base 
    case and scenarios. Assumptions common to all modeled cases include 
    current and future prices of fossil fuels, particularly coal and 
    natural gas, and current and future requirements imposed on the 
    electric sector by environmental laws and regulations. These 
    requirements include: for SO2, continuation of the Title IV 
    Acid Rain Program, with Phase II coverage and levels of permitted 
    emissions; for NOX, Title IV requirements on coal-fired 
    boilers (Phase I and Phase II); emissions cap restrictions in the Ozone 
    Transport Region starting in 1999, and implementation of the Final Rule 
    governing ozone transport issued by the EPA in 1997, modeled in 
    accordance with the EPA's guidance. This EPA Rule imposes a cap on 
    NOX on large utility boilers in 22 states in the eastern 
    United States and limiting summer NOX emissions to 543,800 
    tons; no regulatory restrictions are assumed for mercury or 
    CO2.
        Project Groups commented that, since assumptions made in the EA 
    about future environmental regulations are critical in determining the 
    outcome of the analysis, changes in future environmental regulations 
    (particularly due to legal challenges) from those assumed in the EA 
    could result in different environmental impacts. Accordingly, the 
    comment states that the EA should reflect possible changes. We note 
    that there are many important analytic assumptions embodied in the
    
    [[Page 951]]
    
    modeling for the EA. Environmental regulations are directly represented 
    in the analysis, and changes in these assumed regulations do have a 
    large effect on the results of the modeling. In particular, the 
    presence or absence of SO2 and NOX caps is a key 
    assumption. Nevertheless, these assumptions are based on regulations 
    which are final, as opposed to proposed regulations or speculative 
    regulatory actions. These rules and associated regulatory analyses from 
    EPA were used as the basis for the EA assumptions. Accordingly, it 
    would be premature and speculative to consider changes, if any, from 
    pending legal challenges or speculative future regulatory changes.
        In a broader sense, it is clear that successful competitive energy 
    markets will be complemented by cost-effective environmental 
    regulation, because the incentives for efficient behavior on the part 
    of market participants can be decentralized and the need for intrusive 
    regulatory action is lessened. Emissions trading programs such as those 
    for SO2 and NOX are an important example of such 
    cost-effective regulation.
        Other invariant assumptions include: net electric demand growth 
    (with the exception of New Entry Scenario); load shape (how demand 
    varies with season and time of day within each model region); costs and 
    performance of new power plants; and capacity and generation of 
    nuclear, hydroelectric, pumped storage, and import supply.
        Because of the importance of the transmission system in the Rule, 
    assumptions were made about potential changes that may come about 
    either because of the Rule's requirements or because of its increased 
    incentives for better grid operation and investment. In addition, the 
    Final Rule is expected to develop more competitive bulk electric power 
    markets. Competition is expected to increase the incentives for 
    efficient behavior among market participants. To assess the potential 
    effects of such increased efficiencies on the environment, some 
    assumptions affecting new and existing power plants were changed. 
    Finally, to respond to concerns expressed by parties in the scoping 
    process regarding the role of new entrants in developing competitive 
    power markets, particularly the RTOs, a model scenario was developed 
    that specifically addresses new entry and enhanced consumer choice.
    F. Impacts
        The EA analyzes the electric power capacity and generation 
    projections on a national and regional level for the base case, and 
    presents the corresponding environmental impacts. Projected trends in 
    generating capacity, including economic additions, retirements and 
    modifications, and generation by plant type for the base case, are 
    analyzed for the years 2005, 2010, and 2015. The data indicate that 
    virtually all future capacity additions are expected to be gas-fired 
    combined cycle or combustion turbine units; coal will nevertheless 
    remain the dominant fuel for generation. Growth in natural gas, 
    however, will be rapid, with the share of generation increasing from 13 
    percent in 1997 to 32 percent in 2015; total generating capacity is 
    expected to grow at a slower rate than demand, resulting in plants that 
    will generally be operated at higher capacity factors; regional 
    patterns of generation reflect regional demand growth as well as 
    changes in interregional trade in electricity. In most regions, growth 
    in demand is met by gas-fired (or oil/gas switching) plants, although 
    in the Midwest existing coal-fired capacity meets part of the growth in 
    the early years of the forecast.
        The EA projects national emissions in the base case for 
    SO2, NOX, mercury, and CO2. There are 
    also regional emissions projections for NOX. The analysis 
    indicates the following:
        1. SO2 emissions will decline gradually to 9.5 million 
    tons in 2015. Variations in such emissions during the forecast period 
    primarily reflect economic use of the Title IV emissions banking 
    program, under which emitting parties may elect to over-control 
    SO2 in any year and bank the extra reductions as emission 
    credits for later use;
        2. Regional SO2 emissions generally will follow the same 
    pattern as the national emissions total. However, emissions reductions 
    and shifts are not expected to occur uniformly across regions because 
    the SO2 emissions trading program allows emitting parties 
    with higher costs of pollution control to purchase allowances from 
    emitting parties with lower control costs. This can lead to increases 
    in emissions from certain regions;
        3. NOX emissions are projected to decline to 4.1 million 
    tons in 2015. These reductions are due to the development of 
    NOX regulations under the Clean Air Act. Furthermore, summer 
    or ``ozone season'' (May to September) NOX emissions are 
    projected to decrease to 1.3 million tons in 2015;
        4. Regional NOX emissions are projected to follow a 
    pattern similar to the national trend; however, the implementation of 
    NOX controls is assumed to take the form of an emission cap 
    and permit trading program similar to the Title IV SO2 
    program. Consequently, certain regions may experience different 
    NOX emissions trends because of the relative costs of 
    controlling NOX and the possibility of trading between 
    emitting parties;
        5. CO2 is projected to increase throughout the analysis 
    period by 27 percent. Because CO2 is an unregulated 
    pollutant at the present time, and because both coal and natural gas 
    emit CO2, the rise in both coal and gas-fired generation 
    leads to a substantial increase in CO2 emissions during the 
    analysis period; and
        6. Mercury emissions range between 50.6 and 53.2 tons during the 
    forecast period with no clear trend distinguishable. Mercury is also 
    uncontrolled at the present time, but emissions are closely linked to 
    coal use (with considerable variation of mercury content in coal from 
    specific seams). The relative stability of coal-fired generation in 
    later years of the analysis period leads to the observed pattern of 
    mercury emissions.
        The analysis indicates that the Midwest is expected to produce 
    slightly more power, the East Coast to produce slightly less power. 
    These changes are likely to be greatest in the near-term, and to 
    decline toward baseline levels over time. The Final Rule would result 
    in the slight shifting of the baseline fuel mix projections toward coal 
    and away from fuel oil and, to some extent, natural gas; these changes 
    are small relative to the overall trend in the fuel mix, in which 
    natural gas remains the most rapidly growing fuel. This is consistent 
    with the change in regional levels of generation.
        The analysis shows that the overall emissions of SOX, 
    NOX, mercury, and CO2, are directionally 
    consistent with the observed changes in power generation and fuel mix. 
    That is, emissions tend to increase early in the forecast period and 
    then decline over time, with several instances of emissions reductions. 
    The greatest change in any regulated pollutant (a rise of 3.6 percent 
    or 381,000 tons of SO2 in one scenario) occurs as a result 
    of changing patterns of emissions banking and trading, which is 
    consistent with the design of the SO2 cap and trade 
    regulatory program. Regional variations in annual and summer 
    NOX are also possible and are also consistent with 
    regulatory program design. Emissions budgets are met at all times. 
    Other emission changes are relatively small because coal-fired plants, 
    which contribute a disproportionate share of these emissions, are 
    already heavily utilized and so are unable to increase their output 
    significantly in the rulemaking scenarios. In one scenario designed to 
    examine increased new entry and demand flexibility,
    
    [[Page 952]]
    
    substantial emissions reductions occur as a result of lower demand for 
    electricity combined with cleaner new supply options.
    
