99-26032. REQUEST FOR VIEWS ON DRAFT ANTITRUST GUIDELINES FOR COLLABORATIONS AMONG COMPETITORS  

  • [Federal Register Volume 64, Number 193 (Wednesday, October 6, 1999)]
    [Notices]
    [Pages 54484-54497]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 99-26032]
    
    
    
    [[Page 54483]]
    
    _______________________________________________________________________
    
    Part VI
    
    
    
    
    
    Federal Trade Commission
    
    
    
    
    
    _______________________________________________________________________
    
    
    
    Request for Views on Draft Antitrust Guidelines for Collaborations 
    Among Competitors; Notice
    
    Federal Register / Vol. 64, No. 193 / Wednesday, October 6, 1999 / 
    Notices
    
    [[Page 54484]]
    
    
    
    FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION
    
    
    REQUEST FOR VIEWS ON DRAFT ANTITRUST GUIDELINES FOR 
    COLLABORATIONS AMONG COMPETITORS
    
    AGENCY: Federal Trade Commission.
    
    ACTION: Notice.
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    SUMMARY: The Federal Trade Commission (``FTC'' or ``Commission''), in 
    consultation with the Antitrust Division of the U.S. Department of 
    Justice, has drafted Antitrust Guidelines for Collaborations Among 
    Competitors. The Guidelines, if adopted in final form by the FTC and 
    the Department of Justice (``the Agencies''), will state the antitrust 
    enforcement policy of the Agencies with regard to competition issues 
    raised by collaborations among competitors. The Guidelines should 
    enable businesses to evaluate proposed transactions with greater 
    understanding of possible antitrust implications, thus encouraging 
    procompetitive collaborations, deterring collaborations likely to harm 
    competition and consumers, and facilitating the Agencies' 
    investigations of collaborations. The Agencies are issuing the 
    Guidelines in draft form to obtain advice and suggestions from 
    businesses, consumers, and antitrust practitioners that will assist in 
    ensuring that the Guidelines achieve these goals.
    
    DATES: Views should be submitted in writing as specified below by 
    January 5, 2000.
    
    ADDRESSES: To facilitate efficient review, all views should be 
    submitted in written and electronic form. Six hard copies of each 
    submission should be addressed to Donald S. Clark, Office of the 
    Secretary, Federal Trade Commission, 600 Pennsylvania Avenue, N.W., 
    Washington, D.C. 20580. Submissions should be captioned ``Draft 
    Antitrust Guidelines for Collaborations Among Competitors--Submission 
    of Views.'' Electronic submissions may be made in one of two ways. They 
    may be filed on a 3\1/2\ inch computer disk, with a label on the disk 
    stating the name of the submitter and the name and version of the word 
    processing program used to create the document. (Programs based on DOS 
    or Windows are preferred. Files from other operating systems should be 
    submitted in ASCII text format.) Alternatively, electronic submissions 
    may be sent by electronic mail to jventures@ftc.gov.
    
    FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Policy Planning staff at (202) 326-
    3712.
    
    SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: The draft Guidelines are a product of the 
    Joint Venture Project initiated by the Commission to determine whether 
    antitrust guidance to the business community could be improved through 
    clarifying and updating antitrust policies regarding joint ventures and 
    other forms of competitor collaboration. The Commission has provided 
    opportunity for public input throughout each stage of the project. See 
    62 FR 22945 (1997) and 62 FR 48660 (1997). If adopted in final form, 
    the draft Guidelines will state the Agencies' antitrust enforcement 
    policy with regard to competition issues raised by collaborations among 
    competitors. They are not intended to create or recognize any legally 
    enforceable right or defense in any person or to affect the 
    admissibility of evidence or in any other way to affect the course or 
    conduct of any present or future litigation.
    
        By direction of the Commission.
    Donald S. Clark,
    Secretary.
    
    Antitrust Guidelines for Collaborations Among Competitors
    
    Preamble
    
        In order to compete in modern markets, competitors sometimes need 
    to collaborate. Competitive forces are driving firms toward complex 
    collaborations to achieve goals such as expanding into foreign markets, 
    funding expensive innovation efforts, and lowering production and other 
    costs.
        Such collaborations often are not only benign but procompetitive. 
    Indeed, in the last two decades, the federal antitrust agencies have 
    brought relatively few civil cases against competitor collaborations. 
    Nevertheless, a perception that antitrust laws are skeptical about 
    agreements among actual or potential competitors may deter the 
    development of procompetitive collaborations.1
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \1\ Congress has protected certain collaborations from full 
    antitrust liability by passing the National Cooperative Research Act 
    of 1984 (``NCRA'') and the National Cooperative Research and 
    Production Act of 1993 (``NCRPA'') (codified together at 15 U.S.C. 
    Sec. Sec. 4301-06). Relatively few participants in research and 
    production collaborations have sought to take advantage of the 
    protections afforded by the NCRA and NCRPA, however.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        To provide guidance to business people, the Federal Trade 
    Commission (``FTC'') and the U.S. Department of Justice (``DOJ'') 
    (collectively, ``the Agencies'') previously issued guidelines 
    addressing several special circumstances in which antitrust issues 
    related to competitor collaborations may arise.2 But none of 
    these Guidelines represents a general statement of the Agencies' 
    analytical approach to competitor collaborations. The increasing 
    varieties and use of competitor collaborations have yielded requests 
    for improved clarity regarding their treatment under the antitrust 
    laws.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \2\ The Statements of Antitrust Enforcement Policy in Health 
    Care (``Health Care Statements'') outline the Agencies' approach to 
    certain health care collaborations, among other things. The 
    Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property 
    (``Intellectual Property Guidelines'') outline the Agencies' 
    enforcement policy with respect to intellectual property licensing 
    agreements among competitors, among other things. The 1992 DOJ/FTC 
    Horizontal Merger Guidelines, as amended in 1997 (``Horizontal 
    Merger Guidelines''), outline the Agencies'' approach to horizontal 
    mergers and acquisitions, and certain competitor collaborations.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The new Antitrust Guidelines for Collaborations among Competitors 
    (``Competitor Collaboration Guidelines'') are intended to explain how 
    the Agencies analyze certain antitrust issues raised by collaborations 
    among competitors. Competitor collaborations and the market 
    circumstances in which they operate vary widely. No set of guidelines 
    can provide specific answers to every antitrust question that might 
    arise from a competitor collaboration. These Guidelines describe an 
    analytical framework to assist businesses in assessing the likelihood 
    of an antitrust challenge to a collaboration with one or more 
    competitors. They should enable businesses to evaluate proposed 
    transactions with greater understanding of possible antitrust 
    implications, thus encouraging procompetitive collaborations, deterring 
    collaborations likely to harm competition and consumers, and 
    facilitating the Agencies' investigations of collaborations.
    
    Section 1: Purpose, Definitions, and Overview
    
    1.1  Purpose and Definitions
    
        These Guidelines state the antitrust enforcement policy of the 
    Agencies with respect to competitor collaborations. By stating their 
    general policy, the Agencies hope to assist businesses in assessing 
    whether the Agencies will challenge a competitor collaboration or any 
    of the agreements of which it is comprised.3 However, these 
    Guidelines cannot remove judgment and discretion in antitrust law 
    enforcement. The Agencies evaluate each case in light of its own facts 
    and apply the analytical framework set forth in these Guidelines 
    reasonably and flexibly.4
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \3\ These Guidelines neither describe how the Agencies litigate 
    cases nor assign burdens of proof or production.
        \4\ The analytical framework set forth in these Guidelines is 
    consistent with the analytical frameworks in the Health Care 
    Statements and the Intellectual Property Guidelines, which remain in 
    effect to address issues in their special contexts.
    
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [[Page 54485]]
    
        A ``competitor collaboration'' comprises a set of one or more 
    agreements, other than merger agreements, between or among competitors 
    to engage in economic activity, and the economic activity resulting 
    therefrom.5 ``Competitors'' include firms that are actual or 
    potential competitors 6 in a relevant market.7 
    Competitor collaborations involve one or more business activities, such 
    as research and development (``R&D''), production, marketing, 
    distribution, sales or purchasing. Information sharing and various 
    trade association activities also may take place through competitor 
    collaborations.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \5\ These Guidelines do not address the possible exclusionary 
    effects of agreements among competitors that may foreclose or limit 
    competition by rivals.
        \6\ A firm is treated as a potential competitor if there is 
    evidence that entry by that firm is reasonably probable in the 
    absence of the relevant agreement, or that competitively significant 
    decisions by actual competitors are constrained by concerns that 
    anticompetitive conduct likely would induce the firm to enter.
        \7\ Firms also may be in a buyer-seller or other relationship, 
    but that does not eliminate the need to examine the competitor 
    relationship, if present.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        These Guidelines use the terms ``anticompetitive harm,'' 
    ``procompetitive benefit,'' and ``overall competitive effect'' in 
    analyzing the competitive effects of agreements among competitors. All 
    of these terms include actual and likely competitive effects. The 
    Guidelines use the term ``anticompetitive harm'' to refer to an 
    agreement's adverse competitive consequences, without taking account of 
    offsetting procompetitive benefits. Conversely, the term 
    ``procompetitive benefit'' refers to an agreement's favorable 
    competitive consequences, without taking account of its anticompetitive 
    harm. The terms ``overall competitive effect'' or ``competitive 
    effect'' are used in discussing the combination of an agreement's 
    anticompetitive harm and procompetitive benefit.
    
