96-26517. Implementation of the Telecommunications Act of 1996  

  • [Federal Register Volume 61, Number 202 (Thursday, October 17, 1996)]
    [Rules and Regulations]
    [Pages 54099-54104]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 96-26517]
    
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    
    FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
    47 CFR Part 51
    
    [CC Docket Nos. 96-98 and 95-185; FCC 96-378]
    
    
    Implementation of the Telecommunications Act of 1996
    
    AGENCY: Federal Communications Commission.
    
    ACTION: Final rule; Denial of petitions for stay of rules.
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    SUMMARY: The Federal Communications Commission here denies two 
    petitions seeking a stay of the rules contained in
    
    [[Page 54100]]
    
    the Commission's First Report and Order implementing the 
    Telecommunications Act of 1996. The Commission concluded that 
    petitioners failed to meet the legal criteria required to obtain a stay 
    of the rules. Denial of the petitions seeking a stay of the rules 
    allows the implementation of the Telecommunications Act of 1996 to 
    proceed without delay.
    
    EFFECTIVE DATE: September 16, 1996.
    
    FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: David A. Konuch, 202-418-0199.
    
    SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
    
    Adopted: September 16, 1996
    Released: September 17, 1996
    
    I. Introduction
    
        1. On August 1, 1996, the Commission adopted rules implementing the 
    local competition provisions of the Telecommunications Act of 1996 
    (1996 Act). Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the 
    Telecommunications Act of 1996, CC Docket No. 96-98, First Report and 
    Order, FCC 96-325 (released August 8, 1996), 61 FR 45476 (August 29, 
    1996) (First Report and Order). On August 28, 1996, GTE Corporation 
    (GTE) and the Southern New England Telephone Company (SNET) filed a 
    joint motion for stay of the Commission's rules pending judicial 
    review. Oppositions to the joint motion for stay were filed by the 
    United States Department of Justice and 16 private parties. On 
    September 6, 1996, after we received these oppositions, U S West, Inc. 
    (``U S West'') filed a stay petition similar to that filed by GTE and 
    SNET. The Competitive Telecommunications Association and ALTS filed 
    oppositions to U S West's petition.
        2. For the reasons set forth below, we deny the motions for stay.
    
    II. Summary of the Motions and Oppositions
    
        3. GTE and SNET assert that a petition for review of the 
    Commission's First Report and Order is likely to succeed on the merits 
    because the Commission has exceeded its statutory authority and has 
    acted arbitrarily and capriciously in implementing provisions of the 
    1996 Act. In particular, GTE and SNET contend that the Commission lacks 
    authority to establish national pricing standards for interconnection 
    and unbundled network elements. GTE and SNET argue that, even if the 
    Commission has such authority, the pricing standards in the First 
    Report and Order would force incumbent LECs to offer interconnection, 
    unbundled network elements, and resold services at below-cost rates, 
    allegedly effecting an uncompensated taking in violation of the Fifth 
    Amendment to the United States Constitution. GTE and SNET also maintain 
    that the Commission has established default pricing proxies that are 
    inconsistent with the 1996 Act and the cost study methodology the 
    Commission adopted for use by state commissions. In addition, GTE and 
    SNET assert that the ability of competitors to ``reassemble'' unbundled 
    network elements nullifies the resale and exchange access provisions of 
    the 1996 Act. Finally, GTE and SNET argue that the First Report and 
    Order establishes a number of specific requirements with regard to 
    resale and exchange access charges that conflict with express terms of 
    the 1996 Act.
        4. GTE and SNET contend that they will suffer irreparable harm in 
    the absence of a stay because the Commission's rules will stifle the 
    negotiation process and will require incumbent LECs to offer unbundled 
    elements or services to competitors at below-cost prices. GTE and SNET 
    argue that a stay will cause no harm to others because private 
    negotiations and state-supervised arbitrations can proceed in the 
    absence of Commission rules. GTE and SNET also assert that the public 
    interest favors a stay because of the disruption to business plans that 
    would result if the Court of Appeals reverses the First Report and 
    Order and the Commission subsequently modifies its rules.
        5. U S West agrees with SNET and GTE's arguments, but additionally 
    claims that our default proxy prices, along with our misinterpretation 
    of 47 U.S.C. 252(i), the 1996 Act's ``most favored nation'' provision, 
    will impermissibly ``dictate'' the result of negotiations, as a 
    practical matter. Section 252(i) of the 1996 Act provides that a 
    ``local exchange carrier shall make available any interconnection, 
    service, or network element provided under an agreement approved under 
    [section 252] to which it is a party to any other requesting 
    telecommunications carrier upon the same terms and conditions as those 
    provided in the agreement.'' 47 U.S.C. 252(i). Section 252(i) is known 
    as the 1996 Act's ``most favored nation'' provision, because it enables 
    carriers to obtain any interconnection, service, or network element on 
    terms as favorable as those contained in any state-commission-approved 
    interconnection agreement.
        6. In general, parties opposing grant of the stay motion contend 
    that GTE's and SNET's motion does not satisfy the four factors that we 
    must consider in deciding whether to stay one of our orders. These 
    parties contend movants are unlikely to prevail on the merits of their 
    claims; that movants will suffer no irreparable harm if a stay is not 
    granted; that grant of a stay will harm third parties; and that the 
    public interest does not favor the grant of a stay.
    
