95-3631. Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service Ratemaking for Natural Gas Pipelines; Request for Comments on Alternative Pricing Methods  

  • [Federal Register Volume 60, Number 30 (Tuesday, February 14, 1995)]
    [Notices]
    [Pages 8356-8375]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 95-3631]
    
    
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
    [Docket No. RM95-6-000]
    
    
    Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service Ratemaking for 
    Natural Gas Pipelines; Request for Comments on Alternative Pricing 
    Methods
    
    February 8, 1995.
        The Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (Commission) requests 
    comments on criteria to evaluate rates established through methods 
    other than the traditional cost-of-service ratemaking method. The 
    Commission's traditional approach to rate regulation sets an annual 
    revenue requirement based on operating and capital costs occurring 
    during a historical test period, adjusted for known and measurable 
    changes expected to occur by the time suspended rates take effect. 
    Rates are generally designed to recover the annual revenue requirement 
    based on contract capacity entitlements and projected annual or 
    seasonal volumes.
        Recently, the Commission has received a number of requests from 
    natural gas pipeline companies to approve rates based on various other 
    pricing methods, some of which are cost-based, and some of which are 
    not. For example, the Commission has approved a number of proposals for 
    market-based rates for storage services.\1\ In Stingray Pipeline 
    Company,\2\ the Commission approved a one-year experimental 
    interruptible transportation rate based on costs allocated to 
    Stingray's interruptible service, subject to a price cap. In KN 
    Interstate Gas Transmission Company (KN),\3\ the Commission addressed 
    KN's proposal to offer market-based rates and negotiated terms and 
    conditions of service on its Buffalo Wallow System. Most recently, 
    Florida Gas Transmission Company's section 4 filing in Docket No. RP95-
    103-000 included a ``Market Matching Program,'' under which shippers 
    would have the option of negotiating rates and terms of service 
    different from the tariff rates and terms of service. Florida Gas also 
    proposed an experimental inflation indexing mechanism for rate changes, 
    using cost-of-service rates as the starting point.
    
        \1\Avoca Natural Gas Storage, 68 FERC 61.045 (1994); Koch 
    Gateway Pipeline Co., 66 FERC 61,385 (1994); Bay Gas Storage 
    Company, LTD. 66 FERC 61,354 (1994); Petal Gas Storage Co., 64 FERC 
    61,190 (1993); Transok, Inc., 64 FERC 61,095 (1993); Richfield Gas 
    Storage System, 59 FERC 61,316 (1992).
        \2\66 FERC 61,202 (1994).
        \3\68 FERC 61,401 (1994).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission is interested in developing a framework for 
    analyzing proposals involving alternative pricing methods for natural 
    gas pipelines. There are a number of different ratemaking methods that 
    could be used instead of the traditional individual company embedded 
    cost-of-service method. In addition to market-based pricing, there are 
    a number of cost-based methods that vary from the individual company 
    cost-of-service method traditionally used by the Commission. The 
    Commission recognizes that it may be necessary to develop different 
    criteria for evaluating alternative pricing proposals, depending upon 
    the method proposed. To this end, the Commission's staff has prepared a 
    paper, which is attached, proposing criteria for the evaluation of 
    proposals for market-based rates. The staff paper draws from basic 
    antitrust market power analysis, that has been used in the past by the 
    Commission and in other contexts, to develop a proposed analytical 
    framework to use in evaluating gas pipeline market-based rate 
    proposals. The Commission is interested in receiving comments on all 
    aspects of the staff paper, including the following:
    
        1. a. Under what circumstances are market-based rates 
    appropriate for natural gas pipelines and services regulated by the 
    Commission?
        b. Please identify and discuss any legal issues, beyond those 
    discussed in the staff paper, that should be considered.
        2. a. Are the Department of Justice/Federal Trade Commission 
    Horizontal Merger Guidelines, from which the staff proposal is 
    drawn, the best framework to evaluate market power in the interstate 
    natural gas pipeline context?
        b. Are there other approaches to evaluating market power that 
    would be less burdensome?
        3. a. Are the criteria proposed in the staff paper reasonable, 
    too strenuous, or not strenuous enough?
        b. Should the Commission use a different standard for different 
    types of service, such as mainline transmission, storage, or market 
    hub services?
        4. a. Should the Commission consider treating companies with a 
    small market share differently from larger or dominant sellers, and 
    if so, under what circumstances?
        b. How should the Commission view cases in which large sellers 
    face large buyers (that is, where a single buyer represents a large 
    share of a transporter's market?
        c. Can a buyer's monopsony power mitigate a seller's market 
    power, and if so, how should the Commission analyze such cases?
        5. Do commenters agree or disagree with staff's analysis that 
    capacity release does not constitute a good alternative to firm 
    transportation?
        6. What procedures should the Commission employ to evaluate 
    market-based rate proposals; should the Commission change its 
    current policy of using declaratory orders or ruling on pro forma 
    tariff sheets?
        7. Are there particular requirements the Commission could impose 
    that would increase the availability of shippers' service 
    alternatives and mitigate the market power of a natural gas company 
    that would not otherwise qualify for market-based pricing?
        8. Are there regulatory policies or ratemaking methods that 
    would better serve the Commission's regulatory goals of flexible, 
    efficient pricing in today's environment? For example, should the 
    Commission focus on ``backstop'' proposals, where pipelines would be 
    free to negotiate rates and terms of service, so long as customers 
    could always choose service under traditional cost-of-service rates 
    and terms of service?
    
        In addition, the Commission also invites comments on the criteria 
    for evaluating incentive rate proposals. While the Commission currently 
    has a policy for evaluating cost-based incentive rate proposals, to 
    date no natural gas company has submitted a proposal in response to the 
    Commission's invitation to submit incentive rate proposals for an 
    experimental period. The Commission's October 30, 1992 policy statement 
    on incentive regulation defined the essential elements of an incentive 
    ratemaking policy and set guidelines for incentive rate proposals.\4\ 
    The policy statement adopted two general principles: That incentive 
    regulation should encourage efficiency, and that starting rates under 
    incentive regulation must conform to the Commission's 
    [[Page 8357]] traditional cost-of-service ratemaking standards. The 
    policy statement also established five regulatory standards for the 
    evaluation of specific proposals--that incentive proposals must: (1) Be 
    prospective, (2) be voluntary, (3) be understandable, (4) result in 
    quantified benefits to consumers, and (5) demonstrate how they maintain 
    or enhance incentives to improve the quality of service. The standard 
    pertaining to the quantification of benefits requires the inclusion of 
    an absolute upper limit on the risk to consumers, with the overall cap 
    on incentive rate increases based on projected traditional cost-of-
    service rates. In view of the lack of response to the October 30, 1992 
    policy statement and the changes in the natural gas market that have 
    occurred since the issuance of the policy statement (principally the 
    implementation of Order No. 636), the Commission believes it is 
    appropriate at this time to revisit the issue of incentive rates for 
    pipeline services and requests comments in response to the following 
    questions:
    
        \4\Policy Statement on Incentive Regulation, 61 FERC 61,168 
    (1992).
    
        9. Why have there not been any incentive proposals under the 
    policy established in Docket No. PL92-1-000?
        10. a. Should the Commission change its existing standards for 
    incentive rate proposals?
        b. If so, what specific criteria should the Commission employ 
    when evaluating incentive rates?
        11. Are there models for incentive regulation that the 
    Commission should consider, such as the California performance-based 
    program?
        12. a. What are the benefits and drawbacks of incentive rates, 
    and the policy objectives the Commission should pursue with an 
    incentive rate method?
        b. Is incentive ratemaking appropriate for the natural gas 
    companies regulated by the Commission?
        c. Please identify and discuss any legal issues that the 
    Commission has not yet considered with this type of rate method.
    
        There are other pricing methods which are neither market-based nor 
    incentive-based, such as reference pricing (in which the rate is 
    determined by reference, e.g., to the rates of another company or the 
    price of another product). The Commission also requests comments on 
    criteria for evaluating such proposals:
    
        13. What other rate methods should the Commission consider 
    beyond the market-based and incentive-based methods covered above?
        14. a. What would be the benefits and drawbacks of any such 
    methods?
        b. Please identify and discuss any particular legal or 
    procedural issues raised by a specific method.
        15. What criteria would the Commission use to evaluate such 
    proposals?
    
        The Commission is requesting written comments on these questions 
    and the attached staff paper on market-based rates. The Commission 
    requests parties to identify the numbered questions in their comments 
    to the maximum extent possible. An original and 15 copies of written 
    comments should be filed with the Secretary of the Commission within 60 
    days of the issuance of this notice, and should refer to Docket No. 
    RM95-6-000.
    
        By direction of the Commission.
    Lois D. Cashell,
    Secretary.
    
    Table of Contents
    
    I. The Applicable Legal Standards
    II. The Commission's Prior Experience With Market-Based Rates
        A. The Gas Inventory Charge Cases
        B. The Storage Cases
        C. The Oil Pipeline Cases
        D. The Electric Cases
    III. Proposed Criteria for Evaluating Market-Based Transportation 
    Rate Proposals
        A. General Framework and Criteria
        B. An Example of the Analysis Applied to Firm Transportation
        C. Application of Criteria to Other Services
        D. Review of Market Power Findings
    
    Appendix: Analysis of Other Industries
    
    Market-Based Rates for Natural Gas Companies
    
    A Staff Paper
    
        The Commission has been requested by various companies to approve 
    market-based pricing for both firm and interruptible transportation, 
    for capacity released in the secondary market, for storage and for 
    market hub services such as the ``switching'' and ``parking'' of 
    natural gas. Approval of any of these proposals is contingent on the 
    Commission finding that the company in question lacks significant 
    market power. The purpose of this paper is to propose criteria that 
    could be used to evaluate these proposals.
        In developing these criteria staff has reviewed the Commission's 
    prior experience with market-based ratemaking for natural gas 
    companies, oil pipelines, and public utilities. In those cases the 
    Commission consistently used the same general framework to evaluate 
    requests for market-based rates. In addition, the experiences in three 
    other industries (railroads, telecommunications, and airlines) also 
    have been reviewed to determine whether there are lessons that can be 
    drawn. For illustrative purposes the paper applies the proposed 
    criteria to a hypothetical case. Finally, the paper discusses the other 
    services that may qualify for market-based rates as well as factors the 
    Commission may want to consider in monitoring market-based rates.
    
    I. The Applicable Legal Standards
    
        Operating under the ``just and reasonable'' standard of the Natural 
    Gas Act (NGA), the Federal Power Act (FPA), and the Interstate Commerce 
    Act (ICA), the Commission generally authorizes rates based on the cost 
    of service. However, as the Supreme Court has ruled on numerous 
    occasions,\1\ the just and reasonable standard does not limit the 
    Commission to any particular ratemaking methodology; rather, the 
    Commission has flexibility in selecting ratemaking methods.
    
        \1\See Mobil Exploration & Producing Southeast Inc. v. United 
    Distribution Companies, 498 U.S. 211 (1991) (affirming the 
    Commission's Authority to consolidate existing ``vintage'' price 
    categories and set a single ceiling price for ``old'' gas); Duquesne 
    Light Co. v. Barash, 488 U.S. 299, 310 (1989); Permian Basin Area 
    Rate Cases, 390 U.S. 508, 517 (1979); FPC v. Hope Natural Gas Co., 
    320 U.S. 591, 602 (1944).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Courts have held that non-cost factors can legitimate a departure 
    from cost-based rates. Departures from cost-based rates have been found 
    to be justified when: (1) The changing characteristics of the industry 
    make advisable or necessary a new approach;\2\ (2) the deviations from 
    costs are not unreasonable or inconsistent with statutory 
    responsibilities;\3\ and (3) the regulatory scheme acts as a monitor to 
    determine whether competition will keep prices within a zone of 
    reasonableness or to check rates if it does not.\4\ However, in ruling 
    that rates need not be linked to costs in order to be just and 
    reasonable, the court in Farmers Union II held that the Commission 
    cannot merely assume that competition will ensure just and reasonable 
    prices: ``[m]oving from heavy to lighthanded regulation within the 
    boundaries set by an unchanged statute,'' can only ``be justified by a 
    showing that under the current circumstances the goals and purposes of 
    the statute will be accomplished through substantially less regulatory 
    oversight.''\5\
    
        \2\Farmers Union Central Exchange, Inc. V. FERC, 734 F.2D 1486, 
    1503 (D.C. Cir. 1984) (Farmers Union II), cert. denied sub nom., 
    Williams Pipe Line Co. v. Farmers Union Central Exchange, Inc., 469 
    U.S. 1034 (1984) (citing Permian Basin Area Rate Cases, 390 U.S. 747 
    (1968)).
        \3\Farmers Union II at 1502 (citing Mobil Oil Corp. v. FPC, 417 
    U.S. 283 (1974)).
        \4\Id. at 1509 (citing Texaco, Inc. v. FPC, 474 F.2d 416, 422 
    (D.C. Cir. 1972), vacated, 417 U.S. 380 (1974) (the court of 
    appeal's decision was vacated on other grounds)).
        \5\Id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission's authority to approve market-based rates under the 
    [[Page 8358]] appropriate circumstances was recently and clearly 
    affirmed in Elizabethtown Gas Co. v. FERC.\6\ There, the court upheld 
    the Commission's approval of a natural gas pipeline's proposal, as part 
    of a pre-Order No. 636 restructuring settlement entered into with its 
    customers, to sell gas for resale at market-based prices. Noting that 
    the Supreme Court has held on numerous occasions that the just and 
    reasonable standard does not dictate any single pricing methodology,\7\ 
    the court held that where there is a competitive market, the Commission 
    ``may rely upon market-based prices in lieu of cost-of-service 
    regulation to assure a `just and reasonable' result.''\8\ In sustaining 
    the Commission's approval of market pricing in this case, the court 
    alluded to the Commission's specific finding that the pipeline's 
    markets were ``sufficiently competitive to preclude [the pipeline] from 
    exercising significant market power in its merchant function* * *.''\9\ 
    Specifically, the Commission had determined--and no record evidence to 
    the contrary was cited on appeal--that adequate divertible supplies of 
    gas existed to give customers options to buy from sellers other than 
    the pipeline, thus assuring that the pipeline would have to sell its 
    own gas at competitive prices. This finding, the court reasoned, 
    justified the Commission's conclusion that the pipeline would be able 
    to charge only a price that was just and reasonable within the meaning 
    of section 4 of the NGA.
    
