97-5767. Promoting Wholesale Competition Through Open Access Non- Discriminatory Transmission Services by Public Utilities; Recovery of Stranded Costs by Public Utilities and Transmitting Utilities  

  • [Federal Register Volume 62, Number 50 (Friday, March 14, 1997)]
    [Rules and Regulations]
    [Pages 12274-12484]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 97-5767]
    
    
    
    [[Page 12273]]
    
    _______________________________________________________________________
    
    Part II
    
    
    
    
    
    Department of Energy
    
    
    
    
    
    _______________________________________________________________________
    
    
    
    Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
    
    
    
    _______________________________________________________________________
    
    
    
    18 CFR Parts 35 and 37
    
    
    
    Open Access Non-Discriminatory Transmission Services Provided by Public 
    Utilities; Wholesale Competition Promotion; Stranded Costs Recovery by 
    Public and Transmitting Utilities; Final Rule
    
    
    
    Open Access Same-Time Information System and Standards of Conduct; 
    Final Rule
    
    Federal Register / Vol. 62, No. 50 / Friday, March 14, 1997 / Rules 
    and Regulations
    
    [[Page 12274]]
    
    
    
    DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
    
    Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
    
    18 CFR Part 35
    
    [Docket Nos. RM95-8-001 and RM94-7-002; Order No. 888-A]
    
    
    Promoting Wholesale Competition Through Open Access Non-
    Discriminatory Transmission Services by Public Utilities; Recovery of 
    Stranded Costs by Public Utilities and Transmitting Utilities
    
    Issued March 4, 1997.
    AGENCY: Federal Energy Regulatory Commission.
    
    ACTION: Final rule; order on rehearing.
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    SUMMARY: The Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (Commission) 
    reaffirms its basic determinations in Order No. 888 and clarifies 
    certain terms. Order No. 888 requires all public utilities that own, 
    control or operate facilities used for transmitting electric energy in 
    interstate commerce to have on file open access non-discriminatory 
    transmission tariffs that contain minimum terms and conditions of non-
    discriminatory service. Order No. 888 also permits public utilities and 
    transmitting utilities to seek recovery of legitimate, prudent and 
    verifiable stranded costs associated with providing open access and 
    Federal Power Act section 211 transmission services. The Commission's 
    goal is to remove impediments to competition in the wholesale bulk 
    power marketplace and to bring more efficient, lower cost power to the 
    Nation's electricity consumers.
    
    EFFECTIVE DATE: This rule is effective on May 13, 1997.
    
    FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
    
    David D. Withnell (Legal Information--Docket No. RM95-8-001), Office of 
    the General Counsel, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First 
    Street, N.E., Washington, D.C. 20426, (202) 208-2063
    Deborah B. Leahy (Legal Information--Docket No. RM94-7-002), Office of 
    the General Counsel, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First 
    Street, N.E., Washington, D.C. 20426, (202) 208-2039
    Dan T. Hedberg (Technical Information--Docket No. RM95-8-001), Office 
    of Electric Power Regulation, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 
    First Street, N.E., Washington, D.C. 20426, (202) 208-0243
    Joseph M. Power (Technical Information--Docket No. RM94-7-002), Office 
    of Electric Power Regulation, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 
    First Street, N.E., Washington, D.C. 20426, (202) 208-1242
    
    SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: In addition to publishing the full text of 
    this document in the Federal Register, the Commission also provides all 
    interested persons an opportunity to inspect or copy the contents of 
    this document during normal business hours in the Public Reference Room 
    at 888 First Street, N.E., Washington, D.C. 20426.
        The Commission Issuance Posting System (CIPS), an electronic 
    bulletin board service, provides access to the texts of formal 
    documents issued by the Commission. CIPS is available at no charge to 
    the user and may be accessed using a personal computer with a modem by 
    dialing 202-208-1397 if dialing locally or 1-800-856-3920 if dialing 
    long distance. To access CIPS, set your communications software to 
    19200, 14400, 12000, 9600, 7200, 4800, 2400, or 1200 bps, full duplex, 
    no parity, 8 data bits and 1 stop bit. The full text of this order will 
    be available on CIPS in ASCII and WordPerfect 5.1 format. CIPS user 
    assistance is available at 202-208-2474.
        CIPS is also available through the Fed World system. Telnet 
    software is required. To access CIPS via the Internet, point your 
    browser to the URL address: http://www.fedworld.gov and select the ``Go 
    to the FedWorld Telnet Site'' button. When your Telnet software 
    connects you, log onto the FedWorld system, scroll down and select 
    FedWorld by typing: 1 and at the command line then typing: /go FERC. 
    FedWorld may also be accessed by Telnet at the address fedworld.gov.
        Finally, the complete text on diskette in Wordperfect format may be 
    purchased from the Commission's copy contractor, La Dorn Systems 
    Corporation. La Dorn Systems Corporation is also located in the Public 
    Reference Room at 888 First Street, N.E., Washington, D.C. 20426.
    I. Introduction and Summary
    II. Public Reporting Burden
    III. Background
    IV. Discussion
        A. Scope of the Rule
        1. Introduction
        2. Functional Unbundling
        3. Market-based Rates
        a. Market-based Rates for New Generation
        b. Market-based Rates for Existing Generation
        4. Merger Policy
        5. Contract Reform
        6. Flow-based Contracting and Pricing
        B. Legal Authority
        C. Comparability
        1. Eligibility to Receive Non-discriminatory Open Access 
    Transmission
        a. Unbundled Retail Transmission and ``Sham Wholesale 
    Transactions''
        b. Transmission Providers Taking Service Under Their Tariff
        2. Service that Must be Provided by Transmission Provider
        3. Who Must Provide Non-discriminatory Open Access Transmission
        4. Reservation of Transmission Capacity by Transmission 
    Customers
        5. Reservation of Transmission Capacity for Future Use by 
    Utility
        6. Capacity Reassignment
        7. Information Provided to Transmission Customers
        8. Consequences of Functional Unbundling
        a. Distribution Function
        b. Retail Transmission Service
        c. Transmission Provider
        1. Taking Service Under the Tariff
        2. Accounting Treatment
        D. Ancillary Services
        1. Specific Ancillary Services
        a. Scheduling, System Control and Dispatch Service
        b. Reactive Supply and Voltage Control from Generation Sources 
    Service
        c. Energy Imbalance Service
        (1) Description of Energy Imbalance
        (2) Energy Imbalance Bandwidth
        2. Ancillary Services Obligations
        a. Obligation of a Control Area Utility
        b. Obligation to Provide Dynamic Scheduling
        c. Obligation As Agent
        3. Miscellaneous Ancillary Services Issues
        a. Transmission Provider as Ancillary Services Merchant
        b. QF Receipt of Ancillary Services
        c. Pricing of Ancillary Services
        E. Real-Time Information Networks
        F. Coordination Arrangements: Power Pools, Public Utility 
    Holding Companies, Bilateral Coordination Arrangements, and 
    Independent System Operators . . . 179
        1. Tight Power Pools
        2. Loose Pools
        3. Public Utility Holding Companies
        4. Bilateral Coordination Arrangements
        G. Pro Forma Tariff
        1. Tariff Provisions That Affect The Pricing Mechanism
        a. Non-Price Terms and Conditions
        b. Network and Point-to-Point Customers' Uses of the System (so 
    called ``Headroom'')
        c. Load Ratio Sharing Allocation Mechanism for Network Service
        (1) Multiple Control Area Network
        Customers
        (2) Twelve Monthly Coincident Peak v. Annual System Peak
        (3) Load and Generation ``Behind the Meter''
        (4) Existing Transmission Arrangements associated with 
    Generating Capacity Entitlements (e.g., ``preference power'' 
    customers of PMAs)
        d. Annual System Peak Pricing for Flexible Point-to-Point 
    Service
        e. Opportunity Cost Pricing
    
    [[Page 12275]]
    
        (1) Recovery of Opportunity Costs
        (2) Redispatch Costs
        f. Expansion Costs
        g. Credit for Customers' Transmission Facilities
        h. Ceiling Rate for Non-firm Point-to-Point Service
        i. Discounts
        j. Other Pricing Related Issues Not Specifically Addressed in 
    the Final Rule
        (1) Demand Charge Credits
        (2) In-Kind Transactions
        2. Priority For Obtaining Service
        a. Reservation Priority for Existing Firm Service Customers
        b. Reservation Priority for Firm Point-to-Point and Network 
    Service
        c. Reservation Priorities for Non-firm Service
        3. Curtailment and Interruption Provisions
        a. Pro-rata Curtailment Provisions
        b. Curtailment and Interruption Provisions for Non-firm Service
        4. Reciprocity Provision
        5. Liability and Indemnification
        6. Umbrella Service Agreements
        7. Other Tariff Provisions
        a. Minimum and Maximum Service Periods
        b. Amount of Designated Network Resources
        c. Eligibility Requirements
        d. Two-Year Notice of Termination Provision
        e. Termination of Service for Failure to Pay Bill
        f. Definition of Native Load Customers
        g. Off-System Sales
        h. Requirements Agreements
        i. Use of Distribution Facilities
        j. Losses
        k. Modification of Non-rate Terms and Conditions
        l. Miscellaneous Tariff Modifications
        (1) Ancillary Services
        (2) Clarification of Accounting Issues
        (a) Transmission Provider's Use of Its System (Charging 
    Yourself)
        (b) Facilities and System Impact Studies
        (c) Ancillary Services
        (3) Miscellaneous Clarifications
        (a) Electronic Format
        (b) Administrative Changes
        8. Specific Tariff Provisions
        9. Miscellaneous Tariff Administrative Changes
        10. Pro Forma Tariff Compliance Filings
        H. Implementation
        1. Group 1 Public Utilities
        2. Group 2 Public Utilities
        3. Clarification Regarding Terms and Conditions Reflecting 
    Regional Practices
        4. Future Filings
        5. Waiver
        I. Federal and State Jurisdiction: Transmission/Local 
    Distribution
        J. Stranded Costs
        1. Justification for Allowing Recovery of Stranded Costs
        2. Cajun Electric Power Cooperative, Inc. v. FERC
        3. Responsibility for Wholesale Stranded Costs (Whether to Adopt 
    Direct Assignment to Departing Customers)
        4. Recovery of Stranded Costs Associated With New Wholesale 
    Requirements Contracts
        5. Recovery of Stranded Costs Associated With Existing Wholesale 
    Requirements Contracts
        6. Recovery of Stranded Costs Caused by Retail-Turned-Wholesale 
    Customers
        7. Recovery of Stranded Costs Caused by Retail Wheeling
        8. Evidentiary Demonstration Necessary--Reasonable Expectation 
    Standard
        9. Calculation of Recoverable Stranded Costs
        10. Stranded Costs in the Context of Voluntary Restructuring
        11. Accounting Treatment for Stranded Costs
        12. Definitions, Application, and Summary
        K. Other
        1. Information Reporting Requirements for Public Utilities
        2. Small Utilities
        3. Regional Transmission Groups
        4. Pacific Northwest
        5. Power Marketing Agencies
        a. Bonneville Power Administration (BPA)
        b. Other Power Marketing Agencies
        6. Tennessee Valley Authority
        7. Hydroelectric Power
        8. Residential Customers
        9. Miscellaneous Issues
        V. Environmental Statement
        A. The Appropriate No-Action Alternative
        B. Challenges to Modeling Assumptions
        1. Appropriate Base Case
        2. Challenge to the Use of Computer Modeling
        3. Transmission Assumptions
        4. Plant Availabilities and Heat Rates
        5. Reserve Margins
        6. Northeast MOU
        7. Natural Gas Prices
        8. Expanded Transmission Analysis
        C. Mitigation
        D. Emissions Standards Disparity
        E. Short-Term Consequences of the Rule
        G. Cost Benefit Analysis
        H. Socioeconomic Impacts
        I. Coastal Zone Management Act
        VI. Regulatory Flexibility Act Certification
        A. Docket No. RM95-8-000 (Open Access Final Rule)
        1. Public Utilities
        2. Non-Public Utilities
        B. Docket No. RM94-7-000 (Stranded Cost Final Rule)
        1. Public Utilities
        2. Non-Public Utilities
        VII. Information Collection Statement
        VIII.Effective Date
        Regulatory Text
        Appendix A--List of Petitioners
        Appendix B--Pro Forma Open Access Transmission Tariff
        Statement of Commissioner Hoecker
        Statement of Commissioner Massey
        I. Introduction and Summary
        On April 24, 1996, the Commission issued Final Rules (Order Nos. 
    888 and 889) intended to remedy undue discrimination in the 
    provision of interstate transmission services by public utilities 
    and to address the stranded costs that may result from the 
    transition to more competitive electricity markets.1 At the 
    heart of these rules is a requirement that prohibits owners and 
    operators of monopoly transmission facilities from denying 
    transmission access, or offering only inferior access, to other 
    power suppliers in order to favor the monopolists' own generation 
    and increase monopoly profits--at the expense of the nation's 
    electricity consumers and the economy as a whole.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \1\ Promoting Wholesale Competition Through Open Access Non-
    discriminatory Transmission Services by Public Utilities and 
    Recovery of Stranded Costs by Public Utilities and Transmitting 
    Utilities, Order No. 888, 61 FR 21,540 (May 10, 1996), FERC Stats. & 
    Regs. para. 31,036, clarified, 76 FERC para. 61,009 and 76 FERC 
    para. 61,347 (1996). Order No. 889 is an accompanying rule and 
    specific rehearing arguments on that rule will be addressed 
    separately.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The electric utility industry today is not the industry of ten 
    years ago, or even five years ago. While historically it was assumed 
    that local utilities would be the only ones to generate and transmit 
    power for their customers, today there is a broad array of potential 
    competitors to supply power and widespread transmission facilities that 
    can carry power vast distances. But competitors cannot reach customers 
    if they cannot have fair access to the transmission wires necessary to 
    reach those customers. It is against this industry backdrop that the 
    Commission in Order No. 888 exercised its public interest 
    responsibilities pursuant to sections 205 and 206 of the Federal Power 
    Act (FPA), to reexamine undue discrimination in interstate transmission 
    services and the effect of that discrimination on the electricity 
    customers whom we are bound to protect under the FPA.
        We here reaffirm the legal and policy bases on which Order No. 888 
    is grounded. Utility practices that were acceptable in past years, if 
    permitted to continue, will smother the fledgling competition in 
    electricity markets and undermine the national policies reflected in 
    the Energy Policy Act of 1992 to encourage the development of 
    competitive markets. We firmly believe that our authorities under the 
    FPA not only permit us to adapt to changing economic realities in the 
    electric industry, but also require us to do so, as necessary to 
    eliminate undue discrimination and protect electricity customers. The 
    record supports our conclusion that, absent open access, undue 
    discrimination will continue to be a fact of life in today's and 
    tomorrow's electric power markets. As recent events clearly 
    demonstrate, unbundled electric transmission service will be the 
    centerpiece of a freely traded commodity market in electricity in which 
    wholesale customers can shop for competitively-priced power.
    
    [[Page 12276]]
    
        The only way to effectuate competitive markets and remedy 
    discrimination is through readily available, non-discriminatory 
    transmission access. The Commission estimates the potential 
    quantitative benefits from such access will be approximately $3.8 to 
    $5.4 billion per year in cost savings, in addition to the non-
    quantifiable benefits that include better use of existing assets and 
    institutions, new market mechanisms, technical innovation, and less 
    rate distortion.
        Order No. 888 has two central components. The first requires all 
    public utilities that own, operate or control interstate transmission 
    facilities to offer network and point-to-point transmission services 
    (and ancillary services) to all eligible buyers and sellers in 
    wholesale bulk power markets, and to take transmission service for 
    their own uses under the same rates, terms and conditions offered to 
    others. In other words, it requires non-discriminatory (comparable) 
    treatment for all eligible users of the monopolists' transmission 
    facilities. The non-discriminatory services required by Order No. 888, 
    known as open access services, are reflected in a pro forma open access 
    tariff contained in the Rule. The Rule also requires functional 
    separation of the utilities' transmission and power marketing functions 
    (also referred to as functional unbundling) and the adoption of an 
    electric transmission system information network.
        The second central component of Order No. 888 was to address 
    whether and how utilities will be able to recover costs that could 
    become stranded when wholesale customers use the open access tariffs, 
    or FPA section 211 tariffs, 2 to leave their utilities' power 
    supply systems and shop for power elsewhere. Because of competitive 
    changes occurring at the retail level, as numerous states have begun 
    retail transmission access programs, Order No. 888 also clarifies 
    whether and when the Commission may address stranded costs caused by 
    retail wheeling and the extent of the Commission's jurisdiction over 
    unbundled retail transmission. The Commission further addresses the 
    circumstances under which utilities and their wholesale customers may 
    seek to modify contracts made under the old regulatory regime, taking 
    into account the goals of reasonably accelerating customers' ability to 
    benefit from competitively priced power and at the same time ensuring 
    the financial stability of electric utilities during the transition to 
    competition.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \2\ Under section 211 of the FPA, the Commission, on a case-by-
    case basis upon application by an eligible customer, may order both 
    public utilities and non-public utilities that own or operate 
    transmission facilities used for the sale of electric energy at 
    wholesale to provide transmission services to the applicant if it 
    finds it is in the public interest to issue such order.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        137 entities filed requests for rehearing and/or clarification of 
    Order No. 888. While these parties raise a variety of arguments--
    including legal, policy, and technical arguments--the majority 
    (including a majority of public utilities) agree that we need to 
    harness the benefits that competitive electricity markets can bring to 
    the nation. The disagreements primarily focus on the mechanics of how 
    we should do this, who should pay the costs of the transition to 
    competition, and how long the transition should take.
        First, parties disagree on what is necessary to remedy undue 
    discrimination and to develop truly competitive wholesale markets. Many 
    focus specifically on the tariff terms and conditions of good 
    transmission access and seek changes in the Order No. 888 pro forma 
    tariff. In response to these types of rehearing arguments, the 
    Commission has fine-tuned or changed some of the pro forma tariff terms 
    and conditions to better ensure that they do not permit discrimination 
    and that they result in well-functioning markets. Other petitioners 
    focus on additional structural changes which they believe are 
    necessary, such as mandatory corporate restructuring (divestiture of 
    generation assets) or mandatory creation of independent transmission 
    system operators (ISOs). With regard to restructuring, the Commission 
    continues to believe that functional unbundling of the utility's 
    business, not corporate divestiture or mandatory ISOs, is sufficient to 
    remedy undue discrimination at this time.
        The most contentious arguments raised on rehearing involve how we 
    deal with the transition costs associated with moving to competition. 
    Some utilities have invested millions of dollars in facilities and 
    purchased power contracts based on an explicit or implicit obligation 
    to serve customers and the expectation that those customers would 
    remain on their systems for the foreseeable future. These utilities 
    face so-called ``stranded costs'' which, if not recovered from the 
    customers that caused the costs to be incurred, could be shifted to 
    other customers.
        There are two basic categories of rehearing arguments regarding 
    stranded cost recovery. Most utilities want a guarantee from this 
    Commission that they will recover all stranded costs, whether caused by 
    losing retail customers or wholesale customers. Many customers, on the 
    other hand, want to be able to abrogate existing power supply contracts 
    so that they can immediately leave their current suppliers' systems and 
    shop for cheaper power elsewhere, without paying the sunk costs that 
    their suppliers incurred on their behalf.
        In response to these diverse arguments, the Commission has struck a 
    reasonable balance that, for certain defined circumstances, permits 
    utilities the opportunity to seek extra-contractual recovery of 
    stranded costs from their departing customers and permits customers the 
    opportunity to make a showing that their contracts should be shortened 
    or terminated. Based on our experience in the natural gas area, we have 
    learned that it is critical to address these issues early, but we also 
    have chosen an approach different from that taken in the gas area 
    because of the different circumstances facing the electric industry.
        In balancing the wide array of interests reflected in the rehearing 
    petitions, we have made a number of clarifications and granted 
    rehearing on some issues, but we reaffirm the core elements and 
    framework of Order No. 888. Since the time the final rules issued, as 
    discussed in Section III, the pace of competitive change has continued 
    to escalate in the industry at both the wholesale and retail levels as 
    competitors, customers and state regulatory authorities aggressively 
    seek ways to lower the price of electricity. We therefore believe it is 
    all the more critical that we remedy undue discrimination in interstate 
    transmission services now, and that we do so generically, if we are to 
    fulfill our responsibilities under the FPA to protect consumers and 
    provide a fair and orderly transition to new competitive markets.
        Finally, with respect to environmental issues associated with this 
    rulemaking, certain parties on rehearing continue to challenge the 
    adequacy of our Final Environmental Impact Statement (FEIS). The 
    central issues are whether the Final Rule will increase emissions of 
    nitrogen oxides (NOx) from certain fossil-fuel fired generators, which 
    could affect air quality in downwind areas to which these emissions may 
    be carried, and the Commission's authority to mitigate environmental 
    consequences.
        We deny rehearing on the environmental issues raised and affirm our 
    conclusion that we have satisfied our obligations under NEPA. As 
    discussed in detail in the Final Rule, this rulemaking is expected to 
    slightly increase or slightly decrease total future
    
    [[Page 12277]]
    
    NOx emissions, depending on whether competitive conditions in the 
    electric industry favor the utilization of natural gas or coal as a 
    fuel for the generation of electricity. We also examined mitigation 
    options over the longer term, and found that the preferred approach for 
    mitigating any adverse environmental consequences would be for the 
    Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) and the states to address the 
    problem through regulatory authorities available under the Clean Air 
    Act. The petitions for rehearing have not persuaded us to change this 
    approach. Indeed, we note that since the issuance of Order No. 888, the 
    EPA has concluded that the Rule is unlikely to have any immediate 
    significant adverse environmental impact and thus concurred that the 
    Commission's analysis is adequate under NEPA. We further note that EPA 
    has recently taken steps under the Clean Air Act to address NOx 
    emissions as part of a comprehensive emissions control program, along 
    the lines endorsed by the Commission in the EIS.
        In summary, the Commission believes that our authorities under the 
    FPA not only permit us to adapt to changing economic realities in the 
    electric industry, but also require us to do so to eliminate undue 
    discrimination and protect electricity customers. The measures required 
    in Order No. 888 are necessary to remedy undue discrimination in 
    interstate transmission services and provide an orderly and fair 
    transition to competitive bulk power markets.
        To assist the reader, we provide below a section-by-section summary 
    of key elements of this Order on Rehearing.
    
    Scope of the Rule
    
        In this section we discuss petitions to rehear our requirement that 
    transmission and power sales services be contracted for separately 
    (unbundled). We reaffirm that this requirement is a reasonable and 
    workable means of assuring non-discriminatory open access transmission. 
    In doing so we refuse invitations to require that utilities under our 
    jurisdiction divest themselves of generation or transmission assets. We 
    do, however, make an important clarification involving how we will deal 
    with existing contracts that contain so-called Mobile-Sierra clauses 
    (clauses under which one or both parties agreed not to seek 
    modification of contract terms unless they could show that it is 
    contrary to the public interest not to permit the modification).
        In Order No. 888 we concluded that contracts would not be abrogated 
    by operation of the Rule. Instead, preexisting contracts would continue 
    to be honored until such time as they were revised or terminated. We 
    also found that those who were operating under pre-existing 
    requirements contracts containing Mobile-Sierra clauses would 
    nonetheless be allowed to seek reform of the contracts on a case-by-
    case basis. On rehearing we affirm that public utilities will be 
    allowed to file to amend their Mobile-Sierra contracts for the limited 
    purpose of providing an opportunity to seek recovery of stranded costs, 
    without having to make a public interest showing that such cost 
    recovery should be permitted. However, these utilities will have the 
    burden, on a case-by-case basis, of showing that they had a reasonable 
    expectation of continuing to serve the departing customer after the 
    contract term. We clarify that if the utilities under such contracts 
    seek to modify provisions that do not relate to stranded costs, they 
    will have the burden of showing that the provisions are contrary to the 
    public interest.
        We here make clear that, in turn, customers will be allowed to file 
    to amend their Mobile-Sierra contracts to modify any contract term or 
    to terminate the contract, without having to make a showing that the 
    contract terms are contrary to the public interest. Instead, customers 
    seeking modifications must demonstrate that the provisions they wish 
    modified are no longer ``just and reasonable.'' We reaffirm our 
    conclusion in the Final Rule that if a customer seeks to shorten or 
    eliminate the term of its contract, however, any contract modification 
    approved by the Commission will provide for appropriate stranded cost 
    recovery by the customer's supplying utility.
        These various provisions meet the two-fold need to deal with 
    stranded costs and the contracts under which those costs were incurred. 
    However, as described in Order No. 888, the opportunity to reform 
    Mobile-Sierra contracts extends only to a limited set of contracts--
    those entered into on or before July 11, 1994, for requirements power.
    
    Comparability
    
        In this section we deal with those requesting rehearing of our 
    conclusions regarding what ``comparable'' service is, who is eligible 
    for that service, and how it is to be implemented. We reaffirm our 
    finding that, as a matter of law, we have jurisdiction over the rates, 
    terms and conditions of unbundled transmission service provided to 
    retail customers. We also clarify that we have authority to order 
    ``indirect'' unbundled retail transmission services and that if such 
    transmission is ordered by us in the future, or if it is provided 
    voluntarily, otherwise eligible customers may obtain such service under 
    the open access tariff. We expect public utilities to provide such 
    service in the future and, if they do not, we will not hesitate to 
    order it.
        We modify in two respects the definition of who is eligible for 
    open access transmission service. First, we clarify that, with respect 
    to service that this Commission is prohibited from ordering by section 
    212(h) of the Federal Power Act (retail wheeling directly to an 
    ultimate consumer and ``sham'' wholesale wheeling), entities are 
    eligible for such service under the tariff only if it is provided 
    pursuant to a state requirement or is provided voluntarily. Second, we 
    clarify that retail customers taking unbundled service pursuant to a 
    state requirement (i.e., direct retail service) are eligible for such 
    service only from those transmission providers that the state orders to 
    provide service. These changes are made to make clear that our rules 
    cannot be used to circumvent the proscriptions placed on the Commission 
    against ordering direct retail wheeling.
    
    Ancillary Services
    
        In this section we deal with petitions to rehear our definitions of 
    ancillary services--those services such as scheduling, voltage control, 
    and supplemental reserve service that must or can attend the providing 
    of transmission service--as well as the provisions involving these 
    services. We reaffirm that tariffs must separately state the charges 
    for these services. We do modify some of the definitions of these 
    services to conform to industry needs and practices. Most importantly, 
    we make clear that the transmission provider's sale of ancillary 
    services associated with providing basic transmission service is not a 
    wholesale merchant function and thus does not violate the standards of 
    conduct imposed with Order No. 889.
    
    Coordination Arrangements
    
        The requirement to provide non-discriminatory open access 
    transmission applies to any agreement between utilities that contains 
    transmission rates, terms or conditions. This includes pooling 
    arrangements and agreements between companies contracting to provide 
    each other mutually beneficial transmission services. In Order No. 888 
    we laid out rules under which the open access comparability 
    requirements would apply to tight and loose power pools, public utility 
    holding companies and bilateral coordination agreements.
    
    [[Page 12278]]
    
    We also set out principles that would govern our approval of 
    independent system operator (ISO) agreements.
        In this section we affirm the rules governing coordination 
    agreements. In doing so we clarify the definition of ``loose pool.'' We 
    also make clear that, unlike in other situations where we require 
    utilities to provide not only the services they provide themselves but 
    those they could provide themselves, we will require members of loose 
    pools to offer to third parties only those transmission services that 
    they provide themselves under their pool-wide agreements.
        We also reaffirm our strong commitment to the concept of ISOs and 
    the ISO principles described in Order No. 888. In doing so we reject 
    arguments that we should require that ISOs be formed. At the same time, 
    we emphasize that while there is no ``cookie-cutter'' approach to 
    forming an acceptable ISO, the requirement of fair and non-
    discriminatory rules of governance (Principle One) and the requirement 
    that ISO employees have no financial interest in the economic interests 
    of power marketers--backed by strict conflict of interest provisions--
    (Principle Two) are fundamental to our approving any ISO.
    
    Pro Forma Tariff Provisions
    
        The pro forma tariff is the basic mechanism implementing the 
    requirements of comparable open access transmission. It provides the 
    details of the transmission service obligations imposed on 
    jurisdictional utilities by the Rule. On rehearing we affirm most of 
    the provisions set out in Order No. 888 for the pro forma tariff. We do 
    make changes to conform the pro forma tariff to changes adopted under 
    other sections (for example, the definition of ``eligible customer'').
        The rehearing petitions raised many questions about how particular 
    aspects of the tariff will work. For the most part, these questions 
    cannot be answered generically, but must be resolved on a case-by-case 
    basis in the context of specific fact situations. However, the 
    petitions brought to light issues that require clarifications and in 
    some cases revisions to the tariff. The most significant of these 
    involve discounting practices, provisions governing priority of service 
    and curtailment, and the reciprocity provision.
        Discounting practices. Originally, we provided different rules 
    depending upon whether the transmission provider was offering a 
    discount to itself or an affiliate or offering a discount to a non-
    affiliate. In response to the rehearing petitions, we are making three 
    significant changes to the discounting requirements to better permit 
    the ready identification of discriminatory discounting practices while 
    also providing greater discount flexibility.
        First, any discount offered on transmission services (including 
    supporting ancillary services) by a transmission provider or requested 
    by any customer must now be made only over the OASIS. With this change, 
    all will have the same, timely access to discounted services. In making 
    this change, we clarify that a transmission provider may limit its 
    discounted service to particular time periods.
        Second, once the provider and customer agree on a discount, the 
    details of the discounted service--the price, points of receipt and 
    delivery, and length of service--must be immediately posted on the 
    OASIS.
        Third, we revise our Rule respecting what other transmission paths 
    must be offered at a discount. Originally, in Order No. 888, we 
    required that when a discount was offered over one path, the 
    transmission provider would have to provide that discount over all 
    other unconstrained paths on its system. We will no longer require 
    this. Instead, the discount will be limited to those unconstrained 
    paths that go to the same point(s) of delivery as the discounted 
    service being provided on the transmission provider's system. The 
    discount will extend for the same time period and must be offered to 
    all transmission service customers.
        Priority and Curtailment. We affirm the right of first refusal 
    policy that reservation priority continues for firm service customers 
    served under a contract of one year or more. We also affirm that 
    curtailment must be made on a pro-rata basis and clarify that non-firm 
    point-to-point service is subordinate to firm service. However, we 
    clarify that the pro-rata curtailment requirement extends to only those 
    transactions that alleviate the constraint.
        Reciprocity. In Order No. 888 we conditioned the use of a public 
    utility's open access service on the agreement that, in return, it is 
    offered reciprocal service by non-public utilities that own or control 
    transmission facilities. Such reciprocal service does not have to be 
    through an open access tariff, i.e., a tariff available to all eligible 
    customers, but may be limited to those public utilities from whom the 
    non-public utility obtains open access service. We affirm the 
    reciprocity condition. In doing so, however, we make several 
    clarifications.
        First, a public utility is free to offer transmission service to a 
    non-public utility without requiring reciprocal service in return. In 
    other words, it may voluntarily waive the reciprocity condition. 
    However, if it chooses to do so, transmission service must be provided 
    through the pro forma tariff. Alternatively, bilateral agreements for 
    transmission service provided by the public utility will not be 
    permitted.
        Second, we clarify that under the reciprocity condition a non-
    public utility must agree to offer the Transmission Provider any 
    transmission service the non-public utility provides or is capable of 
    providing on its system. This means that the non-public utility 
    undertaking reciprocity must have an OASIS and must operate under the 
    standards of conduct imposed under Order No. 889 unless it is granted a 
    waiver by the Commission or, where appropriate, by a regional 
    transmission group (RTG) of which it is a member. We also clarify that 
    a non-public utility cannot avoid its responsibilities by obtaining 
    transmission service through other transmission customers. Further, the 
    seller as well as the buyer in the chain of a transaction involving a 
    non-public utility will have to comply with the reciprocity condition.
        Third, we adhere to our decision not to treat generation and 
    transmission (G&T) cooperatives and their member distribution 
    cooperatives as a single unit. Thus, the reciprocity provision extends 
    to the G&T Cooperative and not to its member distribution cooperatives.
        Fourth, we clarify the ``safe harbor'' provision under which a non-
    public utility may get a Commission decision that its transmission 
    tariff suffices to meet reciprocity. A non-public utility may limit the 
    use of any reciprocity tariff that it voluntarily files at the 
    Commission to those transmission providers from whom the non-public 
    utility obtains open access service. A non-public utility also may 
    satisfy reciprocity through bilateral agreements with a public utility. 
    As a related matter, if a public utility believes a non-public utility 
    is violating the reciprocity condition, it may file with the Commission 
    a petition to terminate its service to the non-public utility.
        Fifth, we clarify that non-public utilities may include stranded 
    cost provisions in their reciprocity tariffs.
        Sixth, the order on rehearing removes the term ``interstate'' from 
    the reciprocity provisions. This is to make clear that reciprocity 
    applies even to those who do not own or control interstate transmission 
    facilities; i.e., foreign utilities and those located in the ERCOT 
    region of Texas.
        As to local furnishing bonds held by some public utilities, we 
    clarify that all costs associated with the loss of tax-
    
    [[Page 12279]]
    
    exempt status of those bonds caused by providing open access 
    transmission service are properly considered costs of providing that 
    service. This includes costs of defeasing, redeeming, and refinancing 
    those bonds.
        Other Clarifications. In this order on rehearing we take the 
    opportunity to clarify various other tariff provisions. Among these: 
    Transmission providers do not have to take service under the open 
    access tariff for transmitting power purchased on behalf of their 
    bundled retail customers. Also, the ability to reserve capacity to meet 
    the reliability needs of a transmission provider's native load applies 
    equally to present transmission and transmission that is built in the 
    future.
    
    Implementation
    
        On rehearing, we make no substantive changes to the implementation 
    provisions originally required under Order No. 888. For the most part, 
    the implementation process has been completed. Utilities have made the 
    requisite tariff and compliance filings and public and non-public 
    utilities have, through other orders, been provided guidance as to 
    obtaining waivers of Order No. 888 and Order No. 889 requirements.
        We emphasize that we do not require the abrogation of existing 
    contracts. Rather, the Rule requires only that transmission providers 
    offer transmission under the open access tariff in addition to existing 
    service obligations. Commitments made under existing contracts will 
    continue. Of course, both transmission providers and their customers 
    may seek to revise the terms and conditions of existing contracts by 
    making the necessary filings, as appropriate, under Sections 205 or 206 
    of the Federal Power Act.
    
    State and Federal Jurisdiction
    
        On rehearing we reaffirm our decision that when transmission 
    service is provided to serve retail customers apart from any contract 
    for the retail sale of power, i.e., when it is provided on an unbundled 
    basis, that transmission service is under our jurisdiction. In today's 
    market, and increasingly in the future as more states adopt retail 
    wheeling programs, retail transactions are, and will be, broken down 
    into products that are sold separately--transmission and generation--
    and sold by different entities. The exercise of our jurisdiction over 
    the rates, terms and conditions of unbundled retail transmission will, 
    therefore, become more important. We also recognize that states have 
    jurisdiction over facilities used for local distribution.
        On rehearing we also reaffirm the seven-factor test of Order No. 
    888 to distinguish transmission under our jurisdiction from state-
    jurisdictional local distribution. In doing so, we recognize that our 
    test does not resolve all possible issues. There may be other factors 
    that should be taken into account. The test, therefore, is designed for 
    flexibility to include unique local characteristics and usages. To that 
    end, we will continue to defer to state findings on these matters.
        In addition, we clarify that states have the authority to determine 
    the retail marketing areas of the electric utilities within their 
    respective jurisdictions. We also recognize that states have the 
    concomitant authority to determine the end user services these 
    utilities provide.
    
    Stranded Costs
    
        On rehearing, we reaffirm our basic decisions surrounding the 
    recovery of stranded costs. Utilities will be allowed the opportunity 
    to seek to recover legitimate, prudent, and verifiable wholesale 
    stranded costs. This opportunity is limited to costs associated with 
    serving customers under wholesale requirements contracts executed on or 
    before July 11, 1994 that do not contain explicit stranded cost 
    provisions; and costs associated with serving retail-turned-wholesale 
    customers.
    
        We clarify that we will consider on a case-by-case basis whether to 
    treat a contract extended or renegotiated without a stranded cost 
    provision as an existing contract for stranded cost purposes.
    
        In each case, the opportunity to seek stranded costs is limited to 
    situations in which there is a direct nexus between the availability 
    and use of a Commission-required transmission tariff and the stranding 
    of the costs. The Rule does not allow the recovery of costs that do not 
    arise from the new, accelerated availability of non-discriminatory 
    transmission access.
    
        The Commission also reaffirms its decision that stranded costs 
    should be recovered from the customer that caused the costs to be 
    incurred. The Commission is not requiring other remaining customers, or 
    the utility, to shoulder a portion of its stranded costs that meet the 
    requirements for recovery.
    
        The Commission, as described in Order No. 888, will be the primary 
    forum for addressing the recovery of stranded costs caused by retail-
    turned-wholesale customers. With respect to such cases, we have made 
    several changes.
        First, the Commission has reconsidered its decision respecting 
    cases involving existing municipal utilities that annex retail customer 
    service territories. Under Order No. 888, we found that in such cases 
    the Commission should not be the primary forum for determining stranded 
    cost recovery. On rehearing we now find that such cases should fall 
    within our province.
        Second, we clarify that the opportunity for recovery of stranded 
    costs associated with retail-turned-wholesale customers applies 
    regardless of whether the customer or its new supplier is the one 
    requesting and contracting for the transmission service. To this end, 
    we have revised the definition of ``wholesale stranded cost.''
        With respect to the recovery of stranded costs caused by unbundled 
    retail wheeling, we affirm that the only circumstance in which we will 
    entertain requests for these types of costs is when the state 
    regulatory authority does not have authority under state law to address 
    stranded costs when the retail wheeling is required. We clarify that if 
    a state regulatory authority has in fact addressed such costs, 
    regardless of whether it has allowed full recovery, partial recovery or 
    no recovery, utilities may not apply to the Commission to recover 
    stranded costs caused by the retail wheeling.
    
    Other
    
        In this section we resolve questions concerning our information 
    reporting requirements, regional transmission groups, and the special 
    situations posed by utilities in the Pacific Northwest and by federal 
    power marketing and similar agencies. Here we make some minor 
    clarifications but make no significant changes to Order No. 888.
        We are not persuaded that the information reporting requirements 
    need to be changed at this time. Finally, we reject arguments that 
    would have us fix generically any particular rate methodology for 
    providing open access transmission service under the pro forma tariff.
    
    II. Public Reporting Burden
    
        This order on rehearing issues a number of minor revisions to the 
    Final Rule. We find, after reviewing these revisions, that they do not, 
    on balance, increase the public reporting burden.
        The Final Rule contained an estimated annual public reporting 
    burden based on the requirements of the Open Access Final Rule and the 
    Stranded Cost Final Rule.3 Using the
    
    [[Page 12280]]
    
    burden estimate contained in the Final Rule as a starting point, we 
    evaluated the public burden estimate contained in the Final Rule in 
    light of the revisions contained in this order and assessed whether 
    this estimate needed revision. We have concluded, given the minor 
    nature of the revisions, and their offsetting nature, that our estimate 
    of the public reporting burden of this order on rehearing remains 
    unchanged from our estimate of the public reporting burden contained in 
    the Final Rule. The Commission has conducted an internal review of this 
    conclusion and has assured itself that there is specific, objective 
    support for this information burden estimate. Moreover, the Commission 
    has reviewed the collection of information required by the Final Rule, 
    as revised by this order on rehearing, and has determined that the 
    collection of information is necessary and conforms to the Commission's 
    plan, as described in the Final Rule, for the collection, efficient 
    management, and use of the required information.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \3\ 61 FR 21540 at 21543; FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 31,036 at 
    31,638 (1996). No comments were filed in objection to the public 
    burden estimate contained in the Open Access Final Rule and the 
    Stranded Cost Final Rule.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Persons wishing to comment on the collections of information 
    required by the Final Rule, as modified by this order on rehearing, 
    should direct their comments to the Desk Officer for FERC, Office of 
    Management and Budget, Room 3019 NEOB, Washington, D.C. 20503, phone 
    202-395-3087, facsimile: 202-395-7285 or via the Internet at 
    hillier__t@a1.eop.gov. Comments must be filed with the Office of 
    Management and Budget within 30 days of publication of this document in 
    the Federal Register. Three copies of any comments filed with the 
    Office of Management and Budget also should be sent to the following 
    address: Ms. Lois Cashell, Secretary, Federal Energy Regulatory 
    Commission, Room 1A, 888 First Street, N.E., Washington, D.C. 20426. 
    For further information, contact Michael Miller, 202-208-1415.
    
    III. Background
    
        In the Final Rule, we detailed the events that led up to this 
    rulemaking, including the significant technical, statutory and 
    regulatory changes that have occurred in the electric industry since 
    the FPA was enacted in 1935.4 In particular, we focused on the 
    competitive influences of the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 
    1978, the Congressional mandate in the Energy Policy Act of 1992 to 
    encourage competition in electricity markets, and the need for reform 
    in the industry if consumers are to achieve the benefits that greater 
    competition can bring.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \4\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,638-52; mimeo at 13-51.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In the ten months since the Final Rule issued, competitive changes 
    have escalated at an even faster pace in virtually all areas of the 
    electric industry. These changes are driven not only by the 
    Commission's Final Rule, but also by state restructuring initiatives 
    and by continuing pressures from customers to take advantage of 
    emerging competitive markets and the lower electricity rates they can 
    bring.
        All of the existing 166 public utilities that own, control or 
    operate interstate transmission facilities (listed as Group 1 and Group 
    2 utilities in the Final Rule) have filed the Order No. 888 pro forma 
    open access tariff or requested a waiver of the requirement. Similarly, 
    they either have adopted an electronic information network or requested 
    a waiver of the requirement. Five non-public utilities have submitted 
    reciprocal transmission tariffs and more than 20 have requested a 
    waiver of the reciprocity condition in the pro forma tariff.5
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \5\ As a condition of using a public utility's open access 
    tariff, any user, including non-public utilities, must offer 
    reciprocal comparable transmission access to the public utility in 
    return. Order No. 888 provides a voluntary mechanism whereby non-
    public utilities can obtain Commission confirmation that what they 
    are offering meets the tariff reciprocity condition. Non-public 
    utilities also may seek a waiver of the reciprocity condition.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Significant competitive changes also have accelerated with respect 
    to power pooling, state restructuring initiatives, and Independent 
    System Operators (ISOs). Under Order No. 888 and subsequent 
    implementation orders, the Commission required the filing of revised 
    pooling agreements and joint pool-wide transmission tariffs by December 
    31, 1996, in order to remedy undue discrimination in transmission 
    services provided through interstate power pooling arrangements. Among 
    the power pool filings were a New England (NEPOOL) comprehensive 
    restructuring proposal, a New York proposal, a Pennsylvania-New Jersey-
    Maryland (PJM) compliance filing and a Western Systems Power Pool 
    filing.
        In response to the Commission's encouragement in Order No. 888 of 
    ISOs as a possible means for accomplishing comparable access, a number 
    of utilities and states are well underway in developing this new 
    institution. The fundamental purpose of an ISO is to operate the 
    transmission systems of public utilities in a manner that is 
    independent of any business interest in sales or purchases of electric 
    power by those utilities. The Commission has received several proposals 
    for forming ISOs, one as part of the multi-docketed filing engendered 
    by California's restructuring plan, and others relating to power pool 
    filings. A number of regions are also developing ISO proposals. Some 
    regions previously considering regional transmission groups (RTGs), 
    whose primary purpose is regional planning of transmission facility 
    construction and upgrades, have now broadened their discussions to 
    include an ISO.
        Investor-owned utilities in California, at the order of both the 
    state commission and the legislature, have filed proposals with the 
    Commission that would transfer control of transmission facilities to an 
    ISO in conjunction with the formation of a state-wide power exchange to 
    facilitate both wholesale and retail access. While the case presents 
    many complex issues for the Commission to resolve, the California 
    proposal is fundamentally compatible with the pro-competitive open-
    access requirements of Order Nos. 888 and 889. The Commission's open-
    access policies therefore have provided a framework for California, and 
    other states, to explore customer choice initiatives.
        Other major regions of the country also are instituting ISOs. 
    Member utilities of the PJM Power Pool filed competing ISO proposals 
    with the Commission and are currently working to reconcile the 
    differences between their proposals. The New York Power Pool recently 
    filed a proposal to create an ISO and a power exchange for New York. 
    The New England Power Pool is exploring a new industry structure for 
    its region that centers on the creation of an ISO. Utilities and other 
    market participants in the Electric Reliability Council of Texas have 
    also formed an ISO. Discussions are underway among utilities from 
    Virginia to Wisconsin in an attempt to create a Midwestern ISO. Members 
    of the Mid-America Power Pool are discussing an ISO proposal. In the 
    Pacific Northwest, utilities are involved in negotiations intended to 
    lead to the formation of an independent grid operator (Indego).
        The combined available generation resources of the utilities in 
    these groups is on the order of 428 GW out of a total of approximately 
    732 GW for total U.S. resources (as of the end of 1996). Thus, assuming 
    these ISO arrangements come to fruition, about three-fifths of the 
    industry may have independent system operators controlling their 
    transmission systems.
        Moreover, every state but one has proposed or is considering or 
    developing retail competition programs. For example, New Hampshire, 
    Illinois
    
    [[Page 12281]]
    
    and Massachusetts began pilot programs in the past year, and retail 
    transmission service for these pilot programs currently is being taken 
    pursuant to tariffs approved by both the state commissions and this 
    Commission. The Massachusetts Department of Public Utilities has sent a 
    proposal to the state legislature calling for retail competition to 
    begin in January 1998. The New York Public Service Commission has 
    issued an order proposing that retail competition begin in early 1998. 
    The New Jersey Board of Public Utilities has issued a proposal 
    permitting customer choice beginning in October of 1998. The Vermont 
    Public Service Board has sent a plan to the legislature recommending 
    that full customer choice begin by the end of 1998. The Arizona 
    Corporation Commission has adopted rules to phase in competition over 
    four years, beginning in January 1999. Recently, the Maine Public 
    Utilities Commission issued a final report and recommendation to the 
    legislature for retail competition to begin in January 2000. In 
    addition, Rhode Island and Pennsylvania both have new laws requiring 
    customer choice. These are only a few of the many state initiatives 
    that are under way that will dramatically alter the structure of the 
    electric industry.
        Since Order No. 888 was issued, significant efforts also have been 
    made to ensure that reliability of the transmission grid is maintained 
    and that reliability criteria are compatible with competitive markets. 
    The North American Electric Reliability Council (NERC) has continued 
    its efforts to broaden its membership and to fashion reliability 
    requirements to fit a more competitive electric power industry. For 
    example, the NERC Board of Directors voted to require mandatory 
    compliance by all power market participants with its reliability 
    standards. NERC is also establishing new entities called regional 
    security coordinators to oversee the stability of grid operations and 
    to direct the development of an extensive new communications network. 
    Various NERC committees are considering ways to improve the tracking of 
    power transactions, identify the network impacts of transactions, and 
    reflect the actual flow of power over the network when making 
    reservations for transmission service. These efforts are likely to 
    intensify as the industry continues to adapt to competitive changes 
    occurring in the marketplace.
        Thus, all segments of the electric industry have taken significant 
    steps in the past year in response to the emerging wholesale 
    competitive markets enabled by Order No. 888 as well as state retail 
    competition initiatives. The competitive framework established by Order 
    No. 888, whose centerpiece is non-discriminatory transmission services 
    and a fair and orderly stranded cost recovery mechanism, is critical to 
    the successful transition to, and full development of, the industry 
    restructuring proposals that are well underway in all major regions of 
    the country.
    
    IV. Discussion
    
    A. Scope of the Rule
    
    1. Introduction
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
    Severability of Rules
    
        Several entities assert that the Commission should find that the 
    requirements of open access transmission and stranded cost recovery are 
    not severable.6 They argue that if one of these provisions is 
    invalidated by a court or otherwise removed, the orders in their 
    entirety should be withdrawn or stayed pending reconsideration by the 
    Commission, and public utilities should be allowed to withdraw or file 
    amended transmission tariffs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \6\ E.g., Nuclear Energy Institute, Southern, EEI. EEI and 
    Nuclear Energy Institute also argue that Order No. 889 should not be 
    severable.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Commission will not, at this time, make any determination 
    whether or not the open access transmission, stranded cost recovery and 
    OASIS provisions of Order Nos. 888 and 889 are severable. Accordingly, 
    we make no finding whether, if one of these provisions is invalidated, 
    Order Nos. 888 and 889 should be withdrawn or stayed in their entirety. 
    We believe that our decisions in Order Nos. 888 and 889 will be upheld 
    by the courts. Moreover, it would be premature to consider the 
    appropriateness of a stay or withdrawal at this time. Circumstances at 
    the time of any court order would dictate how we should proceed and we 
    would consider all such circumstances, and the entirety of our policy 
    decisions, before determining how to respond to a court decision.
    2. Functional Unbundling
        In the Final Rule, the Commission found that functional unbundling 
    of wholesale generation and transmission services is necessary to 
    implement non-discriminatory open access transmission.7 At the 
    same time, the Commission recognized that additional safeguards were 
    necessary to protect against market power abuses. Thus, the Commission 
    adopted a code of conduct, discussed in detail in the final rule on 
    OASIS, to ensure that the transmission owner's wholesale power 
    marketing personnel and the transmission customer's power marketing 
    personnel have comparable access to information about the transmission 
    system. The Commission also noted that section 206 of the FPA is 
    available if a public utility seeks to circumvent the functional 
    unbundling requirements.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \7\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,654-56; mimeo at 57-61.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As a further precaution against unduly discriminatory behavior, the 
    Commission stated that it will continue to monitor electricity markets 
    to ensure that functional unbundling adequately protects transmission 
    customers. The Commission also indicated that it would continue to 
    observe both the evolution of competitive power markets and the 
    progress of the industry in adapting structurally to competitive 
    markets. If it subsequently becomes apparent that functional unbundling 
    is inadequate or unworkable in assuring non-discriminatory open access 
    transmission, the Commission indicated that it would reevaluate its 
    position and decide whether other mechanisms, such as ISOs, should be 
    required.
        The Commission concluded that functional unbundling, coupled with 
    these safeguards, is a reasonable and workable means of assuring that 
    non-discriminatory open access transmission occurs. In the absence of 
    evidence that functional unbundling will not work, the Commission 
    indicated that it was not prepared to adopt a more intrusive and 
    potentially more costly mechanism--corporate unbundling--at this time.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Several entities disagree with the Commission's decision to require 
    functional unbundling of wholesale generation and transmission as a 
    means of assuring non-discriminatory open access transmission.8 
    American Forest & Paper argues that utilities must be required to 
    divest or spin-off their generating assets through operational 
    unbundling or divestiture. It alleges that it was arbitrary and 
    capricious, and not supported by evidence, for the Commission to rely 
    on a monopolist's code of conduct to protect against monopoly abuses. 
    Nucor asserts that a financial conflict of interest remains and that 
    the Commission cannot monitor the exchanges of information between 
    utility generation and transmission employees. It declares that a 
    credible
    
    [[Page 12282]]
    
    information disclosure requirement is needed that makes generation cost 
    and production data visible to all participants on a same-time basis. 
    NY Municipal Utilities also believes that the Commission did not go far 
    enough and argues that the Commission should have required operational 
    unbundling, at least for tight power pools.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \8\ E.g., American Forest & Paper, Nucor, NY Municipal 
    Utilities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Commission reaffirms its finding in the Final Rule that, based 
    on the information available at this time, functional unbundling, along 
    with the flexible safeguards discussed in the Final Rule, is a 
    reasonable and workable means of assuring non-discriminatory open 
    access transmission. We see no need to adopt a more intrusive and 
    potentially more costly approach at this time based on speculative 
    allegations that functional unbundling may not work and that more 
    severe measures may be needed. Indeed, despite a number of 
    opportunities to do so, no entity has submitted any evidence suggesting 
    that this less intrusive approach would not work. We do emphasize, 
    however, that we have not adopted a rigid approach, but have indicated 
    a willingness to monitor the situation and, if events require, 
    reevaluate our decision and decide whether another mechanism may be 
    more appropriate. Until we see evidence that functional unbundling will 
    not work, we will continue to require functional unbundling, with the 
    safeguards enumerated in the Final Rule and in Order No. 889.
    3. Market-Based Rates
    a. Market-Based Rates for New Generation
        In the Final Rule, the Commission codified its determination in 
    Kansas City Power & Light Company (KCP&L) 9 that the generation 
    dominance standard for market-based sales from new capacity should be 
    dropped.10 The Commission explained that it had yet to find an 
    instance of generation dominance in long-run bulk power markets and no 
    commenter had presented any evidence to that effect. However, the 
    Commission emphasized that it will not ignore specific evidence 
    presented by an intervenor that a seller requesting market-based rates 
    for sales from new generation nevertheless possesses generation 
    dominance.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \9\ 67 FERC para. 61,183 at 61,557 (1994).
        \10\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,656-57; mimeo at 63-66.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission further clarified that dropping the generation 
    dominance standard for new capacity does not affect the demonstration 
    that an applicant must make in order to qualify for market-based rates 
    for sales from its existing generating capacity.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Several entities take issue with the Commission's determination to 
    drop the generation dominance standard for market-based sales from new 
    capacity.11 American Forest & Paper argues that the Commission 
    should delay its decision until effective competition has been 
    demonstrated to exist in all markets. SC Public Service Authority 
    maintains that the Commission must determine on a case-by-case basis 
    whether public utilities have market power (for both existing and new 
    capacity). It further argues that the Commission must develop an 
    analysis of structural conditions to use in assessing the potential for 
    market power consistent with that used by DOJ and FTC in merger 
    proceedings and that reflects the conditions of the industry. SC Public 
    Service Authority also asserts that the Commission must require as a 
    condition of market rates for sales in the bulk power market, which it 
    defines to be limited to sales to integrated utilities, that the 
    selling utility file rate cases with the Commission and the applicable 
    state commissions to avoid subsidization by captive consumers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \11\ E.g., American Forest & Paper, SC Public Service Authority, 
    TDU Systems, LEPA, San Francisco.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        TDU Systems alleges that the long-run bulk power market upon which 
    the KCP&L decision was based is overly broad and ignores the 
    distinction between firm power, which ``entities subject to others' 
    market power are most commonly in need of'' and other bulk power 
    services. TDU Systems take issue with the Commission's conclusion in 
    KCP&L that large numbers of capacity offers from IPPs and QFs 
    demonstrate that the market abounds with competitors. TDU Systems 
    argues that the Commission's ``assumption that large numbers of offers 
    of power equate with large numbers of offers of firm power is 
    questionable at best, and very likely incorrect.'' 12 Similarly, 
    LEPA argues that the Commission ignored evidence submitted by LEPA in 
    comments ``that the transmission dominant utility still retained 
    monopoly power over RQ [requirements] markets on which LEPA's members 
    are dependent for their bulk power supply.'' Because the Commission 
    ignored the RQ market and the evidence of concentration in that market, 
    LEPA asserts that the Commission's decision is reversible error. LEPA 
    further argues that the Commission ignored the undisputed testimony of 
    LEPA's witness that reliability requirements constrain the geographic 
    scope of the RQ market severely.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \12\ TDU Systems at 92.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        San Francisco argues that the burden to demonstrate affirmatively 
    the absence of capacity constraints as a precondition to receiving 
    authority to charge market-based rates for sales from new capacity 
    should be upon public utility applicants, who possess the information 
    concerning capacity constraints.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We reaffirm our decision to codify the determination in KCP&L that 
    the generation dominance standard for market-based sales from new 
    capacity should be dropped. Petitioners have not presented any evidence 
    that demonstrates generation dominance in long-run bulk power markets 
    and, as discussed in Order No. 888, we have found no such evidence of 
    generation dominance in any of the numerous market-based rate cases 
    decided by the Commission since KCP&L. In addition, as described in 
    Order No. 888, the Commission will consider evidence of generation 
    dominance, including generation dominance that results from 
    transmission constraints, when such evidence is presented by an 
    intervenor in a market-based rate case in which a utility seeks market-
    based pricing associated with new capacity.
        American Forest & Paper's argument that the Commission should delay 
    codification of KCP&L until effective competition has been demonstrated 
    to exist in all markets ignores the fact that we have eliminated the 
    generation dominance standard for market-based rates from new capacity 
    only, and that the generation standard still applies to applications 
    for market-based rates from existing generation. Other entities 
    similarly argue that other markets in which utilities may sell power 
    from new capacity may be highly concentrated with respect to 
    generation, or that these utilities may otherwise be able to exert 
    market power. Specifically, TDU Systems and LEPA express concern that 
    the new policy may result in the exercise of market power over very 
    specific bulk power products.
        To allay these concerns, we note that eliminating the generation 
    dominance showing applies only to sales from new capacity. It does not 
    apply to entire classes of service or to specific products. In 
    addition, the policy eliminates the showing only as a matter of routine 
    in each filing. We reemphasize that the Commission will consider 
    specific evidence of generation dominance
    
    [[Page 12283]]
    
    associated with new capacity at the time the seller seeks market-based 
    rates for the new capacity, including whether the addition of the new 
    capacity, when combined with existing capacity, results in generation 
    dominance. This clearly includes situations where existing sources of 
    generation must be combined with new resources to produce a firm power 
    supply. Where entry barriers are a concern, intervenors are free to 
    raise the issue.
        SC Public Service Authority also raises a number of concerns 
    relating to the ability of utilities to exercise market power if they 
    are permitted to sell new capacity at market-based rates. These 
    concerns generally include how the Commission determines product and 
    geographic markets, and the standards used to determine whether sellers 
    can exercise market power. In response to these concerns, as noted 
    above public utility owners of new capacity must still seek case-by-
    case approval before they can sell power from new capacity at market-
    based rates and, as stated in the Final Rule, intervenors may present 
    specific evidence that a seller requesting such market rates possesses 
    generation dominance or otherwise has market power.13 These 
    requirements include considerations of transmission market power, 
    whether other barriers to entry exist and whether there is evidence of 
    affiliate abuse or reciprocal dealing.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \13\ We do not agree with entities that claim that our decision 
    to rely on evidence raised by intervenors in particular cases with 
    respect to transmission constraints improperly shifts the burden 
    away from the utility, which has the greatest access to information 
    concerning those constraints. Given that we have yet to see any 
    evidence of generation dominance in long-term bulk power markets we 
    do not believe that it is appropriate to burden all market-based 
    rate applicants with significant information requirements as an 
    initial matter. However, if an intervenor raises a specific factual 
    concern with respect to a transmission constraint that may result in 
    the exercise of market power in a particular case, we will examine 
    those facts in a paper or formal hearing. In that context, the 
    utility would be required to come forward with information 
    sufficient to permit a full examination of the effect of the 
    constraint on the applicant's ability to exercise market power.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    b. Market-based Rates for Existing Generation
        In the Final Rule, the Commission found that there is not enough 
    evidence on the record to make a generic determination about whether 
    market power may exist for sales from existing generation.14 The 
    Commission indicated that it would continue its case-by-case approach 
    that allows market-based rates based on an analysis of generation 
    market power in first tier and second tier markets.15 The 
    Commission further indicated that while it will continue to apply the 
    first-tier/second-tier analysis, it will allow applicants and 
    intervenors to challenge the presumption implicit in the Commission's 
    practice that the relevant geographic market is bounded by the second-
    tier utilities. Finally, the Commission stated that it would maintain 
    its current practice of allowing market-based rates for existing 
    generation to go into effect not subject to refund.16 To the 
    extent that either the applicant or an intervenor in individual cases 
    offers specific evidence that the relevant geographic market ought to 
    be defined differently than under the existing test, the Commission 
    indicated that it will examine such arguments through formal or paper 
    hearings.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \14\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,660; mimeo at 73-75.
        \15\ See, e.g., Southwestern Public Service Company, 72 FERC 
    para. 61,208 at 61,996 (1995), reh'g pending.
        \16\ The Final Rule contained a typographical error in which the 
    word ``not'' was erroneously omitted.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        No rehearing requests were filed with respect to this matter.
    4. Merger Policy
        In the Final Rule, the Commission explained that it had issued a 
    Notice of Inquiry (NOI) on the Commission's merger policy in Docket No. 
    RM96-6-000.17 The Commission indicated that it will review whether 
    its criteria and policies for evaluating mergers need to be modified in 
    light of the changing circumstances, including the Final Rule, that are 
    occurring in the electric industry. The Commission concluded that it 
    would review its merger policy in the ongoing NOI proceeding.18
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \17\ FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 35,531 (1996).
        \18\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,661; mimeo at 77-78.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        No rehearing requests were filed with respect to this matter.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We note that on December 18, 1996, the Commission issued, in the 
    NOI proceeding, a Policy Statement that updates and clarifies the 
    Commission's procedures, criteria and policies concerning public 
    utility mergers.19
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \19\ Order No. 592, Policy Statement Establishing Factors the 
    Commission will Consider in Evaluating Whether a Proposed Merger is 
    Consistent with the Public Interest, 77 FERC para. 61,263 (1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    5. Contract Reform
    
    Requirements and Transmission Contracts
    
        In the Final Rule, the Commission concluded that it was not 
    appropriate to order generic abrogation of existing requirements and 
    transmission contracts, but concluded nonetheless that the modification 
    of certain requirements contracts (those executed on or before July 11, 
    1994) on a case-by-case basis may be appropriate.20 The Commission 
    further concluded that, even if customers under such requirements 
    contracts are bound by so-called Mobile-Sierra clauses, they ought to 
    have the opportunity to demonstrate that their contracts no longer are 
    just and reasonable.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \20\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,663-66; mimeo at 84-92.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission found that it would be against the public interest 
    to permit a Mobile-Sierra clause in an existing wholesale requirements 
    contract 21 to preclude the parties to such a contract from the 
    opportunity to realize the benefits of the competitive wholesale power 
    markets. Thus, it explained, a party to a requirements contract 
    containing a Mobile-Sierra clause no longer will have the burden of 
    establishing independently that it is in the public interest to permit 
    the modification of such contract. The party, however, still will have 
    the burden of establishing that such contract no longer is just and 
    reasonable and therefore ought to be modified.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \21\ The Commission defined these as contracts executed on or 
    before July 11, 1994.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission explained that this finding complements the 
    Commission's finding that, notwithstanding a Mobile-Sierra clause in an 
    existing requirements contract, it is in the public interest to permit 
    amendments to add stranded cost provisions to such contracts if the 
    public utility proposing the amendment can meet the evidentiary 
    requirements of the Final Rule. Accordingly, the Commission required 
    that any contract modification approved under this Section must provide 
    for the utility's recovery of any costs stranded consistent with the 
    contract modification. Further, the Commission concluded that if a 
    customer is permitted to argue for modification of existing contracts 
    that are less favorable to it than other generation alternatives, then 
    the utility should be able to seek modification of contracts that may 
    be beneficial to the customer.
    
    Coordination Agreements
    
        The Commission concluded that to assure that non-discriminatory 
    open access becomes a reality in the relatively near future, it was 
    necessary to modify existing economy energy coordination agreements. 
    The Commission stated that it would condition future sales and
    
    [[Page 12284]]
    
    purchase transactions under existing economy energy coordination 
    agreements 22 to require that the transmission service associated 
    with those transactions be provided pursuant to the Final Rule's 
    requirements of non-discriminatory open access, no later than December 
    31, 1996. The Commission also required that, for new economy energy 
    coordination agreements 23 where the transmission owner uses its 
    transmission system to make economy energy sales or purchases, the 
    transmission owner must take such service under its own transmission 
    tariff as of the date trading begins under the agreement.24
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \22\ The Commission defined ``existing'' as those agreements 
    executed prior to 60 days after publication of the Final Rule in the 
    Federal Register.
        \23\ The Commission defined ``new'' as those agreements executed 
    60 days after publication of the Final Rule in the Federal Register.
        \24\ Accordingly, the Commission explained, transmission service 
    needed for sales or purchases under all new economy energy 
    coordination agreements will be pursuant to the Final Rule pro forma 
    tariff.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Finally, the Commission concluded that it would not require the 
    modification of non-economy energy coordination agreements. However, 
    the Commission noted that this does not insulate such agreements from 
    complaints that transmission service provided under such agreements 
    should be provided pursuant to the Final Rule pro forma tariff.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Various utilities oppose the Commission's finding that it is in the 
    public interest to permit the modification of existing requirements 
    contracts that contain Mobile-Sierra clauses. On the other hand, a 
    number of customers assert that the Commission did not go far enough 
    and seek enhanced contract reformation rights.
    
    Utilities Against Contract Reformation
    
        Several utilities argue that the Commission's finding is not 
    supported by substantial evidence.25 Utilities For Improved 
    Transition asserts that the Commission cannot rely on economic theory 
    as a substitute for substantial evidence.26 It argues that the 
    record in this proceeding demonstrates that the marketplace is becoming 
    increasingly competitive without mandatory tariffs, which is evidence 
    of market health, not market problems. It further argues that even if 
    undue discrimination is proven, the remedy is not needed because the 
    record shows that existing programs are meeting the industry's needs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \25\ Utilities For Improved Transition, Union Electric, PSE&G, 
    Carolina P&L.
        \26\ Union Electric adds that there is no evidence that any 
    existing economy energy coordination agreements are unduly 
    discriminatory and require modification.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Southwestern argues that the Commission has improperly chosen to 
    ignore the public interest standard and has failed to make the contract 
    specific analysis here that it performed in Northeast Utils. Serv. Co., 
    66 FERC para. 61,332 (1994), aff'd, 55 F.3d 686 (1st Cir. 1995). PSE&G 
    and Carolina P&L also argue that the Commission failed to demonstrate 
    the ``unequivocal public necessity'' for generically abrogating the 
    Mobile-Sierra clauses and assert that the Commission has presented no 
    evidence as to how the public interest will be served by abrogating 
    these contracts. PSE&G and Carolina P&L further argue that the 
    Commission cannot avoid making a public interest determination ``by the 
    simple expedient of asserting that the public interest requires it to 
    ignore the Mobile-Sierra clauses that required that public-interest 
    determination in the first place.'' 27
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \27\ PSE&G at 6.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Union Electric and PSE&G argue that the Commission, in justifying 
    its public interest finding, inappropriately focused on the interests 
    of the parties to the contract instead of on whether non-parties will 
    be adversely affected by the existing contracts.
        Public Service Co of CO asserts that the Commission should clarify 
    the definition of requirements contract to include long-term block 
    purchases of electricity. It states that it purchases a large 
    percentage of its system requirements under long-term block purchase 
    agreements, and that under the Commission's abrogation policy in Order 
    No. 888, its ability to abrogate these supply arrangements would be 
    treated differently because its contracts do not meet the definition of 
    a ``wholesale requirements contract,'' as defined in new section 
    35.26(b)(1) of the Commission's Regulations. Public Service Co of CO 
    further asserts that the Commission has not adequately explained why it 
    is appropriate or in the public interest to allow partial requirements 
    customers to abrogate their contracts, but not similarly to allow a 
    public utility to abrogate its supply arrangements.28
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \28\ See also PSE&G.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        PSE&G and Carolina argue that the availability of stranded cost 
    recovery cannot support allowing customers to modify rates under 
    Mobile-Sierra clauses that required that public-interest determination 
    in the first place.
        PSE&G and Carolina P&L also argue that no Mobile-Sierra contracts 
    entered into after October 24, 1992 (the date EPAct became law) should 
    be subject to the Rule because since that date customers have been able 
    to apply for an order under section 211 to have power transmitted to 
    them from suppliers other than the utility to whom they are 
    interconnected.
        PSE&G requests that the Commission clarify that the just and 
    reasonable standard used in considering a contract abrogation claim 
    will be limited to a determination of whether the rate is just and 
    reasonable within the cost-based zone of reasonableness of the selling 
    public utility. Such an analysis, PSE&G asserts, should not include a 
    comparison to what other utilities offer to their customers.29
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \29\ See also Carolina P&L.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Customers Seek Enhanced Contract Reformation Rights
    
        TAPS argues that the Commission should apply a just and reasonable 
    standard to requests by all ``victims'' of undue discrimination to seek 
    modifications of requirements or transmission contracts, whether they 
    are subject to Mobile-Sierra or not. On the other hand, TAPS asserts 
    that utilities should be bound to the bargain they extracted from 
    transmission customers. Wisconsin Municipals request that the 
    Commission clarify that parties may seek mandatory abrogation of 
    preexisting transmission contracts or provisions and that the 
    Commission will apply a rebuttable presumption that terms and 
    conditions inferior to the pro forma tariff are unjust and unreasonable 
    on their face.
        CCEM argues that requirements customers should receive blanket 
    conversion rights. At a minimum, CCEM asserts, if a customer seeks 
    conversion, the burden of proof in the proceeding should shift to the 
    utility. CCEM also emphasizes that the question remains why conversion 
    was deemed essential in natural gas markets, but not in the transition 
    to competition in the electric industry.
        Blue Ridge argues:
    
        In neither the power supply nor transmission access case should 
    a provider be allowed to modify existing power supply contracts 
    under any but the Mobile Sierra public interest burden of proof. In 
    both the power supply or transmission access cases, the Commission 
    should articulate the suggested standards for what constitutes a 
    prima facia case. [30]
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \30\ Blue Ridge at 16.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Before responding to the rehearing arguments raised, we wish to 
    clarify our Mobile-Sierra findings. We explained in Order No. 888 that 
    we were making two
    
    [[Page 12285]]
    
    complementary public interest findings. First, as discussed further in 
    Section IV.J, we found that it is in the public interest to permit 
    public utilities to seek stranded cost amendments to existing 
    requirements contracts with Mobile-Sierra clauses. Second, we found 
    that a ``party'' to a requirements contract containing a Mobile-Sierra 
    clause no longer will have the burden of establishing independently 
    that it is in the public interest to permit the modification of such 
    contract, but still will have the burden of establishing that such 
    contract no longer is just and reasonable and therefore ought to be 
    modified. We clarify that, in making this second finding, our reference 
    to a ``party'' to a requirements contract containing a Mobile-Sierra 
    clause was directed at modification of contract provisions by 
    customers. 31 Additionally, it applies to any contract revisions 
    sought, whether or not they relate to stranded costs. 32
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \31\ We note that the fact that a contract may bind a utility to 
    a Mobile-Sierra public interest standard does not necessarily mean 
    that the customer is also bound to that standard. Unless a customer 
    specifically waives its section 206 just and reasonable rights, the 
    Commission construes the issue in favor of the customer. See Papago 
    Tribal Utility Authority v. FERC, 723 F.2d 950, 954 (D.C. Cir. 
    1983).
        \32\ In situations in which a customer institutes a section 206 
    proceeding to modify a contract that binds the utility to a Mobile-
    Sierra public interest standard, the utility may make whatever 
    arguments it wants regarding any of the contract terms, including 
    those unrelated to stranded costs, but will be bound to a Mobile-
    Sierra public interest standard for contract terms that do not 
    relate to stranded costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In response to the Mobile-Sierra rehearing arguments described 
    above, as well as the Mobile-Sierra arguments described in Section IV.J 
    concerning our determinations regarding stranded cost amendments to 
    contracts, the Commission believes it is important to first address the 
    general context in which our Mobile-Sierra determinations have been 
    made. In Order No. 888, the Commission removed the single largest 
    barrier to the development of competitive wholesale power markets by 
    requiring non-discriminatory open access transmission as a remedy for 
    undue discrimination. This action carries with it the regulatory public 
    interest responsibility to address the difficult transition issues that 
    arise in moving from a monopoly, cost-based electric utility industry 
    to an industry that is driven by competition among wholesale power 
    suppliers and increasing reliance on market-based generation rates.
        There are two predominant, overlapping transition issues that arise 
    as a result of our actions in this rulemaking: first, how to deal with 
    the uneconomic sunk costs incurred, and second, how to deal with the 
    contracts that were entered into, under an industry regime that rested 
    on a regulatory framework and set of expectations that are being 
    fundamentally altered. To address these issues, the Commission has 
    balanced a number of important interests in order to achieve what it 
    believes will be a fair and orderly transition to competitive markets. 
    These interests include the financial stability of the electric utility 
    industry and permitting customers to obtain the benefits of competitive 
    markets without undue disruption or unfairness to other customers or 
    industry participants.
        As the above rehearing arguments demonstrate, there is no consensus 
    on how the Commission should manage the transition. In fact, parties 
    offer diverse and conflicting views as to what the Commission should do 
    regarding existing contracts. Some would have us let all contracts run 
    their course with no opportunity for customers to modify or terminate 
    their contracts, no matter how long the contracts or how onerous their 
    terms. Others advocate automatic generic abrogation of all contracts. 
    Yet others want a guaranteed automatic right to renew a contract if it 
    happens to contain favorable rates and terms.33
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \33\ Similarly, as discussed in Section IV.J, parties have taken 
    extreme positions as to stranded cost recovery.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Rather than adopting one extreme position or the other, the 
    Commission has taken a measured approach with regard to contract 
    modification, including modification of contracts that contain Mobile-
    Sierra clauses. Our goal is to balance the desire to honor existing 
    contractual arrangements with the need to provide some means to 
    accelerate the opportunity of parties to participate in competitive 
    markets. To accomplish this balance, the Commission, first, has made 
    Mobile-Sierra public interest findings (discussed further below) only 
    as to a limited set of contracts: those wholesale requirements 
    contracts executed on or before July 11, 1994, which is the date of our 
    first stranded cost proposed rulemaking and which served to put the 
    industry and customers on notice that future contracts should 
    explicitly address the rights, obligations and expectations of parties, 
    including stranded cost obligations.34
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \34\ As to existing economy energy coordination agreements, the 
    Commission concludes that the evidence also supports its decision to 
    condition future sales and purchase transactions that may occur 
    under the ongoing umbrella coordination agreements. Specifically, we 
    are requiring that the transmission service associated with these 
    future transactions be provided pursuant to the Final Rule pro forma 
    tariff. See Public Service Electric & Gas Company, 78 FERC para. 
    61,119, slip op. at 4 and n.7 (1997).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Second, with regard to contract modifications sought by utilities, 
    as discussed in more detail in Section IV.J, utilities that seek to add 
    stranded cost provisions have a high evidentiary burden to meet before 
    they can add contract provisions that permit stranded cost recovery 
    beyond the end of their contract terms; the burden is particularly high 
    in the case of contracts with notice provisions. With regard to 
    modifications of contract provisions that do not relate to stranded 
    costs, a utility with a Mobile-Sierra contract clause will have the 
    burden of showing that the provisions are contrary to the public 
    interest.35
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \35\ As discussed below, pre-July 11, 1994 contracts were 
    entered into during an era in which transmission providers exerted 
    monopoly control over access to their transmission facilities. The 
    unequal bargaining power between utilities and captive customers is 
    the basis for our determination that utilities that have pre-July 11 
    Mobile-Sierra requirements contracts will have to satisfy the public 
    interest standard in order to effectuate any non-stranded cost 
    change to the contract, but that customers to such contracts will be 
    able to effectuate any change by satisfying a just and reasonable 
    standard.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Third, with regard to contract modifications sought by customers, a 
    customer will have to show that the provisions it seeks to modify are 
    no longer just and reasonable.36 If a customer seeks to shorten or 
    eliminate the term of an existing contract, any contract modification 
    approved by the Commission will take into account the issue of 
    appropriate stranded cost recovery by the customer's supplying utility.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \36\ We will not grant the request by PSE&G and Carolina P&L 
    that the just and reasonable standard will be limited to a 
    determination of whether the rate is just and reasonable within the 
    cost-based zone of reasonableness of the selling utility and should 
    not include a comparison to what other utilities offer their 
    customers. Because stranded costs will be taken into account when 
    customers seek contract termination or modification, it would not be 
    appropriate to limit customers in the evidence they may present.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In permitting customers the opportunity to seek these types of 
    modifications, even for contracts that contain Mobile-Sierra clauses, 
    the Commission has based its public interest findings on the 
    unprecedented industry changes facing utilities and their customers. 
    While, as we stated in the Final Rule, there is no market failure in 
    the electric industry that would justify generic abrogation of existing 
    contracts, nevertheless the industry is in the midst of fundamental 
    change. We cannot conclude that it is in the public interest to require 
    all customers to be
    
    [[Page 12286]]
    
    held to requirements contracts that were executed under the prior 
    industry regime, no matter what the circumstances of those contracts.
        In response to parties who challenge the Commission's finding that 
    it would be against the public interest to deny customers an 
    opportunity to seek modification of wholesale requirements contracts 
    executed on or before July 11, 1994,37 these parties ignore the 
    fact that these contracts were entered into during an era in which 
    transmission providers exercised monopoly control over access to their 
    transmission facilities.38 The majority of customers under these 
    types of contracts were captive, i.e., they had no realistic choice but 
    to purchase generation from their local utility because they had no 
    transmission to reach another supplier. Many of these contracts were 
    the result of uneven bargaining power between customers and monopolist 
    transmission providers.39 While monopolist transmission providers 
    may not have exercised monopoly power in all situations,40 the 
    unprecedented competitive changes that have occurred (and are 
    continuing to occur) in the industry may render their contracts to be 
    no longer in the public interest or just and reasonable. These changed 
    circumstances, discussed at length in the Final Rule, and the further 
    changes that will occur as a result of open access transmission, may 
    affect whether such contracts continue to be just and reasonable or not 
    unduly discriminatory both as to the direct customers of the contracts, 
    as well as to indirect, third-party consumers as well.41
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \37\ We note that some of the very parties making this challenge 
    either do not object to the Commission's Mobile-Sierra findings 
    permitting utilities to add stranded cost amendments to their 
    contracts, or ask the Commission to broaden even further the scope 
    of extra-contractual stranded cost recovery under the rule.
        \38\ We also reject arguments that a remedy is not needed 
    because existing programs, i.e., those prior to Order No. 888, are 
    meeting the needs of the industry. This very rulemaking, with the 
    substantial comments filed by entities pointing out the failures of 
    the current system and the need for change, and the extensive 
    restructurings and state-initiated open access programs occurring 
    around the country, on their face, refute these arguments.
        \39\ It is also clear from the number of entities filing 
    comments on the NOPR and rehearing requests of the Final Rule that 
    many entities believe that their contracts were the result of uneven 
    bargaining power and that they should be provided the opportunity to 
    seek to terminate their existing contracts.
        \40\ In an era that was not characterized by competition in the 
    generation sector, the Commission's response was to ensure that the 
    rates for such contracts were no higher than the seller's cost 
    (including a reasonable return on equity). In this way, the 
    Commission sought to limit the seller's ability to reap the benefits 
    of the seller's monopoly position.
        \41\ See FPC v. Sierra Pacific Power Company, 350 U.S. 348, 355 
    (1956); Northeast Utilities Service Company, 66 FERC para. 61,332 
    (1994), aff'd, 55 F.3d 686, 691 (1st Cir. 1995); Mississippi 
    Industries v. FERC, 808 F.2d 1525, 1553 (D.C. Cir. 1987).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We therefore reject arguments that there is no ``evidence'' to 
    support our finding that it is in the public interest to permit review 
    of these contracts in light of the specific circumstances surrounding 
    the contracts and in light of dramatically changed industry 
    circumstances. We emphasize, however, that our decision is to permit an 
    opportunity for review and that we will require a case-by-case showing 
    that any modifications should be permitted. 42 As we explained in 
    the Final Rule, this decision complements our decision that it is in 
    the public interest to permit amendments to add stranded cost 
    provisions to existing contracts if case-by-case evidentiary burdens 
    are met.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \42\ We will not exclude Mobile-Sierra contracts entered into 
    after the effective date of EPAct, as argued by PSE&G and Carolina 
    P&L. As we explained in the Final Rule, there are significant time 
    delays associated with section 211 proceedings. Accordingly, the 
    availability of a section 211 proceeding cannot substitute for 
    readily available service under a filed non-discriminatory open 
    access tariff. FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,646; mimeo at 35. We do not 
    believe that EPAct created the expectation of open access on such a 
    broad scale that we can assume that parties no longer generally 
    expected ``business as usual'' to continue, and we will not presume 
    that the exercise of market power was not at work when Mobile-Sierra 
    contracts were entered into after EPAct. We also note that these 
    arguments are similar to those proffered by opponents of stranded 
    cost recovery, who argue that after EPAct utilities had no 
    reasonable expectation of continuing to serve customers beyond the 
    terms of existing contracts. In this context as well, we will not 
    presume that, after EPAct, utilities could have no reasonable 
    expectation of continuing to serve a customer beyond the contract 
    term.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As we discuss further in our detailed stranded cost discussion in 
    Section IV.J, we do not interpret the Mobile-Sierra public interest 
    standard as practically insurmountable 43 in the extraordinary 
    situation before us where historic statutory and regulatory changes 
    have converged to fundamentally change the obligations of utilities and 
    the markets in which both they and their customers will operate. The 
    ability to meet our overarching public interest responsibilities and to 
    protect consumers would be virtually precluded if we were to apply a 
    practically insurmountable standard of review before taking into 
    account these fundamental industry-wide changes.44
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \43\ As the D.C. Circuit explained in Papago Tribal Utility 
    Authority v. FERC, 723 F.2d 950 (D.C. Cir. 1983) (Papago), there are 
    essentially three contractual arrangements for rate revision: (1) 
    the parties agree that the utility may file new rates under section 
    205, subject to the just and reasonable standard of review; (2) the 
    parties agree to eliminate the utility's right to file rates under 
    section 205 and the Commission's right to change pre-existing rates 
    under section 206's just and reasonable standard (leaving the 
    Commission's indefeasible right to change pre-existing rates that 
    are contrary to the public interest); and (3) the parties agree to 
    eliminate the utility's right to file new rates under section 205, 
    but leave unaffected the Commission's power to change pre-existing 
    rates under section 206's just and reasonable standard of review. 
    723 F.2d at 953. The same contractual arrangements also would apply 
    to non-rate terms and conditions. We here address those contractual 
    arrangements that eliminate the rights of one or both parties to 
    modify a contract under the just and reasonable standard. We note 
    that the Commission always has the indefeasible right under section 
    206 to change rates, terms or conditions that are contrary to the 
    public interest. 723 F.2d at 953-55; see also Florida Power & Light 
    Company, 67 FERC para. 61,141 at 61,398 (1994) appeal dismissed, No. 
    94-1483 (D.C. Cir. July 27, 1995) (unpublished); Southern Company 
    Services, Inc., 67 FERC para. 61,080 at 61,227-28 (1994); 
    Mississippi Industries v. FERC, 808 F.2d 1525, 1552 n.112.
        \44\ We reject the arguments of PSE&G and Carolina P&L that we 
    have failed to demonstrate the ``unequivocal public necessity'' for 
    generically ``abrogating'' Mobile-Sierra clauses and that we have 
    presented no evidence as to how the public interest will be served 
    by abrogating these contracts. We have concluded that there is a 
    public necessity to permit the opportunity to seek contract changes 
    in light of fundamental industry changes. However, we have not 
    abrogated any contracts by this Rule.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        With respect to Public Service Co of CO's argument, we disagree 
    that the definition of a wholesale requirements contract should be 
    modified to include a long-term block purchase of electricity. In the 
    majority of circumstances, such long-term supply contracts are 
    voluntary arrangements in which neither party had market power. It 
    would be inappropriate to make generic Mobile-Sierra findings as to 
    these types of contracts. Parties can avail themselves of the section 
    205 and 206 procedures already available to them if they want to seek 
    modification of such contracts.
        Finally, we reject CCEM's argument that all customers should 
    receive automatic conversion rights because customers were provided 
    such a right in the restructuring of the natural gas industry. We have 
    taken, as is within our discretion, a substantially different approach 
    here from that taken when we restructured the natural gas industry. As 
    we stated in the Final Rule, and as alluded to above, at the time the 
    Commission addressed this situation in the natural gas industry it was 
    faced with shrinking natural gas markets, statutory escalations in 
    natural gas ceiling prices under the Natural Gas Policy Act, and 
    increased production of gas.\45\ Moreover, the natural gas industry was 
    plagued with escalating take-or-pay liabilities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \45\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,664; mimeo at 84.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        There was a market failure in the natural gas industry that 
    required the
    
    [[Page 12287]]
    
    extraordinary measure of generically allowing all customers to break 
    their contracts with pipelines. In contrast, market circumstances in 
    the electric industry today do not compel generic abrogation of 
    contracts. The more moderate approach we have taken will permit us to 
    take into account the fundamental industry changes that have occurred 
    (and will continue to occur), to balance the interests of all affected 
    parties, and to help avoid drastic shocks to industry participants.
    
    Right of First Refusal
    
        In the Final Rule, the Commission concluded that all firm 
    transmission customers (requirements and transmission-only), upon the 
    expiration of their contracts or at the time their contracts become 
    subject to renewal or rollover, should have the right to continue to 
    take transmission service from their existing transmission 
    provider.\46\ If not enough capacity is available to meet all requests 
    for service, the right of first refusal gives the existing customer who 
    had contractually been using the capacity on a long-term, firm basis 
    the option of keeping the capacity. However, the limitations imposed by 
    the Commission are that the underlying contract must have been for a 
    term of one-year or more and the existing customer must agree to match 
    the rate offered by another potential customer, up to the transmission 
    provider's maximum filed transmission rate at that time, and to accept 
    a contract term at least as long as that offered by the potential 
    customer.\47\ Moreover, the Commission indicated that this right of 
    first refusal is an ongoing right that may be exercised at the end of 
    all firm contract terms (including all future unbundled transmission 
    contracts).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \46\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,665; mimeo at 88.
        \47\ The Commission explained that this right of first refusal 
    exists whether or not the customer buys power from the historical 
    utility supplier or another power supplier. If the customer chooses 
    a new power supplier and this substantially changes the location or 
    direction of its power flows, the customer's right to continue 
    taking transmission service from its existing transmission provider 
    may be affected by transmission constraints associated with the 
    change.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Requests for Rehearing
    
        On rehearing, most petitioners agree with or do not contest the 
    notion of providing existing transmission customers with a right of 
    first refusal, but many have requested modification or clarification of 
    the Commission-imposed limitations on such a right. A variety of 
    transmission customers assert that the Commission's right of first 
    refusal provision fails to adequately protect existing transmission 
    customers' rights to continued service and seek changes to the 
    Commission's provision. On the other hand, a number of utilities 
    believe that the Commission should provide additional restrictions on 
    the right of first refusal.
    
    Customers' Positions
    
        APPA argues that (1) existing customers should only have to agree 
    to service that matches the term of any power supply contract for which 
    it will use the transmission arrangement or, in the absence of a 
    generation contract, one year, and (2) the pricing provision should be 
    changed to reflect the current just and reasonable rate, as approved by 
    the Commission, for similar transmission service.
        NRECA also argues that the term and pricing provisions of section 
    2.2 need to be changed. With respect to the term of the contract the 
    customer should be required to match, NRECA asserts that it should be 
    one year, which corresponds to the definition of long-term firm service 
    in the tariff. With respect to the rate, NRECA requests that the 
    Commission cap the obligation to match the price offered by another 
    customer at the maximum transmission rate the incumbent customer is 
    obligated to pay to the transmission provider at the close of the prior 
    contract term.
        TDU Systems argue that the right of first refusal provision fails 
    to take into consideration amounts that TDUs have contributed to the 
    development of the transmission systems through prior transmission 
    rates. TDU Systems are concerned about the possibility of an increase 
    in the price of transmission capped only by the cost of increasing the 
    capacity of the provider's transmission system.
        TAPS requests that the Commission clarify that the transmission 
    provider may only charge its then effective rates for existing, non-
    constrained transmission capacity because to allow opportunity or 
    expansion costs would perpetually put the existing transmission 
    customers on the margin at the end of their contract terms subjecting 
    them to higher rates than the transmission provider.\48\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \48\ See also AEC & SMEPA.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Blue Ridge raises a possible discrepancy between the language in 
    the tariff and the language in the preamble. It asserts that section 
    2.2 ``requires the existing customer to `pay the current just and 
    reasonable rate, as approved by the Commission,' while the Regulatory 
    Preamble requires the customer to `match the rate offered by another 
    potential customer, up to the transmission provider's maximum filed 
    transmission rate at that time.' Order No. 888, mimeo at 88.''
        Tallahassee asks the Commission to clarify that the right of first 
    refusal to presently bundled transmission capacity accrues to the power 
    customer paying the bundled rate and not to the intermediary acting on 
    behalf of the customer.
        AEC & SMEPA maintain that the price and term limitations of section 
    2.2 would place TDUs at a competitive disadvantage vis-a-vis the 
    transmission provider by subjecting TDUs to incremental costs, 
    including the costs of system upgrades, if other new customers are 
    vying to use the transmission system. They state that the Commission 
    must provide existing transmission customers the same rights as the 
    transmission provider's other native load customers.
    
    Utilities' Positions
    
        PSNM argues that imposing a right of first refusal is inconsistent 
    with the Commission's finding that contracts should not be abrogated. 
    In effect, it argues that imposition of the right of first refusal 
    abrogates existing contracts executed with the expectation that 
    capacity could be recalled for the utility's own use upon expiration of 
    the contracts. PSNM explains that it has a constrained transmission 
    system and has been balancing specific contract durations against 
    projected future native loads so that required capacity may be made 
    available for use by third parties in the short-term, but not be 
    committed to those parties at the time it is needed to be recalled. 
    Moreover, PSNM asserts that Order No. 888 is not supported by the right 
    of first refusal process of Order No. 636 because the Commission does 
    not have abandonment authority under the FPA and its authority to 
    require continuation of service is not well-defined and is 
    controversial.\49\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \49\ All transmission contracts with public utility transmitters 
    can only be terminated by a filing with the Commission under FPA 
    section 205. Thus, the Commission has interpreted its section 205 
    authority as permitting it to suspend termination of service for 5 
    months beyond the expiration of a contract's term if such action is 
    necessary to protect ratepayers. See, e.g., Kentucky Utilities 
    Company, 67 FERC para. 61,189 at 61,573 (1994). (While the 
    termination procedures for power sales contracts executed after July 
    9, 1996 were modified in Order No. 888, there were no changes 
    regarding termination procedures for transmission contracts.).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Utilities For Improved Transition and Florida Power Corp argue that 
    section 2.2 of the pro forma tariff should be modified by ``restricting 
    rollover rights to the same points of receipt and delivery as the 
    terminating service and
    
    [[Page 12288]]
    
    by providing the customer notice of a competing application and 90 days 
    in which to file its own application for service for a term at least as 
    long as the competing application.'' (Florida Power Corp at 11-13; 
    Utilities For Improved Transition at 50-53). Similarly, EEI argues that 
    to obtain a priority for continuation of service, customers must be 
    seeking service that is substantially similar to or a continuation of 
    the service they already receive and must be subject to a time limit on 
    the reservation priority. CSW Operating Companies assert that it is 
    unclear how the right of first refusal provision will be implemented.
    
    State Commission Position
    
        VT DPS states that the right of first refusal provision offers 
    inadequate protection: ``While it is true that the existing customer 
    could secure a five year transmission arrangement under a new contract, 
    its right to continuous service is placed in jeopardy if it does not 
    match the six year offer of the competing bidder.'' VT DPS argues that 
    the Commission's bare bones provision opens the opportunity for 
    competitive mischief by the transmission provider. VT DPS proposes that 
    ``the existing customer should be able to renew its contract by 
    matching the highest transmission price offered in the marketplace (up 
    to the tariff maximum rate) and by offering to extend its contract for 
    seven years or the prevailing length of firm transmission contracts in 
    the marketplace, whichever is shorter.'' (VT DPS at 17-21).
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        In this order, the Commission reaffirms its decision to give a 
    reservation priority to existing and future firm transmission customers 
    served under a contract of one year or more, and also addresses 
    petitioner arguments regarding the Commission-imposed limitations 
    associated with the exercise of that priority.
    
    Rationale
    
        Our policy rationale for giving an existing firm transmission 
    customer (requirements and transmission-only),\50\ served under a 
    contract of one year or more, a reservation priority (right of first 
    refusal) when its contract expires is that it provides a mechanism for 
    allocating transmission capacity when there is insufficient capacity to 
    accommodate all requestors. If there are capacity limitations and both 
    customers (existing and potential) are willing to pay for firm 
    transmission service of the same duration, the right of first refusal 
    provides a tie-breaking mechanism that gives priority to existing 
    customers so that they may continue to receive transmission 
    service.\51\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \50\ We clarify that we did not intend the term ``all firm 
    transmission customers'' to include only requirements and 
    transmission-only customers, but intended that it include all 
    bundled firm customers as well.
        \51\ We reject Tallahassee's argument that the right of first 
    refusal should accrue to the power customer paying the bundled rate 
    and not to any intermediary acting on its behalf. Our right of first 
    refusal mechanism is simply a tie-breaker that gives priority to 
    existing firm transmission customers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Contract Term Limitation
    
        We reject arguments to modify the requirement in section 2.2 that 
    existing long-term firm transmission customers seeking to exercise 
    their right of first refusal must agree to a contract term at least as 
    long as that sought by a potential customer. The objective of a right 
    of first refusal is to allow an existing firm transmission customer to 
    continue to receive transmission service under terms that are just, 
    reasonable, not unduly discriminatory, or preferential. Absent the 
    requirement that the customer match the contract term of a competing 
    request, utilities could be forced to enter into shorter-term 
    arrangements that could be detrimental from both an operational 
    standpoint (system planning) and a financial standpoint.
    
    Rate Limitation
    
        We also reject the proposition that either existing wholesale 
    customers or transmission providers providing service to retail native 
    load customers should be insulated from the possibility of having to 
    pay an increased rate for transmission in the future. The fact that 
    existing customers historically have been served under a particular 
    rate design does not serve to ``grandfather'' that rate methodology in 
    perpetuity. Because the purpose of the right of first refusal provision 
    is to be a tie-breaker, the competing requests should be substantially 
    the same in all respects.\52\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \52\ The proposal to restrict the right of first refusal 
    provision to exactly the same points of receipt and delivery as the 
    terminating service would competitively disadvantage existing 
    customers seeking new sources of generation. However, as we stated 
    in Order No. 888, if the customer chooses a new power supplier and 
    this substantially changes the location or direction of the power 
    flows it imposes on the transmission provider's system, the 
    customer's right to continue taking transmission service from its 
    existing transmission provider may be affected by transmission 
    constraints associated with the change. FERC Stats. & Regs. at 
    31,666 n.176; mimeo at 89 n.176.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In response to Blue Ridge's concern regarding a discrepancy between 
    the language in section 2.2 of the tariff and the preamble, we clarify 
    that existing customers who exercise their right of first refusal will 
    be required to pay the just and reasonable rate, as approved by the 
    Commission at the time that their contract ends.\53\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \53\ As Order No. 888 indicates, they may be required to pay the 
    transmission provider's maximum transmission rate.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Mechanics of the Right of First Refusal Process
    
        CSW Operating Companies asked the Commission to clarify the 
    mechanics of exercising the right of first refusal. We have determined 
    not to specify in this order the mechanics by which the right of first 
    refusal mechanism will be exercised for existing firm transmission 
    arrangements. Instead, we intend to address such issues on a case-by-
    case basis, if and when a dispute arises. However, we encourage 
    utilities and their customers to include specific procedures for 
    exercising the right of first refusal in future transmission service 
    agreements executed under the pro forma tariff. And of course, 
    utilities are free to make section 205 filings to propose additions to 
    the pro forma tariff to generically specify procedures for dealing with 
    the issues.
    
    Existing Contracts
    
        By providing existing customers a right of first refusal, we are 
    not, as PSNM claims, abrogating contracts. Moreover, PSNM's concern 
    that the right of first refusal will prohibit utilities from 
    ``recalling'' existing capacity to meet native load growth that was 
    anticipated at the time existing third-party transmission contracts 
    were executed can be addressed in the context of a specific filing by a 
    utility demonstrating that it had no reasonable expectation of 
    continuing to provide transmission service to the wholesale 
    transmission customer at the end of its contract. For future 
    transmission contracts, Order No. 888 permits utilities to reserve 
    existing transmission capacity to serve the needs (current and 
    reasonably forecasted) of its existing native load (retail) customers. 
    Moreover, if a utility provides firm transmission service to a third 
    party for a time until native load needs the capacity, it should 
    specify in the contract that the right of first refusal does not apply 
    to that firm service due to a reasonably forecasted need at the time 
    the contract is executed.
    
    Informational Filings
    
        With respect to all existing requirements contracts and tariffs 
    that provide for bundled rates, the Commission, in the Final Rule, 
    required all public utilities to make informational
    
    [[Page 12289]]
    
    filings setting forth the unbundled power and transmission rates 
    reflected in those contracts and tariffs.54
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \54\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,665-66; mimeo at 89-90.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Requests for Rehearing
    
        Utilities For Improved Transition and VEPCO ask the Commission to 
    clarify whether the unbundled transmission rate should be the current 
    transmission tariff rate (bundled rate likely not to include the 
    current price for transmission service) or an approximation of the rate 
    at the time the contract was executed (may be impossible to determine).
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We previously addressed the determination of the unbundled 
    transmission rate in informational filings in an order issued October 
    16, 1996.55 In that order, we noted that Order No. 888 does not 
    prescribe any specific method for calculating separately-stated 
    transmission and generation rates and public utilities have used 
    different methods in their informational filings. Because of the 
    general lack of controversy over the informational filings and the fact 
    that they are for informational purposes as a benefit to existing 
    customers, the Commission accepted the vast majority of the 
    informational filings. The Commission added, however, that it did not 
    consider the informational rates binding for any future transactions. 
    Accordingly, we need not now prescribe a specific method to calculate 
    the unbundled transmission rate included in informational filings.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \55\ 77 FERC para. 61,025.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Existing Contracts
    
        In the Final Rule, the Commission explained that because it was not 
    abrogating existing requirements and transmission contracts generically 
    and because the functional unbundling requirement applies only to new 
    wholesale services, the terms and conditions of the Final Rule pro 
    forma tariff do not apply to service under existing requirements 
    contracts.56
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \56\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,665; mimeo at 87-88.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        San Francisco asks that the Commission clarify that nothing in 
    Order No. 888 is intended to affect prices, or price-setting 
    methodologies, in existing contracts.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        By order issued July 2, 1996, we clarified that
    
        the filing of an open access compliance tariff on or before July 
    9, 1996 does not supersede an existing transmission agreement that 
    has been accepted by the Commission unless specifically permitted in 
    the agreement on file. If a utility seeks to modify or terminate an 
    existing transmission agreement, it must separately file to modify 
    or terminate such contracts under appropriate procedures under 
    section 205 or 206 of the Federal Power Act, consistent with the 
    terms of its contract.[57]
    
        \57\ 76 FERC para. 61,009 at 61,028 (1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Thus, nothing in Order No. 888 affects prices or price-setting 
    methodologies in existing contracts, unless specifically permitted in 
    the contract on file.
    6. Flow-based Contracting and Pricing
        In Order No. 888, the Commission explained that it would not, at 
    that time, require that flow-based pricing and contracting be used in 
    the electric industry.58 It recognized that there may be 
    difficulties in using a traditional contract path approach in a non-
    discriminatory open access transmission environment. At the same time, 
    however, the Commission noted that contract path pricing and 
    contracting is the longstanding approach used in the electric industry 
    and it is the approach familiar to all participants in the industry. 
    Thus, the Commission was concerned that to require a dramatic overhaul 
    of the traditional approach--such as a shift to some form of flow-based 
    pricing and contracting--could severely slow, if not derail for some 
    time, the move to open access and more competitive wholesale bulk power 
    markets. In addition, the Commission indicated its belief that it would 
    be premature to impose generically a new pricing regime without the 
    benefit of any experience with such pricing. Accordingly, the 
    Commission welcomed new and innovative proposals, but determined not to 
    impose some form of flow-based pricing or contracting in the Final 
    Rule.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \58\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,668; mimeo at 96-98.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        American Forest & Paper argues that contract path pricing should be 
    prohibited. American Forest & Paper asserts that QFs and other 
    independents are being forced by contract path wheeling utilities to 
    indemnify them from liability for third-party claims of inadvertent 
    flow costs resulting from the transaction, while paying postage stamp 
    rates for the entire amount of contracted transmission. American Forest 
    & Paper supports an average postage stamp rate by region, with the 
    utilities within the region agreeing on a way to divide up the rate 
    appropriately.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        As the Commission explained in the Final Rule, we are concerned 
    that a dramatic overhaul of the traditional contract path approach 
    could slow or derail the move to open access and, in any event, is 
    premature without the benefit of any experience with alternative 
    pricing regimes. The Commission, however, welcomes new and innovative 
    proposals from the industry. American Forest & Paper has not presented 
    a case-specific proposal of any detail that would provide the 
    Commission and interested parties the opportunity to test the 
    appropriateness of a change from the contract path approach. Until the 
    Commission has such an opportunity, we are not prepared to change 
    generically the traditional contract path approach with which the 
    electric industry is so familiar.
        Moreover, American Forest & Paper's proposal to prohibit contract 
    path pricing and mandate regional postage-stamp rates would be 
    inconsistent with the rate flexibility that the Commission provided in 
    the Transmission Pricing Policy Statement and embraced in the Final 
    Rule.
    
    B. Legal Authority
    
        In the Final Rule, the Commission responded to commenters 
    challenging the Commission's authority to require open access and 
    reaffirmed its conclusion in the NOPR that it has the authority under 
    the FPA to order wholesale transmission services in interstate commerce 
    to remedy undue discrimination by public utilities.59
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \59\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,668-79 and 31,686-87; mimeo at 
    98-129 and 148-51.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
    Authority To Order Open Access Tariffs
    
        Union Electric challenges the Commission's authority to require 
    wheeling based on arguments that: (1) the Rule overlooks the fact that 
    the AGD case 60 pertained to voluntary actions by the pipelines 
    and the Commission's imposition of open access requirements as a 
    condition on permitting the desired authorizations; (2) the Commission 
    incorrectly treats the Otter Tail case; 61 (3) the legislative 
    histories of the NGA and FPA are different and the legislative history 
    of the FPA does not support the Commission's authority to order 
    wheeling; (4) the Commission made prior contrary statements to the U.S.
    
    [[Page 12290]]
    
    Supreme Court [in its opposition to the grant of certiorari to review 
    the AGD decision] about the nature of Commission authority to order 
    open access and judicial construction of that authority in AGD and 
    Otter Tail;'' (5) as a matter of statutory construction, the Commission 
    cannot rely on sections 205 and 206, which are silent as to wheeling, 
    when sections 211 and 212 contain express wheeling provisions; (6) the 
    four relevant cases recognized by the Commission indicate that the 
    Commission may not directly or indirectly order a public utility to 
    wheel or transmit energy for another entity under sections 205 and 206, 
    notwithstanding the Commission's circumscribed ability to order 
    wheeling under sections 211 and 212; (7) prior to the issuance of the 
    Final Rule the Commission, with a full appreciation of the legislative 
    history behind Part II, consistently held that it lacks the authority 
    to order wheeling under FPA Part II; (8) the Rule fails to assign 
    ``considerable importance'' to the Commission's ``longstanding 
    interpretation of the statute in accordance with its literal 
    language;'' and (9) in legislative hearings preceding enactment of 
    EPAct, the Office of the General Counsel acknowledged the limitations 
    on the Commission's wheeling power.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \60\ Associated Gas Distributors v. FERC, 824 F.2d 981, 998 
    (D.C. Cir. 1987), cert. denied, 485 U.S. 1006 (1988) (AGD).
        \61\ Otter Tail Power Company v. FPC, 410 U.S. 366 (1974) (Otter 
    Tail).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Carolina P&L also challenges the Commission's authority to order 
    open access tariffs, arguing that: (1) Otter Tail specifically states: 
    ``So far as wheeling is concerned, there is no authority granted the 
    commission under Part II of the Federal Power Act to order it, * * *''; 
    (2) the Richmond and FPL cases 62 prohibit the Commission from 
    doing indirectly what it cannot do directly; (3) the AGD case does not 
    support the Commission's authority to order open access through the 
    filing of generic tariffs--in AGD the Commission's authority was based 
    on voluntary actions by the affected pipelines and there are 
    substantial differences between the NGA and the FPA; (4) the 
    legislative history of EPAct indicates that the Commission does not 
    have the authority to mandate open access and can only order open 
    access if section 211 procedures are followed--citing NYSEG and FPL; 
    and (5) section 211 limits the Commission's authority to order open 
    access on a generic basis--where a specific statute addresses an issue, 
    a more general statute should not be read in a manner that conflicts 
    with the specific statute.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \62\ Richmond Power & Light Company v. FERC, 574 F.2d 610 (D.C. 
    Cir. 1978) (Richmond) and Florida Power & Light Company v. FERC, 660 
    F.2d 668 (5th Cir. 1981), cert. denied sub nom. Fort Pierce 
    Utilities Authority v. FERC, 459 U.S. 1156 (1983) (FPL).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        PA Com argues that the Commission's reliance on AGD ``impermissibly 
    expands the limited holding of AGD'' and the Commission improperly 
    relied on sections 205 and 206 of the FPA to require open access 
    generically--the Commission only has case-by-case jurisdiction.
        VA Com declares that the plain meaning of the FPA and cases 
    interpreting sections 206 and 211 show that the Commission does not 
    have the authority to order industry-wide open access.
        FL Com and El Paso argue that the Commission only has limited 
    authority to order wheeling and that the Commission has not made the 
    required findings under section 211.\63\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \63\ We note that Indianapolis P&L also has made legal arguments 
    regarding our authority to order wheeling under Order No. 888. 
    However, it did so in a request for rehearing of a denial of its 
    request for waiver of the Order No. 888 requirements, not in its 
    request for rehearing of Order No. 888. Accordingly, we will address 
    its arguments when we act on its request for rehearing of its waiver 
    denial.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Group Two Section 205 Filings
    
        Union Electric argues that the requirement that Group 2 Public 
    Utilities make section 205 filings is contrary to the voluntary filing 
    scheme inherent in section 205.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
    Overview
    
        The fundamental legal question before us is the scope of the 
    authority granted to the Commission in 1935 to remedy undue 
    discrimination in interstate transmission services and whether that 
    authority permits us sufficient flexibility to define undue 
    discrimination in light of dramatically changed industry circumstances, 
    in order to provide electricity customers the benefits of more 
    competitively priced power. In the NOPR and Order No. 888, the 
    Commission comprehensively examined case law and legislative history 
    relevant to our authority to order open access transmission services as 
    a remedy for undue discrimination.\64\ We also responded at length in 
    Order No. 888 to arguments that questioned our authority to take this 
    step.\65\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \64\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,668-73; mimeo at 98-112. Notice 
    of Proposed Rulemaking and Supplemental Notice of Proposed 
    Rulemaking, FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 32,514 at 33,053-56 (1995).
        \65\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,673-79; mimeo at 112-129.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        On rehearing, as described above, only a few parties continue to 
    question the Commission's authority. As a general matter their 
    rehearings do not raise any arguments, cases, or legislative history 
    not previously considered, and they do not convince us that our action 
    in Order No. 888 is not within our authority under sections 205 and 206 
    of the FPA. We therefore reaffirm our determination that we have not 
    only the legal authority, but the responsibility, to order the filing 
    of non-discriminatory open access tariffs if we find such order 
    necessary to remedy undue discrimination or anticompetitive effects.
        There are several broad points we wish to emphasize in response to 
    the rehearings that have been filed:
        First, there is no dispute that the FPA does not explicitly give 
    this Commission authority to order, sua sponte, open access 
    transmission services by public utilities. However, the fact remains 
    that the FPA does explicitly require this Commission to remedy undue 
    discrimination by public utilities.\66\ The finding of the D.C. Circuit 
    in the AGD case, with regard to sections 4 and 5 of the NGA (which 
    parallel sections 205 and 206 of the FPA), are equally applicable here: 
    the Act ``fairly bristles'' with concerns regarding undue 
    discrimination and it would turn statutory construction on its head to 
    let the failure to grant a general power prevail over the affirmative 
    grant of a specific one.\67\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \66\ See FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,669-70; mimeo at 101-03.
        \67\ 824 F.2d at 998.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Second, there also is no dispute that before Congress enacted the 
    FPA in 1935, it rejected provisions that would have explicitly granted 
    the Commission authority to order transmission to any person if the 
    Commission found it ``necessary or desirable in the public interest.'' 
    However, the fact that Congress rejected an extremely broad common 
    carrier provision does not limit the remedies available to the 
    Commission to enforce the undue discrimination provisions in the 
    FPA.\68\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \68\ See FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,676-78; mimeo at 120-27.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Third, entities on rehearing understandably have focused on 
    statements in case law that indicate limits on the Commission's 
    wheeling authority. They particularly focus on certain statements by 
    the Supreme Court in Otter Tail. The Commission in Order No. 888 fully 
    addressed and considered all relevant case law of which we are aware, 
    including statements in Otter Tail and other court cases indicating 
    limitations on our authority.\69\ We do not dispute these statements 
    and we
    
    [[Page 12291]]
    
    recognize limitations on our authorities. However, the fact remains 
    that none of the cases cited, including Otter Tail, involved the issue 
    of whether this Commission can order transmission as a remedy for undue 
    discrimination and none addressed industry-wide circumstances such as 
    those before us in Order No. 888.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \69\ See FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,668-73; mimeo at 98-110.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Fourth, while Congress in 1978 gave the Commission certain case-by-
    case authority to order transmission access by both public utilities 
    and non-public utilities, and broadened this case-by-case authority in 
    1992, Congress also specifically provided in section 212(e) of the FPA 
    that the case-by-case authorities were not to be construed as limiting 
    or impairing any authority of the Commission under any other provision 
    of law.\70\ Indeed, the legislative history of EPAct shows that when 
    Congress amended the section 211-212 wheeling provisions and the 
    section 212(e) savings clause in 1992,\71\ it was well aware of 
    arguments regarding the scope of the Commission's wheeling authority as 
    a remedy for undue discrimination under section 206. Whereas Congress 
    in 1992 decided to add a flat prohibition on the Commission ordering 
    direct retail wheeling under any provision of the FPA, it did not add a 
    prohibition on the Commission ordering wholesale wheeling to remedy 
    undue discrimination under section 206. It instead retained and 
    modified the savings clause. The issue before us, therefore, hinges on 
    the scope of authority given to this Commission to remedy undue 
    discrimination, not on the scope of authority given to us in 1978 and 
    1992.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \70\ See FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,686-87; mimeo at 148-49.
        \71\ The savings clause in section 212(e) originally provided 
    that no provision of section 210 or 211 shall be treated as 
    ``limiting, impairing, or otherwise affecting any authority of the 
    Commission under any other provision of law.'' In 1992, the 212(e) 
    savings clause was amended to provide that sections 210, 211 and 214 
    ``shall not be construed as limiting or impairing any authority of 
    the Commission under any other provision of law.''
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission is significantly influenced by the decision and case 
    law discussion by the D.C. Circuit in the AGD case. This court opinion 
    contains the most recent and comprehensive discussion of the 
    Commission's legal authority to remedy undue discrimination under NGA 
    provisions that mirror those in the FPA, including the relevant case 
    law concerning the Commission's authority to order transmission under 
    the FPA.\72\ The rehearing arguments do not, and we believe cannot, 
    reconcile the AGD court's discussion and findings with a conclusion 
    that the Commission cannot under any circumstances (as these parties 
    advocate) order wheeling under sections 205 and 206 to remedy undue 
    discrimination.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \72\ AGD, 824 F.2d at 996-999. See also FERC Stats. & Regs. at 
    31,668-73, 31,676-78; mimeo at 98-110 and 120-27.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In sum, we believe that the essential question of the Commission's 
    legal authority to impose the requirements of Order No. 888 turns on 
    the flexibility of the Commission's remedial authority under sections 
    205 and 206 of the FPA to remedy undue discrimination. As was true with 
    respect to the natural gas industry, we acknowledge that Commission 
    precedent for many years nurtured the expectation that we would not, 
    under our authority under the FPA, preclude utilities from using their 
    monopoly power over the nation's transmission systems to secure their 
    monopoly position as power suppliers. However, as described at length 
    in Order No. 888, these policies arose in the context of practical, 
    economic, and regulatory circumstances that gave rise to vertically 
    integrated monopolies and little, if any, competition among power 
    suppliers. In this kind of regime, the interests of customers were most 
    effectively served by the kind of cost-based regulatory regime that has 
    prevailed until very recently. The evolution of third-party generation, 
    facilitated by PURPA and significant technological advances, 
    dramatically altered the economics of power production. The enactment 
    of EPAct recognized these changes and established a national policy 
    intended to favor the development of a competitive generation market, 
    so that the efficiencies of the new marketplace will be available to 
    customers in the form of lower costs for electricity. Utility practices 
    that may have been acceptable a few years ago would, if permitted to 
    continue, smother the fledgling competitive wholesale markets and 
    undermine the efforts of customers to seek lower-price electricity. We 
    firmly believe that our authorities under the FPA not only permit us to 
    adapt to changing economic realities in the electric industry, but also 
    require us to do so, if that is necessary to eliminate undue 
    discrimination and protect electricity customers.
    
