94-27091. Inquiry Concerning the Commission's Pricing Policy for Transmission Services Provided by Public Utilities Under the Federal Power Act; Policy Statement  

  • [Federal Register Volume 59, Number 212 (Thursday, November 3, 1994)]
    [Unknown Section]
    [Page 0]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 94-27091]
    
    
    [[Page Unknown]]
    
    [Federal Register: November 3, 1994]
    
    
    =======================================================================
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
    
    Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
    
    18 CFR Part 2
    
    [Docket No. RM93-19-000]
    
     
    
    Inquiry Concerning the Commission's Pricing Policy for 
    Transmission Services Provided by Public Utilities Under the Federal 
    Power Act; Policy Statement
    
        Issued: October 26, 1994.
    
    AGENCY: Department of Energy, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission.
    
    ACTION: Final rule; policy statement.
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    SUMMARY: The Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (Commission) is 
    issuing this policy statement to announce a general policy regarding 
    the pricing of transmission services provided by public utilities and 
    transmitting utilities under the Federal Power Act.
        The new policy is designed to allow much greater transmission 
    pricing flexibility than was allowed under previous Commission 
    policies.
    
    EFFECTIVE DATE: This policy statement is effective as of October 26, 
    1994.
    
    FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
    
    James H. Douglass, Office of the General Counsel, Federal Energy 
    Regulatory Commission, 825 North Capitol Street, NE., Washington, DC 
    20426, Telephone: (202) 208-2143 (legal issues)
    Stephen J. Henderson, Office of Economic Policy, Federal Energy 
    Regulatory Commission, 825 North Capitol Street, NE., Washington, DC 
    20426, Telephone: (202) 208-0100 (technical issues)
    
    SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: In addition to publishing the full text of 
    this document in the Federal Register, the Commission also provides all 
    interested persons an opportunity to inspect or copy the contents of 
    this document during normal business hours in Room 3104, at 941 North 
    Capitol Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426.
        The Commission Issuance Posting System (CIPS), an electronic 
    bulletin board service, provides access to the texts of formal 
    documents issued by the Commission. CIPS is available at no charge to 
    the user and may be accessed using a personal computer with a modem by 
    dialing (202) 208-1397. To access CIPS, set your communications 
    software to use 300, 1200, or 2400 bps, full duplex, no parity, 8 data 
    bits and 1 stop bit. CIPS can also be accessed at 9600 bps by dialing 
    (202) 208-1781. The full text of this order will be available on CIPS 
    for 30 days from the date of issuance. The complete text on diskette in 
    WordPerfect format may also be purchased from the Commission's copy 
    contractor, La Dorn Systems Corporation, also located in Room 3104, 941 
    North Capitol Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426.E-1
    
    Policy Statement
    
        Issued: October 26, 1994.
    
        The Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (Commission) announces a 
    new policy regarding the pricing of transmission services provided by 
    public utilities and transmitting utilities under the Federal Power Act 
    (FPA).\1\ The new policy is designed to allow much greater transmission 
    pricing flexibility than was allowed under previous Commission 
    policies.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \1\16 U.S.C. 824(e), 796(23).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Greater pricing flexibility is appropriate in light of the 
    significant competitive changes occurring in wholesale generation 
    markets, and in light of our expanded wheeling authority under the 
    Energy Policy Act of 1992 (EPAct).\2\ These recent events underscore 
    the importance of ensuring that our transmission pricing policies 
    promote economic efficiency, fairly compensate utilities for providing 
    transmission services, reflect a reasonable allocation of transmission 
    costs among transmission users, and maintain the reliability of the 
    transmission grid. The Commission also recognizes that advances in 
    computer modeling techniques have made possible certain transmission 
    pricing methods that once would have been impractical.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \2\See 16 U.S.C. 824j, 824k.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Based on the record developed in this proceeding, the Commission 
    concludes that there appears to be a variety of workable, non-
    traditional transmission pricing methods that offer potential 
    improvements in fairness, practicality and economic efficiency. For 
    instance, the Commission believes that distance- sensitive rates using 
    contract path or flow-based methods will be acceptable if properly 
    supported.
        Accordingly, the Commission will permit more flexibility to 
    utilities to file innovative pricing proposals that meet the 
    traditional revenue requirement and will allow such proposals to become 
    effective 60 days after filing,\3\ as long as they satisfy certain 
    pricing principles discussed below. We refer to this category of 
    proposals as conforming proposals. We will also permit utilities to 
    file pricing proposals that deviate from the traditional revenue 
    requirement, as long as they meet certain requirements discussed below. 
    We refer to these filings as non- conforming proposals. Non-conforming 
    proposals will be permitted to go into effect only prospectively from 
    the date the Commission determines that such a pricing proposal meets 
    the statutory requirements of the FPA, i.e., is just and reasonable and 
    not unduly discriminatory or preferential.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \3\Whether to suspend such a filing and impose a refund 
    condition will be decided on a case-by-case basis. See West Texas 
    Utilities Company, 18 FERC  61,189 (1982).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In addition to the guidance in this Policy Statement regarding 
    conforming and non-conforming transmission pricing proposals, there are 
    two specific subject areas for which we have instituted separate 
    proceedings, and which may require transmission pricing flexibility. 
    See Recovery of Stranded Costs by Public Utilities and Transmitting 
    Utilities, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, IV FERC Stats. & Regs.  
    32,507, 59 FR 35274 (July 11, 1994); Alternative Power Pooling 
    Institutions under the Federal Power Act, Notice of Inquiry, FERC 
    Stats. & Regs.  ________ (1994). In those proceedings, we are 
    examining what type of pricing policy is appropriate. We intend to 
    examine whether any special procedural mechanisms are necessary to 
    coordinate our pricing policy and filings proposing alternative power 
    pooling institutions.
    
    I. Introduction
    
        The Commission will consider a broad range of rate design methods, 
    within a utility's embedded original cost revenue requirement, as 
    discussed in Section IV. We will also consider proposals that deviate 
    from a utility's embedded original cost revenue requirement (subject to 
    certain filing procedures and evaluation criteria), as discussed in 
    Section V. The U.S. Supreme Court has recognized the Commission's broad 
    latitude to fix rates. There is no single valid theory of ratemaking. 
    Under the statutory standard of ``just and reasonable'' it is the 
    result reached, not the method employed, which is controlling. Duquesne 
    Light Co. v. Barasch, 488 U.S. 299, 316 (1989) (Duquesne); Federal 
    Power Commission v. Hope Natural Gas Co., 320 U.S. 591, 602 (1944) 
    (Hope). As the Court observed in Duquesne:
    
        The designation of a single theory of ratemaking as a 
    constitutional requirement would unnecessarily foreclose 
    alternatives which could benefit both consumers and investors.
    
    488 U.S. at 316. Consistent with our broad ratemaking authority, in 
    this Policy Statement we announce that we will consider various 
    ratemaking methods to encourage proposals that will produce consumer 
    benefits.
        The Commission's traditional transmission pricing policy has 
    permitted a public utility providing firm transmission service to 
    charge rates designed to yield annual revenues equal to the rolled-in 
    embedded cost\4\ of the utility's integrated transmission grid on a 
    postage stamp basis (i.e., not distance sensitive), including the 
    rolled-in costs of any new facilities or upgrades that become part of 
    the integrated system. For non-firm transmission service, the 
    Commission has permitted rates to reflect, in addition to the variable 
    costs of providing the service, a charge up to a 100 percent 
    contribution to the fixed costs of providing the service, with the 
    proviso that pricing must reflect the characteristics of the service 
    provided, e.g., the degree of interruptibility. Traditionally, 
    transmission rates have been based on a ``contract path'' model, i.e., 
    an assumed transmission path from point A to point B, that may or may 
    not represent the actual flows of power on the grid.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \4\Embedded cost is generally viewed as including a fair rate of 
    return on the original cost of facilities, less depreciation, plus 
    operation and maintenance expenses, and taxes. Embedded costs are 
    those costs reflected in the utility's books of account.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In recent years, the Commission attempted to address the industry's 
    changing needs by modifying its historical transmission pricing 
    policy\5\ to allow a type of incremental cost pricing.\6\ In order to 
    provide new or expanded transmission service, a utility may be required 
    to add expensive transmission assets, which can result in an increase 
    in rolled-in embedded cost rates. To address this possibility, the 
    Commission has allowed a utility to charge transmission-only customers 
    the higher of embedded costs (for the system as expanded) or 
    incremental expansion costs, but not the sum of the two.\7\ When the 
    transmission grid is constrained and the utility chooses not to expand 
    its system, the Commission has allowed a utility to charge the higher 
    of embedded costs or legitimate and verifiable opportunity costs, but 
    not the sum of the two. The opportunity costs, in turn, are capped by 
    incremental expansion costs. This type of pricing has been referred to 
    as ``or'' pricing or Northeast Utilities pricing.\8\ While ``or'' 
    pricing will continue to be allowed under the Commission's pricing 
    policy, the Commission is prepared to move beyond ``or'' pricing to 
    consider other pricing alternatives.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \5\See Northeast Utilities Service Company (Re: Public Service 
    Company of New Hampshire), Opinion No. 364-A, 58 FERC 61,070, reh'g 
    denied,  Opinion No. 364-B, 59 FERC 61,042, order granting motion 
    to vacate and dismissing request for rehearing, 59 FERC 61,089 
    (1992), affirmed in part and remanded in part sub nom. Northeast 
    Utilities Service Company v. FERC, Nos. 92-1165, et al., 993 F.2d 
    937 (1st Cir. 1993), order on remand, 66 FERC 61,332, reh'g denied, 
    68 FERC 61,041 (1994), appeal pending No. 94-1949 (1st Cir. Sept. 
    6, 1994); Pennsylvania Electric Company, 58 FERC 61,278, reh'g 
    denied and pricing policy clarified, 60 FERC 61,034, reh'g denied, 
    60 FERC 61,244 (1992), affirmed sub nom. Pennsylvania Electric Co. 
    v. FERC, 11 F.3d 207 (D.C. Cir. 1993) (Penelec).
        \6\Incremental cost is the cost of increasing the level of 
    service provided. In practice, it typically refers to the cost of 
    additional facilities needed to provide the requested service.
        \7\This current pricing policy is based on three goals that the 
    Commission adopted in the Northeast Utilities case: (1) to hold 
    native load customers harmless, (2) to provide the lowest reasonable 
    cost-based price to third-party firm transmission customers, and (3) 
    to prevent the collection of monopoly rents by transmission owners 
    and promote efficient transmission decisions.
        \8\See supra note 5.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    II. Request for Comments
    