    1.2  Overview of Analytical Framework
    
        Two types of analysis are used by the Supreme Court to determine 
    the lawfulness of an agreement among competitors: per se and rule of 
    reason.8 Certain types of agreements are so likely to harm 
    competition and to have no significant procompetitive benefit that they 
    do not warrant the time and expense required for particularized inquiry 
    into their effects. Once identified, such agreements are challenged as 
    per se unlawful.9 All other agreements are evaluated under 
    the rule of reason, which involves a factual inquiry into an 
    agreement's overall competitive effect. As the Supreme Court has 
    explained, rule of reason analysis entails a flexible inquiry and 
    varies in focus and detail depending on the nature of the agreement and 
    market circumstances.10
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \8\ See National Soc'y of Prof'l. Eng'rs v. United States, 435 
    U.S. 679, 692 (1978).
        \9\ See FTC v. Superior Court Trial Lawyers Ass'n, 493 U.S. 411, 
    432-36 (1990).
        \10\ See California Dental Ass'n v. FTC, 119 S. Ct. 1604, 1617-
    18 (1999); FTC v. Indiana Fed'n of Dentists, 476 U.S. 447, 459-61 
    (1986); National Collegiate Athletic Ass'n v. Board of Regents of 
    the Univ. of Okla., 468 U.S. 85, 104-13 (1984).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        This overview briefly sets forth questions and factors that the 
    Agencies assess in analyzing an agreement among competitors. The rest 
    of the Guidelines should be consulted for the detailed definitions and 
    discussion that underlie this analysis.
        Agreements Challenged as Per Se Illegal. Agreements of a type that 
    always or almost always tends to raise price or to reduce output are 
    per se illegal. The Agencies challenge such agreements, once 
    identified, as per se illegal. Types of agreements that have been held 
    per se illegal include agreements among competitors to fix prices or 
    output, rig bids, or share or divide markets by allocating customers, 
    suppliers, territories, or lines of commerce. The Department of Justice 
    prosecutes participants in such hard-core cartel agreements criminally. 
    Because the courts conclusively presume such hard-core cartel 
    agreements to be illegal, the Department of Justice treats them as such 
    without inquiring into their claimed business purposes, anticompetitive 
    harms, procompetitive benefits, or overall competitive effects.
        Agreements Analyzed under the Rule of Reason. Agreements not 
    challenged as per se illegal are analyzed under the rule of reason to 
    determine their overall competitive effect. These include agreements of 
    a type that otherwise might be considered per se illegal, provided they 
    are reasonably related to, and reasonably necessary to achieve 
    procompetitive benefits from, an efficiency-enhancing integration of 
    economic activity.
        Rule of reason analysis focuses on the state of competition with, 
    as compared to without, the relevant agreement. The central question is 
    whether the relevant agreement likely harms competition by increasing 
    the ability or incentive profitably to raise price above or reduce 
    output, quality, service, or innovation below what likely would prevail 
    in the absence of the relevant agreement.
        Rule of reason analysis entails a flexible inquiry and varies in 
    focus and detail depending on the nature of the agreement and market 
    circumstances. The Agencies focus on only those factors, and undertake 
    only that factual inquiry, necessary to make a sound determination of 
    the overall competitive effect of the relevant agreement. Ordinarily, 
    however, no one factor is dispositive in the analysis.
        The Agencies' analysis begins with an examination of the nature of 
    the relevant agreement. As part of this examination, the Agencies ask 
    about the business purpose of the agreement and examine whether the 
    agreement, if already in operation, has caused anticompetitive harm. In 
    some cases, the nature of the agreement and the absence of market power 
    together may demonstrate the absence of anticompetitive harm. In such 
    cases, the Agencies do not challenge the agreement. Alternatively, 
    where the likelihood of anticompetitive harm is evident from the nature 
    of the agreement, or anticompetitive harm has resulted from an 
    agreement already in operation, then, absent overriding benefits that 
    could offset the anticompetitive harm, the Agencies challenge such 
    agreements without a detailed market analysis.
        If the initial examination of the nature of the agreement indicates 
    possible competitive concerns, but the agreement is not one that would 
    be challenged without a detailed market analysis, the Agencies analyze 
    the agreement in greater depth. The Agencies typically define relevant 
    markets and calculate market shares and concentration as an initial 
    step in assessing whether the agreement may create or increase market 
    power or facilitate its exercise. The Agencies examine the extent to 
    which the participants and the collaboration have the ability and 
    incentive to compete independently. The Agencies also evaluate other 
    market circumstances, e.g. entry, that may foster or prevent 
    anticompetitive harms.
        If the examination of these factors indicates no potential for 
    anticompetitive harm, the Agencies end the investigation without 
    considering procompetitive benefits. If investigation indicates 
    anticompetitive harm, the Agencies examine whether the relevant 
    agreement is reasonably necessary to achieve procompetitive benefits 
    that likely would offset anticompetitive harms.
    
    1.3  Competitor Collaborations Distinguished from Mergers
    
        The competitive effects from competitor collaborations may differ
    
    [[Page 54486]]
    
    from those of mergers due to a number of factors. Mergers completely 
    end competition between the merging parties in the relevant market(s). 
    By contrast, most competitor collaborations preserve some form of 
    competition among the participants. This remaining competition may 
    reduce competitive concerns, but also may raise questions about whether 
    participants have agreed to anticompetitive restraints on the remaining 
    competition.
        Mergers are designed to be permanent, while competitor 
    collaborations are more typically of limited duration. Thus, 
    participants in a collaboration typically remain potential competitors, 
    even if they are not actual competitors for certain purposes (e.g., 
    R&D) during the collaboration. The potential for future competition 
    between participants in a collaboration requires antitrust scrutiny 
    different from that required for mergers.
        Nonetheless, in some cases, competitor collaborations have 
    competitive effects identical to those that would arise if the 
    participants merged in whole or in part. The Agencies treat a 
    competitor collaboration as a horizontal merger in a relevant market 
    and analyze the collaboration pursuant to the Horizontal Merger 
    Guidelines if: (a) The participants are competitors in that relevant 
    market; (b) the formation of the collaboration involves an efficiency-
    enhancing integration of economic activity in the relevant market; (c) 
    the integration eliminates all competition among the participants in 
    the relevant market; and (d) the collaboration does not terminate 
    within a sufficiently limited period 11 by its own specific 
    and express terms.12 Effects of the collaboration on 
    competition in other markets are analyzed as appropriate under these 
    Guidelines or other applicable precedent. See Example 1.13
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \11\ In general, the Agencies use ten years as a term indicating 
    sufficient permanence to justify treatment of a competitor 
    collaboration as analogous to a merger. The length of this term may 
    vary, however, depending on industry-specific circumstances, such as 
    technology life cycles.
        \12\ This definition, however, does not determine obligations 
    arising under the Hart-Scott-Rodino Antitrust Improvements Act of 
    1976, 15 U.S.C. Sec. 18a.
        \13\ Examples illustrating this and other points set forth in 
    these Guidelines are included in the Appendix.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Section 2: General Principles for Evaluating Agreements Among 
    Competitors
    
    2.1  Potential Procompetitive Benefits
    
        The Agencies recognize that consumers may benefit from competitor 
    collaborations in a variety of ways. For example, a competitor 
    collaboration may enable participants to offer goods or services that 
    are cheaper, more valuable to consumers, or brought to market faster 
    than would be possible absent the collaboration. A collaboration may 
    allow its participants to better use existing assets, or may provide 
    incentives for them to make output-enhancing investments that would not 
    occur absent the collaboration. The potential efficiencies from 
    competitor collaborations may be achieved through a variety of 
    contractual arrangements including joint ventures, trade or 
    professional associations, licensing arrangements, or strategic 
    alliances.
        Efficiency gains from competitor collaborations often stem from 
    combinations of different capabilities or resources. For example, one 
    participant may have special technical expertise that usefully 
    complements another participant's manufacturing process, allowing the 
    latter participant to lower its production cost or improve the quality 
    of its product. In other instances, a collaboration may facilitate the 
    attainment of scale or scope economies beyond the reach of any single 
    participant. For example, two firms may be able to combine their 
    research or marketing activities to lower their cost of bringing their 
    products to market, or reduce the time needed to develop and begin 
    commercial sales of new products. Consumers may benefit from these 
    collaborations as the participants are able to lower prices, improve 
    quality, or bring new products to market faster.
    
    2.2  Potential Anticompetitive Harms
    
        Competitor collaborations may harm competition and consumers by 
    increasing the ability or incentive profitably to raise price above or 
    reduce output, quality, service, or innovation below what likely would 
    prevail in the absence of the relevant agreement. Such effects may 
    arise through a variety of mechanisms. Among other things, agreements 
    may limit independent decision making or combine the control of or 
    financial interests in production, key assets, or decisions regarding 
    price, output, or other competitively sensitive variables, or may 
    otherwise reduce the participants' ability or incentive to compete 
    independently.
        Competitor collaborations also may facilitate explicit or tacit 
    collusion through facilitating practices such as the exchange or 
    disclosure of competitively sensitive information or through increased 
    market concentration. Such collusion may involve the relevant market in 
    which the collaboration operates or another market in which the 
    participants in the collaboration are actual or potential competitors.
    
    2.3  Analysis of the Overall Collaboration and the Agreements of 
    Which It Consists
    
        A competitor collaboration comprises a set of one or more 
    agreements, other than merger agreements, between or among competitors 
    to engage in economic activity, and the economic activity resulting 
    therefrom. In general, the Agencies assess the competitive effects of 
    the overall collaboration and any individual agreement or set of 
    agreements within the collaboration that may harm competition. For 
    purposes of these Guidelines, the phrase ``relevant agreement'' refers 
    to whichever of these three the evaluating Agency is assessing. Two or 
    more agreements are assessed together if their procompetitive benefits 
    or anticompetitive harms are so intertwined that they cannot 
    meaningfully be isolated and attributed to any individual agreement. 
    See Example 2.
    
    2.4  Competitive Effects Are Assessed as of the Time of Possible 
    Harm to Competition
    
        The competitive effects of a relevant agreement may change over 
    time, depending on changes in circumstances such as internal 
    reorganization, adoption of new agreements as part of the 
    collaboration, addition or departure of participants, new market 
    conditions, or changes in market share. The Agencies assess the 
    competitive effects of a relevant agreement as of the time of possible 
    harm to competition, whether at formation of the collaboration or at a 
    later time, as appropriate. See Example 3. However, an assessment after 
    a collaboration has been formed is sensitive to the reasonable 
    expectations of participants whose significant sunk cost investments in 
    reliance on the relevant agreement were made before it became 
    anticompetitive.
    
    Section 3: Analytical Framework for Evaluating Agreements Among 
    Competitors
    
    3.1  Introduction
    
        Section 3 sets forth the analytical framework that the Agencies use 
    to evaluate the competitive effects of a competitor collaboration and 
    the agreements of which it consists. Certain types of agreements are so 
    likely to be harmful to competition and to have no significant benefits 
    that they do not warrant the time and expense required for 
    particularized inquiry into their
    
    [[Page 54487]]
    
    effects.14 Once identified, such agreements are challenged 
    as per se illegal.15
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \14\ See Continental TV, Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 
    50 n.16 (1977).
        \15\ See Superior Court Trial Lawyers Ass'n, 493 U.S. at 432-36.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Agreements not challenged as per se illegal are analyzed under the 
    rule of reason. Rule of reason analysis focuses on the state of 
    competition with, as compared to without, the relevant agreement. Under 
    the rule of reason, the central question is whether the relevant 
    agreement likely harms competition by increasing the ability or 
    incentive profitably to raise price above or reduce output, quality, 
    service, or innovation below what likely would prevail in the absence 
    of the relevant agreement. Given the great variety of competitor 
    collaborations, rule of reason analysis entails a flexible inquiry and 
    varies in focus and detail depending on the nature of the agreement and 
    market circumstances. Rule of reason analysis focuses on only those 
    factors, and undertakes only the degree of factual inquiry, necessary 
    to assess accurately the overall competitive effect of the relevant 
    agreement.16
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \16\ See California Dental Ass'n, 119 S. Ct. at 1617-18; Indiana 
    Fed'n of Dentists, 476 U.S. at 459-61; NCAA, 468 U.S. at 104-13.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The following sections describe in detail the Agencies' analytical 
    framework.
    