    V. Regulatory Flexibility Act Certification
    
        The Commission received no comments on its certification, in the 
    NOPR, that the proposed rule would not have a significant economic 
    impact on a substantial number of small entities and that an initial 
    regulatory flexibility analysis is not required by 5 U.S.C. Sec. 603. 
    The Commission adheres to its earlier reasoning and thus concludes that 
    a final regulatory flexibility analysis also is not required.\753\ In 
    making this determination, the Commission is required to examine only 
    the direct compliance costs that a rulemaking imposes upon small 
    businesses. It is not required to consider indirect economic 
    consequences, nor is it required to consider costs that an entity 
    incurs voluntarily.\754\ This rulemaking does not impose significant 
    compliance costs upon small entities. Instead, it leaves them with the 
    choice of whether to join an RTO. The only costs that are mandated are 
    the minimal costs associated with filing a statement, in the event a 
    public utility does not make an RTO filing, explaining its efforts to 
    join an RTO, any barriers it encountered, and any future plans to join 
    an RTO. Thus, this rulemaking will not have a significant economic 
    impact upon any small entities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \753\ See 5 U.S.C. 604.
        \754\ Mid-Tex Elec. Coop. v. FERC, 773 F.2d 327 (D.C. Cir. 1985) 
    (Commission need only consider small entities ``that would be 
    directly regulated''); Colorado State Banking Bd. v. RTC, 926 F.2d 
    931 (10th Cir. 1991) (Regulatory Flexibility Act not implicated 
    where regulation simply added an option for affected entities and 
    did not impose any costs).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    VI. Public Reporting Burden and Information Collection Statement
    
        The OMB regulations require OMB to approve certain reporting and 
    recordkeeping (collections of information) imposed by agency rule.\755\ 
    The NOPR was submitted to OMB at the time of issuance. OMB did not 
    comment nor did it take any action on the proposed rule. FERC 
    identifies the information provided under Part 35 as FERC-516 \756\ and 
    under Part 33 as FERC-519.\757\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \755\ 5 CFR 1320.11, 44 U.S.C. 3507(d).
        \756\ Electric Rate Schedule Filings.
        \757\ Application for Sale, Lease, or Other Disposition, Merger 
    or Consolidation of Facilities or for the Purchase or Acquisition of 
    Securities of a Public Utility.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        No comments from the public on the burden estimate were received. 
    The filing requirements remain essentially the same as those in the 
    NOPR so, therefore, the estimated annual filing burden remains the 
    same. The burden estimates for complying with this proposed rule are 
    set out in Table 1. The total annual hours for collection (reporting + 
    recordkeeping (if appropriate)) is 7,600.
        Information Collection Costs: The Commission has projected the 
    average annualized cost for all respondents to be: Annualized Costs 
    (Operations & Maintenance): $401,518 (7,600 hours  2080 hours 
    per year  x  $109,889=$401,518). The cost per respondent is $7,722 
    (participants and non-participants).
    
                                            Table 1.--Estimated Annual Burden
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                                         Number of       Number of       Hours Per     Total Annual
                     Data Collection                    Respondents      Responses       Response          Hours
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
    FERC-516 \1\....................................              12               1             300           3,600
    FERC-516 \2\....................................              40               1              40           1,600
    FERC-519 \1\....................................              12               1             200           2,400
                                                     ---------------------------------------------------------------
          Totals....................................  ..............  ..............  ..............           7,600
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
    \1\ Filings to propose participation in an RTO under Sec.  35.34(d).
    \2\ Alternative filings under Sec.  35.34(g).
    
        Comments were solicited on the Commission's need for this 
    information, whether the information will have practical utility, the 
    accuracy of the provided burden estimates, ways to enhance the quality, 
    utility, and clarity of the information to be collected, and any 
    suggested methods for minimizing respondents' burden, including the use 
    of automated information techniques.
        Title: FERC-516, Electric Rate Schedule Filings; FERC-519 
    Application for Sale, Lease, or Other Disposition, Merger or 
    Consolidation of Facilities or for the Purchase or Acquisition of 
    Securities of a Public Utility.
    
        Action: Proposed Data Collections.
        OMB Control No.: 1902-0096 and 1902-0082.
        The applicant shall not be penalized for failure to respond to this 
    collection of information unless the collection of information displays 
    a valid OMB control number.
        Respondents: Business or other for profit, including small 
    businesses.
        Frequency of Responses: One time.
        Necessity of Information: The Final Rule revises the requirements 
    contained in 18 CFR part 35. The Commission is promoting the voluntary 
    establishment of RTOs nationwide by December 2001. In particular, the 
    Commission will establish in this rule characteristics and functions 
    which applicants must meet to become Commission-approved RTOs. The 
    Commission will engage in a collaborative process with state officials 
    and others to facilitate RTO development. The rule will require that 
    each public utility that owns, operates or controls transmission 
    facilities participate in one-time filings proposing an RTO or make a 
    filing explaining why they are not participating in an RTO proposal.
        Internal Review: The Commission has assured itself, by means of 
    internal review, that there is specific, objective support for the 
    burden estimates associated with the information requirements. The 
    Commission's Office of Markets, Tariffs and Rates will use the data 
    included in filings under 18 CFR 35.34 to evaluate efforts for the 
    interconnection and coordination of the U.S. electric transmission 
    system and to ensure the orderly formation of RTOs as well as for 
    general industry oversight. These information requirements conform to 
    the Commission's plan for efficient information collection, 
    communication, and management within the electric power industry.
        The Commission received approximately 334 comments and reply 
    comments on its NOPR but none on its reporting burden. The Commission's 
    responses to the comments are addressed in the preamble of this Final
    
    [[Page 953]]
    
    Rule. The Commission is submitting a copy of the Final Rule along with 
    information collection submissions for the data collections identified 
    above to OMB for its review and approval.
        Interested persons may obtain information on the reporting 
    requirements by contacting the following: Federal Energy Regulatory 
    Commission, 888 First Street, NE, Washington, DC 20426 [Attention: 
    Michael Miller, Office of the Chief Information Officer, Phone: (202) 
    208-1415, fax: (202) 208-2425, E-mail: mike.miller@ferc.fed.us] or send 
    your comments to the Office of Management and Budget, Office of 
    Information and Regulatory Affairs, Washington, DC 20503, [Attention: 
    Desk Officer for the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, phone: (202) 
    395-3087, fax: (202) 395-7285].
    