        On June 30, 1993, the Commission issued a notice of technical 
    conference and request for comments concerning these policies and other 
    transmission pricing issues. Inquiry Concerning the Commission's 
    Pricing Policy for Transmission Services Provided by Public Utilities 
    Under the Federal Power Act, IV FERC Stats. & Regs., Notices 35,024 
    (1993) (Pricing Inquiry). The Commission received comments and reply 
    comments from 165 entities, representing a broad cross-section of 
    parties that participate in, or are affected by, the electric utility 
    industry. The Commission also held technical conferences on April 8 and 
    15, 1994, that provided further opportunity for public comment and 
    discussion. A summary of the comments received in this proceeding that 
    included proposals for change is presented in Appendix A.\9\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \9\Appendix A will not appear in the Code of Federal 
    Regulations.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Those commenting expressed a variety of opinions on many 
    transmission pricing issues, including whether transmission rates 
    should reflect distance sensitivity and whether and how to compensate 
    for flows over parallel paths. The commenters were nearly unanimous in 
    their call for the Commission to provide further guidance concerning 
    acceptable pricing methods. Some commenters indicated that such 
    guidance would assist the formation of regional transmission groups 
    (RTGs) by indicating what pricing policies will be acceptable to the 
    Commission.
        While many of the comments expressed dissatisfaction with the 
    Commission's current pricing policy, the comments indicated no 
    consensus for any one alternative pricing method. However, the 
    commenters expressed general agreement that some type of transmission 
    pricing reform by the Commission is needed. There was a strong 
    consensus that such reform should: (1) Allow greater pricing 
    flexibility; (2) provide pricing that is ``transparent''\10\ and easy 
    to administer; (3) promote economic efficiency, that is, allow 
    transmission customers to make informed decisions as to the economic 
    consequences of their choices, and encourage transmission owners to 
    make efficient use of, and investment in, the transmission grid; (4) 
    ensure equity and fairness; and (5) facilitate the development of 
    RTGs.\11\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \10\We interpret the commenters to mean that transmission 
    pricing would be identified separately from generation pricing, that 
    transmission pricing would identify all cost components of the 
    transmission service (e.g., identify ancillary service costs) and 
    that pricing information would be readily available to all bulk 
    power participants.
        \11\Two RTG agreements recently filed with the Commission 
    postpone dealing with the transmission pricing issue by simply 
    providing that pricing shall be consistent with the Commission's 
    transmission pricing policy. See Pacificorp et al. (on behalf of 
    Western Regional Transmission Association), 69 FERC ________ 
    (1994); Southwest Regional Transmission Association, 69 FERC 
    ________) (1994).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        However, there was disagreement regarding the degree to which 
    reform of transmission pricing should stress administrative simplicity 
    versus accuracy. Some commenters advocated the continued use of 
    traditional contract path and postage stamp rates, in part because 
    these rates are simple to administer. Other commenters proposed 
    methods, such as distance sensitive and flow-based rates, that may give 
    better price signals but involve more complexity.
        In response to the comments received, the Commission has decided to 
    revise its policies to permit utilities much greater flexibility. We 
    are prepared to accept a variety of pricing methods in addition to 
    Northeast Utilities pricing. Northeast Utilities pricing will still be 
    acceptable because it fully comports with the pricing principles we 
    adopt today. However, based on the record developed herein, a variety 
    of other pricing methods will also be acceptable.
        The Commission concludes that greater pricing flexibility is now 
    required for several reasons. First, exclusive use of methods that 
    worked reasonably well in the past does not provide sufficient 
    flexibility to accommodate the evolving needs of transmission owners 
    and users in a more competitive era.\12\ It is important to gain 
    practical experience with alternative transmission pricing approaches 
    in order to assess how best to accommodate the current and future needs 
    of the industry in providing efficient and reliable power supply as the 
    industry becomes increasingly competitive. Second, our existing ``or'' 
    pricing policy may not always encourage the most efficient investments 
    in and use of the transmission grid. Third, regional differences (e.g., 
    power flow patterns and population densities) justify a more flexible 
    policy that can account for such differences. Fourth, a more flexible 
    pricing policy may be necessary to implement effectively our RTG 
    policy, which encourages RTGs to deal with a broad range of issues, 
    including pricing, and which suggests that the Commission, in 
    appropriate circumstances, will defer to RTG decision-making.\13\ The 
    Commission is convinced that a more flexible pricing policy can help to 
    achieve broader policy goals and be implemented in a manner that is 
    just and reasonable and not unduly discriminatory or preferential.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \12\See American Electric Power Service Corporation, 67 FERC  
    61,168 at 61,490 (1994).
        \13\Policy Statement Regarding Regional Transmission Groups, 58 
    FR 41626 (Aug. 5, 1993) III FERC Stats. & Regs.  30, 976 (July 30, 
    1993) (RTG Policy Statement).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In developing a more flexible transmission pricing policy, the 
    Commission's basic premise is that comparable access to efficiently 
    priced transmission services is critical to the continued development 
    of a competitive wholesale power market. With this fundamental 
    underpinning in mind, the Commission has developed several pricing 
    principles that new pricing proposals should follow. Some of these 
    principles reflect existing pricing requirements that any new proposal 
    must continue to follow. Other principles, while important, may have to 
    be balanced against one another.
        Before discussing the pricing principles and specific new 
    methodologies that may be acceptable, there are several points we would 
    like to make. First, the Commission believes that improving price 
    signals is an important goal, but recognizes that trade-offs between 
    improved price signals and simplicity are inevitable. On one hand, 
    transmission service is typically a small component of the total cost 
    of electric service and, therefore, arguably does not merit overly 
    complex pricing methods.\14\ On the other hand, in many cases 
    transmission capacity is a scarce and valuable resource, and its 
    pricing can send signals that promote the efficient siting of 
    generation facilities and efficient decisions as to the dispatch of 
    generation. In addition, new technological advances, particularly in 
    computer technology, have made certain innovative pricing methodologies 
    workable in practice. We therefore must balance the sometimes competing 
    goals of better price signals and simplicity when evaluating any new 
    pricing methodologies.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \14\Historically, transmission plant has represented less than 
    12 percent of total electric plant in service for major investor-
    owned Electric Utilities and generally less than 6 percent of the 
    cost of electricity to end users. (Derived from cost data in 1992 
    Energy Information Administration Financial Statistics of Major 
    Investor-Owned Electric Utilities.)
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Second, the Commission also recognizes that it must move beyond 
    certain precedent in order to entertain alternative pricing proposals. 
    For example, instead of requiring a single postage stamp rate for 
    transmission over the integrated transmission system of a corporation, 
    such as a holding company system with several affiliated operating 
    companies,\15\ we will now entertain proposals such as zonal rates\16\ 
    that take distance within the corporation into account, provided that 
    such proposals are consistent with the pricing principles that we adopt 
    today.\17\ Having analyzed new methodologies presented in the record, 
    we believe that some departures from our traditional integrated system 
    pricing requirement will be supportable under the FPA if appropriately 
    developed.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \15\See, e.g., Southern Company Services, 55 FERC 61,173 
    (1991), order on reh'g, 58 FERC 61,093 (1991), aff'd, Alabama Power 
    Company v. FERC, 993 F.2d 1557 (D.C. Cir. 1993).
        \16\Under zonal rates, a utility's facilities are divided 
    (disaggregated) into a number of zones. The total cost assigned to 
    any request for transmission service would depend on the number of 
    zones traversed and the rate for each zone.
        \17\If a utility, or public utility holding company system, 
    proposes to disaggregate its integrated transmission system into 
    distinct components (or zones) for purposes of developing 
    transmission rates for third parties, it must apply the same 
    approach consistently and uniformly across the entire system for all 
    uses of the system, including its own uses.
        We caution that any such zonal approach or other disaggregated 
    approach would also need to appropriately recognize all flows on the 
    system. For example, if flows are used to allocate costs on some 
    lines, flows should be used to allocate costs for all remaining 
    lines in the same way; e.g., it would not be acceptable to presume 
    that each transmission customer proportionally uses and relies upon 
    all remaining lines of the integrated system.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Third, as previously noted, several commenters urged the Commission 
    to provide a framework for reforming pricing that would supplement the 
    Commission's RTG Policy Statement. The Commission continues to believe 
    that it would be appropriate for RTGs to address transmission pricing. 
    We anticipate that the pricing flexibility provided herein, and our 
    willingness to give appropriate deference to RTG decisions, will not 
    only encourage the development of RTGs, but will also encourage RTGs to 
    address transmission pricing, including regional issues affecting such 
    pricing.
        Finally, we do not want our policy to be so rigid that utilities 
    will be prohibited from proposing pricing alternatives that may deviate 
    from the traditional revenue requirement. Because transmission remains 
    a natural monopoly, we believe it will be difficult for transmission 
    owners to support such pricing under the FPA, particularly market-based 
    transmission rates. However, we believe that it would be shortsighted 
    to foreclose completely consideration of such non-conforming proposals. 
    The electric utility industry of today is very different from the 
    electric utility industry that existed only 20 years ago and even five 
    years ago. Just as we today change our policies to reflect recent 
    changes, we must remain flexible if we are to respond to future 
    changes. Accordingly, we detail procedures and standards below that 
    will be used in evaluating transmission pricing proposals that do not 
    conform to the traditional revenue requirement.
        We now turn to the requirements of the FPA and the pricing 
    principles that we have developed consistent with those requirements.
    
    III. Transmission Pricing Principles
    
        Transmission pricing must adhere to the FPA requirement that 
    transmission rates be just and reasonable and not unduly discriminatory 
    or preferential. This requirement is found in sections 205, 206, and 
    212. In addition, section 212(a) requires that wholesale transmission 
    rates for services ordered under section 211 must:
         Permit the recovery of all costs incurred in connection 
    with the transmission services and necessary associated services, 
    including, but not limited to, an appropriate share, if any, of 
    legitimate, verifiable and economic costs, including taking into 
    account any benefits to the transmission system of providing the 
    transmission service, and the costs of any enlargement of transmission 
    facilities;
         Promote the economically efficient transmission and 
    generation of electricity; and
         To the extent practicable, ensure that costs incurred in 
    providing the wholesale transmission services, and properly allocable 
    to the provision of such services, are recovered from the applicant for 
    the 211 order and not from a transmitting utility's existing wholesale, 
    retail, and transmission customers.
    
    Consistent with these statutory requirements, which give the Commission 
    discretion in setting rates within the zone of reasonableness, and in 
    light of the comments received in response to the Pricing Inquiry, we 
    have formulated five principles that will guide our approval of pricing 
    for both firm and non-firm transmission services in the future. The 
    Commission believes these principles comport with the statutory 
    requirements of sections 205, 206 and 212 of the FPA, and, in the 
    interest of developing a uniform transmission pricing policy, we will 
    apply these same principles to the pricing of transmission service 
    whether that service is provided under section 205, 206, or 211 of the 
    FPA.
        The first two principles reflect fundamental requirements 
    previously established by the Commission. A conforming proposal is one 
    that meets the first principle, i.e., it proposes pricing that meets 
    the traditional revenue requirement. A conforming proposal must also 
    meet the second principle, i.e., it must reflect comparability. As to 
    the other three principles, however, these reflect goals that an 
    applicant with a conforming proposal must try to meet, but that 
    ultimately may need to be balanced against one another in the 
    Commission's determination of whether the proposed rates are just and 
    reasonable.
        A non-conforming proposal is one that does not meet the first 
    principle, i.e., it does not propose pricing that meets the traditional 
    revenue requirement. However, a non-conforming proposal must meet the 
    second principle, i.e., it must reflect comparability. If a non-
    conforming proposal does not clearly demonstrate that the comparability 
    requirement is met, it will be rejected. As to the remaining three 
    principles, these reflect goals that an applicant with a non-conforming 
    proposal must try to meet, but that may need to be balanced against one 
    another. In addition, as part of its balancing, the Commission will 
    consider the extent to which the first principle is not met.\18\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \18\A pricing proposal that deviates from cost only slightly may 
    be easier to justify than one that results in prices several times 
    cost.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We discuss these principles in detail below.
    
    1. Transmission Pricing Must Meet the Traditional Revenue Requirement
    
        For conforming proposals, transmission prices must be based on the 
    costs of the transmission service provided. The process of determining 
    transmission prices involves three distinct steps. First, a utility 
    must determine its total company revenue requirement, the capital 
    component of which traditionally has been measured by embedded 
    (depreciated original) cost. Second, a utility must allocate among 
    individual customers or classes of customers that portion of the total 
    revenue requirement that is attributable to providing transmission 
    services, in a manner which appropriately reflects the costs of 
    providing transmission service to such customers or classes of 
    customers. Finally, the utility must design rates to recover those 
    allocated costs from each customer class.
        Different customers may pay different rates if they use the system 
    in different ways. In the aggregate, however, rates are designed so 
    that a transmission owner meets, but does not exceed, its revenue 
    requirement. That is, it should be able to collect revenues from all 
    its customers equal to the sum of its prudently incurred embedded 
    costs, including return on capital.
        There are two reasons for requiring transmission pricing to meet 
    the traditional revenue requirement. First, it appears that 
    transmission will remain a natural monopoly for the foreseeable future. 
    It is unlikely that market-based prices for monopoly services, 
    especially for firm transmission service, could be justified under the 
    FPA at the present time, under the current industry structure. However, 
    it is clear that there is no single appropriate ratemaking method under 
    the FPA. The end result is the appropriate yardstick against which to 
    measure the legality of a rate order, not the ratemaking method. Thus, 
    although no single ratemaking method is necessarily favored by the FPA, 
    this pricing principle will ensure that transmission users pay a just 
    and reasonable price for transmission services and that transmission 
    owners, while being appropriately and adequately compensated,\19\ will 
    not be able to exercise their market power to collect exorbitant rates.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \19\Duquesne, 488 U.S. at 316; Bluefield Water Works & 
    Improvement Co. v. Public Service Commission of the State of West 
    Virginia, 262 U.S. 679 (1923); Hope, 320 U.S. at 602.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Second, we believe that pricing within an embedded cost revenue 
    requirement provides adequate incentives for transmission owners to 
    provide comparable transmission services, as long as the transmission 
    owner has the opportunity for full cost recovery. When upgrades are 
    required, the transmission owner may incur significant expenses related 
    to planning and siting new facilities. For example, a utility may be 
    required to pay for environmental mitigation associated with the 
    construction of new transmission facilities. Such costs will be 
    recoverable by the transmission owner if they are prudently incurred.
        In addition, under the traditional revenue requirement principle, 
    transmission owners clearly may, with appropriate support,\20\ recover 
    the legitimate and verifiable costs of services they provide that are 
    ancillary to transmission services, such as load following, reactive 
    power compensation, and backup power services. However, transmission 
    customers should also be permitted to provide these services themselves 
    or to obtain them from someone else if this is feasible.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \20\See  Northern States Power Company (Minnesota and Wisconsin) 
    Opinion No. 383, 64 FERC 61,324 (1993), reh'g pending (reactive 
    power).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Finally, as discussed in Section IV below, we intend to allow 
    significant latitude and a wide variety of non-traditional rate design 
    proposals, within a cost cap based on the total company revenue 
    requirement.
    