    3.2  Agreements Challenged as Per Se Illegal
    
        Agreements of a type that always or almost always tends to raise 
    price or reduce output are per se illegal.17 The Agencies 
    challenge such agreements, once identified, as per se illegal. 
    Typically these are agreements not to compete on price or output. Types 
    of agreements that have been held per se illegal include agreements 
    among competitors to fix prices or output, rig bids, or share or divide 
    markets by allocating customers, suppliers, territories or lines of 
    commerce.18 The Department of Justice prosecutes 
    participants in such hard-core cartel agreements criminally. Because 
    the courts conclusively presume such hard-core cartel agreements to be 
    illegal, the Department of Justice treats them as such without 
    inquiring into their claimed business purposes, anticompetitive harms, 
    procompetitive benefits, or overall competitive effects.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \17\ See Broadcast Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broadcasting Sys., 
    441 U.S. 1, 19-20 (1979).
        \18\ See, e.g., Palmer v. BRG of Georgia, Inc., 498 U.S. 46 
    (1990) (market allocation); United States v. Trenton Potteries Co., 
    273 U.S. 392 (1927) (price fixing).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        If, however, participants in an efficiency-enhancing integration of 
    economic activity enter into an agreement that is reasonably related to 
    the integration and reasonably necessary to achieve its procompetitive 
    benefits, the Agencies analyze the agreement under the rule of reason, 
    even if it is of a type that might otherwise be considered per se 
    illegal.19 See Example 4. In an efficiency-enhancing 
    integration, participants collaborate to perform or cause to be 
    performed (by a joint venture entity created by the collaboration or by 
    one or more participants or by a third party acting on behalf of other 
    participants) one or more business functions, such as production, 
    distribution, or R&D, and thereby benefit, or potentially benefit, 
    consumers by expanding output, reducing price, or enhancing quality, 
    service, or innovation. Participants in an efficiency-enhancing 
    integration typically combine, by contract or otherwise, significant 
    capital, technology, or other complementary assets to achieve 
    procompetitive benefits that the participants could not achieve 
    separately. The mere coordination of decisions on price, output, 
    customers, territories, and the like is not integration, and cost 
    savings without integration are not a basis for avoiding per se 
    condemnation. The integration must promote procompetitive benefits that 
    are cognizable under the efficiencies analysis set forth in Section 
    3.36 below. Such procompetitive benefits may enhance the participants' 
    ability or incentives to compete and thus may offset an agreement's 
    anticompetitive tendencies. See Examples 5 through 7.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \19\ See Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical Soc'y, 457 U.S. 332, 
    339 n.7, 356-57 (1982) (finding no integration).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        An agreement may be ``reasonably necessary'' without being 
    essential. However, if the participants could achieve an equivalent or 
    comparable efficiency-enhancing integration through practical, 
    significantly less restrictive means, then the Agencies conclude that 
    the agreement is not reasonably necessary.20 In making this 
    assessment, except in unusual circumstances, the Agencies consider 
    whether practical, significantly less restrictive means were reasonably 
    available when the agreement was entered into, but do not search for a 
    theoretically less restrictive alternative that was not practical given 
    the business realities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \20\ See id. at 352-53 (observing that even if a maximum fee 
    schedule for physicians' services were desirable, it was not 
    necessary that the schedule be established by physicians rather than 
    by insurers); Broadcast Music, 441 U.S. at 20-21 (setting of price 
    ``necessary'' for the blanket license).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Before accepting a claim that an agreement is reasonably necessary 
    to achieve procompetitive benefits from an integration of economic 
    activity, the Agencies undertake a limited factual inquiry to evaluate 
    the claim.21 Such an inquiry may reveal that efficiencies 
    from an agreement that are possible in theory are not plausible in the 
    context of the particular collaboration. Some claims--such as those 
    premised on the notion that competition itself is unreasonable--are 
    insufficient as a matter of law,22 and others may be 
    implausible on their face. In any case, labeling an arrangement a 
    ``joint venture'' will not protect what is merely a device to raise 
    price or restrict output; 23 the nature of the conduct, not 
    its designation, is determinative.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \21\ See Maricopa, 457 U.S. at 352-53, 356-57 (scrutinizing the 
    defendant medical foundations for indicia of integration and 
    evaluating the record evidence regarding less restrictive 
    alternatives).
        \22\ See Indiana Fed'n of Dentists, 476 U.S. at 463-64; NCAA, 
    468 U.S. at 116-17; Prof'l. Eng'rs, 435 U.S. at 693-96. Other 
    claims, such as an absence of market power, are no defense to per se 
    illegality. See Superior Court Trial Lawyers Ass'n, 493 U.S. at 434-
    36; United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.S. 150, 224-26 & 
    n.59 (1940).
        \23\ See Timken Roller Bearing Co. v. United States, 341 U.S. 
    593, 598 (1951).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    3.3  Agreements Analyzed Under the Rule of Reason
    
        Agreements not challenged as per se illegal are analyzed under the 
    rule of reason to determine their overall competitive effect. Rule of 
    reason analysis focuses on the state of competition with, as compared 
    to without, the relevant agreement. The central question is whether the 
    relevant agreement likely harms competition by increasing the ability 
    or incentive profitably to raise price above or reduce output, quality, 
    service, or innovation below what likely would prevail in the absence 
    of the relevant agreement.24
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \24\ In addition, concerns may arise where an agreement 
    increases the ability or incentive of buyers to exercise monopsony 
    power. See infra Section 3.31(a).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Rule of reason analysis entails a flexible inquiry and varies in 
    focus and detail depending on the nature of the agreement and 
    marketcircumstances.25 The Agencies focus on only those 
    factors, and undertake only that factual inquiry, necessary to make a 
    sound
    
    [[Page 54488]]
    
    determination of the overall competitive effect of the relevant 
    agreement. Ordinarily, however, no one factor is dispositive in the 
    analysis.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \25\ See California Dental Ass'n, 119 S. Ct. at 1612-13, 1617 
    (``What is required * * * is an enquiry meet for the case, looking 
    to the circumstances, details, and logic of a restraint.''); NCAA, 
    468 U.S. 109 n.39 (``the rule of reason can sometimes be applied in 
    the twinkling of an eye'') (quoting Phillip E. Areeda, The ``Rule of 
    Reason'' in Antitrust Analysis: General Issues 37-38 (Federal 
    Judicial Center, June 1981)).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Under the rule of reason, the Agencies' analysis begins with an 
    examination of the nature of the relevant agreement, since the nature 
    of the agreement determines the types of anticompetitive harms that may 
    be of concern. As part of this examination, the Agencies ask about the 
    business purpose of the agreement and examine whether the agreement, if 
    already in operation, has caused anticompetitive harm.26 If 
    the nature of the agreement and the absence of market power 
    27 together demonstrate the absence of anticompetitive harm, 
    the Agencies do not challenge the agreement. See Example 8. 
    Alternatively, where the likelihood of anticompetitive harm is evident 
    from the nature of the agreement,28 or anticompetitive harm 
    has resulted from an agreement already in operation,29 then, 
    absent overriding benefits that could offset the anticompetitive harm, 
    the Agencies challenge such agreements without a detailed market 
    analysis.30
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \26\ See Board of Trade of the City of Chicago v. United States, 
    246 U.S. 231, 238 (1918).
        \27\ That market power is absent may be determined without 
    defining a relevant market. For example, if no market power is 
    likely under any plausible market definition, it does not matter 
    which one is correct.
        \28\ See California Dental Ass'n, 119 S. Ct. at 1612-13, 1617 
    (an ``obvious anticompetitive effect'' would warrant quick 
    condemnation); Indiana Fed'n of Dentists, 476 U.S. at 459; NCAA, 468 
    U.S. at 104, 106-10.
        \29\ See Indiana Fed'n of Dentists, 476 U.S. at 460-61 (``Since 
    the purpose of the inquiries into market definition and market power 
    is to determine whether an arrangement has the potential for genuine 
    adverse effects on competition, `proof of actual detrimental 
    effects, such as a reduction of output,' can obviate the need for an 
    inquiry into market power, which is but a `surrogate for detrimental 
    effects.' '') (quoting 7 Phillip E. Areeda, Antitrust Law  para. 
    1511, at 424 (1986)); NCAA, 468 U.S. at 104-08, 110 n. 42.
        \30\ See Indiana Fed'n of Dentists, 476 U.S. at 459-60 
    (condemning without ``detailed market analysis'' an agreement to 
    limit competition by withholding x-rays from patients' insurers 
    after finding no competitive justification).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        If the initial examination of the nature of the agreement indicates 
    possible competitive concerns, but the agreement is not one that would 
    be challenged without a detailed market analysis, the Agencies analyze 
    the agreement in greater depth. The Agencies typically define relevant 
    markets and calculate market shares and concentration as an initial 
    step in assessing whether the agreement may create or increase market 
    power 31 or facilitate its exercise and thus poses risks to 
    competition.32 The Agencies examine factors relevant to the 
    extent to which the participants and the collaboration have the ability 
    and incentive to compete independently, such as whether an agreement is 
    exclusive or non-exclusive and its duration.33 The Agencies 
    also evaluate whether entry would be timely, likely, and sufficient to 
    deter or counteract any anticompetitive harms. In addition, the 
    Agencies assess any other market circumstances that may foster or 
    impede anticompetitive harms.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \31\ Market power to a seller is the ability profitably to 
    maintain prices above competitive levels for a significant period of 
    time. Sellers also may exercise market power with respect to 
    significant competitive dimensions other than price, such as 
    quality, service, or innovation. Market power to a buyer is the 
    ability profitably to depress the price paid for a product below the 
    competitive level for a significant period of time and thereby 
    depress output.
        \32\ See Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services, Inc., 
    504 U.S. 451, 464 (1992).
        \33\ Compare NCAA, 468 U.S. at 113-15, 119-20 (noting that 
    colleges were not permitted to televise their own games without 
    restraint), with Broadcast Music, 441 U.S. at 23-24 (finding no 
    legal or practical impediment to individual licenses).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        If the examination of these factors indicates no potential for 
    anticompetitive harm, the Agencies end the investigation without 
    considering procompetitive benefits. If investigation indicates 
    anticompetitive harm, the Agencies examine whether the relevant 
    agreement is reasonably necessary to achieve procompetitive benefits 
    that likely would offset anticompetitive harms.34
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \34\ See NCAA, 468 U.S. at 113-15 (rejecting efficiency claims 
    when production was limited, not enhanced); Prof'l. Eng'rs, 435 U.S. 
    at 696 (dictum) (distinguishing restraints that promote competition 
    from those that eliminate competition); Chicago Bd. of Trade, 246 
    U.S. at 238 (same).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    3.31  Nature of the Relevant Agreement: Business Purpose, Operation 
    in the Marketplace and Possible Competitive Concerns
    
        The nature of the agreement is relevant to whether it may cause 
    anticompetitive harm. For example, by limiting independent decision 
    making or combining control over or financial interests in production, 
    key assets, or decisions on price, output, or other competitively 
    sensitive variables, an agreement may create or increase market power 
    or facilitate its exercise by the collaboration, its participants, or 
    both. An agreement to limit independent decision making or to combine 
    control or financial interests may reduce the ability or incentive to 
    compete independently. An agreement also may increase the likelihood of 
    an exercise of market power by facilitating explicit or tacit 
    collusion,35 either through facilitating practices such as 
    an exchange of competitively sensitive information or through increased 
    market concentration.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \35\ As used in these Guidelines, ``collusion'' is not limited 
    to conduct that involves an agreement under the antitrust laws.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In examining the nature of the relevant agreement, the Agencies 
    take into account inferences about business purposes for the agreement 
    that can be drawn from objective facts. The Agencies also consider 
    evidence of the subjective intent of the participants to the extent 
    that it sheds light on competitive effects.36 The Agencies 
    do not undertake a full analysis of procompetitive benefits pursuant to 
    Section 3.36 below, however, unless an anticompetitive harm appears 
    likely. The Agencies also examine whether an agreement already in 
    operation has caused anticompetitive harm.37 Anticompetitive 
    harm may be observed, for example, if a competitor collaboration 
    successfully mandates new, anticompetitive conduct or successfully 
    eliminates procompetitive pre-collaboration conduct, such as 
    withholding services that were desired by consumers when offered in a 
    competitive market. If anticompetitive harm is found, examination of 
    market power ordinarily is not required. In some cases, however, a 
    determination of anticompetitive harm may be informed by consideration 
    of market power.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \36\ Anticompetitive intent alone does not establish an 
    antitrust violation, and procompetitive intent does not preclude a 
    violation. See, e.g., Chicago Bd. of Trade, 246 U.S. at 238. But 
    extrinsic evidence of intent may aid in evaluating market power, the 
    likelihood of anticompetitive harm, and claimed procompetitive 
    justifications where an agreement's effects are otherwise ambiguous.
        \37\ See id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The following sections illustrate competitive concerns that may 
    arise from the nature of particular types of competitor collaborations. 
    This list is not exhaustive. In addition, where these sections address 
    agreements of a type that otherwise might be considered per se illegal, 
    such as agreements on price, the discussion assumes that the agreements 
    already have been determined to be subject to rule of reason analysis 
    because they are reasonably related to, and reasonably necessary to 
    achieve procompetitive benefits from, an efficiency-enhancing 
    integration of economic activity. See supra Section 3.2.
    
