99-27570. Final Negative Countervailing Duty Determination; Live Cattle From Canada  

  • [Federal Register Volume 64, Number 204 (Friday, October 22, 1999)]
    [Notices]
    [Pages 57040-57069]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 99-27570]
    
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE
    
    International Trade Administration
    [C-122-834]
    
    
    Final Negative Countervailing Duty Determination; Live Cattle 
    From Canada
    
    AGENCY: Import Administration, International Trade Administration, U.S. 
    Department of Commerce.
    
    EFFECTIVE DATE: October 22, 1999.
    
    FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Zak Smith, Stephanie Hoffman, James 
    Breeden, or Melani Miller, AD/CVD Enforcement, Group I, Office 1, 
    Import Administration, U.S. Department of Commerce, 14th Street and 
    Constitution Avenue, NW, Washington, DC 20230; telephone: (202) 482-
    0189, 482-4198, 482-1174, or 482-0116, respectively.
    
    Final Determination
    
        The Department of Commerce determines that countervailable 
    subsidies are not being provided to producers or exporters of live 
    cattle in Canada.
    
    Petitioner
    
        The petition in this investigation was filed on November 12, 1998, 
    by the Ranchers-Cattlemen Action Legal Foundation (R-Calf, referred to 
    hereafter as ``the petitioner'').
    
    Case History
    
        Since the publication of the preliminary determination in the 
    Federal Register on May 11, 1999 (64 FR 25278) (``Preliminary 
    Determination''), the following events have occurred:
        We conducted verification in Canada of the questionnaire responses 
    from the Government of Canada (``GOC''), Government of Alberta 
    (``GOA''), Government of Manitoba (``GOM''), Government of Ontario 
    (``GOO'') and Government of Saskatchewan (``GOS'') from June 16 through 
    June 28 and August 5 through August 13, 1999. We aligned the final 
    determination in this investigation with the final determination in the 
    companion antidumping investigation (see Countervailing Duty 
    Investigation of Live Cattle From Canada; Notice of Alignment With 
    Final Antidumping Duty Determination, 64 FR 35127 (June 30, 1999)) and 
    we postponed the final determination of this investigation until 
    October 4, 1999 (see Notice of Postponement of Final Antidumping 
    Determination: Live Cattle from Canada, 64 FR 40351 (July 26, 1999)). 
    On October 4, 1999, the deadline for this final determination was set 
    for October 12, 1999. See Memorandum to Richard W. Moreland from 
    Valerie Ellis, ``Clarification and Correction of Extension of Final 
    Determination in the Antidumping Investigation of Live Cattle from 
    Canada.'' The petitioner and the respondents filed case briefs on 
    September 3 and we received rebuttal briefs from the petitioner and the 
    respondents on September 10, 1999. In addition, we invited parties to 
    submit factual information and/or argumentation regarding the role and 
    amount of compensation received by cattlemen leasing public grazing 
    lands in Alberta from energy companies leasing oil and gas rights on 
    these lands. We received submissions from both the petitioner and the 
    GOA on September 17, 1999, and rebuttal comments from each party on 
    September 22, 1999.
    The Applicable Statute and Regulations
        Unless otherwise indicated, all citations to the statute are 
    references to the provisions of the Tariff Act of 1930, as amended by 
    the Uruguay Round Agreements Act (``URAA'') effective January 1, 1995 
    (``the Act''). In addition, all citations to the Department of 
    Commerce's (``the Department's'') regulations are to the current 
    regulations codified at 19 CFR Part 351 (April 1998). Although Subpart 
    E of 19 CFR Part 351, published on November 25, 1998 (63 FR 
    65348)(``New CVD Regulations'') does not apply to this investigation, 
    Subpart E represents the Department's interpretation of the 
    requirements of the Act. See 19 CFR 351.702(b).
    
    Scope of Investigation
    
        The scope of this investigation covers live cattle from Canada. For 
    purposes of this investigation, the product covered is all live cattle 
    except imports of (1) bison, (2) dairy cows for the production of milk 
    for human consumption, and (3) purebred cattle and other cattle 
    specially imported for breeding purposes.
        The merchandise subject to this investigation is classifiable as 
    statistical reporting numbers under 0102.90.40 of the Harmonized Tariff 
    Schedule of the United States (``HTSUS''), with the exception of 
    0102.90.40.10, 0102.90.40.72 and 0102.90.40.74. Although the HTSUS 
    subheadings are provided for convenience and customs purposes, the 
    written description of the merchandise under investigation is 
    dispositive.
    
    Injury Test
    
        Because Canada is a ``Subsidies Agreement Country'' within the 
    meaning of section 701(b) of the Act, the
    
    [[Page 57041]]
    
    International Trade Commission (``ITC'') is required to determine 
    whether imports of the subject merchandise from Canada materially 
    injure, or threaten material injury to, a U.S. industry. See section 
    701(a)(2) of the Act. On January 25, 1999, the ITC published its 
    preliminary determination finding that there is a reasonable indication 
    that an industry in the United States is being materially injured, or 
    threatened with material injury, by reason of imports from Canada of 
    the subject merchandise (see 64 FR 3716).
    
    Period of Investigation
    
        The period for which we are measuring subsidies (the ``POI'') is 
    the GOC's fiscal year, April 1, 1997 through March 31, 1998.
    
    Subsidies Valuation Information
    
    Allocation Period
    
        We have used three years as the allocation period in this 
    investigation. Based on information provided by the petitioner, three 
    years is the average useful life (``AUL'') of productive assets for the 
    Canadian cattle industry. Parties are not contesting this AUL.
    
    Subsidy Rate Calculation
    
        Due to the extremely large number of cattle producers in Canada, we 
    have collected subsidy information on an industry-wide or ``aggregate'' 
    basis (i.e., the total amount of benefits provided under a particular 
    program). Moreover, we have limited our investigation to the four 
    largest cattle producing provinces in Canada. Therefore, unless 
    otherwise noted, for each program found to be countervailable, we have 
    calculated the ad valorem subsidy rate by dividing the total amount of 
    the benefit attributed to cattle producers in the four relevant 
    provinces during the POI by the total sales of all cattle in the same 
    four provinces.
    
    Benchmarks for Loans
    
        In our Preliminary Determination, we used a previously verified 
    benchmark interest rate charged by Canadian commercial banks on loans 
    made to the farming sector for purposes of calculating the 
    countervailable benefits from the provincial and federal loan guarantee 
    programs and nonrecurring grants. See Live Swine From Canada; 
    Preliminary Results of Countervailing Duty Administrative Review, 63 FR 
    23723, 23726 (April 30, 1998) (``Live Swine From Canada 1998'').
        For this final determination, we have revised the benchmark rates 
    used to evaluate the provincial loan guarantee programs. At 
    verification, we met with private bank officials in Alberta and 
    Saskatchewan who explained that the cattle associations participating 
    in the loan guarantee programs receive competitive financing because 
    the association loans are large-scale, short-term lending arrangements 
    that provide lenders substantial security against default due to the 
    highly structured nature of the associations. Furthermore, the private 
    bank officials indicated that commercial lending rates obtained by the 
    cattle associations differ among the provinces due to local economic 
    conditions. See Memorandum to Susan Kuhbach from Zak Smith and James 
    Breeden, ``Verification Report for Private Commercial Banks in the 
    Countervailing Duty Investigation of Live Cattle from Canada,'' dated 
    August 27, 1999 (``Private Commercial Bank Verification Report''). 
    Because we believe it is reasonable to assume that the cattle 
    associations will borrow in their home province, province-specific 
    benchmarks offer the best measure of a comparable commercial loan that 
    the associations could actually obtain in the market. See section 
    771(E)(ii) of the Act.
        Based on our discussions with the private bank officials, we 
    calculated a benchmark rate for the loan guarantee programs of prime 
    plus .375 percent and prime plus one percent for Alberta and 
    Saskatchewan, respectively. With respect to Manitoba and Ontario, we 
    did not collect any province-specific information regarding lending 
    rates to cattle associations and, therefore, we have averaged the 
    benchmark rates computed for Alberta and Saskatchewan to calculate the 
    loan guarantee benchmark rate for these provinces.
        For the remaining loan programs investigated in this proceeding, we 
    have continued to use the benchmark rate of prime plus 1.5 percent from 
    Live Swine from Canada 1998 because the recipients of these loans are 
    individual livestock producers and, therefore, the benchmark rate 
    applicable to the cattle associations does not represent a comparable 
    commercial loan. As discussed in Live Swine from Canada 1998, the 
    Department determined that prime plus 1.5 percent represents the 
    national average of the predominant lending rates on comparable long-
    term, prime-based loans made to individual livestock producers in 
    Canada. Accordingly, we have applied this benchmark rate for purposes 
    of measuring the benefit on loans made to individual cattle producers.
        We also note that we have continued to use the figures published by 
    the Bank of Canada to calculate the average prime rate during the POI.
    
    Loan Guarantee Programs
    
        For certain loan guarantee programs that we have found to be 
    countervailable, the respondents were unable to provide the specific 
    loan information required to perform a precise calculation of the 
    countervailable benefit attributable to cattle producers during the 
    POI. They were unable to provide the data because of the nature of the 
    underlying loan instrument (i.e., lines of credit which had no 
    predetermined time frame for the disbursal of principal or set 
    repayment schedule), the extremely large number of loans provided, and 
    the large number of transactions (withdrawals and payments) conducted 
    pursuant to those loans. Therefore, for these programs, we have 
    estimated the countervailable benefit by calculating the difference 
    between the interest actually paid in the POI and the interest that 
    would have been paid on a commercial loan absent a guarantee. See 
    Extruded Rubber Thread From Malaysia: Final Affirmative Countervailing 
    Duty Determination and Countervailing Duty Order, 57 FR 38472 (August 
    25, 1992). This approach does not yield a precise measure of the 
    benefit because the loan instruments being examined are effectively 
    lines of credit with balances and interest rates varying from month-to-
    month. Nonetheless, we believe this methodology is reasonable under the 
    circumstances presented by this investigation.
        Also, the respondents reported various fees that borrowers would 
    have paid in connection with the guaranteed loans. However, the 
    information they presented with respect to fees payable on commercial 
    loans was unclear. So, to avoid a comparison of nominal benchmark rates 
    with effective interest rates on the government-guaranteed loans, we 
    have generally not included the fees in calculating the amounts paid 
    under the government-guaranteed loans. Consequently, we are comparing 
    nominal rates to nominal rates. The one exception to this is the fee 
    specifically paid to FIMCLA for the guarantee, which is an allowable 
    offset under section 771(6)(A) of the Act.
    
    I. Programs Determined To Be Countervailable
    
    Loan and Loan Guarantee Programs
    
    A. Farm Improvement and Marketing Cooperative Loans Act 
    (``FIMCLA'')
    
        Under FIMCLA, the GOC provides guarantees on loans extended by 
    private commercial banks and other lending institutions to farmers 
    across Canada.
    
    [[Page 57042]]
    
    Created in 1987, the purpose of this program is to increase the 
    availability of loans for the improvement and development of farms, and 
    the marketing, processing and distribution of farm products by 
    cooperative associations. Pursuant to FIMCLA, any individual engaged in 
    farming in Canada and any farmer-owned cooperative are eligible to 
    receive loan guarantees covering 95 percent of the debt outstanding for 
    projects that are related to farm improvement or increased farm 
    production. The maximum amount of money that an individual can borrow 
    under this program is C$250,000. For marketing cooperatives, the 
    maximum amount is C$3,000,000. The GOC reported that beef and hog 
    farmers, which are categorized as one group by the FIMCLA 
    administration, received approximately 18 to 27 percent of all 
    guarantees between 1994 and 1998, while other users such as poultry, 
    fruit and vegetables, and dairy producers received less than ten 
    percent of the guarantees.
        A loan guarantee is a financial contribution, as described in 
    section 771(5)(D)(i) of the Act, which provides a benefit to the 
    recipients equal to the difference between the amount the recipients of 
    the guarantee pay on the guaranteed loans and the amount the recipients 
    would pay for a comparable commercial loan absent the guarantee, after 
    adjusting for guarantee fees. Because the beef and pork industries 
    received a disproportionate share of benefits between 1994 and 1998, we 
    determine that the program is specific under section 771(5A)(D)(iii) of 
    the Act. Therefore, we determine that these loan guarantees are 
    countervailable subsidies to the extent that they lower the cost of 
    borrowing, within the meaning of section 771(5) of the Act.
        Because of the large number of guarantees granted under this 
    program, we agreed to use a sample generated by the GOC of loans 
    guaranteed under the program for beef producers throughout Canada. At 
    verification, we examined the GOC's sampling methodology and have 
    determined that this sample yields an accurate reflection of all loans 
    provided to beef producers that receive FIMCLA guarantees.
        To calculate the benefit conferred by this program, we used our 
    long-term fixed-rate or variable-rate loan methodology (depending on 
    the terms of the reported loans) to compute the total benefit on the 
    sampled loans. We then calculated the benefit per dollar loaned to beef 
    producers. This ratio was multiplied by the total value of guaranteed 
    loans outstanding to beef and hog producers in the POI to arrive at the 
    total benefit. We then divided the total benefit attributable to the 
    POI by Canada's total sales of live cattle and hogs during the POI. On 
    this basis, we determine the total subsidy from this program to be 0.04 
    percent ad valorem.
    
    B. Alberta Feeder Associations Guarantee Program
    
        The Alberta Feeder Associations Guarantee Act was established in 
    1938 to encourage banks to lend to cattle producers. The program is 
    administered by the Alberta Department of Agriculture, Food and Rural 
    Development. Under this program, up to 15 percent of the principal 
    amount of commercial loans taken out by feeder associations for the 
    acquisition of cattle is guaranteed. Eligibility for the guarantees is 
    limited to feeder associations located in Alberta. Sixty-two 
    associations received guarantees on loans which were outstanding during 
    the POI.
        A loan guarantee is a financial contribution, as described in 
    section 771(5)(D)(i) of the Act, which provides a benefit to the 
    recipients equal to the difference between the amount the recipients of 
    the guarantee pay on the guaranteed loans and the amount the recipients 
    would pay for a comparable commercial loan absent the guarantee, after 
    adjusting for guarantee fees. Because eligibility is limited to feeder 
    associations, we determine that the program is specific under section 
    771(5A)(D)(i) of the Act. Therefore, we determine that these loan 
    guarantees are countervailable subsidies to the extent that they lower 
    the cost of borrowing, within the meaning of section 771(5) of the Act.
        To calculate the benefit conferred by the loan guarantees, we 
    applied our short-term loan methodology and compared the amount of 
    interest actually paid during the POI by the associations to the amount 
    that would have been paid at the benchmark rate, as described in the 
    Subsidies Valuation Information section, above. We then divided the 
    associations' interest savings by the investigated provinces' total 
    sales of live cattle during the POI. On this basis, we determine the 
    total subsidy from this program to be 0.01 percent ad valorem.
    
    C. Manitoba Cattle Feeder Associations Loan Guarantee Program
    
        The Manitoba Cattle Feeder Associations Loan Guarantee Program was 
    established in 1991 to assist in the diversification of Manitoba farm 
    operations. The program is currently administered by the Manitoba 
    Agricultural Credit Corporation (``MACC''). The provincial government, 
    through MACC, guarantees 25 percent of the principal amount of loans 
    for the acquisition of livestock by feeder associations. Eligibility 
    for the guarantees is limited to feeder associations located in 
    Manitoba. Associations must be incorporated under the Cooperatives Act 
    of Manitoba, have a minimum of fifteen members, an elected board of 
    directors, and a registered brand for use on association cattle. Ten 
    associations received guarantees on loans which were outstanding during 
    the POI.
        A loan guarantee is a financial contribution, as described in 
    section 771(5)(D)(i) of the Act, which provides a benefit to the 
    recipients equal to the difference between the amount the recipients of 
    the guarantee pay on the guaranteed loans and the amount the recipients 
    would pay for a comparable commercial loan absent the guarantee, after 
    adjusting for guarantee fees. Because eligibility is limited to feeder 
    associations, we determine that the program is specific under section 
    771(5A)(D)(i) of the Act. Therefore, we determine that these loan 
    guarantees are countervailable subsidies, to the extent that they lower 
    the cost of borrowing, within the meaning of section 771(5) of the Act.
        To calculate the benefit conferred by the loan guarantees, we 
    applied our short-term loan methodology and compared the amount of 
    interest actually paid during the POI by the associations to the amount 
    that would have been paid at the benchmark rate, as described in the 
    Subsidies Valuation Information section, above. We then divided the 
    associations' interest savings by the investigated provinces' total 
    sales of live cattle during the POI. On this basis, we determine the 
    total subsidy from this program to be less than 0.01 percent ad 
    valorem.
    
    D. Ontario Feeder Cattle Loan Guarantee Program
    
        The Ontario Feeder Cattle Loan Program was established in 1990 to 
    help secure financing for cattle producers. The program is administered 
    by the Ontario Ministry of Agriculture, Food and Rural Affairs 
    (``OMAFRA''). OMAFRA provides a start-up grant of $10,000 to new feeder 
    associations and government guarantees covering 25 percent of the 
    amount borrowed by associations for the purchase and sale of cattle. 
    Eligibility for the guarantees is limited to feeder associations which 
    have at least twenty individuals who own or rent land in Ontario and 
    are not members of other feeder associations.
    
    [[Page 57043]]
    
    Eighteen associations received guarantees on loans which were 
    outstanding during the POI.
        Loan guarantees and grants are financial contributions, as 
    described in section 771(5)(D)(i) of the Act. Loan guarantees provide a 
    benefit to the recipients equal to the difference between the amount 
    the recipients of the guarantee pay on the guaranteed loans and the 
    amount the recipients would pay for a comparable commercial loan absent 
    the guarantee, after adjusting for guarantee fees. In the case of 
    grants, the benefit to recipients is the amount of the grant. Because 
    eligibility for the loan guarantees and grants under this program is 
    limited to feeder associations, we determine that the program is 
    specific under section 771(5A)(D)(i) of the Act. Therefore, we 
    determine that these loan guarantees are countervailable subsidies, to 
    the extent that they lower the cost of borrowing, within the meaning of 
    section 771(5) of the Act. Also, the grants are countervailable 
    subsidies within the meaning of section 771(5) of the Act.
        To calculate the benefit conferred by the loan guarantees, we 
    applied our short-term loan methodology and compared the amount of 
    interest actually paid during the POI by the associations to the amount 
    that would have been paid at the benchmark rate, as described in the 
    Subsidies Valuation Information section, above. We then divided the 
    associations' interest savings by the investigated provinces' total 
    sales during the POI. On this basis, we determine the total subsidy 
    from this program to be 0.01 percent ad valorem.
        Additionally, we determine that the grants provided under this 
    program are non-recurring because the recipients could not expect to 
    receive them on an ongoing basis. However, because the grant amounts 
    were below 0.50 percent of the investigated provinces' sales in the 
    year of receipt in each of the relevant years, we expensed the benefit 
    from the grants. For the POI, we divided the grants received during the 
    POI by the investigated provinces' total sales of live cattle during 
    the POI. On this basis we determine the countervailable subsidy to be 
    less than 0.01 percent ad valorem.
        To calculate the total benefit to cattle producers under this 
    program, we summed the benefit calculated for the loan guarantees and 
    grants. On this basis, we determine the total subsidy from this program 
    to be 0.01 percent ad valorem.
    
    E. Saskatchewan Feeder Associations Loan Guarantee Program
    
        The Saskatchewan Feeder Associations Loan Guarantee Program was 
    established in 1984 to facilitate the establishment of cattle feeder 
    associations in order to promote cattle feeding in Saskatchewan. The 
    program is administered by the Livestock and Veterinary Operations 
    Branch of the Saskatchewan Agriculture and Food Department. This agency 
    provides a government guarantee for 25 percent of the principal amount 
    on loans to feeder associations for the purchase of feeder heifers and 
    steers. Eligibility for the guarantees is limited to feeder 
    associations with at least twenty members over the age of eighteen, who 
    are not active in other feeder associations. One hundred and sixteen 
    associations received guarantees on loans which were outstanding during 
    the POI.
        A loan guarantee is a financial contribution, as described in 
    section 771(5)(D)(i) of the Act, which provides a benefit to the 
    recipients equal to the difference between the amount the recipients of 
    the guarantee pay on the guaranteed loans and the amount the recipients 
    would pay for a comparable commercial loan absent the guarantee, after 
    adjusting for guarantee fees. Because eligibility for the guarantees is 
    limited to feeder associations, we determine that the program is 
    specific under section 771(5A)(D)(i) of the Act. Therefore, we 
    determine that these loan guarantees are countervailable subsidies, to 
    the extent that they lower the cost of borrowing, within the meaning of 
    section 771(5) of the Act.
        To calculate the benefit conferred by the loan guarantees, we 
    applied our short-term loan methodology and compared the amount of 
    interest actually paid during the POI by the associations to the amount 
    that would have been paid at the benchmark rate, as described in the 
    Subsidies Valuation Information section, above. We then divided the 
    associations' interest savings by the investigated provinces' total 
    sales during the POI. On this basis, we determine the total subsidy 
    from this program to be 0.01 percent ad valorem.
    