    VII. Effective Date and Congressional Notification
    
        This rule will take effect March 6, 2000. The Commission has 
    determined, with the concurrence of the Administrator of the Office of 
    Information and Regulatory Affairs of the Office of Management and 
    Budget, that this Rule is a ``major rule'' within the meaning of 
    section 351 of the Small Business Regulatory Enforcement Act of 
    1996.\758\ The Rule will be submitted to both Houses of Congress and 
    the Comptroller General prior to its publication in the Federal 
    Register.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \758\ 5 U.S.C. 804(2).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    VIII. Document Availability
    
        In addition to publishing the full text of this document in the 
    Federal Register, the Commission provides all interested persons an 
    opportunity to view and/or print the contents of this document via the 
    Internet through FERC's Home Page (http://www.ferc.fed.us) and in 
    FERC's Public Reference Room during normal business hours (8:30 a.m. to 
    5:00 p.m. Eastern time) at 888 First Street, N.E., Room 2A, Washington, 
    D.C. 20426.
        From FERC's Home Page on the Internet, this information is 
    available in both the Commission Issuance Posting System (CIPS) and the 
    Records and Information Management System (RIMS).
         CIPS provides access to the texts of formal documents 
    issued by the Commission since November 14, 1994. CIPS can be accessed 
    using the CIPS link or the Energy Information Online icon. The full 
    text of this document will be available on CIPS in ASCII and 
    WordPerfect 8.0 format for viewing, printing, and/or downloading.
         RIMS contains images of documents submitted to and issues 
    by the Commission after November 16, 1981. Documents from November 1995 
    to the present can be viewed and printed from FERC's Home Page using 
    the RIMS link or the Energy Information Online icon. Descriptions of 
    documents back to November 16, 1981, are also available from RIMS-on-
    the-Web; requests for copies of these and other older documents should 
    be submitted to the Public Reference Room.
        User assistance is available for RIMS, CIPS, and the Website during 
    normal business hours from our Help line at (202) 208-2222 (e-mail to 
    WebMaster@ferc.fed.us) of the Public Reference Room at (202) 208-1371 
    (e-mail to public.referenceroom@ferc.fed.us).
        During normal business hours, documents can also be viewed and/or 
    printed in FERC's Public Reference Room, where RIMS, CIPS, and the FERC 
    Website are available. User assistance is also available.
    
    List of Subjects in 18 CFR Part 35
    
        Electric power rates, Electric utilities, Reporting and 
    recordkeeping requirements
    
        By the Commission.
    David P. Boergers,
    Secretary.
    
        In consideration of the foregoing, the Commission amends Part 35, 
    Chapter I, Title 18 of the Code of Federal Regulations, as follows:
    
    PART 35--FILING OF RATE SCHEDULES
    
        1. The authority citation for Part 35 continues to read as follows:
    
        Authority: 16 U.S.C. 791a-825r, 2601-2645; 31 U.S.C. 9701; 42 
    U.S.C. 7101-7352.
    
        2. Part 35 is amended by adding a new Subpart F and a new 
    Sec. 35.34 to read as follows:
    
    Subpart F--Procedures and Requirements Regarding Regional 
    Transmission Organizations
    
    
    Sec. 35.34  Regional Transmission Organizations.
    
        (a) Purpose. This section establishes required characteristics and 
    functions for Regional Transmission Organizations for the purpose of 
    promoting efficiency and reliability in the operation and planning of 
    the electric transmission grid and ensuring non-discrimination in the 
    provision of electric transmission services. This section further 
    directs each public utility that owns, operates, or controls facilities 
    used for the transmission of electric energy in interstate commerce to 
    make certain filings with respect to forming and participating in a 
    Regional Transmission Organization.
        (b) Definitions.
        (1) Regional Transmission Organization means an entity that 
    satisfies the minimum characteristics set forth in paragraph (j) of 
    this section, performs the functions set forth in paragraph (k) of this 
    section, and accommodates the open architecture condition set forth in 
    paragraph (l) of this section.
        (2) Market participant means:
        (i) Any entity that, either directly or through an affiliate, sells 
    or brokers electric energy, or provides transmission or ancillary 
    services to the Regional Transmission Organization, unless the 
    Commission finds that the entity does not have economic or commercial 
    interests that would be significantly affected by the Regional 
    Transmission Organization's actions or decisions; and
        (ii) Any other entity that the Commission finds has economic or 
    commercial interests that would be significantly affected by the 
    Regional Transmission Organization's actions or decisions.
        (3) Affiliate means the definition given in section 2(a)(11) of the 
    Public Utility Holding Company Act (15 U.S.C. 79b(a)(11)).
        (4) Class of market participants means two or more market 
    participants with common economic or commercial interests.
        (c) General rule. Except for those public utilities subject to the 
    requirements of paragraph (h) of this section, every public utility 
    that owns, operates or controls facilities used for the transmission of 
    electric energy in interstate commerce as of March 6, 2000 must file 
    with the Commission, no later than October 15, 2000, one of the 
    following:
        (1) A proposal to participate in a Regional Transmission 
    Organization consisting of one of the types of submittals set forth in 
    paragraph (d) of this section; or
        (2) An alternative filing consistent with paragraph (g) of this 
    section.
        (d) Proposal to participate in a Regional Transmission 
    Organization. For purposes of this section, a proposal to participate 
    in a Regional Transmission Organization means:
        (1) Such filings, made individually or jointly with other entities, 
    pursuant to sections 203, 205 and 206 of the Federal Power Act (16 
    U.S.C. 824b, 824d, and 824e), as are necessary to create a new Regional 
    Transmission Organization;
    
    [[Page 954]]
    
        (2) Such filings, made individually or jointly with other entities, 
    pursuant to sections 203, 205 and 206 of the Federal Power Act (16 
    U.S.C. 824b, 824d, and 824e), as are necessary to join a Regional 
    Transmission Organization approved by the Commission on or before the 
    date of the filing; or
        (3) A petition for declaratory order, filed individually or jointly 
    with other entities, asking whether a proposed transmission entity 
    would qualify as a Regional Transmission Organization and containing at 
    least the following:
        (i) A detailed description of the proposed transmission entity, 
    including a description of the organizational and operational structure 
    and the intended participants;
        (ii) A discussion of how the transmission entity would satisfy each 
    of the characteristics and functions of a Regional Transmission 
    Organization specified in paragraphs (j), (k) and (l) of this section;
        (iii) A detailed description of the Federal Power Act section 205 
    rates that will be filed for the Regional Transmission Organization; 
    and
        (iv) A commitment to make filings pursuant to sections 203, 205 and 
    206 of the Federal Power Act (16 U.S.C. 824b, 824d, and 824e), as 
    necessary, promptly after the Commission issues an order in response to 
    the petition.
        (4) Any proposal filed under this paragraph (d) must include an 
    explanation of efforts made to include public power entities in the 
    proposed Regional Transmission Organization.
        (e) Innovative transmission rate treatments for Regional 
    Transmission Organizations. 
        (1) The Commission will consider authorizing any innovative 
    transmission rate treatment, as discussed in this paragraph (e), for an 
    approved Regional Transmission Organization. An applicant's request 
    must include:
        (i) A detailed explanation of how any proposed rate treatment would 
    help achieve the goals of Regional Transmission Organizations, 
    including efficient use of and investment in the transmission system 
    and reliability benefits to consumers;
        (ii) A cost-benefit analysis, including rate impacts; and
        (iii) A detailed explanation of why the proposed rate treatment is 
    appropriate for the Regional Transmission Organization.
        The applicant must support any rate proposal under this paragraph 
    (e) as just, reasonable, and not unduly discriminatory or preferential.
        (2) For purposes of this paragraph (e), innovative transmission 
    rate treatment means any of the following:
        (i) A transmission rate moratorium, which may include proposals 
    based on formerly bundled retail transmission rates;
        (ii) Rates of return that:
        (A) Are formulary;
        (B) Consider risk premiums and account for demonstrated adjustments 
    in risk; or
        (C) Do not vary with capital structure;
        (iii) Non-traditional depreciation schedules for new transmission 
    investment;
        (iv) Transmission rates based on levelized recovery of capital 
    costs;
        (v) Transmission rates that combine elements of incremental cost 
    pricing for new transmission facilities with an embedded-cost access 
    fee for existing transmission facilities; or
        (vi) Performance-based transmission rates.
        (3) A request for performance-based transmission rates under this 
    paragraph (e) may include factors such as:
        (i) A method for calculating initial transmission rates (including 
    price caps and any provisions for discounting);
        (ii) A mechanism for adjusting initial rates, which may be derived 
    from or based upon external factors or indices or a specific 
    performance measure;
        (iii) Time periods for redetermining initial rates; and
        (iv) Costs to be excluded from performance-based rates.
        (4) An innovative transmission rate treatment or any other rate 
    proposal made for an approved Regional Transmission Organization may be 
    requested as part of any filing that is made under paragraph (d) of 
    this section or in any subsequent rate change proposal under section 
    205 of the Federal Power Act (16 U.S.C. 824d). Unless otherwise ordered 
    by the Commission, an approved Regional Transmission Organization may 
    not include in rates any innovative transmission rate treatment under 
    paragraphs (e)(2)(i) and (e)(2)(ii)(C) of this section after January 1, 
    2005.
        (f) Transfer of operational control. The public utility's proposal 
    to participate in a Regional Transmission Organization filed pursuant 
    to paragraph (c)(1) of this section must propose that operational 
    control of that public utility's transmission facilities will be 
    transferred to the Regional Transmission Organization on a schedule 
    that will allow the Regional Transmission Organization to commence 
    operating the facilities no later than December 15, 2001.
    