    3.31(a)  Relevant Agreements That Limit Independent Decision Making 
    or Combine Control or Financial Interests
    
        The following is intended to illustrate but not exhaust the types 
    of agreements that might harm competition by eliminating independent 
    decision
    
    [[Page 54489]]
    
    making or combining control or financial interests.
        Production Collaborations. Competitor collaborations may involve 
    agreements jointly to produce a product sold to others or used by the 
    participants as an input. Such agreements are often 
    procompetitive.38 Participants may combine complementary 
    technologies, know-how, or other assets to enable the collaboration to 
    produce a good more efficiently or to produce a good that no one 
    participant alone could produce. However, production collaborations may 
    involve agreements on the level of output or the use of key assets, or 
    on the price at which the product will be marketed by the 
    collaboration, or on other competitively significant variables, such as 
    quality, service, or promotional strategies, that can result in 
    anticompetitive harm. Such agreements can create or increase market 
    power or facilitate its exercise by limiting independent decision 
    making or by combining in the collaboration, or in certain 
    participants, the control over some or all production or key assets or 
    decisions about key competitive variables that otherwise would be 
    controlled independently.39 Such agreements could reduce 
    individual participants' control over assets necessary to compete and 
    thereby reduce their ability to compete independently, combine 
    financial interests in ways that undermine incentives to compete 
    independently, or both.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \38\ The NCRPA accords rule of reason treatment to certain 
    production collaborations. However, the statute permits per se 
    challenges, in appropriate circumstances, to a variety of 
    activities, including agreements to jointly market the goods or 
    services produced or to limit the participants' independent sale of 
    goods or services produced outside the collaboration. NCRPA, 15 
    U.S.C. Secs. 4301-02.
        \39\ For example, where output resulting from a collaboration is 
    transferred to participants for independent marketing, 
    anticompetitive harm could result if that output is restricted or if 
    the transfer takes place at a supracompetitive price. Such conduct 
    could raise participants' marginal costs through inflated per-unit 
    charges on the transfer of the collaboration's output. 
    Anticompetitive harm could occur even if there is vigorous 
    competition among collaboration participants in the output market, 
    since all the participants would have paid the same inflated 
    transfer price.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Marketing Collaborations. Competitor collaborations may involve 
    agreements jointly to sell, distribute, or promote goods or services 
    that are either jointly or individually produced. Such agreements may 
    be procompetitive, for example, where a combination of complementary 
    assets enables products more quickly and efficiently to reach the 
    marketplace. However, marketing collaborations may involve agreements 
    on price, output, or other competitively significant variables, or on 
    the use of competitively significant assets, such as an extensive 
    distribution network, that can result in anticompetitive harm. Such 
    agreements can create or increase market power or facilitate its 
    exercise by limiting independent decision making; by combining in the 
    collaboration, or in certain participants, control over competitively 
    significant assets or decisions about competitively significant 
    variables that otherwise would be controlled independently; or by 
    combining financial interests in ways that undermine incentives to 
    compete independently. For example, joint promotion might reduce or 
    eliminate comparative advertising, thus harming competition by 
    restricting information to consumers on price and other competitively 
    significant variables.
        Buying Collaborations. Competitor collaborations may involve 
    agreements jointly to purchase necessary inputs. Many such agreements 
    do not raise antitrust concerns and indeed may be procompetitive. 
    Purchasing collaborations, for example, may enable participants to 
    centralize ordering, to combine warehousing or distribution functions 
    more efficiently, or to achieve other efficiencies. However, such 
    agreements can create or increase market power (which, in the case of 
    buyers, is called ``monopsony power'') or facilitate its exercise by 
    increasing the ability or incentive to drive the price of the purchased 
    product, and thereby depress output, below what likely would prevail in 
    the absence of the relevant agreement. Buying collaborations also may 
    facilitate collusion by standardizing participants' costs or by 
    enhancing the ability to project or monitor a participant's output 
    level through knowledge of its input purchases.
        Research & Development Collaborations. Competitor collaborations 
    may involve agreements to engage in joint research and development 
    (``R&D''). Most such agreements are procompetitive, and they typically 
    are analyzed under the rule of reason.40 Through the 
    combination of complementary assets, technology, or know-how, an R&D 
    collaboration may enable participants more quickly or more efficiently 
    to research and develop new or improved goods, services, or production 
    processes. Joint R&D agreements, however, can create or increase market 
    power or facilitate its exercise by limiting independent decision 
    making or by combining in the collaboration, or in certain 
    participants, control over competitively significant assets or all or a 
    portion of participants' individual competitive R&D efforts. Although 
    R&D collaborations also may facilitate tacit collusion on R&D efforts, 
    achieving, monitoring, and punishing departures from collusion is 
    sometimes difficult in the R&D context.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \40\ See NCRPA, 15 U.S.C. Secs. 4301-02. However, the statute 
    permits per se challenges, in appropriate circumstances, to a 
    variety of activities, including agreements to jointly market the 
    fruits of collaborative R&D or to limit the participants' 
    independent R&D or their sale or licensing of goods, services, or 
    processes developed outside the collaboration. Id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        An exercise of market power may injure consumers by reducing 
    innovation below the level that otherwise would prevail, leading to 
    fewer or no products for consumers to choose from, lower quality 
    products, or products that reach consumers more slowly than they 
    otherwise would. An exercise of market power also may injure consumers 
    by reducing the number of independent competitors in the market for the 
    goods, services, or production processes derived from the R&D 
    collaboration, leading to higher prices or reduced output, quality, or 
    service. A central question is whether the agreement increases the 
    ability or incentive anticompetitively to reduce R&D efforts pursued 
    independently or through the collaboration, for example, by slowing the 
    pace at which R&D efforts are pursued. Other considerations being 
    equal, R&D agreements are more likely to raise competitive concerns 
    when the collaboration or its participants already possess a secure 
    source of market power over an existing product and the new R&D efforts 
    might cannibalize their supracompetitive earnings. In addition, 
    anticompetitive harm generally is more likely when R&D competition is 
    confined to firms with specialized characteristics or assets, such as 
    intellectual property, or when a regulatory approval process limits the 
    ability of late-comers to catch up with competitors already engaged in 
    the R&D.
    
    3.31(b)  Relevant Agreements That May Facilitate Collusion
    
        Each of the types of competitor collaborations outlined above can 
    facilitate collusion. Competitor collaborations may provide an 
    opportunity for participants to discuss and agree on anticompetitive 
    terms, or otherwise to collude anticompetitively, as well as a greater 
    ability to detect and punish deviations that would undermine the 
    collusion. Certain marketing, production, and buying collaborations, 
    for example, may provide opportunities for their participants to 
    collude on price, output,
    
    [[Page 54490]]
    
    customers, territories, or other competitively sensitive variables. R&D 
    collaborations, however, may be less likely to facilitate collusion 
    regarding R&D activities since R&D often is conducted in secret, and it 
    thus may be difficult to monitor an agreement to coordinate R&D. In 
    addition, collaborations can increase concentration in a relevant 
    market and thus increase the likelihood of collusion among all firms, 
    including the collaboration and its participants.
        Agreements that facilitate collusion sometimes involve the exchange 
    or disclosure of information. The Agencies recognize that the sharing 
    of information among competitors may be procompetitive and is often 
    reasonably necessary to achieve the procompetitive benefits of certain 
    collaborations; for example, sharing certain technology, know-how, or 
    other intellectual property may be essential to achieve the 
    procompetitive benefits of an R&D collaboration. Nevertheless, in some 
    cases, the sharing of information related to a market in which the 
    collaboration operates or in which the participants are actual or 
    potential competitors may increase the likelihood of collusion on 
    matters such as price, output, or other competitively sensitive 
    variables. The competitive concern depends on the nature of the 
    information shared. Other things being equal, the sharing of 
    information relating to price, output, costs, or strategic planning is 
    more likely to raise competitive concern than the sharing of 
    information relating to less competitively sensitive variables. 
    Similarly, other things being equal, the sharing of information on 
    current operating and future business plans is more likely to raise 
    concerns than the sharing of historical information. Finally, other 
    things being equal, the sharing of individual company data is more 
    likely to raise concern than the sharing of aggregated data that does 
    not permit recipients to identify individual firm data.
    
    3.32  Relevant Markets Affected by the Collaboration
    
        The Agencies typically identify and assess competitive effects in 
    all of the relevant product and geographic markets in which competition 
    may be affected by a competitor collaboration, although in some cases 
    it may be possible to assess competitive effects directly without 
    defining a particular relevant market(s). Markets affected by a 
    competitor collaboration include all markets in which the economic 
    integration of the participants' operations occurs or in which the 
    collaboration operates or will operate, 41 and may also 
    include additional markets in which any participant is an actual or 
    potential competitor.42
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \41\ For example, where a production joint venture buys inputs 
    from an upstream market to incorporate in products to be sold in a 
    downstream market, both upstream and downstream markets may be 
    ``markets affected by a competitor collaboration.''
        \42\ Participation in the collaboration may change the 
    participants' behavior in this third category of markets, for 
    example, by altering incentives and available information, or by 
    providing an opportunity to form additional agreements among 
    participants.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    3.32(a)  Goods Markets
    
        In general, for goods 43 markets affected by a 
    competitor collaboration, the Agencies approach relevant market 
    definition as described in Section 1 of the Horizontal Merger 
    Guidelines. To determine the relevant market, the Agencies generally 
    consider the likely reaction of buyers to a price increase and 
    typically ask, among other things, how buyers would respond to 
    increases over prevailing price levels. However, when circumstances 
    strongly suggest that the prevailing price exceeds what likely would 
    have prevailed absent the relevant agreement, the Agencies use a price 
    more reflective of the price that likely would have prevailed. Once a 
    market has been defined, market shares are assigned both to firms 
    currently in the relevant market and to firms that are able to make 
    ``uncommitted'' supply responses. See Sections 1.31 and 1.32 of the 
    Horizontal Merger Guidelines.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \43\ The term ``goods'' also includes services.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    3.32(b)  Technology Markets
    
        When rights to intellectual property are marketed separately from 
    the products in which they are used, the Agencies may define technology 
    markets in assessing the competitive effects of a competitor 
    collaboration that includes an agreement to license intellectual 
    property. Technology markets consist of the intellectual property that 
    is licensed and its close substitutes; that is, the technologies or 
    goods that are close enough substitutes significantly to constrain the 
    exercise of market power with respect to the intellectual property that 
    is licensed. The Agencies approach the definition of a relevant 
    technology market and the measurement of market share as described in 
    Section 3.2.2 of the Intellectual Property Guidelines.
    
