99-30741. Prescription of Local Exchange Carrier Price Cap Productivity Offset (``X-Factor'')  

  • [Federal Register Volume 64, Number 227 (Friday, November 26, 1999)]
    [Proposed Rules]
    [Pages 66442-66447]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 99-30741]
    
    
    =======================================================================
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
    
    47 CFR Part 61
    
    [CC Docket Nos. 94-1 and 96-262; FCC 99-345]
    
    
    Prescription of Local Exchange Carrier Price Cap Productivity 
    Offset (``X-Factor'')
    
    AGENCY: Federal Communications Commission.
    
    ACTION: Notice of proposed rulemaking.
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    SUMMARY: This document seeks comment on the represcription of the 
    productivity offset, or ``X-factor,'' in the local exchange carrier 
    price cap formula. The X-factor of 6.5 percent prescribed by the 
    Commission in the 1997 Price Cap Performance Review Order was reversed 
    and remanded to the agency by the U.S. Court of Appeals for the D.C. 
    Circuit. Therefore, the Commission seeks comment on the retroactive 
    prescription of the X-factor for the period affected by the court's 
    remand, from July 1, 1997 to June 30, 2000, and on the prospective 
    prescription, from July 1, 2000 forward. The Further Notice of Proposed 
    Rulemaking (``FNPRM'') identifies three studies on which the historical 
    component of the X-factor prescription may be based: the 1997 staff 
    total factor productivity (``TFP'') study relied upon in the 1997 
    order; a new 1999 staff TFP study; or a staff Imputed X study. This 
    document also seeks comment on whether a consumer productivity dividend 
    (``CPD'') should be included in the X-factor.
    
    DATES: Comments are due on or before December 30, 1999, and reply 
    comments are due on or before January 14, 2000.
    
    ADDRESSES: Federal Communications Commission, 445 12th Street, S.W., 
    Washington, DC 20554.
    
    FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Aaron Goldschmidt, (202) 418-1520.
    
    SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: In 1997, the Commission represcribed the 
    amount by which it annually adjusts price caps for incumbent local 
    exchange carriers subject to the price cap rules (``price cap LECs''). 
    Price Cap Performance Review for Local Exchange Carriers, 62 FR 31939, 
    June 11, 1997 (``1997 Price Cap Review Order''). The revised price cap 
    adjustment required price cap LECs to reduce inflation-adjusted prices 
    for interstate access services by an ``X-factor'' of 6.5 percent 
    annually. Pursuant to petitions for review of the Commission's order, 
    the United States Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia Circuit 
    reversed and remanded the Commission's decision. USTA v. FCC, 188 F.3d 
    521 (D.C. Cir. 1999). The court has stayed issuance of its mandate 
    until April 1, 2000, to allow time for the Commission to conduct this 
    proceeding. USTA v. FCC, Nos. 97-1469 et al., (D.C. Cir. June 21, 
    1999).
        In this Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (``FNPRM'') we seek 
    comment on how we should represcribe an X-factor. More specifically, we 
    seek comment on prescribing two separate X-factors to address 
    retroactively the period affected by the court remand (July 1, 1997 to 
    June 30, 2000), and prospectively the period from July 1, 2000 forward, 
    or a single X-factor to cover the combined period. Specifically, we 
    seek comment on three possible bases for setting the historical 
    component of the X-factor: (1) by relying on the results of the 1997 
    staff TFP study used in the 1997 order; (2) by relying on the results 
    of a new 1999 staff TFP study that makes several adjustments to the 
    1997 staff study; or (3) by relying on the results of a new staff 
    Imputed X study that determines the X-factor that would have produced a 
    competitive level of capital compensation in the interstate 
    jurisdiction during the period between price cap performance reviews.
        Further, we seek comment on resetting, on a forward-looking basis, 
    price cap LEC prices to a level that is consistent with any X-factor 
    prescription in order to rebalance the sharing of benefits of price 
    caps between LECs and their customers. This FNPRM is limited to issues 
    surrounding the setting of the X-factor, and does not include any 
    broader changes to our method of price cap regulation.
        In a separate but related proceeding, the Commission is seeking 
    comment on a proposal submitted by the Coalition for Affordable Local 
    and Long Distance Services (``CALLS''). See Access Charge Reform, Price 
    Cap Performance Review for Local Exchange Carriers, Low-Volume Long 
    Distance Users, Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, 64 FR 
    50527, September 16, 1999. The CALLS proposal would purportedly 
    eliminate the necessity of retrospectively adjusting the X-factor in 
    response to the court's remand. Instead, it would keep the X-factor at 
    6.5 percent, but would target X-factor reductions to the traffic-
    sensitive price cap basket. Once local switching rates reached a 
    certain level, all price cap indices would be frozen. Adoption of the 
    CALLS proposal would also eliminate the need to prescribe an X-factor 
    on a going-forward basis. We seek comment in this proceeding on the 
    prescription of the X-factor because, in the event that the CALLS 
    proposal is not adopted, or not all price cap LECs become signatories 
    to the proposal, the Commission must be prepared to prescribe a new X-
    factor before April 1, 2000.
    