        Note to paragraph (f): The requirement in paragraph (f) of this 
    section may be satisfied by proposing to transfer to the Regional 
    Transmission Organization ownership of the facilities in addition to 
    operational control.
    
        (g) Alternative filing. Any filing made pursuant to paragraph 
    (c)(2) of this section must contain:
        (1) A description of any efforts made by that public utility to 
    participate in a Regional Transmission Organization;
        (2) A detailed explanation of the economic, operational, 
    commercial, regulatory, or other reasons the public utility has not 
    made a filing to participate in a Regional Transmission Organization, 
    including identification of any existing obstacles to participation in 
    a Regional Transmission Organization; and
        (3) The specific plans, if any, the public utility has for further 
    work toward participation in a Regional Transmission Organization, a 
    proposed timetable for such activity, an explanation of efforts made to 
    include public power entities in the proposed Regional Transmission 
    Organization, and any factors (including any law, rule or regulation) 
    that may affect the public utility's ability or decision to participate 
    in a Regional Transmission Organization.
        (h) Public utilities participating in approved transmission 
    entities. Every public utility that owns, operates or controls 
    facilities used for the transmission of electric energy in interstate 
    commerce as of March 6, 2000, and that has filed with the Commission on 
    or before March 6, 2000 to transfer operational control of its 
    facilities to a transmission entity that has been approved or 
    conditionally approved by the Commission on or before March 6, 2000 as 
    being in conformance with the eleven ISO principles set forth in Order 
    No. 888, FERC Statutes and Regulations, Regulations Preamble January 
    1991-June 1996 para. 31,036 (Final Rule on Open Access and Stranded 
    Costs), must, individually or jointly with other entities, file with 
    the Commission, no later than January 15, 2001:
        (1) A statement that it is participating in a transmission entity 
    that has been so approved;
        (2) A detailed explanation of the extent to which the transmission 
    entity in which it participates has the characteristics and performs 
    the functions of a Regional Transmission Organization specified in 
    paragraphs (j) and (k) of this section and accommodates the open 
    architecture conditions in paragraph (l) of this section; and
        (3) To the extent the transmission entity in which the public 
    utility participates does not meet all the requirements of a Regional 
    Transmission Organization specified in paragraphs (j), (k), and (l) of 
    this section,
    
    [[Page 955]]
    
        (i) A proposal to participate in a Regional Transmission 
    Organization that meets such requirements in accordance with paragraph 
    (d) of this section,
        (ii) A proposal to modify the existing transmission entity so that 
    it conforms to the requirements of a Regional Transmission 
    Organization, or
        (iii) A filing containing the information specified in paragraph 
    (g) of this section addressing any efforts, obstacles, and plans with 
    respect to conformance with those requirements.
        (i) Entities that become public utilities with transmission 
    facilities. An entity that is not a public utility that owns, operates 
    or controls facilities used for the transmission of electric energy in 
    interstate commerce as of March 6, 2000, but later becomes such a 
    public utility, must file a proposal to participate in a Regional 
    Transmission Organization in accordance with paragraph (d) of this 
    section, or an alternative filing in accordance with paragraph (g) of 
    this section, by October 15, 2000 or 60 days prior to the date on which 
    the public utility engages in any transmission of electric energy in 
    interstate commerce, whichever comes later. If a proposal to 
    participate in accordance with paragraph (d) of this section is filed, 
    it must propose that operational control of the applicant's 
    transmission system will be transferred to the Regional Transmission 
    Organization within six months of filing the proposal.
        (j) Required characteristics for a Regional Transmission 
    Organization. A Regional Transmission Organization must satisfy the 
    following characteristics when it commences operation:
        (1) Independence. The Regional Transmission Organization must be 
    independent of any market participant. The Regional Transmission 
    Organization must include, as part of its demonstration of 
    independence, a demonstration that it meets the following:
        (i) The Regional Transmission Organization, its employees, and any 
    non-stakeholder directors must not have financial interests in any 
    market participant.
        (ii) The Regional Transmission Organization must have a decision 
    making process that is independent of control by any market participant 
    or class of participants.
        (iii) The Regional Transmission Organization must have exclusive 
    and independent authority under section 205 of the Federal Power Act 
    (16 U.S.C. 824d), to propose rates, terms and conditions of 
    transmission service provided over the facilities it operates. Note to 
    paragraph (j)(1)(iii): Transmission owners retain authority under 
    section 205 of the Federal Power Act (16 U.S.C. 824d) to seek recovery 
    from the Regional Transmission Organization of the revenue requirements 
    associated with the transmission facilities that they own.
        (2) Scope and regional configuration. The Regional Transmission 
    Organization must serve an appropriate region. The region must be of 
    sufficient scope and configuration to permit the Regional Transmission 
    Organization to maintain reliability, effectively perform its required 
    functions, and support efficient and non-discriminatory power markets.
        (3) Operational authority. The Regional Transmission Organization 
    must have operational authority for all transmission facilities under 
    its control. The Regional Transmission Organization must include, as 
    part of its demonstration of operational authority, a demonstration 
    that it meets the following:
        (i) If any operational functions are delegated to, or shared with, 
    entities other than the Regional Transmission Organization, the 
    Regional Transmission Organization must ensure that this sharing of 
    operational authority will not adversely affect reliability or provide 
    any market participant with an unfair competitive advantage. Within two 
    years after initial operation as a Regional Transmission Organization, 
    the Regional Transmission Organization must prepare a public report 
    that assesses whether any division of operational authority hinders the 
    Regional Transmission Organization in providing reliable, non-
    discriminatory and efficiently priced transmission service.
        (ii) The Regional Transmission Organization must be the security 
    coordinator for the facilities that it controls.
        (4) Short-term reliability. The Regional Transmission Organization 
    must have exclusive authority for maintaining the short-term 
    reliability of the grid that it operates. The Regional Transmission 
    Organization must include, as part of its demonstration with respect to 
    reliability, a demonstration that it meets the following:
        (i) The Regional Transmission Organization must have exclusive 
    authority for receiving, confirming and implementing all interchange 
    schedules.
        (ii) The Regional Transmission Organization must have the right to 
    order redispatch of any generator connected to transmission facilities 
    it operates if necessary for the reliable operation of these 
    facilities.
        (iii) When the Regional Transmission Organization operates 
    transmission facilities owned by other entities, the Regional 
    Transmission Organization must have authority to approve or disapprove 
    all requests for scheduled outages of transmission facilities to ensure 
    that the outages can be accommodated within established reliability 
    standards.
        (iv) If the Regional Transmission Organization operates under 
    reliability standards established by another entity (e.g., a regional 
    reliability council), the Regional Transmission Organization must 
    report to the Commission if these standards hinder it from providing 
    reliable, non-discriminatory and efficiently priced transmission 
    service.
        (k) Required functions of a Regional Transmission Organization. The 
    Regional Transmission Organization must perform the following 
    functions. Unless otherwise noted, the Regional Transmission 
    Organization must satisfy these obligations when it commences 
    operations.
        (1) Tariff administration and design. The Regional Transmission 
    Organization must administer its own transmission tariff and employ a 
    transmission pricing system that will promote efficient use and 
    expansion of transmission and generation facilities. As part of its 
    demonstration with respect to tariff administration and design, the 
    Regional Transmission Organization must satisfy the standards listed in 
    paragraphs (k)(1) (i) and (ii) of this section, or demonstrate that an 
    alternative proposal is consistent with or superior to satisfying such 
    standards.
        (i) The Regional Transmission Organization must be the only 
    provider of transmission service over the facilities under its control, 
    and must be the sole administrator of its own Commission-approved open 
    access transmission tariff. The Regional Transmission Organization must 
    have the sole authority to receive, evaluate, and approve or deny all 
    requests for transmission service. The Regional Transmission 
    Organization must have the authority to review and approve requests for 
    new interconnections.
        (ii) Customers under the Regional Transmission Organization tariff 
    must not be charged multiple access fees for the recovery of capital 
    costs for transmission service over facilities that the Regional 
    Transmission Organization controls.
        (2) Congestion management. The Regional Transmission Organization 
    must ensure the development and operation of market mechanisms to
    