        \6\10 F.3d 866, 870 (D.C. Cir. 1993) (Elizabethtown).
        \7\The court cited Mobil Oil Exploration v. U.S., 111 S. Ct. 
    615, 624 (1991): ``* * * the just and reasonable standard does not 
    compel the Commission to use any single pricing formula * * *.'' 10 
    F.3d at 870.
        \8\Id. (quoting Tejas Power Corp. v. FERC, 908 F.2d 998, 1104 
    (D.C. Cir. 1990).
        \9\10 F.3d at 870-71 (quoting Transcontinental Gas Pipe Line 
    Corp., 55 FERC 61,446 at 62,234.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In reaching this result, the court of appeals in Elizabethtown 
    distinguished the Supreme Court's decision in FPC v. Texaco, Inc. 
    (Texaco),\10\ in which the Supreme Court had remanded an FPC order 
    exempting small gas producers from direct regulation of their prices. 
    The Commission order under challenge in Texaco provided that small 
    producers' prices would be subject to scrutiny only as a part of the 
    rates of pipelines and large producers to whom they sold their gas, and 
    then only through review of the pipeline and large producer rates. This 
    indirect review procedure was found by the Court to be permissible 
    under the NGA.\11\ However, the order was remanded because the 
    Commission had not clearly shown how, or even whether, the just and 
    reasonable standard would be applied to the small producers' prices in 
    this process.\12\ The Court admonished that on remand the Commission 
    must adhere to the principle that ``the prevailing price in the market 
    cannot be the final measure of 'just and reasonable' rates mandated by 
    the Act.''\13\
    
        \10\FPC v. Texaco, Inc., 417 U.S. 380, 397 (1974).
        \11\417 U.S. at 387-91
        \12\The Commission stated that the just and reasonable standard 
    would be applied, and enumerated various factors, in addition to 
    prevailing market prices, that would be taken into account. The 
    Court observed that these representations were relevant to the 
    validity of the order, but ruled that because they were not made in 
    the order itself--only on appeal--they were unavailing. 417 U.S. at 
    397.
        \13\417 U.S. at 397.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The court in Elizabethtown reasoned that the point of Texaco was 
    only that if Congress has subjected an industry to regulation because 
    of anticompetitive conditions in the industry, the market cannot be the 
    ``final'' arbiter of the reasonableness of a price.\14\ Further, the 
    court in Elizabethtown stated, in the Texaco proceeding the Commission 
    had not even mentioned the ``just and reasonable'' standard, but rather 
    appeared to apply only the marketplace standard in determining the 
    reasonableness of small producers' rates. In contrast, in the order 
    challenged in Elizabethtown, the Commission had made it clear that it 
    would exercise its section 5 authority if necessary to assure that a 
    market rate is just and reasonable.
    
        \14\Elizabethtown, 10 F.3d at 870.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A hybrid cost/market-based pricing scheme under the FPA was 
    approved by the court in Environmental Action v. FERC.\15\ There the 
    Commission had approved the application of certain regulated and non-
    regulated electric utilities to operate a power pool in which 
    transactions would be priced according to the market, subject to a 
    uniform ceiling price based upon a hypothetical average utility's 
    costs. The court, in rejecting challenges to the pricing mechanism, 
    emphasized the speed and administrative efficiency benefits of market-
    based pricing. In addition, the court also cited the Commission's 
    expressed intention to monitor transactions and invoke its 
    investigatory powers under section 206 (either sua sponte or upon 
    complaint) to redress abuses. Thus, the court concluded that ``[i]n 
    sum, FERC sought to preserve the Pool's efficiencies even as it guarded 
    against price gouging. On the facts in evidence, we find no basis for 
    concluding it acted unreasonably.''\16\
    
        \15\996 F.2d 401 (D.C. Cir. 1993).
        \16\Id. at 410. See also National Rural Telecom Assoc. V. FCC, 
    988 F.2d 174 (D.C. Cir. 1993) (approving flexible pricing for local 
    exchange companies, subject to a ceiling rate).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The court's treatment of market-based pricing policies implemented 
    by other agencies offers little guidance to the Commission since much 
    of the focus on increasing competition and reducing federal regulations 
    has been through statutory reform, rather than through agency 
    interpretation of existing statutory authorities. The bounds of agency 
    authority to interpret existing statutory procedural requirements in a 
    manner to facilitate a move to market-based pricing was addressed by 
    the Supreme Court in MCI Telecommunications Corporation v. American 
    Telephone and Telegraph Company (MCI II),\17\ and by the court of 
    appeals in Southwestern Bell Corporation v. FCC (Southwestern 
    Bell).\18\ However, MCI II and Southwestern Bell do not speak to the 
    substantive validity of market-based regulation under a just and 
    reasonable statutory standard. Judicial precedents, as explained above, 
    uphold the use of market-based ratemaking, or some variation thereon, 
    if the agency finds that clearly delineated non-cost factors (including 
    the Commission's oversight and remedial authorities) are sufficient to 
    protect the interests of consumers.
    
        \17\114 S. Ct. 2223 (1994).
        \18\Nos. 93-1562, 93-1568, 93-1590, and 93-1624 (D.C. Cir. Jan. 
    20, 1995).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    II. The Commission's Prior Experience With Market-Based Rates
    
    A. The Gas Inventory Charge Cases
    
    1. The Analysis Used
        In 1988, the Commission began its movement towards light-handed 
    regulation of some aspects of natural gas markets. The light-handed 
    regulation first appeared with the implementation of market-based gas 
    inventory charges (GIC) for pipeline sales service. In determining 
    whether a pipeline could implement a GIC mechanism, the Commission 
    looked at three key factors: Market definition, the availability of 
    divertible gas supplies and measures of market power. Additionally, the 
    Commission considered whether the transportation of alternative 
    supplies would be on a comparable basis to the terms and conditions of 
    transportation service provided for gas purchased under the GIC. If the 
    supply markets were found to be competitive and transportation terms 
    and conditions [[Page 8359]] comparable, pipelines were permitted to 
    implement a GIC.\19\
    
        \19\See Transwestern Pipeline Company, 43 FERC 61,240 (1988); 
    El Paso Natural Gas Company, 49 FERC 61,262 (1989 and 54 FERC 
    61,316 (1991); and Transcontinental Gas Pipe Line Corporation, 55 
    FERC 61,446 (1991) aff'd Elizabethtown, supra.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In applying these standards in El Paso, for example, the Commission 
    found that the relevant product market was delivered firm gas. El Paso 
    maintained that the product market was not simply natural gas, but 
    energy generally (i.e. fuel oil, coal, propane, hydroelectric power, 
    and purchased power). However, El Paso did not provide sufficient 
    evidence to make such a case. Thus, the Commission excluded alternative 
    fuels from the product market.
        The Commission established that ``firm'' gas was a dimension of the 
    product market since El Paso was proposing to sell firm gas under its 
    GIC. The Commission also found that ``delivered'' gas was a second 
    dimension of the relevant product market because firm gas supplies that 
    could not be transported to the city-gate were not substitutes for 
    supplies under the GIC.
        In defining El Paso's geographic market, the Commission 
    acknowledged that it could consist of the entire United States or North 
    America. The Commission stated, however, that the relevant geographic 
    market was the geographic area containing those suppliers that can 
    affect any attempt by El Paso to exercise market power. The Commission 
    decided to take a cautious approach and considered three areas of gas 
    supplies in order of the most narrowly defined: (1) The counties in the 
    three basins where El Paso purchases gas that are already connected to 
    El Paso's system, (2) all counties in the three basins, and (3) all 
    counties from which El Paso purchased gas in 1987, including counties 
    outside the three basins. The Commission reasoned that if El Paso 
    lacked market power in the most narrowly defined market, then it would 
    also lack market power in a more broadly defined market. Alternatively, 
    even if El Paso could exercise market power in a narrowly defined 
    market, it might be demonstrated that El Paso nonetheless lacked market 
    power when the definition was expanded.
        The Commission found that 1.07 Bcf/d was the minimum measure of the 
    amount of divertible, or alternative, gas supplies needed to prevent El 
    Paso from exercising market power. The 1.07 Bcf/day represented the gas 
    dedicated to El Paso under long-term contracts, together with its 
    affiliates' volumes. The Commission determined that sufficient 
    divertible supplies existed in each of the defined geographic markets, 
    at competitive prices, such that El Paso would be precluded from 
    exercising market power. The Commission defined divertible supplies as 
    those that were uncommitted, or committed under contract to a buyer for 
    no longer than some short period such as one year.
        The Commission then measured each seller's share of the market. To 
    compute El Paso's market share the Commission used its sales to each 
    customer at the time of peak usage. These market shares were then used 
    to compute the level of concentration in the market using the 
    Hirschman-Herfindahl Index (HHI).\20\ The Commission used an initial 
    screen of .18 to determine if the market concentration was low enough 
    to indicate that the competitors in the market could not exercise 
    market power.\21\ The Commission found that the market concentration 
    was low, i.e., below .18.
    
        \20\An HHI is calculated by summing the squares of each seller's 
    market share. For example, if there are two sellers of a product 
    having shares of total sales of 75 percent and 25 percent, 
    respectively, then the HHI will equal 
    (.75)2+(.25)2=.5625+.0625=.625. Rounding to two 
    significant digits, the HHI is .63.
        \21\An HHI of .18 is equivalent to having 5-6 equal sized 
    competitors in the market. In El Paso, the Commission indicated that 
    it would use a case-by-case approach to determine the lack of market 
    power. The HHI was used as an initial screening tool only. El Paso, 
    49 FERC at 61,920. See also Petal Gas Storage Co., 64 FERC 61,190 
    at 62,573 (1993) (market power determined on a case-by-case basis).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission also found that the transportation service to be 
    provided by El Paso for the transportation of third party supplies was 
    comparable, with certain modifications, to the transportation provided 
    under the GIC.
        Therefore, based on this analysis, the Commission found that El 
    Paso lacked market power and permitted the implementation of a market-
    based GIC.
    2. The Subsequent History of the GIC Cases
        On May 11, 1988, the Commission found that Transwestern lacked 
    market power with respect to the gas commodity. Southern California Gas 
    Company (SoCal), the only company directly affected, had sufficient 
    alternative gas supply sources that Transwestern's prices would be 
    constrained. Therefore, the Commission approved, with some 
    modifications, Transwestern's proposed market-based Gas Inventory 
    Charge (GIC).\22\
    
        \22\Transwestern Pipeline Co., 43 FERC 61,240 (1988).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        When Transwestern attempted to put its GIC charges into effect, 
    SoCal nominated zero volumes of Transwestern's gas.\23\ This is an 
    extreme example of a lack of market power; an attempt to get a premium 
    above the available spot price led to virtually a 100 percent reduction 
    in Transwestern's sales.
    
        \23\Foster Natural Gas Report, No. 1741, for the week ended 
    September 21, 1989, pp. 2-3.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In July, 1990, in Tejas Power Corp. v. FERC,\24\ the court of 
    appeals emphasized the importance of a market power determination in 
    the approval of a GIC mechanism, even in the context of a settlement. 
    In Tejas, the court found the Commission's reliance on the agreement of 
    the LDCs, in approving a GIC settlement proposed by Texas Eastern 
    Transmission Corp., was misplaced because there was no finding, 
    supported by substantial evidence, that the pipeline lacked significant 
    market power. All of the Commission's subsequent market-based GIC cases 
    examined the market power of the pipeline applicant.
    
        \24\908 F.2d 998 (D.C. Cir. 1990) (Tejas).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The series of pipeline-by-pipeline GIC cases allowing market-based 
    pricing for the gas commodity was broadened to a generic finding in 
    Order No. 636. The Commission allowed pipelines to have market-based 
    pricing for unbundled gas sales upon full compliance with the final 
    rule.\25\
    
        \25\FERC Regulations Preambles, 30,939 at 30,439.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In conclusion, the Commission's experience with deregulation of the 
    gas commodity has shown that competition can restrain prices. In fact, 
    the statutory wellhead deregulation and the Commission's open access 
    policies have led to a current price for the gas commodity that is well 
    below the regulated prices that prevailed several years ago.
    
    B. The Storage Cases
    
    1. The Analysis Used
        Starting with the the Commission's order in Richfield Gas Storage 
    System (Richfield)\26\ in June 1992, the Commission has permitted 
    companies to institute market-based storage rates subject to light-
    handed regulation when the applicants have shown that they lack 
    significant market power. In making these market determinations, the 
    Commission primarily looked at the defined markets, the availability of 
    good alternatives, and measures of market power. However, the 
    Commission also considered other factors, such as the fact that the 
    applicants were generally new entrants, the applications were generally 
    unopposed, and the possibility of other [[Page 8360]] new entrants. In 
    applying these standards in Koch, for example, the Commission agreed 
    with Koch's definition of product and geographic markets. Koch applied 
    a narrow and broad definition to both markets. Koch argued that if it 
    did not have market power in narrowly defined markets, it would not 
    have market power when the definitions were broadened.
    
        \26\Richfield Gas Storage System, 59 FERC 61,316 (1992).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Koch defined the narrow product market as natural gas storage. The 
    narrow geographic market was defined to contain those storage 
    facilities in the states of Texas, Louisiana, and Mississippi that are 
    connected to Koch.
        The record showed that Koch owned only 11.9 percent of the contract 
    storage capacity and 6.1 percent of the contract storage deliverability 
    in the narrow market. The market concentration was computed using the 
    Hirschman-Herfindahl Index (HHI) to be .13 for capacity and .12 for 
    deliverability indicating a relatively low concentration in the narrow 
    market.
        The Commission also reviewed the fact that five new suppliers may 
    enter the market by 1996 that would potentially have direct connects to 
    Koch.
        The broader product market was defined to include non-storage 
    alternatives and storage alternatives not connected to Koch, such as, 
    capacity release of storage in new or existing storage facilities, 
    purchase of natural gas from producers or other marketers, selling gas 
    to customers that have several suppliers, access to no-notice storage, 
    to name a few. The broader geographic market was defined as 
    alternatives outside of Texas, Louisiana and Mississippi.
        The Commission gave much consideration to whether or not the 
    alternatives identified by Koch were ``good'' alternatives. The 
    Commission defined a good alternative as one that is available soon 
    enough, has a price that is low enough, and has a quality high enough 
    to permit customers to substitute the alternative for Koch's service. 
    In addition, the alternative must be available in sufficient quantity 
    to make Koch's price increase unprofitable.
        The Commission found that good alternatives were available in 
    sufficient quantities and at competitive prices. The Commission 
    determined that unutilized storage capacity was available in large 
    quantities in Texas, Louisiana and Mississippi during peak periods 
    based on statistics found in EIA's Natural Gas Monthly. The Commission 
    reasoned that if this unutilized capacity was not under contract it was 
    available for purchase. Unutilized capacity that was committed under 
    contract, the Commission reasoned, would be available through capacity 
    release. Therefore, given the small size of Koch in relation to other 
    storage providers, the abundant storage alternatives available to 
    Koch's customers, and that the alternatives are ``good'' alternatives, 
    the Commission concluded that Koch could not exercise market power in 
    providing storage service.
    2. The Experience After Approving Market-Based Rates
        The market-based storage cases approved by the Commission 
    (Richfield, Petal, Transok, Bay State, Avoca, and Koch) are quite 
    recent. The companies in question were not subjected to any special 
    reporting requirements. Thus, there is little information currently to 
    evaluate these decisions. In addition, the pipelines in several of 
    these cases executed long term contracts at the same time they were 
    seeking market based rates. The contracts set the prices for the term 
    of the contract. No complaints have been filed so far regarding the 
    market based storage rates. However, one would not expect to see the 
    complaints so early in the process. Complaints would be more likely to 
    occur when the parties seek to negotiate new pricing provisions at the 
    end of the contract term, if new capacity becomes available, or if the 
    circumstances which served as the basis of the Commission's decision 
    changed.
        Earlier, however, the Commission approved an experiment wherein 
    Koch storage was allowed to charge any price it could negotiate up to a 
    cap which exceeded the cost-based rate. The Commission did not make a 
    finding that Koch lacked significant market power. The results of the 
    ``Market Responsive Storage and Delivery Service'' (MRSDS) experiment 
    suggest that competition constrained Koch to prices actually below the 
    cost-based rates. All market-based MRSDS rates charged by Koch were 
    below the cap. During the two full heating seasons of the experiment, 
    customers fully subscribed all the capacity allocated to MRSDS.\27\
    
