2024-25534. Negative Option Rule  

  • Table 1—Summary of Total Quantified Benefits and Costs

    [In millions, 2023 dollars]

    Low High
    Present Discounted Value over 10 years, 2% discount rate
    Benefits $6,133.57 $49,315.39
    Costs 100.89 826.15
    Net Benefits 5,307.43 49,214.50
    Annualized over 10 years, 2% discount rate
    Benefits 682.83 5,490.11
    Costs 11.23 91.97
    Net Benefits 590.86 5,478.88

    (b) Benefits of the Final Rule

    This section describes the beneficial impacts of the Rule, provides quantitative estimates where possible, and describes benefits that are only assessed qualitatively.

    The quantifiable estimates reflect benefits stemming from the decreased amount of time and effort consumers will need to expend cancelling subscriptions, and in contexts where data are available, welfare gains from avoided expenditure for unwanted subscriptions, under the final Rule relative to marketers' compliance with the existing regulatory baseline. This section first estimates per-consumer savings from cancellation mechanisms that would become at least as easy to use as the mechanisms through which consent to the negative option transactions was given and then estimates the number of cancellation transactions to which those benefits apply.

    In addition to these quantified benefits, there are several benefits we do not quantify. First, marketers' compliance with the final Rule is likely to improve consumer confidence in using subscriptions [538] and increase the number of consumers who are willing to subscribe and obtain the convenience, and often cost savings, that subscriptions can provide. Second, research in economics and psychology finds the perceived monetary and psychological costs from switching products or services can lead consumers to make sub-optimal decisions. The final Rule, by reducing these costs through simpler cancellation methods, may improve consumer decision-making by reducing enrollments in subscriptions that consumers do not value and increasing enrollments in subscriptions that they do value.[539] Marketers' compliance with the final Rule, and the consumer confidence that compliance inspires, may also “exert additional competitive pressures on businesses who offer subscription contracts (and) could increase productivity in the sector.” [540]

    Compliance with the final Rule may also result in some allocative effects when consumers can cancel online instead of by telephone. In such cases, consumers will be able to cancel subscriptions at times of the day that may be more convenient to them than the hours that subscription sellers staff their telephone lines and from devices that they find more convenient to use than telephones.[541]

    ( print page 90520)

    Finally, the Commission's estimates of quantified benefits are based on reductions in time and effort from cancelling subscriptions to non-business consumers. The Commission expects small businesses may also benefit in similar ways from less costly cancellations, but it does not quantify such benefits due to lack of data on business cancellation transactions.

    The following subsections then estimate the quantified benefits from reductions in time and effort from cancelling subscriptions. First, in subsection (1), the Commission estimates the per-cancellation benefit relative to the regulatory baseline for (i) online cancellation when only ROSCA-compliant telephonic cancellation was available, (ii) simpler online cancellation when only ROSCA-compliant online cancellation was available, (iii) simpler telephone cancellation when only TSR-compliant cancellation was available, and (iv) online or telephone cancellation when only in-person or mail cancellation was available. The Commission then estimates the number of cancellation transactions in subsection (2), and finally calculates benefits as the per-cancellation benefit in each scenario multiplied by the number of affected transactions in subsection (3).

    (1) Estimating Per-Cancellation Benefits

    For each of the four scenarios below, the Commission estimates a range of benefits that a consumer will gain each time they cancel a negative option subscription. In these scenarios, the Commission assumes a final Rule-compliant online cancellation should take no more than 30 seconds to one minute, based on the Commission's experience that the average time for consumers to read required disclosures and provide consent to a negative option plan online is 30 seconds to one minute. For telephone cancellations under the final Rule, the Commission assumes that a rule-compliant cancellation should take no more than one to two minutes, based on the assumption it takes a telemarketer twice as long to read required disclosures to a consumer as it would take a consumer to read such disclosures to his or herself online.

    (a) Estimated Per-Cancellation Benefit Relative to ROSCA-Compliant Telephonic Cancellation

    For consumers enrolling in negative option plans online, the existing regulatory baseline, ROSCA, requires marketers to provide “simple” cancellation mechanisms. A facially ROSCA-compliant, “simple” telephonic cancellation may, nonetheless, require more time and effort from consumers than was expended when enrolling in the negative option plan. Online subscription sellers' compliance with the final Rule will save consumers that extra measure of time and effort.

    To estimate the average time savings to consumers of a final Rule-compliant “click-to-cancel” mechanism compared to a ROSCA-compliant simple telephonic cancellation, this analysis first assumes that ROSCA-compliant simple telephonic cancellations take no more time than the “average handle time” for all customer service requests made to call centers, which an industry source indicates is six minutes and three seconds.[542] As discussed at the beginning of this subsection, the Commission assumes a final Rule-compliant cancellation should take no more than 30 seconds to one minute, saving consumers between five minutes and three seconds and five minutes and 33 seconds per cancellation relative to a simple telephonic cancellation.

    The Commission then assumes consumers, on average, value their non-work time at 82% of the mean hourly wage of $31.48, or $25.81 ( i.e., .82 × $31.48) per hour.[543] Accordingly, the Commission estimates the faster online cancellations the final Rule will provide, relative to ROSCA-compliant telephonic cancellations, will be valued at between $2.17 ( i.e., 5:03 minutes × $25.81/hour) and $2.39 ( i.e., 5:33 minutes × $25.81/hour).

    (b) Estimated Per-Cancellation Benefit Relative to ROSCA-Compliant Online Cancellation

    For online cancellations of online-entered subscriptions, the Commission lacks a source of average cancellation times presumed to be ROSCA-compliant that is as comprehensive as that used for the average handle times of call centers. The Commission relies, instead, on an experiment that involved signing up for 16 online subscriptions between August 2 to October 4, 2022, then canceling each one, and recording the time it took to cancel, as well as the variety of other obstacles faced in canceling.[544] To estimate the average time for online cancellations, the Commission subtracts the time incurred in canceling the three subscriptions that required telephonic cancellation from the aggregate time reported to cancel all 16 subscriptions. This yields an average of two minutes and 4 seconds per online cancellation.[545]

    Based on the Commission staff's experience, the average time needed to read the required disclosures and provide consent to a negative option feature is 30 seconds to one minute. An online cancellation that took no longer than the provision of online consent would therefore save the consumer between one minute and four seconds and one minute and 34 seconds. Valuing consumers' time at $25.81 per ( print page 90521) hour, as assumed above, the final Rule would therefore save consumers who enroll online and cancel online time that they value at between $0.46 ( i.e., 1:04 seconds × $25.81/hour) and $0.67 ( i.e., 1:34 minutes × $25.81/hour).