    2. Transmission Pricing Must Reflect Comparability
    
        Any new transmission pricing proposal, conforming or non- 
    conforming, must meet the Commission's recently announced comparability 
    standard. In American Electric Power Service Corporation (AEP), 67 FERC 
    61,168 (1994), the Commission articulated a new standard for judging 
    whether access to transmission services is unduly discriminatory, or 
    anticompetitive. The Commission noted that ``[a]n open access tariff 
    that is not unduly discriminatory or anticompetitive should offer third 
    parties access on the same or comparable basis, and under the same or 
    comparable terms and conditions, as the transmission provider's uses of 
    its system.''\21\ This principle has been applied to all open access 
    tariffs filed since AEP, as well as to transmission services provided 
    by RTGs.\22\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \21\67 FERC at 61,490.
        \22\See PacifiCorp, et al. (on behalf of Western Regional 
    Transmission Association), 69 FERC ______; Southwest Regional 
    Transmission Association, 69 FERC at ______.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        There is a relationship between price and quality of service (i.e., 
    in general, higher quality service costs more). In Florida Municipal 
    Power Agency v. Florida Power & Light Co., 67 FERC 61,167 at 61,482 
    (1994) (FMPA), the Commission stated, ``[s]ince FMPA wants to be able 
    to use the transmission system as freely as does Florida Power, it must 
    pay a rate that reflects that equality.'' As a result of the 
    relationship between quality of service and price discussed most 
    recently in FMPA, and the growing importance of service comparability, 
    we will require that pricing be comparable. Comparability of service 
    applies to price as well as to terms and conditions. Comparability of 
    transmission pricing involves a ``golden rule of pricing''--a 
    transmission owner should charge itself on the same or comparable basis 
    that it charges others for the same service.\23\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \23\There is a similar ``golden rule or access''--provide the 
    same or comparable services to others as you provide yourself.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        This golden rule has several implications. First, for purposes of 
    setting FERC-jurisdictional rates, costs must be allocated between 
    jurisdictional and non-jurisdictional customers in a consistent way, to 
    determine the cost responsibility of the two sets of customers.\24\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \24\The Commission is not in any way suggesting any interference 
    with state authority to determine the appropriate ratemaking 
    methodology for bundled retail sales.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Second, when a utility uses its own transmission system to make 
    off-system sales, it should ``pay'' for transmission service at the 
    same price that third-party customers pay for the same service, and 
    credit the transmission revenues to its native load customers. This 
    treatment restricts the transmission owner's ability to gain an unfair 
    advantage in the bulk power market by selling itself transmission 
    service at a discount that would be subsidized by native load and 
    transmission-only customers.\25\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \25\In PSI, for example, the Commission required that PSI take 
    transmission service under its own transmission tariff when making 
    market-based power sales. The Commission adopted this approach to 
    prevent PSI from using its transmission ownership to exercise an 
    unfair competitive advantage in wholesale power markets. Public 
    Service Company of Indiana, Inc., Opinion No. 349, 51 FERC  61,367 
    at 62,201 (1990), order on rehearing, PSI Energy, Inc., 52 FERC  
    61,260, order granting clarification, 53 FERC  61,131 (1990), 
    appeal dismissed sub nom. Northern Indiana Public Service Co. v. 
    FERC, 954 F.2d 736 (D.C. Cir. 1992).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Pricing comparability does not mean that the Commission is 
    endorsing an end result in which there are no differences in prices 
    paid by various customers. For example, the Commission is not 
    suggesting that prices must be based on highly aggregated costs so that 
    all customers face a uniform rate per kWh of service. Rather, we are 
    receptive to pricing proposals that disaggregate costs in order to give 
    better price signals to all users of the system--third parties and the 
    transmission owner itself. Such disaggregation still permits different 
    customers to pay different prices. Pricing comparability does not rule 
    out such a result.
        Finally, comparability of pricing includes certainty of pricing. A 
    transmission customer should have pricing certainty comparable to that 
    of the transmitting utility, e.g., the same transmission pricing 
    certainty for long-term power contracts as the transmitting utility 
    has.
    
    3. Transmission Pricing Should Promote Economic Efficiency
    
        Section 212(a) of the FPA, as amended by EPAct, states that 
    transmission pricing should promote economically efficient generation 
    and transmission of electricity.\26\ In our view, this means that 
    transmission pricing should promote good decision-making and foster:
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \26\16 U.S.C. 824k(a).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
         Efficient expansion of transmission capacity;
         Efficient location of new generators and new load;
         Efficient use of existing transmission facilities, 
    including the efficient allocation of constrained capacity through 
    appropriate market clearing mechanisms; and
         Efficient dispatch of existing generating resources.
    
    To the extent practicable, transmission rates should be designed to 
    reflect marginal costs,\27\ rather than embedded costs, in a manner 
    consistent with the remaining principles. We favor marginal cost prices 
    in order to promote efficient decision-making by both transmission 
    owners and users.\28\ In the short-run, marginal transmission costs are 
    primarily line losses and, when lines are congested, opportunity costs. 
    In the long-run, marginal transmission costs include all the costs of 
    the transmission system and support services. The Commission recognizes 
    the complexity of estimating marginal cost on the transmission grid and 
    of implementing pricing that follows marginal transmission costs, but 
    we encourage experimentation in this area.\29\ On a case-by-case basis, 
    we will balance the desirability of more economically efficient price 
    signals against the additional complexity of implementing such pricing.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \27\Alfred Kahn, infra n.28, defines marginal cost as ``[t]he 
    cost of producing one more unit; it can equally be envisioned as the 
    cost that would be saved by producing one less unit.''
        \28\See 1 Alfred E. Kahn, The Economics of Regulation 63-86.
        \29\Such proposals should be fully supported, with as much 
    detail as possible. See New England Power Company, Opinion No. 352, 
    52 FERC  61,090 (1990), reh'g denied, Opinion No. 352-A, 54 FERC  
    61,055 (1991), aff'd sub nom. Town of Norwood, Massachusetts v. 
    FERC, 962 F.2d 20 (D.C. Cir. 1992).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    4. Transmission Pricing Should Promote Fairness
    
        As a general matter, transmission pricing should be fair and 
    equitable. This has two important implications. First, the EPAct 
    requires that, to the extent practicable, existing wholesale, retail 
    and transmission customers should not pay for the costs incurred in 
    providing wholesale transmission services ordered under section 211. 
    Similarly, we do not believe that third-party transmission customers 
    should subsidize existing customers. We believe this principle should 
    apply equally to transmission services under both section 211 and 
    sections 205 and 206.
        A second implication of the fairness principle is that economic 
    harm that could be created during a period of transition from one 
    pricing approach to another should be mitigated to the extent 
    practicable. Solutions to any transition problems arising from pricing 
    reform should balance fairness considerations associated with any 
    reform against the potential efficiency improvements, and should 
    mitigate the hardships arising from any reform. The major purpose of 
    transmission pricing reform should be to provide more efficient price 
    signals, particularly for new transmission uses, and not simply to 
    reallocate sunk costs.
    
    5. Transmission Pricing Should Be Practical
    
        Transmission pricing should be practical and as easy to administer 
    as appropriate given the other pricing principles. A user should be 
    able to calculate how much it will be charged for transmission service. 
    Some pricing proposals may be so complex that they are difficult to 
    understand and analyze. Such complexity, while not fatal, should be 
    balanced by efficiency gains or other advantages produced by such 
    complexity.
    
    IV. Guidance Regarding Pricing Proposals That Conform to the 
    Traditional Revenue Requirement
    
        In addition to the five general principles above, the Commission 
    provides guidance on specific pricing proposals, including examples of 
    acceptable pricing approaches and clarification of limitations on 
    pricing flexibility.
        It is important for those involved in transmission pricing 
    discussions and negotiations to have a common understanding of the 
    attributes of various pricing proposals. For example, various parties 
    advocate the use of ``megawatt mile'' pricing. Several distinct pricing 
    proposals carry the same ``megawatt mile'' label. Therefore, those 
    proposing transmission pricing reform must provide a clear explanation 
    of their proposal.
        As the industry considers possible pricing reform, the following 
    three attributes of any transmission pricing method should be specified 
    to provide a common framework for analysis:
         The method for measuring cost for purposes of rate design: 
    embedded cost, incremental cost, the Commission's current ``or'' 
    policy, long-run marginal cost, or short-run marginal cost;
         The method for treating power flows: contract path or 
    flow-based approach; and,
         The method for grouping transmission facilities: corporate 
    postage stamp versus more disaggregated approaches, such as zones, or 
    line-by-line methods.\30\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \30\Under a line-by-line pricing method, the costs of each 
    transmission line, or segment, are allocated to individual 
    transmission transactions, based on the usage each transaction makes 
    of each line or segment.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We anticipate that a wide variety of pricing proposals may be 
    reconciled with the traditional revenue requirement. In theory, 
    acceptable cost-based pricing that satisfies our principles could be 
    designed for many combinations of these possible attributes. For 
    example, prices could reflect incremental cost (the first attribute), 
    be based on flow (the second attribute), and be allocated on a line-by-
    line basis (the third attribute). A different approach is taken by 
    changing any one of the attributes, e.g., zones instead of lines. 
    Therefore, many varieties of cost-based pricing are possible.
        We fully intend to be flexible and to consider innovative, 
    conforming pricing approaches that accommodate the changing needs of 
    the competitive bulk power market. This applies to pricing for firm as 
    well as non-firm transmission services. The pricing principles set out 
    in the prior section are intended to guide RTGs and individual 
    utilities in their consideration of new approaches. To provide further 
    guidance, we discuss below examples of new cost-based pricing methods 
    that we believe can be made consistent with our principles. These 
    examples are intended to be illustrative. Other approaches also may be 
    consistent with the principles. In all cases, we emphasize that pricing 
    reform must have a purpose consistent with the principles. We want 
    transmission pricing that supports good and consistent decisionmaking 
    by transmission system users and owners.
    