        \27\Koch Gateway Pipeline Co., 66 FERC 61,385 at 62,301-302 
    (1994).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    C. The Oil Pipeline Cases
    
        In the oil pipeline area, two companies have the authority to 
    charge market-based rates--Buckeye Pipe Line Company, L.P. (Buckeye) 
    and Williams Pipe Line Company (Williams). In both cases the Commission 
    determined that the pipeline lacked market power in markets for which 
    each was allowed to charge market-based rates.\28\
    
        \28\Buckeye Pipe Line Company, L.P., 53 FERC 61,473 (1990). 
    Williams Pipe Line Company, 69 FERC 61,136 (1994). Both cases were 
    litigated and the Commission made its findings that certain markets 
    were competitive based on the records presented at the hearings.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    1. The Analysis Used
        In conducting its analysis of whether the applicant had market 
    power, the Commission first defined the product and geographic markets. 
    It then evaluated whether the applicant had significant market power in 
    those markets by first doing an initial screen for market concentration 
    in each market (using the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index) and then 
    considering, weighing and balancing a number of other factors, such as, 
    the potential entry of competitors into the market, available 
    transportation alternatives, market share, availability of excess 
    capacity, and the presence of large buyers able to exert downward 
    monopsonistic pressure on transportation rates.
        In Buckeye, for example, the relevant product market was defined as 
    the transportation of refined petroleum products. The Commission agreed 
    with the ALJ and rejected the position advanced by ATA that the product 
    market should be markets in which Buckeye transports only jet fuel. The 
    Commission concluded that the ease of product substitution among 
    pipelines is an important reason why the relevant product market should 
    be the transportation of refined petroleum products rather than the 
    transportation of a specific petroleum product, such as gasoline, fuel 
    oil or jet fuel.
        The relevant geographic markets were defined as the areas that 
    include all supplies of transportation from all origins to United 
    States Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis Economic 
    Areas (BEAs).\29\ The Commission concluded that the evidence of record 
    supported the findings of the ALJ that BEAs are shown to be appropriate 
    geographic markets since they are convenient, easily identified and 
    have been used in past studies of the oil pipeline industry.
    
        \29\BEAs are geographic regions surrounding major cities that 
    are intended to represent areas of actual economic activity.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission also concluded that an analysis of market 
    concentration using HHIs should be the first step in evaluating the 
    likelihood of market power being exercised in a given market. Knowing 
    the degree of concentration in a market provides useful information 
    about where on the competitive spectrum that market lies and what other 
    factors will have to be weighed to enable a finding as to the existence 
    or absence of significant market power. For measuring market 
    concentration, the Commission concluded that a proper screening device 
    is an HHI.\30\ The Commission also concluded that the use of delivery 
    data, e.g., deliveries into each BEA, is the best method for 
    calculating HHIs in Buckeye. [[Page 8361]] 
    
        \30\The Commission used an HHI of .18 as an initial screen in 
    Transcontinental Gas Pipe Line Corp. (Transco), 55 FERC 61,446 at 
    62,393 (1991).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In Buckeye (Opinion No. 380), market power was defined as the 
    ability to profitably raise the price above the competitive level for a 
    significant time period. Significant market power was defined as the 
    ability to control market price by sustaining at least a 15% real price 
    increase, without losing sales, for a period of two years. The 
    Commission further concluded that the relevant price for the purposes 
    of making a determination of whether Buckeye can profitably increase 
    its transportation prices above the competitive level is the delivered 
    product price. Because shippers or customers in the destination market 
    often have the option of switching away from purchasing transportation 
    into the market, and, instead, purchasing the delivered product itself, 
    suppliers of transportation must compete with suppliers of the 
    delivered product.
        There were 22 markets examined in Opinion No. 380. The Commission 
    found that in 15 Buckeye lacked significant market power; in two 
    Buckeye had no tariffs on file thus no finding was warranted; in one 
    the record was insufficient and so continued regulation was necessary; 
    and, in four, Buckeye was found to have market power.
    2. The Buckeye Experiment
        In Opinions No. 380 and 380-A, the Commission also authorized a 
    three year experimental program proposed by Buckeye.\31\ During this 
    experiment, rates in each competitive market were subject to two 
    limitations: (1) Individual rate increases could not exceed a ``cap'' 
    of 15% real increase over any two-year period, and (2) individual rate 
    increases would be allowed to become effective without suspension or 
    investigation only if they did not exceed a ``trigger'' of the change 
    in the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) deflator plus 2%. Rate decreases 
    were presumably valid but could not result in rates below marginal 
    costs.
    
        \31\53 FERC 61,473 and 54 FERC 61,117.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In the markets the Commission did not find to be competitive, no 
    rate could be increased by more than the volume-weighted average rate 
    increase in the competitive markets. Conversely, every rate in the 
    ``non-competitive markets'' had to reflect the volume-weighted average 
    of rate decreases in the competitive markets.\32\
    
        \32\On March 24, 1994, the Commission accepted a tariff that 
    extended this experiment for an indefinite period (66 FERC 61,348). 
    However, the Order stated that Buckeye was subject to the 
    requirements of Order No. 561, the simplified and generally 
    applicable ratemaking methodology for oil pipelines, when they take 
    effect on January 1, 1995. On December 6, 1994, the Commission 
    permitted Buckeye to continue its experimental program as an 
    exception to the Commission's oil pricing policies, subject to 
    future reevaluation. Buckeye Pipe Line Co., L.P., 69 FERC 61,302 
    (1994).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        No protests of rate changes or complaints against existing rates 
    were filed during the three year experiment. In addition, no protests 
    were filed in opposition to Buckeye's filing to extend the experiment 
    indefinitely.\33\ Buckeye noted that this lack of opposition to its 
    market-based program was ``in sharp contrast to the years of complex 
    and expensive rate litigation that preceded adoption of * * *'' this 
    program.\34\
    
        \33\66 FERC 61,348.
        \34\October 26, 1994 Buckeye Pipeline filing in Docket No. OR94-
    6-000, et al.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        No rates were changed by more than the GDP+2% trigger during the 
    three year period. In the competitive markets, rate increases were 
    generally well below the trigger, and in the non-competitive markets, 
    rate increases were below the allowed volume-weighted average increase 
    in the competitive markets. The allowable and average actual rate 
    changes are shown in the table below.
    
                              Buckeye Rate Changes                          
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                                                   Non-     
                                                Competitive     competitive 
     Year (April       Cap         Trigger        markets         markets   
     1 to March     (GDP+15%)     (GDP+2%)     average rate    average rate 
         31)        (percent)     (percent)       change          change    
                                                 (percent)       (percent)  
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    90-91.......      19.16          6.16           3.86            3.58    
    91-92.......      22.32          5.16           3.14            2.74    
    92-93.......      20.69          4.53           1.45            0.97    
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Since all changes in rates are based on an index not reflecting the 
    pipeline's costs, there is no danger of the raising of rates in non-
    competitive markets through shifting costs attributable to competitive 
    markets.\35\ This attribute is not exclusive to the Buckeye program; 
    approaches which base rate changes on something other than the 
    pipeline's costs would eliminate this concern about cost shifting.
    
        \35\While there was concern that Buckeye might be able top 
    ``manipulate'' the program by raising prices in the competitive 
    markets solely to raise prices in the non-competitive markets, the 
    Commission found this to be a very unlikely event under the approved 
    program. It nevertheless committed to monitoring for this occurrence 
    during the experiment (53 FERC 61,473). Since the growth rate of 
    revenues was higher in the competitive markets than in the non-
    competitive markets (constant annual growth rates of 6.54% versus 
    2.78% (66 FERC 61,348)), this demonstrates that this potential 
    problem did not occur during the experiment.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Finally, under the market-based program Buckeye was able to engage 
    in some successful marketing in very competitive situations. For 
    example, in Indianapolis, where Buckeye held less than three percent of 
    the market in 1990, Buckeye raised its share to 17 percent in 1993. 
    ``These increased volumes resulted from Buckeye's deep price discounts 
    (as deep as 40%) in 1991 and later a volume incentive tariff to attract 
    new refinery business from a recently restarted independent refinery * 
    * *''\36\ As a result of Buckeye's actions, the total size of the 
    Indianapolis market increased and its concentration decreased.
    
        \36\February 22, 1994 ``Statement of James A. Spicer on behalf 
    of Buckeye Pipe Line Company, L.P.''
        In contrast to oil pipelines, natural gas pipelines are 
    permitted to selectively discount. Thus, gas pipelines would be able 
    to structure such a deal under the Commission's traditional cost-
    based rate regulation.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    D. The Electric Cases
    
        Since 1986, the Commission has approved many applications from 
    public utilities to sell electricity in wholesale transactions at 
    negotiated market-based rates. In a recent order addressing a request 
    for market-based rates from an electricity marketer affiliated with a 
    traditional public [[Page 8362]] utility, the Commission summarized its 
    position. The Commission:
    
        * * * allows market-based rates if the seller (and each of its 
    affiliates) does not have, or has adequately mitigated, market power 
    in generation and transmission and cannot erect barriers to entry. 
    In addition, the Commission considers whether there is evidence of 
    affiliate abuse or reciprocal dealing.\37\
    
        \37\Heartland Energy Services, 69 FERC  61,223 (1994).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Applicants for whom the Commission approved market-based rates are 
    required to file periodic reports or studies to demonstrate their 
    continuing lack of market power and the absence of abusive affiliate 
    practices.
        The first step in evaluating market power in generation is to 
    identify the relevant product and geographic markets.\38\ In those 
    markets, suppliers' market shares are calculated. Low market shares 
    demonstrate that the seller is unlikely to be able to assert market 
    power in that market.\39\ An applicant with a high market share would 
    be subject to further scrutiny.
    
        \38\See, e.g., Kansas City Power & Light, 67 FERC  61,183 
    (1994).
        \39\In PSI, 51 FERC 61,367 (1990), order on reh'g 52 FERC 
    61,963 (1990), the Commission determined that a seller with a 
    market share of less than 20 percent did not dominate the market.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        For example, in Enron Power Enterprises Corporation,\40\ the 
    Commission looked at the market for generating services bid to New 
    England Power Company (NEPCO). In that market, Enron's market share was 
    4 percent. Furthermore, there were 18 projects out of 22 finalists that 
    were not selected. Thus, NEPCO had numerous additional alternatives to 
    choose from other than Enron. In addition, NEPCO negotiated several 
    favorable provisions in its agreement with Enron suggesting that Enron 
    was not a dominant supplier at the time of the solicitation.
    
        \40\52 FERC  61,193 at 61,708-61,709 (1990).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        There have been two additional factors of concern to the Commission 
    in electricity cases: Affiliate abuse and the ability to erect barriers 
    to entry. With respect to affiliate abuse, in recent cases, the 
    Commission has required the affiliated parties to file separately for 
    any sales or purchases of electric power between the marketer and its 
    affiliated utility. In addition, the Commission requires the affiliated 
    marketer to purchase any transmission services it may receive from its 
    affiliated utility under a generally applicable, open-access, 
    comparable tariff.
        With respect to an applicant's ability to erect barriers to entry, 
    only a few electric cases have raised this issue. Some affiliates of 
    natural gas pipelines have sought market rate approval for sales of 
    electricity.\41\ However, the Commission has looked to Order No. 636 
    procedures mandating open access transportation on jurisdictional 
    pipelines to preclude pipelines from erecting barriers to entry.
    
        \41\See, e.g., Hartwell, 60 FERC  61,143 (1992).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As a result of Enron and other cases, the Commission has developed 
    considerable experience in analyzing generation markets. Recently, in 
    Kansas City Power and Light,\42\ the Commission concluded that new 
    generating facilities were being built by many different parties and 
    that there was no evidence that any party could assert market power in 
    markets being served by new facilities. Consequently, as did the 
    Commission in its series of GIC decisions, market power analysis is no 
    longer required when the applicant is proposing sales from new 
    facilities.
    
        \42\67 FERC  61,183 (1994).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission's treatment of transmission market power does not 
    parallel its treatment of market power in generation. The Commission 
    has basically equated applicant ownership or control of transmission 
    facilities with the applicant having market power in transmission in 
    that region.\43\ The Commission therefore requires transmission owners 
    to file generally applicable open-access, comparable transmission 
    tariffs before the Commission will permit them to charge market 
    rates.\44\
    
        \43\See Enron Power Marketing, 65 FERC  61,305 (1993), order on 
    reh'g, 66 FERC  61,244.
        \44\The current policy was announced in Hermiston Generating, 69 
    FERC  61,035 (1994).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    III. Proposed Criteria for Evaluating Market-Based Transportation Rate 
    Proposals
    
    A. General Framework and Criteria
    
        To date, in all cases where the Commission has considered market-
    based rates, the applicant has been required to show that it lacks 
    significant market power in the relevant markets. Market power is 
    defined as the ability of a pipeline to profitably maintain prices 
    above competitive levels for a significant period of time.
        While the Commission has not adopted a mechanistic approach to 
    assessing market power, it has consistently used the same general 
    framework to evaluate requests for market-based rates.
        Using this general framework, Commission staff proposes criteria to 
    evaluate the competitiveness of transportation services. To show a lack 
    of market power over firm transportation, for example, staff 
    anticipates that a pipeline would need, initially, to show that its 
    customers have four to five good alternatives to the applicant's firm 
    transportation service. This is the equivalent of an HHI of .18, which 
    the Commission has used as an initial screen in previous cases.\45\ 
    Staff suggests that only capacity that the applicant shows will be 
    available on other pipelines when the applicant institutes market-based 
    rates could be considered as an alternative.
    
        \45\E.g., Transco, 55 FERC at 62,393.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        One necessary element of showing that customers have alternatives 
    would be the pipeline's agreement to give existing firm transportation 
    customers the right to renominate their contract demand levels if a 
    pipeline is allowed to charge market-based rates under existing 
    contracts. Otherwise, the applicant clearly has market power over its 
    customers if existing contracts prevent its customers from freely 
    choosing alternative service or renegotiating their contracts at the 
    time market forces are permitted to control the rates for services. 
    This situation did not exist in the storage cases where the Commission 
    permitted market-based pricing. In those cases, the applicants were 
    either new entrants or existing entities offering new services. There 
    were no existing contracts in effect that the Commission needed to 
    address. This condition is consistent with the Commission's practice in 
    the GIC proceedings where it allowed customers to renominate their 
    sales contract demand levels if a pipeline instituted a GIC.
        The framework proposed would be the same for all types of services. 
    It consists of three major steps:
    
    1. Define Relevant Markets
        a. Product market: identify good alternatives to the applicant's 
    product; and
        b. Geographic market: identify sellers of good alternatives.
    2. Measure Firm Size and Market Concentration
        a. Measure the size of the market, calculate each seller's 
    market share, and evaluate applicant's market share;
        b. Estimate market concentration using the Herfindahl-Hirschman 
    Index (HHI); and
        c. Evaluate market concentration by using an initial HHI screen 
    of 0.18; a finding in that range is equivalent to finding that 
    customers have at least four or five equal-sized alternatives to the 
    applicant's service.
    3. Evaluate Other Factors
        a. If the applicant's market share is large or the market 
    concentration is high (i.e., HHI exceeds 0.18), examine other 
    factors that might prevent or limit the exercise of market power; 
    [[Page 8363]] 
        b. These other factors might include ease of entry, excess 
    capacity held by competing sellers, and buyer power.
    