    (c) Average Per-Cancellation Benefit Relative to TSR-Compliant Cancellation

    For consumers enrolling in negative option plans via telemarketing, the existing regulatory baseline is the TSR. The TSR does not specify a performance standard specific to negative option cancellations. Although egregious cancellation delays can be pleaded against telemarketers under § 310.3(a)(1)(vii) (requiring disclosure of all material terms and conditions of the negative option feature) or § 310.3(a)(2)(ix) (prohibiting misrepresentation directly or by implication of any material aspect of a negative option feature), the final Rule's requirement that the cancellation mechanism be at least as easy to use as the consent mechanism provides cancellation-specificity to negative options sold through telemarketing that is lacking under the existing regulatory baseline. Because telemarketers have substantial discretion in designing and implementing consent processes specific to their programs, telemarketers will have a clear benchmark for the speed with which they must complete a final Rule-compliant cancellation.

    As described at the beginning of this subsection, the Commission assumes it takes telemarketers between one and two minutes to read the required disclosures to consumers and receive their consent for enrollment in a negative option plan. Using the same average handle time measure of six minutes and three seconds used a previous scenario to proxy for baseline time spent for a telephonic cancellation, the Commission assumes the final Rule will save consumers who consent to a negative option sale via telemarketing, and cancel in the same manner, between four minutes and three seconds and five minutes and three seconds. Evaluating that time saving in the same manner as above, compliance with the final Rule results in a per-cancellation time saving that is worth between $1.74 ( i.e., 4:03 minutes × $25.81/hour) and $2.17 ( i.e., 5:03 minutes × $25.81/hour).

    (d) Estimated Per-Cancellation Benefit Related to In-Person Enrollments

    Some sellers market negative option plans in ways that are not covered by ROSCA or the TSR. Those that involve in-person enrollment and only offer in-person or mail cancellation, in particular, may be highly burdensome to consumers. The final Rule requires sellers who offer in-person enrollment to offer at least one alternate cancellation method that consumers may use remotely, e.g., online [546] or via telephone.

    Providing consumers with an alternative to in-person cancellations will give consumers a faster route to cancel a subscription and may also spare some consumers from incurring additional recurring charges which might accrue during the pendency of a slow cancellation mechanism, enabling consumers to reallocate their spending power in directions of greater utility, resulting in allocative efficiencies.

    Unlike negative option transactions entered into online (ROSCA) or by telephone (TSR), the Commission lacks comprehensive experience with negative option plans that require cancellation in person or through the mail. However, because many gym/fitness center/health studio memberships (hereafter, “gym memberships”) are sold via negative options [547] and may require cancellation via certified mail or in person (sometimes even when consumers can enroll online [548] ), the Commission proxies the per-cancellation benefits of an additional, remote, method of cancellation by looking at those benefits in the context of gym memberships.[549]

    As noted in the comment submitted by comment filed by IHRSA,[550] The Global Health & Fitness Association, “many (fitness club) operations allow several options for agreement termination through simple online solutions including online account management, email cancellation requests, and specific online cancellation buttons or forms” and “[m]any of these options are currently available for members who have purchased their membership either online or in person.” IHRSA did not quantify the share of their member organizations that provide such cancellation opportunities or the number or share of consumer cancellation transactions in which online cancellation is available. Accordingly, the Commission assumes the low-end of the range of quantifiable benefits to consumers who purchased negative option plans in person, but could currently cancel online is the same as the same the low-end of the range for consumers who purchased negative option plans online and had access to online cancellations: $0.46 per cancellation.

    Notwithstanding IHRSA's assertion that many fitness clubs offer online cancellation, at least 25 individual consumers submitted comments attesting to the difficulties of canceling gym memberships. Some wrote in general terms of the difficulties consumers experience in canceling such memberships as something that contributed to their support for the Rule. ( print page 90522)

    • “What seems more troublesome tend to be stuff like gym memberships.” [551]
    • “I work dispute resolutions for a bank. I see so many cases where someone is trying to cancel something like a gym membership and, while they can sign up in person, they for some reason have to mail a certified letter to the companies (sic) home office.” [552]
    • “I have experienced so much frustration ending memberships with gyms, online subscriptions, etc. over many years and welcome help in this matter. So many friends I speak to share similar stories of how they were roped into paying for longer memberships and subscriptions that they no longer wanted.” [553]
    • “Many places, like [specific fitness center chain], require you to go in person to cancel—they won't even let you do it over the phone! This harms anyone that may have trouble leaving the house regularly, including disabled folks and parents of small children and those caring for older or ailing family members, not to mention being horribly inconvenient for everyone else.” [554]

    Many others conveyed personal experiences with burdensome gym membership cancellation. The Commission relies upon these comments to estimate the high-end of the range of quantifiable benefits that the final Rule will provide to consumers who purchase negative option plans in-person. Examples of these include:

    • “I had to write a letter and physically mail it to cancel a gym membership I singed [sic] up for on an iPad.” [555]
    • “Recently it took me three days and several hours to cancel a gym membership (that) had taken less than 20 minutes to join, on line [sic].” [556]
    • “I had to go in person 3 different times because the manager wasn't there so [sic] to cancel it.” This consumer attached a screen shot of the gym's cancellation policy, which read, in part, “There is no contract and you are free to cancel your Direct Debit at any time. If you do decide to cancel your membership, you must allow at least 7 days before the fifth of the month to ensure your payment is cancelled and advise Reception of the cancellation.” Both “(a)tleast 7 days before the fifth of the month,” and the failure to specify whether “7 days” is seven business days or seven calendar days introduce considerable uncertainty as to when, precisely, the consumer must tender a cancellation to avoid the next recurring payment.[557]
    • “Years ago, I had signed up for a gym membership, and after a change in job situation, was no longer able to make use of it. Repeated attempts to reach the gym membership department and cancel my membership went unheeded—a [sic] got a classic runaround, and as often forwarded to unattended phone numbers—and I kept racking up monthly bills for a membership I didn't want . . . . It was only through a personal relationship with someone who worked in the corporate office that I was finally able to get past their automatic renewals and effect a cancellation.” [558]
    • “We wanted to cancel the [gym] membership, but when we called and emailed, we were told we couldn't cancel that way. We had to send a certified letter or go in person. We have gone in person twice to try to cancel or [sic] membership and it has been a nightmare.” [559]
    • “Personally, I have been impacted by my local gym's undisclosed policies and shady cancelation policies that have costed me hundreds of dollars.” [560]
    • “They bill you monthly for your gym membership but when you want to cancel your membership that's when the problems arise. You cannot do it over phone or on their website. You have to go into the gym personally to cancel said membership. Not only that I was told that I'd have to go to the gym [home gym] where I signed up in order to cancel membership. I could only imagine what this would be like had I moved out of the state. Please help us stop these practices.” [561]
    • “I am currently trying to cancel a gym membership and have been overwhelmed by how difficult it has been . . . . I just called my gym . . . and the pre-recorded automated answering message literally says there is no direct line to the gym! That's outrageous!!!” [562]
    • “My personal experience is with my gym membership . . . . Getting out of it was terrible, and I'd hate to see it happen to anyone else.” [563]

    Based on these comments, the Commission makes the simplifying assumption that the worst gym membership cancellation experiences involve three failed attempts at cancellation, each costing one hour of time, and that, because of those cancellation failures, three unwanted monthly charges were processed. The Commission assumes a fourth cancellation attempt, also costing one hour of time, succeeds in halting the recurring payments.