    Option 1: The 1997 Staff TFP Study
    
        We seek comment on whether we should use only the results from the 
    1997 staff TFP study in setting the historical component of the X-
    factor for the remand period. We seek comment on whether, in addressing 
    the court's remand, we are precluded from revising the X-factor using 
    any other methodology, or from supplementing the data in the 1997 staff 
    TFP study.
        The court did not find fault with the 1997 staff TFP study, and did 
    not ask us to revisit it. Instead, the court limited its critique of 
    TFP to our selection of a value at the upper end of the reasonableness 
    range, and with the upward adjustment to the reasonable range.
        In their responses to a 1998 request to refresh the record in our 
    Access Charge Reform proceeding, both USTA and AT&T used the 
    methodology in the 1997 staff TFP study to extend the calculation of 
    the X-factor through 1997. USTA has also calculated an X-factor for 
    1998. We seek comment on the legal and logical arguments supporting 
    consideration of data that have become available after the
    
    [[Page 66443]]
    
    close of the record for the remanded prescription. We note that USTA 
    and AT&T did not agree with each other on the value of the historical 
    component for 1996 and 1997. We seek comment on USTA's and AT&T's 
    updates of the 1997 staff TFP study, and on their recommendations for 
    prescribing an X-factor.
        If we set the X-factor by using the 1997 staff TFP study, the 
    court's remand requires that we justify our selection from within the 
    reasonable range. Within the reasonable range, should we use some 
    measure of central tendency, e.g., the mean or median, as the best 
    estimator of productivity? Could and should we consider prescribing 
    above the mean? If the reasonable range includes a statistically 
    meaningful trend, should this inform our choice? What other 
    justifications could be made for selecting above or below some measure 
    of central tendency? Should these justifications affect our selection 
    from the reasonable range, or are they more relevant to the selection 
    of a CPD?
    
    Option 2: The 1999 Staff TFP Study
    
        In comments filed with the Commission late last year, several 
    parties identified what they believe is a problem in the way in which 
    the 1997 staff TFP study employed the TFP methodology commonly used in 
    economic analysis to set an X-factor. The 1999 staff TFP study takes 
    this potential problem as a point of departure and attempts to correct 
    it. We seek comment on the 1999 staff TFP study, and on its premise 
    that the 1997 staff TFP study methodology may fail to calculate an X-
    factor that is consistent with the objectives of our price cap plan.
        The 1997 staff TFP study subtracts the cost of the labor and 
    material inputs from revenues, and the residual revenue is assumed to 
    be the cost of the capital input. The 1999 staff TFP study attempts to 
    capture the gains in productivity that would have been revealed in a 
    competitive marketplace by varying total capital compensation according 
    to a measure of the competitive capital compensation rate.
        We seek comment on the following method for adjusting the capital 
    compensation in the 1997 staff TFP study. The first step is to identify 
    a competitive price index series to use as a surrogate for the annual 
    change for the cost of capital in a competitive market. The second step 
    is to assume LEC capital compensation in 1991, the first full year of 
    LEC price cap, was at a competitive level. Because price caps were 
    implemented in 1991, the 1999 staff TFP study assumes that LECs earned 
    a normal return in that year. The third step is to combine the 
    competitive price index and the 1991 LEC capital compensation rate to 
    create a competitive LEC capital compensation rate for the historical 
    period. The fourth step is to increase or decrease LEC capital 
    compensation based on this competitive LEC capital compensation rate. 
    The fifth step is to adjust LEC revenues, making appropriate allowance 
    for taxes, for the change in capital compensation. The final step is to 
    recalculate LEC historical TFP using these revised capital compensation 
    and revenue data.
        In addition to updating the data for the period 1996-1998, the 1999 
    staff TFP study makes three other modifications to the 1997 staff TFP 
    study. First, the 1999 staff TFP study uses the recently revised Bureau 
    of Labor Statistics (``BLS'') series on multifactor productivity in 
    place of the antecedent series. Second, the 1999 staff TFP study uses 
    the number of dial equipment minutes, rather than the number of calls, 
    in calculating the local service output index. Third, the 1999 staff 
    TFP study recalculates the labor input to adjust for the fact that all 
    the costs, but only a fraction of the benefits, of the 1992-95 employee 
    buyouts have been recognized on the accounting books. We seek comment 
    on these modifications to the 1997 staff TFP study.
        Several additional aspects of the 1997 staff TFP study may warrant 
    highlighting and comment. The 1999 staff TFP study does not make these 
    adjustments because they either are not easily quantified, or do not 
    make a significant impact on the level of the X-factor. We seek comment 
    on the decision of the 1999 staff TFP study to not make any of these 
    adjustments. We also seek comment on whether there are any additional 
    issues that necessitate adjusting the X-factor, how any such 
    adjustments would affect the X-factor, and how they should be made.
        The court's remand requires that we justify our selection from 
    within a reasonable range. We seek comment on how we should determine 
    the reasonable range and how we should select from within this range. 
    In our determination of the reasonable range in the 1997 Price Cap 
    Review Order, we gave recent years more weight than more distant years. 
    Should we continue to discount more distant years? Should the period 
    under price cap regulation be given more weight than the period under 
    rate-of-return regulation? Given that price cap regulation may have 
    been anticipated by price cap LECs for some years before its 
    introduction, what years should be included in the price cap period?
        We also seek comment on whether additional years of data should be 
    considered in the remand, or whether the X-factor we select should rely 
    on the same years of data as used in the 1997 Price Cap Review Order. 
    We seek comment on the legal and logical arguments supporting 
    consideration of data that have become available after the close of the 
    record for the remanded prescription. Would it be more responsive to 
    the court's remand to prescribe an X-factor based on data available in 
    1997 or to consider the additional data that has become available in 
    the interim in setting the X-factor on a going-forward basis?
    