    III. Discussion
    
        7. Petitioners' motions do not justify relief under the four-part 
    test for evaluating requests for interim relief. That test requires 
    proponents of a stay to demonstrate: (1) That they are likely to 
    prevail on the merits; (2) that they will suffer irreparable harm if a 
    stay is not granted; (3) that other interested parties will not be 
    harmed if the stay is granted; and (4) that the public interest favors 
    the grant of a stay. See Wisconsin Gas Co. v. FERC, 758 F.2d 669, 673-
    74 (D.C. Cir. 1985); Washington Metropolitan Area Transit Authority v. 
    Holiday Tours, Inc., 559 F.2d 841, 843-43 (D.C. Cir. 1977); Virginia 
    Petroleum Jobbers Ass'n v. FPC, 259 F.2d 921, 925 (D.C. Cir. 1958). As 
    discussed below, we do not believe that petitioners have satisfied any, 
    much less all, of these requirements.
    
    A. Irreparable Harm
    
        8. A concrete showing of irreparable harm is an essential factor in 
    any request for a stay. `` `The key word' '' in an analysis of 
    irreparable harm is `` `irreparable.' '' ``[E]conomic loss does not, in 
    and of itself, constitute irreparable harm.'' Also, because competitive 
    harm is merely a type of economic loss, ``revenues and customers lost 
    to competition which can be regained through competition are not 
    irreparable.'' Moreover, even if the alleged harm is not fully 
    remediable, the irreparable harm factor is not satisfied absent a 
    demonstration that the harm is ``both certain and great; * * * actual 
    and not theoretical.'' ``Bare allegations of what is likely to occur 
    are of no value'' under this factor, because we ``must decide whether 
    the harm will in fact occur.'' Petitioners' three different claims of 
    harm absent a stay do not satisfy these exacting standards.
        9. First, GTE and SNET argue specifically that they are harmed by 
    our interpretation of the ``just and reasonable'' standard of 47 U.S.C. 
    251(c) (2) and (3) for the pricing of interconnection and unbundled 
    network elements. They complain, in particular, that the pricing 
    methodology adopted in the First Report and Order unconstitutionally 
    prevents them from recovering the joint and common costs (hereinafter 
    collectively referred to as ``common costs''), and the historical 
    ``embedded'' costs of such offerings to competing carriers. The First 
    Report and
    
    [[Page 54101]]
    