    [[Page 956]]
    
    manage transmission congestion. As part of its demonstration with 
    respect to congestion management, the Regional Transmission 
    Organization must satisfy the standards listed in paragraph (k)(2)(i) 
    of this section, or demonstrate that an alternative proposal is 
    consistent with or superior to satisfying such standards.
        (i) The market mechanisms must accommodate broad participation by 
    all market participants, and must provide all transmission customers 
    with efficient price signals that show the consequences of their 
    transmission usage decisions. The Regional Transmission Organization 
    must either operate such markets itself or ensure that the task is 
    performed by another entity that is not affiliated with any market 
    participant.
        (ii) The Regional Transmission Organization must satisfy the market 
    mechanism requirement no later than one year after it commences initial 
    operation. However, it must have in place at the time of initial 
    operation an effective protocol for managing congestion.
        (3) Parallel path flow. The Regional Transmission Organization must 
    develop and implement procedures to address parallel path flow issues 
    within its region and with other regions. The Regional Transmission 
    Organization must satisfy this requirement with respect to coordination 
    with other regions no later than three years after it commences initial 
    operation.
        (4) Ancillary services. The Regional Transmission Organization must 
    serve as a provider of last resort of all ancillary services required 
    by Order No. 888, FERC Statutes and Regulations, Regulations Preamble 
    January 1991-June 1996 para. 31,036 (Final Rule on Open Access and 
    Stranded Costs), and subsequent orders. As part of its demonstration 
    with respect to ancillary services, the Regional Transmission 
    Organization must satisfy the standards listed in paragraphs (k)(4)(i)-
    (iii) of this section, or demonstrate that an alternative proposal is 
    consistent with or superior to satisfying such standards.
        (i) All market participants must have the option of self-supplying 
    or acquiring ancillary services from third parties subject to any 
    restrictions imposed by the Commission in Order No. 888, FERC Statutes 
    and Regulations, Regulations Preamble January 1991-June 1996 para. 
    31,036 (Final Rule on Open Access and Stranded Costs), and subsequent 
    orders.
        (ii) The Regional Transmission Organization must have the authority 
    to decide the minimum required amounts of each ancillary service and, 
    if necessary, the locations at which these services must be provided. 
    All ancillary service providers must be subject to direct or indirect 
    operational control by the Regional Transmission Organization. The 
    Regional Transmission Organization must promote the development of 
    competitive markets for ancillary services whenever feasible.
        (iii) The Regional Transmission Organization must ensure that its 
    transmission customers have access to a real-time balancing market. The 
    Regional Transmission Organization must either develop and operate this 
    market itself or ensure that this task is performed by another entity 
    that is not affiliated with any market participant.
        (5) OASIS and Total Transmission Capability (TTC) and Available 
    Transmission Capability (ATC). The Regional Transmission Organization 
    must be the single OASIS site administrator for all transmission 
    facilities under its control and independently calculate TTC and ATC.
        (6) Market monitoring. To ensure that the Regional Transmission 
    Organization provides reliable, efficient and not unduly discriminatory 
    transmission service, the Regional Transmission Organization must 
    provide for objective monitoring of markets it operates or administers 
    to identify market design flaws, market power abuses and opportunities 
    for efficiency improvements, and propose appropriate actions. As part 
    of its demonstration with respect to market monitoring, the Regional 
    Transmission Organization must satisfy the standards listed in 
    paragraphs (k)(6)(i) through (k)(6)(iii) of this section, or 
    demonstrate that an alternative proposal is consistent with or superior 
    to satisfying such standards.
        (i) Market monitoring must include monitoring the behavior of 
    market participants in the region, including transmission owners other 
    than the Regional Transmission Organization, if any, to determine if 
    their actions hinder the Regional Transmission Organization in 
    providing reliable, efficient and not unduly discriminatory 
    transmission service.
        (ii) With respect to markets the Regional Transmission Organization 
    operates or administers, there must be a periodic assessment of how 
    behavior in markets operated by others (e.g., bilateral power sales 
    markets and power markets operated by unaffiliated power exchanges) 
    affects Regional Transmission Organization operations and how Regional 
    Transmission Organization operations affect the efficiency of power 
    markets operated by others.
        (iii) Reports on opportunities for efficiency improvement, market 
    power abuses and market design flaws must be filed with the Commission 
    and affected regulatory authorities.
        (7) Planning and expansion. The Regional Transmission Organization 
    must be responsible for planning, and for directing or arranging, 
    necessary transmission expansions, additions, and upgrades that will 
    enable it to provide efficient, reliable and non-discriminatory 
    transmission service and coordinate such efforts with the appropriate 
    state authorities. As part of its demonstration with respect to 
    planning and expansion, the Regional Transmission Organization must 
    satisfy the standards listed in paragraphs (k)(7)(i) and (ii) of this 
    section, or demonstrate that an alternative proposal is consistent with 
    or superior to satisfying such standards.
        (i) The Regional Transmission Organization planning and expansion 
    process must encourage market-driven operating and investment actions 
    for preventing and relieving congestion.
        (ii) The Regional Transmission Organization's planning and 
    expansion process must accommodate efforts by state regulatory 
    commissions to create multi-state agreements to review and approve new 
    transmission facilities. The Regional Transmission Organization's 
    planning and expansion process must be coordinated with programs of 
    existing Regional Transmission Groups (See Sec. 2.21 of this chapter) 
    where appropriate.
        (iii) If the Regional Transmission Organization is unable to 
    satisfy this requirement when it commences operation, it must file with 
    the Commission a plan with specified milestones that will ensure that 
    it meets this requirement no later than three years after initial 
    operation.
        (8) Interregional coordination. The Regional Transmission 
    Organization must ensure the integration of reliability practices 
    within an interconnection and market interface practices among regions.
        (l) Open architecture.
        (1) Any proposal to participate in a Regional Transmission 
    Organization must not contain any provision that would limit the 
    capability of the Regional Transmission Organization to evolve in ways 
    that would improve its efficiency, consistent with the requirements in 
    paragraphs (j) and (k) of this section.
        (2) Nothing in this regulation precludes an approved Regional 
    Transmission Organization from seeking to evolve with respect to its 
    organizational design, market design,
    
    [[Page 957]]
    
    geographic scope, ownership arrangements, or methods of operational 
    control, or in other appropriate ways if the change is consistent with 
    the requirements of this section. Any future filing seeking approval of 
    such changes must demonstrate that the proposed changes will meet the 
    requirements of paragraphs (j), (k) and (l) of this section.
    