    Option 3: The Staff Imputed X Study
    
        As an alternative to either of the TFP methodologies, the Bureau 
    staff also has performed a study, the staff Imputed X study, designed 
    to calculate the X factor that yields the aggregate revenues that would 
    have been generated in a competitive market. While price caps provide 
    incentives for cost reduction similar to those of competition, they do 
    not guarantee that revenues will follow a similar path. In a 
    competitive market, revenues on average will be equal to costs, 
    including compensation of capital at a competitive market level. This 
    method is intended to replicate the effects of a competitive market in 
    apportioning the gains from successful operation between carriers and 
    consumers. The approach used here differs from the TFP approach, inter 
    alia, in that it measures productivity growth by looking at aggregate 
    expense and revenue data rather than by weighting and aggregating 
    categories of physical inputs and outputs. In contrast to both of the 
    TFP approaches, this method appears to have modest data requirements 
    and to be computationally simple and easily understandable. 
    Nevertheless, this method should have the same incentive effects as the 
    TFP approach or any other method of calculating an X-factor.
        The staff Imputed X study calculates the change in 1998 revenue and 
    operating income for each price cap LEC that would result from imposing 
    a hypothetical X-factor from the inception of price caps in 1991 
    through 1998. The results for all price cap LECs are aggregated, and 
    the X-factor required to produce revenues equal to costs, including a 
    competitive level of capital compensation in the aggregate for all 
    LECs, is calculated. The calculation was also performed for 1991 
    through 1995 for comparison with the original TFP study. The 
    calculation takes account of
    
    [[Page 66444]]
    