    Order generally uses the term ``common costs'' to refer to both joint 
    and common costs. Such ``below-cost'' pricing of section 251 offerings, 
    they claim, will result in unrecoverable lost revenues, customers, and 
    goodwill, particularly if state regulators do not allow them to 
    ``rebalance'' (raise) rates for certain retail services that allegedly 
    have been subsidized in the past by the pricing regime that the section 
    251 offerings will erode.
        10. These claims mischaracterize the First Report and Order. 
    Contrary to GTE's and SNET's assertions, our pricing methodology does 
    not require ``below-cost'' pricing. On the contrary, it affirmatively 
    provides for the recovery of all the economic costs of providing 
    interconnection and unbundled network elements, and includes a 
    reasonable profit. We refer to the general pricing methodology we 
    adopted as Total Element Long Run Incremental Cost or ``TELRIC''. As we 
    explained, economic costs are forward-looking costs or, in other words, 
    the costs that an efficient provider would incur to provide the service 
    or facility. We also specifically provided that unbundled element 
    prices shall include a ``normal profit.'' In mischaracterizing our 
    pricing methodology as ``below-cost,'' GTE and SNET must be claiming 
    that historical embedded costs are always greater than economic costs, 
    and that sections 251 and 252 must be read to entitle them to recover 
    historical costs even where those costs exceed economic costs. Both 
    assertions are unfounded. Nothing in section 251 or 252 creates an 
    entitlement for GTE, SNET and other incumbent LECs to assess rates for 
    interconnection and unbundled network elements that are designed to 
    recover historical costs that exceed economic costs. Economists 
    generally agree that historical embedded costs are not the relevant 
    costs in competitive markets, and would, in fact, interfere with the 
    development of efficient competition. Moreover, GTE and SNET are simply 
    wrong in claiming that the Commission's pricing methodology denies them 
    an opportunity to recover common costs. We stated clearly in the First 
    Report and Order that ``for the aggregate of all unbundled elements, 
    incumbent LECs must be given a reasonable opportunity to recover their 
    forward-looking common costs attributable to operating the wholesale 
    network.''
        11. Even accepting GTE's and SNET's reliance on historical costs, 
    their contention that the First Report and Order requires below-cost 
    pricing is speculative. In any given instance, forward-looking costs 
    ``may be higher or lower than historical embedded costs.'' Thus, the 
    claimed loss of revenues--which does not present a question of 
    constitutional deprivation in any event--is premature because the 
    actual revenues that GTE and SNET will receive will not be known until 
    completion of the voluntary negotiations and state arbitration 
    proceedings that will actually set interconnection and unbundled 
    element prices. We expressly stated in the First Report and Order that 
    ``[i]ncumbent LECs may seek relief from the Commission's pricing 
    methodology if they provide specific information to show that the 
    pricing methodology, as applied to them, will result in confiscatory 
    rates.'' Moreover, as DOJ correctly notes in its Opposition at page 3, 
    the Commission possesses discretion in ratemaking matters, so long as 
    the rates that result are just. See, e.g., Duquesne Light Co. v. 
    Barasch, 488 U.S. 299 (1989) (in which the Court rejected a takings 
    claim where a utility was denied recovery of a $34 million capital 
    investment, prudent and reasonable when made, because the financial 
    integrity of the company was not jeopardized). Speculation about 
    anticipated lost revenues in the future does not approach, at this 
    stage, a showing of irreparable harm.
        12. Second, petitioners contend that they will be harmed by the 