        Note: The following appendix will not appear in the Code of 
    Federal Regulations.
    
    Appendix to Preamble--List of Commenters
    
    Abbreviation--Commenter
    
        1. Advisory Committee ISO-NE--Advisory Committee to the Board of 
    Directors of ISO New England.
        2. AEP--American Electric Power Service Corporation and its 
    public utility operating company subsidiaries: Appalachian Power 
    Company, Columbus Southern Power Company, Indiana Michigan Power 
    Company, Kentucky Power Company, Kingsport Power Company, Ohio Power 
    Company. and Wheeling Power Company.
        3. AEPCO--Arizona Electric Power Cooperative, Inc.
        4. Alabama Commission--Alabama Public Service Commission.
        5. Alberta--Provence of Alberta, Electricity Branch.
        6. Allegheny--Allegheny Energy, Inc.
        7. Alliance Companies--American Electric Power Service 
    Corporation, Consumers Energy Company, Detroit Edison Company, 
    FirstEnergy Corp. and Virginia Electric and Power Company.
        8. Alliant Energy--Alliant Energy Corporation.
        9. Aluminum Companies--Alcoa Inc., Columbia Falls Aluminum 
    Company, Kaiser Aluminum & Chemical Corporation and Vanalco, Inc.
        10. American Forest--American Forest & Paper Association.
        11. AMP-Ohio--American Municipal Power-Ohio, Inc.
        12. APPA--American Public Power Association.
        13. APPA et al. (WP)--Legal White Paper prepared on behalf of 
    and sponsored jointly by the American Public Power Association, the 
    Electric Consumers Resource Council, the Transmission Access Policy 
    Study Group and the Transmission Dependent Utility Systems.
        14. APS--Arizona Public Service Company.
        15. APX--Automated Power Exchange, Inc.
        16. Arizona Authority--Arizona Power Authority.
        17. Arizona Commission--Arizona Corporation Commission.
        18. Arizona ISA--Arizona Independent Scheduling Administrator 
    Association.
        19. Arkansas Cities--Cities of Benton, Bentonville, North Little 
    Rock, Osceola, Piggott, Prescott and Siloam Springs, Arkansas; the 
    Clarksville Light and Water Company; Conway Corporation; Hope Water 
    and Light Commission; City Water and Light Plant of the City of 
    Jonesboro, Arkansas; Paragould Light and Water Commission; and the 
    West Memphis, Arkansas Utilities Commission.
        20. Arkansas Consumers--Arkansas Electric Energy Consumers.
        21. Avista--Avista Corporation, Inc.
        22. Bangor Hydro--Bangor Hydro-Electric Company.
        23. BC Hydro--British Columbia Hydro & Power Authority.
        24. Big Rivers--Big Rivers Electric Corporation.
        25. Blue Ridge--Blue Ridge Power Agency.
        26. Brattle Group--The Brattle Group (Peter Fox-Penner and 
    Philip Hanser).
        27. British Columbia Ministry--British Columbia, Canada, 
    Ministry of Employment and Investment, Electricity Development 
    Branch.
        28. Cal DWR--California Department of Water Resources.
        29. Cal ISO--California Independent System Operator Corporation.
        30. California Board--California Electricity Oversight Board.
        31. California Commission--Public Utilities Commission of the 
    State of California.
        32. CalPX--California Power Exchange Corporation.
        33. CAMU--Colorado Association of Municipal Utilities.
        34. Canada DNR--Canada Department of Natural Resources.
        35. CCEM/ELCON--Coalition for a Competitive Electricity Market 
    and the Electricity Consumers Resources Council.
        36. CEA--Canadian Electricity Association.
        37. Consumers Energy--Consumers Energy Company.
        38. Central Maine--Central Maine Power Company and Maine 
    Electric Power Company.
        39. Champion--Champion International Corporation.
        40. Chelan--Public Utility District No. 1 of Chelan County.
        41. Cinergy--Cinergy Services, Inc.
        42. Clarksdale--Clarksdale Public Utilities Commission.
        43. Cleco--Cleco Corporation.
        44. Cleveland--City of Cleveland, Ohio.
        45. CMUA--California Municipal Utilities Association.
        46. Coalition of Alliance Users--Coalition of Municipal and 
    Cooperative Users of Alliance Companies' Transmission.
        47. ComEd--Commonwealth Edison Company.
        48. Conectiv--Conectiv (Atlantic City Electric Company and 
    Delmarva Power & Light Company.
        49. Conlon--Mr. P. Gregory Conlon.
        50. Consumer Groups--Industrial Consumers, American Public Power 
    Association, National Rural Electric Cooperative Association, 
    Transmission Access Policy Study Group, Transmission Dependent 
    Utility Systems, Consumer Federation of America and International 
    Mass Retail Association.
        51. CP&L--Carolina Power & Light Company.
        52. CRC--Colorado River Commission of the State of Nevada.
        53. CREDA--Colorado River Energy Distributors Association.
        54. CSU--Colorado Springs Utilities.
        55. CTA--Competitive Transmission Association, Inc.
        56. Dalton Utilities--Board of Water, Light and Sinking Fund 
    Commissioners of the City of Dalton, Georgia.
        57. Dairyland--Dairyland Power Cooperative.
        58. Desert STAR--Desert STAR.
        59. Detroit Edison--Detroit Edison Company.
        60. Distributed Power--Distributed Power Coalition of America.
        61. DOE--United States Department of Energy.
        62. Dr. Illic--Dr. Marija Illic and Yong Yoon.
        63. Duke--Duke Energy Corporation.
        64. Duquesne--Duquesne Light Company.
        65. Dynegy--Dynegy Inc.
        66. EAL--ESBI Alberta Ltd.
        67. East Kentucky--East Kentucky Power Cooperative, Inc.
        68. East Texas Cooperatives--East Texas Electric Cooperative, 
    Inc., Northeast Texas Electric Cooperative, Inc., Sam Rayburn G&T 
    Electric Cooperative, Inc., Tex-La Electric Cooperative of Texas, 
    Inc.
        69. ECAR--East Central Area Reliability Council.
        70. EEI--Edison Electric Institute.
        71. EME--Edison Mission Energy.
        72. Empire District--Empire District Electric Company.
        73. Enron/APX/Coral Power--Enron Power Marketing, Inc., 
    Automated Power Exchange and Coral Power, L.L.C.
        74. Entergy--Entergy Services Inc.
        75. EPA--United States Environmental Protection Agency.
        76. EPRI--Electric Power Research Institute.
        77. EPSA--Electric Power Supply Association.
        78. Eric Hirst--Mr. Eric Hirst.
        79. Fertilizer Institute--The Fertilizer Institute.
        80. First Rochdale--1st Rochdale Cooperative Group, Ltd.
        81. FirstEnergy--FirstEnergy Corp.
        82. Florida Commission--Florida Public Service Commission.
        83. Florida Power Corp.--Florida Power Corporation.
        84. FMPA--Florida Municipal Power Agency.
        85. FP&L--Florida Power & Light Company.
        86. FTC--Staff of the Bureau of Economics of the Federal Trade 
    Commission.
        87. Gainesville--Gainesville Regional Utilities.
        88. Georgia Transmission--Georgia Transmission Corporation.
        89. GPU Energy--GPU Energy.
        90. Grand Council et al.--Grand Council of the Crees, Greenpeace 
    Canada, the Sierra Club of Canada, Mouvement Au Courant, the Centre 
    D'Analyses de Politiques Energetiques and New England Coalition for 
    Energy Efficiency and the Environment.
        91. Great River--Great River Energy.
        92. H.Q. Energy Services--Energy Services Group of Hydro-Quebec 
    and H.Q. Energy Services (U.S.) Inc.
        93. How Group--OASIS How Working Group.
        94. ICUA--Idaho Consumer-Owned Utilities Association.
    