    the increase in the demand for service that would have resulted from 
    the lower price. Changes in the competitive cost of capital were 
    accounted for by adjusting the capital compensation found reasonable by 
    the Commission at the inception of price caps by an index of bond rates 
    over the period. The index is the same one used for the 1999 staff TFP 
    study to measure the price of capital. Moody's Baa corporate bond rate 
    was used. We noted above that, in a competitive capital market, indexes 
    of bond rates will agree closely. Further, in an efficient market, 
    there are no persistent arbitrage opportunities between different 
    financial instruments, so that we have no reason to expect that the 
    trend of bond rates would differ over time from that of the return on 
    an efficient diversified portfolio. Thus, applying any of several 
    published indices to the allowed rate at the beginning of the period 
    will yield approximately the same estimate of the end-period rate.
        The data used for these estimates differ from those used for the 
    TFP calculations in that they are purely interstate in nature. The TFP 
    calculations used total company data because of the difficulty of 
    separating interstate and intrastate costs for the TFP calculations, 
    despite interstate data being conceptually more appropriate for 
    representing the services regulated by the Commission under price caps. 
    The data for the staff Imputed X study also include all price cap 
    carriers, whereas the TFP studies use data for the regional Bell 
    operating companies (``RBOCs'') only. The calculations assume that a 
    decrease in price would result in an increase in the quantity of 
    service purchased, while the TFP calculations necessarily reflect only 
    experience under the prices that were actually in effect. Finally, the 
    staff Imputed X study does not make an adjustment in expense data 
    comparable to the adjustment made in the 1999 staff TFP study to 
    compensate for the accounting treatment of employee buyouts. To provide 
    a check on the revised TFP calculations, the X-factor calculations 
    using the staff Imputed X study were repeated using data only for the 
    RBOCs and assuming no demand growth in response to lower prices. These 
    calculations were performed for both 1995 and 1998.
        We note that the approach described here is similar to the Direct 
    Model proposed by AT&T, which the Commission has referred to as the 
    Historical Revenue Approach in the 1997 price cap performance review 
    proceeding. The staff Imputed X study differs from the approach 
    proposed by AT&T primarily in that the staff calculation includes an 
    adjustment to take account of likely demand stimulation resulting from 
    a lower price cap, and the calculation takes account of changes over 
    time in competitive return to capital. Data sources and calculations 
    also differ somewhat. In the Price Cap Performance Review for Local 
    Exchange Carriers, 60 FR 19526, April 19, 1995 (``1995 Price Cap Review 
    Order''), the Commission noted that the Historical Revenue Approach has 
    the advantage that it reflects performance in providing the interstate 
    services that are subject to price caps, and includes input cost 
    changes. In comments in the 1997 price cap performance review 
    proceeding, GSA supported the Historical Revenue Approach and noted 
    that it incorporates both TFP growth and the input price differential.
        Most criticisms of AT&T's Historical Revenue Approach dealt with 
    the data and methodology used by AT&T in its calculations. Commenters 
    responding to AT&T's proposal pointed out that data reported under 
    Commission accounting, separations, and other rules may not accurately 
    track economic costs. In its comments in the 1997 price cap performance 
    review proceeding, NYNEX criticized use of the Historical Revenue 
    Approach on the grounds that accounting-based rules are a poor measure 
    of a firm's economic performance. We note that the Commission declined 
    to adopt the Historical Revenue Approach in the 1997 Price Cap Review 
    Order due to administrative concerns and incentive effects.
        We seek comment on the validity of the staff Imputed X study for 
    estimating the appropriate level of the X-factor. Does the X-factor 
    estimated using these data and assumptions accurately represent the 
    productivity growth achievable by the price cap LECs over the period 
    examined? We request comment on the theoretical appropriateness of this 
    methodology. We also seek comment on the following questions: Is an 
    interstate-only calculation conceptually proper, and do the data allow 
    an accurate measure of interstate revenues, expenses, and investment? 
    Calculations reported in the staff Imputed X study show that X-factors 
    calculated on an annual basis appear to increase over time. Are there 
    explanations for the trend we see other than increasing efficiency? 
    Does this apparent trend suggest that an additional adjustment, such as 
    the CPD, is necessary in addition to revising the calculation of the X-
    factor? Alternatively, is the CPD no longer necessary because the 
    approach described here sufficiently passes the benefits of increased 
    efficiency to ratepayers? What is the appropriate method for 
    determining the competitive cost of capital? Is applying an index of 
    bond rates to the rate of return used by the Commission to initialize 
    rates at the inception of price caps a reasonable approach? Would 
    taking account of the mix of debt and equity held by the LECs yield a 
    more accurate estimate of the trend in the cost of capital?
        We request comment on the data and calculations used in the staff 
    Imputed X study. Are more appropriate data sources available, and can 
    adjustments be made that would improve the accuracy of the calculations 
    reported here? AT&T in its Historical Revenue Approach in 1994 used 
    Price Cap Indices (``PCIs'') from the Commission's Tariff Review Plan 
    data to measure actual changes in allowed rates. This approach includes 
    all changes that occurred in the price caps, including exogenous 
    changes not related to the operation of the X factor. Is such an 
    approach conceptually appropriate? Would use of PCIs rather than the X 
    factor in effect more accurately reflect price performance for purposes 
    of these calculations?
        We also seek comment on whether, in responding to the remand, it is 
    appropriate to use data for the period that was available to us at the 
    time of the 1997 Price Cap Review Order, or whether we should make use 
    of the best information available to us now, including data for 
    subsequent years that have become available in the meantime. We seek 
    comment on the legal and logical arguments supporting consideration of 
    data that have become available after the close of the record for the 
    remanded prescription. Would it be more responsive to the court's 
    remand to prescribe an X-factor based on data contemporaneous with the 
    prescription and to consider the additional data in setting the X-
    factor on a going-forward basis? In addition, the court's remand 
    requires that we justify our selection from within a reasonable range. 
    How should we determine a reasonable range for setting the X-factor 
    using the staff Imputed X study, and how we should select from within 
    that range?
    