    Provision of Goods or Services
    
    F. Prairie Farm Rehabilitation Community Pasture Program
    
        The Prairie Farm Rehabilitation Administration (``PFRA'') was 
    created in the 1930s to rehabilitate drought and soil drifting areas in 
    the Provinces of Manitoba, Saskatchewan, and Alberta. The PFRA 
    established the Community Pasture Program to facilitate improved land 
    use through its rehabilitation, conservation, and management. The goal 
    of the Community Pasture Program is to utilize the resource primarily 
    for the summer grazing of cattle to encourage long-term production of 
    high quality cattle. In pursuit of its objectives, the PFRA operates 87 
    separate pastures encompassing approximately 2.2 million acres. At 
    these pastures, the PFRA offers grazing privileges and optional 
    breeding services for fees as established by PFRA. The fees are based 
    upon recovery of the costs associated with the grazing and breeding 
    services.
        The provision of a good or service is a financial contribution as 
    described in section 771(5)(D)(iii) of the Act. To determine whether a 
    benefit is conferred in the provision of the service, it is necessary 
    to examine whether the provider receives adequate remuneration. 
    According to section 771(5)(E) of the Act, the adequacy of remuneration 
    with respect to a government's provision of a good or service ``* * * 
    shall be determined in relation to prevailing market conditions for the 
    good or service being provided or the goods being purchased in the 
    country which is subject to the investigation or review. Prevailing 
    market conditions include price, quality, availability, marketability, 
    transportation, and other conditions of purchase or sale.''
        To determine whether the GOC received adequate remuneration, we 
    compared the prices charged for public pasture services to those 
    charged by private providers of pasture services, adjusted as described 
    below. Given the different nature of the services provided, a simple 
    comparison of the fees charged would not be appropriate. Specifically, 
    we adjusted the private price downward by deducting costs associated 
    with the timing of the sale of cull cows (these costs arise because on 
    private pastures, users are able to remove and cull those cows which do 
    not become pregnant earlier in the season when prices are higher. PFRA 
    patrons, however, have less access to their herds and are only allowed 
    to cull cows at the end of the season when prices are lower.
        The GOC argued that there were other differences that should be 
    taken into account for such things as early weaning and timing of the 
    sale of calves (allegedly, PFRA patrons would prefer to wean and cull 
    calves earlier in the season when prices are higher, but PFRA access 
    rules only allow them to cull at the end of the season when prices are 
    lower), transportation to the pasture (allegedly, PFRA patrons live
    
    [[Page 57044]]
    
    further away from the pastures and, thus, incur greater transportation 
    expenses), and disease associated with commingled pastures. However, we 
    have not made adjustments for such costs because either the GOC did not 
    establish that such costs were faced solely by public pasture patrons 
    or because the GOC was unable to quantify them.
        Comparing the public pasturing price to the adjusted private 
    pasturing price, we determine that the price for private pastures is 
    higher than the price for public pastures. This provides a benefit to 
    the recipients equal to the difference between the amount the 
    recipients pay for public pastures and the amount the recipients would 
    pay for comparable private pasturing.
        Because use of Community Pastures is limited to Canadian farmers 
    involved in grazing livestock, we determine that the program is 
    specific under section 771(5A)(D)(i) of the Act. Therefore, we 
    determine that the provision of public pasture services is a 
    countervailable subsidy within the meaning of section 771(5) of the 
    Act.
        To measure the benefit, we calculated the difference between the 
    price for public pasture service and the adjusted price for privately 
    provided pasture service. This difference was multiplied by the total 
    number of cow/calf pairs serviced by the PFRA during the POI. We 
    treated the resulting amount as a recurring benefit and divided it by 
    the investigated provinces' total sales during the POI. On this basis, 
    we determine the countervailable subsidy to be 0.02 percent ad valorem.
    
    H. Saskatchewan Crown Lands Program
    
        Agricultural Crown land managed by Saskatchewan Agriculture and 
    Food (``SAF'') is made available to all Saskatchewan agricultural 
    producers for lease. Activities carried out on the land include: 
    grazing, cultivation, community pastures, and additional multiple-use 
    activities.
        Leases for grazing dispositions range from one to 33-year terms. 
    Beginning in 1997, SAF set rental rates using a formula which takes 
    account of the average price of cattle marketed over a period in the 
    previous year, the average pounds of beef produced from one animal unit 
    month (``AUM''), the AUM productivity rating of the land in question, 
    reduced stocking expectations, and a fair return for the use of the 
    land and resources. AUMs are defined as the amount of forage required 
    to feed one animal for one month while maintaining the vegetative state 
    of the land in good condition. Lessees are responsible for paying 
    taxes, developing and maintaining water facilities and fences, and 
    providing for public access to the land.
        The provision of a good or service is a financial contribution as 
    described in section 771(5)(D)(iii) of the Act. As discussed above in 
    connection with the PFRA, a benefit is conferred in the provision of a 
    good or service when the prices charged for government-provided goods 
    or services are less than the prices charged by private suppliers. In 
    the case of the Saskatchewan Crown Lands Grazing Program, a simple 
    comparison of the fees charged would not be appropriate because the 
    grazing rights being offered by the GOS differ from those offered by 
    private suppliers. In this regard, the GOS has provided certain 
    quantifiable adjustments. Specifically, we adjusted the private price 
    downward by deducting costs for the construction of fences and water 
    dugouts, and the cost of paying property taxes. Although the GOS argued 
    that there were other differences that should be taken into account for 
    such things as multiple-use requirements, we have not made adjustments 
    for such costs because the GOS was unable to quantify them. Comparing 
    the public grazing lease rate to the adjusted private lease rate, we 
    determine that the price for private leases is higher than the price 
    for a public grazing lease.
        Because the cattle industry is a predominant user of the 
    Saskatchewan Crown Lands Program, we determine that the program is 
    specific under section 771(5A)(D)(iii) of the Act. Therefore, we 
    determine that the provision of public grazing rights is a 
    countervailable subsidy within the meaning of section 771(5) of the 
    Act.
        To measure the benefit, we calculated the difference between the 
    price per AUM for a public grazing lease and the adjusted price per AUM 
    for a private grazing lease. We multiplied this difference by the total 
    AUM provided by SAF. We treated the resulting amount as a recurring 
    benefit and divided it by the investigated provinces' total sales 
    during the POI. On this basis, we determine the countervailable subsidy 
    to be 0.02 percent ad valorem.
    
    I. Manitoba Crown Lands Program
    
        Agricultural Crown land is managed by Manitoba Agriculture Crown 
    Lands (``MACL'') whose primary objective is to administer the 
    disposition of Crown lands and to improve the lands' productivity. 
    Crown agricultural land is made available to farmers through 
    cultivation and grazing leases. Lease holders are required to pay an 
    amount-in-lieu of municipal taxes as well as to construct and maintain 
    fences and watering facilities. Also, the public has access to Crown 
    lands at all times without prior permission of the lessee for such 
    activities as wildlife hunting, forestry, winter sports, hiking, and 
    berry picking. During the POI, MACL administered 1.6 million acres of 
    grazing leases accounting for 707,699 AUMs.
        Leases for grazing dispositions range from one to fifty year terms. 
    MACL sets rental rates each year by multiplying the number of AUMs the 
    leased land is capable of producing in an average year by an annual AUM 
    rental rate. The AUM rental rate is based on recovering the 
    administrative costs for the program using the previous year's actual 
    costs.
        The provision of a good or service is a financial contribution as 
    described in section 771(5)(D)(iii) of the Act. As discussed above in 
    connection with the PFRA, a benefit is conferred in the provision of a 
    good or service when the prices charged for government-provided goods 
    or services are less than the prices charged by private suppliers. In 
    the case of the Manitoba Crown Lands Program, a simple comparison of 
    the fees charged would not be appropriate because the grazing rights 
    being offered by the GOM differ from those offered by private 
    suppliers. In this regard, the GOM has provided certain quantifiable 
    adjustments. Specifically, we adjusted the private price downward by 
    deducting costs for the construction of fences and watering facilities, 
    and the cost of paying an amount-in-lieu of municipal taxes. Although 
    the GOM argued that there were other differences that should be taken 
    into account for such things as multiple-use requirements, we are not 
    making these adjustments because the GOM was unable to quantify them. 
    Comparing the public grazing lease to the adjusted private lease price, 
    we determine that the price for private leases is higher than the price 
    for a public grazing lease.
        Because livestock industries, including cattle, are predominant 
    users of the Manitoba Crown Lands Program, we determine that the 
    program is specific under section 771(5A)(D)(iii) of the Act. 
    Therefore, we determine that the provision of public grazing rights is 
    a countervailable subsidy within the meaning of section 771(5) of the 
    Act.
        To measure the benefit, we calculated the difference between the 
    price per AUM for a public grazing lease and the adjusted price per AUM 
    for a private grazing lease. We multiplied this difference by the total 
    AUM provided by MACL. We treated the resulting amount as a recurring 
    benefit and divided it by the investigated provinces' total sales
    
    [[Page 57045]]
    
    during the POI. On this basis, we determine the countervailable subsidy 
    to be less than 0.01 percent ad valorem.
    
    J. Alberta Crown Lands Basic Grazing Program
    
        Over time, Alberta has developed a system for granting grazing 
    rights on public land. Grazing rights began to be issued on public 
    lands in the early 1930s. Today, through Alberta Agriculture and 
    Municipal Affairs, over 10.5 million acres of land are managed by the 
    GOA including a grazing component of approximately two million AUMs.
        Leases for grazing rights range from one to twenty year terms, but, 
    in practice, all leases are renewed if the lessee is in good standing. 
    Alberta's Public Lands Act dictates how rental prices will be set. 
    Specifically, section 107 states that annual rent will be equal to a 
    percentage of the forage value of the leased land. When determining the 
    forage value of the land, the administering authority is required to 
    consider the grazing capacity of the land, the average gain in weight 
    of cattle on grass, and the average price per pound of cattle sold in 
    the principal livestock markets in Alberta during the preceding year. 
    Beyond paying the lease fee, lessees are also required to construct and 
    maintain capital improvements necessary for livestock and must comply 
    with all multiple-use and conservation restrictions imposed by the 
    government on the land. Lastly, lessees must pay school and municipal 
    taxes charged on the land being leased.
        As noted above, Crown lands have various multiple-use elements, 
    from recreation to oil and gas operations, which are often in conflict 
    with one another. The legislation that manages these diverging 
    interests is the Surface Rights Act. Under Alberta law, the surface of 
    land in the province can be owned by either private entities or the 
    government, but all rights to the subsurface of the land have been 
    reserved to the government. On occasion, the GOA leases subsurface 
    rights to industrial operators (e.g., oil and gas companies) and the 
    Surface Rights Act lays the ground rules for resolving differences 
    between those who control the surface rights and those who lease the 
    subsurface rights.
        Section 12(1) of the Surface Rights Act reads that, ``no operator 
    has a right of entry in respect of the surface of any land* * *until 
    the operator has obtained the consent of the owner and the occupant of 
    the surface of the land or has become entitled to right of entry by 
    reason of an order of the Board.* * *'' It appears from the record that 
    consent from the owner and occupant is usually contingent upon a 
    compensation package being agreed upon between the operator and the 
    owner and occupant. That is, the operator will agree to pay a certain 
    amount of compensation for damages, disruption, access, and other 
    factors to the owner and occupant. If the operator is unable to reach 
    an agreement with the owner and occupant, the operator can ask the 
    Surface Rights Board for a right of entry. In such cases, the Surface 
    Rights Board will issue a right of entry and determine the appropriate 
    amount of compensation. In determining the amount of compensation 
    payable, the Board may consider the market value of the land, the loss 
    of use by the owner or occupant of the area granted to the operator, 
    the adverse effect of the area granted to the operator on the remaining 
    land, the nuisance, inconvenience, and noise caused by the operations, 
    damage to the land granted to the operator, and any other factors the 
    Board considers relevant.
        We determine that grazing leases granted under the Albert Crown 
    Lands Basic Grazing Program are being provided to ranchers grazing 
    livestock, a specific group, within the meaning of section 
    771(5A)(D)(i). Moreover, we determine that the provision of grazing 
    leases is a financial contribution as described in section 
    771(5)(D)(iii) of the Act (provision of a good or service). Therefore, 
    to determine whether these grazing leases result in a countervailable 
    subsidy it is necessary to examine whether they confer a benefit on the 
    recipients of the leases.
        As discussed above in connection with the PFRA, a benefit is 
    conferred in the provision of a good or service when the government 
    receives less than adequate remuneration. Normally adequacy of 
    remuneration can be measured by reference to the prices being charged 
    for the good or service by private suppliers. In the case of grazing 
    rights provided by the GOA, however, a simple price comparison would 
    not be appropriate.
        First, as discussed in connection with the grazing programs of 
    other provinces, certain adjustments must be made to reflect the 
    different costs imposed on the lessees of private and public land. 
    Specifically, we adjusted the average private price downward by 
    deducting costs for the construction of fences and water improvements, 
    the cost of paying property taxes, and a multiple-use cost associated 
    with limitations on forage (we have also taken into account multiple-
    use income, as noted below). Although the GOA argued that there were 
    other differences that should be taken into account for such things as 
    differences in operating and capital costs, we have not made 
    adjustments for such costs because the GOA did not adequately support 
    these claimed adjustments. Comparing the public grazing lease price to 
    the adjusted private lease price, we determine that the price for 
    private leases is higher than the price for a public grazing lease.
        Second, we believe the compensation paid by oil and gas operators 
    to lessees of private and public land to gain access to the oil and gas 
    resources must be accounted for. In response to our request for 
    information and argumentation about so-called ``Bill 31'(which will 
    amend the Public Lands Act and the Surface Rights Act), the GOA pointed 
    to provisions in the Surface Rights Act that appear to give owners and 
    lessees of private and public land equal rights to compensation. In 
    both cases, the oil and gas operator is to negotiate compensation 
    agreements with the owners and lessees before gaining access to the 
    land. If agreement cannot be reached, the operator appeals the matter 
    to the Surface Rights Board. In deciding the amount of compensation to 
    be awarded to the owners and lessees of private or public land, the 
    Surface Rights Board applies the same rules. Moreover, the GOA claims, 
    the amount of compensation received by any owner or lessee cannot be 
    considered excessive, because if the owner or lessee attempts to obtain 
    too large an amount, the oil and gas operator can simply apply to the 
    Surface Rights Board to set the correct amount of compensation.
        Although the statutory provisions in the Surface Rights Act cited 
    by the GOA are consistent with the arguments it has put forward, other 
    information on the record suggests that the compensation received by 
    lessees of public land is excessive. Beginning in March 1997, the GOA 
    undertook a study to examine agricultural leases in the province. One 
    of the main issues examined in the study was compensation for ranchers 
    leasing grazing rights on public lands. The study resulted in a report 
    and, eventually, legislation (Bill 31). Although Bill 31 has not yet 
    been put into effect, it seems clear that one concern the legislation 
    seeks to address is that the province, as owner of the public land, 
    should receive some portion of the compensation now received by lessees 
    of the public land.
        While this, in itself, does not necessarily mean that the 
    compensation currently received by lessees of public land is excessive 
    when compared to the compensation received by lessees of private land, 
    statements made at the time that Bill 31 was proposed and
    
    [[Page 57046]]
    
    debated, lead us to conclude that the compensation received by lessees 
    of private and public land is not equivalent. Specifically, the 
    government's spokesperson on behalf of the bill stated: ``It (Bill 31) 
    does another thing as well: it ensures that public land leasing 
    arrangements are more equitable with private land leasing arrangements. 
    Since the province is the landowner of public land in the right of all 
    Albertans, we were told by our colleagues and those making submissions 
    that the province should act like a landowner. This means that leasing 
    arrangements should be more comparable to the private sector'' 
    (statement by Mr. Thurber, Alberta Hansard, April 14, 1999, page 1035). 
    Similarly, ``the intent of amendments to the Surface Rights Act are to 
    redistribute payments to the landowner (the province) and the 
    agriculture disposition holder (the lessee of public land) more in line 
    with private land arrangements' (statement by Mr. Thurber, Alberta 
    Hansard, May 3, 1999, page 1396).
        These statements appear to support the conclusion that private 
    owners receive more in compensation than the GOA does as owner. There 
    is no indication in the record that the amount of compensation paid by 
    oil and gas operators for private lands exceeds the amount of 
    compensation paid for public lands. Therefore, we conclude that the 
    lessees of public land receive greater compensation than their 
    counterparts on private land.
        If our conclusions are correct, then the differences in 
    compensation amounts to lessees of public and private land would not be 
    reflected in a comparison of fees for the two types of grazing rights. 
    This is because the relatively lower level of compensation received by 
    the lessees of private land will cause that fee to be lower than it 
    would be if they received the higher amount of compensation.
        Therefore, to calculate the difference in compensation amounts that 
    is not reflected in a comparison of fees for the two types of grazing 
    rights, we have attempted to measure the remuneration that we believe 
    the GOA would have received, as owner of the public land, if its 
    leasing arrangements were ``in line with private land arrangements.'' 
    We note that because such information regarding compensation is not 
    available on the record of this investigation, our calculation is an 
    estimate based upon the facts available.
        Information that is on the record indicates that total compensation 
    earned by public lessees is approximately C$40 million per year. It 
    appears that this amount represents compensation for damages, 
    disruption, access, and other factors. Because the law indicates that 
    both private and public lessees are entitled to compensation for 
    damages and disruption we expect that a portion of this C$40 million 
    represents an amount of compensation that would be paid to any lessee 
    regardless of whether the land being leased was private or public. 
    Thus, it would be inappropriate to assume that the C$40 million figure 
    represents compensation that is only obtained by public lessees because 
    they are leasing public land.
        Therefore, it is necessary to estimate the portion of the 
    compensation received by lessees of public land attributable to damages 
    and disruption (which would be the same for a private lessees) versus 
    compensation for access and other factors. In this respect, the GOA has 
    stated that the average compensation package determined by the Surface 
    Rights Board for both public and private lessees amounted to C$1,100 
    per year. Given the number of grazing leases on public land affected by 
    subsurface operations, the total amount attributable to compensation 
    for damages and disruption on public land would be approximately C$15.9 
    million per year. According to the rules followed by the Surface Rights 
    Board in establishing the amount of compensation, this amount would 
    represent the compensation for damages and disruption only. The 
    remainder of the compensation (C$24.1 million) would be for access and 
    other factors.
        We recognize that this is a crude estimate of the amount of 
    compensation that could be expected to flow to the GOA if it received 
    the compensation that we believe currently flows to holders of public 
    land leases. For example, while the C$40 million amount is widely 
    reported, it is not clear where the estimate came from or how it was 
    calculated. Moreover, the amount we have selected, C$24.1 million, is 
    at the upper end of the possible range of estimates. (See statement by 
    Dr. Pannu, a member of the Alberta legislature, as reported in the 
    Alberta Hansard, May 11, 1999, page 1627: ``it's difficult at this 
    point to make a reliable assessment of what additional revenues these 
    changes in the leasing arrangements proposed in this bill will generate 
    for the public treasury. I have seen different figures. I think it 
    could be close to $13 million to $15 million or perhaps more * * *'') 
    We believe that a conservative estimate is appropriate in light of the 
    limited information available to the Department to ensure that a 
    negative final determination is warranted.
        Therefore, because public lessees can expect to receive C$24.1 
    million more in compensation by renting public land as opposed to 
    private land, the public land is more valuable. However, as noted 
    above, we have concluded that the differences in compensation amounts 
    to lessees of public and private land are not reflected in a comparison 
    of fees for the two types of grazing rights. That is, the government is 
    not charging a higher price for its land to capture this value and, 
    thus, is not being adequately remunerated for its provision of public 
    land.
        To measure the benefits received under the Alberta Crown Lands 
    Basic Grazing Program, we have combined the difference calculated by 
    comparing the grazing fees paid for public and private land with the 
    difference in compensation described above. We treated the resulting 
    amount as a recurring benefit and divided it by the investigated 
    provinces' total sales during the POI. On this basis, we determine the 
    countervailable subsidy to be 0.65 percent ad valorem.
    
    Other Programs
    
    K. Northern Ontario Heritage Fund Corporation Agriculture 
    Assistance
    
        The Northern Ontario Heritage Fund Corporation (``NOHFC'') was 
    established in 1988 as a Crown corporation. Its purpose is to promote 
    and stimulate economic development in northern Ontario. NOHFC focuses 
    on funding infrastructure improvements and development opportunities in 
    northern Ontario. Assistance for these projects is available through 
    forgivable performance loans, incentive term loans, and loan 
    guarantees.
        With respect to agricultural projects, all assistance provided by 
    NOHFC is in the form of forgivable performance loans. The types of 
    agricultural projects funded include capital projects, marketing 
    projects and research and development projects. Fifty percent of a 
    project's capital costs are eligible for funding, up to a maximum of 
    C$2.5 million. For marketing projects, fifty percent of the project 
    costs may receive funding, up to a maximum of C$500,000. For research 
    and development projects, 75 percent of the project costs may receive 
    funding, up to a maximum of C$500,000. The loans made available for 
    these projects are interest-free and normally forgiven after two to 
    three years. The extent of debt forgiveness is dependent upon the 
    project meeting its target of increasing the value of farm production 
    by an amount equal to the NOHFC contribution.
    
    [[Page 57047]]
    
        Debt forgiveness is a financial contribution as described in 
    section 771(5)(D)(i) of the Act, which provides a benefit to the 
    recipients equal to the amount of the debt forgiven. Because benefits 
    under this program are only available in northern Ontario, we determine 
    that the program is regionally specific under section 771(5A)(D)(iv) of 
    the Act. Therefore, we determine that this debt forgiveness is 
    countervailable within the meaning of section 771(5) of the Act.
        We further determine that this debt forgiveness is non-recurring 
    because the recipients could not expect to receive it on an ongoing 
    basis. However, because the benefit to cattle producers in Ontario was 
    below 0.50 percent of the investigated provinces' sales in the year of 
    receipt in each of the relevant years, we expensed the debt forgiveness 
    in the year received. To calculate the benefit for the POI, we divided 
    the total amount of the forgiven debt by the investigated provinces' 
    total sales during the POI. On this basis, we determine the 
    countervailable subsidy to be less than 0.01 percent ad valorem.
        Additionally, we determine that a countervailable subsidy is 
    conferred because no interest is charged on these loans. Under section 
    771(5)(E)(ii) of the Act, a benefit arises when loan recipients pay 
    less on government provided loans than they would pay on comparable 
    commercial loans. Pursuant to section 355.49(f) of the 1989 Proposed 
    Regulations, we have treated the balances outstanding during the POI as 
    interest-free, short-term loans. We calculated the benefit from these 
    loans by dividing the amount of interest due at the benchmark rate by 
    the investigated provinces' total sales during the POI. On this basis, 
    we determine the countervailable subsidy to be less than 0.01 percent 
    ad valorem.
        To calculate the total benefit to cattle producers under this 
    program, we summed the benefit calculated for the forgiven debt and the 
    interest-free loans. On this basis, we determine the total subsidy from 
    this program to be less than 0.01 percent ad valorem.
    
    L. Ontario Livestock, Poultry, and Honeybee Protection Act
    
        This program, which is administered by the Ontario Ministry of 
    Agriculture, Food and Rural Affairs, provides compensation to livestock 
    producers whose animals are injured or killed by wolves or coyotes. 
    Producers apply for, and receive, compensation through the local 
    municipal government. The Ontario Ministry of Agriculture, Food and 
    Rural Affairs reimburses the municipality. Grants for damage to live 
    cattle cannot exceed C$1,000 per head. Although the Ministry of 
    Agriculture does not track the proportion of benefits under this 
    program going to dairy cattle or beef cattle producers, the GOO has 
    reported that beef cattle producers are believed to derive the majority 
    of the benefits from the program.
        A grant is a financial contribution as described in section 
    771(5)(D)(i) of the Act, which provides a benefit to recipients in the 
    amount of the grant. Because this program is limited by law to 
    livestock producers, poultry farmers, and beekeepers, we determine that 
    the program is specific under section 771(5A)(D)(i) of the Act. 
    Therefore, we determine that these grants are countervailable within 
    the meaning of section 771(5) of the Act.
        We treated the grants received as a recurring benefit because 
    livestock producers can expect to receive the grants every year. To 
    calculate the benefit, we divided the total amount of grants received 
    by the investigated provinces' total sales of live cattle during the 
    POI. On this basis, we determine the countervailable subsidy to be 0.01 
    percent ad valorem.
    