    As above, the Commission values consumers' time at $25.81/hour. The typical gym membership costs between $40 and $70 a month.[564] The Commission therefore assumes, at the high-end, consumers incur gym membership cancellation costs of $313.25 ( i.e., (4 × $25.81) + (3 × $70)) in the absence of this Rule.[565] As stated previously, the Commission assumes a final Rule-compliant cancellation should take no more one minute at the high end, which has a value of consumers' non-market time of $0.43. Then, to estimate the high-end avoided burden that such consumers would experience under the final Rule, the Commission takes the difference between the high-end cancellation costs in the absence of this Rule ($313.25) and the high-end final Rule-compliant cancellation costs ($0.43), which equates to $312.82. Accordingly, the low-to-high range of benefits provided by the final Rule to consumers who purchase negative option plans in person or through the mail ranges from $0.46 to $312.78.[566]

    (e) Summary of Per-Cancellation Benefits

    Table 2 presents a summary of the per-cancellation benefit the Commission estimates would result from this final Rule. For subscriptions that are currently cancelled over the phone but would be cancelled online under this final Rule, the Commission estimates ( print page 90523) consumers would experience a benefit of between $2.17 and $2.39 per cancellation. For subscriptions that are currently cancelled online and would move to a simpler online cancellation under this Rule, the Commission estimates consumers would experience a benefit of between $0.46 and $0.67 per cancellation. For subscriptions that are currently cancelled over the phone and would move to a simpler telephone cancellation under this Rule, the Commission estimates consumers would experience a benefit of between $1.74 and $2.17 per cancellation. For subscriptions enrolled in person that would be required to provide online or telephone cancellation under this Rule, the Commission estimates consumers would experience a benefit of between $0.46 and $312.82 per cancellation.

    Table 2—Estimates of Benefit per Cancellation

    [In 2023 dollars]

    Low High
    Phone to Online Cancellation $2.17 $2.39
    Online to Simpler Online Cancellation 0.46 0.67
    Phone to Simpler Phone Cancellation 1.74 2.17
    In-Person to Online or Phone Cancellation 0.46 312.82

    (2) Estimating the Number of Consumer Cancellation Transactions

    (a) Baseline Number of Subscriptions

    The Commission regards “consumers” for the purposes of this analysis as the U.S. population over the age of 18; [567] this is estimated to be 269 million in 2025,[568] the first year in the ten-year period over which the Commission estimates the benefits and costs of the final Rule (“Year 1”).

    Because negative option sales are a form of marketing of goods and services, and not an industry or type of output, and because no occupational category is uniquely associated with negative option marketing, no publicly produced data source, such as the Economic Census, tracks the use of negative option marketing in the United States. Accordingly, the Commission must look to other data sources, to estimate the number of subscription cancellations and the channels through which consumer consent was obtained and cancellation mechanisms provided.

    To estimate the aggregate number of consumer cancellation transactions, the Commission relies upon a credible source that found that, as of mid-2023, 83% of American consumers had at least one subscription.[569] The Commission assumes, for the purposes of this analysis, that the percentage of American consumers with at least one subscription remains constant over ten years. Accordingly, in Year 1 the Commission assumes 223.27 million consumers ( i.e.,.83 × 269 million) have at least one subscription.

    To estimate the total number of subscriptions held by U.S. consumers the Commission looks to data on the average number of subscriptions per subscriber. One source, relying upon a large sample of U.S. consumers conducted in late 2023 and early 2024, reported, “[t]he average subscriber now has 4.5 subscriptions.” [570] The Commission therefore applies a multiplier of 4.5 to the number of consumers estimated to have at least one subscription to estimate the aggregate number of subscriptions held by consumers in each year. Continuing with the Year 1 example from above, the Commission assumes the 223.27 million U.S. consumers who have subscriptions collectively hold 1,004,715 subscriptions ( i.e., 223.27 million × 4.5). The Commission acknowledges some uncertainty in these estimates which could lead to overestimation since subscriptions may be held by households of multiple individual consumers or underestimation due to potential growth in subscription-based goods and services.

    (b) Baseline Number of Cancellations

    The Commission next considers how many subscriptions consumers may want to cancel. To do so, we look to subscription “churn,” or cancellation, rate data. Churn rates can reflect intentional cancellations as when a consumer completes a merchant's cancellation process, but can also reflect involuntary or passive cancellations, which occur when the payment mechanism the consumer has on file with the merchant is unable to be processed by the merchant.[571] Churn rates may be calculated on a monthly, quarterly, or annual basis,[572] and some rates do not disclose a time dimension; mischaracterizing a monthly churn rate as an annual churn rate could vastly underestimate the volume of annual cancellations.

    One source reports an aggregate measure of voluntary [573] churn of 3% per month.[574] The Commission assumes ( print page 90524) this rate is constant from month to month and from year to year and therefore assume that the average annual churn rate across all subscriptions is 36%.[575] This churn rate, multiplied by the number of subscriptions held by consumers each year, provides the yearly estimate of how many subscriptions are cancelled by consumers.[576] Continuing with the Year 1 example from above, the Commission therefore estimates 361.70 million cancellations ( i.e.,. 36 × 1,004.72 million) will occur in Year 1 of the analysis and that this number will increase to 384.82 million by Year 10. Table 3 presents the number of subscriptions and total number of cancellations expected in each year.

    Table 3—Number of Subscriptions and Total Cancellations per Year

    [In millions]

    Year Subscriptions Cancellations
    1 1,004.72 361.70
    2 1,012.48 364.49
    3 1,020.25 367.29
    4 1,028.02 370.09
    5 1,035.79 372.88
    6 1,043.56 375.68
    7 1,049.91 377.97
    8 1,056.26 380.25
    9 1,062.61 382.54
    10 1,068.96 384.82

    (c) Number of Cancellations by Enrollment and Baseline Cancellation Method

    As discussed in the estimates of per-cancellation benefits, the estimated per-cancellation benefits stemming from the final Rule depend on the regulatory baseline cancellation methods relative to those that would be made available under the final Rule. To determine the number of cancellations for which the four categories of per-cancellation benefits estimates would apply, the Commission uses data on its enforcement experience to determine the share of cancellations likely to occur through online and telephone methods. For cancellations of subscriptions that are enrolled in person, the Commission uses data on gym membership cancellations as a proxy.