    Consumer Productivity Dividend
    
        In Policy and Rules Concerning Rates for Dominant Carriers, 55 FR 
    42375, October 19, 1990 (``LEC Price Cap Order''), the Commission 
    included a CPD of 0.5 percent in the X-factor offset to ensure that 
    access customers received the first benefits of price caps in the form 
    of reduced rates. This CPD was also included in the X-factor in
    
    [[Page 66445]]
    
    subsequent price cap review orders, including the 1997 Price Cap Review 
    Order, in which it was intended to offset the elimination of sharing 
    requirements. These requirements had compelled price cap LECs to share 
    a portion of their earnings above set percentages with access 
    customers. The sharing requirements were intended to protect consumers 
    against the possibility of an error in the establishment of the X-
    factor. Pursuant to the court's remand, the Commission seeks comment on 
    whether to retain the CPD.
        In remanding this issue to the Commission, the court specifically 
    questioned the quantification of the CPD. When the Commission made its 
    decision to include a CPD in the 1997 X-factor, the record included a 
    study by Strategic Policy Research (``SPR'') that addressed the effects 
    of eliminating the sharing requirements. The SPR study found that the 
    LEC price cap plan with sharing requirements produced less than 35 
    percent of the efficiency incentives of unregulated competition. Those 
    incentives decreased to 18 percent for price cap LECs whose earnings 
    were in the 50-50 sharing category for each year of the four-year 
    review cycle. The Commission discussed the SPR study in some detail in 
    the 1995 Price Cap Review Order. Although the Commission did not 
    determine whether the SPR study accurately quantified the effects of 
    sharing on productivity growth, it concluded that the study showed that 
    there ``are substantial gains in incentives that [sharing] 
    suppresses.'' 1995 LEC Price Cap Review Order. The results of the SPR 
    study were challenged by the Ad Hoc Telecommunications Users Committee 
    (``Ad Hoc''), but Ad Hoc's own results indicated that sharing 
    substantially reduced efficiency incentives. Ad Hoc's more conservative 
    calculations indicated that elimination of sharing would increase 
    efficiency incentives by at least 17 percent for all LECs, and by 41 
    percent for LECs in the 50-50 sharing category. We seek comment on the 
    CPD amount justified on the basis of these studies to ensure that the 
    benefits of sharing elimination would be apportioned between LECs and 
    ratepayers. We also seek comment on additional methods for quantifying 
    a CPD designed to ensure that consumers get a reasonable portion of the 
    benefits from the elimination of sharing.
        We also seek comment on whether a CPD should be included to reduce 
    rates and correct for prior years when the X-factor may have been set 
    too low. As noted above, the calculations used to set prior year X-
    factors may have underestimated LEC productivity. This underestimation 
    may have caused rates to be set at too high a level. A mistake in the 
    X-factor may not be self-correcting, but instead may cause increasingly 
    erroneous prices over time. To obtain efficient prices in the future, 
    it may be necessary both to adjust the value of the X-factor and to 
    reset prices. Therefore, we seek comment on whether we should include 
    in the X-factor a CPD designed to reduce rates, either by a one-time 
    adjustment, or over a multi-year period, if we conclude that the X-
    factor historically has been set too low. If the reduction occurs over 
    a multi-year period, should we account for the time value of money, 
    and, if so, how should we calculate the reduction?
    