    Specific Arguments \73\
    
    The Factual Circumstances Underlying AGD Do Not Mandate A Different 
    Conclusion In This Proceeding
    
        Both Union Electric and Carolina P&L argue that the Commission 
    cannot rely on AGD in support of its actions in the electric industry, 
    and they attempt to distinguish the legal basis on which the Commission 
    acted in requiring open access transportation for gas pipelines. 
    Specifically, they argue that AGD (Order No. 436) pertained to 
    voluntary actions by gas pipelines and that the Commission's imposition 
    of open access requirements was a condition of certificate 
    authorizations to transport gas, whereas the Commission's action in 
    Order No. 888 is a direct mandate.\74\ We believe this is a distinction 
    without a difference. While it is true that the Commission required 
    open access as a condition of granting blanket authorizations for 
    pipelines and authorizations for pipelines authorizing pipelines to 
    transport natural gas,\75\ the critical point is that in both Order No. 
    436 and Order No. 888 the Commission's actions hinged as a legal matter 
    on the parallel provisions of the NGA (sections 4 and 5) and the FPA 
    (sections 205 and 206) that prohibit undue discrimination. Whether 
    persons are seeking to transport natural gas or wheel electric power in 
    interstate commerce, by law they must not unduly discriminate or grant 
    undue preference.\76\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \73\ We do not repeat our lengthy legal analyses in Order No. 
    888, but discuss only those arguments that warrant further 
    discussion.
        \74\ See Union Electric and Carolina P&L.
        \75\ These authorizations are issued under section 7 of the 
    Natural Gas Act and section 311 of the Natural Gas Policy Act.
        \76\ While there is a difference in the statutes in that natural 
    gas transporters must obtain a certificate from the Commission 
    before they can transport gas, there is no difference in the 
    statutory standard applied to the interstate service.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In AGD, the court upheld the Commission's reliance upon sections 4 
    and 5 of the NGA to impose an open-access commitment on any pipeline 
    that secured a blanket certificate to provide gas transportation under 
    section 7 of the NGA or provided transportation under section 311 of 
    the NGPA.\77\ Order No. 436 was not a simple order that relied on the 
    ``voluntary actions'' of affected pipelines. As the court in AGD 
    understood:
    
        \77\ 824 F.2d at 997-98. The court also noted the Commission's 
    reliance on section 16 of the NGA.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Order envisages a complete restructuring of the natural gas 
    industry. It may well come to rank with the three great regulatory 
    milestones of the industry.* * *
    
    [[Page 12292]]
    
        At stake is the role of interstate natural gas pipelines. 
    Although they are obviously transporters of gas, they have until 
    recently operated primarily as gas merchants. They buy gas from 
    producers at the wellhead and resell it, mainly to local 
    distribution companies (``LDCs'') but also to relatively large end 
    users. The Commission has concluded that a prevailing pipeline 
    practice--particularly their general refusal to transport gas for 
    third parties where to do so would displace their own sales--has 
    caused serious market distortions. It has found this practice 
    ``unduly discriminatory'' within the meaning of Sec. 5 of the NGA. 
    Order 436 is its response.
        The essence of Order No. 436 is a tendency, in the industry 
    metaphor, to ``unbundle'' the pipelines' transportation and merchant 
    roles. If it is effective, the pipelines will transport the gas with 
    which their own sales compete; competition from other gas sellers 
    (producers or traders) will give consumers the benefit of a 
    competitive wellhead market. [\78\]
    
        \78\ 824 F.2d at 993-94.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Indeed, since Order No. 436 issued, virtually all jurisdictional 
    natural gas pipelines became ``open access'' transporters of natural 
    gas.
        In analyzing the Commission's authority to remedy undue 
    discrimination, the court never made the distinctions now being put 
    forth by Union Electric and Carolina P&L. Rather, the court 
    specifically focused on the Commission's authority under section 5 of 
    the NGA and upheld the Commission's authority to remedy undue 
    discrimination in the transportation of natural gas by requiring 
    pipelines transporting natural gas to do so on a non-discriminatory 
    basis.\79\ Similarly, the Commission in Order No. 888 found undue 
    discrimination in the transmission of electric energy and required, 
    pursuant to section 206 of the FPA (the FPA provision that parallels 
    section 5 of the NGA), that if public utilities transmit electric 
    energy in interstate commerce, they must do so on a non-discriminatory 
    basis (i.e., offer non-discriminatory open access transmission).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \79\ For example, as the AGD court explained with regard to its 
    discussion of Maryland People's Counsel v. FERC, 761 F.2d 780 (D.C. 
    Cir. 1985), ``we made it clear that blanket-certificate 
    transportation, unconstrained by any nondiscriminatory access 
    provision, might well require remedial action under Sec. 5.'' 824 
    F.2d at 1000.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Moreover, while the Commission may have imposed a ``condition'' on 
    pipelines obtaining blanket certificates or providing section 311 
    transportation in Order No. 436, this does not detract from the court's 
    core finding in AGD that the Commission had the authority under section 
    5 of the NGA to remedy undue discrimination by requiring open access 
    transportation.\80\ The Commission chose in Order No. 436 to impose its 
    open access remedy as a condition to pipelines obtaining a blanket 
    certificate to transport natural gas, but its authority was rooted in 
    the undue discrimination provisions of section 5. Additionally, the 
    practical result of the conditioning was that all jurisdictional 
    pipelines would have to provide open access transportation, a result 
    that was clearly anticipated by the AGD court.\81\ Thus, there is no 
    distinction in the result intended, or the result achieved, in either 
    industry; in both cases, the intent was to remedy undue discrimination 
    pursuant to the statutes governing each industry, and in both cases the 
    result was that all transporters/transmitters must agree to open access 
    non-discriminatory services if they seek to continue owning, 
    controlling or operating monopoly interstate transportation facilities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \80\ We disagree with Union Electric that anything in the 
    Commission's brief to the Supreme Court, opposing certiorari of AGD, 
    contradicts our conclusion. We recognize, as the Commission 
    explained in that brief, that there is no equivalent to section 7 of 
    the NGA in the FPA. While this puts Order No. 888 on a somewhat 
    different factual basis from AGD, it has no material effect on 
    whether we have the authority to remedy undue discrimination by 
    requiring non-discriminatory open access transmission.
        \81\ See 824 F.2d at 993-94 (``The Order envisages a complete 
    restructuring of the natural gas industry. It may well come to rank 
    with the three great regulatory milestones of the industry. * * 
    *'').
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Legislative History Behind the FPA and EPAct Does Not Preclude Our 
    Action
    
        We disagree with the arguments that the legislative history behind 
    Part II of the FPA establishes that the Commission cannot under any 
    circumstance order wheeling under FPA sections 205 and 206.82 We 
    examined the legislative history of sections 205 and 206 at length in 
    the NOPR and Order No. 888 and concluded that it supports our authority 
    to order open access transmission as a remedy for undue 
    discrimination.83 We also have examined the legislative history of 
    the EPAct amendments to sections 211 and 212 and conclude that Congress 
    in EPAct did not resolve the issue of our authority under sections 205 
    and 206 and left untouched whatever pre-existing authorities we had 
    under these sections. The parties have raised nothing new on rehearing 
    to persuade us that our interpretation is wrong. However, there are 
    several arguments that we believe warrant further discussion.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \82\ Parties have raised the legislative history of sections 205 
    and 206, as well as the legislative history of the EPAct amendments 
    to sections 211 and 212.
        \83\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,676-78; mimeo at 120-27. Notice 
    of Proposed Rulemaking and Supplemental Notice of Proposed 
    Rulemaking, FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 32,514 at 33,053-56 (1995). 
    Union Electric points to a statement in the Commission's 1987 brief 
    to the U.S. Supreme Court, opposing certiorari of the AGD case; in 
    that brief the Commission pointed out that the Supreme Court had 
    noted, in Otter Tail, that the legislative histories of the FPA and 
    NGA are ``materially different.'' As we explained in Order No. 888, 
    we have thoroughly reexamined the legislative histories of the NGA 
    and FPA with respect to this issue and now conclude that there is no 
    material difference as to this issue in the legislative histories of 
    the two statutes. Further, such a difference, whether or not it 
    exists, was not crucial to the fundamental holdings of the AGD court 
    and does not preclude that decision from applying equally in the 
    electric industry. See FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,676-78; mimeo at 
    121-26. We also note that in its brief to the Supreme Court the 
    Commission explicitly stated that neither Otter Tail nor any of the 
    other electric cases cited ``presented the question whether the 
    Commission could order wheeling to remedy undue discrimination or 
    anticompetitive behavior. * * *'' FERC Brief at 25 (footnote 
    omitted).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Parties on rehearing argue that the existence of sections 211 and 
    212 limit the Commission's wheeling authority and, in effect, remove 
    our authority under section 206 to order any transmission as a remedy 
    for undue discrimination.84 We disagree. In enacting EPAct, 
    Congress did not resolve the extent of our wheeling authority outside 
    the context of sections 211 and 212.85 As we explained above, 
    while Congress in 1978 gave the Commission certain case-by-case 
    authority to order transmission access, it also specifically provided 
    in section 212(e) of the FPA that the case-by-case authorities were not 
    to be construed as limiting or impairing any authority of the 
    Commission under any other provision of law. Congress retained a 
    similar savings clause when it amended sections 211 and 212 in 1992. 
    Moreover, the legislative history of EPAct shows that when Congress 
    amended sections 211 and 212, it was well aware of arguments regarding 
    the scope of the Commission's remedial authority under section 
    206.86 Whereas Congress added an amendment prohibiting the 
    Commission from ordering direct retail wheeling under any provision of 
    the FPA, it chose not to add a prohibition on the Commission ordering 
    wholesale wheeling as a remedy for undue
    
    [[Page 12293]]
    
    discrimination under sections 205 and 206.87
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \84\ See discussion supra concerning AGD court's understanding 
    that Order No. 436 was not a simple order that relied on voluntary 
    actions of affected pipelines.
        \85\ Contrary to certain assertions, in Order No. 888 we viewed 
    the statute as a whole and determined that section 211 in no way 
    limited the broad authority Congress gave us to eradicate undue 
    discrimination in the electric power industry.
        \86\ See note 71 and related discussion, supra.
        \87\ In response to Carolina P&L's argument that Congress gave 
    the Commission a specific remedy under section 211 and the 
    Commission should not presume that it has additional remedies in 
    such a circumstance, we do not believe that section 211 can credibly 
    be viewed either as a partial substitute for, or as superseding, the 
    sections 205-206 undue discrimination remedial authority that is 
    fundamental to the Federal Power Act. Indeed, section 211 is not 
    written in terms of providing remedial authority to address undue 
    discrimination but rather provides for case-by-case transmission 
    service on request if the service is in the public interest and 
    meets the other criteria in sections 211 and 212.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We are not persuaded that this conclusion is wrong based on 
    rehearing arguments that we ignored other legislative history of EPAct. 
    Carolina P&L argues that we ignored various statements of Senator 
    Wallop following the enactment of EPAct, which it alleges are counter 
    to our claim of authority to order open access transmission as a remedy 
    for undue discrimination. The utility is simply in error that we 
    ignored these statements. We explicitly mentioned Senator Wallop's 
    statements in Order No. 888 and gave our rationale for why section 211 
    does not limit our authority to remedy undue discrimination.88 
    However, we believe it is important to elaborate on the context in 
    which those statements were made and our interpretation of those 
    statements.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \88\ FERC Stat. & Regs. at 31,686-87; mimeo at 148-51.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The primary focus of Senator Wallop's statements is on the 
    transmission authority given by the EPAct amendments to sections 211 
    and 212. These statements emphasize restrictions on our section 211 
    wheeling authority, including the fact that section 211 does not give 
    the Commission authority to order transmission access on its own motion 
    or to order open access transmission.89 We do not quarrel with 
    these statements because sections 211 and 212 clearly do place 
    restrictions on our authority to order access under those provisions. 
    The statements also discuss the differences between the House 
    introduced amendments to sections 211 and 212 (which would have 
    provided broader and in some instances mandatory access authority) and 
    the amendments that finally passed (which were more limited). We also 
    do not disagree that changes were made to the bill that originally was 
    introduced. At issue here, however, is not whether there are 
    restrictions on our section 211 authority, but rather whether we have 
    authority outside the context of section 211 to order transmission as a 
    remedy for undue discrimination. The only statement among Senator 
    Wallop's remarks that addresses this specific issue is one in which he 
    says, ``In my opinion, neither the amendments made by this Act nor 
    existing law give the FERC any authority to mandate open access 
    transmission tariffs for electrical utilities.'' (emphasis added). We 
    do not view one senator's opinion as in any way dispositive of the 
    issue. As discussed supra, when Congress enacted the 1992 section 211 
    amendments it was well aware of the outstanding legal issue of the 
    Commission's authority to order access as a remedy for undue 
    discrimination under section 206. It chose not to clarify this issue by 
    prohibiting the Commission from ordering access, but instead retained 
    the savings clause in section 212(e).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \89\ Most of the statements talk in terms of ``The Conference 
    Report provides. . . .'' and thus are referring only to the section 
    211 and 212 provisions. See, e.g., 138 Cong. Rec. 517616 (Oct. 8, 
    1992).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The issue of our legal authority thus turns on the undue 
    discrimination authority given to us in 1935, and the legislative 
    history of sections 205 and 206. We discussed this at length in Order 
    No. 888.90 On rehearing, several entities emphasize the Otter Tail 
    case and the legislative history referred to in that case. In 
    particular, Union Electric recites Justice Stewart's discussion of the 
    legislative history in his partial dissent in Otter Tail. We do not 
    interpret that discussion to suggest that we do not have the authority 
    to remedy undue discrimination by requiring open access transmission 
    under any circumstance. As we explained in Order No. 888:
    
        \90\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,676-78; mimeo at 120-27.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In the FPA, while Congress elected not to impose common carrier 
    status on the electric power industry, it tempered that 
    determination by explicitly providing the Commission with the 
    authority to eradicate undue discrimination--one of the goals of 
    common carriage regulation. By providing this broad authority to the 
    Commission, it assured itself that in preserving ``the voluntary 
    action of the utilities'' it was not allowing this voluntary action 
    to be unfettered. It would be far-reaching indeed to conclude that 
    Otter Tail, which was a civil antitrust suit that raised issues 
    entirely unrelated to our authority under section 206, is an 
    impediment to achieving one of the primary goals of the FPA--
    eradicating undue discrimination in transmission in interstate 
    commerce in the electric power industry. [91]
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \91\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,670; mimeo at 103.
    
        In response to Union Electric's arguments that Congress explicitly 
    rejected common carrier provisions in 1935, we do not disagree with 
    Union Electric's statement that ``the mandatory wheeling language was 
    not dropped inadvertently.'' 92 The point that we made in Order 
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    No. 888 (quoting AGD) in this regard was that
    
        \92\ Union Electric at 26.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        (1) ``Congress declined itself to impose common carrier status'' 
    (emphasis added) and (2) there is no ``support for the idea that the 
    Commission could under no circumstances whatsoever impose 
    obligations encompassing the core of a common carriage duty.'' 
    [93]
    
        \93\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,677; mimeo at 122.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Nowhere did we ever suggest that the mandatory wheeling language was 
    dropped inadvertently; we simply distinguish a general common carrier 
    obligation imposed ``in the public interest'' from an obligation to 
    provide transmission service deemed necessary to eliminate undue 
    discrimination. Finally, we fully agree with Union Electric's statement 
    that
    
    [a]lthough this ``first Federal effort'' occurred in 1935, the 
    resulting FPA Sections 205 and 206 have not been modified in any 
    relevant respect since that time. Therefore, the range of authority 
    conveyed to the Commission in such sections remains the same today 
    as it did then. [94]
    
        \94\ Union Electric at 27.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    We never suggested otherwise and our conclusion in Order No. 888 is not 
    based on a finding to the contrary.
    
    Case Law Does Not Prohibit Our Ordering Wheeling Under Sections 205 
    and 206 of the FPA
    
        Union Electric, discussing the very cases cited by the Commission 
    in Order No. 888, asserts that ``the Commission fails to recognize 
    their dispositive results prohibiting it from ordering wheeling under 
    the Sections 205 and 206 of the FPA.'' 95 We thoroughly examined 
    all of the case law cited by Union Electric, as evidenced by our 
    discussions in the NOPR and Order No. 888, and disagree that any of 
    those cases prohibit the Commission from ordering wheeling under 
    sections 205 and 206 of the FPA to remedy undue discrimination. Indeed, 
    the AGD court reached the same conclusion.96
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \95\ Union Electric at 30.
        \96\ The only relevant case the AGD court did not discuss was 
    NYSEG. As we explained in Order No. 888, presumably this was because 
    the case did not concern whether the Commission could order wheeling 
    as a remedy for undue discrimination. FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,672 
    n.217; mimeo at 108 n.217.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Union Electric further cites to a variety of FPC cases that it 
    claims demonstrate that the Final Rule exceeds the Commission's 
    statutory authority.97 It appears to have proffered every negative 
    Commission statement it could find with respect to our authority to 
    order wheeling under Part II of the FPA.
    
    [[Page 12294]]
    
    As in the Commission cases cited, we recognize that our authority to 
    order transmission service is not unbounded; if we order transmission, 
    it must be within the scope of authority available to us under the FPA. 
    However, the fact is that none of the cases cited as establishing 
    limits on the Commission's authority addresses the issue before us now, 
    i.e., the Commission's authority to order transmission as a remedy for 
    undue discrimination. Simply stated, the Commission has never before 
    been faced with generic findings of undue discrimination in the 
    provision of interstate electric transmission services, and the extent 
    of its authority to remedy that undue discrimination.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \97\ Union Electric at 33-37.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    The Commission's General Counsel Never Asserted, or Even Suggested, 
    That the Commission Does Not Have the Authority to Order Wheeling 
    as a Remedy for Undue Discrimination
    
        Union Electric spends several pages of its rehearing request 
    asserting that the Commission's own General Counsel has acknowledged 
    the limitations on the Commission's authority to order wheeling. 
    98 In particular, it points to a statement by a Commission OGC 
    witness that ``if Congress intends for the Commission to be able to 
    deal with transmission on its own motion and thereby go further than 
    simply dealing with industry proposals,'' Congress would need ``to 
    include an affirmative statement somewhere in the Act that the 
    Commission could require wheeling on its own motion.'' 99 This 
    same statement was previously raised by EEI and previously addressed in 
    Order No. 888. We do not disagree that this statement was made. 
    However, it must be read in the context of the witness' entire 
    testimony in which the witness stated four times the view that the case 
    law supports the argument that the Commission has authority to order 
    wheeling as a remedy for undue discrimination.100 Indeed, contrary 
    to Union Electric's assertion, the extensive legal analysis set forth 
    by the Commission's witness supports the position relied upon in this 
    proceeding.101 Thus, viewed in the context of the witness' entire 
    testimony, Union Electric's arguments to the contrary are unavailing. 
    Moreover, nowhere did the witness ever suggest, as asserted by Union 
    Electric, that FPA sections 205 and 206 could only be used ``to 
    eliminate unduly discriminatory terms in a wheeling arrangement 
    voluntarily filed with the Commission.'' 102
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \98\ Union Electric at 37-40.
        \99\ Union Electric at 38-39.
        \100\ Hearings on H.R. 1301, H.R. 1543, and H.R. 2224 before the 
    Subcommittee on Energy and Power of the House Committee on Energy 
    and Commerce, 102d Cong., 1st Sess. (May 1, 2 and June 26, 1991), 
    Statement of Cynthia A. Marlette, Associate General Counsel, Federal 
    Energy Regulatory Commission, Report No. 102-60 at 60 (``However, as 
    discussed below, there are strong legal arguments that the 
    Commission's obligation to protect against undue discrimination 
    carries with it the authority to impose transmission requirements as 
    a remedy for undue preference or discrimination.'' ``As discussed 
    below, although the case law in this area has been uncertain, in 
    OGC's opinion there is a strong legal argument that the Commission 
    can require transmission as a remedy for undue preference or undue 
    discrimination.''); at 69-70 (``The weight of the limited case law, 
    particularly the AGD opinion, supports authority to order wheeling 
    as a remedy for undue discrimination where substantial evidence 
    exists.''); at 106 (``I believe that we have substantial authority 
    under the existing case law to mandate access where necessary to 
    remedy anticompetitive effects.'').
        \101\ The statement quoted was preceded by a legal analysis of 
    the Commission's authorities under then existing law, including 
    section 206, and a statement that an examination of the Commission's 
    full authorities might further open up the industry. Further, it was 
    made in the context of case-by-case industry proposals and the 
    Commission's inability to require case-by-case wheeling on its own 
    motion. It did not address section 206 authority to remedy undue 
    discrimination.
        \102\ Union Electric at 39. We note that Union Electric did not 
    cite to any page or particular language to support its assertion.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    The Commission Has the Authority to Order Public Utilities to Make 
    Rate Filings in This Proceeding
    
        We reject Union Electric's argument that our requirement that Group 
    2 Public Utilities make section 205 filings is contrary to the 
    voluntary filing scheme inherent in section 205. It is true that the 
    Commission ordinarily cannot require a utility to make a section 205 
    filing. However, in this situation the section 205 filing was required 
    as a remedy under section 206 of the FPA to establish rates for non-
    discriminatory open access transmission. Acting pursuant to section 206 
    of the FPA, we found that undue discrimination exists in the wholesale 
    transmission of electric power and ordered the filing of non-
    discriminatory open access transmission tariffs to remedy this 
    discrimination. Section 206 further requires that upon such a finding 
    the Commission ``shall determine the just and reasonable rate, charge, 
    classification, rule, regulation, practice, or contract to be 
    thereafter observed and in force. * * *'' Thus, we had the authority to 
    set the rates that would be observed and in force following the 
    effectiveness of open access transmission and initially proposed to set 
    rates for each public utility. However, rather than take this intrusive 
    approach, which necessarily would have required a number of generic 
    assumptions and resulted in less than public utility-specific rates, 
    upon issuance of the Final Rule, we chose to permit these public 
    utilities to make section 205 filings to propose their own rates for 
    the services provided in the pro forma tariff.
    
    The Commission's Prior Failure to Order Wheeling as a Remedy for 
    Undue Discrimination Is Not Dispositive
    
        After discussing several cases that it asserts address the 
    Commission's authority to remedy undue discrimination, Carolina P&L 
    declares that ``[p]erhaps the strongest evidence that the Commission 
    lacks the power to compel wheeling under FPA section 206 is the fact 
    that the Commission has never previously exercised this alleged power, 
    despite numerous opportunities to do so.'' 103 However, the court 
    in AGD succinctly dismissed a similar argument:
    
        \103\ Carolina P&L at 35-36.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        It is finally argued that the Commission's not having imposed 
    any requirements like those of Order No. 436 in the period from 
    enactment in 1938 until the present demonstrates the lack of any 
    power to do so. * * * But as our introductory review of the economic 
    background sought to illustrate, the Commission here deals with 
    conditions that are altogether new. Thus no inference may be drawn 
    from prior non-use. [104]
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \104\ 824 F.2d at 1001. In this regard, we acknowledge that our 
    view of what constitutes undue discrimination has evolved 
    significantly in light of the dramatic economic changes in the 
    industry, as described briefly above and more fully in Order No. 
    888.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Undue Discrimination/Anticompetitive Effects 105
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \105\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,682-84; mimeo at 136-42.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A number of utilities and state commissions argue that the 
    Commission lacks evidence to support a finding of undue 
    discrimination.106
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \106\ E.g., El Paso, Union Electric, Carolina P&L, VA Com, FL 
    Com, PA Com.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        VA Com argues that the Commission failed to make a legally 
    supportable finding of industry-wide undue discrimination: ``FERC 
    apparently drew a conclusion that there was undue discrimination in the 
    NOPR without support and later accepted customers' allegations, without 
    further inquiry, and relied on them in making its finding of industry-
    wide undue discrimination.'' (VA Com at 2-3).
        PA Com and Carolina P&L assert that allegations of undue 
    discrimination do not form a sufficient basis to compel a generic 
    rulemaking. Not coming forward with specific accusations and the 
    identity of specific accusers, PA Com asserts, is unconstitutional as a 
    deprivation of due process.
    
    [[Page 12295]]
    
        With regard to specific allegations of undue discrimination, SoCal 
    Edison argues that the Commission inappropriately relied upon 
    allegations involving SoCal Edison as evidence of undue discrimination. 
    SoCal Edison asks that the Commission declare that it is not making a 
    factual determination as to any particular allegation especially since 
    prior to 1994 the Commission defined discrimination differently. Dalton 
    similarly argues that the Commission has no basis for finding that 
    Georgia Power Company is engaged in unlawful undue discrimination as to 
    new or roll-over transmission services in the operation of the 
    Integrated Transmission System in Georgia (ITS) under the ITS 
    agreement. Moreover, Dalton argues, even if it is found that GPC acted 
    in unduly discriminatory manner, it is not practical or lawful to order 
    open access tariff for new and roll-over services.
        Finally, Carolina P&L argues that the comparability standard does 
    not eliminate the ``requirement'' that parties must be similarly 
    situated before discrimination is present, and that the Commission has 
    not provided factual support for its implicit finding that public 
    utilities and their native load customers are similarly situated to 
    third parties. It cites City of Vernon v. FERC, 845 F.2d 1042 at 1045-
    46 (D.C. Cir. 1988), in support.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        As an initial matter, the Commission grants SoCal Edison's request 
    for clarification that in Order No. 888 we did not make a factual 
    determination as to any particular allegation of past discrimination 
    described in the Final Rule.107 However, we reject arguments that 
    the Commission cannot rely in part on the array of allegations and 
    circumstances raised by customers in individual cases over the years 
    and brought forth in response to the NOPR. The specific allegations are 
    illustrative. However, they present examples of the types of 
    discriminatory incentives and behavior inherent in ownership of 
    monopoly transmission facilities, and also present credible examples of 
    the types of discriminatory behavior in which public utilities could 
    engage in the future. We also reject arguments that customers and the 
    Commission must litigate and make specific findings of discrimination 
    against each public utility before we can take any action to preclude 
    discriminatory behavior that will harm competition and, ultimately, 
    electricity consumers. This is particularly true where the 
    discriminatory behavior clearly is in the economic self-interest of a 
    monopoly transmission owner facing the markedly increased competitive 
    pressures that are driving today's electric utility industry. As we 
    recognized in Order No. 888,
    
        \107\ In response to PA Com's and Carolina P&L's assertions that 
    not coming forward with specific accusations and identities of 
    specific accusers is unconstitutional and a deprivation of due 
    process, we emphasize that the Commission has not denied due process 
    to anyone. The Final Rule does not, nor is it intended to, make 
    specific findings as to any particular utility or any particular 
    allegation raised.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [t]he inherent characteristics of monopolists make it inevitable 
    that they will act in their own self-interest to the detriment of 
    others by refusing transmission and/or providing inferior 
    transmission to competitors in the bulk power markets to favor their 
    own generation, and it is our duty to eradicate unduly 
    discriminatory practices. As the AGD court stated: ``Agencies do not 
    need to conduct experiments in order to rely on the prediction that 
    an unsupported stone will fall.'' 108
    
        \108\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 331,682; mimeo at 136-37.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We believe that the same general discriminatory circumstances that 
    faced us when we required open access transportation in the natural gas 
    industry 109 are also before us today in the electric industry. 
    First, it is uncontested that market power continues to exist in the 
    ownership and operation of the monopoly-owned facilities that comprise 
    the nation's interstate transmission grid. Second, utilities, as a 
    general matter, did not in the past offer comparable transmission 
    services to competitors or to customers. Open access services simply 
    were not made available by utilities until the late 1980s when the 
    Commission began to impose open access as a condition of approval of 
    market-based rates and utility mergers in order to mitigate market 
    power and remedy anticompetitive effects. Rather, the vast majority of 
    utilities historically have declined to transport electric energy that 
    would compete with their own sales or have offered access that is 
    inferior to what they use for their own sales. Third, discrimination in 
    transmission services, when viewed in light of utilities' own uses of 
    their transmission systems compared to what they offer third parties, 
    has denied and will continue to deny customers access to electricity at 
    the lowest reasonable rates. The entities on rehearing have raised 
    nothing to persuade us that it is in the interests of consumers to 
    maintain the self-evident incentives for transmission owners to 
    exercise their monopoly power over transmission to discriminate in 
    favor of their own generation sales--incentives that will only increase 
    in the future as competitive pressures continue to escalate.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \109\ See AGD, 824 F.2d at 999-1000.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission addressed the same argument as that being made by 
    Carolina P&L, that the Commission has not made the requisite finding 
    that third-party transmission customers are similarly situated to 
    public utilities and their native load customers, in 1994 in the NEPOOL 
    and AEP cases.110 In these cases, we recognized that the 
    traditional focus of our undue discrimination analysis had been whether 
    factual differences justify different rates, terms and conditions for 
    similarly situated customers, but concluded that due to changing 
    conditions in the electric utility industry, it was necessary to 
    reevaluate our traditional analysis. As we stated in NEPOOL, the focal 
    point of undue discrimination claims has shifted from claims of undue 
    discrimination in rates and services which the utility offers different 
    customers to claims of undue discrimination in rates and services which 
    the utility offers when compared to its own use of the transmission 
    system.111 ``In this context, framing the analysis in terms of how 
    a public utility treats similarly situated customers is not applicable 
    or instructive.'' 112 The Commission concluded that it therefore 
    must reexamine its application of the standard for undue discrimination 
    claims under sections 205 and 206 of the FPA.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \110\ New England Power Pool, 67 FERC para. 61,402 (1994) 
    (NEPOOL); American Electric Power Service Corporation, 64 FERC para. 
    61,279 (1993), reh'g granted, 67 FERC para. 61,168, clarified, 67 
    FERC para. 61,317 (1994) (AEP).
        \111\ 67 FERC para. 61,042 at 61,132.
        \112\ Id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission further elaborated on its re-examination of undue 
    discrimination in AEP. The Commission cited its NEPOOL discussion and 
    set for hearing the different uses that AEP made of its transmission 
    system and whether there were any operational differences between any 
    particular use that AEP made of the system and the use third parties 
    might need, and, in particular, the degree of flexibility AEP accorded 
    itself in using its transmission system for different purposes. The 
    Commission subsequently set the same issue for hearing in several other 
    cases.113 In the NOPR, however, the Commission concluded that 
    based on what it had learned in the ongoing cases, it would address 
    this issue generically in this rulemaking. We announced in the NOPR our 
    belief that
    
    [[Page 12296]]
    
    all utilities use their own systems in two basic ways: to provide 
    themselves point-to-point transmission service that supports 
    coordination sales, and to provide themselves network transmission 
    service that supports the economic dispatch of their own generation 
    units and purchased power resources (integrating their resources to 
    meet their internal load). Third parties may need one or both of these 
    basic uses in order to obtain competitively priced generation or to 
    have the opportunity to be competitive sellers of power, and the 
    Commission proposed that all public utilities must offer both services 
    on a non-discriminatory open access basis.114
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \113\ Commonwealth Edison Co., 70 FERC para. 61,204 (1995); 
    Wisconsin Electric Power Co., 70 FERC para. 61,074 (1995); and 
    Wisconsin Public Service Corp., 70 FERC para. 61,075 (1995) 
        \114\ FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 32,524 at 33,079.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We affirmed this determination in the Final Rule. We concluded that 
    a public utility must offer transmission services that it is reasonably 
    capable of providing, not just those services that it is currently 
    providing to itself or others. Because a public utility that is 
    reasonably capable of providing transmission services may provide 
    itself such services at any time it finds those services desirable, it 
    is irrelevant that it may not be using or providing that service 
    today.115 Thus, based on the analysis in this record, the 
    Commission has determined that undue discrimination in the provision of 
    transmission services in today's industry does not turn on whether 
    utilities and their native load customers are similarly situated to 
    third parties, but instead turns on whether the utility is providing 
    comparable service, that is, service that it is reasonably capable of 
    providing to other users of the interstate transmission system.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \115\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,690; mimeo at 160.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In short, the Commission is not bound to a static application of 
    its undue discrimination analysis under the FPA and, indeed, has a 
    public interest responsibility to reexamine undue discrimination in 
    light of changed circumstances in the industry.116 That is what we 
    began in NEPOOL and AEP and have completed in this rulemaking. The 
    traditional ``similarly situated'' test, while applicable to 
    discrimination among third-party customers, simply is not applicable 
    when analyzing discrimination between third-party transmission 
    customers and transmission owners. Under Carolina P&L's theory, 
    presumably the only customers that could be shown to be similarly 
    situated would be those who own monopoly transmission facilities and 
    have native load (i.e., captive) customers. This would preserve 
    customer captivity, perpetuate monopoly power and profits, and deny the 
    lowest reasonable rates to consumers. We therefore reject Carolina 
    P&L's arguments.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \116\ There is no ``requirement'' in the FPA that the Commission 
    apply a ``similarly situated'' test. Carolina P&L's reliance on City 
    of Vernon is misplaced. That case involved a claim of discrimination 
    in the type of service offered to a wholesale customer versus that 
    offered to retail customers, and the Commission's application of the 
    ``similarly situated'' and ``same service'' test. Contrary to 
    Carolina P&L's implication, the case does not hold that the 
    Commission is bound to apply a ``similarly situated'' test in 
    analyzing undue discrimination claims under the FPA.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Moreover, the fact that public utilities and their native load 
    customers have been treated differently from third-party transmission 
    customers because they are not among those traditionally considered to 
    be ``similarly situated'' is precisely the target at which Order No. 
    888 takes aim. Historically, competitively-priced power was not broadly 
    available to wholesale customers because the industry was dominated by 
    vertically integrated IOUs 117 and, to the extent cheaper 
    generation alternatives were available in the marketplace, transmission 
    owners either took the cheaper power for their own uses or purchased 
    and re-sold it at a profit.118 Prior to EPAct, most power 
    customers took power from the vertically integrated utilities that 
    provided their transmission service. Transmission-only transactions 
    played a secondary role in bulk power markets, facilitating certain 
    economy transactions and coordination and pooling arrangements that 
    improved utility operational efficiencies, largely as a complement to 
    bundled bulk power transactions. Given the predominantly vertically-
    integrated industry and efficiencies that could be gained through 
    encouragement of coordination and pooling transactions, the Commission 
    was willing to accept utility practices that provided third parties 
    with transmission services that were distinctly inferior to the 
    utility's own uses of the transmission system.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \117\ I.e., investor-owned utilities that owned generation, 
    transmission and distribution facilities and most of whom had 
    captive customers.
        \118\ Very simply, the transmission owner was able to prevent 
    third parties from achieving the maximum savings possible in the 
    generation market by withholding or delaying transmission service. 
    Alternatively, the transmission owner could purchase the power and 
    resell it to the third party at a rate that reflected a mark-up from 
    the first power sale.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In the future, however, unbundled transmission service will be the 
    centerpiece of a freely traded commodity market in electricity, in 
    which all wholesale customers can shop for power. In a market 
    characterized by a significant increase in non-vertically integrated 
    power suppliers and competitively priced power that is now meaningfully 
    available, it is no longer in the interest of wholesale customers for 
    the Commission to tolerate the types of practices that were previously 
    accepted. We cannot allow what have become unduly discriminatory 
    practices to erect barriers between customers and the rapidly emerging 
    competitive electricity marketplace. Accordingly, a primary goal of 
    Order No. 888 is to provide that in the future transmission providers 
    and third-party transmission customers are ``similarly situated'' in 
    the quality of transmission service available to them.
    
    C. Comparability
    
    1. Eligibility to Receive Non-discriminatory Open Access Transmission
        In the Final Rule, the Commission modified the definition of 
    ``eligible customer'' and, among other things, clarified that any 
    entity engaged in wholesale purchases or sales of electric energy, not 
    just those ``generating'' electric power, is eligible.119 The 
    Commission also clarified that entities that would violate section 
    212(h) of the FPA (prohibition on Commission-mandated wheeling directly 
    to an ultimate consumer and sham wholesale transactions) are not 
    eligible. Further, the Commission clarified that foreign entities that 
    otherwise meet the eligibility criteria may obtain transmission 
    services. The Commission also provided for service to retail customers 
    in circumstances that do not violate FPA section 212(h). Persons that 
    would be eligible section 211 applicants also would be eligible under 
    the open access tariff.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \119\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,688-90; mimeo at 154-58.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    a. Unbundled Retail Transmission and ``Sham Wholesale Transactions''
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Several entities assert that there is an inconsistency between 
    tariff language and preamble language and argue that section 1.11 of 
    the tariff should be made consistent with the preamble to ensure that, 
    absent a state-approved program, retail wheeling is not available under 
    the tariff, no matter which party requests service.120 They 
    maintain that the limitation in section 1.11 that the transmission 
    provider only must provide retail transmission service voluntarily or 
    under a state-approved program appears to apply only when a retail 
    customer is the purchaser, not when the transmission purchaser is an 
    electric utility. They suggest the
    
    [[Page 12297]]
    
    following language to remedy the problem: ``however, such entity is not 
    eligible for transmission service that would be prohibited by Sections 
    212(h)(1) and/or 212(h)(2) of the Federal Power Act, unless such 
    service is provided pursuant to a state retail access program or 
    pursuant to a voluntary offer of unbundled retail transmission service 
    by the Transmission Provider.'' (PSE&G at 22; Carolina P&L at 8-9).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \120\ E.g., SoCal Edison, PSE&G, Carolina P&L.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Detroit Edison argues that the Commission should modify the 
    definition to exclude any reference to transmission service provided to 
    retail customers so as to avoid confusion and possible forum shopping. 
    At the least, Detroit Edison argues, the Commission should modify the 
    language to state that transmission service is available to an ultimate 
    consumer to the extent, and only to the extent, that the service is 
    authorized by a lawful state retail access program or pursuant to a 
    voluntary offer of unbundled retail transmission service by the 
    transmission provider.
        NYSEG asserts that the Commission did not apply the section 212(h) 
    limitation to service to retail customers under the tariff. NYSEG 
    requests that the Commission clarify that it will not require retail 
    wheeling beyond the scope of state-mandated retail access programs or 
    beyond the terms of a transmission provider's voluntary offer of retail 
    wheeling service.
        Oklahoma G&E asks the Commission to clarify that the term eligible 
    customer differentiates between a customer eligible to receive 
    transmission service and a customer whose transaction is a sham or 
    would result in mandatory retail wheeling and would therefore be 
    prohibited by section 212(h).
        NYSEG further asserts that the right of first refusal provision 
    would permit a retail customer receiving wheeling service to continue 
    to take that service upon expiration of its contract, which could 
    require the transmission provider, in violation of section 212(h), to 
    continue retail wheeling beyond the scope of its voluntary offer of 
    service or beyond the scope of a state-mandated retail access program.
        SoCal Edison argues that the Commission cannot compel a utility to 
    supply retail transmission service if the utility challenges the 
    authority of the state to require retail wheeling and section 1.11 
    should be revised to reflect this.
        IL Com declares that it ``does not recognize FERC's claim of 
    jurisdiction over retail transmission service provided directly to a 
    retail customer and disputes that unbundled retail wheeling directly to 
    a retail customer is a service provided in interstate commerce.'' (IL 
    Com at 35). Thus, ``if FERC's proposed `deference' to states is to be 
    given any effect, states must be allowed to determine whether the 
    retail transmission component of the retail wheeling program will be 
    provided pursuant to the utility's existing filed wholesale tariff or 
    whether the retail transmission will be provided pursuant to a 
    `separate retail transmission tariff' that is different from the 
    wholesale tariff.'' (IL Com at 36). IL Com concludes that it is 
    inappropriate (and illegal if FERC is overturned on its retail 
    transmission jurisdiction assertion) to include retail customers taking 
    final delivery of unbundled power for their own end uses under retail 
    wheeling programs as eligible customers.
        PA Com argues that it is relevant whether a customer is receiving 
    retail or wholesale service and redefining transmission and local 
    distribution service does not automatically convey jurisdiction to the 
    Commission.
        CCEM asks that the Commission clarify that a retail customer 
    eligible to seek transmission service should be able to seek 
    transmission service not only from the transmission provider, but from 
    any other transmission provider. CCEM also asks that the Commission add 
    the word ``ultimate'' before the word transmission provider in section 
    1.11 of the tariff.
        EEI asks the Commission to ``clarify that the transmission service 
    provider should be allowed to supplement the terms and conditions of 
    the pro forma tariff with additional provisions that specifically 
    relate to the totality of the transmission service being provided, 
    including the use of distribution facilities and any other transmission 
    facilities not currently included in wholesale rates.'' (EEI at 24 
    (emphasis in original)).121
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \121\ See also CSW Operating Companies.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Union Electric argues that a literal reading of the eligibility 
    definition could require retail wheeling by utilities in states other 
    than those required to participate in a particular retail wheeling 
    program.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Commission agrees with those entities that argue that section 
    1.11 of the pro forma tariff does not explicitly prohibit ``sham 
    wholesale transactions'' that could currently be arranged under the 
    tariff by a utility applying for service and designating the retail 
    customer as a point of delivery. We therefore have modified section 
    1.11 to clarify that, with respect to service that we are prohibited 
    from ordering by section 212(h) of the FPA (whether direct retail 
    wheeling or ``sham'' wholesale wheeling), otherwise eligible entities 
    may obtain such service under the tariff only if it is pursuant to a 
    state requirement that such service be provided or pursuant to a 
    voluntary offer of such service. We also have modified the language to 
    clarify that eligibility for unbundled direct retail service required 
    by a state applies only to service from transmission providers that the 
    state orders to provide the service. The modified language states:
    
        Eligible Customer: (i) Any electric utility (including the 
    Transmission Provider and any power marketer), Federal power 
    marketing agency, or any person generating electric energy for sale 
    for resale is an eligible customer under the tariff. Electric energy 
    sold or produced by such entity may be electric energy produced in 
    the United States, Canada, or Mexico. However, with respect to 
    transmission service that the Commission is prohibited from ordering 
    by Section 212(h) of the Federal Power Act, such entity is eligible 
    only if the service is provided pursuant to a state requirement that 
    the Transmission Provider offer the unbundled transmission service, 
    or pursuant to a voluntary offer of such service by the Transmission 
    Provider. (ii) Any retail customer taking unbundled transmission 
    service pursuant to a state requirement that the Transmission 
    Provider offer the transmission service, or pursuant to a voluntary 
    offer of such service by the Transmission Provider, is an eligible 
    customer under the tariff.
    
        Regarding SoCal Edison's argument, the Commission stated in the 
    Final Rule:
    
        Moreover, we are mindful of the fact that we are precluded under 
    section 212(h) from ordering or conditioning an order on a 
    requirement to provide wheeling directly to an ultimate consumer or 
    sham wholesale wheeling. We therefore clarify that our decision to 
    eliminate the wholesale customer eligibility requirement does not 
    constitute a requirement that a utility provide retail transmission 
    service. Rather, we make clear that if a utility chooses, or a state 
    lawfully requires, unbundled retail transmission service, such 
    service should occur under this tariff unless we specifically 
    approve other terms.[122]
    
        \122\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,689-90; mimeo at 158.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Therefore, the Commission is not compelling a utility to provide 
    un-
    bundled retail transmission service.123 Rather, the Commission 
    requires that
    
    [[Page 12298]]
    
    should such service be provided, either pursuant to state mandate or 
    voluntarily, it must be provided pursuant to the pro forma tariff 
    unless the Commission approves alternative terms and conditions.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \123\ We also disagree with NYSEG's assertion that the right of 
    first refusal provision would permit a retail customer receiving 
    wheeling service to continue to receive service after the expiration 
    of its contract and could require the transmission provider to 
    continue wheeling beyond the scope of its voluntary offer of service 
    or beyond the scope of a state-mandated retail access program. 
    Section 212(h) of the FPA would override any provision, including 
    the right of first refusal provision, that may be included in the 
    pro forma tariff.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        However, in light of CCEM's request that we clarify that a retail 
    customer eligible to seek transmission service under the tariff should 
    be able to seek service not only from the transmission provider, but 
    also from any other transmission provider, and in light of Union 
    Electric's concerns regarding retail service eligibility, we believe 
    certain clarifications of our jurisdiction and of the statements made 
    in Order No. 888 are necessary. The statements cited above that were 
    made in Order No. 888 and the eligible customer tariff definition in 
    (ii) above refer to direct retail transmission, i.e., the transmission 
    of electric energy ``directly'' to an ultimate consumer. The Commission 
    is prohibited by section 212(h)(1) of the FPA from ordering this type 
    of retail transmission and that is why customers are eligible for such 
    transmission under the tariff only if the transmission is pursuant to a 
    state order or is provided voluntarily. However, on its face, section 
    212(h) does not prohibit the Commission from ordering public utilities 
    to provide ``indirect'' unbundled retail transmission in interstate 
    commerce, i.e., the transmission necessary to transmit unbundled 
    electric energy to a utility that ultimately will deliver the energy to 
    a customer that is purchasing the unbundled energy at retail either 
    pursuant to a state retail access order or pursuant to voluntary 
    delivery by the local utility.
        We clarify that we believe we have the jurisdiction under the FPA 
    to order indirect retail transmission to an ultimate consumer and that 
    if the Commission under sections 205, 206 or 211 of the FPA orders such 
    transmission, entities that otherwise qualify as eligible customers 
    under the tariff will take transmission service for such indirect 
    retail wheeling pursuant to the pro forma tariff. We note that the 
    Commission may order such transmission on a case-by-case basis or may 
    determine to do so generically in the future. We expect public 
    utilities to provide such indirect retail access under the pro forma 
    tariff and, if they do not, we will not hesitate to order them to do 
    so.
        In response to IL Com's argument that it does not recognize this 
    Commission's claim of jurisdiction over the rates, terms and conditions 
    of unbundled retail transmission that is provided directly to an 
    ultimate consumer, the Commission reaffirms its legal conclusion set 
    forth in the Final Rule.124 As to its claim that we should give 
    deference to the state as to whether such service could be taken under 
    the wholesale tariff or a separate retail tariff on file with the 
    Commission, we reaffirm our conclusion to address this on a case-by-
    case basis. Since the Final Rule issued, the Commission has addressed 
    this in several orders. In New England Power Company, the Commission 
    stated: 125
    
        \124\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,780 and Appendix G (31,966-81); 
    mimeo at 428 and Appendix G.
        \125\ 75 FERC para. 61,356 at 62,141, order on reh'g, 77 FERC 
    para. 61,135 (1996). In the order on rehearing, the Commission 
    permitted a separate retail tariff to remain in effect for the 
    duration of the retail electric pilot programs established in 
    Massachusetts by Massachusetts Electric Company.
    
        As we explained in the Open Access Rule and in the New Hampshire 
    Interim Order, we generally expect retail transmission customers to 
    take service under the same Commission tariff that applies to 
    wholesale customers. While we generally will defer to state requests 
    for a separate retail tariff to accommodate the design and special 
    needs of a state retail access program, the Massachusetts Commission 
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    has made no such request in this case. \15\
    
        \15\ See Open Access Rule, FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,784; New 
    Hampshire Interim Order, 75 FERC at 61,687 & n.3 (both noting that 
    such a separate retail tariff must be consistent with the 
    Commission's open access policies and comparability principles). * * 
    *
    
        Subsequently, in New England Power Company, 76 FERC para. 61,008 
    (1996), the Commission granted a limited waiver of the Open Access Rule 
    requirements for the New Hampshire retail electric competition pilot 
    project. Specifically, the Commission waived the requirement for 
    individual service agreements, and the requirement for customer 
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    deposits. The Commission further announced that:
    
    other public utilities that provide unbundled retail service under a 
    pro forma tariff do not need to apply to retail customers the tariff 
    provisions regarding individual service agreements or customer 
    deposits, unless a state retail program so requires. [ 126]
    
        \126\ 76 FERC at 61,024.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Concerning EEI's request for clarification, the Commission stated 
    in the Final Rule:
    
    all tariffs need not be ``cookie-cutter'' copies of the Final Rule 
    tariff. Thus, under our new procedure, ultimately a tariff may go 
    beyond the minimum elements in the Final Rule pro forma tariff or 
    may account for regional, local, or system-specific factors. The 
    tariffs that go into effect 60 days after publication of this Rule 
    in the Federal Register will be identical to the Final Rule pro 
    forma tariff; however, public utilities then will be free to file 
    under section 205 to revise the tariffs, and customers will be free 
    to pursue changes under section 206.[127]
    
        \127\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,770 n. 514; mimeo at 399 n. 514.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Utilities are free to include customer-specific terms and 
    conditions or terms and conditions limited to certain customers (e.g., 
    a distribution charge) in the customer's service agreement and/or the 
    network customer's network operating agreement.
    b. Transmission Providers Taking Service Under Their Tariff
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        TAPS states that section 1.11 does not seem to require a 
    transmission provider to take service for its purchases, but the 
    preamble does (citing mimeo at 57, 191, 266 and regulatory text in 
    section 35.28(c)(2)). It argues that transmission providers should be 
    required to treat their own usage of the transmission system to serve 
    retail customers under the network service provisions of the tariff. 
    TAPS argues that this result could be achieved through an ISO or by 
    requiring transmission providers to abide by all non-price terms of 
    Parts I and III of the tariff. TAPS also argues that the rates charged 
    network customers must be developed on the same basis as the 
    transmission component of retail rates. It states that the transmission 
    provider's purchases would then be made under Part III of the tariff to 
    the extent they are made for serving retail customers. It further 
    asserts that the Commission's authority and obligation to consider 
    transmission owners' service to retail load in establishing wholesale 
    transmission rates has been long established. At the least, TAPS argues 
    that the Commission should require that a transmission provider take 
    its wholesale purchases under some tariff.
        Similarly, Coalition for Economic Competition asks the Commission 
    to clarify that the requirement to use the pro forma tariff for 
    wholesale purchases and to functionally unbundle wholesale purchases 
    and sales does not apply to purchases made solely to serve retail 
    customers on a bundled basis. It asserts that there is conflicting 
    language in Order No. 888 (citing mimeo at 191) and Order No. 889 
    (citing mimeo at 12) and the pro forma tariff. Coalition for Economic 
    Competition asserts that the Commission does not have jurisdiction over 
    transmission that is part of a bundled retail sale.
    
    [[Page 12299]]
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Several parties have noted on rehearing that there is conflicting 
    language among the Final Rule, Order No. 889 and the pro forma tariff 
    as to whether and to what extent the transmission provider must take 
    service for ``wholesale purchases'' under its own tariff. As discussed 
    below, we clarify that a transmission provider does not have to ``take 
    service'' under its own tariff for the transmission of power that is 
    purchased on behalf of bundled retail customers.
        In a situation in which a transmission provider purchases power on 
    behalf of its retail native load customers, the Commission does not 
    have jurisdiction over the transmission of the purchased power to the 
    bundled retail customers insofar as the transmission takes place over 
    such transmission provider's facilities,128 and therefore the pro 
    forma tariff does not have to be used for such transmission. Moreover, 
    we recognize that purchases made collectively on behalf of native load 
    129 cannot necessarily be identified as going to any particular 
    customer. However, the Commission does have jurisdiction over 
    transmission service associated with sales to any person for resale, 
    and such transmission must be taken under the transmission provider's 
    pro forma tariff. 130
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \128\ To the extent the transmission takes place on the 
    interstate facilities of other public utilities, we would have 
    jurisdiction over such transmission.
        \129\ Native load means ``[t]he wholesale and retail power 
    customers of the Transmission Provider on whose behalf the 
    Transmission Provider, by statute, franchise, regulatory 
    requirement, or contract, has undertaken an obligation to construct 
    and operate the Transmission Provider's system to meet the reliable 
    electric needs of such customers.'' Section 1.19 of the pro forma 
    tariff.
        \130\ All transmission in interstate commerce by a public 
    utility in conjunction with a sale for resale of electric energy is 
    jurisdictional and must be taken under a FERC-jurisdictional tariff. 
    The same is true for all unbundled transmission in interstate 
    commerce to wholesale customers, as well as to unbundled retail 
    customers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Order No. 888, relying on the principle of comparability, 
    established the terms and conditions for network service provided to 
    network customers under the pro forma tariff. Network customers may 
    include the transmission provider itself as well as any other entity 
    receiving Network Integration Service. If the transmission provider 
    purchases energy from another power supplier in order to make sales to 
    its wholesale native load customers, it must take the transmission 
    service necessary to transmit the power from its point(s) of receipt to 
    its point(s) of delivery under the same terms and conditions as other 
    Network Customers.131 As we explained in AES Power, Inc., network 
    customers are entitled to make economy energy purchases from non-
    designated network resources at no additional charge on a basis 
    comparable to the economy energy purchases made by the transmission 
    provider on behalf of its bundled retail customer.132 This applies 
    to the transmission provider as a network transmission customer under 
    its own tariff as well as to other network transmission customers that 
    make economy energy purchases on behalf of their customers. Thus, 
    insofar as all wholesale transmission customer usage is concerned, 
    third-party network customers are treated the same as the transmission 
    owner.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \131\ Under the Order No. 888 pro forma tariff, third-party 
    wholesale customers have the ability to obtain the identical service 
    the transmission provider provides itself when it engages in a sale 
    of electric energy for resale. This may include network or point-to-
    point service.
        \132\ 69 FERC ] 61,145 at 62,300 (1994) (proposed order), 74 
    FERC ] 61,220 (1996) (final order).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    2. Service that Must be Provided by Transmission Provider
        In the Final Rule, the Commission found that a public utility must 
    offer transmission services that it is reasonably capable of providing, 
    not just those services that it is currently providing to itself or 
    others. 133 The Commission explained that because a public utility 
    that is reasonably capable of providing transmission services may 
    provide itself such services at any time it finds those services 
    desirable, it is irrelevant that it may not be using or providing that 
    service today. However, the Commission explained that if a customer 
    seeks a customized service not offered in an open access tariff, a 
    customer may, barring successful negotiation for such service, file a 
    section 211 application.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \133\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,690; mimeo at 160.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Cleveland requests that the Commission make explicit that 
    comparability will be evaluated not only by reference to a transmission 
    provider's wholesale services, but also by comparison to the terms, 
    conditions, and prices applicable to its retail services, whether 
    bundled or unbundled. Cleveland asserts that this is needed so that 
    TDUs are not at a competitive disadvantage in competing with the 
    transmission provider for retail customers. It maintains that this is 
    consistent with the Transmission Pricing Policy and established 
    precedent.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        No clarification is necessary. In determining what transmission 
    services a utility must offer for wholesale sales of electric energy in 
    interstate commerce, the Final Rule explicitly states that ``a public 
    utility must offer transmission services that it is reasonably capable 
    of providing, not just those services that it is currently providing to 
    itself or others.'' 134 Further, the Final Rule requires that 
    network service customers receive service comparable to the service 
    provided to the transmission provider's native load. Because the Rule 
    applies to retail transmission that is voluntarily offered or pursuant 
    to a state retail access program, the requirements to offer services 
    that the utility is reasonably capable of providing and services 
    comparable to those provided to native load would also apply to retail 
    service in these limited retail circumstances.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \134\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,690; mimeo at 160.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    3. Who Must Provide Non-discriminatory Open Access Transmission
        In the Final Rule, the Commission explained that its authority 
    under sections 205 and 206 of the FPA permits it to require only public 
    utilities to file open access tariffs as a remedy for undue 
    discrimination.135 The Commission further explained that it has no 
    authority under those sections of the FPA to require non-public 
    utilities to file tariffs with the Commission.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \135\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,691-92; mimeo at 162-65.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission also discussed three mechanisms that would help 
    alleviate the problems associated with not being able to require non-
    public utilities to provide open access: (1) Broad application of 
    section 211; (2) the reciprocity requirement set forth in the Final 
    Rule; and (3) the formation of RTGs.
        The Commission also indicated that it will not allow public 
    utilities that jointly own interstate transmission facilities with non-
    jurisdictional entities to escape the requirements of open access. 
    Thus, the Commission required each public utility that owns interstate 
    transmission facilities jointly with a non-jurisdictional entity to 
    offer service over its share of the joint facilities, even if the joint 
    ownership contract prohibits service to third parties. The Commission 
    required the public utilities, in a section 206 compliance filing, to 
    file with the Commission, by December 31, 1996, a proposed revision 
    (mutually agreeable
    
    [[Page 12300]]
    
    or unilateral) to their contracts with non-jurisdictional owners.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
    Jointly-Owned Facilities
    
        Union Electric argues that the Final Rule improperly requires a 
    public utility to unilaterally file a modification to agreements that a 
    non-jurisdictional entity opposes, which amounts to a litigation 
    coercion provision. Union Electric notes that it has been told by 
    Associated Electric Cooperative, Inc. that it will oppose any 
    modifications to Union Electric's agreements. Union Electric further 
    states that these facilities are not commonly owned, but rather each 
    party wholly owns its segment of the facilities.
        Dalton asserts that Georgia Power Company cannot comply with the 
    requirement to offer service over its share of joint facilities because 
    the ITS is not owned by members as tenants in common, but instead each 
    member owns specific segments of the transmission grid. Dalton further 
    argues that it is unjust and unreasonable to require Georgia Power 
    Company to give access to the ITS to new and roll-over transmission 
    customers under the Order No. 888 tariff that are unwilling to accept 
    an investment responsibility and an obligation to make balancing 
    payments.
        Associated EC argues that the Commission may modify non-
    jurisdictional contracts only under section 211 of the FPA; the 
    Commission cannot simply modify the contract with respect to the public 
    utility.
        NE Public Power District states that it is party to an agreement 
    with a public utility involving jointly constructed transmission 
    facilities that prohibits use of the transmission capacity by a non-
    party. It asserts that ``[t]he District's contractual rights under its 
    contract constitute valuable property, and the summary annulment of 
    those rights constitutes a violation of Due Process.'' (NE Public Power 
    District at 18-20). Moreover, it argues that blanket invalidation of 
    the terms and conditions of the contracts is contrary to the Sierra-
    Mobile doctrine.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We reject those arguments that maintain that the Commission cannot 
    properly require a public utility to file unilaterally a modification 
    to agreements concerning joint transmission facilities that a non-
    jurisdictional entity opposes. It is without question that the 
    Commission has the exclusive authority to regulate public utilities 
    engaged in the sale for resale and/or transmission of electric energy 
    in interstate commerce to assure that rates, terms and conditions are 
    just and reasonable and not unduly discriminatory. The fact that a 
    public utility may jointly own, with a non-jurisdictional entity, 
    transmission facilities through which it engages in sales for resale 
    and/or transmission of electric energy in interstate commerce does not 
    alter the Commission's authority to regulate that public 
    utility.136 If the Commission finds that a matter needs to be 
    remedied, it may issue an order directed at the public utility. The 
    fact that such an order may affect a non-jurisdictional joint owner 
    does not undermine the validity of the Commission's order.137 
    Otherwise, a public utility could simply enter into joint agreements 
    with non-jurisdictional utilities to the frustration of the 
    Commission's mandate to protect consumers from undue 
    discrimination.138
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \136\ See Policy Statement Regarding Regional Transmission 
    Groups, 64 FERC para. 61,139 at 61,993 (1993); Midwest Power 
    Systems, Inc., 69 FERC para. 61,025 at 61,104-05 (1994). Nor does 
    the form of ownership of the joint facilities have any bearing on 
    the Commission's jurisdiction over public utilities.
        \137\ Though the non-jurisdictional entity would not become 
    subject to Commission regulation.
        \138\ Cf. H.K. Porter Co., Inc. v. Central Vermont Railway, 
    Inc., 366 U.S. 272, 273-75 (1961).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Nor does the exercise of the Commission's powers under the FPA to 
    remedy undue discrimination by public utilities constitute a violation 
    of due process vis-a-vis the non-jurisdictional entity. When the 
    contract was entered into and filed with the Commission it was with the 
    explicit knowledge that the Commission could regulate the rates, terms 
    and conditions of the contract with respect to the jurisdictional 
    services provided thereunder by the public utility. If and when a 
    public utility unilaterally files either to amend or terminate the 
    agreement, the non-jurisdictional party is free to raise any arguments 
    it wishes to support its position that no changes are necessary to 
    ensure that the contract is just and reasonable and not unduly 
    discriminatory or preferential.
    4. Reservation of Transmission Capacity by Transmission Customers
        In the Final Rule, the Commission concluded that firm transmission 
    customers, including network customers, should not lose their rights to 
    firm capacity simply because they do not use that capacity for certain 
    periods of time.139
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \139\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,693; mimeo at 168-70.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        No rehearing requests addressed this matter.
    5. Reservation of Transmission Capacity for Future Use by Utility
        In the Final Rule, the Commission concluded that public utilities 
    may reserve existing transmission capacity needed for native load 
    growth and network transmission customer load growth reasonably 
    forecasted within the utility's current planning horizon.140 
    However, the Commission determined that any such capacity that a public 
    utility reserves for future growth, but is not currently needed, must 
    be posted on the OASIS and made available to others through the 
    capacity reassignment requirements, until such time as it is actually 
    needed and used.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \140\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,694; mimeo at 172.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        CCEM argues that it is discriminatory to allow public utilities and 
    network transmission customers to reserve existing transmission 
    capacity for their native load growth because it (1) limits the 
    determination of ATC, (2) is likely to increase the cost of 
    transmission for other customers, and (3) is inconsistent with a 
    capacity reservation-based system. CCEM argues, however, that if the 
    reservation feature is retained, franchise utilities that reserve 
    capacity must pay the full reservation charges, with no cost shifting 
    to other customers. CCEM further recommends that all reservation 
    payments should be credited directly to firm transmission services and 
    the planning horizon should be limited to a reasonable time into the 
    future.
        American Forest & Paper argues that to achieve comparability, 
    utilities must not be permitted to withhold capacity from the market 
    for the benefit of native load. American Forest & Paper further argues 
    that the Commission must establish mechanisms for evaluating the 
    reasonableness of the utilities' requirements and projections, 
    otherwise they have an incentive to over-forecast and to extend their 
    planning horizons. American Forest & Paper suggests that requiring 
    utilities to establish separate entities to purchase transmission on 
    behalf of their native load would help solve this problem.
        VA Com requests that the Commission clarify what will happen if a 
    utility's forecast of load growth is too low. It argues that native 
    load should not have to bear the burden of any forecast errors and that 
    utilities should be required to reserve sufficient capacity to serve 
    the current and projected needs
    
    [[Page 12301]]
    
    of native load customers. VA Com would also have the definition of 
    native load in section 1.19 of the tariff expanded to include existing 
    distribution cooperatives and others who currently provide service to 
    end users. With respect to reservation priority, VA Com states that the 
    Commission should establish the following reservation priority: native 
    load customers, firm contract customers, and non-firm customers. 
    Finally, VA Com asserts that the calculation of ATC must not include 
    any capacity that may be needed by native load customers.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We will deny the requests of CCEM and American Forest and Paper. We 
    continue to believe that public utilities should be allowed to reserve 
    existing transmission capacity needed for native load growth and 
    network customer load growth reasonably forecasted within the utility's 
    current planning horizon.
        We note that network service is founded on the notion that the 
    transmission provider has a duty to plan and construct the transmission 
    system to meet the present and future needs of its native load and, by 
    comparability, its third-party network customers. In return, the native 
    load and third-party network customers must pay all of the system's 
    fixed costs that are not covered by the proceeds of point-to-point 
    service. This means that native load and third-party network customers 
    bear ultimate responsibility for the costs of both the capacity that 
    they use and any capacity that is not reserved by point-to-point 
    customers. In this regard, native load and third-party network 
    customers face a payment risk that point-to-point customers generally 
    do not face. For these reasons, we do not believe that it is 
    appropriate to require native load and network customers to assume any 
    additional cost responsibility for the capacity that is reserved for 
    their future use.
        In response to CCEM's concerns, we recognize that offering load-
    based network service and reservation-based point-to-point service in 
    one tariff may have disadvantages in that it may result in less than 
    optimal use of the system if a utility overestimates its load. However, 
    by requiring that available capacity reserved for native load be posted 
    on OASIS and be available to others except when actually needed to 
    serve native load, we believe Order No. 888 substantially relieves the 
    incentive to over-reserve for native load and goes a long way toward 
    assuring full and efficient use of the system.
        With regard to the concern raised by VA Com, the transmission 
    provider has an ongoing duty to plan and construct its system in a 
    prudent manner in order to meet all of its firm service obligations. We 
    also reiterate that
    
    public utilities may reserve existing transmission capacity needed 
    for native load growth and network transmission customer load growth 
    reasonably forecasted within the utility's current planning 
    horizon.[141]
    
        \141\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,694; mimeo at 172.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    There is a risk of under-or over-projecting the transmission needs of 
    native load and network customers, and the native load and network 
    customers' cost responsibilities reflect this additional risk. In 
    response to VA Com's request, we note that nothing in our regulations 
    prohibits a state commission from overseeing a utility's retail native 
    load growth projections. Finally, concerns regarding the accuracy of 
    load growth projections for native load and network customers may be 
    raised when a transmission service agreement is filed with the 
    Commission or in a separate section 206 proceeding.
    6. Capacity Reassignment
        In the Final Rule, the Commission concluded that a public utility's 
    tariff must explicitly permit the voluntary reassignment of all or part 
    of a holder's firm transmission capacity rights to any eligible 
    customer.142
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \142\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,696; mimeo at 178-179.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    (1) Reassignable Transmission Services
        The Commission concluded that point-to-point transmission service 
    should be reassignable, but that network transmission service is not 
    reassignable.143
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \143\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,696; mimeo at 179.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    (2) Terms and Conditions of Reassignments
    a. General
        In effecting a reassignment, the Commission found that the assignor 
    may deal directly with an assignee without involvement of the 
    transmission provider.144 Alternatively, the Commission explained 
    that the assignor may request the transmission provider to effect a 
    reassignment on its behalf, in which case the transmission provider 
    must post the available capacity on its OASIS and assure that any 
    revenues associated with the reassignment are credited to the assignor. 
    The Commission further found that, among other things, any assignment 
    must be posted on the transmission provider's OASIS within a reasonable 
    time after its effective date.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \144\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,696-97; mimeo at 179-80.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    b. Contractual Obligations
        The Commission concluded that while assignors and assignees may 
    contract directly with each other, the assignor will remain obligated 
    to the transmission provider and the assignee will be liable solely to 
    the assignor.145 The Commission, however, did permit mutually 
    agreeable alternatives to this approach.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \145\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,697; mimeo at 180-81.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    c. Price Cap
        The Commission concluded that the rate for any capacity 
    reassignment must be capped by the highest of: (1) the original 
    transmission rate charged to the purchaser (assignor), (2) the 
    transmission provider's maximum stated firm transmission rate in effect 
    at the time of the reassignment, or (3) the assignor's own opportunity 
    costs capped at the cost of expansion (Price Cap).146
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \146\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,697; mimeo at 181.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
    Scheduling Transmission Service by Assignees
    
        CCEM requests that the Commission clarify that an assignee of 
    transmission capacity, or its agent, is permitted to schedule 
    transmission service directly with the transmission provider.
    
    Network Transmission Service
    
        American Forest & Paper declares that the Commission erred in 
    finding that network service is not reassignable. American Forest & 
    Paper argues that there is no technical reason for the Commission's 
    position. According to American Forest & Paper, the Commission merely 
    perpetuates the myth that in point-to-point transmission the contract 
    actually determines the path of the flow of electrons. In fact, 
    American Forest & Paper argues, the only issue is arriving at a 
    nondiscriminatory and equitable price.
        VT DPS argues that there is no reason network capacity rights 
    cannot be defined during the period of a reassignment as VT DPS 
    suggested in its comments:
    
        Section 2.6 of the NorAm NIS Rate Schedule (Appendix B to the 
    Initial NOPR comments of VDPS) is a provision which allows the 
    reassignment of network service. Reassignment under the NorAm tariff 
    would work this way: During the period of the assignment, both the 
    original and replacement customers' network service entitlements are 
    defined as specified contract quantities, the sum of which is equal 
    to the original customer's highest coincident peak load during the 
    12 months preceding the
    
    [[Page 12302]]
    
    assignment. During the period of the assignment, that contract 
    quantity, not the actual use of the system by the original and 
    replacement shipper, will be used to determine the two customers' 
    load ratio share responsibility. The original and replacement 
    customers are free to divide responsibility for interim contract 
    demand between them as they see fit.[147]
    
        \147\ VT DPS at 47-48; see also Valero at 29-31.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        PA Coops argue that the Commission failed to explain why network 
    customers have no capacity rights and points to a statement in Order 
    No. 888 that network customers ``should not lose their rights to firm 
    capacity'' as being inconsistent with the Commission's conclusion with 
    respect to the reassignment of network service.
        AMP-Ohio asserts that absent an ongoing pass-through to network 
    customers of the revenue credits associated with sales of point-to-
    point service, the Commission should permit the reassignment of unused 
    transmission capacity by network customers.
        TDU Systems argue that the Commission should permit the assignment 
    of a network customer's right to network transmission service for 
    certain specific purposes. In particular, TDU Systems state that the 
    Commission should permit assignment to allow a customer to coordinate, 
    jointly operate, or pool its system with the systems of other local and 
    regional network customers. TDU Systems argue that this provides an 
    opportunity to maximize efficiencies without presenting the 
    complication that the Commission has perceived with respect to the 
    reassignment of point-to-point transmission capacity.
    
    Price Cap
    
        EEI asserts that the Commission's price cap creates several 
    problems: (1) non-comparable treatment because transmission providers 
    must credit revenues, but resellers can keep the revenues; (2) allowing 
    sale at a price higher than paid could encourage speculation and 
    hoarding; and (3) the transmitting utility's maximum stated rate should 
    not include the utility's opportunity costs.
        CCEM argues that transmission customers that are not transmission 
    providers or affiliates of transmission providers should be freed from 
    the price cap. CCEM claims that in a secondary market at market-based 
    prices, opportunity costs can be communicated and lost opportunity 
    costs averted.
        NRECA believes that the price cap provision that permits an 
    assignor to assign capacity at its own opportunity costs (capped at the 
    cost of expansion) may provide firm point-to-point customers a strong 
    economic incentive to buy up substantial firm capacity for speculative 
    purposes and argues that this provision should be eliminated. NRECA 
    also argues that this provision presents difficult rate substantiation 
    questions when the assignor is not a public utility. Further, NRECA and 
    SoCal Edison note that section 23.1 of the tariff does not include the 
    cap at the cost of expansion.
    
    Calculation of Assignor's Opportunity Costs
    
        SoCal Edison asserts that the Commission must indicate how an 
    assignor should calculate its own opportunity costs with respect to 
    determining the price cap and should indicate that an assignor must 
    abide by the same standard for recovering opportunity costs as the 
    transmission provider. Carolina P&L also asserts that assignors must be 
    held to the same standard as transmission providers when calculating 
    opportunity costs. Carolina P&L further explains that if the 
    opportunity costs are based on the cost of foregone transactions, the 
    assignor should be required to post the price on OASIS.
        Carolina P&L also asks that the Commission clarify how an assignor 
    is to calculate its own opportunity costs. In particular, Carolina P&L 
    asks if an assignor is limited to recovering the opportunity costs to 
    which it is subject under the transmission provider's tariff or can the 
    assignor forfeit the transaction underlying the transmission service 
    and call the resulting difference an opportunity cost?
    
    Resellers Into the Secondary Market
    
        CCEM argues that the Commission should free resellers, ``who but-
    for the resell would not be public utilities,'' from regulation as 
    public utilities or should minimize the regulatory burden on 
    them.148 It further asserts that resellers that are not 
    transmission providers should be treated like unaffiliated power 
    marketers and granted waivers from public utility regulations.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \148\ CCEM makes this argument in its rehearing request of Order 
    No. 889.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Participation in the Secondary Market
    
        CCEM argues that those customers that are permitted to continue to 
    take service under existing agreements ``should be excluded from 
    participating in the secondary market until such time as they agree to 
    comply with the pro forma tariff.'' (CCEM (889 rehearing request) at 
    7).
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
    Scheduling Transmission Service by Assignee
    
        The pro forma tariff does not prohibit the assignee of transmission 
    capacity from scheduling transmission service with the transmission 
    provider. In fact, the tariff provides that ``the Assignee will be 
    subject to all terms and conditions of this Tariff'' (tariff section 
    23.1), which would include the scheduling provision of tariff sections 
    13.8 and 14.6.
    
    Network Transmission Service
    
        We reaffirm our conclusion that network transmission service is not 
    reassignable in the secondary market.149 Parties have raised no 
    new arguments that would persuade us otherwise. PA Coops are 
    nevertheless correct in noting that network customers do have rights to 
    firm capacity. However, a network customer's rights (as well as the 
    transmission provider's planning responsibilities) are defined only in 
    terms of the capacity needed to integrate the network customer's 
    designated resources and its designated loads. These are usage- or 
    load-based rights that are not fixed; they vary as the customer's load 
    varies. Thus, the network customer's capacity rights are not well 
    enough defined to be generally reassignable in the secondary 
    market.150
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \149\ While portions of network transmission service are not 
    reassignable, we would permit the reassignment of a particular 
    network transmission service in its entirety.
        \150\ We note that the question of how network service may be 
    converted into a service that is reassignable is at issue in the 
    Capacity Reservation Tariff NOPR proceeding in Docket No. RM96-11-
    000.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        VT DPS proposes a formula for defining a network customer's 
    entitlement that would be operative during the period of an assignment. 
    However, the proposed definition is simply an artifice derived from the 
    load ratio share calculation. The formula does not result in a 
    reassignable capacity right.
        AMP-Ohio's suggestion regarding the proper treatment of the revenue 
    credits associated with point-to-point service raises a rate issue that 
    should be addressed in a ratemaking proceeding. However, we note that 
    the proper treatment of such credits does not turn on the assignability 
    of network service.
        Finally, TDU Systems' recommendation that network service be 
    reassignable only for pooling and coordination purposes is without 
    merit. If customers wish to avail themselves of network service in 
    order to realize
    
    [[Page 12303]]
    
    benefits associated with joint or coordinated operations with other 
    systems, they can jointly request network service from the transmission 
    provider. To allow customers to opt into and out of network service 
    arrangements under the guise of capacity reassignment would be an abuse 
    of the terms and conditions of the service, which, among other things, 
    requires the transmission provider to plan for the long-term needs of 
    network customers.
    
    Price Cap
    
        We will also reaffirm our conclusions regarding the price cap 
    applicable to capacity reassignment. We continue to believe that 
    customers must be given limited pricing flexibility in order to achieve 
    the full efficiency and risk management benefits of capacity 
    reassignment.
        Contrary to the assertions of EEI and NRECA, we are not persuaded 
    that allowing the customer to reassign capacity at a rate higher than 
    it paid, as a result of charging its own opportunity costs, will lead 
    to speculation and hoarding. As a condition of the open access tariff, 
    the Commission will require customers reassigning transmission capacity 
    to fully develop their method for calculating opportunity costs and 
    provide all information necessary to their customers in order to verify 
    such costs. Further, we reiterate that the potential for hoarding can 
    be mitigated by (1) allowing the transmission provider to sell any 
    reserved but unscheduled point-to-point transmission capacity on a non-
    firm basis, and (2) having a price cap, which allows the reseller to 
    charge no more than a cost-based rate, including its own opportunity 
    cost for reassigned capacity. Therefore, the reseller will find that 
    reassigning transmission capacity to others with higher valued uses 
    will be in its economic self interest. In addition, any hoarding of 
    capacity that has anticompetitive effects can be addressed under 
    section 206.
        We deny CCEM's request to remove the price cap for transmission 
    customers that are not transmission providers or affiliates of 
    transmission providers. As we stated in the Final Rule, we are unable 
    to conclude that competition in the market for reassigned transmission 
    capacity is sufficient to prevent assignors from exerting market power. 
    Thus, we believe the opportunity cost cap should be retained.151
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \151\ We note that if the assignor is a public utility it will 
    in any event have to file a rate schedule for the re-sale 
    (reassignment) of unbundled transmission.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Finally, in response to EEI's request, we clarify that ``the 
    transmission provider's maximum stated firm transmission rate in effect 
    at the time of the reassignment'' does not include the transmission 
    provider's opportunity costs.152 Also, as suggested by NRECA and 
    others, section 23.1 of the pro forma tariff will be revised to 
    indicate that the assignor's opportunity costs are capped at the 
    transmission provider's cost of expansion.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \152\ We also reject as unsupported EEI's comparability argument 
    that transmission providers must treat any transmission service 
    revenues as a revenue credit, but the reseller may keep any 
    transmission resale revenues.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Calculation of Assignor's Opportunity Costs
    
        In response to the requests of SoCal Edison and Carolina P&L, we 
    clarify that the assignor's opportunity costs should be measured in a 
    manner that is analogous to that used to measure the transmission 
    provider's opportunity costs. That is, an assignor's opportunity costs 
    include: (1) increased costs associated with changes in power purchases 
    or in the dispatch of generating units necessary to accommodate a 
    reassignment, and (2) decreased revenues that arise from the assignor 
    having to reduce sales of power in order to effect the 
    reassignment.153
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \153\ In response to Carolina P&L's request, we clarify that the 
    assignor is not limited to recovering the opportunity costs to which 
    it is subject under the transmission provider's tariff, i.e., the 
    transmission provider's opportunity costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Regarding the calculation of opportunity costs, we intend to hold 
    assignors to the same general standard as transmission providers. Thus, 
    consistent with our treatment of transmission providers, we will not 
    require assignors to post their opportunity costs on the OASIS or to 
    make the costs routinely available to the public. We will, however, 
    require assignors to describe to their assignees their derivation of 
    opportunity costs in sufficient detail to satisfy the assignees that 
    the price charged does not exceed the higher of (i) the original rate 
    paid by the reseller, (ii) the transmission provider's maximum rate on 
    file at the time of the assignment, or (iii) the reseller's opportunity 
    cost, as set forth in section 23.1 of the tariff.
    
    Resellers Into the Secondary Market
    
        The issues raised by CCEM with respect to the regulation of 
    resellers into the secondary market are fact specific and, accordingly, 
    we will address such issues on a case-by-case basis.
    
    Participation in the Secondary Market
    
        We reject CCEM's argument that those customers that are permitted 
    by Order No. 888 to continue to take service under existing agreements 
    should be denied access to the secondary market until they agree to 
    comply with the pro forma tariff. CCEM's approach would undermine our 
    determination not to generically abrogate existing agreements, and 
    would slow the growth of the secondary market by limiting the number of 
    eligible participants.
    7. Information Provided to Transmission Customers
        In the Final Rule, the Commission concluded that all necessary 
    transmission information, as detailed in the OASIS Final Rule, must be 
    posted on an OASIS.154
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \154\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,698; mimeo at 183-84.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        No requests for rehearing addressed this matter.
    8. Consequences of Functional Unbundling
    a. Distribution Function
        In the Final Rule, the Commission concluded that the additional 
    step of functionally unbundling the distribution function from the 
    transmission function is not necessary at this time to ensure non-
    discriminatory open access transmission.155
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \155\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,699; mimeo at 186.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        No requests for rehearing addressed this matter.
    b. Retail Transmission Service
        In the Final Rule, the Commission explained that although the 
    unbundling of retail transmission and generation, as well as wholesale 
    transmission and generation, would be helpful in achieving 
    comparability, it did not believe it was necessary.156 The 
    Commission further explained that the matter raises numerous difficult 
    jurisdictional issues that are more appropriately considered when the 
    Commission reviews unbundled retail transmission tariffs that may come 
    before the Commission in the context of a state retail wheeling 
    program.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \156\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,699-700; mimeo at 188.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        CCEM argues that all transmission must be unbundled, including 
    currently bundled retail transmission service, because failure to do so 
    is inconsistent with the Commission's assertion of jurisdiction over 
    the rates, terms, and conditions of unbundled interstate transmission 
    to retail customers and
    
    [[Page 12304]]
    
    authority to address retail stranded costs through its jurisdiction 
    over such costs. CCEM notes that the Commission found it necessary in 
    Order No. 636 to unbundle the pipeline's direct retail sales to achieve 
    comparability (CCEM cites FPC v. Conway Corp., 426 U.S. 271, 273 (1976) 
    and Mississippi River Transmission Corp. v. FERC, 969 F.2d 1215 (D.C. 
    Cir. 1992) for the proposition that the Commission has jurisdiction 
    over all interstate transmission).
        NY Municipal Utilities and American Forest & Paper also argue that 
    the Commission erred in not requiring the unbundling of the 
    transmission component of retail sales. American Forest & Paper 
    believes that such unbundling will facilitate competition by making the 
    generation price transparent to all participants.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We disagree with those entities that argue that the Commission 
    erred in not requiring the unbundling of all transmission service, 
    including the unbundling of transmission from retail service. As we 
    explained in the Final Rule:
    
    when transmission is sold at retail as part and parcel of the 
    delivered product called electric energy, the transaction is a sale 
    of electric energy at retail. Under the FPA, the Commission's 
    jurisdiction over sales of electric energy extends only to wholesale 
    sales. However, when a retail transaction is broken into two 
    products that are sold separately (perhaps by two different 
    suppliers: an electric energy supplier and a transmission supplier), 
    we believe the jurisdictional lines change. In this situation, the 
    state clearly retains jurisdiction over the sale of the power. 
    However, the unbundled transmission service involves only the 
    provision of ``transmission in interstate commerce'' which, under 
    the FPA, is exclusively within the jurisdiction of the Commission. 
    Therefore, when a bundled retail sale is unbundled and becomes 
    separate transmission and power sales transactions, the resulting 
    transmission transaction falls within the Federal sphere of 
    regulation.157
    
        \157\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,781; mimeo at 430-31 (emphasis 
    in original). As discussed in Section IV.I., infra, we believe this 
    jurisdictional determination is supported by the statute and the 
    case law, including the D.C. Circuit's recent decision in United 
    Distribution Companies v. FERC, 88 F.3d 1105 (1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Nor is our decision not to unbundle transmission from retail 
    generation service inconsistent with our assertion of jurisdiction over 
    unbundled interstate transmission to retail customers. As we explained 
    in the Final Rule and described further above, we have exclusive 
    jurisdiction under the FPA over ``transmission in interstate commerce'' 
    by public utilities, which includes the unbundled interstate 
    transmission component of a previously bundled retail 
    transaction.158 Our assertion of jurisdiction in such a situation 
    arises only if the retail transmission in interstate commerce by a 
    public utility occurs voluntarily or as a result of a state retail 
    program.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \158\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,781; mimeo at 431.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    c. Transmission Provider
    1. Taking Service Under the Tariff
        In the Final Rule, the Commission concluded that public utilities 
    must take all transmission services for wholesale sales under new 
    requirements contracts and new coordination contracts under the same 
    tariff used by others (eligible customers).159 For sales and 
    purchases under existing bilateral economy energy coordination 
    agreements, the Commission gave an extension until December 31, 1996 
    for public utilities to take transmission service under the same tariff 
    used by others. The Commission also gave an extension of time to 
    December 31, 1996 for certain existing power pooling and other multi-
    lateral coordination agreements to comply with this 
    requirement.160
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \159\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,700-01; mimeo at 191. See also 
    discussion infra at Section IV.G. Section 1.11 (and Section 13.3).
        \160\ By notice issued September 27, 1996 in Docket Nos. RM95-8-
    000 and RM94-7-001, the Commission revised the compliance dates. It 
    required joint pool-wide section 206 compliance tariffs to be filed 
    no later than December 31, 1996, and pool members to begin taking 
    service under the tariffs 60 days after the section 206 filing. It 
    also gave members of public utility holding companies an extension 
    of time to take service under their system-wide tariff until no 
    later than March 1, 1997.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        This issue is discussed above in Section IV.C.1.b.
    2. Accounting Treatment
        In the Final Rule, the Commission directed utilities to account for 
    all uses of the transmission system and to demonstrate that all 
    customers (including the transmission provider's native load) bear the 
    cost responsibility associated with their respective uses.161
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \161\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,703; mimeo at 198.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        No requests for rehearing addressed this matter.
    
    D. Ancillary Services
    
        In the Final Rule, the Commission concluded that the following six 
    ancillary services must be included in an open access transmission 
    tariff: (1) Scheduling, System Control and Dispatch Service; (2) 
    Reactive Supply and Voltage Control from Generation Sources Service; 
    (3) Regulation and Frequency Response Service; (4) Energy Imbalance 
    Service; (5) Operating Reserve--Spinning Reserve Service; and (6) 
    Operating Reserve--Supplemental Reserve Service.162 The Commission 
    adopted NERC's recommendations for ancillary service definitions and 
    descriptions with modifications.163
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \162\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,703-04; mimeo at 199.
        \163\ In comments on the proposed rule, NERC identified 
    additional interconnected operations services that it indicated may 
    be necessary for reliability. As discussed in the Final Rule, we do 
    not require the transmission provider to be the default provider of 
    these other services.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission determined that the transmission provider must 
    provide and the transmission customer must purchase from the 
    transmission provider the first two services, subject to conditions set 
    out in the Rule. The transmission provider must offer the remaining 
    four services to the transmission customer serving load in the 
    transmission provider's control area. The transmission customer that is 
    serving load in the transmission provider's control area must acquire 
    these four services from the transmission provider or a third party, or 
    self provide.
    1. Specific Ancillary Services
    a. Scheduling, System Control and Dispatch Service
        In the Final Rule, the Commission concluded that Scheduling, System 
    Control and Dispatch Service is necessary to the provision of basic 
    transmission service within every control area.164 The Commission 
    further stated that this service can be provided only by the operator 
    of the control area in which the transmission facilities used are 
    located.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \164\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,716; mimeo at 238.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Wisconsin Municipals asks that the Commission eliminate Schedule 1 
    (Scheduling, System Control and Dispatch Service) as an ancillary 
    service and require transmission providers to include these costs in 
    the transmission revenue requirement so the transmission provider 
    cannot recover these costs twice. Alternatively, Wisconsin Municipals 
    asks that, if customers do their own scheduling through an electronic 
    data link, the charge for scheduling and dispatch be waived.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We disagree with Wisconsin Municipals that we should eliminate this 
    ancillary service and include its
    
    [[Page 12305]]
    
    costs with the transmission revenue requirement. Scheduling requires 
    action by both the customer who provides information about a 
    transaction and the control area that evaluates and accepts (schedules) 
    the transaction. If a transmission provider allows a transmission 
    customer to supply its schedules through an electronic data link, it is 
    merely offering an alternate method of providing the transaction 
    information required. The control area must still decide whether it can 
    schedule a transaction. Further, scheduling a transaction is only one 
    aspect of Scheduling, System Control and Dispatch Service. A control 
    area must also dispatch generating resources to maintain generation/
    load balance and maintain security during the transaction. Only the 
    control area operator can perform these functions. A transmission 
    provider must unbundle the cost of these functions, including 
    scheduling, from its base transmission rate. This requirement to 
    unbundle ancillary services costs from the base transmission rate 
    ensures that double recovery of scheduling costs will not occur.
    b. Reactive Supply and Voltage Control From Generation Sources Service
        In the Final Rule, the Commission concluded that Reactive Supply 
    and Voltage Control from Generation Sources Service is necessary to the 
    provision of basic transmission service within every control 
    area.165 Although a customer is required to take this ancillary 
    service from the transmission provider or control area operator, the 
    Commission stated that a customer may reduce the charge for this 
    service to the extent it can reduce its requirement for reactive power 
    supply.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \165\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,716-17; mimeo at 239.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        NRECA and TDU Systems ask that Schedule 2 of the tariff, Reactive 
    Supply and Voltage Control from Generation Sources Service, be modified 
    to reflect that generation facilities outside a control area can 
    provide reactive power. They argue that parties other than the 
    transmission provider and the transmission customer are able to supply 
    reactive power. Similarly, Santa Clara and Redding ask the Commission 
    to revise Schedule 2 to require the transmission provider to offer this 
    service, but to allow the transmission customer to arrange for this 
    service through a purchase from the transmission provider, self-
    provision, or purchases from third parties.166 Blue Ridge also 
    argues that the Commission should permit self-supply or other local 
    supply when it is feasible and economic to do so.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \166\ See also Cajun. Cajun notes that it does and could 
    continue to provide at least a portion of reactive power.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        APPA, Santa Clara, Redding and Cajun point out an inconsistency 
    between Schedule 2 and the preamble. They assert that Schedule 2 of the 
    tariff should be revised to reflect the preamble language that allows a 
    transmission customer to supply at least a portion of its reactive 
    power service. California DWR says that it is capable of providing 
    Reactive Supply and Voltage Control from Generation Sources Service and 
    that mandating that it purchase this ancillary service makes no sense. 
    California DWR asks the Commission to clarify that it is not required 
    to purchase this ancillary service.
        TAPS asks the Commission to make clear that (1) customer-owned 
    generation facilities that are available to supply reactive power to 
    the transmission provider's transmission system receive a credit, (2) 
    the extent of customer-supplied reactive power may be sufficient to 
    eliminate the need for a separate reactive power charge paid to the 
    transmission provider, and (3) customer-owned generation outside the 
    control area may be eligible for a credit if it is located nearby where 
    it can provide reactive support for the transmission provider's 
    transmission system.167 TAPS further asserts that reactive supply 
    service should be viewed not on a transaction basis but on a gridwide 
    or regionwide basis. Under this approach, according to TAPS, payments 
    would be based on whether the user supplies more than it uses or uses 
    more than it supplies.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \167\ See also APPA.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Control area operators use sources of reactive support to control 
    voltage and maintain a stable power supply system. Because of the 
    limited ability to transmit reactive power, these facilities must be 
    available at or near the point of need. Therefore, reactive power 
    support, and hence the facilities able to provide (or absorb) reactive 
    power, must be distributed throughout the transmission system for the 
    reliable operation of the power system. Over- or under-supply of 
    reactive power at other points in the network do not contribute to a 
    stable system and could harm the reliability of the system.
        Although we agree with NRECA and TDU Systems that generation 
    resources just outside the boundaries of a control area may provide 
    some reactive support within the control area, the control area 
    operator must be able to control the dispatch of reactive power from 
    these generating resources. Accordingly, we will modify Schedule 2 to 
    refer to generating facilities that are under the control of the 
    control area operator instead of in the control area. The transmission 
    customer's service agreement should specify the generating resources 
    made available by the transmission customer that provide reactive 
    support.
        As noted in the Final Rule, a transmission customer can reduce (but 
    not eliminate completely) the reactive supply and voltage control needs 
    and costs that its transaction imposes on the transmission provider's 
    system. For example, a customer who controls generating units equipped 
    with automatic voltage control equipment may be able to use those units 
    to help control the voltage locally and reduce the reactive power 
    requirement of the transaction.168 However, if these units are not 
    always available or are not subject to the direction of the control 
    area operator, their occasional use may not reduce the investment 
    required by the control area operator in reactive power facilities. It 
    merely reduces temporarily the cost of operating these facilities. 
    Consistent with this understanding, we will modify Schedule 2 of the 
    tariff to allow a transmission customer to supply at least part of the 
    reactive power service it requires. We will continue to require 
    reactive power service to be provided by and purchased from the 
    transmission provider. However, a transmission customer may satisfy 
    part of its obligation through self-provision or purchases from 
    generating facilities under the control of the control area operator. 
    The transmission customer's service agreement should specify all 
    reactive supply arrangements.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \168\ The location and operating capabilities of the generator 
    will affect its ability to reduce reactive power requirements.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We deny the California DWR and TAPS request that customer-owned 
    generation facilities that are available to supply reactive power 
    should automatically receive a credit. However, as the Final Rule 
    states, a customer may reduce the charge for this service to the extent 
    it can reduce its requirement for reactive power supply. We do not 
    believe a transmission customer can satisfy all of its reactive 
    requirements or allow the transmission provider to avoid
    
    [[Page 12306]]
    
    investment in reactive power related facilities. Concerning the other 
    request of TAPS, we will not require that the supply of reactive power 
    be on a gridwide or regionwide basis. Because reactive power must be 
    supplied near the point of need, we are not persuaded that gridwide 
    supply is feasible.
    c. Energy Imbalance Service
        In the Final Rule, the Commission concluded that Energy Imbalance 
    Service must be offered for transmission within and into the 
    transmission provider's control area to serve load in the area.169 
    However, the Commission noted, a transmission customer can reduce or 
    eliminate the need for energy imbalance service in several ways.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \169\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,717; mimeo at 240.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Energy Imbalance Service is provided when the transmission provider 
    makes up for any difference that occurs over a single hour between the 
    scheduled and the actual delivery of energy to a load located within 
    its control area. For minor hourly differences between the scheduled 
    and delivered energy, the transmission customer is allowed to make up 
    the difference within 30 days (or other reasonable period generally 
    accepted in the region) by adjusting its energy deliveries to eliminate 
    the imbalance. A minor difference is one for which the actual energy 
    delivery differs from the scheduled energy by less than 1.5 percent, 
    except that any hourly difference less than one megawatt-hour is also 
    considered minor. Thus, the Final Rule established an hourly energy 
    deviation band of /1.5 percent (with a minimum of 1 MW) for 
    energy imbalance. The transmission customer must compensate the 
    transmission provider for an imbalance that falls outside the hourly 
    deviation band and for accumulated minor imbalances that are not made 
    up within 30 days.
    (1) Description of Energy Imbalance
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        North Jersey asserts that the definitions of Energy Imbalance 
    Service and Backup Supply Service are conflicting and need 
    clarification. North Jersey proposes that Energy Imbalance Service be 
    clarified to state that a transmission provider will be required to 
    supply power to a customer ``within the dispatch period of the 
    transmission provider's tariff.'' It states that this assures power 
    when a customer is unable to change its nominations to match its 
    generation capabilities. On the other hand, North Jersey states that 
    Backup Supply Service should be the supply of power for a period longer 
    than the tariff dispatch period.
        NIMO asserts that the Commission should recognize that there is 
    another type of Energy Imbalance Service. If a generator is located in 
    one control area, but transfers the power to load in another control 
    area, there is a potential mismatch between the amount of power 
    scheduled for delivery by the generator and the amount it actually 
    provides to the operator of the control area where it is located.
        Nebraska Public Power District (NPPD) states that allowing third 
    parties to provide Energy Imbalance Service and Regulation and 
    Frequency Response Service could jeopardize system reliability. It 
    argues that the transmission provider must have the right to approve 
    the third party provider of these services and the right to physically 
    meter the loads located out of the transmission provider's control area 
    or otherwise monitor these services to be assured that they are 
    provided satisfactorily.
        NCMPA argues that because of the potential for abuse, the 
    Commission should grant an exemption from an energy imbalance charge if 
    the source of the energy shortfall is a generating resource that has 
    been turned over to the transmission provider's dispatching control for 
    meeting control area requirements.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We clarify that Energy Imbalance Service is used to supply energy 
    for mismatches between scheduled deliveries and actual loads that may 
    occur over an hour. We do not intend it to be used as a substitute for 
    operating reserves when there is an outage of generation supply or 
    transmission. The Final Rule states that if a customer uses either type 
    of operating reserve, it must expeditiously replace the reserve with 
    backup power to reestablish required minimum reserve levels.170
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \170\ Order No. 888 imposes no obligation on the transmission 
    provider to furnish replacement power on a long-term basis if the 
    customer loses its source of supply.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Order No. 888 specifies that there is no obligation on the 
    transmission provider to provide power to the customer for a ``time 
    longer than specified in the tariff'' for the customer's own backup 
    supply to be made available.171 The order also states that ``any 
    arrangements for the supply of such service [i.e., Backup Supply 
    Service] by the transmission provider should be specified in the 
    customer's service agreement.'' 172 We revise the first statement 
    to clarify that the transmission customer's service agreement, not the 
    tariff, should specify any arrangements for backup service by the 
    transmission provider, including the time within which backup power 
    supply will be made available. The time should correspond to the time 
    necessary to restore operating reserves that is generally accepted in 
    the region and consistently followed by the transmission provider.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \171\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,711; mimeo at 222.
        \172\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,711; mimeo at 223.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        NIMO asserts that two types of energy imbalance can occur if the 
    generator and the load are in different control areas. These are (1) a 
    mismatch between the energy scheduled to be received in the load's 
    control area and the actual hourly energy consumed by the load, and (2) 
    a mismatch between energy scheduled for delivery from the generator's 
    control area and the amount of energy actually generated in the hour. 
    The Energy Imbalance Service in the Final Rule applies to the first 
    case only. Although we agree that the second type of mismatch can 
    occur, we will not designate as Energy Imbalance Service a mismatch 
    between energy scheduled and energy generated. Energy Imbalance Service 
    in this Rule applies only to the obligation of the transmission 
    provider to correct the first type of energy mismatch, one caused by 
    load variations.
        In general, the amount of energy taken by load in an hour is 
    variable and not subject to the control of either a wholesale seller or 
    a wholesale requirements buyer. The Energy Imbalance Service that we 
    require as our ancillary service has a bandwidth appropriate for load 
    variations and should have a price for exceeding the bandwidth that is 
    appropriate for excessive load variations. Although NIMO states 
    correctly that, where two control areas are involved, there can also be 
    a mismatch between energy scheduled and energy generated, NIMO has not 
    explained why this mismatch should have the same bandwidth and price as 
    our Energy Imbalance Service. Indeed, we believe it should not.
        A generator should be able to deliver its scheduled hourly energy 
    with precision. If we were to allow the generator to deviate from its 
    schedule by 1.5 percent without penalty, as long as it returned the 
    energy in kind at another time, this would discourage good generator 
    operating practice. A generation supplier could intentionally generate 
    less power when its generating cost is high and make it up when its 
    cost is lower if the second type of mismatch is included in our Energy 
    Imbalance Service. Instead, a generator will have an interconnection 
    agreement with its
    
    [[Page 12307]]
    
    transmission provider or control area operator, and we expect that this 
    agreement will specify the requirements for the generator to meet its 
    schedule, and for any consequence for persistent failure to meet its 
    schedule. This agreement will be tailored to the parties' specific 
    standards and circumstances, and, although such arrangements must not 
    be unduly preferential or discriminatory (e.g., must be comparable for 
    all wholesale sellers, including the transmission provider's own 
    wholesale sales), we prefer not to set these standards generically for 
    all parties.173
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \173\ Many provisions regarding the reliable operation and 
    performance of both generation and load will be included in supply 
    interconnection agreements and transmission customer service 
    agreements. The fact that we have designated six services as 
    necessary to prevent undue discrimination in transmission service 
    should not be interpreted as our having set out a complete set of 
    interconnected operations services and conditions necessary for 
    reliable and orderly bulk power system management.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We disagree with NCMPA's argument regarding an exemption from 
    Energy Imbalance Service when the control area operator controls the 
    generating resource. As discussed above and in the Final Rule, energy 
    imbalance results from a mismatch between a scheduled receipt and 
    actual load in the control area of the transmission provider. Energy 
    imbalance can occur if the actual load differs from the scheduled 
    receipt regardless of who controls the generating resource.
        As specified in the Final Rule, to ensure the reliability of the 
    power system, a transmission customer is obligated to obtain Energy 
    Imbalance Service and Regulation and Frequency Response Service for its 
    transactions. We clarify for NPPD that the transmission customer may 
    not decline the transmission provider's offer of these ancillary 
    services unless it demonstrates to the transmission provider that it 
    has acquired the services from another source. This demonstration must 
    show that the customer's alternative arrangement for ancillary services 
    is adequate and consistent with Good Utility Practice. The transmission 
    customer's service agreement should specify any alternative 
    arrangements for the provision of these (or any other) ancillary 
    services.
    (2) Energy Imbalance Bandwidth
        As explained above, Schedule 4 (Energy Imbalance Service) of the 
    tariff allows the transmission provider to charge a transmission 
    customer serving load in its control area for taking an amount of 
    energy in any hour that is 1.5 percent more or less than the amount of 
    energy scheduled for that hour. In the pro forma tariff, the minimum 
    amount of energy that can be assessed a charge in an hour is one 
    megawatt-hour.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Several entities argue that this energy imbalance bandwidth is too 
    narrow and should be increased.174 APPA asserts that the narrow 
    bandwidth imposes obligations on the transmission customer that the 
    transmission provider does not impose on itself.175 TAPS argues 
    that the 1.5 percent bandwidth ``makes no sense because it simply 
    imposes a penalty for existence as a small utility.'' Redding states 
    that the 1.5 percent energy imbalance bandwidth is not appropriate for 
    transmission to a small utility that does not operate a control area. 
    In opposing the narrow bandwidth, TDU Systems notes that metering error 
    is typically within a range of 2 percent. It further argues 
    that it is impossible for smaller systems with low load factors, larger 
    load swings, and the need to change the output quickly for a single 
    unit to operate within the narrow bandwidth. Others assert that a too-
    narrow bandwidth creates a burdensome level of billings unless schedule 
    changes are permitted more frequently than hourly.176 They fear 
    that meeting the 1.5 percent bandwidth would require expensive dynamic 
    scheduling.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \174\ E.g., APPA, NRECA, Blue Ridge, Cooperative Power, Wabash, 
    TDU Systems, Redding, TAPS.
        \175\ See also TDU Systems.
        \176\ E.g., NRECA, Blue Ridge, Cooperative Power, Wabash.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Some entities recommend a particular alternative bandwidth.177 
    TDU Systems suggests a sliding scale as follows. There would be a 
    bandwidth of 5 percent of scheduled energy for transactions 
    of 500 MW or less, decreasing to 1.5 percent for 
    transactions of 5,000 MW or more, with a minimum bandwidth of 
    5 MWh in all cases. Alternatively, TDU Systems says that 
    network customers could be entitled to a bandwidth equal to their load 
    ratio share of the amount (not percentage) of their transmission 
    provider's inadvertent interchange, again subject to a minimum of 5 
    MWh. TAPS recommends that the deviation bandwidth be changed to 6 
    percent of the transmission customer's daily peak demand, with a 
    minimum bandwidth of 4 MWh.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \177\ E.g., TDU Systems, TAPS, NRECA, Wabash, Redding.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        NRECA proposes an alternative approach (previously set forth in its 
    comments on the proposed rule): a customer's ``energy compensation 
    balance'' should be determined for each hour based on the net energy 
    deviation from the ``bandwidth base,'' which NRECA defines as the 
    greater of (i) the customer's total on-line and available generator 
    capacity associated with the generation dispatched, or (ii) the sum of 
    a customer's maximum hourly demands at each of its recipient 
    interfaces. NRECA states that its proposal sets forth separate 
    compensation based on whether there is an overdelivery or an 
    underdelivery outside a five percent bandwidth.
        Wabash argues that the Commission should use a deviation bandwidth 
    based on a period other than a single hour; for example, use a known 
    historical number, such as the maximum hourly load during the previous 
    calendar year. Wabash states that if a larger bandwidth is not adopted, 
    the Commission should permit a transmission customer that is purchasing 
    spinning or supplemental operating reserves as an ancillary service to 
    use those purchases as the basis for an expanded deviation bandwidth. 
    In addition, Wabash asks the Commission to clarify that an imbalance 
    resulting from a system emergency situation caused by loss or failure 
    of facilities should be counted as ``inadvertent loads'' and repaid in 
    like hours at mutually agreed times and pay-back amounts.
        Redding points out that the NERC (A2 Criterion) establishes a 
    constant bandwidth for every hour of the year and should be used 
    instead. For energy imbalances of less than 1.5 percent, Schedule 4 of 
    the tariff allows the energy to be returned in kind within 30 days, 
    after which payment must be made. Redding argues that the 30-day period 
    should be deleted. Instead the Commission should follow current 
    industry practice of allowing reasonable deviations to be carried 
    forward into the next month so as to avoid an accounting nightmare. 
    Finally, Redding argues that the bandwidth for network service should 
    apply to the entire network load and not to a ``scheduled 
    transaction.''
        Wisconsin Municipals asks the Commission to clarify that if parties 
    have reached a settlement that establishes a wider band, the 
    transmission provider may not use Order No. 888 to avoid this 
    settlement obligation.
        TAPS argues that any charges for exceeding the bandwidth should be 
    cost-based and compensation should be symmetrical for over-and under-
    deliveries.178 TAPS further argues that
    
    [[Page 12308]]
    
    the bandwidth should not be applied by transaction, and customers 
    should not have to pay for imbalances caused by transmission provider 
    dispatch mistakes.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \178\ On the other hand, Wabash argues that pursuant to industry 
    practice, overdeliveries should be treated differently than 
    underdeliveries outside the deviation band. It adds that the rate 
    for underdeliveries should be cost-based.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        TDU Systems states that public utilities should be placed on notice 
    that they will not be permitted to collect 100 mills per kWh for energy 
    supplied by a customer in excess of its schedules, as some have sought 
    in tariffs already filed.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Energy Imbalance Service includes a bandwidth to promote good 
    scheduling practices by transmission customers. It is important that 
    the implementation of each scheduled transaction not overly burden 
    others.
        We do not agree with APPA that the bandwidth imposes an obligation 
    on the transmission customer that the transmission provider does not 
    impose on itself. The Final Rule treats all wholesale customers 
    comparably. The transmission provider must also use its pro forma 
    tariff and apply the same bandwidth for sales to its wholesale 
    customers.
        Many commenters assert that the energy imbalance bandwidth of 
    1.5 percent is too narrow and is difficult to meet for 
    small utilities. Several propose an alternative bandwidth or a larger 
    minimum deviation. We believe that the bandwidth included in the Final 
    Rule pro forma tariff is consistent with what the industry has been 
    using as a standard and is as close to an industry standard as anyone 
    can set at this time. However, we will set a larger minimum deviation 
    to meet the needs of small customers. The minimum energy imbalance is 
    now two megawatt-hours per hour (2 MW minimum in the pro forma tariff). 
    This adequately addresses the concerns raised by small utilities 
    because they may exceed the bandwidth without exceeding this minimum. 
    For example, a transmission customer that transfers less than 133 MW 
    (1.5 percent of 133 MW is 2 MW, the minimum energy imbalance) has a 
    larger percentage bandwidth than 1.5 percent. The bandwidth 
    set forth in the pro forma tariff provides a needed incentive for a 
    transmission customer to deliver an amount of energy each hour that is 
    reasonably close to the amount scheduled, while at the same time 
    recognizing the needs of small utilities. To help customers with the 
    difficulty of forecasting loads far in advance of the hour, the Final 
    Rule pro forma tariff permits schedule changes up to twenty minutes 
    before the hour at no charge. By updating its schedule before the hour 
    begins, a transmission customer should be able to reduce or avoid 
    energy imbalance and associated charges. However, we will allow the 
    transmitting utility and the customer to negotiate and file another 
    bandwidth more flexible to the customer, subject to a requirement that 
    the same bandwidth be made available on a not unduly discriminatory 
    basis.
        We disagree with Wabash's request to require a transmission 
    provider to expand its energy imbalance bandwidth for a transmission 
    customer purchasing spinning and supplemental reserves. Unlike Energy 
    Imbalance Service, which treats deviations between scheduled and actual 
    hourly energy deliveries, spinning and supplemental reserves provide 
    generating capacity that responds to contingency situations (e.g., loss 
    or failure of facilities). Order No. 888 requires a transmission 
    customer to obtain these operating reserve ancillary services for its 
    transactions. Therefore, Wabash is simply requesting a larger energy 
    imbalance bandwidth. We have selected the bandwidth to promote good 
    scheduling practices by transmission customers. A larger bandwidth may 
    introduce poor operating practices that could affect the reliability of 
    the system. If the Energy Imbalance Service bandwidth were larger, 
    energy supplied within this expanded bandwidth could be provided from 
    reserve capacity. Some reserve capacity may not then be available when 
    needed for system reliability. However, as stated in the Final Rule, we 
    will allow a transmission provider to assemble packages of ancillary 
    services (not bundled with basic transmission service) that can be 
    offered at rates that are less than the total of individual charges for 
    the services if purchased separately.179
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \179\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,719; mimeo at 246.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In response to Wabash's other concern, we believe that emergency 
    situations caused by loss or failure of facilities should be addressed 
    in the transmission customer's service agreement (or the generation 
    supplier's separate interconnection agreement) and not as part of 
    Energy Imbalance Service.
        In response to Redding's statement that the NERC (A2 criterion) 
    establishes a constant bandwidth for imbalances, we note that NERC has 
    set a standard for a kind of deviation that is different from our 
    Energy Imbalance Service. NERC's bandwidth is for inadvertent 
    interchange between a control area and all other control areas. Redding 
    has presented no reason that our Energy Imbalance Service bandwidth 
    should be the same as NERC's inadvertent interchange bandwidth. 
    Regarding its concern about the in-kind repayment period, we note that 
    Schedule 4 does not always require a 30-day period for in-kind 
    repayment of energy imbalances; it also permits a term that the 
    transmission provider consistently follows and is generally accepted in 
    the region. In addition, we clarify that the bandwidth for network 
    service applies to the entire network load.
        With respect to Wisconsin Municipals' request, we clarify that the 
    Final Rule does not require parties to a contract that went into effect 
    prior to July 9, 1996 to stop using a wider bandwidth established by 
    settlement. However, service provided pursuant to a settlement that was 
    expressly approved subject to the outcome of Order No. 888 on non-rate 
    terms and conditions must be revised in the subsequent compliance 
    filing to reflect the language contained in the pro forma 
    tariff.180 Subsequent to the compliance tariff filing, public 
    utilities are free to file under section 205 to revise the tariffs 
    (e.g., to reflect various settlement provisions) and customers are free 
    to pursue changes under section 206.181
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \180\ See Order on Non-Rate Terms and Conditions, 77 FERC para. 
    61,144 at 61,538 (1996). The Commission explained:
        Order No. 888 required all tariff compliance filings to contain 
    non-rate terms and conditions identical to the pro forma tariff, 
    with a limited exception for regional practices, and with four 
    attachments where the utility could propose specific inserts.
        \181\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,770 n.514; mimeo at 399 n.514.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In response to arguments regarding the price of Energy Imbalance 
    Service, we note that the Final Rule intentionally does not provide 
    detailed pricing requirements. We require the transmission provider to 
    determine and apply to the Commission for appropriate rates for Energy 
    Imbalance Service as part of its transmission tariff. Transmission 
    customers may address any disagreements with a specific charge in the 
    company's transmission rate case.
    2. Ancillary Services Obligations
        In the Final Rule, the Commission distinguished two groups or 
    categories of ancillary services: (1) services that the transmission 
    provider is required to provide to all of its basic transmission 
    customers under the tariff, and (2) services that the transmission 
    provider is required to offer to provide only to transmission customers 
    serving load in the provider's control area. The Commission required a 
    transmission provider that operates a control area to provide the first 
    group of ancillary services and the transmission customer
    
    [[Page 12309]]
    
    to purchase these services from the transmission provider. The 
    Commission required a transmission provider to offer to provide the 
    ancillary services in the second group to transmission customers 
    serving load in the transmission provider's control area. The 
    Commission required the transmission customer serving load in the 
    transmission provider's area to acquire these services, but allowed the 
    transmission customer to do so from the transmission provider, a third 
    party or self-supply.
        If the transmission provider is a public utility providing basic 
    transmission service, but is not a control area operator, the 
    Commission allowed the transmission provider to fulfill its obligation 
    to provide, or offer to provide, ancillary services by acting as the 
    customer's agent. In this case, if the control area operator is a 
    public utility, the Commission required the control area operator to 
    offer to provide all ancillary services to any transmission customer 
    that takes transmission service over facilities in its control area 
    whether or not the control area operator owns or controls the 
    facilities used to provide the basic transmission service.
    a. Obligation of a Control Area Utility
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Carolina P&L asks the Commission to clarify that the transmission 
    provider is not required to provide control area services to another 
    utility operating a control area that simply chooses not to provide for 
    its own control area obligations. It argues that this is not justified 
    in a competitive bulk power market.
        Maine Public Service asserts that a transmission provider that is 
    not a NERC-recognized control area can provide ancillary services from 
    its own facilities. It asks that the Commission clarify that this is 
    permissible. At a minimum, Maine Public Service states that the 
    Commission must allow transmission providers on a case-by-case basis to 
    establish that they provide ancillary services even if they are not 
    NERC-recognized control areas or do not satisfy the Commission's 
    definition (citing the initial decision in Maine Public Service 
    Company, 74 FERC para. 63,011 (1996)).
        Similarly, California DWR states that it has been operating since 
    1983 as a quasi-control area, self-providing most, if not all, of the 
    ancillary services it uses. It also notes that it provides such 
    services to its utility transmission providers. California DWR argues 
    that it is entitled to appropriate compensation for all ancillary 
    services that it provides to its transmission providers or other 
    parties.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        In response to Carolina P&L, we clarify that the Final Rule does 
    not require a control area operator to provide control area services 
    within another control area.
        Except for the ancillary service called Scheduling, System Control 
    and Dispatch,182 the Final Rule does not preclude a transmission 
    provider that is not a control area operator from offering ancillary 
    services to its transmission customers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \182\ As NERC and others pointed out in their comments on the 
    proposed rule, this service can be provided only by the operator of 
    the control area in which the transmission facilities used are 
    located. FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,716; mimeo at 238.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Order No. 888 requires that a transmission customer obtain or 
    provide ancillary services for its transactions. If a transmission 
    customer can self-supply a portion of its requirement for ancillary 
    services (other than Scheduling, System Control, and Dispatch Service), 
    it should pay a reduced charge for these services. As with the 
    transmission provider, a third party may offer ancillary services 
    voluntarily to other customers if technology permits. However, simply 
    supplying some duplicative ancillary services (e.g., providing reactive 
    power at low load periods or providing it at a location where it is not 
    needed) in ways that do not reduce the ancillary services costs of the 
    transmission provider or that are not coordinated with the control area 
    operator does not qualify for a reduced charge. The transmission 
    customer must make separate arrangements with the transmission provider 
    or control area operator to supply its own ancillary services and 
    specify such arrangements in its service agreement.
    b. Obligation to Provide Dynamic Scheduling
        Dynamic scheduling electronically moves a generation resource or 
    load from the control area in which it is physically located to a new 
    control area. In the Final Rule, the Commission concluded that it would 
    not require the transmission provider to offer Dynamic Scheduling 
    Service to a transmission customer, although a transmission provider 
    may do so voluntarily. If the customer wants to purchase this service 
    from a third party, the Commission stated that the transmission 
    provider should make a good faith effort to accommodate the necessary 
    arrangements between the customer and the third party for metering and 
    communication facilities.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        AMP-Ohio asks that the Commission clarify that the transmission 
    provider is required to provide dynamic scheduling ``to the extent a 
    transmission customer needs and is willing to pay for reasonably priced 
    dynamic scheduling in order to support its operations, including in 
    order to integrate its loads and resources located in more than one 
    control area.'' Wisconsin Municipals also asks the Commission to 
    clarify that dynamic scheduling must be provided if technically 
    feasible and permitted by regional reliability practices.
        Wisconsin Municipals further asks that the Commission clarify that 
    if the transmission provider has agreed to provide dynamic scheduling 
    in a settlement, it may not use its Order No. 888 implementation filing 
    to void this obligation.
        EEI asks that the Commission clarify the residual obligations of a 
    control area utility to an entity that electronically leaves the 
    control area via dynamic scheduling.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        In response to Amp-Ohio and Wisconsin Municipals, we note that 
    dynamic scheduling is not a required ancillary service in Order No. 
    888, and we do not require a transmission provider to offer this 
    service. However, nothing in the Final Rule precludes a transmission 
    provider from offering it as a separate service. Furthermore, offering 
    dynamic scheduling to integrate loads and resources in more than one 
    control area is also not required.
        Wisconsin Municipals' argument with respect to prior settlements 
    has been previously addressed in Section IV.D.1.c.(2) (Energy Imbalance 
    Service).
        We clarify for EEI that, once dynamic scheduling is arranged, each 
    of the two control areas has ancillary service responsibilities under 
    the Rule. The reactive power obligations of the original control area 
    remain and cannot be completely supplied by distant sources. Order No. 
    888 requires, in the case of dynamic scheduling, both control areas to 
    provide the first two ancillary services in their respective control 
    areas, that is, (1) Scheduling, System Control, and Dispatch Service 
    and (2) Reactive Supply and Voltage Control from Generation Sources 
    Service, and the new control area to offer the remaining ancillary 
    services to the dynamically scheduled entity. In addition, the actual 
    energy transfers between the two control areas will require basic 
    transmission service. We
    
    [[Page 12310]]
    
    expect that any additional obligations of a control area operator to an 
    entity that electronically leaves the control area via dynamic 
    scheduling, such as backup procedures for the failure of telemetering 
    equipment, will be set out in the transmission customer's service 
    agreement.
    c. Obligation As Agent
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        A transmission provider must act as an agent to help the customer 
    acquire ancillary services if the transmission provider cannot provide 
    them itself. NRECA asks whether a non-public utility may collect a 
    reasonable fee for its agency services in fulfilling its reciprocity 
    requirement.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        While the Final Rule does not allow a public utility transmission 
    provider acting as an ancillary services agent to collect a fee for its 
    agency service, we do not have similar authority to deny a non-public 
    utility the opportunity to charge a fee for providing an agency 
    service. However, to the extent a non-public utility seeks to collect 
    an agency fee from a public utility, it must meet our comparability 
    requirements and charge a comparable fee to its own wholesale merchant 
    function.
    3. Miscellaneous Ancillary Services Issues
    a. Transmission Provider as Ancillary Services Merchant
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Allegheny asserts that the sale of power in connection with 
    ancillary services would make the transmission provider a wholesale 
    merchant under the Commission's standards of conduct (citing section 
    37.3 of the Commission's Regulations). Allegheny asks that the 
    Commission clarify that a transmission provider's employee responsible 
    for providing ancillary services is not engaged in a wholesale merchant 
    service that would trigger the functional separation requirement.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We clarify that the transmission provider's sale of ancillary 
    services associated with its provision of basic transmission service is 
    not a wholesale merchant function for purposes of Order No. 889. This 
    is because the provision of ancillary services is essential for 
    providing transmission service. However, the sale of ancillary services 
    not associated with the transmission provider's provision of basic 
    transmission service is a wholesale function for purposes of Order No. 
    889. Thus, if an employee is marketing an ancillary service independent 
    of the transmission provider's obligations to provide transmission 
    service, i.e., as a third party to another transmission provider's 
    basic transmission service customer, the employee would be providing a 
    wholesale merchant function and the Order No. 889 Standards of Conduct 
    apply.
    b. QF Receipt of Ancillary Services
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        North Jersey argues that the Commission did not engage in reasoned 
    decisionmaking in ruling that Real Power Loss Service is not an 
    ancillary service. It asserts that this service must be provided by the 
    transmission provider. North Jersey further argues that, because the 
    Commission describes the furnishing of real power loss as a sale of 
    power, this could prevent a PURPA qualifying facility (QF) from being a 
    transmission service customer. North Jersey states that a QF faces 
    power purchase and resell restrictions under the Commission's 
    regulations. North Jersey asks that the Commission find that receipt of 
    Real Power Loss Service from a third party to complete a transmission 
    transaction is not a purchase and resale of power. In addition, North 
    Jersey requests that the Commission clarify that receipt of ancillary 
    services by a QF does not constitute a purchase and resale of electric 
    power that would jeopardize its status as a QF (clarification also 
    requested in ER95-791-000).\183\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \183\ In Docket No. ER95-791 the Commission ruled that this 
    issue was not part of the hearing and that North Jersey should file 
    for a declaratory order to resolve the matter.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Commission disagrees with North Jersey's assertion that Real 
    Power Loss Service should be an ancillary service that must be provided 
    by the transmission provider. As stated in the Final Rule, it is not 
    necessary for the transmission provider to supply Real Power Loss 
    Service to effect a transmission service transaction. Although the 
    transmission customer is responsible for losses associated with its 
    transmission service, supply of losses is purely a generation service 
    that can be (1) self supplied; (2) purchased from the transmission 
    provider, if it offers this service; or (3) purchased from a third 
    party.
        We clarify that a QF arrangement for receipt of Real Power Loss 
    Service or ancillary services from the transmission provider or a third 
    party for the purpose of completing a transmission transaction is not a 
    sale-for-resale of power by a QF transmission customer that would 
    violate our QF rules.
    c. Pricing of Ancillary Services
        In the Final Rule, the Commission concluded that it would consider 
    ancillary services rate proposals on a case-by-case basis and offered 
    general guidance on ancillary services pricing principles.\184\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \184\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,720-21; mimeo at 250-52.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        NRECA and TDU Systems argue that there should be truth in 
    transmission pricing so that the rate is clearly identified as 
    including or excluding ancillary services.
        AEP asserts that if a purchaser of ancillary services has 
    alternative suppliers of these services, then either the transmission 
    provider should not be required to provide those services or it should 
    be able to charge market rates for them. Otherwise, according to AEP, 
    the market is skewed in favor of the customer.
        Illinois Power argues that if a transmitting utility demonstrates 
    that it incurs incremental costs from its obligation to offer to 
    provide the required ancillary services, it should be permitted to 
    recover such costs through an adjustment to base transmission rates.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Final Rule requires unbundling of individual ancillary services 
    from basic transmission service. We point out to NRECA and TDU Systems 
    that the transmission provider must post and update prices for basic 
    transmission and each ancillary service on its OASIS. As discussed 
    below in Section IV.G.1.h. (Discounts), the Commission is revising its 
    policy regarding the discounting of the price of transmission services. 
    There, we establish three principal requirements for discounting basic 
    transmission service.\185\ We clarify here that these principal 
    requirements apply to discounts for ancillary services provided by the 
    transmission provider in support of its provision of basic transmission 
    service. However, because ancillary services are generally not path-
    
    [[Page 12311]]
    
    specific, a discount agreed upon for an ancillary service must be 
    offered for the same period to all eligible customers on the 
    transmission provider's system. In addition, if a transmission provider 
    offers any rate or packaged ancillary service discounts, it must post 
    them on its OASIS and make them available to affiliates and non-
    affiliates on a basis that is not unduly discriminatory. In this 
    manner, any discounting of ancillary service prices is visible to all 
    market participants. We will require that, as soon as practicable, any 
    ``negotiation'' of discounts between a transmission provider and 
    potential transmission (and ancillary) service customers should take 
    place on the OASIS.\186\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \185\ In brief, these are that (1) any offer of a discount made 
    by the transmission provider must be announced to all potential 
    customers solely by posting on the OASIS, (2) any customer-initiated 
    requests for discounts (including requests for one's own use or for 
    an affiliate's use) must occur solely by posting on the OASIS, and 
    (3) once a discount is negotiated, details must be immediately 
    posted on the OASIS. In addition to these three principal 
    requirements, we also require that a discount agreed upon for a path 
    must be extended to certain other paths described in Section 
    IV.G.1.h.
        \186\ ''Negotiation'' would only take place if the transmission 
    provider or potential customer seeks prices below the ceiling prices 
    set forth in the tariff.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We continue to require a transmission provider to provide or offer 
    to provide the six ancillary services, even if the transmission 
    customer has some alternative suppliers. We distinguished these six 
    services from others (e.g., Real Power Loss Services) for which many 
    suppliers are typically available. In some cases, only the transmission 
    provider can provide the ancillary service; in other cases too few 
    providers are available to create a market for these services. Further, 
    we were persuaded by the comments of NERC and others that these 
    services are essential for reliability; if a customer must obtain these 
    services to obtain transmission service there must be a default 
    provider of these services. However, market-based rates for some of the 
    ancillary services may be appropriate if the seller lacks market power 
    for such services. Market power issues regarding ancillary services 
    have to be addressed before market-based rates for ancillary services 
    can be approved, as requested by AEP. We will consider market-based 
    rates for ancillary services on a case-by-case basis.
        In reply to Illinois Power, we agree that the transmission provider 
    may incur incremental costs from its obligation to offer to provide 
    ancillary services. We believe, however, these costs should be included 
    in the price for those services. Order No. 888 requires the 
    transmission provider to unbundle the cost of ancillary services from 
    the base transmission rate. A rebundling of these costs with the base 
    transmission rate, as Illinois Power requests, would not satisfy the 
    unbundling requirement.
    