    A. Examples of Specific Pricing Methods That Conform to the Traditional 
    Revenue Requirement
    
        The following pricing approaches are examples of methods that the 
    Commission would find acceptable, assuming an adequate showing by the 
    utility. In this context, a conforming method is one that clearly meets 
    the first two fundamental requirements and demonstrates that it is 
    capable of satisfying the other three pricing principles (which 
    ultimately may need to be balanced against one another in the 
    Commission's determination of whether the proposed rates are just and 
    reasonable). Of course, the rates resulting from its use must be shown 
    to be just, reasonable and not unduly discriminatory or preferential.
    (1) Examples of Acceptable Transmission Pricing by an Individual 
    Utility
        A variety of pricing proposals from an individual utility could be 
    acceptable under the five pricing principles. The range of possible 
    approaches includes various combinations of: (1) a traditional contract 
    path approach or a flow-based approach; (2) costs aggregated at the 
    utility level, at a zonal level, or at the line-by-line level; and (3) 
    various cost concepts for rate design, such as embedded cost, ``or'' 
    cost, incremental cost, or short-run marginal cost. Not all of these 
    possible combinations, however, would necessarily satisfy our 
    principles.
        Examples of pricing reform that the Commission would approve if 
    proposed by an individual utility and if they satisfy our principles 
    include:
         Zonal ``or'' pricing based on power flows from zone to 
    zone within a utility, or within the members of a holding company 
    system. Zonal rates should be supported by showing the use made of 
    separate zones by an individual transaction. Such rates should be 
    supported by an explanation of the data base required and the computer 
    modeling needed to implement it.
         Flow-based line-by-line rates, based on embedded costs 
    ``or'' pricing. Such rates should be supported by an explanation of the 
    data base required and the computer modeling needed to implement it.
         ``Or'' pricing, at the corporate level using the 
    traditional contract path approach. This is the current Commission 
    standard and remains an acceptable pricing policy that satisfies our 
    pricing principles.
    (2) Examples of Acceptable Transmission Pricing by an RTG
        The Commission will provide substantial latitude for innovative, 
    conforming pricing proposals by a regional transmission group that 
    meets the requirements of our RTG Policy Statement.\31\ We will give 
    more latitude to RTGs than to individual utilities. This is for two 
    reasons. First, an RTG represents the combined interests of both 
    transmission owners and transmission users, as well as the appropriate 
    participation of state authorities, so pricing proposals are likely to 
    represent an appropriate balancing of those interests. Second, the more 
    attractive proposals for treating regional loop flow problems work 
    better if all the utilities in the region use the same method.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \31\Policy Statement Regarding Regional Transmission Groups, 58 
    FR 41626 (Aug. 5, 1993), III FERC Stats. & Regs. 30,976 (July 30, 
    1993); See also PacifiCorp, et al. (on behalf of Western Regional 
    Transmission Association), 69 FERC at ________; Southwest Regional 
    Transmission Association, 69 FERC at ________.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        An RTG could propose any pricing reform that is open to an 
    individual utility and also other reforms that address the loop flow 
    issue. Many approaches to reforming transmission pricing that were 
    suggested in the record of the Pricing Inquiry address the loop flow 
    issue and appear to require a regional approach. From the comments, the 
    Commission discerns two major alternatives to traditional contract path 
    pricing that RTGs could choose for dealing with loop flow:
         ``Enhanced'' contract path pricing, which improves the 
    contractual institutions underlying traditional contract path 
    trading;\32\ and
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \32\``Enhanced contract path'' refers to any approach intended 
    to reconcile capacity rights between points of receipt and delivery 
    and actual power flows on a network of lines.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
         Flow-based pricing, which refers to pricing designed to 
    reflect the actual or projected power flows associated with a 
    transaction.
        Cost-based pricing could be designed to accommodate either of these 
    alternatives. Examples of pricing reform based on a flow-based approach 
    that the Commission would look approvingly on if proposed by an RTG and 
    if consistent with our principles include:
         A MW-mile method, which could be implemented in one of 
    several ways. For example, it could be based on ``or'' pricing and 
    line-by-line power flows. Alternatively, a MW-mile approach could be 
    based on embedded cost for the whole company, allocated as the ratio of 
    transaction-specific megawatt-miles to total megawatt-miles.
         Postage-stamp ``or'' ratemaking at the utility level that 
    is combined with power flow analysis to determine the compensation due 
    to all transmission owners on the parallel paths. This would be a 
    departure from the current contract path approach.
         Zonal ``or'' pricing based on power flow analysis to 
    determine the use a transaction makes of the facilities in each zone.
         Short-run marginal cost pricing with transmission prices 
    based on line-by-line losses and opportunity costs caused by power flow 
    constraints.
        RTGs may be able to design a pricing approach that combines 
    elements of flow-based pricing with elements of contract path pricing. 
    An example might be contract-path pricing for capacity rights to engage 
    in long-term firm transactions combined with flow-based pricing for 
    short-term, nonfirm transactions that are not covered by such rights. 
    As can be seen from these examples, the Commission will provide RTGs 
    substantial flexibility in choosing among a wide range of pricing 
    approaches.
    (3) Examples of Unacceptable Transmission Pricing
        As discussed above, any pricing proposal, even a proposal that does 
    not conform to the traditional revenue requirement, must meet the just 
    and reasonable standard of the FPA. Below we list two types of pricing 
    proposals which we find unacceptable.
         Postage-Stamp ``And'' Pricing: Some utilities have 
    proposed so-called ``and'' pricing, which would add an embedded cost 
    rate to an incremental cost rate for the same service over the same 
    facilities. The proposals have been based on traditional postage stamp 
    ratemaking for which costs are aggregated at the utility level. This 
    type of pricing has been found by the Commission to be unjust and 
    unreasonable.\33\ We cannot see how such an approach is consistent with 
    either our fairness principle or our efficiency principle.\34\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \33\See Penelec, supra n.5.
        \34\The flexibility that we endorse in this Policy Statement 
    regarding cost disaggregation, among other things, addresses the 
    industry's underlying concerns regarding ``or'' pricing. That is, 
    while we cannot justify pricing that purports to recover two 
    measures of a single cost, allowing the entity to account for costs 
    on a disaggregated basis would permit separate pricing for separate 
    facilities or small groupings of facilities. Hence, we would 
    entertain proposals for flow-based line-by-line ``or'' pricing. This 
    would permit the use of embedded costs for some lines when this is 
    the higher of embedded or incremental costs, and the use of 
    incremental cost for other lines when this is the higher of embedded 
    or incremental costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
         Pricing by Individual Utilities to Account for Loop Flow: 
    While individual utilities may propose new and innovative pricing 
    methods that seek to apportion transmission costs on the basis of 
    scheduled flows (e.g., zonal or line-by-line methods), we also believe 
    that it would be inappropriate for individual utilities to reform their 
    own approach to transmission pricing in a way that is inconsistent with 
    regional practices regarding unscheduled or inadvertent flows (loop 
    flow).\35\ We are concerned that individual public utilities may 
    propose approaches to loop flow pricing that lead to a patchwork of 
    mutually inconsistent loop flow pricing methods within a region. 
    Accordingly, a utility's proposal to use flow-based pricing generically 
    to recover the costs of unscheduled inter-utility power flows will be 
    treated as a non-conforming proposal if it is inconsistent with 
    regional loop flow practices, such as use of a contract path 
    convention.\36\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \35\Of course, such individual utility pricing may be 
    appropriate if there are no objections to the loop flow solution 
    from any affected neighboring utilities or transmission customers.
        \36\However, a public utility may seek on a case-by-case basis 
    relief from the Commission, including appropriate compensation, in 
    situations in which it is experiencing severe unscheduled loop flows 
    on its system because of specific power transactions by other 
    neighboring utilities and it has been unable to resolve the problem 
    through existing industry mechanisms. See American Electric Power 
    Service Corp., et al., 49 FERC 61,377 at 62,381 (1989).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    V. Pricing Proposals That Do Not Conform to the Traditional Revenue 
    Requirement
    
        The Commission clearly prefers pricing proposals that are designed 
    not to exceed the traditional revenue requirement. As noted, we believe 
    that given the current industry structure it will be difficult to 
    justify non-conforming proposals. In addition, we believe that the 
    flexibility permitted under this revised transmission pricing policy 
    should be adequate to satisfy the needs of today's electric utility 
    industry, particularly given the current structure of the industry. 
    Nevertheless, the electric utility industry is continuing to evolve\37\ 
    and we must ensure that our policies do not impede the continued 
    development of competitive bulk power markets, or the development of 
    new market structures and transmission arrangements. The Commission 
    will consider pricing proposals necessary to accommodate such 
    developments. Some of the proposals discussed in this proceeding may 
    exceed the traditional embedded cost revenue requirement. Such 
    proposals will be considered provided they meet certain filing 
    procedures and evaluative criteria. We will provide two procedural 
    avenues for considering non-conforming proposals. We will also provide 
    guidance on the type of evidentiary showing necessary to support such 
    proposals.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \37\In recent months, the pace of change in the electric 
    industry has increased dramatically. Certain state proceedings on 
    industry restructuring, as well as proceedings before this 
    Commission, have contributed to the development of innovative 
    proposals by both industry participants and academicians. These 
    evolutionary changes support the need for flexibility and the need 
    to permit non-conforming pricing proposals.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    A. Procedures for Proposals That Do Not Conform to the Traditional 
    Revenue Requirement
    
        Any public utility that seeks non-conforming pricing must have on 
    file with the Commission an open access transmission tariff offering 
    comparable services. Such comparability tariff must have been accepted 
    for filing by the Commission before a non-conforming pricing proposal 
    will be considered. Moreover, utilities proposing non-conforming 
    transmission pricing must submit such pricing proposals either: (a) in 
    conjunction with a section 205 conforming transmission pricing proposal 
    (the non-conforming proposal would be reflected as alternative ``pro 
    forma'' rate sheets to the conforming proposal); or (b) in a petition 
    for declaratory order.
    (1) Alternative ``Pro Forma'' Rate Sheets
        Under this procedure, the Commission and interested parties would 
    review the non-conforming proposal in conjunction with review of a 
    companion conforming pricing proposal.\38\ The conforming proposal 
    would be subject to the notice and suspension procedures of section 
    205. The non-conforming proposal would not. The non-conforming proposal 
    would be litigated at the same time as the conforming proposal, but 
    could not take effect, if at all, until the end of the proceeding. If, 
    at the end of the proceeding, the Commission determines that the 
    alternative, non-conforming rate proposal is acceptable under the FPA, 
    the Commission will allow the utility to make a compliance rate filing, 
    and the rates will be put into effect prospectively.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \38\See Pacific Gas Transmission, 66 FERC 61,384, reh'g denied, 
    67 FERC 61,247 (1994), reh'g pending.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        This procedure will permit the Commission to determine the extent 
    to which the proposal deviates from the traditional revenue 
    requirement, which may be necessary in determining whether the other 
    features of the proposal are sufficient to offset this. It will also 
    permit an examination of how risk, and hence cost of capital, will vary 
    under the conforming and non-conforming proposals. Another benefit of 
    the alternative ``pro forma'' rate sheets procedure is that the utility 
    would be able to implement the non-conforming pricing, assuming it was 
    just and reasonable, immediately following the Commission's final 
    order.
    (2) Declaratory Order Petition
        A utility that wishes to have the Commission consider a non-
    conforming pricing proposal separate from a rate proceeding may bring 
    the matter to the Commission via a petition for declaratory order. Of 
    course, if the Commission found that the utility's proposal met the 
    statutory criteria, the utility would still need to file a rate 
    reflecting the proposal pursuant to FPA section 205. Presumably the 
    section 205 proceeding would be straightforward (i.e. akin to a 
    compliance filing), however, since the Commission would have already 
    addressed the merits of the proposal in the declaratory order.
    
    B. Criteria for Evaluating Proposals That Do Not Conform to the 
    Traditional Revenue Requirement
    
        Utilities proposing non-conforming transmission pricing must fully 
    support such proposals. The utility must supply a complete discussion 
    of how the proposal is intended to take account of the pricing 
    principles. The Commission will consider the relative weight of each 
    pricing principle as applied to the facts of each case. We will hold 
    the comparability principle inviolate, however. Absent such support, 
    the Commission will summarily reject the non-conforming proposal even 
    if the utility has agreed to the procedural requirements set forth 
    above.
        We will also summarily reject non-conforming proposals that do not 
    submit information showing that the proposal can be expected to:
        (a) Produce greater overall consumer benefits than a conforming 
    proposal; and
        (b) Promote competitive bulk power markets.\39\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \39\The reason we are providing flexibility to consider non-
    conforming transmission pricing proposals is because we do not want 
    to reject out of hand innovative proposals that could benefit 
    ratepayers. However, we do not intend to waste resources considering 
    proposals whose sole purpose is to provide more revenue to the 
    transmitting utilities. We will summarily reject such proposals.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        At a minimum, utilities proposing non-conforming transmission 
    pricing must make a showing of benefits to a broad cross-section of 
    consumers which achieve the following:
        (i) Greater access and customer choice;
        (ii) Projected price decreases to customers of delivered power; and
        (iii) Service flexibility and available products to meet customer 
    needs.
    
    As noted, utilities should also explain how the non-conforming proposal 
    promotes competitive bulk power markets.
    