    Prescribing the X-Factor on a Going-Forward Basis
    
        We seek comment on whether we should prescribe an X-factor that 
    would apply as of July 1, 2000 that is different from the retrospective 
    X-factor applicable to the period affected by the court's remand, or 
    whether the X-factor that we prescribe for the period beginning July 1, 
    1997 should continue in place until the next price cap performance 
    review. We also seek comment on whether to include a prospective CPD 
    adjustment in future X-factors to correct for any significant 
    divergences between historic LEC productivity and prior X-factors, and 
    on whether any such adjustment should be made at once or be phased in 
    over several years.
        In this FNPRM we seek comment on prescribing a future X-factor 
    based on the results of the 1999 staff TFP study. In the alternative, 
    we could prescribe an X-factor based on the results of the staff 
    Imputed X study. Finally, we invite parties to comment on other 
    alternatives that could serve as a basis for a future X-factor.
        We also seek comment on how the prescription of the X-factor would 
    affect smaller price cap LECs differently from other price cap LECs, 
    and whether there should be a separate X-factor calculated for smaller 
    price cap LECs.
        In addition, we seek comment on how the Commission's proposed 
    adjustments to the price cap rate structure in Access Charge Reform, 64 
    FR 51258, September 22, 1999 (``Pricing Flexibility Order'') should 
    affect the annual reductions required by our price cap rules. We 
    proposed in the Pricing Flexibility Order to add a ``q'' factor to the 
    formulae used to adjust annually the price cap indices (``PCIs'') for 
    the baskets that contain the charges for local switching and tandem 
    switching. The q factor would reduce switching charges based on growth 
    in demand. The q factor would operate similarly to the g factor present 
    in the common line PCI formula. The g factor is used to share with IXCs 
    the benefits of demand growth that LECs receive from per-minute growth 
    per access line. As proposed, the affected baskets would be reduced 
    annually by both the X-factor and the q factor. The staff studies 
    attached herein, however, may capture in their X-factor estimates some 
    or all of the effect intended to be captured by the q factor. We seek 
    comment on whether a q factor is necessary if an X-factor is adopted 
    that captures its effect, and on how to remove any double counting that 
    might result from the application of both factors. For example, if the 
    X-factor reduction was $10, and the q factor reduction was $4, then we 
    could directly apply $4 to the baskets containing local and tandem 
    switching, and allocate the remaining $6 amongst all the baskets 
    according to our price cap rules.
        We also proposed to adjust on a prospective basis for the past 
    absence of a q factor in the formulae that annually adjust the PCIs of 
    the baskets containing charges for local and tandem switching. We seek 
    comment on how any such adjustment should affect any proposed 
    adjustment to the PCIs for all price cap baskets to offset the 
    cumulative effect of past X-factors that may have been set below the 
    rate of cost reduction actually achieved by LECs. Should we apply the 
    logic suggested in the example of the previous paragraph? If so, should 
    the shift of switching ports to common line increase the common line 
    basket's share of any adjustment based on the past absence of a q 
    factor?
        In addition to proposing a q factor, we proposed to increase the 
    ``g'' factor that applies to certain revenues in the common line basket 
    from g/2 to a full g. We seek comment on whether any prospective 
    adjustment to our X-factor prescription would be appropriate to account 
    for this.
        Finally, we proposed to replace the existing per-minute rate 
    structure for local switching and tandem switching with capacity 
    charges. We seek comment on whether replacing per-minute charges with 
    capacity charges affects future growth in LEC productivity. We seek 
    comment on whether any prospective adjustment to our X-factor is 
    required and on how we would quantify this adjustment.
    
    Ex Parte Presentations
    
        This proceeding shall be treated as a ``permit-but-disclose'' 
    proceeding in accordance with 47 CFR 1.1206(b). Ex parte presentations 
    are permissible if disclosed in accordance with
    
    [[Page 66446]]
    
    Commission rules, except during the Sunshine Agenda period when 
    presentations, ex parte or otherwise, are generally prohibited. Persons 
    making oral ex parte presentations are reminded that memoranda 
    summarizing the presentations must contain summaries of the substance 
    of the presentations and not merely a listing of the subjects 
    discussed. More than a one or two sentence description of the views and 
    arguments presented generally is required. See 47 CFR 1.1206(b)(2). 
    Additional rules pertaining to oral and written presentations are set 
    forth in Sec. 1.1206(b).
    
