96-2547. Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service Ratemaking for Natural Gas Pipelines and Regulation of Negotiated Transportation Services of Natural Gas Pipelines; Statement of Policy and Request for Comments  

  • [Federal Register Volume 61, Number 26 (Wednesday, February 7, 1996)]
    [Notices]
    [Pages 4633-4646]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 96-2547]
    
    
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
    Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
    [Docket Nos. RM95-6-000 and RM96-7-000]
    
    
    Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service Ratemaking for 
    Natural Gas Pipelines and Regulation of Negotiated Transportation 
    Services of Natural Gas Pipelines; Statement of Policy and Request for 
    Comments
    
    Issued January 31, 1996.
    
    I. Introduction
    
        In this docket, the Commission has been exploring the criteria it 
    should use when evaluating rates established through methods other than 
    the traditional cost-of-service ratemaking method. In response to a 
    number of requests from natural gas pipeline companies to approve rates 
    based on various pricing methods, which may or may not be cost-based, 
    the Commission has decided to establish a framework for analyzing 
    certain of such proposals. The Commission solicited comments on the 
    criteria it should use in evaluating non-cost-of-service based 
    proposals \1\ and representatives from all segments of the industry 
    responded. The Commission has reviewed those comments and is now 
    providing the industry with guidance by stating the criteria it will 
    consider when evaluating proposals for market-based rates. Moreover, 
    the Commission will modify its existing policy statement on incentive 
    ratemaking in light of the comments received.
    
        \1\ Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service Ratemaking for 
    Natural Gas Pipelines, 70 FERC para. 61,139 (Feb. 8, 1995) 
    (``Request For Comments'').
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Moreover, the Commission will modify its existing policy statement 
    on incentive ratemaking in light of the comments received.
        The Request for Comments also generated responses from the industry 
    on other non-cost-of-service based alternatives to the Commission's 
    traditional ratemaking methodology. In particular, the Commission has 
    received and reviewed comments on negotiated/recourse rates. Under a 
    negotiated/recourse program the Commission would dispense with cost-of-
    service regulation for an individual shipper when mutually agreed upon 
    by the pipeline and its shipper and permit negotiated terms and/or 
    conditions that could vary from the pipeline's otherwise applicable 
    tariff. A recourse service found in the pipeline's tariff would be 
    available for those shippers preferring traditional cost-of-service 
    rates and services.
        Based on the comments received, the Commission is prepared to 
    permit negotiated rates within the guidelines discussed below. The 
    Commission has determined, however, that in order to make an informed 
    decision, additional consideration and comment is needed regarding the 
    legal and policy implications of negotiated terms and conditions of 
    service. Therefore, the Commission is establishing a separate 
    proceeding to solicit further comments concerning negotiated terms and 
    conditions.
    
    II. Background
    
        In 1989, Congress urged the Commission to ``improve [the] 
    competitive structure [of the natural gas industry] in order to 
    maximize the benefits of [wellhead] decontrol.'' \2\ The Commission 
    responded to Congress in part in Order No. 636 \3\ by taking 
    significant steps to increase competition in the transportation market. 
    By regulating pipelines in a manner that seeks to ensure all shippers 
    have meaningful access to the pipeline transportation grid, the 
    Commission has created a regulatory environment intended to maximize 
    competition.
    
        \2\ H.R. Rep. No. 29, 101st Cong., 1st Sess., at 6 (1989).
        \3\ Pipeline Service Obligations and Revisions to Regulations 
    Governing Self-Implementing Transportation Under Part 284 of the 
    Commission's Regulations, and Regulation of Natural Gas After 
    Partial Wellhead Decontrol, Order No. 636, 57 Fed. Reg. 13267 (April 
    16, 1992), FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 30,939 (April 8, 1992), order 
    on reh'g, Order No. 636-A, FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 30,950 (August 
    2, 1992), order on reh'g, Order No. 636-B, 61 FERC para. 61,272 
    (November 27, 1992), reh'g denied, Order No. 636-C, 62 FERC para. 
    61,007 (January 8, 1993), appeal pending sub nom. United 
    Distribution Companies, et al. v. FERC, Nos. 92-1485, et al.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The result of Order Nos. 436 and 636, combined with the North 
    American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) and the certification of new 
    pipelines, is an increased availability of unbundled transportation and 
    greater integration of upstream and downstream natural gas markets, 
    both domestic and Canadian. As a result, there has been a shift in 
    traditional supply sources; many existing pipeline customers no longer 
    want or need the same amount of firm capacity to their traditional 
    pipeline's supply regions. In addition, the overall natural gas demand 
    has been increasing steadily, albeit modestly. Since 1992, national 
    consumption of natural gas has increased at about 3 percent.\4\ This 
    increased demand has occurred primarily in the industrial and electric 
    end-use markets for natural gas.\5\ Natural gas consumers in these 
    markets often have dual fuel capability,\6\ and for this reason 
    pipelines have sought ratemaking flexibility to respond to alternative 
    fuel competition in these markets.
    
        \4\ In 1992, the overall national consumption of natural gas was 
    19.5 Tcf; in 1994 it reached 20.7 Tcf, a 6 percent increase. Figures 
    for the first nine months of 1995 suggest an increase of 3 percent 
    over the first 9 months of 1994. Natural Gas Monthly, December 1995.
        \5\ See, e.g., Energy Information Administration, Natural Gas 
    Annual 1994, at p. 37 (DOE-EIA-0131(94)/1, November 1995) (``Most of 
    the 476 billion cubic feet increase in consumption was due to 
    increased reliance on natural gas in the electric utility sector., . 
    . ., while industrial consumption grew by 196 billion cubic feet or 
    3 percent.'').
        \6\ See, e.g., National Petroleum Council, The Potential for 
    Natural Gas in the United States, Volume III, Demand and 
    Distribution, (December 1992) at 72-73 and 96.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Pipelines contend that greater flexibility is key to attracting new 
    gas markets and retaining existing markets. 
    
    [[Page 4634]]
    For example, new electric generators have argued that they require 
    long-term price certainty for transportation to finance gas-dependent 
    ventures. In addition, it is asserted that ratemaking flexibility would 
    permit pipelines to tailor natural gas transportation rates for 
    electric generators to meet the swings in gas consumption often 
    experienced by such generators. Pipelines have argued that, because 
    many LDCs are unwilling to commit to long-term firm contracts, greater 
    flexibility in rates and services is needed to retain customer load as 
    old long-term contracts expire. LDCs also want flexibility so they can 
    swing between pipelines to take advantage of the opportunity to 
    purchase gas from different supply regions.
        The Commission has recognized that additional rate design 
    flexibility may be needed in a post-restructuring environment. In cases 
    concerning the appropriate rate treatment for the costs associated with 
    a pipeline's loss of revenues resulting from the expiration of 
    contracts, for instance, parties have argued that they need additional 
    rate design flexibility in order to market excess capacity and recover 
    costs associated with their turned-back capacity.\7\ In Natural Gas 
    Pipeline Company of America,\8\ the Commission indicated its 
    willingness to permit pipelines flexibility in negotiating rates with 
    its current and prospective customers for unsubscribed capacity, 
    including rates which depart from SFV rate design. The Commission also 
    stated that it would entertain, as part of a settlement, a proposal 
    that allows rate flexibility for the capacity that customers had 
    already elected.
    
        \7\ See Southern Natural Gas Co., 73 FERC para. 61,322 (1995); 
    Natural Gas Pipeline Co. of America, 73 FERC para. 61,050 (1995); 
    Transwestern Pipeline Co., 72 FERC para. 61,085, reh'g denied, 72 
    FERC para. 61,089 (1995); and El Paso Natural Gas Co., 72 FERC para. 
    61,083 (1995).
        \8\ 72 FERC para. 61,083 (1995).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In recent filings, pipeline companies also have urged the 
    Commission to permit greater flexibility in service options and terms 
    and conditions in order to meet competition. For example, Panhandle 
    Eastern Pipe Line Corporation (Panhandle) proposed a Limited Firm 
    Transportation (LFT) Service, under which its customers would be 
    guaranteed the ability to schedule firm transportation service for only 
    20 days in any given month.\9\ Trunkline Gas Company proposed a Premium 
    Alternative Transportation (PAT) Service, consisting of interruptible 
    transportation with preferential scheduling and curtailment features 
    for an annual contracting fee.\10\ Trunkline also proposed a Park and 
    Transfer Service to help shippers manage their supply while reducing 
    the frequency of cash-outs and scheduling penalties.\11\
    
        \9\ Panhandle Eastern Pipe Line Co., 72 FERC para. 61,185 
    (1995).
        \10\ Trunkline Gas Co., 73 FERC para. 61,107 (1995).
        \11\ Id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In an attempt to respond to pipelines' requests for added 
    flexibility, the Commission sought comments on alternative methods for 
    pricing of services by natural gas pipeline companies. In its Request 
    for Comments, the Commission stated its interest in developing a 
    framework for analyzing proposals involving alternative pricing 
    methods. Recognizing that there are a number of cost-based, as well as 
    non-cost based alternatives to the Commission's traditional method, the 
    Commission sought comment on fifteen specific questions related to 
    possible ratemaking alternatives.
        In the Request for Comments, the Commission also sought comment on 
    a Commission Staff Paper that proposed criteria for evaluating of 
    proposals for market-based rates. The staff paper applied basic market 
    power analysis, as used in the past by the Commission as well as in 
    other contexts, to develop a proposed analytical framework for 
    evaluating gas pipeline market-based rate proposals.
        The Commission also sought comment on whether changes should be 
    made in its existing policy statement on incentive ratemaking.\12\ The 
    Commission noted that although it has stated the criteria upon which it 
    will evaluate cost-based incentive rate proposals, to date no natural 
    gas company has submitted such a proposal. The Commission raised 
    several specific questions regarding its policy on incentive rate 
    proposals and solicited comments on all aspects of its existing policy 
    statement.
    
        \12\ Policy Statement on Incentive Regulation, 61 FERC para. 
    61,168 (1992).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission received 59 comments from parties representing all 
    segments of the natural gas industry.\13\ The majority of the responses 
    focused on the staff paper and suggestions for criteria for evaluating 
    market-based rate proposals. Furthermore, the responses critically 
    analyzed the Commission's existing incentive rate policy statement and 
    offered sound suggestions for altering the existing policy to meet the 
    needs of the public interest in today's natural gas market.
    
        \13\ A list of the commenters is included as an appendix to this 
    policy statement.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The comments also proposed other alternatives to traditional cost-
    of-service ratemaking. Specifically, INGAA proposed that the Commission 
    approve negotiated/recourse rate applications. Under such applications, 
    pipelines would be allowed to negotiate a rate and/or terms and 
    conditions of service so long as a Commission approved (recourse) rate 
    remained available. Customers would always retain the right to elect 
    the recourse rate and forego negotiation. Various commenters filed 
    responses to INGAA's proposal.\14\ Several of these commenters 
    generally support INGAA's proposal although they object to INGAA's 
    proposal to index the recourse rate.\15\ Comments in opposition to 
    INGAA's proposal focused on issues ranging from cost shifting and 
    degradation of service to preventing undue discrimination and complying 
    with the NGA's filing requirement. INGAA further clarified its proposal 
    on September 25 and November 9, 1995 and commenters filed additional 
    responses thereafter. A detailed discussion of INGAA's proposal and the 
    responses thereto is included as part of the Commission's Request for 
    Comments in Section IV below.
    