        Each of these steps is discussed further below. In section B of 
    this part is an example showing the application of this analysis to a 
    hypothetical interstate pipeline in a market supplied by a number of 
    pipelines.
        There are some services that are more likely to pass these criteria 
    than others. These are discussed more fully in section IV.C. below.\46\ 
    For example, IT and hub services have different characteristics than 
    firm transportation and might more easily satisfy these criteria. If 
    the capacity release program is functioning well, IT service may 
    compete with capacity release offered by all of the pipeline's 
    customers in the relevant zones. Capacity release may be a good 
    alternative for IT service. There are, by definition, several pipelines 
    at each market hub.\47\ Each of the pipelines at the hub may be able to 
    offer the same hub services as good alternatives to each other.
    
        \46\This paper does not attempt to analyze the capacity release 
    market or IT service in any detail but the same general framework 
    would apply to these.
        \47\See ``Importance of Market Centers,'' Office of Economic 
    Policy, FERC (Washington, D.C.), August 21, 1992. Some pipelines 
    have defined market hubs differently.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As a practical matter, it may well be difficult for long-term firm 
    transportation to qualify under this framework. The nature of the 
    transportation grid ensures that pipelines typically face few direct 
    competitors in delivering gas from one point to another. In addition, 
    given the long-term contracting for firm transportation service that 
    exists, staff believes it may be difficult for pipelines to show that 
    customers have the ability to freely move to alternative long-term 
    transportation. For example, if a pipeline that proposes market-based 
    rates for firm transportation has existing long-term contracts for that 
    service, the pipeline would need to allow its customers to terminate 
    their contracts to freely move to alternative services.
    1. Market Definition
        Market definition identifies the specific products or services and 
    the suppliers of those products or services that provide good 
    alternatives to the applicant's product or service. In this market 
    staff would test the applicant's ability to exercise market power. 
    Naturally, the more narrowly the market is defined, the harder it is to 
    show a lack of market power.
        The Commission's order approving market-based storage rates for 
    Koch Gateway, defined good alternatives as follows:
    
        A good alternative is an alternative that is available soon 
    enough, has a price that is low enough, and has a quality high 
    enough to permit customers to substitute the alternative for Koch 
    Gateway's service.\48\
    
        \48\Koch Gateway, 66 FERC at 62,299.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    a. The Product Market
        The applicant's service together with other services that are good 
    alternatives constitute the relevant product market. The applicant must 
    fully, and specifically, define the product market. For example, the 
    applicant must be specific in defining whether the product market 
    consists of firm transportation only, or if the product market consists 
    of off-peak interruptible transportation service only, etc. The 
    applicant must also be responsible for developing and justifying any 
    substitutes for the relevant product that can be considered competitive 
    alternatives, e.g., storage delivery services, gathering services, etc. 
    For example, pipelines might suggest numerous alternatives to FT in 
    their applications: IT, storage services, residual fuel oil, etc.
        It is likely that applicants will argue that the market should be 
    defined broadly. Given the natural monopoly features of many 
    transportation services, staff suggests that the Commission take a more 
    conservative approach and define the product market narrowly as only 
    firm transportation. For purposes of defining relevant gas 
    transportation markets, staff focuses here on the pipeline customers' 
    peak.\49\
    
        \49\During the winter peak period we would expect that excess 
    capacity would be at a minimum and that customers' alternatives 
    would be fewer than in off-peak periods.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    i. Timeliness
        Generally, antitrust authorities have used one year as the time 
    period in which to test whether a product can become a substitute. This 
    is probably not appropriate for long-term firm transportation because 
    capacity on competitors would typically need to be available 
    simultaneously to offer a viable alternative to customers. If the 
    pipeline applicant relies on the existence of capacity that will not be 
    available immediately, it would also need to show that its customers 
    would not be committed to long term contracts on its system under the 
    operation of the right of first refusal rules, so that the alternative 
    would not be available.
    ii. Price
        Along with showing that alternative capacity will be available in a 
    reasonable time frame, the applicant must demonstrate that the price 
    for the available capacity is low enough to effectively restrain the 
    applicant from increasing prices. In prior cases, the Commission has 
    defined such a threshold price level as being at or below the 
    applicant's approved maximum cost-based rate plus 15%.\50\
    
        \50\In Buckeye Pipe Line Company, L.P., Opinion No. 360, the 
    Commission held that a 15 percent increase was an appropriate level 
    to measure market power. 53 FERC 61,473 at 62,681 (1990), order on 
    reh'g, Opinion No. 360-A, 55 FERC 61,084 (1991). However, in 
    Williams Pipe Line Co., Opinion No. 391, the Commission declined to 
    adopt a specific rate increase as a litmus test for market power. 68 
    FERC 61,136 at 61,657. In Koch Gateway Pipeline Company, the 
    Commission suggested that potential alternatives would include 
    services that though presently not used, would be economic if 
    prevailing prices were to rise by a modest amount, e.g., five to 15 
    percent. 66 FERC 61,385.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The regulated price has been used as the prevailing price--a proxy 
    for the competitive price. This is necessary because almost all prices 
    for transportation are regulated and a competitive price level would be 
    at best a guess. However, the use of prevailing prices presents 
    analytic problems. For example, three pipelines that follow parallel 
    courses may have radically different rates because of different 
    historical costs, despite the fact that in a competitive market they 
    would offer almost identical services at almost identical prices. Which 
    of the alternative pipelines' prices should be used as the 
    ``prevailing'' price? This question would have to be addressed in 
    deciding whether the prices of alternatives are appropriate references.
    iii. Quality
        A good alternative must provide service in which the quality is at 
    least as high as that of the service provided by the applicant. In 
    order to make this showing the applicant must first be required to 
    describe its own services. Then, the applicant must demonstrate that 
    any available third party capacity must be comparable in service to the 
    transportation service provided by the applicant.
        Staff believes that with Order Nos. 436 and 636, all interstate 
    pipelines currently provide operationally comparable firm 
    transportation (FT) service.
        However, even if a customer can find available capacity on an 
    alternative pipeline, the overall package of services available may not 
    be comparable to that it currently receives from the applicant. For 
    instance, no-notice service may not be available from other pipelines 
    (though a similar service might be available from third parties). Under 
    Order No. 636 interstate pipelines [[Page 8364]] which offered no-
    notice sales service prior to restructuring were required to offer no-
    notice transportation service to their existing sales customers at the 
    time of unbundling. Pipelines had the option of making no-notice 
    service available to non-sales customers. Thus, while many interstate 
    pipelines currently provide no-notice transportation service, they do 
    not and are not required to offer such service to new customers. Thus, 
    comparable no-notice service probably is not available on other 
    pipelines.
        Also, applicants may wish to demonstrate that intrastate pipelines 
    offer comparable firm transportation service. Transportation services 
    offered by intrastate pipelines under section 311 of the NGPA are also 
    subject to the same open-access and non-discriminatory access standards 
    as interstate pipelines are under Order No. 436. Therefore, to the 
    extent that intrastate pipelines offer firm transportation service, 
    Staff believes that such service would be offered under terms and 
    conditions that are substantially comparable to the firm transportation 
    services offered by open-access interstate pipelines. However, 
    intrastate pipelines are not required to offer firm transportation 
    services and currently only a few intrastate pipelines offer firm 
    transportation. Thus, firm transportation services may not be available 
    on intrastate pipelines.
        Applicants wishing to make a showing that interruptible 
    transportation services make good alternatives to the applicant's firm 
    services would have to demonstrate that an adequate amount of capacity 
    is unsubscribed during peak periods so that the quality of the IT 
    service would be comparable to that of the applicant's FT service.
    b. The Geographic Market
        In addition, in defining the market, one must identify all the 
    sellers of the product or service. The collection of alternative 
    sellers and the applicant constitutes the relevant geographic market. 
    Specifying the relevant product and geographic market tells us what 
    alternatives the customer has if it attempts to avoid a price increase 
    imposed by a seller.
        Geographic market definition is particularly important in 
    transportation markets. Gas pipelines can transport gas out of a 
    producing or origin region. They also deliver gas into a consuming or 
    destination region.
        The applicant must specify both the origin and destination markets 
    for its FT service. Only in that way can the applicant identify good 
    alternatives to the pipeline's service.
        Staff proposes a two-step process of defining the geographic 
    market. First, the applicant would identify those alternative sellers 
    who offer service between the same origin and destination markets. 
    Second, the applicant would identify those competitors that provide 
    service either out of the origin market or into the destination market. 
    This two-step process generally follows the analytic approach developed 
    in the Report of Commissioner Branko Terzic on Competition in Natural 
    Gas Transportation (May 24, 1993).
    i. Transportation Between Markets
        The first stage of the analysis identifies sellers offering 
    transportation service over the same route. Examining different sellers 
    serving the same transportation link simplifies the analysis. For 
    instance, there is no need to consider whether different producing 
    areas offer ``good'' alternatives to each other.
        To show that another pipeline provides a good direct alternative, 
    the applicant must show that customers could purchase the relevant 
    service from the alternative supplier. Such a demonstration will 
    probably include showing that capacity would be available on the 
    alternative, that the customer can obtain any services needed to use 
    the competitor's facilities in both origin and destination markets over 
    the term of the service receiving market-based rates.
        If a customer has a continuing obligation to take gas at a 
    particular receipt point, or to deliver gas to a specific delivery 
    point, beyond the term of its FT contract, competition from parallel 
    pipelines is particularly important in evaluating market power on a 
    pipeline seeking market-based FT rates. Then the applicant may have 
    market power over the shipper even if both the origin and destination 
    markets are otherwise competitive. While the shipper will have good 
    alternatives to the applicant for getting gas to the city-gate, it may 
    not have good alternatives for getting gas from that particular point 
    to its city-gate. It could, of course, sell its contract gas from that 
    particular point on the spot market in the production area and buy an 
    equal amount of spot gas in an area where it had good transportation 
    alternatives. But the spot price at which it sells might be lower than 
    the spot at which it buys, causing extra expense and providing some 
    opportunity for the applicant pipeline to raise its price. 
    Additionally, the shipper may value the reliability of the contract gas 
    and be concerned that it might not be able to buy spot gas when it 
    needs it.
        In practice, parallel route competition is most likely to occur in 
    two situations. One is the secondary market (including pipeline IT) 
    where parties offer service on the same facility. The other is for 
    transportation between well-functioning market centers, as illustrated 
    in the example in part B.
    ii. Transportation at Origin and Destination Markets
        Parallel route competition is not the only source of market 
    discipline on gas transporters. A shipper in the production area will 
    typically have alternative destination markets to which it could send 
    gas. Similarly, a downstream shipper will typically have a choice of 
    several producing areas from which to buy gas. Pipelines that provide 
    such alternative service may offer an additional check on the market 
    power of a shipper.
        Natural gas transportation typically originates in the production 
    area. In the production area (or the mainline receipt point), the 
    applicant must identify the transportation alternatives available to 
    customers. Customers could include producers with gas supplies attached 
    at a receipt point, LDCs, and endusers with firm long-term supply 
    contracts. To define a particular region as an origin market, the 
    pipeline must identify all pipelines which compete with it to move gas 
    out of that area. To demonstrate that these other pipelines are good 
    alternatives (that is, are in the market), the applicant must show that 
    its producer/shippers are physically connected to these other pipeline 
    transportation alternatives.\51\ The applicant must also show that 
    these transportation alternatives provide a netback\52\ to producer/
    shippers roughly the same as they would receive if they used the 
    applicant's transportation.\53\ An alternative is not a good 
    alternative to a producer seeking to move gas out of the origin market 
    if the alternative is [[Page 8365]] associated with a much higher cost 
    than the applicant's cost-based rates, i.e., it must give roughly the 
    same netback.
    
        \51\Alternatively, the applicant could include a seller in the 
    market if the seller can connect to the customer sufficiently 
    cheaply that the customer receives a netback as least as large as it 
    would receive if it used the applicant's transportation service.
        \52\The netback is the delivered price of gas less the 
    transportation costs paid by the producer. That is, the netback is 
    the net price received by the producer.
        \53\The geographic market is a region in which a hypothetical 
    monopolist that is the only present or future provider of the 
    relevant product at locations in that region would profitably impose 
    at least a ``small but significant and nontransitory'' increase in 
    price. In the case of an origin market, the hypothetical monopsonist 
    will impose a small but significant and nontransitory decrease in 
    netbacks. Thus, a service is a good alternative if the netback using 
    the alternative is at least as big as the netback using the 
    applicant's facilities after the netback decrease.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In contrast, the ultimate destination market for gas is typically a 
    city-gate. There, the applicant must identify the transportation 
    alternatives available to endusers and LDCs who want to receive gas in 
    this area. To define a destination market, the applicant must 
    demonstrate that its customers are physically connected to alternative 
    gas transportation facilities that move gas into the area.\54\ The 
    applicant must also demonstrate that those alternatives will deliver 
    gas at a price no higher than would be paid with the use of the 
    applicant's transportation service to deliver gas into the area.\55\
    
        \54\The applicant could include a seller in the destination 
    market if the seller can connect to the customer sufficiently 
    cheaply that the customer pays a delivered gas price no higher than 
    that paid when using the applicant's FT service.
        \55\The geographic market is a region in which a hypothetical 
    monopolist that is the only present or future provider of the 
    relevant product at locations in that region would profitably impose 
    a least a ``small but significant and nontransitory'' increase in 
    price. In the case of an destination market, a service is a good 
    alternative if the delivered gas price using the alternative is less 
    than or equal to the delivered gas price using the applicant's 
    facilities after the price increase.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Applicants for market-based rates might allege that LPG and LNG can 
    be good alternatives to the use of applicant's transportation service. 
    If so, the applicant must show that there are sufficient quantities of 
    these available, and the transport of LPG and LNG into the destination 
    market (e.g., by truck) provides gas at an overall delivered price no 
    higher than the overall delivered price from pipeline transport with a 
    fifteen percent transportation rate increase on the pipeline's 
    transportation rate.
    c. Summary and Conclusion
        Thus, in order to specify a gas transportation market, the 
    applicant must first identify all products and services available as 
    good alternatives to the applicant's customers. Next, the applicant 
    must identify the origin and destination of that transportation. The 
    relevant geographic market will be defined in two steps: First, those 
    alternative sellers that offer service between the same origin and 
    destination markets and second, all economically substitutable 
    transportation sold by pipelines (or other good alternative products 
    and services) serving either the origin market or the destination 
    market.
    2. Firm Size and Market Concentration
        Pipelines might be able to exercise market power if customers have 
    few good alternatives to the pipeline's service either, in the first 
    instance, over a given route or, in a second analysis, separately in 
    origin and destination markets. The applicant might have market power 
    in the origin market if producer/shippers have few good alternatives to 
    transport their product out of the origin area. In the destination 
    market, pipelines might be able to exercise market power if downstream 
    customers have few good transportation alternatives that reach their 
    city-gates. If customers have long term supply contracts, it will be 
    particularly important for the pipeline to demonstrate that it has no 
    market power over customers on a given route.
        There are two ways in which a seller can exercise market power. It 
    can attempt to raise its price acting alone or it can attempt to raise 
    its price by acting together with other sellers.
    i. Acting Alone
        One of the indicators which has been examined to determine whether 
    a seller could exercise market power acting alone is the seller's 
    market share. A large market share is generally a necessary condition 
    for the exercise of market power. If the seller has a small market 
    share it is unlikely that it can exercise market power. But, a company 
    with a large market share may not be able to exert market power if 
    entry into the market is easy\56\ or there are other competitive forces 
    at work.
    