    [[Page 958]]
    
        95. Idaho Commission--Idaho Public Utilities Commission.
        96. Idaho Power--Idaho Power Company.
        97. Illinois Commission--Illinois Commerce Commission.
        98. IMEA--Illinois Municipal Electric Agency.
        99. IMPA--Indiana Municipal Power Agency.
        100. Indiana Commission--Indiana Utility Regulatory Commission.
        101. Indianapolis P&L--Indianapolis Power & Light Company.
        102. Industrial Consumers--Electricity Consumers Resource 
    Council, the American Iron & Steel Institute and the Chemical 
    Manufactures Association.
        103. Industrial Customers--Industrial Customers of Northwest 
    Utilities.
        104. INGAA--Interstate Natural Gas Association of America.
        105. Iowa Board--Iowa Utilities Board.
        106. IPCF--International Powerline Communications Forum.
        107. ISO-NE--ISO New England Inc.
        108. JEA--JEA.
        109. Justice Department--United States Department of Justice.
        110. Kentucky Commission--Kentucky Public Service Commission.
        111. Konolige/Ford/Fleishman--Kit Konolige, Daniel F. Ford and 
    Steven I. Fleishman.
        112. Lenard--Mr. Thomas M. Lenard.
        113. LEPA--Louisiana Energy & Power Authority.
        114. LG&E--LG&E Energy Corp.
        115. Lincoln--Lincoln, Nebraska Electric System.
        116. LIPA--Long Island Power Authority.
        117. Los Angeles--Los Angeles Department of Water and Power.
        118. Loveland Customers--Loveland Area Customers Association.
        119. LPPC--Large Public Power Council.
        120. Manitoba Board--Manitoba Hydro-Electric Board.
        121. MAPP--Mid-Continent Area Power Pool.
        122. Mass Companies--Boston Edison Company, Cambridge Electric 
    Light Company and Commonwealth Electric Company.
        123. Massachusetts Division--Massachusetts Division of Energy 
    Resources.
        124. MEAG--Municipal Electric Authority of Georgia.
        125. Merrill Energy--Merrill Energy LLC.
        126. Metropolitan--Metropolitan Water District of Southern 
    California.
        127. Michigan Commission--Michigan Public Service Commission.
        128. MidAmerican--MidAmerican Energy Company.
        129. Mid-Atlantic Commissions--Delaware Public Service 
    Commission, District of Columbia Public Service Commission, Maryland 
    Public Service Commission, New Jersey Board of Public Utilities and 
    Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission.
        130. Midwest Energy--Midwest Energy, Inc.
        131. Midwest ISO--Midwest Independent Transmission System 
    Operator, Inc.
        132. Midwest ISO Participants--Allegheny Energy, Ameren, Central 
    Illinois Light Company, Cinergy Corp., Commonwealth Edison Company, 
    Hoosier Energy Rural Electric Cooperative, Inc., Illinois Power 
    Company, Kentucky Utilities Company, Louisville Gas & Electric 
    Company, Southern Indiana Gas & Electric Company, Southern Illinois 
    Power Cooperative, Wabash Valley Power Association, Inc. and 
    Wisconsin Electric Power Company.
        133. Midwest Municipals--Missouri River Energy Services, Iowa 
    Association of Municipal Utilities and Minnesota Municipal Utilities 
    Association.
        134. Minnesota Commission--Minnesota Public Utilities 
    Commission.
        135. Minnesota Power--Minnesota Power.
        136. Missouri Commission--Missouri Public Service Commission.
        137. MLGW--Memphis Light, Gas and Water Division.
        138. Montana Commission--Montana Public Service Commission and 
    Montana Department of Environmental Quality.
        139. Montana Power--Montana Power Company.
        140. Montana-Dakota--Montana-Dakota Utilities Co.
        141. NARUC--National Association of Regulatory Utility 
    Commissioners.
        142. NASUCA--National Association of State Utility Consumer 
    Advocates.
        143. NCPA--Northern California Power Agency.
        144. NEMA--National Energy Marketers Association.
        145. NECPUC--New England Conference of Public Utilities 
    Commissioners, Inc.
        146. NEPCO et al.--New England Power Company, National Grid 
    Group, plc and Montaup Electric Company.
        147. NERA--National Economic Research Associates, Inc.
        148. NERC--North American Electric Reliability Council.
        149. Nevada Commission--Public Utilities Commission of Nevada
        150. New Century--New Century Energies, Inc. and its operating 
    utility companies: Public Service Company of Colorado, Southwestern 
    Public Service Company and Cheyenne Light, Fuel and Power Company.
        151. New Orleans--Council of the City of New Orleans.
        152. New Smyrna Beach--Utilities Commission, City of New Smyrna 
    Beach, Florida.
        153. New York Commission--New York State Public Service 
    Commission
        154. Nine Commissions--Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission, 
    Virginia State Corporation Commission, Public Utilities Commission 
    of Ohio, Indiana Utility Regulatory Commission, Illinois Commerce 
    Commission, Michigan Public Service Commission, Missouri Public 
    Service Commission, Arkansas Public Service Commission and Oklahoma 
    Corporation Commission.
        155. NiSource--NiSource Incorporated.
        156. NJBUS--New Jersey Business Users.
        157. NMA/WFA/CEED--National Mining Association, Western Fuels 
    Association, Inc. and Center for Energy and Economic Development.
        158. NU--Northeast Utilities System.
        159. Northwest Council--Northwest Power Planning Council.
        160. NPCC--Northeast Power Coordinating Council.
        161. NPPD--Nebraska Public Power District.
        162. NPRB--Nebraska Power Review Board.
        163. NRECA--National Rural Electric Cooperative Association.
        164. NSP--Northern States Power Company.
        165. NU--Northeast Utilities System.
        166. NWCC--National Wind Coordinating Committee.
        167. NY ISO--New York Independent System Operator, Inc.
        168. NYC--City of New York.
        169. NYEBF--New York Energy Buyers Forum.
        170. NYMEX--New York Mercantile Exchange.
        171. NYPP--Member Systems of the New York Power Pool (Central 
    Hudson Gas & Electric Corporation, Consolidated Edison Company of 
    New York, Inc., Long Island Power Authority, New York State Electric 
    & Gas Corporation, Niagara Mohawk Power Corporation, Orange and 
    Rockland Utilities, Inc., Rochester Gas and Electric Corp. and Power 
    Authority of the State of New York).
        172. Oglethorpe--Oglethorpe Power Corporation.
        173. Ohio Commission--Public Utilities Commission of Ohio.
        174. Oneok--Oneok Power Marketing.
        175. Ontario IMO--Ontario Independent Electricity Market 
    Operator.
        176. Ontario Power--Ontario Power Generation Inc.
        177. Oregon Office--Oregon Office of Energy.
        178. Otter Tail--Otter Tail Power Company.
        179. PacifiCorp--PacifiCorp.
        180. PECO--PECO Energy Company and Horizon Energy.
        181. Pennsylvania Commission--Pennsylvania Public Utility 
    Commission.
        182. PG&E--PG&E Corporation.
        183. PGE--Portland General Electric Company.
        184. PGP--Public Generating Pool.
        185. PJM--PJM Interconnection, L.L.C.
        186. PJM/NEPOOL Customers--PJM Industrial Customer Coalition, 
    NEPOOL Industrial Customer Coalition and Coalition of Midwest 
    Transmission Customers.
        187. Platte River--Platte River Power Authority.
        188. PNGC--Pacific Northwest Generating Cooperative.
        189. Powerex--British Columbia Power Exchange Corporation.
        190. PP&L Companies--PP&L Inc., PP&L EnergyPlus Co., L.L.C., 
    PP&L Montana, L.L.C.
        191. PPC--Public Power Council.
        192. Professor Hogan--Professor William W. Hogan.
        193. Professor Joskow--Professor Paul L. Joskow.
        194. Professor Koch--Professor Charles H. Koch, Jr.
        195. Project Groups--Alliance for Affordable Energy, American 
    Wind Energy Association, Center for Clean Air Policy, Center for 
    Energy Efficiency and Renewable Technologies, Citizen Power, Inc., 
    Citizens
    