        \14\ To date, the Commission has received comments on INGAA's 
    proposal from Brooklyn Union, GRI, IPAA, NGSA, and a group of eight 
    industrial organizations.
        \15\ AGD, Brooklyn Union, and UGI.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    III. Policy on Market-Based Rates
    
        The Commission has determined that where a natural gas company can 
    establish that it lacks significant market power,\16\ market-based 
    rates are a viable option for achieving the flexibility and added 
    efficiency required by the current marketplace. To date, the Commission 
    has reviewed requests by regulated companies to charge market-based 
    rates on a case-by-case basis. The Commission intends to continue in 
    this vein, but is announcing the criteria it will generally use in the 
    review process to aid companies in preparing their proposals. Below, we 
    discuss the criteria the Commission will consider in evaluating any 
    pending or future proposal for market-based rates. Companies may submit 
    proposals meeting the established criteria for system segments and/or 
    specific services offered on a system.
    
        \16\ Transwestern Pipeline Company, 43 FERC para. 61,240 (1988); 
    El Paso Natural Gas Company, 49 FERC para. 61,262 (1989); 
    Transcontinental Gas Pipe Line Corporation, 55 FERC para. 61,446 
    (1991); Richfield Gas Storage System, 59 FERC para. 61,316 (1992); 
    Koch Gateway Pipeline Company, 66 FERC para. 61,385 (1994); Buckeye 
    Pipe Line Company, 53 FERC para. 61,473 (1990), and Williams Pipe 
    Line Company, 69 FERC para. 61,136 (1994).
    
    [[Page 4635]]
    
    
    A. The Comments Received
    
        The majority of the responses to the Request for Comments focused 
    on the staff paper and suggestions for criteria for evaluating 
    proposals for market-based rates.
        The majority of those commenters supported market-based rates where 
    a market is fully competitive.17 Many commenters recognized, 
    however, that it is unlikely that the primary market, i.e., firm 
    transportation by interstate pipeline companies, will meet the proposed 
    criteria for market-based rates.18
    
        \17\ AGA, Edison, Con Edison, ANR/CIG, CNG, Cove Point, INGAA, 
    Koch Gateway, PGT, PEC Pipeline Group, IPAA, Indicated Shippers, 
    Alberta, Florida, Ohio CC, New York, Mark B. Lively, and Transok.
        \18\ Brooklyn Union, Connecticut Natural, IPAMS, Illinois, Ohio 
    PUC, Tejas, Atlanta Gas, Columbia Distribution, Northern 
    Distributors, NI-Gas, UDC, Amoco, NGSA, Texaco, PA. OCA, and PaPUC.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        LDCs, producers, marketers, and state commissions, joined by a few 
    interstate pipeline companies, assert that other markets, for example 
    those for capacity release and interruptible transportation, already 
    are, or can become, competitive enough to permit market-based 
    rates.19 Several parties believe that the markets for short-term 
    firm transportation,20 storage,21 and hub/market center 
    services,22 as well as new markets 23 may also be competitive 
    enough to permit market-based rates. On the other hand, a number of 
    endusers and LDCs take the position that market-based rates should not 
    be allowed for certain markets, including firm transportation,24 
    capacity release,25 short-term firm,26 interruptible 
    transportation,27 and storage.28
    
        \19\ Edison, AGD, Atlanta Gas, Brooklyn Union, Pacific Northwest 
    Commenters, CINergy Gas Companies, Columbia Distribution, 
    Connecticut Natural, Con Edison, Northern Distributors, NI-Gas, 
    Northern Indiana, PSE&G, UDC, Columbia, INGAA, PGT, WINGS, Illinois, 
    Ohio CC, Pa. OCA, PaPUC, and the Ohio PUC.
        \20\ Connecticut Natural, Northern Distributors, UDC, Columbia, 
    INGAA, and WINGS.
        \21\ Edison, APGA, Pacific Northwest Commenters, NI-Gas, INGAA, 
    PGT, WINGS, IPAMS, PaPUC, and Tejas.
        \22\ Edison, APGA, Pacific Northwest Commenters, NI-Gas, INGAA, 
    PGT, WINGS, IPAMS, PaPUC, and Tejas.
        \23\ NI-Gas, Northern Indiana, Columbia, Cove Point, and INGAA. 
    New markets include new construction, new services, or new entrants.
        \24\ AF&PA, Fertilizer Institute, Energy Associates, NWIGU, 
    Petrochemical Energy Group, Pacific Northwest Commenters, Northern 
    Indiana, IOGA, and Ohio CC.
        \25\ AF&PA and NWIGU.
        \26\ APGA.
        \27\ AF&PA, Fertilizer Institute, APGA, and Pacific Northwest 
    Commenters.
        \28\ Energy Associates.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The staff paper issued with the Request for Comments proposed 
    criteria for evaluating market-based rate proposals. The Commission 
    sought comments regarding whether these criteria were appropriate, too 
    strenuous, or not strenuous enough. The majority of pipeline 
    commenters, along with a few others, indicated that the criteria were 
    too strenuous and ignore competitive factors.29 A few pipelines 
    suggest the Commission should avoid ``one size fits all'' approaches 
    and instead use evaluation criteria of a more general nature.30 
    The majority of end-users and regulatory commissions believe the 
    proposed criteria are either reasonable and strenuous enough or require 
    only minor modifications. Specifically, AGD contends that competing 
    products need not be identical. For example, AGD asserts that in the 
    off-peak season, released FT and IT are virtually identical. Therefore, 
    AGD suggests that the criteria be modified to allow for consideration 
    of such differences in product definition.
    
        \29\ Cove Point, INGAA, Tejas, ANR/CIG, Brooklyn Union, KN 
    Interstate, AGA, Koch Gateway, WINGS, Transok, KN Interstate, NGSA, 
    PEC Pipeline Group, and Columbia.
        \30\ Enron, INGAA, and NorAm.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        AGD also argues that the criteria should be modified so that the 
    difference in price to be considered will be the difference in the cost 
    of obtaining delivered gas through the various alternatives. The Pa OCA 
    contends that the timeliness criterion should be more strenuous. Pa OCA 
    states that if projected alternative capacity is delayed or is less 
    than projected, customers should have the option of continuing to pay a 
    traditional cost-of-service rate until workable competition exists. The 
    Ohio CC and Pa OCA state that ``ease of exit'' as well as ``ease of 
    entry'' should be added to the criteria used to define product markets. 
    Pa OCA also suggests that the financial risk to customers be added to 
    the criteria used to define product markets.
        The LDCs, producers, and marketers are evenly divided on the 
    question. Those that oppose the criteria assert that they are too 
    narrow, will lead to overregulation, and that the .18 the summary 
    measure of market concentration known as the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index 
    (HHI) screen is too low.31 Several commenters suggested that other 
    factors, including market competition, market definition, and product 
    substitution, must be considered in evaluating any proposal for market-
    based rates.32
    
        \31\ Cove Point Pipeline, INGAA, Tejas, ANR Pipeline/CIG 
    Pipeline, Brooklyn Union, KN Interstate Pipeline, AGA, Koch Gateway 
    Pipeline, WINGS, Transok Pipeline, PEC Pipeline Group, and Columbia 
    Pipeline.
        \32\ SoCalGas, CNG, Enron, INGAA, and NorAm.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In response to the Commission's inquiry regarding the use of 
    different standards for different types of service, a number of LDCs 
    and pipelines argue that the Commission should use different standards 
    for different services.33 Several commenters assert that the 
    standards should be tailored to the services offered and/or the market 
    to be served.34 In contrast, the few state regulatory commissions 
    who responded on this issue suggest that the same criteria should be 
    used for all services.35
    
        \33\ Wisconsin Distributors, AF&PA, Edison, AGA, AGD, 
    Connecticut Natural, Northern Distributors, NI-Gas, Northern 
    Indiana, UDC, Columbia, INGAA, KN Interstate, WINGS, IPAMS, 
    Illinois, Ohio PUC, and Tejas.
        \34\ SoCalGas, Koch Gateway, and PEC Pipeline Group.
        \35\ Industrial Gas Consumers, APGA, CNG, NGSA, Alberta, 
    Florida, and Ohio CC.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    B. Response to Legal Arguments Opposing Market-Based Rates
    
        A few commenters raised specific arguments regarding the 
    Commission's legal authority to implement market-based rates on a broad 
    scale. Only the IPAA made a broad-based attack on the Commission's 
    legal authority to permit market-based rates. The Commission believes 
    that IPAA's attack is based largely on mistaken premises.
        IPAA asserts that the NGA contemplates ``traditional'' or cost-of-
    service ratemaking and therefore adoption of market-based rates on a 
    wide scale may be contrary to the statutory intent of the NGA. IPAA 
    argues that the Supreme Court has specifically held that NGA Sections 
    5(b), 6(a), 9(a), 10(a) and 14(b) suggest that when Congress enacted 
    the NGA, it contemplated ``traditional'' or cost-of-service ratemaking 
    36 IPAA narrowly construes the Supreme Court decisions in FPC v. 
    Hope,37 and the Permian Basin Area Rate Case 38 as applying 
    solely in cases where the question to be decided is what methods should 
    be used to establish a rate base, not whether some alternative to cost-
    of-service ratemaking would be appropriate.
    
        \36\ Citing, Colorado Interstate Gas Company v. FPC, 324 U.S. 
    581 at 601-2 (1945) (CIG).
        \37\ In Hope, the Court held that the Commission was not bound 
    to use any single formula or combination of formulae in determining 
    rates, but that the Commission's rate-making function ``involves the 
    making of pragmatic adjustments'' and that under the statutory 
    standard ``it is the end result reached not the method employed 
    which is controlling.'' 320 U.S. 591 at 602 (1944).
        \38\ 390 U.S. 747 (1968).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        This is an extremely narrow reading of the case law. Moreover, IPAA 
    does not even acknowledge more recent cases 
    
    [[Page 4636]]
    such as Farmers Union Central Exchange v. FERC,39 which recognized 
    the possibility of moving to light-handed regulation when justified by 
    a showing that the goals and purposes of the statute can be 
    accomplished without traditional regulatory oversight.40 Thus, 
    IPAA's arguments in this regard are not persuasive.
    