    3.32(c)  Research and Development: Innovation Markets
    
        In many cases, an agreement's competitive effects on innovation are 
    analyzed as a separate competitive effect in a relevant goods market. 
    However, if a competitor collaboration may have competitive effects on 
    innovation that cannot be adequately addressed through the analysis of 
    goods or technology markets, the Agencies may define and analyze an 
    innovation market as described in Section 3.2.3 of the Intellectual 
    Property Guidelines. An innovation market consists of the research and 
    development directed to particular new or improved goods or processes 
    and the close substitutes for that research and development. The 
    Agencies define an innovation market only when the capabilities to 
    engage in the relevant research and development can be associated with 
    specialized assets or characteristics of specific firms.
    
    3.33  Market Shares and Market Concentration
    
        Market share and market concentration affect the likelihood that 
    the relevant agreement will create or increase market power or 
    facilitate its exercise. The creation, increase, or facilitation of 
    market power will likely increase the ability and incentive profitably 
    to raise price above or reduce output, quality, service, or innovation 
    below what likely would prevail in the absence of the relevant 
    agreement.
        Other things being equal, market share affects the extent to which 
    participants or the collaboration must restrict their own output in 
    order to achieve anticompetitive effects in a relevant market. The 
    smaller the percentage of total supply that a firm controls, the more 
    severely it must restrict its own output in order to produce a given 
    price increase, and the less likely it is that an output restriction 
    will be profitable. In assessing whether an agreement may cause 
    anticompetitive harm, the Agencies typically calculate the market 
    shares of the participants and of the collaboration.44 The 
    Agencies assign a range of market shares to the collaboration. The high 
    end of that range is the sum of the market shares of the collaboration 
    and its participants. The low end is the share of the collaboration in 
    isolation. In general, the Agencies approach the calculation of market 
    share as set forth in Section 1.4 of the Horizontal Merger Guidelines.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \44\ When the competitive concern is that a limitation on 
    independent decision making or a combination of control or financial 
    interests may yield an anticompetitive reduction of research and 
    development, the Agencies typically frame their inquiries more 
    generally, looking to the strength, scope, and number of competing 
    R&D efforts and their close substitutes. See supra Sections 3.31(a) 
    and 3.32(c).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Other things being equal, market concentration affects the 
    difficulties and
    
    [[Page 54491]]
    
    costs of achieving and enforcing collusion in a relevant market. 
    Accordingly, in assessing whether an agreement may increase the 
    likelihood of collusion, the Agencies calculate market concentration. 
    In general, the Agencies approach the calculation of market 
    concentration as set forth in Section 1.5 of the Horizontal Merger 
    Guidelines, ascribing to the competitor collaboration the same range of 
    market shares described above.
        Market share and market concentration provide only a starting point 
    for evaluating the competitive effect of the relevant agreement. The 
    Agencies also examine other factors outlined in the Horizontal Merger 
    Guidelines as set forth below:
        The Agencies consider whether factors such as those discussed in 
    Section 1.52 of the Horizontal Merger Guidelines indicate that market 
    share and concentration data overstate or understate the likely 
    competitive significance of participants and their collaboration.
        In assessing whether anticompetitive harm may arise from an 
    agreement that combines control over or financial interests in assets 
    or otherwise limits independent decision making, the Agencies consider 
    whether factors such as those discussed in Section 2.2 of the 
    Horizontal Merger Guidelines suggest that anticompetitive harm is more 
    or less likely.
        In assessing whether anticompetitive harms may arise from an 
    agreement that may increase the likelihood of collusion, the Agencies 
    consider whether factors such as those discussed in Section 2.1 of the 
    Horizontal Merger Guidelines suggest that anticompetitive harm is more 
    or less likely.
        In evaluating the significance of market share and market 
    concentration data and interpreting the range of market shares ascribed 
    to the collaboration, the Agencies also examine factors beyond those 
    set forth in the Horizontal Merger Guidelines. The following section 
    describes which factors are relevant and the issues that the Agencies 
    examine in evaluating those factors.
    
    3.34  Factors Relevant to the Ability and Incentive of the 
    Participants and the Collaboration to Compete
    
        Competitor collaborations sometimes do not end competition among 
    the participants and the collaboration. Participants may continue to 
    compete against each other and their collaboration, either through 
    separate, independent business operations or through membership in 
    other collaborations. Collaborations may be managed by decision makers 
    independent of the individual participants. Control over key 
    competitive variables may remain outside the collaboration, such as 
    where participants independently market and set prices for the 
    collaboration's output.
        Sometimes, however, competition among the participants and the 
    collaboration may be restrained through explicit contractual terms or 
    through financial or other provisions that reduce or eliminate the 
    incentive to compete. The Agencies look to the competitive benefits and 
    harms of the relevant agreement, not merely the formal terms of 
    agreements among the participants.
        Where the nature of the agreement and market share and market 
    concentration data reveal a likelihood of anticompetitive harm, the 
    Agencies more closely examine the extent to which the participants and 
    the collaboration have the ability and incentive to compete independent 
    of each other. The Agencies are likely to focus on six factors: (a) The 
    extent to which the relevant agreement is non-exclusive in that 
    participants are likely to continue to compete independently outside 
    the collaboration in the market in which the collaboration operates; 
    (b) the extent to which participants retain independent control of 
    assets necessary to compete; (c) the nature and extent of participants' 
    financial interests in the collaboration or in each other; (d) the 
    control of the collaboration's competitively significant decision 
    making; (e) the likelihood of anticompetitive information sharing; and 
    (f) the duration of the collaboration.
        Each of these factors is discussed in further detail below. 
    Consideration of these factors may reduce or increase competitive 
    concern. The analysis necessarily is flexible: the relevance and 
    significance of each factor depends upon the facts and circumstances of 
    each case, and any additional factors pertinent under the circumstances 
    are considered. For example, when an agreement is examined subsequent 
    to formation of the collaboration, the Agencies also examine factual 
    evidence concerning participants' actual conduct.
    
    3.34(a)  Exclusivity
    
        The Agencies consider whether, to what extent, and in what manner 
    the relevant agreement permits participants to continue to compete 
    against each other and their collaboration, either through separate, 
    independent business operations or through membership in other 
    collaborations. The Agencies inquire whether a collaboration is non-
    exclusive in fact as well as in name and consider any costs or other 
    impediments to competing with the collaboration. In assessing 
    exclusivity when an agreement already is in operation, the Agencies 
    examine whether, to what extent, and in what manner participants 
    actually have continued to compete against each other and the 
    collaboration. In general, competitive concern likely is reduced to the 
    extent that participants actually have continued to compete, either 
    through separate, independent business operations or through membership 
    in other collaborations, or are permitted to do so.
    
    3.34(b)  Control Over Assets
    
        The Agencies ask whether the relevant agreement requires 
    participants to contribute to the collaboration significant assets that 
    previously have enabled or likely would enable participants to be 
    effective independent competitors in markets affected by the 
    collaboration. If such resources must be contributed to the 
    collaboration and are specialized in that they cannot readily be 
    replaced, the participants may have lost all or some of their ability 
    to compete against each other and their collaboration, even if they 
    retain the contractual right to do so.45 In general, the 
    greater the contribution of specialized assets to the collaboration 
    that is required, the less the participants may be relied upon to 
    provide independent competition.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \45\ For example, if participants in a production collaboration 
    must contribute most of their productive capacity to the 
    collaboration, the collaboration may impair the ability of its 
    participants to remain effective independent competitors regardless 
    of the terms of the agreement.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    3.34(c)  Financial Interests in the Collaboration or in Other 
    Participants
    
        The Agencies assess each participant's financial interest in the 
    collaboration and its potential impact on the participant's incentive 
    to compete independently with the collaboration. The potential impact 
    may vary depending on the size and nature of the financial interest 
    (e.g., whether the financial interest is debt or equity). In general, 
    the greater the financial interest in the collaboration, the less 
    likely is the participant to compete with the 
    collaboration.46 The Agencies also assess direct equity 
    investments between or among the participants. Such investments may 
    reduce the incentives of the participants to compete with each other. 
    In either case, the analysis is sensitive to the level of financial 
    interest in the collaboration or in another participant relative to the
    
    [[Page 54492]]
    
    level of the participant's investment in its independent business 
    operations in the markets affected by the collaboration.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \46\ Similarly, a collaboration's financial interest in a 
    participant may diminish the collaboration's incentive to compete 
    with that participant.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    3.34(d)  Control of the Collaboration's Competitively Significant 
    Decision Making
    
        The Agencies consider the manner in which a collaboration is 
    organized and governed in assessing the extent to which participants 
    and their collaboration have the ability and incentive to compete 
    independently. Thus, the Agencies consider the extent to which the 
    collaboration's governance structure enables the collaboration to act 
    as an independent decision maker. For example, the Agencies ask whether 
    participants are allowed to appoint members of a board of directors for 
    the collaboration, if incorporated, or otherwise to exercise 
    significant control over the operations of the collaboration. In 
    general, the collaboration is less likely to compete independently as 
    participants gain greater control over the collaboration's price, 
    output, and other competitively significant decisions.47
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \47\ Control may diverge from financial interests. For example, 
    a small equity investment may be coupled with a right to veto large 
    capital expenditures and, thereby, to effectively limit output. The 
    Agencies examine a collaboration's actual governance structure in 
    assessing issues of control.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        To the extent that the collaboration's decision making is subject 
    to the participants' control, the Agencies consider whether that 
    control could be exercised jointly. Joint control over the 
    collaboration's price and output levels could create or increase market 
    power and raise competitive concerns. Depending on the nature of the 
    collaboration, competitive concern also may arise due to joint control 
    over other competitively significant decisions, such as the level and 
    scope of R&D efforts and investment. In contrast, to the extent that 
    participants independently set the price and quantity 48 of 
    their share of a collaboration's output and independently control other 
    competitively significant decisions, an agreement's likely 
    anticompetitive harm is reduced.49
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \48\ Even if prices to consumers are set independently, 
    anticompetitive harms may still occur if participants jointly set 
    the collaboration's level of output. For example, participants may 
    effectively coordinate price increases by reducing the 
    collaboration's level of output and collecting their profits through 
    high transfer prices, i.e., through the amounts that participants 
    contribute to the collaboration in exchange for each unit of the 
    collaboration's output. Where a transfer price is determined by 
    reference to an objective measure not under the control of the 
    participants, (e.g., average price in a different unconcentrated 
    geographic market), competitive concern may be less likely.
        \49\ Anticompetitive harm also is less likely if individual 
    participants may independently increase the overall output of the 
    collaboration.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    3.34(e)  Likelihood of Anticompetitive Information Sharing
    
        The Agencies evaluate the extent to which competitively sensitive 
    information concerning markets affected by the collaboration likely 
    would be disclosed. This likelihood depends on, among other things, the 
    nature of the collaboration, its organization and governance, and 
    safeguards implemented to prevent or minimize such disclosure. For 
    example, participants might refrain from assigning marketing personnel 
    to an R&D collaboration, or, in a marketing collaboration, participants 
    might limit access to competitively sensitive information regarding 
    their respective operations to only certain individuals or to an 
    independent third party. Similarly, a buying collaboration might use an 
    independent third party to handle negotiations in which its 
    participants' input requirements or other competitively sensitive 
    information could be revealed. In general, it is less likely that the 
    collaboration will facilitate collusion on competitively sensitive 
    variables if appropriate safeguards governing information sharing are 
    in place.
    