    (i) In-Person Subscriptions

    As a proxy for the number of subscriptions entered into in person, the Commission uses a report from Renew Bariatrics that claims 19 percent of the U.S. population are members of gyms or health clubs.[577] The Commission assumes gym members are uniformly distributed by age and multiplies the U.S. adult population by 19 percent to estimate that 51.11 million adults will have active gym membership subscriptions when this final Rule goes into effect. An IHRSA article from 2019 stated the average health club has an annual attrition rate of 28.6 percent.[578] Interpreting this to mean 28.6 percent of all adult gym members cancel their memberships each year, the Commission estimates 14.62 million gym membership subscriptions will be cancelled in the first year of this Rule. In Year 10, the Commission estimates 15.55 million gym membership subscriptions will be cancelled. The Commission uses these estimates as a proxy for the total number of subscriptions that are entered into in person and cancelled each year.

    The Commission acknowledges several limitations with this proxy. To begin, there are likely many other types of businesses, such as car washes, lawn care, pest control, and personal care and grooming establishments, that may offer in-person subscription enrollment. To the extent these subscriptions are not included in the count, the estimates may be understated. Further, the source that states 19 percent of the population are members of gyms does not specify the age distribution of the gym members. The Commission has assumed children and adults are distributed uniformly across that 19 percent; however, if adults are more likely to have gym memberships than children, the estimates of gym memberships and cancellations among adults will be understated. On the other hand, gym memberships are not always individual memberships; multiple family members may share a single-family membership. In estimating the number of gym memberships and cancellations, the Commission has assumed each adult gym member has their own subscription, which may overestimate the number of subscriptions and cancellations.

    (ii) Online and Telephone Subscriptions

    The Commission assumes all subscriptions that are not entered into in person are instead entered into either online or over the phone. Subtracting the in-person subscription, as proxied by gym membership cancellations, from the total number of cancellations, the Commission estimates 347.08 million subscriptions entered into either online or over the phone will be canceled in the first year of this Rule. This number would increase to 369.27 million cancellations in Year 10.

    To estimate the distribution of cancellation methods for these subscriptions that are entered into online and over the phone, the Commission reviewed matters it has brought and resolved [579] in which complaints specifically alleged negative option cancellation mechanisms that violated ROSCA, the TSR, or section 5.[580] The Commission found 54 matters met these criteria.

    Online [581] enrollment was possible in 42 of 54 matters that met the review ( print page 90525) criteria. In the remaining 12 matters, enrollment occurred over the phone. Among the 42 matters in which online enrollment was possible, only six firms offered online [582] cancellation,[583] and the remaining 36 firms offered only telephonic cancellation.[584] Among the 12 matters in which enrollment occurred over the telephone; none of the firms offered online cancellation, therefore, the Commission treats these 12 matters as if only telephone cancellation was available.[585] To summarize, the Commission finds that, among subscriptions that are entered into online and over the phone, 66.7 percent ( i.e., 36/54) offered online enrollment and only telephone cancellation, 11.1 percent ( i.e., 6/54) offered online enrollment and online cancellation, and 22.2 percent ( i.e., 12/54) offered telephone enrollment and telephone cancellation. Extrapolating the baseline cancellation methods from enforcement matters may weight the online enrollment/telephone cancellation subscriptions and the telephone enrollment/telephone cancellation subscriptions more heavily than is currently experienced in the market. It also assumes that there are no subscriptions offered in the baseline with cancellation methods that are already compliant with the provisions of this Rule. The Commission explores the impacts of these limitations in a sensitivity analysis in section (d).

    Multiplying the distribution of cancellation methods for subscriptions entered into online and over the phone by the total number of cancellations of online and telephone subscriptions, the Commission estimates the annual number of cancellations that fall into each of these categories. In Year 1, the Commission estimates that, in the absence of this final Rule, there would be 231.39 million cancellations by telephone of subscriptions entered into online, 38.56 million online cancellations of subscriptions entered into online, and 77.13 million telephone cancellations of subscriptions entered into over the phone.

    (iii) Summary of Subscription Cancellations by Enrollment and Baseline Cancellation Method

    Table 4 provides the number of subscription cancellations each year distributed across the four enrollment and regulatory baseline cancellation method categories: online enrollment and telephone cancellation; online enrollment and online cancellation; telephone enrollment and telephone cancellation; and in-person enrollment.

    Table 4—Cancellations by Enrollment and Baseline Cancellation Method

    [In millions]

    Year Online enrollment, telephone cancellation Online enrollment, online cancellation Telephone enrollment, telephone cancellation In-person enrollment
    1 231.39 38.56 77.13 14.62
    2 233.18 38.86 77.73 14.73
    3 234.96 39.16 78.32 14.84
    4 236.75 39.46 78.92 14.96
    5 238.54 39.76 79.51 15.07
    6 240.33 40.06 80.11 15.18
    7 241.79 40.30 80.60 15.27
    8 243.26 40.54 81.09 15.37
    9 244.72 40.79 81.57 15.46
    10 246.18 41.03 82.06 15.55

    (3) Total Quantified Benefits

    To estimate total benefits from this final Rule, the Commission first matches the enrollment and baseline cancellation method categories from the previous section to the four scenarios used to estimate the per-cancellation benefit. The Commission assumes that, under this final Rule, subscriptions enrolled online and cancelled over the phone in the baseline would move to online cancellations; subscriptions enrolled online and cancelled online would move to simpler online cancellation; subscriptions enrolled over the phone and cancelled over the phone would move to simpler telephone cancellation; and subscriptions enrolled in person would allow online or phone cancellation.

    Next, the Commission multiplies the number of cancellations in each baseline category by the matched per-cancellation benefit on the low- and the high-end and then sums across all four categories to obtain total benefits each year. Those totals are presented in Table 5. In the first year following implementation of the final Rule, the Commission estimates the benefits will ( print page 90526) range between $661.52 million and $5.32 billion. In Year 10, the Commission estimates the benefits will range between $703.82 million and $5.66 billion. Using a 2 percent discount rate, the Commission estimates the present discounted value of benefits over 10 years to range between $6.13 and $49.32 billion. Annualized over 10 years using a 2 percent discount rate, the Commission estimates the benefits to range between $682.83 million and $5.49 billion per year.

    Table 5—Total Quantified Benefits

    [In millions, 2023 dollars]

    Year Low High
    1 $661.52 $5,318.76
    2 666.63 5,359.88
    3 671.75 5,401.01
    4 676.86 5,442.14
    5 681.98 5,483.26
    6 687.09 5,524.39
    7 691.27 5,558.00
    8 695.45 5,591.62
    9 699.63 5,625.23
    10 703.82 5,658.84
    Present Discounted Value of Benefits over 10 years, 2% discount rate 6,133.57 49,315.39
    Annualized Benefits over 10 years, 2% discount rate 682.83 5,490.11

    (c) Estimated Costs of the Final Rule

    This section describes the costs associated with firms coming into compliance with the final Rule, provides quantitative estimates where possible, and describes costs that are only assessed qualitatively. Whereas benefits were estimated based on cancellation transactions, compliance costs are estimated on the basis of firms covered by the final Rule. The Commission first examines the comment record on compliance costs and then estimates the compliance costs for the initial year and subsequent nine years following implementation of the final Rule.