        \39\ 734 F.2d 1486, 1509 (1991) Farmers Union II.
        \40\ See also, Elizabethtown Gas Co. v. FERC, 10 F.3d 866, 870 
    (D.C. Cir. 1993) (Elizabethtown) (Court of Appeals affirmed 
    Commission approval of market-based rates, under appropriate 
    circumstances, as meeting the requirements of the NGA.)
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        IPAA also maintains that an essential demand in the pipelines' 
    request for market-based rates is that the Commission ignore the 
    statutory prohibition against ``undue discrimination.'' IPAA claims 
    that the pipelines wish to be able to discriminate in rates, terms, and 
    conditions, which it argues would violate the NGA and possibly of the 
    antitrust laws. Simply put, IPAA maintains pipelines want to charge 
    some customers higher rates in order to subsidize lower rates for 
    affiliates and other favored customers, in violation of the NGA.
        The Commission does not share IPAA's view. First, the scenario IPAA 
    fears is possible only if a pipeline exercises market power. A company 
    cannot make one group of customers subsidize another unless it has 
    market power over the group that would pay the higher rates. If a 
    pipeline has market power over a service then the Commission cannot 
    permit it to charge market-based rates for that service. In addition, 
    the Commission has carefully scrutinized affiliate relationships and 
    generally has taken special precautions, imposing special rules, where 
    affiliates are involved. In those instances the Commission has 
    recognized that the normal market controls will not work with affiliate 
    transactions. Finally, the statute does not prohibit all differences in 
    rates. The prohibition in the NGA is against unduly discriminatory 
    behavior. Thus, under Part 284 of the Commission's regulations, the 
    Commission has allowed differences in rates by permitting pipelines to 
    discount rates for certain types of service and for certain 
    customers.41 The Commission has maintained that these differences 
    in rates are justified if the discount is necessary to meet competitive 
    circumstances and the customers are not in similar competitive 
    positions.
    
        \41\ 18 CFR 284.7 (1995).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Hadson asserts that the Commission has failed to explain how 
    Commission rulings that prohibit restrictions on the resale of electric 
    power as per se violations of the FPA,42 and prohibit restrictions 
    on the resale of natural gas as violative of NGA standards,43 are 
    consistent with its determination that resale restrictions on the sale 
    of pipeline capacity are required under the NGA.44
    
        \42\ Citing, Gulf States Utilities Co., 5 FERC para. 61,066 
    (1978) (Gulf States), Central Maine Power Co., 18 FERC para. 61,126 
    (19982); Louisiana Power & Light Co., 14 FERC para. 61,075 at 
    61,130-31 (1981); Central Telephone & Utilities Corp., 10 FERC para. 
    61,213 (1980); and Empire District Electric Co., 5 FERC para. 61,083 
    (1978).
        \43\ Citing, City of Florence v. Tennessee Gas Pipeline, 24 FERC 
    para. 61,395 (1983) (City of Florence) (the Commission voided a 
    restriction in a pipeline LDC contract on the resale of natural gas 
    by the distributor).
        \44\ Hadson at 19.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Hadson's concerns are misplaced. The Commission has determined that 
    non-dominant sellers of electric power cannot exercise market 
    power.45 Likewise, it has determined that markets for the sale of 
    natural gas are sufficiently competitive that the market, subject to 
    Commission oversight and intervention, serves to ensure that rates for 
    the sale of these commodities are just and reasonable. To the extent 
    this is true for primary sales of electric power and natural gas, the 
    proposition is even more true with respect to resales of the 
    commodities. Gulf States, City of Florence and their progeny address 
    sales, not transportation, and the distinction is critical. Congress 
    recognized the distinction when it deregulated wellhead prices. The 
    level of competition that exists for the sale of natural gas has not 
    been demonstrated to exist for the transportation of natural gas. If 
    the market does not serve to ensure just and reasonable rates for the 
    primary market one cannot simply assume that it will ensure just and 
    reasonable rates for the secondary market.
    
        \45\ See, e.g., Louisville Gas and Electric Company, 62 FERC 
    para. 61,016 at 61,143-4 and cases cited at footnote 16. (Non-
    traditional rates may be acceptable if the seller can demonstrate 
    that it lacks market power over the buyer or has adequately 
    mitigated its market power. The seller can demonstrate that it lacks 
    market power (or has adequately mitigated its market power) by 
    showing, among other things, that neither it nor its affiliates is a 
    dominant firm in the sale of generation in the relevant market.)
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Hadson also asserts that lifting cost-based caps and/or moving away 
    from cost-based ratemaking for the transportation of gas by interstate 
    pipelines will interfere with the goals of the NGA. Hadson's comments 
    merely reiterate the reasons for using a market analysis as the 
    starting point for evaluating any market-based rate proposal. Absent a 
    showing that a particular company lacks market power or that sufficient 
    regulatory safeguards, e.g., a cost-of-service fallback rate, can be 
    implemented to eliminate the potential exercise of market power, the 
    Commission would continue some form of cost-based ratemaking.46 
    Where a company can show a lack of market power, then competition in 
    the market would ensure that the company's rates will be just and 
    reasonable. In either case, the goals and purposes of the NGA are met 
    in that any rates that would be charged would be just and reasonable, 
    either under a cost-based or a market-based analysis.
    
        \46\ See the discussion of Negotiated/Recourse Rates below.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Hadson also asserts that Farmers Union Central Exchange v. 
    FERC,47 which affirmed the possibility of light-handed regulation 
    of oil pipelines, recognized that the movement to light-handed 
    regulation is justified only by a showing that the goals and purposes 
    of the statute can be accomplished without traditional regulatory 
    oversight. Hadson asserts that the staff paper does not address the 
    potential for serious disruption of the industry in the event that a 
    future Commission (or a reviewing court) decides to apply court rulings 
    applicable for other regulated industries, such as the 
    telecommunications industry, and require strict tariffing.48 
    Hadson states that the Commission should either revisit its assertion 
    of NGA jurisdiction over shippers (via blanket certificates) or assure 
    the public that the procedures under which everyday business is 
    conducted will not be confounded by a subsequent finding that the 
    structure does not comport with the filed rate doctrine. Hadson is 
    merely repeating arguments advanced in opposition to the Commission 
    exercising its NGA jurisdiction over marketers. The Commission 
    previously addressed these concerns when it reaffirmed that sales by 
    marketers are resales subject to the Commission's NGA jurisdiction. 
    These 
    
    [[Page 4637]]
    issues need not be addressed again in this context.49
    
        \47\ 734 F.2d 1486, 1509 (1991) Farmers Union II.
        \48\ Hadson refers to a line of Federal Communications 
    Commission cases which stand for the proposition that an agency 
    should be mindful of specific statutory procedural requirements when 
    it undertakes reform of substantive regulatory policies and 
    programs. Citing, MCI Telecommunications Corp. v. ATT, ______ U.S. 
    ______, 114 S.Ct. 2223 (1994) (MCI II), Southwestern Bell Corp. v. 
    FCC, 43 F.3d 1515 (D.C. Cir. 1995) (Southwestern Bell), and Maislin 
    Industries, U.S. Inc. v. Primary Steel, Inc., 49 U.S. 116 (1990). 
    Neither MCI II nor Southwestern Bell speak to the substantive 
    validity of alternative, non-cost based, ratemaking methodologies. 
    These cases address the methods of implementing statutory 
    requirements for rate filings that agencies can legitimately employ. 
    The cases do not speak to the methods of deriving the rates that 
    ultimately must be filed. With respect to such methods, the doctrine 
    advanced in Hope still applies.
        \49\ See, Removal of Outdated Regulations Pertaining to the 
    Sales of Natural Gas Production, Docket No. RM94-18-001, 69 FERC 
    para. 61,055 at 61,217 (1994), appeal docketed sub nom. Hadson Gas 
    Systems, Inc. v. FERC, No. 95-1111 (D.C. Cir.).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        IPAA asserts that, assuming for the sake of argument alternative 
    pricing methods could be sustained on appeal, some very specific 
    statutory requirements with respect to filing and approval of rates and 
    the prohibition against undue discrimination must be considered. Citing 
    Environmental Action v. FERC 50 and Transwestern Pipeline Co. v. 
    FERC,51 IPAA maintains that a formula or rule means that something 
    must be filed from which an actual rate can be calculated; a rate 
    dependent solely upon the market does not qualify as a ``formula'' or 
    ``rule.''
    
        \50\ In Environmental Action v. FERC, 996 F.2d 401 (D.C. Cir. 
    1993) (Environmental Action), the proposed pricing plan was ruled to 
    have been acceptable because there was a filed rate cap, and any 
    discrimination was held to be potential.
        \51\ In Transwestern v. FERC, 897 F.2d 570 (D.C. Cir. 1990) 
    (Transwestern), the Court determined that filing a ``rate `formula' 
    or rate `rule' '' can satisfy the filing requirements of Section 4; 
    however, given the Court's ruling that the issue of market-based 
    rates was moot in that case because there had been no customer 
    nominations under Transwestern's program, the determination with 
    respect to a rate formula or rule appears to be have been dicta.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission's implementation of market-based rates for pipelines 
    and storage companies comports with the filed rate doctrine. The 
    Commission has not attempted to eliminate tariffs, as was the case in 
    the telecommunications industry, and does not do so here. Currently, 
    for the few proposals that have been approved, the Commission has 
    required the company to file tariff sheets for the service with market-
    based rates. The Commission will continue this practice in any future 
    declaratory orders ruling on market-based rate proposals.
    
    C. The Criteria
    
        The Commission's framework for evaluating requests for market-based 
    rates addresses two principal purposes: (1) Whether the applicant can 
    withhold or restrict services and, as a result, increase price by a 
    significant amount for a significant period of time, and (2) whether 
    the applicant can discriminate unduly in price or terms and conditions. 
    Undue discrimination is especially a concern when an applicant for 
    market-based rates can deal with affiliates.
        Before the Commission can conclude that a seller will not withhold 
    or restrict services, significantly increase price over an extended 
    period of time, or unduly discriminate, it must either (1) find that 
    there is a lack of market power because customers have sufficient good 
    alternatives or (2) mitigate the market power (i.e., permit market-
    based pricing only if specified conditions are met that prevent the 
    exercise of market power). Market power is defined as the ability of a 
    pipeline to profitably maintain prices above competitive levels for a 
    significant period of time.52 To date, in all cases where the 
    Commission has considered market-based rates, the applicant has been 
    required to show that it lacks significant market power in the relevant 
    markets. The staff paper set out a general framework for evaluating 
    requests for market-based rates. The Commission now adopts this general 
    framework, as discussed below, as its criteria for evaluating the 
    competitiveness of transportation services.
    