        \56\Given the nature of the interstate pipeline industry, ease 
    of entry would be difficult to show except in cases involving minor 
    facilities. For major facilities, the cost of construction and the 
    time needed for environmental analysis would suggest that entry may 
    not be easy.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The applicant must submit calculations (and supporting data) of its 
    market share in all relevant origin and destination areas.
    ii. Acting Together with Other Sellers
        A second way in which a seller can exercise market power is to act 
    together with other sellers to raise prices. To evaluate whether a 
    seller can act together with others to exercise market power, the 
    Commission has typically examined the market's concentration.
        To measure market concentration, one generally considers the 
    summary measure of market concentration known as the Herfindahl-
    Hirschman Index (HHI). If the HHI is small, less than .18, then one can 
    generally conclude that sellers cannot exercise market power in this 
    market. A small HHI indicates that customers have sufficiently diverse 
    sources of supply in this market that no one firm or group of firms 
    acting together could profitably raise market price. If the HHI is 
    greater than .18 then additional analysis is needed to determine if the 
    seller can exercise market power.
        The applicant should be required to submit calculations of the HHI 
    for the relevant markets. The HHI must be computed for each origin 
    market as well as each destination market. The Commission should 
    require applicants to submit information for each mainline receipt 
    point (origin market) and each delivery point (destination market). If 
    the applicant wishes to argue for a broader market definition it should 
    also include calculations for its market definitions. Only sales or 
    capacity figures associated with good alternatives should be used in 
    calculating the HHI. In calculating the HHIs, the applicant should be 
    required to aggregate the capacity of affiliated companies into one 
    estimate for those affiliates as a single seller.\57\
    
        \57\The capacity on pipeline systems owned or controlled by the 
    applicant's affiliates should not be considered among the customer's 
    alternatives. Rather, the capacity of its affiliates offering the 
    same product should be included in the market share calculated for 
    the applicant. Similarly, alternative pipelines must be aggregated 
    with their respective affiliates in order to identify meaningful 
    alternatives to customers. It is not reasonable to expect a profit-
    maximizing firm to allow its affiliates to compete with one another.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In the GIC cases, the Commission established a threshold level for 
    the HHI at .18.\58\ In an oil pipeline case, the Commission used .25 as 
    an initial screen.\59\ The Commission may wish to establish a standard 
    under which it will presume no potential for the exercise of joint 
    market power exists. Since the Commission has a positive obligation 
    under the Natural Gas Act to ``protect consumers against exploitation 
    at the hands of natural gas companies,''\60\ staff believes it would be 
    appropriate to use the relatively strict initial screen of .18. This 
    would indicate that there are four to five good alternatives to the 
    applicant's service in each market.
    
        \58\El Paso Natural Gas Company, 49 FERC 61,262 (1989). See 
    also Buckeye, 53 FERC at 62,667.
        \59\See Williams Pipe Line Co., Opinion No. 391, 68 FERC  
    61,136 (1994).
        \60\FPC v. Hope Natural Gas Co., 320 U.S. 591, 610 (1944). See 
    also Elizabethtown, supra n. 6 (sustaining the Commission's approval 
    of market pricing based on the Commission's conclusion that the 
    pipeline's markets were sufficiently competitive to preclude it from 
    exercising significant market power); Farmers Union II, supra n.2 
    (holding that the Commission cannot merely assume that competition 
    will ensure just and reasonable prices).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    3. Entry and Other Competitive Factors
        Even if the applicant's market share were large in a concentrated 
    (and properly identified) market, one might not conclude that the 
    applicant would be able to exercise market power. For 
    [[Page 8366]] example, if the applicant were to increase its price, 
    entry into the market might be so easy that sellers attracted by the 
    profit opportunity created by the higher price would quickly take 
    customers away from the applicant by offering a lower price. This would 
    make the applicant's price increase unprofitable. Thus, the applicant 
    would not be able to exercise market power, despite its large market 
    share and despite the high market concentration.\61\
    
        \61\As stated before, entry would probably only be relevant for 
    gas pipelines in the case of minor facilities such as facilities 
    that could be constructed under a blanket certificate.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Ease of entry is one of several competitive factors that might lead 
    to the conclusion that an applicant lacks market power. It is most 
    likely to apply to circumstances that do not require the large sunk 
    costs of major construction--for instance, perhaps in offering short-
    haul market center services. Another competitive factor that might be 
    alleged by an applicant would be the presence of buyer power. An 
    applicant might argue that if a single buyer is a large customer of the 
    pipeline, is knowledgeable and sophisticated in its buying, and has 
    been in business for a lengthy period of time, the buyer may have the 
    knowledge and large-scale purchasing power to negotiate reasonable 
    rates even in a concentrated market. However, just because buyers 
    develop sophisticated purchasing systems and market knowledge as the 
    result of dealing with various suppliers in numerous markets, there 
    still is reason to have some skepticism that a buyer in a single 
    destination area served by one or a few pipelines will have such 
    capabilities.
        The applicant must demonstrate that sufficient quantities of good 
    alternatives are available to its customers to make a price increase 
    unprofitable. In other words, the applicant must show that customers 
    would replace a significant proportion of its throughput with other 
    transportation alternatives if the applicant raised its price.
    
    B. An Example of the Analysis Applied to Firm Transportation
    
    1. Introduction
        To illustrate the application of the market power analysis 
    discussed above to a request for market-based transportation rates, 
    staff shows an analysis of a hypothetical filing by an interstate 
    pipeline. In that hypothetical filing, the ABC Pipeline Company seeks 
    Commission approval to offer firm transportation (FT) at market-based 
    rates. ABC's primary proposal is for market-based FT rates for its 
    entire system (see map). As an alternative, ABC requests market-based 
    rates for firm transportation between two market centers, the Free 
    Parking Hub, located in the production area, and the Just Visiting Hub, 
    located in its market area. In its alternative proposal ABC Pipeline 
    offers cost-based rates for service upstream of the Free Parking Hub 
    and downstream of the Just Visiting Hub. Finally, as part of its 
    alternate proposal ABC Pipeline is proposing to add facilities so that 
    it will interconnect with all the pipelines at the Free Parking Hub. 
    The interconnections will allow ABC to provide switching service at the 
    hub. ABC proposes market-based rates for the switching service.
    
                                                     BILLING CODE 6717-01-P
    [[Page 8367]]
    
    [GRAPHIC][TIFF OMITTED]TN14FE95.004
    
    
    BILLING CODE 6717-01-C
    [[Page 8368]]
    
        The facts in this hypothetical are patterned after the facts of a 
    large pipeline company and one of its major customers. Facts have been 
    added or changed to better illustrate points in the analysis.
        In order to analyze ABC's proposal, staff identifies the relevant 
    product and geographic markets, measures the size of the market, and 
    calculates market shares and the market's concentration using the 
    Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI). Where market shares and the HHI are 
    high, staff examines other competitive factors that might constrain the 
    exercise of market power.
        A two step analysis is used to examine both of ABC's proposals. 
    First, one examines whether there is sufficient competition along 
    parallel routes for the proposed market-based services. Second, if 
    there is not, one examines if there is sufficient competition in the 
    origin and destination markets to constrain the exercise of market 
    power. The Commission would deny ABC Pipeline's request if it finds 
    that ABC has market power over customers on the relevant routes and in 
    either origin areas or destination areas of the geographic market. To 
    identify relevant geographic markets, one first identifies pairs of 
    origin and destination markets. The pipeline might identify one such 
    pair as the hypothetical Baltic field and City Distribution Company 
    (City).\62\
    
        \62\Of course, the pipeline would need to provide the same 
    information for all other origin and destination markets.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    2. The Applicant's Primary Proposal
    a. The Relevant Facts
        City Distribution is a large natural gas public utility that serves 
    millions of customers. Its service area covers a large metropolitan 
    area. City's service area is located 100 miles downstream of the Just 
    Visiting Hub.
        City has its own storage facilities with a maximum daily storage 
    withdrawal capability of 1.0 Bcf/day and a total working gas capacity 
    of approximately 30 Bcf. Its peak day system demand is approximately 
    3.0 Bcf/day. Thus, at full utilization of its storage, City needs at 
    least 2.0 Bcf/day (3.0 Bcf/day--1.0 Bcf/day) of transportation capacity 
    on its peak day to meet customer demand.
        City has over 30 interconnections with five interstate pipelines: 
    ABC Pipeline Company, the Short Line Pipeline Company, the Boardwalk 
    Pipeline Company, the Ventnor Pipeline Company, and the Pennsylvania 
    Pipeline Company. Table 1 shows City's contract rights to, and use of, 
    transportation capacity on all pipeline connections to its city gate 
    for 1994. Table 1 shows the total capacity of the pipelines in City's 
    metropolitan area. The totals include capacity used to serve another 
    LDC within that metropolitan area.
    
                                     Table 1                                
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                                    MDQ                     
                      Pipeline                     Rights    USE    Capacity
                                                   (Bcf)    (Bcf)     (Bcf) 
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    ABC Pipeline (FT)...........................      1.3      1.5       1.5
    The Short Line Pipeline.....................      0.3      0.2       0.3
    Boardwalk Pipeline (FT).....................      0.2      0.2       0.7
    All Sources of IT...........................  .......      0.3  ........
    The Ventnor Pipeline........................      0.2      0.2       0.7
    The Pennsylvania Pipeline...................      0.1      0.1       0.1
                                                 ---------------------------
      Total.....................................      2.1      2.5       3.3
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        City currently purchases a portion of its peak day from gas 
    produced in the Baltic field. ABC Pipeline is currently the only 
    pipeline that connects to the gathering system in the Baltic field. 
    Table 2 displays the nearest pipelines and the estimated cost to 
    connect these pipelines to the Baltic field gathering system :
    
                                     Table 2                                
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                                                  Connection
                             Pipeline*                              costs   
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    The Atlantic Pipeline......................................   $1,000,000
    The Ventnor Pipeline.......................................    2,400,000
    The Boardwalk Pipeline.....................................   17,000,000
    The St. James Pipeline.....................................   15,000,000
    The Park Place Pipeline....................................  12,000,000 
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    *The Atlantic and Ventnor Pipelines are affiliated, as are the Boardwalk
      and Park Place Pipelines.                                             
    
    b. Product Market
        In its filing to the Commission, ABC might allege that there are 
    numerous good alternatives to its FT service for City. It might start 
    by alleging that two other pipelines directly connect areas that are 
    very close to the Baltic field and City's city gate, and offer good 
    alternatives to customers on both ends of the pipeline. It might 
    further argue that customers on each end can use FT and interruptible 
    transportation (IT) service on other pipelines leading to different 
    market areas (in the case of Baltic field shippers) or other supply 
    areas (in City's case).
        FT on other pipelines may be a good alternative to ABC Pipeline's 
    FT. However, ABC must demonstrate that its customers can actually get 
    firm capacity on these other pipelines and that the quality of such FT 
    is comparable to its own. Also, ABC must demonstrate that other 
    pipelines can provide FT that is price competitive with ABC's.
        IT service on other pipelines might be a good alternative for FT. 
    Indeed, Table 1 shows that City used 0.3 Bcf of IT to meet its 
    transportation needs on its 1994 peak day. ABC might argue that similar 
    levels of IT have been available at peak for many years and can be 
    expected to be available in the future. If so, this suggests that, at a 
    minimum, IT was of a sufficiently high quality (i.e., had a 
    sufficiently low probability of interruption) that it could substitute 
    for FT in the past and could probably do so in the future. However, ABC 
    Pipeline would need to present evidence that IT was provided at a price 
    that rendered the price of delivered gas using IT at or below the price 
    of delivered gas using FT. That might not be the case if City's receipt 
    of IT required payment of IT rates on several upstream pipelines, 
    thereby making IT not price competitive. City might have been forced to 
    purchase IT even if its price were much higher than that of FT. Also, 
    the IT shown in Table 1 was received by City over several pipelines, 
    including ABC Pipeline. Thus, because ABC would be able to affect the 
    delivered price of gas using IT service, it cannot be counted as a good 
    product alternative to ABC Pipeline's own FT.
        Therefore, for both the primary and alternate proposals, staff is 
    defining the product market to include ABC Pipeline's FT and FT on 
    other pipelines. However, interruptible transportation is included in 
    the product market for switching service at the Free Parking Hub.
    c. Geographic Market: Parallel Route
        In its application, ABC might argue that three pipelines provide 
    service from the same production area as the Baltic field to the same 
    metropolitan area as City and thus are parallel routes: ABC Pipeline 
    (with 1.5 Bcf of capacity), the Boardwalk Pipeline (with .7 Bcf of 
    capacity) and the Ventnor Pipeline (with .7 Bcf of capacity). ABC 
    computes an HHI of .39 for these three routes--equivalent to about 
    three equally large firms. ABC might argue that this provides some 
    degree of competition, which combined with other factors, would justify 
    a market-based rate. One of the factors ABC mentions is that City has 
    buyer power because of its size. However, ABC Pipeline does not provide 
    sufficient factual basis to evaluate the level of City's buyer power, 
    so staff is unable to consider this factor.
        A closer examination of the example would show that there are no 
    parallel route pipelines. Neither of the other [[Page 8369]] pipelines 
    directly connect with the producers in the Baltic field. Each would 
    need to build significant facilities to reach the same origin market. 
    Finally, the applicant has not shown that capacity would be available 
    on either of the two other pipelines in the same time frame for which 
    it seeks market-based pricing.
    d. Geographic Market: Destination Area
        The relevant geographic destination market includes all alternative 
    sellers that can provide FT to City's city-gate priced at or below 
    transportation services over ABC's system, assuming a 15 percent FT 
    price increase by ABC. If ABC Pipeline wished to include all the 
    pipelines listed in Table 1, it would have to demonstrate that their 
    transportation services met this criteria. It would also have to 
    demonstrate that the transportation services over those pipelines at 
    least matched the quality of transportation service over ABC Pipeline.
        Consider a simple measure of market size and concentration first. 
    Table 3 displays market shares and market concentration for the FT 
    suppliers to City in 1994. Market shares are calculated based on 
    capacity at City's city-gate. There is additional pipeline capacity 
    within the metropolitan area. ABC Pipeline, however, has not provided 
    evidence to show that the capacity could be easily connected to City's 
    city-gate. Absent such a showing staff has used the lower capacity 
    rights figures in our calculations.
    