    (1) The Comment Record

    The comment record has not provided specific data useful to the estimation of the costs of compliance with the disclosure, cancellation, and recordkeeping requirements of the final Rule.

    Some industry commenters addressed compliance costs by providing broad, aggregate, conclusory cost estimates; because those costs were not itemized by specific features of the Rule as proposed in the NPRM, the Commission is unable to use those comments to estimate compliance costs relevant to the substantially narrowed scope of the final Rule in comparison to the Rule proposed in the NPRM.[586] The same is generally true of testimony and expert reports submitted in conjunction with the informal hearing. Those materials did not focus on providing specific, relevant, data that would permit estimating compliance costs of the final Rule.[587]

    ( print page 90527)

    Another commenter addressed the Paperwork Reduction Act cost estimate in the NPRM in a way that conflated it with the totality of compliance costs. IFA, which represents firms, including small firms, in the fitness, preventative healthcare, personal wellness or children's extracurricular activities industries, commented, “the FTC's estimate (in the NPRM) that it will cost companies merely three hours annually at $22.15/hr to comply is grossly understated for IFA's members.” [588] The Commission agrees the final Rule's compliance costs will exceed the Paperwork Reduction Act costs discussed in the NPRM because the Paperwork Reduction Act costs only include burden associated with information collection requirements, such as recordkeeping and disclosure costs, while the total compliance costs include those costs as well as costs of familiarization with the Rule and costs to bring cancellation mechanisms into compliance. IFA did not, however, provide a sufficiently detailed alternative estimate of annual or ongoing general compliance or recordkeeping costs for its members.[589] Similarly, IFA provided no information on the enrollment mechanisms used by its members nor an estimate of what share of its members offer negative option plans.[590]

    IFA did, however, comment that many of its members already offer consumers the ability to pause or “freeze” memberships, noting, “consumers take advantage of alternatives to membership cancellation at rates of 10% to 40%, with many consumers electing to reactivate their memberships, saving thousands of dollars annually in increased membership rates and additional initiation fees.” While pause/freeze capabilities are indeed beneficial to consumers, they do not relieve a firm from an obligation to offer a cancellation mechanism. IFA did not provide similar data on what percentage of its member firms' consumers are dissatisfied with pause/freeze opportunities and seek authentic cancellations or what cancellation mechanisms its member firms make available to consumers.

    The technological capability to pause or freeze subscriptions suggests the presence of software architecture “scaffolding” upon which a cancellation mechanism could be built at a modest incremental cost. Alternatively, the offering of subscription pauses or freezes by some IFA members may suggest those members use the services of third-party e-commerce hosting platforms or payment processors who routinely provide consumer subscription account management tools relied on by businesses, including small businesses. As discussed, below, existing software scaffolding and the utilization of third-party consumer subscription management tools can facilitate low- (and even no-) cost compliance with some of the final Rule's requirements.

    (2) Initial Compliance Costs

    The Commission has previously estimated that 106,000 firms offer negative option plans.[591] The Commission assumes that to come into compliance with the final Rule, all 106,000 firms selling negative option plans will need to expend some resources to familiarize themselves with the final Rule and some firms will incur costs related to improvements in their pre-consent disclosures and cancellation mechanisms.

    Familiarization costs: No commenters presented estimates expressly related to the costs of legal and managerial review of the final Rule and front-line staff training needed to come into compliance. The U.K. “Impact Assessment,” using surveys and interviews with managers of firms that sold goods and services via negative options, found that firms would need between four and 16 hours of “senior staff” time, depending upon the size of the firm, to gain familiarization with their proposed rule, and between zero and 80 hours of “service staff” time, again depending upon the size of the firm.[592] The Commission assumes that similarities between American and British firms are such that the same units of time are relevant for American firms to gain familiarity with the final Rule. In the American context, the Commission assumes “senior staff time” is proxied by “attorney time,” and uses the mean hourly wage for attorneys, $84.84 per hour, to estimate those costs.[593] Similarly, the Commission assumes “service staff time” is proxied by the average of mean wages for salespersons and clerical workers, which is $23.27.[594] Accordingly, the ( print page 90528) Commission estimates the aggregate initial year familiarization costs as ranging between $35.97 million and $341.22 million.

    Disclosures: Clear and conspicuous disclosures are already required by the existing regulatory baseline; § 425.4(a)(1)-(4) of the final Rule adds specificity to those disclosures, albeit in a flexible way.[595] As estimated below, the Commission assumes some marketers are already in compliance with the disclosure requirements of the final Rule; for these marketers, there are no incremental costs of compliance with the disclosure requirements of the final Rule.

    For online marketers, the current regulatory baseline is ROSCA, which requires marketers to clearly and conspicuously disclose all material terms of the transaction before obtaining the consumer's billing information. To the extent ROSCA-covered marketers' current disclosures lack the specificity required by the final Rule, the Commission estimates changes will be needed only to textual elements of such marketers' websites and that no changes to the underlying website architecture will be needed. The Commission further assumes any such changes, if needed, will be made by website developers, whose mean hourly wage is $45.95.[596] Similarly, some telemarketers and in-person negative option marketers may need to modify their sales agents' scripts to incorporate the disclosures required by the final Rule. Without loss of generality, the Commission assumes the mean wage rates of marketers' staff who will make such script changes is proxied by the mean wage rates of web developers.[597] Although in the Commission's experience these changes should take very little time, perhaps as little as one hour, the Commission adopts a range of one to 10 hours to complete this task.[598]

    Accordingly, the Commission estimates that for those marketers whose disclosures are not already in compliance with the requirements of the final Rule, disclosure compliance costs will range between $45.95 and $459.50.

    Cancellation mechanisms: Section 425.6 of the final Rule requires negative option marketers to provide a simple cancellation mechanism that is in the same medium, and at least as simple for the consumer to use, as the mechanism by which the consumer provided consent to the negative option plan. Additional requirements are medium-specific. For example, when consent is provided through an interactive electronic medium, the cancellation mechanism (also provided through an interactive electronic medium) must be easy for the consumer to find when the consumer seeks cancellation information (for example, on a website, the cancellation mechanism cannot be hidden in “terms and conditions” or otherwise difficult to find) and cannot require interactions with live or virtual representatives (such as chatbots) if no such interactions were required when the consumer consented.

    When consent is provided over the telephone, the final Rule requires that telephonic cancellation must be available during normal business hours and not be more costly for the consumer to use than the telephone call the consumer used to consent to the negative option feature.

    When consumer consent to a negative option plan is provided via an in-person method, the marketer must offer cancellation opportunities, where practical, in a like manner. In addition, the marketer must offer an alternative simple cancellation mechanism through an interactive electronic medium or by providing a telephone number that satisfies all final Rule requirements related to use of those cancellation media.