        \52\ Enron Storage Company, 73 FERC para. 61,206 (1995); 
    Williams Pipeline Company, 68 FERC para. 61,136 (1994); Avoca 
    Natural Gas Storage, 68 FERC para. 61,045 (1994); Koch Gateway 
    Pipeline Company, 66 FERC para. 61,385 (1994); Bay Gas Storage 
    Company, 66 FERC para. 61,354 (1994); Transok, Inc., 64 FERC para. 
    61,095 1993); and Richfield Gas Storage System, 59 FERC para. 61,316 
    (1992).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission's analysis of whether a pipeline has the ability to 
    exercise market power will include three major steps: (1) Define the 
    relevant markets; (2) measure a firm's market share and market 
    concentration; and (3) evaluate other relevant factors. Each of these 
    steps was articulated in the staff paper. They are discussed, with 
    certain noted changes, again below.
    1. Market Definition
        The first step is to define the relevant market. Market definition 
    identifies the specific products or services and the suppliers of those 
    products or services that provide good alternatives to the applicant's 
    ability to exercise market power. The term ``good alternatives'' has 
    been defined as ``an alternative that is available soon enough, has a 
    price that is low enough, and has a quality high enough to permit 
    customers to substitute the alternative'' for the applicant's 
    service.53
    
        \53\ Koch Gateway Pipeline Company, 66 FERC para. 61,385 at 
    62,299 (1994).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        a. The Product Market.  The applicant's service together with other 
    services that are good alternatives constitute the relevant product 
    market. The Commission will require the applicant to define the product 
    market fully and specifically. The applicant must also show how each of 
    the substitute services in the product market are adequate substitutes 
    to the applicant's service in terms of quality, price and availability. 
    For example, the relevant product market may consist of off-peak 
    interruptible transportation service only. The Commission will consider 
    any substitutes for the relevant product that can be considered 
    competitive alternatives, e.g., storage delivery services. Pipelines 
    might suggest numerous alternatives to FT in their applications: IT, 
    storage services, residual fuel oil, etc. A narrow definition of the 
    product market, for example, peak period, firm transportation or off-
    peak, interruptible transportation, will better enable the Commission 
    to critically evaluate the real alternatives that are available to the 
    proposed service.
        i. Timeliness. The definition of the product market may vary 
    depending on the time period considered. For example, whether a service 
    is a good alternative to a pipeline's interruptible service will depend 
    on the time periods chosen for review. The staff paper noted that, 
    although antitrust authorities have used one year as the time period in 
    which to test whether a product can become a substitute, a one year 
    time period was probably not appropriate for long-term firm 
    transportation because capacity on competitors would typically need to 
    be available simultaneously to offer a viable alternative to customers. 
    Because long-term firm contracts typically do not offer customers the 
    ability to shift between alternatives, the one year time period may not 
    be appropriate.
        A few commenters argue that the Commission should adopt a more 
    strenuous timeliness criterion.54 They assert that if the 
    projected alternative capacity is delayed or is less than projected, 
    customers should have the option of continuing to pay a traditional 
    cost-of-service rate until workable competition exists.
    
        \54\ Pa OCA and Ohio CC.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission will not define a specific time period within which 
    a product must become available in order to be a substitute. The 
    Commission believes that this determination is dependent upon the type 
    of product services at issue. As more product services become 
    available, the duration of service agreements is likely to vary 
    considerably from the traditional 20-year firm transportation 
    agreement. Therefore, the ability to establish whether a product is or 
    can become a good alternative will depend upon the specifics of the 
    product it is replacing. However, if a pipeline applicant relies on the 
    existence of capacity that will not be available immediately, it should 
    also show that its customers will not be committed to long term 
    contracts on its system within the relevant time period. 
    
    [[Page 4638]]
    In this regard, customers should be given the option of reducing 
    service demand levels once the alternative capacity and/or service 
    becomes available.
        ii. Price. Along with showing that alternative capacity will be 
    available in a reasonable time frame, the Commission will also evaluate 
    whether the price for the available capacity is low enough to 
    effectively restrain the applicant from increasing prices. The price 
    increase threshold is important because with a lower threshold it 
    becomes ostensibly more difficult for a potential alternative to the 
    applicant's service to be considered a good alternative. In prior 
    cases, the Commission has defined such a threshold price level as being 
    at or below the applicant's approved maximum cost-based rate plus 15 
    percent.55
    
        \55\ In Buckeye Pipe Line Company, L.P., Opinion No. 360, 53 
    FERC para. 61,473 at 62,61 (1990), order on reh'g, Opinion No. 360-
    A, 55 FERC para. 61,084 (1991), the Commission held that a 15 
    percent increase was an appropriate level to measure market power. 
    However, in Williams Pipe Line Co., Opinion No. 391, 68 FERC para. 
    61,136 at 61,657, the Commission declined to adopt a specific rate 
    increase as a litmus test for market power. In Koch Gateway Pipeline 
    Company, 66 FERC para. 61,385, the Commission suggested that 
    potential alternatives would include services that though presently 
    not used, would be economic if prevailing prices were to rise by a 
    modest amount, e.g., five to fifteen percent.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several of the commenters suggest that the 15 percent threshold for 
    price changes is inappropriate.56 They assert that a threshold at 
    the 5-10 percent level is more consistent with current similar 
    standards in the Department of Justice's merger guidelines. The 
    Commission has studied the arguments made on this issue and we agree. 
    Accordingly, the Commission will adopt a pricing threshold of 10 
    percent. The Commission believes that if a company can sustain an 
    increase in its rates in the order of 10 percent or more without losing 
    significant market share, the company is in a position to exercise 
    market power to the detriment of the public interest.
    
        \56\ Industrial Gas Consumers, NI-Gas, UDC, Alberta, and 
    Illinois.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Although the Commission is adopting 10 percent as its standard 
    price change threshold, it is not precluding individuals from making an 
    argument for either a higher or lower threshold in any particular case. 
    Applicants are free to argue for a higher threshold where they believe 
    circumstances permit. Similarly, participants in the application 
    proceeding are free to argue for lower thresholds. The Commission will 
    consider the arguments presented and make a determination of the 
    appropriate price change threshold on an individual basis whenever the 
    issue is raised. In cases where the issue is not raised, the Commission 
    will use 10 percent as the applicable price increase threshold. In 
    addition, when applicants propose an appropriate threshold for price 
    increases, they should also propose the time period over which the 
    price increase could be sustained.
        iii. Quality. A good alternative must provide service in which the 
    quality is at least as high as that of the service provided by the 
    applicant. After the Commission has a full and complete description of 
    the service(s) proposed for market-based rate treatment, it will 
    evaluate whether any available third party capacity is comparable in 
    service to the transportation service provided by the applicant.
        In the aftermath of Order Nos. 436 and 636, the Commission believes 
    that all interstate pipelines currently provide operationally 
    comparable firm transportation service. However, even if a customer can 
    find available capacity on an alternative pipeline, the overall package 
    of services available may not be comparable to that it currently 
    receives from the applicant. For instance, no-notice service may not be 
    available from other pipelines (though a similar service may be 
    available from third parties). Under Order No. 636, interstate 
    pipelines that offered no-notice sales service prior to restructuring 
    were required to offer no-notice transportation service to their 
    existing sales customers at the time of unbundling. Pipelines had the 
    option of making no-notice service available to customers who were not 
    sales customers. Thus, while many interstate pipelines currently 
    provide no-notice service, they do not and are not required to offer 
    such service to new customers. Thus, comparable no-notice service may 
    not be available on other pipelines.
        Also, applicants may wish to demonstrate that intrastate pipelines 
    offer comparable firm transportation service. Transportation services 
    offered by intrastate pipelines under Section 311 of the NGPA are also 
    subject to open-access and non-discriminatory access standards as 
    interstate pipelines are under Order Nos. 436 and 636. Therefore, to 
    the extent that intrastate pipelines offer firm transportation service, 
    the Commission believes that such service could be offered under terms 
    and conditions that are substantially comparable to the firm 
    transportation services offered by open-access interstate pipelines. 
    However, intrastate pipelines are not required to offer firm 
    transportation services and currently only a few intrastate pipelines 
    offer such service. Thus, firm transportation may not be available on 
    intrastate pipelines. Where it is available, pipelines are free to 
    argue that firm intrastate transportation service is a comparable 
    alternative to services proposed for market-based rates.
        Applicants wishing to make a showing that interruptible 
    transportation services make good alternatives to the applicant's firm 
    services should demonstrate that an adequate amount of capacity is 
    unsubscribed during peak periods so that the quality of the IT service 
    is comparable to that of the applicant's FT service.
    2. The Geographic Market
        In addition, in defining the market, the Commission will look to 
    identify all the sellers of the product or service. The collection of 
    alternative sellers and the applicant constitutes the relevant 
    geographic market. Specifying the relevant product and geographic 
    market tells the Commission what alternatives the customer has if it 
    attempts to avoid a price increase imposed by an applicant. Geographic 
    market definition is particularly important in transportation markets. 
    Gas pipelines can transport gas out of a producing or origin region. 
    They also deliver gas into a consuming or destination region. The 
    Commission will identify both the origin and destination markets for 
    the relevant service. Only in that way can the Commission evaluate 
    whether there are good alternatives to the pipeline's service.
        The Commission expects that typical proposals will adopt a two-step 
    process of defining the geographic market. First, the applicant will 
    identify those alternative sellers who offer service between the same 
    origin and destination markets. Second, the applicant will identify 
    those competitors that provide service either out of the origin market 
    or into the destination market.
        a. Transportation Between Markets. The first stage of the analysis 
    identifies sellers offering transportation service over the same route. 
    Examining different sellers serving the same transportation link 
    simplifies the analysis. For instance, there is no need to consider 
    whether different producing areas offer ``good'' alternatives to each 
    other.
        To show that another pipeline provides a good direct alternative, 
    the applicant must show that customers could purchase the relevant 
    service from the alternative supplier. Such a demonstration will likely 
    include showing that capacity would be available on the alternative and 
    that the customer can obtain any services 
    
    [[Page 4639]]
    needed to use the competitor's facilities in both origin and 
    destination markets over the term of the service receiving market-based 
    rates.
        If a customer has a continuing obligation to take gas at a 
    particular receipt point, or to deliver gas to a specific delivery 
    point, beyond the term of its FT contract, competition from parallel 
    pipelines is particularly important in evaluating market power on a 
    pipeline seeking market-based FT rates. In these circumstances, the 
    applicant may have market power over the shipper even if both the 
    origin and destination markets are otherwise competitive. While the 
    shipper will have good alternatives to the applicant for getting to the 
    city-gate, it may not have good alternatives for getting gas from the 
    shipper's particular receipt point to its city-gate. It could of 
    course, sell its contract gas from that particular point on the spot 
    market in the production area and buy an equal amount of spot gas in an 
    area where it had good transportation alternatives. But the spot price 
    at which it sells might be lower than the spot price at which it buys, 
    causing extra expense and providing some opportunity for the applicant 
    pipeline to raise its price. Additionally, the shipper may value the 
    reliability of the contract gas and be concerned that it might not be 
    able to buy spot gas when it needs it.
        b. Transportation at Origin and Destination Markets. Parallel route 
    competition is not the only source of market discipline on gas 
    transporters. A shipper in the production area will typically have 
    alternative destination markets to which it could send gas. Similarly, 
    a downstream shipper will typically have a choice of several producing 
    areas from which to buy gas. Pipelines that provide such alternative 
    service may offer an additional check on the market power of a shipper.
        Natural gas transportation typically originates in the production 
    area. In the production area (or the mainline receipt point), the 
    applicant must identify the transportation alternatives available to 
    customers. Customers could include producers with gas supplies attached 
    at a receipt point, LDCs, and endusers with firm long-term supply 
    contracts. To define a particular region as an origin market, the 
    pipeline must identify all pipelines which compete with it to move gas 
    out of that area. As a general matter, to demonstrate that these other 
    pipelines are good alternatives (that is, are in the market) the 
    applicant must show that its producer/shippers are physically connected 
    to these other pipeline transporters. Alternatively, the applicant 
    could include an alternative pipeline in the market if it can connect 
    to the producer/shipper sufficiently cheaply that the producer/shipper 
    receives a netback 57 at least as large as it would receive if it 
    used the applicant's transportation service. The applicant must also 
    show that these transportation alternatives provide a netback to 
    producer/shippers roughly the same as they would receive if they used 
    the applicant's transportation. An alternative is not a good 
    alternative to a producer seeking to move gas out of the origin market 
    if the alternative is associated with a much higher cost than the 
    applicant's cost-based rates, in other words, it must give roughly the 
    same netback.
    