    application of the interim default proxy rates that the Commission 
    adopted. This argument is fatally flawed in that there is no certainty 
    that those proxies will ever be applied to petitioners. These proxies 
    were established for use by the states if a state was not able to set 
    prices based on economic cost studies consistent with our methodology 
    within the statutory arbitration periods. If, as these carriers assert, 
    the proxy rates are unreasonably below costs, they have every 
    incentive, and possess the information necessary, to present credible 
    economic cost studies to the relevant state commissions to allow the 
    state commissions to set prices for interconnection and unbundled 
    network elements that are based on actual cost studies, rather than by 
    proxies. Their claims of harm thus lack the requisite certainty and 
    concreteness for a stay. Further, as discussed below, the carriers' 
    challenges to those proxies mischaracterize the Commission's action and 
    are unfounded on the merits.
        13. Third, petitioners argue that the Commission's rules 
    unreasonably constrain both their ability to negotiate the terms of 
    voluntary agreements with other telecommunications carriers that 
    request interconnection or unbundled network elements, and the states' 
    ability to arbitrate the terms of such agreements if voluntary 
    negotiations fail. Quite apart from the fact that the statute directs 
    the Commission to adopt implementing rules in 47 U.S.C. 251(d)(1), 
    these allegations of harm also are too speculative to justify 
    injunctive relief. Section 251(d)(1) provides that, ``[w]ithin 6 months 
    after the date of enactment of the Telecommunications Act of 1996, the 
    Commission shall complete all actions necessary to establish 
    regulations to implement the requirements of this section.'' We also 
    note that section 253(a) provides that ``[n]o State or local statute or 
    regulation, or other State or local legal requirement, may prohibit or 
    have the effect of prohibiting the ability of any entity to provide any 
    interstate or intrastate telecommunications service.'' Further, section 
    253(d) provides that ``[i]f, after notice and an opportunity for public 
    comment, the Commission determines that a State or local government has 
    permitted or imposed any statute, regulation, or legal requirement that 
    violates subsection (a) or (b) [relating to the states' ability to take 
    certain actions], the Commission shall preempt the enforcement of such 
    statute, regulation, or legal requirement to the extent necessary to 
    correct such violation or inconsistency.'' Our rules clearly do not 
    prohibit voluntary negotiations between incumbent LECs and their 
    potential competitors, as contemplated in 47 U.S.C. 252(a). Indeed, 
    they facilitate them. Petitioners are free to negotiate agreements with 
    other carriers upon any terms they choose so long as they are not 
    discriminatory and are consistent with the public interest. Although we 
    fully expect the existence of our rules to provide a context in which 
    free negotiations can proceed consistent with the pro-competitive 
    purposes of the 1996 Act, petitioners cannot plausibly suggest in view 
    of the explicit mandate of 47 U.S.C. 251(d)(1) that they have a 
    cognizable right to negotiate without any rules adopted by the FCC.
        14. We also conclude that petitioners have not demonstrated that 
    the FCC's decision to interpret the just and reasonable rate standard 
    would necessarily harm them, as compared with a decision to allow 
    states independently to interpret that standard in arbitration 
    proceedings. To the extent that states might adopt different standards 
    absent any FCC guidance, such standards could conceivably be either 
    more or less favorable to incumbent local exchange carriers.
        15. Finally, it is a meaningful response to all of the harms that 
    petitioners allege that nothing in the
    