    [[Page 959]]
    
    for Pennsylvania's Future, Delaware Division of the Public Advocate, 
    Environmental Law & Policy Center of the Midwest, Land & Water Fund 
    of the Rockies, Legal Environmental Assistance Foundation, 
    Minnesotans for an Energy-Efficient Economy, Natural Resources 
    Defense Council, Northwest Energy Coalition, Office of the People's 
    Counsel of the District of Columbia, Pace Energy Project, 
    Pennsylvania Energy Project, Public Citizen, PJM Public Interest/
    Environmental User Group, Renew Wisconsin, Southern Environmental 
    Law Center, Tennessee Valley Energy Reform Coalition, Union of 
    Concerned Scientists, Wisconsin's Environmental Decade.
        196. PSE&G--Public Service Electric and Gas Company.
        197. PSNM--Public Service Company of New Mexico.
        198. Public Citizen--Public Citizen.
        199. Puget--Puget Sound Energy, Inc.
        200. Rayburn--Rayburn Country Electric Cooperative, Inc.
        201. RECA--Residential Electric Consumers Association.
        202. Reliant--Reliant Energy, Incorporated.
        203. RUS--Rural Utilities Service of the Department of 
    Agriculture.
        204. Salomon Smith Barney--Global Power Group of Salomon Smith 
    Barney.
        205. San Francisco--City and County of San Francisco.
        206. SCE&G--South Carolina Electric & Gas Company.
        207. Seattle--Seattle City Light Department.
        208. SERC--Southeastern Electric Reliability Council.
        209. Sierra Pacific--Sierra Pacific Resources, Inc.
        210. Sithe--Sithe Energies, Inc.
        211. SMUD--Sacramento Municipal Utility District.
        212. Snohomish--Public Utility District No. 1 of Snohomish 
    County, Washington.
        213. SNWA--Southern Nevada Water Authority.
        214. SoCal Cities--Cities of Anaheim, Azusa, Banning, Colton, 
    and Riverside, California.
        215. SoCal Edison--Southern California Edison Company.
        216. Sonat--Sonat Power Marketing, L.P.
        217. South Carolina Authority--South Carolina Public Service 
    Authority.
        218. South Carolina Commission--Public Service Commission of 
    South Carolina.
        219. Southern Company--Southern Company Services, Inc., acting 
    as agent for Alabama Power Company, Georgia Power Company, GulfPower 
    Company, Mississippi Power Company and Savannah Electric and Power 
    Company.
        220. SPP--Southwest Power Pool, Inc.
        221. SPRA--Southwestern Power Resources Association.
        222. SRP--Salt River Project Agricultural Improvement and Power 
    District.
        223. St. Joseph--St. Joseph Light & Power Company.
        224. Statoil--Statoil Energy, Inc.
        225. STDUG--Southwest Transmission Dependent Utility Group.
        226. Steel Dynamics--Steel Dynamics, Inc.
        227. Tacoma Power--City of Tacoma, Department of Public 
    Utilities, Light Division.
        228. Tallahassee--City of Tallahassee, Florida.
        229. Tampa Electric--Tampa Electric Company.
        230. TANC--Transmission Agency of Northern California.
        231. TAPS--Transmission Access Policy Study Group.
        232. TDU Systems--Alabama Electric Cooperative, Inc., Arkansas 
    Electric Cooperative Corporation, Golden Spread Electric 
    Cooperative, Kansas Electric Power Cooperative, Inc., North Carolina 
    Electric Membership Corporation, Old Dominion Electric Cooperative, 
    Seminole Electric Cooperative, Inc., and South Mississippi Electric 
    Power Association.
        233. Tennessee Authority--Tennessee Regulatory Authority.
        234. TEP--Tucson Electric Power Company.
        235. Texas Commission--Public Utility Commission of Texas.
        236. Trans-Elect--Trans-Elect, Inc.
        237. Transenergie--Transenergie.
        238. Transmission ISO Participants--Baltimore Gas & Electric, 
    Boston Edison Company, Cambridge Electric Light Company, 
    Commonwealth Energy Company, Conectiv, GPU Energy, Niagara Mohawk 
    Power Company, Northeast Utilities Service Company, PECO Energy 
    Company, PP&L, Inc., Potomac Electric Power Company, Public Service 
    Electric and Gas Company, Vermont Electric Power Company, Inc.
        239. Tri-State--Tri-State Generation and Transmission 
    Association, Inc.
        240. Turlock--Turlock Irrigation District.
        241. TVA--Tennessee Valley Authority.
        242. TXU Electric--TXU Electric Company.
        243. UAMPS--Utah Associated Municipal Power Systems.
        244. UMPA--Utah Municipal Power Agency.
        245. United Illuminating--United Illuminating Company.
        246. UtiliCorp--UtiliCorp United, Inc.
        247. Utility Engineers--Utility Economic Engineers.
        248. Vernon--City of Vernon, California.
        249. Virginia Commission--Virginia State Corporation Commission.
        250. Virginia Power--Virginia Electric and Power Company.
        251. Washington Commission--Washington Utilities and 
    Transportation Commission.
        252. WEPCO--Wisconsin Electric Power Company.
        253. WICF--Western Interconnection Coordination Forum.
        254. Williams--Williams Companies, Inc.
        255. Wisconsin Commission--Public Service Commission of 
    Wisconsin.
        256. Wolverine Cooperative--Wolverine Power Supply. Cooperative, 
    Inc.
        257. WPPI--Wisconsin Public Power, Inc.
        258. WPSC--Wisconsin Public Service Corporation.
        259. Wyoming Commission--Wyoming Public Service Commission.
    
    [FR Doc. 00-2 Filed 1-5-00; 8:45 am]
    BILLING CODE 6717-01-P
    
    
    

Document Information

Effective Date:
3/6/2000
Published:
01/06/2000
Department:
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
Entry Type:
Rule
Action:
Final Rule.
Document Number:
00-2
Dates:
This Final Rule will become effective March 6, 2000.
Pages:
810-959 (150 pages)
Docket Numbers:
Docket No. RM99-2-000, Order No. 2000
PDF File:
00-2.pdf
CFR: (4)
18 CFR 35.34(i)(3)
18 CFR 35.34(i)(3)(ii)
18 CFR 35.34(j)(4)(ii)
18 CFR 35.34