    E. Real-Time Information Networks
    
        In the Final Rule, the Commission concluded that in order to remedy 
    undue discrimination in the provision of transmission services it is 
    necessary to have non-discriminatory access to transmission 
    information, and that an electronic information system and standards of 
    conduct are necessary to meet this objective.\187\ Therefore, in 
    conjunction with the Final Rule, the Commission issued a final rule 
    adding a new Part 37 that requires the creation of a basic OASIS and 
    standards of conduct.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \187\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31, 722; mimeo at 255-56.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Rehearing requests raising arguments with respect to specific 
    aspects of OASIS and standards of conduct are addressed in Order No. 
    889-A, issued concurrently with this order.
    
    F. Coordination Arrangements: Power Pools, Public Utility Holding 
    Companies, Bilateral Coordination Arrangements, and Independent System 
    Operators
    
        In the Final Rule, the Commission explained that its requirement 
    for non-discriminatory transmission access and pricing by public 
    utilities, and its specific requirement that public utilities unbundle 
    their transmission rates and take transmission service under their own 
    tariffs, apply to all public utilities' wholesale sales and purchases 
    of electric energy, including coordination transactions.\188\ While the 
    Commission ``grandfathered'' certain existing requirements agreements 
    and non-economy energy coordination agreements, it also determined that 
    certain existing wholesale coordination arrangements and agreements 
    must be modified to ensure that they are not unduly discriminatory. The 
    Commission then discussed (as set forth further below) how and when 
    various types of coordination agreements will need to be modified, and 
    when public utility parties to coordination agreements must begin to 
    trade power under those agreements using transmission service obtained 
    under the same open access transmission tariff available to non-
    parties.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \188\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,725-27; mimeo at 266-70.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission explained that it was addressing four broad 
    categories of coordination arrangements and accompanying agreements: 
    ``tight'' power pools, ``loose'' power pools, public utility holding 
    company arrangements, and bilateral coordination arrangements.
        In addition, the Commission explained that ISOs may prove to be an 
    effective means for accomplishing comparable access and, accordingly, 
    provided guidance on minimum ISO characteristics.
    1. Tight Power Pools
        The Commission required public utilities that are members of a 
    tight pool to file, within 60 days of publication of the Final Rule in 
    the Federal Register, either: (1) an individual Final Rule pro forma 
    tariff; or (2) a joint pool-wide Final Rule pro forma tariff.\189\ 
    However, the Commission required them to file a joint pool-wide Final 
    Rule pro forma tariff no later than December 31, 1996, and to begin to 
    take service under that tariff for all pool transactions no later than 
    December 31, 1996.\190\ The Commission also required the public utility 
    members of tight pools to file reformed power pooling agreements no 
    later than December 31, 1996 if the agreements contain provisions that 
    are unduly discriminatory or preferential.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \189\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,727-28; mimeo at 270-72.
        \190\ By notice issued September 27, 1996, the Commission 
    extended the date by which public utilities that are members of 
    tight power pools must take service under joint pool-wide open 
    access transmission tariffs from no later than December 31, 1996 to 
    60 days after the filing of their joint pool-wide section 206 
    compliance tariff.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        If a reformed power pooling agreement allows members to make 
    transmission commitments or contributions in exchange for discounted 
    transmission rates, the Commission indicated that the pool may file a 
    transmission tariff that contains an access fee (or file a higher 
    transmission rate) for non-transmission owning members or non-members, 
    justified solely on the basis of transmission-related costs.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Consumers Power asks the Commission to clarify that Order No. 888 
    does not preclude the Michigan Electric Coordinated Systems (MECS) from 
    being in compliance by removing all transmission functions from pool 
    control and allowing pool members or the pool to take transmission 
    service from transmission-owning pool members under their open access 
    tariffs. It asserts that this would be an interim placeholder 
    alternative while retail deliberations continue in Michigan. 
    Furthermore, as one of the two members of MECS, Consumers Power 
    indicates that it would be willing to consider further modifications 
    that would liberalize membership criteria during the transition period 
    if the Commission otherwise clarifies that the MECS Pool is in 
    compliance with Order No. 888.
    
    [[Page 12312]]
    
        NY Municipals request that the Commission clarify that, 
    particularly if generation services are to be provided at market-based 
    rates, monopoly transmission services must continue to be provided at 
    cost-based rates (raised in connection with the NYPP). They also ask 
    that the Commission clarify that joint pool-wide tariffs must 
    incorporate transmission rates that are uniform (non-pancaked) and 
    strictly based on the embedded costs of the transmission facilities and 
    related transmission expenses. Moreover, NY Municipals argue that 
    transmission owners should receive a credit based on the depreciated 
    costs of their transmission facilities.
        TAPS also asks the Commission to clarify that pool-wide and system-
    wide tariffs must contain non-pancaked rates.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        While Consumers Power's proposal to remove transmission functions 
    from pool control, if implemented in a non-discriminatory fashion, 
    would satisfy the comparability requirements of Order No. 888, the 
    Commission encourages Consumers Power to pursue a pool-wide 
    tariff.\191\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \191\ It is not clear from the rehearing request exactly how the 
    current members of MECS are proposing to remove all transmission 
    functions from pool control and to take transmission service under 
    their individual open access tariffs. For example, this may preclude 
    the continuation of joint economic dispatch of generating facilities 
    belonging to Consumer Power and Detroit Edison, which the rehearing 
    request appears to assume would continue. However, the Commission 
    will address the adequacy of any such proposal in the context of the 
    appropriate compliance filings.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        NY Municipal Utilities' concern that rates for transmission service 
    will not be priced at cost-based rates is ill-founded. While Order No. 
    888 does not establish any specific pricing methodology for tariff 
    transmission service, the Commission expects all transmission rate 
    proposals filed on compliance to be cost based and to meet the standard 
    for conforming proposals set out in the Commission's Transmission 
    Pricing Policy Statement. (See 18 CFR 2.22).
        Regarding NY Municipal Utilities' and TAPS's requests for a uniform 
    tariff with non-pancaked rates, Order No. 888 does not require a non-
    pancaked rate structure unless a non-pancaked rate structure is 
    available to pool members. Although the Commission has encouraged the 
    industry to reform transmission pricing, the Commission's current 
    policy does not mandate a specific transmission rate structure.
        With regard to NY Municipal Utilities' concern about market-based 
    rates for generation, public utility owners of existing NYPP generation 
    are not eligible to charge market-based power sales rates absent 
    Commission approval. Order No. 888 allows market-based rates only if 
    the seller in a case-specific filing demonstrates it meets the 
    Commission's well-established criteria of showing that it and its 
    affiliates do not have or have adequately mitigated transmission market 
    power and generation market power, that there are no other barriers to 
    entry, and there is no evidence of affiliate abuse or reciprocal 
    dealing. With regard to requests to make market-based sales from new 
    generation, the seller does not have to submit evidence of generation 
    market power in long-run bulk power markets (subject to challenge where 
    specific evidence can be presented); 192 however, for sales from 
    existing generation at market-based rates, the applicant must 
    demonstrate that it lacks, or has fully mitigated, generation market 
    power.193
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \192\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,657; mimeo at 64-65; section 
    35.27.
        \193\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,660; mimeo at 73-74.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In response to NY Municipals' request that transmission owners that 
    contribute transmission facilities to a power pool should receive a 
    rate credit based on the depreciated costs of those transmission 
    facilities, we agree that this is one possible way of reflecting a pool 
    member's contributions or commitments of transmission facilities. 
    However, NY Municipals has provided no rationale as to why we should 
    limit the broader approach we adopted in Order No. 888 to this single 
    mechanism.194
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \194\ See FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,727-28; mimeo at 271-72.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    2. Loose Pools
        In the Final Rule, the Commission found that public utilities 
    within a loose pool must file, within 60 days of publication of the 
    Final Rule in the Federal Register, either: (1) an individual Final 
    Rule pro forma tariff; or (2) a pool-wide Final Rule pro forma 
    tariff.195 However, the Commission required that they file a joint 
    pool-wide Final Rule pro forma tariff no later than December 31, 1996, 
    and begin to take service under that tariff for all pool transactions 
    no later than December 31, 1996. 196 The Commission also required 
    that the public utility members of loose pools file reformed power 
    pooling agreements no later than December 31, 1996 if the agreements 
    contain provisions that are unduly discriminatory or preferential. They 
    also must file a joint pool-wide tariff no later than December 31, 
    1996.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \195\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,728; mimeo at 272-74.
        \196\ By notice issued September 27, 1996, the Commission 
    extended the date by which public utility members of loose power 
    pools must take service under joint pool-wide open access 
    transmission pro forma tariffs from no later than December 31, 1996 
    to 60 days after the filing of their joint pool-wide section 206 
    compliance tariff.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        If a reformed pooling agreement allows members to make transmission 
    commitments or contributions in exchange for discounted transmission 
    rates, the Commission determined that the pool may file a transmission 
    tariff that contains an access fee (or a higher transmission rate) for 
    non-transmission owning members or non-members, justified solely on the 
    basis of transmission-related costs.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Union Electric asserts that the definition of loose pools is so 
    vague that many public utilities, regional organizations and multi-
    lateral arrangements, which are not actually pools, may incorrectly be 
    deemed loose pools by third parties. Thus, Union Electric asks the 
    Commission to clarify that members or parties to multi-lateral 
    arrangements only need to offer transmission services pursuant to their 
    own individual company tariffs.
        EEI asks the Commission to clarify the nature of the tariffs that 
    loose pools may file to comply with the Rule to ensure that the members 
    are not required to file tariffs for services that they do not now 
    provide. EEI also requests that, where members of loose pools currently 
    provide transmission services to each other, they may continue to 
    provide such services to each other under each member's individual pro 
    forma tariff in lieu of a pool-wide tariff (provided that those 
    services are made available to all eligible entities on a non-
    discriminatory basis). Similarly, Montana Power argues that members of 
    loose pools should be allowed to meet comparability by filing 
    individual open access tariffs, without having to file a pool-wide 
    tariff.197
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \197\ See also Public Service Co of CO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Public Service Co of CO asserts that the primary purpose of the 
    Inland Power Pool is to provide for reserve sharing during emergency 
    conditions, although the pool agreement also allows for economy 
    transactions. It argues that another way to comply with the Rule should 
    be to eliminate the economy energy schedule of the Inland Power Pool 
    Agreement. Moreover, Public Service Co of CO argues that given the 
    number of non-jurisdictional entities within the Inland Power Pool, it 
    may be impossible to agree on a pool-wide tariff. El Paso adds that 
    Inland Power Pool should not be treated as a loose
    
    [[Page 12313]]
    
    pool because it functions as a reserve sharing mechanism and not as a 
    pool.
        Utilities For Improved Transition asks the Commission to clarify 
    that pool members or members of other entities do not have to provide 
    more transmission services than they already provide on a voluntary 
    basis to each other. It contends that there is no record to support a 
    broader obligation and would cause massive disruption and the 
    disintegration of many existing pools. Utilities For Improved 
    Transition maintains that pools should have substantial leeway to 
    develop arrangements reflecting their diverse memberships and the 
    diverse contributions made.
        VEPCO seeks clarification whether the Commission intended to impose 
    the single-system tariff requirement only with respect to multilateral 
    agreements that provide for system-wide transmission rates for the 
    parties to the agreements.
        TAPS asks the Commission to clarify that section 35.28(c)(3) 
    includes all pools and all holding company systems, as well as any 
    multi-lateral agreement so long as the multi-lateral agreement 
    explicitly or implicitly addresses transmission (e.g., by providing for 
    a transaction without assessing transmission costs in connection with 
    that transaction).
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        In response to parties seeking clarification of the definition of a 
    loose pool, the Commission clarifies that a loose pool is any 
    multilateral arrangement, other than a tight power pool or a holding 
    company arrangement, that explicitly or implicitly contains discounted 
    and/or special transmission arrangements, that is, rates, terms, or 
    conditions. The Commission requires public utilities that are members 
    of a loose pool to either (1) reform their pooling arrangements in 
    accordance with Order No. 888 or (2) excise all discounted and/or 
    special arrangements transmission service from the pooling arrangement. 
    That is, in the latter case the members could continue to provide other 
    services (e.g., generation), but would cease to be a loose pool for 
    purposes of Order No. 888.
        The primary goal of Order No. 888's requirements for pooling 
    arrangements, including ``loose'' pools, is to ensure comparability 
    regarding transmission services that are offered on a pool-wide basis. 
    We believe comparability for loose pools can be achieved if pooling 
    agreements are modified: (1) to allow open membership and (2) to make 
    the transmission service in the loose pool agreement available to 
    others. While the Commission encourages pool-wide transmission tariffs 
    that offer the full range of transmission services included in the pro 
    forma tariff, we will not require, under the comparability principles 
    of Order No. 888, that pool members offer to third parties transmission 
    services that they do not provide to themselves on a pool-wide basis. 
    For example, if existing loose pool members do not offer network 
    services to each other, they do not have to expand the pool services to 
    offer network services to themselves or any third parties. 
    Additionally, we do not find it to be unduly discriminatory to provide 
    some pool-wide transmission services to members under a pooling 
    agreement and to provide other transmission services to members under 
    the individual tariff of each member, as long as members and non-
    members have access to the same transmission services on a comparable 
    basis and pay the same or a comparable rate for transmission.198
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \198\ See FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,728; mimeo at 273-74.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission notes that the Inland Power Pool agreement provides 
    for non-firm transmission service (Service Schedule D) for emergency 
    service, scheduled outage service, and economy energy service. The 
    Inland Power Pool agreement provides members preferential transmission 
    rates for deliveries of emergency service, i.e., members will provide 
    free non-firm transmission service at a higher priority than any other 
    non-firm transactions. Such preferential service is not available to 
    non-members. We consider any rates, terms or conditions of transmission 
    service that favor members over non-members to be unduly discriminatory 
    and preferential, whether embodied explicitly or implicitly in a loose 
    pooling agreement. Pool members can either amend the agreement to 
    provide comparable services to others and open the pool to new members, 
    or amend the agreement to eliminate any preferential transmission 
    availability and/or pricing.
        In response to TAPS, the Commission agrees that Section 35.28(c)(3) 
    applies to any pool, holding company system or multi-lateral agreement 
    that contains explicit or implicit transmission rates, terms, or 
    conditions.199 For example, if a utility offers transmission 
    without charge as part of such an agreement, it must offer transmission 
    to all parties requesting a similar service either without charge or at 
    an access fee or other transmission rate that comparably reflects 
    transmission-related costs borne by members of the agreement.200
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \199\ See FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,726; mimeo at 268-69 (filing 
    of open access tariffs by public utility pool members is not enough 
    to cure undue discrimination in transmission if those entities can 
    continue to trade with a selective group within a power pool; the 
    same holds true for certain bilateral arrangements allowing 
    preferential pricing or access) and FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,727-
    28; mimeo at 270-272 (tight and loose pools must file joint pool-
    wide tariffs).
        \200\ See FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,730; mimeo at 278.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    3. Public Utility Holding Companies
        In the Final Rule, the Commission required that holding company 
    public utility members, with the exception of the Central and South 
    West (CSW) System, file a single system-wide Final Rule pro forma 
    tariff permitting transmission service across the entire holding 
    company system at a single price within 60 days of publication of the 
    Final Rule in the Federal Register.201
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \201\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,728-29; mimeo at 274-77.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        With respect to CSW, the Commission directed the public utility 
    subsidiaries of CSW to consult with the Texas, Arkansas, Oklahoma and 
    Louisiana Commissions and to file not later than December 31, 1996 a 
    system tariff that will provide comparable service to all wholesale 
    users on the CSW System, regardless of whether they take transmission 
    service wholly within ERCOT or the SPP, or take transmission service 
    between the reliability councils over the North and East 
    Interconnections.
        The Commission gave public utilities that are members of holding 
    companies an extension of the requirement to take service under the 
    system tariff for wholesale trades between and among the public utility 
    operating companies within the holding company system until December 
    31, 1996--the same extension it granted to power pools.202 In 
    addition, the Commission indicated that it may be necessary for 
    registered holding companies to reform their holding company 
    equalization agreement to recognize the non-discriminatory terms and 
    conditions of transmission service required under the Final Rule pro 
    forma tariff.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \202\ By notice issued September 27, 1996, the Commission 
    extended the date by which public utilities that are members of 
    holding companies must take service under their system-wide tariffs 
    from December 31, 1996 to no later than March 1, 1997.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        FL Com asks the Commission to clarify whether it intends to require 
    operating company members of a registered holding company to charge 
    each other the same wheeling charge to be charged to others even though 
    others pay nothing for transmission construction. FL Com argues that 
    such
    
    [[Page 12314]]
    
    a charge would be inconsistent with the Commission's traditional 
    treatment of public utility holding companies as a single entity.
        AL Com asks the Commission to clarify that ``intra-holding company 
    transactions in support of economic dispatch across a single integrated 
    system should not be subjected to additional transmission charges, 
    while transactions between operating companies for the benefit of 
    wholesale customers not included within the definition of native load 
    customer require distinct transmission charges.'' 203
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \203\ AL Com at 1-4.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Southern asks the Commission to clarify that transactions between 
    public utility operating subsidiaries within a holding company system 
    for the benefit of native load customers fall within the network 
    service for which they are assigned cost responsibility under the Final 
    Rule tariff.
        AEP asserts that the Commission has provided no reason for 
    requiring holding companies to use the pro forma tariff for intra-pool 
    transactions. AEP asks the Commission to clarify whether the Rule 
    applies to AEP. It asserts that the Preamble states that all members of 
    holding company systems must use the pro forma tariff for intra-system 
    transactions, but the regulatory text requires only a member of a 
    public utility holding company ``arrangement or agreement that contains 
    transmission rates, terms or conditions * * *.'' AEP explains that the 
    AEP System Interconnection Agreement and Transmission Agreement do not 
    contain transmission rates, terms or conditions and the members do not 
    offer transmission service to one another.
        However, AEP argues that, if the Rule applies to AEP, Order No. 888 
    contains no explanation of why or how a different intra-pool allocation 
    of transmission costs than would result from the pro forma tariff 
    prejudices transmission users. It asserts that (1) AEP's allocation has 
    been subject to extensive review over the last few years, (2) AEP 
    treats itself as a single system, not as a collection of individual 
    members, (3) each member carries its fair share of transmission costs, 
    and (4) compliance with the Commission's requirement would be onerous. 
    If the Commission does not remove this requirement, AEP requests waiver 
    of the requirement.
        Similarly, Allegheny Power asserts that its Power Supply Agreement 
    (PSA) does not provide for ``wholesale trades.'' It argues that the PSA 
    is immaterial to all transmission services, including intra-company 
    exchanges. Because the PSA is an existing contract that the Final Rule 
    does not propose to abrogate, Allegheny Power asserts that the PSA need 
    not be reformed under the Final Rule. Allegheny states that it will 
    provide new wholesale service to itself and others under its open 
    access tariff which was accepted for filing on December 6, 1995 in 
    Docket No. ER96-58.
        Union Electric assumes that the ``rule is intended solely to mean 
    that a holding company system would use the network integration part of 
    the tariff, for its intra-system `wholesale trades.' Indeed, if Union 
    Electric and CIPS were required to take point-to-point service for 
    their wholesale trades, they would be placed in an inferior and non-
    comparable position vis-a-vis customers on the Ameren tariff who will 
    be entitled to single-system transmission service for a single or 
    postage-stamp charge.'' (Union Electric notes that Union Electric and 
    CIPS are currently seeking approval to merge, with the combined 
    facilities being operated as the Ameren System.)
        NU believes that Order No. 888 could be construed to require NU 
    System Companies to charge each other as separate entities for 
    transmission service in connection with intra-system cost allocations 
    as if off-system wholesale sales had occurred. NU argues, however, that 
    this is inconsistent with Commission precedent in treating the NU 
    System Companies as a single integrated system and would give retail 
    native load customers service inferior to that of wholesale native load 
    (i.e., network) customers. NU further argues that it will result in 
    duplicative transmission charges for energy flows between the NU System 
    Companies. Moreover, NU asserts that viewing NU as a single system for 
    establishing transmission rates, but as separate companies with respect 
    to energy flows that result from economic dispatch of their generation 
    to native load is inconsistent with the treatment of multistate non-
    holding company utilities and is thus discriminatory.
        Blue Ridge seeks clarification that, to avoid double payment for 
    transmission, ``CSW must file its compliance filing resolving 
    comparability issues and the appropriate CSW ERCOT transmission rate 
    prior to September 1, 1996.'' Blue Ridge asserts that CSW must resolve 
    a potential conflict between its rate structure and the new PUCT 
    wheeling rule by September 1, 1996 (contemplated effective date for 
    interim PUCT transmission rates).
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        In requiring holding companies to file a pool-wide tariff, the 
    Commission does not intend that transmission service provided by the 
    operating subsidiaries to one another on behalf of their respective 
    native loads be subjected to additional transmission charges. The 
    Commission recognizes that the operating subsidiaries of a holding 
    company bear cost responsibility for transmission facilities by virtue 
    of ownership of such facilities. In many, if not all cases, 
    transmission costs are equalized among operating subsidiaries through 
    transmission equalization agreements (e.g., AEP's Transmission 
    Agreement).
        However, the Commission does intend, pursuant to Order No. 888, 
    that holding company operating subsidiaries take transmission service 
    under the same tariff rates, terms, and conditions as third-party 
    customers that seek transmission service over the holding company 
    system. This applies to all holding company systems that rely upon the 
    transmission facilities of the individual operating subsidiaries to 
    support central economic dispatch--including AEP and Allegheny. 
    However, as suggested by Southern and Union Electric, the Commission 
    anticipates that transmission service for an operating subsidiary's 
    native load would be treated as network service under the pro forma 
    tariff. Accordingly, the CP demands of each operating subsidiary's 
    native load would establish each operating subsidiary's transmission 
    cost responsibility related to network service over the integrated 
    transmission facilities of the holding company system.
        Thus, in response to the AL and FL Commissions, Southern, and NU, 
    intra-holding company transactions in support of economic dispatch 
    would not be subjected to ``additional'' transmission charges.204 
    The load ratio pricing mechanism of the network portion of the tariff 
    should ensure that each operating company bears its proportionate share 
    of transmission costs without jeopardizing or otherwise penalizing 
    these types of intra-system transactions. Moreover, any off-system 
    sales would have to be taken under the point-to-point provisions of the 
    tariff. As we noted in Order No. 888, ``it may be necessary for 
    registered holding companies to reform their holding
    
    [[Page 12315]]
    
    company equalization agreement to recognize the non-discriminatory 
    terms and conditions of transmission service required under the Final 
    Rule pro forma tariff.'' 205 However, nothing in Order No. 888 
    mandates any change to the method chosen for apportioning transmission 
    revenues among the operating companies, which may be based, for 
    example, upon equalizing transmission investment responsibility.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \204\ The Commission notes that Order No. 888 requires that all 
    third party tariff customers taking network or point-to-point 
    service pay a transmission rate which reflects an appropriate share 
    of transmission costs, including those related to transmission 
    construction.
        \205\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,729; mimeo at 277.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The concerns raised here by Blue Ridge are resolved on an interim 
    basis because the PUCT has accepted the filing of CSW's Federal tariff 
    as adequate in the Texas proceeding until differences between the Order 
    No. 888 rate structure and the PUCT rate structure are resolved. If, 
    CSW implements a new ERCOT transmission tariff in response to actions 
    of the PUCT, then affected parties may bring any remaining concerns to 
    the Commission's attention at that time through a section 206 
    complaint.
        We note that the issue raised here by Blue Ridge is very similar to 
    the one raised by Tex-La and East Texas Electric Cooperative, and 
    addressed by the Commission's recent order, in Houston Lighting & Power 
    Co., 77 FERC para. 61,113 at 61,439 (1996). There, the Commission found 
    that it would be premature to address this issue at that time, and 
    noted that parties would have an opportunity to raise their concerns 
    after the PUCT finalizes its ERCOT tariff.
    4. Bilateral Coordination Arrangements
        In the Final Rule, the Commission required that any bilateral 
    wholesale coordination agreements executed after the effective date of 
    the Final Rule would be subject to the functional unbundling and open 
    access requirements set forth in the Rule.206 In addition, the 
    Commission required that all bilateral economy energy coordination 
    contracts executed before the effective date of the Rule be modified to 
    require unbundling of any economy energy transaction occurring after 
    December 31, 1996. Moreover, the Commission permitted all non-economy 
    energy bilateral coordination contracts executed before the effective 
    date of the Rule to continue in effect, but subject to section 206 
    complaints.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \206\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,729-30; mimeo at 277-78.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        To compute the unbundled coordination compliance rate, the 
    Commission indicated that the utility must subtract the corresponding 
    transmission unit charge in its open access tariff from the existing 
    coordination rate ceiling. However, the Commission noted, if a 
    utility's transmission operator offers a discounted transmission rate 
    to the utility's wholesale marketing department or an affiliate for the 
    purposes of coordination transactions, the same discounted rate must be 
    offered to others for trades with any party to the coordination 
    agreement. In addition, the Commission explained that discounts offered 
    to non-affiliates must be on a basis that is not unduly discriminatory.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        SoCal Edison seeks clarification as to how Order No. 888 affects 
    package agreements (i.e., bilateral contracts that provide some or all 
    of requirements service, coordination service, or transmission 
    service). In particular, SoCal Edison asks (1) what specific functions 
    of each must be modified to comply with Order No. 888; (2) whether a 
    sale of non-firm energy made pursuant to a package agreement must 
    comply with the unbundling requirements for coordination contracts; (3) 
    whether the requirement to remove preferential transmission access or 
    pricing provisions applies to existing or future transmission services 
    provided pursuant to package agreements; if so, what is the deadline; 
    and (4) whether the rulings with respect to Mobile-Sierra apply to 
    package agreements.207
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \207\ Anaheim, in an answer opposing SoCal Edison's request for 
    clarification regarding its package agreements, requests that these 
    agreements be dealt with on a case-by-case basis ``in context.'' 
    (Anaheim Answer). While answers to requests for rehearing generally 
    are not permitted, we will depart from our general rule because of 
    the significant nature of this proceeding and accept the Anaheim 
    Answer.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        APPA argues that the Commission should require all coordination 
    arrangements to be subject to Order No. 888. CCEM asserts that to the 
    extent non-economy energy coordination agreements are allowed to remain 
    bundled, they should be identified in connection with determinations of 
    available transfer capacity and, because they should only be a 
    transitional matter, should be subject to a sunset date of December 31, 
    1996.
        According to Utilities For Improved Transition, requiring the 
    subtraction of the current tariff transmission rate from the current 
    rate ceiling, without increasing the residual sales price, will force 
    transmission providers to fail to recover their full costs of providing 
    service because the Commission has previously prohibited these rates 
    from including a transmission component (citing Green Mountain, 63 FERC 
    para. 61,071 at 61,307-08 (1993) and Cleveland Electric, 63 FERC para. 
    61,244 at 62,277-78 (1993)).208
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \208\ See also VEPCO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Union Electric also argues that the Commission should delete the 
    requirement that the utility subtract the corresponding transmission 
    unit charge in its open access tariff from the existing coordination 
    rate ceiling. According to Union Electric, actual bilateral economy 
    sales do not include adders for recovery of transmission costs, but are 
    typically limited to production or generation costs. Union Electric 
    further asserts that the definition of economy energy coordination 
    agreement is so open-ended, it may apply to many types of coordination 
    transactions that are not mere energy economy sales. Union Electric 
    argues that a split-the-savings charge cannot be unbundled in the 
    manner described by the Commission because it is an incorrect 
    assumption that the rate ceiling for every economy energy coordination 
    sales agreement includes a transmission cost component. If Union 
    Electric is required to arbitrarily subtract a transmission charge for 
    its economy sales, it argues that it will be penalized. At a minimum, 
    it argues, a utility should be permitted to submit a list of economy 
    coordination rate schedules that it believes to be already unbundled 
    and should not have to subtract a transmission charge. Alternatively, 
    it argues that the Commission should not require unbundling unless the 
    Commission determines that the existing rate ceiling has been cost 
    justified on a basis that includes an allowance for the full recovery 
    of transmission function cost.209
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \209\ See also Florida Power Corp (if the Commission requires an 
    unbundled transmission rate, it must allow transmission providers to 
    reformulate their unbundled economy energy agreements to recover 
    both their capacity and energy costs and the costs of transmission).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        SoCal Edison represents that its package agreements include 
    requirements services as well as coordination services. For existing 
    bilateral economy energy coordination agreements, Order No. 888, as 
    clarified by the Commission's May 17 Order, requires the unbundling of 
    transmission from generation for all such contracts on or before 
    December 31, 1996.210 Thus, any economy energy service included in 
    existing package agreements must be unbundled.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \210\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,730; mimeo at 277.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Regarding non-firm energy sales made under a package agreement, 
    SoCal Edison provides no information distinguishing that service from 
    other
    
    [[Page 12316]]
    
    economy energy coordination transactions, which include all ``if, as 
    and when available'' services (see section 35.28(b)(2)). Absent more 
    information, non-firm energy sales should be unbundled.
        We further note that our requirements concerning unbundling of 
    bilateral coordination arrangements apply regardless of whether such 
    arrangements are governed by the public interest or just and reasonable 
    standard of review.
        With respect to APPA's concerns, the Final Rule provides that all 
    bilateral economy energy coordination contracts executed before the 
    effective date of the Final Rule must be modified to require unbundling 
    of any economy energy transaction occurring after December 31, 1996. 
    Non-economy energy bilateral coordination contracts executed before the 
    effective date of the Final Rule, however, were allowed to continue in 
    effect, but subject to complaints filed under section 206 of the 
    FPA.211 We drew this distinction for both policy and practical 
    reasons. The ability to use discounts on transmission in order to favor 
    short-term economy energy sales made out of the transmission provider's 
    own generation was of particular concern to the Commission. Thus, in 
    order to eliminate the ability of transmission providers to exercise 
    undue discrimination for short-term coordination transactions under 
    existing umbrella-type agreements, we required unbundling by December 
    31, 1996.212 However, non-economy energy coordination agreements 
    presented a different situation.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \211\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,730; mimeo at 277.
        \212\ Approximately 300 filings to unbundle this category were 
    filed by December 31, 1996.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In the Final Rule, we expressed a particular concern with not 
    abrogating non-economy energy coordination agreements, which we 
    indicated may reflect complementary long-term obligations among the 
    parties.213 Non-economy energy coordination agreements consist for 
    the most part of long-term reliability arrangements. Providing for the 
    abrogation of these arrangements could cause special problems for the 
    reliable operation of the grid. Examples include agreements governing 
    sales during emergency or maintenance periods. These agreements, unlike 
    economy energy agreements where trade is on an ``as, if and when 
    available'' basis, often have specified terms governing the parties' 
    responsibilities. As a result, many non-economy energy coordination 
    agreements are more akin to requirements contracts than to economy 
    energy coordination agreements. Therefore, we determined to permit this 
    category of contracts to run their course, absent a case specific 
    complaint. The burden would be on the complainant to demonstrate that 
    the transmission component of a non-economy energy coordination 
    agreement is unduly discriminatory or otherwise unlawful. The 
    Commission would decide based on the facts of the case whether 
    unbundling is the appropriate remedy. Neither CCEM nor APPA have 
    presented evidence or convincing arguments as to why these types of 
    agreements should be unbundled generically.214
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \213\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,666; mimeo at 90.
        \214\ Regarding CCEM's request that non-economy energy 
    coordination agreements be identified in determining available 
    transfer capacity (ATC), we note that all data used to calculate ATC 
    and total transfer capacity (TTC) must be made publicly available 
    upon request pursuant to section 37.6(b)(2)(ii) of the OASIS 
    regulations.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission affirms the requirement in Order No. 888 that the 
    transmission rate for any economy energy coordination service be 
    unbundled. The Commission states in Order No. 888 that to adequately 
    remedy undue discrimination, public utilities must remove preferential 
    transmission access and pricing provisions from agreements governing 
    their transactions.215 In the cases cited by Utilities For 
    Improved Transition, the Commission prohibited the utility from 
    charging a split-savings rate plus a contribution to fixed costs. The 
    Commission has long allowed utilities to set their coordination rates 
    by reference to their own costs (cost-based ceilings) or by dividing 
    the pool of benefits (fuel cost differentials) brought about by the 
    transaction.216 Utilities have been free to design a rate using 
    either method but not both. Regardless of the method adopted to set a 
    bundled rate on file (a seller's own costs or a sharing of transaction 
    benefits), a bundled rate constitutes the total charge for all 
    components and must now be unbundled.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \215\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,726; mimeo at 268-69.
        \216\ See e.g., Illinois Power Company, 62 FERC para. 61,147 at 
    62,062 (1993).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A split-savings rate is set without reference to the seller's fixed 
    costs and, therefore, Union Electric's argument is not germane. We are 
    not requiring that the present rate be adjusted upward or downward. 
    Rather, we are requiring disassembly of the existing rate into 
    component parts one of which represents the rate being charged for 
    transmission service. If a utility is no longer satisfied that an 
    existing rate is compensatory, with regard to either the generation 
    component or the transmission component, it may file an appropriate 
    revision under section 205.
    
    ISO Principles
    
        In the Final Rule, the Commission set out certain principles that 
    will be used in assessing ISO proposals that may be submitted to the 
    Commission in the future.217 The Commission emphasized that these 
    principles are applicable only to ISOs that would be control area 
    operators, including any ISO established in the restructuring of power 
    pools.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \217\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,730-32; mimeo at 279-86.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission set forth the following principles for ISOs:
        1. The ISO's governance should be structured in a fair and non-
    discriminatory manner.
        2. An ISO and its employees should have no financial interest in 
    the economic performance of any power market participant. An ISO should 
    adopt and enforce strict conflict of interest standards.
        3. An ISO should provide open access to the transmission system and 
    all services under its control at non-pancaked rates pursuant to a 
    single, unbundled, grid-wide tariff that applies to all eligible users 
    in a non-discriminatory manner.
        4. An ISO should have the primary responsibility in ensuring short-
    term reliability of grid operations. Its role in this responsibility 
    should be well-defined and comply with applicable standards set by NERC 
    and the regional reliability council.
        5. An ISO should have control over the operation of interconnected 
    transmission facilities within its region.
        6. An ISO should identify constraints on the system and be able to 
    take operational actions to relieve those constraints within the 
    trading rules established by the governing body. These rules should 
    promote efficient trading.
        7. The ISO should have appropriate incentives for efficient 
    management and administration and should procure the services needed 
    for such management and administration in an open competitive market.
        8. An ISO's transmission and ancillary services pricing policies 
    should promote the efficient use of and investment in generation, 
    transmission, and consumption. An ISO or an RTG of which the ISO is a 
    member should conduct such studies as may be necessary to identify 
    operational problems or appropriate expansions.
        9. An ISO should make transmission system information publicly 
    available on a timely basis via an electronic
    
    [[Page 12317]]
    
    information network consistent with the Commission's requirements.
        10. An ISO should develop mechanisms to coordinate with neighboring 
    control areas.
        11. An ISO should establish an alternative dispute resolution (ADR) 
    process to resolve disputes in the first instance.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
    General Comments
    
        NY Municipal Utilities argue that if the NYPP participants (or 
    other tight pools) elect to establish an ISO, the ISO Principles should 
    be made mandatory for the protection of transmission dependent 
    utilities.
        NY Com asks the Commission to clarify that it will allow 
    flexibility to states and utilities in structuring proposals that meet 
    the goals underlying the ISO principles. It explains that the parties 
    to New York's electric competition proceeding are discussing the 
    formation of an ISO in which transmission owners control the system 
    operator, but would have to divest their competitive generation. NY Com 
    further notes that it has not decided that matter yet, but it does not 
    want to see such options foreclosed.
        Minnesota P&L argues that certain functions, particularly those 
    involving local area circumstances and safety, are better handled at 
    the local level. It further argues that control area responsibilities 
    of an ISO should focus on regional issues and operations, and on 
    establishing and enforcing uniform criteria and guidelines for local 
    control area operations in order to assure non-discriminatory treatment 
    of all transmission customers.
        AMP-Ohio asserts that the Commission should require the separation 
    of transmission, generation and distribution through an ISO and, at a 
    minimum, the Commission should include a Stage 3 of implementation to 
    bring ISOs to reality.
    
    ISO Principle 1
    
        NYPP argues that the Commission should not include a rigid ban on 
    transmission owner leadership in ISO governance because it is the 
    transmission owner that is ultimately responsible for the reliability 
    of the bulk power system.218
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \218\ Sithe, in a response to the NYPP's request for 
    clarification, opposes the ``transmission owners only'' ISO sought 
    by NYPP. (Sithe Response). Subsequently, NYPP filed an objection to 
    Sithe's pleading and request that it be rejected. (NYPP Objection). 
    NYPP explains that its rehearing was a request that the Commission 
    refrain from setting fixed rules for ISO governance in advance, not 
    an argument that the Commission should adopt one particular 
    mechanism or another for all ISOs. While answers to requests for 
    rehearing generally are not permitted, we will depart from our 
    general rule because of the significant nature of this proceeding 
    and accept the Sithe Response and NYPP Objection.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    ISO Principle 2
    
        NYPP asks that the Commission revise this principle to take a more 
    flexible approach to significant employee issues. NYPP explains that it 
    has 81 management employees on the payroll of individual member systems 
    and that pension rights (accrual rights based on an average salary) and 
    medical insurance (preexisting conditions) are through the individual 
    member systems.
    
    ISO Principle 3
    
        SoCal Edison asks that this principle be revised to permit a 
    separate access charge for each utility in order to avoid cost 
    shifting. Anaheim seeks revision of this principle to require that an 
    ISO provide comparable compensation to all transmission owners that 
    make transmission facilities available for use by the ISO.
    
    ISO Principle 5
    
        Anaheim asks that this principle be revised to make clear that ISO 
    arrangements should seek to encourage participation by all transmission 
    owners within the region.
    
    ISO Principle 6
    
        NYPP seeks clarification that an ISO needs control over more than 
    some generation facilities because the more generating facilities 
    operating under an ISO the more reliability there is. Thus, it asserts 
    that the Commission should clarify that its description of ISO control 
    of generation does not require only a minimalist approach to ISO 
    generation control.
    
    ISO Principle 8
    
        SoCal Edison seeks revision of this principle to remove the 
    language linking the ISO to performing studies necessary to identify 
    appropriate grid expansions. According to SoCal Edison, an ISO should 
    not be a project sponsor or should not conduct planning studies to 
    determine what facilities should be constructed because those actions 
    would compromise its independence. In addition, SoCal Edison seeks 
    revision of this principle to permit a transmission usage charge that 
    incorporates locational marginal cost pricing for managing transmission 
    congestion.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We reaffirm our strong commitment to the concept of ISOs, and to 
    the ISO principles described in Order No. 888. We continue to believe 
    that properly structured ISOs can be an effective way to comply with 
    the comparability requirements of open access transmission service. 
    Nevertheless, we do not believe at this time that it is appropriate to 
    require public utilities or power pools to establish ISOs, as suggested 
    by AMP-Ohio. We think it is appropriate to permit some time to confirm 
    whether functional unbundling will remedy undue discrimination before 
    reconsidering our decision that ISO formation should be voluntary.
        A number of the above rehearing requests on ISOs are from New York 
    parties and deal with ongoing efforts in New York that would reform the 
    New York Power Pool pooling agreements, restructure power markets, and 
    possibly form an ISO. Some of these arguments are in apparent conflict; 
    for example, the NY Municipal Utilities argue that the 11 ISO 
    principles should be made mandatory if the New York Power Pool 
    participants elect to establish an ISO, while the NY Com argues that 
    the Commission should clarify Order No. 888 to state that it will allow 
    flexibility to states and utilities in structuring proposals that meet 
    the goals underlying the ISO principles. We note that since the time 
    the rehearing requests were filed, the NY Power Pool has filed 
    amendments to its pooling agreements on December 30, 1996 and also has 
    filed, on January 31, 1997, various agreements and tariffs designed to 
    implement an ISO and market exchange. To the extent the rehearing 
    requests from New York parties deal with matters that have been filed 
    with the Commission subsequent to the rehearing requests, the 
    Commission will address the issues raised in the context of those 
    filings.
        In response to NY Com's request for clarification that we provide 
    flexibility to states and their utilities in structuring ISO proposals, 
    the Commission at this time clearly cannot, and does not intend to, 
    prescribe a ``cookie cutter'' approach to ISOs. However, the Commission 
    does believe that certain basic principles must be met to ensure non-
    discriminatory transmission services. We reaffirm our view that ISO 
    Principles 1 (independence with respect to governance) and 2 
    (independence with respect to financial interests) are fundamental to 
    ensuring that an ISO is truly independent and would not favor any class 
    of transmission users. As the Commission stated in its recent order on 
    the proposed PJM ISO:
    
        The principle of independence is the bedrock upon which the ISO 
    must be built if stakeholders are to have confidence that it
    
    [[Page 12318]]
    
    will function in a manner consistent with this Commission's pro-
    competitive goals.[219]
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \219\ Atlantic City Electric Company, et al., 77 FERC para. 
    61,148 (1996) (mimeo at 36-41); see also Pacific Gas & Electric 
    Company, 77 FERC para. 61,204 (1996).
    
    ISO governance that is disproportionately influenced by transmission 
    owners, unless they have fully divested their interests in generation, 
    is not consistent with ISO Principle 1. We remain concerned that ISO 
    proposals that do not include governance by a fair representation of 
    all system users may not be independent, although we reserve final 
    judgment on any specific governance structure until we have an 
    opportunity to review a specific proposal.220
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \220\ In making this finding, we are not suggesting that an 
    independent transmission company, which owns only transmission, is 
    undesirable. However, an ISO, which separates ownership and 
    operation, is designed in large part to recognize that transmission 
    owners today have significant generation or load interests that may 
    bias their operational decisions.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In response to the argument made by NYPP that transmission owner 
    leadership in ISO governance may be needed because transmission owners 
    are ultimately responsible for the reliability of the bulk power 
    system, we emphasize that reliability is of primary importance to this 
    Commission and that the formation and operation of an ISO should not in 
    any way impair reliability. We believe that one of the main purposes of 
    an ISO is to make an independent party, the ISO, responsible for at 
    least short-term reliability. Even if both the transmission owners and 
    the ISO will be responsible for some aspects of reliability, this does 
    not affect our finding that the governance of the ISO must be 
    independent of the transmission owners so that the ISO can carry out 
    its own responsibilities in a not-unduly discriminatory manner.
        In response to arguments of the NYPP that the Commission should 
    revise Principle 2 to take a more flexible approach to employee issues, 
    we reaffirm the necessity of requiring the employees of an ISO to be 
    financially independent of market participants and note that Principle 
    2 suggests that a short transition period should be adequate for ISO 
    employees to sever all financial ties with former transmission owners. 
    We recognize that some flexibility may be necessary regarding the 
    length of a transition period, but believe that ISO employees must in 
    fairly short order be independent of all financial ties to any market 
    participants, if we are to achieve not unduly discriminatory practices 
    in generation and transmission markets.
        A number of additional parties seek other revisions to or 
    clarifications of the ISO Principles. For example, Minnesota P&L 
    requests clarification or rehearing to ensure that the Commission 
    provides sufficient flexibility to permit local operators, under the 
    general supervision and control of the ISO, to perform local 
    operational functions, such as performing switching operations. In 
    response to this concern, we note that Principle 3 (open access under a 
    single tariff) says that the portion of the transmission grid operated 
    by a single ISO should be as large as possible. Our view, as described 
    above, is that an ISO, which includes all affected users, should be 
    responsible for operation of the system and ensuring reliability. The 
    ISO may use some combination of actual physical control over facilities 
    and virtual control of facilities by others (i.e., the ISO exercises 
    control over facilities by instructing the transmission owners' or 
    generation owners' staffs as to the actions to be taken). The broad 
    range of interested parties that establish the ISO must determine what 
    services the ISO will perform and what services transmission owners or 
    others will perform under ISO supervision.
        We deny the requests by Socal Edison and Anaheim to revise ISO 
    Principle 3 to permit separate access charges for each utility to avoid 
    cost shifting. We think ISO Principle 3 already provides sufficient 
    flexibility to accommodate the concerns of these parties with respect 
    to design of access charges and compensation to owners for transmission 
    facilities under operational control of the ISO.
        Similarly, we see no reason to revise Principle 5 (control of 
    interconnected operations) as requested by Anaheim. We agree with 
    Anaheim that wide participation of transmission owners in a region will 
    help ensure open access and increase efficient transmission 
    coordination. ISO Principle 3 says that the portion of the transmission 
    grid operated by a single ISO should be as large as possible. ISO 
    Principle 5 says that an ISO should have control over the operation of 
    interconnected transmission facilities within its region. These 
    principles, as written, address Anaheim's concern.
        With respect to NYPP's request for clarification of ISO Principle 6 
    (dealing with constraints), we note that the description of ISO 
    Principle 6 in the Final Rule says that the ISO may need to exercise 
    some level of operational control over generation facilities in order 
    to regulate and balance the power system.221 We do not think it is 
    appropriate for the Commission to give further generic guidance now on 
    what constitutes the proper level of operational control over 
    generation. The ISO, including all stakeholders, needs to address this 
    issue, based on the structure of power markets and perhaps other local 
    considerations, in preparing a specific proposal for our approval.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \221\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,731; mimeo at 283.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Finally, we deny SoCal Edison's request for revision of ISO 
    Principle 8 (pricing). In response to SoCal Edison's concern, ISO 
    Principle 8 allows the use of appropriate locational marginal cost 
    pricing. The principle allows flexibility regarding which regional 
    organization of market participants (ISO or RTG) conducts the necessary 
    studies to identify the need for expansion. We are unpersuaded by SoCal 
    Edison's arguments that the fact that an ISO is involved in planning 
    for transmission facility expansion would in any way compromise the 
    independence of the ISO.
    
    G. Pro Forma Tariff
    
        In the Final Rule, the Commission combined the requirements for 
    point-to-point transmission service and network transmission service 
    into a single pro forma tariff.222 The Commission explained that 
    this eliminates many of the differences between the two NOPR pro forma 
    tariffs, provides a unified set of definitions, and consolidates 
    certain common requirements such as the obligation to provide ancillary 
    services. The Commission also noted that it was issuing an accompanying 
    Notice of Proposed Rulemaking in Docket No. RM96-11-000 in which it was 
    seeking comments on whether a different form of open access tariff--one 
    based solely on a capacity reservation system--might better accommodate 
    competitive changes occurring in the industry while ensuring that all 
    wholesale transmission service is provided in a fair and non-
    discriminatory manner. 223
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \222\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,733; mimeo at 288-89.
        \223\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,733; mimeo at 289.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    1. Tariff Provisions That Affect The Pricing Mechanism
    a. Non-Price Terms and Conditions
        In the Final Rule, the Commission explained that the Final Rule pro 
    forma tariff is intended to initiate open access, with non-price terms 
    and conditions based on the contract path model of power flows and 
    embedded cost ratemaking.224 It emphasized that the Final Rule pro 
    forma tariff is not intended to signal a preference for contract path/
    embedded cost pricing for the future. The Commission indicated
    
    [[Page 12319]]
    
    that it will in the future entertain non-discriminatory tariff 
    innovations to accommodate new pricing proposals.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \224\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,734-35; mimeo at 291-93.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission further indicated that, by initially requiring a 
    standardized tariff, it intends to foster broad access across multiple 
    systems under standardized terms and conditions. However, the 
    Commission emphasized that the tariff provides for certain deviations 
    where it can be demonstrated that unique practices in a geographic 
    region require modifications to the Final Rule pro forma tariff 
    provisions.
        Finally, the Commission stated that it will allow utilities to 
    propose a single cost allocation method for network and point-to-point 
    transmission services.
    b. Network and Point-to-Point Customers' Uses of the System (so called 
    ``Headroom'')
        In the Final Rule, the Commission explained that it will not allow 
    network customers to make off-system sales within the load-ratio 
    transmission entitlement at no additional charge.225 The 
    Commission further explained that use of transmission by network 
    customers for non-firm economy purchases, which are used to displace 
    designated network resources, must be accorded a higher priority than 
    non-firm point-to-point service and secondary point-to-point service 
    under the tariff. In addition, the Commission found that off-system 
    sales transactions, which are sales other than those to serve the 
    transmission provider's native load or a network customer's load, must 
    be made using point-to-point service on either a firm or non-firm 
    basis. In rejecting the ``headroom'' concept (where a network customer 
    can make off-system sales as long as its total use of the system does 
    not exceed its coincident peak demand), the Commission explained that 
    it was not requiring any utility to take network service to integrate 
    resources and loads and if any transmission user (including the public 
    utility) prefers to take flexible point-to-point service,226 they 
    are free to do so. Further, the Commission explained that any point-to-
    point customer may take advantage of the secondary, non-firm 
    flexibility provided under point-to-point service equally, on an as-
    available basis.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \225\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,751; mimeo at 342-43.
        \226\ See Florida Municipal Power Agency v. Florida Power & 
    Light Company, 74 FERC para. 61,006 at 61,013 and n.70 (1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        A number of entities argue that it is unreasonable to permit firm 
    point-to-point customers to receive non-firm service, up to their 
    contract demand, at no additional charge, at secondary receipt and 
    delivery points, but to require transmission providers and network 
    customers to purchase transmission for all off-system sales, including 
    non-firm sales made in competition with sales made by the point-to-
    point customer.227 FPL asserts that having built and paid for the 
    entire transmission network, the owner and the network customer should 
    have the flexibility to use the network as they need. Utilities For 
    Improved Transition declare that just as the firm point-to-point 
    customer is permitted to maximize the use of its contract demand, the 
    transmission provider and network customer should be entitled to 
    maximize their long-term fixed cost obligation (citing AES Power, Inc., 
    69 FERC para. 61,345 at 62,300 (1994) (AES) for the proposition that 
    the utility and its native load customers are obligated to pay all the 
    costs of the transmission system without regard to the amount of energy 
    actually scheduled).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \227\ E.g., FPL, Utilities For Improved Transition, TDU Systems, 
    Carolina P&L, AEC & SMEPA, VT DPS, EEI.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        FPL and Carolina P&L suggest two possible solutions: (1) allow the 
    transmission provider and network customer to have rights to the 
    headroom beneath their fixed cost obligations at no additional charge, 
    or (2) restrict the no-charge use of firm point-to-point headroom to 
    transmission service associated with non-firm purchases to serve load. 
    Under either of these options, they assert, the firm point-to-point 
    customer's rights to make non-firm off-system sales would be on an even 
    competitive footing with the transmission provider or network customer.
        PA Coops maintain that network customers should have the right to 
    reassign/sell unused capacity below their 12-month rolling average peak 
    demand at no additional charge. Cajun argues that network customers 
    should be allowed to use the transmission system for non-firm (and 
    perhaps firm) coordination transactions at no additional cost, provided 
    the network customer's total use of the transmission system does not 
    exceed its load ratio share. Cajun notes that the Commission seems to 
    have determined elsewhere in the Rule that a network customer has 
    already paid for the full use of its load ratio share (citing mimeo at 
    332 and 338). In addition, Cajun states that requiring the network 
    customer to use point-to-point service results in the network customer 
    paying twice for the same capacity.
        VT DPS argues that the Commission should permit network users to 
    make limited use of their network capacity to make off-peak off-system 
    sales. It asserts that UtiliCorp's network tariff, filed in Docket No. 
    ER95-203, provides a useful model: ``the level of capacity utilized by 
    the company or the customer for its combined network load and off-
    system sales load would be fixed by the tariff as the highest 
    coincident peak load experienced by the transmitting utility in the 
    three years preceding the off-system sale.'' According to VT DPS, this 
    places all firm users on a par. In contrast, VT DPS argues that the 
    Commission's solution is arbitrary and patently inadequate. VT DPS 
    claims that concerned parties are not just transmission providers, but 
    include state agencies and entities that need to take network service. 
    VT DPS further argues that the lower priority for secondary service 
    under the point-to-point tariff may pose an unacceptable risk to public 
    utilities with firm obligations to serve their load, and having to 
    agree to a fixed demand quantity may be unsatisfactory for public 
    utilities with growing customer loads and a statutory obligation to 
    serve those loads.
        LEPA argues that:
    
    [t]he Commission erred in not finding that in order to compete, one 
    must be able to utilize base load units of 500MW size because entry 
    without the ability to employ such base load units would make the 
    putative entrant unable to compete; that in order to employ such 
    units, or portions of them, the entrant had to engage in the 
    coordinated development of base load units; that such coordinated 
    development requires use of transmission for that purpose so as to 
    be able to sell portions of the output of a baseload unit off-
    system, and that without 'headroom,' the cost of transmission for 
    that purpose would not be comparable with the cost of transmission 
    for the same purpose of the owner of the transmission. (LEPA at 5).
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The requests for rehearing on this issue present no arguments that 
    were not fully considered in Order No. 888. Petitioners continue to 
    claim that transmission providers and network customers are 
    competitively disadvantaged vis-a-vis point-to-point transmission 
    customers due to the point-to-point customers' ability to use as 
    available, non-firm service over secondary points of receipt and 
    delivery at no additional cost. The Commission attempted to strike a 
    balance on this issue in Order No. 888 by allowing both network and 
    point-to-point services to be priced on the same basis (i.e., no longer 
    summarily rejecting the use of the average of the 12 monthly system
    
    [[Page 12320]]
    
    peaks as the denominator for the rate for point-to-point service). 
    Additionally, the Commission established a lower priority for the non-
    firm secondary point-to-point service than for either economy purchases 
    by network customers or for stand-alone non-firm point-to-point 
    service, as discussed in Section IV.G.3.b. Accordingly, we believe that 
    these concerns have been sufficiently addressed.
        Furthermore, these entities want to be allowed to make off-system 
    sales under their network service at no additional charge as long as 
    their total use of the system does not exceed their load ratio share. 
    They claim that it is inequitable not to allow such ``headroom'' sales 
    under the network service while allowing firm point-to-point customers 
    to use non-firm transmission service up to their contract demands using 
    secondary receipt and delivery points at no additional charge. As the 
    Commission stated in Order No. 888, customers are not obligated to take 
    network transmission service.228 If customers want to take 
    advantage of the as-available, non-firm service over secondary points 
    of receipt and delivery through the point-to-point service, they may 
    elect to take firm point-to-point transmission service in lieu of the 
    network service. We further note that transmission providers must take 
    point-to-point transmission service for their own off-system sales, 
    which results in comparable treatment for both the transmission 
    provider and network customers. Transmission providers and other 
    customers taking point-to-point transmission service do not need to be 
    allowed to make ``headroom'' sales because they have access to as-
    available, non-firm service over secondary points of receipt and 
    delivery at no additional charge through their point-to-point service.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \228\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,751; mimeo at 342-43.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Cajun's argument that a network customer has already paid for the 
    full use of its load-ratio share of the system ignores the fact that 
    network service is based on integrating a network customer's resources 
    with its load, not on making off-system sales. This is why network 
    customers pay for service on a load-ratio basis. If Cajun is concerned 
    that it may need to pay for both network service and point-to-point 
    service, Cajun can simply elect to take point-to-point service for all 
    of its transmission needs.
        VT DPS' claim that the lower priority accorded to transmission 
    service to secondary points of receipt and delivery under flexible 
    point-to-point service would present an ``unacceptable risk'' to public 
    utilities is unsubstantiated. If the risk of having this secondary 
    service curtailed is too great, this customer has the option to: (1) 
    take stand-alone non-firm point-to-point service (which has a higher 
    priority), (2) take this service on a firm point-to-point basis, or (3) 
    take network service, which has a higher priority for economy purchases 
    than either stand-alone non-firm or secondary non-firm point-to-point 
    service.
        With respect to LEPA's argument, the Commission has the goal of 
    encouraging competition in the generation market, not discouraging 
    generation competition by erecting barriers to entry such as arbitrary 
    generator size. Furthermore, LEPA's argument that comparability is not 
    achieved without allowing headroom is incorrect because both network 
    customers as well as the transmission provider must obtain point-to-
    point transmission service to accommodate transmission for wholesale 
    sales.
    c. Load Ratio Sharing Allocation Mechanism for Network Service
        In the Final Rule, the Commission concluded that the load ratio 
    allocation method of pricing network service continues to be reasonable 
    for purposes of initiating open access transmission.229 The 
    Commission also reaffirmed the use of a twelve monthly coincident peak 
    (12 CP) allocation method because it believed the majority of utilities 
    plan their systems to meet their twelve monthly peaks. However, the 
    Commission stated that it would allow utilities to file another method 
    (e.g., annual system peak) if they demonstrate that it reflects their 
    transmission system planning.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \229\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,736; mimeo at 296-97.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        With respect to concerns raised about pancaked rates for network 
    service provided to load served by more than one network service 
    provider, the Commission indicated that if a customer wishes to exclude 
    a particular load at discrete points of delivery from its load ratio 
    share of the allocated cost of the transmission provider's integrated 
    system, it may do so. However, customers that elect to do so, the 
    Commission explained, must seek alternative transmission service for 
    any such load that has not been designated as network load for network 
    service. The Commission indicated that this option is also available to 
    customers with load served by ``behind the meter'' generation 230 
    that seek to eliminate the load from their network load ratio 
    calculation.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \230\ Behind-the-meter generation means generation located on 
    the customer's side of the point of delivery.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    (1) Multiple Control Area Network Customers
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        A number of entities argue that excluding load from the designation 
    of Network Load does not solve the pancaking problem and results in the 
    network customer paying even more transmission charges. They contend 
    that a network customer must still pay two network charges and point-
    to-point charges to be able to operate its resources across two control 
    areas. The Commission's approach, they argue, makes it impossible for a 
    network customer with loads and resources in multiple control areas to 
    integrate those loads and resources on an economic dispatch 
    basis.231 In essence, these entities state that a network customer 
    must frequently dispatch resources in one transmission provider's 
    control area (control area A) to serve that customer's load (in the 
    case of a G&T cooperative, the load of a member system or third-party 
    requirements customer) located in an adjacent control area of another 
    transmission provider (control area B). As a result, they believe, the 
    tariff essentially requires that network load in control area B, served 
    by resources in control area A, must be counted as load in control area 
    B. Alternatively, they believe that the tariff allows the transmission 
    of resources in control area A to load in control area B as point-to-
    point transmission that requires an additional charge. These entities 
    argue that either of these situations produces uneconomic results for 
    multiple control-area network customers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \231\ E.g., NRECA, TDU Systems, Blue Ridge.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        To avoid these problems, these entities propose that a network 
    customer be allowed to use its network service to transmit power and 
    energy from resources in control area A to serve load in control area B 
    without designating the control area B load as network load for billing 
    purposes. These entities suggest that no additional compensation should 
    be required if such transfers to load in adjacent control areas plus 
    other network transactions on behalf of the transmission customer in 
    control area A do not exceed the customer's coincident demand in 
    control area A. They also maintain that the ultimate solution is a 
    regional system operated by an ISO. At the very least, TDU Systems 
    contends, the Commission should require provision of service to network 
    customers with loads and resources
    
    [[Page 12321]]
    
    located on multiple systems under a rate that recovers the customer's 
    load ratio share--but no more--of the transmission owners' collective 
    transmission investment in the control areas that the customer 
    straddles.
        AMP-Ohio maintains that rational economic transmission pricing 
    policies demand elimination of the pancaking of rates caused by the 
    arbitrary ownership boundaries of individual utilities.
        TAPS asks that the Commission clarify that the Commission will look 
    closely at how to create and promote region-wide rates when evaluating 
    mergers and market-based rate proposals. It argues that the Commission 
    should be receptive to section 211 filings seeking non-pancaked rates 
    and should establish a Stage 3 for the purpose of addressing directly 
    the need for transmission access on a non-pancaked, regional basis.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        In the Final Rule, the Commission addressed concerns regarding 
    pancaked rates for network service for customers with load in multiple 
    control areas.232 Tariff section 31.3 allows a network customer 
    the option to exclude all load from its designated network load that is 
    outside the transmission provider's transmission system, and to serve 
    such load using point-to-point transmission service.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \232\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,736; mimeo at 297.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        NRECA and TDU Systems, however, argue that network customers 
    located in multiple control areas should not have to pay for any 
    additional point-to-point transmission service to make sales to non-
    designated load located in a separate control area. We disagree. 
    Because the additional transmission service to non-designated network 
    load outside of the transmission provider's control area is a service 
    for which the transmission provider must separately plan and operate 
    its system beyond what is required to provide service to the customer's 
    designated network load, it is appropriate to have an additional charge 
    associated with the additional service.
        AMP-Ohio's concerns regarding ``arbitrary ownership boundaries of 
    individual utilities,'' and TAP's proposal to require regional rates 
    are beyond the scope of Order No. 888.233 However, as the 
    Commission explained in the Final Rule, it encourages the voluntary 
    formation of regional transmission groups, as well as the establishment 
    of regional ISOs, and will address those matters on a case-by-case 
    basis.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \233\ These entities do not explain how the Commission could 
    force non-public utility control area operators, of which there are 
    approximately 62 out of 138 in the United States (as of October 
    1996), to accede to these pricing policies.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    (2) Twelve Monthly Coincident Peak v. Annual System Peak
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Several utilities ask that the Commission eliminate the requirement 
    that charges for network service be calculated using a 12-month rolling 
    average load ratio share and allow utilities discretion to determine 
    the way network customers pay. 234 They assert that the 
    requirement makes it impossible to recover the full cost of service 
    when customers begin or terminate service. They suggest a unit charge 
    based on a formula rate that is trued up each year or a month-by-month 
    load ratio share calculation.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \234\ E.g., Utilities For Improved Transition, Florida Power 
    Corp, VEPCO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        NE Public Power District states that the definition of load ratio 
    share in section 1.16 of the pro forma tariff, taken together with 
    sections 34.2 and 34.3 of the pro forma tariff require the use of the 
    12-CP method and the inclusion of losses to the generator bus. This, it 
    argues, is inconsistent with the Commission's statement that 
    ``[u]tilities that plan their systems to meet an annual system peak * * 
    * are free to file another method if they demonstrate that it reflects 
    their transmission system planning.'' (NE Public Power District at 22-
    23). NE Public Power District argues that utilities should be allowed 
    to use CP demands measured at delivery points at some common specified 
    voltage. It further asks the Commission to clarify whether the monthly 
    peak includes or excludes transmission losses.
        EEI and AEP argue that transmission reservations for services of 
    less than one month's duration and any discounted firm transactions 
    should not be counted in the load ratio calculation when determining 
    the 12 CP on point-to-point rates, but that the revenues from these 
    services should be credited to all firm transmission users.
        Montana Power argues that the Commission's pricing approach 
    discriminates against native load customers because all non-network 
    uses of the system do not occur at full, non-discounted prices for the 
    entire month and the effects of discounts will be shouldered by native 
    load customers. According to Montana Power, this is a disincentive to 
    utilities to offer discounts and creates a possibility of gaming by 
    network customers buying one day firm point-to-point reservations to 
    reduce their network load ratio shares.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        While the Commission reaffirmed the use of a twelve monthly 
    coincident peak (12 CP) allocation method for pricing network service 
    in the Final Rule, the Commission also stated:
    
    [u]tilities that plan their systems to meet an annual system peak * 
    * * are free to file another method if they demonstrate that it 
    reflects their transmission system planning.\235\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \235\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,736; mimeo at 296-97.
    
    Accordingly, utilities are free to propose in a section 205 filing an 
    alternative to the use of the 12-month rolling average (e.g., annual 
    system peak) in the load ratio share calculation, subject to 
    demonstrating that such alternative is consistent with the utility's 
    transmission system planning and would not result in overcollection of 
    the utility's revenue requirement. Any proposed alternative would also 
    be subject to any future filing conditions established by the 
    Commission.\236\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \236\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,770; mimeo at 398-99.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We also are not convinced that we should require the calculation of 
    load ratios using a particular method on a generic basis. Any such 
    proposals, including those concerning the treatment of discounted firm 
    transmission transactions in the load ratio calculation and revenue 
    credits associated with such transactions, are best resolved on a fact-
    specific, case-by-case basis.
        Finally, the Final Rule does not prohibit utilities from ``us[ing] 
    CP demands measured at delivery points at some common specified 
    voltage'' as claimed by NE Public Power District. Treatment of 
    transmission losses can be accomplished in different ways by different 
    transmission providers under the pro forma tariff, such as adjustment 
    to a consistently applied voltage level.
        Regarding NE Public Power District's allegation that certain 
    sections of the pro forma tariff do not allow the use of the annual 
    system peak method in the load ratio share calculation, the Commission 
    recognizes that certain rate methodologies may require minor 
    adjustments to the non-price terms and conditions to be consistent with 
    the proposed rate methodology. However, any modifications to the non-
    price terms and conditions established in the pro forma tariff must be 
    fully supported by the utility and the appropriateness of such proposed 
    changes will be evaluated by the Commission for
    
    [[Page 12322]]
    
    consistency with the proposed rates or rate methodologies. The 
    remainder of NE Public Power District's concerns are case-specific and 
    should be raised by NE Public Power District at such time as a 
    transmission provider makes a filing.
    (3) Load and Generation ``Behind the Meter''
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Several entities request clarification \237\ concerning the 
    definition of Network Load in pro forma tariff section 1.22, which 
    provides, in pertinent part, that:
    
        \237\ E.g., AMP-Ohio, TAPS.
    
        A Network Customer may elect to designate less than its total 
    load as Network Load but may not designate only part of the load at 
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    a discrete Point of Delivery.
    
        These entities maintain that section 1.22 is too restrictive and is 
    inconsistent with the Final Rule's treatment of load served from 
    ``behind the meter'' generation.\238\ Specifically, these entities 
    request that the Commission clarify that a network customer can exclude 
    from its designated network load a portion of load at a discrete point 
    of delivery, which is served from generation behind the meter. In 
    support of this position, a number of petitioners cite to FMPA v. FPL, 
    74 FERC para. 61,006 at 61,012-13, in which they claim the Commission 
    allowed network customers to exclude load served by behind the meter 
    generation.\239\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \238\ See FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,736 and 31,743; mimeo at 297 
    and 317.
        \239\ E.g., TAPS, Central Minnesota Municipal.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        TAPS asserts that there is no operational or economic reason to 
    require the designation of all load at a discrete point of delivery as 
    network load.
        FMPA argues that network customers should not be charged a network 
    rate to use their own transmission (or distribution) system to serve 
    loads that are located beyond the transmission owner's system. FMPA 
    interprets the Final Rule on this issue as allowing a network customer 
    that has behind-the-meter generation to serve part of its behind the 
    meter load from such generation; thus, a customer can exclude that 
    load, which is served without using the transmission provider's 
    transmission system, from the load ratio share. FMPA's interpretation 
    of section 1.22 is that ``a network customer may not import power using 
    both point-to-point and network transmission service at the same 
    delivery point, but that this Section does not prevent a network 
    customer from serving load from generation when both are behind the 
    delivery point and when the transaction does not rely upon use of the 
    transmission provider's transmission system.'' (FMPA at 5). FMPA 
    requests that the Commission clarify the language in section 1.22 
    consistent with its interpretation above.
        Michigan Systems asks the Commission to modify section 1.22 because 
    the ``clause may be interpreted to require network integration 
    transmission service customers to pay a second time for the 
    transmission of power that is already being transmitted under other 
    arrangements, such as transmission ownership. The clause could also be 
    interpreted to allow the transmission provider to charge customers for 
    the transmission of power which does not use the transmitter's system, 
    such as for transmission from 'behind the meter' generation to 'behind 
    the meter' load.'' (Michigan Systems at 5-13).
        Wisconsin Municipals ask the Commission to ``clarify that a partial 
    designation is appropriate if (1) only part of the load behind a 
    particular delivery point relies upon the transmission provider's 
    transmission system for service or (2) a network customer is 
    responsible for serving only a portion of the load behind a discrete 
    delivery point.'' (Wisconsin Municipals at 17-18).
        Blue Ridge asks the Commission to clarify that it intended to allow 
    for multiple ownership of resources by customers who are not network 
    customers.
    
    Utility Position
    
        FPL and Carolina P&L ask the Commission to clarify that section 
    1.22 and the Rule (see also Original Sheet No. 94 and FMPA I, 67 FERC 
    para. 61,167 at 61,481-82 (1994)) mean that regardless of whether or 
    not a customer has behind the meter or local generation at a delivery 
    point, if a customer wants to purchase network service to serve load at 
    a delivery point, it must purchase network service for all such load--
    the customer cannot split the load into network and point-to-point 
    components at a specific point of delivery.\240\ Otherwise, FPL states, 
    there would be a split system with the potential to game the system and 
    problems with how it would work.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \240\ Utilities For Improved Transition argues that a 
    transmission dependent utility should be required to serve its load 
    using only network transmission service. It asserts that such a 
    utility should not be allowed to avoid its full cost responsibility 
    by using point-to-point firm during peak periods and non-firm 
    service during non-peak periods. See also VEPCO.
        Moreover, FMPA filed an answer in opposition to the requests for 
    clarification of FP&L, Carolina P&L and others concerning the 
    definition of network load and related issues. (FMPA Answer). 
    Likewise, Michigan Systems and TAPS filed answers opposing these 
    requests for rehearing. (Michigan Systems Answer and TAPS Answer). 
    While answers to requests for rehearing generally are not permitted, 
    we will depart from our general rule because of the significant 
    nature of this proceeding and accept the FMPA Answer, Michigan 
    Systems Answer and TAPS Answer.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        AEP argues that the option in section 1.22 of excluding load from 
    network load should be deleted. AEP states that, as the Commission 
    recognized in its original FMPA v. FPL order, the provision is contrary 
    to the comparability standard. Specifically, AEP argues that 
    transmission-owning utilities do not and cannot offer themselves 
    partial integration service electing to pay only a portion of the 
    network costs, but rather must pay for the entire network, which 
    integrates all of the transmission-owning utility's resources and 
    loads. According to AEP, the load served by behind-the-meter generation 
    is not isolated from the system, which is there to serve that load when 
    the behind-the-meter generation is unavailable. Allowing a network 
    customer to use short-term non-firm point-to-point transmission, AEP 
    asserts, allows customers to evade a large portion of the network's 
    costs, which they will do on an unconstrained system such as AEP.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We disagree that the prohibition in tariff section 1.22 against a 
    network customer designating only part of a load at a discrete point of 
    delivery as network load is either inconsistent with the Final Rule's 
    treatment of generation ``behind the meter'' or is contrary to the 
    Commission's decisions in FMPA I and FMPA II.
        The Commission addressed ``behind the meter'' generation in the 
    Final Rule as follows:
    
    if a customer wishes to exclude a particular load at discrete points 
    of delivery from its load ratio share of the allocated cost of the 
    transmission provider's integrated system, it may do so. [citing 
    Florida Municipal Power Agency v. Florida Power & Light Company, 74 
    FERC para. 61,006 (1996), reh'g pending.] Customers that elect to do 
    so, however, must seek alternative transmission service for any such 
    load that has not been designated as network load for network 
    service. This option is also available to customers with load served 
    by 'behind the meter' generation that seek to eliminate the load 
    from their network load ratio calculation.\241\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \241\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,736; mimeo at 297.
    
    Implicit in the Commission's discussion of this issue in the Final Rule 
    and also in FMPA I and FMPA II, in permitting
    
    [[Page 12323]]
    
    the ``exclusion of a particular load,'' is that the Commission will 
    allow a network customer to exclude the entirety of a discrete load 
    from network load, but not just a portion of the load served by 
    generation behind the meter.
        In its request for rehearing of FMPA I, FMPA requested that the 
    Commission confirm its interpretation of the Commission's finding in 
    FMPA I that:
    
    [FMPA] can choose to serve an amount of load in a city from 
    generation in the city, so long as FMPA does not sometimes serve 
    that level of load from external generation or use that generation 
    to serve member loads outside the city.\242\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \242\ FMPA II at 61,012 (emphasis added).
    
    On rehearing in FMPA II, the Commission did not grant FMPA's request to 
    allow a partial designation of network load. Furthermore, the 
    Commission provided an example of how FMPA could request that certain 
    of its loads and resources be excluded from network integration 
    transmission service. The Commission explained that FMPA could choose 
    to exclude the loads of the cities of Ft. Pierce and Vero Beach from 
    the request for network integrated transmission service and 
    alternatively request point-to-point transmission service to transmit 
    power from resources in those cities to other FMPA members or from FMPA 
    member cities to Ft. Pierce and Vero Beach.\243\ The Commission neither 
    stated that it would allow a partial designation of a discrete load as 
    network load nor provided any examples of such treatment.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \243\ FMPA II at 61,011.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Additionally, throughout the pro forma tariff, network customers 
    are consistently prohibited from designating only a portion of a 
    discrete network load. For example, tariff section 31.2 provides:
    
        To the extent that the Network Customer desires to obtain 
    transmission service for a load outside the Transmission Provider's 
    Transmission System, the Network Customer shall have the option of 
    (1) electing to include the entire load as Network Load for all 
    purposes under Part III of the Tariff and designating Network 
    Resources in connection with such additional Network Load, or (2) 
    excluding that entire load from its Network Load and purchasing 
    Point-To-Point Transmission Service under Part II of the Tariff. 
    [Emphasis added]
    
    Accordingly, we find that no inconsistency exists between the tariff 
    language and either the language in the Final Rule or the Commission's 
    findings in FMPA I or FMPA II.
        In support of its position to allow a partial designation of 
    network load at a point of delivery, TAPS claims that there are no 
    operational reasons to require the designation of all load at a 
    discrete point of delivery as network load. We disagree. Utilities, 
    both commenting on the NOPR and on rehearing (e.g., AEP rehearing at 
    19-20 and Florida Power & Light at 14-18), express concern that 
    customers allowed to divide a discrete load between point-to-point and 
    network services would create a ``split system.'' The concept of 
    allowing a ``split system'' or splitting a discrete load is 
    antithetical to the concept of network service. A request for network 
    service is a request for the integration of a customer's resources and 
    loads. Quite simply, a load at a discrete point of delivery cannot be 
    partially integrated--it is either fully integrated or not integrated. 
    Furthermore, such a split system creates the potential for a customer 
    to ``game the system'' thereby evading some or all of its load-ratio 
    cost responsibility for network services.\244\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \244\ The load-ratio cost responsibility is based on the network 
    customer's monthly contribution to the transmission system peak 
    (i.e., coincident peak billing).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        For example, FMPA asserts that if a FMPA member city has a peak 
    load of 100 MW and behind the meter generation of 75 MW, FMPA should be 
    allowed to designate a portion of its load as network load (e.g., 60 
    MW), and to serve the remaining load (e.g., 40 MW) from its behind-the-
    meter generation.\245\ However, as a number of utilities note, this 
    would lead to the possibility of gaming the system. For example, if at 
    the time of the monthly system peak the FMPA member city generates more 
    than 40 MW (or takes short-term firm transmission service (or a 
    combination of the two)), it may be able to lower its monthly 
    coincident peak load for network billing purposes,\246\ and thereby 
    reducing if not eliminating its load-ratio cost responsibility for 
    network service. Because network and native load customers bear any 
    residual system costs on a load-ratio basis, any cost responsibility 
    evaded by a network customer in this manner would be borne by the 
    remaining network customers and native load.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \245\ FMPA at 3-4.
        \246\ While this customer could lower its coincident peak use of 
    the transmission system, it could be making substantial use of the 
    transmission system during all other hours of the month but yet have 
    little or no load-ratio cost responsibility.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        FPL also raises several fundamental operational problems associated 
    with allowing partial network service or creating a ``split system:''
    
        If all the loads are included in a single control area, how does 
    the transmission provider know what portion of the power delivered 
    is serving the point-to-point load (which presumably would not be 
    counted toward the network's load ratio)?
        Using the same 100 MW load example previously mentioned where 
    there is a 40/60 network/point-to-point split, there would have to 
    be a determination of how the split would be done in non-peak 
    situations. Are the first 40 MW of load all network load, or all 
    point-to-point load, or split on a 40/60 basis?
        If the system purchases economy power from non-local resources, 
    how is that delivery allocated between the network portion (for 
    which there would be no point-to-point scheduling, curtailment, or 
    transmission charges) and the point-to-point portion (which must be 
    arranged and paid for separately under a point-to-point tariff)?
    
        The bottom line is that all potential transmission customers, 
    including those with generation behind the meter, must choose between 
    network integration transmission service or point-to-point transmission 
    service. Each of these services has its own advantages and risks.\247\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \247\ Customers taking network integration transmission service 
    choose to have the transmission provider integrate their generation 
    resources with their loads. Network service is a service comparable 
    to the service that the transmission provider provides to its retail 
    native load, where the Transmission Provider includes the network 
    customers resources and loads (projected over a minimum ten-year 
    period) into its long-term planning horizon. Because network service 
    is usage based, network customers pay on the basis of their total 
    load, paying a load-ratio share of the costs of the transmission 
    provider's transmission system on an ongoing basis. In contrast, 
    point-to-point transmission service is more transitory in nature. 
    Point-to-point service is frequently tailored for discrete 
    transactions for various time periods, which may or may not enter 
    into the transmission provider's planning horizon. A point-to-point 
    transmission service customer is only responsible for paying for its 
    reserved capacity on a contract demand basis over the contract term.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In choosing between network and point-to-point transmission 
    services, the potential customer must assess the degree of risk that it 
    is willing to accept associated with the availability of firm 
    transmission capacity. Customers choosing point-to-point service, based 
    solely on the amount of transmission capacity reserved (or contract 
    demand), may face a relatively higher risk associated with the 
    availability of firm transmission capacity. For example, if a customer 
    with a peak load of 100 MW, and behind the meter generation of 75 MW, 
    chooses to serve a portion of its load with point-to-point transmission 
    service (e.g., 60 MW) and the remaining load (e.g., 40 MW) with its 
    behind-the-meter generation, this customer faces the risk that, should 
    its generation behind the meter become unavailable, the transmission 
    provider may not have firm transmission capacity available to serve the 
    remaining 40 MW of that
    
    [[Page 12324]]
    
    customer's load. One way to minimize this risk would be for the 
    customer to reserve and pay for additional firm point-to-point 
    transmission service to protect against the unavailability of its 
    behind-the-meter generation. Alternatively, the customer could choose 
    network service in which the transmission provider will plan and 
    provide for firm transmission capacity sufficient to meet the 
    customer's current and projected peak loads, including integration of 
    the customer's behind-the-meter generation as a network resource.
        For the reasons stated above, a network customer will not be 
    permitted to take a combination of both network and point-to-point 
    transmission services under the pro forma tariff to serve the same 
    discrete load. Accordingly, the requests for rehearing to modify tariff 
    section 1.22 are hereby rejected.
        Moreover, the Commission will allow a network customer to either 
    designate all of a discrete load \248\ as network load under the 
    network integration transmission service or to exclude the entirety of 
    a discrete load from network service and serve such load with the 
    customer's ``behind-the-meter'' generation and/or through any point-to-
    point transmission service.249
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \248\ We also clarify that while the tariff prohibits the 
    designation of only part of the load at a discrete point of 
    delivery, this prohibition also applies to network customers with a 
    discrete load served by multiple points of delivery. In other words, 
    for the same reasons explained above, a customer may not choose to 
    have part of a discrete load served under network integration 
    service at one or more delivery points and at the same time have the 
    remaining portion of the same load served under point-to-point 
    transmission service at other delivery points.
        \249\ An example of excluding the entirety of a discrete load 
    would be a municipal power agency excluding the entire load of a 
    member city with generation behind the meter, while requesting 
    network service to serve the remaining member cities' loads. The 
    excluded load of the member city must be met using a combination of 
    generation behind the meter and any remote generation that may be 
    necessary. The member city would be responsible for arranging any 
    point-to-point transmission service under the pro forma tariff that 
    may be necessary to import the power and energy from any remote 
    generation.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    (4) Existing Transmission Arrangements associated with Generating 
    Capacity Entitlements (e.g., ``preference power'' customers of PMAs)
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Several entities argue that section 1.22 of the pro forma tariff is 
    arbitrary and cannot be reconciled with the Final Rule's determination 
    not to abrogate existing agreements. \250\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \250\ E.g., NRECA, TDU Systems, AEC & SMEPA.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Specifically, several transmission customers claim that the 
    prohibition against designating only part of the load at a discrete 
    point of delivery is problematic for customers with existing 
    transmission arrangements for receiving preference power or capacity 
    entitlements from power marketing agencies (PMAs). For example, Central 
    Minnesota Municipal argues that the limiting language of section 1.22 
    should be eliminated as it would preclude Mountain Lake (a member of 
    Central Minnesota Municipal) from using network transmission and, at 
    the same time, point-to-point transmission for WAPA power under a 
    separate arrangement. These transmission customers assert that if they 
    designate all of the load at a discrete point of delivery as network 
    load, and pay for such network load on a load-ratio basis, then the 
    transmission provider is paid twice for the same transmission service--
    once through the existing transmission arrangement and a second time 
    through the network service.
        NRECA and TDU Systems argue that if a customer chooses to use 
    network service under the pro forma tariff to supplement its existing 
    arrangements to meet future full requirements, the Commission should 
    amend section 1.22 so the transmission provider cannot overcharge the 
    customer:
    
        A Network Customer may elect to designate less than its total 
    load as Network Load. Where a Network Customer has elected not to 
    designate a particular load as a Network Load, the Network Customer 
    is responsible for making separate arrangements under Part II of the 
    Tariff for any Point-to-Point Transmission Service that may be 
    necessary for such non-designated load, unless such non-designated 
    load is served pursuant to other arrangements. [251]
    
        \251\ NRECA at 78-79; TDU Systems at 32.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Alternatively, the transmission customer may choose not to 
    designate any load at a discrete point of delivery as network load. 
    However, these transmission customers note that the preference power 
    allotments received from PMAs typically do not equal the total load of 
    a customer at a discrete point of delivery. Therefore, the customer 
    would need to acquire additional point-to-point transmission service 
    for any remaining transmission needs. Accordingly, these transmission 
    customers conclude that the existence of their current transmission 
    arrangements precludes them from receiving network service which they 
    claim does not allow the comparable use of the system that the 
    transmission provider enjoys.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Commission recognizes that existing power and transmission 
    arrangements represent a transitional problem as customers begin to 
    take service under the pro forma tariff. Clearly, the Commission did 
    not intend for a transmission provider to receive two payments for 
    providing service to the same portion of a transmission customer's 
    load. Any such double recovery is unacceptable and inconsistent with 
    cost causation principles. Neither did the Commission intend to allow a 
    transmission customer to designate less than its total load as network 
    load at a discrete point of delivery even though a portion of that load 
    is served under a pre-existing contract. We clarify that such a 
    transmission customer has several alternatives it can pursue using 
    either point-to-point or network transmission service.
        Using network transmission service, the network customer would 
    designate its existing generation supply contract(s) as a network 
    resource(s) and the associated load served under such contract(s) 
    designated as network load. The network customer then has two options: 
    pursue negotiations with the transmission provider to obtain a credit 
    on its network service bill for any separate transmission arrangements 
    or for the unbundled transmission rate component of the existing 
    generation supply contract or (2) seek to have any separate 
    transmission or the unbundled transmission rate component of its 
    generation supply contract eliminated in recognition of the network 
    transmission service now being provided and paid for under the 
    tariff.252
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \252 Clearly, any such modification of existing contracts would required the agreement of all parties and a filing with the Commission.\
    
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Using point-to-point transmission service, the transmission 
    customer would identify the discrete points of delivery being served 
    under existing generation supply and existing transmission contracts 
    and acquire additional point-to-point transmission service under the 
    tariff for any remaining load at those discrete points of delivery.
        Any of these three alternatives should address concerns regarding 
    the possibility of double recovery. Furthermore, a transmission 
    customer may file a complaint under section 206 with the Commission to 
    address any claims of double recovery that it is unable to resolve with 
    the transmission provider.
    d. Annual System Peak Pricing for Flexible Point-to-Point Service
        In the Final Rule, the Commission indicated that it will allow a 
    transmission provider to propose a formula rate that assigns costs
    
    [[Page 12325]]
    
    consistently to firm point-to-point and network services.253 The 
    Commission added that it will no longer summarily reject a firm point-
    to-point transmission rate developed by using the average of the 12 
    monthly system peaks.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \253\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,737-38; mimeo at 301-04.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission explained that it still believed that it was 
    appropriate for utilities to use a customer-specific allocated cost of 
    service to account for diversity, but based on the changed 
    circumstances since Southern Company Services, Inc., 61 FERC para. 
    61,339 (1992) (Southern), it indicated that it would now permit an 
    alternative. Thus, the Commission indicated that it will allow all firm 
    transmission rates, including those for flexible point-to-point 
    service, to be based on adjusted system monthly peak loads.
        In order to prevent over-recovery of costs for those who use this 
    approach, the Commission explained that it will require transmission 
    providers to include firm point-to-point capacity reservations in the 
    derivation of their load ratio calculations for billings under network 
    service. In addition, the Commission explained that revenue from non-
    firm transmission services should continue to be reflected as a revenue 
    credit in the derivation of firm transmission tariff rates. The 
    Commission noted that the combination of allocating costs to firm 
    point-to-point service and the use of a revenue credit for non-firm 
    transmission service will satisfy the requirements of a conforming rate 
    proposal enunciated in our Transmission Pricing Policy 
    Statement.254
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \254\ FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 31,005 (1994).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Blue Ridge maintains:
    
        The sea change in the Commission's approach to the pricing of 
    transmission services is not warranted by any claimed change in 
    circumstances and Blue Ridge accordingly requests rehearing and 
    rejection of the new approach. At a minimum, the Commission should 
    clarify that any deviation from use of an annual peak divisor (or 
    other methodology based on system capability) for setting point-to-
    point transmission rates will be considered only on a case-by-case 
    basis.
    