    M. Ontario Rabies Indemnification Program
    
        This program is administered by the Farm Assistance Branch of the 
    Ontario Ministry of Agriculture, Food and Rural Affairs. It is designed 
    to encourage farmers to report cases of rabies in livestock by 
    compensating livestock producers for damage caused by rabies. Farmers 
    may receive grants up to a maximum of C$1,000 per head of cattle under 
    this program. Sixty percent of the grants are funded by the GOO and 40 
    percent by the GOC.
        A grant is a financial contribution as described in section 
    771(5)(D)(i) of the Act which provides a benefit to recipients in the 
    amount of the grant. Because the legislation establishing this program 
    expressly limits these grants to livestock producers, we determine that 
    the program is specific under section 771(5A)(D)(i) of the Act. 
    Therefore, we determine that these grants are countervailable within 
    the meaning of section 771(5) of the Act.
        We treated the grants received as a recurring benefit because 
    farmers can expect to receive the grants every year. To calculate the 
    benefit, we divided the total amount of grants received by the 
    investigated provinces' total sales of live cattle during the POI. The 
    amount of the total amount of grants was taken from updated information 
    supplied to the Department at verification. On this basis, we determine 
    the countervailable subsidy to be less than 0.01 percent ad valorem.
    
    N. Saskatchewan Livestock and Horticultural Facilities Incentives 
    Program
    
        The purpose of this program is to promote the diversification of 
    Saskatchewan's rural economy by encouraging investment in livestock and 
    horticultural facilities. This program allows for an annual rebate of 
    education and health taxes paid on building materials and stationary 
    equipment used in livestock operations, as well as greenhouses, and 
    vegetable and raw fruit storage facilities.
        A tax benefit is a financial contribution as described in section 
    771(5)(D)(ii) of the Act which provides a benefit to the recipient in 
    the amount of the tax savings. Because the legislation establishing 
    this program expressly limits the tax benefits to the livestock and 
    horticulture industries, we determine that the program is specific 
    under section 771(5A)(D)(i) of the Act. Therefore, we determine that 
    this tax benefit is countervailable within the meaning of section 
    771(5) of the Act.
        In calculating the benefit, we treated the tax savings as a 
    recurring benefit and divided the tax savings received by the 
    investigated provinces' total sales during the POI. On this basis, we 
    determine the countervailable subsidy to be less than 0.01 percent ad 
    valorem.
    
    II. Programs Determined To Be Not Countervailable
    
    A. Canadian Wheat Board
    
    Introduction
    
        The Canadian Wheat Board (``CWB'') has the exclusive authority to 
    market Canadian feed and malting barley in export markets. In the 
    Canadian domestic market, the CWB has exclusive marketing authority 
    only with respect to malting barley. The petitioner alleges that the 
    CWB's pooling system (described below) sends distorted market signals 
    to Canadian farmers. Further, the petitioner argues that the system of 
    marketing feed barley in Canada imposes excessive costs on farmers, 
    with the result that less feed barley is exported than there otherwise 
    would be. Consequently, the petitioner alleges, more feed barley is 
    available on the domestic market, which artificially lowers prices paid 
    by Canadian cattle producers. Although the CWB system may not involve 
    the explicit export restriction present in Certain Softwood Lumber 
    Products from Canada, 57 FR 22570 (May 28, 1992) (``Lumber'') and 
    Leather from Argentina, 55 FR 40212 (October 2, 1990) (``Leather''), in 
    the
    
    [[Page 57048]]
    
    petitioner's view, the CWB's control over, and operations in, the feed 
    barley market have the same result as the export restrictions which the 
    Department found countervailable in those cases.
        In the Preliminary Determination, we preliminarily concluded that, 
    even if the CWB controlled exports, it nonetheless did not provide a 
    benefit to Canadian producers of live cattle because Canadian domestic 
    prices were not lower than prices in the United States in the POI. In 
    making our price comparisons for the Preliminary Determination, we 
    compared U.S. prices for feed barley in Great Falls, Montana, with 
    several Canadian domestic prices. We preliminarily found that Canadian 
    domestic prices were comparable to U.S. prices.
        Since the Preliminary Determination, we have conducted a thorough 
    analysis of all aspects of the Canadian feed barley market and its 
    relation to the cattle industry. We analyzed where barley is produced 
    and consumed within Canada, the total production of both feed and 
    malting varieties of barley, marketing options available to barley 
    farmers, exports of feed barley, the operations of the CWB, feed barley 
    prices within and outside the area in Canada under the control of the 
    CWB (i.e., the ``designated area''), and additional feed barley prices 
    in the United States. We find that the CWB has extensive control over 
    the feed barley export market and that its operations in that market 
    can, and do, have a major impact in the domestic feed barley market. 
    However, as in the Preliminary Determination, we find that the 
    operations of the CWB did not provide a benefit to the producers of 
    live cattle during the POI.
    
    Canadian Barley Production
    
        There are two primary agricultural areas in Canada: the prairies in 
    western Canada (Alberta, Saskatchewan and Manitoba), and southern 
    Ontario and Quebec. Eighty percent of Canadian farmland is in the 
    prairies. The large majority of Canadian grain is grown on the 
    prairies, although some grain is also grown in the southernmost 
    portions of Ontario and Quebec.
        The growing conditions in western Canada and the eastern provinces 
    are very different, which leads to different growing patterns in each 
    area. The climate in the prairies is drier and cooler with a shorter 
    growing season; the predominant crops are barley, wheat, and oilseeds. 
    Conversely, because Ontario is warmer and receives more rainfall, the 
    climate there is more conducive to growing corn and soybeans. While 
    Ontario has some barley production, barley is not the predominant crop 
    in the area.
        In the most recent crop year (1998/1999), Canada produced a total 
    of 12.7 million metric tons of barley. Over ninety percent of this 
    barley was grown in the prairies; 400,000 metric tons were grown in 
    Ontario. The percentage of prairie production by province was: 48 
    percent in Alberta, 37 percent in Saskatchewan, 14 percent in Manitoba, 
    and less than one percent in British Columbia. Although 70 percent of 
    Canadian barley is seeded as malting varieties (for which higher prices 
    can be obtained), only 30 percent is actually sold as malting barley. 
    The malting barley that is not sold for malting is consumed as feed 
    barley.
        Almost half of all Canadian barley production occurs in Alberta, in 
    a north-south belt extending from Lethbridge in the south to Edmonton 
    in the north. From Edmonton, the barley growing area arcs in a 
    southeastwardly direction towards Winnipeg. A small portion of 
    southeastern Alberta and a much larger section of southern Saskatchewan 
    are less productive for growing barley because of less rainfall and 
    warmer temperatures.
        In Ontario, the barley growing area is primarily located on the 
    peninsula that extends south between Lake Huron, on the west, and Lakes 
    Erie and Ontario, on the east. Some grain is also grown around Ottawa. 
    The primary crop grown in Ontario is corn; barley production occurs on 
    the fringe of the growing area where corn cannot grow because of cooler 
    temperatures or unfavorable soil conditions.
    
    Canadian Cattle Production
    
        Canadian beef cattle production is primarily concentrated in 
    western Canada (82 percent), with 12 percent in Ontario, and 5 percent 
    in Quebec. Western Canadian beef production by province is: 46 percent 
    in Alberta, 21 percent in Saskatchewan, 11 percent in Manitoba, and 5 
    percent in British Columbia. Similar to barley production, almost half 
    of all Canadian beef cattle production occurs in Alberta. Many farmers 
    throughout the prairies produce both cattle and barley. The primary 
    consumers of feed barley are feedlots, and the majority of Canadian 
    feedlots (approximately 70 percent) are located in southern Alberta, 
    between Lethbridge and Calgary.
    
    CWB Organizational Principles and History
    
        The CWB had its origins in the early 1900s. It was during this time 
    that two of the fundamental principles of the CWB and the marketing of 
    Canadian barley were established: single-desk selling and the 
    ``pooling'' of costs and revenues. Since we are only concerned with 
    feed barley, single-desk selling in the context of this investigation 
    means that the CWB is the sole exporter of western Canadian feed 
    barley. This authority requires barley farmers to sell via a single 
    entity in export markets rather than competing against one another. 
    Barley farmers can compete with each other with respect to feed barley 
    sales in Canada--though not with respect to malting barley sales in 
    Canada. In theory, according to the CWB, the absence of multiple 
    sellers and the ability to sell at different prices in different 
    markets allows the single desk seller to obtain a higher overall price 
    for Canadian grain.
        The pooling mechanism is perhaps the defining feature of the CWB's 
    operations. The CWB operates a separate ``pool'' for each of the four 
    crops under its authority (wheat, durum wheat, feed barley and 
    ``designated'' or malting barley). Pooling means that the CWB pays 
    every farmer the same amount for a given quantity and quality of grain 
    based on the weighted-average price received for all the barley 
    marketed in the pool year, regardless of when in the crop year the 
    farmer sells to the CWB and regardless of the specific sales prices the 
    CWB realizes on the individual sales of that grain. (The payment 
    mechanism--involving initial, adjustment, interim and final payments--
    is discussed below.) According to the CWB, the pooling mechanism is a 
    risk management tool designed to protect farmers from adverse price 
    fluctuations that may occur throughout the year.
        Prior to 1974, the CWB controlled all sales of barley, including 
    domestic sales of feed barley. Responding to pressure from eastern 
    livestock producers who wanted access to western grain and western 
    grain producers who wanted to sell grain in the east, the GOC removed 
    domestic sales of feed barley from the CWB's jurisdiction in 1974. In 
    the same year, the GOC established the Reserve Stock Program, 
    apparently to ensure that western livestock producers would continue to 
    have a reliable source of feed barley. This program was terminated in 
    1979.
        In 1984, the Western Grain Transportation Act (``WGTA'') came into 
    effect. Under this program, the GOC paid the difference between the 
    ``crow rate'' (a ceiling on rail rates dating back to 1897) and an 
    unregulated rate. In 1985, the province of Alberta began the Crow 
    Benefit Offset Program to offset the higher local grain prices caused 
    by
    
    [[Page 57049]]
    
    the WGTA. The program essentially subsidized the purchase of barley by 
    livestock producers and may have resulted in an increase of livestock 
    production in the province. The WGTA subsidies continued until 1995.
        On August 1, 1993, the GOC permitted non-CWB entities to export 
    barley, thereby creating the so-called ``Continental Barley Market'' 
    (``CBM''). As a result of Canadian judicial intervention, the CBM 
    lasted only until September 10, 1993. During the CBM, exports of 
    Canadian feed barley to the United States increased dramatically 
    compared to prior periods. Whether this was due to the ability of 
    individual farmers to export or other factors (e.g., flooding in the 
    United States) has been subject to much dispute. Economists also differ 
    on the impact of the CBM on U.S. and Canadian prices, specifically, 
    whether the CBM resulted in the convergence of U.S. and Canadian 
    domestic feed prices. The petitioner suggests that the CBM is 
    indicative of the market that would exist in the absence of the CWB.
    
    CWB Act
    
        The current statutory authority for the CWB was enacted in 1935. 
    The CWB Act: (1) Codifies the CWB's exclusive control over feed and 
    malting barley exports; (2) establishes the governance structure and 
    mission of the CWB; and (3) delineates the relationship between the GOC 
    and CWB. Under section 45 of the CWB Act, ``no person shall export from 
    Canada [wheat or barley] owned by a person other than the Board.'' This 
    provision grants the CWB its export monopoly authority with respect to 
    all barley produced in Canada. Section 45 of the CWB Act also grants 
    the CWB authority over interprovincial trade in barley.
        During the POI, the CWB was a Crown corporation governed by five 
    commissioners appointed by the GOC. Farmers were represented on an 
    advisory board that could only make recommendations to the 
    commissioners. Pursuant to section 7 of its statutory authority, the 
    CWB's mandate is to sell grain ``for such prices as it considers 
    reasonable with the object of promoting the sale of grain produced in 
    Canada in world markets.''
        The CWB Act establishes the following three financial relationships 
    between the CWB and the GOC: (1) The GOC guarantees all approved 
    borrowings of the CWB, (2) the GOC guarantees the initial payment, 
    adjustments, and interim payments made to farmers (discussed further 
    below), and (3) the GOC guarantees credit extended to purchasers of CWB 
    grain. (See sections 6, 7 and 19 of the CWB Act.)
        In addition to the financial ties between the GOC and the CWB, the 
    CWB Act promulgates other means by which the GOC may exert authority 
    over CWB operations. Section 18 of the CWB Act allows for GOC policy 
    directions via an order by the Governor-in-Council (``GIC''). Under 
    section 32, the amount of the initial payment must be approved by the 
    GOC. Finally, the CWB is required to provide a proprietary, detailed 
    annual reporting of the CWB's operations to the GIC.
    
    1998 Amendment to the CWB Act
    
        In 1996, the GOC established the Western Grain Marketing Panel 
    (``WGMP'') to review the marketing system of western Canadian grain. As 
    a result of the WGMP, an amendment to the CWB Act (``the amendment'') 
    was passed in June 1998 and became operational on December 31, 1998. 
    Parts of the amendment were implemented in June and December 1998, 
    while others have yet to be formally implemented. Below is a discussion 
    of certain key WGMP recommendations and the provisions that were passed 
    to implement these recommendations.
        Change in legal status. As noted, under the old CWB Act, the CWB 
    was a Crown corporation. Pursuant to the amendment, it became a 
    ``shared-governance'' corporation. The new governance structure created 
    by the amendment granted more direct control of the CWB to the farmers 
    through the Board of Directors. Specifically, ten members of the new 
    Board of Directors are elected by grain producers and the remaining 
    five members, including the president, are appointed by the GOC. The 
    new Board of Directors is responsible for managing the business and 
    affairs of the CWB and directing strategic planning. The old Advisory 
    Board was disbanded.
        Removal of feed barley from CWB jurisdiction. The WGMP recommended 
    that the CWB should remain solely responsible for marketing malting 
    barley, but that farmers should be allowed to export feed barley 
    directly or sell it to the CWB. In 1997, the GOC held a plebiscite 
    asking farmers if they wanted to continue the current marketing system 
    or sell their barley without the CWB. Sixty-three percent of farmers 
    voted to maintain the current system. Thus, the CWB's exclusive control 
    over both feed and malting barley exports has continued.
        Early closing of pools. Under the old CWB Act, the CWB could only 
    make final payments on pools in January following the end of the crop 
    year (e.g., January 1999 for the 1997-98 crop year). The amendment 
    grants the CWB the authority to close a pool early (i.e., prior to the 
    end of the crop year). The CWB wanted the ability to close a pool in 
    situations where export prices decline precipitously. Under these 
    circumstances, the CWB could terminate the existing pool once it became 
    apparent that prices were steadily declining. Farmers who delivered 
    their barley to the pool would receive the weighted-average price 
    received during the time the pool was open. After the old pool was 
    closed, a new pool could be established. The first pool would reflect 
    the higher prices in the beginning of the year, and the second pool 
    would reflect the lower prices at the end of the year. By ending a pool 
    early, the pool payment farmers receive for their grain would be more 
    reflective of their initial expectations. Ending pools early in a 
    falling market could also be used as a mechanism to ensure that the GOC 
    would not have to cover a pool deficit (i.e., reimbursing the CWB for 
    the difference between the payments made to farmers in the course of 
    the crop year and the actual revenues received on barley pool sales).
        Cash Purchase Option. As recommended by the WGMP, the amendment 
    allows the CWB to make cash purchases from farmers and other 
    participants on the open market. The reason for this change is to allow 
    the CWB to purchase grain directly from farmers when the CWB has 
    selling opportunities but the CWB's estimates of the final pool payment 
    the farmer will receive--the Pool Return Outlooks and Estimated Pool 
    Returns (the PROs and EPRs, discussed below)--are not attracting 
    sufficient supplies to take advantage of those opportunities. However, 
    prior to the adoption of the amendment in 1998, the livestock industry 
    expressed concern that use of this provision by the CWB might raise 
    feed barley prices to the Canadian livestock industry. This provision 
    has not yet been proclaimed in force by Parliament. Therefore, the cash 
    purchase option has not yet been exercised by the CWB.
    
    CWB Operations
    
        The Canadian crop year is from August 1 to July 31. Barley is 
    normally planted in the spring. Harvesting begins the first or second 
    week of August and may continue through October, depending on the 
    weather. Once the grain is harvested, the farmer can begin to deliver 
    grain immediately through the acreage-based system, or through the 
    ``delivery contract system'' throughout the year. Relatively small 
    amounts of
    
    [[Page 57050]]
    
    grain are delivered under the acreage-based system. The primary method 
    of sale and delivery to the CWB is through the delivery contract 
    system.
        Under the delivery contract system, there are four contract series 
    throughout the year, each with a different deadline (for the 1997-98 
    crop year, the deadlines were: series A, October 31; series B, December 
    31; series C, February 27; and series D, May 29). On the contract, the 
    farmer identifies, inter alia, the station to which he normally 
    delivers (he can deliver anywhere he wants), the series for which he is 
    offering grain, and the net amount he expects to deliver. Because the 
    farmer will not know the exact weight of his barley until it is 
    delivered, the CWB allows an 85 percent tolerance.
        After the CWB receives all contracts offered under a particular 
    series, it tabulates the offers and determines whether it will accept 
    all the grain. The factors that are taken into consideration in this 
    analysis are: the amount and types of grain offered, the sales 
    requirements identified up to that point, and any transportation 
    constraints. The acceptance rate for every series in the POI was 100 
    percent. In the last five years, the CWB has consistently accepted all 
    the barley offered to it, except for series C in the 1995-96 crop year, 
    when it only accepted fifty percent of the grain offered.
        Once the series contracts have been offered and accepted, delivery 
    of the barley must be ``called'' by the CWB. A ``call'' or ``delivery 
    call'' is essentially an instruction issued by the CWB to farmers 
    telling them when and where to deliver their barley. The CWB must issue 
    a call before a farmer can deliver his grain.
        A number of factors are analyzed by the CWB in determining when the 
    grain should be called into the handling system: the total amount 
    offered, immediate sales commitments, the quantity of grain already in 
    the handling system, where grain is located, any transportation 
    constraints, and outstanding delivery calls (if any). Any one call can 
    be less than 100 percent of the accepted series amount. However, 
    acceptance of a farmer's offer commits the CWB to call all the grain 
    accepted at some point before the end of the crop year. Once a call is 
    announced, farmers may deliver their grain.
        Pursuant to section 24 of the CWB Act, farmers are legally 
    prevented from delivering to a grain elevator unless, inter alia, they 
    have a permit book, the grain was produced on the lands described in 
    the permit book, and the quantity of grain delivered does not exceed 
    the amount authorized by the CWB. When the farmer delivers the grain to 
    the elevator, the elevator manager grades it, and makes the initial 
    payment (discussed below) on behalf of the CWB to the farmer. The 
    delivery is recorded in the farmer's permit book and applied against 
    the contract the farmer established with the CWB to calculate the net 
    outstanding balance of grain due under that contract.
        Every farmer that sells into the pool receives the payment for his 
    crop in installments. Upon delivery of the grain to the elevator, the 
    farmer receives the published initial payment adjusted for freight to 
    either Vancouver or St. Lawrence (the two primary export points), less 
    any grain company deductions for elevation and cleaning. The initial 
    payment set by the CWB is based on market projections, CWB-specific 
    sales prospects, and an evaluation of export prices. While there is no 
    fixed rule, initial payments historically have been set at 70-75 
    percent of the projected final return. As noted above, the initial 
    payment must be approved by the GOC.
        During the year, the CWB may make adjusted or interim payments. 
    After the pool year is closed, the farmer normally receives a final 
    payment. The sum of these payments equals the ``pool payment,'' which 
    is the total return the farmer receives for barley delivered to the 
    CWB.
        Once the barley has been called, delivered and stored, it must 
    eventually be moved to an export point. This is generally done by rail. 
    The allocation of the two Canadian railroads' resources is arranged by 
    a government/private sector committee called the Car Allocation Policy 
    Group (``CAPG''). This group sets policies and coordinates the movement 
    of barley and other grain through the system. CAPG has representatives 
    from grain companies, railways, farmers, small shippers, and the CWB. 
    It performs capacity planning for four-month and one-year periods. It 
    evaluates market demand information from shippers and supply 
    information from railroads to determine where and when the 
    transportation constraints will arise. During high usage periods, the 
    CAPG attempts to allocate resources equally; in other words, access is 
    not rationed by price. (See section 28 of the CWB Act, which enables 
    the CWB to ``provide for the allocation of railway cars.'')
    
    Pricing Signals
    
        Starting in late February to early March prior to the crop year 
    (e.g., February 1997 for the August 1,1997/July 31, 1998 crop year), 
    the CWB publishes, on a monthly basis, the Pool Return Outlook (PRO), 
    which is a range within which the CWB expects the final pool return to 
    fall. The monthly PROs are the main tool a farmer has in determining 
    how much barley to grow and in deciding whether to sell his grain 
    domestically, or to the CWB for export. Once the pool year is in 
    progress and sales have been completed, the CWB has a better idea of 
    the final pool return. In March of the crop year (e.g., March 1998 for 
    the August 1, 1997/July 31, 1998 crop year), the CWB announces the 
    Estimated Pool Return (EPR), which is a fixed number, not a range. EPRs 
    are issued again in June and September.
        When determining the PROs and EPRs for feed barley, many factors 
    are examined, including: harvest conditions, foreign subsidies, 
    carryover stocks from the previous year, and the quality and quantity 
    of the U.S. corn crop. (The price of corn and barley are closely 
    related over time because both are used as livestock feed and both have 
    similar nutritional value for livestock. In the United States, corn is 
    the primary feed for cattle.) Both the PROs and EPRs generally reflect 
    prices in export markets rather than the domestic market.
    
    The Producer Direct Sales Program
    
        The Producer Direct Sales (``PDS'') Program allows farmers to 
    export barley on their own account to the U.S. market. Section 46 of 
    the CWB Act and section 14 of the CWB regulations provide the mechanism 
    by which the CWB grants export licenses under the PDS program to 
    individual farmers both inside and outside the designated area (i.e., 
    the area under the control of the CWB).
        Pursuant to section 46(d) of the CWB Act, the terms and conditions 
    for the granting of licenses can include:
    
        * * * recovery from the applicant by the Board * * * of a sum 
    that, in the opinion of the Board, represents the pecuniary benefit 
    enuring to the applicant pursuant to the granting of the license, 
    arising solely by reason of the prohibition of exports of [the 
    covered products] without a license and the then existing 
    differences between prices of [the covered products] inside and 
    outside Canada.
    