    3.34(f)  Duration of the Collaboration
    
        The Agencies consider the duration of the collaboration in 
    assessing whether participants retain the ability and incentive to 
    compete against each other and their collaboration. In general, the 
    shorter the duration, the more likely participants are to compete 
    against each other and their collaboration.
    
    3.35  Entry
    
        Easy entry may deter or prevent profitably maintaining price above, 
    or output, quality, service or innovation below, what likely would 
    prevail in the absence of the relevant agreement. Where the nature of 
    the agreement and market share and concentration data suggest a 
    likelihood of anticompetitive harm that is not sufficiently mitigated 
    by any continuing competition identified through the analysis in 
    Section 3.34, the Agencies inquire whether entry would be timely, 
    likely, and sufficient in its magnitude, character and scope to deter 
    or counteract the anticompetitive harm of concern. If so, the relevant 
    agreement ordinarily requires no further analysis.
        As a general matter, the Agencies assess timeliness, likelihood, 
    and sufficiency of committed entry under principles set forth in 
    Section 3 of the Horizontal Merger Guidelines.50 However, 
    unlike mergers, competitor collaborations often restrict only certain 
    business activities, while preserving competition among participants in 
    other respects, and they may be designed to terminate after a limited 
    duration. Consequently, the extent to which an agreement creates 
    opportunities that would induce entry and the conditions under which 
    ease of entry may deter or counteract anticompetitive harms may be more 
    complex and less direct than for mergers and will vary somewhat 
    according to the nature of the relevant agreement. For example, the 
    likelihood of entry may be affected by what potential entrants believe 
    about the probable duration of an anticompetitive agreement. Other 
    things being equal, the shorter the anticipated duration of an 
    anticompetitive agreement, the smaller the profit opportunities for 
    potential entrants, and the lower the likelihood that it will induce 
    committed entry. Examples of other differences are set forth below.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \50\ Committed entry is defined as new competition that requires 
    expenditure of significant sunk costs of entry and exit. See Section 
    3.0 of the Horizontal Merger Guidelines.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        For certain collaborations, sufficiency of entry may be affected by 
    the possibility that entrants will participate in the anticompetitive 
    agreement. To the extent that such participation raises the amount of 
    entry needed to deter or counteract anticompetitive harms, and assets 
    required for entry are not adequately available for entrants to respond 
    fully to their sales opportunities, or otherwise renders entry 
    inadequate in magnitude, character or scope, sufficient entry may be 
    more difficult to achieve.51
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \51\ Under the same principles applied to production and 
    marketing collaborations, the exercise of monopsony power by a 
    buying collaboration may be deterred or counteracted by the entry of 
    new purchasers. To the extent that collaborators reduce their 
    purchases, they may create an opportunity for new buyers to make 
    purchases without forcing the price of the input above pre-relevant 
    agreement levels. Committed purchasing entry, defined as new 
    purchasing competition that requires expenditure of significant sunk 
    costs of entry and exit--such as a new steel factory built in 
    response to a reduction in the price of iron ore--is analyzed under 
    principles analogous to those articulated in Section 3 of the 
    Horizontal Merger Guidelines. Under that analysis, the Agencies 
    assess whether a monopsonistic price reduction is likely to attract 
    committed purchasing entry, profitable at pre-relevant agreement 
    prices, that would not have occurred before the relevant agreement 
    at those same prices. (Uncommitted new buyers are identified as 
    participants in the relevant market if their demand responses to a 
    price decrease are likely to occur within one year and without the 
    expenditure of significant sunk costs of entry and exit. See id. at 
    Sections 1.32 and 1.41.)
    
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [[Page 54493]]
    
        In the context of research and development collaborations, 
    widespread availability of R&D capabilities and the large gains that 
    may accrue to successful innovators often suggest a high likelihood 
    that entry will deter or counteract anticompetitive reductions of R&D 
    efforts. Nonetheless, such conditions do not always pertain, and the 
    Agencies ask whether entry may deter or counteract anticompetitive R&D 
    reductions, taking into account the following:
        Where market participants typically can observe the level and type 
    of R&D efforts within a market, the principles of Section 3 of the 
    Horizontal Merger Guidelines may be applied flexibly to determine 
    whether entry is likely to deter or counteract a lessening of the 
    quality, diversity, or pace of research and development. To be timely, 
    entry must be sufficiently prompt to deter or counteract such harms. 
    The Agencies evaluate the likelihood of entry based on the extent to 
    which potential entrants have (1) core competencies (and the ability to 
    acquire any necessary specialized assets) that give them the ability to 
    enter into competing R&D and (2) incentives to enter into competing R&D 
    in response to a post-collaboration reduction in R&D efforts. The 
    sufficiency of entry depends on whether the character and scope of the 
    entrants' R&D efforts are close enough to the reduced R&D efforts to be 
    likely to achieve similar innovations in the same time frame or 
    otherwise to render a collaborative reduction of R&D unprofitable.
        Where market participants typically cannot observe the level and 
    type of R&D efforts by others within a market, there may be significant 
    questions as to whether entry would occur in response to a 
    collaborative lessening of the quality, diversity, or pace of research 
    and development, since such effects would not likely be observed. In 
    such cases, the Agencies may conclude that entry would not deter or 
    counteract anticompetitive harms.
    
    3.36  Identifying Procompetitive Benefits of the Collaboration
    
        Competition usually spurs firms to achieve efficiencies internally. 
    Nevertheless, as explained above, competitor collaborations have the 
    potential to generate significant efficiencies that benefit consumers 
    in a variety of ways. For example, a competitor collaboration may 
    enable firms to offer goods or services that are cheaper, more valuable 
    to consumers, or brought to market faster than would otherwise be 
    possible. Efficiency gains from competitor collaborations often stem 
    from combinations of different capabilities or resources. See supra 
    Section 2.1. Indeed, the primary benefit of competitor collaborations 
    to the economy is their potential to generate such efficiencies.
        Efficiencies generated through a competitor collaboration can 
    enhance the ability and incentive of the collaboration and its 
    participants to compete, which may result in lower prices, improved 
    quality, enhanced service, or new products. For example, through 
    collaboration, competitors may be able to produce an input more 
    efficiently than any one participant could individually; such 
    collaboration-generated efficiencies may enhance competition by 
    permitting two or more ineffective (e.g., high cost) participants to 
    become more effective, lower cost competitors. Even when efficiencies 
    generated through a competitor collaboration enhance the 
    collaboration's or the participants' ability to compete, however, a 
    competitor collaboration may have other effects that may lessen 
    competition and ultimately may make the relevant agreement 
    anticompetitive.
        If the Agencies conclude that the relevant agreement has caused, or 
    is likely to cause, anticompetitive harm, they consider whether the 
    agreement is reasonably necessary to achieve ``cognizable 
    efficiencies.'' ``Cognizable efficiencies'' are efficiencies that have 
    been verified by the Agencies, that do not arise from anticompetitive 
    reductions in output or service, and that cannot be achieved through 
    practical, significantly less restrictive means. See infra Sections 
    3.36(a) and 3.36(b). Cognizable efficiencies are assessed net of costs 
    produced by the competitor collaboration or incurred in achieving those 
    efficiencies.
    
    3.36(a)  Cognizable Efficiencies Must Be Verifiable and Potentially 
    Procompetitive
    
        Efficiencies are difficult to verify and quantify, in part because 
    much of the information relating to efficiencies is uniquely in the 
    possession of the collaboration's participants. Moreover, efficiencies 
    projected reasonably and in good faith by the participants may not be 
    realized. Therefore, the participants must substantiate efficiency 
    claims so that the Agencies can verify by reasonable means the 
    likelihood and magnitude of each asserted efficiency; how and when each 
    would be achieved; any costs of doing so; how each would enhance the 
    collaboration's or its participants' ability and incentive to compete; 
    and why the relevant agreement is reasonably necessary to achieve the 
    claimed efficiencies (see Section 3.36 (b)). Efficiency claims are not 
    considered if they are vague or speculative or otherwise cannot be 
    verified by reasonable means.
        Moreover, cognizable efficiencies must be potentially 
    procompetitive. Some asserted efficiencies, such as those premised on 
    the notion that competition itself is unreasonable, are insufficient as 
    a matter of law. Similarly, cost savings that arise from 
    anticompetitive output or service reductions are not treated as 
    cognizable efficiencies. See Example 9.
    
    3.36(b)  Reasonable Necessity and Less Restrictive Alternatives
    
        The Agencies consider only those efficiencies for which the 
    relevant agreement is reasonably necessary. An agreement may be 
    ``reasonably necessary'' without being essential. However, if the 
    participants could have achieved or could achieve similar efficiencies 
    by practical, significantly less restrictive means, then the Agencies 
    conclude that the relevant agreement is not reasonably necessary to 
    their achievement. In making this assessment, the Agencies consider 
    only alternatives that are practical in the business situation faced by 
    the participants; the Agencies do not search for a theoretically less 
    restrictive alternative that is not realistic given business realities.
        The reasonable necessity of an agreement may depend upon the market 
    context and upon the duration of the agreement. An agreement that may 
    be justified by the needs of a new entrant, for example, may not be 
    reasonably necessary to achieve cognizable efficiencies in different 
    market circumstances. The reasonable necessity of an agreement also may 
    depend on whether it deters individual participants from undertaking 
    free riding or other opportunistic conduct that could reduce 
    significantly the ability of the collaboration to achieve cognizable 
    efficiencies. Collaborations sometimes include agreements to discourage 
    any one participant from appropriating an undue share of the fruits of 
    the collaboration or to align participants' incentives to encourage 
    cooperation in achieving the efficiency goals of the collaboration. The 
    Agencies assess whether such agreements are reasonably necessary to 
    deter opportunistic conduct that otherwise would likely prevent the 
    achievement of cognizable efficiencies. See Example 10.
    