        TAPS also argues that the use of the same denominator for two 
    different services is inconsistent, unjust and discriminatory. It 
    asserts that the Commission should use a system capability divisor for 
    allocating fixed costs between reservation-based and load-based firm 
    service.
        TAPS also asserts that most utilities plan their transmission 
    systems to cover the annual system peak estimated conservatively on the 
    higher side in order to meet unusually high loads reliably, rather than 
    planning on the basis of the twelve monthly peaks as stated in Order 
    No. 888. Therefore, TAPS asks that the Commission maintain 1 CP pricing 
    for point-to-point service. TAPS argues that the Commission should 
    allow transmission providers and customers to demonstrate the 
    appropriate measure for each transmission system's capability in 
    utility-specific proceedings.
        If the Commission uses a 12 CP denominator, TAPS requests that the 
    Commission clarify that capacity reservations should be established 
    consistently with that denominator and should recognize the 
    inappropriateness of using such rates as a cap for non-firm rates. It 
    asserts that non-firm rates should be limited to actual variable costs 
    of transmission, plus losses, plus a modest adder as a contribution 
    toward fixed costs. At the very least, TAPS argues that the cap should 
    be developed using a more appropriate denominator, e.g., system 
    capability.
        TAPS further argues that if the rate divisor is based on 
    experienced 12 CP, the capacity reservations and the divisor should be 
    measured at the delivery points (as it is for native load customers), 
    not the higher of the receipt or delivery points, to avoid a mismatch 
    between the rate divisor and billing determinants.255
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \255\ See also NE Public Power District.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Wisconsin Municipals and TAPS argue that if a 12 CP divisor is 
    used, customers must have the flexibility to vary their monthly 
    nomination under the point-to-point tariff.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        With respect to TAPS argument that the annual system peak method 
    would be appropriate for most systems, the Commission has determined in 
    Order No. 888 that this issue is best resolved on a case-by-case basis 
    and specifically provided utilities the opportunity to propose to use 
    other allocation methods, including the annual system peak method 
    sought by TAPS.256
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \256\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,736; mimeo at 296-97.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission already recognized the potential for a mismatch 
    between the rate divisor and billing determinants that TAPS now raises 
    on rehearing. We explicitly stated in the Final Rule that
    
    [t]he adjusted system monthly peak loads consist of the transmission 
    provider's total monthly firm peak load minus the monthly coincident 
    peaks associated with all firm point-to-point service customers plus 
    the monthly contract demand reservations for all firm point-to-point 
    service.[257]
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \257\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,738; mimeo at 303.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Use of the adjusted system monthly peak loads in the rate divisor 
    for flexible point-to-point transmission service eliminates the 
    mismatch concern raised by TAPS.
        We have also fully addressed in the Final Rule those arguments 
    objecting to the use of the average of the 12 monthly peaks in 
    determining a firm point-to-point transmission rate and no further 
    discussion is required. The other arguments raised with respect to this 
    section are fact specific and best addressed in individual rate 
    proceedings where the use of an annual system peak versus an average of 
    the 12 monthly peaks in determining a firm point-to-point transmission 
    rate is more appropriately evaluated.
    e. Opportunity Cost Pricing
    (1) Recovery of Opportunity Costs
        The Commission emphasized in the Final Rule that it had fully 
    explained its rationale for allowing utilities to charge opportunity 
    costs in Northeast Utilities and Penelec.258 The Commission also 
    explained that transmission providers proposing to recover opportunity 
    costs must adhere to the following requirements:
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \258\ Northeast Utilities Service Company (Northeast Utilities), 
    56 FERC para. 61,269 (1991), order on reh'g, 58 FERC para. 61,070, 
    reh'g denied, 59 FERC para. 61,042 (1992), order granting motion to 
    vacate and dismissing request for rehearing, 59 FERC para. 61,089 
    (1992), aff'd in relevant part and remanded in part, Northeast 
    Utilities Service Company v. FERC, 993 F.2d 937 (1st Cir. 1993); 
    Pennsylvania Electric Company (Penelec), 58 FERC para. 61,278 at 
    62,871-75, reh'g denied, 60 FERC para. 61,034 (1992), aff'd, 
    Pennsylvania Electric Company v. FERC, 11 F.3d 207 (D.C. Cir. 1993).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        (1) A fully developed formula describing the derivation of 
    opportunity costs must be attached as an appendix to their proposed 
    tariff;
        (2) Proposals must address how they will be consistent with 
    comparability; and
        (3) All information necessary to calculate and verify opportunity 
    costs must be made available to the transmission customer.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        VT DPS disputes the Commission's holding with respect to 
    opportunity costs and argues that rate filings seeking recovery of 
    opportunity costs should be summarily rejected. It asserts that, 
    contrary to statements by the Commission, courts have not endorsed 
    opportunity cost pricing for transmission customers and maintains that 
    the Commission's failure to consider objections to opportunity cost
    
    [[Page 12326]]
    
    pricing on the merits ``directly flouts the court's ruling'' in 
    Northeast Utilities. According to VT DPS, opportunity costs are 
    inherently unverifiable: ``there are insuperable difficulties in 
    proving the existence of lost opportunity costs in any fashion which 
    can readily and objectively be applied.'' At a minimum, VT DPS asserts, 
    opportunity costs arising more than five years out are unverifiable and 
    should not be permitted. Moreover, VT DPS argues that the right to 
    challenge the verifiability of opportunity costs is not adequate 
    protection because it is wasteful and burdensome (citing Cajun Electric 
    Power Cooperative v. FERC, 28 F.3d 173 at 179 (D.C. Cir. 1994) 
    (Cajun)).
        VT DPS also asserts that the Commission's treatment is inconsistent 
    with its treatment of gas pipeline pricing policies, which do not 
    permit the assessment of opportunity costs in gas pipeline 
    transportation rates. In addition, VT DPS asserts that opportunity cost 
    pricing for firm transportation service would allow the transmitting 
    utility to charge more for firm transmission of a third party's power 
    supplies than it charges its own native load for the transmission 
    component of native load service. Finally, VT DPS claims that 
    opportunity cost pricing contravenes Cajun because opportunity cost 
    pricing has a chilling effect on competition in New England and 
    nationally. VT DPS challenges whether a tariff provision that permits 
    the imposition of opportunity costs ``precludes the mitigation of [a 
    utility's] market power.''
        CCEM asserts that there is no justification for allowing 
    opportunity cost charges when such charges can be eliminated in the 
    secondary or released capacity market, without the discriminatory 
    charge. It notes that opportunity costs are not allowed in any other 
    industry and the Commission should not allow recovery of lost profits.
        American Forest & Paper argues that the only way to ensure 
    comparability is to require that transmission services are priced for 
    all customers based upon embedded cost principles (including pricing 
    for expansions). It opposes opportunity cost pricing as being 
    discriminatory because wheeling customers are required to compensate 
    the transmitting utility for its lost opportunities to make economy 
    purchases or sales to benefit native load. It further argues that 
    transmission capacity was not designed to facilitate non-firm, 
    unplanned economy purchases or sales on behalf of native load. American 
    Forest & Paper also asserts that allowing redispatch costs incorrectly 
    presupposes that native load has a superior right to the transmission 
    system. According to American Forest & Paper, neither of these costs 
    (opportunity/redispatch) should be imposed on the former sales, now 
    transmission-only, customers--the transmission customer is no more 
    responsible for the alleged transmission constraint than the existing 
    native load customer who adds to its requirements or the new customer 
    locating in the service territory. It maintains that firm transmission 
    contracts cannot by definition displace opportunity sales because there 
    is no ``opportunity'' until there is capacity in excess of the firm 
    transmission contractual commitments. In addition, American Forest & 
    Paper asserts that opportunity cost pricing may create difficulties for 
    IPPs, i.e., a lender may not finance projects because of cost 
    uncertainty related to varying revenue flows caused by opportunity cost 
    pricing. It believes that utilities should be required to establish a 
    separate subsidiary to make opportunity purchases or sales on its 
    behalf, which may minimize self dealing.259 It further asserts 
    that expansions should be subject to embedded cost pricing--unlike in 
    gas pipeline expansions, electric transmission expansions invariably 
    affect an integrated network.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \259\ The Commission has effectively achieved this result for 
    opportunity sales by requiring separation of the transmission 
    provider's wholesale merchant from its transmission operation 
    employees.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        CCEM asserts that, if opportunity cost pricing is maintained, 
    transmission customers should be given the information they need to 
    avert or mitigate opportunity-cost exposure. In particular, it argues 
    that customers need information on the run status and cost of 
    generating units that the transmission provider controls in advance of 
    any proposed redispatch. In addition, CCEM argues that transmission 
    providers should be required to inform customers of a redispatch in 
    advance.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        As an initial matter, many of the arguments raised are collateral 
    attacks on Penelec, Northeast Utilities, and the Commission's 
    Transmission Pricing Policy Statement. These matters are not the 
    subject of this proceeding, but rather Order No. 888 simply applies the 
    policy already in place. Therefore, these arguments are not properly 
    raised in this proceeding.260
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \260\ These arguments include those made by VT DPS concerning 
    Northeast Utilities and alleged inconsistencies with our natural gas 
    policies.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission does not believe that any changes are necessary to 
    its policy on opportunity cost recovery.261 In the Final Rule, we 
    fully explained our rationale for allowing utilities to charge 
    opportunity costs and no arguments have been presented on rehearing 
    that would persuade us otherwise.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \261\ Under the Commission's transmission pricing policy, 
    utilities are limited to charging the higher of embedded costs or 
    opportunity/incremental costs. See Order on Reconsideration and 
    Clarifying Policy Statement, 71 FERC para. 61,195 (1995). 
    Opportunity costs are capped by incremental expansion costs. 
    Opportunity costs are viewed as a form of incremental or marginal 
    cost pricing and include: (1) out-of-rate costs or costs associated 
    with the uneconomic dispatch of generating units necessary to 
    accommodate a transaction; and (2) costs that arise from a utility 
    having to reduce its off-system purchases or sales in order to avoid 
    a potential constraint on the transmission grid. We note that Order 
    No. 888 requires that off-system sales by the transmission provider 
    must be made under the point-to-point provisions of the pro forma 
    tariff.
        If a utility expands its transmission system so that it can 
    provide the requested transmission service, it can charge the higher 
    of its embedded costs or its incremental expansion costs. When a 
    transmission grid is constrained and a utility does not expand its 
    system, the Commission has allowed a utility to charge transmission-
    only customers the higher of embedded costs or legitimate and 
    verifiable opportunity costs (``or'' pricing), but not the sum of 
    the two (``and'' pricing).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As has been our policy, we will continue to determine the 
    appropriateness of opportunity cost pricing proposals on a case-by-case 
    basis. We continue to believe that opportunity cost pricing will 
    promote efficient decision-making by both transmission owners and users 
    and will not result in unduly discriminatory or anticompetitive 
    pricing. We have stated that because any transmission pricing proposal 
    must meet the comparability standard, we will have ample opportunity to 
    address any concerns that opportunity cost pricing may be unfair and 
    anticompetitive or otherwise inconsistent with the comparability 
    standard, including those concerns raised by CCEM with respect to the 
    need for advance information as to any proposed redispatch.
        We note that in compliance filings made pursuant to Order No. 888, 
    most utilities did not make the tariff changes necessary to charge 
    opportunity costs to customers under the pro forma tariff. Absent a 
    subsequent section 205 filing, these transmission providers will not be 
    able to charge opportunity costs under their compliance tariffs. Where 
    transmission providers did modify their tariff to allow for opportunity 
    costs, the Commission is reviewing the proposed charges on a case-by-
    case basis.
    (2) Redispatch Costs
        In the Final Rule, the Commission clarified that redispatch is 
    required only if it can be achieved while maintaining
    
    [[Page 12327]]
    
    reliable operation of the transmission system in accordance with 
    prudent utility practice.262
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \262\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,739-40; mimeo at 307-09.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission further explained that the recovery of redispatch 
    costs requires that: (1) a formal redispatch protocol be developed and 
    made available to all customers; and (2) all information necessary to 
    calculate redispatch costs be made available to the customer for audit. 
    The Commission also noted that the rates proposed must meet the 
    standards for conforming proposals in the Transmission Pricing Policy 
    Statement.
        The Commission also explained in the Final Rule that if the 
    transmission provider proposes to separately collect redispatch costs 
    on a direct assignment basis from a specific transmission customer, the 
    transmission provider must credit these revenues to the cost of fuel 
    and purchased power expense included in its wholesale fuel adjustment 
    clause.263
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \263\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,740; mimeo at 309.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        TAPS asserts that there is too much uncertainty with respect to the 
    treatment of redispatch costs. It asserts that the Commission should 
    require a section 205 filing for each corridor/constraint for which 
    redispatch costs are intended to be shared among the transmission 
    provider and network customers. Once there has been a determination 
    regarding a particular corridor/constraint, TAPS argues that ``it would 
    be appropriate to charge network customers for redispatch costs through 
    a mechanism with no fewer protections than a fuel clause.'' It further 
    argues that redispatch costs, like opportunity costs, should be capped 
    at the cost of the upgrade and, at the least, the Commission should 
    clarify that application of the redispatch sharing provision should be 
    adjudicated in particular cases.
        TDU Systems states that it does not object to a redispatch 
    obligation that is necessary to ensure transmission system reliability, 
    but they object to the fact that a transmission provider can determine 
    that a transmission constraint will arise as a result of the sale of 
    additional firm transmission service by the transmission provider. It 
    asks the Commission to clarify that the transmission constraint that 
    would trigger a redispatch obligation cannot be caused by a 
    transmission provider's sale of additional firm transmission 
    capability.
        Wisconsin Municipals asks the Commission to clarify that recovery 
    of redispatch costs on a load ratio basis, without a section 205 
    filing, is limited to when such action is necessary for reliability 
    reasons alone (not for economic reasons), and that in all other 
    circumstances a section 205 filing must be made and costs directly 
    assigned to the customer receiving the economic benefit of the 
    redispatch. It further asserts that if redispatch is allowed for 
    economic reasons, it must be offered on a comparable, non-
    discriminatory basis to all customers and the transmission provider, 
    provided the beneficiary agrees to accept a direct assignment.
        Several utilities argue that redispatch costs are a subset of 
    opportunity costs and that the Commission should not use both terms in 
    the tariff because it implies different standards apply to transmission 
    providers and their customers (e.g., sections 23.1 and 27).264 
    They request that the Commission only use the term ``redispatch costs'' 
    in the pro forma tariff and impose the same redispatch obligations on 
    network customers as are imposed on transmission providers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \264\ E.g., Utilities For Improved Transition, Florida Power 
    Corp, VEPCO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        No rehearing requests addressed the subject of fuel adjustment 
    clause treatment for redispatch costs.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Commission believes that the obligation to create additional 
    transmission capacity to accommodate a request for firm transmission 
    service should properly lie with the transmission provider, not a 
    network customer.
        The Commission clearly established in the Final Rule that utilities 
    are to be given ``substantial flexibility * * * to propose appropriate 
    pricing terms, including opportunity cost pricing [of which redispatch 
    costs are a subset], in their compliance tariff.'' 265 The 
    Commission further required that any such rate proposals must meet the 
    standards for conforming proposals in the Transmission Pricing Policy 
    Statement. Accordingly, TAPS is free to pursue its concerns in any 
    relevant compliance filings.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \265\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,739; mimeo at 307-08.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Tariff sections 33.2 and 33.3 clearly establish that redispatch of 
    all Network Resources and the transmission provider's own resources are 
    only to be performed to maintain the reliability of the transmission 
    system, not for economic reasons. Such costs are to be shared between 
    network customers and the transmission provider on a load ratio basis. 
    Similarly, the Commission clarified in Order No. 888, in modifying the 
    transmission customer's redispatch obligation, that such change was 
    ``to limit the redispatch obligation to reliability reasons.'' 266 
    Therefore, no further clarification is necessary.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \266\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,767; mimeo at 388.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Other redispatching provisions under the tariff (e.g., sections 
    13.5 and 27) refer to situations where the transmission provider can 
    relieve a system constraint more economically by redispatching the 
    transmission provider's resources than through constructing Network 
    Upgrades in order to provide the requested transmission service. 
    However, in this circumstance, redispatch is conditioned upon the 
    eligible customer agreeing to compensate the transmission provider for 
    such redispatch costs. Section 13.5 of the pro forma tariff further 
    requires that any such redispatch costs to be charged to the 
    transmission customer on an incremental basis must be specified in the 
    customer's service agreement prior to initiating service. These tariff 
    requirements would appear to satisfy Wisconsin Municipals concerns 
    because a section 205 filing must be made to directly assign costs to 
    the customer receiving the economic benefit of the redispatch.
        Regarding the argument that only the term ``redispatch costs'' 
    should be used in the pro forma tariff, we note that the Commission 
    followed this suggestion in drafting the pro forma tariff. The only 
    exception is the use of opportunity costs in section 23.1 of the 
    tariff, which caps the compensation for resellers at the higher of: (1) 
    the original rate, (2) the transmission provider's maximum rate on file 
    at the time of the assignment or (3) the reseller's opportunity cost. 
    We further note that their concerns that different standards may be 
    applied to transmission providers than to their customers are addressed 
    in section IV.C.6 (Capacity Reassignment).
    f. Expansion Costs
        In the Final Rule, the Commission allowed transmission providers to 
    propose any method of collecting expansion costs that is consistent 
    with the Commission's transmission pricing policy.267 The 
    Commission explained that ``or'' pricing sends the proper price signal 
    to customers and promotes efficiency and further indicated that ``and'' 
    pricing will not be allowed.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \267\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,741; mimeo at 312-13.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission also indicated that any request to recover future 
    expansion
    
    [[Page 12328]]
    
    costs will require a separate section 205 filing.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Several entities argue that requiring section 205 filings for all 
    transmission expansion costs would impose difficult burdens on 
    transmission providers that use formula rates because they would have 
    to try to distinguish between replacement costs, which are included in 
    formula rates, and expansion costs, which are not.268 They assert 
    that section 205 filings should be required only for system expansion 
    costs that the transmission provider proposes to recover on a direct 
    assignment or incremental cost basis, but not for costs to be recovered 
    on an embedded cost basis.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \268\ E.g., Utilities For Improved Transition, Florida Power 
    Corp, VEPCO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        TDU Systems maintain that to the extent Order No. 888's provisions 
    concerning direct assignment of transmission facilities indicate a 
    change in the historic policy of rolling transmission investments into 
    rate base, there is a risk TDUs will bear a disproportionate share of 
    the transmission burden relative to transmission owners under the 
    Commission's ``or'' pricing policy. According to TDU Systems, 
    transmission owners should be required to permit customers to 
    substitute their own lower cost capital for that of the owner's.
        SoCal Edison and Carolina P&L ask the Commission to clarify that a 
    transmission provider has no obligation to build or upgrade its 
    facilities for short-term firm point-to-point transmission customers 
    (Secs. 13.5, 15.4 and 1.13). SoCal Edison states that if a transmission 
    provider is required to build, the Commission should clarify that any 
    costs must be directly assigned to the requesting customer.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Final Rule does not change the Commission's filing requirements 
    for recovery of transmission expansion costs or other transmission-
    related expenses. The Rule does not impose a section 205 filing 
    requirement to the extent that existing formula rates do not require 
    that such a filing be made to add transmission investment. However, 
    consistent with the Commission's transmission pricing principles in 
    effect prior to Order No. 888, a decision to price transmission on an 
    incremental cost basis, or to directly assign facilities, are cost 
    assignments that require a section 205 filing.
        The Final Rule also does not change the Commission's transmission 
    pricing policies. Under our transmission pricing policy, a utility is 
    still permitted to charge the higher of incremental expansion costs 
    ``or'' a rolled-in embedded cost rate. There is no bias in the Final 
    Rule that should cause TDU customers or any other customer to pay a 
    disproportionate share of transmission costs. Moreover, we note that we 
    also encourage joint planning/building options and regional solutions 
    such as RTGs and ISOs.
        We do not believe that any change is necessary with regard to the 
    obligation to build or expand. While both sections 13.5 and 15.4 
    obligate the transmission provider to expand or upgrade its 
    transmission system to accommodate an application for firm point-to-
    point transmission service, these sections are conditioned upon the 
    transmission customer agreeing to compensate the transmission provider 
    for such upgrade. In light of this compensation requirement, we do not 
    anticipate that transmission providers will be requested to upgrade 
    facilities in order to accommodate requests for short-term point-to-
    point transmission service. However, in the unlikely event that a 
    short-term firm point-to-point transmission customer agrees to pay the 
    costs of such upgrades, we believe that it is appropriate to require a 
    transmission provider to expand its system to accommodate the request.
    g. Credit for Customers' Transmission Facilities
        In the Final Rule, the Commission concluded that credits related to 
    customer-owned facilities are more appropriately addressed on a case-
    by-case basis, where individual claims for credits may be evaluated 
    against a specific set of facts.269 The Commission stressed that 
    while certain facilities may warrant some form of cost credit, the mere 
    fact that transmission customers may own transmission facilities is not 
    a guaranteed entitlement to such a credit. The Commission further 
    explained that it must be demonstrated that a transmission customer's 
    transmission facilities are integrated with the transmission system of 
    the transmission provider in order to establish a right to credits. The 
    Commission also noted that consistent with its ruling in FMPA 
    II,270 if a customer wishes not to integrate certain loads and 
    resources, and thereby exclude them from its load ratio share of the 
    allocated cost of the integrated system, it may do so by separately 
    contracting for point-to-point transmission service.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \269\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,742-43; mimeo at 316-18.
        \270\ Florida Municipal Power Agency v. Florida Power & Light 
    Company, 74 FERC para. 61,006 (1996), reh'g pending.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        APPA asserts that several differences between the treatment of 
    transmission customers' and transmission providers' facilities are not 
    comparable and must be corrected: (1) transmission providers' 
    facilities include those owned, controlled or operated by the 
    transmission provider, but to obtain credit, transmission customers 
    must own the facilities; (2) transmission providers are under no 
    obligation to engage in joint planning and historically have refused, 
    thus putting the matter beyond the control of the customer; and (3) 
    facilities of the customer must serve all of the transmission 
    provider's power and transmission customers, but a transmission 
    provider can include facilities in rates that serve only certain 
    customers. APPA also maintains that the Commission failed to provide 
    sufficient guidance to allow customers to ascertain the type of 
    transmission facilities for which they can expect to receive credit.
        Several entities assert that the standard as to existing customer-
    owned facilities is inherently ambiguous--the Final Rule preamble says 
    integrated into the ``plans or operations'' of the transmitting 
    utility, but section 30.9 of the tariff says the ``planning and 
    operations'' of the transmission provider (emphasis added).271 
    Further, they assert, it is unreasonable to require, as a key to 
    integration, that ``the transmission provider is able to provide 
    transmission service to itself or other transmission customers over 
    those facilities'' because it may be that the facilities are necessary 
    to provide network service to the customer that owns the facilities and 
    a credit would be appropriate. They argue that if transmission 
    facilities serve load included in the network customer's network load, 
    the transmission customer should get a credit.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \271\ E.g., NRECA, Blue Ridge, TDU Systems.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Blue Ridge states that ``[i]f the Commission does intend to change 
    its standard or otherwise codify the result of FMPA II, then Blue Ridge 
    urges rehearing and suggests a more analytical, policy oriented 
    approach to the issue.'' (Blue Ridge at 31). It recommends adding the 
    following language to the end of section 30.9 of the tariff concerning 
    credit for new facilities: ``or if such facilities are integrated with, 
    and support the
    
    [[Page 12329]]
    
    Transmission Provider's Transmission system.'' (Blue Ridge at 
    Attachment 1).
        FMPA argues that a transmission provider can avoid paying credits 
    for transmission that is functionally the same as that of the 
    transmission provider simply by refusing to jointly plan. It asserts 
    that the Commission should adopt either the Commission's integration 
    test, without requiring joint planning, or a functionality test that 
    considers whether the facilities of the customer and transmission 
    provider are similar. Moreover, it argues that a more inclusive 
    definition of the grid would better achieve comparability and 
    competitive generation markets and would remove incentives to avoid 
    joint planning. It argues that crediting customer-owned transmission 
    also promotes the establishment of regional grids.
        Several entities state that the standard as to future network 
    customer-owned facilities should be modified to make joint planning 
    mandatory on the part of the transmission provider, who otherwise has 
    little incentive to cooperate and coordinate.272 They claim that 
    in joint planning, plans cannot be developed by the transmission 
    provider alone. They further argue that the Commission should not deem 
    the lack of joint planning dispositive of the operation and planning 
    issue.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \272\ E.g., NRECA, TDU Systems, TAPS.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        TAPS asks the Commission to clarify that credits will be provided 
    for existing, as well as future, facilities if the integration 
    requirement is met.
        Wisconsin Municipals asks the Commission to clarify that the level 
    of customer-owned credits is a rate issue and that if parties have 
    negotiated provisions for credits, the Final Rule cannot be used by 
    transmission providers to avoid the obligations undertaken in a 
    settlement.
        NRECA and TDU Systems assert that the Commission should not abandon 
    its historical practice of rolling in transmission facilities for 
    purposes of transmission pricing; otherwise, the Commission must 
    examine the function of all transmission facilities in a transmission 
    provider's rate base and exclude them if they are not ``integrated'' 
    (referencing Order No. 888 at 317 n.452). They argue that because 
    customers would have to file section 206 filings to enforce this, the 
    Commission should require transmission providers to file under section 
    205 the identity of those facilities that will be included in the 
    transmission rate base, those that will be excluded, and the supporting 
    data.
        Turlock wants the Commission to provide concrete guidelines as to 
    the eligibility of facilities for customer credits. Moreover, Turlock 
    asserts that credits may be appropriate for point-to-point customers as 
    well--especially in Northern California where PG&E, according to 
    Turlock, encouraged customers to build facilities. Turlock finds this 
    particularly important where PG&E has proposed to switch from 
    subfunctionalized ratemaking to system-wide rolled-in ratemaking. It 
    asserts that, if there are system-wide rolled in rates without a credit 
    provision, there may be a violation of the ``or'' pricing policy.
        Several entities ask the Commission to clarify that the crediting 
    provision works on a comparable basis for transmission customers and 
    providers.273 They ask the Commission to clarify that the phrase 
    ``serve all of its power and transmission customers'' in section 30.9 
    is to be measured by the facilities that the transmission provider 
    rolls into rate base to determine transmission rates and the 
    transmission component of requirements rates. For example, they argue 
    that because AEP rolls radial lines into rate base, comparable 
    customer-owned lines should receive a credit. They also ask the 
    Commission to clarify that the test that facilities are integrated into 
    the planning and operations of the transmission provider is an 
    objective standard that is satisfied by evidence that the transmission 
    provider's load flow studies take into account the transmission 
    customer's facilities. They assert that the standard should not be a 
    subjective one that depends on whether the transmission provider says 
    that it includes customer facilities in its planning and operations.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \273\ E.g., IMPA, TAPS, AMP-Ohio, Michigan Systems.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        AMP-Ohio adds that the integration requirement should also be 
    satisfied by evidence that the transmission provider includes costs in 
    its rate base or transmission expenses that are associated with 
    transmission facilities of utilities that it acquires. Michigan Systems 
    also asks that the Commission clarify that the test in section 30.9 is 
    a functional test and not whether the transmission owner says it is 
    integrating its operations.
        Michigan Systems states that it has no objection to leaving 
    determinations of credits to rate cases, as an abstract matter, but 
    asserts that the Commission should make clear that it will not 
    implement newly-filed tariffs in a way that imposes multiple or 
    inconsistent charges for transmission in the interim. Otherwise, it 
    asserts, transmission dependent utilities may be out of business if 
    they must wait years to get credit for grid transmission they already 
    own and that they must pay to finance. Michigan Systems also states 
    that it would be illegal to require systems to pay for transmission by 
    applying a load ratio share based on total loads when they have made 
    investments under contracts for transmission to serve a portion of 
    those loads.
        TAPS states that the Commission must define what it means by 
    ``integrated.'' TAPS asserts that the term should mean grid facilities 
    used to integrate the network customer's resources and loads. It 
    further asserts that the Commission should continue to use the test 
    whether the facilities serve a comparable function. Unless a proper 
    credit is provided, TAPS maintains, network customers could pay twice 
    for transmission. TAPS adds that without proper crediting, the 
    Commission cannot require load ratio pricing of network service.
        TAPS asks the Commission to clarify the method it will use to 
    calculate the credit in individual cases and suggests that the 
    Commission adopt the method TAPS proposed in its initial comments in 
    this proceeding.
        With respect to joint ownership of transmission facilities or 
    ownership of transmission facilities through a joint exercise of powers 
    agency (JPA) or a Generation and Transmission Cooperative, TANC asks 
    that the Commission provide for proportionate entitlement to a credit 
    among those who have invested in, and are entitled to the use of, such 
    facilities. TANC also argues that the credit should apply to facilities 
    used to complete a transaction under the transmission provider's point-
    to-point tariff. Further, TANC asserts that upon a showing that the 
    facilities are integrated, the credit in section 30.9 should be 
    mandatory and asks that the Commission provide guidance as to the 
    method of either calculating or applying the credit.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Commission reaffirms its finding in Order No. 888 that the 
    question of credits for customer-owned facilities is best resolved on a 
    fact-specific, case-by-case basis.274 Accordingly, the Commission 
    does not believe that the rehearing requests seeking specific guidance 
    regarding various aspects of
    
    [[Page 12330]]
    
    customer credits are appropriate for resolution at this time.275
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \274\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,742; mimeo at 316.
        \275\ Wisconsin Municipals' argument with respect to prior 
    settlements has been previously addressed in Section IV.D.1.c.(2) 
    (Energy Imbalance Bandwidth).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In order to conform the Final Rule preamble language with the 
    tariff provisions of Order No. 888,276 we will modify section 30.9 
    of the pro forma tariff to provide that a customer may receive a credit 
    for its own facilities if it demonstrates that ``its transmission 
    facilities are integrated into the plans or operations (instead of 
    ``planning and operations'') of the transmission provider to serve its 
    power and transmission customers.'' 277 The intent of section 30.9 
    of the pro forma tariff is that, for a customer to be eligible for a 
    credit, its facilities must not only be integrated with the 
    transmission provider's system, but must also provide additional 
    benefits to the transmission grid in terms of capability and 
    reliability, and be relied upon for the coordinated operation of the 
    grid. Indeed, in the Final Rule we explicitly stated that the fact that 
    a transmission customer's facilities may be interconnected with a 
    transmission provider's system does not prove that the two systems 
    comprise an integrated whole such that the transmission provider is 
    able to provide transmission service to itself or other transmission 
    customers over these facilities.278
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \276\ See FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,742-43; mimeo at 316-17.
        \277\ As we noted in FMPA II, this fundamental cost allocation 
    concept applies to the transmission provider as well. Just as the 
    customer cannot secure credit for facilities not used by the 
    transmission provider to provide service, the transmission provider 
    cannot charge the customer for facilities not used to provide 
    transmission service. 74 FERC para. 61,006 at 61,010 n.48 (1996).
        \278\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,742-43; mimeo at 317.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission further stated in the Final Rule that where disputes 
    over credits for customer-owned facilities arise, it encourages all 
    parties not to seek formal resolution at the Commission, but to first 
    pursue alternative dispute resolution. In this regard, the customer at 
    the time it is requesting network service could also request that a 
    study be undertaken by the company to analyze the impact and benefit of 
    the customer's facilities provided to the integrated transmission 
    network.
        We share the concern of APPA and others that transmission providers 
    have not allowed transmission customers to participate in the planning 
    process for new transmission projects. Allowing potential transmission 
    customers the opportunity to participate in transmission projects is 
    important in ensuring that regional transmission needs are met 
    efficiently. One way of accomplishing this goal is through an RTG, ISO, 
    or other regional entity that has an open planning process. Where such 
    entities do not exist, we strongly encourage public utilities to hold 
    an open season for all transmission expansion projects, including those 
    in response to a service request, so that all entities in the region 
    have an opportunity to identify their future needs and participate in 
    the project.
        Finally, requests for the Commission to mandate joint-planning are 
    addressed below in the discussion of section 1.12 of the pro forma 
    tariff.
    h. Ceiling Rate for Non-firm Point-to-Point Service
        In the Final Rule, the Commission stated that it is important to 
    continue to allow pricing flexibility.279 The Commission explained 
    that, in accordance with its current policies, the rate for non-firm 
    point-to-point transmission service may reflect opportunity costs. The 
    Commission further explained that, if a utility chooses to adopt 
    opportunity cost pricing, the non-firm rate is effectively capped by 
    the availability of firm service and is not subject to a separately-
    stated price cap. On the other hand, the Commission explained that, if 
    a utility chooses not to adopt opportunity cost pricing, the non-firm 
    rate is capped at the firm rate.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \279\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,743-44; mimeo at 319-20.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Duquesne asks the Commission to clarify that the phrase ``the non-
    firm rate is capped at the firm rate'' does not mean that the 
    Commission is deviating from its principles that non-firm transmission 
    service must be priced in a manner that (i) reflects the 
    interruptibility of the service, and (ii) is economically efficient.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        With regard to Duquesne's request, we clarify that the firm 
    transmission rate simply represents a maximum rate or price cap for 
    non-firm transmission prices. We emphasize that non-firm transmission 
    prices should reflect the interruptibility of the service and should 
    promote efficient use of the transmission system, subject to this price 
    cap. Accordingly, while in some circumstances non-firm transmission 
    rates may be set at the firm transmission rate level, the Commission 
    expects that non-firm transmission rates would, in most instances, be 
    priced below the price cap.
    i. Discounts
        In the Final Rule, the Commission stated that if a transmission 
    provider offers a rate discount to its affiliate, or if the 
    transmission provider attributes a discounted rate to its own wholesale 
    transactions, the same discounted rate must also be offered at the same 
    time to non-affiliates on the same transmission path and on all 
    unconstrained transmission paths.280 In addition, the Commission 
    required that discounts from the maximum firm rate for the provider's 
    own wholesale use or its affiliate's wholesale use must be transparent, 
    readily understandable, and posted on the transmission provider's OASIS 
    in advance so that all eligible customers have an equal opportunity to 
    purchase non-firm transmission at the discounted rate.281 Finally, 
    the Commission explained that discounts offered to non-affiliates must 
    be on a basis that is not unduly discriminatory and must be reported on 
    the OASIS within 24 hours of when available transmission capability 
    (ATC) is adjusted in response to the transaction.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \280\ All offers or agreements to provide rate discounts to 
    affiliates (including the Transmission Provider's wholesale 
    merchant) on a particular path must be posted immediately on the 
    OASIS and be available for a long enough period to allow non-
    affiliates to obtain the same discounted service on that path and on 
    other paths for which the transmission provider must provide the 
    same discount. We modify below our requirement regarding which other 
    paths must receive the same discount.
        \281\ The Commission also stated that the same requirements will 
    apply to discounts for firm transmission service. The Commission 
    added that if a transmission provider offers an affiliate a discount 
    for ancillary services, or attributes a discounted ancillary service 
    rate to its own transactions, it must offer at the same time the 
    same discounted rate to all eligible customers. The Commission noted 
    that discounted ancillary services rates must be posted on the OASIS 
    pursuant to Part 37 of the Commission's regulations.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
    Utility Position
    
        A number of utilities assert that the affiliate discounting 
    provision is too broad.282 SoCal Edison asserts that if the 
    affiliate discounting provision is kept, the requirement to discount 
    similarly for non-affiliates on unconstrained paths should be limited 
    to offers on the same day only for new transmission services and only 
    for the duration of the service offered to the affiliate.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \282\ E.g., SoCal Edison, Entergy, Southwestern, PacifiCorp, 
    Montana Power, AEP, Utilities For Improved Transition, EEI.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Entergy and Southwestern assert that the Commission should change 
    the discount language, which provides that
    
    [[Page 12331]]
    
    whenever the transmission provider offers a discount to an affiliate, 
    or attributes a discount to its own transaction, it must offer a 
    comparable discount to all similarly situated transmission customers. 
    Southwestern believes that the Commission does not justify its 
    different treatment of discounts to affiliates and discounts to non-
    affiliates--section 205(b) of the FPA states that a public utility may 
    not give any undue preference or advantage to any person. Southwestern 
    also notes that for gas pipelines, the Commission required that 
    affiliate discounts be available to similarly situated shippers (citing 
    18 CFR 161.3(h)(1)).
        PacifiCorp suggests replacing the last sentence of section 
    37.6(c)(3) of the OASIS regulations with the following sentence: ``With 
    respect to any discount offered to its own power customers or its 
    affiliates, the Transmission Provider must, at the same time, post on 
    the OASIS an offer to provide the same discount to all Transmission 
    Customers on the same transmission path and on all other unconstrained 
    transmission paths parallel thereto for deliveries to the same Point of 
    Delivery.'' It argues that the Commission's approach of requiring the 
    same discount to all transmission customers on the same path and on all 
    unconstrained transmission paths would discourage discounting, even 
    when done to attract counter-wheeling to relieve constraints.283
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \283\ See also Washington Water Power.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several utilities argue that the discount language should be 
    changed to require only that the same discount be offered to all 
    customers on the same path.284 Otherwise, Montana Power asserts, 
    transmission providers will be reluctant to offer discounts to its own 
    marketers so as to protect revenues on other paths.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \284\ E.g., Montana Power, Allegheny, Puget.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        AEP suggests that the discount language be changed to require that 
    the discount be made available for all unconstrained paths terminating 
    at the same interface.
        Illinois Power argues that the Commission should require discounts 
    for equivalent (i.e., similarly situated) service requests, on the 
    basis of location, term and time of service, which it asserts conforms 
    to the Commission's standards for natural gas pipelines (citing 18 CFR 
    161.3(h)). Otherwise, it asserts, the Commission's approach will result 
    in inefficient use of scarce transmission capacity and thereby 
    discourage efficient bulk power trading.
        VEPCO asserts that transmission providers must be given more 
    flexibility to accommodate differences in regional wholesale markets 
    and to maximize the movement of economical capacity and energy. It 
    states that a transmission provider will provide discounts only if they 
    are not detrimental to existing committed agreements or potential 
    future revenue--revenue from additional sales must offset the decrease 
    in revenues from making discounts. It suggests that preferential 
    treatment can be reduced by the following constraints: (1) offer the 
    same discount to all transmission requests to the same points of 
    delivery for the same time, and (2) a discount should not apply to 
    service already agreed to but not yet provided at that point. Utilities 
    For Improved Transition adds the following constraint: evaluate request 
    for discount on whether it would increase volume without reducing total 
    revenues.285 Florida Power Corp asserts that because 
    communications regarding discounts must be posted on OASIS, 
    preferential treatment would be readily apparent.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \285\ See also Florida Power Corp.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        EEI states that the discount requirement has the potential to 
    arbitrarily reduce the revenue that the transmission provider may be 
    able to obtain over alternative paths that may be unconstrained, but of 
    greater potential value than the path(s) identified as appropriate for 
    discounting. It adds that the requirements for posting discounts should 
    be the same regardless of affiliation and should be limited to the 
    specific transmission path(s) discounted by the transmission provider.
        Carolina P&L argues that the Commission should permit selective 
    discounting of non-firm transmission service on a posted-in-advance (on 
    OASIS) basis that will not create a most favored nations situation 
    merely because the transmission provider or an affiliate availed itself 
    of the posted discount.
    
    Customer Position
    
        Tallahassee asks the Commission to clarify that the transmission 
    provider must automatically apply the discount to any eligible customer 
    or, at the minimum, provide actual and timely notice of the discount's 
    availability.
        Similarly, PA Coops asserts that ``[i]f transmission service is 
    being discounted to any customer, affiliated or not, for a specific 
    level of service at a specific point in time, it should be equally 
    discounted to all customers receiving the same transmission service. To 
    do otherwise is unduly discriminatory.'' (PA Coops at 11).
        TAPS asserts that all discounts must be posted in advance, the 
    reasons for the discounts should be transparent, the transmission 
    provider should keep all requests for discounts in a log, and short-
    lived discounts should not be permitted.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        In response to the arguments raised with respect to discounting, we 
    will revise our policy on discounting transmission service. This 
    revised policy will assure consistency with our standards of conduct 
    requirements, which preclude a utility's wholesale merchant function 
    from having access to its transmission system information (including 
    price) not posted on the OASIS that is not otherwise also available to 
    the general public or that is not also publicly available to all 
    transmission users. The revised policy also should result in less 
    opportunity for affiliate abuse and enable better monitoring of 
    potential abuse. Additionally, we have concluded that the same policy 
    should apply regardless of whether the discount is for the transmission 
    provider's own wholesale use (i.e., wholesale merchant function), for 
    the transmission provider's affiliate, or for a non-affiliate.
        A transmission provider should discount only if necessary to 
    increase throughput on its system. While the potential for abuse is 
    most obvious in situations involving the transmission provider's own 
    wholesale use or use by an affiliate (own use/affiliate),286 we 
    must also be concerned with a transmission provider agreeing to 
    discount to non-affiliates in any unduly discriminatory manner. To 
    satisfy these dual concerns, we believe that any ``negotiation'' 
    287 between a transmission provider and potential transmission 
    customers should take place on the OASIS. Toward this end, we believe 
    three principal requirements are appropriate. (These requirements would 
    remain even after negotiation takes place on the OASIS.)
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \286\ We clarify that own use/affiliate transactions include all 
    transactions where the transmission provider or any of its 
    affiliates is either the buyer, seller, marketer, or broker of 
    wholesale power.
        \287\ ''Negotiation'' would only take place if the transmission 
    provider or potential customer seeks prices below the ceiling prices 
    set forth in the tariff.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        First, any offer of a discount for transmission services made by 
    the transmission provider must be announced to all potential customers 
    solely by posting on the OASIS. This requirement, which will ensure 
    that all potential transmission customers under
    
    [[Page 12332]]
    
    the pro forma tariff will have equal access to discount information, 
    will guard against own use/affiliate customers gaining an unfair timing 
    advantage concerning the availability of discounts.
        Second, we will require that any customer-initiated requests for 
    discounts occur solely by posting on the OASIS, regardless of whether 
    the customer is an own use/affiliate or a non-affiliate. We have 
    considered, and rejected at least for now, a more restrictive approach 
    which would require that all discounts be initiated solely through 
    offers by the transmission provider. Under such an arrangement, 
    negotiations for discounts would effectively take place by customers 
    accepting or not accepting the offered discount. While such an 
    arrangement could better protect against affiliate abuse, it might be 
    less efficient.288 Accordingly, we will permit customer-initiated 
    requests for discounts but will require that such requests be visible 
    (via posting on the OASIS) to all market participants.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \288\ For example, requiring the transmission provider to wait 
    to see if an offered 5% discount clears the market would appear to 
    be less efficient than permitting the customer to advise the 
    transmission provider (via the OASIS) of its need for a higher 
    discount in order to take service.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Finally, we will require that, once the transmission provider and 
    customer agree to a discounted transaction, the details (e.g., price, 
    points of receipt and delivery, and length of service) be immediately 
    posted on the OASIS. This requirement will be equally applicable 
    regardless of whether the customer is an own use/affiliate or non-
    affiliate.
        We will also revise our policy with respect to the transmission 
    paths on which a discount must be offered. Many petitioners argue that 
    the policy in Order No. 888, particularly that the discount rate must 
    be offered over all unconstrained paths, is too broad, and may provide 
    disincentives for the efficient operation of the transmission grid. 
    Their concerns include, for example, the possibility that the policy 
    would inhibit the transmission provider from offering discounts that 
    would relieve line constraints. For example, PacifiCorp argues that it 
    would be reluctant to offer a discount on northbound power flows that 
    would relieve transmission constraints on transmission paths that are 
    normally used for southbound flows, if by virtue of discounting 
    northbound flows, it would also be required to discount all 
    unconstrained southbound flows. Another concern is that while requiring 
    discounts on all unconstrained paths could conceivably result in more 
    service being provided, it may not have that effect. Since the level of 
    transmission revenues will decline if the discount applies to all 
    unconstrained paths and this, in turn, could reduce the credit to firm 
    transmission users for non-firm service revenues, transmission 
    providers may simply decide not to discount a particular unconstrained 
    path. In light of these persuasive arguments, we will no longer require 
    the transmission provider to provide the same discount over all 
    unconstrained paths.
        Under our revised policy, if the transmission provider offers a 
    discount on a particular path, i.e., from a point of receipt to a point 
    of delivery, the transmission provider must offer the same discount for 
    the same time period on all unconstrained paths that go to the same 
    point(s) of delivery on the transmission provider's system. In this 
    regard, a point of delivery includes an interconnection with another 
    control area. Also, if a power purchaser can take delivery at more than 
    one point of delivery (such as two substations serving a municipality), 
    we would consider these to be the same point of delivery for 
    discounting purposes.
        This change provides some flexibility to transmission providers to 
    set prices for transmission service efficiently and at the same time 
    maintains the requirement that public utilities provide comparable 
    service at rates that are not unduly discriminatory or preferential. 
    The change is designed to ensure that the transmission owner will 
    provide the same discounted service to its competitors that it provides 
    to itself or its affiliates for their wholesale sales.
        The Commission considered requiring the transmission provider 
    offering a discount on a particular path to offer discounts on all 
    unconstrained paths that go from the same points of receipt on the 
    transmission provider's system and decided that such a requirement was 
    not necessary to ensure comparability.
        We further clarify that a transmission provider may limit its 
    offers of discounts over the OASIS to particular time periods. There is 
    nothing per se unduly discriminatory in offering a discount in one 
    period and not in another.\289\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \289\ Thus, there is no need to revise contracts to reflect 
    later offered discounts.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Finally, we recognize that even with this revised policy utilities 
    may engage in affiliate abuse by offering discounts only at times or 
    along paths that are of advantage to it or its affiliates. While 
    requiring the posting of discount information on the OASIS does not 
    completely eliminate the possibility of affiliate abuse, these 
    procedures will allow ready identification of unduly discriminatory or 
    preferential transactions, and thus make easier the preparation of 
    complaints that the transmission provider is engaging in a pattern of 
    discounting that indicates affiliate abuse, such as offering discounts 
    preferentially at times or on paths that only the transmission provider 
    or its affiliate can take advantage of, without offering discounts at 
    times or on paths that its competitors can take advantage of.
        We will require that all ``negotiation'' take place on the OASIS as 
    soon as practicable, as explained in Order No. 889-A.
    j. Other Pricing Related Issues Not Specifically Addressed in the Final 
    Rule
    (1) Demand Charge Credits
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        VT DPS argues that demand charge credits for curtailments or 
    interruptions are needed to provide an incentive to utilities to 
    provide high quality service. It points out that the Commission has 
    allowed demand charge credits in the gas pipeline context (citing 
    Tennessee Gas Pipeline Co., 71 FERC para. 61,399 at 62,580).290
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \290\ See also Valero.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Commission does not believe that electrical systems will be 
    less reliable as a result of our initiatives on competition and open 
    access in the Final Rule. As such, the Commission does not intend to 
    require demand charge credits on a generic basis to encourage reliable 
    transmission service. However, because the Commission has not mandated 
    any particular rate design methodology under the Final Rule pro forma 
    tariff, customers are free to argue in the compliance filing 
    proceedings or subsequent section 205 proceedings that demand charge 
    credits are reasonable in the context of a particular rate design 
    method.
    (2) In-Kind Transactions
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        CCEM asserts that in-kind transactions in reformed power pool 
    agreements should be abolished because of the uncertainty of valuing 
    non-cash transactions and the potential for cross subsidizing the 
    utilities' generation sales. It contends that a cash equivalent 
    transaction for all formerly in-kind transactions among transmission 
    owners is needed.
    
    [[Page 12333]]
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        To satisfy CCEM's concerns, the Commission concludes that in-kind 
    transactions must be provided on a non-discriminatory basis. The 
    Commission recently found that in-kind transactions (i.e., transactions 
    with payment by energy returned in kind instead of by a monetary 
    charge) with no unbundling requirement ``could hide and, thereby, mask 
    unduly preferential terms and rates,'' which is precisely one of the 
    practices that the Final Rule is intended to remedy.291 While we 
    will now require that all in-kind transactions be provided on an 
    unbundled basis, we stress that we are not prohibiting in-kind 
    transactions. Utilities are free to enter into contracts that contain 
    in-kind compensation for the wholesale generation component, as long as 
    it unbundles such transactions. Consistent with Arizona, unless the 
    other party to the transaction contracts for transmission service under 
    that utility's open access pro forma tariff, that utility must obtain 
    the necessary transmission and ancillary services under the terms of 
    its open access transmission tariff and must separately state the 
    transmission and ancillary service prices that it will recover from the 
    customer.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \291\ Arizona Public Service Company, Order Addressing 
    Functional Unbundling Issues, 78 FERC para. 61,016 (slip op. at 11) 
    (1997) (Arizona).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    2. Priority For Obtaining Service
    a. Reservation Priority for Existing Firm Service Customers
        In the Final Rule, the Commission indicated that a transmission 
    provider may reserve in its calculation of ATC transmission capacity 
    necessary to accommodate native load growth reasonably forecasted in 
    its planning horizon.292
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \292\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,745; mimeo at 323-24.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        This issue is discussed in Section IV.C.5. (Reservation of 
    Transmission Capacity for Future Use by Utility).
    b. Reservation Priority for Firm Point-to-Point and Network Service
        In the Final Rule, in response to concerns that network service 
    should have a reservation priority over point-to-point service because 
    of pricing differences, the Commission allowed utilities the 
    opportunity to eliminate the differences in pricing between network and 
    point-to-point services by permitting utilities to adopt point-to-point 
    reservations as the customer load.293 The Commission explained 
    that utilities are free to propose a single cost allocation method for 
    the two services.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \293\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,746-47; mimeo at 326-29.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In addition, the Commission provided that reservations for short-
    term firm point-to-point service (less than one year) will be 
    conditional until one day before the commencement of daily service, one 
    week before the commencement of weekly service, and one month before 
    the commencement of monthly service. According to the Commission, these 
    conditional reservations may be displaced by competing requests for 
    longer-term firm point-to-point service. The Commission explained that 
    after the deadline, the reservation becomes unconditional, and the 
    service would be entitled to the same priorities as any long-term 
    point-to-point or network firm service.
        Moreover, the Commission explained that the Final Rule pro forma 
    tariff does not propose point-to-point or network service with various 
    degrees of firmness beyond the simple categories of firm and non-firm. 
    It explained that when a customer requests firm transmission service, 
    reservation priorities are established based first on availability, and 
    in the event the system is constrained, based on duration of the 
    underlying firm service request--customers may choose the ``firmness'' 
    of service they want by electing to take non-firm service, or by 
    reserving and paying for firm service.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        NRECA and TDU Systems declare that provisions making reservations 
    for short-term firm point-to-point service conditional will not reduce 
    the incentive to cream skim, i.e., a customer has an incentive to 
    submit reservations for very short terms without fear of not getting 
    service because it can always increase its request to match another 
    longer request. They suggest an alternative: all native load, network, 
    and long-term firm (one year or more) requests would be given priority 
    over short-term firm requests, which would have priority over non-firm 
    requests.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Final Rule has sufficiently minimized the potential for cream 
    skimming. Further, we note that the alternative proposed by NRECA & TDU 
    Systems has substantially been adopted in Order No. 888. Specifically, 
    Order No. 888 provides: (1) public utilities the right to reserve 
    existing transmission capacity needed for native load growth and 
    network transmission customer load growth,294 and (2) existing 
    transmission customers the right of first refusal.295 The only 
    entities not covered above--potential long-term firm customers--must 
    submit their service applications as far in advance as practicable.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \294\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,694; mimeo at 172.
        \295\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,665 and 31,694; mimeo at 88 & 
    172.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    c. Reservation Priorities for Non-firm Service
        In the Final Rule, the Commission found that network economy 
    purchases should have a reservation priority over non-firm point-to-
    point and secondary point-to-point uses of the transmission 
    system.296
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \296\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,748; mimeo at 332-33.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
     Rehearing Requests
    
        North Jersey argues that non-firm service should be allocated on a 
    first-come, first-served basis, and where multiple customers request 
    service at the same time, available capacity should be allocated on a 
    pro rata basis. It asserts that the proposed priority system based on 
    duration of non-firm service would simply encourage non-firm customers 
    to request service for longer durations than needed.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We reject North Jersey's argument that the proposed priority system 
    based on duration of non-firm service would encourage non-firm 
    customers to request service for longer durations than needed. North 
    Jersey ignores the fact that section 14.2 of the pro forma tariff 
    establishes a right for eligible customers with existing non-firm 
    reservations to match any longer term reservation before being 
    preempted.
        A related matter is discussed in Section IV.G.3.b below.
    3. Curtailment and Interruption Provisions 297
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \297\ In the Final Rule pro forma tariff, the Commission defines 
    curtailment as: ``A reduction in firm or non-firm transmission 
    service in response to a transmission capacity shortage as a result 
    of system reliability conditions.'' (pro forma tariff section 1.7). 
    The pro forma tariff defines interruption as: ``A reduction in non-
    firm service due to economic reasons pursuant to Section 14.7.'' 
    (pro forma tariff section 1.15). The distinction between curtailment 
    and interruption may have been blurred in Order No. 888 and this 
    order attempts to clarify that distinction.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    a. Pro-Rata Curtailment Provisions
        In the Final Rule, the Commission found that curtailment on a pro-
    rata basis is appropriate for curtailing transactions that 
    substantially relieve a
    
    [[Page 12334]]
    
    constraint.298 The Commission explicitly allowed the transmission 
    provider discretion to curtail the services, whether firm or non-firm, 
    that substantially relieve the constraint.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \298\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,749; mimeo at   335-36.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission also indicated that it would consider granting 
    deference to an alternative curtailment method to avoid hydro spill if 
    such a regional practice is generally accepted and adhered to across 
    the region.
        The Commission further found that under network and point-to-point 
    service, the transmission provider may propose a rate treatment 
    (penalty provision) to apply in the event a customer fails to curtail 
    service as required under the Final Rule pro forma tariff and indicated 
    that such proposals will be evaluated on a case-by-case basis on 
    compliance.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        PA Com asserts that pro rata curtailment fails to hold native load 
    harmless to the extent practical as required by the FPA. PA Com points 
    out that on January 19, 1994, PJM initiated pro-rata load shedding, in 
    part to preserve economic transactions, leaving customers in 
    Pennsylvania without power during a record cold spell.
        VA Com argues that pro rata curtailment may harm native load 
    customers and section 206 complaints are after the fact and of little 
    assistance to native load. VA Com argues that curtailment priority (in 
    order of curtailment) should be: non-firm, contract firm, and then 
    native load, and that utilities should have flexibility to curtail on a 
    pro-rata basis within classes, subject to state curtailment policy.
        Several entities argue that provision must be made for preference 
    in curtailment priorities obtained through settlement, through payment 
    of good and valuable consideration, or under existing transmission 
    contracts.299 Turlock argues that customers should be able to 
    obtain a variation from the pro rata scheme if they can show that they 
    have made either past or future investments to improve constrained 
    facilities and that the quid pro quo for their investment is improved 
    curtailment priority.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \299\ E.g., Santa Clara, Redding, TANC.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Allegheny asks the Commission to clarify that it did not intend to 
    require public utilities to shed (through pro rata curtailment) native 
    transmission load customers in order to preserve some portion of 
    service to through system users of the grid. According to Allegheny, 
    the FPA mandates that service reliability to franchise customers must 
    be maintained and through-system users are not similarly situated to 
    native transmission load customers and should not be treated the same 
    in an emergency because through system customers can protect 
    themselves, but native transmission load customers cannot. Allegheny 
    adds that failure to maintain system reliability would violate section 
    211 of the FPA.
        CCEM asserts that hard and fast priority rules are needed to 
    prevent inconsistent rules from developing for different utilities, 
    pools, or control areas.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Assertions that the pro-rata curtailment provision in the tariff 
    may harm native load customers are misplaced. The Commission clarified 
    in the Final Rule that it was not requiring a pro-rata curtailment of 
    all transactions at the time of a constraint, but rather curtailment of 
    those transactions, whether firm or non-firm, that effectively relieve 
    the constraint.300 The Commission also required that such 
    curtailments be made on a non-discriminatory basis, including the 
    transmission provider's own wholesale use of the system. The Commission 
    further explained that the pro-rata curtailment provision was intended 
    to apply to situations where multiple transactions could be curtailed 
    to relieve a constraint. Of course, if curtailment of multiple 
    transactions is necessary, non-firm service would be curtailed prior to 
    firm service. However, the Commission established that, in emergencies, 
    the transmission provider had the discretion to interrupt firm service 
    under the tariff to ensure the reliability of its transmission system.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \300\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,749; mimeo at 335.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In terms of reliability, we believe that sufficient safeguards have 
    been established to protect native load. In particular, the 
    transmission provider is responsible for planning and maintaining 
    sufficient transmission capacity to safely and reliably serve its 
    native load. Order Nos. 888 and 889 permit the transmission provider to 
    reserve, in its calculation of ATC, sufficient capacity to serve native 
    load.
        Allegations that a utility did not curtail on a non-discriminatory 
    basis, but instead favored a certain class of customer or type of 
    transaction should be filed in a section 206 complaint proceeding to be 
    reviewed on a case-specific basis. While it is true that such 
    complaints will be processed on an after-the-fact basis, it is only on 
    a fact-specific basis that such complaints can be fully and adequately 
    reviewed.
        Additionally, tariff section 14.7 does in fact establish that for 
    curtailment purposes, non-firm point-to-point transmission shall be 
    subordinate to firm transmission service and non-firm service may also 
    be interrupted for economic reasons. However, adopting curtailment 
    schemes based solely on classes of service, as proposed by the VA Com, 
    is inappropriate. Specifically, VA Com's proposal to curtail all non-
    firm transmission transactions prior to firm transactions could 
    exacerbate an emergency situation. For example, a curtailment could be 
    necessary due to a constraint affecting northbound transactions. 
    However, curtailing all non-firm transactions, including southbound 
    transactions (or counterflows), could worsen the situation. 
    Accordingly, the Commission believes the approach established in the 
    Final Rule of allowing non-discriminatory curtailments of the 
    transaction(s) that effectively relieve(s) the constraint is 
    appropriate.
        In response to CCEM's concerns regarding the potential for 
    inconsistent rules for different utilities, pools or control areas, the 
    Commission explained in the Final Rule that any proposed deviations 
    from the non-price terms and conditions of the pro forma tariff, such 
    as regional practices, must be adequately supported by the utility 
    proposing the change.
        Finally, Order No. 888 did not abrogate existing contracts; 
    301 therefore, customers with unique curtailment priorities 
    established by pre-existing contracts would not have these priorities 
    eliminated for the term of the existing contract.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \301\ We note that in Order No. 888 we partially modified 
    existing economy energy coordination agreements. FERC Stats. & Regs. 
    at 31,666; mimeo at 91.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    b. Curtailment and Interruption Provisions for Non-firm Service
        In the Final Rule, the Commission explained that it had clarified 
    in the pro forma tariff that a network customer's economy purchases 
    have a higher priority than non-firm point-to-point transmission 
    service (citing AES Power, Inc. 302). 303
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \302\ 69 FERC para. 61,145 at 62,300 (1994) (proposed order), 74 
    FERC para. 61,220 (1996) (final order).
        \303\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,750; mimeo at 338-39.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission also revised the pro forma tariff to allow the 
    transmission provider to curtail non-firm service for reliability 
    reasons or to interrupt the service for economic reasons (i.e., in 
    order to accommodate (1) a request for
    
    [[Page 12335]]
    
    firm transmission service, (2) a request for non-firm service of 
    greater duration, (3) a request for non-firm transmission service of 
    equal duration with a higher price, or (4) transmission service for 
    economy purchases by network customers from non-designated resources). 
    The Commission further explained that a firm point-to-point customer's 
    use of transmission service at secondary points of receipt and delivery 
    will continue to have the lowest priority.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        For comparability, CCEM asserts that secondary receipt points 
    should be made subordinate to other firm services, 304 but should 
    have priority over non-firm point-to-point transactions. CCEM also 
    argues that non-firm point-to-point service, once scheduled, should not 
    be interrupted to accommodate non-firm service for a network service 
    economy purchase.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \304\ A firm point-to-point customer has a right to change its 
    receipt points if capacity is available. These changed receipt 
    points are known as secondary receipt points. The issue addressed 
    here is the priority that is assigned to those secondary receipt 
    points.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        VT DPS argues that firm flexible point-to-point service over 
    secondary points of receipt and delivery should have a priority over 
    non-firm point-to-point service (citing sections 14.2 and 14.7 of the 
    pro forma tariff). It argues that this priority is necessary to reflect 
    the fact that point-to-point customers pay for firm service and to be 
    consistent with the treatment of network customers. VT DPS notes that 
    in the natural gas industry the Commission has found that such priority 
    is essential to reflect the fact that firm customers are paying for 
    firm service (citing Order No. 636-B).
        APPA asks the Commission to clarify the conditions under which the 
    Commission will allow non-firm service to be interrupted by the 
    transmission provider solely for economic reasons. APPA claims that 
    this clarification is needed so as to prevent interruption of service 
    on a discriminatory basis.
        CCEM states that non-firm point-to-point transmission service does 
    not provide the user with a specific capacity reservation, and 
    therefore such service should bear no reservation or demand-like 
    charges and the customer should pay a commodity-only charge only for 
    when the service is being provided. 305 It contends, for example, 
    that if a customer schedules one week of weekly non-firm transmission 
    service and is interrupted on the second day of service, the customer 
    should only pay for the service it used and should have no 
    responsibility to take or to pay for service for the remainder of the 
    week. Alternatively, it argues that if there are reservation charges 
    and the non-firm customer pays for service on a ``take-or pay basis'' 
    regardless of use, non-firm service should not be subject to being 
    bumped once service is scheduled and power is flowing. Moreover, if the 
    non-firm point-to-point transmission customer does pay reservation 
    charges on a ``take-or-pay basis,'' the non-firm reserved capacity 
    should be tradeable in a secondary market.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \305\ See also Tallahassee.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We reject CCEM's proposal to prevent scheduled non-firm 
    transmission service from being interrupted to accommodate economy 
    purchases for network customers. Non-firm service is provided on an 
    interruptible basis. To the extent CCEM wishes to obtain service that 
    cannot be interrupted to accommodate other transactions, it has the 
    option of requesting firm service in the form of either network or 
    point-to-point transmission service.
        APPA's concerns have already been addressed by the Commission. In 
    the Final Rule, the Commission specifically listed the economic reasons 
    that a transmission provider could interrupt non-firm point-to-point 
    transmission to include:
    
    accommodat[ing] (1) a request for firm transmission service, (2) a 
    request for non-firm service of greater duration, (3) a request for 
    non-firm transmission service of equal duration with a higher price, 
    or (4) transmission service for economy purchases by network 
    customers from non-designated resources.[306]
    
        \306\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,750; mimeo at 338.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        CCEM's arguments are misplaced in that they focus on the specific 
    rate (including any potential credits for service interruption) that 
    utilities may propose for non-firm point-to-point transmission service. 
    Order No. 888 did not mandate any pricing methodology to be used for 
    non-firm point-to-point transmission service. Rather, the Commission 
    established the minimum non-price terms and conditions necessary to 
    ensure comparable service. As the Commission explained in the Final 
    Rule, utilities are free to propose any rates for non-firm point-to-
    point transmission in a section 205 filing consistent with the 
    Commission's Transmission Pricing Policy Statement.307 However, 
    the Commission will evaluate the appropriateness of such proposed rates 
    against the non-price terms and conditions established in the pro forma 
    tariff or other non-price terms and conditions proposed and fully 
    supported by the utility.308
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \307\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,769-70; mimeo at 395-99.
        \308\ We note that CCEM has pursued these arguments (raised on 
    rehearing) in utility-specific rate cases and its objections will be 
    addressed there.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission has previously addressed VT DPS' point.309 Non-
    firm point-to-point customers pay for non-firm service as their 
    service. Firm point-to-point customers, on the other hand, contract and 
    reserve a specified amount of service over designated points of receipt 
    and delivery. The Commission permitted these firm point-to-point 
    customers to use secondary non-firm service (from points of receipt/
    delivery other than those designated in their service agreement) on an 
    as-available basis at no additional charge. Because the firm point-to-
    point customers taking secondary non-firm are accorded this scheduling 
    flexibility at no additional charge, they are properly accorded a lower 
    priority than stand alone, non-firm transmission. In contrast, network 
    customers are responsible for paying for a percentage of total system 
    transmission costs in order to serve their designated network loads 
    whether the energy is from designated network resources or from non-
    designated resources on an as-available basis.310 Because the 
    network customer pays a load-ratio share of total transmission costs, 
    it receives a higher priority. Significantly, if any firm point-to-
    point customer wants to avail itself of the higher priority associated 
    with economy energy purchases under the network tariff, it is free to 
    do so by undertaking the cost responsibilities associated with network 
    service.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \309\ See FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,750; mimeo at 338, and AES 
    Power, Inc., 69 FERC para. 61,145 at 62,300 (1994) (proposed order), 
    74 FERC para. 61,220 (1996) (final order).
        \310\ This is comparable to the service a utility provides its 
    native load.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Finally, in response to VT DPS, we note that we have chosen 
    different approaches in the electric and natural gas areas. In this 
    regard, we recognize that there is a trade-off between encouraging 
    tradable capacity rights versus maximizing revenues that can be 
    credited against the transmission provider's costs of providing 
    transmission service. On the electric side, fully developed 
    transmission capacity trading rights simply do not exist at this time, 
    and so we have chosen to emphasize an approach that maximizes revenues 
    to be credited to transmission customers. However, we will continue to 
    evaluate our approach in the context of any future transmission rate 
    proposal that is based on the concept of tradable capacity rights.
    
    [[Page 12336]]
    
    4. Reciprocity Provision
        In the Final Rule, the Commission concluded that it was appropriate 
    to require a reciprocity provision in the pro forma tariff.311 The 
    Commission explained that this provision will be applicable to all 
    customers, including non-public utility entities such as municipally-
    owned entities and RUS cooperatives, that own, control or operate 
    interstate transmission facilities and that take service under the open 
    access tariff, and any affiliates of the customer that own, control or 
    operate interstate transmission facilities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \311\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,760-63; mimeo at 370-378.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission developed a voluntary safe harbor procedure under 
    which non-public utilities would be allowed to submit to the Commission 
    a transmission tariff and a request for declaratory order that the 
    tariff meets the Commission's comparability (non-discrimination) 
    standards. The Commission explained that if it finds that a tariff 
    contains terms and conditions that substantially conform or are 
    superior to those in the Final Rule pro forma tariff, it will deem it 
    an acceptable reciprocity tariff and require public utilities to 
    provide open access service to that non-public utility.
        If a non-public utility chooses not to seek a Commission 
    determination that its tariff meets the Commission's comparability 
    standards, the Commission declared that a public utility could refuse 
    to provide open access transmission service. However, any such denial 
    must be based on a good faith assertion that the non-public utility has 
    not met the Commission's reciprocity requirements.
        In support of its decision to adopt a reciprocity provision, the 
    Commission explained that it was not requiring non-public utilities to 
    provide transmission access, but was conditioning the use of public 
    utilities' open access services on an agreement to offer open access 
    services in return. The Commission noted that non-public utilities can 
    choose not to take service under public utility open access tariffs and 
    can instead seek voluntary service from the public utility on a 
    bilateral basis.
        The Commission further explained that the reciprocity requirement 
    strikes an appropriate balance by limiting its application to 
    circumstances in which the non-public utility seeks to take advantage 
    of open access on a public utility's system. However, the Commission 
    recognized that Congress has determined that certain entities in the 
    bulk power market can use tax-exempt financing by issuing bonds that do 
    not constitute ``private activity bonds'' 312 or by financing 
    facilities with ``local furnishing'' bonds.313 The Commission 
    stated that it was not its purpose to disturb Congress' and the IRS's 
    determinations with respect to tax-exempt financing. Therefore, the 
    Commission clarified that reciprocal service will not be required if 
    providing such service would jeopardize the tax-exempt status of the 
    transmission customer's (or its corporate affiliates') bonds used to 
    finance such transmission facilities.314
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \312\ See 26 U.S.C. Sec. 141. Interest on private activity bonds 
    is taxable unless the bonds are qualified bonds for which a specific 
    exception is included in the Internal Revenue Code.
        \313\ See 26 U.S.C. Sec. 142.
        \314\ The Commission also clarified that reciprocal service will 
    not be required if providing such service would jeopardize a G&T 
    cooperative's tax-exempt status.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        With respect to local furnishing bonds, which are available to a 
    handful of public utilities, the Commission noted that Congress, in 
    section 1919 of the Energy Policy Act, amended section 142(f) of the 
    Internal Revenue Code to provide that a facility shall not be treated 
    as failing to meet the local furnishing requirement by reason of 
    transmission services ordered by the Commission under section 211 of 
    the FPA if ``the portion of the cost of the facility financed with tax-
    exempt bonds is not greater than the portion of the cost of the 
    facility which is allocable to the local furnishing of electric 
    energy.'' 315 So that any local furnishing bonds that may exist do 
    not interfere with the effective operation of an open access 
    transmission regime, the Commission required any public utility that is 
    subject to the Open Access Rule that has financed transmission 
    facilities with local furnishing bonds to include in its tariff a 
    similar provision that it will not contest the issuance of an order 
    under section 211 of the FPA requiring the provision of such service, 
    and will, within 10 days of receiving a written request by the 
    applicant, file with the Commission a written waiver of its rights to a 
    request for reciprocal service from the applicant under section 213(a) 
    of the FPA and to the issuance of a proposed order under section 
    212(c).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \315\ 26 U.S.C. Sec. 142(f)(2)(A).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In addition, the Commission limited the reciprocity requirement to 
    the applicant and corporate affiliates. The Commission explained that 
    if a G&T cooperative seeks open access transmission service from the 
    transmission provider, then only the G&T cooperative, and not its 
    member distribution cooperatives, would be required to offer 
    transmission service. However, if a member distribution cooperative 
    itself receives transmission service from the transmission provider, 
    then it (but not its G&T cooperative) must offer reciprocal 
    transmission service over any interstate transmission facilities that 
    it may own, control or operate.
        Furthermore, the Commission explained that a non-public utility, 
    for good cause shown, may file a request for waiver of all or part of 
    the reciprocity requirement.
        The Commission also explained that the reciprocity requirement will 
    apply to any entity that owns, controls or operates interstate 
    transmission facilities that uses a marketer or other intermediary to 
    obtain access. The Commission added that it would apply the same 
    criteria to waive the reciprocity condition for small non-public 
    utilities as for small public utilities.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
    Reciprocity Provision--Public Power Position
    
        A number of public power entities argue that the reciprocity 
    provision should be eliminated because the Commission cannot require 
    indirectly what it cannot require directly.316 Several other 
    public power entities add that the reciprocity obligation is beyond the 
    jurisdiction of the Commission because the transmission obligations of 
    non-public utilities (e.g., municipal utilities) are established and 
    limited to those required by sections 211 and 212 of the FPA.317 
    Tallahassee asserts that the Commission's conditioning approach has the 
    effect of excluding an entire class of transmission customer from open 
    access, i.e., those unable to grant reciprocal service. This, 
    Tallahassee asserts, is discriminatory and contrary to the purpose of 
    the Final Rule and the requirements of sections 205, 206 and 212 of the 
    FPA. TANC argues that the Commission does not have the discretion to 
    grant or withhold open access transmission on the condition that the 
    customer consent to doing something that the Commission admits it 
    cannot directly order: ``The Commission has never `conditioned' its 
    duty to allow only just and reasonable rates on any action by the 
    customer.'' (TANC at 16).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \316\ E.g., NRECA, Oglethorpe, AEC & SMEPA, TANC.
        \317\ E.g., Redding, Tallahassee, TANC, Dairyland.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A number of entities challenge the Commission's assertion that the 
    reciprocity requirement for non-public
    
    [[Page 12337]]
    
    utilities is voluntary.318 Dairyland contends that the alternative 
    of seeking a bilateral agreement is illusory--even if it could be 
    obtained--because Order No. 888 provides that any bilateral wholesale 
    coordination agreement executed after July 9, 1996 will be subject to 
    open access requirements. Dairyland argues that the phrase ``subject to 
    open access requirements'' presumably would include the reciprocity 
    requirement for non-public utilities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \318\ E.g., NRECA, Dairyland, TDU Systems, AEC & SMEPA.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        AEC & SMEPA assert that there is no record support for the 
    contention that non-public utilities are responsible for closed systems 
    or that such systems, if any, have an impact on the market.
        NRECA asserts that if the reciprocity provision is retained, the 
    Commission should ``modify its terms to incorporate the statutory 
    standards and protections which FPA sections 211 and 212 contain.'' 
    319
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \319\ NRECA at 29. NRECA specifically lists the following: 
    reliability of electric service; impairment of contracts; ability to 
    cease service; all costs associated with the service must be 
    recovered; retail marketing areas; and prohibitions on retail 
    wheeling and sham wholesale transactions. See also Oglethorpe.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Umatilla Coop asks the Commission to clarify that distribution 
    cooperatives will not become subject to the reciprocity requirements 
    merely because they purchase power from affiliated cooperatives that 
    are acting as power marketers. TDU Systems assert that a cooperative 
    should not have to render reciprocal service if it would interfere with 
    its ability to obtain RUS loan financing.
        TAPS declares that the transmission provider alone should not have 
    access to third-party systems through reciprocity. It maintains that 
    the utility's long-term transmission customers should also be afforded 
    access to those third-party systems so that the transmission provider 
    does not have a competitive advantage. TAPS argues that a third-party 
    should be required to have an open access tariff available.
    
    Reciprocity Provision--Utility Position
    
        A number of utilities argue that the exemption from reciprocity for 
    distribution cooperatives should be eliminated.320 EEI and 
    Montana-Dakota Utilities assert that G&Ts could eliminate their 
    reciprocity obligation by selling or transferring their transmission 
    facilities to their distribution owner/members. Southwestern argues 
    that the exception for distribution cooperatives puts public utilities 
    at a competitive disadvantage in that distribution cooperatives can use 
    a public utility's system to compete with the public utility, but a 
    public utility cannot use the distribution cooperatives' systems to 
    compete to sell power to their customers.321 It adds that the 
    exception allows distribution cooperatives to hide behind shell G&Ts. 
    For example, Southwestern argues that Golden Spread Electric 
    Cooperative is a shell G&T because it owns only small amounts of 
    facilities. It concludes that reciprocal access may become especially 
    important if a state implements a retail access plan because section 
    211 cannot be used to obtain transmission for retail access over a 
    distribution cooperative's system.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \320\ E.g., EEI, Entergy, Montana-Dakota Utilities, 
    Southwestern, Oklahoma E&G, Southern.
        \321\ See also Oklahoma E&G.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Southern claims that cooperatives have argued in courts and in 
    Congress that a G&T cooperative and its distribution cooperative owners 
    are unified economic interests in which the interest of the whole is 
    equal to the sum of the parts, and that federal courts have upheld this 
    view (citing one case--City of Morgan City v. South Louisiana Electric 
    Cooperative Ass'n, 49 F.3d 1074 (5th Cir. 1995) (Morgan City)).
        EEI claims that clarification of certain aspects of reciprocity is 
    needed: (1) public utilities may not be able to determine if reciprocal 
    service is comparable because non-public utilities do not have to 
    provide Form 1 data, and thus non-public utilities should be required 
    to submit additional data; (2) non-public utilities should be required 
    to functionally unbundle, charge rates to themselves and others that 
    reflect the cost of using the system themselves, comply with the 
    standards of conduct, and establish an OASIS; (3) non-public utility 
    members of an RTG should be required to offer reciprocal service 
    comparable to that provided by public utility members; and (4) a non-
    public utility should be required to provide all services it is 
    reasonably capable of providing. Carolina P&L adds that a customer 
    should be required to provide the full panoply of transmission services 
    that it is capable of providing because the customer has a right to 
    take any type of service from the transmission provider even though it 
    may only choose one particular service.
        Tucson Power asks the Commission to clarify how it will determine 
    the comparability of a non-public utility's tariff. It asserts that 
    first, under the safe harbor option, the Commission should clarify (1) 
    that non-public utilities must comply with the Commission's rules of 
    practice and procedure, and (2) how it will determine that the rates, 
    terms and conditions of the reciprocal service are comparable to the 
    service the non-public utility provides itself (Tucson Power argues 
    that this could require submittal of data comparable to that contained 
    in Form 1). Second, the Commission should eliminate the option that 
    would require the public utility to determine whether the request by 
    the non-public utility is consistent with the tariff. Finally, under 
    the RTG option, the Commission should clarify that the evidentiary 
    requirements for non-public utilities that are members of an RTG will 
    be the same as for non-public utilities using the safe harbor 
    procedure, i.e., any disputes regarding compliance should be resolved 
    by the Commission, not the RTG.
        A number of utilities assert that the Commission should not limit 
    the right to obtain reciprocity only to the public utility that 
    provides the transmission service because power could actually flow 
    over other public utilities' transmission lines. They argue that the 
    Commission should ensure that open access transmission is as widely 
    available as possible.322 EEI asserts that Federal power marketing 
    agencies, including BPA, should be required to provide comparable open 
    access transmission.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \322\ E.g., Montana-Dakota Utilities, Southern, EEI.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Oklahoma G&E argues that Order No. 888 violates the Constitution's 
    equal protection principles because it does not require universal open 
    access. It asserts that the Commission has created an arbitrary 
    distinction between classes of utilities that is unrelated to the 
    Commission's objective and therefore is constitutionally invalid. 
    Oklahoma G&E contends that the proper approach is to proceed under 
    EPAct for all transmitting utilities on a case-by-case basis.
        Detroit Edison asks the Commission to clarify that the supplier and 
    the recipient of power are direct beneficiaries and must be considered 
    transmission customers for reciprocity purposes. Otherwise, Detroit 
    Edison contends, parties from jurisdictional transmission transactions 
    may be able to evade reciprocity.
    
    Reciprocity Provision--Other Arguments
    
        CCEM argues that reciprocity should be expanded to require a 
    transmission customer obtaining open access service also to provide 
    open-access transmission service to all eligible customers. Otherwise, 
    CCEM maintains, transmission owners will be able to penetrate into 
    wholesale markets controlled by non-public utilities, but power 
    marketers will not.
    
    [[Page 12338]]
    
        CCEM asks the Commission to clarify that when a non-public utility 
    obtains open access from a power pool, member of a power pool, or 
    parties to some form of bilateral coordination agreement, its 
    reciprocity obligation extends to all eligible customers, including all 
    members of the pool or parties to the agreement.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We continue to believe that it is appropriate to condition the use 
    of public utility open access tariffs on the agreement of the tariff 
    user to provide reciprocal access to the transmission provider. No 
    eligible customer, including a non-public utility, that takes advantage 
    of non-discriminatory open access transmission tariff services should 
    be allowed to deny service or otherwise discriminate against the open 
    access provider. As we explained in the Final Rule,
    
    [n]on-public utilities, whether they are selling power from their 
    own generation facilities or reselling purchased power, have the 
    ability to foreclose their customers' access to alternative power 
    sources, and to take advantage of new markets in the traditional 
    service territories of other utilities. While we do not take issue 
    with the rights these non-public utilities may have under other 
    laws, we will not permit them open access to jurisdictional 
    transmission without offering comparable service in return. We 
    believe the reciprocity requirement strikes an appropriate balance 
    by limiting its application to circumstances in which the non-public 
    utility seeks to take advantage of open access on a public utility's 
    system.[323]
    
        \323\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,762; mimeo at 374.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Contrary to arguments raised on rehearing, we are not requiring 
    non-public utilities to provide transmission access. Instead, we are 
    conditioning the use of public utility open access tariffs, by all 
    customers including non-public utilities, on an agreement to offer 
    comparable (not unduly discriminatory) services in return.324 It 
    would not be in the public interest to allow a non-public utility to 
    take non-discriminatory transmission service from a public utility at 
    the same time it refuses to provide comparable service to the public 
    utility. This would restrict the operation of robust competitive 
    markets and would harm the very ratepayers that Congress has charged us 
    to protect. Very simply, we refuse to take a head-in-the-sand approach 
    and order a remedy for undue discrimination that will permit the 
    beneficiaries of the remedy to engage in unduly discriminatory actions.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \324\ As discussed infra, non-public utilities may seek a waiver 
    of the reciprocity condition. We therefore reject Tallahassee's 
    argument that we are excluding an entire class of transmission 
    customer from open access, i.e., those unable to grant reciprocal 
    service. If the Commission determines that a particular customer 
    truly is not able to reciprocate, the reciprocity condition can be 
    waived. These situations are obviously different from situations 
    involving entities that do not wish to provide reciprocal service.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Moreover, non-public utilities are free to seek from a public 
    utility a waiver of the open access tariff reciprocity condition. We 
    note that this is a modification of our statements in Order No. 888, in 
    which we said that non-public utilities could seek a voluntary offer of 
    transmission service from a public utility on a bilateral basis. Since 
    the time Order No. 888 issued, we have concluded that except in unusual 
    circumstances, public utility services should be provided pursuant to 
    the open access tariff and not pursuant to separate bilateral 
    agreements.325 This applies to all customers, including non-public 
    utilities. Therefore, rather than requesting a bilateral agreement in 
    order to avoid the reciprocity condition, non-public utilities instead 
    may ask a utility for a waiver of the reciprocity condition in the 
    utility's open access tariff. We disagree with Dairyland that this type 
    of alternative approach is illusory. If the public utility chooses 
    voluntarily to grant a waiver, the reciprocity condition would not 
    apply.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \325\ See Public Service Electric & Gas Company, 78 FERC para. 
    61,119, slip op. at 4 and n.7 (1997).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We reject NRECA's request that we incorporate in the reciprocity 
    condition the statutory standards and protections of FPA sections 211 
    and 212. NRECA states on rehearing that mandated services to third 
    parties would endanger cooperatives' ability to provide service to 
    members, or increase members' costs. It further states that sections 
    211 and 212 provide substantive protections to ensure continued service 
    to the transmitting utility's own customers, and to avoid their 
    subsidization of services to third parties. NRECA appears to believe 
    that these substantive protections are not provided outside the context 
    of sections 211 and 212. We disagree. We believe the protections that 
    NRECA is seeking are contained in the pro forma tariff and, as required 
    by section 6 of the tariff, the non-public utility must offer its 
    service on similar terms and conditions.326
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \326\ With regard to the basic substantive protections such as 
    reliability, opportunity to recover costs, and the standards for 
    rates, terms and conditions of transmission service, we see no 
    relative distinctions between sections 211 and 212 and sections 205 
    and 206 of the FPA.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We also reject requests that we not grant the exception to 
    reciprocity provided in the Final Rule for distribution cooperatives 
    and joint action agencies. We continue to believe that if a G&T 
    cooperative seeks open access transmission service from the 
    transmission provider, then only the G&T cooperative, and not its 
    member distribution cooperatives, should be required to offer 
    transmission service.327 Without a corporate affiliation between 
    G&T cooperatives and their member distribution cooperatives, we do not 
    believe it is appropriate to apply the reciprocity condition to the 
    member distribution cooperatives. To do so would result in the member 
    distribution cooperatives being bound by their G&T 
    cooperatives.328
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \327\ In response to Southern's citation to Morgan City, while 
    this case provides some background as to the relationship between 
    G&T cooperatives and distribution cooperatives, it in no way 
    suggests that the relationship rises to the level of a corporate 
    affiliation.
        \328\ However, in response to Umatilla Coop, we clarify that to 
    the extent a distribution cooperative purchases power from an 
    affiliated cooperative that is acting as a power marketer, the 
    distribution cooperative will be subject to the reciprocity 
    condition because of the marketing affiliate relationship between 
    the two. Moreover, as we explained in the Final Rule, the 
    reciprocity condition also applies to any entity that owns, controls 
    or operates transmission facilities and that uses a marketer or 
    other intermediary to obtain access. FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,763; 
    mimeo at 378.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Carolina P&L has brought to our attention a possible 
    misunderstanding as to the meaning of comparable transmission service 
    that a non-public utility must agree to provide as a condition of using 
    an open access tariff. Because a non-public utility may choose any type 
    of service from a public utility transmission provider that the 
    transmission provider provides or is capable of providing, we clarify 
    that a non-public utility seeking to take service under the 
    transmission provider's open access tariff must likewise agree to offer 
    to provide the transmission provider any service that the non-public 
    utility provides or is capable of providing on its system in order to 
    satisfy reciprocity. We note that in the Final Rule we explained that 
    ``[a]ny public utility that offers non-discriminatory open access 
    transmission for the benefit of customers should be able to obtain the 
    same non-discriminatory access in return.'' 329 In this regard, 
    because a public utility must have an OASIS and a standard of conduct 
    for employee separation, so must a non-public utility that seeks open 
    access transmission from a public utility.330
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \329\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,760; mimeo at 370.
        \330\ See South Carolina Public Service Authority (Santee 
    Cooper), 75 FERC para. 61,209 (1996); Central Electric Cooperative, 
    Inc., 77 FERC para. 61,076 (1996). Of course, the non-public utility 
    can always seek a waiver of the OASIS and standard of conduct 
    requirements. Such a waiver request will be evaluated under the same 
    criteria applicable to a waiver requests by a public utility.
    
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [[Page 12339]]
    
        At the same time, however, we deny requests to expand the 
    reciprocity condition.331 Although we believe that non-public 
    utilities should provide open access transmission as a matter of 
    policy, to require non-public utilities to offer transmission service 
    to entities other than the public utility transmission providers 
    increases the chances that they could lose tax-exempt status. 
    Accordingly, we have adopted a policy that recognizes the statutory tax 
    restrictions placed on non-public utilities but also balances the 
    fundamental unfairness of requiring a utility to make its facilities 
    available to someone who could use that access to the competitive 
    disadvantage of the utility. Ultimately the public interest is best 
    served by nationwide open access and, if the tax issue is favorably 
    resolved, we may revisit the matter.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \331\ In reaching this conclusion, we note that the electric 
    industry currently conducts business using contract path pricing. If 
    we are presented with a regional proposal for flow-based pricing, we 
    will reconsider whether there is a need to expand reciprocity as 
    requested by certain entities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Moreover, in response to Detroit Edison, we take this opportunity 
    to clarify that reciprocity would apply to a wholesale purchaser if a 
    generation seller obtains transmission service from a public utility to 
    sell to such purchaser and such purchaser owns, operates or controls 
    interstate transmission facilities. The same would be true where the 
    seller owns, operates and controls interstate transmission facilities 
    and the buyer arranges for the transmission service. Just as with 
    marketers or other intermediaries, we do not intend to allow 
    reciprocity to be defeated simply on the basis of whether the seller or 
    buyer requests transmission. Such a result would elevate form over 
    substance.
        With respect to TDU System's assertion that reciprocal service 
    should not have to be rendered if it would interfere with RUS loan 
    financing, we note that we have already indicated that reciprocal 
    service need not be provided if tax-exempt status would be jeopardized. 
    If TDU Systems is arguing that we should not require reciprocal service 
    if RUS attaches such a condition in its regulation of RUS-financed 
    cooperatives, we reject such an argument. Such cooperatives have the 
    option to seek bilateral service agreements.
        We reject EEI's and Tucson Power's argument that non-public 
    utilities must provide Form 1 data in order to provide comparable 
    service. The Form 1 data would be relevant only if the Commission were 
    setting non-public utilities' rates. Such a detailed review is not 
    necessary, however. See Santee Cooper, 75 FERC para. 61,209 (1996). 
    Similarly, there is no need to have non-public utilities follow our 
    Rules of Practice and Procedure to satisfy reciprocity.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
    Safe Harbor/Waiver Provisions
    
        NRECA states that the following issues related to safe harbor 
    status and declaratory order requests need clarification: (1) under 
    what statutory authority is the Commission considering such petitions? 
    (2) what rights do non-public utilities have to obtain review of 
    Commission determinations with which they disagree? (3) how closely 
    will a reciprocal tariff have to conform to Order No. 888 to win 
    approval? (4) will non-public utilities have to pay the standard fee 
    (now $11,550) with a declaratory order petition? 332 and (5) will 
    the Commission allow non-public utilities to include a stranded cost 
    recovery provision similar to section 26 of the pro forma tariff? 
    333
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \332\ NRECA raises comparable questions with respect to waiver 
    procedures.
        \333\ See also TANC.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Oglethorpe asserts that the Commission should not use these 
    procedures to assert jurisdiction over non-public transmitting 
    utilities. Dairyland contends that requiring non-public utilities to 
    invoke declaratory order or waiver proceedings just to assert the clear 
    statutory protections contained in sections 211 and 212 is unwarranted.
        TANC declares that the safe harbor provisions do not cure the 
    problems created by reciprocity. It argues that the safe harbor 
    provision expands the transmission access that must otherwise be 
    offered by non-public utilities, i.e., rather than just providing 
    reciprocal service to the transmission provider, under the safe harbor 
    provision, the non-jurisdictional entity must offer open access to any 
    eligible customers.
        Blue Ridge alleges that the safe harbor and waiver provisions face 
    practical administrative problems. It asserts that a waiver itself will 
    result in disputes and that the application of the waiver principle to 
    non-public utilities is based on questionable statutory authority. It 
    requests that the Commission add the following language to section 6 of 
    the tariff: ``If the Transmission Customer is a non-public utility, the 
    Transmission Provider must demonstrate a need for transmission service 
    from such entity.'' (Blue Ridge at 39).
        TAPS asks that the Commission accord the filing of a waiver 
    application by a small non-public utility system, or inclusion in an 
    application of a sworn statement of inapplicability, the same 
    protections afforded larger non-public utility systems that file under 
    the safe harbor mechanism.
        Arkansas Cities ask the Commission to clarify that ``utilities like 
    Arkansas Cities' members, which do not operate a control area, do not 
    own `transmission' facilities and primarily purchase energy for resale 
    at retail are not subject to the transmission reciprocity condition 
    contained in Order 888, and are also not required to file a request for 
    a waiver from the requirements of Order 888 and 889.'' (Arkansas Cities 
    at 18-19)
        SWRTA and NWRTA ask the Commission to clarify that RTGs have the 
    authority to issue limited waivers of the reciprocity requirements of 
    Order Nos. 888 and 889 to qualifying non-public utility members of 
    RTGs, and that the Commission will accord deference to an RTG's 
    determination with respect to a non-public utility member's request for 
    waiver of, or exemption from, these requirements.334 They note 
    that SWRTA's bylaws have a Commission-approved waiver process and 
    disputes would go to arbitration or to the Commission.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \334\ WRTA supports NWRTA in NWRTA's rehearing request.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Southern and EEI argue that public utilities should have a parallel 
    ``safe harbor''--the right to seek a declaratory order as to whether 
    the transmission service being offered by a non-public utility 
    satisfies its reciprocity obligation.
        Tallahassee asks that the Commission clarify the good faith 
    assertion a public utility must make that the non-public utility has 
    not met the reciprocity requirements. It asserts that the section 211 
    good faith request rules form an appropriate standard by which to 
    measure a good faith assertion.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Several entities raise procedural and jurisdictional concerns with 
    respect to our safe harbor and waiver provisions. At the outset, we 
    emphasize that this Commission does not have jurisdiction over non-
    public utilities under sections 205 and 206 and that the safe harbor 
    mechanism and waiver provisions do not, and indeed cannot, give us such 
    jurisdiction. Rather the safe harbor and waiver procedures are 
    voluntary means for non-public utilities to obtain a Commission 
    determination that they meet the reciprocity condition in the open 
    access tariffs and thereby avoid
    
    [[Page 12340]]
    
    potential delays or denials of open access service based on allegations 
    that the transmission requestor does not meet reciprocity. In Santee 
    Cooper, issued subsequent to the Final Rule, the Commission recognized 
    that it lacks jurisdiction under sections 205 and 206 over transmission 
    rates, terms and conditions offered by non-public utilities, but 
    explained that it has the authority to evaluate non-jurisdictional 
    activities to the extent they affect the Commission's jurisdictional 
    responsibilities.
        We clarify that non-public utilities that disagree with a 
    Commission determination are free to request rehearing of a Commission 
    order, as occurred in Santee Cooper. If aggrieved by the Commission's 
    final order, they may appeal under section 313 of the FPA. Also, with 
    respect to the filing fee a non-public utility entity would have to pay 
    in making a declaratory order request, the Commission in Santee Cooper 
    explained that its regulations specifically exempt states, 
    municipalities and anyone who is engaged in the official business of 
    the Federal Government from filing fees.335 Because of the nature 
    of the safe harbor and waiver provisions, we will also waive the filing 
    fee for declaratory orders for all other non-public utilities in these 
    circumstances.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \335\ 75 FERC at 61,694-95 (citing 18 CFR 381.108).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As to the question of how closely a reciprocal tariff will have to 
    conform to Order No. 888, the Commission determined in Santee Cooper 
    that:
    
        As part of its compliance filing * * * the Authority must submit 
    a single tariff that conforms to the Open Access Rule pro forma 
    tariff.[336]
    
        \336\ 75 FERC at 61,701.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    The Commission further explained that ``[t]he Open Access Rule requires 
    that reciprocity tariffs contain terms and conditions which 
    substantially conform or are superior to those in the Open Access Rule 
    pro forma tariff.'' 337 We clarify, however, that in that case the 
    utility chose to offer an open access tariff, whereas Order No. 888 
    provides, as a condition of service, that reciprocal access be offered 
    to only those transmission providers from whom the non-public utility 
    obtains open access service. Therefore, a non-public utility may so 
    limit the use of any voluntarily offered tariff, as long as the tariff 
    otherwise substantially conforms to the pro forma tariff. We also note 
    that non-public utilities are free to enter into bilateral agreements 
    to satisfy the reciprocity condition. With respect to such bilateral 
    reciprocal agreements, we must leave these agreements to case-by-case 
    determinations. Which terms and conditions may be necessary for a non-
    public utility to provide reciprocal service to the public utility in a 
    bilateral agreement is necessarily a fact-specific matter not 
    susceptible to resolution in a generic rulemaking proceeding. 
    Additionally, we clarify that non-public utilities may include stranded 
    cost recovery provisions in any reciprocity tariffs that they may 
    file.338
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \337\ Id.
        \338\ Because we have not extended the reciprocity condition to 
    rate aspects of a non-public utility's tariff, we would not evaluate 
    any stranded cost recovery mechanism and, as with respect to all 
    terms and conditions of non-jurisdictional tariffs, the Commission 
    is without jurisdiction to enforce such a charge.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In response to TANC's concern that the safe harbor provision 
    expands the transmission access that must otherwise be offered by non-
    public utility entities, and Blue Ridge's concern that the safe harbor 
    and waiver provisions raise practical administrative problems, we 
    emphasize that both of these procedures are purely voluntary and a non-
    public utility can avoid any perceived problems simply by not taking 
    part in either process. We note that several entities have voluntarily 
    availed themselves of these procedures without any apparent 
    hardships.339
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \339\ E.g., Santee Cooper, Omaha Public Power District (filed 
    petition for declaratory order on October 17, 1996, which was 
    docketed as NJ97-2-000), Southern Illinois Power Cooperative (filed 
    petition for declaratory order on October 8, 1996, which was 
    docketed as NJ97-1-000).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Arkansas Cities' various waiver requests are best addressed on a 
    case-by-case basis that permits a full airing of the factual 
    circumstances surrounding each entity seeking a waiver. As we explained 
    in a recent order, ``the Commission will not address waiver requests in 
    a generic rulemaking proceeding, but will require entities seeking 
    waiver of all or part of Order Nos. 888 and 889 to submit separate, 
    fact-specific requests. * * *'' 340
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \340\ 76 FERC para. 61,009 at 61,027 (1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        EEI's and Southern's request that public utilities be provided a 
    parallel ``safe harbor'' (i.e., the right to seek a declaratory order 
    as to whether the transmission service being offered by a non-public 
    utility satisfies its reciprocity obligation) is denied. In the Final 
    Rule, we explained that a public utility may refuse to provide open 
    access transmission service to a non-public utility if its denial is 
    based on a good faith assertion that the non-public utility has not met 
    the Commission's reciprocity requirements. 341 Moreover, a public 
    utility can file a petition to terminate transmission service if a non-
    public utility is violating the reciprocity condition of its open 
    access service agreement with the public utility.342
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \341\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,761; mimeo at 372.
        \342\ For the same reason, we deny Tallahassee's request that we 
    clarify the good faith assertion a public utility must make that the 
    non-public utility has not met the reciprocity condition.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In response to SWRTA and NWRTA's request to clarify that RTGs have 
    the authority to issue limited waivers of the reciprocity conditions of 
    the Order No. 888 pro forma tariffs, we recognize that RTGs have 
    procedures in place to resolve disputes that may arise concerning a 
    non-public utility member's request for service from a public utility 
    member. Because RTGs have these dispute resolution procedures in place, 
    we clarify that RTGs, which are in themselves reciprocal voluntary 
    arrangements, may determine whether to apply reciprocity between and 
    among member public utilities and member non-public utilities, subject 
    to the RTG dispute resolution procedures authorized by this Commission.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
    Retail Wheeling
    
        Dairyland contends that the Commission improperly requires a non-
    public utility to provide retail wheeling if it uses the open access 
    tariff of a public utility that allows retail access either voluntarily 
    or as part of a state-mandated program.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Contrary to Dairyland's contention, nothing in the Final Rule 
    requires a non-public utility to provide retail wheeling. Section 
    212(h) of the FPA explicitly prohibits the Commission from ordering 
    retail transmission directly to an ultimate consumer. If a non-public 
    utility offers reciprocal service, its tariff would have to include the 
    same explicit provision contained in the pro forma tariff, which states 
    that an eligible customer cannot obtain transmission that would violate 
    section 212(h) of the FPA, unless pursuant to a state program that 
    requires the transmission provider to offer such wheeling.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
    OASIS
    
        Southern argues that the Commission should explicitly require that 
    non-public utilities must comply with Order No. 889 as part of the 
    reciprocity obligation.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We agree with Southern and, as discussed above, absent a waiver, 
    will
    
    [[Page 12341]]
    
    require non-public utilities to comply with Order No. 889 as part of 
    the reciprocity obligation.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
    Foreign Entities
    
        In the Open Access Rule, we decided that a foreign entity that 
    otherwise meets the eligibility criteria should be able to obtain 
    service under a United States public utility's open access tariff. 
    However, like United States non-public utilities (which also are not 
    under our section 205-206 jurisdiction), a foreign entity that owns or 
    controls transmission facilities and that takes transmission service 
    under a United States public utility's open access tariff must comply 
    with the reciprocity provision in the tariff.343 The reciprocity 
    provision ensures that when a public utility provides service under its 
    open access tariff to a transmission-owning entity that is not subject 
    to the open access requirement, the public utility will be able to 
    receive service in turn from that entity. In our discussion of the 
    reciprocity provision, we pointed out that if a non-jurisdictional 
    entity that owns or controls transmission does not wish to provide 
    service to the public utility, it can choose not to use the public 
    utility's open access tariff and can instead seek voluntary service 
    from the public utility on a contractual basis.344
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \343\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,689; mimeo at 156.
        \344\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,761; mimeo at 373.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        On rehearing, Ontario Hydro argues that the Commission has 
    ``unilateral[ly] impos[ed]'' the reciprocity requirement on foreign 
    entities in violation of the North American Free Trade Agreement 
    (NAFTA).345 It declares that
    
        \345\ 32-3 Int'l Legal Materials 682 (1993); 19 U.S.C.A. 
    Sec. 3301 et seq. (1995 Supp.)(legislation implementing NAFTA).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [u]nder the principle of national treatment, the citizens of each 
    party to NAFTA * * * are allowed the same market access within 
    another treaty party's market as is provided to the citizens of such 
    other party. A party to these agreements cannot withhold access to 
    its market by conditioning it upon receipt of equal access into the 
    market of another party, because the result would be market access 
    less favorable for the other party * * * than that accorded the 
    party's own citizens. 346
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \346\ Ontario Hydro at 4-7.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Ontario Hydro claims that the Open Access Rule ``makes open access 
    the law of the land for wholesale transmission service within the 
    United States * * *'' and that Canadian entities are thus entitled to 
    such access on an unconditional basis.347 Next, it accuses the 
    Commission of trying to ``coerce'' Canada to ``conform its market 
    access policy'' to United States policy and of ``impos[ing] U.S. 
    regulatory policies'' on Canadian markets.348 Finally, Ontario 
    Hydro argues that even aside from the NAFTA issue, under the FPA the 
    Commission does not have jurisdiction over foreign entities and thus 
    cannot require reciprocity.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \347\ Ontario Hydro at 5.
        \348\ Ontario Hydro at 5, 3.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We disagree with Ontario Hydro's claim that NAFTA's national 
    treatment principle requires us to allow a Canadian transmission-owning 
    entity (or its corporate affiliate) to take advantage of a United 
    States public utility's open access tariff--a tariff we have required 
    the utility to adopt--while simultaneously refusing to allow the United 
    States utility to use the Canadian entity's transmission facilities. 
    NAFTA's national treatment principle requires that each signatory 
    ``accord national treatment to the goods'' of other signatories in 
    accordance with Article III of the General Agreement on Tariffs and 
    Trade (GATT).349 National treatment means that the United States 
    ``must not discriminate between foreign and domestic energy on the 
    basis of nationality * * *'' and that Canadian electricity must be 
    treated ``no less favorabl[y] than U.S. electricity, under all U.S. 
    laws and rules respecting the sale, * * * distribution, and use of * * 
    * electricity.'' Thus, this Commission must accord Canadian energy 
    supplies treatment that is no less favorable than the treatment 
    accorded United States supplies.350 Ontario Hydro's 
    interpretation, however, would twist this principle into a requirement 
    that Canadian entities be treated better than United States entities, 
    including United States non-public utilities that are subject to the 
    reciprocity condition.351
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \349\ NAFTA Article 301, citing GATT, 61 Stat. A5, A18-A19 
    (1947). ``Goods'' under NAFTA include transmission service. NAFTA, 
    Articles 606, 609.
        \350\ Iroquois Gas Transmission System, L.P., et al., 53 FERC 
    para.61,194 at 61,700-01 (1990), aff'd sub nom. Louisiana 
    Association of Independent Power Producers and Royalty Owners v. 
    FERC, 958 F.2d 1101 (D.C. Cir. 1992), quoting United States-Canada 
    Free Trade Agreement Implementation Act of 1988, Report of the 
    Committee on Energy and Commerce, House of Representatives, H.R. 
    Rep. No. 100-816, Part 7, 100th Cong., 2d Sess. at p. 7 (1988). The 
    Free Trade Agreement is a predecessor to NAFTA.
        \351\ We have no section 205-206 jurisdiction over non-public 
    United States utilities, just as we have no jurisdiction over 
    foreign entities. Ontario Hydro's claim that the Open Access Rule 
    ``makes open access the law of the land for wholesale transmission 
    service within the United States'' is wrong; open access is not the 
    law of the land for United States non-public utilities, since we 
    have no section 205-206 jurisdiction over them.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Under Order No. 888, all public utility open access tariffs contain 
    a reciprocity condition that applies to all users of the tariff within 
    the United States, including United States non-public utilities, unless 
    the condition is waived either by the Commission or the public utility 
    provider. Under the reciprocity condition, non-public utilities do not 
    have to offer an open access tariff (i.e., a tariff that offers 
    transmission service to any eligible customer), but rather must offer 
    comparable transmission services only to those transmission providers 
    whose open access tariffs the non-public utility uses.352 The same 
    condition applies to foreign utilities. Thus, Ontario Hydro is in plain 
    error in arguing that application of the reciprocity condition to 
    foreign entities would result in less favorable treatment than that 
    accorded to United States citizens. Ontario Hydro's reading of NAFTA 
    would place transmission-owning Canadian entities (or their corporate 
    affiliates) in a better position than any domestic entity; not only 
    would Canadian entities not be subject to the open access requirement, 
    but, unlike domestic non-public utilities, they would be able to use 
    the open access tariffs we have mandated without providing any 
    reciprocal service. Ontario Hydro has cited no precedent demonstrating 
    that NAFTA imposes such an unreasonable requirement.353
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \352\ United States public utilities, of course, are separately 
    required by Order No. 888 to have on file open access tariffs and 
    thus meet reciprocity through the separate, more stringent open 
    access requirement.
        \353\ Ontario Hydro also complains that the reciprocity 
    obligation of domestic non-public utilities is subject to various 
    limitations and waiver provisions. These provisions apply to foreign 
    entities as well.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Moreover, we are not ``coercing'' Canada into adopting our policies 
    or ``imposing'' open access on Canadian entities; we are simply placing 
    the same condition on a Canadian entity's use of a United States 
    utility's open access tariff as on a domestic non-public utility's use 
    of that tariff. However, consistent with the approach we have taken in 
    other contexts involving foreign utilities seeking to transact in 
    United States electricity markets, we are amenable to a variety of 
    approaches for Canadian utilities to meet the reciprocity 
    condition.354
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \354\ In recent cases involving the mitigation of transmission 
    market power of Canadian utilities that are affiliates of power 
    marketers that seek to sell power at market-based rates in the 
    United States, the Commission has explicitly acknowledged the 
    sovereign authority of Canadian governments over Canadian entities 
    and has said that we will be ``amenable to a variety of approaches'' 
    for foreign utilities to mitigate transmission market power. British 
    Columbia Power Exchange Corporation, 78 FERC para.61,024 (1997); 
    accord, TransAlta Enterprises Corporation, 75 FERC para.61,268 
    (1996) and Energy Alliance Partnership, 73 FERC para.61,019 (1995).
    
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [[Page 12342]]
    
        Ontario Hydro is also wrong in its claim that even aside from 
    NAFTA, we lack authority under the FPA to require reciprocity when a 
    foreign entity wishes to use a domestic utility's open access tariff. 
    Just as we are not asserting jurisdiction over domestic non-public 
    utilities under sections 205 or 206 of the FPA, we also are not 
    asserting jurisdiction over foreign entities. Rather, we are simply 
    placing the same reasonable and fair condition on both types of 
    entities' uses of the transmission ordered in the Final Rule.355
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \355\ EEI and Ontario Hydro note that section 6 of the tariff 
    limits the obligation of foreign utilities to provide reciprocal 
    service to ``facilities used for transmission of electric energy in 
    interstate commerce owned, controlled or operated by the 
    Transmission Customer. . . .'' (EEI at 14). This is inconsistent 
    with the preamble, which says that the reciprocity provision applies 
    to foreign entities (whose transmission facilities may not be 
    ``interstate''). We recognize that the language in section 6 of the 
    pro forma tariff conflicts with the preamble language of the Final 
    Rule. We are modifying section 6 of the tariff accordingly.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
    Unconstitutional as Applied to NE Public Power District
    
        NE Public Power District asserts that the reciprocity provision as 
    applied to NE Public Power District (a public corporation and political 
    and governmental subdivision under Nebraska law) is unconstitutional. 
    It argues that reciprocity would intrude into the sovereignty of 
    Nebraska and would negate the decision of Nebraska's citizens to use 
    their own governmental institutions to provide electric service. 
    Moreover, contrary to the Commission's assertion, NE Public Power 
    District states that it does not have a real choice in deciding whether 
    to use the transmission service of public utilities. Because it is 
    beyond the power of Congress to compel Nebraska to adopt a federally 
    prescribed program for providing its citizens with electric utility 
    services, NE Public Power District argues that it must follow that a 
    federal agency lacks the constitutional and statutory authority to 
    compel a Nebraska state instrumentality to adopt a FERC-drafted tariff 
    and to modify its contracts.
        NE Public Power District states that section 201(f) of the FPA 
    exempts state-owned utilities from the jurisdiction of the Commission 
    and that sections 211-213 are the exclusive means by which the 
    Commission can require non-public utilities to perform involuntary 
    transmission service. It asserts that the Commission should exempt 
    publicly-owned utilities from application of the Final Rule and notes 
    that virtually all non-public utility entities are, or soon will be, 
    voluntary participants in power pools, RTGs, or other similar 
    organizations. Thus, NE Public Power District argues that there is no 
    compelling public interest to require these entities now to submit to 
    the reciprocity provision.
        In addition, NE Public Power District argues that compliance would 
    conflict with Nebraska law and bond covenants, i.e., Nebraska law, for 
    example, does not permit a public entity to agree in advance of a 
    dispute to submit to binding arbitration. NE Public Power District 
    states that it is bound by a bond covenant that prohibits it from 
    rendering service free of charge and requires that a customer's default 
    must be cured within a specific time. It also argues that these 
    requirements are in conflict with section 7.3 of the pro forma tariff.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Under the Supremacy Clause of the Constitution, Nebraska law cannot 
    and does not override this Commission's authorities and 
    responsibilities under the FPA. Rather, this Commission has exclusive 
    jurisdiction over the rates, terms and conditions of transmission in 
    interstate commerce by public utilities, including reciprocity 
    conditions contained in the tariffs of public utilities. Nothing in 
    Order No. 888 compels Nebraska to adopt a ``federally prescribed 
    program.'' While we do not have full jurisdiction over non-public 
    utilities,\356\ our actions in regulating jurisdictional matters may 
    impact those who wish to use jurisdictional services or to enter into 
    agreements with public utilities. The Commission's obligation is to 
    ensure that public utilities' services are just and reasonable and not 
    unduly discriminatory or preferential and non-public utilities can 
    choose to comply or not regarding matters within our exclusive 
    jurisdiction. Moreover, as we explained above, NE Public Power District 
    can seek waiver of the reciprocity condition on a case-by-case basis.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \356\ We do have jurisdiction over many non-public utilities 
    under certain sections of the FPA, e.g., sections 210, 211 and 212.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
    QF Position
    
        American Forest & Paper asks the Commission to clarify that QFs are 
    exempted from the reciprocity requirement or, in the alternative, grant 
    them a blanket waiver. It states that QFs are not allowed to provide 
    transmission service for third parties. Moreover, it asserts that there 
    are unlikely to be many requests for transmission service over a QF's 
    interconnection line and such cases should be handled on a case-by-case 
    basis.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We will not grant QFs an exemption from the reciprocity condition 
    or grant them a blanket waiver, but will address this issue on a case-
    by-case basis if and when it arises. Because most QFs own little 
    transmission, it is not likely that they will be asked to provide 
    reciprocal service.
        Furthermore, in a proceeding involving a QF, we explained that use 
    of a QF's transmission line by a non-QF would not affect its QF status:
    
        It would not fail the ownership test for QF status because, 
    consistent with the requirements of the Public Utility Regulatory 
    Policies Act of 1978 (PURPA), the Oxbow Geothermal facility would 
    continue to be ``owned by a person not primarily engaged in the 
    generation or sale of electric power (other than electric power 
    solely from cogeneration facilities or small power production 
    facilities).'' 16 U.S.C. Sec. 796(18)(B)(1994).[357]
    
        \357\ Oxbow Power Marketing, 76 FERC para. 61,031 at 61,179 
    (1996), reh'g pending. We did note, however, that the QF would 
    become a public utility to the limited extent it provides 
    transmission service over its line on behalf of others.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    If a QF that owns, controls or operates interstate transmission 
    facilities seeks open access transmission from a public utility, it 
    must agree to provide reciprocal service to that public utility. Of 
    course, the QF could file a waiver request in a separate proceeding, as 
    set forth in the Final Rule and clarified in a subsequent order.\358\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \358\ See Order Clarifying Order Nos. 888 and 889 Compliance 
    Matters, 76 FERC para. 61,009 at 61,027 (1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
    Tax-Exempt Financing Issues
    
    Reciprocity and Private Activity Bonds
        EEI asks the Commission to require non-public utilities claiming 
    that their tax status is a bar to granting reciprocity to substantiate 
    such claim in a safe harbor proceeding and to take reasonable measures 
    to request the IRS to allow them to provide reciprocal service while 
    retaining their tax status. If the Commission decides not to require a 
    safe harbor proceeding, EEI requests that the Commission require non-
    public utilities to substantiate their tax concerns and to demonstrate 
    to each public utility from which they seek service that they are 
    actively pursuing
    
    [[Page 12343]]
    
    the issue with the IRS.\359\ It also urges that the Commission require 
    any request for exemption from the reciprocity requirement that is 
    based on jeopardy to tax-exempt status be filed with the Commission as 
    part of a request for declaratory order in a safe harbor proceeding. 
    Moreover, it requests that the Commission require a non-public utility 
    to specifically identify the facilities it cannot use without 
    jeopardizing its tax-exempt financing and to provide copies of, and 
    specifically reference the tax provisions in, the related financing 
    agreements that embody this restriction.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \359\ See also Tucson Power.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Centerior asks that the Commission condition receipt of open access 
    transmission service by municipal utilities upon the elimination or 
    mitigation of tax subsidies and regulatory inequities. Southern 
    maintains that tax-exempt status can remain undisturbed if non-public 
    utilities do not seek open access transmission service from public 
    utilities. Thus, Southern asserts, non-public utilities can weigh the 
    benefits of transmission service under the Final Rule against the 
    potential threat to their tax benefits, and make the choice that serves 
    their best interest. At a minimum, it argues, the Commission should 
    await the determinations of the IRS before finalizing this aspect of 
    the reciprocity provision, rather than confer yet another unique 
    benefit on non-public utilities.\360\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \360\ See also SoCal Edison. It asserts that the Commission 
    should require publicly-owned utilities to provide open access on 
    the same terms as other utilities after a short transitional period 
    that provides an opportunity for the IRS and/or Congress to address 
    the interrelationship between open access transmission and tax-
    exempt financing.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        CAMU asks that the Commission defer reciprocity obligations until 
    the IRS has clarified the status of private use limitations within the 
    context of transmission access. Otherwise, CAMU asserts, innocent 
    investors could suffer penalties because the Commission moved too 
    quickly on this sensitive issue.
    
    Local Furnishing Bonds
    
        Local Furnishing Utilities and ConEd state that section 5.1 of the 
    pro forma tariff applies to ``Transmission Service,'' which is defined 
    in section 1.48 to include point-to-point service, but not network 
    service. They ask the Commission to clarify that the phrase 
    ``transmission service'' also applies to network service.
        Local Furnishing Utilities and ConEd ask that the Commission 
    confirm that all costs associated with the loss of tax-exempt status, 
    including defeasing, redeeming, and refinancing tax-exempt bonds, will 
    be considered costs of providing transmission that must be borne by the 
    customer for whom the transmission is provided. They state that 
    defeasance and refinancing costs are just as attributable to the 
    particular transmission service causing such defeasance or redemption 
    as the costs of expanding the system are attributable to the service 
    that cause the need for such expansion. They ask that the Commission 
    clarify that a transmission provider may include in its tariff a 
    provision permitting the recovery of such costs, even if a filing under 
    section 205 of the FPA is required. ConEd asserts that if a customer 
    does not want to pay costs associated with the loss of tax-exempt 
    status on the bonds, the Commission should allow the transmission 
    provider to decline to provide the requested service.
        Local Furnishing Utilities and ConEd also assert that section 5.2 
    of the pro forma tariff should be clarified to state that issuance of a 
    section 211 order by the Commission is a condition precedent to the 
    provision of transmission service. Local Furnishing Utilities states 
    that there is a question whether the Commission should insist on waiver 
    of the issuance of a proposed order under section 212(c). According to 
    Local Furnishing Utilities, the negotiations that normally would follow 
    the issuance of a proposed order are likely to provide the only 
    opportunity to demonstrate and review the costs associated with the 
    loss of tax-exempt status.
        Local Furnishing Utilities and ConEd assert that sections 5.1 and 
    5.2(i) of the pro forma tariff improperly limit the safe harbor 
    protection of section 1919 of EPAct to transmission providers that 
    financed ``transmission facilities'' with local furnishing bonds. 
    Because of this, they assert, the safe harbor is not available to 
    ConEd, all of whose local furnishing bonds have been used to finance 
    its distribution system. They argue that section 5.1 should apply to 
    service that would jeopardize the tax-exempt status of bonds that 
    finance distribution or generation, as well as transmission, 
    facilities. NE Public Power District contends that section 5.2(ii) 
    should be amended ``to make it clear that interim service need not be 
    begun if rendering the service would endanger the tax-exempt status of 
    the provider's bonds, unless the customer agrees to bear the financial 
    consequences of such loss of tax-exempt status and has the wherewithal 
    to do so.'' (NE Public Power District at 22-23).
        SoCal Edison argues that local furnishing utilities should be 
    required to comply with the Final Rule without any exception based upon 
    their tax-exempt bonds.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
    Private Activity Bonds
    
        As we explained in Order No. 888, it is not our purpose to disturb 
    Congress's and the IRS's determinations with respect to tax-exempt 
    financing. With respect to private activity bonds, we reaffirm our 
    finding that reciprocal service will not be required if providing such 
    service would jeopardize the tax-exempt status of the transmission 
    customer's (or its corporate affiliates') bonds used to finance such 
    transmission facilities. We remain hopeful that the IRS in its private 
    activity bond rulemaking will, to the maximum extent possible, remove 
    regulatory impediments that limit the ability of industry participants 
    to provide reciprocal open access. As we indicated in Order No. 888, 
    after the IRS acts, we will reexamine our policy to ensure that the 
    reciprocity condition is applied broadly to achieve open access without 
    jeopardizing tax-exempt financing.\361\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \361\ We note that on January 10, 1997, the IRS issued final 
    regulations on the definition of private-activity bonds applicable 
    to tax-exempt bonds issued by state and local governments, but 
    reserved section 1.141-7 dealing with output contracts to further 
    consider the issues raised by regulatory changes in the electric 
    power industry. 62 FR 2275 (January 16, 1997).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We will reject the request of EEI and Tucson Power that the 
    Commission require non-public utilities to substantiate in a safe 
    harbor proceeding a claim that their tax status is a bar to granting 
    reciprocity. As we stated in Order No. 888, if a non-public utility has 
    sought a declaratory order on a voluntarily-filed tariff, we request 
    that it identify the services, if any, that it cannot provide without 
    jeopardizing the tax-exempt status of its financing. However, we cannot 
    require that a non-public utility use the safe harbor mechanism, 
    whether to file a reciprocal tariff with the Commission or to 
    substantiate a claim as to loss of tax-exempt status. As we explain 
    above, the safe harbor procedure is a voluntary means for non-public 
    utilities to obtain a Commission determination that they meet the 
    reciprocity condition in the open access tariffs and thereby avoid 
    potential delays or denials of open access service based on allegations 
    that the transmission requestor does not meet reciprocity.
        Nevertheless, just as we believe that it is appropriate to 
    condition the use of public utility open access tariffs on the
    
    [[Page 12344]]
    
    agreement of the tariff user to provide reciprocal access to the 
    transmission provider, we also believe it is appropriate to condition 
    the use of public utility open access tariffs on the agreement of the 
    non-public utility tariff user to substantiate any claim that providing 
    reciprocal transmission service would jeopardize the tax-exempt status 
    of its financing. The non-public utility can provide such 
    substantiation by identifying for the customer the services that it 
    cannot provide without jeopardizing its tax-exempt financing.\362\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \362\ In response to EEI's request that the Commission require a 
    non-public utility to provide copies of, and specifically reference 
    the tax provisions in, the related financing agreements, we note 
    that the level of detail needed to substantiate a non-public 
    utility's claim that providing reciprocal transmission service would 
    jeopardize the tax-exempt status of its financing is likely to 
    depend on the facts of each case. As a result, what will constitute 
    adequate substantiation is properly determined on a case-by-case 
    basis. Additionally, we will reject EEI's request that the 
    Commission require non-public utilities to demonstrate that they are 
    actively pursuing the issue with the IRS. As we explain above, the 
    IRS is currently examining these issues; we in turn will reexamine 
    our policy after the IRS acts to ensure that the reciprocity 
    condition is applied broadly to achieve open access without 
    jeopardizing tax-exempt financing.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Southern suggests that tax-exempt status can remain undisturbed if 
    non-public utilities do not seek open access transmission service from 
    public utilities and, therefore, that non-public utilities can weigh 
    the benefits of transmission service under the Rule against the 
    potential threat to their tax benefits. We believe it is important to 
    remember why we required open access in the first place--as a remedy 
    for undue discrimination in transmission services in interstate 
    commerce. Southern would force a non-public utility to give up a 
    Congressionally-mandated right as a condition to taking open access 
    transmission. Clearly Southern's suggestion is misplaced and 
    overbroad.\363\ For this reason, we believe that our decision not to 
    require reciprocal service if providing such service would jeopardize 
    the non-public utility's tax-exempt financing--pending action by the 
    IRS in its private activity bond rulemaking--is appropriate for the 
    time being.\364\ We reiterate that we will reexamine our policy after 
    the IRS acts. As we state above, we believe that ultimately the public 
    interest is best served by nationwide open access.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \363\ We will reject Centerior's request that the Commission 
    condition receipt of open access transmission service by non-public 
    utilities upon the elimination or mitigation of tax subsidies. As we 
    stated in Order No. 888, Congress has entrusted the IRS with the 
    responsibility for implementing laws governing tax-exempt financing, 
    and it is not this Commission's purpose to disturb Congress's and 
    the IRS's determinations in that regard.
        \364\ In response to CAMU, we note that the Commission has, in 
    effect, deferred--pending IRS action--a non-public utility's 
    reciprocity obligation in cases in which the provision of reciprocal 
    service would jeopardize the tax-exempt status of the non-public 
    utility's financing.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Local Furnishing Bonds
    
        We clarify, in response to Local Furnishing Utilities and ConEd, 
    that the reference to ``Transmission Service'' in section 5.1 of the 
    pro forma tariff was intended to be to ``transmission service,'' and 
    thereby to apply to point-to-point service as well as network service. 
    We have revised section 5.1 accordingly.
        We further clarify that all costs associated with the loss of tax-
    exempt status, including the costs of defeasing, redeeming, and 
    refinancing tax-exempt bonds, are properly considered costs of 
    providing transmission services. Therefore, a customer that takes 
    service, understanding that such service will result in loss of tax-
    exempt status, shall be responsible for such costs to the extent 
    consistent with Commission policy, and a transmission provider may 
    include in its tariff a provision permitting it to seek recovery of 
    such costs. We clarify that if the transmission customer is not willing 
    to pay the costs associated with the transmission provider's loss of 
    tax-exempt status, the transmission provider will not be required to 
    provide the requested service.\365\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \365\ Of course if the transmission provider can provide part of 
    the requested service without jeopardizing tax-exempt status, it 
    should offer to provide such service.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Local Furnishing Utilities and ConEd also ask the Commission to 
    revise section 5.2 of the pro forma tariff to state that issuance of a 
    section 211 order by the Commission is a condition precedent to the 
    provision of transmission service. Under the tariff provision adopted 
    by Order No. 888 to address situations in which the provision of 
    transmission service would jeopardize the tax-exempt status of any 
    local furnishing bonds used to finance a local furnishing utility's 
    facilities, the customer requesting transmission service would tender 
    an application under section 211 of the FPA. Within ten days of 
    receiving a copy of the section 211 application, the transmission 
    provider ``will waive its rights to a request for service under Section 
    213(a) of the [FPA] and to the issuance of a proposed order under 
    Section 212(c) of the [FPA] and shall provide the requested 
    transmission service in accordance with the terms and conditions of 
    this Tariff.'' \366\ We clarify that the Commission, upon receipt of 
    the transmission provider's waiver of its rights to a request for 
    service under section 213(a) and to the issuance of a proposed order 
    under section 212(c), shall issue an order under section 211.\367\ Upon 
    issuance of the order under section 211, the transmission provider 
    shall be required to provide the requested transmission service in 
    accordance with the terms and conditions of the tariff. Section 5.2 of 
    the pro forma tariff has been revised accordingly.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \366\ Pro Forma Open Access Transmission Tariff, Section 
    5.2(ii).
        \367\ We will reject Local Furnishing Utilities' request that 
    the Commission reconsider whether it should insist on the 
    transmission provider's waiver of the issuance of a proposed order 
    under section 212(c). As Order No. 888 indicates, this aspect of the 
    local furnishing provision of the tariff is similar to a provision 
    included in the transmission tariff of San Diego G&E, one of the 
    Local Furnishing Utilities. Waiver of the issuance of a proposed 
    order enables a transmission provider to expeditiously provide 
    service under section 5.2 of the pro forma tariff, thereby ensuring 
    that any local furnishing bonds that may exist do not interfere with 
    the effective operation of an open access transmission regime. 
    Although Local Furnishing Utilities now apparently support the 
    issuance of a proposed order on the basis that the negotiations that 
    normally would follow are likely to provide an opportunity to review 
    the costs associated with the loss of tax-exempt status, we believe 
    that any dispute as to costs subsequently can be resolved without 
    causing any delay in the provision of the requested transmission 
    service. For example, the service could be provided at the maximum 
    rate allowed by the Commission, subject to refund.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Local Furnishing Utilities and ConEd also contend that the language 
    of sections 5.1 and 5.2(i) of the pro forma tariff improperly limits 
    the safe harbor protection of section 1919 of EPAct to transmission 
    providers that financed transmission facilities with local furnishing 
    bonds. ConEd expresses concern that although all of its electric local 
    furnishing bonds have been used to finance its distribution system, the 
    test as to whether those bonds have been used for the ``local 
    furnishing'' of electricity is based in part on whether ConEd has been 
    a ``net importer'' of energy into its service territory. As a result, 
    ConEd argues that the use of its transmission system to wheel power 
    from a generating source located inside ConEd's service territory to a 
    customer located outside its service territory could cause ConEd to 
    violate the net importer rule and thereby lose the tax exemption for 
    the bonds used to finance its distribution system. ConEd asks the 
    Commission to modify sections 5.1 and 5.2 of the pro forma tariff to 
    make clear that those provisions apply to transmission providers that 
    have financed any ``facilities'' (i.e., distribution and generation, 
    not just transmission, facilities) with local furnishing bonds.
        As we explained in Order No. 888, we believe the local furnishing 
    bonds
    
    [[Page 12345]]
    
    provision in section 5 of the pro forma tariff is necessary and 
    appropriate so that any local furnishing bonds that may exist do not 
    interfere with the effective operation of an open access transmission 
    regime. If the provision of transmission service pursuant to Order No. 
    888 would result in the loss of tax-exempt status for local furnishing 
    bonds, regardless of whether the facilities financed with those bonds 
    are transmission, distribution, or generation facilities, it is our 
    intent that the provisions of section 5 would apply. Thus, we clarify 
    in response to ConEd and Local Furnishing Utilities that, to the extent 
    the provision of transmission under an open access tariff would 
    jeopardize the tax-exempt status of local furnishing bonds used to 
    finance distribution or generation facilities (even if no transmission 
    facilities were financed with such bonds), 368 such situation 
    would fall within the reference to ``facilities that would be used in 
    providing . . . transmission service'' contained in sections 5.1 and 
    5.2(i). This is so because the loss of tax-exempt status in such 
    circumstances would be directly attributable to the provision of 
    transmission services under the Rule.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \368\ ConEd suggests that this might occur if, for example, the 
    provision by ConEd of transmission service were to cause it to 
    violate the net importer rule and thereby lose the tax exemption for 
    bonds used to finance its local distribution system. Although we 
    clarify above that section 5 of the pro forma tariff would apply to 
    this situation, we note that it is not clear that wheeling required 
    by the Commission would be counted for purposes of determining 
    whether a public utility is a ``net importer.'' In its committee 
    report on the bill that became the Energy Policy Act, the House Ways 
    and Means Committee stated:
        The committee believes further that, in applying the IRS ruling 
    position that a local furnishing utility that is interconnected with 
    other utilities (other than for emergency transfers of electricity) 
    must be a net importer of electricity, the determination of whether 
    the utility is a net importer should be made without regard to 
    electricity generated by another party that is wheeled by the 
    utility to a point outside its service area pursuant to a FERC order 
    authorized under the bill.
        H.R. Rep. No. 102-474(VI), 102d Cong., 2d Sess. 25 (1992), 
    reprinted in 1992 U.S.C.C.A.N. 2232, 2236.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Further, we said in Order No. 888 that ``we will require any public 
    utility that is subject to the Open Access Rule that has financed 
    transmission facilities with local furnishing bonds to include in its 
    tariff'' a provision similar to section 5 of the pro forma 
    tariff.369 We clarify that we did not intend by this statement 
    that the section 5 local furnishing bonds provision would only apply to 
    public utilities that have financed transmission facilities with local 
    furnishing bonds, and not those that have financed generation and 
    distribution facilities with such bonds. As we explain above, it is our 
    intent that the provisions of section 5 apply if the provision of 
    transmission service pursuant to an open access tariff would result in 
    the loss of tax-exempt status for local furnishing bonds, regardless of 
    whether the facilities financed with those bonds are transmission, 
    distribution, or generation facilities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \369\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,763; mimeo at 377.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
    Unfunded Mandates Reform Act
    
        NE Public Power District 370 argues that the final regulations 
    adopted in this proceeding ``constitute[] an unfunded mandate under the 
    Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995 * * * .'' 371 It declares 
    that Order No. 888 imposes significant costs upon local governments and 
    that the Commission was required under the Unfunded Mandates Reform Act 
    to consider the financial impact of its rulemaking upon state and local 
    governments and to prepare and issue as part of its rulemaking process 
    a statement containing certain specified analyses and estimates 
    concerning this matter and a description of its pre-issuance 
    consultations with state and local government authorities. To support 
    its argument NE Public Power District relies upon: (a) Executive Order 
    No. 12875, Enhancing the Intergovernmental Partnership (Executive 
    Order); 372 and (b) the Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995 (the 
    Act). 373
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \370\ NE Public Power District is a public corporation and a 
    political subdivision of the State of Nebraska that generates, 
    transmits and delivers electric energy to wholesale and retail 
    customers throughout the state.
        \371\ NE Public Power District at 2. NE Public Power District 
    asserts that the Commission failed to respond to this issue as 
    raised by NE Public Power District in its comments.
        \372\ Executive Order No. 12875, 3 CFR 699-71 (1994); 58 Fed. 
    Reg. 58,093-094 (1993). The Executive Order provides that, unless 
    required by statute, no Executive department or agency shall 
    promulgate any regulation that creates a mandate upon state, local 
    or tribal governments unless it either: (a) provides the funds 
    necessary to carry out the obligations; or (b) before promulgating 
    the regulation, provides to the Director of the Office of Management 
    and Budget: (1) a description of its consultation with the affected 
    governments; (2) a statement of their concerns and copies of 
    communications it has received from them; and (3) the reasons why it 
    thinks the regulations should issue.
        \373\ The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act is Pub. L. No. 104-4, 109 
    Stat. 48 (1995) (to be codified at 2 U.S.C. Secs. 602, 632, 653, 
    658, 1501-1504, 1511-1516, 1531-1538, 1551-1556 and 1571).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We disagree with NE Public Power District. The Executive Order 
    applies to every ``executive department * * * [and] agency. * * * '' 
    374 It defines ``executive agency'' as ``any authority of the 
    United States that is an `agency' under 44 U.S.C. Sec. 3502(1), other 
    than those considered to be independent regulatory agencies, as defined 
    in 44 U.S.C. Sec. 3502 (10).'' 375 In section 3502(10), the 
    Federal Energy Regulatory Commission is defined as an independent 
    regulatory agency. As a result, the Executive Order does not apply to 
    the Commission.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \374\ 3 CFR at 670; 58 FR 58093 (1993).
        \375\ 3 CFR at 671; 58 FR at 58094 (1993) (emphasis supplied).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Act similarly applies to federal agencies, but, as with the 
    Executive Order, does not apply to independent regulatory agencies. 
    376 Although the Act does not define ``independent regulatory 
    agency,'' there is no indication that Congress intended to exclude the 
    Commission from the definition. In fact, in all instances in which 
    Congress has defined the term ``independent regulatory agency'' of 
    which we are aware, the Commission has been included.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \376\ 90 Stat 50 (to be codified at 2 U.S.C. Sec. 658).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As noted, the Commission is defined as an independent regulatory 
    agency in Title 44 U.S.C. Also, Title 42 U.S.C. Sec. 7176 provides 
    that:
    
        For the purposes of chapter 9 of title 5, United States Code * * 
    * [Executive Reorganization], the [Federal Energy Regulatory] 
    Commission shall be deemed to be an independent regulatory agency. 
    [377]
    
        \377\ 42 U.S.C.A. Sec. 7176 (1995) (Department of Energy 
    Organization Act) (P.L. 95-91, 91 Stat. 586) (1977). See also Pub. 
    L. No. 104-13, the Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995 Sec. 3502(5), 109 
    Stat. 165 (1995) (to be codified at 44 U.S.C. Sec. 3502(5)), which 
    provides that ``the term `independent regulatory agency' means 
    [among other agencies] * * * the Federal Energy Regulatory 
    Commission.''
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Accordingly, we find that the Commission is an independent regulatory 
    agency as used in the Act; therefore, it is not covered by the Act.
        Moreover, even if the Act applied to the Commission, the Final Rule 
    will not impose a Federal mandate on state, local or tribal 
    governments.
        Section 305 of the Act defines a ``Federal mandate'' as:
    
    any provision in [a] statute or regulation or [in] any Federal court 
    ruling that imposes an enforceable duty upon State, local, or tribal 
    governments[,] including a condition of Federal assistance or a duty 
    arising from participation in a voluntary Federal program.[378]
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \378\ 109 Stat. 70 (to be codified at 2 U.S.C. Sec. 1555) 
    (emphasis supplied).
    