    Initial Regulatory Flexibility Act Analysis
    
        As required by the Regulatory Flexibility Act (``RFA''), 5 U.S.C. 
    603, the Commission has prepared this Initial Regulatory Flexibility 
    Analysis (``IRFA'') of the possible significant economic impact on 
    small entities by the policies and rules proposed in this FNPRM. The 
    RFA, 5 U.S.C. 601 et seq., has been amended by the Contract With 
    America Advancement Act of 1996, Public Law 104-121, 110 Stat. 847 
    (1996) (``CWAAA''). Title II of the CWAAA is the Small Business 
    Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act of 1996 (``SBREFA''). Written 
    public comments are requested on this IRFA. Comments must be identified 
    as responses to the IRFA and must be filed by the deadlines for 
    comments on the FNPRM provided below. The Office of Public Affairs will 
    send a copy of the FNPRM, including this IRFA, to the Chief Counsel for 
    Advocacy of the Small Business Administration. In addition, the FNPRM 
    and IRFA (or summaries thereof) will be published in the Federal 
    Register. 5 U.S.C. 603(a).
        Need for and Objectives of the Proposed Rules. The court has 
    remanded to the Commission the selection of a 6.5 percent productivity 
    offset, or X-factor, in the LEC price cap formula. In this FNPRM we 
    seek comment on how we should represcribe an X-factor. We seek comment 
    on prescribing one or more X-factors to address retroactively the 
    period affected by the court remand (July 1, 1997 to June 30, 2000), 
    and we seek comment on represcribing one or more X-factors from July 1, 
    2000 forward. Further, we seek comment on resetting, on a forward-
    looking basis, price cap LEC prices to a level that is consistent with 
    any X-factor prescription in order to rebalance the sharing of benefits 
    of price caps between LECs and their customers.
        Legal Basis. The proposed action is supported by sections 1, 4(i), 
    4(j), 201-205, and 303(r) of the Communications Act of 1934, as 
    amended, 47 U.S.C. 151, 154(i), (j), 201-205, and 303(r).
        Description and Estimate of the Number of Small Entities to Which 
    the Proposed Rules Will Apply. The RFA directs agencies to provide a 
    description of and, where feasible, an estimate of the number of small 
    entities that may be affected by the proposed rules, if adopted. 5 
    U.S.C. 603(b)(3). The RFA generally defines the term ``small entity'' 
    as having the same meaning as the terms ``small business,'' ``small 
    organization,'' and ``small governmental jurisdiction.'' 5 U.S.C. 
    601(6). In addition, the term ``small business'' has the same meaning 
    as the term ``small business concern'' under the Small Business Act. 15 
    U.S.C. 632. A small business concern is one which: (1) is independently 
    owned and operated; (2) is not dominant in its field of operation; and 
    (3) satisfies any additional criteria established by the Small Business 
    Administration (``SBA''). 5 U.S.C. 601(3) (incorporating by reference 
    the definition of ``small business concern'' in 15 U.S.C. 632). 
    Pursuant to the RFA, the statutory definition of a small business 
    applies ``unless an agency, after consultation with the Office of 
    Advocacy of the Small Business Administration and after opportunity for 
    public comment, establishes one or more definitions of such term which 
    are appropriate to the activities of the agency and publishes such 
    definition(s) in the Federal Register.'' 5 U.S.C. 601(3). The SBA has 
    defined a small business for Standard Industrial Classification 
    (``SIC'') category 4813 (Telephone Communications, Except 
    Radiotelephone) to be an entity that has no more than 1,500 employees. 
    13 CFR 121.201.
        We have included small incumbent LECs in this RFA analysis. As 
    noted above, a ``small business'' under the RFA is one that, inter 
    alia, meets the pertinent small business size standard (e.g., a 
    telephone communications business having 1,500 or fewer employees), and 
    ``is not dominant in its field of operation.'' 5 U.S.C. 601(3). The 
    SBA's Office of Advocacy contends that, for RFA purposes, small 
    incumbent LECs are not dominant in their field of operation because any 
    such dominance is not ``national'' in scope. See Letter from Jere W. 
    Glover, Chief Counsel for Advocacy, SBA, to William E. Kennard, 
    Chairman, FCC (May 27, 1999). SBA regulations interpret ``small 
    business concern'' to include the concept of dominance on a national 
    basis. 13 CFR 121.102(b). Since 1996, out of an abundance of caution, 
    the Commission has included small incumbent LECs in its regulatory 
    flexibility analyses. See, e.g., Implementation of the Local 
    Competition Provisions of the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 61 FR 
    45476, August 29, 1996. We have therefore included small incumbent LECs 
    in this RFA analysis, although we emphasize that this RFA action has no 
    effect on Commission analyses and determinations in other, non-RFA 
    contexts.
        The proposals in the FNPRM apply only to price cap LECs. At the 
    current time, there are 13 price cap LECs. Of these companies, 11 are 
    listed in the Commission's most recent Statistics of Communications 
    Common Carriers (``SOCC'') report as having more than 1,500 employees. 
    Consequently, we estimate that 2 or fewer providers of local exchange 
    service are small price cap LECs that may be affected by these 
    proposals.
        Description of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping and Other 
    Compliance Requirements. We expect that, on balance, the proposals in 
    this FNPRM will not change price cap LECs' administrative burdens or 
    cause price cap LECs to incur any additional costs associated with 
    proposed reporting and recordkeeping requirements. The studies would 
    establish new X-factors that price cap LECs would need to utilize in 
    their price cap calculations, but otherwise should not affect their 
    administrative burdens or costs.
        Steps Taken to Minimize Significant Economic Impact on Small 
    Entities, and Significant Alternatives Considered. The RFA requires 
    agencies to describe any significant alternatives that it has 
    considered in reaching its proposed approach, which may include the 
    following four alternatives: (1) the establishment of differing 
    compliance or reporting requirements or timetables that take into 
    account the resources available to small entities; (2) the 
    clarification, consolidation, or simplification of compliance or 
    reporting requirements under the rule for small entities; (3) the use 
    of performance rather than design standards; and (4) an exemption from 
    coverage of the rule, or any part thereof, for small entities. 5 U.S.C. 
    603(c)(1)-(4). In the instant proceeding we are seeking comment on the 
    prescription of the productivity offset, or X-factor, portion of the 
    price cap formula. Therefore, only the first and last possible 
    alternatives listed in section 603(c) of the RFA would be applicable. 
    In the FNPRM, we seek comment on how the prescription of the X-factor 
    would affect smaller price cap LECs differently from other price cap 
    LECs, and whether there should be a separate X-factor calculated for 
    smaller price cap LECs. We also do
    