    [[Page 54102]]
    
    First Report and Order prevents incumbent local exchange carriers from 
    taking steps substantially to protect themselves by seeking to insert 
    into their voluntary agreements provisos that permit reformation of the 
    terms of those agreements in the event that the order is overturned or 
    modified pursuant to judicial review. Similarly, nothing in the order 
    prevents states, in arbitrating such agreements, from imposing such 
    provisos.
    
    B. Harm to Others
    
        16. Petitioners also have not proved that a grant of their motions 
    would not harm others. As discussed more fully below (paras. 28-31), 
    the ``stay'' they seek would not simply maintain the status quo, but 
    rather would have a significant impact on whether potential new 
    competitors currently involved in negotiations and state arbitration 
    proceedings choose to enter local exchange and exchange access markets 
    at this crucial time, and, if so, whether their entry would be pursuant 
    to statutory standards as interpreted by the Commission, or some other 
    standards. To the extent that petitioners claim that the Commission's 
    interpretations burden them with lost revenues and competitive harm, 
    other interpretations allowing them to charge new entrants higher rates 
    or to impose upon them more restrictive terms likely would burden new 
    entrants and, consequently, retard or even eliminate competitive entry. 
    As between incumbent LECs and new entrants, the former are more likely 
    to be able to repair the adverse consequences of any erroneous decision 
    on whether to grant a stay.
        17. Moreover, to the extent that petitioners argue not only that 
    the Commission adopted an erroneous pricing standard, but also that the 
    Commission erred by failing to leave the standard to individual states, 
    the carriers are advocating a system that clearly would cause new 
    entrants particular harm and might even discourage them from entering 
    these markets. As we noted in the First Report and Order, efficient 
    entry strategies in many cases require entry on a regional, rather than 
    state-by-state, basis. The removal of national standards could severely 
    impede, or at least increase the cost of, such strategies.
    
    C. Public Interest
    
        18. GTE and SNET assert that a stay would serve the public interest 
    because it would leave interconnection negotiations to private parties, 
    and arbitrations in the hands of state regulators, where Congress 
    intended them to be. They also contend that ``progress toward 
    competition will be gravely impaired'' in the absence of a stay because 
    the Commission's rules will give potential competitors false signals 
    that may ``encourage entry by companies that would not normally enter 
    if they had known the true costs involved.'' GTE and SNET claim that 
    this means that a stay is necessary to protect the public from such 
    ``uneconomic entry'' and from the disruptions that would attend 
    corrective actions if the Commission's rules were overturned. U S West 
    additionally claims that the public interest will be harmed because the 
    Commission's rules and ``inflexible prices'' will ``prevent carriers 
    from negotiating interconnection agreements with each other on terms 
    that are more advantageous than the defaults.''
        19. Contrary to GTE's and SNET's argument that a stay is needed to 
    avoid ``entry by companies that would not normally enter,'' a stay 
    might discourage entry by some who have every reasonable qualification 
    to compete and would do so under our rules. A stay in this crucial 
    initial period for the development of local exchange and local access 
    competition would not serve the public interest unless our rules were 
    virtually certain to be set aside on review and the actions taken on 
    interconnection requests in the meantime were irreversible. We believe 
    that our rules correctly carry out the objectives of Congress in 
    adopting section 251. Congress expressly mandated rulemaking by the 
    Commission to implement effectively the new statutory requirements. 
    Congress also made clear that time was of the essence, directing us to 
    ``complete all actions necessary to establish [such] regulations'' by 
    August 8, 1996. As explained more fully below (paras. 30-31), a stay of 
    our rules would subvert Congress' plan to have such rules in place 
    during arbitration proceedings. Moreover, as we emphasized in the First 
    Report and Order, the rules we adopted under section 251 will have a 
    significant impact on the implementation of other provisions of the 
    1996 Act. We noted, for example, that our 251 rules ``will help the 
    states, the DOJ, and the FCC carry out their responsibilities under 
    section 271, and assist BOCs in determining what steps must be taken to 
    meet the requirements of section 271(c)(2)(B), the competitive 
    checklist.'' Section 271 establishes the requirements that a BOC must 
    satisfy in order to receive authorization to provide in-region 
    interLATA telecommunications services. Section 271(c)(2)(B) sets forth 
    a specific ``checklist'' of requirements that a BOC must meet as part 
    of the authorization process.
        20. As to any necessary corrections after the fact, we believe that 
    agreements and arbitrations can take account of this possibility. As 
    noted above (paragraph 15), agreements and arbitrations could include 
    provisos calling for revisions if the Commission's rules should be 
    struck down. The joint motion acknowledges that the agreements can be 
    revised after the fact if the Commission's rules are upheld after a 
    stay is granted; its assertion that such revisions would not work if a 
    stay is denied and the rules later are struck down is implausible and 
    unexplained.
        21. We further reject U S West's argument that our rules will harm 
    the public interest by providing carriers with insufficient flexibility 
    to negotiate agreements. For the reasons set out in this Order and in 
    the First Report and Order, we believe that our rules provide all 
    carriers with a full and fair opportunity, pursuant to the requirements 
    of the 1996 Act, voluntarily to negotiate interconnection agreements.
        22. In summary on this point, the primary beneficiary of the 
    competitive policies our rules were designed to implement is the 
    public. We conclude that a stay would disserve the public interest 
    profoundly by eliminating our rules from the process of negotiation and 
    arbitration at the very most crucial time.
    