        The Open Access Final Rule imposes requirements only on certain 
    public utilities 379 and, pursuant to section 201(f) of the FPA, 
    state and local
    
    [[Page 12346]]
    
    governments, and their agencies, authorities and instrumentalities, are 
    not public utilities. Additionally, although the Final Rule will allow 
    public utilities' transmission tariffs to contain reciprocity 
    provisions in order to ensure that public utilities offering open 
    access transmission to others can obtain similar service from open 
    access users, the reciprocity provision is not an enforceable duty. A 
    duty is mandatory; it is an obligation to perform and is compulsory. 
    380 The reciprocity provision is merely a condition of receiving a 
    benefit, i.e., open access transmission service from a public utility. 
    381 There is no requirement that NE Public Power District 
    promulgate an open access tariff and apply to FERC for a declaratory 
    order. Moreover, as we explained above, non-public utilities, such as 
    NE Public Power District, are free to seek from a public utility a 
    waiver of the open access tariff reciprocity condition.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \379\ I.e., those that own, operate or control interstate 
    transmission facilities and do not obtain a waiver from the 
    Commission.
        \380\ Dayton Hudson Corp. v. Eldridge, 742 S.W. 2d 482, 485-86 
    (1987); Kerrigan v. Errett, 256 N.W. 2d 394, 399 (1977); Huey v. 
    King, 415 S.W. 2d 136, 138 (1967); Black's Law Dictionary 505 (6th 
    ed. 1990).
        \381\ A state or municipal power authority, such as NE Public 
    Power District, does not have to agree to reciprocity, and the 
    Commission cannot force it to do so. The Commission is not requiring 
    state or municipal power authorities to provide transmission access. 
    If non-public utilities elect not to take advantage of open access 
    services because they don't want to meet the tariff reciprocity 
    provision, they can still seek voluntary, bilateral transmission 
    service from public utilities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        With regard to the Stranded Cost Final Rule, while it applies to 
    non-public utilities as well as public utilities, it does not impose a 
    duty on any entity since it merely permits public utilities and 
    transmitting utilities to seek recovery of certain costs. As a result, 
    since the Open Access and Stranded Cost final rules will not impose an 
    enforceable duty on state, municipal or tribal power agencies such as 
    NE Public Power District, the rules are not Federal mandates as defined 
    in the Act.
        Because the Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995 does not apply to 
    the Commission and, in any event, the Open Access/Stranded Cost final 
    rules do not impose Federal mandates on state, local or tribal 
    governments, we reject NE Public Power District's argument that the 
    Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995 is applicable here.
    5. Liability and Indemnification
        In the Final Rule, the Commission explained that the 
    indemnification provision was broken into two parts (set forth in 
    section 10.1 (Force Majeure) and section 10.2 (Indemnification) of the 
    pro forma tariff).382 The Commission explained that the first part 
    is a force majeure provision which provides that neither the 
    transmission provider nor the customer will be in default if a force 
    majeure event occurs, but also provides that both the transmission 
    provider and customer will take all reasonable steps to comply with the 
    tariff despite the occurrence of a force majeure event.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \382\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,765-66; mimeo at 384-85.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission explained that the second portion of the provision 
    provides for indemnification against third party claims arising from 
    the performance of obligations under the tariff. The Commission limited 
    the indemnification portion of the provision so that it is only the 
    transmission customer who indemnifies the transmission provider from 
    the claims of third parties. The Commission explained that the revised 
    provision provides that the customer will not be required to indemnify 
    the transmission provider in the case of negligence or intentional 
    wrongdoing by the transmission provider.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        A number of utilities argue that the Commission has expanded 
    transmitter liability beyond the existing standard in the industry, 
    i.e., gross negligence.383 They assert that the Commission has 
    provided no basis to subject transmission providers to liability, 
    including consequential damages, due to ordinary negligence. KCPL 
    points out that 21 of 25 states addressing this issue hold that a 
    utility should not be liable for ordinary negligence. It declares that 
    society will be worse off in litigation expenses and wasted human 
    resources if utilities are held liable for simple negligence. It adds 
    that the electric industry is much more susceptible to liability from 
    interruptions of service than gas pipelines (refuting the Commission's 
    reliance on Pacific Interstate Offshore Company, which it states is 
    traceable to United Gas Pipeline Co. v. FERC, 824 F.2d 417 (5th Cir. 
    1987)). Florida Power Corp asks the Commission to modify section 10.2 
    to provide that a customer must indemnify the transmission provider 
    except where a finder of fact determines that the transmission provider 
    has committed gross or intentional wrongdoing. It also argues that the 
    Commission should eliminate liability of both the transmission provider 
    and the customer to the other for consequential damages.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \383\ Coalition for Economic Competition, EEI, KCPL, Florida 
    Power Corp.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Southern argues that the exception language in section 10.2 should 
    be changed to ``except where a court has determined that the 
    Transmission Provider has engaged in intentional wrongdoing or has been 
    grossly negligent.'' (Southern at 20-21). Southern also argues that the 
    Commission should limit consequential damages arising from negligence 
    in the operation of the transmission system.
        Puget asserts that the exception language in section 10.2 should be 
    changed to ``except in cases of and to the extent of comparative or 
    contributory negligence or intentional wrongdoing by the Transmission 
    Provider.'' (Puget at 18). It also asserts that the Commission should 
    exclude liability for special, incidental, consequential, or indirect 
    damages.
        EEI argues that the Commission should add a new section 10.3: ``If 
    the Transmission Provider is found liable for any damages associated 
    with this Tariff, those damages shall be limited to direct damages, and 
    the Transmission Provider shall not be liable for any special, indirect 
    or consequential damages of any nature by virtue of the transactions 
    conducted under this Tariff.'' (EEI at 26).
        Coalition for Economic Competition argues that the Commission 
    should modify section 10.2 to provide that the transmission provider 
    will not be liable to a transmission customer or any third party for 
    damages caused by interruptions or irregular or defective service, 
    except if gross negligence or wilful misconduct caused such 
    damages.384 Coalition for Economic Competition asserts that the 
    definition of force majeure should include ordinary negligence and asks 
    that the Commission clarify that a utility is not liable for force 
    majeure events.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \384\ See also EEI at 26 (suggesting ``except in cases of a 
    finding by a trier of fact of gross negligence or intentional 
    wrongdoing by the Transmission Provider'').
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        CCEM also argues that transmission customer indemnity in section 
    10.2 should attach only to legal actions brought by customers of the 
    transmission customer or third-party beneficiaries of those customers.
        On the other hand, TDU Systems argues that the indemnity provision 
    unfairly provides the transmission provider with virtually total 
    indemnification for acts on its side of the delivery point, but 
    provides no reciprocal protection to the transmission customers for 
    damage incurred on the customers' system in connection with purchasing 
    the transmission provider's services.
    
    [[Page 12347]]
    
        CSW Operating Companies asks the Commission to revise the pro forma 
    tariff to provide that a transmission provider will not be liable for 
    errors in an estimate made in good faith and in accordance with its 
    published procedure. They propose the following language:
    
        Information posted on the OASIS concerning the availability of 
    transfer capability will be based on the Transmission Provider's 
    best estimates given the information readily and actually available 
    to the transmission provider. No such estimate will be binding on 
    the Transmission Provider for any purpose.
    
    Alternatively, they ask the Commission to clarify that as long as a 
    transmission provider in good faith follows its published methodology 
    for determining ATC and TTC it will be deemed not to be negligent.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The purpose of the force majeure provision in the pro forma tariff 
    is to ensure that neither the customer nor the transmission provider is 
    held in default in the event of an unpredictable and uncontrollable 
    force majeure event. It was not the Commission's intention that the 
    force majeure clause provide an avenue for a party to claim that it is 
    excused from liability for its own negligence. A force majeure event 
    does not include an act of negligence or intentional wrongdoing. The 
    pro forma tariff will be changed accordingly.385
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \385\ See Tex-La Electric Cooperative of Texas, Inc., 69 FERC 
    para. 61,269 (1994) (requiring clarification that force majeure 
    clause in electric transmission agreement does not excuse 
    negligence); Avoca Natural Gas Storage, 68 FERC para. 61,045 (1994) 
    (requiring modification of force majeure provision to ensure that 
    parties would be liable for negligence or intentional wrongdoing).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The purpose of the indemnification provision is to allocate the 
    risks of a transaction, and the costs associated with those risks, to 
    the party on whose behalf the transaction has been conducted, the 
    transmission customer. As the tariff does not obligate the customer to 
    perform services on behalf of the transmission provider, there is no 
    comparable basis for imposing an indemnification obligation on the 
    transmission provider.386
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \386\ The Commission notes that in the past it may have accepted 
    agreements containing gross negligence in force majeure and 
    indemnification provisions. Consistent with the Commission's general 
    policy of not abrogating existing contracts, we leave those 
    provisions undisturbed.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As is explained in the Final Rule, the Commission does not believe 
    it appropriate to extend the indemnification obligation so that it 
    would apply even in cases where the transmission provider has been 
    negligent. The contention that electric transmission outages are either 
    more frequent or more costly than gas outages does not serve to 
    distinguish the electric transmission situation from the gas pipeline 
    cases in which the Commission has found that indemnification clauses 
    should not protect the pipeline owner from its own negligence.387 
    In either case, it would be inappropriate to require the customer to 
    indemnify the transmission provider from damages arising from the 
    transmission provider's own negligence. We note, however, that 
    liability is a separate issue from indemnification. Despite the absence 
    of indemnification protection, there is nothing in the indemnification 
    provision that would preclude transmission providers from relying on 
    the protection of state laws, when and where applicable, protecting 
    utilities or others from claims founded in ordinary negligence.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \387\ See, e.g., Pacific Interstate Offshore Company, 62 FERC 
    para. 61,260 at 62,733-734 (1993) (requiring amendment of 
    indemnification provisions that required indemnification except in 
    cases of ``gross negligence'').
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        With respect to the issue of consequential and indirect damages, 
    the indemnification provision already provides protection to the 
    transmission provider from consequential and indirect damage claims by 
    third parties except in cases of negligence or intentional wrongdoing 
    by the transmission provider. The Commission sees no need to further 
    extend this protection. Again, we note that liability is a separate 
    issue from indemnification, and that nothing in these provisions 
    precludes transmission providers or customers from relying, when and 
    where such law is applicable, on the protection of statutes or other 
    law protecting parties from consequential or indirect damages.
        Furthermore, we will not revise the pro forma tariff, as requested 
    by CSW Operating Companies, to provide that a transmission provider 
    will not be liable for errors in an estimate made in good faith or in 
    accordance with its published procedure. We believe that a utility 
    should have no different a liability standard for operating an OASIS 
    than for its other operations.388
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \388\ See, e.g., Texas Eastern Transmission Corporation, 62 FERC 
    para. 61,015 at 61,107 (1993).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    6. Umbrella Service Agreements
        The Commission received requests for clarification regarding this 
    issue, which was not specifically addressed by the Commission in the 
    Final Rule.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        SoCal Edison argues that it is too burdensome to require a separate 
    Completed Application and a separate Service Agreement to be executed 
    for each individual service transaction for short-term firm and non-
    firm transmission service (and filed with the Commission). SoCal Edison 
    contends that requiring a separate service agreement for each short-
    term firm transaction to be filed with the Commission will stifle 
    transactions in the short-term market. It indicates that it suggested a 
    simpler approach in Docket No. ER96-222-000 that would establish a non-
    transaction specific Service Agreement and a Completed Application that 
    would contain the specific transaction information, but would not be 
    filed with the Commission, but would be made available for 
    audit.389
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \389\ To date, the Commission has only issued a suspension order 
    in this proceeding.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        SoCal Edison misinterprets the tariff provisions regarding service 
    agreements for non-firm point-to-point transmission service. Tariff 
    section 14.5 details the treatment of service agreements for non-firm 
    transmission service:
    
        The Transmission Provider shall offer a standard form Non-Firm 
    Point-To-Point Transmission Service Agreement (Attachment B) to an 
    Eligible Customer when it first submits a Completed Application for 
    Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service pursuant to the tariff. 
    (Emphasis added)
    
        Moreover, in tariff section 18 (Procedures for Arranging for Non-
    Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service) requires that a separate 
    service agreement be executed for each individual service transaction 
    as claimed by SoCal Edison. In the pro forma tariff, the Commission 
    established a non-transaction specific (or ``umbrella'') service 
    agreement in an attempt to streamline the application procedures for 
    non-firm point-to-point transmission service. Therefore, the service 
    agreement for non-firm point-to-point transmission service need only be 
    executed and filed with the Commission once, when the transmission 
    customer first applies for non-firm point-to-point transmission 
    service. Subsequent non-firm transactions by the same customer only 
    require the submission of a completed application (as provided in 
    tariff sections 18.1 and 18.2) by that customer, which will be 
    submitted via the transmission provider's OASIS (when the OASIS is 
    fully implemented). Accordingly, no changes are required to
    
    [[Page 12348]]
    
    the application procedures for non-firm point-to-point service.
        However, we do find SoCal Edison's arguments persuasive that 
    streamlined procedures should also be applied to applications for firm 
    point-to-point transmission service with a duration of less than one 
    year (short-term firm). We agree that there is no compelling reason to 
    require the submission of separate service agreements for every short-
    term firm transaction. Accordingly, we will adopt an ``umbrella'' 
    service agreement approach (as is currently used for non-firm point-to-
    point transactions) and require a service agreement of general 
    applicability to be filed with the Commission when the first short-term 
    firm transaction is arranged between the transmission provider and 
    customer.
        In order to facilitate an umbrella service agreement approach for 
    short-term firm transmission service, minor modifications have been 
    made to several sections of the pro forma tariff 390 as well as to 
    Attachment A (Form of Service Agreement For Firm Point-To-Point 
    Transmission Service). Notably, pages 3 and 4 of the service agreement, 
    containing transaction specific information, is now required only for 
    long-term firm point-to-point transmission service.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \390\ See changes to tariff sections 1.33, 1.34, 13.4, 13.7 and 
    17.3.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    7. Other Tariff Provisions
    a. Minimum and Maximum Service Periods
        In the Final Rule, the Commission adopted a one-day minimum term 
    for firm point-to-point service.391 The Commission also concluded 
    that it will not specify a maximum term for either firm point-to-point 
    or network transmission service. However, the Commission modified the 
    tariff to require that an application for transmission service specify 
    the length of service being requested.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \391\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,752-53; mimeo at 346-47.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        CCEM states that a competitive market for hourly trades should be 
    allowed to develop (transmission and ancillary services). It argues 
    that contrary to the Commission's goal of comparability, the Rule 
    effectively allows only incumbent utilities to participate in hourly 
    markets on behalf of their own or network loads (citing section 13.1 of 
    the pro forma tariff).
        American Forest & Paper argues that firm and non-firm service 
    should be made available on an hourly basis and that the Commission 
    should assure that utilities make non-firm service available.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        It is unclear as to what hourly ``trades'' CCEM is referring. If 
    CCEM is referring to off-system sales, the transmission provider is 
    obligated to take transmission for any off-system sales under point-to-
    point transmission service under its tariff. Inasmuch as the tariff 
    does not require the provision of hourly firm transmission, in order to 
    provide itself with hourly firm transmission, the transmission provider 
    would either: (1) reserve firm point-to-point service on a daily basis 
    in order to participate in the hourly market or (2) propose in a 
    section 205 filing to modify its tariff to voluntarily provide hourly 
    firm point-to-point service. Under either circumstance, comparability 
    would be maintained as all point-to-point customers would have equal 
    access to the hourly market.
        If CCEM is referring to purchases, hourly economy purchases by the 
    transmission provider on behalf of its native load customers are also 
    available on a comparable basis to network customers. However, if CCEM 
    is referring to specific purchases made on behalf of a particular 
    wholesale customer, this resale must be provided under point-to-point 
    transmission service, as described above.
        The Commission has rejected hourly firm point-to-point transmission 
    service as a mandatory service to be provided under the Tariff.392 
    Many entities would not oppose hourly firm service if afforded a lower 
    priority, i.e., if they were curtailed before longer-term firm 
    services. However, with this lower priority there may be little or no 
    difference between the pro forma tariff non-firm service and 
    curtailable firm hourly service. The Commission adopted the one-day 
    minimum term for firm service to address concerns that customers would 
    engage in ``cream skimming'' by taking firm service only during the 
    hours at the daily peak while taking non-firm service for other hours, 
    and thereby avoiding paying a fair share of the costs of the 
    transmission system. However, this does not mean that the Commission 
    would not allow such services if voluntarily proposed by a transmission 
    provider.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \392\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,752; mimeo at 346.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Finally, in response to American Forest & Paper, the transmission 
    provider has every incentive to make non-firm service available to all 
    eligible customers in order to benefit native load customers, as the 
    revenues generated by this service are typically used as a revenue 
    credit to offset the costs of providing firm service. In addition, 
    parties may raise concerns with the Commission in a section 206 
    complaint if the transmission provider offers non-firm transmission 
    service in a non-comparable, i.e., unduly discriminatory fashion.
    b. Amount of Designated Network Resources
        In the Final Rule, the Commission indicated that it will not change 
    the limitation on the amount of resources a network customer may 
    designate. 393 The Commission explained that a transmission 
    provider is required to designate its resources and is subject to the 
    same limitations required of any other network customer.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \393\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,753-54; mimeo at 349-50.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission further explained that limiting the amount of 
    resources to those that the customer owns or commits to purchase will 
    protect a utility from having to incur costs that are out of proportion 
    to the customer's load.
        With respect to the allocation of interface capacity under network 
    service, the Commission clarified that a customer is not limited to a 
    load ratio percentage of available transmission capacity at every 
    interface. It explained that a customer may designate a single 
    interface or any combination of interface capacity to serve its entire 
    load, provided that the designation does not exceed its total load.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        A number of entities state that section 30.8 of the pro forma 
    tariff should be clarified to conform to the Final Rule preamble. The 
    preamble states that a network customer should not be limited to a load 
    ratio percentage of available transmission capacity at every interface, 
    but may designate a single interface or any combination of interface 
    capacity to serve its entire load, provided that the designation does 
    not exceed its total load. However, they point out that section 30.8 of 
    the pro forma tariff provides that a network customer's use of the 
    transmission provider's total interface capacity with other 
    transmission systems may not exceed the network customer's load ratio 
    share.394
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \394\ E.g., NRECA, Blue Ridge, TDU Systems, Cleveland, AEC & 
    SMEPA, Wisconsin Municipals, TAPS.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        TAPS and Wisconsin Municipals ask the Commission to clarify the 
    inconsistency by deleting the phrase ``Ratio Share'' at the end of the 
    section 30.8. TAPS argues that section 30.8 of
    
    [[Page 12349]]
    
    the tariff conflicts with the preamble, other sections of the tariff 
    itself (see section 28), and recent Commission orders (Wisconsin Public 
    Service Corporation, 74 FERC para. 61,022 at 61,064 and FMPA v. FPL, 67 
    FERC 61,167 at 61,484). It further argues that load ratio restrictions 
    on total interface usage would expand the market power of transmission 
    providers.
        EEI and Southern state that under section 30.8 and the related 
    preamble language, it is unclear how the concept of load ratio share 
    should be applied in the context of interface capacity, (i.e., is the 
    network customer entitled to a load ratio share of available 
    transmission capacity or total transmission capacity for an 
    interface?). They argue that ATC is the appropriate basis for 
    calculating shares of interface capacity and state that the Commission 
    should specify that network service entitles the user to a load ratio 
    share of the available capacity of each interface. EEI adds that if 
    sufficient interface capacity is available, a request by a network 
    customer to use available interface capacity to bring in resources for 
    network load in excess of its load ratio share of the interface should 
    be accommodated under the point-to-point tariff and treated on a first-
    come, first-served basis.395
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \395\ TAPS filed a response opposing these requests for 
    rehearing. (TAPS Response). As we explained above, we will accept 
    the TAPS Response.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Florida Power Corp states that ``[i]n order to clarify that network 
    customers may obtain transmission service over the transmission 
    provider's interfaces in excess of their load ratio shares, the 
    Commission should clarify that additional interface capability may be 
    purchased (subject to availability) as firm point-to-point transmission 
    service.'' (Florida Power Corp at 29).
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We agree that the pro forma tariff should be conformed to the 
    preamble language in the Final Rule so that the interface capacity is 
    limited to the customer's total load, not a load ratio share. This is 
    consistent with the Commission's recent rehearing order in FMPA v. FPL:
        We clarify that the phrase ``that is, up to its share of the load, 
    3%'' was not intended to limit FMPA's use of each interface to a 
    discrete ratio (3%). Rather, FMPA, as well as Florida Power, can use 
    each interface, if capacity is available, to service its entire network 
    load. If the interface is [constrained] [sic], they will either pay 
    redispatch costs or expansion costs based on their load ratio 
    share.[396]
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \396\ 74 FERC at 61,018.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    c. Eligibility Requirements
        In the Final Rule, the Commission found that a non-discriminatory 
    open access transmission tariff must be made available, at a minimum, 
    to any entity that can request transmission services under section 211 
    and to foreign entities. 397
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \397\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,754; mimeo at 351.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        VT DPS and Valero state that the Final Rule does not appear to 
    contemplate that marketers will buy network service or that one network 
    service customer might serve a portion of the requirements of another 
    network customer. Thus, they argue that network load can be double 
    counted. To resolve this problem, they argue, service should be made 
    available to suppliers rather than load, as provided in the NorAm NIS 
    tariff, Section 1.5.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Power marketers are specifically named in the definition of 
    Eligible Customer (Section 1.11), and nothing in the Network 
    Integration Transmission Service prohibits marketers from serving 
    customers and designating those customers' loads (or portions thereof) 
    as the marketers' Network Loads.
        Additional rehearing requests regarding eligibility are addressed 
    in Section IV.C.1. (Eligibility to Receive Non-discriminatory Open 
    Access Transmission).
    d. Two-Year Notice of Termination Provision
        In the Final Rule, the Commission deleted the notice of termination 
    provision from the tariff.398
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \398\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,754-55; mimeo at 353.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        No requests for rehearing addressed this matter.
    e. Termination of Service for Failure to Pay Bill
        In the Final Rule, the Commission stated that section 7.3 of the 
    Final Rule pro forma tariff provides that in the event of a customer 
    default, the transmission provider may, in accordance with Commission 
    policy, file and initiate a proceeding with the Commission to terminate 
    service.399
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \399\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,794; mimeo at 467.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        El Paso asserts that the Commission does not have the authority to 
    prohibit a transmission provider from terminating service to a customer 
    that has failed to pay its bill until permission from the Commission 
    has been obtained. It argues that the Commission does not have 
    abandonment authority under the FPA.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        El Paso is not correct. Under section 205 of the FPA, public 
    utilities are allowed to effectuate changes in rates, charges, 
    classification or service only after providing 60 days notice to the 
    Commission and the public. Because a termination of service is clearly 
    a change in service, public utilities must file notice of a termination 
    60 days prior to the proposed effective date.
        In Portland General Electric Company, 75 FERC para. 61,310, reh'g 
    denied, 77 FERC para. 61,171 (1996), we denied a requested waiver of 
    section 35.15 of the Commission's Rules of Practice and Procedure to 
    permit the utility to terminate service in the event of customer 
    default. We indicated that we had previously explained the reasons for 
    requiring public utilities to file notices of termination when seeking 
    to discontinue service 400 and further explained that
    
        \400\ E.g., to protect wholesale purchasers--and, by extension, 
    ultimate consumers--from losing service unjustly; to provide the 
    Commission an opportunity to ensure that the termination is just and 
    reasonable. 77 FERC at 61,171.
    
    electricity is not just any commercial good or service. Rather, 
    Congress in the Federal Power Act has charged us with ensuring that 
    sales for resale or transmission of electricity in interstate 
    commerce by public utilities take place at rates, terms and 
    conditions that are just and reasonable.[401]
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \401\ Id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    f. Definition of Native Load Customers
        The Commission defined the term ``Native Load Customers'' in 
    section 1.19 of the pro forma tariff as:
    
        The wholesale and retail power customers of the Transmission 
    Provider on whose behalf the Transmission Provider, by statute, 
    franchise, regulatory requirement, or contract, has undertaken an 
    obligation to construct and operate the Transmission Provider's 
    system to meet the reliable electric needs of such customers.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        The pro forma tariff defines native load customers as ``[t]he 
    wholesale and retail power customers of the Transmission Provider. * * 
    *'' Cooperative Power argues that the definition of native load 
    customers should recognize that joint planning is a sufficient 
    criterion, and that construction and operation by the
    
    [[Page 12350]]
    
    transmission provider should not be necessary for native load status to 
    be conferred. It asserts that under joint planning, the loads of 
    transmission-only customers are considered native, therefore the 
    Commission should eliminate the word power from the definition.402
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \402\ Dairyland filed a supplemental request for rehearing 
    raising similar arguments. (Dairyland Supplement). We will accept 
    this pleading as a motion for reconsideration, not as a request for 
    rehearing, because it was not filed within the 30-day statutory 
    period for rehearing requests. See 16 U.S.C. Sec. 8251(a).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        NRECA and TDU Systems state that traditional wholesale customers 
    that have long been on the system, have assisted in paying for past 
    expansions, and will likely continue to be captive to a provider's 
    monopoly transmission service, should have ``native load equivalent'' 
    rights if they take network or long-term firm service. If the 
    transmission provider has planned and will plan in the future for a 
    customer's full or partial needs, they argue that the customer should 
    be treated as the equivalent of native load. They point out that 
    section 1.19 of the tariff limits native load status only to wholesale 
    power customers of the transmission provider.
        VA Com argues that the definition of native load in section 1.19 of 
    the tariff should include existing distribution cooperatives and others 
    who currently provide service to end users.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We reject Cooperative Power's suggestion to include transmission-
    only point-to-point customers in the definition of native load. We note 
    that network customers are provided with rights comparable to native 
    load customers because the transmission provider includes their network 
    resources and loads in its long-term planning horizon. However, a 
    point-to-point transmission service customer is not similarly situated 
    to native load and Network Customers. The Network service formula rate 
    requires the Network customer to pay a load-ratio share of the costs of 
    the transmission provider's transmission system on an ongoing basis, 
    while a point-to-point transmission service customer is only 
    responsible for paying on a contract demand basis over the contract 
    term. The network customer and the native load of the transmission 
    provider pay all the residual costs of the transmission system and face 
    greater risks of rate fluctuations due to facility additions and 
    variations in load of both its and other customers. In contrast, the 
    point-to-point transmission service customer may be more transitory in 
    nature electing shorter terms of service and specific forms of service 
    tailored for discrete services over specific time periods that do not 
    necessarily enter into the transmission provider's planning horizon. To 
    the extent a transmission customer desires similar rights and cost 
    responsibilities to a native load customer, it can always elect to take 
    network service.
        We further note that, in granting a right of first refusal to 
    existing customers, we afforded existing transmission only point-to-
    point customers a priority to continue to use the transmission 
    provider's system.
        VA Com's proposed change to the definition of native load was made 
    in conjunction with its proposed change in the reservation priority 
    (highest priority for ``native load'', followed by firm contract 
    customers and lastly, non-firm customers). Because we are rejecting VA 
    Com's proposed reservation priority (see Section IV.G.3.a. above), we 
    will also reject its proposed conforming change to the definition of 
    native load as proposed by VA Com.
    g. Off-System Sales
        Regarding the unbundling of off-system sales, the Final Rule 
    required that all bilateral economy energy coordination contracts 
    executed before the effective date of Order No. 888 must be modified to 
    require unbundling of any economy energy transaction occurring after 
    December 31, 1996.403 Concerning the treatment of revenues from 
    transmission associated with off-system sales, the Commission stated in 
    the Final Rule that revenue from non-firm services should continue to 
    be reflected as a revenue credit in the derivation of firm transmission 
    tariff rates.404
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \403\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,700; mimeo at 191.
        \404\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,738; mimeo at 304.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Montana Power asserts that the Commission should clarify that off-
    system sales that originate from generating plants or power purchases 
    outside the transmission provider's system and do not use the 
    transmission provider's transmission system should not be automatically 
    assessed point-to-point charges.
        Maine Public Service asks the Commission to clarify that revenues 
    from off-system sales are not to be credited where the sales do not use 
    the transmission provider's system (referencing sections 1.44 and 8.1 
    of the pro forma tariff). Maine Public Service states that it makes 
    sales from Maine Yankee (which is not located on Maine Public Service's 
    system) to customers not on its system and that it should not have to 
    credit these sales revenues to its transmission customers.
        Wisconsin Municipals asks the Commission to clarify that the 
    provision and level of revenue credits are rate issues and that if 
    parties have negotiated provisions for revenue credits, the Final Rule 
    cannot be used to avoid obligations undertaken in a settlement.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Utilities must take all transmission services for wholesale sales 
    under new requirements contracts and new coordination services under 
    the same tariff used by eligible customers. The Commission provided an 
    extension until December 31, 1996, for utilities to take transmission 
    service under the same tariff for their economy energy transactions, 
    certain power pooling arrangements, and other multi-lateral 
    arrangements.405 The above criteria, however, only apply when a 
    utility transmission system is being used to accommodate off-system 
    sales. Therefore, a utility would not be required to take point-to-
    point transmission service if its transmission system is not being used 
    for the transaction.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \405\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,700; mimeo at 191.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Maine Public Service's concern is misplaced. Maine Public Service 
    states that certain of its sales do not use its own transmission system 
    and that it pays other utilities for such transmission service. 
    However, Section 8.1 only specifies the treatment of revenues the 
    transmission provider receives from transmission service it provides 
    itself when making third-party sales using point-to-point transmission 
    service under its tariff. If Maine Public Service is not the 
    transmission provider for these third-party sales, then Section 8.1 
    does not apply to such transactions.
        Wisconsin Municipals' argument with respect to prior settlements 
    has been previously addressed in Section IV.D.1.c.(2) (Energy Imbalance 
    Bandwidth).
    h. Requirements Agreements
        A detailed description of the Commission's unbundling requirements 
    pertaining to requirements agreements is described below.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Blue Ridge requests that the Commission clarify the definitions of 
    requirements, economy and non-economy energy coordination agreements. 
    In addition, Blue Ridge
    
    [[Page 12351]]
    
    seeks clarification regarding which dates are to be used to distinguish 
    between existing and new contracts (July 11, 1994 or July 9, 1996).
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The definitions of economy and non-economy energy coordination 
    agreements are addressed in section IV.F.4. (Bilateral Coordination 
    Arrangements). With respect to Blue Ridge's concern regarding 
    requirements agreements, we defined requirements contracts broadly in 
    section 35.28(b)(1) of the Commission's regulations as ``any contract 
    or rate schedule under which a public utility provides any portion of a 
    customer's bundled wholesale power requirements.'' The definition is 
    intended to encompass partial requirements service, since that service 
    is intended to meet the bundled load requirements of a customer that is 
    not provided from other sources such as self-generation or unit power 
    purchases. In contrast, a non-economy energy coordination agreement is 
    not intended to meet, by itself, the entirety of a customer's bundled 
    power requirement or the residual partial power requirement of a 
    customer. For example, a 50 MW unit power purchase or a long-term firm 
    power purchase would supply long-term firm power but a customer would 
    likely need an additional partial requirements agreement to supply the 
    residual amount of its load requirement.
        Regarding Blue Ridge's request for clarification of the dates for 
    new and existing agreements, the Commission explicitly stated in Order 
    No. 888 that any bilateral wholesale coordination agreements executed 
    after July 9, 1996 would be subject to the functional unbundling and 
    open access requirements set forth in the Rule.406 In addition, 
    the Commission required that all bilateral economy energy coordination 
    contracts executed on or before July 9, 1996 be modified to require 
    unbundling of any economy energy transaction occurring after December 
    31, 1996. The Commission permitted all non-economy energy bilateral 
    coordination agreements executed before July 9, 1996 to continue in 
    effect subject to section 206 complaints.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \406\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,729-30; mimeo at 277-78.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        For the purpose of distinguishing between existing and new 
    wholesale requirements contracts and for stranded investment recovery 
    provisions, the Commission established July 11, 1994 as the applicable 
    date.407 For a utility to recover stranded investment costs in new 
    requirements contracts, it must include explicit provisions in the 
    contract for stranded investment recovery. Existing requirements 
    contracts would not need a similar provision to be eligible for 
    stranded investment recovery.408 Utilities are required to 
    unbundle all new requirements contracts. The requirement that utilities 
    unbundle existing wholesale requirements contracts is for informational 
    purposes and will enable existing requirements customers to evaluate 
    and compare the transmission component of existing contracts to 
    alternative contracts prior to the existing contracts' expiration 
    dates.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \407\ Mimeo at 769.
        \408\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 33,110 and 31,804-05; mimeo at 85 
    and 497-98.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    i. Use of Distribution Facilities
        The Commission received requests for clarification regarding this 
    issue which was not specifically addressed by the Commission in the 
    Final Rule.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        CSW Operating Companies asks the Commission to make clear that to 
    the extent a transmission provider makes available to transmission 
    customers the use of distribution facilities, the terms governing the 
    use of and the charges for such use should be set forth in the 
    customer's service agreement.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Utilities are free to include customer-specific terms and 
    conditions or terms and conditions limited to certain customers (e.g., 
    a distribution charge) in a customer's service agreement and/or the 
    network customer's network operating agreement.
    j. Losses
        The Commission received requests for clarification regarding this 
    issue which was not specifically addressed by the Commission in the 
    Final Rule.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        VT DPS asserts that network customers should not have to bear 
    losses twice--the tariffs allow collection of losses over all network 
    load, even that supplied by behind the meter generation. It argues that 
    losses should only be paid on power actually transmitted over the 
    company's system.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The pro forma tariff neither specifies the applicable Real Power 
    Loss factors (see tariff section 28.5) nor the demand levels to which 
    the loss factors should be applied. Accordingly, concerns regarding the 
    loss calculation for a customer should be raised when the transmission 
    provider files with the Commission a service agreement for a network 
    customer.
    k. Modification of Non-Rate Terms and Conditions
        The Commission's requirements pertaining to modification of non-
    rate terms and conditions is described below.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        TAPS asserts that the language of section 35.28(c)(1)(v) and the 
    preamble of Order No. 888 are inconsistent. TAPS argues that the 
    Commission should require a demonstration of consistency with and 
    superiority to the terms and conditions of the pro forma tariff and 
    indicate that it will not allow deviations that seek to withdraw the 
    minimum terms and conditions of non-discriminatory transmission. 
    According to TAPS, the Commission should also clarify that the 
    Commission will not let onerous tariff terms creep in through the back 
    door, i.e., through service agreements. TAPS also maintains that the 
    Commission should not allow transmission providers to use conformity as 
    an excuse to evade commitments.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Order No. 888 allows a utility the flexibility to propose, after 
    the compliance tariffs go into effect, to modify non-rate terms and 
    conditions of the tariff if it can ``demonstrate[] that such terms * * 
    * are consistent with, or superior to, those in the compliance 
    tariff.'' These are the same principles that are referenced in the 
    regulation language (deviations allowed if the transmission provider 
    can demonstrate the deviation is consistent with the principles of 
    Order No. 888). While utilities are free to file revised tariffs after 
    their compliance filings, any filing including service agreements will 
    be carefully reviewed by the Commission to assure that the revised 
    tariffs and service agreements are just and reasonable and consistent 
    with the principles of Order No. 888.
        With regard to TAPS' concern about transmission providers evading 
    commitments, we reiterate that we will not require abrogation of 
    existing contracts (and the commitments reflected therein) except on a 
    case-specific basis.
    l. Miscellaneous Tariff Modifications
    (1) Ancillary Services
        The Commission explained that the pro forma tariff incorporates 
    conforming revisions consistent with the
    
    [[Page 12352]]
    
    determinations discussed in the Final Rule.409
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \409\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,763; mimeo at 378.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    (2) Clarification of Accounting Issues
        In the Final Rule, the Commission offered clarifications on the 
    Final Rule pro forma tariff requirements and certain other accounting 
    issues related to the Final Rule.410
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \410\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,763-64; mimeo at 379-80.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    (a) Transmission Provider's Use of Its System (Charging Yourself)
        In the Final Rule, the Commission stated that the purpose of 
    functional unbundling is to separate the transmission component of all 
    new transactions occurring under the Final Rule pro forma tariff, 
    thereby assisting in the verification of a transmission provider's 
    compliance with the comparability requirement. With respect to off-
    system sales, the Commission stated that the transmission provider 
    would book to operating revenue accounts those revenues received from 
    the customer to whom it made the off-system sale.411 The 
    Commission required that the transmission service component and energy 
    component of those revenues be recorded in separate subaccounts of 
    Account 447, Sales for Resale.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \411\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,764; mimeo at 380-81.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        APPA argues that the revenue from the transmission component of all 
    off-system uses must be included in the credit if comparability is to 
    be achieved.
        APPA also argues that booking revenue credits to Account 447 for a 
    test year reduction does not ensure timely receipt by customers. It 
    asserts that a monthly pass-through to all firm transmission customers 
    is needed.
        APPA further argues that a properly functioning revenue credit does 
    away with the perception of disparate treatment of network and point-
    to-point customers. Similarly, TDU Systems argues that comparability 
    requires that revenues attributable to transmission owners' use of 
    their transmission systems be flowed through to customers' benefit 
    immediately so that transmission owners and customers receive 
    comparable price signals with regard to their uses of the system.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The precise methodology to be used to credit revenues from off-
    system sales for the benefit of the tariff customers should be 
    addressed in the compliance filing proceedings and will depend on the 
    particular rate design methodology that is ultimately employed. APPA's 
    proposed monthly pass-through of revenue credits raises potential 
    issues including: (1) use of estimates versus actuals; (2) the 
    appropriate time period to be utilized; and (3) firm versus non-firm 
    distinctions. Accordingly, the issue of determining appropriate revenue 
    credits is properly left for case-by-case determinations. However, we 
    agree with APPA that revenue from the transmission component of all 
    off-system uses of the transmission system (whether by the transmission 
    provider or a transmission customer) must be treated on a comparable 
    basis, whether through rate design or through revenue credits.
    (b) Facilities and System Impact Studies
        In the Final Rule, the Commission explained that comparability 
    mandates that to the extent a transmission provider charges 
    transmission customers for the costs of performing specific facilities 
    studies or system impact studies related to a service request, the 
    transmission provider also must separately record the costs associated 
    with specific studies undertaken on behalf of its own native load 
    customers, or, for example, for making an off-system sale.412
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \412\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,764; mimeo at 381-82.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        No requests for rehearing addressed this matter.
    (c) Ancillary Services
        In the Final Rule, the Commission indicated that, at this time, it 
    was not convinced that the amounts involved or the difficulty 
    associated with measuring the cost of ancillary services warrants a 
    departure from our present accounting requirements.413
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \413\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,764-65; mimeo at 382-83.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        No requests for rehearing addressed this matter.
    (3) Miscellaneous Clarifications
    (a) Electronic Format
        In the Final Rule, the Commission required that public utilities, 
    in addition to complying with the requirements of Part 35, submit a 
    complete electronic version of all transmission tariffs and service 
    agreements in a word processor format, with the diskette labeled as to 
    the format (including version) used, initially and each time changes 
    are filed.414
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \414\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,766; mimeo at 386.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        No requests for rehearing addressed this matter.
    (b) Administrative Changes
        In the Final Rule, the Commission set forth a number of tariff 
    modifications that it indicated needed no further explanation.415
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \415\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,766-67; mimeo at 386-88.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    8. Specific Tariff Provisions
        The Commission attached a pro forma tariff to the Final Rule as 
    Appendix D. A number of entities have sought rehearing of various 
    sections of that pro forma tariff. Their arguments and the Commission's 
    responses are set forth below.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Oklahoma G&E asks that the Commission add a definition for 
    ``Interconnection'' that would be an interface where one or more points 
    of delivery or points of receipt are located.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We disagree with Oklahoma G&E that there is a need to add a 
    definition for ``Interconnection'' to the Final Rule pro forma tariff. 
    Oklahoma G&E has not supported its need for the proposed change and has 
    failed to identify any potential problems that may result if its 
    definition is not included.
    
    Sections 1.12, 15.4 and 32.4
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Cajun argues that the Commission should mandate joint planning in 
    the development of Facilities Studies. It alleges that a transmission 
    provider's independent long-range plans frequently include longer, 
    higher voltage facilities than are needed for the transmission 
    customers' requirements. It further alleges that absent mandatory joint 
    transmission planning, the transmission customers will always be paying 
    for the incremental capacity cost of transmission enhancements that 
    only fit into the Transmission Provider's independent long-range plans.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        A joint planning mandate as recommended by Cajun, NRECA and others 
    is beyond the scope of this proceeding. However, the Commission 
    encourages utilities to engage in joint planning with other utilities 
    and customers and to allow affected customers to participate in 
    facilities studies to the extent practicable. Moreover, on a regional 
    basis, the Commission encourages the formation
    
    [[Page 12353]]
    
    of RTGs and ISOs to represent the needs of all participants in a region 
    in the planning process.
    Section 1.14
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        CCEM asserts that the term Good Utility Practice is vague. It 
    argues that the Commission should delete the reference to regional 
    practices, but if it does not, the term should be clearly defined in 
    each utility's tariff.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Commission recognizes that unique operating practices and 
    conditions exist on a regional basis throughout the industry. 
    Accordingly, the Commission permits certain deviations to the non-price 
    terms and conditions of the tariff. In the Final Rule, we stated that 
    any proposed modifications by the utility to the tariff to recognize 
    regional operations and practices must be demonstrated to be 
    reasonable, generally accepted in the region, and consistently adhered 
    to by the transmission provider.416
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \416\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,770; mimeo at 397-98. The 
    Commission has applied its approach to regional practices in filings 
    made in compliance with Order No. 888. See, e.g., American Electric 
    Power Service Corporation, et al., 78 FERC para. 61,070 (1997); 
    Allegheny Power System, Inc., et al., 77 FERC para. 61,266 (1996); 
    Atlantic City Electric Company, et al., 77 FERC para. 61,144 (1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Sections 1.22 and 1.25
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Blue Ridge requests clarification that a portion of a designated 
    network resource need not consist of the entirety of a generating unit.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Blue Ridge's request for clarification in the definition of 
    ``Network Load'' in Tariff Section 1.22 and ``Network Resource'' in 
    Tariff Section 1.25 is not necessary. Blue Ridge's concerns are based 
    on the mistaken premise that a designated network resource must consist 
    of the entirety of a generating unit. Tariff sections 1.25 and 30.1 
    explicitly specify that a network resource can be a portion of a 
    generating resource or unit. Indeed, the Commission recently emphasized 
    this point:
    
        Ohio Cooperatives have disregarded the fact that a designated 
    resource can be a part of a unit. In this example, Ohio Cooperatives 
    would make two network designations for the 300 MW unit: a 100 MW 
    designation for the 100 MW load on one system and a 200 MW 
    designation for the 200 MW on the other system.417
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \417\ Order On Non-Rate Terms and Conditions, 77 FERC para. 
    61,144 (mimeo at 15-16) (1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Sections 1.25 and 30.1
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        TDU Systems asserts that these sections should not be read to 
    require assignment of specific Network Resources to specific control 
    areas. They state that multiple control area network customers need to 
    be able to dispatch their resources economically to serve their loads. 
    They argue that the Commission would be in error to require that a 
    transmission customer's resources be segmented if they are being 
    dispatched to serve network load in one of several control areas and 
    once so segmented, sales from such units be considered either third-
    party sales or become interruptible as to network load in a second 
    control area and thus are not deemed Network Resources. They further 
    argue that TDU systems with loads and resources in multiple control 
    areas must be allowed to designate as Network Resources for each 
    control area the totality of their resources which meet the owned or 
    purchased requirements of section 1.25.
        TDU Systems argues that these sections should be revised to include 
    resources that are leased by a network customer on terms tantamount to 
    ownership, or which, at a minimum, afford the network customer a first 
    call right to that generating resource.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        TDU Systems' proposed revision to recognize leased resources 
    appears reasonable and we revise these sections of the pro forma 
    tariff, in relevant part, as follows (new text underlined, deleted text 
    in brackets):
    
    1.25  Network Resource: Any designated generating resource owned, [or] 
    purchased or leased by a Network Customer under the Network Integration 
    Transmission Service Tariff.
    30.1  Designation of Network Resources: Network Resources shall include 
    all generation owned, [or] purchased or leased by the Network Customer 
    designated to serve Network Load under the Tariff.
    
    Sections 1.33 and 1.34
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        CCEM states that sections 1.33 and 1.34 should be changed to 
    facilitate umbrella service agreements that include all points of 
    receipt and delivery on a transmission provider's system.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Consistent with our ruling in section IV.G.6 (Umbrella Service 
    Agreement) regarding umbrella type service agreements for short-term 
    firm point-to-point transmission service, we will modify sections 1.33 
    and 1.34 to require that Points of Receipt and Points of Delivery be 
    specified in the service agreement for only Long-Term (more than one 
    year) Firm Point-to-Point Transmission service.
    
    Section 1.47
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Wisconsin Municipals asks the Commission to clarify that a utility 
    is not prevented from including the load of interruptible customers in 
    the denominator of the fraction used to perform the load ratio 
    calculation. It claims that this is important in Wisconsin where the 
    transmission system is planned without regard to the distinction 
    between firm and interruptible power customers (interruptible customers 
    are not subject to interruption for transmission reasons).
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The treatment of interruptible loads in the planning and operation 
    of the Wisconsin transmission grid present a unique, case-specific 
    situation that is best addressed on a case-by-case basis. As the 
    Commission stated in the Final Rule:
    
    all tariffs need not be ``cookie-cutter'' copies of the Final Rule 
    tariff. Thus, under our new procedure, ultimately a tariff may go 
    beyond the minimum elements in the Final Rule pro forma tariff or 
    may account for regional, local, or system-specific factors. The 
    tariffs that go into effect 60 days after publication of this Rule 
    in the Federal Register will be identical to the Final Rule pro 
    forma tariff; however, public utilities then will be free to file 
    under section 205 to revise the tariffs, and customers will be free 
    to pursue changes under section 206.[418]
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \418\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,770 n. 514; mimeo at 399 n. 514.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Section 1.48
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Oklahoma G&E asks the Commission to clarify that the term 
    ``Transmission Service'' as used in the pro forma tariff includes 
    service provided on a network basis as well as on a point-to-point 
    basis.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Commission used the term ``Transmission Service'' throughout 
    the pro forma tariff to refer only to point-to-point service and not 
    network service. We also note that the term ``transmission service'' 
    (in lower case), which is also used throughout the pro
    
    [[Page 12354]]
    
    forma tariff, was used to refer to both point-to-point and network 
    service. Oklahoma G&E has not identified any problems associated with 
    our use of these terms and therefore has not supported its proposed 
    modification.
    
    Section 1.49
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Santa Clara and Redding state that the transmission system is 
    defined as facilities owned, controlled or operated and that this could 
    result in the same transmission facilities being the part of the 
    transmission system of two entities (e.g., COTP, which is owned by 
    TANC, but operated by Western Area Power Administration (WAPA)). They 
    ask the Commission to clarify that only one such entity should have the 
    obligation to provide transmission service.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        This presents a fact-specific situation that is best addressed on a 
    case-by-case basis. This situation would appear to arise for WAPA and 
    TANC only if either utility receives a request for reciprocal 
    transmission service or if either utility files a voluntary tariff. The 
    appropriate entity to include the COTP facility in its transmission 
    system for purposes of a transmission tariff may depend upon the 
    circumstances of the transmission request. Therefore, a resolution of 
    this question is appropriately deferred until such time as reciprocal 
    service using the COTP facility is requested.
    
    Section 3
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        CCEM asks the Commission to clarify that a transmission customer 
    may switch its supplier of ancillary services.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Final Rule requires that transmission customers obtain all 
    necessary ancillary services for their transactions. They must purchase 
    certain of these services from the transmission provider, but can self 
    supply or obtain certain services from a third party. Consistent with 
    these requirements, a transmission customer may switch suppliers of 
    ancillary services not required to be provided by the transmission 
    provider if it continues to demonstrate that it satisfies its ancillary 
    service obligations.
    
    Section 5.1
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        ConEd points out that this section applies to Transmission Service, 
    which the tariff defines to mean point-to-point service only. It 
    requests that this section be clarified to include network service.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The use of the term ``Transmission Service'' in section 5.1 of the 
    pro forma tariff was an inadvertent error. We will change the term 
    ``Transmission Service'' used in section 5.1 to ``transmission 
    service'' so as to include both point-to-point and network transmission 
    service.
    
    Section 6
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        CCEM asks the Commission to require that the text of the required 
    sworn statement by non-transmission owning entities that they are not 
    assisting an Eligible Customer be included in the tariff.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We will deny CCEM's request as unnecessary. The Commission does not 
    believe that it must mandate the precise text of the required sworn 
    statement. Rather, the entity requesting transmission service properly 
    has the burden of explaining in a sworn statement the circumstances of 
    its service request, including on whose behalf it may be requesting 
    service (for itself or for another party).
    
    Section 8
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        CCEM argues that, consistent with Commission policy for natural gas 
    pipelines, transmission providers should be required to refund all 
    ``penalties'' that are in excess of the costs incurred to balance 
    transmitting system operations (citing Transco, 55 FERC para. 61,446 at 
    62,372 (1991) and TETCO, 62 FERC para. 61,015 at 61,117 (1993)).
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        CCEM's argument is premature. Order No. 888 did not establish a 
    rate or a penalty for Energy Imbalance Service. CCEM is free to raise 
    this concern at such time as utilities file their proposed rates for 
    Energy Imbalance Service.
    
    Section 11
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        CCEM contends that an unconditional and irrevocable letter of 
    credit is extremely costly to obtain and could be used as subterfuge 
    for discriminatorily denying service. CCEM argues that if an 
    irrevocable letter of credit is used, a transmission provider should 
    not be able to draw on it until it tenders a bill that has been 
    improperly refused. (CCEM attached a proposed conditional letter of 
    credit to its rehearing request). Several entities argue that a letter 
    of credit should not be required for existing customers with a 
    satisfactory credit history and should only apply to new customers or 
    those with a history of payment delinquency.419
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \419\ E.g., Santa Clara, Redding, TANC.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        While a transmission provider may require an unconditional and 
    irrevocable letter of credit, if a customer believes that the 
    transmission provider unreasonably rejected an alternative security 
    proposal, it may seek relief through the dispute resolution procedures 
    established in Tariff Section 12. Moreover, if a customer believes a 
    transmission provider is attempting to use the unconditional and 
    irrevocable letter of credit in an unduly discriminatory manner, it may 
    file a complaint raising such concern in a section 206 filing.
    
    Section 12
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        According to Public Service Co of CO, the dispute resolution 
    procedures: (1) Should allow a party to appeal an arbitration award on 
    the basis that arbitrators have misinterpreted the requirements of the 
    pro forma tariff and (2) where a utility is a member of an RTG, should 
    allow the RTG dispute resolution procedures to be exclusive. Otherwise, 
    Public Service Co of CO argues, entities may perceive that the 
    Commission's procedures are more favorable than the RTG's and decide 
    not to join. Moreover, it asserts that when a utility that is a member 
    of an RTG has a dispute with a customer that is a non-member, the 
    customer's forum should be the Commission, or the RTG's procedures if 
    those procedures apply to non-members.
        Dispute Resolution Associates asks the Commission to require that 
    prior to submission of disputes for arbitration or Commission 
    disposition, disputants should be required to pursue a mediated 
    resolution with a qualified individual. If unsuccessful, it states that 
    parties can elect arbitration or Commission disposition. If successful, 
    it states that parties will have avoided litigation related costs and 
    will not have jeopardized their ongoing business relationship. Dispute 
    Resolution Associates also argues that representatives at all 
    negotiating sessions should be authorized to enter into an agreement 
    and asks that the Commission clarify that dispute resolution is one of 
    the minimum requirements of the Final Rule. It also asks that the 
    Commission require that any filed separate retail transmission
    
    [[Page 12355]]
    
    tariffs must include section 12 type dispute resolution procedures.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Concerning the first issue raised by Public Service Co of CO, even 
    if the arbitrator misinterprets the requirements of the pro forma 
    tariff, the dispute resolution procedures require such decision (as it 
    affects terms and conditions of service) to be filed with the 
    Commission. Section 12.2 provides:
    
        The final decision of the arbitrator must also be filed with the 
    Commission if it affects jurisdictional rates, terms and conditions 
    of service or facilities.
    
        As to Public Service Co of CO's second concern, a utility's 
    membership in an RTG with its own Dispute Resolution Procedures 
    presents a fact specific situation to which a generic response is not 
    appropriate. Whether both parties to a dispute are members of the RTG 
    or only one of the parties is a member may have some bearing on which 
    set of Dispute Resolution Procedures should apply.
        Regarding Dispute Resolution Associates concerns, a utility is free 
    to propose an initial process using ``mediated resolution with a 
    qualified individual'' prior to using the Dispute Resolution 
    Procedures. However, we see no need to modify the tariff to introduce 
    such a proposed requirement as the Commission is not aware of other 
    parties similarly claiming excessive costs or the threat of 
    ``jeopardizing ongoing business relationship[s]'' due to the present 
    Dispute Resolution Procedures. Finally, any attempts to delete the 
    Dispute Resolution Procedures from any tariff on file with the 
    Commission would require the transmission provider to demonstrate that 
    its proposed modifications are consistent with or superior to the pro 
    forma tariff terms and conditions.
    
    Section 13.2
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        CCEM asserts that the term ``reserved service'' should be changed 
    to ``requested service.'' Utilities For Improved Transition and Florida 
    Power Corp assert that the limitations on unconditional reservations 
    are too stringent and that the Commission should modify the third 
    sentence of section 13.2 to provide: ``If the Transmission System 
    becomes oversubscribed, requests for longer-term service may preempt 
    requests for shorter-term service up to a time period before the 
    requested commencement of service that is equal to the requested term 
    of service.''
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We will deny CCEM's request to replace the term ``reserved 
    service'' in tariff section 13.2 with ``requested service.'' CCEM has 
    not attempted to identify any uncertainties caused by the current 
    wording of this section or explain any improvements that its proposed 
    change would make.
        Utilities For Improved Transition and Florida Power Corp's proposal 
    to revise the deadline for when reservations for short-term firm 
    transmission become unconditional is contrary to the Commission's 
    intent in adopting the conditional reservation approach for short-term 
    firm transmission and is rejected. Specifically, for service requests 
    greater than a single day, week or month, Utilities For Improved 
    Transition and Florida Power Corp's proposal decreases the period of 
    time that such request is conditional; in other words, such request 
    increases the unconditional reservation period, thus reducing the 
    amount of longer-term transactions that the transmission provider can 
    accommodate.
    
    Sections 13.2 and 14.2
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        CCEM notes that short-term firm point-to-point transmission service 
    customers that have already reserved service have a right to match any 
    longer-term requests for service before being preempted pursuant to 
    section 13.2. However, CCEM states that these tariff sections do not 
    establish a deadline for when such right must be exercised. Because the 
    tariff established a conditional reservation period for short-term firm 
    transmission service (during which time longer-term firm transmission 
    requests can preempt shorter-term conditional reservations) CCEM 
    suggests that a shorter-term firm transmission customer should be 
    allowed to exercise its right to match longer-term service requests up 
    until the end of the conditional reservation period. CCEM requests a 
    similar clarification for non-firm transmission service but does not 
    propose specific modification.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        While we agree with CCEM regarding the need to establish a deadline 
    for exercising the right to match longer-term service requests for both 
    short-term firm and non-firm transmission services, we will reject 
    CCEM's proposed deadline for short-term firm transmission service. 
    CCEM's proposed deadline would create market inefficiency by allowing 
    the holder of the shorter-term firm transmission service an excessive 
    amount of time to exercise its right to match the longer-term service. 
    We feel that such a proposal could constitute a form of hoarding that 
    would stifle the consummation of potential transactions and should not 
    be allowed. CCEM's proposal would work to the detriment of any and all 
    potential customer(s) requesting longer short-term firm transmission 
    service. By allowing the original transmission customer to delay its 
    response, the subsequent potential customer will be disadvantaged and 
    may be required to make last minute alternative arrangements.
        We believe that an especially quick response time is necessary for 
    hourly non-firm transmission service customers to match longer-term 
    service requests. Hourly non-firm transmission customers must exercise 
    their right to match longer-term service requests immediately upon 
    notification by the transmission provider of a longer-term competing 
    request for non-firm transmission service. For non-firm transmission 
    service other than hourly transactions and short-term firm transmission 
    service, we believe a customer should exercise its right to match 
    longer-term service requests as soon as practicable. The prompt 
    exercising of such right is particularly critical where scheduling 
    deadlines for such transactions are imminent. However, even for 
    transactions with longer lead-times before service is to commence, we 
    believe a response deadline of no more than 24 hours from being 
    informed by the transmission provider of a longer-term competing 
    request for transmission service is appropriate. Accordingly, the 
    customer will be required to respond to the transmission provider as 
    soon as practicable after notification of a longer-term request for 
    service, but no longer than 24 hours from being notified or earlier if 
    required to comply with the scheduling requirements for such services 
    in tariff section 13.8 and 14.6. Tariff sections 13.2 and 14.2 will be 
    modified accordingly.
    
    Section 13.5
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Several utilities argue that section 13.5 is too broad because it 
    also applies to costs that are included in rates on an embedded cost 
    basis (which they claim can be evaluated when the transmission provider 
    makes a rate filing).420 They recommend that the Commission
    
    [[Page 12356]]
    
    modify the last sentence of the section as follows:
    
        \420\ E.g., Florida Power Corp, Utilities For Improved 
    Transition, VEPCO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        If redispatch costs or Network Upgrade costs are to be charged 
    to the Transmission Customer on an incremental basis or costs 
    relating to Direct Assignment Facilities that are to be charged to 
    the Transmission Customer, the obligation of the customer to pay 
    such costs shall be specified in the Service Agreement prior to the 
    initiation of service.'' (Utilities For Improved Transition at 74-
    75).
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Commission's intent in tariff section 13.5 was to require that 
    any proposal to assess incremental charges to a customer must be 
    specified in that customer's service agreement. Florida Power Corp and 
    VEPCO correctly note that tariff section 13.5 inadvertently requires 
    that any redispatch, network upgrade or direct assignment facilities, 
    whether assessed on an incremental basis or included in embedded cost 
    rates, must be specified in a customer's service agreement. To 
    eliminate this unintended result, tariff section 13.5 is revised in 
    relevant part as follows (new text underlined):
    
        Any redispatch, Network Upgrade or Direct Assignment Facilities 
    costs to be charged to the Transmission Customer on an incremental 
    basis under the Tariff will be specified in the Service Agreement 
    prior to initiating service.
    
    Section 13.6
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        CCEM asserts that the term ``Good Utility Practice'' should be 
    deleted. CCEM claims that the inclusion of regional practices in Good 
    Utility Practice makes the phrase vague and unpredictable. CCEM 
    proposes that the Commission replace this phrase with a qualifier that 
    pertains only to reliability and safety. According to PA Coops, equal 
    priority places inordinate and unwarranted pressure on state siting and 
    regulatory authorities to approve transmission projects required to 
    provide service that may primarily benefit out of state parties. NYSEG 
    argues that the Commission is not authorized to require curtailment of 
    bundled retail service because it does not have jurisdiction over the 
    rates, terms, and conditions of such service. It asserts that 
    transactions subject to proportional curtailment should not include a 
    transmitting utility's own use of its system to transmit its owned and 
    purchased generation to native load customers as part of bundled retail 
    service or services under rate schedules that are grandfathered. For 
    transactions subject to proportional curtailment, NYSEG argues that 
    allocation of curtailments will be comparable only if those multiple 
    transactions being curtailed are of the same type of service and if 
    each of the multiple transactions is for the same duration--these 
    curtailments should be made on the same basis as required for non-firm 
    PTP service. It asks the Commission to clarify that the curtailment 
    requirements are not applicable to existing transmission contracts.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        CCEM's concerns center on the inclusion of the phrase regional 
    practices in the definition of Good Utility Practice in section 1.14 of 
    the pro forma tariff. These concerns are answered in section 1.14 
    above.
        PA Coops' argument that long-term firm point-to-point transmission 
    customers should be curtailed before network service customers and 
    native load ignores the fact that the transmission provider has an 
    obligation under the pro forma tariff to expand or upgrade its 
    transmission system in response to requests for such long-term point-
    to-point transmission requests. In turn, such long-term firm point-to-
    point transmission customers undertake an obligation to pay for any 
    transmission facility additions necessary for the provision of service 
    pursuant to the tariff. Comparability requires that all long-term firm 
    transmission customer be treated on a not unduly discriminatory basis 
    in terms of curtailment priority.
        Regarding NYSEG's arguments, the purpose of the curtailment 
    provisions of the pro forma tariff is not to ``requir[e] curtailment of 
    bundled retail service'' as NYSEG claims. Rather, the provision simply 
    requires the transmission provider to curtail network and point-to-
    point transmission services on a basis comparable to the curtailment of 
    the transmission provider's service to its native load. Indeed, we have 
    repeatedly indicated that we do not have jurisdiction over bundled 
    retail sales.
        NYSEG's concerns regarding curtailment provisions in existing 
    contracts are addressed above in Section IV.G.3.a. (Pro-rata 
    Curtailment Provisions).
    
    Section 13.7
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Utilities For Improved Transition and Florida Power Corp state that 
    section 13.7 of the pro forma tariff makes it uneconomic to engage in 
    system sales transactions on a firm basis because it requires the 
    transmission provider to impose a separate charge for transmission from 
    each generating station. They ask that the Commission clarify that if 
    there is a sale from multiple generators, a reservation of transmission 
    from each point of receipt will be required only in the amount of the 
    expected relative contribution of each generating station to the energy 
    that is sold. If it is not so clarified, they argue that the Commission 
    should make one of the following modifications: (1) permit the customer 
    to designate more than one generating station as a single point of 
    receipt if it provides likely loadings of the units to the transmission 
    provider; (2) provide that where the customer takes service from a 
    group of generating stations on an economic dispatch basis, the 
    reserved capacity is the sum of the reservations at the points of 
    delivery (must also provide likely loadings); or (3) add a new 
    subsection to Article 31 that provides that a network integration 
    transmission customer may also reserve service on a contract demand 
    basis for periods as short as one day (but do not reduce the one-year 
    minimum term for load-based network service).
        CSW Operating Companies asserts that the Commission should permit 
    sales of power from multiple points of receipt, but such multiple 
    generating units should be considered a single point of receipt. 
    According to CSW Operating Companies, this provides maximum 
    flexibility, lessens the need to establish secondary points of receipt, 
    and is consistent with FMPA v. FPL, 74 FERC para. 61,006 at 61,014 
    (1996). They ask that the Commission revise section 13.7(b) to provide: 
    ``The Transmission Customer may purchase transmission service to make 
    sales of capacity and energy from multiple generating units that are on 
    the Transmission Provider's Transmission System. Such multiple 
    generating units shall be considered a single Point of Receipt when the 
    underlying sale is to be made on a system basis and not from specific 
    generating units.'' (CSW Operating Companies at 10-11). TAPS requests 
    that the Commission clarify that a network customer may make system 
    sales to third parties using the point-to-point provisions without 
    designating each generating resource as a point of receipt. Moreover, 
    it asks that if the Commission intends to depart from FMPA v. FPL, that 
    transmission providers be held to the same burden.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Several utilities request rehearing on the tariff's requirement 
    that sales of capacity and energy from multiple generating units must 
    be designated as multiple points of receipt under point-to-point 
    transmission service. These parties generally claim that this tariff 
    requirement makes system sales
    
    [[Page 12357]]
    
    transactions uneconomical and is contrary to the Commission's 
    determination in FMPA v. FPL, 74 FERC para. 61,006 at 61,014 (1996).
        As the Commission stated in the Final Rule:
    
    all tariffs need not be ``cookie-cutter'' copies of the Final Rule 
    tariff. Thus, under our new procedure, ultimately a tariff may go 
    beyond the minimum elements in the Final Rule pro forma tariff or 
    may account for regional, local, or system-specific factors. The 
    tariffs that go into effect 60 days after publication of this Rule 
    in the Federal Register will be identical to the Final Rule pro 
    forma tariff; however, public utilities then will be free to file 
    under section 205 to revise the tariffs, and customers will be free 
    to pursue changes under section 206.[421]
    
        \421\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,770 n. 514; mimeo at 399 n. 514.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Utilities that advocate modifying the pro forma tariff to accommodate 
    system sales are free to file their specific proposals with the 
    Commission in a section 205 filing.422 Such proposals are best 
    reviewed on a case-specific basis where the type of system sales 
    engaged in by the transmission provider or transmission customer can be 
    identified and described in detail. In order to ensure comparability, 
    any proposed tariff modifications submitted in order to facilitate 
    system sales of the transmission provider must also apply for sales by 
    transmission customers as well.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \422\ See Commonwealth Edison Company and Commonwealth Edison 
    Company of Indiana, Inc., 78 FERC para. 61,090 (January 31, 1997).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Section 13.7(b)
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Blue Ridge argues that because units at the same geographic 
    location can be connected to the system at different electrical 
    locations, such as connections at different voltage levels (e.g., one 
    unit connected at 500 kV and another unit connected at 230 kV), the 
    Commission should replace the phrase ``at the same generating plant'' 
    with ``at the same electrical location.'' (Blue Ridge at   23-24).
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Blue Ridge's proposed change is unsupported. The rationale 
    supporting the need for such change and its intended result is unclear 
    and unexplained and appears to be unnecessary and overly restrictive. 
    Many generating units at a single plant are connected to the 
    transmission grid at multiple voltages. Therefore, taking Blue Ridge's 
    proposal to its logical end, a customer could face an additional charge 
    at a single unit for every voltage level connection. In contrast, the 
    intent of section 13.7(b) of the pro forma tariff is to treat multiple 
    units at a single plant as a single point of receipt to avoid charging 
    a customer an unnecessary additional charge.
    
    Section 13.8
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        CCEM asks the Commission to clarify that permissible scheduling 
    changes extend to changes in the amount of power scheduled, the 
    generation source, and delivery and receipt points. AMP-Ohio asserts 
    that if the transmission provider can accommodate a change, the 
    customer should be able to change its schedule less than 20 minutes 
    before the hour or during the hour, and during an emergency or when the 
    customer is attempting to remain within the 1.5% deviation band. It 
    also asks the Commission to clarify that customers should be allowed to 
    aggregate multiple points of delivery of less than a whole megawatt to 
    be stated in whole megawatts (as is allowed for points of receipt). 
    Otherwise, AMP-Ohio asserts, this would preclude small utilities from 
    receiving service under a transmission provider's open access tariff.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We agree with CCEM that permissible scheduling changes include the 
    amount of power scheduled (up to the amount of capacity reservation 
    stated in the customer's service agreement). However, a proposed 
    modification to the generation source or to receipt and delivery points 
    on a firm basis under the pro forma tariff is not simply a scheduling 
    change, as maintained by CCEM, but is a new request for service, as set 
    forth in pro forma tariff section 22.2.
        AMP-Ohio's request regarding scheduling changes ignores the 
    optional language in section 13.8 of the pro forma tariff, which 
    permits a reasonable time limitation (other than the stated twenty 
    minute deadline) that is ``generally accepted in the region and is 
    consistently adhered to by the transmission provider.'' Accordingly, 
    the pro forma tariff may be amended by the transmission provider to 
    reflect the prevailing practice in the region.
        AMP-Ohio's request regarding scheduling changes to allow the 
    customer to stay within the deviation band of 1.5 percent may not be 
    feasible depending upon the ramping rates of the particular generating 
    units and may allow erratic scheduling by customers that could 
    interfere with the transmission provider's ability to provide load 
    following service.
        AMP-Ohio's request for clarification that customers should be 
    allowed to aggregate multiple points of delivery of less than a whole 
    megawatt is unnecessary. Tariff section 17.2(viii) specifically allows 
    customers to combine their requests for service for either points of 
    receipt or points of delivery in order to satisfy the minimum 
    transmission capacity requirement.
    
    Section 14.2
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Tallahassee asks the Commission to clarify that a non-firm customer 
    facing possible interruption for economic reasons will be allowed to 
    match the duration and price of the surviving transaction and that once 
    a non-firm transaction begins, it will not be preempted without 
    whatever notice is sufficient and appropriate in the region, but the 
    time period should be no shorter than 1-2 hours.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The pro forma tariff does allow a customer to match a longer term 
    reservation before being preempted. Moreover, non-firm transmission 
    transactions, by definition, are interruptible for economic reasons (on 
    a non-discriminatory basis) at any time. To the extent a prevailing 
    regional practice exists regarding advance notice of interruption, the 
    transmission provider may incorporate such a provision in its tariff.
    
    Section 14.4
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        CCEM asks the Commission to clarify that a non-firm point-to-point 
    service agreement is an Umbrella Agreement and a non-firm point-to-
    point customer should be able to schedule a transaction at different 
    primary and secondary receipt points and schedule changes in primary 
    points with no filing requirement.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The form of service agreement for non-firm transmission service is 
    a non-transaction specific umbrella service agreement (See Attachment B 
    to the pro forma tariff). Therefore, the service agreement does not 
    require a specification of receipt and delivery points for non-firm 
    point-to-point transmission service. However, we note that changes to 
    the receipt or delivery points for non-firm transmission service other 
    than those points reserved by the transmission customer in its service 
    request are not ``schedule'' changes as claimed by CCEM, but will 
    require the
    
    [[Page 12358]]
    
    submission of a new application for service pursuant to Tariff Section 
    18.
    
    Section 14.6
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        CCEM asks the Commission to clarify that ``scheduling changes'' for 
    non-firm transmission include changes in the amounts scheduled, changes 
    in receipt and delivery points, or changes in primary points.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        This issue is addressed in Section 13.8 above.
    
    Sections 17, 18 and 29.2
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        The EPRI/NERC Working Group (formerly the ``What and How Industry 
    Working Group'') identifies certain areas in the pro forma tariff 
    ``where the perceived scope of OASIS has grown beyond that which is 
    feasible in Phase 1'' of OASIS. (EPRI/NERC Working Group at 2). EPRI/
    NERC Working Group references various information required in the 
    application process under the pro forma tariff that is required to be 
    submitted via OASIS to the transmission provider. EPRI/NERC Working 
    Group explains that a substantial amount of information required under 
    the pro forma tariff ``cannot be provided via the OASIS in Phase 1'' 
    (e.g., service agreements, requests for (A) non-firm point-to-point 
    transmission service in the next hour, (B) multiple receipt and 
    delivery points, (C) addition of new network loads or resources, 
    loadflow and stability data).
        The EPRI/NERC Working Group also claims that tariff section 17.1 
    creates confusion as it first requires that ``[a] request for Firm 
    Point-To-Point Transmission Service * * * must contain a written 
    Application * * *'' to the transmission provider, but then requires 
    ``[a]ll Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service requests should be 
    submitted by entering the information listed below on the Transmission 
    Provider's OASIS.'' (Emphasis added). The EPRI/NERC Working Group 
    asserts that the above language confuses the process of an 
    ``application for service agreement'' versus the process of ``a request 
    for transmission service'' by a customer who already has a service 
    agreement.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Commission recognizes that implementation of the OASIS is being 
    accomplished in phases. In recognition of this fact, section 17.1 of 
    the pro forma tariff provides:
    
        Prior to implementation of the Transmission Provider's OASIS, a 
    Completed Application may be submitted by (i) transmitting the 
    required information to the Transmission Provider by telefax, or 
    (ii) providing the information by telephone over the Transmission 
    Provider's time recorded telephone line.
    
    Moreover, we clarify that if Phase 1 of OASIS implementation does not 
    support the submission of certain information over the OASIS, such 
    information may be submitted by telephone or telefax (facsimile), as 
    provided in the pro forma tariff, and promptly (within one hour) posted 
    on OASIS by the Transmission Provider.423
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \423\ On December 27, 1996, the Commission issued an order that 
    found that
        During Phase 1, a request for transmission service made after 
    2:00 p.m. of the day preceding the commencement of such service, 
    will be ``made on the OASIS'' if it is made directly on the OASIS, 
    or, if it is made by facsimile or telephone and promptly (within one 
    hour) posted on the OASIS by the Transmission Provider.
        77 FERC para. 61,335 (1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Concerning the EPRI/NERC Working Group's apparent confusion 
    regarding service application processes, we previously explained in 
    Section IV.G.6 that the Commission is modifying the application process 
    for firm point-to-point transmission transaction of less than one year 
    (short-term firm transactions). The Commission will permit an 
    ``umbrella service agreement'' approach where all of a customer's 
    short-term firm transactions can be arranged under a single non-
    transaction specific umbrella service agreement rather than requiring a 
    new service agreement for each short-term firm transaction. In 
    contrast, service agreements for firm point-to-point transmission 
    transactions of one year or more (long-term firm transactions) are 
    transaction specific and require a separate service agreement for each 
    transaction.
    
    Section 17.1
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        CCEM states that the 60 days in advance to request service should 
    be shortened to 6 days. For service shorter than one year, it argues 
    that the procedures should not be left to negotiation with a 
    monopolist. For service greater than one month but less than one year, 
    it asserts that a request should be submitted 3 days in advance; for 
    weekly service, schedules should be submitted by some specific hour the 
    day before service is to commence; and for hourly or daily service, 
    schedules should be submitted no later than 20 minutes in advance.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        CCEM has provided no support for its proposal to shorten the lead 
    time for requests for firm service from sixty days to six days. Sixty 
    days in advance of the commencement of long-term (greater than one 
    year) firm service is not an unreasonable time period. It provides 
    transmission providers time to conduct security analyses, as well as 
    perform system impact studies and facility studies that may be 
    necessary. Accordingly, CCEM's request is denied.
    
    Section 17.2
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        CCEM argues that information concerning the location of the 
    generating facility and the load ultimately served is not required in 
    connection with a good faith request under the Policy Statement 
    Regarding Good Faith Request for Transmission Services and should not 
    be required in a Completed Application. However, if it is required, 
    CCEM argues that it should remain confidential and not be disclosed. It 
    further asks the Commission to clarify that a point-to-point customer 
    can designate all receipt and delivery points in order to obtain 
    umbrella-type service and can schedule receipt and delivery points as 
    primary or secondary and can change primary points by filing another 
    schedule.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We will deny CCEM's proposed changes in part as unnecessary. The 
    locations of generating facilities and loads are needed by the 
    transmission provider to allow it to analyze whether the requested 
    transmission service can be accommodated over the existing transmission 
    system, as well as to plan upgrades and transmission facility 
    additions.424
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \424\ We further note that CCEM's reference to the Commission's 
    Policy Statement Regarding Good Faith Request for Transmission 
    Services does not support its position. As we there stated,
        [a] good faith request for transmission service should also 
    contain a specific, technical description of the requested services 
    in sufficient detail to permit the transmitting utility to model the 
    additional services or its transmission system.
        FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 30,975 at 30,863.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Tariff section 17.2 already requires that ``the transmission 
    provider shall treat this [confidential] information consistent with 
    the standards of conduct contained in Part 37 of the Commission's 
    regulations.''
        With respect to CCEM's request to permit umbrella-type service, we 
    note that we have adopted an umbrella-type service agreement approach 
    for short-term firm transmission service, as
    
    [[Page 12359]]
    
    discussed in Section IV.G.6 (Umbrella Service Agreements).
    
    Section 17.3
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        CCEM asserts that a customer determined to be creditworthy should 
    not have to submit a deposit for firm point-to-point transmission 
    service. CCEM would limit this section to those customers found not to 
    be creditworthy and asks the Commission to clarify that only the costs 
    of system impact studies or facilities studies can be deducted from the 
    deposit.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Section 17.3 reflects a standard requirement in many existing 
    tariffs and other agreements on file with this Commission. CCEM 
    provides no compelling reason to revise this tariff provision.
        We also deny CCEM's request regarding deductions from the deposit. 
    We will not preclude a utility from demonstrating that it incurs costs 
    other than system impact studies or facilities studies in processing a 
    service application and arguing that these costs should be deducted 
    from a deposit.
    
    Section 17.4
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        CCEM argues that a deficiency determination should be made in, at 
    most, one day.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        CCEM provides no compelling reason to revise this tariff provision. 
    CCEM's argument also ignores the fact that certain applications involve 
    more complex unique transactions and associated arrangements which may 
    require more time to review than other more standard applications. 
    CCEM's apparent concern regarding deficient applications should be 
    mitigated by the pro forma tariff requirement that the transmission 
    provider must attempt to remedy minor deficiencies in the application 
    informally with the transmission customer.
    
    Section 17.5
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        CCEM asserts that a transmission provider should respond to a 
    completed application for firm transmission service within 10 minutes 
    for hourly service, 10 minutes for daily service, 4 hours for weekly 
    service, 1 day for monthly service, 2 days for service longer than one 
    month but less than one year, and 5 days for service one year or 
    longer.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Section 17.5 requires the transmission provider to notify the 
    eligible customer as soon as practicable, but no later than 30 days 
    after receipt of a completed application if it can provide the service 
    or if a system impact study will be required. We do not believe that 
    further specificity in establishing deadlines for each type of service 
    and duration of service is necessary. However, we are clarifying 
    section 17.5 to require that all responses be made on a non-
    discriminatory basis. If CCEM believes the transmission provider is 
    engaging in discriminatory behavior by delaying responses to service 
    requests (or by responding to service requests by its wholesale 
    merchant function more quickly than it responds to service requests by 
    unaffiliated customers), it can file a section 206 complaint with the 
    Commission.
    
    Section 17.7
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Several utilities ask the Commission to clarify that, if 
    transmission facilities have been constructed to accommodate a request 
    for transmission service, delays by the customer in commencing service 
    should be prohibited or the customer should pay the full carrying 
    charges on the facilities during the period of delay (less any revenues 
    received).425 Similarly, EEI and Southern argue that if new 
    facilities are constructed, but the customer postpones service by 
    paying a reservation fee, fairness requires that the customer bear its 
    cost responsibility for the new construction at the time the facilities 
    are ready to be used.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \425\ E.g., Utilities for Improved Transition, Florida Power 
    Corp, VEPCO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Because different factual circumstances could exist that may lead 
    to alternative solutions to the problem, we will not adopt a generic 
    resolution. Rather, the Commission believes it appropriate to allow 
    each utility to propose solutions in subsequent section 205 filings 
    with the Commission.
    
    Section 19
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        VA Com asks the Commission to clarify that determining the 
    necessity of a transmission facility upgrade or addition remains a 
    state prerogative. It asserts that native load customers may face 
    reduced reliability, or may incur costs associated with premature 
    additions, if calculations of ATC are incorrect. In addition, it 
    asserts that generating facilities can also be used to relieve regional 
    capacity constraints--``For example, a current proposal by Virginia 
    Electric and Power Company (``Virginia Power'') seeks the Virginia 
    Commission's approval of a major new transmission line. Virginia Power 
    alleges that the line is needed since it would increase the 
    availability of emergency off-system supplies and allow it to lower its 
    capacity reserve requirements. If the Virginia Commission were to 
    approve the line, it is conceivable that FERC could direct Virginia 
    Power to use this additional interchange capability to facilitate 
    wholesale wheeling transactions. In such an event, native load 
    customers may be adversely affected since the utility would be forced 
    to suffer diminished reliability or build additional generation or 
    transmission facilities.'' (VA Com at 10-12). CCEM asks the Commission 
    to require studies for short-term firm point-to-point service or 
    requests for capacity that are posted on the OASIS.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        In the Final Rule, the Commission explicitly stated that
    
    public utilities may reserve existing transmission capacity needed 
    for native load growth and network transmission customer load growth 
    reasonably forecasted within the utility's current planning horizon. 
    However, any capacity that a public utility reserves for future 
    growth, but is not currently needed, must be posted on the OASIS and 
    made available to others through the capacity reassignment 
    requirements, until such time as it is actually needed and 
    used.426
    
        \426\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,694; mimeo at 172.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    This ability to reserve capacity to meet the reliability needs of 
    native load would apply equally to transmission built in the future.
        VA Com requested clarification of the intended treatment by the 
    Commission in the ATC calculation of a transmission line built in lieu 
    of generation for purposes of lowering reserve requirements for native 
    load. If it seeks to withhold capacity in response to a request for 
    service by an eligible customer, the transmission provider will have 
    the burden of proof to demonstrate that any reserved capacity is needed 
    for meeting native load and network customers' load growth or for 
    purposes of meeting a reserve requirement level that is reasonable.
        CCEM's request is unnecessary because system impact studies and 
    facilities studies are required pursuant to tariff section 19 for both 
    long-term and short-term firm point-to-point transmission service.
    
    [[Page 12360]]
    
    Sections 19.2 and 32.2
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Utilities For Improved Transition and VEPCO ask the Commission to 
    modify these sections to require that a system impact study agreement 
    specify the estimated charge instead of the maximum charge so that the 
    transmission provider may collect all prudently incurred study costs.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Utilities For Improved Transition and VEPCO correctly note that the 
    use of the phrase ``maximum'' in the language of tariff sections 19.2 
    and 32.2 may prevent a utility from collecting the full costs of 
    conducting a system impact study despite acting in a prudent manner. 
    Accordingly, the relevant portion of these sections are modified as 
    shown below to eliminate this potential inequity (deleted text in 
    brackets):
    
        (i) The System Impact Study Agreement will clearly specify [the 
    maximum charge, based on] the Transmission Provider's estimate of 
    the actual cost, and time for completion of the System Impact Study. 
    The charge shall not exceed the actual cost of the study.
    
    Sections 19.3 and 19.4
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        TAPS asserts that the 15-day periods for customers to execute a 
    service agreement after completion of a system impact study are too 
    short and should be lengthened to 30 days or the transmission provider 
    should be allowed to provide an extension for cause (with public 
    notice) while the customer is pursuing an agreement in good faith.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        TAPS' proposed changes are not necessary because the eligible 
    customer is provided a sufficient response time considering the 
    situation to which the eligible customer is responding. Specifically, 
    the 15-day period in section 19.3 refers to the situation where the 
    transmission provider has conducted a system impact study and concluded 
    that the requested service can be provided without the need to modify 
    its transmission system. TAPS provides no reason why the eligible 
    customer requesting the service should not be prepared to immediately 
    accept the offer to provide service at the transmission provider's 
    standard rate (without the need for upgrades, the eligible customer 
    would not be assessed incremental transmission charges).
        Similarly, the 15-day period in section 19.4 refers to the time in 
    which the eligible customer has to execute a facilities study agreement 
    in which it agrees to pay the transmission provider for the costs of 
    conducting a facilities study. In contrast, when the facilities study 
    is completed and the eligible customer is provided with a good faith 
    estimate of any direct assignment facilities and/or share of any 
    network upgrades, section 19.4 provides the eligible customer with 30 
    days to respond.
    
    Section 22.1(d)
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Utilities For Improved Transition and Florida Power Corp ask the 
    Commission to modify this section to require that a request for 
    modification of service on a non-firm basis be made by submitting a 
    modification to the original application with an OASIS posting. 
    Otherwise, they assert, this section implies that such modifications 
    would occur without using the transmission provider's OASIS.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Utilities For Improved Transition and Florida Power Corp 
    misinterpret this section of the tariff. The Commission's intention is 
    simply to clarify that the customer's request to modify its firm 
    transmission service to receive service over secondary receipt and 
    delivery points on a non-firm basis would not require a separate 
    application for non-firm transmission service. The concerns expressed 
    with respect to posting on the OASIS are addressed in Order No. 889-A.
    
    Section 23.1
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        CCEM asserts that the Commission sHhould specify the filings 
    necessary for assignment of service referenced in this section or 
    delete the clause. In addition, CCEM asks the Commission to clarify 
    that the identical services will be provided at no additional cost to 
    the assignee or the reseller.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The pro forma tariff is a tariff of general applicability. For 
    administrative reasons, the listing of every conceivable situation in 
    which an assignment or transfer of service from one entity to another 
    may require a separate filing is not feasible. For example, if the 
    Commission lists only a single situation that requires a separate 
    filing and subsequently determines another situation would also require 
    a filing, all of the pro forma tariffs on file with the Commission 
    would need to be revised to reflect the change.
        CCEM's request that the Commission clarify that reassigned services 
    will be provided at no extra cost is also denied. CCEM ignores the fact 
    that nothing in the pro forma tariff prevents the transmission provider 
    from seeking a change in rates pursuant to a section 205 filing whether 
    such filing relates to a general increase in rates to all transmission 
    customers or to additional costs the transmission provider asserts it 
    incurs due to providing service to an assignee. As always, the 
    transmission provider bears the burden of proof of demonstrating that 
    its proposal is just and reasonable.
    
    Section 23.2
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        CCEM asks the Commission whether an assignee can change primary 
    points if there is only a partial assignment.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Whether the assignment is full or partial is immaterial. If an 
    assignee wishes to change its receipt or delivery points on a firm 
    basis (full or partial), the request will be treated as a new request 
    for service as required under tariff sections 22.1 and 23.1. However, 
    if an assignee wishes to change receipt or delivery points on a non-
    firm (full or partial) basis, such change can be accomplished without 
    the need for a new service agreement as provided in pro forma tariff 
    section 22.1.
    
    Sections 25 and 34
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        VT DPS asks the Commission to revise these sections to state that 
    ``all firm customers should share in non-firm revenues'' consistent 
    with the language of the preamble.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        VT DPS' request is denied. The Commission did not intend to mandate 
    the rate methodology used to reflect any cost reductions that may be 
    associated with the provision of non-firm transmission service. While 
    the Commission would generally expect all firm customers to share in 
    non-firm revenues, the use of revenue credits is not the only 
    acceptable method of reflecting non-firm system usage. The transmission 
    provider's method of reflecting revenues from non-firm service should 
    be addressed on a case-by-case basis.
    
    Section 29.1
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        TAPS contends that, to avoid improper use of operating agreements 
    by transmission providers, the
    
    [[Page 12361]]
    
    Commission should either permit network operating agreements to be 
    filed in unexecuted form or include a network operating agreement as 
    part of the pro forma tariff.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The network operating agreement is expected to be a highly detailed 
    agreement between the transmission provider and network customer that 
    establishes the integration of the network customer within the 
    transmission provider's transmission system. Due to the unique 
    characteristics of network customers' systems and the level of 
    customer-specific information and arrangements required under a network 
    operating agreement, it is likely that each network operating agreement 
    will be different for each customer. Accordingly, the Commission does 
    not believe it appropriate to mandate a particular form of network 
    operating agreement for inclusion in the pro forma tariff. However, if 
    a transmission provider wishes to include a generic form of network 
    operating agreement in its pro forma tariff (to be modified as required 
    and as mutually agreed to on a customer-specific basis), it may propose 
    to do so in a section 205 filing or it may file an unexecuted network 
    operating agreement in a section 205 filing.
        To the extent a customer believes a transmission provider is 
    engaging in unduly discriminatory practices via the network operating 
    agreement, the customer may file a section 206 complaint with the 
    Commission.
    
    Section 29.4
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        TDU Systems asserts that this section does not identify who should 
    determine what facilities are ``necessary to reliably deliver capacity 
    and energy. * * *'' It asks the Commission to clarify that this is 
    solely the responsibility of the transmission customer.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        TDU Systems' argument ignores tariff section 35.1, which specifies:
    
    [t]he Network Customer shall plan, construct, operate and maintain 
    its facilities in accordance with Good Utility Practice and in 
    conformance with the Network Operating Agreement. (emphasis added)
    
    Accordingly, the determination of what network customer facilities are 
    ``necessary to reliably deliver capacity and energy * * *'' is to be 
    agreed upon by both the transmission provider and network customer and 
    specified in the network operating agreement. To the extent the parties 
    do not agree, the transmission provider will file an unexecuted network 
    operating agreement with the Commission and we will resolve the 
    dispute.
    
    Section 30.1
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        VT DPS argues that, consistent with section 30.7, section 30.1 
    should not require that a network resource be available on a strictly 
    non-interruptible basis.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        VT DPS' request is denied. The Commission believes that a network 
    customer should only be allowed to designate non-interruptible network 
    resources. To allow otherwise would interfere with the planning process 
    as well as the day-to-day operation of the transmission system to 
    integrate resources with customer's loads (e.g., the transmission 
    provider will be unable to plan for what generation resource will be 
    available to meet a customer's load in the event its designated 
    resource is subject to interruption). Similarly, for operational 
    purposes on a day-to-day basis, an interruption of a network customer's 
    designated resource could cause a transmission constraint.427 
    Because constraints affecting reliability may lead to curtailment or 
    redispatch of all network resources, other network customers would be 
    affected by such interruptions on a load-ratio basis. However, to the 
    extent a network customer wishes to use an interruptible generation 
    source, it can still use this generation source on an as-available 
    basis to import energy to serve its load pursuant to pro forma tariff 
    section 28.4.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \427\ While firm resources can also go off line, the probability 
    of this happening is less than that for interruptible resources.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Section 30.4
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        PA Coops ask the Commission to modify this section ``to permit the 
    Network Resources to be operated at outputs that exceed the Network 
    Customer's designated Network Load plus losses when the Network 
    Resource's output is being sold to a third party or the Network 
    Resource is called upon to be operated by the Network Customer's power 
    pool, ISO or control area operator.'' (PA Coops at 8-9). Similarly, 
    Santa Clara and Redding ask the Commission to modify the last sentence 
    to state: ``* * * exceeds its designated Network Load, plus non-firm 
    sales delivered under Part II, plus losses'' so that network resources 
    will not remain idle when they could otherwise generate non-firm power 
    and energy for sale at competitive prices.
        In addition, TDU Systems argues that the arbitrary limits on the 
    ability of network customers to operate Network Resources prevents 
    economic dispatch or the use of resources to meet load requirements and 
    limits the ability to schedule the output of Network Resources between 
    and among control areas, effectively preventing the network customer 
    from operating an integrated system.428 TDU Systems asserts that 
    the Commission should not presume that a network customer's economic 
    dispatch will burden a transmission provider, but should require a 
    transmission provider to demonstrate that such a burden will occur. 
    TAPS asks the Commission to clarify this section so as to bar not the 
    operation of network resources in excess of network load, but rather 
    the usage of network service in connection with operation of such 
    resources in excess of network load. TAPS adds that section 30.4 is 
    contrary to FMPA v. FPL, 74 FERC at 61,014-15. AEC & SMEPA argues that 
    the Commission should provide the necessary latitude for such resources 
    to be used across multiple control areas to service the total load of 
    transmission users.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \428\ See also NRECA.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Preliminarily, TDU Systems and others' argument that a designated 
    network resource must consist of the entirety of a generating unit is 
    mistaken, as we explained in sections 1.22 and 1.25 above. The 
    Commission's intent in requiring that the output of network resources 
    not exceed network load plus losses is to prevent designated network 
    resources from being used to make firm sales to third parties. This is 
    consistent with the pro forma tariff's requirement in sections 1.25 and 
    30.1 that:
    
        Network Resources may not include resources, or any portion 
    thereof, that are committed for sale to non-designated third party 
    load or otherwise cannot be called upon to meet the Network 
    Customer's Network Load on a non-interruptible basis.
    
        Absent a requirement that network resources always be available to 
    meet a customer's network loads, reliability of service to the network 
    customer as well as to native load and other network customers could be 
    affected, as we describe in detail in section 30.1 above. If a network 
    customer desires to enter into a firm sale from its designated network 
    resources or use such network resources for meeting reserve 
    requirements, it must eliminate the appropriate resources or portions 
    thereof from its designated network
    
    [[Page 12362]]
    
    resources pursuant to pro forma tariff section 30.
        Santa Clara, Redding and others contend that this limitation 
    improperly restricts the use of network resources for non-firm sales. 
    It was not the Commission's intent to prohibit the network customer 
    from engaging in non-firm sales from idle designated network resources. 
    We find that the non-firm operation of network resources will not 
    affect the availability of such resources on a firm basis because such 
    non-firm uses are subject to interruption. Accordingly, the 
    Commission's concerns regarding the reliable provision of network 
    service are satisfied.
        Furthermore, as noted by Pennsylvania Coops, emergencies could 
    arise in which the transmission provider may request that a network 
    customer alter the operation of its network resources in response to a 
    contingency, which action could result in a violation of the limitation 
    in section 30.4. Therefore, the Commission believes an exception to the 
    network resources output limitation is also appropriate for such 
    emergency situations. Accordingly, tariff section 30.4 is revised, in 
    relevant part, consistent with the above findings, as shown below 
    (emphasis added):
    
        The Network Customer shall not operate its designated Network 
    Resources located in the Network Customer's or Transmission 
    Provider's Control Area such that the output of those facilities 
    exceeds its designated Network Load, plus non-firm sales delivered 
    pursuant to Part II of the Tariff, plus losses. This limitation 
    shall not apply to changes in the operation of a Transmission 
    Customer's Network Resources at the request of the Transmission 
    Provider to respond to an emergency or other unforeseen condition 
    which may impair or degrade the reliability of its Transmission 
    System.
    
        The remaining concerns expressed by TDU Systems with respect to the 
    economical operation of a network customer's loads and resources 
    located in multiple control areas are addressed above in Section 
    IV.G.1.b. (Network and Point-to-Point Customers' Uses of the System 
    (so-called ``Headroom'')).
    
    Section 30.6
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        CSW Operating Companies asks the Commission to clarify that a 
    customer has the obligation to replace the loss of a resource that is 
    not physically interconnected with the transmission provider's 
    transmission system within the time that is customary in the region or 
    be subject to curtailment and suggests language to be included as 
    section 33.8. CSW Operating Companies indicates that it intends to 
    include a provision addressing this issue in the form of a network 
    operating agreement included in the individual companies' Final Rule 
    compliance tariffs.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Commission agrees with CSW Operating Companies that the 
    appropriate place to address detailed operational requirements such as 
    this is the Network Operating Agreement. If disputes arise, they can be 
    addressed on a case-by-case basis.
    
    Section 30.7
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Wisconsin Municipals asks the Commission to clarify that, for 
    purposes of comparability between network and point-to-point customers, 
    a customer may not reserve capacity for firm point-to-point 
    transmission service until the customer can show that it owns or has 
    committed to purchase generation under an executed contract that it 
    intends to use over the reserved transmission contract path. Wisconsin 
    Municipals claims that without the requirement to demonstrate ownership 
    or contractual rights to the output of a generation resource, the 
    point-to-point customers will have the advantage over network customers 
    of being able to reserve transmission service over facilities with 
    limited available transmission capacity earlier than network customers. 
    Wisconsin Municipals also argues, in essence, that a single or a few 
    point-to-point customers would be able to engage in hoarding of 
    transmission capacity by reserving all available transmission capacity 
    over certain transmission facilities.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The arguments presented by Wisconsin Municipals in support of its 
    proposal are misplaced. Wisconsin Municipals' assertion that point-to-
    point customers would be able to reserve transmission service over 
    facilities with limited available transmission capacity earlier than 
    network customers overlooks the fact that the Final Rule allows 
    transmission providers to reserve existing transmission capacity needed 
    for native load growth and network transmission customer load growth 
    reasonably forecasted within the transmission provider's current 
    planning horizon.429 Wisconsin Municipals' concerns regarding 
    hoarding of transmission capacity are answered in Section IV.C.6. 
    (Capacity Reassignment). Finally, Wisconsin Municipals' argument that 
    comparability requires that both network and point-to-point customers 
    be required to demonstrate ownership or contractual rights to the 
    output of a generation resource is not persuasive. Network and firm 
    point-to-point transmission service are different services. Firm point-
    to-point transmission service is available for periods as short as one 
    day, whereas network service is designed to accommodate a longer term 
    of service with a minimum term of service of one year. The requirement 
    to demonstrate ownership or contractual rights to generation for 
    network service is necessary because the transmission provider must be 
    able to serve the network load from any of the designated resources. In 
    contrast, point-to-point service is a capacity reservation service 
    between specified points of receipt and points of delivery. 
    Accordingly, this network requirement does not need to be extended to 
    firm point-to-point service under the guise of comparability.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \429\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,694; mimeo at 172.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Section 31.2
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        TDU Systems asks the Commission to clarify that an application for 
    new network load for an existing network customer need only address the 
    additional network service needed to serve the new Network Load and 
    does not in any way implicate the existing network service for which 
    the network customer has already contracted.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        No clarification is necessary. Tariff section 31.2 explicitly 
    states in relevant part:
    
        A designation of new Network Load must be made through a 
    modification of service pursuant to a new Application. (Emphasis 
    added)
    
    Section 32.3
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        TDU Systems asserts that this section requires too short a time for 
    customers to evaluate a system impact study. It argues that, at a 
    minimum, customers should have 60 days to evaluate a study and, in the 
    event of a dispute, the application should remain viable until the 
    dispute is resolved (also argues that the time periods set forth in 
    sections 19.1, 19.4, 32.1, 32.3 and 32.4 are too short).
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        TDU Systems' proposed changes are not necessary as the pro forma 
    tariff provides an eligible customer sufficient time to respond to a 
    system impact
    
    [[Page 12363]]
    
    study. Specifically, the 15-day period in section 32.3 refers to a 
    situation where the transmission provider has conducted a system impact 
    study and concluded that the requested service can be provided without 
    the need to modify its transmission system. TDU Systems provides no 
    reason why the eligible customer should not be prepared to immediately 
    accept the offer of providing service at the transmission provider's 
    standard rate (without the need for upgrades, the eligible customer 
    would not be assessed incremental transmission charges).
        Similarly, the 15 day period in sections 19.1, 19.4, 32.1 and 32.4 
    refer to the time in which the eligible customer has to agree to 
    execute an agreement to pay the transmission provider for costs of 
    conducting studies (a system impact study in sections 19.1 and 32.1 and 
    a facilities study in sections 19.4 and 32.4). TDU Systems provides no 
    reason why it should not be prepared to accept or reject the relatively 
    minor costs of further studies to determine whether its requested 
    transmission service can be accommodated by the transmission provider.
        In contrast, when the facilities study is completed and the 
    eligible customer is provided with a good faith estimate of any direct 
    assignment facilities and/or share of any network upgrades, the 
    eligible customer is given 30 days to respond, which is more than a 
    sufficient time.
    
    Sections 33.2 and 34.4
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        TAPS asserts that the Commission cannot shunt aside the need for 
    ongoing revenue crediting to reduce transmission charges as a rate 
    issue, while allowing monthly redispatch costs to be collected monthly 
    in charges under the tariff. It contends that the Commission must 
    require revenues to be shared on an ongoing, load-ratio basis.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        As discussed above, redispatch of all Network Resources and the 
    transmission provider's own resources is only to be performed to 
    maintain the reliability of the transmission system, not for economic 
    reasons. As a result, the frequency of redispatch charges being 
    assessed to network customers is expected to be infrequent. In 
    addition, the Commission is according substantial flexibility to public 
    utilities to propose appropriate pricing terms in their compliance 
    tariff, which includes the treatment of revenue credits. As mentioned 
    above, there are several methods that utilities can use to properly 
    reflect a benefit from non-firm transmission service to firm 
    transmission customers. We do not believe it appropriate to mandate a 
    specific method, such as automatic monthly flow through of revenue 
    credits, at this time. However, TAPS may pursue this issue when 
    utilities file their compliance rates or subsequent 205 rate filings.
    
    Section 34.3
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Several utilities assert that because the monthly transmission 
    system load is composed in part of the contract demands of all firm 
    point-to-point transmission customers and under the Rule the charge for 
    firm point-to-point service may be derived by dividing the transmission 
    cost of service by the sum of the transmission provider's 12 monthly 
    peak firm transmission loads, the transmission provider is prevented 
    from recovering its entire cost of service.\430\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \430\ E.g., Utilities For Improved Transition, Florida Power 
    Corp, VEPCO (asserts that rates for firm point-to-point service 
    should be developed in the same way).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Maine Public Service states that parties should be allowed to argue 
    on a case-by-case basis that firm transmission revenues should be 
    credited instead of including the demands in the denominator (it 
    indicates that this issue is pending in Docket No. ER95-836). It 
    asserts that the revenue credit method would prevent transmission 
    providers that offered discounts from unjustly being penalized for that 
    decision and is the only method that permits utilities to have an 
    opportunity to recover their costs. It adds that the Commission 
    established procedures to keep gas pipelines whole in this same 
    situation.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        While the Commission established one method of calculating load 
    ratios and allocating costs in Order No. 888,\431\ utilities are free 
    to propose alternative pricing methodologies in a section 205 filing 
    consistent with the Commission's Transmission Pricing Policy 
    Statement.\432\ We note, however, such utilities will have the burden 
    of demonstrating that these methods would not result in over-
    collections of their revenue requirement.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \431\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,738; mimeo at 304.
        \432\ See FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,768-70; mimeo at 394-99.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Section 34.4
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        TDU Systems asks the Commission to clarify, as a matter of 
    comparability, that any mechanism proposed by a transmission provider 
    to collect charges based on opportunity costs associated with 
    redispatch must provide for the collection of other customers' like 
    costs and payments to those customers.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        This issue is addressed in Section IV.G.1.e. (Opportunity Cost 
    Pricing).
    
    Schedules 7 and 8
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        TAPS asks the Commission to clarify that these schedules do not 
    approve ``heightened'' charges for short-term services.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Commission did not specify transmission rates for any tariff 
    services in Order No. 888. The rates for long-term firm transmission, 
    short-term firm transmission and non-firm transmission services are to 
    be proposed by the transmission provider, as listed on Tariff schedules 
    7 and 8, and filed with the Commission. TAPS' argument regarding 
    ``heightened'' charges for these services is therefore premature. TAPS 
    is free to raise this concern at such time as utilities file their 
    proposed transmission rates.
    
    Attachment G
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Santa Clara and Redding ask the Commission to modify Attachment G 
    so that, where interconnection/operational standards are in place and 
    working effectively, additional standards are not imposed simply as a 
    result of switching to the pro forma tariff from its current 
    interconnection service.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The pro forma tariff does not specifically require that the network 
    operating agreement between the transmission provider and network 
    customer must be a new agreement. However, the network operating 
    agreement is expected to be a highly detailed agreement between the 
    transmission provider and network customer establishing the integration 
    of the network customer within the transmission provider's transmission 
    system. Existing agreements between the customer and transmission 
    provider may not provide all of the information required or make all of 
    the technical arrangements required under the pro
    
    [[Page 12364]]
    
    forma tariff (e.g., redispatch and ancillary services information and 
    arrangements.) Nevertheless, to the extent the transmission customer is 
    currently receiving network integration transmission service or similar 
    service and its present interconnection agreement fully comports with 
    the requirements of the terms and conditions of the tariff including 
    the informational requirements specified in tariff sections 33 and 35, 
    then the present interconnection/operations agreement can be 
    substituted for a network operating agreement or modified 
    appropriately.
    9. Miscellaneous Tariff Administrative Changes
        Due to administrative oversight, certain tariff sections require 
    minor corrections or modifications. Because of the administrative 
    nature of these changes, we believe that no further discussion is 
    needed.
    Section 12.1  Internal Dispute Resolution Procedures
    --Changes ``Transmission Service'' to ``transmission service''
    Section 13.6  Curtailment of Firm Transmission Service
    --Changes the description regarding curtailment of multiple 
    transactions to:
    
    the Transmission Provider will curtail service to Network Customers 
    and Transmission Customers taking Firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service on a basis comparable to the curtailment of service to the 
    Transmission Provider's Native Load Customers.
    10. Pro Forma Tariff Compliance Filings
        Absent a waiver, all public utilities must submit, no later than 
    July 14, 1997, a compliance filing that reflects the tariff changes set 
    forth in this order on rehearing.\433\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \433\ To the extent a public utility has been granted a waiver 
    of the Order No. 888 tariff filing requirements (or a non-public 
    utility for reciprocity purposes), it need not submit a request for 
    a separate waiver of the requirements of this order on rehearing.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A conforming pro forma tariff, containing all the revisions and 
    clarifications contained in this order on rehearing, is attached as 
    Appendix B. In addition, an electronic version of the conforming pro 
    forma tariff will be made available on the Commission's electronic 
    bulletin board service (Commission Issuance Posting System (CIPS)) in 
    redline/strikeout form in WordPerfect 5.1 format.
    