    We discussed this section of the CWB Act extensively at verification. 
    One literal interpretation of section 46(d) is that it requires that 
    any difference between the price the CWB offers a farmer and the price 
    the farmer can obtain by exporting his barley independently must be 
    paid to the CWB in return for the granting of the export license. 
    Obviously, such an interpretation would discourage the exportation of 
    barley by any entity other than the CWB. In practice, the CWB has
    
    [[Page 57051]]
    
    interpreted this provision to mean that the farmer wishing to export 
    independently must pay the difference between the total pool return and 
    a price set under the PDS program. Although the precise manner by which 
    the CWB determines this price is proprietary, in essence, the PDS price 
    is based upon the export opportunities of the CWB.
        In order to export barley under the PDS program, farmers within the 
    designated area must (at least, on paper) deliver their grain to the 
    CWB--for which they will receive the normal pool payments--and then 
    repurchase that barley at the posted daily PDS price. In the 1997-1998 
    crop year, a very small percentage of Canadian feed barley exports went 
    through the PDS program.
    
    Analysis of CWB Operations
    
        The Canadian grain marketing system--of which the CWB is an 
    integral part--is highly regulated and institutionalized. Certain CWB 
    policies and programs indicate that the operations of the CWB, with 
    respect to feed barley, may have goals other than promoting the 
    interests of barley farmers. Moreover, while there may not be an overt 
    restraint on exports by the CWB, there are certain aspects of the CWB 
    pooling system and Canadian grain marketing system overall that could 
    have the same result as an overt restraint on exports.
        As noted above, the CWB's mandate is to sell grain ``for such 
    prices as it considers reasonable with the object of promoting the sale 
    of grain produced in Canada in world markets.'' According to its annual 
    reports (see, for example, page 2 of the CWB's 1997-1998 Annual Report 
    in Exhibit CWB-34), the CWB's mission is to maximize returns to western 
    Canadian grain farmers. However, the CWB has also stated that it must 
    balance this objective with the need of processors to source grain at a 
    price that allows them to compete in the finished product market (see, 
    for example, page 17 of the CWB's 1995-1996 Annual Report in the 
    petitioner's November 6, 1998 submission at exhibit A-1 and 
    verification exhibit CWB-14). Arguably, this pricing policy with 
    respect to downstream processors, along with the CWB value-added 
    program discussed below, demonstrates that the operations of the CWB 
    may be guided by government policy objectives inconsistent with the 
    actions expected of a normal market actor.
        Similarly, we verified that the CWB has a value-added program 
    intended to increase the domestic value-added of the cereal grains it 
    markets. Although the current objective of the value-added program 
    relates primarily to the milling and malting industries, the value-
    added program is very broad and includes anything involved in 
    processing cereal grains. Some value-added programs have centered on 
    the livestock industry.
        During the 1997-1998 crop year, the CWB held its second annual 
    ``Moving Up Market'' conference. At this conference, the livestock 
    feeding industry was one area of focus. Brochures from the conference 
    and copies of the presentations given by two CWB officials and a 
    private sector representative from the hog industry were collected on 
    verification. Included in the presentation by the Chief Commissioner of 
    the CWB were the following statements:
    
        The government in this province [Alberta] is encouraging the 
    processing of raw products into fully processed consumer goods to 
    capture the value which is added by processing rather than simply 
    exporting bulk agricultural goods.
        The CWB shares the same desire to see Canadian processors using 
    as much of Prairie farmers' cereal grains as possible * * *.
        The western Canadian livestock feeding industry secures 
    virtually all of its feed grain requirements from Prairie farmers. 
    In an open and competitive environment, this huge and growing market 
    for feed grains may eventually make the export of feed barley from 
    western Canada a thing of the past.
    
    (See verification exhibit CWB-14.)
        These statements indicate, at a minimum, that the CWB supports a 
    policy of increased domestic value-added for barley grown on the 
    prairies.
        With respect to the CWB pooling mechanism, one CWB-commissioned 
    study notes that if prices in the export markets suddenly rise, the 
    PRO/EPRs, which are estimates of the average price to be received by 
    the CWB throughout the year, will not rise commensurately. (See The CWB 
    and Barley Marketing by Schmitz, et al., in verification exhibit CWB-
    7.) As a result, farmers, who might otherwise attempt to take advantage 
    of the higher prices, might not offer their barley to the CWB to be 
    sold in the export market. Under these circumstances, the impact on the 
    market would be the same as an overt export restriction: more feed 
    barley will be supplied to the domestic market and domestic feed barley 
    prices will be potentially lower.
        In general, some economists maintain that the heavily regulated 
    nature of the Canadian marketing system for grain has slowed 
    productivity in grain handling, increased marketing costs and reduced 
    farm returns. They argue that the CWB does not pursue improvements in 
    the marketing and handling system the same way that private entities 
    would in response to market forces. (See, for example, Carter and 
    Loyns, The Economics of Single Desk Selling of Western Canadian Grain, 
    attached as Exhibit 5k, to the R-Calf petition.) A 1995 study by KPMG 
    Management Consulting estimated that up to twenty percent of 
    operational costs could be saved annually through reduced regulation, 
    the introduction of transparent incentives, and improved accountability 
    (See Rapid Grain Flow-Transfoming Grain Logistics prepared for the 
    Western Grain Elevator Association, April 1995). If unnecessary or 
    additional costs are imposed on the farmer when he seeks to export, the 
    impact on the market would be the same as an overt export restriction: 
    more feed barley will be supplied to the domestic market and domestic 
    feed barley prices will be potentially lower.
        Some economists also argue that the ``selection rate'' for malting 
    barley is lower in Canada relative to other countries. (The ``selection 
    rate'' is the percentage of malting barley that is actually sold as 
    malting barley; malting barley not selected for malting is sold as feed 
    barely.) As a result, more barley grown as malting barley is sold as 
    feed barley in both the domestic and export markets. (See, for example, 
    D. Demcey Johnson, Single Desk Selling of Canadian Barley, in the 
    petitioner's July 29,1999 submission at Exhibit 6.) Arguably, this 
    scenario might also depress feed prices in the domestic market. The CWB 
    argues that the determination of what qualifies as malting barley is 
    made by private entities and other public entities of the Canadian 
    government. However, while the record indicates that the CWB is not 
    directly involved in the selection of malting barley, the CWB does seek 
    to ensure that barley it sells as feed barley is not re-sold in another 
    market as malting barley.
    
    Pricing Analysis
    
        To determine if the operations of the CWB have provided a benefit 
    to the producers of live cattle in Canada during the POI, we made 
    numerous price comparisons between Canadian domestic prices, several 
    U.S. domestic prices (some of which are representative of the largest 
    feed barley consumer markets in the world), and the CWB export price to 
    the United States. Specifically, the benchmark prices we used were the 
    prices in Portland, an average price in the U.S. based on several 
    different price series, and CWB export prices to the United States. We 
    did not make any adjustments to the reported prices other than freight, 
    where appropriate.
    
    [[Page 57052]]
    
        First, we compared the domestic and export marketing options that 
    would be available to a barley farmer in Saskatoon, Saskatchewan in an 
    open market. We used a farmer in Saskatoon as representative of 
    Canadian barley farmers because Saskatoon is located in the center of 
    the Canadian barley growing area and because the best data we have for 
    freight adjustments pertain to Saskatoon. We compared domestic and 
    export opportunities, as represented by Lethbridge and Portland, 
    respectively. We used Portland prices because these prices are 
    representative of export prices to large, traditional global consumers 
    of feed barley (e.g., Saudi Arabia and Japan) (see September 22, 1999, 
    Memorandum to File, ``Portland and Pacific Northwest (PNW) prices'').
        We adjusted both the domestic and export prices back to Saskatoon 
    by freight (rail freight for export, truck freight for domestic). See 
    October 12, 1999, Memorandum to Susan Kuhbach, ``Pricing Analysis for 
    the Canadian Wheat Board (CWB) for the Final Determination'' (``CWB 
    Analysis Memorandum'') and Final Calculations. We observed that, during 
    the POI the export prices in Portland were similar to those in 
    Lethbridge. Although Lethbridge prices have been lower historically, 
    especially in the 1995-1996 crop year, there is no consistent pattern 
    of the Portland prices significantly exceeding the Canadian price. 
    Beginning in November 1997, the Canadian domestic price has been 
    higher.
        Second, we compared the CWB export price to the U.S. with the 
    domestic price in Lethbridge. We observed the same price relationships 
    described above during the POI and the prior two years.
        Third, we compared the weighted average price in the designated 
    area with the average price of barley in the United States during the 
    POI without making any adjustments for freight. To calculate the 
    designated area price, we took various Canadian ``Off-Board'' prices in 
    the designated area (Lethbridge, Calgary, Saskatoon, Melfort and 
    Winnipeg) and weighted them by cattle production in the different 
    areas. We used cattle production as a proxy for barley consumption 
    because the majority of barley consumed in Canada is consumed by 
    cattle. For U.S. prices, we calculated a simple average of prices for 
    feed barley at various locations (Duluth, Bottineau, Cando, Churchs 
    Ferry, Rugby, Stanley, Great Falls, Golden Triangle, Northcentral, and 
    Portland). We used all U.S. pricing points on the record except 
    Minneapolis, East Coast (Norfolk Terminal) and PNW. We did not include 
    the Minneapolis price series as those prices are for malting barley. 
    East Coast prices were omitted because no data is reported for most 
    months during the POI. We did not have sufficient information to weight 
    average the U.S. prices by consumption. We observed that, during the 
    POI, the average price in the U.S. was usually lower than the average 
    price in the designated area.
        Finally, we compared an average price in the two primary growing 
    areas in Canada with geographically comparable growing areas in the 
    United States which are approximately the same distance from export 
    ports. Specifically, we compared an average price in Alberta with an 
    average price in Montana, and an average price in Saskatchewan with an 
    average price in North Dakota. In both of these comparisons, we 
    observed that, during the POI (the only period for which we have all 
    the needed data), the Canadian price was often higher than the U.S. 
    price.
        Thus, based on the above price comparisons, we determine that the 
    operations of the CWB did not provide a benefit to the producers of 
    live cattle during the POI. Therefore, we determine that the operations 
    of the CWB during the POI did not provide an indirect countervailable 
    subsidy.
    
    Provision of Goods or Services
    
    B. Saskatchewan Pasture Program
    
        The Saskatchewan Pasture Program has been in place since 1922. It 
    is designed to provide supplemental grazing to Saskatchewan livestock 
    producers and to maintain grazing and other fragile lands in permanent 
    cover to promote soil stability. Saskatchewan Agriculture and Food 
    operates 56 provincial community pastures encompassing 804,000 acres. 
    At these pastures, the SAF offers grazing, breeding, and health 
    services for fees established by SAF. Fees are based upon recovery of 
    the costs associated with the grazing and breeding services of each 
    pasture.
        The provision of a good or service is a financial contribution as 
    described in section 771(5)(D)(iii) of the Act. As discussed above in 
    connection with the PFRA, a benefit is conferred in the provision of a 
    good or service when the prices charged for government-provided goods 
    or services are less than the prices charged by private suppliers. In 
    the case of the Saskatchewan Pasture Program, a simple comparison of 
    the fees charged would not be appropriate because the pasture services 
    being offered by the SAF differ from those offered by private 
    providers. In this regard, the GOS has provided a quantifiable 
    adjustment. Specifically, we adjusted the private price downward by 
    deducting costs associated with the timing of the sale of cull cows. 
    Although the GOS argued that there were other differences that should 
    be taken into account for such things as commingling, pasture 
    condition, delivery and pickup periods, we have not made adjustments 
    for such costs because either the GOS did not establish that such costs 
    were faced solely by public pasture patrons or because the GOS was 
    unable to quantify them.
        Comparing the public pasturing price to the adjusted private 
    pasturing price, we determine that the price for private pastures is 
    lower than the price for public pastures. Therefore, we determine that 
    the government is adequately remunerated for its provision of pasture 
    services. Thus, no countervailable subsidy exists.
    
    C. Alberta Grazing Reserve Program
    
        Like the federal government's PFRA Community Pasture Program, 
    Alberta developed community pastures (reserves) on which multiple 
    ranchers' herds can graze. Grazing reserves also provided multiple-use 
    opportunities to other users.
        Traditionally, government employees supervised and managed the 
    animals on the reserves, and maintained and built range infrastructure. 
    However, as of April 1, 1999, the GOA ceased to perform management 
    activities on 32 of its 37 grazing reserves as a result of a 
    privatization initiative. Under the privatization initiative, livestock 
    management responsibilities were shifted to grazing associations and 
    new, negotiated fees have been established. However, during the POI, 
    the government operated 20 reserves, accounting for approximately 
    170,000 AUMs. The 17 remaining reserves were privately operated and 
    accounted for approximately 150,000 AUMs.
        Priority in issuing permits for use of the reserves is given to 
    residents who operate a ranch or farm. The Minister of Lands and 
    Forests establishes the amount to be paid for stock grazing on each 
    pasture operated by the GOA. The GOA reported that the grazing revenues 
    obtained from this program exceed the cost of the grazing aspects of 
    the program and cover many of the multiple-use functions of the land.
        The provision of a good or service is a financial contribution as 
    described in section 771(5)(D)(iii) of the Act. As discussed above in 
    connection with the PFRA, a benefit is conferred in the provision of a 
    good or service when the
    
    [[Page 57053]]
    
    prices charged for government-provided goods or services are less than 
    the prices charged by private suppliers. In the case of the Alberta 
    Grazing Reserve Program, we determine that the government is charging 
    more than the private providers of the same services. Specifically, the 
    fees charged by the private grazing associations to its members were 
    lower than those charged by the government. Based on the above, we 
    determine that the government is receiving adequate remuneration for 
    its provision of grazing services. Thus, no countervailable subsidy 
    exists.
        We also examined whether the amount charged by the GOA to the 
    private grazing associations for the reserves they operate provided 
    adequate remuneration tot he GOA. We found that the fee charged is 
    comparable to the adjusted private grazing lease price discussed under 
    the ``Alberta Crown Lands Basic Grazing Program'' section above. 
    Therefore, we determine that the government is being adequately 
    remunerated for its provision of grazing land to grazing associations. 
    Thus, no countervailable subsidy exists.
    
    Green Box Programs
    
        Under section 771(5B)(F) of the Act, domestic support measures 
    provided with respect to the agricultural products listed in Annex 1 to 
    the 1994 WTO Agreement on Agriculture (``Agriculture Agreement'') shall 
    be treated as noncountervailable if the Department determines that the 
    measures conform fully with the provisions of Annex 2 of the 
    Agriculture Agreement. Our New CVD Regulations further state that we 
    will determine that a particular domestic support measure conforms 
    fully to the green box criteria in the Agriculture Agreement if we find 
    that the measure (1) is provided through a publicly-funded program 
    (including government revenue forgone) not involving transfers from 
    consumers; (2) does not have the effect of providing price support to 
    producers; and (3) meets the relevant policy-specific criteria and 
    conditions laid out in Annex 2 of the Agriculture Agreement. As was 
    noted above in the Applicable Statute and Regulations section, although 
    Subpart E of 19 CFR Part 351 of our New CVD Regulations does not apply 
    to this investigation, Subpart E represents the Department's 
    interpretation of the requirements of the Act and is, thus, referenced 
    here.
        The GOC requested ``green box'' treatment for three programs in 
    this investigation: The Canada-Alberta Beef Industry Development Fund 
    (``CABIDF''), the Feed Freight Assistance Adjustment Fund (``FFAF''), 
    and the Saskatchewan Beef Development Fund (``SBDF''). Because the FFAF 
    was not used during the POI, we do not reach the issue of green box 
    treatment for FFAF. See the Programs Preliminarily Determined To Be Not 
    Used section, below. The claims made relating to CABIDF and SBDF are 
    discussed in detail below. A more detailed discussion of the 
    Department's analysis of this issue can be found in the Department's 
    Memorandum to Richard Moreland: ``Green Box Claims Made by the 
    Government of Canada,'' dated May 3, 1999, which is on file in the 
    Central Records Unit.
    
    D. Canada-Alberta Beef Industry Development Fund
    
        CABIDF, which was established by the GOC and the GOA in April 1997, 
    supports research, development, and related activities connected to the 
    beef industry in Alberta. It is administered by the Alberta Department 
    of Agriculture, Food, and Rural Development and run by the Alberta 
    Cattle Commission and the Alberta Agricultural Research Institute. To 
    receive funding through this program, applicants must submit a series 
    of research proposals that are evaluated on the basis of the project's 
    relationship to the Funds's research priorities (which are discussed in 
    the Preliminary Determination), its scientific merits, and the 
    usefulness of the project results to the beef industry, directly or 
    indirectly. Final proposals are evaluated for technical merit by a 
    scientific committee consisting of industry experts and scientists, and 
    are then approved or rejected based on these evaluations by CABIDF's 
    governing committee.
        In order to determine whether CABIDF qualifies for green box 
    treatment under section 771(5B)(F) of the Act, we examined whether 
    CABIDF met the criteria specified in the Act and further detailed in 
    the Agriculture Agreement. With regard to the first criterion noted 
    above, in the original and supplemental questionnaire responses, the 
    GOC and the GOA stated that all monies used to fund this program came 
    directly from the government, whether on a provincial or on a federal 
    level. We verified that no funds for this program were received from 
    any entity other than federal and provincial governments during the 
    POI. The funds went directly to CABIDF applicants. No transfers from 
    consumers were involved.
        As for the second criterion, none of the projects that have been 
    approved by CABIDF have the effect of providing price support to 
    producers.
        With regard to the last criterion, the policy-specific criteria 
    that must be met in this case are those listed under paragraph 2, Annex 
    2 of the Agriculture Agreement. Paragraph 2 focuses on policies that 
    provide services or benefits to the agriculture or rural community. It 
    includes sub-paragraph (a), which covers projects for research, 
    including general research, research in connection with environmental 
    programs, and research programs relating to particular products (sub-
    paragraph (a)).
        According to its authorizing statute, the purpose of CABIDF is to 
    ``provide financial contributions in the form of grants to enhance 
    research and industry development activities with the objective of 
    promoting and enhancing the competitiveness of the beef industry in 
    Alberta.'' Officials confirmed that each project approved through 
    CABIDF is approved solely because of its potential scientific research 
    value to the Alberta beef industry, and that projects approved are all 
    research-related projects. We verified that all of the projects that 
    have been funded by CABIDF since the program's inception in April 1997 
    have been related to scientific research activities for the beef 
    industry and the agriculture industry in general. All of the approved 
    projects consisted of grants, not revenue forgone, and we verified that 
    none were paid directly to producers or processors.
        Based on our analysis, we find that CABIDF is eligible for green 
    box treatment under section 771(5B)(F) of the Act, and, thus, is not 
    countervailable.
    
    E. Saskatchewan Beef Development Fund
    
        SBDF, which is administered by the Agriculture Research Branch of 
    the Saskatchewan Ministry of Agriculture and Food, supports the 
    development and diversification of Saskatchewan's beef industry through 
    the funding of various projects related to production research, 
    technology transfer, and development and promotion of new products. The 
    ministry-appointed, producer-run governing board, the Saskatchewan Beef 
    Development Board, meets once a year to review and approve project 
    proposals that it deems to be of general benefit to the cattle and beef 
    industries. Priority is given to public research institutions 
    conducting research, development, and promotion activities that will be 
    generally available to the industry.
        In order to determine whether SBDF qualifies for green box 
    treatment under section 771(5B)(F) of the Act, we examined whether the 
    SBDF met the criteria specified in the Act and further
    
    [[Page 57054]]
    
    laid out in the Agriculture Agreement, which were described in detail 
    above. With regard to the first criterion, in the original and 
    supplemental questionnaire responses, the GOS reported that all monies 
    used to fund this program came directly from the provincial government. 
    We verified that no funds for this program were received from any non-
    public entity during the POI. The funds went directly to SBDF 
    applicants. No transfers from consumers were involved.
        As for the second criterion, none of the projects that have been 
    approved by SBDF have the effect of providing price support to 
    producers.
        Finally, with regard to the last criterion, the policy-specific 
    criteria that must be met in this case are also those which are listed 
    under paragraph 2, Annex 2 of the Agriculture Agreement. In particular, 
    the relevant criteria are contained in sub-paragraphs (a), (c), (d), 
    and (f) of paragraph 2, which focus on programs relating to research, 
    training services, extension and advisory services, and marketing and 
    promotion services.
        The regulations governing SBDF state that the purpose of the 
    program is to provide for the enhancement of the Saskatchewan beef and 
    beef cattle industry through research, development, and promotional 
    activities that the board considers to be in the best interests of the 
    industry. We verified that each of the thirteen projects that received 
    funding distributions through the SBDF during the POI was either a 
    research or an extension and advisory program. All of the approved 
    projects consisted of grants, not revenue forgone, and we confirmed 
    that none were paid directly to producers or processors.
        Based on our analysis, we find that SBDF is eligible for green box 
    treatment under section 771(5B)(F) of the Act and, thus, is not 
    countervailable.
    
    Other Programs
    
    F. Net Income Stabilization Account
    
        The Net Income Stabilization Account (``NISA'') is designed to 
    stabilize an individual farm's overall financial performance through a 
    voluntary savings plan. Participants enroll all eligible commodities 
    grown on the farm. Farmers may then deposit a portion of the proceeds 
    from their sales of eligible NISA commodities (up to three percent of 
    net eligible sales) into individual savings accounts, receive matching 
    government deposits, and make additional, non-matchable deposits, up to 
    20 percent of net sales. The matching deposits come from both the 
    federal and provincial governments.
        NISA provides stabilization assistance on a ``whole farm'' basis. 
    This means that a farmer's eligibility to receive assistance depends on 
    total farm profits, not the profits earned on individual commodities. A 
    producer can withdraw funds from a NISA account under a stabilization 
    or minimum income trigger. The stabilization trigger permits withdrawal 
    when the gross profit margin from the entire farming operation falls 
    below an historical average, based on the previous five years. If poor 
    market performance of some products is offset by increased revenues 
    from others, no withdrawal is triggered. The minimum income trigger 
    permits the producer to withdraw the amount by which income from the 
    farm falls short of a specific minimum income level.
        In Live Swine From Canada; Final Results of Changed Circumstances 
    Countervailing Duty Administrative Review, and Partial Revocation, 61 
    FR 45402 (August 29, 1996), we found that NISA is not de jure specific. 
    Moreover, for hog producers, we found that NISA was not de facto 
    specific. Therefore, the issue in this investigation is whether NISA is 
    de facto specific with respect to cattle producers.
        To make our determination, we have examined whether cattle 
    producers are dominant users of the program, or whether cattle 
    producers receive disproportionately large benefits under the program. 
    We found no evidence that cattle producers are dominant users or 
    receive disproportionate benefits from the NISA program. Specifically, 
    the GOC provided information on farmer withdrawals of NISA funds during 
    the POI and the two preceding years. Because NISA does not collect or 
    maintain information concerning withdrawals on a commodity-by-commodity 
    basis, the GOC reported farmer withdrawals by categorizing farms by the 
    source of the majority of their revenues. That is, a farm with over 
    fifty percent of its revenues from a particular commodity's sale, such 
    as cattle, was classified as a farm of that commodity. On this basis 
    the GOC reported that, during the POI, cattle farms accounted for 7.7 
    percent by value of total withdrawals from NISA.
        We have also analyzed whether NISA is regionally specific because 
    certain commodities, including cattle, in certain provinces are not 
    eligible commodities under the program. In that regard, we determine 
    that NISA is not limited to a particular region. While certain 
    commodities are not eligible for matching funds within certain 
    provinces, the producers of these commodities elect not to participate 
    at their own choice, not because the program is limited to an 
    enterprise or industry located in a particular region.
        Based on the above analysis, we determine that NISA assistance is 
    not limited to a specific enterprise or industry, or group of 
    enterprises or industries. Therefore, we determine that assistance 
    received by cattle producers under the NISA program is not 
    countervailable.
    