    D. Likelihood of Success on the Merits
    
        23. Because of the clear failure of petitioners to meet the 
    irreparable harm, harm to others, and public interest requirements for 
    obtaining a stay, we do not address specifically in this order all 
    their claims that we exceeded our statutory authority or that we acted 
    arbitrarily or capriciously. All the significant arguments raised by 
    the petitioners were squarely addressed in the First Report and Order. 
    We addressed issues concerning the Commission's authority under the 
    1996 Act to establish national pricing rules in section II.C. and II.D. 
    of the order. We discussed the legal and economic bases for the 
    establishment of the Commission's pricing methodology, including the 
    Fifth Amendment takings issue and the justification for the default 
    proxy ceilings and ranges, in section VII of the order. We addressed 
    arguments about whether we should permit competitors to reassemble 
    unbundled network elements, including possible effects on the resale 
    provisions of the 1996 Act and our access charge rules, in sections 
    V.H. and VII.B., respectively. In
    
    [[Page 54103]]
    
    section V.J., we set forth our rationale for including vertical 
    features within the definition of unbundled local switching; and in 
    sections IV.H., V.J., and VII.B., we discussed the compensation to 
    incumbent LECs for modifications made to their networks to accommodate 
    interconnection and unbundling. Finally, in section XIV.B of the First 
    Report and Order, we addressed arguments regarding the rights of third 
    parties to obtain ``any individual interconnection, service, or network 
    element arrangement'' under section 252(i). We need not repeat those 
    discussions in this order.
        24. We will note, however that where the GTE and SNET address the 
    merits of the First Report and Order, they often mischaracterize and 
    distort the import of our analysis and conclusions. For instance, our 
    default proxy pricing measures are only interim approaches, setting 
    bounds for unbundled element pricing in the absence of state-approved 
    forward-looking cost studies. Our proxies will assist states in the 
    very near term when, because of time or staff resource constraints, 
    they may be unable to set prices by conducting or approving forward-
    looking economic cost studies within the statutory time period set for 
    arbitrations. Indeed, the first set of state arbitrations must be 
    completed in early November under the deadlines established in the Act.
        25. An example of GTE and SNET's misguided arguments on the merits 
    is their criticism of the Commission's unbundled loop proxy 
    calculation. In asserting that the Commission ``might just as well have 
    picked the default prices out of a hat,'' petitioners omit any mention 
    of the several pages of the order describing how we calculated our loop 
    proxy figures. As detailed in section VII.C. of the First Report and 
    Order, our proxy ceilings are based on prices set by six state 
    commissions as their best estimates of forward-looking costs after 
    analysis of economic cost studies. We then derived price ceilings for 
    individual states throughout the nation by adjusting the average of the 
    prices in these six states by the relative loop costs in those states, 
    as estimated by the two forward-looking economic cost-based models that 
    received significant comment by parties during this proceeding. To 
    allow a reasonable margin to enable the proxy ceiling to capture the 
    variation among states' forward-looking economic costing prices, we 
    then adjusted the resulting prices upward by five percent.
        26. Contrary to GTE and SNET's arguments, it is no surprise, and 
    certainly not error, that the price ceiling for Florida--or for 
    Connecticut, Colorado, Michigan, Illinois, or Oregon, for that matter--
    does not equal the results of the cost studies in those individual 
    states. We concluded that an average of the six states' prices 
    represented the best estimate of forward-looking loop costs available 
    to us at that time, and that relying on an average of the nationwide 
    relative costs from the Hatfield and BCM models was the best method for 
    deriving proxy price ceilings in individual states. We believe our 
    methodology is reasonable, even though our proxy ceiling in Florida is 
    $13.68 while the Florida Commission set a $20 per loop price for GTE 
    Florida. We note that the price set by the Florida Commission for GTE-
    Florida was itself significantly higher than those the commission set 