    H. Implementation
    
        In the Final Rule, the Commission set forth the details of the 
    implementation procedures and included special implementation 
    requirements for coordination arrangements (power pools, public utility 
    holding companies, and bilateral coordination arrangements).\434\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \434\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,768-70; mimeo at 393-400.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    The Revised Procedures
    
        The Commission adopted slightly different implementation procedures 
    for Group 1 public utilities (tendered for filing open access tariffs 
    before the date of issuance of the Rule) and for Group 2 public 
    utilities (did not tender for filing open access tariffs before the 
    date of issuance of the Rule).
    1. Group 1 Public Utilities
        In the Final Rule, the Commission required Group 1 public 
    utilities, within 60 days following publication of the Final Rule in 
    the Federal Register, to make section 206 compliance filings that 
    contain the non-rate terms and conditions set forth in the Final Rule 
    pro forma tariff and identify any terms and conditions that reflect 
    regional practices, as discussed below.\435\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \435\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,768-69; mimeo at 394-96.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As to rates, the Commission noted that a transmission tariff rate 
    is already in effect for all Group 1 public utilities, except for the 
    few with recently-tendered applications that have not yet been accepted 
    for filing.
        The Commission noted, however, that if a Group 1 public utility 
    determined that certain rate changes are necessitated by the revised 
    non-rate terms and conditions, it may file a new rate proposal under 
    FPA section 205. The Commission indicated that such filings must be 
    ``conforming'' \436\ under the Transmission Pricing Policy Statement 
    and must be made no later than 60 days after publication of the Final 
    Rule in the Federal Register and intervenors may raise any concerns 
    with the filings within 15 days after such filings. \437\ The 
    Commission imposed a blanket suspension for any filings by Group 1 
    public utilities proposing rate changes necessitated by the new non-
    rate terms and conditions. The Commission further indicated that these 
    rates will go into effect, subject to refund, 60 days after publication 
    of this Rule in the Federal Register (the same day on which the non-
    rate terms and conditions of the Final Rule pro forma tariff go into 
    effect).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \436\ As described in the Transmission Pricing Policy Statement, 
    a ``conforming'' proposal is one that meets the traditional revenue 
    requirement and reflects comparability. FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 
    31,005 at 31,141.
        \437\ Given the brief comment period on the compliance filings, 
    the Commission required public utilities to serve copies of their 
    compliance filings (via overnight delivery) on: all participants in 
    their current open access rate proceedings (if applicable); all 
    customers that have taken wholesale transmission service from the 
    utility after the date of issuance of the Open Access NOPR; and the 
    state agencies that regulate public utilities in the states of those 
    participants and customers. By order issued July 2, 1996, the 
    Commission extended the comment period from 15 days to 30 days.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    2. Group 2 Public Utilities
        In the Final Rule, the Commission indicated that Group 2 public 
    utilities will be treated the same as Group 1 public utilities with 
    regard to non-rate terms and conditions, but will be treated slightly 
    differently from Group 1 as to rates, since Group 2 utilities have not 
    filed any proposed rates.\438\ The Commission required these utilities 
    to either: (i) within 60 days following publication of the Final Rule 
    in the Federal Register, make section 206 compliance filings that 
    contain the non-rate terms and conditions set forth in the Final Rule 
    pro forma tariff and identify any terms and conditions that reflect 
    regional practices, as discussed below; and (ii) within 60 days 
    following publication of the Final Rule in the Federal Register, make 
    section 205 filings to propose rates for the services provided for in 
    the tariff, including ancillary services; or (iii) make a ``good 
    faith'' request for waiver. The Commission added that the rates must 
    meet the standards for conforming proposals in the Commission's 
    Transmission Pricing Policy Statement and comply with the guidance 
    concerning ancillary services set forth in this order.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \438\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,769; mimeo at 396-97.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission explained that intervenors may raise any concerns 
    with these filings within 15 days after the filing.\439\ The Commission 
    imposed a blanket suspension for all such rate filings and indicated 
    that they will go into effect, subject to refund, 60 days after the 
    publication of this Rule in the Federal Register (the same day on which 
    the terms and conditions of the compliance tariffs go into effect).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \439\ The Commission held that Group 2 public utilities must 
    serve a copy of their filings (via overnight delivery) on all 
    customers that have taken wholesale transmission service from them 
    since March 29, 1995 (the date of issuance of the Open Access NOPR) 
    and on the state agencies that regulate public utilities in the 
    states where those customers are located. By order issued July 2, 
    1996, the Commission extended the comment period from 15 days to 30 
    days.
    
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [[Page 12365]]
    
    3. Clarification Regarding Terms and Conditions Reflecting Regional 
    Practices
        In the Final Rule, the Commission explained that it had built a 
    degree of flexibility into the tariffs to accommodate regional and 
    other differences. \440\ It explained that certain non-rate Final Rule 
    pro forma tariff provisions specifically allow utilities either to 
    follow the terms of the provision or to use alternatives that are 
    reasonable, generally accepted in the region, and consistently adhered 
    to by the transmission provider (e.g., time deadlines for scheduling 
    changes, time deadlines for determining available capacity). In 
    addition, it explained that other tariff provisions require utilities 
    to follow Good Utility Practice (section 1.14 of the Final Rule pro 
    forma tariff).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \440\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,769-70; mimeo at 397-98.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    4. Future Filings
        In the Final Rule, the Commission indicated that once the 
    compliance tariff and conforming rates go into effect, which would be 
    60 days after publication of the Rule in the Federal Register, a public 
    utility (either Group 1 or Group 2) may file pursuant to section 205 a 
    tariff with terms and conditions that differ from those set forth in 
    this Rule, provided that, among other things, it demonstrates that such 
    terms and conditions are consistent with, or superior to, those in the 
    compliance tariff.441 However, the Commission emphasized that the 
    public utility may not seek to litigate fundamental terms and 
    conditions set forth in the Final Rule. In addition, the Commission 
    explained that the public utility may file whatever rates it believes 
    are appropriate, consistent with the Transmission Pricing Policy 
    Statement.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \441\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,770; mimeo at 398-99.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    5. Waiver
        In the Final Rule, the Commission found that it is reasonable to 
    permit certain public utilities for good cause shown to file, within 60 
    days after the Rule is published in the Federal Register, requests for 
    waiver from some or all of the requirements of this Rule.442 The 
    Commission explained that the filing of a request in good faith for a 
    waiver from the requirement to file an open access tariff will 
    eliminate the requirement that such public utility make a compliance 
    filing unless thereafter ordered by the Commission to do so. The 
    Commission emphasized, however, that it will not exempt such public 
    utility from providing, upon request, transmission services consistent 
    with the requirements of the Final Rule.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \442\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,770; mimeo at 399-400.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Wisconsin Municipals asserts that the Commission should ``require 
    utilities (if requested by their customers) to honor the settlements to 
    which they have agreed and to file the pro forma tariff, modified to 
    incorporate settlement provisions that exceed the minimum provisions of 
    the pro forma tariff, as their implementational filing.'' 
    Alternatively, it asks that the Commission ``require parties with 
    settlements to make a Section 205 filing one day following their 
    implementation filing, change any rates, terms and conditions in the 
    pro forma tariff as necessary to incorporate any superior provisions 
    from their settlement tariffs into the pro forma tariff, and seek any 
    waivers necessary to make the settlement tariff effective 
    immediately.'' (Wisconsin Municipals at 7-10).
        Blue Ridge requests rehearing of the ``unbalanced tariff 
    implementation process that rolls over the due process rights of 
    transmission customers.'' It asserts that utilities should not have the 
    right to file a ```Good Utility Practices,' blank check variance for 
    regional practices in the compliance docket.'' (Blue Ridge at 33-35). 
    Blue Ridge further requests that Group 1 utilities file compliance 
    tariffs in the same docket as their pending open access dockets and 
    asks that subsequent changes be in a separate docket as a new general 
    rate case. Blue Ridge also states that the Commission should explicitly 
    mention that customers have the right to file section 206 requests to 
    change the tariffs.
        Indianapolis P&L argues that the pricing requirements are unjust, 
    unreasonable, unlawful, confiscatory and an abuse of discretion as to 
    Indianapolis P&L. It asserts that its rates are not based on embedded, 
    original cost, but, as a matter of Indiana law, its utility property is 
    valued at the ``fair value,'' which exceeds the embedded original cost 
    of such property. It declares that it is impossible for Indianapolis 
    P&L to comply with both the comparability requirement and the 
    requirement that transmission rates be based on original cost. It 
    states that the requirement to provide transmission service and 
    generation-based ancillary services at rates based on original cost is 
    not comparable to Indianapolis P&L's own use of its assets. 
    Accordingly, it argues that the Commission should allow Indianapolis 
    P&L to set its initial open access rates on a fair value, long-run 
    marginal cost basis. Alternatively, it states that the Commission could 
    grant Indianapolis P&L a waiver from the requirements of the Open 
    Access Rule.
        Indianapolis P&L further argues that the imposition of an 
    obligation to enlarge generation to provide ancillary services is 
    beyond the Commission's statutory authority. It explains that 
    Indianapolis P&L is an incidental transmission owner and a relatively 
    small public utility and asks that the Commission grant it waiver from 
    the requirements of open access and OASIS. In deciding whether to grant 
    a waiver, it asserts that the Commission should also consider system 
    size and configuration, the amount of wholesale revenues or MWH sales, 
    or the availability of competing transmission paths.
        Union Electric argues that the final rules violate procedural due 
    process and that the implementation schedule is unrealistically 
    ambitious. It argues that where the final rules call for changes from 
    the NOPRs that could not be reasonably anticipated, they amount to 
    deprivation of due process and rights to fairness in the administrative 
    process. Indeed, it points out, the Commission itself has not even 
    completed its promulgation of the OASIS Final Rule. Union Electric is 
    concerned that it has not had an adequate time to comply with and 
    comment on the rules.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Wisconsin Municipals has misinterpreted the Commission's findings 
    in Order No. 888, and thus its concerns are without merit. While it is 
    true that Order No. 888 requires all public utilities to make 
    compliance filings containing the non-price terms and conditions set 
    forth in the Final Rule pro forma tariff,443 Order No. 888 also 
    states that ``we are not abrogating existing requirements and 
    transmission contracts generically. * * *'' 444 In short, the 
    Commission is not requiring (or even generically allowing) the 
    abrogation of existing transmission contracts, but is only requiring 
    that jurisdictional transmission providers must also offer transmission 
    service under the Final Rule pro forma tariff in addition to whatever 
    commitments the provider will continue to have under its existing 
    contracts. 445
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \443\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,768-69; mimeo at 394-96.
        \444\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,665; mimeo at 87-88.
        \445\ See also discussion of prior settlements in Section 
    IV.D.1.c.(2) (Energy Imbalance Bandwidth).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As to Wisconsin Municipals' assertions that prior individual 
    settlement provisions may exceed the
    
    [[Page 12366]]
    
    minimum provisions of the pro forma tariff, the Commission believes 
    that such arguments should be addressed on a case-by-case basis. 
    446
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \446\ See IES Utilities, Inc., et al., 78 FERC para. 61,023 
    (1997).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Two additional points are pertinent. First, we note that although 
    we are not generically abrogating existing transmission contracts, 
    utilities retain whatever existing rights they had to propose 
    unilateral changes under section 205 of the FPA if they want to convert 
    a customer to service under the tariff, and customers retain their 
    section 206 right to seek reformation of existing transmission 
    contracts if they are unjust, unreasonable, unduly discriminatory or 
    preferential. Second, where a utility has treated similarly-situated 
    customers differently--serving one under a more favorable bilateral 
    contract and another under a less favorable tariff provision--
    traditional undue discrimination remedies may be available.
        We deny Blue Ridge's rehearing requests because the Commission does 
    not intend to assume the regulatory responsibility of identifying in 
    the first instance all of the regional practices around the country 
    that could (and should) properly be reflected in the compliance 
    tariffs. Transmission customers opposed to deviations related to 
    regional practices not only had the opportunity to protest the 
    compliance filings when they were tendered, 447 but these 
    customers also have the right to file section 206 requests to change 
    these tariffs at any time. In addition, Blue Ridge's request that 
    customers be given 45 days to respond to compliance filings instead of 
    15 days is moot. In an order issued July 2, 1996,448 we took three 
    actions to address this concern: (1) we gave entities 30 days, instead 
    of 15 days, to respond to Order No. 888 compliance filings; (2) we 
    agreed to post an electronic version of all Order No. 888 compliance 
    filings on the Commission's Electronic Bulletin Board; and (3) we 
    required all public utilities making a compliance filing to also serve 
    a copy of their filing on electronic diskette to any eligible customer 
    or state regulatory agency requesting a copy. We believe that these 
    actions not only provided all interested parties with access to the 
    compliance filings more quickly, but also provided these parties 
    sufficient time to analyze the information once they received 
    it.449 Moreover, the time periods provided for making and 
    responding to Order No. 888 compliance filings have expired.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \447\ We do note that most of these concerns have been addressed 
    in our orders dealing with the compliance filings on non-rate terms 
    and conditions. See, e.g., Atlantic City Electric Company, et al., 
    77 FERC para. 61,144 (1996); Allegheny Power System, Inc., et al., 
    77 FERC para. 61,266 (1996).
        \448\ 76 FERC para. 61,009 at 61,026-27 (1996) (July 2 Order).
        \449\ We also note that utilities were required in Order No. 888 
    to explicitly identify any regional practices in their compliance 
    filings.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        With regard to Blue Ridge's first clarification request, we provide 
    the following guidance. Utilities that had pending open access filings 
    at the time that the Final Rule was implemented had the non-price terms 
    and conditions of those pending tariffs superseded by their Order No. 
    888 compliance filings. Any customer concerns about the non-rate tariff 
    terms and conditions in the compliance filing should be raised in the 
    compliance docket, and any future customer concerns should be raised in 
    a separate, future section 206 complaint filed by the customer.
        Furthermore, we reject Indianapolis P&L's rate issue because, if 
    this utility believes that it operates under special circumstances that 
    require it to use ``non-conforming'' pricing methods, it is free to 
    file such a proposal under section 205. The merits of Indianapolis 
    P&L's arguments are more appropriately addressed in such a section 205 
    proceeding. The Commission will not alter its generic policy (which is 
    the subject of this rulemaking) merely to address the particular needs 
    of one party.
        In addition, with regard to both of Indianapolis P&L's concerns, we 
    note that pursuant to the Commission's July 2 Order, the Commission 
    indicated that it would not address waiver requests in a generic 
    proceeding and that parties would have to file such requests separately 
    for separate docketing. We further note that Indianapolis P&L filed a 
    separate waiver request on July 9, 1996, which was docketed as OA96-
    81.450
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \450\ By order issued September 11, 1996, the Commission denied 
    Indianapolis P&L's requested waiver of all the requirements of Order 
    No. 888. On October 8, 1996, Indianapolis P&L sought rehearing of 
    that order and a stay of the requirements of Order No. 888. These 
    pleadings are now pending before the Commission.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We also reject Union Electric's argument that the final rules 
    violate procedural due process. Union Electric has had every 
    opportunity to raise arguments with regard to every step in the 
    Commission's derivation and implementation of the final rules. 
    Moreover, with regard to Union Electric's claim that it was given an 
    inadequate amount of time to comprehend and implement the final rules, 
    we note that virtually every public utility, including Union Electric, 
    complied with the Open Access Rule on a timely basis, and there have 
    been very few complaints that the rules are hard to comprehend.
    
    I. Federal and State Jurisdiction: Transmission/Local Distribution
    
        In the Final Rule, the Commission explained that after reviewing 
    the extensive analysis of the FPA, legislative history, and case law 
    contained in both the initial Stranded Cost NOPR and in the Open Access 
    NOPR, and the comments received on that analysis, it reaffirmed its 
    assertion of jurisdiction over the transmission component of an 
    unbundled interstate retail wheeling transaction.451 The 
    Commission also reaffirmed and clarified its determinations regarding 
    the tests to be used to determine what constitute Commission-
    jurisdictional transmission facilities and what constitute state-
    jurisdictional local distribution facilities in situations involving 
    unbundled wholesale wheeling and unbundled retail wheeling.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \451\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,780-85; mimeo at 427-42.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission also explained that where states unbundle retail 
    sales, it will give deference to their determinations as to which 
    facilities are transmission and which are local distribution, provided 
    that the states, in making such determinations, apply the seven 
    criteria discussed in the NOPR and reaffirmed by the Commission. In 
    addition, the Commission clarified that there is an element of local 
    distribution service in any unbundled retail transaction, and further 
    clarified other aspects of its jurisdictional ruling to preserve state 
    jurisdiction over matters that are of local concern and will remain 
    subject to state jurisdiction if retail unbundling occurs.
        The Commission reaffirmed its legal determination that if unbundled 
    retail transmission in interstate commerce occurs voluntarily by a 
    public utility or as a result of a state retail access program, this 
    Commission has exclusive jurisdiction over the rates, terms, and 
    conditions of such transmission. The Commission found compelling the 
    fact that section 201 of the FPA, on its face, gives the Commission 
    jurisdiction over transmission in interstate commerce (by public 
    utilities) without qualification.
        The Commission further explained that when a retail transaction is 
    broken into two or more products that are sold separately, the 
    jurisdictional lines change. In this situation, the Commission 
    emphasized that the state clearly retains jurisdiction over the sale of 
    the power, but the unbundled
    
    [[Page 12367]]
    
    transmission service involves only the provision of ``transmission in 
    interstate commerce'' which, under the FPA, is exclusively within the 
    jurisdiction of the Commission.
        The Commission recognized that in asserting jurisdiction over 
    unbundled retail transmission in interstate commerce by public 
    utilities, it was in no way asserting jurisdiction to order retail 
    transmission directly to an ultimate consumer. It explained that its 
    assertion of jurisdiction is that if unbundled retail transmission in 
    interstate commerce by a public utility occurs voluntarily or as a 
    result of a state retail wheeling program, the Commission has exclusive 
    jurisdiction over the rates, terms, and conditions of such transmission 
    and public utilities offering such transmission must comply with the 
    FPA by filing proposed rate schedules under section 205.
        The Commission further clarified that nothing in its jurisdictional 
    determination changes historical state franchise areas or interferes 
    with state laws governing retail marketing areas of electric utilities. 
    It explained that while its jurisdiction cannot affect whether and to 
    whom a retail electric service territory (marketing area) is to be 
    granted by the state, and whether such grant is exclusive or non-
    exclusive, neither can state jurisdiction affect this Commission's 
    exclusive jurisdiction over transmission in interstate commerce by 
    public utilities.
        The Commission also adopted a new section 35.27(b) as follows:
    
        Nothing in this part (i) shall be construed as preempting or 
    affecting any jurisdiction a state commission or other state 
    authority may have under applicable state and federal law, or (ii) 
    limits the authority of a state commission in accordance with state 
    and federal law to establish (a) competitive procedures for the 
    acquisition of electric energy, including demand-side management, 
    purchased at wholesale, or (b) non-discriminatory fees for the 
    distribution of such electric energy to retail consumers for 
    purposes established in accordance with state law.
    
        With respect to the Commission's adoption of the Open Access NOPR's 
    functional/technical tests for determining what facilities are 
    Commission-jurisdictional facilities used for transmission in 
    interstate commerce and what facilities are state-jurisdictional local 
    distribution facilities, the Commission concluded that it could not 
    divine a bright line for unbundled retail transmission by the public 
    utility that previously provided bundled retail service to the end 
    user. The Commission added that the limited case law, including 
    Connecticut Light & Power Company v. FPC (CL&P) and Federal Power 
    Commission v. Southern California Edison Company (the Colton 
    case),452 supports a case-by-case determination.453 
    Accordingly, the Commission stated that its technical test, with its 
    seven indicators, will permit reasoned factual determinations in 
    individual cases.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \452\ 324 U.S. 515 (1945) (CL&P); 376 U.S. 205 (1964) (Colton).
        \453\ The Commission included a detailed legal analysis in 
    Appendix G to Order No. 888. The Commission explained that it was 
    particularly persuaded by the Supreme Court's statement that whether 
    facilities are used in local distribution is a question of fact to 
    be decided by the Commission as an original matter. See CL&P, 324 
    U.S. at 534-35).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission made two clarifications regarding local distribution 
    in the context of retail wheeling. First, it explained that even if its 
    technical test for local distribution facilities were to identify no 
    local distribution facilities for a specific transaction, states have 
    authority over the service of delivering electric energy to end users. 
    Second, the Commission explained that through their jurisdiction over 
    retail delivery services, states have authority not only to assess 
    retail stranded costs but also to assess charges for so-called stranded 
    benefits, such as low-income assistance and demand-side management.
        Thus, under this interpretation of state/federal jurisdiction, the 
    Commission explained, customers have no incentive to structure a 
    purchase so as to avoid using identifiable local distribution 
    facilities in order to bypass state jurisdiction and thus avoid being 
    assessed charges for stranded costs and benefits.
        The Commission further determined that it is appropriate to provide 
    deference to state commission recommendations regarding certain 
    transmission/local distribution matters that arise when retail wheeling 
    occurs.
        In instances of unbundled retail wheeling that occurs as a result 
    of a state retail access program, the Commission indicated that it will 
    defer to recommendations by state regulatory authorities concerning 
    where to draw the jurisdictional line under the Commission's technical 
    test for local distribution facilities, and how to allocate costs for 
    such facilities to be included in rates, provided that such 
    recommendations are consistent with the essential elements of the Final 
    Rule.454 Moreover, the Commission indicated that it will consider 
    jurisdictional recommendations by states that take into account other 
    technical factors that the state believes are appropriate in light of 
    historical uses of particular facilities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \454\ In order to give such deference, the Commission noted its 
    expectation that state regulators will specifically evaluate the 
    seven indicators and any other relevant facts and make 
    recommendations consistent with the essential elements of the Rule.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As a means of facilitating jurisdictional line-drawing, the 
    Commission stated that it will entertain proposals by public utilities, 
    filed under section 205 of the FPA, containing classifications and/or 
    cost allocations for transmission and local distribution facilities. 
    However, the Commission explained that, as a prerequisite to filing 
    transmission/local distribution facility classifications and/or cost 
    allocations with the Commission, utilities must consult with their 
    state regulatory authorities. If the utility's classifications and/or 
    cost allocations are supported by the state regulatory authorities and 
    are consistent with the principles established in the Final Rule, the 
    Commission indicated that it will defer to such classifications and/or 
    cost allocations.
        Furthermore, the Commission stated that deference to state 
    commissions with regard to rates, terms, and conditions may be 
    appropriate in some circumstances. The Commission explained that when 
    unbundled retail wheeling in interstate commerce occurs, the 
    transaction has two components for jurisdictional purposes--a 
    transmission component and a local distribution component. It again 
    emphasized that the Commission has jurisdiction over facilities used 
    for the transmission component of the transaction, and the state has 
    jurisdiction over facilities used for the local distribution component. 
    Thus, the Commission stated, the rates, terms and conditions of 
    unbundled retail transmission by a public utility must be filed at the 
    Commission. However, the Commission added, if the unbundled retail 
    wheeling occurs as part of a state retail access program, it may be 
    appropriate to have a separate retail transmission tariff 455 to 
    accommodate the design and special needs of such programs. In such 
    situations, the Commission indicated that it will defer to state 
    requests for variations from the FERC wholesale tariff to meet these 
    local concerns, so long as the separate retail tariff is consistent 
    with the Commission's open access policies and comparability principles 
    reflected in the tariff prescribed by the Final Rule. In addition, the 
    Commission indicated that
    
    [[Page 12368]]
    
    the rates must be consistent with its Transmission Pricing Policy 
    Statement, and the guidance set forth in Order No. 888 concerning 
    ancillary services. 456
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \455\ The Commission noted that such a tariff could be different 
    from the tariff that applies to wholesale customers, but that such 
    tariff would still be filed with the Commission under FPA section 
    205.
        \456\ In applying the principles of the Final Rule to retail 
    transmission tariffs, the Commission emphasized that it clearly 
    cannot order retail wheeling directly to an ultimate consumer. 
    (citing FPA section 212(h)).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission also expressed concern, just as it did with buy-sell 
    arrangements in the gas industry, that buy-sell arrangements can be 
    used by parties to obfuscate the true transactions taking place and 
    thereby allow parties to circumvent Commission regulation of 
    transmission in interstate commerce. Thus, the Commission reaffirmed 
    its conclusion that it has jurisdiction over the interstate 
    transmission component of transactions in which an end user arranges 
    for the purchase of generation from a third-party. Moreover, the 
    Commission indicated that it will address these transactions on a case-
    by-case basis.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
    Oppose Commission Assertion of Jurisdiction Over Unbundled Retail 
    Transmission
    
        Several state commissions indicate that, recognizing that the case 
    law is not dispositive concerning the question of unbundled retail 
    transmission services (either because the cases do not involve the 
    transmission of power to retail customers or ``fence off'' local 
    distribution from federal regulation), at least one court (Wisconsin-
    Michigan Power Company v. FPC, 197 F.2d 472 (7th Cir. 1952), cert. 
    denied, 345 U.S. 934 (1953)) explicitly applied the wholesale/retail 
    distinction to distinguish transmission and local distribution 
    services. 457 Thus, they argue, the Commission should apply the 
    wholesale versus retail analysis to the question of unbundled retail 
    transmission.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \457\ E.g., NARUC, WI Com, WY Com.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        IL Com asserts that retail transmission by a public utility 
    directly to an end user has always (even before the FPA was enacted) 
    been subject to regulation by the states. It contends that no change in 
    law has occurred which justifies the Commission's claim of expanded 
    jurisdiction. Moreover, it disagrees with the Commission's conclusion 
    that the unbundled delivery by the previous public utility generation 
    supplier directly to an end user is in interstate commerce. It argues 
    that the FPA was never intended to disturb the jurisdiction of state 
    regulators that existed prior to its passage and that retail 
    transmission of electric energy by a public utility to an end user was 
    under state jurisdiction before the Attleboro decision and has remained 
    under state jurisdiction in the over sixty years following Attleboro. 
    Even after unbundling, according to IL Com, transmission to a retail 
    customer still involves a retail sale of transmission.
        NARUC and VA Com assert that the legislative history provides 
    little support for the Commission's conclusion that the act of 
    unbundling generation from delivery serves to shift jurisdiction from a 
    state commission to the Commission. If anything, they contend, the 
    jurisdictional structure of the FPA is predicated on the distinction 
    between retail and wholesale transactions, not bundled and unbundled 
    services. They assert that the Commission should conclude that the 
    rates, terms and conditions of service for delivery of power by a 
    utility to an end-use customer are subject to the jurisdiction of the 
    state commission regulating the utility, regardless of the identity of 
    the party generating or reselling the power or the facilities used to 
    transport the power.
        NARUC asserts that the Commission did not address a point raised in 
    NARUC's reply comments as to how the removal of generation serves to 
    unbundle the retail delivery function into separate transmission and 
    distribution services. It maintains that the Commission simply assumes 
    that a resulting transmission transaction is created when power is sold 
    to a retail consumer by someone other than the utility delivering the 
    power. 458
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \458\ See also IA Com (use of a utility's transmission system to 
    serve its own retail customers is a bundled part of the retail sale 
    transaction, which supports a simpler jurisdictional test holding 
    that a movement of power by the last utility in any chain of 
    delivery to a retail customer is a distribution transaction).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        MI & NH Coms ask the Commission to vacate those portions of the 
    Rule that find that the Commission has jurisdiction over the 
    transmission component of an unbundled retail sale in a local retail 
    wheeling transaction. They assert that the Commission should confine 
    its activity to wholesale transactions or those interstate transactions 
    that do not implicate matters of local concern. They argue that the 
    dual federal/state regulatory scheme establishes that Congress' intent 
    is that state regulation of retail wheeling is not preempted by federal 
    law as established in FPA section 201. They oppose unnecessary federal 
    intrusion into local matters under a one-size-fits-all approach and 
    assert that the retail wheeling initiatives in New Hampshire and 
    Michigan are tailored to the unique utility environment in each state.
        Central Illinois Light argues that unbundling of retail electric 
    service does not change the states' longstanding jurisdiction over 
    retail electric service and local distribution, even when that service 
    involves the use of transmission in interstate commerce. It asserts 
    that 201(b)(1) (``transmission of electric energy in interstate 
    commerce'') cannot be read in a vacuum.
        MN DPS & MN Com and OH Com assert that the Commission should have 
    no role in the regulation of retail services, be they bundled or 
    unbundled. They argue that, in refusing to grant the Commission 
    authority over retail wheeling, Congress left jurisdiction over retail 
    electric service to the states. They conclude that the Final Rule 
    contains insufficient legal and/or policy justification for the 
    Commission's assertion of jurisdiction over unbundled retail 
    transmission services.
        MN DPS & MN Com assert: ``FERC bases its usurpation of state 
    authority over retail transmission rates on its claim that 
    balkanization would occur without the assertion of FERC authority. 
    Therefore, the parties are entitled to rehearing so that this essential 
    issue can be further analyzed.'' (MN DPS & MN Com at 1-3).
        FL Com argues that the Commission has not justified why the act of 
    unbundling prices expands the Commission's jurisdiction into retail 
    marketing areas. It argues that Section 212(g) of the FPA has the 
    effect of prohibiting the Commission from usurping existing state 
    jurisdiction over retail transmission service, whether bundled or 
    unbundled. According to FL Com, FERC's jurisdiction over transmission 
    terminates at the territorial boundary of each electric utility in 
    Florida. It supports wheeling in jurisdiction for state commissions and 
    wheeling out and wheeling through jurisdiction for the Commission.
        IN Com opposes federalization of retail wheeling transactions 
    within a state's boundaries as contrary to the FPA's legislative 
    history and case law.
        NJ BPU asserts that by claiming jurisdiction over unbundled retail 
    transmission, the Commission is creating a disincentive for states to 
    implement retail access because, by ordering retail access, the states 
    may be relinquishing their jurisdiction over unbundled retail 
    transmission terms and conditions--jurisdiction that they would 
    maintain under a bundled scenario. 459 PA Com argues that the 
    Commission does not have the authority
    
    [[Page 12369]]
    
    to order retail wheeling and that the jurisdictional formula is 
    challengeable on engineering and legal grounds. It concludes that the 
    Commission does not have jurisdiction over unbundled interstate retail 
    transmission service. PA Com notes that the 1996 House and Senate 
    hearings have raised the question whether the Commission has the 
    statutory authority to restructure the electric industry. PA Com 
    questions the Commission's definition of the ``traditional tasks of 
    state and federal regulators'' on the basis of section 201(b) of the 
    FPA, the Supremacy Clause, and the Tenth Amendment of the U.S. 
    Constitution.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \459\ See also PA Com.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Support Broader Assertion of Jurisdiction by the Commission Over Retail 
    Wheeling
    
        NY Utilities declare that the Commission has jurisdiction over 
    retail wheeling from the source to the load, but does not have 
    jurisdiction over transmission in bundled retail service. They assert 
    that the Commission's reliance on state jurisdictional local 
    distribution as a predicate to abstain from allowing retail wheeling 
    stranded cost recovery is without foundation. They further assert that 
    a unique element that sets local distribution apart from transmission 
    is not the size of the facility or the length of travel, but that 
    transportation is bundled with a retail sale. According to NY 
    Utilities, the plain meaning of the FPA shows that local distribution 
    is bundled retail service. They claim that the legislative history, to 
    the extent necessary, and court cases support FERC jurisdiction over 
    all aspects of retail wheeling, but makes clear that the Commission 
    cannot regulate bundled retail service. They add that the NGA also 
    demonstrates that local distribution means bundled retail service.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        In concluding that this Commission has exclusive jurisdiction over 
    the rates, terms and conditions of unbundled retail transmission by 
    public utilities in interstate commerce, the Commission in Order No. 
    888 thoroughly examined the statutory language of the FPA and its 
    legislative history, and relevant FPA and NGA case law. While the state 
    commissions on rehearing would like us to draw a bright line that gives 
    them, to varying degrees, jurisdiction over retail interstate 
    transmission by public utilities, no party on rehearing has raised any 
    legislative history or case law that was not previously considered and 
    that would support the proposition that states have jurisdiction over 
    any unbundled transmission in interstate commerce. As explained below, 
    we reaffirm our jurisdictional interpretation on rehearing and believe 
    that it is supported by the recent decision in United Distribution 
    Companies v. FERC.460
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \460\ 88 F.3d 1105, 1152-53 (1996) (United Distribution 
    Companies).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Many of the rehearing arguments focus on the fact that states 
    historically (even prior to the FPA) regulated retail transmission 
    insofar as it was a component of bundled electric service to an end 
    user, and they argue that by asserting jurisdiction over unbundled 
    retail transmission, the Commission is somehow ``taking away'' 
    jurisdiction the states previously had. The flaw in these arguments is 
    their inherent assumption that jurisdiction over transmission service 
    turns upon the question of whether the transmission service is being 
    provided for ``wholesale'' or ``retail'' power sales. That is not the 
    case. The question of jurisdiction rather turns upon the extent of the 
    Commission's exclusive jurisdiction over transmission in interstate 
    commerce under the FPA. The fact that states historically regulated 
    most retail transmission service as a part of a bundled retail power 
    sale is not the result of a legal requirement; it is the practical 
    result of the way electricity has historically been bought and sold. 
    However, the shape of power sales transactions is rapidly changing. 
    Rather than claiming ``new'' jurisdiction, the Commission is applying 
    the same statutory framework to a business environment in which, as 
    discussed below, retail sales and transmission service are provided in 
    separate transactions.
        In the past, retails ales occurred almost exclusively on a bundled 
    basis (i.e., the same entity provided a delivered product called 
    electric energy and transmission was part and parcel of that product). 
    The FPA clearly reserves the right to regulate retail sales of electric 
    energy to the states. As we explained in the Final Rule, however, in 
    today's markets, and increasingly in the future as more states adopt 
    retail wheeling programs, retail transactions are being broken into 
    products that are being sold separately: transmission and generation. 
    Moreover, these products are being sold increasingly by two or more 
    different entities. For example, a transaction may involve transmission 
    service from one or more transmission providers who move power from a 
    distant generation supplier, over the interstate transmission grid, to 
    an end user. Because these types of products and transactions were not 
    prevalent in the past, the jurisdictional issue before us did not arise 
    and, contrary to IL Com's argument, the Commission cannot be viewed as 
    ``disturbing'' the jurisdiction of state regulators prior to and after 
    the Attleboro case.461
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \461\ Public Utilities Commission v. Attleboro Steam & Electric 
    Co., 273 U.S. 83 (1927).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As we also explained in the Final Rule, the legislative history of 
    the FPA and the relevant case law similarly reflect the historical 
    market structure in which electricity and transmission generally were 
    bought on a bundled basis.462 Today's unbundled world simply was 
    not contemplated and the cases do not resolve dispositively this 
    jurisdictional issue. The case law focuses primarily on the bright line 
    between wholesale sales and retail sales of energy, and transmission in 
    interstate as opposed to intrastate commerce. It does not address 
    unbundled retail interstate transmission.463 We therefore have 
    interpreted the case law in light of changed circumstances and have 
    relied in the first instance on the plain wording of the statute. We 
    find compelling that section 201 of the FPA, on its face, gives the 
    Commission jurisdiction over transmission in interstate commerce 
    without qualification; unlike our jurisdiction over sales of electric 
    energy, which section 201 specifically limits to sales at wholesale, 
    the statute does not limit our transmission jurisdiction over public 
    utilities to wholesale transmission.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \462\ The case law is addressed extensively in Appendix G to the 
    Final Rule and will not be repeated here.
        \463\ On rehearing, several parties argue that at least one 
    court case, Wisconsin-Michigan Power Co. v. FPC, 197 F.2d 472 (7th 
    Cir. 1952), cert. denied, 345 U.S. 934 (1953) explicitly applied the 
    wholesale/retail distinction to distinguish transmission and local 
    distribution services. The Commission discussed this case in detail 
    in Appendix G to the Final Rule, FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,974-75; 
    mimeo at 22-25. As we stated there, the court's interpretation of 
    the legislative history of the FPA was at odds with both the plain 
    words of the statute as well as the language of the House Report on 
    the FPA (H.R. Rep. No. 1318 at 27). It also did not mention the 
    Senate Report on the FPA, which clearly recognized jurisdiction over 
    all interstate transmission lines, whether or not a sale of energy 
    is carried by those lines (S. Rep. No. 621 at 48). We therefore 
    reject arguments that this single case is in any way dispositive of 
    the issue before us.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Since the time Order No. 888 issued, the D.C. Circuit has addressed 
    a similar issue in interpreting section 1(b) of the NGA, the provision 
    that parallels section 201(b) of the FPA. Under section 1(b), the 
    Commission's jurisdiction does not apply ``to the local distribution of 
    natural gas or to the facilities used for such distribution.'' 
    Similarly, under section 201(b) of the FPA, the Commission shall not 
    have jurisdiction, except as specifically provided, ``over
    
    [[Page 12370]]
    
    facilities used for the generation of electric energy or over 
    facilities used in local distribution * * *'' In responding to 
    arguments regarding the scope of state authority over ``local 
    distribution'' of natural gas, the court distinguished between bundled 
    and unbundled sales:
    
        States have been--and are still--permitted to regulate LDCs' 
    bundled sales of natural gas to end-users because those transactions 
    include transportation over local mains and the retail sales of gas. 
    In contrast, states have never regulated the terms and conditions of 
    interstate pipeline transportation. When the gas sales element is 
    severed--i.e., unbundled--from the transactions, FERC retains 
    jurisdiction over the interstate transportation component.'' [United 
    Distribution Companies, 88 F.3d at 1153 (footnote omitted) (emphasis 
    in original).]
    
    The court's reasoning is also applicable to and supports our 
    jurisdictional determination in Order No. 888.
        Several state commissions point to section 212(h) of the FPA and 
    argue that Congress, in refusing to grant the Commission authority to 
    order retail wheeling, left all jurisdiction over retail transmission 
    to the states. We disagree. What Congress did in section 212(h) was to 
    prohibit us from ordering transmission directly to an ultimate 
    consumer. We readily recognize and respect this prohibition. However, 
    the ability to order retail wheeling is a separate issue from whether 
    we have jurisdiction over the rates, terms and conditions of retail 
    wheeling in interstate commerce that is ordered by a state or that is 
    provided voluntarily. Congress, in enacting section 212(h), did nothing 
    to modify our jurisdiction under sections 201, 205 and 206 over the 
    rates, terms and conditions of interstate transmission by public 
    utilities.
        Similarly, we reject FL Com's arguments that section 212(g) of the 
    FPA prohibits the Commission from asserting any jurisdiction over 
    unbundled retail transmission. Section 212(g) prohibits the Commission 
    from issuing an order that is inconsistent with any state law that 
    governs retail marketing areas of electric utilities. As we stated in 
    the Final Rule, while our jurisdiction cannot affect whether and to 
    whom a retail electric service territory (marketing area) is to be 
    granted by the state, and whether such grant is exclusive or non-
    exclusive, neither can state jurisdiction affect this Commission's 
    exclusive jurisdiction over the rates, terms and conditions of 
    transmission in interstate commerce by public utilities. We also reject 
    arguments by the FL Com that this Commission's jurisdiction over 
    transmission terminates at the territorial boundary of each electric 
    utility in Florida. This argument is flatly contrary to the 
    longstanding interpretation of the FPA by the United States Supreme 
    Court.464
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \464\ See FPC v. Southern California Edison Co., 376 U.S. 205 
    (1964) (Colton case). IN Com makes a similar argument and opposes 
    ``federalization'' of retail wheeling within a state's boundaries. 
    We reject this argument on the same basis.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission's Seven Factor Test
    
        IL Com argues that the Commission should withdraw its technical 
    test. It contends that retail wheeling jurisdiction should follow 
    function and that the function served by public utility facilities in 
    providing retail service does not change upon the unbundling of service 
    to retail customers. According to IL Com, Commission jurisdiction would 
    extend to the service of delivering electric energy by a public utility 
    to wholesale customers, regardless of the nature and extent of the 
    public utility's facilities used to make that delivery. Similarly, it 
    asserts, state jurisdiction would extend to the service of delivering 
    electric energy by a public utility directly to retail customers, 
    regardless of the nature and extent of the public utility's facilities 
    used to make that delivery.
        NARUC argues that the seven-factor test does not result in the 
    bright line discussed in FPC v. Southern California Edison Company, 376 
    U.S. 205 (1964). The facility-by-facility categorization of utility 
    systems on a company-specific basis, it asserts, is hardly consistent 
    with the Court's decision to make case-by-case analysis unnecessary.
        OH Com asserts that the seven factors provide no useful insight 
    into the nature of local distribution service. It adds that reliance 
    upon technical tests to determine local distribution lacks legal 
    foundation. It further contends that the jurisdictional bright line 
    established by Congress focuses upon the nature of the transaction, not 
    the functional or technical characteristics of a particular wire, in 
    determining whose jurisdictional authority attaches to a particular 
    transaction and facilities. It concludes that the Commission should 
    adopt the Ohio-proposed retail marketing area ``wheeling in'' 
    jurisdictional approach.
        PA Com contends that the Commission's seven indicia are not 
    acceptable measures of local distribution and challenges each factor.
        NH & MI Coms declare that the criteria for distinguishing 
    transmission facilities from local distribution facilities should not 
    be limited to the seven given in the Rule, but should allow 
    consideration of any other relevant criteria for separating local 
    concerns from matters legitimately federal in nature.
        NJ BPU argues that the engineering-driven definition does not 
    resolve many of the hazy areas. To the extent that the seven factors do 
    not reflect or cannot be reconciled with the particular circumstances, 
    it contends that the states may be hamstrung in their ability to make 
    reasoned decisions that comport with Order No. 888.465
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \465\ See also WI Com (criteria do not appropriately reflect the 
    mixed nature of many facilities in systems that are closely 
    integrated and the application of the criteria to the electric 
    system in Wisconsin would supplant state jurisdiction over a large 
    number of facilities whose primary functions are local reliability 
    and retail service).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Similarly, NY Com argues that five of the seven factors (1, 2, 4, 
    6, and 7) are not accurate when applied to large metropolitan areas and 
    remote rural areas. It asserts that local distribution facilities are 
    not necessarily close to retail customers and the assumption that local 
    distribution facilities are primarily radial in character fails to 
    account for network systems. It adds that reconsignment or 
    transportation of power to different markets can and does occur at the 
    local distribution level. It further adds that the presence of meters 
    is not a discerning characteristic of where interstate transmission 
    ends and local distribution begins; meters are frequently not part of 
    the transmission/local distribution interface. Nor, according to NY 
    Com, are local distribution systems necessarily of reduced voltage. 
    Instead of the 7 criteria, NY Com argues that the Commission should 
    adopt a functional measure of local distribution based on factors 3 and 
    5 (interstate transmission ends and local distribution begins where 
    electricity flows into a comparatively restricted geographic area and 
    does not flow back out of that area and the power is consumed in that 
    area) and on the traditional classification of the facilities by the 
    state regulatory body (or what the utility has traditionally classified 
    as local distribution).
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Several parties on rehearing do not like the seven-factor technical 
    test for local distribution facilities that was set forth in Order No. 
    888. That test takes into account both technical and functional 
    characteristics of the transaction involved. The parties on rehearing 
    propose instead a variety of bright line tests. For example, IL Com 
    wants state jurisdiction to extend to the ``service'' of delivering 
    electric energy to retail customers, which it would define to give it 
    jurisdiction regardless of the
    
    [[Page 12371]]
    
    nature and extent of the facilities used to make the delivery. OH Com 
    proposes that the Commission adopt a retail marketing area ``wheeling 
    in'' jurisdictional approach which would give it jurisdiction over 
    facilities within territorial boundaries.
        In response, we do not interpret the FPA to permit us in effect to 
    rewrite the statute to give states jurisdiction over interstate 
    transmission services. Moreover, we reject arguments of OH Com that our 
    seven-factor test lacks legal foundation, and arguments of NARUC that 
    we are somehow bound to develop a bright line test. While Congress 
    established a jurisdictional bright line between wholesale and retail 
    sales of energy, there is no such bright line that we can divine with 
    regard to transmission and local distribution facilities. The Supreme 
    Court, in both Colton and CL&P,466 has instructed us that whether 
    facilities are used in local distribution is a question of fact to be 
    decided by the Commission as an original matter. The seven factors will 
    permit us to undertake this fact-specific determination.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \466\ See Colton, 376 U.S. at 210 n.6; CL&P, 324 U.S. at 531-36.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We acknowledge the concerns raised by several state commissions 
    that the seven-factor test does not, as NJ BPU puts it, resolve many of 
    the hazy areas, and that there may be other factors that should be 
    taken into account in particular situations. The seven-factor test is 
    intended to provide sufficient flexibility to take into account unique 
    local characteristics and historical usage of facilities used to serve 
    retail customers. We specifically stated in the Final Rule that we will 
    consider jurisdictional recommendations by states that take into 
    account other technical factors that states believe are appropriate in 
    light of historical uses of particular facilities. Moreover, we will 
    defer to facility classifications and/or cost allocations that are 
    supported by state regulatory authorities. For example, in the ongoing 
    California electric utility restructuring proceeding, the Commission 
    deferred to the State PUC's recommendations regarding the split between 
    state jurisdictional local distribution facilities and Commission-
    jurisdictional transmission facilities.467
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \467\ Pacific Gas and Electric Company, et al., 77 FERC para. 
    61,325 at 61,325 (1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Oppose Transmission of Public Utility Purchases for Sale at Retail
    
        IL Com objects to the transmission unbundling requirement if it is 
    intended to require public utilities to take transmission services 
    under their own FERC tariffs for purchases of power intended for 
    distribution by the public utility to retail customers. According to IL 
    Com, a distinction must be made between the public utility's use of its 
    transmission system in cases in which the public utility purchases 
    wholesale power for sale for resale, and cases in which the public 
    utility purchases wholesale power to serve native load retail 
    customers. It argues that the Commission cannot legally regulate, or 
    place conditions on, the manner in which a utility uses its 
    transmission system to make sales of electric energy at retail. It 
    contends that the Commission must exempt public utility power purchases 
    for sale at retail from the unbundling requirement. It recommends that 
    the Commission insert the words ``for sale for resale'' after the word 
    ``purchases'' in section 35.28(c)(2) and after the word ``purchase'' in 
    section 35.28(c)(2)(i).
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Commission rejects arguments of IL Com that if unbundled retail 
    wheeling occurs either voluntarily or as a result of a state retail 
    program, we cannot require the utility to take service under its own 
    transmission tariff for sales to retail customers. This requirement is 
    a term and condition of unbundled retail interstate transmission 
    service and, as explained above, therefore is within our exclusive 
    jurisdiction. Additionally, this should not in any way infringe on 
    state retail programs or service to retail customers. Rather, it 
    ensures that non-discriminatory transmission services are provided to 
    all potential retail power competitors.
        Further, as stated previously in Section IV.C.1.b (Transmission 
    Providers Taking Service Under Their Tariff), we clarify that a 
    transmission provider does not have to ``take service'' under its own 
    tariff for the transmission of power that is purchased on behalf of 
    bundled retail customers.
    
    Oppose Buy-Sell Transaction Analysis
    
        PA Com asserts that there is a potential for jurisdictional 
    conflict with respect to buy-sell transactions that is a direct 
    consequence of the technical-functional test (which PA Com challenges).
        IL Com argues that states have exclusive authority to regulate buy-
    sell arrangements as bundled retail sales. It further argues that the 
    Commission cannot make a bundled retail sale into an unbundled retail 
    sale simply by characterizing it as the functional equivalent of an 
    unbundled retail sale; by re-characterizing them the Commission is 
    effectively ordering the unbundling of buy-sell arrangements. It 
    asserts that buy-sell arrangements on the electric side are not an end 
    run around clear federal jurisdiction and that the Commission should 
    withdraw its assertion of jurisdiction over the retail transmission 
    component of unbundled retail sales.
        VT DPS contends that the Commission's rationale is flawed: ``FERC's 
    analysis rests on the same very shaky ground as its similar claim of 
    jurisdiction over buy-sell arrangements by local gas distribution 
    companies.'' According to VT DPS, all retail transactions are subject 
    to state jurisdiction and asks the Commission to clarify that the 
    Commission defines buy-sell as it did in the NOPR, but also acknowledge 
    that it has no jurisdiction over such arrangements.
        IN Com asserts that in the absence of any record of abusive and 
    undermining actions by states under the guise of buy-sell arrangements, 
    there is not even a remedial justification to touch buy-sell 
    transactions. It contends that a difference between the FPA and the NGA 
    warrants different treatment--the FPA exempts from FERC jurisdiction 
    local distribution and transmission of electric energy in intrastate 
    commerce. By redefining interstate transmission, IN Com claims that the 
    Commission proposes to do away with the meaning history has accorded to 
    a variety of transactions previously considered wholly intrastate in 
    nature. According to IN Com, states should be allowed to experiment 
    with and allow different forms of buy-sell transactions as part of the 
    evolving marketplace.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Four parties (PA Com, IL Com, VT DPS and IN Com) have raised 
    concerns regarding the Commission's determination that it has 
    jurisdiction over the interstate transmission component of transactions 
    in which an end user arranges for the purchase of generation from a 
    third party. The Commission reiterates that we will have to address 
    these situations on a case-by-case basis. We disagree with IL Com that 
    States have exclusive authority to regulate the interstate transmission 
    component of buy-sell transactions. Similarly, we deny the VT DPS 
    request that we acknowledge no jurisdiction over such arrangements. The 
    fact remains that these arrangements could be used by parties to 
    obfuscate the true transactions taking place and thereby allow parties 
    to circumvent Commission regulation of transmission in interstate 
    commerce. We reserve our authorities to ensure that public utilities 
    and their
    
    [[Page 12372]]
    
    customers are not able to circumvent non-discriminatory transmission in 
    interstate commerce. In response to VT DPS' contention that the 
    Commission's analysis here rests on the same shaky ground as its 
    similar claim of jurisdiction over buy-sell arrangements by local gas 
    distribution companies, we note that the D.C. Circuit recently affirmed 
    the Commission's assertion of jurisdiction over buy/sell arrangements 
    under the Natural Gas Act.468
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \468\ United Distribution Companies, 88 F.3d at 1154-57.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    State Jurisdiction Over the Service of Delivering Electric Energy 
    to End Users
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        IL Com states that it is far from clear what FERC contemplates by 
    the ``service'' of delivery of electric energy by a delivering utility 
    in the retail wheeling transaction. It is equally unclear to IL Com 
    whether the ``service'' to which Order No. 888 refers is a public 
    utility activity over which state regulators would have jurisdiction. 
    IL Com argues that it is the Illinois legislature, not FERC, that 
    determines whether IL Com can regulate something called ``delivery 
    service.'' 469
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \469\ See also AK Com (should not create a fictional concept of 
    delivery service--the legal reality is that, under retail 
    competition, state law will establish a customer's right to be 
    served and a generation owner's right to produce power. AK Com 
    asserts that the state can then attach conditions to those rights).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        MO/KS Coms ask the Commission to clarify the meaning of the 
    statement that even when the test for local distribution facilities 
    identifies no local distribution facilities, the Commission believes 
    that states have authority over the service of delivering electric 
    energy to end users. According to MO/KS Coms:
    
        The authority to shop at retail and to sell at retail do not 
    exist in the FPA. If the Commission's goal is to recognize the 
    States' authority to establish conditions on retail competition, it 
    need only acknowledge the State jurisdiction to establish the 
    opportunity to shop and sell at retail. If this is what the 
    Commission is seeking to accomplish by its discussion of `delivery 
    service,' then we support the Commission.470
    
        \470\ MO/KS Coms at 1-13.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Coalition for Economic Competition asserts that the Commission 
    failed to consider that the sale of electric energy may take place 
    outside of the state into which the energy is transmitted, and that the 
    local regulatory commission may have no jurisdiction over either the 
    sale or the transmission of the energy.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Several parties ask us to clarify our conclusion that even when the 
    seven-factor test for local distribution facilities does not identify 
    local distribution facilities, we believe states have authority over 
    the ``service'' of delivering electric energy to end users. We clarify 
    that states have the authority to determine the retail marketing areas 
    of electric utilities within their jurisdictions, and the end user 
    services that those utilities must provide, but we did not in Order No. 
    888 intend to opine on the extent of authority given by state 
    legislatures to their state commissions. Rather, our statement 
    regarding state authority over the ``service'' of delivering electric 
    energy is intended to recognize the historical and local nature of 
    delivering power to end users and the states' legitimate concerns and 
    responsibilities in regulating local matters.
    
    Deference to States
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
    Support Broader Deference
        NARUC and IL Com argue that the Commission should not simply defer 
    to state recommendations concerning the application of the seven-factor 
    test or the recovery of stranded costs, but should conclusively rely on 
    the findings by state commissions.
        NY Com argues that the Commission should not limit deference to 
    instances in which states order retail wheeling, but should defer to 
    all state commission recommendations regarding the definition of local 
    distribution facilities.
        FL Com asserts that the Rule fails to say where deference will be 
    given. It argues that the Rule should state that when a state 
    commission has held a proceeding on matters related to the requirements 
    of the Rule, the Commission shall give deference to the state 
    commission decisions. Moreover, it asserts that the Commission should 
    codify the deference standard: ``When a state commission has held a 
    proceeding on matters related to the requirements of this rule, the 
    Commission shall give deference to the state commission decisions.'' 
    (FL Com at 7-9).
        The commitment to defer to a state regulatory commission or agency, 
    argues NE Public Power District, should be clarified with respect to 
    utilities located in Nebraska, which has no such commission or agency. 
    NE Public Power District assumes that deference will be accorded to 
    decisions of NE Public Power District's Board of Directors; if not, it 
    asks the Commission to clarify.
        PA Com asks the Commission to clarify what a state regulatory 
    agency must demonstrate to secure deference and to define the term 
    ``consult.'' PA Com states that, in discussing the seven indicia, the 
    Commission states that it will ``consider'' jurisdictional 
    recommendations by states, which PA Com asserts is much different from 
    deference. It also asserts that the Commission must clarify what it 
    will do if a utility's classifications and/or cost allocations are not 
    supported by state regulatory authorities.
    
    Oppose Deference to State Authorities
    
        TANC argues that the Commission erred in deferring to state 
    regulatory authorities in drawing jurisdictional lines for local 
    distribution facility classifications and/or cost allocations. 
    According to TANC, the Commission unlawfully and unnecessarily 
    abdicated its jurisdiction under the FPA (citing New England Power Co. 
    v. New Hampshire, 455 U.S. 331, and Nantahala Power and Light Co. v. 
    Thornburg, 476 U.S. 953). With respect to ISOs, it asserts that the 
    Commission should not defer to state authority in making determinations 
    with respect to classifications of facilities.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        In response to NARUC and IL Com's arguments that this Commission 
    should not simply defer to state commissions regarding application of 
    the seven-factor test but instead should conclusively rely on the 
    findings of state commissions, we believe this is inconsistent with the 
    case law which states that local distribution it is a matter of fact 
    for the Commission to determine as an original matter.471 
    Additionally, we have an independent obligation to ensure that we are 
    fulfilling our responsibilities under the FPA to regulate facilities 
    that are used in interstate commerce. We cannot delegate our 
    jurisdiction. However, we intend to provide broad deference to states 
    in determining what facilities are Commission-jurisdictional 
    transmission facilities and what facilities are state-jurisdictional 
    local distribution facilities, so long as our comparability principles 
    are not compromised and we are able to fulfill our responsibilities 
    under the statute.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \471\ See Colton and Connecticut Light and Power, supra.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We reject FL Com's suggestion that we codify the deference 
    standard. This is neither necessary nor appropriate. In response to NE 
    Public Power District's request that we clarify to whom we would give 
    deference in Nebraska, we clarify that because Nebraska does not have 
    an electric regulatory commission or agency, there is no appropriate 
    regulatory entity to whom our deference standard would apply; 
    accordingly, we will address the transmission/local
    
    [[Page 12373]]
    
    distribution issue for Nebraska without giving deference to any 
    particular entity. In response to PA Com's request that we clarify what 
    we will do if a utility's classifications and/or cost allocation 
    proposals are not supported by state regulatory authorities, we will 
    make a determination based on the factual record before us in a 
    particular case, taking into account the views of the state regulatory 
    authority.
        TANC has argued that we have unlawfully abdicated our jurisdiction 
    by deferring to state recommendations. TANC confuses delegation of 
    jurisdiction, which we cannot do, with willingness to defer to states 
    based on their application of criteria that we have provided. Even in 
    the cases in which the Commission defers to states' views, we will 
    still independently evaluate all material issues and proceed only where 
    substantial evidence supports the states' views. The Commission clearly 
    can entertain requests for deference in these circumstances.
    
    J. Stranded Costs
    
        As indicated in our prior discussion in Section IV.A.5, there are 
    two major overlapping transition issues that arise as a result of this 
    rulemaking: stranded cost recovery and how to deal with contracts 
    entered into under the prior regulatory regime. We here address 
    stranded cost recovery and, as in the prior discussion, we believe it 
    is important to explain the general context in which our stranded cost 
    determinations have been made before addressing the various rehearing 
    requests on this issue.
        In Order No. 888, the Commission removed the single largest barrier 
    to the development of competitive wholesale power markets by requiring 
    non-discriminatory open access transmission as a remedy for undue 
    discrimination. This action carries with it the regulatory public 
    interest responsibility to address the difficult transition issues that 
    arise in moving from a monopoly, cost-based electric utility industry 
    to an industry that is driven by competition among wholesale power 
    suppliers and increasing reliance on market-based generation rates. The 
    most critical transition issue that arises as a result of the 
    Commission's actions in this rulemaking is how to deal with the 
    uneconomic sunk costs that utilities prudently incurred under an 
    industry regime that rested on a regulatory framework and a set of 
    expectations that are being fundamentally altered.
        The Commission determined in Order No. 888 that it must address 
    stranded costs, and that it must do so at an early stage--particularly 
    in light of the lessons learned from our experience with similar issues 
    in the natural gas area. We noted that when we did a similar 
    restructuring in the gas industry, the D.C. Circuit invalidated the 
    Commission's efforts precisely because the Commission had failed to 
    deal with the stranded cost problem in a satisfactory manner.472 
    We explained that, based on the lesson of AGD, the Commission cannot 
    change the rules of the game without providing a mechanism for recovery 
    of the costs caused by such regulatory-mandated change.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \472\ Associated Gas Distributors v. FERC, 824 F.2d 981 (D.C. 
    Cir. 1987), cert. denied, 485 U.S. 1006 (1988) (AGD).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Since the time Order No. 888 issued, we have been provided with 
    additional guidance from the court in the natural gas area, which has 
    further helped to inform our decisions here. In its decision on review 
    of Order No. 636,473 the D.C. Circuit upheld the Commission's 
    decision to allow the recovery of gas supply realignment costs. In so 
    doing, the court, while questioning a specific feature of the stranded 
    cost recovery mechanism employed in Order No. 636, has nevertheless 
    again reaffirmed the basic principle that stranded cost recovery is an 
    appropriate component of a regulatory policy aimed at accomplishing a 
    fair and reasonable transition to competitive markets. The question as 
    to the Commission's ability to allow the recovery of stranded costs has 
    been laid to rest.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \473\ United Distribution Companies v. FERC, 88 F.3d 1105 (1996) 
    (United Distribution Companies).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The task before the Commission in this rulemaking is thus to 
    determine how best to meet its responsibility to address the costs of 
    the transition to a competitive industry, particularly insofar as those 
    costs are stranded, or in effect rendered unrecoverable, as a result of 
    the transmission access required by us under the FPA.474 As the 
    rehearing arguments demonstrate, there is no consensus on how the 
    Commission should address the stranded cost issue. In fact, petitioners 
    are at polar extremes as to what the Commission should do regarding 
    stranded costs. Some argue that the Commission has gone too far in 
    permitting utilities to seek recovery of stranded costs, whether such 
    costs are associated with wholesale requirements contracts, with 
    retail-turned-wholesale customers, or with retail customers that obtain 
    retail wheeling.475 Others argue that the Commission has not gone 
    far enough and that it must broaden the scope of stranded cost recovery 
    permitted under the Rule. Indeed, some would have us be the guarantor 
    for recovery of all uneconomic costs that might be stranded in the move 
    to more competitive markets, no matter how tenuous the nexus to this 
    Rule, and irrespective of state-Federal jurisdictional complexities. 
    Some support the Commission's decision to recover stranded costs 
    directly from the departing customers. Others would prefer that the 
    Commission require utilities to absorb a portion of their stranded 
    costs or that the Commission spread the burden of stranded costs among 
    all of the utility's customers. Some object that the Commission's 
    approach to stranded costs in the electric industry is different from 
    that adopted in the gas industry. Some entities support the 
    Commission's revenues lost approach for measuring a departing 
    customer's stranded cost obligation. Others propose different methods 
    for computing stranded costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \474\ Such access may be the open access required under this 
    Rule or case-by-case transmission access ordered pursuant to FPA 
    section 211.
        \475\ We note that the regulations implementing this Rule use 
    ``wholesale stranded cost'' and ``retail stranded cost'' as 
    shorthand terms to refer to the different situations in which a 
    utility may experience stranded costs. However, as the definitions 
    of those terms make clear, it is not the nature of the costs 
    (wholesale vs. retail) that is controlling for purposes of stranded 
    cost recovery under this Rule. Rather, the controlling factors are 
    the status of the customer (wholesale transmission services customer 
    vs. retail transmission services customer) with whom the costs are 
    associated, and whether the transmission tariffs used by the 
    customer to escape its former power supplier (thus causing the 
    stranding of costs to occur) were required by this Commission or by 
    a state commission. As a result, ``retail stranded costs'' refers to 
    stranded costs associated with retail wheeling customers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Given the plethora of positions that entities have raised both 
    initially and on rehearing concerning stranded costs, the Commission 
    has taken a careful, measured approach with regard to stranded cost 
    recovery. The Commission has balanced a number of important interests 
    in order to achieve what it believes will be a fair and orderly 
    transition to competitive markets. These interests include the 
    financial stability of the electric utility industry, upholding the 
    regulatory bargain under which utilities made major capital 
    investments, and not shifting costs to customers that had no 
    responsibility for causing those costs to be incurred. The Commission 
    also has adopted an approach that, for purposes of stranded cost 
    recovery from wholesale transmission customers, relies on the nexus 
    between stranded costs and the use of transmission tariffs required by 
    this Commission and, for purposes of stranded cost recovery from retail 
    customers, recognizes state commission
    
    [[Page 12374]]
    
    jurisdiction but fills potential regulatory gaps that could arise in 
    the transition to new market structures.
        The balancing of interests and considerations described above is 
    reflected in the following central components of the Rule's stranded 
    cost provisions, which are reaffirmed herein.476 First, the 
    Commission has determined that the most reasonable, legally supportable 
    approach is one that permits utilities to seek recovery of wholesale 
    stranded costs under this Rule (whether the stranded costs are 
    associated with a departing wholesale requirements customer or with a 
    retail-turned-wholesale customer) only in those cases in which there is 
    a direct nexus between the availability and use of Commission-required 
    transmission access 477 and the stranding of costs. In order for 
    the utility to be eligible to seek recovery of stranded costs from a 
    departing customer, the customer must have obtained access to a new 
    generation supplier through the use of the former supplying utility's 
    Commission-required transmission tariff (i.e., its open access tariff 
    or a tariff ordered pursuant to FPA section 211), not through the use 
    of another utility's transmission system.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \476\ We reaffirm below our basic determinations, but make 
    certain clarifications on limited issues and grant rehearing on the 
    municipal annexation issue.
        \477\ As we explain below, by ``Commission-required transmission 
    access'' we mean the open access transmission required under this 
    Rule or required pursuant to a section 211 order, as well as 
    transmission provided prior to Order No. 888 (and not pursuant to a 
    section 211 order) where such transmission was provided on a case-
    by-case basis to comply with the Commission's comparability 
    requirement. See note 484 infra.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Other cost recovery issues are more appropriately addressed outside 
    the context of this Rule. For example, the Rule is not intended to 
    apply to costs associated with the normal risks of competition, such as 
    self-generation, cogeneration, or loss of load, that do not arise from 
    the new, accelerated availability of Commission-required transmission 
    access. If a customer leaves its utility supplier by exercising options 
    that could have been undertaken prior to mandatory transmission under 
    Order No. 888 or the Energy Policy Act, or that do not rely on access 
    to the former seller's transmission, there is no direct nexus to 
    Commission-required transmission access and thus no opportunity for 
    stranded cost recovery under the Rule.
        Second, the Commission has limited the opportunity to seek stranded 
    cost recovery under the Rule primarily to two discrete situations: (1) 
    Costs associated with customers under wholesale requirements contracts 
    executed on or before July 11, 1994 (referred to in the Rule as 
    ``existing wholesale requirements contracts'') that do not contain an 
    exit fee or other explicit stranded cost provision; and (2) costs 
    associated with retail-turned-wholesale customers. With regard to the 
    existing wholesale requirements contracts, the Commission also has made 
    a finding that it is in the public interest to permit amendments to add 
    stranded cost provisions to these contracts, even if they contain 
    Mobile-Sierra clauses, if case-by-case evidentiary burdens are met. We 
    do not interpret the Mobile-Sierra public interest standard as 
    practically insurmountable in extraordinary situations such as this one 
    where historic statutory and regulatory changes have converged to 
    fundamentally change the obligations of utilities and the markets in 
    which they and their customers will operate.
        Third, Order No. 888 does not guarantee that a utility will be 
    allowed to recover stranded costs. Rather, it provides an opportunity 
    for such recovery. To be eligible to recover stranded costs from a 
    departing customer in a particular case, the utility must demonstrate 
    that it incurred costs to provide service to the customer based on a 
    reasonable expectation of continuing service to that customer beyond 
    the contract term.478 In the case of stranded costs associated 
    with wholesale requirements contracts customers, if the contract 
    contains a notice of termination provision, that provision is strong 
    evidence that the parties were aware that at some point in the future 
    the customer might seek to find another supplier. Therefore, there is a 
    rebuttable presumption of no reasonable expectation, and therefore no 
    opportunity for stranded cost recovery unless the utility can overcome 
    the presumption.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \478\ We have made a minor revision to the regulatory text, 
    section 35.26(c)(2), to conform the language of that section with 
    sections 35.26(b) (1) and (5). A conforming revision has been made 
    to section 35.26(d)(2)(i).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission has concluded that direct assignment of stranded 
    costs to the departing customer (through either an exit fee or a 
    surcharge on transmission) is the appropriate method for recovery of 
    stranded costs under the Rule. In reaching this conclusion, the 
    Commission carefully weighed the arguments supporting direct assignment 
    of stranded costs against those supporting a more broad-based approach, 
    such as spreading stranded costs to all transmission users of a 
    utility's system, and also took into account the fact that we applied a 
    different approach in the natural gas area. The central considerations 
    that support a direct assignment approach in the electric industry are 
    that the approach follows the traditional regulatory concept of cost 
    causation, it avoids shifting costs to customers that had no 
    responsibility for causing them to be incurred or for causing them to 
    be stranded, and it is still possible to apply such an approach at this 
    stage of the industry's evolution.
        There is no question that, without the stranded cost recovery 
    mechanism, some customers would be far more likely to switch to lower-
    cost suppliers and enjoy sooner the benefits of a competitive power 
    market. But, as detailed in Order No. 888, such an approach may result 
    in higher costs for other customers. We thus have had to balance the 
    potential for earlier benefits for some customers against other public 
    interest considerations, most particularly the need to provide a fair 
    mechanism by which utilities can recover the costs of past investments 
    under traditional regulatory concepts of prudently incurred costs and 
    cost causation. The result is not to deny competitive advantages, but 
    only to delay their full realization for some customers so that all 
    customers ultimately will benefit.
        While Order No. 888's cost causation approach is different from the 
    Order No. 636 cost spreading approach that was affirmed in the United 
    Distribution Companies case, we believe it is the preferable approach 
    given the early stage of the electric utility's competitive transition. 
    We do not read the court's opinion as precluding the Commission from 
    adopting a direct assignment approach in Order No. 888, particularly 
    where, as here, the Commission has fully explained and justified the 
    reasons for following traditional cost causation principles. In 
    addition, although the United Distribution Companies court remanded for 
    further consideration (in light of Order No. 636's cost spreading 
    approach) the decision not to require any pipeline absorption of gas 
    supply realignment costs, the Commission has fully explained how its 
    decision in Order No. 888 not to require any utility absorption of 
    stranded costs is consistent with its decision to follow traditional 
    cost causation principles. With respect to the fundamental conclusion 
    that utilities should be permitted an opportunity to recover their 
    prudently incurred costs, Order No. 888 is fully consistent with Order 
    No. 636. Although the Commission in Order No. 888 chose a direct 
    assignment method (rather than the cost-spreading
    
    [[Page 12375]]
    
    approach in Order No. 636) for purposes of allocating stranded cost 
    responsibility among customers, the approach used by the Commission in 
    Order No. 888 is not governed by decisions in Order No. 636, but in 
    either event the Commission must demonstrate that its choice of methods 
    is based on reasoned decision-making.
        In considering the stranded cost issues that may arise in the 
    transition to competitive markets, the Commission also has taken 
    cognizance of significant changes involving retail customers and the 
    stranded cost issues that arise as retail customers convert to 
    wholesale customer status (e.g., through municipalizations) in order to 
    obtain the open access afforded by Order No. 888, or as they obtain 
    retail wheeling required by state commissions. These situations involve 
    new and complex jurisdictional issues and represent the bulk of 
    potential stranded costs facing the industry. We believe it is 
    important to clarify the Commission's decisions as to when it will 
    entertain requests for stranded cost recovery in these situations, and 
    our reasons for doing so.
        The Commission's determination that it, rather than the states, 
    should be the primary forum for addressing stranded costs associated 
    with a retail-turned-wholesale customer 479 is limited to those 
    cases in which there is a direct nexus between the availability and use 
    of Commission-required transmission access and the stranding of costs. 
    We believe we have both the authority and the obligation to provide an 
    opportunity for stranded cost recovery in these situations because the 
    bundled retail customer would not be able to obtain access to the new 
    supplier but for the Commission's order requiring transmission. The 
    creation of a new wholesale entity to purchase power on behalf of 
    retail customers would not, by itself, trigger stranded costs. In the 
    absence of transmission access from the historical supplier of the 
    retail customers, the new entity would have to remain on the historical 
    supplier's generation system because it would have no way to reach 
    other power suppliers, and stranded costs would not occur.480 
    Therefore, there is a causal nexus between the stranded costs and the 
    availability and use of the tariff services required by the 
    Commission.481 Moreover, because of this causal nexus between the 
    use of a jurisdictional utility's Commission-required transmission 
    tariff and the potential for foregone revenues by that jurisdictional 
    utility as a result of the Commission-required access, the stranded 
    costs associated with a retail-turned-wholesale customer are properly 
    viewed as economic costs that are jurisdictional to this Commission.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \479\ In Order No. 888 and here, we sometimes use the shorthand 
    expression ``retail-turned-wholesale'' customer. By this we do not 
    mean that a retail customer who is an ultimate consumer ceases to be 
    an ultimate consumer, or that this customer begins to purchase 
    electric energy for resale. Rather, in a ``retail-turned-wholesale 
    customer'' situation, such as the creation of a municipal utility 
    system, a newly-created entity becomes a wholesale power purchaser 
    on behalf of retail customers who were formerly bundled customers of 
    the historical local utility power supplier. The new municipal 
    utility is the conduit by which retail customers, if they cannot 
    obtain direct retail access, can reach power suppliers other than 
    their historical local utility power supplier. Although the retail 
    customers remain bundled retail customers, in that they become the 
    bundled customers of the new entity, we call this a ``retail-turned-
    wholesale customer'' situation because the new entity in effect 
    ``stands in the shoes'' of the retail customers for purposes of 
    obtaining wholesale transmission access and new power supply.
        \480\ Exceptions would be self-generation or construction by the 
    new entity of its own transmission line, in which case, as noted 
    earlier, the stranded cost provisions of Order No. 888 would not 
    apply because such options have always been available as 
    alternatives to purchasing power from the historical supplying 
    utility and do not involve the use of the utility's transmission 
    facilities under an open access tariff. Thus the departure of 
    customers under these circumstances cannot be linked to the open 
    access requirements of this Rule.
        \481\ As discussed in greater detail in Sections IV.J.6 and 
    IV.J.12 below, we clarify that the opportunity for recovery of 
    stranded costs in a retail-turned-wholesale situation is limited to 
    cases in which the former bundled retail customer subsequently 
    becomes, either directly or through another wholesale transmission 
    purchaser, an unbundled wholesale transmission services customer of 
    its former supplier. We have revised section 35.26(b)(1)(i) of the 
    Commission's regulations accordingly.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In contrast, in the situation in which a bundled retail customer 
    obtains retail wheeling, stranded costs are directly caused by the 
    availability and use of unbundled retail services required by the state 
    commission, not this Commission. 482 Thus, the Commission believes 
    that states, not the Commission, should be the primary forum for costs 
    associated with a bundled retail customer that obtains retail wheeling. 
    The Commission's decision to entertain requests to recover stranded 
    costs caused by retail wheeling in only a limited circumstance (where 
    the state regulatory authority does not have authority under state law 
    to address stranded costs when the retail wheeling is required) is 
    based on a policy decision by this Commission that it will step in to 
    fill a regulatory ``gap'' that could result in no effective forum in 
    which utilities would have an opportunity to seek recovery of prudently 
    incurred costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \482\ Unbundled retail transmission services required by a state 
    commission could be taken under the same pro forma open access 
    tariff used by wholesale customers or, if determined appropriate by 
    the Commission, under a separate retail tariff filed at the 
    Commission. The critical point, however, is that in either case, the 
    unbundled services are required by the state and not by this 
    Commission.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Finally, after considering various proposals regarding how stranded 
    costs should be calculated, and reviewing the arguments of petitioners 
    on rehearing, the Commission continues to believe that the revenues 
    lost approach is the fairest and most efficient way to determine the 
    amount of stranded cost assigned to a departing customer during the 
    transition to a competitive wholesale bulk power market. The Commission 
    has rejected an asset-by-asset approach as overly complicated and 
    costly.
        We respond below to the specific arguments raised on rehearing and 
    elaborate on the above determinations.
    1. Justification for Allowing Recovery of Stranded Costs
        In Order No. 888, the Commission concluded that utilities should be 
    given the opportunity to seek recovery of legitimate, prudent and 
    verifiable stranded costs associated with a limited set of wholesale 
    requirements contracts executed on or before July 11, 1994. 483 We 
    stated that utilities that entered into contracts to make wholesale 
    requirements sales under an entirely different regulatory regime should 
    have an opportunity to recover stranded costs that occur as a result of 
    customers leaving the utilities' generation systems through Commission-
    jurisdictional open access tariffs or FPA section 211 orders to reach 
    other power suppliers. We explained that utilities that made large 
    capital expenditures or long-term contractual commitments to buy power 
    years ago to supply their customers should not now be held responsible 
    for failing to foresee the actions this Commission would take to alter 
    the use of their transmission systems in response to the fundamental 
    changes that are taking place in the industry. We found that recent 
    significant statutory and regulatory changes are central to the 
    circumstances that now place at risk the recovery of past investment 
    decisions of utilities. We indicated that we will not ignore the 
    effects of these changes as we fashion policies that will govern 
    possible recovery of these costs in the transition to an open access 
    regulatory regime.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \483\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,788-91; mimeo at 451-58.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We stated that while there has always been some risk that a utility 
    would lose a particular customer, in the past that risk was smaller. It 
    was not
    
    [[Page 12376]]
    
    unreasonable for the utility to plan to continue serving the needs of 
    its wholesale requirements customers and retail customers, and for 
    those customers to expect the utility to plan to meet their future 
    needs. We concluded that with the new open access transmission, 
    484 the risk of losing a customer is radically increased. If a 
    former wholesale requirements customer or a former retail customer uses 
    the new open access to reach a new supplier, the utility is entitled to 
    seek recovery of legitimate, prudent and verifiable costs that it 
    incurred under the prior regulatory regime to serve that customer. The 
    utility, however, would have the burden of demonstrating that it had a 
    reasonable expectation of continuing to serve the departing customer.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \484\ In Order No. 888, we explained that by ``new open access'' 
    or ``open access transmission'' we were referring to Commission-
    jurisdictional open access tariffs or to a tariff ordered pursuant 
    to FPA section 211. Although we generally refer in the text of Order 
    No. 888 and the text of this order to the open access tariffs 
    required under this Rule and to tariffs required pursuant to a 
    section 211 order, we clarify that the ``new open access'' or ``open 
    access transmission'' described in this Rule also includes 
    transmission provided prior to Order No. 888 (and not pursuant to a 
    section 211 order) where such tariff filings were made on a case-by-
    case basis to comply with the Commission's comparability 
    requirement. To avoid any confusion on this point, we refer in this 
    order to all such open access transmission as ``Commission-mandated 
    transmission access'' or ``Commission-required transmission 
    access.''
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests Opposing, or Seeking Limitations on, Stranded Cost 
    Recovery
    
        Several entities challenge the Commission's decision to give 
    utilities an opportunity to recover legitimate, prudent and verifiable 
    stranded costs. NASUCA argues that the transition to wholesale 
    competition was underway before and apart from the NOPR. It asserts 
    that the drivers of the developing competition include voluntary open 
    access filings by utilities seeking mergers or market-based rate 
    authority and section 211 of the FPA, as amended by the Energy Policy 
    Act of 1992 (Energy Policy Act). According to NASUCA, stranded 
    investment results from legislative, not regulatory action, and the 
    stranded cost issue does, and would, exist without the Open Access 
    Rule. It contends that an acceleration of the competitive wholesale 
    transformation does not change its nature or origins. NASUCA also 
    contends that the issuance of the Open Access Rule does not justify 
    stranded cost recovery on ``regulatory compact'' grounds because it is 
    not a fundamental change.
        Other entities object that there is no basis for the Commission to 
    impute an extra-contractual obligation to serve wholesale requirements 
    customers.485 These entities argue, for example, that utilities 
    could and should have protected themselves from any potential stranded 
    costs through individual customer contracts.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \485\ E.g., American Forest & Paper, Blue Ridge, TDU Systems, IN 
    Consumer Counselor, IN Consumers, IL Com.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        IN Consumer Counselor and IN Consumers object that Order No. 888 
    attempts to transform the obligation to provide a utility with an 
    ``opportunity'' for a fair return when prices are regulated into an 
    ``entitlement'' to ``recover legitimate, prudent and verifiable costs 
    that it incurred under the prior regulatory regime.'' 486
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \486\ IN Consumer Counselor at 9 (citing Order No. 888, mimeo at 
    452-53); IN Consumers at 10 (same).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several entities submit that the Commission has not adequately 
    addressed the potential anticompetitive impact of stranded cost 
    recovery.487 Some argue that giving utilities the opportunity to 
    recover wholesale stranded costs will delay the opportunity for 
    historically captive customers to benefit from competitive 
    alternatives.488 Central Illinois Light contends that the Rule is 
    arbitrary and capricious because it will have different impacts on 
    different customers, which Central Illinois Light asserts will be due 
    to accidents of circumstance rather than the conscious application of 
    rational policy choices. IN Consumers objects that two similarly-
    situated customers of the utility for identical transmission services 
    will be required to pay substantially different rates for the same 
    service (where one previously purchased its power requirements from the 
    utility, while the other used an alternate source of supply).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \487\ E.g., APPA, IN Consumer Counselor, IN Consumers, Suffolk 
    County, TDU Systems, Specialty Steel, Occidental Chemical, Central 
    Illinois Light, American Forest & Paper, Nucor, Blue Ridge.
        \488\ E.g., APPA, IN Consumer Counselor, IN Consumers, Suffolk 
    County, TDU Systems, Specialty Steel.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Central Illinois Light also objects that even a partial allowance 
    of stranded costs will likely encourage predatory pricing. It says that 
    the Commission has failed to adequately address the harm that stranded 
    cost ``subsidies'' pose to low-cost utilities with little or no 
    stranded costs. Others contend that the Rule would subvert economic 
    efficiency by unjustly enriching utilities that have not attempted to 
    meet the new market demands, to the detriment of those utilities that 
    have.489 According to Occidental Chemical, the Commission has made 
    no finding that the pro-competitive goals of Order No. 888 can be 
    accomplished in light of the costs and uncertainties presented by 
    stranded cost recovery.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \489\ E.g., American Forest & Paper, Nucor, Blue Ridge.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several entities also challenge the adequacy of the factual record 
    for allowing wholesale stranded cost recovery and argue that utilities 
    have not provided the hard data on wholesale stranded costs that the 
    Commission needs to justify Order No. 888.490 Central Illinois 
    Light objects that the Commission failed to note or to discuss data 
    presented by commenters showing that only a small group of high-cost 
    utilities need some stranded cost protection. American Forest & Paper 
    argues that the Commission has failed to demonstrate on the record the 
    existence of any stranded wholesale investment that was or could be 
    caused by the transition to open access transmission.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \490\ E.g., ELCON, TDU Systems, Central Illinois Light, American 
    Forest & Paper.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        SC Public Service Authority repeats its earlier request that the 
    Commission deny market-based rate authority to any utility that elects 
    to recover stranded costs from departing customers.491 It objects 
    that the Commission failed to specifically respond to its previous 
    comments on this issue.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \491\ See also American Forest & Paper (unless a utility agrees 
    not to seek stranded costs under the Rule, the utility should not be 
    found to have mitigated its transmission market power for purposes 
    of charging market-based rates, merging with other utilities or 
    otherwise, simply by filing an open access tariff).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        American Forest & Paper objects that utilities that voluntarily 
    filed open access tariffs cannot use the stranded cost rule because 
    their loss of customers cannot be said to have occurred only because of 
    the Rule. It submits that only those utilities who had to be forced to 
    offer open access transmission are being rewarded.
        San Francisco asks that the Commission include ``exercise of pre-
    existing contract rights for transmission and designation of wholesale 
    loads'' or similar language as one of the examples (listed in footnote 
    718) of situations for which stranded costs may not be sought. San 
    Francisco explains that it wants to ensure that PG&E would not have any 
    basis to argue that any load loss PG&E suffers as a result of San 
    Francisco's designation of municipal loads would be eligible for 
    stranded cost recovery.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We will deny the requests for rehearing of our decision to allow
    
    [[Page 12377]]
    
    utilities an opportunity to seek recovery of legitimate, prudent, and 
    verifiable stranded costs. As we indicated in Order No. 888, we learned 
    from our experience with natural gas that, as both a legal and a policy 
    matter, we cannot ignore these costs. The U.S. Court of Appeals for the 
    District of Columbia Circuit invalidated the Commission's first open 
    access rule for gas pipelines because the Commission failed to deal 
    with the uneconomic take-or-pay situation that many pipelines faced as 
    a result of regulatory changes beyond their control.492 That same 
    court has subsequently affirmed the Commission's decision to allow the 
    recovery of costs that are stranded in the transition to a competitive 
    natural gas industry, most recently by upholding the Commission's 
    decision in Order No. 636 to allow the recovery of gas supply 
    realignment costs.493
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \492\ AGD, 824 F.2d at 1021.
        \493\ United Distribution Companies, 88 F.3d 1105 (1996). 
    Although the court remanded that aspect of Order No. 636 that allows 
    pipelines to recover 100 percent of their gas supply realignment 
    costs without requiring any pipeline absorption, we explain in 
    Section IV.J.3 below how Order No. 888 is fully consistent with that 
    remand.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Here we are faced, once again, with an industry transition in which 
    there is the possibility that, as a result of statutory and regulatory 
    changes beyond their control, certain utilities may be left with large 
    unrecoverable, legitimate and prudent costs or that those costs will be 
    unfairly shifted to other (remaining) customers. Thus, in order to 
    satisfy our regulatory responsibilities, we must directly and timely 
    address the costs of the transition by allowing utilities to seek 
    recovery of legitimate, prudent and verifiable stranded costs.494 
    While the transition to wholesale competition may have begun before the 
    NOPR, we strongly disagree with NASUCA's claim that the Open Access 
    Rule does not justify stranded cost recovery because an acceleration of 
    the transition does not change its nature or origins. The driving force 
    behind the development of wholesale competitive markets is the 
    widespread transmission access made available through Commission-
    mandated transmission tariffs,495 including transmission tariffs 
    ordered pursuant to FPA section 211 and the transmission tariffs 
    required by the Commission's Open Access Rule.496 Furthermore, as 
    explained in the Rule and as further discussed below, it is the ability 
    of customers to obtain readily available Commission-mandated 
    transmission access that significantly increases the potential for 
    wholesale stranded costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \494\ See FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,789; mimeo at 453-54.
        \495\ As we explain above, Commission-mandated transmission 
    tariffs is meant to include all open access tariffs filed pursuant 
    to Commission order, including tariffs filed under this Rule, 
    tariffs ordered pursuant to FPA section 211, and tariffs that were 
    filed on a case-by-case basis to comply with the Commission's 
    comparability requirement.
        \496\ As a result of the Open Access Rule, 47 Group 2 public 
    utilities, which had no open access transmission tariff available 
    prior to Order No. 888, submitted and had available on July 9, 1996 
    non-discriminatory open access transmission tariffs. In addition, 
    101 Group 1 public utilities, which had some version of open access 
    available prior to Order No. 888, filed new open access tariffs 
    effective July 9, 1996 in order to conform to the terms and 
    conditions of non-discriminatory open access service specified in 
    the pro forma tariff. Thus, as of July 9, 1996, 148 of the 166 
    public utilities had filed Order No. 888 open access tariffs. At 
    least ten others filed open access tariffs after July 9, 1996 (e.g., 
    after the Commission dealt with their waiver requests). This, in the 
    Commission's view, represents an unprecedented acceleration of the 
    transition to competitive bulk power markets. From the issuance of 
    the Open Access NOPR in March 1995 until the effective date of Order 
    No. 888 on July 9, 1996 is only a little more than one year.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Order No. 888 requires the functional unbundling of a public 
    utility's wholesale services. Under the Rule, all public utilities that 
    own, control or operate facilities used for transmitting electric 
    energy in interstate commerce were required by July 9, 1996 to file 
    open access transmission tariffs that contain minimum terms and 
    conditions of non-discriminatory service (or to seek waiver), and to 
    take transmission service (including ancillary services) for their own 
    new wholesale sales and purchases of electric energy under the open 
    access tariffs. As a result of Order No. 888, wholesale requirements 
    customers that previously were captive customers of their public 
    utility suppliers (i.e., they had no choice but to take bundled sales 
    and transmission services from their suppliers) will be able at the 
    expiration of their contracts to take unbundled transmission service 
    (i.e., transmission-only service) from their former suppliers in order 
    to reach new suppliers. While in the past there has been some risk of 
    stranded costs due to customers ``leaving'' a supplier's system through 
    self-generation or perhaps municipalization, there was little or no 
    ability to shop for alternative power such as that which will occur as 
    a result of readily available Commission-mandated transmission access. 
    Contrary to NASUCA's claims, Order No. 888, coupled with section 211 of 
    the FPA, creates the opportunity, as a matter of law, for an existing 
    wholesale requirements customer to use the transmission owner's 
    facilities to reach a new supplier.497 This leaves the former 
    supplying utility with significant risk that it will be unable to 
    recover costs that the utility incurred based on a reasonable 
    expectation that it would continue to serve the departing customer.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \497\ NASUCA and other petitioners offer no persuasive evidence 
    that meaningful competition took root prior to the availability of 
    the new transmission access requirements. The few utilities that did 
    provide transmission service under open access tariffs prior to the 
    announcement of the Commission's comparability requirement did not 
    offer third parties comparable service. To the contrary, such 
    tariffs contained numerous disparities in the transmission service 
    that the utilities provided to third parties in comparison to their 
    own uses of the transmission system. See, e.g., Entergy Services, 
    Inc., 58 FERC para. 61,234, order on reh'g, 60 FERC para. 61,168 
    (1992), remanded, sub nom., Cajun Electric Power Cooperative, Inc. 
    v. FERC, 28 F.3d 173, 179-80 (D.C. Cir. 1994) (tariff contained 
    limitations on point-to-point service and did not provide network 
    service; tariff reserved transmission provider's right to cancel 
    service in certain instances, even where a customer had paid for 
    transmission system modifications). While the desire of customers 
    for competitive power markets may have preceded Commission-mandated 
    open access, customers had no assurance they could reach alternative 
    suppliers until the Commission required utilities to provide 
    transmission service on a comparable basis.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Thus, the regulatory and statutory changes contained in Order No. 
    888 and in amended section 211, which will act in tandem to provide the 
    transmission access necessary to develop the competitive wholesale 
    markets envisioned by Congress in the Energy Policy Act, have a direct 
    nexus to the potential for wholesale stranded costs. This nexus makes 
    it critical that the Commission address this transition issue 
    responsibly and equitably. Having balanced the goals of competition, 
    the nexus between potential stranded costs and transmission access, and 
    the regulatory bargain under which utilities invested billions of 
    dollars in reliance on the prior regulatory regime, we believe that 
    utilities are entitled to an opportunity to seek recovery of stranded 
    costs and that our actions in Order No. 888 are not only legally 
    supportable, but also represent sound public policy.
        In response to those entities who argue that there is no basis for 
    imputing an extra-contractual obligation to serve wholesale 
    requirements customers, as we explained in Order No. 888, we believe 
    there previously has been an implicit obligation to serve at wholesale 
    in many cases. Such obligation is based, in large part, on the 
    recognition that historically most wholesale requirements customers 
    were captive and had no means of reaching alternative suppliers. The 
    local utility supplied bundled generation and transmission services to 
    these customers on the assumption that they would remain as customers. 
    Accordingly, the utility had a concomitant obligation to plan to supply 
    these customers'
    
    [[Page 12378]]
    
    continuing needs, and planned its system taking account of the 
    wholesale load. In many cases the wholesale customers participated by 
    supplying load forecasts. Consistent with this practical obligation to 
    serve, the Commission viewed the supplying utility as the supplier of 
    first resort, and did not allow a utility to terminate service without 
    prior Commission approval. Before Order No. 888, the Commission's 
    regulations required prior notification and approval of the proposed 
    cancellation or termination of a wholesale requirements contract. We 
    note that although Order No. 888 eliminates the prior notice of 
    cancellation or termination requirement for power sales contracts 
    executed on or after July 9, 1996 (the effective date of the Open 
    Access Rule) that are to terminate by their own terms,498 it 
    expressly retains the prior notice of cancellation or termination 
    requirement for any power sales contract executed before that date.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \498\ The Rule requires that the utility notify the Commission 
    of the date of termination for this class of contracts within 30 
    days after the termination takes place. The Rule retains the prior 
    notice of cancellation or termination requirement for power sales 
    contracts executed on or after July 9, 1996 if termination is on 
    grounds other than expiration of the contract by its terms at the 
    end of the contract. See Portland General Electric Company, 75 FERC 
    para. 61,310, reh'g denied 77 FERC para. 61,171 (1996) (Commission 
    authorization required for termination of power sales contract in 
    the event of the commencement of a bankruptcy proceeding, failure to 
    perform any obligation under the contract, or failure to provide 
    adequate assurance of the ability to perform).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        It is important to note, however, that while the stranded cost 
    recovery provisions of the Rule are based on the implicit obligation to 
    serve, the Rule does not guarantee any extra-contractual wholesale 
    stranded cost recovery, much less across-the-board recovery of such 
    costs by all public utilities. To the contrary, it provides an 
    opportunity for such recovery only for a discrete set of requirements 
    contracts (those executed on or before July 11, 1994 that do not 
    contain an exit fee or other explicit stranded cost provision), and the 
    Rule requires that a utility must meet a heavy burden of proving 
    eligibility to recover costs in a particular case: before a departing 
    customer is required to pay a stranded cost exit fee or transmission 
    surcharge, the utility must demonstrate that it incurred costs to 
    provide service to a customer based on a reasonable expectation of 
    continuing service to that customer beyond the end of the 
    contract.499
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \499\ To the extent there is any misunderstanding, we clarify 
    that the intent of the Rule to permit the ``opportunity'' to recover 
    stranded costs is not an ``entitlement'' to recover such costs. As a 
    result, the passage in Order No. 888 to which IN Consumer Counselor 
    and IN Consumers object (FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,789, mimeo at 
    452-53) should read ``we believe that the utility is entitled to an 
    opportunity to recover legitimate, prudent and verifiable costs that 
    it incurred under the prior regulatory regime to serve that 
    customer'' (emphasis to show added language).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We believe that we adequately address in both Order No. 888 and in 
    Section IV.J.2 below the concerns various entities have expressed as to 
    the potential anticompetitive impact of stranded cost recovery. 
    Although we recognize that stranded cost recovery may delay some of the 
    benefits of competitive bulk power markets for some customers, we 
    believe that customers as a whole will benefit from a fair and orderly 
    transition. Indeed, we are particularly concerned that the failure to 
    assign stranded cost responsibilities to customers that have access to 
    alternative suppliers will leave captive customers exposed to the risk 
    of greater cost burdens, thereby shifting to captive customers the 
    costs that were originally incurred for the benefit of the (typically 
    larger) customers who have the flexibility to take early advantage of 
    competing power suppliers. Avoiding this potential cost shifting 
    problem is an important goal of our decision to address the stranded 
    cost problem as part and parcel of the decision to mandate open access. 
    As we said in Order No. 888:
    
    such transition costs must nevertheless be addressed at an early 
    stage if we are to fulfill our regulatory responsibilities in moving 
    to competitive markets. The stranded cost recovery mechanism that we 
    direct here is a necessary step to achieve pro-competitive results. 
    In the long term, the Commission's Rule will result in more 
    competitive prices and lower rates for consumers.[500]
    
        \500\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,794; mimeo at 468-69.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We do not believe that allowing utilities an opportunity to seek 
    stranded cost recovery will prevent us from achieving the pro-
    competitive goals of Order No. 888. To the contrary, as discussed below 
    in Section IV.J.3, we think that it is necessary to provide utilities 
    the opportunity to seek to recover stranded costs if we are to have a 
    fair and orderly transition to more competitive bulk power markets. The 
    opponents of Order No. 888's stranded cost approach argue that the 
    transition to fully competitive bulk power markets will be slower if we 
    allow utilities an opportunity to seek to recover stranded costs from 
    departing customers, and with respect to some customers that may well 
    be true. As noted earlier, some customers because of their size and 
    limited contractual obligations with their current utility suppliers 
    have the ability immediately to leave the system. If they are allowed 
    to do so without paying the costs incurred to provide them expected 
    future service, the economic attractiveness of departing the system is 
    obviously enhanced and the benefits of competition, for these 
    customers, obviously come sooner rather than later. However, the pace 
    at which fully competitive markets are achieved, while important, is 
    not the only consideration. It is the Commission's responsibility to 
    ensure that the costs of open access are fairly assigned and that the 
    benefits of Order No. 888's open access requirements will be fairly 
    available to all customers. These dual goals compel us toward a 
    balanced approach that, although perhaps delaying somewhat the benefits 
    of competition, nevertheless ensures that all customers will share in 
    those benefits without undermining historic principles of cost recovery 
    upon which utilities were entitled to rely in planning their systems.
        Moreover, as we explain in Section IV.J.3 below, we have carefully 
    examined different methods of allocating stranded costs that are found 
    to be properly recoverable, including assigning the costs directly to 
    the departing customer or spreading the costs to all transmission users 
    of a utility's system. We recognize that the direct assignment approach 
    to stranded cost recovery delays competition for some customers because 
    it attaches a price tag for customers who have the immediate ability to 
    leave the system. However, we have identified the advantages and 
    disadvantages of each approach and have concluded, on balance, that 
    direct assignment is the preferable approach for both legal and policy 
    reasons.
        In response to the concerns of some entities that stranded cost 
    ``subsidies'' may harm low-cost utilities with little or no stranded 
    costs, or otherwise may unjustly enrich utilities that have not 
    attempted to meet the new market demands to the detriment of those that 
    have, we again emphasize the limited and transitional nature of the 
    stranded cost recovery opportunity allowed under Order No. 888.501 
    It is clearly not the Commission's intent that utilities with little or 
    no stranded cost exposure be competitively disadvantaged by the Open 
    Access Rule. Those utilities with little or no stranded costs will be 
    similarly situated with other new suppliers in the sense that they will 
    all
    
    [[Page 12379]]
    
    face the potential of not being able to compete immediately for certain 
    wholesale customers who are determined to have an obligation to pay 
    stranded costs. These customers may find it to be uneconomic to shop 
    from new power suppliers because they may have to pay costs they caused 
    to be incurred under the prior industry regime before they are able to 
    switch suppliers. However, this will be during a transition period 
    only, and only with respect to a discrete set of contracts and only 
    where the utility meets its burden of proof with respect to a 
    particular departing customer.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \501\ As we indicate in Section IV.J.9 below, we disagree that 
    the Rule's definition of stranded costs artificially and 
    unjustifiably improves the competitive position of an inefficient 
    utility.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We reject as misplaced IN Consumers' argument that the Open Access 
    Rule is discriminatory because two ``similarly-situated'' customers for 
    ``identical'' transmission services (one who previously purchased 
    transmission bundled with its power requirements from the utility and 
    now seeks to purchase only unbundled transmission, and the other who 
    previously used an alternative source of supply and seeks to purchase 
    unbundled transmission from the utility) will pay substantially 
    different rates for the same service. The error in this argument is 
    that the two customers in the example are not ``similarly-situated'' 
    precisely because one of them was a former bundled wholesale 
    requirements customer of the utility for whom the utility may have 
    incurred costs to meet reasonably expected customer demand, whereas the 
    other was never a generation customer of the utility and thus 
    appropriately bears no cost responsibility for stranded generation 
    costs incurred by that utility. Indeed, this example illustrates 
    precisely the reason underlying the Commission's stranded cost 
    mechanism. If a utility had previously served a customer as a seller of 
    generation as well as a transmitter, it is allowed an opportunity to 
    show that it incurred costs based on a reasonable expectation of 
    continuing to serve the power needs of that customer beyond the 
    contract term. Similarly, contrary to Central Illinois Light's claim, 
    if different treatment of different customers were to occur, it would 
    not be due to ``accidents of circumstance''--it would be the result of 
    the conscious application by the Commission of its decision to give a 
    utility the opportunity to recover stranded costs from a wholesale 
    requirements customer if the utility can demonstrate that it incurred 
    costs to provide service to the customer based on a reasonable 
    expectation that it would continue to serve the customer after the 
    contract term.
        In response to the claims of those entities that challenge the 
    factual record for allowing wholesale stranded cost recovery, we 
    believe that the record in this proceeding clearly demonstrates the 
    need to give utilities the opportunity to recover wholesale stranded 
    costs. We have shown that the Rule's open access requirement will 
    significantly alter historical relationships among traditional 
    utilities and their customers. Indeed, that is one of its objectives. 
    In the longer term, we seek to have all power supply arrangements 
    priced by the competitive marketplace. However, utilities prudently 
    incurred costs under a prior regulatory regime that created an 
    expectation of an opportunity for recovery of those costs. Common sense 
    indicates that a utility that historically supplied bundled generation 
    and transmission services to a wholesale requirements customer and that 
    reasonably expected to continue to serve the customer may have incurred 
    costs to provide service to that customer that could be stranded if the 
    customer uses open access transmission to reach a new generation 
    supplier.502 As we learned from our experience in restructuring of 
    the natural gas industry, open access and unbundling did in fact 
    exacerbate the take-or-pay problems in the gas industry because it gave 
    customers more options. That is what we are doing in the electric 
    industry as well. As a result, we have concluded that utilities should 
    be permitted to seek recovery of stranded costs in certain limited and 
    defined circumstances.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \502\ As the AGD court noted: ``Agencies do not need to conduct 
    experiments in order to rely on the prediction that an unsupported 
    stone will fall.'' 824 F.2d at 1008.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We disagree with those entities that argue that utilities have not 
    provided sufficient data on the existence of wholesale stranded costs 
    to justify the approach adopted by the Commission in Order No. 888. 
    Presumably these entities would require us to calculate specific 
    stranded cost estimates for every public utility before we could act to 
    address this critical issue. However, where the Commission decides to 
    act by means of a generic rule,503 the Commission is not required 
    to make individual findings on a utility-by-utility basis.504 
    Moreover, the Rule does not say that all utilities with wholesale 
    contract customers will be allowed to recover stranded costs, only that 
    those utilities that have requirements contracts that were executed on 
    or before July 11, 1994 that do not contain an exit fee or explicit 
    stranded cost provision and that can meet the required evidentiary 
    showing would be allowed such recovery. On this basis, our decision to 
    give utilities the opportunity to seek stranded cost recovery for 
    certain wholesale requirements contracts is not dependent on a showing 
    that any particular utility will actually be eligible to recover 
    stranded costs as a result of the open access requirement.505
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \503\ As we noted in Order No. 888, there is no question that it 
    is within the Commission's discretion to decide whether to act 
    through rule or through case-by-case adjudication. FERC Stats. & 
    Regs. at 31,679; mimeo at 127-28.
        \504\ See AGD, 824 F.2d at 1008.
        \505\ Indeed, we are somewhat puzzled by the argument that we 
    may not act in the absence of ``hard data'' that the potential 
    stranded cost problem is widespread and huge. Here we provide only 
    the opportunity to seek stranded cost recovery for a concededly 
    narrow subset of cases that we believe may give rise to a valid 
    claim for extracontractual recovery. If as petitioners suggest the 
    problem is modest and confined to a small number of utilities, the 
    evidentiary process will sort that out, and the potential effect on 
    departing customers and on the pace of competition will be similarly 
    modest.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We also will reject SC Public Service Authority's request that the 
    Commission deny market-based rate authority for all utilities seeking 
    stranded cost recovery. SC Public Service Authority has failed to 
    demonstrate that the ability to seek stranded cost recovery would, by 
    definition, eliminate the potential for mitigation of any generation or 
    transmission market power. If an entity believes that a utility seeking 
    market-based rate authority does not satisfy the Commission's criteria 
    for the grant of market-rate authority (e.g., because the utility has, 
    or has failed to mitigate, market power in generation or transmission), 
    that entity will have ample opportunity to present its case in the 
    market-based rate proceeding.
        American Forest & Paper's objection that utilities that voluntarily 
    filed open access tariffs cannot utilize the stranded cost provisions 
    and therefore that only utilities who were forced to offer open access 
    transmission are being rewarded is misplaced. First, there is nothing 
    in Order No. 888 that prohibits a utility that voluntarily filed an 
    open access transmission tariff from seeking recovery of stranded costs 
    if it can demonstrate a reasonable expectation of continuing to serve a 
    particular wholesale customer beyond the term of its existing contract. 
    Second, many of the ``open access'' tariffs accepted prior to Order No. 
    888, while an improvement upon the status quo of no access, did not 
    contain the minimum terms and conditions of non-discriminatory service, 
    including functional unbundling. Order No. 888 required utilities that 
    tendered for filing open access tariffs prior to the issuance of the 
    Rule (Group 1 public utilities) to make section 206 compliance filings 
    that
    
    [[Page 12380]]
    
    contain the non-rate terms and conditions set forth in the Open Access 
    Rule pro forma tariff. That tariff expressly includes provisions 
    allowing a transmission provider to seek to recover stranded costs in 
    accordance with the terms, conditions and procedures set forth in Order 
    No. 888. Of the 101 public utilities that had some version of open 
    access available prior to Order No. 888, all now have open access 
    tariffs on file that contain provisions that expressly allow the 
    transmission provider to seek to recover stranded costs as provided in 
    Order No. 888.
        We also will decline San Francisco's request that the Commission 
    include ``exercise of pre-existing contract rights for transmission and 
    designation of wholesale loads'' or similar language as an example of a 
    situation for which stranded costs may not be sought.506 We are 
    not prepared to make individual factual determinations in the context 
    of this Rule.507 As specific requests for stranded cost recovery 
    are presented to the Commission, they will be addressed based on the 
    facts presented and the merits of the particular request.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \506\ In making this determination we do not decide whether such 
    situations demonstrate the presence or lack of a reasonable 
    expectation of continuing to serve a customer after the expiration 
    of an existing wholesale requirements contract (i.e., one that was 
    executed on or before July 11, 1994).
        \507\ San Francisco will have sufficient opportunity to raise 
    the argument in any PG&E stranded cost recovery case.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests Seeking Broader Stranded Cost Recovery
    
        In sharp contrast to the entities seeking rehearing of the 
    Commission's decision to allow stranded cost recovery, other entities 
    ask the Commission to expand the scope of the stranded cost recovery 
    allowed by Order No. 888. Various entities ask that the scope of 
    stranded cost recovery be expanded to include situations in which the 
    departing customer does not take unbundled transmission from the former 
    supplier and in which previously existing municipal utilities annex 
    additional territory or otherwise expand.508 These entities 
    disagree with the Commission's analysis in Order No. 888 that the 
    opportunity to seek recovery should be precluded in situations in which 
    the departing wholesale customer ceases to purchase power from the 
    utility but does not use the utility's transmission system to reach 
    another supplier. The Commission excluded these situations because the 
    costs would not be stranded as a result of the Commission's open access 
    transmission requirement, but rather as a result of the exercise of a 
    preexisting competitive option. The entities argue on rehearing that 
    such costs are attributable to the Commission's efforts to restructure 
    the wholesale power market. Several argue that there is no good policy 
    reason for addressing stranded costs only where linked directly to the 
    Open Access Rule or section 211 orders because a variety of federal 
    actions, not just the Open Access Rule and section 211 orders, have 
    created a competitive wholesale power market and the specter of 
    stranded costs caused by customers departing their traditional utility. 
    They contend that, but for the Commission's creation of a vibrant power 
    market, EPAct, and other pre-Order No. 888 efforts by the Commission to 
    expand transmission access, the preexisting options would not have been 
    (and historically were not) exercised.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \508\ E.g., EEI, Coalition for Economic Competition, Puget, 
    Centerior, Southern. The issue of expanding the rule to encompass 
    municipal annexations and expansions is discussed in greater detail 
    in section IV.J.6 below.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Puget argues that even when a departing customer can import its new 
    power supply without using its former supplier's transmission system, 
    it frequently will be the case that the power supply would not be 
    available to the customer if open access transmission rules were not in 
    place to permit that power to move from distant generators over 
    intervening utilities' transmission facilities.509
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \509\ Puget submits that the potential for customers not taking 
    unbundled transmission services from their former suppliers is 
    particularly acute in the Pacific Northwest due to BPA's ownership 
    of much of the region's transmission facilities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        EEI expresses concern that strict application of the ``but for open 
    access'' test would create new incentives to evade stranded cost 
    recovery.510 According to EEI, the Rule would deny recovery for 
    costs stranded pursuant to a voluntarily negotiated transmission 
    service agreement, but would permit recovery if such agreement were 
    ordered pursuant to FPA section 211. In this manner, EEI contends that 
    the Rule will discourage parties from settling transmission disputes. 
    It says that any transmission agreement negotiated under ``the threat'' 
    of section 211 should be entitled to stranded cost recovery if 
    providing service results in the stranding of legitimate and prudent 
    costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \510\ NIMO contends that the Commission erred by failing to 
    address the extent to which Order No. 888's exceptions to the 
    general policy of full stranded cost recovery (e.g., no recovery for 
    customer use of new transmission provider or municipal annexations) 
    create an opportunity for customers to avoid payment of part or all 
    of their share of utility stranded costs, will enable customers to 
    take advantage of such opportunities in ways that will reduce rather 
    than enhance overall economic efficiency, and will deprive utilities 
    of a reasonable opportunity to recover their prudently incurred 
    costs or will shift costs unfairly among customers. See also Puget.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        PSE&G and Carolina P&L express concern that denying stranded cost 
    recovery where the departing customer does not use the former 
    supplier's transmission system will create an artificial incentive to 
    build ``contract path'' lines designed to thwart stranded cost 
    recovery. They maintain that the existence of alternative transmission 
    paths should not be a bar to stranded cost recovery where the departing 
    customer avails itself of the Commission's Mobile-Sierra finding 
    permitting customers to challenge the terms of their contracts under 
    the just and reasonable standard. They assert that, notwithstanding the 
    availability of alternative transmission, the only way that the 
    customer could have availed itself of the Mobile-Sierra finding was as 
    a result of the Commission's Open Access Rule.
        Several entities contend that the FPA's requirement of just and 
    reasonable rates and the Fifth Amendment's requirement to avoid 
    confiscation require the Commission to address stranded costs that 
    result when a departing customer does not use the former supplier's 
    transmission system or that result from municipal annexation.511 
    According to Puget, the ultimate Constitutional test will be whether 
    Order No. 888 will afford a fair overall return on all prudent utility 
    investments under the Constitutional standards set forth by the Supreme 
    Court.512 Coalition for Economic Competition submits that, as was 
    the case in the context of the unbundling of natural gas pipelines, the 
    Commission cannot ignore stranded costs resulting from the unbundling 
    of electric services and should acknowledge its Constitutional 
    obligations to address the recovery of all stranded costs, including 
    those that result from municipal expansion and those that result when a
    
    [[Page 12381]]
    
    customer does not obtain transmission services from its former 
    supplier.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \511\ E.g., Puget, Coalition for Economic Competition, NIMO. 
    These parties make a similar argument in the case of stranded costs 
    that result from retail wheeling. See section IV.J.7 below.
        \512\ Puget cites in support Stone v. Farmers' Loan & Trust 
    Company, 116 U.S. 307, 331 (1886); Federal Power Commission v. Hope 
    Natural Gas Company, 320 U.S. 591, 602 (1944); and Duquesne Light 
    Company v. Barasch, 488 U.S 299, 307-08 (1989). Puget objects that 
    the stranded cost recovery mechanism in Order No. 888 is too narrow 
    and too easy to circumvent; it can be denied for failure to satisfy 
    the reasonable expectation test or based on a finding that costs are 
    not legitimate and verifiable. Puget argues that stranded cost 
    recovery is constitutionally required and that the recovery 
    mechanism must be amended to ensure full recovery of prudently 
    incurred stranded costs, including PURPA contract costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        SC Public Service Authority also asks the Commission to allow the 
    recovery of stranded costs that result from the loss of indirect 
    customers (e.g., customers of wholesale requirements customers). It 
    argues that if such indirect customers can get access to a new source 
    of power through open access tariffs, the requirements of the utility's 
    direct customer will decrease, and the supplying utility will suffer 
    stranded costs. SC Public Service Authority states that because of the 
    nexus between open access and the departure of the indirect customer, 
    utilities that suffer stranded costs in the event of the loss of an 
    indirect customer should have an opportunity to recover those costs 
    under the reasonable expectation standard.
        A number of entities also ask the Commission to find that open 
    access transmission and stranded cost recovery are necessary to 
    accomplish the remedy ordered by the Commission and thus are not 
    severable.513 To this end, they submit that if the Commission's 
    ability to provide for stranded cost recovery is reduced or 
    substantially modified, public utilities should be able to withdraw 
    filed tariffs or to file amended tariffs. It is their position that 
    deletion or substantial change of the open access or stranded cost 
    provisions by the Commission or by a court would vitiate the basis on 
    which the Commission premised the Rule.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \513\ E.g., EEI, Oklahoma G&E, Nuclear Energy Institute, 
    Southern. Southern requests that the Commission add a section 35.29 
    to the regulatory text providing: ``Sections 35.26 and 35.28 of this 
    part constitute unseverable portions of a unitary action of the 
    Commission.''
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In an effort to ensure that stranded cost recovery procedures do 
    not become a vehicle for lengthy and expensive litigation over whether 
    there is a sufficient nexus to open access, several entities ask the 
    Commission to place on the departing generation customers the burden to 
    demonstrate the absence of a nexus between their actions and the 
    availability of open access transmission under the Rule in those cases 
    where: (i) the contract has no term or termination provision; (ii) the 
    Commission issues an order under section 206 reducing the term of the 
    contract; or (iii) there is legitimate municipalization.514
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \514\ E.g., Carolina P&L, PSE&G.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We will deny the requests for rehearing that ask us to expand the 
    scope of stranded cost recovery to include situations in which the 
    departing customer does not take unbundled transmission from its former 
    supplier but instead obtains transmission from another utility or 
    obtains power from a third party supplier who is located in the 
    customer's service territory and thus requires no transmission from the 
    former supplier.515 As the Commission stated in Order No. 888, the 
    premise of the Rule is that where the former requirements supplier had 
    a reasonable expectation of serving beyond the contract term and the 
    customer uses the open access transmission tariff of its former 
    requirements supplier to obtain power from a new generation supplier, 
    the customer must pay the costs that were incurred on its behalf under 
    the prior regulatory regime. The Rule is not intended, however, to 
    apply to the recovery of costs associated with the normal risks of 
    competition, such as self-generation, cogeneration, or loss of load, 
    that do not arise from the new, accelerated availability of non-
    discriminatory open access transmission. If a customer leaves its 
    utility supplier by exercising options that could have been undertaken 
    prior to mandatory transmission under Order No. 888 or the Energy 
    Policy Act, or that do not rely on access to the former seller's 
    transmission (such as access to another power supplier through another 
    utility's transmission system or self-generation), there is no direct 
    nexus to Commission-mandated transmission access.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \515\ We discuss in Section IV.J.6 below our disposition of the 
    rehearing requests that support recovery of costs stranded as a 
    result of municipal annexation or expansion. In response to EEI's 
    argument that the Rule would deny recovery for costs stranded 
    pursuant to a voluntarily-negotiated transmission service agreement 
    and would discourage parties from settling transmission disputes, we 
    find EEI's arguments in support of its position to be vague and 
    cursory. However, we do not interpret the Rule in any way as 
    precluding parties from addressing stranded cost issues through 
    settlement, including settlement of a transmission dispute. To the 
    contrary, we fully expect that the renegotiation of contracts, 
    including transmission agreements, would provide parties with a 
    useful means for resolving stranded cost issues without litigation. 
    We believe that a negotiated rate that includes an amount for 
    stranded cost recovery could be found to be just and reasonable.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        For example, if a customer is able to obtain power from a new 
    supplier by using the transmission system of another utility, it is 
    likely that the customer could have made these arrangements in the 
    absence of the new open access rules. The new transmission provider 
    would have had little incentive to deny transmission services to the 
    customer in order to protect another utility's existing power supply 
    arrangement, since it was not the customer's power supplier in the 
    first place. As Order No. 888 suggested, it is likely that the 
    neighboring utility would have a positive incentive to provide the 
    transmission service in order to increase its transmission revenues, 
    and that this incentive is unchanged by open access 
    transmission.516
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \516\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,849-50; mimeo at 624-26.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Although EEI and others argue that EPAct and the Commission's pre-
    Order No. 888 efforts to expand transmission access have facilitated 
    the exercise of pre-existing competitive options, the fact remains that 
    such options historically were available before open access. For this 
    reason, we conclude that costs incurred as a result of the exercise of 
    pre-existing competitive options do not fall within the scope of Order 
    No. 888.
        A number of entities argue that, even where the departing customer 
    obtains access to another power supplier through the transmission 
    system of another utility (i.e., not that of its former supplier), the 
    power supply would not have been available to the customer if open 
    access transmission rules were not in place to permit that power to 
    move from distant generators over intervening utilities' transmission 
    facilities. Some argue that there is no good policy reason for 
    addressing stranded costs only where linked directly to the Open Access 
    Rule (or to a section 211 order) because a variety of federal actions 
    have created a competitive wholesale power market and the specter of 
    stranded costs caused by customers departing their traditional utility. 
    While these arguments may have superficial appeal, the effective result 
    would be to provide for recovery of stranded costs from departing 
    customers under the Rule no matter how tenuous the nexus to Commission-
    mandated transmission access. The Commission has to exercise reasonable 
    judgment and reasonable line drawing regarding the link between its 
    actions in this Rule and the decision to allow an opportunity for 
    extra-contractual stranded cost recovery from the departing customer. 
    The Commission believes that requiring a direct nexus between 
    Commission-mandated transmission access (namely, requiring that the 
    departing customer obtain access to another power supplier through the 
    use of its former supplier's Commission-required tariff--i.e., an open 
    access tariff or a tariff ordered pursuant to section 211) and the 
    special stranded cost recovery procedures of this Rule is the most 
    reasoned and supportable approach because it establishes a clear link 
    between availability of the transmission tariff
    