                                     Table 3                                
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                               MDQ                          
                     Seller                   rights   Market   Contribution
                                              (Bcf)     share      to HHI   
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    ABC Pipeline (FT)......................      1.3       .62         .38  
    Short Line Pipeline....................      0.3       .14         .02  
    Boardwalk Pipeline.....................      0.2       .10         .01  
    Ventnor Pipeline.......................      0.2       .10         .01  
    Pennsylvania Pipeline..................      0.1       .05       --     
                                            --------------------------------
      Total................................      2.1      1.01         .42  
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In this instance, ABC has a very large market share, 62 percent. 
    Also, the HHI is quite high (.42) indicating that the market is 
    concentrated. The market's HHI is well above the threshold levels of 
    .18-.25 commonly used by antitrust authorities to identify competitive 
    markets. Were ABC to seek Commission approval for market-based 
    transportation rates, it would have to document that there are other 
    factors, such as ease of entry, excess capacity, etc., that would 
    eliminate the ability to exercise market power that is not ruled out by 
    these high market shares and high HHI.
        ABC Pipeline might also allege that released capacity on its own 
    system and on other pipelines would provide good alternatives for City. 
    However, in one very important respect released capacity, especially on 
    ABC Pipeline itself, will have little, if any, impact on the assessment 
    of ABC Pipeline's underlying market power in the primary long-run FT 
    market. An analogy might help. Suppose there were only one manufacturer 
    of automobiles, but robust used-car and leasing markets. Would the 
    manufacturer have monopoly power? Yes. Even with a perfectly 
    competitive secondary market for automobiles, the manufacturer could 
    ``contrive'' a scarcity by making fewer new automobiles and charging a 
    higher price than necessary to cover costs.\63\
    
        \63\See U.S. v. Aluminum Co. of America, 148 F.2d 416, 424 (2d 
    Cir. 1945). The main issue in this case was whether secondary scrap 
    aluminum was in the same market as primary aluminum. Judge Learned 
    Hand held that since Alcoa had produced the metal reappearing as 
    reprocessed scrap, it would have taken into account in its output 
    decisions the effect of scrap reclamation on future prices, and 
    therefore secondary scrap should not be in the same market as 
    primary aluminum.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Similarly, if a pipeline has market power, it would exploit it by 
    ``contriving a scarcity.'' Although a pipeline with a well-functioning 
    capacity release program might not withhold existing capacity, it could 
    choose not to expand. Customers can only release capacity they don't 
    need; they can't build. As demand grows, a pipeline with market power 
    could simply enjoy higher prices and refuse to build even if its 
    customers were willing to pay the incremental cost of expansion. It 
    would build only when the market clearing price for FT went above the 
    monopoly price.
        Thus, this analysis suggests that the secondary market on ABC 
    Pipeline may discipline market power the pipeline may have in selling 
    IT and unsubscribed or ``short-term'' FT, but not in new primary FT. 
    Released capacity on other pipelines might discipline any market power 
    ABC Pipeline may have in the long-term FT market, but the secondary 
    market on ABC Pipeline can do little to discipline its market power in 
    supplying primary FT.
    
    e. Other Competitive Factors
    
        ABC Pipeline might argue that entry is sufficiently easy that ABC 
    would be constrained from exercising market power by new firms quickly 
    entering the market at relatively low cost. It seems unlikely that 
    building major new transportation facilities to serve City would be 
    inexpensive or timely. Rather, in a densely-populated urban area, 
    building a new pipeline would likely be a contentious political and 
    environmental issue. ABC Pipeline might, however, argue that the 
    Boardwalk Pipeline or other pipelines could expand their existing 
    interconnections with City. To support this argument it would need to 
    show that the connections could be made without great expense or delay.
        It may be that the four other pipelines have significant amounts of 
    excess capacity at or close to City's city-gate. In the event that ABC 
    Pipeline were to attempt to exercise market power, arguably such excess 
    capacity could be used by City to defeat such an attempt. However, 
    evidence currently at hand suggests that only the Short Line Pipeline 
    has excess capacity.
        Finally, staff did not address ABC Pipeline's argument regarding 
    buyer power since the destination market was so highly concentrated and 
    the analysis was not fully developed.
    f. The Destination Area: Caveats and Conclusion
        The market share and HHI calculations in this example are based on 
    simplifying assumptions which minimize market shares and market 
    concentration. First, by assuming that any of City's customers could be 
    supplied by any of the five pipelines connecting to City, staff has 
    intentionally expanded the market and thereby lowered market shares and 
    HHI.
        Second, staff did not include no-notice service. For this higher 
    quality service City may have very few alternatives indeed, since no-
    notice service would only be available to pre-restructuring customers 
    on the alternative pipelines.
        Rather than ABC Pipeline, the Ventnor Pipeline or the Short Line 
    Pipeline might file for market-based transportation rates to serve City 
    on the basis that the market shares shown in Table 1 document their 
    lack of market power, despite the destination market's high HHI. If, 
    however, City fully utilized all of its FT at peak, then the Ventnor 
    Pipeline or the Short Line Pipeline would be able to exercise market 
    power despite their small shares of the market. Therefore, the Ventnor 
    Pipeline or the Short Line Pipeline would have to demonstrate that City 
    had alternatives at peak, as well as demonstrating that they lacked 
    market power in the origin markets.
    [[Page 8370]]
    
    g. Geographic Market: The Origin Area
        ABC's pipeline is connected with the gathering system in the Baltic 
    field in Louisiana. ABC Pipeline is the only inter or intrastate 
    pipeline that is connected to this gathering system.
        As for good alternative suppliers in the origin area, ABC Pipeline 
    would have to demonstrate that the quality of FT on other pipelines is 
    comparable to its own. Also, ABC would have to demonstrate that other 
    pipelines can provide FT that is priced competitively with ABC's.
        To show that other pipelines could become good FT alternatives, ABC 
    Pipeline would have to show that other pipelines could easily connect 
    with the gathering system in the Baltic field. Or, ABC Pipeline might 
    argue that the producers could build gathering lines to connect to 
    these other pipelines at a nominal cost. In either case, ABC would have 
    to show that building these facilities would not reduce the netback to 
    these producers.
        In this example, all of the pipelines would have significant 
    connection costs. At most, it appears that only on Atlantic would the 
    cost of connecting the Baltic field result in a price increase of less 
    than 15%. Thus, in the Baltic origin area, producers seem to have at 
    most one good pipeline alternative to ABC Pipeline. The conclusion, 
    therefore, is that staff cannot rule out the possibility, indeed 
    likelihood, that ABC Pipeline has market power over shippers 
    transporting gas out of the Baltic field origin area.
    h. Primary Proposal: Conclusion
        Our conclusion from analysis of this hypothetical is simple and 
    straightforward. It is conceptually possible to demonstrate that 
    pipelines lack significant market power over shippers buying 
    transportation from supply fields to their city-gate customers. 
    However, the City example suggests that such a showing would be 
    difficult.
    3. The Applicant's Alternate Proposal
    a. The Relevant Facts
        ABC Pipeline has also included a more limited market based proposal 
    in its filing. ABC argues, at a minimum, it should be able to charge 
    market-based rates for service between two market centers on its 
    system, the Free Parking Hub and the Just Visiting Hub, and for its 
    proposed new switching service at the Free Parking Hub. Table 5 shows 
    the six pipelines at the Free Parking Hub and their capacity:
    
                                     Table 5                                
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                                     MDQ                    
                                                    rights   Market    HHI  
                                                    (Bcf)    share          
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    ABC Pipeline.................................      2.0      .21      .04
    Oriental.....................................     *1.8      .29      .08
    Vermont......................................     *1.0  .......  .......
    Reading......................................      2.3      .24      .06
    Pacific......................................       .8      .08      .01
    Mediterranean................................      1.7      .18      .03
                                                  --------------------------
      Total......................................      9.6     1.00     .22 
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    *Since Vermont and Oriental are affiliated their capacity has been      
      combined in computing market shares and HHIs.                         
    
        Table 6 shows the five pipelines at the Just Visiting Hub:
    
                                     Table 6                                
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                                     MDQ                    
                                                    rights   Market    HHI  
                                                    (Bcf)    share          
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    ABC Pipeline.................................      2.0      .20      .04
    Short Line Pipeline..........................       .5      .05  .......
    The Pennsylvania.............................     *2.7      .54      .29
    Reading......................................     *2.5  .......  .......
    Oriental.....................................      2.1      .21      .04
                                                  --------------------------
      Total......................................      9.8     1.00     .37 
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    *Since the Pennsylvania and Reading are affiliated their capacity has   
      been combined in computing market shares and HHIs.                    
    
        Three pipelines provide firm transportation service between the two 
    hubs. Their capacity on the route is shown in Table 7. In computing 
    market shares and HHIs staff has used the lower of the pipeline's 
    capacity at the Just Visiting and Free Parking Hubs as our estimate of 
    the maximum amount of capacity that shippers can reserve between the 
    two hubs.
    
                                     Table 7                                
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                                     MDQ                    
                                                    rights   Market    HHI  
                                                    (Bcf)    share          
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    ABC Pipeline.................................      2.0      .33      .11
    Reading......................................      2.3      .38      .14
    Oriental.....................................      1.8      .30      .09
                                                  --------------------------
      Total......................................      6.1    *1.01     .34 
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    *Total does not equal 1 due to rounding.                                
    
        ABC Pipeline generally defines the product market as firm 
    transportation. However, ABC argues that interruptible switching 
    service at the Just Visiting Hub and the Free Parking Hub is the 
    functional equivalent of firm service.
    b. Geographic Market: Parallel Route
        In the example, three pipelines provide firm transportation service 
    between the Free Parking Hub (origin market) and the Just Visiting Hub 
    (destination market): ABC Pipeline (with a .33 market share), Reading 
    Pipeline (with a .38 market share), and Oriental (with a .30 market 
    share). This results in an HHI of .34 for this route--equivalent to 
    three equal sized firms. ABC Pipeline might argue that the three 
    parallel route pipelines provide some degree of competition. ABC might 
    argue that when this is combined with additional competition at the 
    origin and destination markets there is sufficient competition to 
    justify market-based rates.
        In its alternate proposal ABC has not proposed market-based rates 
    for transportation upstream of the Free Parking Hub or downstream of 
    the Just Visiting Hub. Instead, it proposes a regulated rate for such 
    services that would recover only the (relatively small) costs of the 
    facilities between the Baltic field and the Free Parking Hub or between 
    the Just Visiting Hub and City's city-gate. This would ensure ABC could 
    not use market-based rates to exercise market power over shippers at 
    the extremities of its system. However, such a proposal would raise 
    serious cost allocation issues between ABC's market-based and cost-
    based services.
        In the alternate proposal there is the possibility of parallel 
    route competition because there are three pipelines that serve both the 
    origin and destination markets. However, this is only the beginning of 
    the analysis. ABC Pipeline must also show that: its customers can 
    switch gas between ABC and the alternative pipelines at a low cost; its 
    customers can actually get firm capacity on the Reading and the 
    Oriental Pipelines; and the quality and price of firm service on these 
    alternative pipelines is comparable to that provided on ABC Pipeline.
        ABC argues that the Free Parking Hub is a header that offers firm 
    switching service at minimal cost and that the Just Visiting Hub offers 
    interruptible switching service among all the pipelines. The first may 
    offer the customers good alternatives. The second probably does not. 
    Potential market power problems here might be mitigated if firm 
    switching service was offered at the Just Visiting Hub.
        ABC argues that capacity release programs can make capacity 
    available on the alternative pipelines. However, it has not shown that 
    customers can obtain the same long-term FT service through the release 
    program. Potential market power problems might be mitigated if ABC 
    could show that its customers could buy the same long-term service 
    through the release market (perhaps if the customers had many 
    [[Page 8371]] years remaining on their contracts) or at some future 
    time when the capacity on all the pipelines would be available 
    simultaneously. It would also need to show that such alternatives would 
    be competitively priced. It could do this either by analyzing regulated 
    prices or by showing that all other pipelines would be able to match 
    any likely market-based price on ABC. This would be a difficult showing 
    for any pipeline if it was the only pipeline in the market seeking 
    market-based rates.
        In the alternate proposal there is possible parallel route 
    competition between the origin and destination markets. However, even 
    if all additional market power problems were mitigated, the HHI of the 
    route is still well above the .18 screen staff is using. So, staff 
    moves to the second step in the analysis to examine the origin and 
    destination markets separately.
    c. Geographic Markets: Destination Markets
        ABC Pipeline might argue four other pipelines serve the Just 
    Visiting Hub and each of these pipelines would serve as a good 
    alternative to its service. ABC might also argue two other pipelines, 
    the Ventnor and the Boardwalk have facilities near the Just Visiting 
    Hub.As with the parallel route analysis, these pipelines cannot be 
    considered good alternatives unless ABC Pipeline can demonstrate its 
    customers can get firm transportation capacity at a price and quality 
    comparable to its own service.
        The data indicate that the Just Visiting Hub is highly 
    concentrated. In computing the HHI for the destination market the two 
    affiliates, the Reading and the Pennsylvania, are treated as one firm. 
    Because these two pipelines control half the capacity at the hub, the 
    HHI of .37 is actually higher than that for the parallel route.\64\
    
        \64\This example demonstrates the effect that pipeline 
    affiliation can have on market concentration. If Reading and 
    Pennsylvania were not affiliated, the HHI for the Just Visiting Hub 
    would be .22, significantly lower than the .37 HHI calculated with 
    affiliate market share combined. An HHI of .22 is much closer to a 
    level which might be deemed indicative of an unconcentrated market.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        If ABC Pipeline could show that the Ventnor and the Boardwalk 
    Pipelines could easily connect to the Just Visiting Hub this would 
    significantly reduce the HHI and make it easier to support market-based 
    rates for ABC Pipeline. Alternatively, ABC Pipeline might argue that 
    market power at the Just Visiting Hub is minimal if it could show that 
    there are other market centers close to the Just Visiting Hub that 
    could be accessed by pipelines serving the Free Parking Hub. If ABC 
    Pipeline could not show additional competitive factors that reduce 
    market power, the data would not support market-based rates.
    d. Hub Services
        To justify market-based rates for service between two markets, ABC 
    must show that both the origin and destination markets are competitive. 
    ABC has not shown that the destination market, the Just Visiting Hub, 
    is competitive. Therefore, it has not supported its proposal for 
    market-based rates between the two hubs. However, ABC has also 
    requested market-based rates for hub services at the Free Parking Hub.
        To support its proposal for market-based rates for hub services, 
    ABC Pipeline might argue that currently the Mediterranean Pipeline 
    interconnects with the five other pipelines at the Free Parking Hub. 
    When ABC builds its additional interconnections there will be two 
    pipelines that connect with all the pipelines at the Free Parking Hub. 
    In addition, these pipelines have several other alternative points of 
    interconnection within a 100 mile radius of the hub and within the same 
    rate zone. ABC argues that its customers can get the equivalent of 
    ABC's switching service at these points of interconnection. ABC has 
    provided a chart which shows that in addition to its proposed new 
    facilities a shipper on any one of the five other pipelines has at 
    least three alternative interconnections for each pipeline within the 
    same rate zone. Some of these are direct interconnections and some 
    require switching service at other nearby production area hubs. 
    Further, interruptible capacity is consistently available within the 
    production area and is of a very high quality, i.e., curtailments are 
    rare. Thus, each shipper has at least three good alternatives to ABC's 
    proposed switching service at the Free Parking Hub. This means that the 
    highest HHI for ABC's switching service with any pipeline is .25.
        The HHI of .25 for switching service is above staff's initial 
    screen. However, there are other competitive factors that would reduce 
    ABC's ability to exercise market power. One of these factors is the 
    open access requirement that all open access pipelines must receive or 
    deliver gas to other pipelines if capacity is available. By scheduling 
    receipts and deliveries at the alternative points of interconnection a 
    shipper can get the equivalent of switching service. And, when this is 
    part of the basic point-to-point transportation service, there is no 
    additional charge. Another competitive factor is ease of entry. In this 
    area some of the pipelines could build additional interconnections at 
    minimal cost. It would be economic to build these interconnections if 
    ABC attempted to exercise market power by charging excessive rates.
        ABC has shown that its customers would have good alternatives to 
    its switching service. Therefore, market-based rates are appropriate 
    for its switching service at the Free Parking Hub.
    e. Conclusion
        Given the high level of concentration in the route and in the 
    destination market, it is unlikely that ABC Pipeline could justify 
    market-based rates for service between the two hubs. However, using the 
    same criteria, market-based rates can be supported for hub services at 
    the Free Parking Hub.
        In the example, staff has assumed that a pipeline might have both 
    cost and market-based FT rates on its system. Any such proposal would 
    require a method for allocating costs between cost-based and market-
    based services.\65\
    
        \65\For example, it would be necessary to identify the cost of 
    the facilities used for the market-based services as well as any 
    related operation and maintenance costs. Also, there would need to 
    be an allocation of common and joint costs, such as administrative 
    costs, between the cost and market-based services.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    4. Results of Analysis of Hypothetical
        Staff must conclude that ABC would find it difficult to justify 
    market-based rates for point-to-point FT on its system. Based on 
    current data ABC may be able to justify market-based rates for some hub 
    services. In the future, ABC may be able justify market-based rates for 
    more services. As the transportation market evolves, pipelines may find 
    it economic to build connections to more hubs. This will increase the 
    number of alternatives at each hub and thus will make it easier to 
    satisfy the criteria for market-based rates for hub services or for 
    transportation between hubs.
    