    The costs negative option sellers will incur in the initial year following implementation of the final Rule to bring their cancellation mechanisms into compliance with the final Rule will depend upon their pre-existing cancellation mechanisms. No commenter provided research or data on the frequency of use of different cancellation mechanisms across negative option marketers or on the incremental costs to make the existing cancellation mechanism compliant with the requirements of the final Rule.[599]

    Because the comment record has not provided sufficient data to estimate the costs of compliance with the final Rule's cancellation requirements, the Commission turns to data from the U.K.'s “Impact Assessment” on regulating subscriptions there. Based on these sources, the Commission finds some sellers of negative option plans are already in compliance with the cancellation requirements of the final Rule, and many others will incur only minimal costs to make their cancellation flows compliant with the final Rule.

    The relevant experimental research looked at the cancellation practices of 16 online subscription sellers, many of them large and well-known firms, and noted the cancellation mechanisms made available to consumers and how easy those mechanisms were for consumers to locate and use.[600] Although the number of firms sampled in this research was small, publicly available data on total enrollments, located for just seven of the 16 firms, collectively numbered over 350 million,[601] which may lend significance ( print page 90529) to this research beyond what might otherwise be associated with a sample size of 16 firms. Moreover, the methodology of the study suggests that the researcher's experiences with enrollment and cancellation likely would be typical of any consumer undertaking the same enrollment and cancellation tasks with those firms.

    The experimental research found that 18.75% ( i.e., 100 × 3/16) of the online marketers studied offered online cancellations in a straightforward, easy to use manner such that it took the researcher less than one minute to complete a subscription cancellation. The Commission therefore assumes that 18.75% of online sellers of negative option plans will not need to change their websites to come into compliance with the cancellation requirements of the final Rule. Although this research did not specifically measure the adequacy of pre-consent disclosures, the Commission assumes that companies who make cancellation so easy for consumers perform equally well in making disclosures. Accordingly, the Commission assumes that the 18.75% of online firms selling negative options that will not incur incremental costs to comply with the final Rule's cancellation requirements also will not incur any incremental costs to comply with the final Rule's disclosure requirements. The Commission assumes that the remaining 81.25% of online negative option sellers that lacked such easy-to-use cancellation mechanisms also performed less well in making the disclosures required by the final Rule, such that they would incur initial year compliance costs of improving their disclosures as indicated by the range estimated above.

    The same research found that 62.5% ( i.e., 100 × 10/16) of sampled online negative option sellers had cancellation paths that took longer for consumers to complete as a result of nomenclature, not website architecture. These sites, rather than using straightforward terms such as “unsubscribe” or “cancel,” put the cancellation path under titles such as “auto-renew” or “edit plan,” [602] and locating the cancellation mechanism delayed the researcher in completing the cancellation task because of the non-intuitive labeling of the entry point into the cancellation mechanism. In such instances, more intuitive, consumer-friendly labeling of the existing cancellation architecture is assumed to be what is needed for these sites to come into compliance with the cancellation requirements of the final Rule. The Commission assumes such relabeling will not require any additional programming or changes to the underlying website architecture. In the Commission's experience, such “cosmetic” changes can be made quickly and inexpensively, possibly in as little as one hour of a website developer's time. The Commission notes, however, that the U.K. “Impact Assessment,” in considering “general updates to websites such as reflecting the clearer communication on contract conditions and updating cancellation options,” estimated that such changes would “require eight hours' work from an IT professional and that these costs are uncorrelated with the size of the business.” [603] The website changes contemplated in that assessment likely exceed those required to merely relabel consumer-facing elements of an existing cancellation architecture. Out of an abundance of caution, however, the Commission uses the U.K.'s estimate of eight hours as an upper bound on the time required to make the needed changes and further assumes that the relevant “IT professionals” are website developers, which, as noted previously, have a mean wage rate of $45.95. Accordingly, the Commission assumes each firm that needs to relabel existing cancellation mechanisms to make those mechanisms easy for consumers to locate and use will spend between $45.95 ( i.e., 1 × $45.95) and $367.60 ( i.e., 8 × $45.95) to come into compliance with the final Rule's cancellation requirements.

    Lastly, the aforementioned research found that 18.75% ( i.e., 100 × 3/16) of online negative option sellers offered only telephonic cancellation. Such firms, because they were online sellers, clearly had online ordering and payment website architecture in place, and so had “scaffolding” upon which online cancellation architecture could be built. No commenter provided relevant data on the costs of building-out a “click-to-cancel” mechanism in such instances, and the U.K “Impact Assessment” indicated it “lacked high quality evidence on the costs businesses would incur” to integrate “easy exiting mechanisms into websites.” As a result, the “Impact Assessment” turned to “external estimates” from “[t]he U.S. eCommerce agency OuterBox [which] indicates a possible range of costs. It suggests that integrating simple tools into an existing eCommerce platform would cost most businesses approximately $500” in 2022.[604] In 2023 dollars, that amount is $532.05.[605] The Commission notes, however, that many payment processors and website hosting platforms used by many businesses, particularly small and medium-sized businesses, provide marketers with consumer subscription account management tools that provide consumers with “click-to-cancel” functionality at no direct [606] incremental cost to marketers.[607] As no commenter ( print page 90530) provided information on (1) how many negative option sellers comply with ROSCA by offering only telephonic cancellation, (2) what specific costs they would face to provide an online cancellation mechanism, or (3) whether they would build such functionality themselves or use a third-party payment processor or hosting platform to provide it for them, we estimate such costs to range between $0 and $532.05 per firm.

    Accordingly, the Commission assumes that most online marketers of negative option plans will face minimal IT costs of coming into compliance with the cancellation requirements of the final Rule.[608]

    As noted previously, telemarketers have substantial control over both how long the consent process takes and how long it takes a consumer to complete a cancellation over the telephone. If compliance with the final Rule expedites the cancellation process over the phone, telemarketers may experience cost-savings associated with such resources. Furthermore, no telemarketers or call centers that provide services to telemarketers submitted comments relating to what costs telemarketers would incur to bring cancellation mechanisms into compliance with the final Rule. Because of this, and because the Commission has previously found that only 2,000 [609] of 106,000 firms selling negative options were telemarketers (and no commenter has disputed this finding), the Commission proceeds as if telemarketers face no incremental costs in complying with the final Rule's cancellation requirements. However, to reduce any potential downward bias [610] this might introduce into the compliance cost estimate, the Commission does not subtract the estimated number of telemarketers (2,000) from the total estimated number of online negative option marketers in its calculations of costs. Similarly, the Commission lacks data on how many of the 106,000 firms selling negative option plans currently offer only in-person or by-mail cancellations.[611] The final Rule requires such firms to add a cancellation mechanism that consumers can easily use in a remote manner, e.g., through interactive electronic media or by telephone.

    Lastly, the Commission considers the initial year recordkeeping costs required by the Rule, which are estimated in section XIII to be $6.54 million when aggregated across all 106,000 firms.