    G. Alberta Public Grazing Lands Improvement Program
    
        Established in 1970 and terminated in 1995, this program provided a 
    partial credit toward the payment of rent on a public grazing land 
    disposition if the lessee undertook certain pre-approved capital range 
    improvement projects. The leaseholder was required to pay for all the 
    costs incurred for these capital improvements, and was reimbursed for 
    25 to 50 percent of these costs through credits on the rental fees 
    otherwise due annually. All improvements belong to the government and, 
    once the improvements are created, the lessee is required to maintain 
    them at his or her own expense.
        In order for a financial contribution to exist under this program, 
    the GOA must forego rental fees, or a portion thereof, that are 
    otherwise due as described in section 771(5)(D)(ii) of the Act. 
    However, in this case the reduction in the rental fees corresponds to 
    range improvements on behalf of the government. Furthermore, the 
    increased value of the land as a result of the improvements is captured 
    upon the next setting of rental fees. Based on the above analysis, we 
    determine that this program does not provide a financial contribution 
    and, therefore, we determine that the program is not countervailable.
    
    H. Saskatchewan Crown Land Improvement Policy
    
        The Crown Land Improvement Policy is designed to provide rental 
    adjustments when Crown land lease holders make capital improvements to 
    the land, such as clearing, bush removal, or breaking and reseeding. In 
    return for the lessee's funding of these improvements, Saskatchewan 
    Agriculture and Food (``SAF'') agrees not to increase the rental rate 
    for a certain period of time, depending on the length of the 
    improvement project or may reduce the basis for rent. SAF is willing to 
    reduce the rental rate or freeze the rate because during the 
    improvement project the actual stocking rate of the land is lower than 
    the potential, the improvements do not result in an immediate increase 
    in the
    
    [[Page 57055]]
    
    productive value of the land, and any improvements belong to the Crown.
        In order for a financial contribution to exist under this program 
    the GOS must forego rental fees, or a portion thereof, that are 
    otherwise due as described in section 771(5)(D)(ii) of the Act. 
    However, in this case the reduction in the rental fees corresponds to a 
    reduction in the land's carrying capacity while improvements are 
    undertaken. The increased value of the land as a result of the 
    improvements is captured upon the next setting of rental fees. Based on 
    the above analysis, we determine that this program does not provide a 
    financial contribution and, therefore, we determine that the program is 
    not countervailable.
    
    I. Saskatchewan Breeder Associations Loan Guarantee Program
    
        The Saskatchewan Breeder Associations Loan Guarantee Program was 
    established in 1991 to facilitate the establishment of cattle breeder 
    associations, in an effort to promote cattle breeding in Saskatchewan. 
    The program is administered by the Livestock and Veterinary Operations 
    Branch of the Saskatchewan Agriculture and Food Department. This agency 
    provides a guarantee on 25 percent of the principal amount of loans to 
    breeder associations for the purchase of certain breeding cattle. 
    Eligibility is limited to breeder associations which consist of at 
    least twenty individuals who are residents of Saskatchewan and over the 
    age of eighteen. One hundred and seven associations received guarantees 
    on loans which were outstanding during the POI.
        Breeding livestock is not covered by the order of this 
    investigation. Therefore, we determine that this program does not 
    provide a countervailable subsidy to the subject merchandise because 
    any potential subsidy would benefit merchandise other than that covered 
    by this investigation.
    
    III. Programs Determined To Be Not Used
    
        Based upon the information provided in the responses, we determine 
    that the producers of the subject merchandise under investigation did 
    not apply for or receive benefits under the following programs during 
    the POI.
    
    A. Feed Freight Assistance Adjustment Fund
    
        Of the four responding provinces in this investigation, only one, 
    Ontario, participated in the Feed Freight Assistance Adjustment Fund 
    program. Specifically, in the year prior to the POI, the first year of 
    the FFAF, a grant was provided to Ontario producers. However, because 
    the benefit was below 0.5 percent of the investigated provinces' total 
    sales, we expensed this grant in the year received. Thus, cattle 
    producers received no benefit during the POI from grants received prior 
    to the POI. We verified that, during the POI, Ontario did not receive 
    benefits under FFAF. Therefore, we determine that the FFAF program was 
    not used during the POI.
    
    B. Canadian Adaptation and Rural Development (CARDS) Program in 
    Saskatchewan
    
    C. Western Diversification Program
    
    IV. Programs Determined To Be Terminated
    
    A. Ontario Export Sales Aid Program
    
    V. Other Programs Reviewed
    
        The GOC demonstrated that, for the following programs, any benefit 
    to the subject merchandise would be so small that there would be no 
    impact on the overall subsidy rate, regardless of a determination of 
    countervailability. In light of this, we do not consider it necessary 
    to determine whether benefits conferred under these programs to the 
    subject merchandise are countervailable.
    
    A. Ontario Bear Damage to Livestock Compensation Program
    
    B. Ontario Livestock Programs for Purebred Dairy Cattle, Beef, and 
    Sheep Sales Assistance Policy/Swine Assistance Policy
    
    C. Ontario Artificial Insemination of Livestock Act
    
    Interested Party Comments
    
    Canadian Wheat Board
    
    Comment 1: Indirect Subsidies
    
        The petitioner argues that, according to Georgetown Steel Corp. v. 
    United States, 801 F.2nd 1308, 1315 (Fed. Cir. 1986), a subsidy is 
    defined as any action that distorts or subverts the market process and 
    results in a misallocation of resources. In determining the existence 
    of a countervailable subsidy, according to Section 771(5)(C) of the 
    Act, it is irrelevant whether the subsidy was provided directly or 
    indirectly.
        The petitioner further contends that the SAA and Department 
    precedent make clear that the Department intends to countervail 
    indirect subsidies, such as export restraints. As such, the GOC need 
    not compel Canadian barley growers to supply the cattle industry. 
    According to the petitioner, it is sufficient that feed barley is 
    produced and sold only to cattle and other livestock producers. 
    Specific end-use market control over exports, and the resulting 
    depression of domestic prices, is sufficient to direct lower-priced 
    feed barley to Canadian cattle producers. The provision of goods, 
    albeit by a private party, may be countervailed when the price of those 
    goods is the result of a government program distorting the market.
        The GOC argues that the URAA added a definition of 
    ``countervailable subsidy'' to U.S. law which requires that a 
    ``financial contribution'' and a resulting benefit be conferred before 
    a ``subsidy'' can be said to exist. Further, a financial contribution 
    may be only one of four specifically enumerated forms of government 
    action, including the ``provision of goods,'' which is the allegation 
    in this case. This requirement may result from private action in 
    situations in which the government ``entrusts or directs a private 
    entity to make a financial contribution'' such as the provision of 
    goods. The GOC argues that neither the GOC nor the CWB entrusted or 
    directed Canadian barley producers to do anything. To the contrary, 
    barley producers have complete discretion over decisions concerning 
    whether to offer barley to the CWB, to sell it to domestic cattle or 
    other livestock producers, to use it as feed on one's own farm, or, for 
    that matter, to do nothing with it at all. Indeed, according to the 
    GOC, barley producers remain free to produce another product, or to 
    change their line of business altogether. According to the GOC, since 
    the CWB is neither providing goods to cattle producers nor entrusting 
    or directing any private entity to do so, no financial contribution 
    exists in this instance and, thus, no subsidy.
        Department's Position: It is our position that indirect subsidies, 
    such as export restraints, are potentially countervailable. In the 
    preamble of the New CVD Regulations, we stated that while export 
    restraints ``may be imposed to limit parties'' ability to export, they 
    can also, in certain circumstances, lead those parties to provide the 
    restrained good to domestic purchasers for less than adequate 
    remuneration'' (at 65351). Thus, the provision of a good, whether 
    provided directly or indirectly, for less than adequate remuneration 
    constitutes a financial contribution under section 771(5)(D) of the 
    Act. In this case, although we have found no benefit during the POI, 
    record evidence indicates that the CWB is not immune to the interests 
    of cattle producers in its policy determinations.
    
    [[Page 57056]]
    
    Comment 2: CWB Control, Inefficiency, and Market Distortions
    
        The petitioner states that the CWB is legally and operationally in 
    a position to control the barley market, restrain exports, oversupply 
    the domestic market, and thereby reduce the costs incurred by Canadian 
    cattlemen. The petitioner argues that, whether or not the CWB's control 
    amounts to a direct and utter restriction on exports, the Canadian 
    marketing and handling system, of which the CWB is a key institution, 
    prevents exports which otherwise would have occurred because it creates 
    a disincentive for Canadian barley farmers to offer feed barley for 
    export.
        Specifically, the petitioner suggests that the CWB system creates 
    inefficiencies and increased marketing costs, which causes less barley 
    to be exported than would be in the absence of the CWB. The petitioner 
    provides economic studies which show that the CWB's control limits the 
    ability of the Canadian market to arbitrage with export markets. The 
    petitioner further argues that theory and empirical evidence show that 
    the CWB's control of exports lowers domestic feed barley prices.
        The petitioner argues that the ``direct and discernible effect'' on 
    prices caused by the CWB's control is that export price signals to 
    barley farmers (the PROs and EPRs) are distorted. Thus, because barley 
    producers perceive export demand to be at price levels far below actual 
    export prices, less barley is offered to the CWB and more is available 
    on the domestic market at lower prices. The effect of the CWB barley 
    export control is made evident in the long-term, substantial disparity 
    between domestic and export prices. The petitioner further argues that 
    this price differential was not affected by the cessation of rail 
    freight subsidies and that the effects of U.S. Export Enhancement 
    Program (EEP) and E.U. subsidies are independent from the question 
    whether the CWB's restraints on exports have distorted barley prices in 
    Canada.
        The GOC states that the CWB system itself does not create a 
    disincentive to offer barley as the petitioner alleges. Regarding the 
    argument that the CWB system is inefficient, the GOC points to other 
    studies on the record that refute this conclusion. The GOC also points 
    to the fact that the allegedly inflated distribution costs that lead to 
    inefficiencies relate to activities outside of the CWB's jurisdiction. 
    Nonetheless, the GOC claims, any effect of an alleged inefficiency 
    cannot be equated with an export restriction and cannot give rise to a 
    subsidy.
        The GOC further states that record evidence shows that PROs and 
    EPRs do, in fact, provide adequate pricing signals to barley farmers. 
    There is nothing on the record to suggest that the pricing signals 
    during the POI did not reflect the market realities in export markets. 
    Furthermore, any alleged price differentials are caused by the removal 
    of freight subsidies and U.S. EEP and E.U. subsidies, distortions which 
    are outside of the CWB's control, according to the GOC.
        Department's Position: As discussed above, we agree that certain 
    aspects of the CWB system can be market-distorting and can have the 
    same result as an overt export restraint. For example, Canadian barley 
    farmers are not able to respond to sudden increases in export prices 
    because of the rigidity of the CWB's pricing system for barley. 
    Regarding the alleged inefficiency of the system arising from increased 
    marketing costs, the evidence on the record is not necessarily 
    conclusive. Nonetheless, as described in the CWB section above, we did 
    not find significant price differentials between prices inside the 
    designated area and U.S. prices, some of which reflect prices to the 
    major consumers of feed barley in world markets. Thus, we determine 
    that Canadian cattlemen did not receive a benefit during the POI.
    
    Comment 3: Canadian Barley Producers as a Private Entity
    
        The GOC states that Canadian barley producers cannot qualify as a 
    ``private entity'' under any normal meaning of the term. Thus, the 
    Department cannot conclude that they were ``entrusted or directed'' to 
    provide an indirect subsidy.
        The petitioner states that both Lumber and Leather, as well as 
    Department practice, have shown that the term ``private entity'' is and 
    has been interpreted to encompass inducement of more than one private 
    entity.
        Department's Position: Although we have found that the CWB system 
    did not provide a benefit to Canadian cattlemen during the POI, we 
    believe that barley farmers may be considered a private entity. We 
    further note that both the SAA (at 926) and the preamble to the New CVD 
    Regulations (at 65350) make clear that the Department considers the 
    phrase ``private entity'' to include groups of entities or persons.
    
    Comment 4: Cross-Border Comparisons
    
        The petitioner states that the Department erred in its preliminary 
    analysis of prices by relying on a comparison of Canadian domestic 
    prices to only U.S. interior prices in Great Falls. According to the 
    petitioner, a rational exporter would not ship to Great Falls, which is 
    a surplus barley area, but would seek out the highest export prices 
    (i.e., the U.S. PNW/Portland, Saudi Arabia or Japan). Moreover, in 
    prior cases such as Lumber, the Department has relied on prices from 
    the most important export markets for comparison purposes. Without this 
    type of cross-border comparison, the petitioner argues, it would be 
    impossible to measure benefits conferred on the domestic industry.
        The GOC argues that cross-border comparisons should not be used at 
    all in this analysis. Any analysis should be made by looking at 
    prevailing market conditions for the good or service being provided in 
    the country subject to the investigation, Canada. The proper inquiry is 
    the price cattlemen would otherwise pay in Canada, not alternate 
    markets.
        Department's Position: We agree with the petitioner that a 
    comparison of only Great Falls and Canadian domestic prices does not 
    necessarily answer the question of whether domestic feed barley prices 
    in Canada are lower than prices outside of Canada. A thorough analysis 
    should also account for other U.S. and world market prices. As 
    described in the CWB section above, we made several price comparisons, 
    some of which are similar to those suggested by the petitioner, and 
    found no price differential.
        We disagree with the GOC that cross-border comparisons are 
    inappropriate to test whether Canadian domestic feed barley prices are 
    artificially low. When confronted with an adequate remuneration issue, 
    the Department will normally seek to measure the adequacy of 
    remuneration by comparing the government price to market-determined 
    prices within the country. However, in certain circumstances, market 
    prices may not exist in the country or it may be difficult to find a 
    ``market'' price that is independent of market distortions caused by 
    government action. With respect to export restriction programs in 
    particular, international prices are not necessarily the benchmarks we 
    use to determine if a benefit exists; in such cases, international 
    prices are merely the starting point of our analysis. See Lumber. 
        The only domestic barley prices on the record that may be 
    independent of the CWB's influence are prices for barley grown in 
    Ontario. However, we verified that the Ontario barley market is very 
    different from that in the
    
    [[Page 57057]]
    
    designated area because the barley market in Ontario is very thin and 
    is subject to significant price fluctuations. Additionally, to the 
    extent that cattle are raised in Ontario, they are primarily fed corn 
    rather than barley. Thus, we do not believe Ontario provides a reliable 
    comparison price.
        Because there is not an appropriate market price within Canada, we 
    used other prices against which to compare barley prices in the 
    designated area. Given that these price comparisons did not yield 
    significant, consistent price differentials through the POI, further 
    analysis of whether Canadian domestic feed barley prices are lower than 
    they would be absent the CWB is unnecessary.
    
    Comment 5: The CWB's Producer Direct Sales (``PDS'') Program
    
        The petitioner argues that the PDS program eliminates any economic 
    or rational incentive to export unless the exporter can obtain an 
    export price that is substantially higher than the Canadian domestic 
    price and the PDS price. Thus, it acts as a substantial restraint on 
    exports.
        The GOC argues that the PDS program is a safety valve for producers 
    to allow them to pursue higher returns that they find through export 
    spot opportunities. Furthermore, the CWB actively assists producers in 
    pursuing this option.
        Department's Position: Based on our analysis, the PDS program does 
    not encourage farmers to export independently. In theory, the PDS 
    program allows barley farmers to export for their own account. However, 
    as a practical matter, in order to benefit from the PDS program, 
    farmers essentially have to find extraordinary sales opportunities 
    because the PDS price is set relatively high and consistently higher 
    than the CWB pool return. Thus, it is unlikely that a barley farmer 
    would be able to find sales opportunities sufficiently attractive to 
    make the PDS program a worthwhile endeavor. Nevertheless, as noted 
    above, we have concluded that, even assuming a restraint on exports, 
    the operations of the CWB did not provide a benefit to Canadian 
    cattlemen during the POI.
    
    Comment 6: Freight Adjustments
    
        The GOC states that any comparisons of barley prices must account 
    for freight. Although the petitioner did attempt to make a freight 
    adjustment in a few of its price comparisons, the adjustments were 
    ``absurdly low'' and, after proper adjustments for freight are made, 
    the price differentials alleged by the petitioner disappear.
        The petitioner provides several price comparisons which show a 
    significant, long-term price differential between prices in the 
    designated area and prices in export markets. In a few of these 
    comparisons, the petitioner made an adjustment for freight based upon 
    freight costs from Calgary to Vancouver. According to the petitioner, 
    even after one accounts for freight, there is still a significant price 
    differential.
        Department's Position: Freight is a key element in the price of 
    Canadian feed barley; all feed barley prices throughout the designated 
    area track the price in Lethbridge. To reflect this market reality, for 
    example, feed barley futures contracts traded on the Winnipeg Commodity 
    Exchange are designed with ``regional discounts'' which account for the 
    location of barley and the cost of shipping that barley to Lethbridge 
    (as well as local supply and demand factors). See CWB Verification 
    Report at 16. Therefore, any comparison of prices at different 
    geographic locations must account for freight costs.
        Although the petitioner adjusted an average price in the designated 
    area for freight, the adjustments did not adequately reflect the real 
    cost of transporting grain grown throughout the designated area to 
    Vancouver. Specifically, the petitioner used the freight rate from 
    Calgary to Vancouver to adjust an average price based on prices 
    throughout the designated area. The train route from Calgary to 
    Vancouver is shorter than all other points in the designated area and, 
    therefore, freight costs from this point are likely to be lower than 
    everywhere else. Record evidence shows that freight costs to Vancouver 
    from other points in the designated area can be substantially more than 
    the cost of freight from Calgary.
        Therefore, in making our point-to-point price comparisons, we made 
    freight adjustments which corresponded with the specific location of 
    the barley price used in the comparison (i.e., Saskatoon or 
    Lethbridge). After adjusting for freight in our point-to-point 
    comparisons, we found no consistent pattern of price differentials when 
    comparing the prices of feed barley sold in the designated area and the 
    prices of feed barley outside of Canada.
    
    Comment 7: Export Price Benchmarks
    
        The petitioner argues that the Department should use several 
    pricing series to represent export prices: (1) Canadian export 
    statistics, (2) U.S. Portland and PNW prices, (3) PDS prices, and (4) 
    U.S. import statistics. With respect to Canadian export statistics, the 
    petitioner first notes that Canadian ``exports'' to the U.S. are in 
    fact U.S. import statistics prepared by the U.S. Census Bureau and 
    argues that the Department should not disregard the U.S. import data as 
    it did in the Preliminary Determination in calculating Canadian export 
    prices to the U.S. Furthermore, the petitioner argues that this data 
    provides a better basis for computing overall available export 
    opportunities than the actual transaction data reported by the CWB by 
    virtue of the additional charges incurred by the CWB on the transaction 
    data and because any reporting errors in the U.S. import data due to 
    freight would be minor.
        The petitioner further suggests that U.S. prices in Portland or the 
    PNW should be used over prices in Great Falls (as was done in the 
    Preliminary Determination) because, as stated in comment 4 above, a 
    rational exporter would not ship to Great Falls, but to the market that 
    provides the highest price. Moreover, according to the petitioner, 
    record evidence indicates that Portland prices may be indicative of the 
    best export opportunity available.
        Finally, the petitioner suggests that PDS prices could be used as 
    an export price because the PDS prices represent the best determination 
    of the CWB as to its own export opportunity price. In addition, the 
    petitioner states that because PDS prices are posted daily at all 
    elevators, they are not affected by freight charges and, thus, do not 
    need to be adjusted for freight costs.
        The GOC argues that each of the petitioner's export price 
    suggestions suffers from numerous factual and legal shortcomings. 
    First, the Canadian export statistics and U.S. import statistics are 
    unreliable because they reflect shipments, not sales, and thus cannot 
    be compared with Canadian domestic sales prices. Moreover, as 
    established at verification, some values reported in the U.S. import 
    statistics do, in fact, include freight. Second, there is no evidence 
    on the record to suggest that Portland or PNW prices are the prices 
    that Canadian cattlemen would pay in the absence of the CWB. Moreover, 
    when proper freight adjustments are made to this price series, the 
    differential disappears. Third, PDS prices do not reflect conditions in 
    Canada or the price that Canadian cattlemen would pay, and there is no 
    evidence that significant quantities of barley could be sold at PDS 
    prices. In addition, the petitioner is incorrect in stating that PDS 
    prices would not need to be adjusted for freight because they are 
    posted at all elevators. PDS prices are based in Vancouver and St. 
    Lawrence and, thus,
    
    [[Page 57058]]
    
    would have to be adjusted for freight when comparing them to prices 
    within the designated area. Fourth, with respect to U.S. import 
    statistics, it is not reasonable to assert that these statistics are 
    more reliable than actual CWB transaction data, especially in light of 
    the known deficiencies with the U.S. data.
        Department's Position: As described in the CWB section above, we 
    made several price comparisons. In doing so, we used prices from a 
    variety of sources (including the petitioner's second suggestion to use 
    Portland prices), making appropriate adjustments for freight when 
    necessary. For further discussion of the prices selected for our 
    comparisons, see CWB Analysis Memorandum.
        With respect to PDS prices, although they are posted at every 
    elevator throughout the designated area, PDS prices are based in 
    Vancouver or St. Lawrence and the amount a farmer would have to pay to 
    ``repurchase'' his barley from the pool would be net of freight from 
    that location to either Vancouver or St. Lawrence. Thus, to compare 
    accurately PDS prices with prices in the designated area, PDS prices 
    need to be adjusted for freight. We note that if one were to employ the 
    petitioner's suggestion and compare PDS prices to designated area 
    prices, after adjusting for freight, there is not a consistent price 
    differential. See Final Calculations.
        With respect to the petitioner's first and fourth pricing 
    suggestions, the evidence on the record makes clear that there are 
    problems with both the Canadian export statistics and U.S. import 
    statistics. For example, the import/export statistics reflect 
    shipments, not sales, and thus, cannot reliably be compared with 
    domestic sales prices. In addition, the Canadian export statistics to 
    Japan include values for both feed and malting barley. We further note 
    that although the export/import statistics are reported f.o.b. at the 
    port, the particular port is unknown so there is no means to adjust 
    those figures precisely for freight to make an appropriate comparison 
    with domestic prices.
        Furthermore, we determine that the actual CWB export sale 
    transactions to the U.S. that we verified are more reliable than prices 
    derived from secondary sources such as U.S. import statistics. We 
    conducted a thorough verification of the CWB's export sales and 
    confirmed that all prices were reported accurately and that all freight 
    adjustments were reasonable. In addition, record evidence demonstrates 
    that, in certain instances, freight is improperly included in the 
    values reported in the U.S. statistics. For these reasons, we did not 
    rely on derived prices from the volume and value figures reported in 
    the export/import statistics.
    