    C. Application of Criteria to Other Services
    
        Under the standards proposed above, as the example involving ABC 
    Pipeline shows, it is unlikely that FT rates for any city-gate customer 
    would be market-based. The same is true for any rates paid by producers 
    directly attached at the other end of the pipe. What role, then, beyond 
    the gas commodity and storage services, would market-based prices play?
        The answer is that market prices may play an important role in 
    capacity-release, IT, and market-center services.
        As illustrated in the ABC Pipeline example, the many new sources of 
    FT [[Page 8372]] potentially available through the capacity release 
    market will have little or no effect on a pipeline's long-run market 
    power. They may, however, have a strong effect on either the primary 
    capacity holder's (i.e. LDC's) or the pipeline's ability to exercise 
    market power in the capacity release market, the short-term firm 
    market, or the IT market. For these services, there are very few 
    existing long term contracts. Moreover, a major interstate pipeline may 
    have 10 to 20 different holders of FT capacity within a zone. Flexible 
    (secondary) firm receipt and delivery point rights, in concept, give 
    any of these primary holders or their replacements the ability to move 
    gas to any upstream city-gate on the system. Thus, the secondary market 
    in FT may well be unconcentrated. If released FT can be shown to be a 
    good substitute for IT or short-term FT from the pipeline, then the 
    released FT, IT and short-term FT market will be unconcentrated.
        Any such arguments would depend on the effectiveness of the 
    capacity release program in making released capacity at least the equal 
    of IT. While it is doubtful that any such showing could be made now, 
    with further improvements in the capacity release program this could 
    occur.
        In addition, part of the showing must contain evidence that LDCs 
    could not frustrate ``secondary firm'' firm deliveries made at their 
    city-gates by controlling the flows behind their own city-gate delivery 
    points. Flexible receipt and delivery points are the key to a 
    competitive finding; if an LDC is, aside from the pipeline, the only 
    source of FT to its city-gate then it has market power. If secondary 
    firm is an effective alternative, however, then there is a good 
    likelihood that these markets would pass the stringent tests laid out 
    above.
        Some market-center services, such as short-term switching and 
    parking, may also pass the test. Market-centers, by their nature, are 
    where many pipelines intersect and, often, where there are multiple 
    suppliers of storage service. In such cases, it is likely that the 
    providers could show that customers will have many good alternatives at 
    the market-center itself or in nearby market-centers.
        In conclusion, application of the standards laid out in part IV.A 
    is likely to mean continued cost-based regulation of primary FT, but 
    may permit market pricing for released FT, IT and short-term FT and for 
    market-center services such as switching and parking.
        All-in-all, the potential for further reliance on market pricing is 
    rather modest. On the other hand, market pricing in the capacity 
    release and market-center services markets could be a key to their 
    success. Hubs could play an important role in further perfecting the 
    spot market for gas, but to do so is likely to require creative 
    approaches to new services and new ways of adding value to the gas 
    commodity. Creative, economical, new services are far more likely to 
    develop under market pricing than under a cost-of-service approach.
    D. Review of Market Power Findings
        As discussed in part I, an important factor to the court of appeals 
    in Elizabethtown, in which the Commission permitted gas sales at market 
    prices, was the Commission's assurance that it would exercise its 
    section 5 authority if necessary to assure that the market price was 
    just and reasonable. This means that the Commission must consider how 
    it will monitor market-based rates so that it can exercise its 
    oversight responsibilities.
        In past cases the Commission established, on a case-by-case basis 
    some reporting requirements for companies authorized to charge market 
    based rates.\66\ The Commission may want to consider developing 
    standard periodic reporting requirements on prices and quantities in 
    market-based transactions. Periodic reports would make it possible for 
    the Commission to monitor market-based rates to ensure that the rates 
    are within a zone of reasonableness. The Commission may also want to 
    establish a more formal procedure for reporting changes in 
    circumstances that could affect the market power finding, i.e., 
    circumstances that reduce the number of good alternatives in a 
    market.\67\ If circumstances change the Commission could either 
    reconsider its prior market power findings or wait until a complaint is 
    filed to take action.
    
        \66\For example, Transwestern was required to file monthly 
    reports of market based sales under Rate Schedule ISS. 43 FERC 
    61,240 (1988). Buckeye was required to file annual reports showing 
    rates, volumes, and revenues for each destination market. See 66 
    FERC 61,348, for a review of these reports. For electric utilities, 
    the Commission has required power marketers selling at market based 
    rates to file quarterly reports showing prices and quantities for 
    individual transactions [e.g., Heartland, 68 FERC 61,223 (1994)]. 
    Among other things, the reports are intended ``to provide for 
    ongoing monitoring of the marketer's ability to exercise market 
    power.''
        \67\For example, assume in the original market power analysis 
    the Commission found there were four good alternatives in an origin 
    market. A subsequent corporate merger of two of the pipelines and 
    the abandonment of facilities by another would reduce the number of 
    good alternatives to two. There have been no new entrants into the 
    origin market. These changes probably would significantly affect the 
    continuing validity of the original market power finding.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Appendix: Analysis of Other Industries
    
        As discussed in the paper, the FERC has consistently used the 
    same general framework to evaluate when the market, rather than 
    cost-of-service rate regulation, could be relied upon to produce 
    just and reasonable rates. This framework has been evolving for over 
    one hundred years in antitrust litigation and analysis and has now 
    been codified in the DOJ/FTC merger guidelines. FERC is neither the 
    first agency to choose light-handed regulation where a lack of 
    significant market power can be shown, nor the only one to use 
    antitrust standards as a framework for the showing. The general 
    framework, however, is far from a set of mechanical rules; the 
    application of the framework to a particular industry calls for many 
    specific decisions and to an individual case requires many judgement 
    calls.\1\
    
        \1\Judge (now Justice) Stephen Breyer gives an example of how a 
    merger ``pessimist'' might assess a proposed airline merger quite 
    differently from a merger ``optimist,'' though both use the same 
    antitrust framework and agree on all the facts. See discussion of 
    the interplay between antitrust and deregulation of the airline and 
    telephone industries in his contribution to the ``Symposium: 
    Anticpating Antitrust's Centennial: Antitrust, Deregulation and the 
    Newly Liberated Market Place,'' 75 California Law Review 1005-1047 
    (May 1987).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Interstate Commerce Commission (ICC), the first national 
    regulatory agency and pioneer in cost-of-service ratemaking, was 
    also among the first to move toward deregulation or light-handed 
    regulation for railroads and trucks. About twenty years ago the ICC 
    began to lessen or eliminate regulation of railroads and trucks, the 
    FCC allowed new entrants to compete for long distance telephone 
    service and the CAB relaxed its price and entry controls over the 
    airlines. The experience of these three agencies may provide some 
    useful guidance for the Commission in deciding whether certain 
    natural gas pipeline transportation services should be permitted 
    market-based pricing and, if so, how those services should be 
    identified.
        Railroads, airlines, long distance telephones and natural gas 
    pipelines all have much in common besides being regulated. They are 
    all transportation/transmission networks characterized by a high 
    ratio of fixed to variable costs, making ``load factor'' the key to 
    unit operating costs, and, with the possible exception of airlines, 
    all have significant economies of scale (an element of ``natural 
    monopoly''). However, there are also significant differences among 
    all of these industries so analogies and policy conclusions based on 
    their similar characteristics should be made cautiously.
    
    A. Interstate Commerce Commission Regulation of Railroads
    
        Railroads and natural gas pipelines have some important 
    characteristics in common. Both transport using assets that are 
    immobile once they are constructed, though railroads invest in 
    ``rolling stock'' as well track and roadbed. Further, both exhibit 
    the same ``natural monopoly characteristic'' that the construction 
    costs necessary for one company to transport a given amount between 
    two points are usually significantly [[Page 8373]] lower than the 
    construction costs necessary for two companies to jointly transport 
    the same amount between those points. Finally, both industries make 
    extensive use of eminent domain granted from Federal and state 
    governments to acquire land to build networks.
        One significant difference between the two, however, is that 
    pipelines carry a fungible product while railroads generally do not. 
    That is, a pipeline customer who tenders gas in Louisiana and 
    withdraws gas in Chicago, does not care if the gas withdrawn came 
    from Appalachia while the tendered Louisiana gas went somewhere 
    else. In contrast, a railroad customer in Chicago expecting a 
    shipment of Louisiana shrimp will be very unhappy if Appalachian 
    coal is delivered instead. Another important difference is that 
    railroads face major intermodal transportation competition (air 
    competition and trucks everywhere and barges in some areas), while 
    there is no viable intermodal competition to pipelines in 
    transporting natural gas.
        Important characteristics are similar enough between railroads 
    and pipelines that the Interstate Commerce Commission's (ICC's) 
    handling of market-based pricing may inform FERC's handling of the 
    issue. Of particular note are: (1) The ICC's initial rejection 
    followed by the acceptance of the traditional economic paradigm used 
    to evaluate competitiveness, (2) the guidelines now used by the ICC 
    in evaluating competitiveness, and (3) evaluations of the effects of 
    increased reliance on market forces.
    
    1. Recent Changes in Railroad Regulation\2\
    
        \2\The information provided here on the Interstate Commerce 
    Commission is drawn from the Interstate Commerce Commission 
    Decision, ``Product and Geographic Competition'' Ex Parte No. 320 
    (Sub-No. 3), October 24, 1985.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Before 1976, all rail rates were subject to regulation by the 
    Interstate Commerce Commission (ICC) under the statutory ``just and 
    reasonable'' standard.\3\ The Railroad Revitalization and Regulatory 
    Reform Act of 1976 was enacted to restore financial stability to the 
    industry.\4\ This restoration was to be accomplished partially 
    through reducing regulatory restraints on railroad pricing decisions 
    by limiting ICC jurisdiction over maximum rates to situations where 
    railroads have ``market dominance.''\5\
    
        \3\Former Section 1(5) of the Interstate Commerce Act.
        \4\Pub. L. No. 94-210, 90 Stat 31, February 5, 1976.
        \5\Market dominance was defined in the statues as ``an absence 
    of effective competition from other carriers or modes of 
    transportation for the traffic or movement to which a rate 
    applies.''
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Market dominance determinations thus became of the utmost 
    importance when rates were challenged. The ICC initially adopted 
    three ``presumptions'' of market dominance: the railroad handled 70% 
    of traffic (the ``market share'' presumption), revenues exceeded 
    160% of the variable costs (the ``cost'' presumption), and the 
    shipper had a substantial investment in rail-related plant or 
    equipment (the ``rail investment'' presumption). Any one of these 
    presumptions being established and unrebutted would establish market 
    dominance and ICC jurisdiction.
        The ICC determined that the relevant market in the ``market 
    share'' presumption would be confined to direct carrier competition 
    for the specific product movement. The ICC explicitly rejected the 
    traditional antitrust framework used to evaluate competition; the 
    ICC determined that product competition (competition by other 
    products), or geographic competition (availability of the same 
    product from alternative sources or destinations) was not relevant.
        Several years of experience combined with the need to implement 
    the Staggers Rail Act of 1980,\6\ caused the ICC to abandon the 
    initial presumptions and adopt new guidelines which incorporate the 
    traditional economic paradigm for evaluating competition. The ICC 
    ``. . . concluded that the presumptions did not necessarily reflect 
    the degree of railroad market power, and therefore, yielded 
    inaccurate market dominance determinations.* * * The quantitative 
    measures (i.e., the market share, cost, and rail investment 
    presumptions) were found to be poor indicators of market dominance 
    in the widely varying fact situations to which they were designed to 
    apply.''\7\
    
        \6\Pub. L. No. 96-448, 94 Stat. 1895 (1980). One part of the Act 
    directed the ICC to make a finding of no dominance if the carrier 
    shows that a challenged rate would yield a revenue-to-variable cost 
    percentage less than a given percentage. More generally, the Act 
    made it federal policy to rely on competition, rather than 
    regulation, to establish reasonable rail rates. Additionally the Act 
    allowed railroads to enter into confidential agreements with 
    shippers, cancel existing joint rates with other railroads that were 
    not sufficiently profitable, and set time limits on the abandonment 
    process.
        \7\``Product and Geographic Competition,'' supra. The adopted 
    guidelines were listed in Appendix C.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    2. Current ICC Guidelines for Evaluating Market Dominance
    
        Some of the ICC market dominance guidelines have no apparent 
    relevance to FERC because they deal with intermodal transportation 
    competition. However, other aspects of the ICC guidelines deal with 
    issues nearly identical to those important to FERC in analyzing 
    competition. These potentially informative portions of the 
    guidelines are briefly summarized here.\8\
    
        \8\It is interesting to also note, that while developing these 
    guidelines, the ICC refused to adopt specific HHI levels for reasons 
    that are similar to those stated by FERC when refusing to adopt 
    specific HHI levels in Gas Inventory Charge and Oil Pipeline cases.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The ICC ``market dominance'' guidelines lay out what type of 
    evidence is considered important.
        Regarding competition from other railroads, the number of 
    alternatives and the feasibility of alternatives are important. 
    Feasibility is evidenced by (1) the physical characteristics of the 
    alternative, (2) the direct access of both the shipper and receiver, 
    (3) the cost of using the alternative, and (4) the evidence of 
    relevant investment or long-term contracts.
        Regarding geographic competition, considered important are: (1) 
    The number of alternative destinations for shippers or alternative 
    sources for receivers, (2) the number of alternative destinations or 
    sources served by alternative carriers, (3) the suitability of the 
    product available at each relevant source or required at each 
    relevant destination, (4) the operational and economic feasibility 
    of transportation from alternative sources or to alternative 
    destinations, (5) the accessibility of alternative transportation, 
    (6) the capacity of alternative sources to supply the product or 
    alternative destinations to absorb the product, and (7) the evidence 
    of relevant investment or long-term contracts.
        Regarding product competition, considered important are: (1) the 
    substitutability and availability of the substitute products, and 
    (2) all costs of using the substitute product relative to using the 
    product in question.
    