    Because of the aforementioned data limitations emerging from the comment record, the Commission applies the findings of the experimental research above, which looked only at online sellers, to the full number of firms, 106,000, that it has previously estimated to be marketers of negative option plans. This approach comports with a general proposition made by the report submitted by IAB.[612]

    Accordingly, the Commission makes the following estimates of initial year compliance costs.

    Familiarization costs: All 106,000 firms selling negative options will collectively incur final Rule familiarization costs of between $35.97 million and $341.22 million.

    Disclosure costs: 19,875 firms ( i.e.,.1875 × 106,000) will incur no costs in bringing their disclosures into compliance with the requirements of the final Rule because their disclosures are already compliant. The remaining 86,125 firms will collectively incur costs of between $3.96 million ( i.e., $45.95 × 86,125) and $39.58 million ( i.e., $459.50 × 86,125) to make their disclosures compliant with the final Rule.

    Cancellation costs: 19,875 firms ( i.e.,.1875 × 106,000) will incur no costs in bringing their cancellation mechanisms into compliance with the final Rule. 66,250 firms ( i.e.,.625 × 106,000) collectively will incur costs of between $3.04 million ( i.e., 1 × $45.95 × 66,250) and $24.35 million ( i.e., 8 × $45.95 × 66,250) to bring their online cancellation mechanisms into compliance with the final Rule by relabeling consumer-facing elements of their existing cancellation architecture. 19,875 firms ( i.e.,.1875 × 106,000) collectively will incur costs of between $0 and $10.57 million ( i.e., 19,875 × $532.05) to bring their telephonic cancellation mechanisms into compliance with the final Rule.

    The Commission notes that this analysis does not quantify costs for the firms selling negative option plans that offer only in-person or by-mail cancellation. The Commission assumes that, in complying with this final Rule, these firms will choose to provide the alternative cancellation method (by phone, online, or both) that makes the most economic sense. The Commission also assumes that the cost of processing a cancellation over the phone should be similar to or less than the cost of processing a cancellation in person or by-mail for these firms. Therefore, the Commission assumes that these firms will not incur significant compliance ( print page 90531) costs to provide an alternative cancellation method.

    Recordkeeping costs: Collectively, firms will incur recordkeeping costs of $6.54 million annually.

    Total Initial Year Costs: Summing costs enumerated above, the Commission estimates the costs of the Rule in the first year will range between $49.52 and $422.26 million. These costs are presented in Table 6. The Commission assumes that these costs will be incurred by the end of the initial year following the Rule's implementation.

    Table 6—Total Initial Year Compliance Costs

    [In millions, 2023 dollars]

    Low High
    Familiarization Costs $35.97 $341.22
    Disclosure Costs 3.96 39.57
    Cancellation Mechanisms Costs 3.04 34.93
    Recordkeeping Costs 6.54 6.54
    Total Initial Year Costs 49.52 422.26

    (3) Ongoing Compliance Costs, Years 2 Through 10

    Compliant disclosures, cancellation paths, and consumer-facing information about cancellation mechanisms will form a “template” that can be used without any incremental compliance costs as new subscription products are added to a marketer's retinue of products offered for sale via a negative option plan. The information relevant to the sale of a new product may be “dropped” into the template in a fill-in-the-blank way. The Commission assumes marketers, in the ordinary course of business, know what is required for the disclosures ( e.g., the amounts consumers will be charged, when, by date or frequency, such charges will occur, when consumers must act to stop recurring charges, etc.) and consider the costs of entering this information into established disclosure templates to be a routine cost of doing business, not an incremental cost required by compliance with the final Rule. The same will also be true for negative option plans that are telemarketed or sold in person; once a telemarketing script or an in-person sales disclosure form is developed in the initial year of compliance, it becomes a template that readily can be used as new subscription products are offered over time. Accordingly, once a marketer comes into compliance with the final Rule there should be no incremental costs of ongoing compliance with respect to disclosures and cancellation mechanisms, and the costs of adding, changing, or deleting products the marketer offers for sale via negative option will be no different from what they would have been absent the final Rule.

    The Commission can seek redress or civil penalties for violations of the final Rule. Absent the final Rule, enforcement actions against unfair or deceptive negative option practices would be brought under section 5 where civil penalties are not available and where, post- AMG, it is difficult to obtain redress. Accordingly, some negative option marketers may pay closer attention to underlying claims made for products marketed using negative option sales because of the monetary relief available for violations of the final Rule relative to a section 5 enforcement action. This, however, is no different than what any firm should do to assure that it is not in violation of section 5, and the Commission considers the costs of attentiveness to section 5 compliance as part of the existing regulatory baseline, not as costs that are incremental to complying with the final Rule.

    The U.K.'s “Impact Assessment” of its regulatory treatment of subscription plans did not estimate ongoing compliance costs because “the size of these costs . . . are likely small in comparison to the one-off cost and benefits.” [613] In further support of this, the “Impact Assessment” cited a report that found that on-going costs were meaningful only in relation to sending reminders to consumers about their subscriptions, and only for firms that used postal mail delivery and not electronically delivered reminders.[614] The final Rule does not contain a “reminder” requirement, and so the ongoing costs of sending reminders to consumers, small though they may be, are not ongoing costs of compliance with the final Rule.

    The experts' report submitted by IAB estimated 10 hours of attorney time for annual compliance checks for the Rule proposed in the NPRM. Because the final Rule has removed the most complex (and, therefore, costly) features of the proposed Rule ( e.g., double consent, the treatment of “saves” in cancellation flows, and the issuance of annual “reminders” for some subscriptions), the Commission assumes half of the annual compliance check hours assumed in IAB's experts' report, five hours, is an upper bound on attorney hours needed for annual compliance checks. Moreover, the Commission assumes that some firms will incur no incremental annual compliance check costs, either because their pre-existing business practices followed what the final Rule requires or because the platforms or payment processors they use provide compliant disclosures and cancellation flows.[615]

    Accordingly, the Commission estimates the aggregate annual costs of compliance checks to range between $0 and $44.97 million ( i.e., 106,000 × 5 hours × $84.84/hour). Inclusive of recordkeeping costs, total ongoing costs range between $6.54 million ( i.e., $0 + $6.54 million) and $51.51 million ( i.e., $44.97 million + $6.54 million).

    (4) Summary of Total Costs

    Table 7 presents the initial and recurring costs of this Rule in each year, as well as the present discounted value and annualized costs over 10 years using a 2 percent discount rate. The Commission estimates that in Year 1, the initial costs will range between $49.52 and $422.26 million. In each of the following years, the Commission estimates that the recurring costs will range between $6.54 and $51.51 million. The Commission estimates that the ( print page 90532) present discounted value of costs over ten years, using a 2 percent discount rate, will range between $100.89 and $826.15 million. The Commission estimates that these costs, annualized over ten years using a 2 percent discount rate, would range between $11.23 and $91.97 million per year.