        \57\ The netback is the delivered price of gas less the 
    transportation costs paid by the producers. That is, the netback is 
    the net price received by the producer.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Koch Gateway argues that a good alternative does not necessarily 
    have to be physically connected to a pipeline. The Commission agrees. 
    Although typically an applicant will have to demonstrate that its 
    customers are physically connected to alternative gas transportation 
    facilities that move gas into the area, the Commission will allow 
    flexibility and permit applicants to argue that even if the customer is 
    not physically connected to the alternative, it can serve as good 
    alternatives to the proposed service.
        Applicants for market-based rates might allege that liquified 
    petroleum gas (LPG) and liquified natural gas (LNG) can be good 
    alternatives to the use of an applicant's transportation service. If 
    so, the applicant must show that there are sufficient quantities of 
    these available, and that LPG and LNG can be transported into the 
    destination market (e.g., by truck) at an overall delivered price that 
    is equal to or less than the overall delivered price the applicant 
    pipeline would charge to deliver natural gas. The prices considered 
    here must be within the pipeline's price increase threshold.
        Thus, in order to specify a gas transportation market, the 
    applicant must first identify all products and services available as 
    good alternatives to the applicant's customers. Next, the applicant 
    must identify the origin and destination of that transportation. The 
    relevant geographic market will be defined in two steps: first, those 
    alternative sellers that offer service between the same origin and 
    destination markets and second, all economically substitutable 
    transportation sold by pipelines (or other good alternative products 
    and services) serving either the origin market or the destination 
    market.
        Pipelines might be able to exercise market power if customers have 
    few good alternatives to the pipeline's service either, in the first 
    instance over a given route or, in a second analysis, separately in 
    origin and/or destination markets. The applicant might have market 
    power in the origin market if producer/shippers have few good 
    alternatives to transport their product out of the origin area. In the 
    destination market, pipelines might be able to exercise market power if 
    downstream customers have few good transportation alternatives that 
    reach their city-gates. If customers have long term supply contracts, 
    it will be particularly important for the pipeline to demonstrate that 
    it has no market power over customers on a given route.
    3. Firm Size and Market Concentration
        There are two ways in which a seller can exercise market power. It 
    can attempt to raise its price acting alone or it can attempt to raise 
    its price by acting together with other sellers.
        a. Acting Alone. One of the indicators that has been examined to 
    determine whether a seller could exercise market power acting alone is 
    the seller's market share. A large market share is generally a 
    necessary condition for the exercise of market power. If the seller has 
    a small market share it is unlikely that it can exercise market power. 
    But, a company with a large market share may not be able to exert 
    market power if entry into the market is easy 58 or there are 
    other competitive forces at work.
    
        \58\ Given the nature of the interstate pipeline industry, ease 
    of entry would be difficult to show except in cases involving minor 
    facilities. For major facilities, the cost of construction and the 
    time needed for environmental analysis and certification would 
    suggest that entry may not be easy.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The applicant must submit calculations (and supporting data) of its 
    market share in all relevant path or origin and destination areas.
        b. Acting Together with Other Sellers. A second way in which a 
    seller can exercise market power is to act together with other sellers 
    to raise prices. To evaluate whether a seller can act together with 
    others to exercise market power, the Commission typically has examined 
    the market's concentration.
        To measure market concentration, one generally considers the 
    summary measure of market concentration known as the Herfindahl-
    Hirschman Index (HHI). If the HHI is small then one can generally 
    conclude that sellers cannot exercise market power in this market. A 
    small HHI indicates that customers have sufficiently diverse sources of 
    supply in 
    
    [[Page 4640]]
    this market that no one firm or group of firms acting together could 
    profitably raise market price. If the HHI is higher then additional 
    analysis may be needed to determine if the seller can exercise market 
    power.
        The Commission will analysize the HHI calculation for the relevant 
    markets. The HHI will be evaluated for each relevant path and/or origin 
    market and each destination market utilizing the relevant data for each 
    mainline receipt point (origin market) and each delivery point 
    (destination market). If an applicant wishes to argue for either a 
    broader or narrower market definition, it should also include 
    calculations for its market definitions. Only sales or capacity figures 
    associated with good alternatives should be used in calculating the 
    HHI. In addition, applicants should aggregate the capacity of 
    affiliated companies into one estimate for those affiliates as a single 
    seller.59
    
        \59\ The capacity on pipeline systems owned or controlled by the 
    applicant's affiliates should not be considered among the customer's 
    alternatives. Rather, the capacity of an applicant's affiliates 
    offering the same product are to be included in the market share 
    calculated for the applicant. Similarly, alternative pipelines must 
    be aggregated with their respective affiliates in order to identify 
    meaningful alternatives to customers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In the gas inventory charge (GIC) cases, the Commission established 
    a threshold level for the HHI at .18.60 An HHI at this level 
    indicates that there are four to five good alternatives to the 
    applicant's service in each of the relevant markets. In an oil pipeline 
    case, the Commission used a slightly higher HHI of .25 as an initial 
    screen.61
    
        \60\ El Paso Natural Gas Company, 49 FERC para. 61,262 (1989). 
    See also Buckeye, 53 FERC at 62,667.
        \61\ See Williams Pipe Line Co., Opinion No. 391, 68 FERC para. 
    61,136 (1994).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several commenters suggested that the HHI should be raised. 
    Suggestions ranged from 0.25 to 0.35.62 Others argued that the 
    Commission should not adopt an arbitrary numerical threshold of 
    concentration but should do a thorough review of actual market 
    conditions on particular pipeline systems instead.63
    
        \62\ AGD, Cove Point, INGAA, Tejas, ANR/CIG, and Brooklyn Union.
        \63\ Brooklyn Union and KN Interstate.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission will not adopt a rigid brightline threshold level 
    for the HHI, below which an applicant would automatically qualify for 
    market-based rates, or above which an applicant would be excluded from 
    market-based rates. Rather, the Commission will use 0.18 HHI as an 
    indicator of the level of scrutiny to be given to the applicant. If the 
    HHI is above 0.18, the Commission will give the applicant closer 
    scrutiny because the index indicates that the market is more 
    concentrated and the applicant may have significant market power. An 
    HHI below 0.18 would result in less scrutiny of the applicant's 
    potential to exercise significant market power because it would 
    indicate that the market is less concentrated.
        The Commission is primarily concerned about whether an individual 
    applicant seller (including affiliates) can exercise market power. The 
    HHI will be one of the factors that the Commission will evaluate. 
    However, market shares and HHIs alone do not give a comprehensive view 
    of all important factors. The impact of other competitive factors on 
    the Commission's analysis of market-based rate proposals is discussed 
    below.
    4. Entry and Other Competitive Factors
        Even if the applicant's market share were large in a concentrated 
    (and properly identified) market, one still might not conclude that the 
    applicant would be able to exercise market power. For example, if the 
    applicant increased its price, entry into the market might be so easy 
    that sellers attracted by the profit opportunity created by the higher 
    price would quickly take customers away from the applicant by offering 
    a lower price. This would make the applicant's price increase 
    unprofitable. Thus, the applicant would not be able to exercise market 
    power, despite its large market share and despite the high market 
    concentration.64 Ease of entry is one of several competitive 
    factors that might lead to the conclusion that an applicant lacks 
    market power. It is most likely to apply to circumstances that do not 
    require the large sunk costs of major construction--for instance, 
    perhaps in offering short-haul market center services.
    
        \64\ As stated before, entry would probably only be relevant for 
    gas pipelines in the case of minor facilities such as facilities 
    that could be constructed under a blanket certificate.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Another competitive factor that might be established by an 
    applicant would be the presence of buyer power. An applicant might 
    argue that if a single buyer is a large customer of the pipeline, is 
    knowledgeable and sophisticated in its buying, and has been in business 
    for a lengthy period of time, the buyer may have the knowledge and 
    large-scale purchasing power to negotiate reasonable rates even in a 
    concentrated market. However, just because buyers develop sophisticated 
    purchasing systems and market knowledge as the result of dealing with 
    various suppliers in numerous markets, there still is reason to have 
    some skepticism that a buyer in a single destination area served by one 
    or a few pipelines will have such capabilities.
        The Commission will evaluate whether sufficient quantities of good 
    alternatives are available to the applicant's customers to make a price 
    increase unprofitable. In other words, are customers able to replace a 
    significant proportion of their throughput with other transportation 
    alternatives if the applicant were to raise its price?
        There may be cases where an applicant has completed its own 
    analysis of its market-based rate proposal using the criteria stated 
    above and concludes that it cannot, under existing circumstances, 
    establish that it lacks market power with respect to its proposed 
    service. Yet, the company may be able to identify certain conditions or 
    changes that it could implement to mitigate the effects of market power 
    and make market-based rates a viable option. In such cases, the 
    Commission would be willing to evaluate proposals for any conditions or 
    changes that the applicant would propose as mitigation for its 
    potential exercise of market power.
        For example, a pipeline might suggest that the Commission permit 
    market-based rates for pipeline segments, such as for new laterals for 
    new service. In order to mitigate its market power and thereby make 
    itself eligible for market-based rates for service provided on that 
    lateral, the applicant might propose to refrain voluntarily from 
    allocating costs attributtable to the lateral to its other, cost-of-
    service based services. The applicant might also voluntarily agree to 
    an open tap policy for services provided on the lateral. Under such a 
    policy the applicant (in return for getting permission from the 
    Commission to charge market-based rates) would agree to allow any 
    entity to interconnect with its facilities. Such an open tap policy 
    would help protect against withholding capacity by undersizing or 
    overpricing the new lateral. The interconnection would be for the 
    purpose of producing potential competitive suppliers to the services 
    for which the applicant seeks market-based rates. Thus, the 
    interconnection could be (depending on what the applicant is proposing) 
    for a lateral, a loop, an extension, or any other facilities that could 
    compete with the applicant's market-based services.
        Applicants proposing such conditions or changes should state so 
    specifically in their proposals.
    