    C. Guidance Regarding Proposals That Do Not Conform to the Traditional 
    Revenue Requirement
    
        We believe that a non-conforming proposal that results from a 
    diverse group such as an RTG, with fair and nondiscriminatory 
    governance and decisionmaking procedures, would more easily be found 
    just and reasonable than a non-conforming proposal from an individual 
    utility, for the same reason we would afford more deference to a 
    conforming RTG transmission pricing proposal than an individual utility 
    conforming proposal.
        Although the Commission has been willing, under appropriate 
    circumstances, to permit market-based pricing for sales of generation, 
    the Commission intends to treat market-based transmission rate 
    proposals as non-conforming. Such rates obviously are not cost-based 
    and the Commission does not believe market-based transmission pricing 
    is appropriate at this time. Although the transmission system has 
    multiple owners, the basic provision of firm transmission service is 
    not competitive in most, if not all, circumstances. Rather, each owner 
    can exert considerable market power by controlling the access, pricing 
    and expansion of its portion of the grid. In addition, regulatory 
    approval for new transmission lines is increasingly difficult to obtain 
    and franchised owners are typically the only entities that possess 
    rights of eminent domain. In these circumstances, unlike for sales of 
    generation, the Commission cannot rely on competitive market forces to 
    discipline prices for firm transmission service. Accordingly, any 
    transmission owner advocating a market-based transmission pricing 
    method must demonstrate how it has alleviated these serious concerns.
        Some cost-based pricing approaches adhere to a traditional embedded 
    (depreciated original) cost revenue requirement more closely than 
    others. Replacement cost methods and long-run marginal cost methods of 
    pricing, for example, may result in revenue levels that would exceed 
    the traditional revenue requirement. Pricing methods designed to allow 
    a transmission owner to recover more than its traditional revenue 
    requirement (depreciated original cost) are non-conforming and would 
    need to satisfy the procedures and criteria for non-conforming 
    proposals.
    
    VI. Alternative Institutions and Associated Pricing
    
        The Commission is aware that industry participants have begun to 
    discuss alternative institutional arrangements, such as ``pool 
    companies'' and ``transmission companies.'' Some of these institutions 
    apparently are intended to facilitate efficient wholesale power 
    trading, and may require alternative approaches for the pricing of 
    transmission services. We believe that these alternative institutions 
    hold great potential. They may assist in the resolution of some 
    difficult federal-state jurisdictional issues and in developing 
    mechanisms for resolving or minimizing stranded cost issues. While we 
    are encouraged that such ideas are under discussion, and are open to 
    considering the particular pricing needs of alternative institutions, 
    these concepts are currently in an early, formative stage. The concepts 
    associated with these ideas have not been adequately explored in this 
    pricing docket or in any other Commission forum. Therefore, concurrent 
    with issuing this Policy Statement, we are opening a separate docket to 
    initiate an inquiry regarding alternative power pooling institutions 
    and their particular pricing needs.\40\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \40\See Alternative Power Pooling Institutions under the Federal 
    Power Act, Notice of Inquiry, FERC Stats. and Regs. ________.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    VII. Conclusion
    
        The transition to a competitive wholesale bulk power market depends 
    on the availability of comparable transmission services. Comparable 
    transmission service, in turn, must have appropriate prices, terms and 
    conditions. To that end, the Pricing Inquiry has provided the basis for 
    a productive dialogue among the various entities affected by and 
    participating in the transition to a post-EPAct competitive bulk power 
    market, including transmission owners, transmission users, and Federal 
    and state regulators.
        It is critical that transmission services be priced in a manner 
    that appropriately compensates transmission owners and creates adequate 
    incentives for system expansion when such expansion is efficient. Of 
    course, any transmission pricing proposal will have to be evaluated 
    under the standards of the FPA. The Commission must ensure that any 
    such proposal is just, reasonable, and not unduly discriminatory or 
    preferential. A great many of the approaches discussed in this 
    proceeding have the potential to provide better (i.e., more efficient) 
    price signals. But they also have the potential to complicate and 
    prolong the process of determining appropriate rates for transmission 
    services.
        This Policy Statement provides a framework for understanding these 
    competing interests, as well as a basis for continuing the transmission 
    pricing dialogue. The Commission has consciously avoided endorsing any 
    particular commenter's specific pricing methodology. Instead, the 
    Policy Statement attempts to provide guidance while still encouraging 
    industry efforts at innovation. Indeed, a great many of the proposals 
    that were submitted during the Pricing Inquiry are highly theoretical 
    and would need to be tested and evaluated in the context of individual 
    cases.
        The commenters in the Pricing Inquiry almost unanimously requested 
    that the Commission allow flexibility. To that end, the Commission has 
    attempted to provide pricing principles and general guidance that allow 
    broad experimentation consistent with federal law and the physics of 
    transmission. Certain experiments, particularly pricing methods that 
    attempt to recognize loop flow, clearly require regional involvement 
    and cooperation if they are to be effective. RTGs are encouraged to 
    address such issues as pricing reform and loop flow.
        The Commission encourages filing utilities and new groups that may 
    form, such as RTGs and pool companies, to work closely with state 
    regulatory authorities in developing transmission pricing policy. The 
    Commission is committed to cooperating with all affected parties, 
    especially state regulatory authorities, to ensure that any such 
    pricing reform is implemented in an equitable manner and facilitates an 
    orderly transition to a fully competitive bulk power market. Our 
    pricing principles are expected to provide the foundation for the 
    industry to continue its exploration of transmission pricing reform.
        Finally, the Commission in this Policy Statement has proposed 
    procedures under which non-conforming pricing proposals will be 
    considered. We believe these procedures are flexible enough to permit 
    utilities to propose non-conforming pricing innovations which they 
    believe will benefit ratepayers and promote the development of a 
    competitive bulk power market.
        The Commission is making this Policy Statement effective 
    immediately. It is based on the voluminous record developed to date in 
    the Pricing Inquiry. We will accept motions for reconsideration 
    submitted within 30 days in order to help us refine the principles 
    established herein and to provide an opportunity to respond to any 
    questions or clarify any ambiguity. We will apply the Policy Statement 
    to transmission pricing proposals submitted in individual cases filed 
    after the date of this Policy Statement.
    
    List of Subjects in 18 CFR Part 2
    
        Administrative practice and procedure, Electric power, Natural gas, 
    Pipelines, Reporting and recordkeeping requirements.
    
        By the Commission.
    Lois D. Cashell,
    Secretary.
    
        In consideration of the foregoing, the Commission amends Part 2, 
    Chapter I, Title 18 of the Code of Federal Regulations as set forth 
    below.
    
    PART 2--GENERAL POLICY AND INTERPRETATIONS
    
        1. The authority citation for Part 2 continues to read as follows:
    
        Authority: 15 U.S.C. 717-717w, 3301-3432; 16 U.S.C. 792-825y, 
    2601-2645; 42 U.S.C. 4321-4361, 7101-7352.
    
        2. Part 2 is amended by adding Sec. 2.22, to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 2.22  Pricing Policy for Transmission Services Provided Under the 
    Federal Power Act.
    
        (a) The Commission has adopted a Policy Statement on its pricing 
    policy for transmission services provided under the Federal Power Act. 
    That Policy Statement can be found at 69 FERC 61,086. The Policy 
    Statement constitutes a complete description of the Commission's 
    guidelines for assessing the pricing proposals. Paragraph (b) of this 
    section is only a brief summary of the Policy Statement.
        (b) The Commission endorses transmission pricing flexibility, 
    consistent with the principles and procedures set forth in the Policy 
    Statement. It will entertain transmission pricing proposals that do not 
    conform to the traditional revenue requirement as well as proposals 
    that conform to the traditional revenue requirement. The Commission 
    will evaluate ``conforming'' transmission pricing proposals using the 
    following five principles, described more fully in the Policy 
    Statement.
        (1) Transmission pricing must meet the traditional revenue 
    requirement.
        (2) Transmission pricing must reflect comparability.
        (3) Transmission pricing should promote economic efficiency.
        (4) Transmission pricing should promote fairness.
        (5) Transmission pricing should be practical.
        (c) Under these principles, the Commission will also evaluate 
    ``non-conforming'' proposals which do not meet the traditional revenue 
    requirement, and will require such proposals to conform to the 
    comparability principle. Non-conforming proposals must include an open 
    access comparability tariff and will not be allowed to go into effect 
    prior to review and approval by the Commission under procedures 
    described in the Policy Statement.
    
        Note: This Appendix will not appear in the Code of Federal 
    Regulations
    
    Appendix A--Summary of Comments on the Inquiry Concerning the 
    Commission's Pricing Policy for Transmission Services in Docket No. 
    RM93-19-000
    
        The request for comments for the inquiry concerning the 
    Commission's pricing policy for transmission services in Docket No. 
    RM93-19-000 was issued on June 30, 1993. The date for filing 
    responses was extended to November 8, 1993 and reply comments to 
    January 24, 1994. Technical conferences were held on April 8 and 15, 
    1994. The first day of the conference covered current policy issues. 
    The second day was devoted to advanced pricing concepts and 
    implementation issues.
        Comments were received from 165 individual commenters. Five 
    categories of commenters are investor-owned utilities (IOUs, 67 
    commenters), municipal and cooperative utilities (Muni/Coop, 39 
    commenters), non-utility generators and independent power producers 
    (NUGs/IPPs, 15 commenters), Regulatory/Government entities (25 
    commenters), and Others (19 commenters). A list of the commenters is 
    at the end of this appendix; it shows the categories under which 
    their comments are summarized and the acronyms used in this 
    appendix.
        A summary of the comments is provided here. The summary is 
    organized in the same manner as the two-day conference (current 
    policy and advanced pricing concepts). The current policy issues are 
    subdivided into eight comment areas and advanced pricing into four 
    comment areas as follows:
    
    Current Policy Issues
    
    (1) General Criteria for Transmission Service Pricing
    (2) ``And'' Versus ``Or'' Pricing and Related Incentives
    (3) Incremental Pricing
    (4) Network Service
    (5) Ancillary Services
    (6) Direction Aspects of Power Flows
    (7) Non-Firm Transmission Pricing
    (8) Regional Transmission Groups
    
    Advanced Pricing Concepts/Implementation Issues
    
    (1) Alternative Pricing Concepts
    (2) Distance/Flow-Based Rates
    (3) Contract Path versus Measured Power Flows
    (4) Spot Market Pricing
    
        The Commission also received comments on stranded costs in the 
    course of this Inquiry, but these are not addressed in this Pricing 
    Policy Statement because stranded cost is the subject of a proposed 
    rule.\41\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \41\Docket No. RM94-7-000, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, June 
    29, 1994.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Current Policy Issues
    