    3.37  Overall Competitive Effect
    
        If the relevant agreement is reasonably necessary to achieve 
    cognizable
    
    [[Page 54494]]
    
    efficiencies, the Agencies assess the likelihood and magnitude of 
    cognizable efficiencies and anticompetitive harms to determine the 
    agreement's overall actual or likely effect on competition in the 
    relevant market. To make the requisite determination, the Agencies 
    consider whether cognizable efficiencies likely would be sufficient to 
    offset the potential of the agreement to harm consumers in the relevant 
    market, for example, by preventing price increases.52
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \52\ In most cases, the Agencies' enforcement decisions depend 
    on their analysis of the overall effect of the relevant agreement 
    over the short term. The Agencies also will consider the effects of 
    cognizable efficiencies with no short-term, direct effect on prices 
    in the relevant market. Delayed benefits from the efficiencies (due 
    to delay in the achievement of, or the realization of consumer 
    benefits from, the efficiencies) will be given less weight because 
    they are less proximate and more difficult to predict.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Agencies' comparison of cognizable efficiencies and 
    anticompetitive harms is necessarily an approximate judgment. In 
    assessing the overall competitive effect of an agreement, the Agencies 
    consider the magnitude and likelihood of both the anticompetitive harms 
    and cognizable efficiencies from the relevant agreement. The likelihood 
    and magnitude of anticompetitive harms in a particular case may be 
    insignificant compared to the expected cognizable efficiencies, or vice 
    versa. As the expected anticompetitive harm of the agreement increases, 
    the Agencies require evidence establishing a greater level of expected 
    cognizable efficiencies in order to avoid the conclusion that the 
    agreement will have an anticompetitive effect overall. When the 
    anticompetitive harm of the agreement is likely to be particularly 
    large, extraordinarily great cognizable efficiencies would be necessary 
    to prevent the agreement from having an anticompetitive effect overall.
    
    Section 4: Antitrust Safety Zones
    
    4.1  Overview
    
        Because competitor collaborations are often procompetitive, the 
    Agencies believe that ``safety zones'' are useful in order to encourage 
    such activity. The safety zones set out below are designed to provide 
    participants in a competitor collaboration with a degree of certainty 
    in those situations in which anticompetitive effects are so unlikely 
    that the Agencies presume the arrangements to be lawful without 
    inquiring into particular circumstances. They are not intended to 
    discourage competitor collaborations that fall outside the safety 
    zones.
        The Agencies emphasize that competitor collaborations are not 
    anticompetitive merely because they fall outside the safety zones. 
    Indeed, many competitor collaborations falling outside the safety zones 
    are procompetitive or competitively neutral. The Agencies analyze 
    arrangements outside the safety zones based on the principles outlined 
    in Section 3 above.
        The following sections articulate two safety zones. Section 4.2 
    sets out a general safety zone applicable to any competitor 
    collaboration.53 Section 4.3 establishes a safety zone 
    applicable to research and development collaborations whose competitive 
    effects are analyzed within an innovation market. These safety zones 
    are intended to supplement safety zone provisions in the Agencies' 
    other guidelines and statements of enforcement policy.54
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \53\ See Sections 1.1 and 1.3 above.
        \54\ The Agencies have articulated antitrust safety zones in 
    Health Care Statements 7 & 8 and the Intellectual Property 
    Guidelines, as well as in the Horizontal Merger Guidelines. The 
    antitrust safety zones in these other guidelines relate to 
    particular facts in a specific industry or to particular types of 
    transactions.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    4.2  Safety Zone for Competitor Collaborations in General
    
        Absent extraordinary circumstances, the Agencies do not challenge a 
    competitor collaboration when the market shares of the collaboration 
    and its participants collectively account for no more than twenty 
    percent of each relevant market in which competition may be 
    affected.55 The safety zone, however, does not apply to 
    agreements that are per se illegal, or that would be challenged without 
    a detailed market analysis,56 or to competitor 
    collaborations to which a merger analysis is applied.57
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \55\ For purposes of the safety zone, the Agencies consider the 
    combined market shares of the participants and the collaboration. 
    For example, with a collaboration among two competitors where each 
    participant individually holds a 6 percent market share in the 
    relevant market and the collaboration separately holds a 3 percent 
    market share in the relevant market, the combined market share in 
    the relevant market for purposes of the safety zone would be 15 
    percent. This collaboration, therefore, would fall within the safety 
    zone. However, if the collaboration involved three competitors, each 
    with a 6 percent market share in the relevant market, the combined 
    market share in the relevant market for purposes of the safety zone 
    would be 21 percent, and the collaboration would fall outside the 
    safety zone. Including market shares of the participants takes into 
    account possible spillover effects on competition within the 
    relevant market among the participants and their collaboration.
        \56\ See supra notes 28-30 and accompanying text in Section 3.3.
        \57\ See Section 1.3 above.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    4.3  Safety Zone for Research and Development Competition Analyzed 
    in Terms of Innovation Markets
    
        Absent extraordinary circumstances, the Agencies do not challenge a 
    competitor collaboration on the basis of effects on competition in an 
    innovation market where three or more independently controlled research 
    efforts in addition to those of the collaboration possess the required 
    specialized assets or characteristics and the incentive to engage in 
    R&D that is a close substitute for the R&D activity of the 
    collaboration. In determining whether independently controlled R&D 
    efforts are close substitutes, the Agencies consider, among other 
    things, the nature, scope, and magnitude of the R&D efforts; their 
    access to financial support; their access to intellectual property, 
    skilled personnel, or other specialized assets; their timing; and their 
    ability, either acting alone or through others, to successfully 
    commercialize innovations. The antitrust safety zone does not apply to 
    agreements that are per se illegal, or that would be challenged without 
    a detailed market analysis,58 or to competitor 
    collaborations to which a merger analysis is applied.59
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \58\ See supra notes 28-30 and accompanying text in Section 3.3.
        \59\ See Section 1.3 above.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Appendix
    
    Section 1.3
    
    Example 1 (Competitor Collaboration/Merger)
    
    Facts
    
        Two oil companies agree to integrate all of their refining and 
    refined product marketing operations. Under terms of the agreement, the 
    collaboration will expire after twelve years; prior to that expiration 
    date, it may be terminated by either participant on six months' prior 
    notice. The two oil companies maintain separate crude oil production 
    operations.
    
    Analysis
    
        The formation of the collaboration involves an efficiency-enhancing 
    integration of operations in the refining and refined product markets, 
    and the integration eliminates all competition between the participants 
    in those markets. The evaluating Agency likely would conclude that 
    expiration after twelve years does not constitute termination ``within 
    a sufficiently limited period.'' The participants'' entitlement to 
    terminate the collaboration at any time after giving prior notice is 
    not termination by the
    
    [[Page 54495]]
    
    collaboration's ``own specific and express terms.'' Based on the facts 
    presented, the evaluating Agency likely would analyze the collaboration 
    under the Horizontal Merger Guidelines, rather than as a competitor 
    collaboration under these Guidelines. Any agreements restricting 
    competition on crude oil production would be analyzed under these 
    Guidelines.
    
    Section 2.3
    
    Example 2 (Analysis of Individual Agreements/Set of Agreements)
    
    Facts
    
        Two firms enter a joint venture to develop and produce a new 
    software product to be sold independently by the participants. The 
    product will be useful in two areas, biotechnology research and 
    pharmaceuticals research, but doing business with each of the two 
    classes of purchasers would require a different distribution network 
    and a separate marketing campaign. Successful penetration of one market 
    is likely to stimulate sales in the other by enhancing the reputation 
    of the software and by facilitating the ability of biotechnology and 
    pharmaceutical researchers to use the fruits of each other's efforts. 
    Although the software is to be marketed independently by the 
    participants rather than by the joint venture, the participants agree 
    that one will sell only to biotechnology researchers and the other will 
    sell only to pharmaceutical researchers. The participants also agree to 
    fix the maximum price that either firm may charge. The parties assert 
    that the combination of these two requirements is necessary for the 
    successful marketing of the new product. They argue that the market 
    allocation provides each participant with adequate incentives to 
    commercialize the product in its sector without fear that the other 
    participant will free-ride on its efforts and that the maximum price 
    prevents either participant from unduly exploiting its sector of the 
    market to the detriment of sales efforts in the other sector.
    
    Analysis
    
        The evaluating Agency would assess overall competitive effects 
    associated with the collaboration in its entirety and with individual 
    agreements, such as the agreement to allocate markets, the agreement to 
    fix maximum prices, and any of the sundry other agreements associated 
    with joint development and production and independent marketing of the 
    software. From the facts presented, it appears that the agreements to 
    allocate markets and to fix maximum prices may be so intertwined that 
    their benefits and harms ``cannot meaningfully be isolated.'' The two 
    agreements arguably operate together to ensure a particular blend of 
    incentives to achieve the potential procompetitive benefits of 
    successful commercialization of the new product. Moreover, the effects 
    of the agreement to fix maximum prices may mitigate the price effects 
    of the agreement to allocate markets. Based on the facts presented, the 
    evaluating Agency likely would conclude that the agreements to allocate 
    markets and to fix maximum prices should be analyzed as a whole.
    
    Section 2.4
    
    Example 3 (Time of Possible Harm to Competition)
    
    Facts
    
        A group of 25 small-to-mid-size banks formed a joint venture to 
    establish an automatic teller machine network. To ensure sufficient 
    business to justify launching the venture, the joint venture agreement 
    specified that participants would not participate in any other ATM 
    networks. Numerous other ATM networks were forming in roughly the same 
    time period.
        Over time, the joint venture expanded by adding more and more 
    banks, and the number of its competitors fell. Now, ten years after 
    formation, the joint venture has 900 member banks and controls 60% of 
    the ATM outlets in a relevant geographic market. Following complaints 
    from consumers that ATM fees have rapidly escalated, the evaluating 
    Agency assesses the rule barring participation in other ATM networks, 
    which now binds 900 banks.
    
    Analysis
    
        The circumstances in which the venture operates have changed over 
    time, and the evaluating Agency would determine whether the exclusivity 
    rule now harms competition. In assessing the exclusivity rule's 
    competitive effect, the evaluating Agency would take account of the 
    collaboration's substantial current market share and any procompetitive 
    benefits of exclusivity under present circumstances, along with other 
    factors discussed in Section 3.
    
    Section 3.2
    
    Example 4 (Agreement Not to Compete on Price)
    
    Facts
    
        Net-Business and Net-Company are two start-up companies. Each has 
    developed and begun sales of software for the networks that link users 
    within a particular business to each other and, in some cases, to 
    entities outside the business. Both Net-Business and Net-Company were 
    formed by computer specialists with no prior business expertise, and 
    they are having trouble implementing marketing strategies, distributing 
    their inventory, and managing their sales forces. The two companies 
    decide to form a partnership joint venture, NET-FIRM, whose sole 
    function will be to market and distribute the network software products 
    of Net-Business and Net-Company. NET-FIRM will be the exclusive 
    marketer of network software produced by Net-Business and Net-Company. 
    Net-Business and Net-Company will each have 50% control of NET-FIRM, 
    but each will derive profits from NET-FIRM in proportion to the 
    revenues from sales of that partner's products. The documents setting 
    up NET-FIRM specify that Net-Business and Net-Company will agree on the 
    prices for the products that NET-FIRM will sell.
    
    Analysis
    
        Net-Business and Net-Company will agree on the prices at which NET-
    FIRM will sell their individually-produced software. The agreement is 
    one ``not to compete on price,'' and it is of a type that always or 
    almost always tends to raise price or reduce output. The agreement to 
    jointly set price may be challenged as per se illegal, unless it is 
    reasonably related to, and reasonably necessary to achieve 
    procompetitive benefits from, an efficiency-enhancing integration of 
    economic activity.
    