    D. Filing Procedures
    
        The Request for Comments asked whether the Commission should 
    continue its current policy of using declaratory orders for ruling on 
    market-
    
    [[Page 4641]]
    based rate proposals, or if some other procedural avenue was more 
    appropriate. Several commenters support continuing the current practice 
    of issuing declaratory orders.65 Others suggest that full 
    evidentiary hearings are required in at least some, if not all, 
    cases.66 However, the majority support a case-by-case review of 
    proposals with the Commission issuing an order on the proposal as 
    appropriate.67
    
        \65\ NI-Gas, SoCalGas, Columbia, KN Interstate, Koch Gateway, 
    PEC Pipeline Group, Florida, and Transok.
        \66\ Petrochemical Energy Group, APGA, Northern Distributors, 
    Wisconsin Distributors, Indicated Shippers, NGSA, Illinois, and Ohio 
    CC.
        \67\ Fuel Managers, Industrial Gas Consumers, CINergy Gas 
    Companies, Columbia Distribution, Northern Distributors, Northern 
    Indiana, SoCalGas, UDC, ANR/CIG, CNG, Koch Gateway, NorAm, PEC 
    Pipeline Group, Williston Basin, Texaco, and Ohio CC.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission will continue its current policy of using 
    declaratory orders to rule on requests for market-based rates on a 
    case-by-case basis. In cases where a certificate of public convenience 
    and necessity is required, the review will occur as part of the 
    certificate process.
        Applying the criteria stated in the sections above, applications 
    for market-based rates should contain the following information: (1) A 
    detailed description of the service(s) proposed for market-based rate 
    treatment; (2) a statement defining the relevant product and geographic 
    markets necessary for establishing that the applicant lacks market 
    power with respect to the particular service(s) at issue. Such 
    statement should state the relevant time period for comparing services 
    within the product and geographic markets; an analysis describing how 
    the prices for relevant alternative services compare to the relevant 
    price increase threshold; and a detailed description of good 
    alternatives to the proposed service(s); (3) market share and HHI 
    calculations; and (4) discussion of other relevant competitive factors 
    and their import. In addition, pipelines should include in each 
    application a proposal for accounting for the costs and revenues 
    resulting from the proposed service. An application should be 
    sufficient to establish on its own, without further inquiry or support, 
    that the proposed service or services meet the criteria for market-
    based rates presented in this policy statement.
        Applications for market-based rates will be noticed in the Federal 
    Register. Interested parties will have an opportunity to intervene in 
    the proceeding and to present a response to the proposal. The 
    Commission will consider the information provided in the application, 
    any information provided by intervenors in response thereto, and will 
    take any intermediate steps, including issuing data requests or 
    convening a technical conference, that may be necessary to complete its 
    evaluation of the proposal. The Commission will either conduct a paper 
    hearing, based upon the initial filing and responses thereto, or set 
    the matter for a formal evidentiary hearing before an administrative 
    law judge, as appropriate. Upon completing its evaluation, the 
    Commission will issue a declaratory order ruling whether the service 
    meets the requirements of market-based rates. If the service meets the 
    standards then the applicant can make the appropriate tariff filing 
    necessary to set its market-based rates into effect. Commission 
    approval of market-based rate proposals will be prospective only, thus 
    eliminating concerns regarding refund liability. The Commission's 
    determinations in these circumstances will be based upon the facts 
    presented in the proposal. Accordingly, the Commission may reconsider 
    its ruling should the circumstances on the pipeline change such that 
    market-based rates are no longer appropriate.
    
    IV. Policy on Incentive Rates
    
        In circumstances where market-based rates are not appropriate, the 
    Commission will continue cost-based rate regulation. In October 1992, 
    the Commission issued a Policy Statement on Incentive Regulation to 
    allow companies that have market power nevertheless to receive some of 
    the benefits of greater flexibility and efficiency that are associated 
    with market-based rates.68 Incentive rate proposals, while cost-
    based, are intended to result in better service options at lower rates 
    for consumers while providing regulated companies with the opportunity 
    to earn higher returns. Incentive regulation is not intended for 
    competitive markets. It is intended for markets where the continued 
    existence of market power prevents the Commission from implementing 
    light-handed regulation without harm to consumers. The Commission 
    continues to believe that incentive rate mechanisms have potential to 
    benefit both natural gas companies and consumers by fostering an 
    environment where regulated companies that retain market power can 
    achieve greater efficiency and cost-effectiveness.
    
        \68\ Policy Statement on Incentive Regulation, 61 FERC para. 
    61,168 (1992).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In the Policy Statement, the Commission explained that incentive 
    regulation differs from traditional regulation in that it fosters long-
    term efficiency. It accomplishes this by: (1) divorcing rates from the 
    underlying cost-of-service, (2) lengthening the period between rate 
    cases; and (3) sharing the benefits of cost savings between consumers 
    and stockholders on a current basis. The Commission set out five 
    criteria that incentive rate proposals must meet to gain Commission 
    approval. Under the policy adopted in 1992, proposals for incentive 
    rate programs must: (1) Be prospective; (2) be voluntary; (3) contain 
    incentive mechanisms that are understandable to all parties; (4) result 
    in quantified benefits to consumers; and (5) demonstrate how they 
    maintain or enhance incentives to improve the quality of service. Each 
    of these criteria were discussed at length in the Policy Statement. 
    After articulating the criteria to be utilized in evaluating proposals 
    for incentive rate proposals, the Commission invited companies to 
    submit such proposals for consideration.
        Since the issuance of the Policy Statement, the Commission has not 
    received any requests for approval of incentive rate proposals. For 
    this reason, and in light of the changes in the natural gas market that 
    have occurred as a result of the implementation of Order No. 636, the 
    Commission decided to revisit the issue of incentive rates for pipeline 
    services. Therefore, in the Request for Comments, the Commission sought 
    responses to specific questions regarding its incentive rate Policy 
    Statement. These questions included: (a) why there have not been any 
    incentive proposals under the policy established in Docket No. PL92-1-
    000; (b) whether the Commission should change its existing standards 
    for incentive rate proposals; (c) if so, what specific criteria the 
    Commission should employ when evaluating incentive rates; (d) whether 
    there are models for incentive regulation that the Commission should 
    consider, such as the California performance-based program; (e) what 
    the benefits and drawbacks of incentive rates are, and what policy 
    objectives the Commission should pursue with an incentive rate method; 
    and (f) whether incentive ratemaking is appropriate for the natural gas 
    companies regulated by the Commission.
        Many of those responding to questions regarding the Commission's 
    current standards for evaluating incentive rate proposals favor 
    changing the current standards. Specifically, the majority of those 
    pipelines that 
    
    [[Page 4642]]
    responded encourage a change in the standards away from ``quantifying'' 
    benefits to customers and eliminating the cost-of-service cap on 
    incentive rates.69 Commenters also encourage elimination of the 
    requirement that rates under incentive programs could be no higher than 
    they would have been under traditional cost-of-service 
    regulation.70
    
        \69\ WINGS, NorAm, Williston Basin, Alberta, ANR/CIG, Columbia, 
    Enron and INGAA.
        \70\ INGAA, WINGS, Enron, and NorAm.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission has reviewed the comments and re-evaluated its 
    existing policy in light of current conditions in the natural gas 
    industry. Based on these comments, the Commission recognizes that it is 
    problematic to compare incentive-based rates with existing cost-of-
    service rates or with what rates would have been under cost-of-service 
    pricing after incentive-based regulation is implemented. Comparisons of 
    incentive-based rates with previous cost-based rates compare service 
    and rates in different time periods.
        Moreover, the ability of pipelines to profit from cost reductions 
    remains a key ingredient of most incentive-based options. Imbedded in 
    the typical incentive-based proposal is the expectation that, over 
    time, this ability to profit will drive industry costs down and 
    therefore lead to rates that are lower than they would have been under 
    traditional cost-based regulation. In consideration of all of these 
    points, the Commission believes it is appropriate to modify its 
    existing policy.
        In reply to the Request for Comments, INGAA, six pipelines, and the 
    Alberta Regulatory Commission suggested elimination of the requirement 
    to quantify benefits. Also, five pipelines specifically recommended 
    that the Commission eliminate the requirement that rates under 
    incentive regulation be no higher than they would have been under 
    traditional cost-of-service regulation. The Commission agrees with 
    these recommendations. Although both quantifiable benefits and 
    comparisons shall remain two of the goals of any incentive rate 
    program, these requirements are eliminated from the Commission's stated 
    criteria for evaluating incentive rate proposals. Instead of requiring 
    firms to quantify the benefits of any performance-based proposal, the 
    Commission will require pipelines proposing such programs to share with 
    their ratepayers the efficiency gains of the program. Any pipeline 
    proposal must explicitly specify the performance standards it defines, 
    the mechanism for sharing benefits with customers, and a method for 
    evaluating the proposal. Pipeline companies are invited to submit 
    proposals that fulfill these requirements as well as the three other 
    criteria articulated in our prior Policy Statement.
        Commenters also encouraged the Commission to require participation 
    in any proposed incentive rate program continue for a prescribed period 
    of time, such as four or five years. Commenters argue that this will 
    prevent individual pipelines from moving in and out of incentive rate 
    programs in an attempt to game the system.
        The current policy states that the fact that incentive regulation 
    is voluntary,
    
    does not mean that utilities should be completely free to abandon 
    their programs should their profits decline. Such a policy could 
    encourage inefficient investments in risky cost-cutting innovations, 
    and it would be unfair to consumers. Instead, programs may include 
    conditions under which utilities could opt out after an initial 
    commitment.71
    
        \71\ Policy Statement, 61 FERC at 61,589.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission later stated that the exact period of time between 
    rate reviews under incentive rate programs would be decided on a case-
    by-case basis.72
    
        \72\ Id., at 61,603.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission is not inclined to prescribe in this policy 
    statement a length of time during which performance-based rate 
    proposals must be operative. The particulars of any one program are 
    likely to be so company specific as to make such a requirement 
    impractical. Nevertheless, the Commission is no less committed to the 
    requirement that pipelines agree to operate under such programs for a 
    specified period than it was at the time of the original policy 
    statement. Therefore, the Commission clarifies that approval of an 
    incentive rate program proposal will require a commitment by the 
    pipeline that it will continue in the program for a specified length of 
    time as appropriate for the particular pipeline system at issue. 
    Proponents of such proposals should suggest a desired duration for 
    operation under any proposed incentive plan along with arguments 
    supporting the proposal.
        The Commission will consider on a timely basis incentive rate 
    proposals filed under the revised criteria. Such proposals may take a 
    variety of forms.73 The considerable state regulatory activity in 
    developing performance and incentive-based ratemaking mechanisms 
    attests to the vitality of such approaches. Incentive rates may be 
    usefully developed by pipelines and their customers as a means of 
    reaching long-term accord on some of the difficult issues now 
    confronting the industry. Alternative dispute resolution may also play 
    an important role in achieving agreement on system-wide incentive 
    rates, and the Commission supports such efforts.
    
        \73\ Incentive Regulation for Natural Gas Pipelines: A Specific 
    Proposal with Options, OEP Technical Report 89-1, September 1989; 
    Incentive Regulation: A Research Report, OEP Technical Report 89-3, 
    November 1989.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission is setting forth a policy for market-based rates 
    today. The incentive rates policy is still emerging. The Commission 
    encourages pipelines to file new incentive or performance-based rate 
    proposals and concepts for Commission consideration.
    