    Table 7—Total Quantified Costs

    [In millions, 2023 dollars]

    Year Low High
    1 $49.52 $422.26
    2 6.54 51.51
    3 6.54 51.51
    4 6.54 51.51
    5 6.54 51.51
    6 6.54 51.51
    7 6.54 51.51
    8 6.54 51.51
    9 6.54 51.51
    10 6.54 51.51
    Present Discounted Value of Costs over 10 years, 2% discount rate 100.89 826.15
    Annualized Costs over 10 years, 2% discount rate 11.23 91.97

    (d) Sensitivity Analysis

    As a sensitivity analysis, the Commission considers an alternative method that does not rely on data from historical enforcement matters for distributing subscription cancellations across the baseline cancellation methods used to estimate quantified benefits. This alternative method assumes the majority of subscriptions are enrolled online and can be cancelled online in the baseline; whereas, in the main analysis, the majority of subscriptions are enrolled online and can only be cancelled by phone in the baseline. Compared with the main analysis, this alternative method produces lower total quantified benefits by $419.77 to $449.53 million annualized per year, yet the estimated range of quantified benefits still exceeds the estimated range of quantified costs.

    (1) Number of Cancellations by Enrollment and Baseline Cancellation Method

    Under this sensitivity analysis, the Commission assumes that the baseline number of subscriptions and cancellations is the same as in the main analysis. The Commission also assumes the number of in-person subscriptions, as proxied for by gym memberships, is the same as in the main analysis. What differs here is the approach for determining the share of cancellations likely to occur through online and telephone methods.

    The main analysis uses enforcement data to determine the share of cancellations likely to occur through online and telephone methods. This data may suffer from selection bias if, among other factors, only the more egregious violations are pursued through enforcement methods. This approach also assumes no marketers of negative option plans comply with this Rule in the baseline. Further, because the data only include resolved cases and resolved cases tend to be older, they are less likely to reflect the current state of the market.

    In this alternative analysis, the Commission uses statistics discussed in the NPRM—that 106,000 firms offer negative option plans and 2,000 of those firms are telemarketers.[616] Based on that, the Commission assumes 1.9 percent ( i.e., 2,000/106,000) of subscriptions and cancellations are enrolled and cancelled over the phone in the baseline. The Commission then assumes the remaining cancellations of subscriptions that were not enrolled over the phone or in person were instead enrolled online.[617]

    To estimate the distribution of baseline cancellation methods of subscriptions enrolled online, the Commission uses the results from an experiment in which a researcher consented to 16 online subscriptions between August 2 to October 4, 2022 and then canceled each one, recording the time it took to cancel along with a variety of other obstacles faced in cancelling.[618] Of the 16 online subscriptions, three were found to be easy to cancel online, indicating they are likely in compliance with this Rule; three required phone calls to cancel; and the remaining 10 had a non-straightforward online cancellation method. Based on these results, the Commission assumes 18.75 percent ( i.e., 3/16) of online subscriptions have Rule-compliant cancellation methods in the baseline; 18.75 percent ( i.e., 3/16) of online subscriptions require telephone cancellation in the baseline; and 62.5 percent ( i.e., 10/16) of online subscription offer non-Rule-compliant online cancellations in the baseline.

    Table 8 provides the number of subscription cancellations each year distributed across the enrollment and regulatory baseline cancellation methods: online enrollment and telephone cancellation; online enrollment and non-Rule-compliant online cancellation; online enrollment and Rule-compliant online cancellation; telephone enrollment and telephone cancellation; and in-person enrollment. ( print page 90533)

    Table 8—Sensitivity Analysis: Cancellations by Enrollment and Baseline Cancellation Method

    [In millions]

    Year Online enrollment, telephone cancellation Online enrollment, non-compliant online cancellation Online enrollment, compliant online cancellation Telephone enrollment, telephone cancellation In-person enrollment
    1 63.79 212.63 63.79 6.87 14.62
    2 64.28 214.27 64.28 6.93 14.73
    3 64.78 215.92 64.78 6.98 14.84
    4 65.27 217.56 65.27 7.03 14.96
    5 65.76 219.21 65.76 7.08 15.07
    6 66.26 220.85 66.26 7.14 15.18
    7 66.66 222.19 66.66 7.18 15.27
    8 67.06 223.54 67.06 7.22 15.37
    9 67.46 224.88 67.46 7.27 15.46
    10 67.87 226.23 67.87 7.31 15.55

    (2) Estimating Total Benefits

    To estimate total quantified benefits under this sensitivity analysis, the Commission uses the same matching of enrollment and baseline cancellation methods to per-cancellation benefit estimates as in the main analysis. The only difference here is that the Commission assumes consumers who experience Rule-compliant online cancellations in the baseline will not see any additional benefit as a result of this final Rule.

    As in the main analysis, the Commission multiplies the number of cancellations in each category by the matched per-cancellation benefit on the low- and the high-end and then sums across all five categories to obtain total quantified benefits each year. Those totals are presented in Table 9 below. In the first year following implementation of the final Rule, the Commission estimates the benefits under this sensitivity analysis will range between $254.85 million and $4.88 billion. In Year 10, the Commission estimates the benefits will range between $271.15 million and $5.20 billion. Using a 2 percent discount rate, the Commission estimates the present discounted value of benefits over 10 years to range between $2.36 and $45.28 billion. Annualized over 10 years using a 2 percent discount rate, the Commission estimates the benefits to range between $263.06 million and $5.04 billion per year. These annualized benefits estimates are between $419.77 and $449.53 million less per year than the estimates from the main analysis.

    Table 9—Sensitivity Analysis: Estimates of Benefits

    [In millions, 2023 dollars]

    Year Low High
    1 $254.85 $4,883.26
    2 256.82 4,921.01
    3 258.79 4,958.77
    4 260.76 4,996.53
    5 262.73 5,034.29
    6 264.70 5,072.05
    7 266.31 5,102.91
    8 267.92 5,133.77
    9 269.54 5,164.63
    10 271.15 5,195.49
    Present Discounted Value of Benefits over 10 years, 2% discount rate 2,362.97 45,277.43
    Annualized Benefits over 10 years, 2% discount rate 263.06 5,040.58
    Difference in Annualized Benefits from Main Analysis −419.77 −449.53

Document Information

Effective Date:
1/14/2025
Published:
11/15/2024
Department:
Federal Trade Commission
Entry Type:
Rule
Action:
Final rule.
Document Number:
2024-25534
Dates:
Effective date: This rule is effective January 14, 2025.
Pages:
90476-90545 (70 pages)
RINs:
3084-AB60: Use of Prenotification Negative Option Plans
RIN Links:
https://www.federalregister.gov/regulations/3084-AB60/use-of-prenotification-negative-option-plans
Topics:
Advertising, Consumer protection, Trade practices
PDF File:
2024-25534.pdf
CFR: (1)
16 CFR 425