    for BellSouth and United/Centel--the other local telephone companies 
    for which the state commission has set unbundled loop prices in 
    Florida. We concluded that the reliability of our foundation estimate 
    was enhanced by using an average of the prices established in all six 
    states for which information was available, rather than using just one 
    state or the six states individually. We did not, and could not in the 
    time frame permitted under the statute, independently verify the 
    accuracy of the six states' unbundled loop prices, many of which also 
    were interim in nature. Instead, we emphasized that each state, in our 
    judgment, used a standard that appeared to be reasonably close to the 
    forward-looking economic cost methodology specified in the First Report 
    and Order, although perhaps not consistent in every detail with our 
    prescribed methodology. Finally, we also are unpersuaded by GTE and 
    SNET's assertion that it was a fatal error to rely on the Florida cost 
    studies because the Florida Commission failed to include any 
    ``significant'' contribution to GTE Florida's common costs. It is not 
    clear on its face that the ``insignificant'' contribution to common 
    costs is inconsistent with our requirement that there be a reasonable 
    allocation of common costs. In addition, the Florida Commission 
    affirmatively found that their rates were not below GTE Florida's 
    costs, and explicitly provided for recovery of a reasonable profit. GTE 
    and SNET have not demonstrated that use of the Florida Commission 
    prices as part of setting a proxy ceiling for unbundled loop prices was 
    so unreasonable as to result in a flawed loop proxy methodology. In 
    sum, we set default proxy price ceilings and ranges for use by state 
    commissions, in the absence of fully approved forward-looking cost 
    studies, based on the best evidence available to us within the 
    statutory time period for our decision.
        27. Finally, petitioners' discussion of our proxy prices simply 
    ignores two key characteristics of our proxy rules. First, our order 
    makes clear that these proxies are interim in nature, and that states 
    utilizing the proxies must replace them with prices based on the 
    results of forward-looking cost studies as they become available. 
    Second, our rules permit incumbent LECs to obtain a price higher than 
    the Commission's proxy ceiling by submitting to a state commission 
    during an arbitration an economic cost study that demonstrates that the 
    incumbent LEC's costs do in fact exceed the proxy price. If the 
    forward-looking costs for petitioners are in fact higher than our proxy 
    price ceiling, as applied in an individual state, they need only 
    demonstrate that to the state commission.
    
    E. Special Circumstances of This Case
    
        28. In addition to movants' failure to satisfy the four-part test 
    for evaluating requests for stay, the circumstances of this specific 
    case particularly militate against the grant of their motions. 
    Ordinarily when we are asked to stay the effectiveness of one of our 
    orders or rules, the moving party seeks to maintain the status quo 
    until a reviewing authority can sort out the issues and render its 
    decision on the merits. That is not the case here, as the Joint Motion 
    itself recognizes. Under the terms of the 1996 Act, many voluntary 
    negotiations for private interconnection agreements and state-
    supervised arbitrations that are now under way will be completed before 
    the end of the year, because Congress established strict timetables to 
    govern the negotiation and arbitration process. The question is whether 
    those proceedings will reflect the principles established by the 
    Commission to implement section 251.
        29. Petitioners do not seek to preserve the status quo, but to 
    overturn Congress's requirement that state arbitrators ensure that 
    approved interconnection agreements reflect the Commission's 
    regulations implementing section 251. It is doubtful, in these 
    circumstances, that the ordinary standards for evaluating stay motions 
    should apply because, where the objective of the motion is not to 
    maintain the status quo, the courts have applied a more demanding 
    standard.
        30. In our view, it is important that the regulations established 
    in the First Report and Order not be stayed while negotiation and 
    arbitration proceedings are taking place. As we stated in the First 
    Report and Order, the negotiations between incumbent LECs and new
    