    Comment 8: Use of Actual Versus Bid or Offer Prices
    
        The petitioner suggests that, in determining the proper domestic 
    pricing series to use for comparison purposes, the Department should 
    rely on pricing series based on ``bid'' or ``offer'' prices as well as 
    pricing series that measure actual transactions. (``Bid'' prices are 
    the prices at which elevators are willing to purchase barley from the 
    producer; ``offer'' prices are the prices at which the elevator is 
    willing to sell (or offer) barley to consumers. The difference between 
    bid and offer prices is the elevator margin.) Moreover, the Department 
    should not exclude particular pricing series on the grounds that they 
    include elevation charges. According to the petitioner, if there is a 
    high level of competition among elevators, some may absorb elevation 
    charges and others may not. Since there is no means to adjust for these 
    differentials, there would be no reason to exclude certain price series 
    that are based on commercial elevator offer prices.
        The GOC, while it does not object to the use of pricing series 
    based on bids or offers, believes that the other pricing series, 
    especially those based on cash or transaction prices, are equally or 
    more reliable and should not be discarded in favor of bid or offer 
    prices.
        Department's Position: We have used both price series based on 
    actual transactions and those based on bid or offer prices in our 
    calculations to determine a domestic price for comparison purposes. 
    Further, we agree with the petitioner that there is no means on the 
    record to adjust precisely for elevation charges. See CWB Analysis 
    Memorandum.
    
    Comment 9: Reliance on Lethbridge as a Domestic Pricing Point
    
        The petitioner states that the Department should not rely too 
    heavily on Lethbridge prices in calculating Canadian domestic prices 
    for the final determination. The petitioner argues that, since 
    Lethbridge is a net import market for barley, Lethbridge prices would 
    be indicative of the high-water mark, not of overall price levels in 
    the designated area.
        The GOC argues that, since barley transactions are carried out by 
    private barley producers and not by the GOC, there is no real 
    ``government barley price'' in Canada to which any comparison can be 
    done. However, if prevailing prices in the designated area are 
    construed as a government price, Lethbridge prices are the most obvious 
    to use as a domestic point since Lethbridge is the point in Western 
    Canada from which all other feed barley is priced.
        Department's Position: Although we agree with the petitioner that 
    we should not rely exclusively on Lethbridge prices as the measure of 
    the domestic prices for barley in Canada, we agree with the GOC that 
    Lethbridge is an important pricing point in the designated area. 
    Therefore, we have used, but not relied exclusively upon, Lethbridge 
    prices in our various comparisons.
        As discussed in the CWB section above, in the first comparison, we 
    adjusted the Lethbridge price downward to account for truck freight 
    from Saskatoon. In the second comparison, we relied entirely on 
    Lethbridge because certain CWB export sales were reported only on a 
    Lethbridge basis, which made Lethbridge the only useable Canadian 
    comparison price. In the third and fourth comparisons, we combined the 
    Lethbridge price with other Canadian prices to calculate average 
    prices. Thus, in the last two comparisons, we accounted for barley 
    prices throughout the designated area.
    
    Comment 10: Prices of Western Canadian Barley Sold in Ontario
    
        The petitioner states that an analysis of domestic prices within 
    the designated area should not include the Ontario locations of Thunder 
    Bay and Georgian Bay because these points are not within the designated 
    area.
        The GOC argues that, although the Ontario pricing points to which 
    the petitioner refers are physically located outside of the designated 
    area, prices in these locations represent prices of Western Canadian 
    barley and can be properly included in the analysis.
        Department's Position: For the final determination, we have 
    modified the average price for the designated area to exclude Ontario 
    prices. Although the GOC is correct in stating that Ontario prices for 
    Thunder Bay and Georgian Bay are for barley produced in the designated 
    area and shipped to Ontario, these prices would include freight to 
    Ontario. Thus, the inclusion of these prices in the average designated 
    area price that we calculated for use in one of our price comparisons 
    would not be appropriate.
    
    [[Page 57059]]
    
    Comment 11: Use of Facts Available To Determine Export Prices to Japan
    
        The petitioner argues that the Department should use adverse facts 
    available when determining the export price to Japan because the CWB 
    failed to provide pricing information that it maintains as the sole 
    exporter of Canadian barley.
        The GOC states that, to its knowledge, it has submitted information 
    that has been satisfactory to the Department. Moreover, the GOC asserts 
    that the information it has submitted has allowed the Department to 
    sufficiently address the major issues at hand.
        Department's Position: Although we would have preferred to obtain 
    CWB third country pricing data, we have determined that, for the 
    purposes of this investigation, there is sufficient pricing information 
    on the record to make appropriate price comparisons based upon 
    published pricing surveys at specific locations. Thus, the use of 
    adverse facts available based upon deficient secondary sources is not 
    warranted.
    
    Comment 12: Countervailability of Provincial Loan Guarantee Programs
    
        The GOA, GOS, GOM and GOO contend that their respective loan 
    guarantee programs do not provide a countervailable benefit as defined 
    in Section 771(5)(E)(iii) of the statute because the programs do not 
    lower the cost of borrowing. Respondents state that the Department 
    confirmed at verification that it is the highly structured nature and 
    security requirements of the associations participating in the loan 
    guarantee programs, and not the guarantees, that determine the interest 
    rates charged to participants. Specifically, respondents argue that the 
    guarantee is commercially insignificant when compared to other aspects 
    of the program such as the substantial security provided to lenders by 
    the associations, the local monitoring undertaken by each associations' 
    staff and the branding requirements with respect to the cattle 
    purchased by association members.
        The petitioner argues that, contrary to respondents' assertion, the 
    verification record does not establish that the loan guarantee programs 
    are not countervailable. Absent the loan guarantee programs, individual 
    cattle producers would be seeking to obtain loans rather than large 
    cattle associations. These small cattle operations would face 
    dramatically higher interest rates and stringent loan terms. This is 
    evidenced by the Saskatchewan Agricultural Value-Added Loan Fund, where 
    borrowers pay prime plus 4 percent. The petitioner urges the Department 
    to use this as the benchmark for the provincial loan guarantee 
    programs.
        In the event that the Department uses information obtained from 
    banks at verification to derive the benchmark rate, the petitioner 
    contends that the Department should, at a minimum, apply a benchmark 
    rate of prime plus 2.25 percent for purposes of the final 
    determination. Petitioner asserts that this interest rate, derived from 
    comments made by Saskatchewan commercial lenders at verification, more 
    accurately reflects the cost of borrowing for association members than 
    the benchmark rate used at the Preliminary Determination.
        Department's Position: At verification, private bank officials 
    explained that several attributes of the associations were considered 
    in setting the interest rate on association loans. Specifically, bank 
    officials mentioned that the administrative and managerial features of 
    the associations provide lenders with substantial security against 
    default. We agree that these attributes would make these loans 
    attractive to lending institutions, even absent the guarantees. 
    Nevertheless, the provincial governments do provide the guarantees on 
    these loans. As discussed in the ``Programs Determined To Be 
    Countervailable'' section, the guarantees are financial contributions 
    and specific to cattle producers. Therefore, we have analyzed whether 
    the guarantees confer a benefit by measuring the difference between the 
    amount the associations pay on the guaranteed loans and the amount they 
    would pay for a comparable commercial loan absent the guarantee.
        Regarding the petitioner's claim, we disagree that we should use 
    interest rates that would be paid by individual farmers as a benchmark 
    for loans taken out by associations. This is because loans to 
    individual cattle producers do not represent ``comparable commercial 
    loans'' to loans taken out by associations. Thus, we have not 
    incorporated the lending rates available under the Saskatchewan 
    Agricultural Value-Added Loan Fund into our analysis. Moreover, we 
    verified that this program does not currently exist and that cattle 
    producers never participated in it. Consequently, loan rates 
    established by that program are not relevant to this investigation.
    
    Comment 13: Alberta Feeder Association Loan Guarantee
    
        First, the GOA contends that the Department failed to take into 
    account the marginal nature of the government guarantee. The GOA 
    explains that the program only guarantees 15 percent of the total 
    amount of the loan and, therefore, it is not credible for such a small 
    guarantee to have the economic impact reflected in the Department's 
    preliminary benchmark rate.
        Second, the GOA argues that the Department should incorporate the 
    discounted lending rates obtained by Alberta feeder associations from 
    bank marketing efforts into its calculation of the provincial benchmark 
    rate. The GOA notes that the identical interest rate was offered to a 
    variety of borrowers throughout Canada during the POI and, therefore, 
    the Department should not treat these lending arrangements as a 
    subsidy.
        Finally, the GOA contends that because the benchmark rates obtained 
    at verification are fixed rates, the Department should adjust the 
    floating rate feeder association loans to the equivalent fixed rate. 
    The GOA states that the Department confirmed at verification that 
    lenders offer borrowers a choice of fixed or variable rate loans, and 
    that banks set the two rates so they present equivalent financial risk 
    to the loans. Consequently, the GOA argues, the Department can adjust 
    the variable interest rates on loans that are guaranteed to what they 
    would be if they had been taken out as fixed rate loans and compare 
    them to the fixed rate benchmark.
        Department's Position: As discussed in the Subsidies Valuation 
    Information section, we have revised the benchmark interest rate used 
    at the Preliminary Determination with respect to the provincial loan 
    guarantee programs and have calculated province-specific benchmark 
    rates based on verified information. The Alberta benchmark rate was 
    calculated by averaging the verified range of lending rates the 
    associations could obtain in the market absent the government 
    guarantee. Accordingly, the benchmark rate we derived from the 
    information collected at verification captures the marginal nature of 
    the guarantee. In addition, our revised benchmark included the 
    discounted lending rates the feeder associations received from bank 
    marketing efforts because the association membership was eligible for 
    these rates regardless of the government guarantee.
        With respect to the GOA's assertion that we should adjust variable 
    rate association loans to the equivalent fixed rate, it is not clear 
    from the verification record that the benchmark information we 
    collected was expressed in terms of fixed rates only. Therefore, we 
    have not
    
    [[Page 57060]]
    
    made an upward adjustment to the floating rate loans for our final 
    results.
    
    Comment 14: The Base Prime Rates Should Be Adjusted To Reflect Bank 
    Prime Rates
    
        The petitioner argues that the Department should upwardly adjust 
    the prime rate used in the Preliminary Determination to reflect the 
    commercial prime rate available to borrowers during the POI. Petitioner 
    states that the Department verified that the base-lending rate used to 
    calculate the interest charged on association loans is the bank prime 
    rate, which is typically the Bank of Canada prime rate plus a spread of 
    .25 percent to .5 percent. Therefore, for purposes of the final 
    determination the Department should add the average of this range, or 
    .375 percent, to the prime rate used in the Preliminary Determination. 
        The GOC, GOA and GOS each comment that the petitioner is mistaken 
    and that the rate the Department used in its Preliminary Determination 
    was the commercial prime rate of interest charged by private Canadian 
    banks. Respondents note that this information was discussed and 
    confirmed at verification.
        Department's Position: As noted by the respondents, we verified 
    that the prime rate used as the base-lending rate in our calculations 
    at the Preliminary Determination was ``bank prime,'' or the prime rate 
    charged by private commercial banks in Canada. Accordingly, we have not 
    adjusted the prime rate for purposes of our final results.
    
    Comment 15: Exclusion of Saskatchewan Breeder Association Loan 
    Guarantee Program
    
        The GOS argues that because the Department specifically excluded 
    breeding livestock from the scope of this investigation, the Department 
    should exclude the Saskatchewan Breeder Association Loan Guarantee 
    program from further consideration. The respondent notes that the 
    Department verified that this program is available only in connection 
    with the purchase of breeding stock. Furthermore, the respondent notes 
    that in previous determinations related to livestock the Department has 
    declined to countervail programs related to breeding livestock because 
    breeding stock was not covered by the order. See Live Swine from 
    Canada; Preliminary Results of Countervailing Duty Administrative 
    Reviews, 55 FR 20812, 20817 (May 21, 1990) (``Live Swine from Canada 
    1990'').
        The petitioner contends that the respondent's argument fails to 
    recognize that participants in the Saskatchewan Breeder Association 
    Loan Guarantee program can sell the calves born to breeding livestock 
    purchased with loans made available under this program. Because calves 
    need not be sold for breeding purposes and may be placed directly into 
    the production cycle, the benefits from this program accrue to all 
    cattle producers. In addition, the petitioner argues that the 
    respondent's reference to Live Swine from Canada 1990 should be 
    disregarded by the Department because the program in question was 
    limited to veterinary care provided directly to breeding stock.
        Department's Position: We agree with the GOS and have not 
    countervailed this program because breeding livestock is not covered by 
    the scope of this investigation. As noted by the GOS, we verified that 
    loans from this program are limited to the purchase of breeding stock. 
    As in Live Swine from Canada 1990, any benefits would thus be tied to 
    breeding stock only. While we agree with the petitioner that the 
    program in question is different from that examined in Live Swine from 
    Canada 1990, the fact remains that in both cases the alleged benefits 
    from each program go directly to non-subject merchandise and, thus, are 
    not covered by the scope of the respective investigations.
    
    Comment 16: Specificity of FIMCLA
    
        The GOC argues that the FIMCLA program is not specific because the 
    value of the benefits received by the hog and cattle industries are in 
    proportion to these producers share of the Canadian agricultural 
    economy. The GOC notes that in the Preliminary Determination, the 
    Department compared the number of FIMCLA loan guarantees obtained by 
    the cattle and hog industries to the total number of FIMCLA loan 
    guarantees approved during the POI, without reference to any benchmark 
    of proportionality. The GOC contends that this analysis is flawed for 
    two reasons.
        First, the GOC argues that it is Department practice to compare the 
    benefits received by a particular enterprise with some objective 
    benchmark in order to determine proportionality. See Certain Steel 
    Products from Korea, 58 FR 37338, 37343 (July 9, 1993) (``Korean 
    Steel''). Second, the GOC contends that the Department recently 
    emphasized that it looks to the value, not the number, of guaranteed 
    loans for purposes of assessing disproportionality of loan guarantees. 
    See Stainless Steel Plate from South Africa, 64 FR 15553, 15564 (March 
    31, 1999).
        The GOC states that use of the farm cash receipts statistics 
    submitted to the Department would permit the Department to address 
    these flaws. The GOC explains that this data demonstrates that, during 
    the POI, the share of FIMCLA benefits received by the cattle and hog 
    industries was significantly less than the share of farm cash receipts 
    generated by those industries. Accordingly, the Department should find 
    that FIMCLA is not specific and, therefore, not countervailable.
        The petitioner counters that the GOC's argument is flawed for 
    various reasons and that the Department should continue to find the 
    FIMCLA program de facto specific in accordance with section 
    771(5A)(D)(iii) of the Act. With respect to the GOC's argument for an 
    objective benchmark, the petitioner contends that only in unusual 
    circumstances will the Department resort to examining de facto 
    specificity by determining whether the benefits received by a 
    particular enterprise or industry or group were disproportionate in 
    relation to the economy as a whole. In support of its argument, the 
    petitioner cites 19 CFR 351.525 of the New CVD Regulations, which 
    discusses that the type of subsidy under investigation in Korean Steel, 
    governmental use of the economy-wide banking system to direct credit to 
    steel producers, required a broader analysis. (See Countervailing 
    Duties; Final Rule, 63 FR 65348, 65359 (November 25, 1998). The 
    petitioner argues that unlike Korean Steel, the FIMCLA program targets 
    only one sector of the Canadian economy rather than the entire economy. 
    Therefore, use of an external reference point is not warranted in this 
    situation. Rather, the Department should continue with its standard 
    methodology of examining the level of benefits received by one industry 
    in comparison to other industries participating in the program.
        The petitioner further argues that, in case an outside reference 
    point is applied, the use of farm cash receipts is not reasonable. The 
    petitioner notes that to the extent the farm cash receipts simply 
    reflect the effects of subsidization, it would not be surprising that 
    the amount of subsidies would parallel the dispersion of income. 
    Moreover, long-term loans should not be measured on this basis because 
    the GOC has reported this information for only one year, which was a 
    calender year and not the POI.
        Finally, the petitioner contends that the starting point of the 
    Department's analysis of specificity is the number of users. (See 
    Countervailing Duties; Final Rule, 63 FR 65348, 65359 (November 25, 
    1998)). Using this methodology, the beef and hog industries have 
    historically
    
    [[Page 57061]]
    
    received between 25 and 30 percent of the FIMCLA loan guarantees and, 
    as such, the Department's Preliminary Determination regarding FIMCLA 
    should be upheld.
        Department's Position: We disagree with the GOC in part. 
    Disproportionality is fact-specific and determined on a case-by-case 
    basis. As noted by the petitioner, the nature of the subsidy being 
    investigated in Korean Steel was unusual and required a special 
    analytical framework. Our typical specificity analysis examines 
    disproportionality by reference to actual users of the program. In 
    other words, we compare the share of the subsidy received by producers 
    of the subject merchandise to the shares received by other industries 
    using the program. See Final Negative Countervailing Duty Determination 
    and Final Negative Critical Circumstances Determination: Certain 
    Laminated Hardwood Trailer Flooring (LHF) from Canada, 62 FR 5201, 5209 
    (February 4, 1997). Consistent with our usual practice, we have 
    compared the level of benefits received by the beef and hog sectors 
    under the FIMCLA program to the assistance received by the other 
    agricultural industries participating in the program.
        We agree, however, with the GOC that our disproportionality 
    analysis should focus on the level of benefits provided rather than on 
    the number of subsidies given to different industries. Therefore, we 
    have revised our analysis to compare the value of the loan guarantees 
    provided to industries participating in the FIMCLA program. Based on 
    this comparison, we continue to find that the beef and hog industries 
    received a disproportionate amount of assistance under the FIMCLA 
    program during the POI. Accordingly, we confirm our preliminary finding 
    that the FIMCLA program is de facto specific to the beef and hog 
    sectors in accordance with section 771(5A)(D)(iii) of the Act.
    
    Provision of Goods or Services
    
    Comment 17: PFRA
    
        The GOC argues that the Act does not permit the Department to 
    countervail the public pastures provided under the PFRA if the price 
    charged by the government for their use is consistent with the 
    prevailing market. PFRA rates are comparable to the private pasture 
    rates reported for Manitoba and Saskatchewan, according to the GOC, 
    when the factors that diminish the value of public pastures are taken 
    into account. The GOC argues that PFRA pastures have the following 
    disadvantages: cows are commingled, cattle owners' access to their 
    cattle is restricted, the PFRA forage is of poorer quality, certain 
    specialty services are not provided, and public pastures are subject to 
    multiple use. Because of such factors, according to the GOC, many of 
    the surveyed ranchers indicated that they prefer private land over PFRA 
    pastures and that many PFRA patrons move to private land when it 
    becomes available.
        The GOC requests that adjustments be made to private pasture rates 
    to account for the differences between the two types of pasture 
    services. The GOC notes that it has provided information on adjustments 
    for three differences relating to: (1) The timing of the sale of cull 
    cows, (2) early weaning and timing of the sale of calves, and (3) 
    transportation to the pasture. The GOC urges the Department to make 
    these adjustments and contends that when the adjustments are made, the 
    Department will conclude that PFRA pasture services are not provided 
    for less than adequate remuneration.
        Lastly, while the GOC was only able to quantify the factors 
    mentioned above, the GOC states that the Department should also 
    consider other factors (disease associated with commingled pastures and 
    the failure to provide specialized services offered by private 
    pastures) that diminish the value of PFRA pastures.
        The petitioner urges the Department to examine closely the 
    differences in the public and private pastures alleged by the GOC. 
    Specifically, according to the petitioner, the GOC has not established 
    that cattle producers using private pastures have greater flexibility 
    than public pasture users with respect to the timing of cattle removal. 
    According to the petitioner, the timing of cattle removal on public 
    pastures is not as rigid as portrayed by the GOC because roundup dates 
    on public pastures are not necessarily set at the same time for all 
    lessees and can be negotiated with the Pasture Manager. To support its 
    argument, the petitioner cites to the PFRA Rules and Regulations, which 
    state that when round up dates are not set the resulting date will be 
    ``a matter of mutual agreement between the patrons and the Pasture 
    Manager and will depend upon pasture operation at the time.'' Thus, 
    according to the petitioner, the GOC has not established that cattle 
    producers cannot remove cattle from public pastures on request.
        Moreover, the petitioner claims that the GOC has failed to support 
    the amount of the adjustment for culled cows. Specifically, the GOC has 
    not established that producers cull one cow in ten on private pastures 
    or that owners place older cows on public pastures.
        Lastly, the petitioner states that the GOC has not supported its 
    claim that private pastures provide grazing within 25 miles from the 
    patron's farm or that transportation costs between private and public 
    pastures are materially different.
        The petitioner also challenges the GOC's reliance on a survey 
    conducted for the purposes of this investigation to substantiate the 
    need for these adjustments. According to the petitioner, the Department 
    should not make adjustments that reflect the personal preferences of a 
    limited survey of cattlemen. The petitioner argues that the personal 
    preferences of the surveyed ranchers are not sufficient to establish 
    that the PFRA pastures do not have an advantage over private pastures.
        Department's Position: In accordance with section 771(5)(E) of the 
    Act, when comparing the prices charged for public pasture services to 
    those charged by private providers we have attempted to ensure that the 
    prices compared are for nearly identical services. That is, when 
    feasible, we have taken into account prevailing market conditions which 
    include price, quality, availability, marketability, transportation, 
    and other conditions of purchase or sale. In this regard, when it 
    appears that a difference exists between a public good or service and a 
    benchmark good or service, we will consider making an adjustment when 
    the difference is quantifiable and is clearly demonstrated by evidence 
    on the record. See Lumber at 22595.
        In this case, we agree that the GOC has identified and supported 
    certain adjustments that should be made. Specifically, we adjusted for 
    the difference in costs associated with the timing of the sale of cull 
    cows on private and public pastures. Since ranchers using private 
    pastures have access to their herds and, hence, can cull cows in mid-
    summer, they receive a different service and a price adjustment is 
    warranted. While the GOC argued that this adjustment should be larger, 
    the information on the record did not fully substantiate the 
    calculations suggested by the GOC. For example, while the GOC suggested 
    that old cows would be culled in mid-summer, while cow prices are at 
    their peak, we agree with the petitioner that there is no evidence that 
    a patron would actually pay to have an old cow pastured for a season if 
    the cow was already planned to be culled. Finally, while the petitioner 
    has argued that PFRA patrons may be able to manage their herds and 
    benefit from the early sale of culled cows and calves in the same 
    manner as private pasture patrons, we found at
    
    [[Page 57062]]
    
    verification that the PFRA roundup and drop off procedures are quite 
    rigid and do not generally allow for the management that the petitioner 
    suggests.
        With respect to the transportation adjustment urged by the GOC, the 
    record does contain evidence that nearly ten percent of community 
    pasture patrons incur high transportation costs because they live 
    further than 50 miles from their respective pastures. However, the GOC 
    did not provide evidence that this was unique to users of public 
    pastures. Regarding the requested adjustment for differences in weaning 
    and the timing of the sale of calves, the GOC did not provide evidence 
    indicating that the majority of private pasture patrons choose to wean 
    their calves early or that they actually sell calves at different times 
    than community pasture patrons. Finally, as in the Preliminary 
    Determination and as noted above, we have not made adjustments for 
    costs that the GOC was unable to quantify.
        With respect to the petitioner's challenge of the GOC's survey, 
    while the number of people surveyed was limited, we determine that the 
    survey conducted by the GOC provides an objective and representative 
    measure of the costs faced by patrons of private pastures in Canada.
    