    1. General Criteria for Transmission Service Pricing
    
        The first comment area deals with the proposed criteria for 
    assessing transmission pricing reform. Commenters generally find the 
    criteria proposed in Staff's Discussion Paper\42\ acceptable. 
    However, certain criteria are more readily agreed upon than others. 
    Most commenters uniformly agree that the proposed criteria should: 
    (1) Be simple to carry out and to administer; (2) promote efficient 
    use of and investment in the transmission grid; (3) provide 
    appropriate price signals to transmission customers; and (4) ensure 
    equity and fairness during and beyond the transition period.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \42\Staff appendix to Inquiry Concerning the Commission's 
    Pricing Policy for Transmission Service Provided by Public Utilities 
    Under the Federal Power Act, FERC States. & Regs. 35,024 (1993).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Other proposed criteria by commenters include that transmission 
    pricing policy should:
         Ensure system reliability;
         Be flexible (i.e., no ``one size fits all'' pricing 
    methodology) and specifically recognize regional differences;
         Encourage the formation of Regional Transmission Groups 
    (RTGs) and give substantial deference to pricing methodologies 
    developed by RTGs;
         Provide for coordination between state and Federal 
    pricing policies and encourage collaborative policy development;
         Provide for grandfathering of existing contracts and 
    arrangements when implementing any new policies;
         Promote competition in generation; 
         Unbundle rates for transmission services;
         Ensure nondiscriminatory rates, terms, and conditions;
         Not allow native load customers to subsidize firm 
    wheeling;
         Give deference to negotiated agreements (with some 
    commenters adding, where equal bargaining power is involved);
         Ensure rate predictability and transparency of rate 
    derivation; and,
         Allow customers an option to have stable prices over 
    time (although this would not limit parties to fixed rate 
    contracts).
        One criterion emphasized by most commenters is that the 
    Commission should exercise maximum flexibility in pricing 
    transmission service. Specifically, many commenters stress that the 
    Commission should not attempt to rigidly apply a single transmission 
    pricing methodology in all cases, to all entities, or to all 
    regions. A general concern raised is that the Commission must 
    recognize the substantial differences present between customer 
    groups, utilities, state and local regulatory bodies, and regional 
    differences. Accordingly, the Commission must resist the temptation 
    to apply one pricing methodology in all cases.
        One common view expressed by many Muni/Coops commenters is that 
    the industry must move from a structure where multiple transmission 
    system pricing occurs to a structure where transmission is viewed on 
    a regional basis in conjunction with the development of large, 
    regional power markets. Many commenters advocate the regional 
    transmission grid approach but differ in how the industry and the 
    Commission should advance toward this goal. Some appear to take a 
    more cautious approach. For example, some commenters note that the 
    Commission can only obtain meaningful answers to the questions posed 
    in its transmission pricing inquiry if it first determines the shape 
    of the industry it envisions (such as the regional transmission grid 
    approach or the traditional model based on individually owned and 
    operated transmission systems). APPA\43\ contends that before 
    considering changes in traditional transmission pricing, the 
    Commission should develop and articulate a clear statement of its 
    ``vision'' for the electric industry and specify ``where the 
    industry is going, how it will get there, likely impediments, and 
    what steps are necessary for that vision to be fulfilled.'' Many 
    Muni/Coops commenters also argue that the Commission must first 
    determine if the benefits of transmission pricing reform will 
    outweigh the costs of such reform.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \43\Commenters are referred to by acronym here; acronyms are 
    defined in a list at the end of this appendix.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several Regulatory/Government entities commenters recommend that 
    the following general principles be included in addition to the 
    Commission's proposed criteria:
         The Commission's pricing policies should reflect 
    differences between the rights and responsibilities of native load 
    customers (including retail and wholesale requirements customers) 
    and other users of the transmission system; any transmission pricing 
    policy must ensure that native load customers will be held harmless; 
    and,
         The Commission should seek to promote voluntary 
    resolution of case-specific pricing issues by giving appropriate 
    deference to consensual agreements produced through arms-length 
    negotiations involving all affected parties.
        NARUC proposes a consultative process to develop complimentary 
    policies that truly coordinate and render coherent regulation of 
    transmission service. The general goals include coherence of public 
    policy, economic efficiency and reliability in electricity markets, 
    efficiency of processes and decision-making, dialogue between 
    federal and state decision-makers and appropriate input from 
    constituent groups and affected parties as necessary. The 
    Pennsylvania Commission concludes that without careful consideration 
    of the role of state agencies and their interest in economic and 
    environmental impacts, bulk power wheeling as envisioned by the 
    Commission is, and will remain, a theoretical, economic model.
    
    2. ``And'' Versus ``Or'' Pricing and Related Incentives
    
        The ``and'' versus ``or'' issue dominated the pricing comments. 
    While arguments on all sides of the issue were expressed, the 
    commenters generally opposed the Commission's current corporate 
    ``or'' policy and alternatively advocated either some form of the 
    ``and'' pricing method or corporate-average embedded cost-based 
    rates. The positions of the commenters are described below:
        The ``And'' Method: Most IOUs, most Regulatory/Government 
    entities and some Other entities support the ``and'' methodology. 
    These commenters state that the Commission's ``or'' pricing policy 
    does not hold the native load customers harmless and violates FPA 
    section 212(a) (because native load customers and shareholders 
    subsidize third party wheeling customers). When additional 
    facilities are needed to serve third party wheeling load, and 
    incremental (or opportunity) costs are greater than average embedded 
    cost, native load customers subsidize that service (because no cost 
    recognition is given to the third party's use of the existing 
    transmission system, without which the transmission service could 
    not be provided). Additionally, if incremental expansion cost 
    related to third party transmission requests are not allowed by 
    state regulators in retail rates, the transmitting utility will not 
    be made whole. Finally, the Commission's policy on opportunity cost 
    which applies the ``higher of'' test over the entire transaction 
    period instead of an hourly basis precludes opportunity cost 
    recovery in most cases, sends the wrong hourly price signals to 
    transmission customers, and is overly burdensome administratively.
        The ``Or'' Method: Most NUGs/IPPs commenters agree that the 
    Commission's current corporate ``or'' policy sends the correct price 
    signal for third-party transmission (as long as opportunity costs 
    are ``legitimate and verifiable'' and continue to be capped at 
    incremental expansion costs). However several commenters oppose 
    pricing based on opportunity costs (as monopoly rents for a 
    constrained system).
        The Average Embedded Cost Method: Most of the Muni/Coops, some 
    NUGs/IPPs, and some Other entities generally support the return to 
    traditional corporate-average embedded cost-based rates. The 
    majority of the Muni/Coops commenters and some of the Other 
    commenters oppose both the ``or'' and the ``and'' transmission 
    pricing methods (as yielding excessive rates and impeding the 
    competitive generation market that EPAct permits). Such commenters 
    recommend the traditional policy of charging average embedded cost-
    based transmission rates. Many of these commenters argue that a 
    transmission-dependent utility (TDU) cannot be considered a 
    ``marginal'' customer, subject to incremental and opportunity cost 
    pricing, because the transmission system was designed to accommodate 
    the TDU's use and has been paid for proportionally by the TDU. 
    Furthermore, these commenters argue that applying incremental 
    pricing to TDUs is anticompetitive and inconsistent with the EPAct 
    because (1) it forces TDUs to favor power purchases from the host 
    utility over those from a competing power supplier, and (2) TDUs 
    compete with the host utility for requirements customers (who are 
    charged an average embedded cost rate by the host utility).
        Commenters views regarding the incentives and disincentives 
    inherent in corporate ``or'' pricing primarily fall into three basic 
    positions:
        (1) Although groups disagreed among themselves on how to 
    calculate various cost-based transmission rates, most Muni/Coops, 
    most Regulatory/Government entities, most NUGs/IPPs, and some others 
    do not believe in allowing any incentives, or premiums above cost-
    based rates, properly calculated. Most of these commenters agreed 
    that, when a monopoly resource is involved, such incentives amount 
    to allowing ``monopoly rents.'' Transmission is and will remain a 
    natural monopoly, therefore, no incentive is needed beyond recovery 
    of the transmitting utility's prudently-incurred costs and a fair 
    return on its invested capital. Premiums allow the transmission 
    monopolist a competitive advantage in the generation market. 
    Furthermore, there is no need for incentives with the passage of the 
    transmission provisions of the Energy Policy Act; the legal 
    requirement to provide transmission service is sufficient incentive.
        (2) Most NUGs/IPPs believe the current incentives provided by 
    the incremental pricing part of the ``or'' policy are appropriate. 
    However, many of these commenters oppose pricing based on 
    opportunity costs (as monopoly rents for a constrained system).
        (3) Those advocating ``and'' pricing, such as most IOUs and some 
    Others, believe that further incentives are needed. The current 
    ``or'' policy does not sufficiently compensate utilities for all 
    costs of providing service, thus effectively requiring native load 
    customers to subsidize transmission customers. If utilities are 
    forced to absorb potential cost underrecovery and the risk 
    associated with the ``or'' pricing methodology, then the rate of 
    return should be adjusted to reflect greater risks assumed by 
    engaging in third party wheeling transactions.
    
    3. Incremental Cost Pricing
    
        Under the Commission's current corporate ``or'' policy, third-
    party transmission users may be required to pay the incremental cost 
    of a grid expansion if the incremental cost of the expansion is 
    greater than corporate-average embedded cost. Such incremental 
    pricing can be structured in one of two ways--a contract approach in 
    which each user pays the incremental cost of the upgrade it 
    occasions, and an average incremental price based on the average 
    cost of all upgrades to the transmission system for a group of 
    users.
        Most, though not all, commenters believe that contract pricing 
    is the preferred pricing model. IOUs in particular favor contract 
    pricing because it provides more certainty that a utility's revenue 
    requirements are fully recovered. If incremental pricing increases 
    the risk of less than full revenue recovery, either shareholders or 
    residual customers will bear the extra risks. Most wholesale 
    customers also appear to favor contract pricing, though some have 
    concerns that contract pricing, with different prices for each user, 
    may result in price discrimination. These commenters suggest that 
    similarly situated customers should have the same price, but have 
    different notions of what this would mean.
        For many of the difficult practical issues associated with 
    incremental pricing, there is no consistent position taken by all or 
    even most members of any interest group that supports incremental 
    cost pricing. For example, many commenters believe that average 
    incremental cost pricing gives the wrong price signal to both the 
    transmission owner and user. These commenters are concerned that the 
    average incremental cost price does not signal the true cost of the 
    transmission service. A few commenters argue that this will result 
    in underbuilding of the transmission system. Others suggest that 
    this may result in overbuilding, although IOUs in particular doubt 
    this result, given the difficulties inherent in siting, 
    certification and construction of new transmission facilities.
        Additionally, commenters are split on the issue of 
    administrative costs and other implementation problems that may 
    result under each pricing model. Some commenters argue that contract 
    pricing entails maintaining separate contracting provisions for each 
    user, with attendant high costs. Other commenters suggest that 
    average incremental cost pricing is more difficult, given the need 
    to estimate incremental costs, and the problems associated with 
    changing average incremental rates as a result of incremental cost 
    changes. One commenter suggests that it is simply not possible to 
    reconcile average incremental pricing with an embedded cost 
    transmission revenue requirement.
        Several commenters suggested that it would be appropriate to 
    allow utilities some flexibility to adopt either incremental cost 
    pricing approach. The challenge for the Commission would be to 
    determine under what conditions such flexibility would be warranted, 
    in order to protect both the third-party transmission users and the 
    remaining wholesale and retail customers from being charged for 
    inappropriate costs. Other commenters suggest that some 
    experimentation may be in order. If the Commission chooses to allow 
    such experimentation, it may learn a great deal about the magnitude 
    of the practical problems, as well as potential solutions for those 
    problems.
    
    4. Network Service
    
        The Staff Discussion Paper defined network service as allowing 
    the user to vary its schedule and points of delivery and receipt 
    without paying additional charges for each change. Commenters were 
    asked to discuss the reasonableness of this definition and to 
    provide recommendations on pricing network service. Most IOUs assert 
    that utilities cannot provide third party transmission users with 
    unlimited flexibility in choosing and switching points of receipt 
    and delivery. Unless the transmission customer specifies the points 
    of receipt and delivery, the nature of the generation, and the loads 
    to be served, the transmitting utility will have no way to determine 
    the impact of the proposed network arrangement on its system in 
    terms of either reliability or cost. Unlimited flexibility could 
    require transmission upgrades and make long term planning more 
    difficult (with the potential for overbuilding). If network service 
    is to include unlimited scheduling flexibility, it should be 
    considered a premium service (priced higher than point-to-point 
    service) since it requires higher transmission capacity margins to 
    ensure reliability.
        Most Muni/Coops, Regulatory/Government entities, NUGs/IPPs and 
    some Other commenters agree with the Commission's definition of 
    network service. Most Muni/Coops, NUGs/IPPs and some Other 
    commenters insist that network service should be priced on an 
    average embedded cost basis (with no non-cost-based network rate 
    premiums or percentage adders). These commenters argue that such 
    premiums would place network customers at a permanent competitive 
    disadvantage in obtaining economical generation sources and in 
    generation sales, compared to the transmitting utility. Many 
    commenters agree that network access should not be totally flexible, 
    nor be unduly rigid with reservation requirements and excessively 
    advanced scheduling requirements; rather, they believe it should be 
    subject to the same conditions faced by the transmitting utility, 
    and provide access to transmission on an ``as if owned'' basis.
        APPA asserts that it is not aware of any party that is seeking 
    network access without regard to the control area utility's own 
    transmission needs, or that is requesting network service with total 
    flexibility, i.e., no scheduling or backup requirements. APPA adds 
    that it agrees with EEI on two points concerning utilities receiving 
    network service: ``they should state in planning models the sources 
    of power that most probably will be used to serve loads, and they 
    should schedule generation to serve load with the transmitting 
    utility.''
        Regulatory/Government entities generally agree that accurate 
    pricing of network service will depend on the nature of the network 
    and any revenue pooling between transmission providers. Therefore, 
    Regulatory/Government entities urge the Commission to be flexible 
    and not mandate any particular method for pricing network service.
    