    [[Page 12382]]
    
    and the decision of the customer to seek an alternative supplier.
        With regard to potential stranded costs associated with situations 
    that could have occurred prior to the Open Access Rule and prior to the 
    Energy Policy Act (such as self-generation), under traditional 
    ratemaking such costs (albeit not previously labeled as potential 
    ``stranded'' costs) would in most cases be reallocated in the next rate 
    case to remaining customers. The fact that this Rule does not permit a 
    utility to seek recovery of these types of costs from the departing 
    customer does not mean that the Commission may not, in appropriate 
    circumstances, permit their recovery through traditional ratemaking 
    means. However, many factors will influence cost recovery in the 
    future, including whether the utility is selling at cost-based or 
    market-based rates and the transitional period to more competitive bulk 
    power markets. The Commission will address these matters on a case-by-
    case basis.
        We do not agree with those commenters who contend that the 
    Commission's failure in Order No. 888 to allow for the recovery of 
    costs incurred by a utility when a departing customer does not use the 
    former supplier's transmission system to reach a new supplier would be 
    confiscatory in violation of the Constitution. As the Supreme Court 
    explained in Duquesne, ``[t]he guiding principle has been that the 
    Constitution protects utilities from being limited to a charge for 
    their property serving the public which is so `unjust' as to be 
    confiscatory.''517 However, Order No. 888 addresses only the 
    recovery of legitimate, prudent and verifiable costs that are stranded 
    if a former wholesale requirements customer or a former retail customer 
    uses a Commission-mandated transmission tariff to reach a new supplier. 
    As discussed above, Order No. 888 does not by its terms bar the 
    recovery of costs that do not result from the use of Commission-
    required transmission access (i.e., costs that result when a departing 
    customer does not use the former supplying utility's open access 
    tariff). Utilities may, as before, seek recovery of such non-open 
    access-related costs on a case-by-case basis in individual rate 
    proceedings. The Commission will not prejudge those issues here. As a 
    result, the argument that the Commission's treatment of stranded costs 
    in Order No. 888 (i.e., its failure to treat certain costs as costs for 
    which recovery may be sought under the Rule) will result in rates that 
    will be so unjust as to be confiscatory is misplaced.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \517\ 488 U.S. at 307.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We deny SC Public Service Authority's request that the Commission 
    allow a utility to seek recovery of stranded costs that result from the 
    loss of indirect customers (i.e., the loss of the utility's customer's 
    customers). The Commission does not believe it is appropriate or 
    feasible to allow a public utility (or a transmitting utility under 
    section 211 of the FPA) to seek recovery of stranded costs from an 
    indirect customer (i.e., a customer of a wholesale requirements 
    customer of the utility). The reasonable expectation analysis would 
    apply only to the direct wholesale customer of the utility, not to the 
    indirect customer. A utility may seek to recover stranded costs from a 
    direct wholesale customer (subject to the requirements of the Rule), 
    but it is up to the direct wholesale customer, through its contracts 
    with its customers or through the appropriate regulatory authority, to 
    seek to recover stranded costs from its customers.
        We also deny PSE&G's and Carolina P&L's request that a utility be 
    allowed to seek stranded cost recovery in cases where the departing 
    customer uses the Commission's Mobile-Sierra finding to get out of the 
    contract under the just and reasonable standard and uses alternative 
    suppliers and alternative transmission.518 We disagree with their 
    argument that the only way that the customer could have availed itself 
    of a Mobile-Sierra finding was as a result of the Commission's open 
    access rules and thus the necessary nexus is met. A customer to a 
    Mobile-Sierra contract always has the option of instituting a 
    proceeding under section 206 of the FPA and making a showing of why, 
    under Mobile-Sierra, it is in the public interest to modify the 
    contract.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \518\ These parties appear to refer to a situation in which a 
    customer is able to modify or terminate its contract, but would use 
    the transmission system of a utility other than that of its former 
    supplier in order to reach a new generation supplier. In this 
    circumstance, the Rule would not permit the former supplier to seek 
    stranded costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We will not, at this time, make any determination whether or not 
    the requirements of open access transmission and stranded cost recovery 
    are severable. As we indicated in Order No. 888, we issued the Stranded 
    Cost Final Rule simultaneously with the Open Access Rule because we 
    believe that the recovery of legitimate, prudent and verifiable 
    stranded costs is critical to the successful transition of the electric 
    industry to a competitive, open access environment.519 We believe 
    that our decision to allow stranded cost recovery will be upheld by the 
    courts. Moreover, as we discuss in Section IV.A.1 above, it would be 
    premature to consider at this time what the Commission would do if one 
    or more of the provisions of the Rule are not upheld. Circumstances at 
    the time of any court order would dictate how we should proceed and we 
    would consider all such circumstances, and the entirety of our policy 
    decisions, before determining how to respond to a court decision.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \519\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,789-90; mimeo at 454-55.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Further, we decline to place on departing generation customers the 
    burden of demonstrating that no nexus exists between their actions and 
    the availability of open access transmission under the Rule in cases 
    involving no term or termination provision, an order under section 206 
    reducing the term of the contract, or municipalization. The proponents 
    of such a proposal, Carolina P&L and PSE&G, attempt to justify it as a 
    means to ensure that stranded cost recovery procedures do not become a 
    vehicle for lengthy and expensive litigation over whether there is a 
    sufficient nexus to open access in the three identified situations. 
    However, Order No. 888 places the burden on the utility seeking 
    stranded cost recovery to demonstrate that the costs for which it seeks 
    recovery fall within the scope of the Rule and that it had a reasonable 
    expectation of continuing service. In this regard, the Rule tracks the 
    requirement of sections 205 and 206 of the FPA that a public utility 
    demonstrate the justness and reasonableness of its proposed rates. 
    Carolina P&L and PSE&G fail to explain why it would be appropriate for 
    customers (as opposed to the utilities seeking recovery) in the three 
    identified situations to bear the initial burden of demonstrating why 
    costs should not be recovered from them under the Rule.520 As a 
    result, we reject their proposal.521
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \520\ In addition, the proposal would not eliminate lengthy 
    litigation. It would only change the burden of proof in whatever 
    litigation occurs.
        \521\ We note, however, that in a section 206 proceeding brought 
    by a customer seeking to shorten or terminate a contract, the 
    customer has the burden (as it would in any section 206 case that it 
    initiates) of presenting sufficient evidence that the contract is no 
    longer just and reasonable. As we stated in the Rule, the utility 
    must present any stranded cost claim at that time. See FERC Stats. & 
    Regs. at 31,664, 31,813; mimeo at 86-87, 521-22.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests--Stranded Cost Recovery By Transmitting Utilities 
    That Are Not Public Utilities
    
        A number of entities contend that the Commission's decision to 
    limit stranded cost recovery for transmitting utilities that are not 
    public utilities to section
    
    [[Page 12383]]
    
    211 proceedings is inconsistent with its decision to impose the 
    reciprocity requirement on those utilities, violative of the principle 
    of comparability, and unduly discriminatory and 
    anticompetitive.522 NRECA submits that if the Commission has the 
    statutory authority to require non-public utilities to render 
    transmission service outside of a section 211 proceeding through the 
    reciprocity, RTG and power pool provisions of the Rule, then it must 
    exercise that authority to ensure stranded cost recovery by such non-
    public utilities. Noting that the Rule does not address how a non-
    public utility that chooses voluntarily to provide an open access 
    tariff can recover its stranded costs, SC Public Service Authority asks 
    the Commission to confirm on rehearing that non-jurisdictional 
    utilities can include a provision for recovery of stranded costs in 
    their tariffs provided pursuant to the Final Rule.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \522\ E.g., NRECA, TDU Systems, Dairyland Coop.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Commission's jurisdiction over the recovery of stranded costs 
    by non-public utilities, and thus our ability to permit an opportunity 
    for recovery of such costs, is limited by statute. While we have the 
    statutory authority to ensure that non-public utilities have the 
    opportunity to seek recovery of stranded costs in proceedings under 
    sections 211 and 212 of the FPA,523 we do not have such authority 
    under sections 205 and 206 of the FPA. However, we clarify that nothing 
    in the Final Rule was intended to preclude non-public utilities from 
    including stranded cost provisions in voluntary reciprocity tariffs or 
    from otherwise recovering stranded costs under applicable law. We 
    discuss these matters in detail below.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \523\ Stranded costs could also conceivably arise as a result of 
    an ordered interconnection under section 210. However, the rates for 
    such an interconnection would be established pursuant to section 212 
    and could therefore also include stranded costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As we stated in Order No. 888 in response to commenters' objections 
    that the Rule would give public utilities a greater opportunity than 
    other transmitting utilities to recover stranded costs, our 
    jurisdiction over transmitting utilities that are not also public 
    utilities is limited. If the selling utility is a transmitting utility 
    that is not a public utility, its power sales contracts are not subject 
    to this Commission's jurisdiction under sections 205 and 206 of the 
    FPA. Thus, we can provide such a transmitting utility an opportunity to 
    recover stranded costs only through Commission-jurisdictional 
    transmission rates fixed under sections 211 and 212 of the FPA.524
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \524\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,791; mimeo at 458. If such a 
    transmitting utility seeks stranded cost recovery in a proceeding 
    under sections 211 and 212, it would, consistent with the provisions 
    of the Rule, be limited to recovery associated with requirements 
    contracts executed on or before July 11, 1994 that do not contain an 
    exit fee or other explicit stranded cost provision.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The open access tariff reciprocity provision, which applies to all 
    open access customers that own, operate, or control transmission 
    facilities or are affiliates of entities that own, operate or control 
    such facilities, and that do not obtain a waiver of the provision, does 
    not create jurisdiction for the Commission to fix the rates for these 
    utilities. Contrary to the suggestions of some, the tariff reciprocity 
    provision is not based on any statutory authority of the Commission to 
    require non-public utilities to render transmission service outside of 
    a section 211 proceeding. As we make clear in Order No. 888, we do not 
    have authority under sections 205 and 206 of the FPA to require non-
    public utilities to file tariffs (or rate schedules for that matter) 
    with the Commission.525 In permitting a public utility to deny 
    transmission service to any person that requests service under an open 
    access tariff unless that person provides reciprocal non-discriminatory 
    transmission services to the transmission provider, we are not acting 
    under any statutory authority to require non-public utilities to 
    provide transmission access. Rather, out of fairness, we are 
    conditioning the use of open access services by all customers, 
    including non-public utilities, on an agreement to offer comparable 
    transmission services in return to the public utility transmission 
    provider.526
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \525\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,691; mimeo at 162.
        \526\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,760-62; mimeo at 370-74.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We clarify that a non-public utility that chooses voluntarily to 
    offer an open access tariff for purposes of demonstrating that it meets 
    the reciprocity provision can include a stranded cost provision in its 
    tariff. However, adjudication of any stranded cost claims under that 
    tariff is not subject to the Commission's jurisdiction.527 With 
    the exception of our section 210 interconnection and sections 211-212 
    transmission rate jurisdiction, we do not have jurisdiction over the 
    rates of non-public utilities. If a non-public utility wishes to 
    recover stranded costs pursuant to a tariff or otherwise, it can seek 
    to do so subject to the review of the appropriate regulatory 
    authority.528
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \527\ Although the Commission would not determine the rate, 
    including the stranded cost component of the rate, of a non-public 
    utility, we would review a public utility's claim that it is 
    entitled to deny service to a non-public utility because the 
    stranded cost component of the non-public utility's transmission 
    rate is being applied in a way that violates the principle of 
    comparability.
        \528\ We note that in the case of stranded cost claims presented 
    to the Commission by BPA or one of the other PMAs, our review would 
    be limited to that set forth in the applicable statutes and any 
    relevant delegation of authority from the Secretary of Energy. See, 
    e.g., Pacific Northwest Electric Power Planning and Conservation 
    Act, 16 U.S.C. Sec. 839-839h (1985) (Northwest Power Act); 
    Department of Energy Delegation Order No. 0204-108, as amended, 48 
    FR 55,664 (1983), amended, 51 FR 19,744 (1986), amended, 56 FR 
    41,835 (1991), amended, 58 FR 59,716 (1993) (delegation order 
    relating to Western Area Power Administration).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests--Stranded Cost Recovery for Transmission Dependent 
    Utilities
    
        NRECA and TDU Systems challenge the Commission's decision not to 
    guarantee a transmission dependent utility that is not a public utility 
    stranded cost recovery when the transmission dependent utility's 
    customers leave its system by using the open access tariff of another 
    utility. They submit that the ability of transmission dependent 
    utilities to compete with public utility transmission providers in an 
    open access environment would be severely affected by their inability 
    to recover stranded costs on a basis comparable to those transmission 
    providers. They argue that the open access provisions of Order No. 888 
    will result in the stranding of costs incurred by non-transmission 
    owning, non-public utilities to serve customers that depart to other 
    suppliers. They contend that these customers are already located in 
    close proximity to, and interconnected to, public utilities; thus it is 
    likely that they would use the open access tariffs of these public 
    utilities to obtain their new power supplies. NRECA and TDU Systems 
    argue that this situation should meet the ``but for open access'' 
    nexus. On this basis, they assert that Order No. 888 is no less the 
    proximate cause of the departure of customers of transmission dependent 
    utilities than it is of the departure of public utility transmission 
    owners' customers. They object that the Commission takes no account of 
    the anticompetitive effects of disregarding costs stranded on 
    transmission dependent utilities' systems as a result of open access.
        Dairyland Coop asks the Commission to recognize a generation and 
    transmission (G&T) cooperative and its member distribution cooperatives 
    as a single economic unit for purposes of stranded cost recovery (such 
    that conversion of a distribution
    
    [[Page 12384]]
    
    cooperative's retail customer to a wholesale customer may result in 
    stranded costs for the G&T cooperative). It objects that the Commission 
    implicitly rejected comments to this effect without discussion in Order 
    No. 888.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We deny the requests for rehearing of our decision not to permit 
    transmission dependent utilities and electric cooperatives to seek 
    stranded cost recovery unless they are public utilities or transmitting 
    utilities that would otherwise qualify under the Rule. With regard to 
    transmission dependent utilities, as we indicated in Order No. 888, the 
    limited opportunity for stranded cost recovery contained in the Rule 
    would not likely apply in the case of transmission dependent utilities, 
    who own little or no transmission and the majority of whom would not be 
    public utilities or transmitting utilities subject to the Commission's 
    jurisdiction.529 The opportunity for extra-contractual wholesale 
    stranded cost recovery is allowed only where the departing customers 
    use open access (or section 211 access) on the transmission systems of 
    their former generation suppliers and only for a discrete set of 
    requirements contracts executed on or before July 11, 1994 that do not 
    contain explicit stranded cost provisions (involving the bundled 
    provision of generation and transmission) and retail-turned-wholesale 
    situations for which the utility can demonstrate that it had a 
    reasonable expectation of continuing service. Even though it may be the 
    case that transmission dependent utilities lose generation customers 
    that are able to use open access tariffs of other utilities to reach 
    new suppliers, there was nothing to keep these other utilities from 
    offering such transmission service before Order No. 888. These other 
    utilities had no economic incentive to deny such service before Order 
    No. 888. Thus, in the scenario posited in the rehearings, the 
    transmission dependent utilities do not meet the fundamental premise of 
    the Rule: that a utility that historically has supplied bundled 
    generation and transmission services to a wholesale requirements 
    customer and incurred costs to meet reasonably expected customer demand 
    should have an opportunity to recover legitimate, prudent and 
    verifiable costs that may be stranded because open access use of the 
    utility's transmission system enables a generation customer to shop for 
    power.530
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \529\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,790; mimeo at 456-57.
        \530\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,790; mimeo at 456-57.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        However, this is not to say that a transmission dependent utility 
    that is not a public utility, or other non-public utility entities 
    (such as RUS-financed cooperatives), cannot seek recovery of the cost 
    of any resulting uneconomic assets through their contracts with their 
    customers or through the appropriate regulatory authority. The 
    Commission has no objection to these entities being able to seek such 
    cost recovery through the appropriate regulatory channels. However, 
    because the Commission does not have jurisdiction over these entities 
    (other than through sections 211 and 212 in the case of non-public 
    utility transmitting utilities), it does not have authority to allow 
    them to recover these costs.531
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \531\ Unless these entities own some transmission used in 
    interstate commerce or are engaged in sales for resale, and are not 
    otherwise exempt under FPA section 201(f), they would not be public 
    utilities under sections 205 and 206. Most transmission dependent 
    utilities are not public utilities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We also deny Dairyland Coop's request that the Commission recognize 
    a G&T cooperative and its member distribution cooperatives as a single 
    economic unit for purposes of stranded cost recovery. If a cooperative 
    obtains its financing through RUS, it is not a public utility subject 
    to our jurisdiction under sections 205 and 206 of the FPA. Although the 
    Commission has no objection to these G&T cooperatives being able to 
    seek cost recovery (including recovery of costs on behalf of their 
    distribution cooperatives) through the appropriate regulatory channels, 
    this Commission does not have authority to allow them to seek recovery 
    of stranded costs unless access is obtained through a section 211 
    order.532
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \532\ A G&T cooperative that is a transmitting utility could 
    seek recovery of stranded costs if it is ordered to provide 
    transmission services that permit its distribution cooperative to 
    reach another supplier and if it had a requirements contract with 
    the distribution cooperative that was executed on or before July 11, 
    1994.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In the case of a G&T cooperative that is a public utility (of which 
    there are just a handful at the present time), such a cooperative would 
    have to have a jurisdictional wholesale requirements contract with its 
    distribution cooperative in order to be able to seek recovery of 
    stranded costs under the Rule. In the case of a jurisdictional G&T 
    cooperative, the request that the G&T be treated as a single economic 
    unit with the distribution cooperative (such that departure of a 
    distribution cooperative's retail customer would be treated as 
    resulting in stranded costs for the G&T cooperative for which the G&T 
    could seek recovery) is, in effect, a request for recovery of stranded 
    costs from an indirect customer. As we discuss above, the Commission 
    does not believe it is appropriate or feasible to allow a public 
    utility (or a transmitting utility under section 211 of the FPA) to 
    seek recovery of stranded costs from an indirect customer (i.e., a 
    customer of a wholesale requirements customer of the utility) under 
    this Rule. The reasonable expectation analysis would apply only to the 
    direct wholesale customer of the utility, not to the indirect customer. 
    It is up to the direct wholesale customer of the utility, through its 
    contracts with its customers or through the appropriate regulatory 
    authority, to seek to recover such costs from its customers.
        Commenters have provided no basis for making an exception in the 
    case of cooperatives. Moreover, to treat a G&T cooperative and its 
    member distribution cooperatives as a single economic unit for stranded 
    cost purposes would be inconsistent with the Commission's decision not 
    to treat cooperatives as a single unit for purposes of Order No. 888's 
    reciprocity provision.
        In Order No. 888, in response to arguments raised by cooperatives, 
    the Commission agreed to limit the reciprocity requirement to corporate 
    affiliates. In other words, if a G&T cooperative seeks open access 
    transmission service from the transmission provider, only the G&T 
    cooperative (not its member distribution cooperatives) would be 
    required to offer transmission service. If a member distribution 
    cooperative itself receives transmission service from the transmission 
    provider, then it (but not its G&T cooperative) must offer reciprocal 
    transmission service over its interstate transmission facilities, if 
    any.533 Dairyland has provided no basis to support treating 
    cooperatives differently for stranded cost purposes and reciprocity 
    purposes. We accordingly will deny Dairyland's request for rehearing on 
    this issue.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \533\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,763; mimeo at 377-78.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests Opposing Limitation of Recovery to Wholesale 
    Requirements Customers
    
        PA Munis argues that it is inequitable and anticompetitive for 
    ``wholesale requirements customers'' but not other ``wholesale 
    customers'' to have to pay stranded costs, repeating an argument that 
    it made in its comments on the supplemental stranded cost NOPR. It says 
    that there is no difference in the firm power provided by public 
    utilities
    
    [[Page 12385]]
    
    to ``wholesale requirements customers'' and to ``wholesale customers'' 
    and no difference in the generating facilities required and the costs 
    of operation between the production of firm capacity and energy 
    required for ``wholesale requirements sales'' and ``wholesale sales.'' 
    PA Munis submits that the total amount of wholesale requirements power 
    purchased in the United States is less than two percent of the total 
    amount of firm power sales. It argues that requiring only wholesale 
    requirements customers to pay stranded costs would restrict the ability 
    of such customers to switch suppliers while not similarly restricting 
    large firm wholesale customers. It contends that wholesale firm 
    requirements customers therefore will not have equal access under the 
    Rule because of the increased transmission rates for stranded costs 
    that would not be levied on other large wholesale firm customers. Pa 
    Munis says this produces the same result found unlawful in the Maryland 
    People's Counsel case 534--equal access to all wholesale customers 
    is virtually denied by the chilling effect of stranded costs borne only 
    by wholesale requirements customers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \534\ Maryland People's Counsel v. FERC, 761 F.2d 780 (D.C. Cir. 
    1985) (Maryland People's Counsel I). See also Maryland People's 
    Counsel v. FERC, 761 F.2d 768 (D.C. Cir. 1985) (Maryland People's 
    Counsel II).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        In Order No. 888, the Commission fully addressed the concerns of PA 
    Munis. We again address below the major distinctions between 
    requirements and other customers and deny rehearing.
        In Order No. 888, we explained that the historical and practical 
    relationship between a utility and its wholesale requirements 
    customers, including the expectation of continued service, justifies 
    allowing public utilities the opportunity to seek to recover the 
    stranded costs covered by this Rule from only those customers and not 
    from non-requirements customers that contract separately for 
    transmission services to deliver their purchased power or from 
    wholesale customers that purchase non-requirements power. Requirements 
    customers historically were long-term customers who by definition 
    depended upon their local suppliers because they were captive 
    customers. Utilities had no obligation to provide transmission service 
    that would allow these customers to reach other suppliers, and there 
    were no other transmission facilities in proximity to those of the 
    supplying utility. And the service involved requirements power; that 
    is, these customers were dependent upon the wholesale supplier for all 
    or part of their power. Utilities thus assumed they would continue 
    serving these customers and may have made significant investments based 
    on that long-term expectation. These same assumptions cannot be made 
    for short-term, non-firm transactions and other wholesale non-
    requirements firm transactions. Unlike requirements customers, these 
    customers had other options. Thus, the supplying utility could not 
    assume that these customers would remain on its system.
        With regard to short-term transactions, utilities did not (and do 
    not today) generally make investments for short-term economy-type 
    transactions. Rather, such transactions were entered into only when the 
    utility temporarily had available capacity or energy that could be 
    provided to the buyer at a price higher than the seller's incremental 
    cost and lower than the buyer's decremental cost. The utility was not 
    obligated in any way--either explicitly or implicitly--to provide for 
    the needs of coordination customers. Because coordination transactions 
    were not the cause of stranded investment decisions, it would be 
    inappropriate to allocate such costs to non-requirements 
    customers.535
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \535\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,790-91; mimeo at 457-58.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        With regard to long-term, non-requirements firm transactions, such 
    as unit power sales contracts, we note that there was no implied 
    obligation to serve customers to these transactions as there was for 
    requirements customers. Generating units were not built for the purpose 
    of entering into these arrangements. Therefore, because utilities did 
    not incur costs on behalf of non-requirements firm power sales 
    customers, such customers have not caused costs to be stranded and 
    should not be required to pay stranded cost charges. Accordingly, we 
    reaffirm limiting the opportunity for stranded cost recovery to costs 
    associated with wholesale requirements contracts.536
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \536\ We clarify, however, that a contract may meet our 
    definition of wholesale requirements contract even though it does 
    not carry the label ``requirements contract.'' The definition refers 
    to a contract that provides any portion of a customer's bundled 
    wholesale power requirements. As discussed above, whether or not a 
    contract meets this definition hinges upon whether the customer 
    depended upon the wholesale supplier for all or part of its power 
    because it could not obtain transmission access to reach other 
    suppliers, i.e., it was captive to the historical local supplier.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We recognize PA Munis' concern that if a utility meets the 
    evidentiary requirements of the Rule and is allowed to recover stranded 
    costs from wholesale requirements customers, such customers may see 
    little or no savings in the short-term by switching power suppliers, 
    since a stranded cost charge (in the form of either an exit fee or a 
    surcharge on transmission) would be paid in addition to the power price 
    paid a new supplier. However, as we discuss above and in Section IV.J.2 
    below, we believe that stranded costs are transition costs that must be 
    addressed at an early stage if we are to fulfill our regulatory 
    responsibilities in moving to competitive markets. Further, as we 
    explain in Section IV.J.3 below, although spreading the costs to all 
    transmission users of a utility's system (rather than imposing them 
    directly on the departing wholesale requirements customer) might enable 
    the customer to see earlier power cost savings than would result if 
    stranded costs were directly assigned to the customer, we have 
    concluded that this potential benefit to a broad-based approach is 
    outweighed by a significant countervailing disadvantage--namely, the 
    violation of the cost-causation principle of ratemaking. The Commission 
    rejects a broad-based approach for the electric industry primarily 
    because the potential power cost savings to the departing generation 
    customer would be realized only by shifting costs that are directly 
    attributable to the departing generation customer to the other users of 
    the utility's transmission system.
        Contrary to PA Munis's claim, we believe that the circumstances 
    surrounding the opportunity to seek stranded cost recovery from 
    wholesale requirements customers that is permitted in Order No. 888 are 
    distinguishable from the issues that were before the court in the 
    Maryland People's Counsel cases. Those cases involved challenges to 
    Commission orders that permitted pipelines to transport gas at lowered 
    prices to ``non-captive consumers'' (large industrial end users capable 
    of switching to alternative fuels) without any obligation to provide 
    the same service to ``captive consumers'' such as local distribution 
    companies and their residential customers. In Maryland People's Counsel 
    I, the court invalidated the Commission's authorization of a ``special 
    marketing program'' under which a pipeline and its producer would agree 
    to amend their high-priced gas purchase contract to permit the producer 
    to sell the committed gas elsewhere at market prices and to credit the 
    volume of such sales against the pipeline's high-priced purchase 
    obligations. Eligibility to purchase the
    
    [[Page 12386]]
    
    cheaper released gas was limited to industrial users. The court found 
    that the Commission had failed to provide a reasonable basis for its 
    decision to exclude ``captive customers'' from eligibility to purchase 
    the cheaper released gas.537 In Maryland People's Counsel II, the 
    court invalidated the Commission's approval of blanket authority for 
    interstate transportation of natural gas sold directly by producers to 
    fuel-switchable end users. The court held that the Commission had 
    failed to consider the anticompetitive effects of failing to require 
    the pipelines to provide the same service to captive consumers on 
    nondiscriminatory terms.538
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \537\ See 761 F.2d 768.
        \538\ See 761 F.2d at 781-82.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In contrast to the Maryland People's Counsel cases, the Commission 
    in Order No. 888 is not discounting services for one class of customers 
    to the exclusion of another, nor is it ordering that public utilities 
    provide transmission access to only a specified customer group. To the 
    contrary, Order No. 888 requires all public utilities that own, control 
    or operate facilities used for transmitting electric energy in 
    interstate commerce to provide open access transmission to any 
    ``eligible customer,'' with ``eligible customer'' defined broadly to 
    include ``any electric utility (including the Transmission Provider and 
    any power marketer), Federal power marketing agency, or any person 
    generating electric energy for sale for resale.'' 539 Among other 
    things, Order No. 888 gives wholesale requirements customers that 
    previously were captive customers of their public utility suppliers the 
    opportunity at the expiration of their contracts to take unbundled 
    transmission service from their former suppliers in order to reach new 
    suppliers. At the same time, the Commission recognizes that the 
    departure of a wholesale requirements customer in this circumstance may 
    strand costs that the former supplying utility incurred based on a 
    reasonable expectation that it would continue to serve the customer 
    beyond the contract term. As a result, Order No. 888 gives the former 
    supplying utility the opportunity to seek recovery of costs stranded by 
    the wholesale requirements customer's departure.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \539\ Pro Forma Open Access Transmission Tariff, section 1.11.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In further contrast to the Maryland People's Counsel cases, the 
    Commission addresses in this Order (above) PA Munis' claim that it is 
    inequitable and anticompetitive that only wholesale requirements 
    customers and not other wholesale customers are subject to the stranded 
    cost provisions of Order No. 888. The Commission has explained in 
    detail the rationale for its decision that public utilities should be 
    allowed an opportunity to seek to recover the stranded costs covered by 
    this Rule only from wholesale requirements customers. The Commission 
    has also addressed in Section IV.J.2 below the concerns expressed by 
    some as to the potential anticompetitive effect of stranded cost 
    charges.
    
    Rehearing Request--ERCOT
    
        The TX Com 540 asks the Commission to clarify that ERCOT 
    utilities may not use a section 211 proceeding as a vehicle to obtain 
    wholesale or retail stranded cost recovery. 541 It notes that 
    based on the definitions in section 35.26 of ``wholesale stranded 
    cost'' 542 and ``wholesale transmission service,'' 543 the 
    Rule applies only to interstate service and does not apply to the 
    intrastate service provided by the utilities within ERCOT, yet the 
    Commission suggests that it might permit a utility in ERCOT to recover 
    stranded costs in a section 211 proceeding. Even if the Commission 
    concludes that it has the authority to resolve stranded cost issues for 
    ERCOT utilities, TX Com asks the Commission to establish a preference 
    for resolution of transmission and stranded cost issues in ERCOT by TX 
    Com. It suggests that uncertainty and gaming as to the choice of a 
    forum could be avoided by executing a Memorandum of Understanding 
    between TX Com and the Commission that would require interested persons 
    to submit disputes to TX Com. Further, to the extent that the new ERCOT 
    transmission access rules adopted by the TX Com may be deemed as the 
    cause of stranded costs in ERCOT, TX Com asserts that it should be 
    allowed to resolve issues related to such stranded costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \540\ TX Com's request for rehearing was filed out-of-time on 
    May 29, 1996 with a request that the Commission accept the rehearing 
    request for filing as of May 24, 1996. TX Com explains it had made 
    arrangements with a courier company to pick up its rehearing request 
    on May 23, 1996 and deliver and file the rehearing request with the 
    Commission before 5 p.m. on May 24, 1996. TX Com states that the 
    courier company failed to pick up the rehearing request on May 23 as 
    previously arranged. TX Com says that when it became aware on May 24 
    that its rehearing request was not enroute to the Commission, it 
    faxed a copy of the rehearing request to a copier and delivery 
    service in Washington, D.C. The pleading, which was not signed, was 
    delivered to the Commission prior to 5 p.m. on May 24. TX Com states 
    that Commission personnel rejected the filing apparently because it 
    was not signed. TX Com asks that the Commission find good cause 
    under Rule 2001 of the Commission's Rules of Practice and 
    Procedures, 18 CFR 385.2001 (1996), to accept its rehearing request 
    for filing as of May 24, 1996. Under the circumstances, we will 
    accept the rehearing request for filing as of May 24, 1996.
        \541\ Texas Utilities Electric Company filed on June 21, 1996 a 
    motion for leave to file and response to TX Com's rehearing request. 
    Texas Utilities opposes TX Com's positions on rehearing. While 
    answers to requests for rehearing generally are not permitted, 18 
    CFR 385.213(a)(2) (1996), we will depart from our general rule 
    because of the significant nature of this proceeding and will accept 
    Texas Utilities' response.
        \542\ ``Wholesale stranded cost'' is defined as ``any 
    legitimate, prudent and verifiable cost incurred by a public utility 
    or a transmitting utility to provide service to: (1) a wholesale 
    requirements customer that subsequently becomes, in whole or in 
    part, an unbundled wholesale transmission services customer of such 
    public utility or transmitting utility; or (ii) a retail customer, 
    or a newly created wholesale power sales customer, that subsequently 
    becomes, in whole or in part, an unbundled wholesale transmission 
    services customer of such public utility or transmitting utility.'' 
    Order No. 888, mimeo at 768.
        \543\ ``Wholesale transmission services'' is defined as 
    ``ha[ving] the same meaning as provided in section 3(24) of the 
    Federal Power Act (FPA): the transmission of electric energy sold, 
    or to be sold, at wholesale in interstate commerce.'' Order No. 888, 
    mimeo at 768.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        In City of College Station, Texas,544 the Commission repeated 
    its view, first articulated in 1979, that sections 211 and 212 of the 
    FPA clearly give the Commission jurisdiction to order transmission 
    services within ERCOT, subject to the special rate provision for ERCOT 
    utilities in section 212(k).545 The Commission indicated that if 
    it issues a final order in that case setting rates for transmission 
    services within ERCOT, it will comply with section 212(k) and give 
    deference to the TX Com's ratemaking methodology insofar as practicable 
    and consistent with section 212(a).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \544\ 76 FERC para. 61,138 (1996).
        \545\ Section 212(k), added by EPAct, provides as follows: (1) 
    RATES.--Any order under section 211 requiring provision of 
    transmission services in whole or in part within ERCOT shall provide 
    that any ERCOT utility which is not a public utility and the 
    transmission facilities of which are actually used for such 
    transmission service is entitled to receive compensation based, 
    insofar as practicable and consistent with subsection (a), on the 
    transmission ratemaking methodology of the Public Utility Commission 
    of Texas. 16 U.S.C. Sec. 824k(k) (1994).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Our jurisdiction to order transmission services within ERCOT 
    includes the authority to address costs that are stranded by a section 
    211 transmission order.546 Consistent with the special rate 
    provision in section 212(k), we clarify
    
    [[Page 12387]]
    
    that we will give deference to the TX Com's ratemaking methodology, 
    including any provisions or procedures related to stranded cost 
    recovery, insofar as it is practicable and consistent with section 
    212(a) and consistent with the principle of comparability set out in 
    Order No. 888.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \546\ To clarify that the Order No. 888 stranded cost provisions 
    apply to the intrastate utilities within ERCOT, solely in the 
    context of a section 211 proceeding, we will revise the definition 
    of ``wholesale transmission services'' in section 35.26(b)(3) to 
    read: ``Wholesale transmission services means the transmission of 
    electric energy sold, or to be sold, at wholesale in interstate 
    commerce or ordered pursuant to section 211 of the Federal Power Act 
    (FPA).''
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    2. Cajun Electric Power Cooperative, Inc. v. FERC 547
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \547\ 28 F.3d 173 (D.C. Cir. 1994) (Cajun).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In Order No. 888, the Commission explained why it does not 
    interpret the Cajun court decision as barring the recovery of stranded 
    costs and why the record developed in this generic proceeding fully 
    addresses the court's concerns regarding meaningful access to 
    alternative suppliers.548
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \548\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,793-95; mimeo at 464-70.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We also addressed the court's concern that the method of recovery 
    in that case (a charge in the departing customer's transmission rate) 
    might constitute an anticompetitive tying arrangement. We explained 
    that the stranded cost recovery procedure we prescribe in the Open 
    Access Rule is only a transitional mechanism that is intended to enable 
    utilities to recover costs prudently incurred under a different 
    regulatory regime. The purpose and effect of the stranded cost recovery 
    mechanism that we approved in the Rule is to facilitate the transition 
    to competitive wholesale power markets. We concluded that while 
    stranded cost recovery may temporarily delay some of the benefits of 
    competitive bulk power markets for some customers, such transition 
    costs must be addressed at an early stage if we are to fulfill our 
    regulatory responsibilities in moving to competitive markets.
        In reaching these conclusions, the Commission applied the 
    traditional regulatory concept of cost causation. We stated that it is 
    not an illegal tying arrangement to hold a customer accountable for the 
    cost consequence of leaving an incumbent supplier if, under our rules, 
    the incumbent supplier must show a reasonable expectation of providing 
    continuing service to that customer before it can recover stranded 
    costs from the customer.
        In addition, in response to the Cajun court and commenters in this 
    proceeding as to the need to provide as much certainty as possible for 
    departing customers concerning their potential stranded cost 
    obligation, the Commission included a formula for calculating a 
    departing customer's potential stranded cost obligation. We explained 
    that the revenues lost formula is designed to provide certainty for 
    departing customers and to create incentives for the parties to address 
    stranded cost claims between themselves without resort to litigation.
    
    Rehearing Requests Arguing That the Commission Has Not Resolved the 
    Cajun Court's Concerns
    
        Several entities submit that the Commission has not resolved the 
    Cajun court's tying concerns. They argue that tying arrangements are 
    still the essence of the stranded cost recovery method mandated by 
    Order No. 888, and that a tying arrangement is a per se antitrust 
    violation that is not subject to justification by reference to the 
    reasons for the restraint or the expected ancillary benefits.549 A 
    number of these entities object that the Commission does not address 
    the court's substantive concern that a stranded cost provision is the 
    antithesis of competition.550 Several object that the Commission 
    brushes aside the acknowledged anticompetitive effects of the rule as 
    being ``transitional only,'' suggesting that short-term anticompetitive 
    impacts are acceptable as long as the Commission is doing something 
    that will be good for customers in the long term.551 They also 
    contend that the anticompetitive effects would not be limited to a 
    transitional period, or that the transitional period could last 
    indefinitely, thereby diluting or even nullifying the benefits of 
    competition for years to come.552
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \549\ See, e.g., ELCON, Suffolk County, Central Illinois Light, 
    American Forest & Paper, TDU Systems, Blue Ridge, Nucor, IN Consumer 
    Counselor, IN Consumers, APPA, PA Munis, VT DPS, Valero.
        \550\ E.g., Central Illinois Light, American Forest & Paper.
        \551\ E.g., American Forest & Paper, PA Munis.
        \552\ E.g., American Forest & Paper, Occidental Chemical, PA 
    Munis.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several entities submit that the Commission erred in concluding 
    that the stranded cost rules contained in Order No. 888 would allow 
    customers ``meaningful'' access to alternative power suppliers.553 
    Among other things, these entities contend that there is no showing in 
    the Order that transmission providers will not continue to exercise 
    monopoly power over their transmission systems and that competition in 
    generation will not be stifled by the stranded cost recovery mechanism.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \553\ E.g., Arkansas Cities, IN Consumer Counselor, IN 
    Consumers, Occidental Chemical, PA Munis.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Some entities also object that the stranded cost procedures 
    contained in Order No. 888 fail to provide certainty in the computation 
    of recoverable stranded costs. They argue that the prospect of stranded 
    cost liability and related litigation add costs of potential deal-
    killing magnitude to any power supply acquisition considered by a 
    customer.554
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \554\ E.g., APPA, Arkansas Cities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        APPA and ELCON challenge the Commission's description of Western 
    Resources, Inc. v. FERC 555 as affirming the Commission's ability 
    to allow stranded cost recovery. APPA argues that Western Resources 
    does not justify the stranded cost provisions of Order No. 888 because 
    it was a filed rate doctrine case, not a stranded cost case. APPA says 
    that Western Resources involved no consideration of any allegation of 
    anticompetitive conduct and no allegation that the utilities' proposal 
    constituted an illegal tying arrangement.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \555\ 72 F.3d 147 (D.C. Cir. 1995) (Western Resources).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We will deny the requests for rehearing advanced on the basis of 
    the Cajun case. We disagree with those entities that contend that the 
    Commission has not resolved the Cajun court's tying concerns. As an 
    initial matter, we note that the parties that have raised this issue on 
    rehearing ignore the fact that while this Commission has a 
    responsibility to consider the anticompetitive effects of regulated 
    aspects of interstate utility operations,556 it has other 
    statutory and regulatory public interest considerations which it must 
    balance in order to engage in reasoned decisionmaking. In this 
    proceeding, we have carefully balanced our responsibilities to remedy 
    undue discrimination and to consider anticompetitive effects, our goal 
    to eliminate market power of utilities and anticompetitive effects in 
    the long run, and the need to provide a transition to competitive 
    markets that is fair, that maintains a stable electric utility 
    industry, and that recognizes the obligations incurred in a past, non-
    competitive regulatory regime. As discussed below, we do not believe 
    that the stranded cost proposal adopted in the Rule results in an 
    illegal tying arrangement, as argued on rehearing. We believe we have 
    given reasoned consideration to any potential transitory
    
    [[Page 12388]]
    
    anticompetitive effects of our stranded cost policy and that we have 
    met the directives of the court in Cajun.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \556\ The Commission's power under the FPA carries with it the 
    responsibility to consider, in appropriate circumstances, the 
    anticompetitive effects of regulated aspects of interstate 
    operations pursuant to sections 202 and 203, and under like 
    directives contained in sections 205, 206, and 207. Gulf States 
    Utilities Company v. FPC, 411 U.S. 747 (1973). While the Commission 
    lacks principal responsibility for implementing antitrust policy, it 
    retains an obligation to give reasoned consideration to the bearing 
    of antitrust policy on matters within its jurisdiction. Alabama 
    Power Company, et al. v. FPC, 511 F.2d 383 (D.C. Cir. 1974).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In considering the Cajun decision, it is important to note that the 
    Cajun court assumes the presence of a competitive market in the 
    electric utility industry, but such a competitive market does not now 
    exist. Instead, the Commission is in the process of trying to bring 
    about a competitive market and to manage the transition 
    thereto.557 When the Commission undertook a similar restructuring 
    in the gas industry, the D.C. Circuit invalidated the Commission's 
    efforts precisely because the Commission had failed to deal with the 
    stranded cost problem in a satisfactory manner.558
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \557\ In contrast to the situation in Order No. 888, the Cajun 
    court did not have before it a generic, Commission-imposed recovery 
    mechanism for distinguishing stranded costs associated with the 
    Commission's ordering of industry-wide open access from all 
    uneconomic costs.
        \558\ See AGD, 824 F.2d at 1021.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As we indicated in Order No. 888, we do not believe it is an 
    illegal tying arrangement to hold a customer accountable for the 
    consequences of leaving an incumbent supplier if, before the incumbent 
    supplier can recover legitimate, prudent and verifiable stranded costs 
    from the departing customer, it must show that it incurred costs to 
    provide service to the customer based on a reasonable expectation of 
    continuing to serve the customer. Order No. 888 provides no guarantee 
    of stranded cost recovery. Moreover, Order No. 888 provides the 
    opportunity to recover stranded costs only for a discrete set of 
    wholesale requirements contracts--those executed on or before July 11, 
    1994 that do not contain an exit fee or other explicit stranded cost 
    provision--and for retail-turned-wholesale customers. Thus, it is not 
    necessarily the case that customers will have to pay stranded costs 
    when they leave their current suppliers. To the contrary, before a 
    utility can recover stranded costs from a customer, the utility must 
    overcome certain evidentiary hurdles (including a rebuttable 
    presumption of no reasonable expectation of continuing service if the 
    contract contains a notice of termination provision). Particularly 
    given the narrowly tailored circumstances under which stranded cost 
    recovery is permissible under the Rule, we do not view it as the 
    antithesis of competition.
        We dismiss as misplaced the claims that Order No. 888's stranded 
    cost recovery mechanism is a tying arrangement that is a per se 
    antitrust violation that cannot be justified by reference to the 
    reasons for the restraint or the expected ancillary benefits. Any 
    ``tying'' that might result from the Rule is by regulatory order, not 
    through monopoly power, and is justified as a means to avoid unfair 
    cost shifting and to achieve the pro-competitive benefits of the Rule. 
    As we stated in Order No. 888, the purpose and effect of the stranded 
    cost recovery mechanism that we approve are to facilitate the 
    transition to competitive wholesale power markets, not to prevent a 
    generation customer of a utility from being able to reach alternative 
    suppliers through its former supplier's transmission.559
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \559\ Cf. Eastman Kodak Company v. Image Technical Services, 
    Inc., 504 U.S. at 486-87 (Scalia, J. dissenting) (``Per se rules of 
    antitrust illegality are reserved for those situations where logic 
    and experience show that the risk of injury to competition from the 
    defendant's behavior is so pronounced that it is needless and 
    wasteful to conduct the usual judicial inquiry into the balance 
    between the behavior's procompetitive benefits and its 
    anticompetitive costs.'').
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        To be sure, imposing a stranded cost charge might, in the short 
    run, make some customers indifferent to whether they stay with their 
    current suppliers and avoid stranded costs, or go with new suppliers 
    but pay stranded costs to the former suppliers.560 There is no 
    question that, without the stranded cost recovery mechanism, some 
    customers would be far more likely to switch to lower-cost suppliers 
    and enjoy sooner the benefits of a competitive power market. But, as 
    detailed in Order No. 888, such an approach may result in higher costs 
    for other customers. We thus have had to balance the potential for 
    earlier benefits for some customers against other public interest 
    considerations, most particularly the need to provide a fair mechanism 
    by which utilities can recover the costs of past investments under 
    traditional regulatory concepts of prudently incurred costs and cost 
    causation. The result is not to deny competitive advantages, but only 
    to delay their full realization for some customers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \560\ In effect, we recognize that we may have to endure some 
    short-term delay in the transition from monopoly suppliers to 
    competitive suppliers. However, this is not anticompetitive; it is a 
    necessary part of a scheme that is procompetitive overall. See 
    American Gas Association v. FERC, 888 F.2d 136, 149 (D.C. Cir. 1989) 
    (``If conditioning access is a necessary part of a scheme that is 
    procompetitive overall, however, then it does not violate the NGPA 
    [Natural Gas Policy Act] even if it may seem to be anticompetitive 
    when viewed in isolation.'').
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In any event, we do not believe that the Commission-imposed 
    mechanism of allowing the utility to recover stranded costs from the 
    departing customer through its transmission rates falls within the 
    category of an illegal tying arrangement under the antitrust laws. As 
    the Supreme Court has defined it, ``[a] tying arrangement is `an 
    agreement by a party to sell one product but only on the condition that 
    the buyer also purchases a different (or tied) product, or at least 
    agrees that he will not purchase that product from any other 
    supplier.''' 561
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \561\ Eastman Kodak Company v. Image Technical Services, 504 
    U.S. 451, 461 (1992).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Here there is no ``tying'' of ``products.'' 562 Instead, the 
    Rule provides a mechanism for recovering costs associated with a prior 
    contract. We have not adopted a rule under which a customer may 
    purchase transmission from a utility only on the condition that the 
    customer also purchases a different product, namely, power, from the 
    utility.563 To the contrary, the Commission, through the Order No. 
    888 open access transmission requirement, is attempting to provide the 
    customer with the opportunity to obtain unbundled transmission from a 
    former supplying utility as a means to reach a new generation supplier. 
    Whatever else, the stranded costs are not charges for ``products'' and 
    thus there is no ``tying'' in the conventional sense. At best, there is 
    only a condition: in obtaining unbundled transmission, the customer 
    must also pay appropriate costs stranded by its use of Commission-
    required transmission access.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \562\ A ``service'' can constitute a ``product'' for purposes of 
    a tying analysis. See Eastman Kodak Company v. Image Technical 
    Services, Inc., 504 U.S. at 462.
        \563\ The Rule requires all transmission customers to purchase 
    at least some reactive supply and voltage control service from the 
    transmission provider. However, the Commission found that the cost 
    of such services is ``part of the cost of basic transmission 
    service.'' FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,706; mimeo at 209. That is, it 
    is a necessary part of providing the service and thus, by 
    definition, not a ``tying.''
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Finally, it is not clear how often departing customers will be 
    obligated to pay stranded costs. Stranded cost recovery is by no means 
    guaranteed under the Rule, nor is it clear what portion of a utility's 
    uneconomic investment will be recoverable as stranded costs. Even when 
    a utility is able to meet the evidentiary standard and the Commission 
    approves imposition of a stranded cost charge, the customer is free to 
    pay off its obligation immediately. If it chooses to pay off the 
    stranded cost obligation over time, that charge would not be imposed 
    indefinitely on the customer. We have limited the scope of contracts 
    and costs for which utilities may seek stranded cost recovery. This 
    limitation--to certain contracts and demonstrated costs--in our 
    judgment fairly allocates between utility and customer the
    
    [[Page 12389]]
    
    burdens and benefits of open access transmission.
        Nor is it true that the Rule does not allow customers 
    ``meaningful'' access to alternative power suppliers. The Final Rule 
    pro forma tariff contains terms and conditions ensuring the provision 
    of non-discriminatory transmission service. The requirements that a 
    public utility take service under its own tariff for wholesale sales 
    and purchases, adopt a non-discriminatory transmission information 
    network, and separate power marketing and transmission functions 
    further ensure non-discrimination and remove constraints to fair 
    competition. The result is meaningful access to alternative suppliers 
    that goes far beyond what was offered in the transmission tariff under 
    review in Cajun.
        Contrary to the claims of some, the Open Access Rule does not 
    guarantee that a utility may sell its power at market-based rates. The 
    open access compliance tariff required by Order No. 888 does mitigate 
    transmission market power.564 However, the Commission's Rule does 
    not generically grant market-based rate authority to utilities that 
    file compliance tariffs. Utilities must still demonstrate on a case-by-
    case basis that they not only have mitigated transmission market power 
    but also do not have market power in generation 565 or other 
    barriers to entry.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \564\ Such tariff is a condition, but not the sole condition, 
    for market-based rates. See, e.g., Delmarva Power & Light Company, 
    et al., 76 FERC para. 61,331 (1996); accord Southern Company 
    Services, Inc., 71 FERC para. 61,392 at 62,536 (1995); Heartland 
    Energy Services, Inc., et al., 68 FERC para. 61,223 at 62,059-60 
    (1994).
        \565\ A seller requesting market-based rates is not required to 
    demonstrate any lack of generation market power with respect to 
    sales from capacity for which construction commenced on or after the 
    effective date (July 9, 1996) of the Rule. 18 CFR 35.27(a). However, 
    if specific evidence is presented by an intervenor that a seller 
    requesting market-based rates for sales from new generating capacity 
    nevertheless has generation dominance, the Commission will evaluate 
    whether the seller has generation dominance with respect to the new 
    capacity. FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,657; mimeo at 65-66.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Notwithstanding the objections by some commenters that the stranded 
    cost procedures of Order No. 888 fail to provide certainty in the 
    computation of stranded cost charges, we believe that directly 
    assigning stranded costs to departing generation customers using the 
    revenues lost formula is the fairest and most efficient way to balance 
    the competing interests of those involved. The alternatives that we 
    considered (an up-front broad-based approach or an as-realized broad-
    based approach) have significant disadvantages and are extensively 
    discussed in Order No. 888.566 Following a careful evaluation of 
    the alternatives, we concluded that a revenues lost formula to 
    calculate a customer's stranded cost obligation is more reasonable and 
    provides greater certainty than would other approaches, such as those 
    that rely on broad-based surcharge schemes that impose costs that may 
    never be incurred or those that result in widely fluctuating 
    transmission rates.567 As we stated in Order No. 888, while we 
    recognize that some commenters oppose the revenues lost approach as 
    imprecise, any ratemaking method that relies on estimates will be 
    subject to forecasting error.568 Nevertheless, we have gone to 
    great lengths to provide specificity with respect to the calculation of 
    the components of the formula.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \566\ See FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,797-800; mimeo at 477-85.
        \567\ Under the revenues lost approach, a customer's stranded 
    cost obligation is calculated by subtracting the competitive market 
    value of the power the customer would have purchased (on an average 
    annual basis) from the average annual revenues that the customer 
    would have paid had it remained on the utility's generation system, 
    and multiplying the result by the period of time the utility 
    reasonably could have expected to serve the customer beyond the 
    contract termination but for the open access required under Order 
    No. 888. See FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,839-45 for a detailed 
    explanation of the various components of the formula.
        \568\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,841; mimeo at 600-01.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In response to those commenters that argue that Order No. 888's 
    stranded cost procedures will add costs of potential deal-killing 
    magnitude to any power supply acquisition considered by a customer, we 
    believe that, to the contrary, use of the formula will narrow the scope 
    of disputes over the calculation of stranded costs, lend precision to 
    the stranded cost amount it produces, and provide certainty to 
    departing generation customers with respect to their stranded cost 
    obligations.
        APPA and ELCON object to the Commission's reference to Western 
    Resources as a case affirming the Commission's ability to allow 
    stranded cost recovery. Notwithstanding their efforts to distinguish 
    Western Resources (for example, as a filed rate doctrine case, not a 
    stranded cost case, and as a case involving no allegation of 
    anticompetitive conduct), they have failed to make a convincing 
    argument that our description of that case as ``confirm[ing] the 
    validity of Commission-imposed stranded cost recovery mechanisms in the 
    transition to competitive markets'' 569 is not accurate. The case 
    depends upon the validity of the Commission's decision to allow the 
    recovery of costs stranded in the transition of the natural gas 
    industry to a competitive market and supports the Commission's ability 
    to allow stranded cost recovery in general. The same court, in United 
    Distribution Companies, has recently confirmed the Commission's ability 
    to allow the recovery of costs stranded in the transition to 
    competitive markets, limiting its concerns to issues about ``how'' 
    stranded costs should be recovered and from whom.570
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \569\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,793; mimeo at 464-65.
        \570\ 88 F.3d at 1129, 1182-83.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    3. Responsibility for Wholesale Stranded Costs (Whether To Adopt Direct 
    Assignment to Departing Customers)
        In Order No. 888, the Commission concluded that direct assignment 
    of stranded costs to the departing wholesale generation customer 
    through either an exit fee 571 or a surcharge on transmission is 
    the appropriate method for recovery of such costs. We concluded that 
    the departing generation customer (and not the remaining generation or 
    transmission customers or shareholders) should bear the legitimate and 
    prudent obligations that the utility undertook on that customer's 
    behalf. In reaching this decision, we carefully weighed the arguments 
    supporting direct assignment of stranded costs against those supporting 
    the broad-based approach of spreading stranded costs to all 
    transmission users of a utility's system. After a detailed review of 
    the advantages and disadvantages of each approach, we concluded that, 
    on balance, direct assignment is the preferable approach for both legal 
    and policy reasons.572 Our primary considerations were that direct 
    assignment is consistent with the well-established principle that the 
    one who has caused a cost to be incurred should pay that cost and that 
    it will result in a more accurate determination of a utility's stranded 
    costs than would an up-front, broad-based transmission surcharge.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \571\ We defined ``exit fee'' as the charge that will be payable 
    by a departing generation customer upon the termination of its 
    requirements contract with a utility (if the utility is able to 
    demonstrate that it reasonably expected to continue serving the 
    customer beyond the term of the contract), whether payable in a 
    lump-sum payment or an amortization of a lump-sum payment. (The same 
    charge also can be paid as a surcharge on the customer's 
    transmission rate.)
        \572\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,797-800; mimeo at 477-85.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission also acknowledged that the direct assignment 
    approach adopted in Order No. 888 is different from the approach taken 
    for the natural
    
    [[Page 12390]]
    
    gas industry. We explained why we believe that difference to be 
    justified by pointing out a number of differences between the 
    transition of the electric industry to an open transmission access, 
    competitive industry and the transition of the natural gas industry to 
    open access transportation service by interstate natural gas 
    pipelines.573 We also declined to require a utility seeking 
    stranded cost recovery to shoulder a portion of its stranded costs on 
    the basis that such a requirement would be a major deviation from the 
    traditional principle that a utility should have a reasonable 
    opportunity to recover its prudently incurred costs, and explained why 
    we applied a different approach in the gas area.574
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \573\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,800-802; mimeo at 485-90.
        \574\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,802-03; mimeo at 490-92.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests Opposing Full Recovery From Departing Customers
    
        A number of entities submit that the Commission has not adequately 
    explained its decision not to require some utility sharing of stranded 
    costs when the utility can satisfy the reasonable expectation criteria. 
    They object that the Commission did not meaningfully consider the 
    arguments made by commenters concerning utility responsibility (such as 
    poor management decisions) for stranded costs.575
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \575\ E.g., ELCON, IL Industrials, San Francisco, Nucor. Other 
    entities that urge the Commission to require shareholders to 
    shoulder a portion of the utility's stranded costs include Central 
    Illinois Light, AR Com, American Forest & Paper, Nucor, and 
    Occidental Chemical. American Forest & Paper and Nucor suggest that 
    full recovery destroys incentives to mitigate. Several entities also 
    support spreading the costs to all of the utility's customers. E.g., 
    American Forest & Paper, Central Illinois Light, AR Com.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        ELCON argues that departing customers are not the sole cause of 
    stranded costs. IL Industrials submits that the statement in the Rule 
    that utility shareholders ``'had no responsibility for causing the 
    legitimate, prudent and verifiable costs to be incurred''' is 
    untrue.576 It argues that although utilities may have had a legal 
    obligation to serve and meet projected demands, how the utility chose 
    to meet those obligations was under the utility's control. IL 
    Industrials asserts that shareholders should bear some of the risk 
    associated with the decisions of their management that were less than 
    optimal. At a minimum, IL Industrials argues that the Commission should 
    consider on a case-by-case basis (when it determines whether a utility 
    has incurred legitimate and verifiable stranded costs) whether some 
    amount of stranded costs should be shared with shareholders.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \576\ IL Industrials at 4-6 (citing Order No. 888, mimeo at 491-
    92).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        NASUCA challenges the Commission's statement in Order No. 888 that 
    requiring a utility to shoulder a portion of its stranded costs ``would 
    be a major deviation from the traditional principle that a utility 
    should have a reasonable opportunity to recover its prudently incurred 
    costs.'' 577 It contends that there is no constitutionally 
    guaranteed right of recovery of all prudent investment.578 NASUCA 
    further asserts that full recovery of uneconomic investment is not the 
    norm. It submits that the Commission has rejected utility demands for 
    full recovery of cancelled electric generation facilities.579
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \577\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,802; mimeo at 490.
        \578\ NASUCA cites in support of its position Covington & 
    Lexington Turnpike Road Company v. Sandford, 164 U.S. 578 (1896); 
    Market Street Railway Company v. Railroad Commission, 324 U.S. 548 
    (1945) (Market Street); Duquesne Light Company v. Barasch, 488 U.S. 
    299, 315-16 (1989).
        \579\ NASUCA cites in support of its position New England Power 
    Company, 8 FERC para. 61,054 (1979), aff'd sub nom. NEPCO Municipal 
    Rate Committee v. FERC, 668 F.2d 1327 (D.C. Cir. 1981), cert. 
    denied, 457 U.S. 1117 (1982). NASUCA states that in that case, 
    prudently incurred plant investment was abandoned because changing 
    circumstances rendered the investment uneconomic; the Commission 
    provided for a ten-year amortization of the plant investment, with 
    no return on the unamortized balance. NASUCA says that this 
    precedent demonstrates that the ``regulatory compact'' does not 
    require full cost recovery.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        San Francisco cites Market Street as support for the proposition 
    that the risk of unmarketability should fall, in whole or in part, on 
    utility shareholders who knew of competitive risks and who have been 
    compensated for those risks through rates of return.
         A number of parties object that the Commission, in declining to 
    require some shareholder sharing of stranded costs, is allowing the 
    electric utility industry to claim more generous recoveries under Order 
    No. 888 than it allowed the gas industry, and that it has provided no 
    adequate rationale for this difference in treatment.580 San 
    Francisco states that although the Rule attempts to distinguish 
    shareholder sharing in the natural gas industry ``as an extraordinary 
    measure given the nature of the take-or-pay problem and the prevailing 
    environment at that time,'' 581 the Commission has not identified 
    how the nature of the take-or-pay problem was any more 
    ``extraordinary'' than the nature of stranded costs in electric 
    restructuring, or explain its reference to ``the prevailing environment 
    at that time.''
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \580\ E.g., Central Illinois Light, Occidental Chemical.
        \581\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,802; mimeo at 491.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Occidental Chemical submits that the Commission's decision not to 
    allocate a portion of stranded costs to utilities on cost causation 
    grounds contradicts the Commission's actions in Order No. 636, in which 
    it required interruptible and new shippers, as beneficiaries of open 
    access, to share in the costs of the transition.582 Central 
    Illinois Light states that the Commission should allow partial recovery 
    of stranded costs and thereby correct key differences in the 
    Commission's responses to gas and electric transition costs.583
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \582\ Occidental Chemical argues that requiring gas customers to 
    choose their suppliers during an open season enabled the pipelines 
    to place a dollar value on their take-or-pay obligations. Shippers 
    thus knew at the outset what their gas supply realignment (GSR) 
    surcharge would be and could negotiate with other suppliers 
    accordingly. Occidental Chemical says that most pipelines have 
    already recouped their GSR costs and have made the transition to a 
    competitive supply market in under three years. It argues that, on 
    the other hand, allowing electric stranded costs to be recovered 
    over an indefinite period will blunt the pro-competitive effect of 
    Order No. 888.
        \583\ Central Illinois Light supports a recovery mechanism that 
    would allow utilities to allocate stranded costs to requirements 
    customers on a demand basis and to all transmission customers on a 
    commodity basis. It argues that this would recognize the greater 
    cost responsibility of requirements customers, recognize the 
    benefits obtained by all transmission customers from open access, 
    and reduce the charges to all customers to a more reasonable level.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Occidental Chemical also objects that the Commission failed to 
    address the merits of its suggestion that the Commission grant a 
    utility a presumption of prudence in return for absorbing a percentage 
    of its stranded costs.
        ELCON, in a supplement to its rehearing request,584 submits 
    that the D.C. Circuit's remand in United Distribution Companies of the 
    aspect of Order No. 636 that allocated 100 percent of gas supply 
    realignment costs to customers and none to pipelines has implications 
    for the Commission's decision in Order No. 888 to allocate 100 percent 
    of stranded costs to departing customers without any shareholder 
    sharing of the costs. ELCON suggests that although the D.C. Circuit 
    indicated that a finding of threat to the financial viability of the 
    pipeline sector might justify such allocation, there is no evidence in 
    the record in the Order No. 888 proceeding, and the Commission has made 
    no finding, that wholesale stranded cost recovery jeopardizes the 
    financial viability of the utility sector. It
    
    [[Page 12391]]
    
    adds that, to the extent the Commission relies on strict cost causation 
    principles in Order No. 888, it is not clear how departing wholesale 
    customers who signed contracts in 1985 could have ``caused'' utilities 
    to incur uneconomic assets such as expensive nuclear facilities that 
    were planned and ordered in the 1970s.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \584\ We will accept this pleading as a motion for 
    reconsideration, not as a request for rehearing, because it was not 
    filed within the 30-day statutory period for rehearing requests. See 
    16 U.S.C. Sec. 825l(a).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        As we explained in Order No. 888, we decided not to require a 
    utility meeting the requirements for stranded cost recovery to shoulder 
    a portion of its stranded costs because such a requirement would be a 
    major deviation from the traditional principle that a utility should 
    have a reasonable opportunity to recover its prudently incurred 
    costs.585 Our decision (which allows assignment of legitimate, 
    prudent and verifiable stranded costs to departing requirements 
    generation customers, not to shareholders or other customers of the 
    utility) also follows the cost causation principle that has been 
    fundamental to our regulation since 1935.586 It is important, in 
    this regard, to distinguish between assuring recovery of all uneconomic 
    costs (which Order No. 888 does not do) and providing an opportunity 
    for recovery where the evidentiary requirements of the Rule are met.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \585\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,802; mimeo at     490-91.
        \586\ In response to ELCON's argument that it is not clear how 
    departing wholesale customers who signed contracts in 1985 could 
    have ``caused'' utilities to incur uneconomic assets such as 
    expensive nuclear facilities that were planned and ordered in the 
    1970s, we note that customers taking requirements service generally 
    pay an allocated share of total embedded costs, including the cost 
    of investments made before the customer began service. This pricing 
    principle is consistent with the method that Order No. 888 adopts 
    for calculating a departing customer's stranded cost obligation. The 
    revenues lost approach is not an asset-by-asset approach. Instead, 
    it is an approach that looks at a utility's current rates, which are 
    based on all the utility's assets, which may include both high cost 
    and low cost generating facilities of various ages, and relies on 
    the presumption that the fixed costs allocated to departing 
    customers under their current rates are properly assignable to them. 
    Thus, if a utility is able to demonstrate that it had a reasonable 
    expectation of continuing to serve the customer after the contract 
    term, the customer's stranded cost obligation would be computed 
    based on the average annual revenues that the customer would have 
    paid had it remained a customer of the utility; the calculation of 
    stranded costs would not be tied to any particular investments that 
    the utility made in a particular unit. As we explain in Section 
    IV.J.9 below, the use of present annual revenues as the basis for 
    the stranded cost calculation is based, among other things, on the 
    presumption that present rates include all just and reasonable costs 
    of providing service.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Allowing full recovery of stranded costs under Order No. 888 is not 
    equivalent to allowing 100 percent recovery of the costs of all 
    uneconomic assets. A utility may have uneconomic assets for a variety 
    of reasons, including a decline in load, customer shifts to natural 
    gas, customer energy conservation, loss of a large industrial customer, 
    customer self-generation, and a customer gaining transmission access 
    through another utility's transmission system. The Rule does not 
    provide for the recovery of the costs of such uneconomic assets.
        Instead, the Rule defines a discrete set of uneconomic costs that 
    are stranded by FPA section 211 or Order No. 888 transmission service 
    (when a customer uses the former supplying utility's transmission 
    system to reach a new supplier) for which utilities may seek recovery. 
    However, even as to this set of costs the Rule does not guarantee 100 
    percent recovery. To be eligible to recover such costs, a utility must 
    satisfy the reasonable expectation test set forth in Order No. 888. 
    Even then, the utility will be eligible to recover only costs that are 
    legitimate, prudent and verifiable.
        In response to those entities that argue that departing customers 
    are not the sole cause of stranded costs and that poor management 
    decisions may be partly to blame, we reiterate that a determination 
    that a utility has a reasonable expectation of continuing to serve a 
    customer would not, in all circumstances, mean that costs incurred by 
    the utility were prudent. As we said in Order No. 888, we cannot make a 
    blanket assumption that all claimed stranded costs were prudently 
    incurred. We explained that prudence of costs, depending upon the facts 
    in a specific case, may include different things, such as prudence in 
    operation and maintenance of a plant, and the utility's ongoing 
    obligation to exercise prudence in retaining existing investments and 
    power purchase contracts and in entering into new ones.587 We 
    clarified, however, that we do not intend to relitigate the prudence of 
    costs previously recovered.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \587\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,850; mimeo at 626.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Thus, to the extent that costs have not been previously recovered 
    by a utility, and depending upon the facts presented, a customer from 
    whom a utility is seeking to recover stranded costs may be able to 
    challenge the prudence of those costs. If such prudence challenge is 
    successful, then the utility would not be entitled to recovery of the 
    imprudently incurred costs, through stranded cost recovery or 
    otherwise. We believe that this fully addresses the concerns of those 
    entities that contend that departing customers should not be 
    responsible for costs that result from poor management decisions or 
    other actions by the utility.588
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \588\ Whether poor management decisions or other actions are 
    imprudent would be decided on a case-by-case basis. See, e.g., New 
    England Power Company, Opinion No. 231, 31 FERC para. 61,047 at 
    61,081-84, reh'g denied, Opinion No. 231-A, 32 FERC para. 61,112 
    (1985), aff'd sub nom., Violet v. FERC, 800 F.2d 280 (1st Cir. 
    1986); Minnesota Power & Light Company, Opinion No. 86, 11 FERC 
    para. 61,312 at 61,644-45, order on reh'g, 12 FERC para. 61,264 
    (1980). However, a utility's costs are presumed prudent and a person 
    challenging such costs would have the burden of going forward with 
    evidence that raises a serious doubt as to prudence. Id., 11 FERC at 
    61,645.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As we explained in Order No. 888, our decision not to require 
    utilities to shoulder a portion of their stranded costs is based on the 
    traditional principle that a utility should have a reasonable 
    opportunity to recover its prudently incurred costs. 589 NASUCA's 
    reliance on the Commission's cancelled plant policy to support its 
    argument that full recovery of uneconomic investment is not the norm is 
    misplaced. The Commission's cancelled plant policy, which allows a 
    utility to recover 50 percent of its prudently-incurred investment in a 
    cancelled or abandoned plant, relates only to plants that are cancelled 
    or abandoned prior to entering commercial service and thus prior to 
    becoming used and useful.590 The Commission has taken a different 
    approach in the case of electric generating plants that are prematurely 
    shut down after having been in commercial operation for a number of 
    years. In the latter instance (which more closely resembles the type of 
    costs for which a utility might seek recovery under Order No. 888 than 
    does the cancelled plant before operation scenario), the Commission has 
    allowed 100 percent recovery of prudently-incurred unamortized 
    investment.591
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \589\ See, e.g., Maryland v. Louisiana, 451 U.S. 725, 748 
    (1981); Office of Consumers' Counsel v. FERC, 914 F.2d 290, 292 
    (D.C. Cir. 1990); City of New Orleans, Louisiana v. FERC, 67 F.3d 
    947, 954 (1st Cir. 1995).
        \590\ See New England Power Company, Opinion No. 295, 42 FERC 
    para. 61,016, reh'g denied in part and granted in part, Opinion No. 
    295-A, 43 FERC para. 61,285 (1988). We note that the Supreme Court 
    case on which NASUCA relies to support its argument that there is no 
    constitutionally guaranteed right of recovery of all prudent 
    investment, Duquesne, also involved electrical generating facilities 
    that were planned but never built. See 488 U.S. 299 (1989).
        \591\ See Yankee Atomic Electric Company, Opinion No. 390, 67 
    FERC para. 61,318, (Yankee Atomic), reh'g denied, 68 FERC para. 
    61,364 (1994), remanded on other grounds, Town of Norwood, 
    Massachusetts v. FERC, 80 F.3d 526 (D.C. Cir. 1996), offer of 
    settlement accepted, letter dated January 30, 1997, Docket No. ER92-
    592-005. This case involved a nuclear plant that had been in 
    operation for over 30 years. In affirming the Commission's decision 
    to allow full recovery and not to apply Opinion No. 295's recovery 
    rule for plants abandoned before operation, the court explained:
        Although ratepayers generally `bear the expense of depreciation' 
    and although investors generally `are entitled to recoup from 
    consumers the full amount of their investment in depreciable assets 
    devoted to public service,' [citations omitted] Opinion No. 295 
    makes a logical exception to this full recovery rule for plants 
    abandoned before operation; in such cases, ratepayers have not 
    benefitted from the plant. The situation here is quite different. 
    Because customers have benefitted from the operation of the plant 
    for over 30 years, and because ceasing plant operations will benefit 
    customers by lowering rates, such an exception is unwarranted. 
    Moreover, applying Opinion No. 295's recovery rule would not, as it 
    would in the case of a plant that never began operations, promote 
    economic efficiency.'' 80 F.3d at 532.
        In Yankee Atomic, the Commission also allowed recovery of 100 
    percent of construction work in progress and of post-shutdown O&M 
    expenditures.
    
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [[Page 12392]]
    
        San Francisco's and NASUCA's reliance on Market Street is also 
    distinguishable. That case involved an industry (street railway) that 
    had been rendered economically obsolete by market forces. The electric 
    industry today, in contrast, is clearly not obsolete. Moreover, the 
    costs that Order No. 888 gives a utility an opportunity to recover even 
    in the face of market forces would not become stranded but for 
    statutory and regulatory changes.
        A number of parties contend that the Commission has not provided an 
    adequate rationale for its different treatment of shareholder sharing 
    in the natural gas industry. ELCON also relies on the D.C. Circuit's 
    remand in United Distribution Companies of Order No. 636's holding that 
    pipelines could recover 100 percent of their gas supply realignment 
    (GSR) costs. After further review of this matter in light of the 
    Court's decision in United Distribution Companies, we reaffirm that, 
    even though the Commission permitted pipelines to recover take-or-pay 
    costs based on ``cost spreading'' and ``value of service'' principles, 
    stranded electric utility costs should be recovered based on 
    traditional cost causation principles. This is because, despite the 
    fact that both sets of costs are incurred in connection with a 
    transition to unbundled, open access service, there are also 
    substantial differences between the circumstances surrounding the two 
    industries' incurrence of their respective transition costs.
        The pipelines' take-or-pay problems began before the Commission 
    initiated open access transportation in Order No. 436. The severe gas 
    shortages of the 1970s led to enactment of the Natural Gas Policy Act 
    (NGPA), which initiated a phased decontrol of most new gas prices and 
    established ceiling prices for controlled gas, including incentive 
    prices for price-controlled new gas higher than the ceiling prices 
    previously established by the Commission under the NGA.592 To 
    avoid future shortages, pipelines then entered into long-term take-or-
    pay contracts at the high prices made possible by the NGPA, and those 
    high prices stimulated producers to greatly increase exploration and 
    drilling.593 When demand unexpectedly fell and supply increased, 
    the pipelines found themselves contractually bound to take or pay for 
    high-priced gas which they could not sell. Even before Order No. 436 
    issued in October 1985, pipeline take-or-pay exposure was approaching 
    $10 billion.594 In 1986, as pipelines were just beginning to 
    implement open access transportation under Order No. 436 and before the 
    August 1987 issuance of Order No. 500, the pipelines' outstanding 
    unresolved take-or-pay liabilities peaked at $10.7 billion.595
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \592\ Order No. 500-H, Regulations Preambles 1986-1990, FERC 
    Stats. & Regs. para. 30,867 at 31,509 (1989).
        \593\ Id. at 31,509-10.
        \594\ Id. at 31,513.
        \595\ Id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission and the industry had never previously faced a take-
    or-pay problem of this nature or magnitude. In earlier times, pipelines 
    had made take-or-pay payments to particular producers, and the 
    Commission had a policy of permitting such payments to be included in 
    rate base and then recovered as a gas cost when the pipeline later took 
    the gas under make-up provisions in the contract.596 By 1983, 
    however, the pipelines could not manage their take-or-pay problems, and 
    stopped honoring the bulk of their take-or-pay liabilities.597 
    They then sought settlements with the producers to reform or terminate 
    the uneconomic take-or-pay contracts and to resolve outstanding take-
    or-pay liabilities. Because pipelines had never previously incurred 
    significant take-or-pay settlement costs, the Commission had no policy 
    concerning whether and how pipelines were to recover those costs. The 
    Commission commenced establishing such a policy in an April 1985 policy 
    statement,598 just six months before Order No. 436. When Order No. 
    500 issued, few take-or-pay settlement costs had yet been included in 
    pipelines' rates. However, since the pipelines' outstanding take-or-pay 
    liabilities were in the neighborhood of $10 billion, it was clear that 
    pipelines would incur massive costs in their settlements with 
    producers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \596\ Regulatory Treatment of Payments Made in Lieu of Take-or-
    Pay Obligations, Regulations Preambles 1982-85, FERC Stats. & Regs. 
    para. 30,637 at 31,301 (1985).
        \597\ In Order No. 500-H, the Commission found that, although 
    pipelines incurred total take-or-pay exposure over the period 
    January 1, 1983 through June 30, 1987 of over $24 billion, they made 
    take-or-pay payments totalling only $.7 billion. Order No. 500-H, 
    Regulations Preambles 1986-1990 para. 30,867 at 31,514.
        \598\ Regulatory Treatment of Payments Made in Lieu of Take-or-
    Pay Obligations, Regulations Preambles 1982-85, FERC Stats. & Regs. 
    para. 30,637 (1985).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In short, when the Commission first addressed the issue of how to 
    allocate take-or-pay settlement costs in Order No. 500, it did so under 
    the shadow of the pipelines' vast outstanding take-or-pay exposure. The 
    essential problem, therefore, was to decide which customers' rates 
    should be raised to reflect the billions of dollars of take-or-pay 
    settlement costs that the pipelines were incurring, but that the 
    pipelines had still not filed to recover. To have allocated those costs 
    solely to any one segment of the industry would have imposed a crushing 
    new burden on that segment. For example, if the Commission had 
    allocated the take-or-pay settlement costs entirely to bundled sales 
    customers who chose to convert to transportation-only service, those 
    customers would have ended up far worse off than if they remained as 
    bundled sales customers.
        As a result of all these facts, the fundamental premise of Order 
    No. 500 was, as the Court expressed it in KN Energy, that ``the 
    extraordinary nature of this problem requires the aid of the entire 
    industry to solve it.'' 599 In order to accomplish this result, 
    Order No. 500 established an equitable sharing mechanism for pipelines 
    to use in recovering their take-or-pay settlement costs as an 
    alternative to recovery through their commodity sales rates. Relying on 
    ``cost spreading'' and ``value of service'' principles, the Commission 
    permitted pipelines to allocate their take-or-pay settlement costs 
    among all the pipelines' customers. The Commission also required the 
    pipelines using the equitable sharing mechanism to absorb a portion of 
    the costs in return for the ability to recover an equal portion through 
    a fixed charge. Importantly, pipelines using the equitable sharing 
    mechanism and agreeing to absorb a portion of the costs were given a 
    presumption that their take-or-pay settlement costs were prudent. Those 
    who did not choose to avail themselves of the sharing/absorption 
    mechanism could still file for recovery of take-or-pay costs pursuant 
    to the traditional ratemaking methodology. Because the pipelines' cash 
    flow problems were so severe and they could not reasonably expect to 
    recover their costs through their sales
    
    [[Page 12393]]
    
    rates, they readily availed themselves of the special mechanism, with 
    its presumption of prudence, rather than the more protracted 
    traditional ratemaking option.600
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \599\ 968 F.2d 1295, 1301 (D.C. Cir. 1992).
        \600\ By contrast, Order No. 888 does not provide a presumption 
    of prudence for utilities' stranded cost recovery proposals. Once 
    again, the more traditional concept that the utility must prove 
    costs were prudently incurred will apply.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Court in KN Energy upheld the Commission's use of cost 
    spreading in connection with the allocation of take-or-pay costs among 
    a pipeline's open access customers.601 The Court held that ``the 
    ratemaking rationales of Order No. 500 can be reconciled with the NGA, 
    given the unusual circumstances surrounding the take-or-pay problem, 
    and the limited nature--both in time and scope--of the Commission's 
    departure from the cost-causation principle.'' 602 The Court 
    emphasized that ``[w]e hold only--and quite narrowly--that in the 
    context of Order No. 500 the Commission has not betrayed its 
    obligations to the NGA or precedent by employing these ratemaking 
    principles in its attempt to bring closure to the take-or-pay drama.'' 
    603
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \601\ The Court did not review the Order No. 500/528 requirement 
    that pipelines absorb a share of the take-or-pay costs. See AGA v. 
    FERC, 888 F.2d 136, 152 (D.C. Cir. 1989), and AGA v. FERC, 912 F.2d 
    1496, 1519 (D.C. Cir. 1990), cert. denied, 498 U.S. 1084 (1991), 
    both holding the absorption requirement not ripe for review.
        \602\ KN Energy, 968 F.2d at 1301.
        \603\ Id. at 1302.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The unusual circumstances that justified the departure from cost 
    causation principles in Order Nos. 500/528 are not present in the 
    electric industry. In Order No. 888's discussion of the Commission's 
    decision not to order any generic abrogation of existing requirements 
    and transmission contracts between electric utilities and their 
    customers, we have already pointed out:
    
        At the time the Commission addressed this situation in the 
    natural gas industry, it was faced with shrinking natural gas 
    markets, statutory escalations in natural gas prices under the 
    Natural Gas Policy Act, and increased production of gas. In other 
    words, there was a market failure in the industry. * * * In 
    contrast, there is no such market failure in the electric 
    industry.[604]
    
        \604\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,664; mimeo at 84.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The electric utility costs potentially stranded by Order No. 888 
    are fixed costs arising from the utility's electric generation 
    business, including, for example, depreciation expense associated with 
    the utilities' own generation facilities and a return on the original 
    cost of its investment in those facilities. They also include costs 
    associated with mandatory QF purchase contracts. Unlike take-or-pay 
    settlement costs, these costs are not an extraordinary expense that the 
    Commission has never previously encountered. Rather, the stranded 
    electric costs that are subject to the direct assignment provisions of 
    Order No. 888 are ordinary costs that have always been, and are 
    currently, included in the utility's rates for electric generation 
    approved by the Commission. And there is no pre-existing industry-wide 
    market failure. Thus, we are not confronted at the start of the 
    electric open access program with a vast outstanding cost not currently 
    reflected in the electric utilities' rates, as we were at the start of 
    the natural gas open access program.
        Therefore, unlike the situation with the natural gas industry, 
    stranded electric utility costs can be allocated among customers based 
    upon traditional cost causation principles without imposing inequitable 
    and unreasonable burdens on particular customer classes. Direct 
    assignment to departing requirements generation customers through the 
    stranded cost recovery mechanism contained in the Rule is consistent 
    with the traditional cost causation principle because it recognizes the 
    link between the incurrence of stranded costs and the decision of a 
    particular generation customer to use open access transmission on the 
    utility's system to leave the utility's generation system and shop for 
    power, and bases the utility's ability to recover stranded costs on its 
    ability to demonstrate that it incurred costs with the reasonable 
    expectation that the customer would remain on its generation system 
    beyond the term of the contract. The stranded costs are measured as the 
    difference between revenues the utility would have recovered from the 
    customer and the market value of the utility's power.
        In essence, therefore, all that the direct assignment provisions of 
    Order No. 888 require is that certain customers (those whom a utility 
    is able to demonstrate it reasonably expected to continue serving 
    beyond the contract term) who convert to transmission-only service 
    continue, for a period, to bear certain generation costs that they were 
    previously bearing. This helps to minimize immediate cost shifts to the 
    remaining generation customers, and is thus consistent with the Court's 
    concerns in AGD about cost shifts due to open access 
    transportation.605 At the same time, it does not impose any 
    crushing new burden on the converting generation customers, as would 
    have happened if in the natural gas industry the Commission had 
    allocated the take-or-pay settlement costs entirely to pipeline sales 
    customers who converted to transportation-only service.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \605\ See, e.g., AGD, 824 F.2d at 1026.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        On the issue of utility absorption of stranded costs, as ELCON 
    points out, the D.C. Circuit in United Distribution Companies remanded 
    Order No. 636 to the Commission for further explanation as to why the 
    Commission had exempted pipelines from sharing in Order No. 636 GSR 
    costs in light of: (1) Its reliance on ``cost spreading'' and ``value 
    of service'' principles in allocating GSR costs among the pipelines' 
    customers, and (2) the absorption requirement in Order Nos. 500/528. As 
    the Court explained:
    
        If the Commission intends to assign GSR costs according to these 
    `cost spreading' and `value of service' principles, it must do so 
    consistently or explain the rationale for proceeding in another 
    manner. We approved the invocation of those principles in KN Energy 
    because FERC had concluded that the take-or-pay crisis could be 
    resolved only by spreading costs throughout the `entire industry' 
    968 F.2d at 1301 (emphasis added), and because we recognized that 
    `all segments of the industry' * * * will benefit, id. (emphasis 
    added), from restructuring.[606]
    
        \606\ United Distribution Companies, 88 F.3d at 1189.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        For the reasons discussed above and in Order No. 888, we have 
    chosen to use traditional cost causation principles both in allocating 
    stranded electric costs to certain electric utility customers and in 
    finding that the utilities should be given an opportunity for full 
    recovery of certain legitimate, prudent, and verifiable stranded costs. 
    Thus, Order No. 888 does not present the issue of whether the 
    Commission inconsistently applied ratemaking principles to the recovery 
    of stranded costs that was of concern to the court in United 
    Distribution Companies when it remanded the analogous portion of Order 
    No. 636.
        Moreover, based on the facts summarized above, the Commission 
    concludes that the rationale we used to support the Order Nos. 500/528 
    absorption requirement is not valid for electric utility costs stranded 
    by Order No. 888. Order No. 528-A, where the Commission gave its 
    fullest justification for that absorption requirement, did not rely on 
    either the ``cost spreading'' or ``value of service'' rationales to 
    support the absorption requirement.607 Order Nos. 500/528 
    consistently recognized that the Commission must ``provide a pipeline a 
    reasonable opportunity to
    
    [[Page 12394]]
    
    recover its prudently incurred costs.'' 608 However, Order No. 
    528-A reasoned that, because the take-or-pay problem was caused more by 
    general market conditions than by any regulatory action of the 
    Commission, it was appropriate to require the pipelines to share in the 
    losses arising from those market conditions as a condition to using the 
    alternative recovery mechanism.609
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \607\ Order No. 528-A, 54 FERC para. 61,095 at 61,303-05 (1991).
        \608\ Order No. 500-H, Regulations Preambles 1986-1990, FERC 
    Stats. & Regs. at 31,575. Those orders permitted all pipelines to 
    seek full recovery of their take-or-pay settlement costs through 
    their sales commodity rates. The Commission required pipelines to 
    absorb a share of their Order No. 500/528 take-or-pay costs only if 
    they chose to use the alternative, equitable sharing recovery 
    mechanism.
        \609\ Order No. 528-A, 54 FERC at 61,303-05.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In these circumstances, the Commission concludes that it would not 
    be reasonable to require electric utilities to bear costs that, unlike 
    the Order Nos. 500/528 take-or-pay costs, arise as the direct result of 
    Congress' and the Commission's change in the regulatory regime through 
    FPA section 211 and Order No. 888. This is particularly the case since 
    the electric utilities' potential stranded costs relate to large 
    capital expenditures or long-term contractual commitments (some 
    mandated by federal law) to buy power made many years ago in reliance 
    on the preexisting regulatory regime.
        Moreover, in a separate order, the Commission is responding to the 
    United Distribution Companies remand by reaffirming the policy 
    established in Order No. 636 that pipelines should be permitted full 
    recovery of their prudently incurred GSR costs. In that order, the 
    Commission finds that the rationale Order No. 528-A used to support the 
    Order Nos. 500/528 absorption requirement is inapplicable to GSR costs. 
    The remand order explains that, in the face of extraordinary market 
    conditions, Order Nos. 500/528 adopted extraordinary measures. However, 
    as we are finding here with respect to stranded electric utility costs, 
    the remand order holds that the extraordinary market circumstances that 
    gave rise to the requirement for pipeline absorption of gas supply 
    costs in Order Nos. 500/528 were not present at the time of Order No. 
    636. Even before the Commission initiated open access transportation in 
    Order No. 436, the market was preventing pipelines from recovering 
    costs incurred under their take-or-pay contracts. The Order Nos. 500/
    528 absorption requirement reflected the preexisting effect of the 
    market, which would have required absorption even without open access 
    transportation under Order No. 436. The remand order finds that, 
    contrary to the situation when Order No. 436 issued, at the time of 
    Order No. 636, pipelines were generally able to take gas under their 
    few remaining high-priced take-or-pay contracts from the late 1970s and 
    early 1980s and were no longer accumulating significant additional 
    take-or-pay obligations. This was because the pipelines were still 
    performing a significant sales service and had reformed most of their 
    uneconomic take-or-pay contracts.610
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \610\ A number of entities (e.g., VT DPS, Valero, Occidental 
    Chemical) challenge the Commission's suggestion that, after Order 
    No. 436, many of the former bundled sales customers of the pipeline 
    had departed. To the extent that Order No. 888 suggested that many 
    pipelines' sales customers had terminated their sales service before 
    Order No. 636 issued, we note that, as the Commission indicated in 
    Order No. 636, pipeline sales constituted less than 20 percent of 
    total annual throughput on major pipelines. FERC Stats. & Regs. 
    para.30,939 at 30,400. However, the Commission also found that in 
    1991 over 60 percent of peak day capacity on major pipelines that 
    made bundled sales was reserved for pipeline firm sales service. Id. 
    at 30,399. Thus, we clarify that although on an annual basis 
    customers were buying most of their gas from other suppliers, 
    pipelines were making significant sales of gas, particularly on peak 
    days.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The remand order accordingly holds that the Commission's regulatory 
    actions in Order No. 636 have caused the pipelines to incur the GSR 
    costs. This is particularly the case because Order No. 636 required the 
    pipelines to unbundle their natural gas and transportation sales and 
    forbade the pipelines from making sales unless they were made by a 
    separate sales or marketing entity. Order No. 888 also requires 
    generation or commodity sales to be unbundled from sales of 
    transmission. In these circumstances, traditional ratemaking principles 
    require the Commission to allow the pipelines an opportunity to recover 
    the full amount of the expenses caused by its actions. Thus, the 
    Commission's approach to Order No. 636 GSR costs is similar to its 
    approach in Order No. 888 to stranded electric generation costs.
    
    Rehearing Requests Citing Other Inconsistencies Between Commission 
    Treatments of the Gas and Electric Industries
    
        VT DPS and Valero submit that Order No. 888 does not satisfactorily 
    distinguish the Commission's rejection of gas pipelines' attempts to 
    impose exit fees on departing customers. They argue that the Commission 
    opposed the imposition of such exit fees in the gas context as 
    anticompetitive because it would force customers desiring to switch 
    suppliers when their contracts expired to pay the supply costs of both 
    the new and former suppliers.
        VT DPS and Valero take issue with the Commission's attempt to 
    distinguish a recent El Paso case 611 as a ``post-restructuring'' 
    case under Order No. 636. They contend that the Commission consistently 
    applied the same policy (rejection of gas pipeline attempts to impose 
    exit fees) before restructuring under Order No. 636. They further claim 
    that the Commission cannot articulate a plausible basis for permitting 
    utilities with notice provisions to file for exit fees, having denied 
    El Paso's proposal outright without giving it an opportunity to rebut 
    the presumption.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \611\ El Paso Natural Gas Company, 72 FERC para.61,083 (1995) 
    (El Paso).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        VT DPS and Valero also state that the ``stranded'' costs for which 
    the Commission allowed recovery under Order No. 636 were costs that 
    would be rendered unrecoverable because the costs would not be incurred 
    to provide transportation service and because there would be no 
    wholesale load from which to recover the costs. They indicate that the 
    Commission has held that such gas costs are stranded only if rendered 
    unrecoverable as a direct result of the restructuring required under 
    Order No. 636. They submit that when a utility loses wholesale load or 
    a municipality establishes a new distribution system and the utility 
    cannot resell the capacity left unused, the utility's costs are not 
    necessarily ``stranded''--i.e., rendered unrecoverable--any more than 
    if the utility's load declines because of conservation, an economic 
    downturn or an increase in self-generation. They argue that the 
    Commission should limit utility stranded cost claims solely to those 
    cases where the utility can demonstrate that its costs have been 
    rendered unrecoverable as a direct result of the Rule.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We explained in Order No. 888 why we disagree with the argument 
    that the Commission cannot impose an exit fee to recover stranded costs 
    because the Commission did not allow gas pipelines to do so. We noted 
    that the Rule establishes procedures for providing a potential 
    departing generation customer advance notice (before it leaves its 
    existing supplier) of the stranded cost charge (whether it is to be 
    paid as an exit fee or a transmission surcharge) that will be applied 
    if the customer decides to buy power elsewhere and the Commission 
    decides the utility has satisfied the stranded cost recovery criteria 
    of the Rule, e.g., the reasonable expectation criterion. We indicated 
    that in the natural gas context, in contrast, the Commission has 
    prohibited
    
    [[Page 12395]]
    
    pipelines from developing and charging an ``exit fee'' after a customer 
    had implemented its gas purchase decision, noting that otherwise, the 
    customer would not know in advance the full cost consequences of its 
    nomination decision.612
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \612\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,802; mimeo at 489.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We continue to believe that the Commission's decisions concerning 
    natural gas pipeline exit fees, relied on by VT DPS and Valero, are not 
    inconsistent with Order No. 888's limited approval of exit fees for the 
    recovery of certain stranded electric utility costs. VT DPS and Valero 
    point first to two cases decided by the Commission in 1988 and 1989 
    involving Gas Inventory Charges (GICs) proposed by Transwestern 
    Pipeline Company (Transwestern) 613 and El Paso Natural Gas 
    Company (El Paso) 614 pursuant to our Order No. 500 policy 
    statement. However, those cases are not relevant here, essentially 
    because the exit fees at issue in those cases were not designed to 
    recover costs arising from the transition to open access 
    transportation, unlike the stranded electric utility costs at issue 
    here.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \613\ Transwestern Pipeline Company, 44 FERC para. 61,164 at 
    61,536 (1988) (Transwestern).
        \614\ El Paso Natural Gas Company, 47 FERC para. 61,108 at 
    61,314, reh'g denied, 48 FERC para. 61,202 (1989).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In the Transwestern case cited by VT DPS and Valero, Transwestern 
    included in its proposal to implement a GIC a request for permission to 
    assess an exit fee. The exit fee would have been charged to its largest 
    local distribution company customer if that customer initially chose to 
    nominate purchases under the GIC but then subsequently reduced its 
    nominations. The Commission found the proposed exit fee inconsistent 
    with both (1) its policy that GIC customers know in advance the full 
    cost consequences of their nomination decisions and (2) its objective 
    that prices under the GIC be constrained by market forces.
        However, this holding was not applicable to Transwestern's recovery 
    of costs incurred as part of its transition to open access 
    transportation, since the Commission did not intend the GIC as a 
    vehicle for recovery of such transition costs. The GIC was intended 
    solely as a forward-looking charge that would recover costs the 
    pipeline would incur in the future under its reformed, market 
    responsive gas supply contracts.615 The Commission's intent was 
    that, before implementing GICs, pipelines would negotiate settlements 
    of their existing uneconomic take-or-pay contracts and file to recover 
    the resulting settlement costs under the Order No. 500 equitable 
    sharing mechanism.616 Indeed, in the Transwestern order cited by 
    VT DPS and Valero, the Commission suggested that Transwestern postpone 
    implementation of its GIC until it had renegotiated its supply 
    contracts and filed to recover the resulting costs under the Order No. 
    500 equitable sharing mechanism.617
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \615\ Order No. 500, Regulations Preambles (1986-1990), FERC 
    Stats. & Regs. para.30,761 at 30,793-94 (1987).
        \616\ CPUC v. FERC, 988 F.2d 154, 168 (D.C. Cir. 1993), quoting, 
    Transwestern Pipeline Company, 55 FERC para.61,157 at 61,509 (1991).
        \617\ Transwestern, 44 FERC at 61,536. The 1989 El Paso order 
    cited by VT DPS and Valero (47 FERC para.61,108) reiterated the 
    policy established in Transwestern concerning exit fees in the 
    context of GICs. The El Paso order is distinguishable from our 
    approach to exit fees in Order No. 888 for the same reasons as 
    Transwestern.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        That mechanism included a fixed take-or-pay charge analogous to the 
    direct assignment provisions of Order No. 888. The Commission permitted 
    pipelines to allocate to sales customers who converted from sales to 
    transportation the same fixed take-or-pay charge that those customers 
    would have been allocated had they not converted.618 Moreover, in 
    a later order involving Transwestern's recovery of take-or-pay 
    settlement costs under its Order No. 500 equitable sharing mechanism, 
    the Commission expressly held:
    
        \618\ Natural Gas Pipe Line Company, 46 FERC para. 61,335 at 
    62,013 (``Consistent with the court's holding in AGD, that Part 284 
    transportation and CD conversion must be accompanied by take-or-pay 
    relief, the Commission finds that a pipeline's sales customers who 
    convert to transportation must continue to be liable for the take-
    or-pay costs allocated to them without regard to the fact that they 
    are no longer sales customers but only transportation customers.''), 
    reh'g denied, 47 FERC para.61,247 (1989); Transwestern Pipeline 
    Company, 65 FERC para.61,060 at 61,473 (1993), reh'g denied, 66 FERC 
    para.61,287 at 61,827-828 (1994), aff'd sub nom. Western Resources, 
    Inc. v. FERC, 72 F.3d 147 (D.C. Cir. 1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In appropriate circumstances, the Commission may approve exit 
    fees for departing customers, either through a condition on the 
    abandonment of the purchase obligation of customers subject to the 
    Commission's jurisdiction or through tariff language giving 
    appropriate notice of such a fee before the departure.[619]]
    
        \619\ Transwestern Pipeline Company, 64 FERC para.61,145 at 
    62,166 (1993), reh'g denied, 66 FERC para.61,287 (1994). However, as 
    illustrated by the situation described in the cited Transwestern 
    order, some sales customers had departed altogether from the systems 
    of their historical pipeline suppliers before the Commission 
    recognized the need for continued allocation of Order No. 500 take-
    or-pay costs to those customers. In these circumstances, the filed 
    rate doctrine prevented such continued allocation.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As discussed in the preceding section of this order, the direct 
    assignment provisions of Order No. 888, in essence, require that 
    certain electric generation customers who convert to transmission-only 
    service continue, for a period, to bear certain generation costs that 
    they were previously bearing. That requirement is similar to the 
    Commission's requirement, in connection with its Order No. 500 program, 
    that pipeline sales customers who convert to transportation-only 
    service continue to pay the same Order No. 500 fixed take-or-pay charge 
    as they would have paid had they not converted.
        VT DPS and Valero also claim that permitting electric utilities to 
    recover stranded generation costs through exit fees to customers 
    converting to transmission-only service is inconsistent with our 1995 
    order in El Paso,620 rejecting that pipeline's exit fee proposal. 
    We see no inconsistency. El Paso proposed, several years after its 
    restructuring pursuant to Order No. 636, to impose an exit fee on its 
    firm transportation customers who terminated or reduced their firm 
    transportation service. The fee was designed to require the departing 
    firm transportation customer to continue to pay a portion of El Paso's 
    fixed transmission costs for a period of time after the customer's 
    departure. The fee bore no relationship to El Paso's pre-restructuring 
    merchant function, since it was designed to recover El Paso's costs of 
    performing open access transportation service after its restructuring.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \620\ 72 FERC para.61,083 (1995).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In both Order No. 888 and this order, we are acting consistently 
    with El Paso. Similar to our refusal in El Paso to permit a pipeline to 
    impose an exit fee on customers departing its transportation system 
    altogether (whether for all or a portion of their firm service), so 
    also here we are refusing to permit electric utilities to recover 
    stranded costs from customers who depart their transmission systems 
    altogether. We believe that, in that situation, there is no direct 
    nexus between the customer's departure (and the stranding of costs) and 
    Commission-required transmission access, since the customer is not 
    using its former supplier's open access tariff to reach an alternative 
    power supplier.
        Order No. 888 thus permits an exit fee only to electric generation 
    customers who, although they stop purchasing power from the utility, 
    become transmission-only customers of the former supplying 
    utility.621 By contrast,
    
    [[Page 12396]]
    
    El Paso proposed an exit fee to transmission customers terminating 
    their transmission service. In short, the exit fee we have found 
    acceptable in Order No. 888 is related to the electric utility's pre-
    restructuring generation service, unlike El Paso's rejected exit fee, 
    which bore no relationship to El Paso's pre-restructuring merchant 
    service.622
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \621\ In Order Nos. 636-A and 636-B, the Commission not only 
    rejected exit fees where the customer left the system altogether, 
    but also found exit fees unnecessary for the recovery of GSR costs 
    in the circumstance in which a bundled sales customer converts to 
    transportation-only service. See Order No. 636-B, 61 FERC para. 
    61,272 at 62,041 (1992). Exit fees were unnecessary in the latter 
    circumstance because under the Commission's method of allocating GSR 
    costs to all firm transportation customers based on their contract 
    demands, a former bundled sales customer would pay the same GSR 
    costs after terminating its sales service (through the volumetric 
    surcharge on transportation) as it would if it had remained as a 
    sales customer.
        \622\ As we explained in Order No. 888, the Commission did not 
    treat a notice of termination provision in El Paso's contract as a 
    conclusive presumption that El Paso had no reasonable expectation of 
    continuing to serve certain customers, as VT DPS and Valero contend. 
    FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,802, note 639; mimeo at 489, note 639. 
    Instead, the July 1995 El Paso order acknowledged that the April 
    1995 Supplemental Stranded Cost NOPR had proposed that the existence 
    of a notice of termination provision in a contract be treated as a 
    ``rebuttable'' presumption of no reasonable expectation. On that 
    basis, the Commission suggested in dicta that ``[e]ven if the rules 
    proposed in [the Supplemental Stranded Cost] NOPR were applied here 
    [which they were not], El Paso would have difficulty justifying'' 
    its exit fee proposal under the NOPR's reasonable expectation 
    standard given the existence of a notice of termination provision in 
    the contract. 72 FERC at 61,441 (emphasis added).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Finally, VT DPS's and Valero's comments concerning the Commission's 
    treatment of Order No. 636 ``stranded costs'' attempt to make 
    distinctions that do not make a difference for purposes of the 
    Commission's treatment of Order No. 888 stranded costs. We have 
    explained above that the electric industry's transition to an open 
    transmission access, competitive industry is different in a number of 
    respects from the natural gas industry's transition to open access 
    transportation service by interstate natural gas pipelines. We also 
    have explained why a different approach to recovery of legitimate, 
    prudent and verifiable stranded costs in the electric industry is 
    justified. On this basis, the Commission's definition and treatment of 
    ``stranded'' costs under Order No. 636 need not dictate our definition 
    and treatment of stranded costs under Order No. 888. In any event, in 
    response to VT DPS's and Valero's request that the Commission limit 
    utility stranded cost claims solely to those cases where the utility 
    can demonstrate that its costs have been rendered unrecoverable as a 
    direct result of the Rule,623 we note that Order No. 888 does 
    require a causal nexus between the availability and use of Commission-
    required transmission access and the stranding of costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \623\ Under their proposal, it appears that costs would be 
    ``unrecoverable'' only if there were no wholesale load from which to 
    recover the costs. This would result in shifting costs to customers 
    that had no responsibility for causing them to be incurred or for 
    causing them to be stranded. In Order No. 888, we rejected such an 
    approach as fundamentally unfair and as inconsistent with the well-
    established principle of cost causation.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests Opposing Recovery of Stranded Costs in Transmission 
    Rates
    
        VT DPS and Valero submit that although the Commission has not 
    proposed to depart from cost-based ratemaking methodologies in 
    establishing transmission rates, Order No. 888 contravenes cost 
    causation principles by recovering generating costs in transmission 
    rates.624 They argue that although the court in KN Energy held 
    that the Commission might depart from strict cost-causation principles 
    to permit pipelines to recover gas supply costs from transportation 
    customers in extraordinary circumstances, the ``extraordinary 
    circumstances'' were that the pipelines had no remaining sales 
    customers and thus were left with no vehicle for recovering gas supply 
    costs. On this basis, the court approved a mechanism under which gas 
    supply costs were spread over virtually all transmission users. They 
    describe as incongruous the Commission's claim in Order No. 888 that 
    permitting direct assignment of stranded power costs in a transmission 
    rate is a cost-based approach.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \624\ In support of this argument, they cite CPUC v. FERC, 894 
    F.2d 1372, 1380-81 (D.C. Cir. 1990) as standing for the proposition 
    that, in a cost-based transmission rate, there is no logical basis 
    for including gas-supply related expenses or savings in the rates 
    for customers who take only transmission service. See also American 
    Forest & Paper (no justification for including excess generation 
    costs in transmission rates).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        VT DPS and Valero further argue that even if the Commission were 
    inclined to justify stranded cost recovery from departing customers on 
    non-cost grounds, the Commission cannot show that the circumstances 
    justifying similar cost recovery from gas pipeline transportation 
    customers exist at the wholesale level in the electric industry 
    because: (1) unlike its approach to gas pipelines, the Commission has 
    not proposed to allow existing wholesale electric customers to get out 
    of their contracts early; (2) there is no industry-wide problem; 
    wholesale sales account for only a small fraction of the total business 
    of regulated electric utilities, while gas pipelines had virtually all 
    wholesale sales; and (3) direct assignment of generating costs only to 
    departing customers is the antithesis of the cost-spreading rationale 
    that provided the justification for the limited departure from cost-
    causation principles permitted in KN Energy. They contend that, in any 
    event, the Commission cannot spread costs broadly even if they are 
    recovered from all transmission customers because the largest users are 
    retail customers that would be exempt from wholesale stranded cost 
    surcharges.
        A number of other entities also oppose the recovery of stranded 
    generation costs in transmission rates.625 Some of them contend 
    that section 212(a) of the FPA limits the transmitting utility to the 
    recovery of transmission-related costs.626 PA Munis contends that 
    the plain language of section 212, as amended by EPAct, limits the 
    rates that can be charged under a section 211 order to those `` `which 
    permit the recovery by such utility of all the costs incurred in 
    connection with the transmission services and necessary associated 
    services * * * '''627 PA Munis contends that Congress would not 
    have limited recovery to the costs incurred in connection with the 
    transmission services and necessary associated services if it had 
    intended to allow the transmission rates to include part of a utility's 
    costs for unused generation facilities completely unrelated to the cost 
    of the transmission facilities.628 PA Munis asserts that the 
    legislative history of EPAct supports its position that there is no 
    authorization for the Commission to include unused generation costs as 
    part of the transmission costs that are allocable to transmission under 
    section 212.629
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \625\ E.g., TX Com, APPA, IN Consumer Counselor, IN Consumers, 
    PA Munis, AR Com, MO/KS Coms.
        \626\ E.g., APPA, PA Munis, IN Consumer Counselor, IN Consumers.
        \627\ PA Munis at 28. PA Munis also argues that the last 
    sentence of section 212(a) makes it clear that the ``rates, charges 
    * * * for transmission services provided pursuant to an order under 
    section 211 shall ensure that to the extent practicable, costs 
    incurred in providing the wholesale transmission services, and 
    properly allocable to the provision of such services are recovered * 
    * *. ' '' (emphasis added by PA Munis).
        \628\ See also IN Consumers, IN Consumer Counselor.
        \629\ PA Munis cites in support the following excerpt from House 
    Report No. 102-474, Part I: This section [211] also provides that 
    FERC shall permit the transmitting utility to recover all prudent 
    costs incurred in connection with providing transmission services, 
    plus a reasonable return on investment, including an appropriate 
    share of the costs of any enlargement of transmission facilities 
    necessary to provide such service. H.R. Rep. No. 102-474, Part I, 
    102d Cong., 2d Sess. 194 (1992), reprinted in 1992 U.S.C.C.A.N. 
    1959, 2017 (emphasis supplied by PA Munis).
    