    3. The Effect of Reducing Railroad Regulation
    
        The 1976 Railroad Revitalization and Regulatory Reform Act and 
    the 1980 Staggers Act were intended to improve the financial health 
    of the railroad industry. By most measures, the railroads' financial 
    condition has improved since 1980. Return on investment averaged 
    about 4.9% from 1980 to 1988; this is up from the 2.5% average in 
    the 1970s. Debt has declined from about 36% of total capital in 1980 
    to about 24% in 1988.\9\
    
        \9\General Accounting Office, ``Railroad Regulation: Economic 
    and Financial Impacts of the Staggers Rail Act of 1980,'' May 1990.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        While the regulatory reforms were successful in improving the 
    financial condition of railroads, these reforms have not achieved 
    total financial health for the industry. ``[T]he railroad industry 
    as a whole has not achieved revenue adequacy--that is, its return on 
    investment has not equaled or exceeded the current cost of 
    capital.''\10\
    
        \10\Id. at p. 5.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Regarding the effects on rates rather than on the railroad's 
    financial condition, a recent journal article concludes ``* * * the 
    effect of deregulation on prices has generally been to lower them. 
    With price decreases and cost savings from deregulation, welfare 
    gains from deregulation are likely to be positive.''\11\
    
        \11\Wesley W. Wilson, ``Market-Specific Effects of Rail 
    Deregulation,'' Journal of Industrial Economics, 62 (March, 1994), 
    pp. 1-22. See this article's ``References'' for other articles 
    evaluating the effect of deregulation on prices.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    B. Market-Based Rates in Long Distance Telecommunications
    
        To the extent there are similarities between long distance 
    telecommunications and natural gas pipeline services, lessons can be 
    learned from the FCC's experience with market based pricing. The FCC 
    used a market power framework in its Competitive Carrier 
    Proceedings, when determining the appropriate regulation for long 
    distance service.
    
    1. Comparison of the Industries
    
        The long distance telecommunications market has some 
    similarities to the natural gas pipeline market. First, with the 
    original copper and, most recently, fiber optic cable methods of 
    providing service, it has natural monopoly characteristics. Second, 
    it has long been considered a public utility and until recently, was 
    subject to standard cost-of-service regulation. Third, it provides 
    long- [[Page 8374]] line service, and (since divestiture in 1984) 
    inter-connects with independent local networks to deliver the 
    service.
        There are several differences as well. First, there is no 
    production area nor market area for calls, although call 
    concentration is higher in metropolitan areas. Second, the customer 
    cannot determine the route that his calls take on a carrier, and may 
    not switch carriers within the path. Third, calls are not fungible 
    or interchangeable, as are gas molecules. For example, a customer 
    wants to talk to his or her family, friends, or business associates, 
    not someone else's.
    
    2. History of Long Distance Service
    
        The history of telecommunications regulation has been one of 
    playing catch-up to technological change. Local and long- distance 
    services were assumed to be natural monopolies, to be provided by 
    AT&T. The fixed plant was expensive, and subject to a declining 
    average cost of service, and all customers needed to be 
    interconnected.
        The natural monopoly disappeared with microwave technology 
    because after a critical mass, more traffic requires a roughly 
    proportionate increase in towers and more transmitters.\12\ In 1977, 
    the FCC allowed MCI into the market. It also allowed general OCC 
    (Other Common Carrier) entry in 1977. In 1979, the FCC began the 
    Competitive Carrier proceedings which ultimately effectively allowed 
    market-based pricing for carriers other than AT&T. The two largest 
    OCCs, MCI and Sprint, currently control 25% of the long-distance 
    market.\13\ Local services remained a natural monopoly.\14\
    
        \12\Huber, Peter W., The Geodesic Network II: 1993 Report on 
    Competition in the Telephone Industry, p. 3.4.
        \13\Wall Street Journal, July 22, 1994, p. A2.
        \14\Meanwhile, technology has begun to remove the local natural 
    monopoly for telephone service. There are a large number of 
    potential and credible providers of local service including cable 
    television providers and radio-based and cellular carriers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    3. Light-Handed Regulation of Non-Dominant Firms
    
        In the Competitive Carrier proceedings,\15\ the FCC minimized 
    the regulation of OCCs. It based its actions on two principles: 
    First, in order to retain business with prices above total costs a 
    firm must possess market power and some firms did not. Second, 
    regulation imposes costs. There are the administrative costs of 
    compiling, maintaining, and distributing information necessary to 
    comply with reporting and licensing requirements. More significant 
    costs on society come from the loss of dynamism which can result. 
    The FCC cited to the Averch-Johnson effect in which rate of return 
    regulation can distort the input choices of a regulated firm away 
    from production at minimum cost. It also discussed effective 
    competition being limited by firms being required to give advance 
    notice of innovative marketing plans and having those initiatives 
    subject to public comment and review. The FCC said that the posting 
    of prices and legal obligation to refrain from ``unjust and 
    unreasonable discrimination'' may well result in artificially 
    stabilizing prices to the consumer's eventual disadvantage.
    
        \15\First Report and Order, 85 F.C.C. 2d 5 (1980).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Competitive Carrier characterized carriers as dominant 
    (eventually only AT&T) or non-dominant. Initially, it defined 
    dominant firms as firms with market power.\16\ The FCC said that it 
    focused on certain market features to determine if a firm can 
    exercise market power: The number and size distribution of competing 
    carriers, the nature of barriers to entry and the availability of 
    reasonably substitutable services.\17\
    
        \16\Notice of Inquiry and Proposed Rulemaking, 77 F.C.C. 2d at 
    350 (1979); and First Report and Order, at p. 21.
        \17\First Report and Order at p. 21.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As the FCC refined its determination of which carriers could be 
    subject to lighter-handed regulation, it concluded that once a 
    determination of market power was made, it would look at the degree 
    of power before determining whether regulations conferred greater 
    benefits on customers than costs.\18\
    
        \18\Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 84 F.C.C. 2d at 499-
    500 (1981); and Second Report and Order. 91 F.C.C. 2d (1982).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The agency reasoned that non-dominant carriers lacked 
    (substantial) market power, and that the costs outweighed the 
    benefits of regulating such firms. It held that non-dominant firms:
         Can't charge excessive rates;
         Can't discriminate without losing their customers; and
         Can't pass on the costs of inefficient investments to 
    customers.
        Applying its definitions, the FCC determined that AT&T was a 
    dominant carrier because of its historical market power, immense 
    financial and technological base, control over monopoly 
    interconnection facilities, and substantial cross-subsidization 
    potential. In addition, it is an effective price leader.\19\ Over 
    time, the FCC found that all other carriers were non-dominant.
    
        \19\Notice of Inquiry and Proposed Rulemaking, 77 F.C.C. 2d at 
    352-353; and First Report and Order, supra.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The FCC decreased the regulations for non-dominant carriers in 
    two phases: streamlining and forbearance. Under both, non-dominant 
    carriers were required to charge just and reasonable and non-
    discriminatory rates. With streamlining, the FCC presumed that 
    tariff filings were legal, and required no cost justification of the 
    tariffs.\20\ Forbearance went further than streamlining, by not 
    requiring tariff filings from non-dominant firms. The Supreme Court 
    later overruled this, as discussed in part I above.
    
        \20\Streamlining also gave (1) blanket approval for expansions, 
    (2) reeduced the filing period (substantially) to 14 days, and (3) 
    required no financial information.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    C. The Cab and Airlines
    
        Airline transportation and its regulation has many similarities 
    to gas pipeline transportation. On any given trip, the variable cost 
    of flying the aircraft is essentially the cost of the fuel used, 
    just as the variable cost of transporting gas is the fuel used by 
    the compressors. Unit costs, therefore, are highly sensitive to 
    utilization or load factors. Economies of scale attainable through 
    the use of larger airplanes, however, have been thought to be less 
    important than for gas pipelines.\21\ Airline companies, like 
    pipeline companies, needed a public convenience & necessity 
    certificate to serve or abandon any interstate route; rates and 
    terms and conditions were strictly regulated. Discounts were 
    allowed, if at all, after a hearing at which competitors could 
    either challenge the proposed rates or match them.
    
        \21\Bailey et al., provide some of the evidence indicating that 
    economies of scale are modest at pp. 50-54. Fred Kahn, however, 
    suggests that, from hindsight, economies of scale were 
    underestimated. The ``thoroughgoing'' movement to a hub and spoke 
    system was not foreseen. See ``Surprises of Airline Deregulation,'' 
    American Economic Review, May, 1985, 316-322.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Differences were and are important. Airlines generally have 
    little substantial investment in immobile assets like roadbed, track 
    or in laying pipe. Airports, landing slots and air-traffic control 
    are generally government supplied. Economies of aircraft scale, 
    while present, are less pronounced than for pipelines. Air traffic, 
    in contrast to natural gas, is not fungible. When you go to pick up 
    your grandparents at the airport, you expect unique rather than 
    generic grandparents to deplane. Regulation was thought necessary, 
    not because airlines were a natural monopoly, but because they were 
    thought to be subject to ``excessive competition.'' Under this 
    theory, regulation was necessary to prevent airlines from 
    bankrupting each other through overbuilding and excessive price 
    competition.\22\ Another purpose was to provide direct subsidies to 
    encourage the growth of general aviation. The history of airline 
    deregulation also differs greatly from that for natural gas 
    pipelines. While the CAB itself, under Alfred Kahn, initiated some 
    important changes in 1977 under the Civil Aviation Act (1938), 
    Congress decided, in 1978, to phase out all CAB regulation and the 
    agency itself by 1985. The change from a highly regulated 
    environment designed to minimize competition to a free entry 
    environment emphasizing price competition occurred in a remarkably 
    short time.
    
        \22\See Stephen Breyer, Regulation and Its Reform, Harvard, 
    1982, 197-221; and Elizabeth Bailey, David Graham and Daniel Kaplan, 
    Deregulating the Airlines, MIT, 1985, 11-26.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    1. Problems That Led to Deregulation
    
        The Senate held hearings on airline regulation in February 1975. 
    The study released later that year was highly critical of the 
    CAB.\23\ Stephen Breyer,\24\ summarized the study as revealing 
    several ``serious defects'' relating to rates, routes, efficiency 
    and agency procedures, two of which were:
    
        \23\Senate Comm. on the Judiciary, Subcomm. on Admin. Practice 
    and Procedure, 94th Cong., 1st Sess., Civil Aeronautics Board 
    Practices and Procedures. (1975).
        \24\Breyer was the Committee's chief investigator.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Rates. Regulation led to high prices and overcapacity. Because 
    the airline industry was highly competitive and because the CAB 
    prevented price competition, the airlines channeled their 
    competitive energies into providing more and costlier service--more 
    flights, more planes, more frills * * * Yet the planes themselves 
    flew more than half empty. (Breyer, 1982, 200)
        Routes. Regulation effectively closed the industry to newcomers 
    and guaranteed relatively stable market shares to firms already in 
    the industry. (Id., 205)
        The Airline Deregulation Act was signed into law in 1978. The 
    Act phased out the CAB's authority and the Board itself ceased 
    operations entirely by 1985.
    
    2. The Role of Market Power Analysis in Airline Deregulation and Merger 
    Policy
    
        Market power analysis was an important factor in the rapid 
    deregulation of airlines and an even more important factor in the 
    merger policy that controlled consolidation within and exit from the 
    industry. An important element of the case against regulation was 
    that but for regulation, the industry would be much less 
    concentrated at the national level than it was under CAB regulation. 
    The relevant market for the traveler was usually defined to be the 
    ``city-pair,'' the two cities between which the traveler wishes to 
    fly.\25\ Advocates of deregulation did not argue that each airline 
    would find itself battling hosts of actual competitors. They claimed 
    only that the threat of entry into a particular market by airlines 
    not currently serving that market would hold prices down. An airline 
    that serves city A and city B, but does not fly between them, can 
    enter the A-B market at very low cost, and there are several such 
    airlines serving most major routes. [[Page 8375]] 
    
        \25\The analog for pipeline transportation would be ``origin-
    destination'' pairs, but both the Commission and DOJ have generally 
    analyzed pipeline origin and destination markets separately. Why the 
    difference? Oil and gas are fungible, airline passengers and freight 
    are not.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Board based its assessment of the likely effects of a merger 
    on two related findings: that concentration measures based on city-
    pair markets alone are not an accurate gauge of competitive 
    performance and that potential entry would have an important 
    disciplining effect on performance. (Bailey et al, 1985, 173-202). 
    Market definitions were often contested. The DOJ in the Northwest/
    Republic merger, for example, argued that the relevant product 
    market was ``non-stop'' flights between city- pairs. In other cases 
    witnesses have argued over whether the appropriate definition should 
    be airport pairs, city pairs, or the complex of services 
    representative of a hub and spoke network. But in all cases the same 
    general relevant market definition framework has been used.
        Breyer (1987) suggested that antitrust rules designed to deal 
    with industry in general may not properly reflect the unique 
    features of the airline industry. For example, he cautioned against 
    applying the ``optimistic'' merger view that is more lenient on 
    higher concentration thresholds and places great store on 
    ``potential competitors,'' fearing that such an antitrust view would 
    not be stringent enough. On the other hand, he would be more lenient 
    than the merger guidelines with respect to the ``failing company'' 
    or efficiency defenses for merger, to reflect that fact that the 
    airline industry is emerging from forty years of regulation.
    
    3.The Effects of Airline Deregulation
    
        Virtually all observers agree that airline fares have been much 
    lower and traffic immensely larger than they would have been absent 
    deregulation.\26\ However, as Alfred Kahn put it, there were some 
    ``unpleasant surprises'' as well.\27\ Although in the early years 
    there was much new entry, most failed and national concentration in 
    the industry failed to decline as most proponents of deregulation 
    had predicted. Quality of service declined. Another unpleasant 
    surprise to Kahn was ``the persistence-indeed, intensification-of 
    price discrimination * * *'' despite which the airline industry has 
    experienced severe losses and only a few carriers have been 
    profitable.
    
        \26\Elizabeth Bailey, David Graham, and Daniel Kaplan, 
    Deregulating the Airlnes (MIT, 1985), and Steven Morrison and 
    Clifford Winston, The Economic Effects of Airline Deregulation 
    (Brookings, 1986).
        \27\Alfred Kahn, ``Supreses of Airline Deregulation,'' American 
    Economic Review (May, 1988).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [FR Doc. 95-3631 Filed 02-13-95; 8:45 am]
    BILLING CODE 6717-01-P
    
    

Document Information

Published:
02/14/1995
Department:
Energy Department
Entry Type:
Notice
Document Number:
95-3631
Pages:
8356-8375 (20 pages)
Docket Numbers:
Docket No. RM95-6-000
PDF File:
95-3631.pdf