    5. Ancillary Services
    
        The Staff Discussion Paper gave examples of ancillary services 
    and requested comments on other examples (including how such 
    services should be priced). Most IOUs recommend that unless third 
    party customers obtain ancillary services elsewhere, they should 
    compensate the wheeling utility for the services provided to prevent 
    the native load customers from subsidizing these services. IOUs note 
    that as bulk power markets are becoming more competitive and 
    independent power producers are supplying ever increasing amounts of 
    generation, these support type services that were once provided on a 
    reciprocal basis among utilities are not being provided by many 
    suppliers because they are either unwilling or unable to provide 
    such service.
        One of the main concerns of the Muni/Coops commenters is that 
    costs associated with ancillary services should not already be 
    included in the average cost-based transmission rate. Additionally, 
    several commenters insist that transmission customers should be 
    given the option to provide such services themselves, or obtain them 
    from other utilities, and receive full credit. These commenters also 
    express concern regarding discriminatory pricing. Such commenters 
    urge that any charges for ancillary services assessed to a 
    transmission customer should be the same as the costs faced by the 
    transmitting utility for the same service.
        NUGs/IPPs, Regulatory/Government entities and Others generally 
    did not address this issue.
        Other claimed ancillary services include: Backup and Standby 
    Service; Loss Service; Redispatch Costs; Control Center Service; 
    Emergency Services; fast starts, ``BlackStart'' capability (starting 
    up a generating station with no external power supply), regulation, 
    and stability.
        Graves, et al. proposed that ancillary services could be 
    provided by an independent entity, which they call a ``Poolco'' 
    (e.g., an existing power pool, an RTG, NERC subregion, or consortium 
    of independent generators). Their version of a Poolco would not 
    participate directly in real power MW brokerage or energy supply; 
    rather, it would own and operate a relatively small collection of 
    generation and flow control assets sufficient to assure the 
    integrity of the system, relying on tieline flows, voltage 
    measurements at a few key load centers, and forecast control-area 
    load changes (over the next few hours).
    
    6. Direction Aspects of Power Flows
    
        The power flows caused by a transmission transaction may be 
    either with, or counter to, the prevailing flows. The incremental 
    effects of transmission transactions may also raise issues with 
    respect to the use of multiple parallel paths and the incremental 
    effects on transmission losses.
    
    A. Directional Flows
    
        Most commenters (most IOUs, some Muni/Coops, and some 
    Regulatory/Government entities) suggest that charges should be 
    applied for all power flows on a system (regardless of direction). 
    Several commenters indicate that reverse flows exist only under some 
    system conditions and that changes in transmission system 
    configuration (due to line outages) and changes in generating unit 
    dispatch, may eliminate any reverse flows. Such commenters also 
    claim that all transmission elements support all power flows. 
    Accordingly, reverse flows should only be credited if they provide a 
    direct economic benefit to the utility.
        Other commenters (some Muni/Coops, some Regulatory/Government 
    entities, and most Others) argue that it is important for the 
    Commission to adopt a transmission pricing method which recognizes 
    flow direction and discounts transmission service which ``unloads'' 
    the system and helps to relieve constrained transmission lines. 
    These commenters suggest that this type of pricing signal encourages 
    the most efficient use of the transmission system.
    
    B. Loop Flows
    
        Few comments on this issue were received from Muni/Coops, NUGs/
    IPPs, Regulatory/Government entities and Others. There did not 
    appear to be any consensus among the IOUs on the best method to 
    address loop flow problems.
        Southern Companies indicates that loop flows were often short-
    lived and were viewed as part of the normal interconnected 
    operations among utilities. It was once commonly viewed that loop 
    flows on one utility's system would most likely be offset by loop 
    flows on its neighboring systems. In instances where the flows were 
    a problem, negotiated solutions were reached. LG&E notes that bulk 
    power transactions were once predominantly multi-directional and 
    covered shorter distances so that transactions evened out over time.
        However, in today's marketplace transactions are more numerous, 
    over longer distances, and unidirectional. As a result, loop flows 
    do not even out over time. In the new competitive environment, 
    Southern Companies, AEP and Northern States claim the situation has 
    changed. In the emerging bulk power market, many more long term firm 
    transactions in a single direction are contemplated which will more 
    adversely impact flows over interconnected systems. These commenters 
    state that it also may be more difficult in a competitive 
    environment to negotiate solutions to parallel flow problems. 
    Consumers believes that uncertainty about loop-flow compensation may 
    be a significant potential barrier to the more rapid development of 
    competition among new generators.
    
    C. Losses
    
        Many commenters (some IOUs, most Muni/Coops, some Others) argue 
    that losses vary in proportion to the distance over which the energy 
    is moved, and accordingly, contend that incremental losses send a 
    more appropriate price signal to the customer (by more closely 
    linking cost causation and cost recovery). Tabors claims that 
    efficiency requires pricing losses at the margin, which can be 
    accomplished using load flow calculations and Optimal Power Flow 
    modeling techniques. On the other hand, many commenters recommend 
    average system line losses. Several of these commenters insist that 
    they should be charged for line losses on the same cost basis that 
    the transmitting owners use for their own dispatch and charge their 
    native load customers.
    
    7. Non-Firm Transmission Pricing
    
        A fundamental issue of non-firm transmission service pricing is 
    whether or not a contribution to capital costs over and above the 
    variable cost of transmission (losses and opportunity costs) should 
    be made for non-firm service. One view is that users of non-firm 
    service should not pay for capacity costs since capacity is not 
    built for them and their service can always be interrupted. On the 
    other end of the spectrum are those that advocate a contribution of 
    up to 100 percent of fixed costs, since firm customers need to be 
    compensated for the use of the transmission system that they support 
    in its entirety.
        Most IOUs indicate that non-firm users of the transmission 
    system should contribute to the capital costs of the system. They 
    believe the Commission should rely on its historical precedent, 
    which allows a contribution of up to 100 percent of fixed costs for 
    non-firm service with the revenues being credited to native load 
    customers. Some believe the shareholders should receive some of the 
    revenues from non-firm transactions. Other commenters suggest 
    minimal regulation of non-firm transactions as long as the price 
    does not exceed a cap equal to its fully allocated transmission 
    costs.
        Many of the Muni/Coops commenters state that there are no fixed 
    costs associated with providing non-firm transmission services and 
    note that groups in different parts of the country (e.g., PJM, 
    NEPOOL, MAPP and ERCOT) do not include contributions to fixed costs 
    in non-firm transmission pricing. Many commenters believe that no 
    demand charges for non-firm transmission are necessary and argue 
    that such demand charges may have a negative impact on the 
    efficiencies of the economy energy market for short term 
    transactions. For example, Consumer Working Group recommends:
        Limiting non-firm rates to real costs (i.e. losses) would 
    eliminate the artificial dead zone created by the incentive 
    transmission rates now allowed. By granting all market participants 
    (and not just transmission owners) access at cost to non-firm 
    transactions, all consumers would benefit from increased 
    coordination. Such nondiscriminatory, cost-based pricing of non-firm 
    transmission would serve the EPAct's purpose of stimulating 
    competition in bulk power markets and would promote economically 
    efficient generation of electricity as expressly mandated by Section 
    212(a). (Consumer Working Group Reply at 21)
    
    8. Regional Transmission Groups
    
        All segments of the industry supported the Commission's 
    encouragement of the development of such groups. Many commenters 
    believe that RTGs represent the best method available to deal with 
    the difficult transmission pricing issues presented in Staff's 
    Discussion Paper. Some commenters cautioned that to be successful, 
    RTGs must be certified by the Commission to ensure proper 
    representation of all groups within the electric utility industry. 
    Many commenters anticipate RTGs will facilitate coordinated regional 
    planning, regional measurement of power flows and regional 
    methodologies to determine the price of any firm wheeling 
    transaction within the region. The information available on a 
    regional basis will allow planning to alleviate current and future 
    transmission constraints within the region as well as send a clear 
    price signal to third party customers requesting service. RTG's will 
    also provide information as to what transmission capacity is 
    available and the need for any transmission enhancements within the 
    region to accommodate the requested transaction.
    
    Advanced Pricing Concepts/Implementation Issues
    
    1. Alternative Pricing Concepts
    
        Numerous commenters proposed alternative pricing methods, other 
    than those pricing methods normally permitted by this Commission. 
    The methodologies advanced by these commenters varied from 
    conceptual ideas to detailed formulas. Certain concepts and methods 
    were advocated by more than one and in some cases several 
    commenters, including:
         Combinations of, or hybrids between, the ``or'' and the 
    ``and'' policies, many of which advocated recovery of all 
    incremental costs and some contribution (but not necessarily 100%) 
    to average embedded system costs.
         Variations of recovering strictly incremental or 
    marginal cost pricing; i.e., rates based on long-run incremental 
    cost pricing for long-term firm transmission service and short-run 
    marginal costs for other transactions. Another commenter proposed 
    short-run marginal costs for transactions not requiring upgrades.
         Numerous proposals for a single transmission owner and 
    for regional pricing, planning and operating approaches; for 
    example: (1) The forced divestiture of all utilities' transmission 
    assets and formation of a single transmission owning national grid 
    company or ``gridco''; (2) joint ownership, operation and pricing of 
    all transmission within an established region with all transmission 
    users obtaining load ratio shares of the regional grid and paying on 
    an average embedded load ratio basis; (3) a proposal simply to price 
    transmission in a region as if there were a single transmission 
    owner; and (4) many suggestions for the Commission to further 
    examine the companies formed in Norway, Sweden, New Zealand, 
    Victoria (Australia), India, Argentina, England and Wales.
         Establishing a secondary market in transmission 
    rights--transmission purchasers having the capacity to contractually 
    broker, resell, trade, partially assign, or assign firm purchase 
    entitlements as they choose. Capacity trading will provide for the 
    repackaging of capacity rights to fit market needs, thereby creating 
    a market mechanism to ``price'' and ``clear'' transmission services 
    as a commodity.
         Numerous proposals advocating that the Commission 
    require the unbundling of rates for transmission and sales services. 
    Unbundling would require transmission owners to include a separate 
    (transparent) transmission charge in any use of the utility's 
    transmission system for the delivery of power in the wholesale 
    market, including that utility's own wholesale sales. Transmission 
    terms and conditions should be the same for all wholesale 
    transactions, regardless of whether the seller is the owner of the 
    transmission facilities used for the transaction.
    
    2. Distance/Flow-Based Rates
    
        Alternatives to postage stamp rates would make rates sensitive 
    to the transmission distance involved in providing the service. 
    Alternatives suggested include various ``MW-mile'' approaches and 
    other methods based on load flows (such load flow methods can also 
    treat issues involving multiple parallel paths and transmission 
    losses associated with particular transmission transactions). 
    Commenters' support is split between distance-based pricing and 
    postage stamp rates.
        Regulatory/Government commenters express a clear preference for 
    distance-sensitive rates (over postage stamp rates). Most 
    Regulatory/Government entities, some IOUs, some NUGs/IPPs, and some 
    Others argue that distance-based rates would compensate the 
    transmitter for increased transmission costs as more of its system 
    is used. This encourages more efficient use of the transmission 
    system. Where more miles of the transmission system are utilized, 
    distance-sensitive rates reflect the proper cost causation. Several 
    commenters believe that simplified distance-sensitive pricing 
    methods, such as some MW-mile methods, used in conjunction with 
    approaches such as zonal pricing that reflects system constraints, 
    would be appropriate. Numerous commenters advocating distance-based 
    rates recommend zonal pricing as a compromise between the 
    administrative simplicity of postage stamp rates and more 
    appropriate price signals of certain distance-based rate methods.
        Most Muni/Coops, some IOUs, and some NUGs/IPPs support postage 
    stamp rates and criticize distance-sensitive pricing due to its 
    dependence upon power flow studies involving a base and a change 
    case. Many commenters note that power flows on a transmission system 
    are in constant change, thereby creating a very large number of 
    possible system parameters that could be included in load flow 
    analyses and therefore requiring many simplifying assumptions. 
    Consequently, any attempt to derive a normal base case power flow on 
    which to model an incremental power flow would be flawed and 
    unreliable, particularly for individual utilities located in heavily 
    interconnected networks. Therefore, these commenters prefer the 
    administrative convenience of postage stamp rates over the 
    complexity and questionable accuracy of distance-sensitive rates 
    based on power flow studies.
    