    Comment 18: Appropriate Benchmark for Provincial Public Lease and 
    Pasturing Rates
    
        With respect to all three provinces which offer Crown lands for 
    grazing and pasturing, the petitioner argues that the Department should 
    rely on an average of the private rates for full-service pasturing in 
    Manitoba and Saskatchewan and the private lease rate for land reported 
    by the GOA as a representative benchmark. According to the petitioner, 
    the statute specifically requires the Department to determine the 
    adequacy of remuneration based on prevailing conditions ``in the 
    country.''
        The GOA contends that, not only is there no justification for using 
    the hybrid number the petitioner has developed on areas outside of 
    Alberta, but that the petitioner's data do not meet the criteria 
    outlined in the Department's regulations at 19 CFR 351.511(a) for a 
    proper benchmark because they simply do not represent the value of 
    comparable land. The GOA further states that the Department is obliged 
    by the Act and its regulations to use a benchmark that represents the 
    prevailing market value of the good or service being evaluated. 
    According to the GOA, the goods are public grazing leases in the 
    various provinces and the only ``prevailing market value'' for a good 
    with such inherently local value is a local, provincial benchmark.
        Department's Position: As stated in the Final Affirmative 
    Countervailing Duty Determination: Certain Stainless Steel Wire Rod 
    From Italy, 63 FR 40474, 40481 (July 29, 1998), ``the adequacy of 
    remuneration is normally determined in relation to local prevailing 
    market conditions as defined by section 771(5)(E) of the Act to 
    include, ``* * * price, quality, availability, marketability, 
    transportation, and other conditions of purchase or sale.'' 
    Consequently, the lease rates for private land in each province, when 
    accurate and available, are an appropriate starting point for 
    comparison to the respective lease rates for public land in each 
    province.
    
    Comment 19: Use of Facts Available With Respect to Alberta Crown Lands 
    Basic Grazing Program
    
        The petitioner argues that the Department should reject the GOA's 
    entire response with respect to the leasing of Crown lands and instead 
    apply adverse facts available because the GOA failed to report 
    benefits, in the form of excess compensation from oil and gas 
    companies, from the leasing of such lands.
        The GOC and the GOA argue that the petitioner's comments on this 
    issue and the petitioner's August 25, 1999, submission which first 
    raised Bill 31 should be stricken from the record because the 
    petitioner's submission was untimely. Specifically, the GOA cites to 
    the Department's regulations at 19 CFR 351.301(b)(1) pointing out that 
    the deadline for submission of factual information related to the GOA 
    was June 9, 1999, which was seven days prior to the Alberta 
    verification.
        Department's Position: We disagree with the respondents that the 
    petitioner's information regarding Bill 31 and the compensation system 
    for lessees of public and private land should be stricken from the 
    record. Although it was initially submitted after the deadline, we 
    subsequently requested the information under section 351.301(c)(2)(i) 
    of our regulations. Moreover, we believe this bill was highly relevant 
    to the information sought in the our questionnaire. Bill 31 amends, 
    among other acts, Alberta's Public Lands Act and the Surface Rights 
    Act, the legislation underlying one of the programs being investigated 
    in this proceeding (the Alberta Crown Lands Basic Grazing Program). 
    Although the change in the Act may have occurred after the period of 
    investigation and may not yet be in effect, our questionnaire 
    specifically requested that the GOA describe any anticipated changes in 
    the program and asked for documentation substantiating the GOA's 
    answer.
        We believe that disclosure of Bill 31 would have given the 
    Department a fuller understanding of the lease system in effect during 
    the POI. In particular, information regarding the passage of Bill 31 
    includes statements implying that cattlemen who graze their livestock 
    on public lands in Alberta receive excessive compensation from oil and 
    gas operators who lease the subsurface rights. As the petitioner 
    originally alleged, and we sought to investigate, the question of 
    whether the GOA was adequately remunerated for its provision of Crown 
    lands has been a central issue throughout this case. Therefore, as 
    stated above, we believe this information was highly relevant to our 
    enquiry.
        In light of this, the petitioner has argued that the Department 
    should reject all of the GOA's response with respect to the Alberta 
    Crown Lands Basic Grazing Program. However, we do not believe the 
    criteria for making such a determination have been met. In particular, 
    section 782(e) of the Act states that we shall not decline to consider 
    information that is necessary to the determination if the information 
    is timely, verifiable, not so incomplete that it cannot serve as a 
    reliable basis for a determination, can be used without undue 
    difficulties, and the interested party has demonstrated that it acted 
    to the best of its ability. All of the information presented by the 
    GOA, other than information regarding the Surface Rights Act and Bill 
    31, complies with these criteria and, thus, it would be inappropriate 
    for us to disregard the information in making our determination.
        However, with respect to the impact the Surface Rights Act and Bill 
    31 have on our adequacy of remuneration determination, we are using the 
    facts otherwise available. The use of facts available is supported 
    under section 776(a) of the Act because the necessary information is 
    not available on the record. Although interested parties were given the 
    opportunity and did submit information on this issue, the approaching 
    deadline for determination did not provide us the opportunity to make 
    the additional inquiries necessary for us to make a determination that 
    does not rely on the facts available. In choosing the appropriate facts 
    available, the petitioner has argued that we should use an inference 
    that is adverse to the interests of the GOA. However, we do not agree 
    that the GOA failed to cooperate by not acting to the best of its
    
    [[Page 57063]]
    
    ability. While the GOA did not provide information that we believe was 
    relevant to our determination, its conclusion that the information was 
    not relevant, particularly in light of the fact that Bill 31 is not yet 
    in effect, does not imply that the GOA did not act to the best of its 
    ability and, thus, failed to cooperate. We also note that when the 
    Department specifically asked parties to submit information regarding 
    Bill 31, the GOA did so. Therefore, an adverse inference in this 
    instance would not be appropriate when determining the appropriate 
    facts available.
    
    Comment 20: Oil and Gas Compensation and the Adequacy of Remuneration
    
        The petitioner argues that if the Department continues to accept 
    the response of the GOA, the Department should include the benefit from 
    oil and gas compensation when determining the countervailability of the 
    program. According to the petitioner, the application of Alberta's 
    Surface Rights Act and Public Lands Act results in lessees of public 
    land profiting from excess compensation paid by oil and gas companies 
    for access to leased land. In support of its argument, the petitioner 
    cites to the legislative history of Bill 31 and articles published at 
    the time of its passage. The petitioner argues that the approximately 
    C$40 million of compensation received annually, as cited in the 
    articles, exceeds any actual compensation for damages to lessee 
    property or disruption suffered from oil and gas operations. 
    Furthermore, the petitioner argues that the GOA has not submitted any 
    evidence that private lessees receive the same amount of compensation 
    as public lessees. In fact, the petitioner asserts that oil and gas 
    companies compensate public lessees as they would compensate private 
    landowners, not lessees.
        The GOA contends that the petitioner's characterization of the 
    application of Alberta's Surface Rights Act and Public Lands Act, 
    especially in relation to Bill 31, is misinformed and based on public 
    misperceptions about surface compensation rights in Alberta. According 
    to the GOA, the Alberta Surface Rights Act gives equal rights to all 
    owners and occupants of both public and private land to obtain 
    compensation from industrial operators for the damages caused when 
    industrial operations interfere with existing land use. The GOA 
    contends that public lessees do not have any advantage over private 
    lessees with respect to obtaining compensation and, thus, no adjustment 
    is necessary when comparing public rates for the leasing of land to 
    private rates for the leasing of land. The GOA also states that Alberta 
    law does not permit cattle ranchers on public grazing leases to charge 
    access fees to anyone. Specifically, the GOA notes that the Surface 
    Rights Act reads, ``an operator who proposes to exercise a right of 
    entry on land, other than land owned by the Crown * * * shall pay * * * 
    an entry fee. * * *'' The GOA also notes that, under the Surface Rights 
    Act, any compensation paid to a tenant is for loss of use and other 
    damages to the leasehold operations and does not include any payment 
    for the value of the land itself or for access to that land. Lastly, 
    the GOA argues that there is no basis for crediting the petitioner's 
    C$40 million figure as fact because none of the many quotations that 
    cite it give a source for the number and Alberta officials have been 
    unable to find any source for it.
        Department's Position: As noted in the program write-up, we found 
    that, under the current application of the Surface Rights Act, lessees 
    of public land benefit from the provision of the land at less than 
    adequate remuneration. Specifically, public lessees appear to receive 
    more compensation from oil and gas companies for use and access to the 
    land than they would if leasing the same land from a private provider. 
    Hence, public land is more valuable to a lessee than private land and 
    this value is not reflected in the rate charged by the government. 
    Therefore, the government is not adequately remunerated for the 
    provision of the land.
    
    Comment 21: Appropriate Benchmark for Alberta's Public Lease Rates
    
        The petitioner argues that the Department should look to other 
    provinces if the private lease rate data provided for a specific 
    province is inadequate. In this regard, the petitioner argues that the 
    GOA has not established that the lease rate it reported for private 
    land is a ``full-service'' rate that requires an adjustment for 
    development costs, such as fences and water. To the contrary, according 
    to the petitioner, there is evidence that the private lease rate is not 
    a ``full-service'' rate. The petitioner notes that the lease rate for 
    private land reported by the GOA is much lower than the rate for 
    private full-service pasturing reported by the GOC for Manitoba and 
    Saskatchewan.
        Moreover, the petitioner contends that the GOA's reported lease 
    rate for private land is based on a limited survey (the Custom Rates 
    Survey) which could only account for .04 percent of Alberta's cattle 
    population.
        The GOA argues that the data from the Whole Farm Data Base, which 
    represents a far larger sample of private leases than the Custom Rates 
    Survey used in the Preliminary Determination, demonstrate that the 
    private rental rate reported in the Custom Rates Survey is higher than 
    the norm in Alberta. Regardless of which survey information the 
    Department feels is the most appropriate, however, the GOA argues that 
    all of the Alberta-specific numbers were generated from longstanding 
    government surveys and, thus, provide a far more reliable benchmark 
    than any non-Alberta data.
        Department's Position: With respect to the two studies reported by 
    the GOA, we note that both the Custom Rates Survey and the Whole Farm 
    Enterprise Analysis were both conducted prior to the initiation of this 
    investigation and, while limited in the number of those surveyed, we 
    determine that they are objective and representative of the costs faced 
    by lessees of private and public land in Alberta. Therefore, we have 
    averaged the lease rates for private land from the Custom Rates Survey 
    and the Whole Farm Enterprise Analysis for purposes of identifying an 
    appropriate benchmark.
        We agree with the petitioner that the lease rate for private land 
    reported by the GOA is lower than the rate for full-service private 
    pasturing in Manitoba and Saskatchewan, as reported by the GOC. 
    However, we do not believe the comparison is on point. The two rates 
    which the petitioner has compared are prices for two very different 
    things. The lease rate for private land is a price for the provision of 
    a specific good: land. The rate for full-service private pasturing is a 
    price for the provision of a type of service: pasturing. Therefore, the 
    comparison suggested by the petitioner does not undermine the 
    reliability of the lease rate for private land reported by the GOA.
    
    Comment 22: Appropriate Adjustments to Benchmark for Alberta's Public 
    Lease Rates
    
        The GOA argues that the Department correctly adjusted the benchmark 
    rate for taxes and developmental costs in the Preliminary 
    Determination, and that both testimony from government experts and the 
    results of the GOA's survey, which was confirmed at verification, 
    indicate that lease holders of private land do not incur these 
    developmental costs. Thus, in order to develop a fair comparison 
    between public and private leases, the GOA argues that these 
    adjustments should continue to be made.
        In addition, the GOA posits that the Department should make 
    additional adjustments. First, the GOA notes that
    
    [[Page 57064]]
    
    lessees of public land are only allowed to forage up to 50 percent of 
    the land due to the multiple-use restraints placed on Crown lands. This 
    requirement means that to get the same amount of forage, the lessees 
    must fence in more land and develop additional dugouts, all of which 
    contribute to added costs. According to the GOA, this was supported at 
    verification, where it was demonstrated that lease holders on private 
    land can utilize a far higher percentage of their leased forage for 
    cattle grazing than can lease holders on public land. To further 
    support its argument, the GOA notes that the Whole Farm Data Base 
    indicated that grazing leases for public land support fewer AUMs per 
    acre than grazing leases for private land. Second, the GOA argues that 
    the Whole Farm Data Base also established significant differences 
    between operating costs incurred by lessees of private and public 
    lands. Again, the GOA argues that an adjustment should be made for this 
    difference as well.
        The petitioner argues that the Department should reject the GOA's 
    proposed adjustments in their entirety. First, the petitioner states 
    that adjustments for multiple-use costs of leasing land are unjustified 
    unless the Department adjusts for multiple-use income such as 
    compensation related to oil and gas exploration and extraction (see 
    Comment 20: Oil and Gas Compensation and the Adequacy of Remuneration, 
    above). Second, the petitioner contends that the GOA has not 
    established that a lessee of public land must fence and water at least 
    50 percent more land to graze the same number of cattle since the GOA 
    has not established that private lessees are not required to preserve 
    forage for other users as well. Finally, the petitioner argues that the 
    Department should not adjust for operating and capital costs because, 
    even if grazing lessees on public land incur more operating and capital 
    costs than private lessees, these costs have not been shown to be 
    directly related to conditions only on public pasture. According to the 
    petitioner, the cost differences could arise because the lessees of 
    public land are less adept managers or less prudent buyers than private 
    lessees.
        Department's Position: In order to make the comparison required by 
    section 771(5)(E) of the Act, we found it necessary to adjust the lease 
    rate for private land downward to account for differences between the 
    leases of public and private land. Specifically, we adjusted for 
    differences in costs associated with the paying of taxes, construction 
    of fences, construction of water dugouts, and a multiple-use cost for 
    limits on forage. While the respondent has argued that the multiple-use 
    cost adjustment should include expenses for additional fencing and 
    water facilities, we note that there is no evidence supporting the 
    contention that an additional dugout is necessary other than an 
    anecdotal statement that ``cattle will not travel more than one-half 
    mile for water.'' However, contrary to the petitioner's claim, there is 
    evidence on the record supporting the contention that additional acres 
    must be used by a public land lessee to obtain the same amount of 
    forage as a private land lessee and, thus, additional fencing would be 
    required. Specifically, public land lessees may only forage 50 percent 
    of their land, which results in fewer AUM being available per acre than 
    a lessee of private land has at his or her disposal.
        With respect to additional adjustments for differences in operating 
    and capital costs, while we did make some of these adjustments in the 
    Preliminary Determination, we have not done so for this final 
    determination. While the GOA was able to quantify them, the GOA did not 
    provide adequate explanation as to why differences exist for such 
    expense. Nor did the GOA adequately demonstrate that the difference is 
    solely attributable to the fact that one group of farmers leases public 
    land while another group leases private land. Therefore, we have not 
    made adjustments for these costs. Finally, as in the Preliminary 
    Determination and as noted above, we have not made adjustments for 
    costs that the GOA was unable to quantify.
        Lastly, with respect to the petitioner's argument that the 
    Department should only make adjustments for multiple-use costs if we 
    take into account multiple-use income, such as excess compensation from 
    oil and gas companies, as noted in Comment 24, we have taken into 
    account the application of the Surface Rights Act and the resulting 
    differences in compensation between private and public lessees when 
    examining the adequacy of remuneration.
    
    Comment 23: Alberta Grazing Reserves
    
        The petitioner argues that the Department should not use the rates 
    charged by privatized reserves as a benchmark for the full-service 
    rates for Alberta's public grazing reserves. In the petitioner's view, 
    such a comparison would be inappropriate because the privatized reserve 
    rates may be subsidized through a ``sublease.'' With respect to this 
    ``sublease,'' the petitioner argues that, as facts available, the 
    Department should compare the average rate charged by the GOA to 
    privatized reserves for government land to the unadjusted average rate 
    noted above in order to ascertain the subsidy provided to the 
    privatized reserves.
        The petitioner also argues that rather than calculating an average 
    rate for full-service public grazing reserves in Alberta, the 
    Department should calculate five average full-service rates for 
    Alberta's public grazing reserves based upon the four regions of 
    Alberta's Traditional Community Pasture program and the Special Areas 
    pastures.
        The GOA argues that evidence on the record demonstrates that 
    Alberta's privatized reserves are charging their clientele lower prices 
    than the government was charging when the reserves were in government 
    hands. According to the GOA, this evidence confirms that the 
    government-run reserves have been charging rates consistent with the 
    commercial market. The GOA argues further that the government's charge 
    to the privatized reserves for use of government land is not 
    subsidized. According to the GOA the rates qualify as being market-
    determined because they were developed through arm's-length 
    negotiations and the rates are also consistent with properly adjusted 
    private grazing lease benchmarks.
        Department's Position: We have examined the possibility of whether 
    the rates for private pasturing may be subsidized through the 
    government's provision of land at less than adequate remuneration to 
    the operators of the privatized reserves. In doing so, we have looked 
    at the rental fees charged by the government to the privatized reserves 
    (less maintenance fees). The resulting average rental charge was higher 
    than the adjusted rate for leases on private land derived from our 
    examination of the Alberta Crown Lands Basic Grazing Program. 
    Therefore, we determine that the government is adequately remunerated 
    for its provision of land to the privatized reserves.
        With respect to the petitioner's argument that we should calculate 
    five separate full-service public pasture rates, we note that such a 
    task is unnecessary as the range of prices charged by the government 
    for the public pastures are all lower than the private pasturing rate 
    reported by the GOA.
    
    Comment 24: Specificity of the Provision of Crown Lands in Manitoba and 
    Saskatchewan
    
        Both the GOS and the GOM argue that the provision of Crown lands in 
    the two provinces is neither de jure nor de facto
    
    [[Page 57065]]
    
    specific. According to the GOM and the GOS, Crown lands are available 
    to all agriculture and objective criteria and conditions are used to 
    determine agricultural producers' eligibility for the various uses of 
    Crown lands. Both governments note that not all land is suitable for 
    agriculture and that determinations on suitability are made by 
    professional agrologists. Based on the above, the two governments 
    contend that the provision of Crown lands is not specific because Crown 
    lands are available to the entire agricultural sector.
        The petitioner argues that the provision of Crown lands in both 
    provinces is specific. With respect to Manitoba, the petitioner notes 
    that the Manitoba Crown Lands Act expressly limits access to farmers 
    through forage and cropping leases. According to the petitioner, 
    because forage leases are provided for the grazing of livestock, 
    including cattle, the law expressly limits forage leases to the 
    livestock industry. Additionally, the petitioner argues that all leases 
    are limited to a group of enterprises or industries in accordance with 
    the Act and the Department's precedent.
        With respect to Saskatchewan, the petitioner notes that 
    Saskatchewan's Provincial Lands Act makes leases available only for 
    purposes of grain farming, cattle grazing, or perennial hay production. 
    As for Saskatchewan's pasture program, the petitioner notes that the 
    Saskatchewan Provincial Community Pasture Regulations define livestock 
    as cattle or sheep only. Thus, according to the petitioner, the laws 
    and regulations governing Saskatchewan's Crown lands expressly limit 
    access to grazing leases and community pastures to the cattle industry 
    specifically, or a group of enterprises or industries, including the 
    cattle industry.
        Department's Position: While the respondents have argued that both 
    the Saskatchewan Crown Lands Program and the Manitoba Crown Lands 
    Program are not specific, we have found otherwise. The programs are 
    limited by law and regulation to certain subsets of agricultural 
    producers. Moreover, both provinces' programs are specific as a matter 
    of fact in accordance with section 771(5A)(D) of the Act.
        The GOS reported that, during the POI, approximately 800,000 acres 
    of Crown lands were leased for cultivation and 5.4 million acres were 
    leased for grazing. The GOM reported that, during the POI, 21,716 acres 
    of Crown lands were leased for cultivation and approximately 1.6 
    million acres were leased for grazing. Based on the above, we find that 
    those industries which utilize grazing leases, livestock industries 
    such as cattle, are predominant users of both programs and, thus, the 
    programs are de facto specific.
    
    Comment 25: Use of Facts Available With Respect to Manitoba Crown Lands 
    Program
    
        The petitioner argues that while the GOM did submit the underlying 
    data from Manitoba Agriculture's 1997 survey at verification, it failed 
    to do so prior to verification despite Department requests. The 
    petitioner further argues that, in light of this, the GOM failed to 
    establish that the Department should make adjustments to the lease 
    rates for private land. Consequently, the petitioner urges the 
    Department to reject the GOM's response with respect to this program 
    and to rely on alternative lease rates for private land as ``facts 
    otherwise available.''
        The GOM argues that it fully cooperated with the Department and 
    never withheld information. The GOM contends that it could not 
    ``provide copies of any reports or summaries related to this study'' 
    because there were no formal reports and, thus, none were available to 
    provide. In support of its position, the GOM cites to the Department's 
    verification report which states, ``because results of the survey were 
    never published or distributed, no reports of the data were prepared or 
    published * * *. However, they have the computer tabulated results from 
    the survey and provided a spreadsheet of those results.'' Therefore, 
    according to the GOM, nothing was withheld from the Department.
        Department's Position: We have found the GOM to be fully 
    cooperative throughout this proceeding. The underlying data, which 
    supports the lease rates for private land reported by the GOM, was 
    reviewed and taken as an exhibit at verification. The data was not in 
    the form of a report or a summary related to the study, which is what 
    we asked for in our supplemental questionnaire. Rather, as noted in the 
    verification report, no reports of the data were prepared or published 
    and, thus, the GOM did not ignore a request for information when it 
    responded to our supplemental questionnaire.
    