    V. Negotiated/Recourse Rates and Terms of Service
    
    A. The Proposals
    
        Where pipelines do not attempt to establish a lack of market power 
    and do not want to undertake an incentive rate program, there are yet 
    other alternatives to traditional cost-of-service regulation that could 
    be used. In the Request for Comments, the Commission sought comment on 
    other ratemaking methods that would better serve the goal of flexible, 
    efficient pricing in today's environment. Included in the Commission's 
    request were ``backstop proposals, where pipelines would be free to 
    negotiate rates and terms of service, so long as customers could always 
    choose service under traditional cost-of-service rates and terms of 
    service.''74
    
        \74\ 70 FERC at 61,394.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In its initial comments INGAA proposes negotiated rates and terms 
    for service as an option. Under INGAA's plan, the Commission would 
    dispense with cost-of-service regulation for an individual shipper when 
    mutually agreed upon by the pipeline and a shipper and permit 
    negotiated rates and terms and conditions of service that could vary 
    from the pipeline's otherwise applicable tariff. A recourse service 
    that is on file in the pipeline's tariff would always be available for 
    those shippers preferring traditional cost-of-service rates and 
    services.
        As originally proposed by INGAA, the recourse rate would escalate 
    the recourse rate based on a pipeline industry index, less a one 
    percent productivity factor. INGAA proposed that the Commission modify 
    its current incentive policy statement to eliminate the cost-of-service 
    cap and the quantifiable benefits test. Subsequently, INGAA changed its 
    proposal to make the index component voluntary and optional. INGAA 
    claims the recourse rate, which would be established 
    
    [[Page 4643]]
    initially through a Section 4 rate case, would be lower than a cost-
    based rate, over time, through the workings of the productivity 
    adjustment. While INGAA provided a detailed discussion of its indexing 
    proposal, initially few details were provided on the scope of 
    negotiated rates and terms and conditions.
        Brooklyn Union and PSE&G also endorsed negotiated rates backstopped 
    by a recourse rate in their initial comments. Both parties emphasized 
    the recourse rate would be for traditional tariff service priced on a 
    cost-of-service basis and protected from adverse rate or operational 
    impact from the individually customized services.
    
    B. Comments on INGAA's Proposal
    
        In response to INGAA's proposal, AGD, Brooklyn Union, and UGI, 
    while generally supporting negotiated/recourse rates, object to INGAA's 
    proposal to index the recourse rate. These parties ask the Commission 
    to allow negotiated/recourse rates as soon as possible without 
    complicating matters by tying the negotiated/recourse rate concept to 
    incentive rates. AGD and UGI also express concerns that recourse rate 
    payers should be protected from cost shifting or degradation of their 
    service resulting from negotiated rates.
        NGSA and IPAA oppose INGAA's negotiated rate proposal contending it 
    would allow the pipeline to use its market power to discriminate among 
    its customers by providing additional service benefits to some 
    customers and denying them to others. Further, they argue that, if the 
    negotiated service agreements were not filed with the Commission, it 
    would be difficult to obtain the necessary facts to support a 
    discrimination complaint.
        AGD, Brooklyn Union, and NGSA/IPAA object that INGAA's incentive 
    rate proposal does not provide for a sharing of efficiency gains. NGSA 
    and IPAA support the Commission's current incentive rate policy 
    statement requiring quantification of consumer benefits.
        In a September 25, 1995 filing, INGAA clarified its proposal to 
    emphasize that it would be voluntary, there would be no cost shifting, 
    and it would be up to individual pipelines whether to propose indexing 
    of the recourse rate. INGAA also suggested that pipelines would file a 
    form of notice for negotiated rates, similar to transportation discount 
    reports, identifying the customer, the negotiated rate or formula, the 
    recourse rate, and contract quantity and duration. According to INGAA, 
    the Commission would resolve complaints about discrimination, undue 
    affiliate preference, or deleterious effects on other services. In a 
    November 7, 1995 filing, INGAA further clarified its proposal stating 
    that SFV is not affected because its proposal leaves any existing SFV 
    rate design in place.75 INGAA adds that the Commission's scrutiny 
    of costs and allocation plans during the rate cases that will establish 
    recourse rates will assure that these rates do not contain unapproved 
    cross subsidies. INGAA asserts that competition will provide the 
    necessary quality assurance and that the recourse rate will be on file 
    with the Commission and will thereby meet the NGA's filing requirement. 
    INGAA contends that its proposal calls for filing information on the 
    negotiated transactions, similar to the data required by Order No. 581 
    for discount rates and that required for the index of customers, after 
    the negotiations are concluded. In this way INGAA asserts that the 
    negotiated/recourse rates can comply with the requirements of the NGA 
    while meeting the need of certain customers to keep key data in the 
    negotiated rate proprietary to protect their competitive positions.
    
        \75\ A just and reasonable recourse rate would be derived using 
    traditional cost-of-service rate methodologies including SFV.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In response to INGAA's November 7 filing, NGSA argues that it would 
    be inappropriate for any action to be taken on ``recourse rates'' by 
    the Commission in this docket without providing other parties an 
    opportunity to examine and comment fully on INGAA's new proposal. NGSA 
    states that INGAA's proposals raise serious questions as to whether 
    they would achieve the essential goals of bringing greater efficiency 
    and competition to the interstate natural gas transportation industry 
    while protecting all customers from the exercise of market power, undue 
    discrimination, and cross subsidization. NGSA states that INGAA's 
    proposal is lacking in critical details and therefore requires 
    additional study and comment.76
    
        \76\ On January 23, 1996, NGSA further supplemented its response 
    and clarified the goals it believes alternative rate proposals must 
    meet to be successful.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A group of industrial end-user trade associations77 also 
    responded to INGAA's November 7 filing. The Industrials urge the 
    Commission to reject INGAA's negotiated/recourse rate proposal. The 
    Industrials criticize INGAA's proposal suggesting it would lead to 
    market-based rates in a market lacking workable competition, and would 
    result in ``severe damage to the objectives of Order No. 636 and the 
    overall policy of developing an integrated transportation grid''. The 
    Industrials strongly support SFV rates as key to a robust secondary 
    market and fear that negotiation of non-SFV rates will lead to a hodge-
    podge of individual rates and services, encourage LDC's to hoard 
    capacity, and ultimately impede producers and end-users from accessing 
    interstate capacity.
    
        \77\ The Petrochemical Energy Group, Process Gas Consumers and 
    the Georgia Industrial Group, Chemical Manufacturers Association, 
    American Iron and Steel Institute, American Forest & Paper 
    Association, Council of Industrial Boiler Owners, Praxair Inc., and 
    the California Manufacturers Association (``The Industrials'').
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    C. Discussion of Negotiated/Recourse Rates and Services
    
        The Commission believes that negotiated/recourse service programs 
    could be a viable way of achieving flexible, efficient pricing when 
    market-based rates are not appropriate. Negotiating different rates and 
    service terms for individual shippers could result in wide flexibility 
    in service offerings including individually tailored seasonal service 
    and rates, short-term services, or special rates for more flexible 
    terms and conditions. Greater rate flexibility has previously been tied 
    to a showing that a pipeline lacks market power. Under this method, 
    however, the availability of a recourse service would prevent pipelines 
    from exercising market power by assuring that the customer can fall 
    back to cost-based, traditional service if the pipeline unilaterally 
    demands excessive prices or withholds service. Thus, the recourse rate 
    mitigates market power. At a minimum, negotiated/recourse services 
    offer the potential for increased market responsiveness in pipeline 
    services without protracted disputes regarding market power.
        Although the proposal as presented by INGAA and others has many 
    attractive features, it raised a number of concerns as well. The first 
    issue of concern involves associating negotiated/recourse proposals 
    with incentive/performance-based programs. As stated previously, 
    INGAA's original proposal called for recourse rates to be indexed. The 
    Commission is concerned that choosing an appropriate index will be 
    extremely problematic. Questions regarding whether it is appropriate to 
    index recourse rates and what, if anything, would be an appropriate 
    index to use must be addressed prior to a pipeline implementing such a 
    proposal.
        Another concern involves situations where the availability of the 
    recourse service alone is not sufficient to mitigate a pipeline's 
    exercise of market power. In its response to INGAA's initial proposal, 
    NGSA expressed its concern that the 
    
    [[Page 4644]]
    availability of customized terms and conditions would be at the sole 
    discretion of the pipeline. The pipeline would thus be in a position to 
    discriminate among its customers in providing enhanced service 
    flexibility, argues NGSA, favoring affiliates or customers who, for 
    whatever reason, were able to obtain a negotiated deal with the 
    pipeline. NGSA's concerns will be further considered in the separate 
    proceeding discussed below. The Commission is also concerned about the 
    extent to which the concept of negotiated terms and conditions of 
    service is compatible with the requirements, goals and objectives of 
    Order No. 636. Specifically, what effect, if any, negotiated terms of 
    service are likely to have on: capacity release; flexible receipt and 
    delivery points; the use of secondary receipt and delivery points; and 
    no-notice transportation service. For example, if a pipeline agrees to 
    provide a shipper priority of service at certain points, or additional 
    flexibility in exchange for a higher rate, what effect would this have 
    on other shippers served under the recourse service?
        The Commission is particularly concerned about maintaining the 
    integrity of the recourse service. In order to be successful, the 
    recourse service must remain a viable alternative to negotiated 
    service. Otherwise, if the recourse service remains stagnant, in time, 
    the recourse service will become outmoded and will cease to be a viable 
    alternative to negotiated service. Since the purpose of the recourse 
    service is to act as a check against pipeline market power, such a 
    result is impermissible. Therefore, some means may be needed to ensure 
    the continued viability of the recourse service. The Commission is 
    concerned about how this would be accomplished and whether any specific 
    conditions concerning recourse services are needed.
        Since open access transportation began, the Commission has required 
    flexibility in terms and conditions to be offered on a non-
    discriminatory basis uniformly to all shippers under a given rate 
    schedule. When competitive pressure forces a pipeline to liberalize its 
    tariff to satisfy a few shippers, the tariff is amended and all 
    shippers enjoy the benefits. To date the Commission has not permitted 
    narrow classification of customer groups. If the Commission permitted 
    the negotiation of terms of service pipelines would be able to offer 
    special flexibility to selected customers. In that case, what 
    standards, if any, would the Commission use to determine what 
    constitutes undue discrimination? Likewise, are explicit new 
    restrictions needed to prevent pipelines from tying access to a 
    negotiated premium service to the use of the pipeline's other services 
    as well as new restrictions from granting affiliate preferences 
    necessary?
        Finally, the Commission is concerned that negotiated/recourse 
    proposals meet the requirements of Section 4 of the NGA. To satisfy the 
    requirement in the NGA that rates, terms and conditions of service must 
    be on file with the Commission, some form of filing the negotiated rate 
    and terms of service will be necessary.
    
    D. Proposals for Negotiated/Recourse Services
    
        As stated previously, negotiated/recourse programs may serve to add 
    flexibility and efficiency to pipeline services in cases where a 
    company does not apply for market-based rates for its services and does 
    not wish to pursue incentive rate programs. For this reason, the 
    Commission is willing to entertain, on a shipper-by-shipper basis, 
    requests to implement negotiated rates where customers retain the 
    ability to choose a cost-of-service based tariff rate. The Commission 
    already permits individualized rates under its rate discount policies. 
    In allowing the further negotiation of rates, the Commission is 
    confident that there are a number of mechanisms available to permit 
    this added flexibility while ensuring that inappropriate cost shifting 
    does not take place.
        Requests to implement negotiated rates may be made for new or 
    existing contracts. Companies making such requests must use their 
    existing Commission approved tariff rates applicable to the service as 
    their recourse rate unless they are filing a new rate case 
    simultaneously. The recourse rate will be available for existing 
    capacity holders that do not negotiate a rate with the pipeline, 
    thereby ensuring that existing customers will always have a cost-of-
    service based rate available for capacity they have under contract. 
    Specifically, this policy statement does not change the right of first 
    refusal requirements in section 284.221(d)(2)(ii) that the highest rate 
    that an existing shipper must match if it wishes to continue its 
    transportation arrangement is the maximum recourse rate established in 
    the pipeline's tariff.
        A question arises when capacity is constrained. The predicate for 
    permitting a pipeline to charge a negotiated rate is that capacity is 
    available at the recourse rate. For purposes of allocating capacity, 
    shippers willing to pay more than the maximum recourse rate would be 
    considered to have paid the maximum recourse rate. Therefore, a shipper 
    willing to pay only the recourse rate cannot lose access to capacity 
    merely because someone else is willing to pay a negotiated rate. When 
    there are more requests for capacity than there is capacity available, 
    then the pipeline must allocate capacity among those shippers willing 
    to pay either the negotiated rate or the maximum recourse rate, for 
    example on a pro rata basis if required by its tariff.78 This pro 
    rata allocation would also apply to situations where the pipeline must 
    allocate limited capacity for such services as interruptible 
    transportation.
    