    [[Page 66447]]
    
    not believe it would be appropriate to exempt small price cap LECs from 
    the application of an X-factor. We seek comment on these issues and 
    urge commenting parties to support their comments with specific 
    evidence and analysis.
        Federal Rules that May Duplicate, Overlap, or Conflict With the 
    Proposed Rules. None.
    
    Filing of Comments and Reply Comments
    
        Pursuant to 47 CFR 1.415, 1.419, interested parties may file 
    comments on or before December 30, 1999 and reply comments on or before 
    January 14, 2000. Comments may be filed using the Commission's 
    Electronic Comment Filing System (``ECFS'') or by filing paper copies.
        Comments filed through the ECFS can be sent as an electronic file 
    via the Internet to http://www.fcc.gov/e-file/ecfs.html>. In 
    completing the transmittal screen, commenters should include their full 
    name, Postal Service mailing address, and the applicable docket or 
    rulemaking number. Parties may also submit an electronic comment by 
    Internet e-mail. To get filing instructions for e-mail comments, 
    commenters should send an e-mail to ecfs@fcc.gov, and should include 
    the following words in the body of the message, ``get form .'' A sample form and directions will be sent in reply. Only 
    one copy of electronically-filed comments must be submitted.
        Parties who choose to file by paper must file an original and four 
    copies of each filing. All filings must be sent to the Commission's 
    Secretary, Magalie Roman Salas, Office of the Secretary, Federal 
    Communications Commission, 445 12th Street, S.W., Room TW-B204, 
    Washington, D.C. 20554.
        Parties who choose to file by paper should also submit their 
    comments on diskette. The diskette should be submitted to: Wanda 
    Harris, Federal Communications Commission, Common Carrier Bureau, 
    Competitive Pricing Division, 445 12th Street, S.W., Fifth Floor, 
    Washington, D.C. 20554. The submission should be on a 3.5 inch diskette 
    formatted in an IBM compatible format using WordPerfect 5.1 for Windows 
    or compatible software. The diskette should be accompanied by a cover 
    letter and should be submitted in ``read only'' mode. The diskette 
    should be clearly labeled with the commenter's name, proceeding 
    (including the docket number in this case), type of pleading (comments 
    or reply comments), date of submission, and the name of the electronic 
    file on the diskette. The label should also include the following 
    phrase: ``Disk Copy--Not an Original.'' Each diskette should contain 
    only one party's pleadings, preferably in a single electronic file. In 
    addition, commenters must send diskette copies to the Commission's copy 
    contractor, International Transcription Service, Inc., 1231 20th 
    Street, N.W., Washington, D.C. 20036. Comments and reply comments will 
    be available for public inspection during regular business hours in the 
    FCC Reference Center, 445 12th Street, S.W., Room CY-A257, Washington, 
    D.C. 20554.
    
    Ordering Clauses
    
        Pursuant to the authority contained in sections 1, 4(i), 4(j), 201-
    205, and 303(r) of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended, 47 
    U.S.C. 151, 154(i), (j), 201-205, and 303(r), Notice Is Hereby Given of 
    the rulemaking described above and that Comment Is Sought on those 
    issues.
        The Commission's Office of Public Affairs, Reference Operations 
    Division, Shall Send a copy of this Further Notice of Proposed 
    Rulemaking, including the Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis, to 
    the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the Small Business Administration.
    
    List of Subjects in 47 CFR Part 61
    
        Communications common carriers, Tariffs.
    
    Federal Communications Commission.
    Magalie Roman Salas,
    Secretary.
    [FR Doc. 99-30741 Filed 11-24-99; 8:45 am]
    BILLING CODE 6712-01-P
    
    
    

Document Information

Published:
11/26/1999
Department:
Federal Communications Commission
Entry Type:
Proposed Rule
Action:
Notice of proposed rulemaking.
Document Number:
99-30741
Dates:
Comments are due on or before December 30, 1999, and reply comments are due on or before January 14, 2000.
Pages:
66442-66447 (6 pages)
Docket Numbers:
CC Docket Nos. 94-1 and 96-262, FCC 99-345
PDF File:
99-30741.pdf
CFR: (1)
47 CFR 61