    3. Contract Path Versus Measured Power Flows
    
        The mismatch between the contract path for a transaction and the 
    actual flows creates pricing and equity concerns. Utilities are 
    split regionally on whether to adopt loop flow, or parallel path, 
    pricing reform or retain contract path pricing. Most Western 
    utilities favor retaining contract path pricing. Western utilities 
    maintain that the topology of the WSCC makes it well suited to the 
    use of phase shifters to control the loop flow problem. In addition, 
    the development of Flexible AC Transmission technology may provide 
    additional devices to augment existing control strategies.
        Many utilities in the Midwest and the East favor adopting loop 
    flow pricing because over time contract path pricing has left many 
    systems uncompensated for parallel flows. These utilities argue that 
    contract path pricing is outmoded because (1) transmission services 
    have become long-term single direction transactions, (2) many new 
    market entities do not own transmission so that reciprocity is not 
    possible, and (3) negotiated solutions are less possible as 
    competition expands.
        Many utilities in favor of loop flow pricing are concerned that 
    the associated transition costs are formidable. Parallel flows 
    constantly change with changes in the dispatch of generation. In 
    addition, some utilities urge the development of RTGs first before 
    implementing loop flow pricing. In fact, there is general agreement 
    that RTGs are an appropriate institution for addressing many of the 
    industry's problems including pricing issues and the siting and 
    construction of transmission facilities.
        While there is widespread dissatisfaction with contract path 
    pricing outside of the West, there is considerable uncertainty about 
    how to address the parallel flow problem effectively. Many parties 
    believe that contract path pricing and loop flow pricing can be 
    combined to address the problem, while other parties believe that 
    these two methods are incompatible. Still other parties offer an 
    array of variations on the contract path pricing and loop flow 
    pricing methods. For example, Hogan's ``contract network'' approach 
    and PacifiCorp's proposal are variations on the contract path 
    pricing method. The GAPP experiment, which the Interregional 
    Transmission Coordination Forum stresses as the way to identify the 
    pricing method to compensate for parallel flows, is a preliminary 
    type of loop flow pricing. The Texas Planned Capacity Wheeling 
    Service and Southern Company's Transmission Cost Actual Path Pricing 
    are also examples of loop flow pricing. Finally, many parties argue 
    that alternatives to contract path pricing should be pursued on a 
    voluntary basis.
    
    4. Spot Pricing for Non-firm Transmission
    
        Few commenters express outright opposition to spot pricing, but 
    most advocate a cautious approach to implementation. Those in the 
    latter category comprise a diverse group of IOUs (including EEI), 
    coops, state commissions and industrial groups. Many suggest that 
    spot pricing schemes should continue to be studied, but not 
    considered for implementation at this time. Some encourage the 
    Commission to conduct experiments similar to the Southwest Bulk 
    Power Experiment and the WSPP.
        Those opposed to spot pricing generally believe that the 
    benefits are not worth the costs. Some argue that the successful 
    implementation of spot pricing for transmission requires a 
    competitive market in generation that does not now exist. However, 
    some commenters that see promise in spot pricing argue that the 
    necessary market institutions and technology exist today. They cite 
    the operation of tight power pools, electronic bulletin boards, and 
    the WSCC experiment as evidence of this fact.
        Some commenters argue that the ``up to'' transmission rates that 
    many utilities now use for non-firm transmission service effectively 
    approximate spot transmission pricing. However, others believe that 
    rate design for spot transmission pricing raises a number of 
    difficult issues, such as the use of one-part versus two-part rates, 
    and the appropriate definition of the cost of transmission service.
        Several commenters offer highly developed policy proposals or 
    technical models for use in implementing spot pricing. In 
    particular, Hogan and Putnam believe that all participants in the 
    power market should have access to economic dispatch with marginal 
    cost pricing. Hogan argues that transmission rights cannot be built 
    on the traditional wheeling model that assumes that specific power 
    moves to specific customers. He claims that only by stepping away 
    from such misleading assumptions can the Commission design a set of 
    pricing and access reforms that are consistent with the underlying 
    economics and will support an efficient competitive electricity 
    market.
    
    List of Commenters in the Transmission Pricing Policy Inquiry
    
        The following parities filed either initial or reply comments. 
    Acronyms used in this appendix are defined here.
    
    Investor-Owned Electric Utilities and Associations
    
     1. Allegheny Power Service Corporation
     2. American Electric Power System Companies (AEP)
     3. Arizona Public Service Company
     4. Association of Electric Companies of Texas
     5. Atlantic City Electric Company
     6. Bangor Hydro-Electric Company
     7. Carolina Power and Light Company
     8. Centerior Energy Corporation
     9. Central and South West Services, Inc.
    10. Central Illinois Public Service Company
    11. Central Louisiana Electric Company
    12. Commonwealth Edison Company
    13. Consumers Power Company/CMS Energy (Consumers)
    14. Dayton Power and Light Company
    15. Detroit Edison Company
    16. Dominion Resources, Inc.
    17. Duke Power Company
    18. Duquesne Light Company
    19. Edison Electric Institute (EEI)
    20. Entergy Services, Inc.
    21. Florida Power Corporation
    22. Florida Power Corporation, Wisconsin Electric Power Company, and 
    Wisconsin Public Service Corporation
    23. Houston Lighting & Power Company
    24. Idaho Power Company
    25. Indianapolis Power & Light Company
    26. Iowa-Illinois Gas and Electric Company
    27. LG&E Energy Corp.
    28. Long Island Lighting Company
    29. Louisville Gas and Electric Company
    30. Midwest Power Systems, Inc.
    31. Montana Power Company
    32. New England Power Service
    33. New York State Electric & Gas Corporation
    34. Niagara Mohawk Power Corporation (Niagara Mohawk)
    35. Northeast Utilities System Companies
    36. Northern States Power Company (Northern States)
    37. Ohio Edison Company
    38. Otter Tail Power Company
    39. PacifiCorp
    40. Pacific Gas and Electric Company
    41. Pennsylvania-New Jersey-Maryland Interconnection
    42. Pennsylvania Power & Light Company
    43. Philadelphia Electric Company
    44. Portland General Electric Company
    45. PSI Energy Inc. and Cincinnati Gas & Electric Company
    46. Public Service Company of Colorado
    47. Public Service Company of New Mexico
    48. Public Service Electric and Gas Company
    49. Puget Sound Power & Light Company
    50. San Diego Gas & Electric Company
    51. Sierra Pacific Power Company
    52. South Carolina Electric & Gas Company
    53. Southern California Edison Company
    54. Southern California Gas Company
    55. Southern Companies
    56. Southwestern Public Service Company
    57. Tampa Electric Company
    58. Texas Utilities Electric Company
    59. Tucson Electric Power Company
    60. Union Electric Company
    61. United Illuminating Company
    62. Unitil Power Corporation
    63. Utility Working Group
    64. Washington Water Power Company
    65. Western Resources, Inc. and Kansas Gas and Electric Company
    66. Wisconsin Electric Power Company
    67. Wisconsin Public Service Corporation
    
    Municipals, Cooperatives and Government-Owned Electric Utilities 
    and Related Associations
    
     1. Alabama Electric Cooperative, Inc. and South Mississippi 
    Electric Power Association
     2. Allegheny Electric Cooperative, Inc.
     3. American Public Power Association (APPA)
     4. Arizona Power Authority
     5. Associated Electric Cooperative, Inc.
     6. Basin Electric Power Cooperative
     7. Bonneville Power Administration
     8. California Department of Water Resources
     9. City of Anaheim, California
    10. City of Vernon, California
    11. Colorado Association of Municipal Utilities
    12. Colorado Joint Transmission Principles Participants
    13. Consumer Working Group
    14. East Kentucky Power Cooperative, Inc., Saluda River Electric 
    Cooperative, Inc., and Wolverine Power Supply Cooperative
    15. East Texas Cooperatives
    16. Florida Municipal Power Agency, Michigan Municipal Cooperative 
    Group and Wolverine Power Supply Cooperative
    17. Indiana Municipal Power Agency
    18. Irrigation and Electrical Districts Association of Arizona
    19. Large Public Power Council
    20. Lincoln Electric System
    21. Massachusetts Municipal Power Systems
    22. Missouri Basin Municipal Power Agency
    23. Municipal Electric Authority of Georgia
    24. National Rural Electric Cooperative Association
    25. Northern California Power Agency
    26. Oglethorpe Power Corporation
    27. Old Dominion Electric Cooperative, Inc.
    28. Public Generating Pool
    29. Sacramento Municipal Utility District
    30. South Texas Electric Cooperative, Inc. and Medina Electric 
    Cooperative, Inc.
    31. Tennessee Valley Authority
    32. Transmission Access Policy Study Group
    33. Transmission Agency of Northern California
    34. Transmission Dependent Systems
    35. Turlock Irrigation District
    36. Utah Associated Municipal Power Systems
    37. Wabash Valley Power Association, Inc.
    38. Wisconsin Public Power, Inc. SYSTEM
    39. Wisconsin Wholesale Customers
    
    Non-Traditional Utility Generators (NUGs, IPPs, EWGs and Qfs), 
    Power Marketers Foreign Entities and Related Associations
    
     1. American Wind Energy Association
     2. British Columbia Power Exchange Corporation (POWEREX)
     3. California Independent Energy Producers Association
     4. Electric Generation Association
     5. Enron Power Marketing, Inc.
     6. Fuel Managers Association
     7. Geothermal Resources Association
     8. Hydro-Quebec
     9. InterCoast Power Marketing Company
    10. Kvaener Energy Development Inc. and Citizens Power & Light Co.
    11. LG&E Power, Inc.
    12. National Independent Energy Producers
    13. National Power Plc
    14. Ontario Hydro
    15. Torco Energy Marketing, Inc.
    
    State Regulatory Commissions and Other Government Agencies
    
     1. Alabama Public Service Commission
     2. California Energy Commission
     3. California Public Utilities Commission
     4. Florida Public Service Commission
     5. Georgia Public Service Commission
     6. Idaho Public Utilities Commission
     7. Illinois Commerce Commission
     8. Indiana Utility Regulatory Commission
     9. Kansas Corporation Commission
    10. Maine Public Utilities Commission and the Vermont Department of 
    Public Service
    11. Massachusetts Department of Public Utilities
    12. Michigan Public Service Commission
    13. National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC)
    14. Nevada Public Service Commission
    15. New York State Department of Public Service
    16. Ohio Public Utilities Commission the Ohio Sitting Board
    17. Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission
    18. Sharp, The Hon. Philip R., Chairman, Subcommittee on Energy and 
    Power
    19. Texas Public Utility Commission
    20. United States Department of Energy
    21. United States Department of Justice
    22. Virginia State Corporation Commission
    23. Wallop, The Hon. Malcolm, Senate Committee on Energy and Natural 
    Resources
    24. Washington State Energy Office
    25. Wisconsin Public Service Commission
    
    Others
    
     1. American Forest and Paper Association (American Forest & Paper)
     2. Burns, Robert E.
     3. Committee on Regional Electric Power Cooperation
     4. Direct Electric Inc. (Direct Electric)
     5. Drazen-Brubaker & Associates, Inc.
     6. Electricity Consumers Resource Council, the American Iron and 
    Steel Institute and the Chemical Manufacturers Association
     7. Electric Power Research Institute
     8. Ernst & Young Utilities Consulting/Frederick L. McCoy
     9. Hogan, William W. (Hogan)
    10. Incentives Research, Inc., and Massachusetts Institute of 
    Technology (Graves, et al.)
    11. Institute of Electrical and Electronic Engineers
    12. Interregional Transmission Coordination Forum
    13. Joint Consumer Advocates
    14. Lively, Mark B.
    15. New York Mercantile Exchange
    16. Ohio Office of the Consumers' Counsel
    17. Putnam, Hayes & Bartlett, Inc. (Putnam)
    18. SASY Inc.
    19. Tabors Caramanis & Associates (Tabors)
    
    [FR Doc. 94-27091 Filed 11-2-94; 8:45 am]
    BILLING CODE 6717-01-P
    
    
    

Document Information

Effective Date:
10/26/1994
Published:
11/03/1994
Department:
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
Entry Type:
Uncategorized Document
Action:
Final rule; policy statement.
Document Number:
94-27091
Dates:
This policy statement is effective as of October 26, 1994.
Pages:
0-0 (1 pages)
Docket Numbers:
Federal Register: November 3, 1994, Docket No. RM93-19-000
CFR: (1)
18 CFR 2.22