        \78\ If a pipeline has 100 dth of available capacity and there 
    are two shippers who request that capacity, one is willing to pay no 
    more than the recourse rate of $5.00/dth and another a negotiated 
    rate of $6.00/dth, then each would be allocated 50 dth on a pro rata 
    basis.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Because pipeline tariffs state that the pipeline will charge a rate 
    between the maximums and minimums stated on the rate sheets, pipelines 
    will need to file conforming tariff sheets indicating that the rate for 
    the service will be either the rates stated on its existing rate 
    schedule or a rate mutually agreed upon by the pipeline and its 
    customer. When a rate is negotiated, the pipeline will need to file a 
    numbered tariff rate sheet stating the exact legal name of the customer 
    and the negotiated rate for the service. A pipeline may make the 
    conforming change to its tariff to indicate that the rate may be a 
    negotiated rate, either at the time it requests to put a particular 
    negotiated rate into effect or at some earlier time. In addition, 
    pipelines should also include along with the conforming tariff change, 
    a proposal for accounting for the costs and revenues resulting from the 
    proposed service.
        A pipeline may file the numbered tariff sheet implementing the 
    negotiated rate at the time it intends the rate to go into effect. The 
    Commission does not intend to suspend the effectiveness of negotiated 
    rate filings or impose a refund obligation for those rates. For these 
    reasons, the Commission will readily grant requests to waive the 30 day 
    notice requirement. Issues regarding the appropriate allocation of 
    costs between recourse rate shippers and negotiated rate shippers will 
    be addressed fully in the pipeline's Section 4 rate cases.79 At 
    that time, the Commission will consider issues 
    
    [[Page 4645]]
    relating to cross-subsidization and interested parties will be able to 
    raise any concerns they may have regarding the proper allocation of 
    costs. Therefore, the Commission does not intend to review a pipeline's 
    negotiated rates at the time filed. However, customers that wish to 
    argue that they are similarly situated with a customer receiving a 
    negotiated rate and that a pipeline has been unduly discriminatory may 
    file a complaint with the Commission at any time. The Commission will 
    use its authority under Section 5 to investigate the complaint and, if 
    a remedy is appropriate, will order a prospective rate change.
    
        \79\ The Commission recognizes that not all pipelines currently 
    have a requirement to file a Section 4 rate case. For those 
    pipelines that elect to charge negotiated rates and are not required 
    to file a Section 4 rate case, the Commission may consider, on its 
    own motion or on complaint by a recourse shipper, using its Section 
    5 authority to investigate whether the pipeline's recourse rates 
    remain a viable cost-based alternative to negotiated rates.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Pipelines are reminded that, pursuant to Sections 284.8(b) and 
    284.9(b), they are expected to negotiate rates with their customers in 
    a manner that is not unduly discriminatory and that treats similarly 
    situated shippers similarly. In addition, customers electing the 
    recourse rate should be no worse off as a result of the use of 
    negotiated rates than they would be absent the use of negotiated rates. 
    Pipelines offering negotiated rates will have the burden of justifying 
    revenue projections from negotiated services if the pipeline's method 
    of achieving such projections deviate from traditional methods. In 
    other words, recourse rate shippers should not bear the responsibility 
    of unsubscribed capacity alone and pipelines should continue to market 
    all unsubscribed capacity.
        The Commission believes that a pipeline's negotiation of individual 
    rates with shippers should not affect the way a pipeline accounts for 
    the recovery of transition costs. For example, the Commission specified 
    in Natural Gas Pipeline Company of America80 that pipelines treat 
    transition costs as the last item discounted. One of the main purposes 
    of this policy was to ensure that transition costs are spread as evenly 
    as possible among all the pipeline's customers and to reduce the 
    shifting of costs to the pipeline's captive customers. Consistent with 
    this policy, if a pipeline negotiates a rate with a customer that does 
    not include transition costs, the pipeline will be at risk for the 
    collection of those costs and cannot reallocate them to its recourse 
    rate shippers.
    
        \80\ 69 FERC para. 61,029 (1994), order on reh'g, 70 FERC para. 
    61,317 (1995).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Currently, pipelines' maximum tariff rates are subject to a variety 
    of surcharges, in addition to those that relate to transition costs, 
    e.g., ACA, operational Account No. 858, and GRI.81 The Commission 
    expects that pipelines' recovery and treatment of these costs will not 
    change for shippers under negotiated rate contracts. As is currently 
    the case, pipelines who negotiate to provide services at less than the 
    maximum tariff rate will be subject to the same Commission policies, 
    such as the Natural policy on the attribution of discounting. The 
    Commission expects that, to the extent pipelines wish to deviate from 
    these existing policies, they will be willing to accept the risk of 
    underrecovery of these costs.
    
        \81\ GRI's funding mechanism for 1996 and 1997 is designed to 
    collect 50 percent of GRI's Commission-approved budget through 
    reservation surcharges and 50 percent through the volumetric 
    surcharge. 71 FERC para. 61,130 (1995). Negotiated rates could 
    change the mix of reservation/usage billing units. GRI has expressed 
    concerns that pipelines may not recover full GRI revenue levels or 
    pipelines may leave GRI if market-based or negotiated rates are 
    implemented.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Because of the number of issues remaining concerning whether 
    negotiation of terms and conditions of service is appropriate, the 
    Commission is not willing to permit the negotiation of individual 
    shipper customized terms of service at this time. Commission 
    willingness to entertain requests for negotiated rates expands on the 
    flexibility in rates already permitted by the Commission with 
    discounting. In allowing further negotiation of rates, the Commission 
    is confident that there are a number of mechanisms to ensure that 
    inappropriate cost shifting does not take place. However, further 
    discussion with the industry of all the ramifications of negotiated 
    terms of service is needed.
        Therefore, the Commission is establishing a separate proceeding in 
    which it will consider this issue and is inviting interested 
    participants to file comments on the issues raised above, as well as 
    any other issue that should be considered before permitting pipelines 
    to negotiate terms of service with individual shippers. Participants 
    interested in commenting on these issues should submit their written 
    comments in Docket No. RM96-7-000 within 60 days of the date of this 
    order.
    
        By the Commission.
    Lois D. Cashell,
    Secretary.
    
    Appendix
    
    Commenters
    
    Alberta Department of Energy (Alberta)
    American Gas Association (AGA)
    American Forest and Paper Association (AF&PA)
    American Public Gas Association (APGA)
    Amoco Energy Trading Corporation and Amoco Production Company (Amoco)
    ANR Pipeline Company and Colorado Interstate Gas Company (ANR/CIG)
    Associated Gas Distributors (AGD)
    Atlanta Gas Light Company and Chattanooga Gas Company (Atlanta Gas 
    Light)
    Brooklyn Union Gas Company (Brooklyn Union)
    Cascade Natural Gas Corporation, Northwest Natural Gas Company, 
    Washington Natural Gas Company and Washington Water Power Company 
    (Pacific Northwest Commenters)
    Cincinnati Gas & Electric Company, Union Light, Heat and Power Company 
    and Lawrenceburg Gas Company (CINergy Gas Companies)
    Cities of Lenox, et al. (Lenox)
    Columbia Gas Transmission Corporation and Columbia Gulf Transmission 
    Company (Columbia)
    Columbia Gas Distribution Companies (Columbia Distribution)
    Connecticut Natural Gas Corporation (Connecticut Natural)
    Consolidated Edison Company of New York, Inc. (Con Edison)
    Consolidated Natural Gas Company (CNG)
    Cove Point LNG Limited Partnership (Cove Point)
    Enron Interstate Pipelines (Enron)
    Fertilizer Institute
    Florida Public Service Commission (Florida)
    Fuel Managers Association (Fuel Managers)
    Gas Research Institute (GRI)
    Hadson Gas Systems, Inc. (Hadson)
    Illinois Commerce Commission (Illinois)
    Independent Oil & Gas Association of West Virginia (IOGA)
    Independent Petroleum Association of Mountain States (IPAMS)
    Indicated Shippers
    Industrial Gas Consumers (IGC)
    Interstate Natural Gas Association of America (INGAA)
    KN Interstate Natural Gas Transmission Company (KN Interstate)
    Koch Gateway Pipeline Company (Koch Gateway)
    Natural Gas Supply Association (NGSA)
    NorAm Gas Transmission Company (NorAm)
    Northeast Energy Associates and North Jersey Energy Associates (Energy 
    Associates)
    Northern Distributor Group (Northern Distributors)
    Northern Illinois Gas Company (NI-Gas)
    Northern Indiana Public Service Company (Northern Indiana)
    Northwest Industrial Gas Users (NWIGU)
    Office of the Ohio Consumers' Counsel (Ohio CC)
    Pacific Gas and Electric Company1
    
        \1\ Filed but had no comments. 
        
    [[Page 4646]]
    
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Pacific Gas Transmission Company (PGT)
    Pennsylvania Office of Consumer Advocate (Pa OCA)
    Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission (PaPUC)
    Petrochemical Energy Group (PEG)
    Public Service Commission of the State of New York (New York)
    Public Service Electric and Gas Company (PSE&G)
    Public Utilities Commission of Ohio (Ohio PUC)
    Public Utilities Commission of the State of California\1\
    Southern California Edison Company (SoCal Edison)
    Southern California Gas Company (SoCalGas)
    Tejas Power Corporation (Tejas)
    Texaco Natural Gas Inc. (Texaco)
    Texas Eastern Transmission Corporation, Panhandle Eastern Pipe Line 
    Company, Trunkline Gas Company and Algonquin Gas Transmission Company 
    (PEC Pipeline Group)
    Transok, Inc. (Transok)
    UGI Utilities, Inc.
    United Distribution Companies (UDC)
    Williams Interstate Natural Gas System (WINGS)
    Williston Basin Interstate Pipeline Company (Williston Basin)
    Wisconsin Distributor Group (Wisconsin Distributors)
    
    [FR Doc. 96-2547 Filed 2-6-96; 8:45 am]
    BILLING CODE 6717-01-P
    
    

Document Information

Published:
02/07/1996
Department:
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
Entry Type:
Notice
Document Number:
96-2547
Pages:
4633-4646 (14 pages)
Docket Numbers:
Docket Nos. RM95-6-000 and RM96-7-000
PDF File:
96-2547.pdf