    [[Page 54104]]
    
    entrants are not analogous to traditional commercial negotiations in 
    which each party owns or controls something the other party desires. 
    Under section 251, monopoly providers are required to make available 
    their facilities and services to requesting carriers that intend to 
    compete directly with the incumbent LECs for their customers and, 
    consequently, incumbents have strong incentives to resist such 
    obligations. Our national rules serve the critical role of equalizing 
    bargaining power by establishing certain baseline principles that will 
    ``reduce delay and lower transaction costs''--burdens that we have 
    found ``impose particular hardships for small entities that are likely 
    to have less of a financial cushion than larger entities.'' A stay 
    would undermine that critical role at a most important time, 
    disproportionately harming the competition that the statute 
    contemplates from new entrants.
        31. Moreover, Congress made clear that it wants our rules to be in 
    place at this critical time. Congress specifically ordered the 
    Commission to ``complete all actions necessary to establish regulations 
    to implement the requirements'' of section 251 by August 8, 1996. It 
    explained that it is ``important that the Commission rules to implement 
    new section 251 be promulgated within six months after the date of 
    enactment, so that potential competitors will have the benefit of being 
    informed of the Commission's rules in requesting access and 
    interconnection before the statutory window in new section 271(c)(1)(B) 
    shuts.'' Section 271(c)(1)(B) authorizes a Bell Operating Company (BOC) 
    to apply for approval to offer in-region interLATA telecommunications 
    services if it does not receive a request for access and 
    interconnection from a facilities-based competitor within seven months 
    after enactment. In section 252(c)(1), Congress further ordered state 
    arbitrators resolving interconnection disputes and imposing conditions 
    on telecommunications companies to ``ensure that such resolution and 
    conditions meet the requirements of section 251, including the 
    regulations prescribed by the Commission.'' Under the statute, those 
    state arbitrators must ``conclude the resolution of any unresolved 
    issues not later than 9 months after the date on which the local 
    exchange carrier received the [interconnection] request.'' Because many 
    LECs requested interconnection shortly after the enactment of the 1996 
    Act on February 8, 1996 (with the consequence that arbitration of such 
    requests must be completed soon), a stay of our rules would frustrate 
    implementation of the procedure established by Congress. As a matter of 
    mathematical certainty, the arbitrations cannot be completed on the 
    timetable established by Congress--with the arbitrators ensuring that 
    the agreements reflect the regulations prescribed by the Commission, as 
    Congress directed in section 252(c)(1)--if the regulations are stayed.
    
    IV. Ordering Clauses
    
        32. Accordingly, it is ordered that the joint motion for stay filed 
    by GTE Corporation and the Southern New England Telephone Company is 
    denied.
        33. It is further ordered that the motion for stay filed by U S 
    West, Inc., is denied.
    
    List of Subjects in 47 CFR Part 51
    
        Communications common carriers, Telephone.
    
    Federal Communications Commission.
    William F. Caton,
    Acting Secretary.
    [FR Doc. 96-26517 Filed 10-16-96; 8:45 am]
    BILLING CODE 6712-01-P
    
    
    

Document Information

Published:
10/17/1996
Department:
Federal Communications Commission
Entry Type:
Rule
Action:
Final rule; Denial of petitions for stay of rules.
Document Number:
96-26517
Dates:
September 16, 1996.
Pages:
54099-54104 (6 pages)
Docket Numbers:
CC Docket Nos. 96-98 and 95-185, FCC 96-378
PDF File:
96-26517.pdf
CFR: (1)
47 CFR 51