    Comment 26: Appropriate Benchmark for Manitoba's Public Lease Rates
    
        The GOM argues that the Department did not use the correct 
    benchmark in its Preliminary Determination because it blended core and 
    fringe private lease rates. Instead, the GOM states that the Department 
    should use the lease rate for private fringe lands only. The GOM notes 
    that at verification, the Department found that the fringe areas are 
    typical of the areas where most (85 percent) Crown lands are located 
    and, thus, the fringe areas are more directly comparable.
        If the Department uses the information submitted by the GOM, the 
    petitioner argues that the Department should not accept the GOM's claim 
    that the rental rate for private fringe land, as reported in the 1997 
    survey, is more comparable to the rate charged for Crown lands. 
    According to the petitioner, the claim is an assertion, not supported 
    in the record. Furthermore, the petitioner contends that the location 
    of the land is immaterial because if Crown lands are located in the 
    fringe area, then the number of AUMs the Minister could permit to graze 
    on the land would presumably be less than in the core area. Thus, the 
    Department should continue to use the average lease rate for private 
    land in the fringe and core areas, as was done in the Preliminary 
    Determination.
        Department's Position: We agree with the GOM that the majority of 
    Crown lands are located in fringe areas. At verification we reviewed 
    maps and vegetation inventories that supported the GOM's claim with 
    respect to fringe and core areas. However, we do not agree that the 
    lease rate for public grazing land should be compared solely to the 
    private fringe area rate because not all of the GOM's Crown lands are 
    located in fringe areas. Instead, we have used a weighted average lease 
    rate for private land based on both core and fringe area rates.
    
    Comment 27: Appropriate Adjustments to Benchmark for Manitoba's Public 
    Lease Rates
    
        The petitioner states that the Department should only adjust lease 
    rates for private land downward if the GOM establishes that the lease 
    rates for private land include additional services that are not covered 
    by lease rates for public land. In the petitioner's view, the GOM 
    failed to do this. The petitioner notes, for example, that a majority 
    of the private land lessees questioned for the 1997 survey indicated 
    that they are required to pay for fence and water system maintenance 
    and yet, the GOM is requesting an adjustment for these items.
        The GOM responds by noting that the Department reviewed in detail 
    at verification, in three provinces, the various reasons why lessees 
    are willing to improve public Crown lands available for lease, and why 
    the adjustments made by the Department are appropriate. The GOM also 
    notes
    
    [[Page 57066]]
    
    that the 1997 survey asked lessees whether they were required to pay 
    for the repairs and maintenance on the fence and/or watering system, 
    not the installation of fences or watering systems, which is what the 
    adjustment is attempting to capture.
        Department's Position: Based on our review of the information, we 
    are persuaded that it is necessary to adjust the lease rate for private 
    land downward to account for differences between the leases on private 
    and public land. Lease rates for private land are generally for land 
    which is fenced, has a water system, and where the owner of the land 
    pays local taxes. Conversely, the lessees of public land are expected 
    to construct fences and watering systems and pay local taxes. Thus, we 
    adjusted for differences in costs associated with the paying of taxes, 
    construction of fences and construction of water dugouts. While the 
    petitioner notes that the 1997 survey indicates that lessees of private 
    land are required to pay for fence and water system maintenance, we 
    agree with the GOM that the claimed adjustment is for fence and water 
    system construction, not maintenance.
    
    Comment 28: Appropriate Benchmark for Saskatchewan's Public Lease Rates
    
        With respect to Saskatchewan's Crown lands, the petitioner argues 
    that the no-service lease rate for private land reported by the GOC 
    does not include additional costs such as fencing, water provision, and 
    taxes. Thus, it is inappropriate as a benchmark rate. Nonetheless, if 
    it is used as a benchmark, it should not be adjusted.
        The GOS contends that ``no-service'' refers only to livestock 
    management and does not mean that rates for leases on private land do 
    not cover additional costs. The GOS contends that the petitioner is 
    merely attempting to confuse the issue by suggesting that the 
    Department compare the cost of both renting land and pasturing cattle 
    with the cost of simply renting land.
        Department's Position: We agree with the GOS that the GOC's survey 
    refers to whether pasture services are provided and not whether taxes 
    are paid by the landlord or whether some of the land is already fenced 
    with dugouts. Therefore, the no-service rate is an appropriate 
    benchmark and adjustments for these differences are appropriate.
    
    Comment 29: Appropriate Adjustments to Benchmark for Saskatchewan's 
    Public Lease Rates
    
        The petitioner argues that the adjustments to the lease rate for 
    private grazing land reported by the GOS are unreasonable because they 
    are higher than the difference between the no-service and full-service 
    pasturing rates in Saskatchewan, and higher than the estimated 
    adjustment costs in Manitoba. Therefore, according to the petitioner, 
    any adjustment for alleged costs included in lease rates for private 
    land should be capped at the difference between the no-service and 
    full-service pasturing rates. When comparing the lease rate for public 
    land to an adjusted full-service lease rate for private pasturing, the 
    petitioner notes that a benefit is found.
        The GOS states that because a private no-service lease still 
    includes various responsibilities of the private landlord, which are 
    not included in a Crown lands lease, adjustments are necessary in order 
    to assure the ``comparability'' contemplated by the Department's 
    regulations.
        Department's Position: We adjusted the lease rate for private land 
    downward to account for costs associated with the paying of taxes, 
    construction of fences and construction of water dugouts. However, 
    while the respondent has argued that we should make a full adjustment 
    for these expenses, we note that the no-service rate being relied upon 
    as a benchmark does not always include the provision of fences. At 
    verification, we learned that no-service ``was identified as the simple 
    rental of land, which may or may not be fenced.'' See Page Eight of the 
    Memorandum to Susan Kuhbach from James Breeden and Zak Smith, 
    ``Verification Report for the Government of Canada in the 
    Countervailing Duty Investigation of Live Cattle from Canada,'' dated 
    August 27, 1999. While we acknowledge that the overwhelming evidence in 
    this investigation indicates that leased private land has fences, in 
    this case, because the rate being relied upon is a ``no-service'' rate 
    and the record indicates that this particular rate does not always 
    include the provision of fences, we have not made a full adjustment for 
    fencing costs. Rather, we have made a partial adjustment by dividing 
    the fence expense in half.
        While we agree with the petitioner that the adjustments to the 
    lease rate for private land are greater than the difference between the 
    no-service private pasturing rate and the full-service private 
    pasturing rate in Saskatchewan, and greater than the claimed 
    adjustments in Manitoba, we do not agree that this comparison is 
    appropriate. First, the petitioner is comparing pasturing rates and 
    land leasing rates, two different things. Second, the petitioner is 
    comparing experiences in two different provinces. There is no reason to 
    expect that local tax rates will be similar across provinces or that 
    the cost of construction materials and/or labor will not vary amongst 
    provinces, especially when there is evidence to the contrary. In that 
    regard, we note that the information on these adjustments is fully 
    supported by the record evidence and verification. Specifically, the 
    GOS provided supporting source documentation for each adjustment in the 
    form of audited financial statements, invoices, and contracts.
    
    Comment 30: Saskatchewan's Community Pastures
    
        The GOS argues that while it previously suggested that full-service 
    private pastures were most similar to the GOS' community pastures, it 
    now believes that partial-service private pastures provide a better 
    comparison. According to the GOS, Saskatchewan's community pastures do 
    not offer the same range of services as full-service private pastures 
    and instead more closely resemble partial-service private pastures 
    which have shared responsibility and work between the customer and the 
    land owner.
        The GOS cites to several factors in support of its argument. First, 
    the GOS contends that the full-service rate provided by the PFRA study 
    does not include any commingled herds, while its community pastures are 
    commingled. Second, the GOS contends that the majority of private 
    pastures used to generate the full-service rate consist of improved 
    pasture, while community pastures are generally less productive native 
    range. Third, the GOS asserts that while a full-service pasture will 
    move cattle to more productive land and offer supplemental feed when 
    forage becomes less productive, such services are not offered by 
    community pastures. Fourth, the GOS states that in full-service private 
    pastures calves are often weaned early, placed on higher quality feed, 
    and that producers have general control over the breeding program. 
    According to the GOS, such options are not available on community 
    pastures. Lastly, the GOS argues that, full-service private pastures 
    allow producers to deliver and pick up cattle at their convenience. 
    According to the GOS such flexibility allows private users to cull cows 
    (usually ten percent of a herd) which are not bred by mid-summer, a 
    time when culled cows yield a higher price than at the end of the 
    season. According to the GOS we should adjust for this difference 
    because community pastures require pickup and delivery on a fixed 
    schedule and do not allow pickup mid-summer.
    
    [[Page 57067]]
    
        The petitioner argues that the GOS has not established that 
    partial-service pastures are more comparable to community pastures. 
    According to the petitioner, the GOC survey data, upon which the GOS is 
    relying, does not provide information indicating which rate, if any, 
    includes improved pasture or convenient owner access to herds for the 
    control of calves, breeding, and removal times. The petitioner contends 
    that because the GOS has failed to establish that full-service private 
    pastures offer materially different services than the GOS' community 
    pastures, the Department should continue to compare the full-service 
    private pasture rate to the community pasture rate.
        With respect to possible adjustments to the full-service rate, the 
    petitioner argues that the GOS has failed to quantify the value of the 
    alleged costs associated with commingling and access, failed to 
    establish that on private pastures cows are culled in July (mid-
    summer), and has failed to establish that ten percent of cows are 
    culled each year.
        Department's Position: We agree with the petitioner that the GOC 
    survey data do not provide information indicating that partial-service 
    private pasturing is more similar to GOS community pasturing than full-
    service pasturing. As noted in the verification report, with respect to 
    the GOC survey, ``full-service was identified as situations where the 
    cows are cared for during the entire season and the customer only needs 
    to drop off his or her cows and pick them up. Partial-service was 
    identified as shared responsibility and work between the customer and 
    the land owner.'' Thus, while it may be true that full-service private 
    pasturing in Saskatchewan offers more services than GOS community 
    pasturing, there is no information on the record that would indicate 
    that partial-service private pasturing offers a better comparison to 
    the pasturing services offered by the GOS.
        We have made certain downward adjustments to the full-service 
    private pasture rate to account for differences between full-service 
    pasturing offered on private land and public pasturing. Specifically, 
    we adjusted for the difference in costs associated with the timing of 
    the sale of cull cows. While the GOS argued that this adjustment should 
    be larger, the information on the record did not fully substantiate the 
    calculations suggested by the GOS. For example, the GOS relied upon the 
    GOC's statement that ten percent of cows are culled each year to 
    support its argument for making an adjustment to account for 
    differences in access to those cows which do not become pregnant. 
    However, there is no evidence to support the assumption that the ten 
    percent of cows culled each year are only those cows which do not 
    become pregnant. Rather, it is reasonable to believe that some of these 
    cows are culled on the basis of age alone and were never planned to be 
    bred. In that regard, there is no evidence that a patron would actually 
    pay to have an old cow pastured for a season if the cow was already 
    planned to be culled. Finally, as in the Preliminary Determination and 
    as noted above, we have not made adjustments for costs that the GOS was 
    unable to quantify.
    
    Other Comments
    
    Comment 31: Allocation of Benefits By Total Sales Value Of Cattle
    
        The GOC argues that the Department's regulations require it to 
    distribute the benefits from those programs found to be countervailable 
    across all products that have received the alleged benefits (19 CFR 
    351.525). The respondent contends that the Department's calculation of 
    the denominator in the Preliminary Determination did not comply with 
    this standard because certain programs that were found to be 
    countervailable and included in the numerator did not correspond to any 
    component included in the denominator. In support of its argument, the 
    respondent refers to Industrial Phosphoric Acid from Israel, in which 
    the Department reaffirmed the necessity that the ``calculation of a 
    subsidy reflect the same universe of goods. Otherwise, the rate 
    calculated will either over or understate the subsidy attributable to 
    the subject merchandise.'' See Industrial Phosphoric Acid from Israel, 
    63 FR 13626, 13630 (March 20, 1998). Because the benefits in this 
    investigation have been attributed to five commercially distinct 
    products (calves, feeder cattle, backgrounded cattle, slaughter cattle, 
    cull cows and bulls), the respondent argues that the sales value of all 
    five of these products must be included in the denominator for purposes 
    of correctly attributing benefits to the subject merchandise.
        The petitioner argues that respondents have not demonstrated that 
    benefits from particular programs impact any one of the ``distinct'' 
    cattle production stages it identifies, or should only be allocated to 
    that phase. Furthermore, petitioner explains that the use of total 
    Canadian cattle sales during the POI will likely count the same animal 
    more than once because cattle are moved through the different 
    production stages within the same year, thereby capturing multiple 
    sales of the same animal. Therefore, the sales figures advocated by 
    respondents are inflated. The petitioner contends that the Department 
    should continue to allocate subsidies over finished cattle or, 
    alternatively, compute the subsidy rate on a production, or volume, 
    basis rather than a value basis.
        Department's Position: Contrary to respondent's assertions, the 
    attribution approach applied in this investigation accurately measures 
    the countervailable benefits conferred and is consistent with the 
    countervailing duty statute. Although we recognize that there are 
    distinct commercial segments within the cattle industry, the respondent 
    incorrectly implies that the total value of the animal is equal to the 
    sum of transactions specific to the animal as it moves through the 
    different stages of the production cycle, thereby inflating the 
    universe of sales to which the benefits apply. This flaw in the 
    respondent's argument is illustrated by the petitioner's assertion that 
    using total cattle sales will likely result in the double counting of 
    certain animals due to the nature of the production cycle. Therefore, 
    in order to avoid overvaluing the denominator, we have continued to 
    apply the methodology used in our Preliminary Determination in which we 
    calculated total sales value by adding domestic slaughter and 
    international export statistics.
        Based on information collected at verification, we have also 
    included an amount for on-farm consumption to this figure. As a result, 
    we have allocated the countervailable benefits received by cattle at 
    each stage of the production cycle over the sales value of ``finished'' 
    cattle, or animals that have completed the production cycle. We believe 
    this attribution method most accurately captures a comparable universe 
    of goods as discussed in Industrial Phosphoric Acid from Israel.
    
    Comment 32: NISA and Regional Specificity
    
        The petitioner argues that NISA benefits provide a regional subsidy 
    because producers' geographic location determines eligibility under the 
    program. The petitioner notes that cattle and calves are eligible 
    commodities for NISA benefits in a select number of provinces and to 
    the extent that a producer is eligible for the NISA program based on 
    its geographic location, the program is regionally specific. According 
    to the petitioner it is most important to note that, while Alberta 
    cattle are not eligible commodities under the program, Alberta is the 
    largest provincial
    
    [[Page 57068]]
    
    producer. Based on this fact, the petitioner contends that NISA is 
    targeted to cattle producers in other regions where cattle production 
    is less intensive. According to the petitioner, the rationale for why 
    cattle are not eligible commodities in certain provinces is not 
    relevant to an examination of specificity. Instead, for the petitioner, 
    the key questions is whether ranchers in over half of Canada receive 
    NISA benefits for their livestock. As this is not the case, the 
    petitioner contends that the Department should recognize the specific 
    nature of the program.
        The GOC argues that the Department's precedent demonstrates that a 
    ``program is determined to be regional, and, therefore, limited only 
    when its funding is specifically authorized by the central government 
    to benefit only some regions within its jurisdiction.* * *'' See 
    Certain Granite Products from Spain, 53 FR 24340 (June 28, 1988). Thus, 
    according to the GOC, only when the granting authority has excluded 
    certain regions from participating in programs will regional 
    specificity be found. The GOC notes that, while the petitioner has said 
    that a producer's geographic location determines its eligibility under 
    NISA,'' NISA operates in all provinces and no provinces are excluded 
    (noting that Yukon and the Northwest Territories can join if they so 
    choose).
        The GOC further notes that a large number and wide variety of 
    commodities are covered by NISA and the fact that not every producer 
    commodity group in every province participates in NISA does not 
    transform NISA into a regional subsidy. First, the GOC argues that 
    farmers in all of the provinces participate and the lack of 
    participation by some provinces as to certain commodities does not 
    alter the fact that all provinces are eligible and that producers in 
    all provinces receive benefits. With respect to those provinces 
    (Alberta, British Columbia, and Quebec) for which cattle are not 
    eligible commodities, the GOC notes that other agricultural commodities 
    in each of these provinces are covered by NISA. Lastly, the GOC argues 
    that to avoid any further re-investigation of NISA, the Department 
    should make clear in the final determination that the program is non-
    specific not only to cattle but as to all other agricultural 
    commodities.
        Department's Position: Section 771(5A)(D)(iv) of the Act reads, 
    ``where a subsidy is limited to an enterprise or industry located 
    within a designated geographical region within the jurisdiction of the 
    authority providing the subsidy, the subsidy is specific.'' We have 
    found that NISA operates in all Canadian provinces. That is, NISA 
    benefits are not limited to an enterprise or industry located within a 
    specific geographical region within Canada. First, NISA is a whole-farm 
    program in which any farmer that produces an eligible commodity can 
    participate. The number of eligible commodities is exhaustive and 
    demonstrates that the benefits are not limited to a particular 
    enterprise or industry. Furthermore, the eligibility of commodities is 
    dependent on a particular commodity associations desire to participate. 
    Thus, no commodities are excluded by federal or provincial government 
    action. Second, the farmers that may participate in NISA are not 
    located within a specific geographical region. Rather, producers in all 
    provinces receive benefits, regardless of their location. Eligibility 
    for NISA participation is based upon the commodities that a farmer 
    produces, not his or her geographic location. Therefore, as noted in 
    the Preliminary Determination, benefits provided through the NISA 
    program are not limited to a particular region. While certain 
    commodities are not eligible for matching funds within certain 
    provinces, it is because the producers of these commodities choose not 
    to participate, not because the program is limited to an enterprise or 
    industry located in a particular region.
        With respect to the GOC's comment that we should find NISA non-
    counteravailable for all products, we note that our investigation of 
    NISA only related to whether cattle receive a counteravailable subsidy. 
    We have not examined whether the program is counteravailable to other 
    commodities.
    
    Comment 33: Saskatchewan Livestock and Horticultural Facilities 
    Incentives Program
    
        The GOS argues that the Livestock and Horticultural Facilities 
    Incentives Program (``LHFIP'') is an adjustment to, and is integrally 
    linked with, the provincial sales tax. According to the GOS, the 
    provincial sales tax (the Education and Health Tax (``E&H Tax'')) 
    offers a standard tax exemption to all agricultural production. Thus, 
    the GOS argues that LHFIP is not limited only to the livestock and 
    horticultural industries and, therefore, is not counteravailable. The 
    GOS contends that the LHFIP was introduced as part of a series of 
    adjustments to the E&H Tax, and is intended to put livestock operations 
    on the same footing as other agricultural operations with respect to 
    the E&H Tax exemption for agricultural inputs and the lack of an 
    exemption for certain construction materials.
        Citing to the New CVD Regulations, the GOS argues that all of the 
    Department's conditions for integral linkage are met. According to the 
    GOS, the LHFIP has the same purpose and same effective benefit as the 
    E&H Tax legislation and was linked with the E&H Tax at inception.
        Lastly, the GOS notes that the functioning of the LHFIP is 
    analogous to a VAT rebate program that the Department found 
    noncountervailable in Standard Chrysanthemums From the Netherlands; 
    Final Results of Countervailing Duty Administrative Reviews, 61 FR 
    47886 (September 11, 1996).
        Department's Position: In examining the legislation and regulations 
    governing both the LHFIP and the E&H Tax, we find that, even if the two 
    programs were found to be integrally linked under the regulations 
    governing this case, the program would still be specific, and, thus, 
    countervailable. According to the laws and regulations for the E&H Tax 
    and the GOS itself, although most agricultural inputs to production 
    (such as machinery, fertilizer, seed, chemicals, and livestock) are 
    exempt from the E&H Tax, the E&H Tax continues to be levied on certain 
    construction materials and equipment for all agricultural products that 
    could be used for both agricultural and non-agricultural purposes. 
    Although the LHFIP created an exemption from the E&H Tax for livestock 
    and horticultural producers, the tax on these types of construction 
    materials is apparently still levied on other agricultural producers 
    not related to livestock and horticulture production. Thus, even if the 
    programs were integrally linked, because the legislation administering 
    these programs expressly makes them available to only certain 
    industries, they would still be specific. Therefore, any determination 
    on the integral linkage of these programs is not necessary.
    
    Verification
    
        In accordance with section 782(i) of the Act, we verified the 
    information used in making our final determination. We followed 
    standard verification procedures, including meeting with government 
    officials, and examining relevant accounting records and original 
    source documents. Our verification results are outlined in detail in 
    the public versions of the verification reports, which are on file in 
    the Central Records Unit of the Department of Commerce, Room B-099.
    
    [[Page 57069]]
    
    Summary
    
        The total net countervailable subsidy rate for all producers or 
    exporters of live cattle in Canada is 0.77 percent, ad valorem, which 
    is de minimis. Therefore, we determine that countervailable subsidies 
    are not being provided to producers or exporters of live cattle in 
    Canada.
    
    Return or Destruction of Proprietary Information
    
        This notice will serve as the only reminder to parties subject to 
    Administrative Protective Order (``APO'') of their responsibility 
    concerning the return or destruction of proprietary information 
    disclosed under APO in accordance with 19 CFR 355.34(d). Failure to 
    comply is a violation of the APO.
        This determination is published pursuant to section 705(d) and 
    777(i) of the Act.
    
        Dated: October 12, 1999.
    Robert S. LaRussa,
    Assistant Secretary for Import Administration.
    [FR Doc. 99-27570 Filed 10-21-99; 8:45 am]
    BILLING CODE 3510-DS-P
    
    
    

Document Information

Effective Date:
10/22/1999
Published:
10/22/1999
Department:
International Trade Administration
Entry Type:
Notice
Document Number:
99-27570
Dates:
October 22, 1999.
Pages:
57040-57069 (30 pages)
Docket Numbers:
C-122-834
PDF File:
99-27570.pdf