    Example 5 (Specialization without Integration)
    
    Facts
    
        Firm A and Firm B are two of only three producers of automobile 
    carburetors. Minor engine variations from year to year, even within 
    given models of a particular automobile manufacturer, require re-design 
    of each year's carburetor and re-tooling for carburetor production. 
    Firms A and B meet and agree that henceforth Firm A will design and 
    produce carburetors only for automobile models of even-numbered years 
    and Firm B will design and produce carburetors only for automobile 
    models of odd-numbered years. Some design and re-tooling costs would be 
    saved, but automobile manufacturers would face only two suppliers each 
    year, rather than three.
    
    Analysis
    
        The agreement allocates sales by automobile model year and 
    constitutes an agreement ``not to compete on * * * output.'' The 
    participants do not combine production; rather, the
    
    [[Page 54496]]
    
    collaboration consists solely of an agreement not to produce certain 
    carburetors. The mere coordination of decisions on output is not 
    integration, and cost-savings without integration, such as the costs 
    saved by refraining from design and production for any given model 
    year, are not a basis for avoiding per se condemnation. The agreement 
    is of a type so likely to harm competition and to have no significant 
    benefits that particularized inquiry into its competitive effect is 
    deemed by the antitrust laws not to be worth the time and expense that 
    would be required. Consequently, the evaluating Agency likely would 
    conclude that the agreement is per se illegal.
    
    Example 6 (Efficiency-Enhancing Integration Present)
    
    Facts
    
        Compu-Max and Compu-Pro are two major producers of a variety of 
    computer software. Each has a large, world-wide sales department. Each 
    firm has developed and sold its own word-processing software. However, 
    despite all efforts to develop a strong market presence in word 
    processing, each firm has achieved only slightly more than a 10% market 
    share, and neither is a major competitor to the two firms that dominate 
    the word-processing software market.
        Compu-Max and Compu-Pro determine that in light of their 
    complementary areas of design expertise they could develop a markedly 
    better word-processing program together than either can produce on its 
    own. Compu-Max and Compu-Pro form a joint venture, WORD-FIRM, to 
    jointly develop and market a new word-processing program, with expenses 
    and profits to be split equally. Compu-Max and Compu-Pro both 
    contribute to WORD-FIRM software developers experienced with word 
    processing.
    
    Analysis
    
        Compu-Max and Compu-Pro have combined their word-processing design 
    efforts, reflecting complementary areas of design expertise, in a 
    common endeavor to develop new word-processing software that they could 
    not have developed separately. Each participant has contributed 
    significant assets--the time and know-how of its word-processing 
    software developers--to the joint effort. Consequently, the evaluating 
    Agency likely would conclude that the joint word-processing software 
    development project is an efficiency-enhancing integration of economic 
    activity that promotes procompetitive benefits.
    
    Example 7 (Efficiency-Enhancing Integration Absent)
    
    Facts
    
        Each of the three major producers of flashlight batteries has a 
    patent on a process for manufacturing a revolutionary new flashlight 
    battery--the Century Battery--that would last 100 years without 
    requiring recharging or replacement. There is little chance that 
    another firm could produce such a battery without infringing one of the 
    patents. Based on consumer surveys, each firm believes that aggregate 
    profits will be less if all three sold the Century Battery than if all 
    three sold only conventional batteries, but that any one firm could 
    maximize profits by being the first to introduce a Century Battery. All 
    three are capable of introducing the Century Battery within two years, 
    although it is uncertain who would be first to market.
        One component in all conventional batteries is a copper widget. An 
    essential element in each producers' Century Battery would be a zinc, 
    rather than a copper widget. Instead of introducing the Century 
    Battery, the three producers agree that their batteries will use only 
    copper widgets. Adherence to the agreement precludes any of the 
    producers from introducing a Century Battery.
    
    Analysis
    
        The agreement to use only copper widgets is merely an agreement not 
    to produce any zinc-based batteries, in particular, the Century 
    Battery. It is ``an agreement not to compete on * * * output'' and is 
    ``of a type that always or almost always tends to raise price or reduce 
    output.'' The participants do not collaborate to perform any business 
    functions, and there are no procompetitive benefits from an efficiency-
    enhancing integration of economic activity. The evaluating Agency 
    likely would challenge the agreement to use only copper widgets as per 
    se illegal.
    
    Section 3.3
    
    Example 8 (Rule-of-Reason: Agreement Quickly Exculpated)
    
    Facts
    
        Under the facts of Example 4, Net-Business and Net-Company jointly 
    market their independently-produced network software products through 
    NET-FIRM. Those facts are changed in one respect: rather than jointly 
    setting the prices of their products, Net-Business and Net-Company will 
    each independently specify the prices at which its products are to be 
    sold by NET-FIRM. The participants explicitly agree that each company 
    will decide on the prices for its own software independently of the 
    other company. The collaboration also includes a requirement that NET-
    FIRM compile and transmit to each participant quarterly reports 
    summarizing any comments received from customers in the course of NET-
    FIRM's marketing efforts regarding the desirable/undesirable features 
    of and desirable improvements to (1) that participant's product and (2) 
    network software in general. Sufficient provisions are included to 
    prevent the company-specific information reported to one participant 
    from being disclosed to the other, and those provisions are followed. 
    The information pertaining to network software in general is to be 
    reported simultaneously to both participants.
    
    Analysis
    
        Under these revised facts, there is no agreement ``not to compete 
    on price or output.'' Absent any agreement of a type that always or 
    almost always tends to raise price or reduce output, and absent any 
    subsequent conduct suggesting that the firms did not follow their 
    explicit agreement to set prices independently, no aspect of the 
    partnership arrangement might be subjected to per se analysis. Analysis 
    would continue under the rule of reason.
        The information disclosure arrangements provide for the sharing of 
    a very limited category of information: customer-response data 
    pertaining to network software in general. Collection and sharing of 
    information of this nature is unlikely to increase the ability or 
    incentive of Net-Business or Net-Company to raise price or reduce 
    output, quality, service, or innovation. There is no evidence that the 
    disclosure arrangements have caused anticompetitive harm and no 
    evidence that the prohibitions against disclosure of firm-specific 
    information have been violated. Under any plausible relevant market 
    definition, Net-Business and Net-Company have small market shares, and 
    there is no other evidence to suggest that they have market power. In 
    light of these facts, the evaluating Agency would refrain from further 
    investigation.
    
    Section 3.36(a)
    
    Example 9 (Cost Savings from Anticompetitive Output or Service 
    Reductions)
    
    Facts
    
        Two widget manufacturers enter a marketing collaboration. Each will 
    continue to manufacture and set the
    
    [[Page 54497]]
    
    price for its own widget, but the widgets will be promoted by a joint 
    sales force. The two manufacturers conclude that through this 
    collaboration they can increase their profits using only half of their 
    aggregate pre-collaboration sales forces by (1) taking advantage of 
    economies of scale--presenting both widgets during the same customer 
    call--and (2) refraining from time-consuming demonstrations 
    highlighting the relative advantages of one manufacturer's widgets over 
    the other manufacturer's widgets. Prior to their collaboration, both 
    manufacturers had engaged in the demonstrations.
    
    Analysis
    
        The savings attributable to economies of scale would be cognizable 
    efficiencies. In contrast, eliminating demonstrations that highlight 
    the relative advantages of one manufacturer's widgets over the other 
    manufacturer's widgets deprives customers of information useful to 
    their decision making. Cost savings from this source arise from an 
    anticompetitive output or service reduction and would not be cognizable 
    efficiencies.
    
    Section 3.36(b)
    
    Example 10 (Efficiencies From Restrictions on Competitive 
    Independence)
    
    Facts
    
        Under the facts of Example 6, Compu-Max and Compu-Pro decide to 
    collaborate on developing and marketing word-processing software. The 
    firms agree that neither one will engage in R&D for designing word-
    processing software outside of their WORD-FIRM joint venture. Compu-Max 
    papers drafted during the negotiations cite the concern that absent a 
    restriction on outside word-processing R&D, Compu-Pro might withhold 
    its best ideas, use the joint venture to learn Compu-Max's approaches 
    to design problems, and then use that information to design an improved 
    word-processing software product on its own. Compu-Pro's files contain 
    similar documents regarding Compu-Max.
        Compu-Max and Compu-Pro further agree that neither will sell its 
    previously designed word-processing program once their jointly 
    developed product is ready to be introduced. Papers in both firms' 
    files, dating from the time of the negotiations, state that this latter 
    restraint was designed to foster greater trust between the participants 
    and thereby enable the collaboration to function more smoothly. As 
    further support, the parties point to a recent failed collaboration 
    involving other firms who sought to collaborate on developing and 
    selling a new spread-sheet program while independently marketing their 
    older spread-sheet software.
    
    Analysis
    
        The restraints on outside R&D efforts and on outside sales both 
    restrict the competitive independence of the participants and could 
    cause competitive harm. The evaluating Agency would inquire whether 
    each restraint is reasonably necessary to achieve cognizable 
    efficiencies. In the given context, that inquiry would entail an 
    assessment of whether, by aligning the participants' incentives, the 
    restraints in fact are reasonably necessary to deter opportunistic 
    conduct that otherwise would likely prevent achieving cognizable 
    efficiency goals of the collaboration.
        With respect to the limitation on independent R&D efforts, possible 
    alternatives might include agreements specifying the level and quality 
    of each participant's R&D contributions to WORD-FIRM or requiring the 
    sharing of all relevant R&D. The evaluating Agency would assess whether 
    any alternatives would permit each participant to adequately monitor 
    the scope and quality of the other's R&D contributions and whether they 
    would effectively prevent the misappropriation of the other 
    participant's know-how. In some circumstances, there may be no 
    ``practical, significantly less restrictive'' alternative.
        Although the agreement prohibiting outside sales might be 
    challenged as per se illegal if not reasonably necessary for achieving 
    the procompetitive benefits of the integration discussed in Example 6, 
    the evaluating Agency likely would analyze the agreement under the rule 
    of reason if it could not adequately assess the claim of reasonable 
    necessity through limited factual inquiry. As a general matter, 
    participants' contributions of marketing assets to the collaboration 
    could more readily be monitored than their contributions of know-how, 
    and neither participant may be capable of misappropriating the other's 
    marketing contributions as readily as it could misappropriate know-how. 
    Consequently, the specification and monitoring of each participant's 
    marketing contributions could be a ``practical, significantly less 
    restrictive'' alternative to prohibiting outside sales of pre-existing 
    products. The evaluating Agency, however, would examine the experiences 
    of the failed spread-sheet collaboration and any other facts presented 
    by the parties to better assess whether such specification and 
    monitoring would likely enable the achievement of cognizable 
    efficiencies.
    
    [FR Doc. 99-26032 Filed 10-5-99; 8:45 am]
    BILLING CODE 6750-01-P
    
    
    

Document Information

Published:
10/06/1999
Department:
Federal Trade Commission
Entry Type:
Notice
Action:
Notice.
Document Number:
99-26032
Dates:
Views should be submitted in writing as specified below by January 5, 2000.
Pages:
54484-54497 (14 pages)
PDF File:
99-26032.pdf