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [[Page 12397]]
    
        AR Com and MO/KS Coms argue that the FPA does not allow the 
    Commission to include costs in a transmission rate that are not caused 
    by the provision of transmission service.630 MO/KS Coms contend 
    that retail stranded costs are largely generation costs that were not 
    caused by any request to use transmission service or by any actual 
    transmission usage, and are not an opportunity cost of providing 
    transmission service. Citing the language in section 212 of the FPA 
    allowing the transmitting utility to recover ``all costs incurred in 
    connection with the transmission services and necessary associated 
    services,'' AR Com contends that nowhere does the Energy Policy Act or 
    any other relevant statute authorize the collection of retail, non-
    transmission costs through transmission rates.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \630\ They cite in support of this proposition Farmers Union 
    Central Exchange, Inc. v. FERC, 734 F.2d 1486 (D.C. Cir.), cert. 
    denied, Williams Pipe Line Company v. Farmers Union Central 
    Exchange, Inc., 469 U.S. 1034 (1984).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We disagree with VT DPS's and Valero's argument that Order No. 888 
    contravenes cost causation principles by recovering generating costs in 
    transmission rates. As the court in United Distribution Companies 
    stated: `` `Cost causation' correlates costs with those customers for 
    whom a service is rendered or a cost is incurred.'' 631 Whether 
    stranded costs are recovered through a surcharge on the transmission 
    rates of a departing generation customer, or through an exit fee, the 
    point is that under Order No. 888 they are recovered from the customer 
    that caused them to be incurred. The only distinction is the mechanism 
    by which they are recovered from that customer.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \631\ 88 F.3d at 1188-89.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission is not aware of any prohibition on permitting 
    recovery through a transmission rate of what has traditionally been 
    recovered through the generation component of a rate, so long as the 
    utility does not double recover and the customer does not pay more than 
    the costs that it caused to be incurred.632 Indeed, the Commission 
    has been upheld in permitting opportunity costs (foregone economic 
    savings) to be charged as a transmission rate when they are higher than 
    a traditional embedded cost transmission rate.633 There is no 
    significant difference between an ``opportunity cost'' component of a 
    transmission rate and a stranded cost charge imposed through 
    transmission rates. Both concern the recovery of generation costs. To 
    be sure, in the former case these generation costs are incurred by 
    reason of using high cost generation instead of substituting lower cost 
    generation, and in the latter case the costs are ``incurred'' by reason 
    of the loss of a customer.634 But, for purposes of cost recovery, 
    these are distinctions without a difference. In both situations, the 
    transmission rate is used to recover something other than the capital, 
    operating, and maintenance costs of facilities used to provide the 
    transmission service at issue. If the Commission were without authority 
    to provide for cost recovery of these other types of costs in 
    transmission rates, the court would not have affirmed the volumetric 
    surcharge on transportation in KN Energy, nor would it have affirmed 
    the opportunity cost charge in Penelec.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \632\ Additionally, we note that a stranded cost surcharge to 
    transmission is merely a vehicle for collecting the exit fee. The 
    surcharge would be in effect only until the stranded cost obligation 
    is met. It is not a component of the transmission rate in the sense 
    that a transmission customer who uses a very large amount of 
    transmission while the rate is in effect would pay more than its 
    stranded cost obligation.
        \633\ See Pennsylvania Electric Company v. FERC, 11 F.3d 207 
    (D.C. Cir. 1993) (Penelec). As the Commission explained, opportunity 
    costs are the actual costs that a utility incurs by providing 
    transmission service to a customer instead of using the transmission 
    itself to reduce its generation costs on behalf of its native load 
    (i.e., the foregone economy energy transfers). Pennsylvania Electric 
    Company, 60 FERC para.61,034 at 61,120, 61,126 (1992), aff'd, 
    Penelec, 11 F.3d 207.
        \634\ Technically, the costs in the latter situation were 
    previously incurred as a result of investment by the utility on 
    behalf of the departing customer. However, the costs are 
    ``incurred'' in the sense of becoming stranded when the customer 
    leaves the utility's system. In both situations, recovery of the 
    costs is permitted through transmission rates in order to keep the 
    utility (and its other customers) from unfairly suffering economic 
    losses as a result of providing transmission to others.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As we note above, we are not proposing a departure from strict 
    cost-causation principles such as that allowed in KN Energy, where the 
    pipeline was allowed to recover 50 percent of its take-or-pay 
    settlement costs through a volumetric surcharge on all transportation 
    customers, including those that had never purchased gas from the 
    pipeline.635 Because we disagree with VT DPS's and Valero's 
    position that recovery of stranded costs through a surcharge on 
    transmission constitutes recovery on non-cost grounds,636 we will 
    reject their requests for rehearing on this issue.637
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \635\ Moreover, we note that, in addressing the natural gas 
    industry's transition costs, the Commission did rely on traditional 
    cost causation principles in approving pipeline proposals to 
    allocate fixed take-or-pay charges to sales customers converting to 
    transportation-only service. See Transwestern Pipeline Company, 65 
    FERC para.61,060 at 61,473 (1993), reh'g denied, 66 FERC para.61,287 
    at 61,825-28 (1994). The Commission found that the pipelines entered 
    into their take-or-pay contracts to serve their sales customers. The 
    conversion of those customers to open access transportation required 
    pipelines to enter into settlements with producers to shed gas 
    supplies. Therefore, there was a causal connection between the 
    customer's conversion and the pipeline's incurrence of the take-or-
    pay settlement costs. Here, there is a similar causal connection 
    between the stranding of generation investment made on behalf of a 
    wholesale customer and that customer's decision to use Commission-
    mandated open access transmission to reach a new supplier.
        \636\ The case on which VT DPS and Valero rely, CPUC v. FERC, 
    involved the disposition of a pipeline's production-related deferred 
    tax reserve when the switch to NGPA pricing mooted application of 
    tax normalization (which sought to match the timing of a customer's 
    contribution toward a cost with enjoyment of any offsetting tax 
    benefit). The Commission's decision not to credit the deferred tax 
    reserve to current users of the pipeline's transmission service was 
    based, among other things, on a determination that the deferred tax 
    fund was completely unrelated to the pipeline's transmission 
    service. See 894 F.2d at 1378-80. In contrast, as discussed below, 
    the costs for which this Rule provides an opportunity for recovery 
    would not have been stranded but for Commission-mandated 
    transmission access.
        \637\ We also reject AR Com's argument that the Farmers Union 
    case prohibits the Commission from allowing the recovery of non-
    transmission costs in a transmission rate in the limited 
    circumstances proposed in Order No. 888. The issues before the court 
    in that case are distinguishable from the recovery of stranded 
    generation costs in transmission rates. Farmer's Union involved the 
    court's review of a Commission order establishing maximum rate 
    ceilings to be applied to oil pipelines in which the Commission 
    invoked non-cost factors (the need to stimulate additional oil 
    pipeline capacity) as one reason for setting high maximum rates. The 
    use of non-cost factors was itself not at issue. Rather, the court 
    found that the Commission had ``failed to specify in any detail how 
    `non-cost' factors, such as the need to stimulate additional 
    pipeline capacity, might justify its decision to set maximum rates 
    at such high levels.'' 734 F.2d at 1501. In Order No. 888, in 
    contrast, the Commission has fully explained the basis for giving 
    utilities an opportunity to recover stranded costs from departing 
    customers through a surcharge to the customers' transmission rates.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We also reject the argument that section 212 of the FPA prohibits 
    the recovery of stranded generation costs in transmission rates. There 
    is nothing on the face of the statute or in its legislative history to 
    support this position. In fact, section 212(a) permits recovery of 
    ``legitimate, verifiable and economic costs'' of providing transmission 
    service. Stranded costs clearly are an economic cost of providing 
    transmission when the stranding results from the ordered transmission 
    service. By definition, the costs for which this Rule provides an 
    opportunity for recovery would not have been stranded but for 
    Commission-mandated transmission access. Stranded costs under this Rule 
    are the costs that a utility incurred to provide service to a customer 
    based on a reasonable expectation that the utility would continue to 
    serve the customer beyond the term of their contract, and that become 
    stranded when the customer uses Commission-mandated
    
    [[Page 12398]]
    
    transmission access to reach a new generation supplier. In this 
    respect, stranded costs, like opportunity costs,638 are not costs 
    associated with the actual facilities used to provide transmission 
    service. Rather, they are an ``economic cost'' of providing the 
    transmission service at issue.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \638\ See note 633 supra.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    4. Recovery of Stranded Costs Associated With New Wholesale 
    Requirements Contracts
        In Order No. 888, we concluded that future wholesale requirements 
    contracts should explicitly address the mutual obligations of the 
    seller and buyer, including the seller's obligation to continue to 
    serve the buyer, if any, and the buyer's obligation, if any, if it 
    changes suppliers. This means that utilities must address potential 
    stranded cost issues when negotiating new contracts or be held strictly 
    accountable for the failure to do so.
        We stated that we will allow recovery of wholesale stranded costs 
    associated with any new requirements contract (executed after July 11, 
    1994, or extended or renegotiated to be effective after July 11, 1994) 
    only if explicit stranded cost provisions are contained in the 
    contract. We defined ``explicit stranded cost provision'' (for 
    contracts executed after July 11, 1994) as a provision that identifies 
    the specific amount of stranded cost liability of the customer(s) and a 
    specific method for calculating the stranded cost charge or rate. 
    However, for purposes of requirements contracts executed after July 11, 
    1994 but before May 10, 1996 (the date on which Order No. 888 was 
    published in the Federal Register), we clarified that a provision that 
    specifically reserved the right to seek stranded cost recovery 
    consistent with what the Commission permits in the Final Rule (without 
    identifying the specific amount of stranded cost liability of the 
    customer(s) and calculation method) nevertheless will be deemed an 
    ``explicit stranded cost provision.'' On the other hand, a provision in 
    a requirements contract executed after July 11, 1994 but before May 10, 
    1996 that merely postpones the issue of stranded cost recovery without 
    specifically providing for such recovery will not be considered an 
    ``explicit stranded cost provision.'' We said that, after May 10, 1996, 
    a provision must identify the specific amount of stranded cost 
    liability of the customer(s) and a specific method for calculating the 
    stranded cost charge or rate in order to constitute an ``explicit 
    stranded cost provision.'' 639
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \639\ See Orange and Rockland Utilities, Inc., 76 FERC para. 
    61,037 (1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We also concluded that a requirements contract that is extended or 
    renegotiated for an effective date after July 11, 1994 becomes a 
    ``new'' requirements contract for which stranded cost recovery will be 
    allowed only if explicitly provided for in the contract.
        We decided not to impose a regulatory obligation on wholesale 
    requirements suppliers to continue to serve the power needs of their 
    existing requirements customers beyond the end of the contract term. 
    The only exception to this would be if the customer decides to remain a 
    requirements customer for the period for which the Commission finds 
    that the supplying utility reasonably expected to continue serving the 
    customer. In such a case, the supplying utility will be obligated to 
    offer continuing service to the requirements customer for the period 
    the utility reasonably expected to continue serving the customer.
        We also decided to no longer require prior notice of termination 
    under section 35.15 for any power sales contract executed on or after 
    July 9, 1996 (the effective date of the Final Rule pro forma tariff) 
    that is to terminate by its own terms (such as on the contract's 
    expiration date), but to require written notification of the 
    termination of such contract within 30 days after termination takes 
    place. We said that we will continue to require prior notice of the 
    proposed termination of any power sales contract executed before July 
    9, 1996 (even if the contract is to terminate by its own terms) as well 
    as any unexecuted power sales contract that was filed before that date.
        Further, we decided to retain the section 35.15 filing requirement 
    for all transmission contracts because the Commission must be assured 
    that transmission owners are not exerting market power in negotiating 
    or terminating transmission contracts. This filing requirement will 
    provide the customer an opportunity to notify the Commission if the 
    termination terms are disputed or if the customer was not given 
    adequate opportunity to exercise its limited right of first refusal 
    under the Final Rule (see Section IV.A.5).640
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \640\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,804-06; mimeo at 497-501.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Requests for Rehearing
    
        Utilities For Improved Transition asks the Commission either to 
    clarify that it will enforce stranded cost provisions as agreed to by 
    the parties and accepted for filing by the Commission (presumably even 
    if they do not meet the definition of ``explicit stranded cost 
    provision'' contained in the Preamble 641), or to modify the 
    definition contained in the Preamble (and add the term to the list of 
    definitions in section 35.26(b)) to give contracting parties the option 
    of specifying either a specific amount of stranded cost liability or a 
    formula for calculating the stranded cost charge or rate. Utilities For 
    Improved Transition contends that, particularly in the case of long-
    term contracts, the parties may not be able to quantify what the 
    stranded cost liability will be at the time they enter into a contract.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \641\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,805; mimeo at 497.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several entities assert that if the Commission is to permit 
    recovery for stranded costs, it should include a symmetrical mechanism 
    to permit customers with below-market rates or net undervalued assets a 
    means to continue to receive power at below-market rates if the 
    customer had a reasonable expectation of continued service.642 OH 
    Consumers' Counsel objects that the only exception in Order No. 888 to 
    the Commission's decision not to impose a regulatory obligation on a 
    utility to continue to serve existing requirements customers beyond the 
    end of the contract ``would be if the customer decides to remain a 
    requirements customer for the period for which the Commission finds 
    that the supplying utility reasonably expected to continue serving the 
    customer.'' 643 According to OH Consumers' Counsel, this language 
    nullifies the customer's reasonable expectation of continuation of 
    service under its existing contractual arrangement.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \642\ E.g., TDU Systems, OH Consumers' Counsel. TDU Systems 
    proposes that the Commission give a requirements customer the choice 
    of extending its existing contract at existing rates for a period 
    corresponding to the customer's expectation of continued service or 
    receiving a payment from the utility consisting of the difference 
    between what the customer must pay for new supplies and what it paid 
    under the contract. TDU Systems describes the latter option as a 
    ``benefits lost'' approach modeled after the ``revenues lost'' 
    approach of Order No. 888.
        \643\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,805; mimeo at 498 (emphasis 
    added by OH Consumers' Counsel).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        TDU Systems similarly says that the Commission has not explained 
    why the suppliers' expectations are to be honored, but the customers' 
    expectations are not. TDU Systems objects that the Commission failed to 
    explain why it rejected allowing requirements customers to demonstrate 
    a reasonable expectation that they would continue to be able to obtain 
    supplies of power at rates based on embedded cost after the expiration 
    of
    
    [[Page 12399]]
    
    their supply contracts. TDU Systems submits that the case for providing 
    extra-contractual relief to wholesale purchasers is more compelling 
    than the case for providing extra-contractual relief to wholesale 
    suppliers. It argues that it is likely that some cooperatives and 
    municipal utilities would not survive the drastic impact to their 
    businesses that the elimination of cost-based rates could bring.
        OH Consumers' Counsel submits that the filing of a section 206 
    complaint by customers of utilities with rates below market does not 
    provide adequate protection or symmetry for the customers. It contends 
    that a section 206 case is an inadequate remedy because: (1) the 
    utility holds all of the necessary information for analyzing such a 
    case, but the procedure shifts the burden of proof from the utility to 
    the customer; and (2) it provides only delayed relief for parties who 
    could be irreparably harmed by the imposition of the market-based 
    rates.
        TDU Systems argues that eliminating the prior notice of termination 
    requirement in section 35.15 for post-July 9, 1996 wholesale 
    requirements contracts will result in discrimination and 
    monopolization. It contends that the Commission closes its eyes to the 
    fact that termination of a requirements contract can affect 100 percent 
    of a customer's power supply, while it is likely to affect less than 10 
    percent of a large public utility's load. It submits that eliminating 
    the prior notice of termination requirement is tantamount to finding 
    that termination of all such contracts by their terms will be just and 
    reasonable, but that no such finding can presently be supported. TDU 
    Systems maintains that there remains significant market power in the 
    markets in which transmission dependent utilities, especially small 
    transmission dependent utilities, operate. It recommends that the 
    Commission use section 35.15 to require that wholesale contracts not be 
    terminated unless such termination is just and reasonable.
        PA Munis objects that the Commission did not specifically address 
    in Order No. 888 its proposal that contracts approved after July 11, 
    1994 (but executed before that date) be treated as new contracts. It 
    submits that under the Commission's reasoning in setting the July 11, 
    1994 cut-off date, utilities that executed requirements contracts after 
    that date had no reasonable expectation that they would be permitted to 
    recover costs by seeking to amend the contract. It argues that the same 
    reasoning applies where the contract was executed but not approved or 
    accepted by the Commission by the July 11, 1994 notice date.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We will clarify the definition of ``explicit stranded cost 
    provision'' for requirements contracts executed after July 11, 1994. As 
    long as the contracting parties are in agreement, a provision in a 
    post-July 11, 1994 requirements contract will be considered an 
    ``explicit stranded cost provision'' if it identifies either the 
    specific amount of stranded cost liability of the customer or a 
    specific method for calculating the stranded cost charge or rate.
        We will reject the arguments of TDU Systems and OH Consumers' 
    Counsel that ``symmetry'' requires that the Commission provide a 
    generic mechanism in this Rule to allow existing requirements customers 
    with below-market rates a means to continue to receive power beyond the 
    contract term at the pre-existing contract rate if the customer had a 
    reasonable expectation of continued service. Unlike the generic 
    findings we have made with respect to extra-contractual recovery of 
    stranded costs associated with requirements contracts executed on or 
    before July 11, 1994, we do not have a sufficient basis on which to 
    make generic findings that customers under such contracts may be 
    entitled to extend a contract at the existing rate. Utilities' 
    expectations may have resulted in millions of dollars of investments on 
    behalf of certain customers and the possibility of shifting the costs 
    of those investments to other customers that did not cause the costs to 
    be incurred. In the case of customers' expectations, however, even if 
    customers generally expected to stay on a supplier's system beyond the 
    contract term, it is not likely that most customers could have expected 
    to continue service at the existing rate unless specified in the 
    contract. Moreover, the consequences of customers' expectations as a 
    general matter would not have the potential to shift significant costs 
    to other customers.
        Nevertheless, our conclusion that we cannot make generic findings 
    or provide a generic formula for addressing this issue does not mean 
    that a customer under a contract may not exercise its procedural rights 
    under section 206 to show that the contract should be extended at the 
    existing contract rate,644 or to make such a showing in the 
    context of a utility's proposed termination of a contract pursuant to 
    the section 35.15 notice of termination (approval) requirement, which 
    we have retained for power supply contracts executed prior to July 9, 
    1996 (the effective date of the Rule).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \644\ If the customer under a contract has not waived its rights 
    to seek changes to the contract, it may exercise its procedural 
    rights under section 206 to show that failure to extend the contract 
    at the existing contract rate would not be just and reasonable. If 
    the customer has waived its rights to challenge the contract (i.e., 
    it is bound by a Mobile-Sierra standard), it may exercise its rights 
    under section 206 to show that it would be contrary to the public 
    interest not to extend the contract at the existing rate. Although 
    OH Consumers' Counsel objects that a section 206 proceeding is an 
    inadequate remedy because it places the burden of proof on the 
    customer, we believe that it is appropriate that the customer, as 
    the complainant in such a case, bear the burden of proof.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We believe that while the relationship between utilities and their 
    wholesale requirements customers may have given rise to an inference or 
    expectation on the part of the wholesale requirements customer that the 
    contract would continue beyond the stated term, it is not clear to what 
    extent a customer could demonstrate a reasonable expectation that such 
    continued service would be at the existing contract rate (which may be 
    below the market price). This is particularly the case for contracts in 
    which the utility has not waived its unilateral right to make section 
    205 filings to change the rates. Even in contracts where rates were 
    fixed for the contract term, however, if the utility were to agree to 
    extend such a contract for a new term, the rates under that contract 
    would not necessarily have remained the same. On this basis, a customer 
    may be able to demonstrate that it had a reasonable expectation of 
    continued service beyond the contract term, but not necessarily at the 
    same rate level. It is for this reason that we believe this issue must 
    be addressed on a case-by-case basis and that this Rule is not the 
    proper mechanism for granting the relief sought by TDU Systems and OH 
    Consumers Counsel.
        Nevertheless, we do not intend to prejudge whether a requirements 
    customer could ever make a showing that it reasonably expected service 
    beyond the contract term at the existing contract price. Nor do we 
    intend to preclude a customer from attempting to make such a showing in 
    appropriate circumstances.
        We also believe that we adequately addressed in Order No. 888 TDU 
    Systems' argument that elimination of the prior notice of termination 
    requirement in section 35.15 for post-July 9, 1996, wholesale 
    requirements contracts will result in discrimination and 
    monopolization. As we stated in Order No. 888, we believe that the 
    concerns of TDU Systems can be fully addressed without retaining the 
    section
    
    [[Page 12400]]
    
    35.15 prior notice of termination requirement for post-July 9, 1996 
    contracts. While we have agreed to provide for extra-contractual 
    stranded cost recovery as a transition matter, it is our objective 
    that, prospectively, parties should address their mutual expectations 
    clearly through contract terms that explicitly address the mutual 
    obligations of the seller and buyer at contract expiration. This would 
    include the seller's obligation to continue to serve the buyer after 
    contract expiration, if any. If the customer believes that termination 
    of its contract at the end of the term would not be just and reasonable 
    (or, in the case of a Mobile-Sierra contract, would not be in the 
    public interest), it can file a complaint with the Commission under 
    section 206 of the FPA.
        We will reject PA Munis' request that contracts approved after July 
    11, 1994 (but executed before that date) be treated as ``new'' 
    contracts for purposes of stranded cost recovery because modifying the 
    notice date at this point in the proceeding would work an inequitable 
    result. Beginning with the initial stranded cost NOPR, the Commission 
    put entities on notice that contracts ``executed'' on or before July 
    11, 1994 would constitute ``existing'' contracts. Although a utility 
    arguably could have amended such an existing contract to include an 
    explicit stranded cost provision prior to its (post-July 11, 1994) 
    approval by the Commission, the NOPR did not require the utility to do 
    so. As a result, it would be unfair for the Commission to change the 
    cut-off terms now.
    5. Recovery of Stranded Costs Associated With Existing Wholesale 
    Requirements Contracts
        In Order No. 888,645 the Commission concluded that it would 
    permit utilities the opportunity to seek recovery of legitimate, 
    prudent and verifiable stranded costs for ``existing'' wholesale 
    requirements contracts (executed on or before July 11, 1994) that do 
    not already contain exit fees or other explicit stranded cost 
    provisions.646 We explained why we believe that July 11, 1994--the 
    date on which the initial Stranded Cost NOPR was published and, thus, 
    on which the industry was put on notice of the proposal to disallow 
    prospectively extra-contractual recovery of stranded costs--is the 
    appropriate date for distinguishing ``existing'' requirements contracts 
    from ``new'' requirements contracts.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \645\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,809-814; mimeo at 510-24.
        \646\ We explained that if an existing requirements contract 
    includes an explicit provision for payment of stranded costs or an 
    exit fee, we will assume that the parties intended the contract to 
    cover the contingency of the buyer leaving the system, and we will 
    reject a stranded cost amendment to such a contract unless the 
    contract permits renegotiation of the existing stranded cost 
    provision or the parties to the contract mutually agree to a new 
    stranded cost provision. Similarly, we said that we will reject a 
    stranded cost amendment to an existing requirements contract if the 
    contract prohibits stranded cost recovery (or precludes recovery for 
    termination or reduction of service) or prohibits renegotiation of 
    an existing stranded cost or exit fee provision, unless the parties 
    to the contract mutually agree to a new stranded cost provision.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We noted our desire that utilities attempt to renegotiate with 
    their customers existing requirements contracts that do not contain 
    exit fees or other explicit stranded cost provisions. If a contract is 
    not renegotiated to add such a provision, we explained that, before the 
    expiration of the contract: (1) A public utility or its customer may 
    file a proposed stranded cost amendment to the contract under sections 
    205 or 206; or (2) a public utility in a section 205 proceeding, or a 
    transmitting utility in a section 211 proceeding, may file a proposal 
    to recover stranded costs associated with any such existing contract 
    through its transmission rates for a customer that uses the utility's 
    transmission system to reach another generation supplier.
        We also concluded that, even if an existing requirements contract 
    contains an explicit Mobile-Sierra 647 provision, it is in the 
    public interest to permit the public utility to seek a unilateral 
    amendment to add stranded cost provisions if the contract does not 
    already contain exit fees or other explicit stranded cost 
    provisions.648 We explained why our determination that it is in 
    the public interest to give public utilities a limited opportunity to 
    propose contract changes unilaterally to address stranded costs if 
    their contracts do not already explicitly do so satisfies the public 
    interest standard of the Mobile-Sierra doctrine. We also indicated that 
    customers with Mobile-Sierra contracts that do not explicitly address 
    stranded costs may file complaints under section 206 of the FPA to 
    propose to address stranded costs in existing requirements contracts.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \647\ See United Gas Pipeline Company v. Mobile Gas Service 
    Corporation, 350 U.S. 332 (1956); FPC v. Sierra Pacific Power 
    Company, 350 U.S. 348 (1956).
        \648\ As a complement to our finding that, notwithstanding a 
    Mobile-Sierra clause in an existing requirements contract, it is in 
    the public interest to permit amendments to add stranded cost 
    provisions to such contracts if the public utility proposing the 
    amendment can meet the evidentiary requirements of this Rule, we 
    concluded that customers under Mobile-Sierra contracts ought to have 
    the opportunity to demonstrate that their contracts no longer are 
    just and reasonable.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We concluded that a public utility or its customer should be 
    allowed to file a proposed stranded cost amendment, or a public utility 
    or transmitting utility should be allowed to file a proposal to recover 
    stranded costs through a departing generation customer's transmission 
    rates, at any time prior to the expiration of the contract.
    
    Rehearing Requests--July 11, 1994 Cut-Off Date
    
        Utilities For Improved Transition, repeating an argument raised in 
    previous comments in this proceeding, objects to the Commission's July 
    11, 1994 cut-off date for distinguishing between ``existing'' and 
    ``new'' requirements contracts. It argues that stranded cost recovery 
    should be assured for all contracts executed before the effective date 
    of the Rule (i.e., July 9, 1996), not just those executed before July 
    11, 1994. It asserts that parties to contracts executed after July 11, 
    1994 but before July 9, 1996 should have the same opportunity as 
    parties to pre-July 11, 1994 contracts to offer evidence as to their 
    reasonable expectations. Utilities For Improved Transition asserts that 
    agencies may not promulgate retroactive rules without express statutory 
    authority,649 and that the FPA does not give the Commission such 
    statutory authority.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \649\ Citing Motion Picture Association of America v. Oman, 969 
    F.2d 1154 (1992); Bowen v. Georgetown University Hospital, 488 U.S. 
    204 (1988).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Puget raises a somewhat different point. It notes that the 
    definition of a ``new'' requirements contract as ``any wholesale 
    requirements contract * * * extended or renegotiated to be effective 
    after July 11, 1994'' (emphasis added) was not proposed until March 29, 
    1995 (in the supplemental stranded cost NOPR). Puget states that the 
    initial stranded cost NOPR proposed to give a utility three years from 
    the date of Federal Register publication of the final stranded cost 
    rule to negotiate or to file for stranded cost recovery. According to 
    Puget, the March 1995 supplemental stranded cost NOPR proposed a 
    retroactive change by defining a contract executed prior to July 11, 
    1994 but extended or renegotiated to be effective after that date as a 
    ``new'' contract and by removing the three-year window for negotiating 
    stranded cost recovery. By this change, Puget argues that the extension 
    of a contract between the date of Federal Register publication of the 
    initial NOPR (July 11, 1994) and the issuance of the supplemental NOPR 
    (March 29, 1995) may have converted it into a ``new'' rather than an 
    ``existing''
    
    [[Page 12401]]
    
    contract for stranded cost recovery purposes. Puget asks the Commission 
    to revise the definition of ``existing wholesale requirements 
    contract'' in Order No. 888 and 18 CFR 35.26 to include contracts 
    executed on or before July 11, 1994 that were extended prior to the 
    issuance of the supplemental stranded cost NOPR (March 29, 1995) and 
    for which stranded cost provisions were filed with the Commission prior 
    to issuance of Order No. 888. Puget submits that failure to do so would 
    be arbitrary and capricious and would deprive utilities with such 
    contracts of adequate notice of a proposed rule.650
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \650\ Puget notes that it executed a letter agreement with the 
    Port of Seattle on January 12, 1995 to continue in place the terms 
    of an existing contract until February 2, 1996, or the execution of 
    a new agreement, whichever was earlier. It says that the parties 
    were working within the context of the initial stranded cost NOPR, 
    which would have given Puget three years from the date of the 
    publication of the final rule to negotiate or file for stranded cost 
    recovery. However, based on the definition of ``new'' contract in 
    the Supplemental NOPR, the extension of the Puget/Port of Seattle 
    contract may have converted it into a ``new'' rather than an 
    ``existing'' contract for stranded cost recovery purposes. Puget 
    states that it filed an amendment to the contract on December 28, 
    1995, that included stranded cost recovery provisions. Those 
    provisions are pending in Docket Nos. ER96-714-000 and ER96-697-000. 
    On January 10, 1997, the presiding judge issued an Initial Decision 
    in Docket No. ER96-714-001 finding that Puget, by executing the 
    January 1995 letter agreement, had not waived its eligibility to 
    recover stranded costs. See Puget Sound Power & Light Company, 78 
    FERC para. 63,001 (1997).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We will reject Utilities For Improved Transition's rehearing 
    request because we believe that we adequately explained in Order No. 
    888 why adoption of the July 11, 1994 cut-off date is appropriate and 
    does not constitute retroactive rulemaking. We said in Order No. 888 
    that because all parties were put on notice in the initial stranded 
    cost NOPR that July 11, 1994 would be the operable date for the 
    ``existing''/``new'' contract distinction, utilities that executed 
    requirements contracts after that date could have had no reasonable 
    expectation that they would be permitted to recover any costs extra-
    contractually. Moreover, we explained that because the costs at issue 
    are extra-contractual costs, the Commission's notice to all parties 
    that contracts executed after July 11, 1994 (the date that the initial 
    NOPR was published in the Federal Register) will be enforced by their 
    terms as far as stranded cost recovery is concerned does not constitute 
    ``retroactive rulemaking.'' The Commission has merely put all parties 
    on notice that the opportunity for extra-contractual stranded cost 
    recovery would not be available for any requirements contracts executed 
    after July 11, 1994.
        The July 11, 1994 date is appropriate because it is the date on 
    which all interested parties were given notice in the Federal Register 
    that the recoverability of stranded costs for contracts executed on or 
    before that date that did not provide for such recovery was at issue. 
    The parties to requirements contracts executed after July 11, 1994 have 
    been free to provide for stranded cost recovery in the contract, or 
    not. The point is that, for requirements contracts executed after the 
    cut-off date, stranded cost recovery will be governed solely by the 
    terms of the contract.
        We believe that Puget has raised a valid point concerning the 
    potential impact of the Commission's decision in the March 29, 1995 
    supplemental stranded cost NOPR to treat extensions or renegotiations 
    of existing contracts as ``new'' contracts for stranded cost purposes 
    on parties that extended or renegotiated an existing contract prior to 
    March 29, 1995. However, we expect that the situation described by 
    Puget may be an isolated instance. On this basis, we do not believe it 
    necessary to modify the definition of ``existing wholesale requirements 
    contracts'' in Order No. 888 and 18 CFR 35.26 as requested by Puget. 
    Nevertheless, we clarify that we will consider on a case-by-case basis 
    whether to waive the provisions of 18 CFR 35.26 and to treat a contract 
    extended or renegotiated (without adding a stranded cost provision) to 
    be effective after July 11, 1994 but before March 29, 1995 as an 
    existing contract for stranded cost purposes.651
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \651\ As discussed in note 650, supra, the presiding judge in 
    Docket No. ER96-714-001 recently issued an Initial Decision finding 
    that Puget did not waive its eligibility to recover stranded costs 
    when it entered into a January 1995 letter agreement with the Port 
    of Seattle extending the term of the parties' 25-year sales contract 
    for up to one year to accommodate further negotiations. Puget Sound 
    Power & Light Company, 78 FERC para. 63,001 (1997).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests--Mobile-Sierra
    
        Several entities challenge the Commission's generic Mobile-Sierra 
    public interest finding. According to APPA, the Commission cannot make 
    the public interest determination in a generic rulemaking, whether for 
    stranded cost or non-stranded cost modifications.
        A number of entities object that the Commission does not identify 
    any utilities whose existence is jeopardized without full wholesale 
    stranded cost recovery.652 PA Munis and APPA assert that vague 
    allegations of harm if utilities do not recover stranded costs do not 
    satisfy the public interest standard which they view to be 
    ``practically insurmountable.'' 653 American Forest & Paper 
    contends that there is not one fact to support the Commission's 
    assumption about threats to the financial stability of the electric 
    utility industry. ELCON submits that significant retail stranded cost 
    exposure does not justify the rule on wholesale stranded cost recovery.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \652\ See, e.g., ELCON, PA Munis, APPA.
        \653\ See also ELCON.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        VT DPS and Valero submit that the Commission has not explained how 
    allowing utilities to abrogate their contracts to extract exit fees 
    from former customers vindicates any public interest. They argue that 
    even assuming that wholesale customers depart en mass, the customers 
    can only do so as their contracts expire; thus, the exodus, if it 
    occurs, will be a trickle, not a flood. VT DPS and Valero maintain that 
    even if some utilities were put at risk, it would not justify a generic 
    rule. They contend that based on AGD v. FERC,654 a generic 
    solution is not proper for a problem existing only in ``isolated 
    pockets.''
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \654\ 824 F.2d at 1019.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        PA Munis submits that, even assuming that the financial integrity 
    of some utilities may be threatened, the missing link in the 
    Commission's logic for a generic rule is that there is no protection 
    for customers having Mobile-Sierra contracts with public utilities that 
    are not faced with financial problems or cost shifting to third parties 
    as a result of the open access requirements. PA Munis asserts that, at 
    a minimum, each utility having Mobile-Sierra contracts should be 
    required to show on an individual basis that the public interest 
    standard has been satisfied.
        American Forest & Paper argues that Order No. 888 is not made even-
    handed by allowing requirements customers to also challenge fixed-rate, 
    fixed-term contracts. It submits that letting a customer file to amend 
    a contract only as long as that amendment also addresses stranded costs 
    is a ``heads you win, tails I lose'' proposition for the customer.
        APPA and TDU Systems request clarification of the scope of the 
    Commission's decision to allow a utility ``to seek modification of 
    contracts that may be beneficial to the customer'' if the customer is 
    permitted to argue for modification of existing contracts that are 
    less-favorable to it than other generation alternatives. APPA expresses 
    concern that this language could be interpreted to mean that once a
    
    [[Page 12402]]
    
    customer seeks modification of stranded cost provisions in an existing 
    contract, the utility may be able to challenge its entire contract with 
    the customer. If this means the utility can modify contract provisions 
    unrelated to stranded costs, APPA submits that the Commission has 
    failed to address the Mobile-Sierra public interest issues associated 
    with modifying non-stranded cost provisions in an existing contract. If 
    not, APPA contends that the Commission should clarify the language. 
    APPA objects that the Commission has not placed any limits on the types 
    of modifications that a selling utility can make, nor specified the 
    types of changes that it thinks a utility will likely make. It states 
    that the Commission needs to explain why joint modification by both the 
    seller and the purchaser can meet the public interest standard. 
    According to APPA, the Commission has not explained the need for 
    symmetrical treatment of contracts negotiated at a time when the 
    Commission has found that the supplying public utilities were 
    exercising their monopoly over transmission facilities in an unduly 
    discriminatory manner.
        APPA also contends that the Commission's reliance on Northeast 
    Utilities 655 is misplaced because that case involved the 
    Commission's review of a newly-filed contract, as opposed to subsequent 
    review of a contract previously accepted and approved by the 
    Commission. APPA further asserts that Northeast Utilities involved an 
    affiliate transaction, whereas this rulemaking is targeted at arm's-
    length agreements between unrelated selling and purchasing utilities. 
    According to APPA, this rulemaking does not present any of the concerns 
    at issue in an affiliate transaction, and the Commission should have 
    applied the ``practically insurmountable'' public interest standard 
    doctrine from Papago, the classic ``low-rate'' case.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \655\ Northeast Utilities Service Company v. FERC, 55 F.3d 686 
    (1st Cir. 1995) (Northeast Utilities).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We disagree with those entities that argue that the Commission 
    cannot make the public interest determination in a generic rulemaking. 
    It is well established that it is within the Commission's discretion to 
    decide whether we act through rule or through case-by-case 
    adjudications.656 As we explained in Order No. 888, we believe it 
    is appropriate that our public interest finding be made on a generic 
    basis given the fact that, by this Rule, we are requiring full open 
    access that could significantly affect historical relationships among 
    traditional utilities and their customers and the ability of utilities 
    to recover prudently incurred costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \656\ See Order No. 888, FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,679; mimeo at 
    127-28.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        At the same time, however, we are not eliminating the need for 
    case-by-case demonstrations that stranded cost recovery should be 
    allowed. Our public interest finding is that utilities be permitted to 
    seek extra-contractual recovery of stranded costs in certain defined 
    circumstances and that they be allowed to recover stranded costs only 
    if they make a case-specific demonstration.
        Our holding applies only to wholesale requirements contracts (with 
    Mobile-Sierra clauses) executed on or before July 11, 1994 that do not 
    contain an exit fee or other explicit stranded cost provision. We will 
    not permit modification of any contract that addresses the stranded 
    cost issue explicitly, unless the contract specifically permits such 
    modifications. Instead, we are examining requirements contracts that do 
    not clearly address the issue in the context of the traditional 
    regulatory regime under which they were signed--a regulatory 
    environment in which it was assumed as a matter of course that the 
    great majority of requirements customers would stay with their original 
    suppliers and that these suppliers had a concomitant obligation to plan 
    to supply these customers' continuing needs.
        Further, utilities with Mobile-Sierra contracts that seek recovery 
    of stranded costs will have the burden, on a case-by-case basis, of 
    showing they had a reasonable expectation of continuing to serve the 
    departing generation customer. Although we have decided on a generic 
    basis that it is in the public interest to permit public utilities with 
    Mobile-Sierra contracts to make unilateral filings, we are not 
    automatically approving any amendment that a particular utility might 
    file. If a public utility unilaterally files a proposed stranded cost 
    amendment under either section 205 or 206 of the FPA, this does not 
    necessarily mean that the Commission will find it appropriate to allow 
    such amendment. In addition, customers with Mobile-Sierra contracts 
    that do not explicitly address stranded costs may also file complaints 
    under section 206 of the FPA to propose to address stranded costs in 
    existing requirements contracts. The Commission will analyze any 
    proposed stranded cost amendment to a Mobile-Sierra contract, whether 
    proposed by the utility or by its customer, based on the particular 
    circumstances surrounding that contract. Thus, the case-by-case 
    findings that some commenters seek will, in effect, be made when the 
    Commission determines whether to approve a proposed stranded cost 
    amendment to a particular contract.657
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \657\ Because the Commission's public interest finding only 
    applies to utilities that would seek to amend their contracts to add 
    stranded cost provisions (not to those that face no stranded cost 
    exposure and thus no need to amend their contracts to add stranded 
    cost provisions), we reject as misplaced PA Munis' claim that there 
    is no protection for customers having Mobile-Sierra contracts with 
    public utilities that are not faced with financial problems or cost 
    shifting to third parties as a result of the open access 
    requirements.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Although several entities have raised various challenges to the 
    sufficiency of the Commission's public interest finding, we believe 
    that we have satisfied the public interest standard by showing how 
    third parties may ultimately bear the burden if public utilities with 
    Mobile-Sierra contracts are not given any opportunity to propose 
    contract changes to address stranded costs.658 As we explained in 
    Order No. 888, if the Commission fails to give a public utility this 
    opportunity, and the utility's financial ability to continue the 
    provision of safe and reliable service is impaired, third parties 
    (customers relying on the public utility for their electric service) 
    will be placed at risk. Similarly, if the Commission fails to give a 
    public utility the opportunity to directly assign costs to the 
    customers on whose behalf they were incurred, and some of the utility's 
    customers leave the utility's generation system for that of another 
    supplier without paying such costs, third parties (the utility's 
    remaining customers) may be harmed by having to bear costs that were 
    not incurred to serve them and that are stranded by the other 
    customers' departures via open access transmission. We believe that 
    protective action in the public interest is particularly necessary 
    where, as here, a utility's rates could become insufficient because of 
    fundamental changes in the industry that largely result from 
    legislative or regulatory changes that could not be anticipated.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \658\ As noted above, this finding applies only to wholesale 
    requirements contracts with Mobile-Sierra clauses if the contracts 
    were executed on or before July 11, 1994 and do not contain an exit 
    fee or other explicit stranded cost provision.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In response to those entities that contend that speculation of 
    financial jeopardy or generalized statements of what may occur without 
    reference to particular public utilities is not sufficient to satisfy 
    the public interest standard, we disagree. The Commission need not make 
    findings about particular utilities because the Rule does not
    
    [[Page 12403]]
    
    award stranded costs--it simply sets out generic criteria for 
    determining recovery in a particular case. If a utility does not meet 
    the criteria, there will be no stranded cost recovery. The public 
    interest determination rests on the obvious conclusion that the failure 
    of a utility to recover costs prudently incurred and financed based on 
    investor expectation of traditional cost recovery clearly adds 
    regulatory risk that investors reasonably did not expect.
        VT DPS's and Valero's reliance on AGD as support for the 
    proposition that, even if some utilities were put at risk, a generic 
    solution is not proper for a problem existing only in ``isolated 
    pockets'' is misplaced. The AGD court found that the Commission had not 
    adequately justified its decision to give all bundled firm sales 
    customers of a pipeline that decided to offer service under Order No. 
    436 the option to reduce their contract demand by 100 percent. In 
    noting the lack of support for ``an industry-wide solution for a 
    problem that exists only in isolated pockets,'' the court expressed 
    concern that the remedy adopted by the Commission (``such drastic 
    action as 100% CD reduction'' 659) was too broad.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \659\ 824 F.2d at 1019.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In Order No. 888, in contrast, the Commission has determined that 
    it is in the public interest to give a limited class of utilities--
    those that are parties to wholesale requirements contracts that were 
    executed on or before July 11, 1994 that do not contain an exit fee or 
    other explicit stranded cost provision and that contain Mobile-Sierra 
    clauses--an opportunity to seek to add a stranded cost provision to the 
    contract. Thus, the narrow scope of the Commission's Mobile-Sierra 
    public interest finding is a far cry from the broad remedy (100 percent 
    CD reduction) that the court remanded in AGD. Indeed, it more closely 
    resembles the type of limited generic action that the AGD court 
    suggested would be proper when it stated: ``This is not to say, of 
    course, that the Commission could not use generic rules to identify a 
    limited class of LDCs to be entitled to reduce CD when special 
    conditions are present.''660
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \660\ Id. at 1019-20.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We explained in Order No. 888 that we were making two complementary 
    public interest findings. First, as described above, is our decision 
    that it is in the public interest to permit public utilities to seek 
    stranded cost amendments to existing requirements contracts with 
    Mobile-Sierra clauses. Second, we found that a ``party'' to a 
    requirements contract containing a Mobile-Sierra clause no longer will 
    have the burden of establishing independently that it is in the public 
    interest to permit the modification of such contract, but still will 
    have the burden of establishing that such contract no longer is just 
    and reasonable and therefore ought to be modified. We clarify that, in 
    making this second finding, our reference to a ``party'' to a 
    requirements contract containing a Mobile-Sierra clause was directed at 
    modification of contract provisions by customers.661 Additionally, 
    this second finding applies to any contract revisions sought, whether 
    or not they relate to stranded costs.662
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \661\ We note that the fact that a contract may bind a utility 
    to a Mobile-Sierra standard does not mean that the customer is also 
    bound to that standard. Unless a customer specifically waives its 
    section 206 just and reasonable rights, the Commission construes the 
    issue in favor of the customer.
        \662\ In situations in which a customer institutes a section 206 
    proceeding to modify a contract that binds the utility to a Mobile-
    Sierra standard, the utility may make whatever arguments it wants 
    regarding any of the contract terms, including those unrelated to 
    stranded costs, but will be bound to a Mobile-Sierra standard for 
    contract terms that do not relate to stranded costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We also concluded that ``if a customer is permitted to argue for 
    modification of existing contracts that are less favorable to it than 
    other generation alternatives, then the utility should be able to seek 
    modification of contracts that may be beneficial to the customer.'' 
    663 We clarify in response to APPA and TDU Systems that this 
    statement was not intended to imply that the Commission had made 
    Mobile-Sierra findings that would permit utilities with Mobile-Sierra 
    contracts to seek non-stranded cost amendments to contracts that may be 
    favorable to a customer, based on a showing that the contracts are no 
    longer just and reasonable. Our Mobile-Sierra findings as to public 
    utility sellers apply only when utilities seek to add stranded cost 
    provisions or make other modifications related to stranded costs. Thus, 
    if a utility with a Mobile-Sierra contract initiates a section 206 
    proceeding in which it seeks to modify contract provisions that do not 
    relate to stranded costs, it will have to show that it is contrary to 
    the public interest not to modify the contract.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \663\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,664, 31,813; mimeo at 86, 521.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As we stated in Order No. 888, the most productive way to analyze 
    contract modification issues is to consider simultaneously both the 
    selling public utility's claims, if any, that it had a reasonable 
    expectation of continuing to serve the customer beyond the term of the 
    contract and the customer's claim, if any, that the contract no longer 
    is just and reasonable and therefore ought to be modified. We said that 
    if a customer brings a claim in a section 206 proceeding to shorten or 
    terminate a contract, the selling public utility must bring any 
    stranded cost claim with respect to that customer in that section 206 
    proceeding. Our goal is to ensure that all of the issues expected to be 
    raised by the parties when a customer departs a utility's generation 
    system can be efficiently litigated in one proceeding. Therefore, we 
    have similarly required that if the customer intends to claim that the 
    notice or termination provision of its existing requirements contract 
    is unjust and unreasonable, it must present that claim in any 
    proceeding brought by the selling public utility to seek recovery of 
    stranded costs. We disagree with American Forest & Paper's argument 
    that it is a ``no-win'' situation if a customer seeking to modify a 
    contract must present that claim in any stranded cost proceeding 
    brought by the selling public utility. To the contrary, providing the 
    customer to a Mobile-Sierra contract with the opportunity to 
    demonstrate that its contract is no longer just and reasonable and that 
    its term should be shortened or eliminated could be beneficial to the 
    customer, notwithstanding the customer's potential stranded cost 
    obligation. As we explained in the Rule:
        [G]iven the industry circumstances now facing us, both selling 
    utilities and their customers ought to have an opportunity to make 
    the case that their existing requirements contracts ought to be 
    modified. By providing both buyers and sellers this opportunity, the 
    Commission attempts to strike a reasonable balance of the interests 
    of all market participants.[664]]
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \664\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,814; mimeo at 522-23.
    
        In response to APPA's analysis of Northeast Utilities, it is true, 
    as APPA asserts, that Northeast Utilities involved the Commission's 
    initial review of a contract, not modification of a previously accepted 
    and approved contract, and that the contract involved an affiliate 
    transaction, while this rulemaking is targeted at arm's-length 
    agreements. However, we do not believe that these differences bear on 
    the precedential value of this case to the circumstances presented in 
    the Rule. To the contrary, we believe that Northeast Utilities provides 
    valuable guidance concerning application of the public interest 
    standard where, as here, a failure to allow limited contract 
    modification may harm the public interest by harming third parties.
        We disagree with APPA's contention that the Commission should have 
    applied the ``practically
    
    [[Page 12404]]
    
    insurmountable'' standard from ``the classic `low-rate' case, namely, 
    Papago.''665 As we have stated on several occasions, ``we do not 
    interpret the public interest standard of review * * * as imposing on 
    us a practically insurmountable burden in situations in which we are 
    protecting non-parties to a contract.'' 666 Additionally, we do 
    not interpret the public interest standard as practically 
    insurmountable in extraordinary situations such as this one where 
    historic statutory and regulatory changes have converged to 
    fundamentally change the obligations of utilities and the markets in 
    which they and their customers will operate. In this circumstance, we 
    believe the public interest test is met where the Commission determines 
    that it is necessary to allow parties to seek contract amendments in 
    order to protect the stability and financial integrity of the electric 
    industry in general during the transition to competition as well as the 
    interest of third parties affected by the transition. This type of 
    situation simply was not addressed in Papago.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \665\ APPA at 49. It should be noted that, as the Northeast 
    Utilities court indicated, the Papago court's description of the 
    public interest standard as ``practically insurmountable'' was 
    dictum. 55 F.3d at 691. Further, Papago did not involve a 
    contractual arrangement for rate revision where the parties ``by 
    broad waiver * * * eliminate both the utility's right to make 
    immediately effective rate changes under Sec. 205 and the 
    Commission's power to impose changes under Sec. 206, except the 
    indefeasible right of the Commission under Sec. 206 to replace rates 
    that are contrary to the public interest.'' Papago, 723 F.2d at 953. 
    Instead, Papago involved a contractual regime that ``contractually 
    eliminate[d] the utility's right to make immediately effective rate 
    changes under Sec. 205 but [left] unaffected the power of the 
    Commission under Sec. 206 to replace not only rates that are 
    contrary to the public interest but also rates that are unjust, 
    unreasonable, or unduly discriminatory or preferential to the 
    detriment of the contracting purchaser.'' Id. See also id. at 953-
    54.
        \666\ Southern Company Services, Inc., 67 FERC para. 61,080 at 
    61,228 (1994); see also Florida Power & Light Company, 67 FERC para. 
    61,141 at 61,398-99 (1994).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Congress has entrusted the Commission with the statutory 
    responsibility to protect the public interest. As we explained in 
    Northeast Utilities Service Company: 667
    
        \667\ 66 FERC para. 61,332 at 62,081, reh'g denied, 68 FERC 
    para. 61,041 (1994).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Protection of the `public interest' provides the justification 
    for the Commission's power to regulate public utilities under Part 
    II [of the FPA]. Specifically, section 201(a) of the FPA declares 
    `that the business of transmitting and selling electric energy for 
    ultimate distribution to the public is affected with a public 
    interest' and that federal regulation of matters related to 
    generation (to the extent provided in Parts II and III of the FPA) 
    and of the transmission and sale at wholesale of electric energy in 
    interstate commerce `is necessary in the public interest.'
    
    Consistent with our statutory obligations under the FPA, the Commission 
    has an overriding responsibility to protect non-parties affected by 
    Mobile-Sierra contracts, including consumers, to ensure that matters 
    entrusted to our jurisdiction function smoothly during the 
    restructuring transition, and to fairly balance the interests of 
    utilities and customers during the transition. 668 The ability to 
    meet our overarching public interest responsibilities would be 
    virtually precluded if we must apply a practically insurmountable 
    standard of review before we can take action to address industry-wide 
    transition issues.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \668\ 66 FERC at 62,081-83; see also Southern, 67 FERC at 
    61,228-29.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests Supporting Limited Transition Period
    
        Several entities request rehearing of the Commission's decision not 
    to establish a three-to five-year period within which stranded cost 
    recovery could be raised. They assert that if the Commission truly 
    views stranded investment as a transition process, the transition 
    should not be an extended one.669
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \669\ E.g., Central Montana EC, Central Illinois Light.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Commission will deny the requests for rehearing on this point. 
    As we explained in Order No. 888, although we considered limiting the 
    period within which stranded cost recovery could be raised, there is no 
    uniform time remaining on requirements contracts executed on or before 
    July 11, 1994. 670 As a result, any limitation on the period in 
    which parties could propose amendments covering stranded costs, such as 
    three years, would affect market participants unequally. Those with 
    long terms remaining on their contracts could object that immediately 
    addressing the issue would not be cost effective. A utility with a long 
    remaining term might not even seek stranded cost recovery depending on 
    the competitive value of its assets near the end of the contract 
    term.671 However, such a utility would invariably seek to preserve 
    its option to seek stranded cost recovery if its failure to do so 
    within a short period resulted in a waiver of its right to do so. 
    Having determined that it is generally appropriate to leave in place 
    existing requirements contracts, it is not then reasonable to create a 
    time limitation on stranded cost recovery that would encourage a 
    supplier to seek early termination in order to preserve its stranded 
    cost recovery rights.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \670\ It is not possible for the Commission to come up with a 
    reliable yardstick of the remaining terms of existing requirements 
    contracts. The Commission's files do not categorize rate schedules 
    as requirements, coordination and transmission-only contracts. 
    Moreover, there is no uniform format for requirements contracts. 
    Many have evergreen provisions, the terminology of which varies from 
    contract-to-contract (e.g., some may be year-to-year, others may 
    roll over).
        \671\ The value of its assets could vary over time as new 
    technologies emerge, fuel costs fluctuate, or environmental 
    requirements change.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        On this basis, we believe that we have adequately explained the 
    rationale for our decision to allow stranded cost claims to be raised 
    at any time prior to the termination of the contract, instead of within 
    three to five years of the effective date of the Rule.
    6. Recovery of Stranded Costs Caused by Retail-Turned-Wholesale 
    Customers
        In Order No. 888, we concluded that this Commission should be the 
    primary forum for addressing the recovery of stranded costs caused by a 
    retail-turned-wholesale customer.672 We stated that if such a 
    customer is able to reach a new generation supplier because of the new 
    open access (through the use of a FERC-filed open access transmission 
    tariff or through transmission services ordered pursuant to section 211 
    of the FPA), any costs stranded as a result of this wholesale 
    transmission access should be viewed as ``wholesale stranded costs.'' 
    We explained that there is a clear nexus between the FERC-
    jurisdictional transmission access requirement and the exposure to non-
    recovery of prudently incurred costs and that, in these circumstances, 
    this Commission should be the primary forum for addressing recovery of 
    such costs. 673
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \672\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,818-19; mimeo at 534-37.
        \673\ We indicated that we will require the same evidentiary 
    demonstration for recovery of stranded costs from a retail-turned-
    wholesale customer (and will apply the same procedures for 
    determining stranded cost obligation) as that required in the case 
    of a wholesale requirements customer.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We said we will not be the primary forum for stranded cost recovery 
    in situations in which an existing municipal utility annexes territory 
    served by another utility or otherwise expands its service territory. 
    We indicated that in these situations there is no direct nexus between 
    the FERC-jurisdictional transmission access requirement and the 
    exposure to non-recovery of prudently incurred costs. The risk of an 
    existing municipal utility expanding its territory was a risk prior
    
    [[Page 12405]]
    
    to the Energy Policy Act and prior to any open access requirement.
        Nevertheless, we did express concern that there may be 
    circumstances in which customers and/or utilities could attempt, 
    through indirect use of open access transmission, to circumvent the 
    ability of any regulatory commission--either this Commission or state 
    commissions--to address recovery of stranded costs. We reserved the 
    right to address such situations on a case-by-case basis.
    
    Rehearing Requests Opposing Retail-Turned-Wholesale Jurisdiction
    
        A number of entities challenge the Commission's assertion that 
    costs associated with retail-turned-wholesale customers would not be 
    stranded but for the FERC-jurisdictional transmission access 
    requirement. They assert that the condition precedent to 
    municipalization is the operation of a state process, and thus that it 
    cannot be the case that the recovery of costs caused by a retail-
    turned-wholesale customer is ``not subject to regulation by the 
    States.'' They submit that such costs would not be stranded but for the 
    action of state legislators or state regulators in granting authority 
    for the customer's status change. They argue that any nexus that the 
    Commission's authority under the FPA has to wholesale transmission 
    services subsequently provided to the new wholesale customer is 
    entirely derivative of the state's action.674
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \674\ E.g., NARUC, TAPS, Nucor, Suffolk County, IL Com, Multiple 
    Intervenors, APPA, CAMU, WI Com, NASUCA.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A number of entities argue that jurisdiction over costs that are 
    stranded when a retail customer becomes a wholesale customer should be 
    left to the states because the facilities used to provide retail 
    service to these retail customers were subject to state jurisdiction 
    and were included in retail rate base when the service was 
    rendered.675 They argue that because the Commission had no 
    jurisdiction over the public utility facilities and costs incurred to 
    serve retail-turned-wholesale customers, it has no jurisdiction to 
    address those public utility costs if they become stranded. Thus, 
    according to these entities, the conversion of the customer from retail 
    to wholesale does not simultaneously effectuate a conversion of the 
    costs from retail to wholesale.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \675\ E.g., ELCON, IL Com, IN Com, American Forest & Paper, AR 
    Com, MO/KS Coms, NJ BPU, Suffolk County, WY Com, VA Com, FL Com, 
    NARUC, TAPS.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        AR Com and MO/KS Coms submit that jurisdiction over the costs 
    incurred for historical retail customers does not shift unless the 
    parties themselves make those costs a part of their new wholesale 
    contract. NY Com submits that the Commission should recognize the 
    states' jurisdiction to set the level of stranded costs associated with 
    retail-turned-wholesale customers to be recovered in wholesale 
    transmission rates set by FERC. FL Com asserts that state authorities 
    are in a better position to assess the extent of stranded facilities 
    and their costs, and that the Commission's involvement should be 
    limited to that requested by a state by petition.
        OH Com states that the Commission's position on stranded costs 
    associated with retail-turned-wholesale customers invites second-
    guessing of state commission determinations and encourages forum 
    shopping by introducing more than one stranded cost treatment within a 
    single state jurisdiction. It expresses concern that utilities may seek 
    to creatively disaggregate into generation, transmission, and 
    distribution companies in ways to deliberately recast traditional 
    retail relationships as wholesale in an effort to obtain favorable 
    regulatory treatment of stranded costs.
        IN Com submits that Order No. 888's treatment of stranded costs 
    associated with retail-turned-wholesale customers will discourage state 
    legislatures from making municipalization more available. VT DPS and 
    Valero argue that the threat of a stranded cost surcharge will erect a 
    new barrier to the formation of municipal utilities. They note that the 
    Rule refers to one commenter's observation that, if Otter Tail could 
    have made a stranded cost claim against the municipal utility that 
    Elbow Lake planned to create, Otter Tail would not have needed to 
    refuse to wheel and there would never have been an Otter Tail case. 
    They submit that the Commission never addressed whether, or why, it 
    believed the point to be wrong.
        VT DPS and Valero also assert that the Rule represents a major 
    inconsistency with prior Commission treatment of municipalization. They 
    submit that the Commission historically promoted franchise competition 
    between municipalities and utilities by holding tariff provisions that 
    restrict such competition to be anticompetitive and 
    unreasonable.676
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \676\ VT DPS and Valero cite in this regard Florida Power & 
    Light Company, 8 FERC para. 61,121 (1979); Power Authority of the 
    State of New York v. FERC, 743 F.2d 93 (2d Cir. 1984); Metropolitan 
    Transportation Authority v. FERC, 796 F.2d 584 (2d Cir. 1986).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        American Forest & Paper submits that recovery of 100 percent of 
    stranded costs caused by municipalization is inconsistent with the 
    Commission's actions in the natural gas industry, where the Commission 
    has encouraged competition at the retail level through competitive 
    bypass and has not created barriers to competitive entry by imposing 
    transition charges or exit fees on converting customers.677
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \677\ American Forest & Paper cites in support of its position 
    Great Lakes Gas Transmission Limited Partnership, 68 FERC para. 
    61,376 (1994).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Nucor objects that the Rule does not address the substantive 
    findings, the common sense rationale, or the jurisdictional distinction 
    drawn in United Illuminating.678 It contends that the Commission's 
    observation in Order No. 888 that there may not be a state regulatory 
    forum for the recovery of stranded costs associated with retail-turned-
    wholesale customers and hence that the Commission should be the primary 
    forum for addressing such stranded costs is flawed because there always 
    is a state forum to address such cost recovery (the adequacy of the 
    relief provided is a very distinct issue) and open access transmission 
    does not and cannot cause retail competition to occur.679
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \678\ United Illuminating Company, 63 FERC para. 61,212, reh'g 
    denied, 64 FERC para. 61,087 (1993) (United Illuminating).
        \679\ See also Suffolk County Rehearing (Commission's analysis 
    in United Illuminating was correct; nothing has changed to warrant 
    the Commission's rejection of that analysis).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We will reject the requests for rehearing of our decision to be the 
    primary forum for addressing the recovery of stranded costs caused by 
    retail-turned-wholesale customers. We find the requests for rehearing 
    on this issue unpersuasive. While it may be the case, as some entities 
    suggest, that state action is a condition precedent to 
    municipalization, the rehearing petitions ignore the fact that the Rule 
    covers situations in which open access is also a condition precedent to 
    the municipalized customers leaving their existing supplier's system. 
    Order No. 888 does not propose that the Commission be the primary forum 
    for stranded cost recovery for all cases of municipalization. Instead, 
    our holding is limited to those cases in which the new wholesale entity 
    uses Commission-mandated transmission access to obtain new power supply 
    on behalf of retail customers that were formerly supplied
    
    [[Page 12406]]
    
    power by the utility providing the transmission service.680
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \680\ In the case of municipalization, the bundled retail 
    customers of a local utility become the bundled retail customers of 
    the new municipal utility. As explained above, we call this a 
    ``retail-turned-wholesale customer'' situation because the new 
    municipal entity in effect ``stands in the shoes'' of the retail 
    customers for purposes of obtaining wholesale transmission access 
    and new power supply.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As we explained in Order No. 888, in such cases there is a direct 
    nexus between the FERC-jurisdictional transmission access requirement 
    and the exposure to non-recovery of costs stranded as a result of this 
    wholesale transmission access. Thus, the stranded costs associated with 
    retail-turned-wholesale customers for which Order No. 888 provides an 
    opportunity for recovery would not have been incurred but for the 
    action of this Commission in requiring a utility to make unbundled 
    transmission services available. In these cases, the former bundled 
    retail customers of the historical supplying utility (now the bundled 
    retail customers of the new municipal system) would not have obtained 
    access to new power supply but for the Commission's order mandating 
    transmission. Without the regulatory mandate to provide access, the 
    utility would have indirectly continued sales to the same retail 
    customers because the new municipal utility purchasing power on the 
    retail customers' behalf would have had no way to reach other power 
    suppliers. In this situation, there would be no stranded generation 
    costs. In other words, the creation of a municipal utility intermediary 
    to purchase power at wholesale would not, by itself, trigger stranded 
    costs. Rather, it is the access from the historical supplier of the 
    bundled retail customers that is the condition precedent to reaching 
    other power suppliers and thereby triggering stranded costs. Therefore, 
    there is a clear causal nexus between the stranded costs and the 
    availability and use of the tariff required by the Commission.
        Costs that are exposed to nonrecovery when a retail customer or a 
    newly-created wholesale power sales customer ceases to purchase power 
    from the utility and does not use the utility's transmission system to 
    reach a new generation supplier (e.g., through self-generation or use 
    of another utility's transmission system) do not meet the definition of 
    ``wholesale stranded costs'' for which the Rule provides an opportunity 
    for recovery. Such costs are outside the scope of the Rule because such 
    costs would not be stranded as a direct result of the new open access.
        In response to the argument that conversion of a customer from 
    retail to wholesale would not simultaneously effectuate a conversion of 
    the costs from retail to wholesale, we believe this argument confuses 
    the issue. We note that we have defined stranded costs as wholesale or 
    retail on the basis of whether wholesale or retail open access is the 
    cause of the costs being stranded, not on the basis of the original 
    retail or wholesale characteristic of the costs. Thus, even though 
    costs may have been originally incurred as retail-related costs, the 
    precipitating event that results in such costs being stranded in the 
    retail-turned-wholesale customer scenario is the use by the new 
    wholesale customer of the Commission-mandated tariff. When a customer 
    is able to use the Commission-required tariff to reach another 
    generation supplier, it causes the utility to incur an economic cost in 
    providing transmission service that is equal to the foregone revenues 
    that the utility reasonably expected to receive under a state 
    regulatory regime. Thus, because of the causal nexus between the use of 
    a former supplying utility's Commission-mandated transmission tariff 
    and the potential for foregone revenues by that utility as a result of 
    the Commission-required access, the costs stranded by a retail-turned-
    wholesale customer are properly viewed as economic costs that are 
    jurisdictional to this Commission.
        In response to those entities that express concern that the 
    Commission's position on stranded costs associated with retail-turned-
    wholesale customers invites second-guessing of state commission 
    determinations, we emphasize that we have assumed primary authority to 
    address such costs only in a limited category of cases where there is a 
    direct nexus between the availability of Commission-required open 
    access and the stranding of costs when the former customer uses the 
    former supplying utility's transmission system (through its open access 
    tariff or a section 211 order) to reach a new supplier. We indicated in 
    Order No. 888 that if the state has permitted any recovery from 
    departing retail-turned-wholesale customers, such amount will not be 
    stranded for purposes of this Rule. We will deduct that amount from the 
    costs for which the utility will be allowed to seek recovery under this 
    Rule from the Commission. In so doing, however, we are not second-
    guessing the states as to what a utility may recover under state law. 
    Additionally, we will give great weight in our proceedings to a state's 
    view of what might be recoverable.
        We also reject the argument that the Commission's position on 
    stranded costs associated with retail-turned-wholesale customers 
    encourages forum shopping. To the contrary, as we said in Order No. 
    888, to avoid forum shopping and duplicative litigation of the issue, 
    we expect parties to raise claims before this Commission in the first 
    instance. We believe that this Commission should be the primary forum 
    because, without the open access provided by the Rule, the new 
    municipal utility would not be able to reach a new supplier and, as a 
    result, would not cause the utility to incur stranded costs (as defined 
    in this Rule).
        We reject as misplaced arguments that the Rule represents a major 
    inconsistency with the Commission's historical promotion of franchise 
    competition between municipalities and utilities and that it will 
    discourage municipalization.681 It continues to be the 
    Commission's policy to encourage competition. Indeed, the goal of Order 
    No. 888 is to remove impediments to competition in the wholesale bulk 
    power marketplace and to bring more efficient, lower cost power to the 
    Nation's electricity consumers. However, the purpose of the stranded 
    cost policy is neither to encourage nor to discourage municipalization, 
    but rather to facilitate a fair transition to competition and to ensure 
    stability in the industry during that transition. As we discuss 
    elsewhere in this order, we believe that this Commission must address 
    the recovery of the costs of moving from a monopoly-regulated regime to 
    one in which all sellers can compete on a fair basis and in which 
    electricity is more competitively priced. On this basis, we believe 
    that if a new wholesale entity such as a municipal utility uses 
    Commission-required open access to reach a new supplier on behalf of 
    its retail customers (previously retail customers of the former 
    supplier), the former supplying utility should be given an opportunity 
    to recover legitimate, prudent and verifiable costs that it
    
    [[Page 12407]]
    
    incurred under the prior regulatory regime to serve that customer.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \681\ In response to VT DPS and Valero, we note that whether or 
    not Otter Tail may have agreed to wheel power for the municipal 
    utility that Elbow Lake planned to create if Otter Tail could have 
    made a stranded cost claim against that municipal utility is of no 
    moment to the Commission's decision in Order No. 888 to allow 
    utilities the opportunity to seek recovery of stranded costs 
    associated with retail-turned-wholesale customers. The Court in 
    Otter Tail did not address the stranded cost issue because it was 
    not presented in that case. Nor was the Court presented with the 
    extraordinary circumstances--the historic statutory and regulatory 
    changes, including the requirement of open access, that have 
    converged to fundamentally change the obligations of utilities and 
    the markets in which they operate--that have justified this 
    Commission's Order No. 888 stranded cost policy.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In response to American Forest & Paper's argument that recovery of 
    100 percent of stranded costs caused by municipalization is 
    inconsistent with the Commission's policy in the natural gas industry 
    of allowing competitive bypass without imposing transition charges or 
    exit fees on converting customers, we note that industrial gas 
    customers who bypass a local distribution company's (LDC) facilities do 
    not escape transition costs quite so easily as suggested by American 
    Forest & Paper. It is true that, when the end user bypasses the LDC to 
    reach an interstate pipeline different from the pipeline serving the 
    LDC, the Commission views the bypass as a risk of competition from 
    which the LDC should not be shielded.682 However, when the end 
    user bypasses the LDC to reach the same interstate pipeline that serves 
    the LDC, the Commission may take certain actions to minimize adverse 
    effects on the LDC and its remaining customers.683 Moreover, an 
    end user that bypasses an LDC to reach the same pipeline that serves 
    the LDC would, in any event, be allocated a share of the pipeline's gas 
    supply realignment costs (if any), since those costs are allocated 
    based on current contract demand (or usage).684 Accordingly, we 
    see no inconsistency between our bypass policy for the natural gas 
    industry and Order No. 888's treatment of stranded costs associated 
    with retail-turned-wholesale customers. Similar to our refusal to 
    shield LDCs from the adverse effects of an end user's bypass to reach a 
    different pipeline than serves the LDC, Order No. 888 does not provide 
    an opportunity for stranded cost recovery where a retail-turned-
    wholesale customer uses another utility's transmission system to reach 
    a new supplier. As we note above, the opportunity for recovery of 
    stranded costs associated with retail-turned-wholesale customers is 
    limited to those cases in which the former retail customer obtains 
    (either directly or through another wholesale transmission purchaser) 
    unbundled transmission services from its former supplying utility. In 
    the case of an end use customer bypassing the LDC to reach the same 
    pipeline that serves the LDC, the end use customer would similarly be 
    allocated a share of the pipeline's gas supply realignment costs. As a 
    result, American Forest & Paper's attempt to rely on the Commission's 
    gas bypass policy is misplaced.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \682\ Texas Gas Transmission Corporation, 65 FERC para. 61,275 
    (1993).
        \683\ Texas Gas Transmission Corporation, 69 FERC para. 61,245, 
    reh'g, 70 FERC para. 61,207 (1995) (requiring pipeline to offer LDC 
    a reduction in its contract demand).
        \684\ See Southern Natural Gas Company, 75 FERC para. 61,046 at 
    61,158 (1996); Arcadian Corporation v. Southern Natural Gas Company, 
    67 FERC para. 61,176 at 61,538 (1994). See also United Distribution 
    Companies, 88 F.3d at 1181. As the United Distribution Companies 
    court noted, the Commission has given an LDC relief (and required 
    the bypassing customer to bear its share of transition costs) if the 
    LDC can show a direct nexus between the bypass and the pipeline, 
    although the Commission has declined to adopt a generic rule 
    addressing this issue. 88 F.3d at 1180-81.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We also disagree with those entities that argue that the Commission 
    has failed to adequately distinguish Order No. 888's treatment of 
    stranded costs associated with retail-turned-wholesale customers with 
    the Commission's decision in United Illuminating. As we stated in Order 
    No. 888, we recognize that we took a different approach to stranded 
    cost recovery associated with retail-turned-wholesale customers in 
    United Illuminating, where we suggested that state and local regulatory 
    authorities or the courts should be able to provide an adequate forum 
    to address retail franchise matters, including recovery of stranded 
    costs caused by municipalization, but said we would consider revisiting 
    the question if United Illuminating could demonstrate the lack of a 
    forum.685 However, we explained that since the issuance of that 
    decision we have had an opportunity to re-analyze the nature of the 
    stranded cost problem when a retail customer becomes a wholesale 
    customer, including the potential that there might not be a state 
    regulatory forum for recovery of such costs. In these circumstances, we 
    have determined that where such costs are stranded as a direct result 
    of Commission-mandated wholesale transmission access, these costs 
    should be viewed as costs of the transition to competitive wholesale 
    bulk power markets and this Commission should be the primary forum for 
    addressing their recovery.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \685\ 63 FERC at 62,583-84.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In response to Nucor's objection that there always is a state forum 
    to address stranded cost recovery associated with retail-turned-
    wholesale customers, with the adequacy of the relief being a distinct 
    issue, we clarify that our primary concern in retail-turned-wholesale 
    situations is not whether there is an adequate state regulatory forum 
    for the recovery of stranded costs associated with retail-turned-
    wholesale customers. Rather, our primary concern is that wholesale 
    customers (whether or not formerly retail) should be responsible for 
    the costs incurred to meet their power needs that are stranded when 
    they use the wholesale transmission ordered by this Commission to reach 
    new suppliers. Our decision to be the primary forum in the case of 
    stranded costs associated with retail-turned-wholesale customers is 
    based on the causal nexus between regulatory-mandated wholesale 
    transmission access and the stranding of costs when a new municipal 
    utility uses such access to obtain new power supply on behalf of retail 
    customers previously served by the former supplying utility.
    
    Rehearing Requests Seeking Expansion of Retail-Turned-Wholesale 
    Jurisdiction
    
        Other entities seek rehearing of the Commission's decision not to 
    be the primary forum for stranded cost recovery in situations in which 
    an existing municipal utility annexes territory served by another 
    utility or otherwise expands its service territory.686 A number of 
    them argue that the loss of existing retail customers through municipal 
    annexations or expansions is no different from the loss of retail 
    customers through new municipalization because existing municipal 
    systems are likely to use Commission-jurisdictional open access 
    transmission to obtain resources to supply power to the annexed 
    loads.687 They submit that, just as with newly-municipalized 
    customers, such costs would not be stranded but for the action of this 
    Commission.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \686\ E.g., EEI, SoCal Edison, Centerior, Atlantic City, PSE&G, 
    Puget, Public Service Co of CO, Coalition for Economic Competition.
        \687\ E.g., EEI, SoCal Edison, PSE&G, Puget, Public Service Co 
    of CO, Coalition for Economic Competition. Coalition for Economic 
    Competition suggests, for example, that villages and large 
    industrial customers may opt to join existing municipal systems 
    that, in most cases, will use Commission-jurisdictional transmission 
    tariffs to obtain resources to supply power to the annexed loads.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Some of these entities express concern that the Rule will encourage 
    retail-turned-wholesale transactions to be undertaken as annexations 
    rather than through the formation of new entities to avoid stranded 
    costs. 688 Public Service Co of CO contends that Order No. 888, in 
    conjunction with the Commission's section 211 order in American 
    Municipal Power Ohio, Inc.,689 may facilitate municipal 
    annexations by enabling municipal systems to serve new territory 
    through the establishment of second delivery points.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \688\ E.g., EEI, Coalition for Economic Competition, Atlantic 
    City, Puget, Public Service Co of CO.
        \689\ 74 FERC para. 61,086, final order directing transmission 
    service, 76 FERC para. 61,265 (1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Coalition for Economic Competition and Puget also argue that the 
    Commission must consider stranded
    
    [[Page 12408]]
    
    costs that arise from municipal expansion in order to satisfy its 
    statutory obligation under the FPA to ``set just and reasonable'' 
    rates. They contend that there is no justification for charging one 
    rate to former retail customers taking transmission services through a 
    new municipal utility and another rate to those taking service through 
    municipal annexation or through use of another utility's transmission 
    system.
        PSE&G suggests that the distinction between new municipalization on 
    the one hand and municipal annexation or expansion on the other hand 
    may lead to unnecessary controversy and litigation as entities wrangle 
    over whether a given expansion/annexation is really an expansion or a 
    municipalization. It says that a situation could arise where a 
    municipality serves one town in order to serve thousands of additional 
    customers in a second town. According to PSE&G, it is not clear from 
    the Rule whether the Commission would consider this an expansion of a 
    municipality's service territory or a new municipalization.
        Puget submits that the stranded cost recovery mechanism must not be 
    subject to being frustrated by simple artifices such as having the new 
    supplier (instead of the departing customer) request and contract for 
    transmission service. SoCal Edison seeks clarification of the 
    Commission's authority to mandate stranded cost recovery if a retail 
    customer disconnects from a utility's system and accesses another 
    generation supplier by interconnecting with a public power entity (who 
    in turn would interconnect with a neighboring jurisdictional utility). 
    It asks the Commission to clarify that such a transaction effectively 
    constitutes a municipalization, not an expansion of a service 
    territory, and that the Commission, under FPA section 211, can compel 
    the recovery of stranded costs by having the ``new'' jurisdictional 
    utility assess a stranded cost charge and pass the revenues on to the 
    utility from whose system the customer departed.
        SoCal Edison seeks several additional clarifications. It states 
    that it understands that the Commission's primary forum status in no 
    way prevents or interferes with a state's authority to order stranded 
    cost recovery from departing retail customers. If this is not the case, 
    SoCal Edison seeks rehearing on this issue. SoCal Edison also asks the 
    Commission to clarify that the Commission retains the discretion to 
    defer to a state stranded cost calculation methodology if appropriate 
    to do so on the facts of a particular case.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We have carefully reviewed the arguments made by petitioners 
    seeking rehearing of our decision not to be the primary forum for 
    stranded cost recovery in the case of municipal annexations. Based on 
    that review we have decided to reconsider our decision. This conclusion 
    is based in large part upon the very significant similarities between 
    the creation of a new municipal utility system (also referred to as 
    municipalization) and the expansion of an existing municipal utility 
    system (e.g., through annexation of additional retail service 
    territory). We recognize that the same nexus to Commission-required 
    transmission access that forms the basis for our decision to allow a 
    utility to seek stranded cost recovery in cases of new 
    municipalization--use of the former supplying utility's transmission 
    system--is likely to be present in some cases of municipal annexation. 
    In the case of both new municipalizations and annexations, the bundled 
    retail customers of a local utility become the bundled retail customers 
    of a municipal utility (in one case a new municipal utility, in the 
    other an existing municipal utility) that will use the transmission 
    system of the retail customers' former supplier in order to access 
    other suppliers.
        As we explain above, in a ``retail-turned-wholesale customer'' 
    situation, such as the creation of a municipal utility system, a newly-
    created entity becomes a wholesale power purchaser on behalf of the 
    retail customers. It is the conduit by which retail customers, if they 
    cannot obtain direct retail access, can reach power suppliers other 
    than their historical local utility power supplier. Although the retail 
    customers remain bundled retail customers, in that they become the 
    bundled customers of the new entity, we call this a ``retail-turned-
    wholesale customer'' situation because the new entity in effect 
    ``stands in the shoes'' of the retail customers for purposes of 
    obtaining wholesale transmission access and new power supply. The same 
    analogy applies to newly-annexed customers; they become ``new'' 
    wholesale customers in the sense that the wholesale entity obtains 
    transmission and new power supply on their behalf.
        Accordingly, we clarify that this Commission will be the primary 
    forum for addressing the recovery of stranded costs if an existing 
    municipal utility uses the transmission system of its annexed retail 
    customers' former supplier to access new suppliers to serve the annexed 
    load. As long as Commission-required transmission access (the former 
    supplier's open access tariff or transmission services ordered under 
    FPA section 211) is the vehicle that enables an existing municipal 
    utility to obtain power supplies to serve annexed loads, we believe 
    that any costs stranded as a result of this wholesale transmission 
    access are properly viewed as economic costs that are jurisdictional to 
    this Commission. In such a case, the bundled retail customers that are 
    annexed by an existing municipal utility would, through the municipal 
    utility, use the transmission system of their former supplier to obtain 
    access to new supplies and thereby expose their former supplier to non-
    recovery of prudently incurred costs. As in the case of new municipal 
    systems that use the transmission system of their retail customers' 
    former supplier, such costs would not be stranded but for the action of 
    this Commission in requiring a utility to make unbundled transmission 
    services available.690
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \690\ SoCal Edison requests clarification that a transaction in 
    which a retail customer disconnects from a utility's system and 
    accesses another generation supplier by interconnecting with a 
    public power entity, who in turn would interconnect with a 
    neighboring jurisdictional utility, constitutes a municipalization, 
    not an expansion of a service territory. Because we have decided to 
    treat municipal annexations (or expansions) and new 
    municipalizations similarly for purposes of stranded cost recovery 
    under the Rule, SoCal Edison's request is moot to the extent that it 
    envisions a scenario in which the former supplier's transmission 
    system is used to access a new generation supplier. However, as 
    discussed below, the Rule would not provide an opportunity to seek 
    recovery of stranded costs if the municipal entity in the scenario 
    described by SoCal Edison does not use the former supplier's 
    transmission system.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Just as we will not be the primary forum for stranded cost recovery 
    for all new municipalizations, so also we will not be the primary forum 
    for stranded cost recovery for all cases of municipal annexation. 
    Instead, our holding is limited to those cases in which the existing 
    municipal system uses Commission-mandated transmission access from the 
    annexed customers' former supplying utility to obtain power from a new 
    supplier. Costs that are exposed to nonrecovery when an existing 
    municipal utility does not use the transmission system of the retail 
    customers' former supplier to reach a new generation supplier (e.g., 
    through self-generation or use of another utility's transmission 
    system) do not meet the definition of ``wholesale stranded costs'' for 
    which the Rule provides an opportunity for recovery. Such costs are 
    outside the scope of the Rule because such costs would not be stranded 
    as a direct result of Commission-required transmission access.
    
    [[Page 12409]]
    
        We reject as misplaced the argument that the Commission, by failing 
    to address costs that arise if a municipal utility (whether a new 
    municipal utility or an existing municipal utility that annexes 
    additional retail customer territory) does not use the historical 
    supplying utility's transmission system, has not met its statutory 
    obligation to ``set just and reasonable'' rates. The Commission in this 
    rulemaking has not determined any utility's just and reasonable rates. 
    Further, Order No. 888 does not by its terms bar the recovery of costs 
    that do not result from the use of Commission-required transmission 
    access. Utilities may, as before, seek recovery of such non-open 
    access-related costs on a case-by-case basis in individual rate 
    proceedings. The Commission will not prejudge those issues here.
        As we indicated in Order No. 888, we also are concerned that there 
    may be circumstances in which customers and/or utilities could attempt, 
    through indirect use of open access transmission, to circumvent the 
    ability of any regulatory commission--either this Commission or state 
    commissions--to address recovery of stranded costs.691 We 
    reiterate that we reserve the right to address such situations on a 
    case-by-case basis.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \691\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,819; mimeo at 536-37.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We share the concern expressed by Puget that a retail-turned-
    wholesale customer should not be allowed to avoid any stranded cost 
    obligation that it may have under Order No. 888 simply by having its 
    new supplier be the entity that requests and contracts for transmission 
    service from the former supplying utility. We clarify that the 
    opportunity for recovery of stranded costs associated with retail-
    turned-wholesale customers under Order No. 888 applies if the 
    transmission system of the former supplier is used to transmit the 
    newly obtained power supplies to the departing retail customer, 
    regardless of whether the customer or its new supplier is the actual 
    entity that requests and contracts for the unbundled transmission 
    service. We have revised the definition of ``wholesale stranded cost'' 
    in section 35.26(b)(1)(ii) accordingly to include the situation in 
    which the retail customer subsequently becomes, either directly or 
    through another wholesale transmission purchaser, an unbundled 
    wholesale transmission services customer of the former supplying 
    utility.
        We clarify in response to SoCal Edison's request that our decision 
    to be the primary forum for recovery of stranded costs from retail-
    turned-wholesale customers is not intended to prevent or to interfere 
    with the authority of a state to permit any recovery from departing 
    retail customers, such as by imposing an exit fee prior to creating the 
    wholesale entity. As we indicated in Order No. 888, if the state has 
    permitted any such recovery from a departing retail-turned-wholesale 
    customer, that amount will not in fact be stranded. Accordingly, we 
    will deduct that amount from the costs for which the utility will be 
    allowed to seek recovery from this Commission.692
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \692\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,819; mimeo at 537.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We clarify in response to SoCal Edison's request that the 
    Commission has the discretion to defer to a state stranded cost 
    calculation methodology. However, because we recognize that state 
    retail access plans may present questions that need to be addressed on 
    a case-by-case basis, we will consider whether to exercise that 
    discretion on a case-by-case basis.
    7. Recovery of Stranded Costs Caused by Retail Wheeling
        In Order No. 888, we concluded that both this Commission and the 
    states have the legal authority to address stranded costs that result 
    when retail customers obtain retail wheeling in order to reach a 
    different generation supplier, and that utilities are entitled, from 
    both a legal and a policy perspective, to an opportunity to recover all 
    of their prudently incurred costs.693 We explained that this 
    Commission's authority to address retail stranded costs (i.e., stranded 
    costs associated with retail wheeling customers) is based on our 
    jurisdiction over the rates, terms, and conditions of unbundled retail 
    transmission in interstate commerce by public utilities, and that the 
    authority of state commissions to address retail stranded costs is 
    based on their jurisdiction over local distribution facilities and the 
    service of delivering electric energy to end users. Because it is a 
    state decision to permit or to require the retail wheeling that causes 
    stranded costs to occur, we decided we generally will leave it to state 
    regulatory authorities to deal with any stranded costs occasioned by 
    retail wheeling. The only circumstance in which we will entertain 
    requests to recover stranded costs caused by retail wheeling is when 
    the state regulatory authority 694 does not have authority under 
    state law to address stranded costs when the retail wheeling is 
    required. In such a case, we will permit a utility to seek a customer-
    specific surcharge to be added to an unbundled transmission rate.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \693\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,824-26; mimeo at 553-58.
        \694\ ``State regulatory authority'' has the same meaning as 
    provided in section 3(21) of the FPA:
        `State regulatory authority' has the same meaning as the term 
    `State commission', except that in the case of an electric utility 
    with respect to which the Tennessee Valley Authority has ratemaking 
    authority (as defined in section 3 of the Public Utility Regulatory 
    Policies Act of 1978), such term means the Tennessee Valley 
    Authority.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We noted that most states have a number of mechanisms for 
    addressing stranded costs caused by retail wheeling. We indicated that 
    rates for services using facilities used in local distribution to make 
    a retail sale are state-jurisdictional, and that states will be free to 
    impose stranded costs caused by retail wheeling on facilities or 
    services used in local distribution. We also said that states may use 
    their jurisdiction over local distribution facilities or services to 
    recover so-called stranded benefits.
        We stated that we believe our approach to stranded costs associated 
    with retail wheeling customers represents an appropriate balance 
    between federal and state interests that ensures that the rates for 
    transmission in interstate commerce by public utilities (except in a 
    narrow circumstance) will not be burdened by retail costs.
        We expressed concern about the cost-shifting potential in a holding 
    company or other multi-state situation, where denial of retail stranded 
    cost recovery by a state regulatory authority could, through operation 
    of the reserve equalization formula in a Commission-jurisdictional 
    intra-system agreement, inappropriately shift the disallowed costs to 
    affiliated operating companies in other states. We said that we will 
    deal with such situations if they arise pursuant to public utility 
    filings under section 205 or complaints under section 206. Thus, the 
    need to amend a jurisdictional agreement to prevent stranded costs 
    associated with retail wheeling customers from being shifted to 
    customers in other states will be addressed on a case-by-case basis. We 
    encouraged the affected state commissions in such situations to seek a 
    mutually agreeable approach to this potential problem. If such a 
    consensus solution resulted in a filing to modify a jurisdictional 
    agreement, we indicated that we would accord such a proposal deference, 
    particularly if other interested parties support the filing. In the 
    event that the state commissions and other interested parties cannot 
    reach consensus that would prevent cost shifting, we said that the 
    Commission would ultimately have to resolve the
    
    [[Page 12410]]
    
    appropriate treatment of such stranded costs.
    
    Rehearing Requests Opposing Any Commission Involvement in Stranded 
    Costs Associated With Retail Wheeling Customers
    
        A number of entities dispute the Commission's statement that both 
    it and the states have the legal authority to address stranded costs 
    that result from retail wheeling. Central Illinois Light contends that 
    the Commission's claim of dual jurisdiction is inconsistent with FPC v. 
    Southern California Edison Company.695 It says that the court in 
    that case recognized that Congress meant to draw a bright line easily 
    ascertained between state and federal jurisdiction, making unnecessary 
    case-by-case analysis. Central Illinois Light asserts that the 
    Commission has stepped over the bright line into the states' exclusive 
    jurisdiction over retail rates.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \695\ 376 U.S. 205, 215-16 (1964).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        IA Com seeks rehearing of the Commission's assertion of concurrent 
    jurisdiction with state authorities over stranded costs associated with 
    retail wheeling customers on the ground that it is based on the 
    Commission's erroneous assertion of jurisdiction over unbundled retail 
    transmission.
        IL Com says that regardless of whether the Commission's claim of 
    jurisdiction over retail transmission is upheld, the Commission's 
    ruling that there is joint jurisdiction over retail stranded costs is 
    in error. According to IL Com, the Commission has no authority over 
    such stranded costs. IL Com also disputes the Commission's 
    characterization of the derivation of state authority to address such 
    stranded costs. It says that state commission authority does not derive 
    only from states' jurisdiction over local distribution facilities and 
    the service of delivering electric energy to end users. IL Com submits 
    that state commission authority to address retail stranded costs 
    derives from the existence of state commission jurisdiction over the 
    facilities and costs at the time of their incurrence.
        A number of entities contend that Commission jurisdiction over 
    transmission facilities used in interstate commerce does not give it 
    jurisdiction over stranded investment in retail generating 
    assets.696 Several argue that the fact that a retail wheeling 
    customer might need transmission access from its former supplier does 
    not change the character of the costs that are stranded. They maintain 
    that retail stranded costs are not costs of providing unbundled 
    transmission service, but are costs associated with providing what was 
    formerly bundled retail service, over which the Commission has no 
    jurisdiction.697
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \696\ E.g., Central Illinois Light, IN Consumer Counselor, IN 
    Consumers, Nucor, FL Com, WI Com, VA Com, AR Com, MO/KS Com, OH Com, 
    APPA. For example, FL Com asserts that costs for facilities that are 
    currently under the jurisdiction of state authorities do not become 
    the Commission's jurisdiction because retail wheeling is instituted; 
    in most cases, the states approved both the construction and the 
    cost recovery for these facilities under bundled rate structures. FL 
    Com submits that the states are in a better position to judge the 
    extent and value of assets that may become stranded as a result of 
    retail wheeling.
        \697\ E.g., APPA, AR Com, MO/KS Coms, OH Com.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several entities argue that it is solely the action of the state 
    that allows a given utility's retail customers to seek alternative 
    sources of supply; therefore, there is no nexus between the 
    Commission's wholesale transmission rule and any costs that might be 
    stranded by a state-established customer choice regime.698
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \698\ E.g., NARUC, TAPS.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A number of entities submit that the provision of FPA section 201 
    that federal regulation is ``to extend only to those matters which are 
    not subject to regulation by the States'' bars any attempt by the 
    Commission to displace or supplant an admittedly legitimate exercise of 
    state authority over retail stranded costs.699 NASUCA submits that 
    all state commissions have the authority to establish just and 
    reasonable rates for the retail electric utilities in their respective 
    jurisdictions.700 It maintains that only state regulators are in a 
    position to rule on the treatment of costs that were allowed in retail 
    rates pursuant to state laws; the Commission has no knowledge or 
    expertise regarding the specific state legal frameworks in which these 
    costs were included in rates. NY Com argues that the Commission does 
    not have jurisdiction to determine the rate treatment of costs devoted 
    to retail service and, thus, lacks authority to allow recovery if a 
    state decides not to do so.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \699\ E.g., NASUCA, NY Com, WY Com, NARUC. The Consumer's 
    Utility Counsel Division of the Georgia Governor's Office of 
    Consumer Affairs filed comments on June 24, 1996, in support of 
    NARUC's request for rehearing on the jurisdictional issues 
    pertaining to the recovery of retail stranded costs. While answers 
    to requests for rehearing generally are not permitted, 18 CFR 
    385.213(a)(2) (1996), we will depart from our general rule because 
    of the significant nature of this proceeding and will accept these 
    comments.
        \700\ According to NASUCA, whether or not that authority 
    includes a requirement that a utility receive 100 percent return on 
    stranded costs (or something less) is a matter to be determined by 
    the state courts and legislatures.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        VA Com argues that section 201(b)(1) of the FPA restricts the 
    Commission's jurisdiction to wholesale sales. It says that a departing 
    retail customer remains a retail customer, regardless of the supplier. 
    VA Com concludes that no portion of the transaction is a wholesale 
    sale, and that there are no wholesale costs associated with a retail 
    wheeling transaction.701
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \701\ See also AR Com (one retail transaction is replaced by 
    another retail transaction; there is no wholesale transaction and no 
    wholesale costs over which the Commission has jurisdiction).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A number of entities seek rehearing of the Commission's decision 
    that it will entertain stranded cost claims when the state regulatory 
    authority does not have authority under state law to address stranded 
    costs when the retail wheeling is required.702 NARUC submits that 
    Congress did not intend the Commission to become involved in 
    adjudicating legal questions regarding the breadth of state law 
    authority granted state commissions by their legislatures. NARUC 
    expresses concern that the Commission would second-guess a state cost 
    recovery determination and promote forum shopping. Once a balance has 
    been struck at the state level concerning the terms of restructuring, 
    NARUC submits that it is inconceivable that the Commission would have 
    either the desire or authority to second-guess a state's legislative 
    and regulatory processes.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \702\ E.g., NARUC, Central Illinois Light, IN Com, American 
    Forest & Paper, IN Consumer Counselor, IN Consumers, IL Com.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several entities object that the Commission effectively would 
    authorize recovery of stranded costs associated with a retail wheeling 
    customer if a state legislature withholds from the state regulatory 
    agency the authority to approve stranded cost recovery.703 They 
    submit that just because a state has not given its regulatory 
    commission the authority to impose stranded costs in the case of retail 
    wheeling does not confer jurisdiction on the Commission to impose such 
    charges. They contend that the state legislature should be the final 
    arbiter of state policy. IL Com submits that if a state legislature 
    chooses not to give its state commission the authority to act on 
    stranded costs, ``that can be taken as a clear indication that the 
    state's legislature most certainly does not want FERC to address 
    them.'' 704 Central Illinois Light objects that the Commission has 
    offered no reason why it will accept the decision
    
    [[Page 12411]]
    
    of the regulatory agency, but not that of the legislature.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \703\ E.g., Central Illinois Light, IN Com, American Forest & 
    Paper, IN Consumer Counselor, IN Consumers, IL Com. TX Com considers 
    that it has the power to address stranded cost issues related to 
    retail transmission service.
        \704\ IL Com at 38 (emphasis in original).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        AMP-Ohio and Cleveland ask the Commission to clarify that its 
    deference to the determinations of the states is to the authority of 
    the states as exercised through state legislative bodies (and other 
    political subdivisions with legislative authority) as well as to state 
    regulatory bodies. They submit that if the state legislature, or a 
    local government acting in accordance with its authority, enacts retail 
    wheeling legislation that expressly limits the ability of its 
    regulatory body to permit recovery of stranded costs, even barring all 
    such recovery, the Commission should not become involved.
        Several entities ask the Commission to clarify that Order No. 888 
    does not permit utilities to apply to the Commission for recovery of 
    stranded costs associated with a retail wheeling customer when a state 
    regulatory authority has ``addressed'' a request for the same stranded 
    costs but has not allowed 100 percent recovery.705 ELCON gives two 
    hypothetical examples to which it asks the Commission to respond: one 
    where a state regulatory authority possesses full stranded cost 
    recovery authority but allows only 50 percent recovery; the other where 
    the state legislature provides the state regulatory authority by 
    statute with the power to permit recovery of up to 50 percent of 
    identified stranded costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \705\ E.g., ELCON, NASUCA, IL Com, NY Com.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We reaffirm our conclusion that both this Commission and the states 
    have the legal authority to address stranded costs that result when 
    retail customers obtain retail wheeling in interstate commerce from 
    public utilities in order to reach a different generation supplier, but 
    that, because it is a state decision to permit or require the retail 
    wheeling that causes retail stranded costs to occur, we will leave it 
    to state regulatory authorities to deal with any stranded costs 
    occasioned by retail wheeling. The only circumstance in which we will 
    entertain requests to recover stranded costs caused by retail wheeling 
    is when the state regulatory authority does not have authority under 
    state law to address stranded costs when the retail wheeling is 
    required.
        We will reject the requests for rehearing that oppose any 
    Commission involvement in stranded costs associated with retail 
    wheeling customers. We disagree with those entities that challenge our 
    conclusion that both this Commission and the states have the legal 
    authority to address stranded costs that result from retail wheeling 
    (variously described by those entities as dual, concurrent, or joint 
    jurisdiction). The Commission explained in detail in Order No. 888 the 
    legal basis for concluding that this Commission and the state 
    commissions each have jurisdiction over separate aspects of a retail 
    wheeling transaction.706 This Commission has jurisdiction over the 
    rates, terms, and conditions of unbundled retail transmission in 
    interstate commerce by public utilities. State commissions have 
    jurisdiction over local distribution facilities and the service of 
    delivering electric energy to end users. Based on our respective 
    jurisdictions over separate aspects of the retail wheeling transaction, 
    we believe either has the authority to provide the former supplying 
    utility with an opportunity to recover costs stranded when the 
    departing customer uses retail transmission in interstate commerce to 
    reach a new supplier, but that here, unlike the retail-turned-wholesale 
    scenario, the state commission should be the primary forum because 
    these costs are stranded by the action of the state. We would act only 
    if the primary forum is not available. We have made a policy decision 
    that this Commission will step in to fill a regulatory ``gap'' that 
    could result in no effective forum under which utilities would have an 
    opportunity to seek recovery of prudently incurred costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \706\ See FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,780-85; mimeo at 427-42 and 
    Appendix G.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several entities argue that the Commission does not have 
    jurisdiction over stranded investment in retail generating assets, that 
    use of Commission-jurisdictional transmission does not change the 
    character of the costs that are stranded, that stranded costs 
    associated with retail wheeling customers are not costs of providing 
    unbundled transmission service, but are costs associated with providing 
    what was formerly bundled retail service, and that only state 
    regulators are in a position to rule on the treatment of costs that 
    were allowed in retail rates pursuant to state laws. While we agree 
    that stranded costs associated with retail wheeling are costs that are 
    retail in character in the sense that they are in retail bundled rates 
    and become stranded as a result of retail wheeling required by the 
    state commission, we do not believe this precludes the Commission from 
    exercising jurisdiction in the limited circumstances of the Rule.
        As an initial matter, we note that there are rarely separate retail 
    and wholesale generating facilities. Retail customers and wholesale 
    requirements customers get energy from the same facilities, each buying 
    a ``slice of the system.'' Typically all generating assets go into both 
    the retail and the wholesale rate bases for determining retail and 
    wholesale rates. Rates are determined by allocating the total 
    generating costs among customer classes. The parties confuse the issue 
    before us to the extent they suggest that state commissions, not this 
    Commission, have ``jurisdiction'' over certain ``costs.'' Neither the 
    state commissions nor this Commission has exclusive jurisdiction over 
    ``costs.'' Each regulatory authority has jurisdiction to determine 
    ``rates'' for services subject to its jurisdiction and, in determining 
    rates, may take into account all of the costs incurred by the utility. 
    Under historical cost-of-service ratemaking, each regulatory authority, 
    in exercising its respective ratemaking jurisdiction, reviews the total 
    costs incurred by a utility to provide service and makes its separate 
    and independent determination of what costs may be recovered through 
    rates within its jurisdiction.707 Generating costs continually 
    shift between retail and wholesale rates over time.708
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \707\ If a utility is regulated by both this Commission and a 
    state commission, each commission, in setting cost-of-service rates 
    within its jurisdiction, will separately and independently determine 
    the utility's total cost of providing service (also known as the 
    utility's total revenue requirement). This will be based on the 
    expenses incurred in providing service and a reasonable profit on 
    the utility's assets that are used to provide the service. The 
    commissions may differ as to what assets are appropriately included 
    in total rate base, what other costs are appropriately included in 
    the total cost of service, and what rate of return should be 
    permitted. Once each regulatory authority has determined the 
    appropriate total revenue requirement, it then will determine what 
    portion of that total revenue requirement should be borne by the 
    utility's wholesale customers and what share should be borne by 
    retail customers (also called cost allocation). Each commission may 
    also reach different conclusions on this split as well. Thus, under 
    historical cost-based ratemaking, regulatory authorities do not 
    carve out so-called ``wholesale costs'' that only this Commission 
    can take into account in determining rates subject to its 
    jurisdiction or so-called ``retail costs'' that only a state 
    commission can take into account in determining rates subject to 
    state jurisdiction. Additionally, this Commission and state 
    commissions have the discretion to determine whether costs are 
    appropriately recovered through a transmission, generation, or 
    distribution component of a rate (also called functionalization of 
    costs) within their respective jurisdictions.
        \708\ We reject arguments that stranded retail generation costs 
    are not a cost of providing unbundled retail transmission. While 
    such costs are not a cost of operating the physical transmission 
    system, nevertheless, they are an economic cost incurred as a result 
    of being required to provide retail transmission.
    
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [[Page 12412]]
    
        More importantly, both the state commission and this Commission 
    have a responsibility to oversee the financial health of the utilities 
    we regulate. Each has jurisdiction to make judgments about recovery of 
    the costs of the assets in the utility's total rate base. Utilities are 
    entitled to a regulatory forum that can adjudicate claims that they are 
    or are not entitled to recovery of costs incurred regardless of the 
    initial retail or wholesale ``character'' of those costs, and we 
    believe we have the authority and obligation to fill a regulatory 
    ``gap'' that could occur.709
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \709\ This is not a regulatory ``gap'' in the sense that the 
    Commission would be asserting authority over matters not within its 
    jurisdiction. However, the Commission would be filling a regulatory 
    ``gap'' to the extent that the utility normally would have the 
    opportunity to seek approval from its state regulatory commission to 
    recover costs in retail rates from a departing retail customer or to 
    reallocate those costs to other retail customers. In circumstances 
    where the utility does not have this opportunity because the state 
    regulatory authority has no authority to address the issue, we may 
    appropriately fill this regulatory ``gap'' to permit recovery from 
    the departing customer through the retail transmission rate.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In response to the argument that it is solely the action of the 
    state that allows a retail customer to seek alternative sources of 
    supply and, as a result, there is no nexus between the Commission's 
    wholesale transmission rule and any costs that might be stranded by a 
    state-established customer choice regime, we agree. Indeed, as we 
    indicate in Order No. 888, we decided to leave it to state regulatory 
    authorities to deal with any stranded costs occasioned by retail 
    wheeling (with a limited exception) because it is a state decision to 
    permit or require the retail wheeling in the first instance that causes 
    retail stranded costs to occur. Our determination, as explained above, 
    is to fill any regulatory gap that arises as a result of interstate 
    wheeling. We believe that it is necessary for the Commission to act as 
    a backstop in this limited instance to ensure that costs stranded as a 
    result of retail wheeling do not go unrecovered because the state 
    regulatory authority lacks the authority under state law to address 
    such costs. At the same time, as we stated in Order No. 888, we believe 
    that most states have a number of mechanisms for addressing stranded 
    costs caused by retail wheeling. We emphasize that this Rule is not 
    intended to preempt the exercise of any existing state authority with 
    respect to the assessment of a stranded cost or stranded benefits 
    charge on a retail customer that obtains retail wheeling.
        In response to arguments that the Commission's decision will result 
    in second-guessing or interfering with a state's legislative processes 
    and decisions, we believe these arguments are premature. As a general 
    matter, we do not expect that our decision to be a backstop will 
    interfere with legislative decisions that specifically address stranded 
    cost matters and the scope of the state regulatory authority's 
    authority in determining stranded costs. If states or parties to a 
    retail stranded cost recovery case brought before this Commission 
    believe that a Commission decision on the issue would interfere with 
    state legislative decisions, they should raise their arguments, and 
    support therefore, at that time.
        We clarify that Order No. 888 does not permit utilities to seek 
    recovery from the Commission of stranded costs associated with retail 
    wheeling customers if a state regulatory authority with authority to 
    address retail wheeling stranded costs has in fact addressed such 
    costs, regardless of whether the state regulatory authority has allowed 
    full recovery, partial recovery, or no recovery.
    
    Rehearing Requests Supporting Broader Jurisdiction Over Stranded Costs 
    Associated With Retail Wheeling Customers
    
        A number of entities seek rehearing of the Commission's decision 
    not to serve as a backstop for all stranded costs associated with 
    retail wheeling customers. Some assert that the Commission has the 
    legal authority to address independently stranded costs that arise from 
    retail wheeling and that the Commission cannot lawfully abdicate or 
    delegate such authority to the states.710 Coalition for Economic 
    Competition submits that the Commission correctly concluded that it has 
    jurisdiction over retail transmission rates, terms and conditions and 
    the authority to address retail wheeling stranded costs. Thus, it 
    argues that the Commission is without the power to make a ``policy 
    determination'' that results in the Commission not exercising its legal 
    authority over stranded costs associated with retail wheeling 
    customers. It asserts that, just as the Commission recognizes that it 
    ``cannot simply turn over its jurisdiction'' to the states to determine 
    facilities subject to Commission jurisdiction,711 the Commission 
    cannot turn over its jurisdiction to establish stranded cost charges 
    that it correctly determined it has the authority to establish. 
    Coalition for Economic Competition argues that the Commission should 
    adopt a stranded cost recovery policy similar to the policy the 
    Commission has adopted with respect to the determination of state/
    federal jurisdiction, whereby the Commission would defer to state 
    stranded cost determinations so long as they are consistent with the 
    Commission's policy.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \710\ E.g., Utilities For Improved Transition, Coalition for 
    Economic Competition.
        \711\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,784; mimeo at 439.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Utilities For Improved Transition argues that the Commission's 
    authority over public utility rates for the transmission of electric 
    power, both wholesale and retail, is plenary and exclusive. As a 
    result, it submits that the Commission may not avoid responsibility for 
    costs stranded by transmission of retail power.712 Illinois Power 
    contends that Congress did not authorize the Commission to reject 
    jurisdictional rate filings whenever the Commission regards the state 
    commissions as a more convenient or appropriate forum.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \712\ Utilities For Improved Transition argues that, based on 
    Consolidated Edison Company of New York, Inc., 15 FERC para. 61,174 
    at 61,405 (1981) and other cases, the Commission has jurisdiction 
    over the entire delivery service (rendered on both the transmission 
    and local distribution facilities) as a transmission transaction. 
    Utilities For Improved Transition submits that states do not have 
    authority over rates on local distribution facilities used to 
    complete a transmission transaction.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        EEI and the Coalition for Economic Competition contend that 
    virtually all retail stranded costs can only occur through the vehicle 
    of Commission-jurisdictional transmission in interstate commerce. They 
    submit that the Commission, having recognized the clear nexus between 
    FERC-jurisdictional transmission and stranded costs in the retail-
    turned-wholesale context, cannot fail to recognize the same clear nexus 
    in the retail wheeling context.
        Utilities For Improved Transition says that it is legally 
    immaterial whether stranded costs are caused by the Commission's 
    ordering the transmission or the states' doing so; the determining 
    factor is who has the jurisdiction to make the rates for the service, 
    not who has the jurisdiction to order the service.
        Coalition for Economic Competition and Utilities For Improved 
    Transition contend that the Commission must consider stranded costs 
    that arise from retail wheeling in order to satisfy its statutory 
    obligation under the FPA to ``set just and reasonable'' rates. 
    Coalition for Economic Competition maintains that FPA sections 201, 205 
    and 206 do not give the Commission the flexibility to allow stranded 
    costs in certain jurisdictional wheeling rates (e.g., wholesale 
    wheeling and new municipalizations) but to exclude them from other 
    jurisdictional wheeling rates (e.g., retail wheeling, municipal
    
    [[Page 12413]]
    
    annexation, and bypass).713 Utilities For Improved Transition says 
    that the just and reasonable standard requires the Commission to 
    backstop the states to ensure that there is full stranded cost 
    recovery. It objects that Order No. 888's disposition of jurisdiction 
    creates a problem of cross-class discrimination (wholesale versus 
    retail) and inter-class discrimination (some retail versus the 
    remainder of the retail).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \713\ EEI states that the Commission did not rebut EEI's 
    argument that the Commission's failure to address all retail 
    stranded costs was unduly discriminatory.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Coalition for Economic Competition further argues that the 
    Commission's failure to address all stranded costs associated with 
    retail wheeling customers will result in an improper taking under the 
    Constitution.714 It also argues that the Commission is not 
    permitted to disregard its findings in Order No. 888 which, according 
    to Coalition for Economic Competition, ``inexorably'' lead to the 
    conclusion that Commission action on ``all'' stranded costs (including 
    retail wheeling, municipal annexation, and bypass stranded costs) is 
    required.715
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \714\ In support of its argument, Coalition for Economic 
    Competition cites Federal Power Commission v. Hope Natural Gas 
    Company, 320 U.S. 591, 602 (1944); Duquesne Light Company v. 
    Barasch, 488 U.S 299, 307-08 (1989).
        \715\ Coalition for Economic Competition at 14.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Illinois Power argues that the FPA does not authorize the 
    Commission to discriminate among utilities based on the state of their 
    residence, and that the Commission must allow all utilities to seek 
    interstate rate recovery of just and reasonable retail stranded costs. 
    Illinois Power asserts that the Rule will lead to the absurd, unduly 
    discriminatory result that utilities located in states whose 
    legislatures have failed to provide for stranded cost recovery will be 
    better off than those located in states that provide for only limited 
    stranded cost recovery. It supports use of the Commission's statutory 
    authority to establish a uniform, national method for retail stranded 
    cost recovery.
        Coalition for Economic Competition also contends that the 
    Commission's decision to let the states deal with retail stranded costs 
    is arbitrary and capricious because the Commission failed to consider 
    the arguments that stranded cost opponents will make before state 
    commissions, such as that a state lacks jurisdiction to impose stranded 
    cost charges or that the state imposition of such charges may be 
    preempted or found to be an undue burden on interstate commerce. It 
    further argues that the Commission's reliance on state jurisdiction 
    over the service of delivering electric energy to the end user does not 
    reflect reasoned decisionmaking. It submits that the Commission has 
    failed to consider that the sale of electric energy may take place 
    outside of the state into which the energy is transmitted, in which 
    case the state commission may have no jurisdiction over either the sale 
    or the transmission of the energy and, accordingly, no authority to 
    consider stranded costs.
        A number of entities ask the Commission to act on requests for 
    retail stranded cost recovery when the state commission lacks authority 
    or has authority to order recovery, but has declined to do so or has 
    only allowed partial recovery.716
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \716\ E.g., Centerior, Southern, SoCal Edison.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Lastly, TX Com notes that section 35.26(d) (dealing with recovery 
    of retail stranded costs) refers only to public utilities. It suggests 
    that the omission of a reference to transmitting utilities appears to 
    be inadvertent and should be corrected.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Commission will reject the requests for rehearing of our 
    decision not to assume a backstop role for all stranded costs 
    associated with retail wheeling customers. We explained in Order No. 
    888 that commenters that describe our action as an unlawful abdication 
    or delegation of authority misconstrue the nature of our decision to 
    leave stranded costs associated with retail wheeling customers (with a 
    limited exception) to state regulatory authorities.717 We have not 
    ``abdicated'' or ``delegated'' to state regulatory authorities our 
    jurisdiction over the rates, terms, and conditions of retail 
    transmission in interstate commerce; if retail transmission in 
    interstate commerce by a public utility occurs, public utilities 
    offering such transmission must comply with the FPA by filing proposed 
    rate schedules under section 205.718 Instead, we have made a 
    policy determination that the recovery of stranded costs associated 
    with retail wheeling customers--an issue over which either this 
    Commission or state commissions could exercise authority by virtue of 
    their jurisdiction over retail transmission in interstate commerce and 
    over local distribution facilities and services, respectively--is 
    primarily a matter of local or state concern for which the primary 
    forum should be the state commissions. However, if the state regulatory 
    authority does not have authority under state law to be the forum to 
    address stranded costs when the retail wheeling is required, then we 
    will entertain requests to recover such costs. As we explain above in 
    response to the rehearing petitioners that oppose any Commission 
    involvement in stranded costs associated with retail wheeling 
    customers, we have made a policy decision that this Commission will 
    step in to fill a regulatory ``gap'' that could result in no effective 
    forum under which utilities would have an opportunity to seek recovery 
    of prudently incurred costs.719
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \717\ We also explained that the case law they cite (which they 
    refer to again in their rehearing requests) to support the 
    proposition that an agency is not authorized to abdicate its 
    statutory responsibility or to delegate to parties and intervenors 
    regulatory responsibilities is factually distinguishable and 
    inapposite. See FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,825 and note 765; mimeo at 
    554-55 and note 765.
        \718\ The entities who argue that the Commission has abdicated 
    or delegated its jurisdiction to the states misconstrue the 
    Commission's jurisdiction to determine rates for unbundled 
    transmission in interstate commerce as somehow including exclusive 
    ``jurisdiction'' over ``costs.'' However, as discussed above, 
    neither this Commission nor the state commissions has exclusive 
    ``jurisdiction'' over ``costs.'' Rather, each has jurisdiction to 
    determine ``rates'' for services subject to its jurisdiction. It is 
    in the course of determining ``rates'' for unbundled transmission in 
    interstate commerce that this Commission can take into account 
    various costs incurred by a utility to provide jurisdictional 
    service. A state commission can take those same costs into account 
    in making its separate and independent determinations of what costs 
    may be recovered through rates within its jurisdiction. See note 
    707, supra, and accompanying text.
        \719\ Based on these same considerations, we reject Coalition 
    for Economic Competition's request that the Commission assume a 
    backstop role for all stranded costs associated with retail wheeling 
    customers but defer to state stranded cost determinations so long as 
    they are consistent with the Commission's policy.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We disagree with Coalition for Economic Competition's argument that 
    our findings in Order No. 888 ``inexorably'' lead to the conclusion 
    that Commission action on ``all'' stranded costs (including retail 
    wheeling and bypass stranded costs) is required, much less that the 
    Commission has ignored the findings in Order No. 888. To the contrary, 
    as we explain in Section IV.J.1, it is not the purpose of this Rule to 
    allow utilities an opportunity to seek to recover ``all'' uneconomic 
    costs that might be stranded when a customer leaves its utility 
    supplier. We have fully explained our reasons for adopting an approach 
    that, for purposes of stranded cost recovery from wholesale 
    transmission customers, relies on the nexus between stranded costs and 
    the use of transmission tariffs required by this Commission and, for 
    purposes of stranded cost recovery from retail customers, recognizes 
    state commission jurisdiction but fills potential regulatory gaps that 
    could arise in the transition to new market structures.
    
    [[Page 12414]]
    
        We disagree with those entities that contend that the Commission 
    must consider retail stranded costs in order to satisfy our statutory 
    obligation under the FPA to set just and reasonable rates. In 
    determining just and reasonable rates for jurisdictional transmission 
    service, which currently are determined on a cost basis, the Commission 
    satisfies its statutory obligation under the FPA by allowing utilities 
    an opportunity to recover their prudently incurred costs plus a 
    reasonable rate of return. As we have explained above, this may include 
    the costs of use of the physical transmission system, as well as 
    economic costs incurred by the utility when it provides transmission 
    service (e.g., stranded costs). However, in situations in which a state 
    regulatory authority has the authority to address recovery of retail 
    stranded costs, there is no regulatory ``gap,'' and there is no 
    obligation for this Commission to provide a second opportunity for 
    recovery.720
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \720\ If the state regulatory authority is the forum before 
    which to seek recovery, the utility may make whatever arguments it 
    wishes regarding the justness and reasonableness of its rates, as 
    well as any unconstitutional taking arguments it may have, before 
    the state forum. Further, it can pursue appeals of unfavorable 
    decisions through the state court system.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We reject arguments that FPA sections 201, 205 and 206 do not give 
    the Commission the flexibility to allow stranded costs in certain 
    jurisdictional wheeling rates (wholesale wheeling and new 
    municipalizations) but to exclude them from other jurisdictional 
    wheeling rates (retail wheeling in interstate commerce and use of 
    another utility's transmission tariff), and that this policy somehow 
    makes rates discriminatory. Recovery of this type of cost through a 
    transmission rate is obviously not the norm, but is necessitated by the 
    need to deal with the transition costs associated with this Rule. As 
    discussed in detail in the Rule, the Commission has carefully balanced 
    the interests of utilities as well as customers in concluding that the 
    opportunity for stranded cost recovery through transmission rates 
    should be permitted in only two general circumstances: (1) in the case 
    of wholesale stranded costs, where there is a direct nexus to 
    Commission-required transmission access; and (2) in the case of retail 
    stranded costs, where there otherwise would be a regulatory gap because 
    a state regulatory authority lacks authority under state law to address 
    stranded costs at the time that retail wheeling is required. We see 
    nothing in the FPA that precludes us from exercising this flexibility 
    and, indeed, the parties have not pointed to anything that, in our 
    opinion, precludes us from exercising this discretion.
        We reject the argument that virtually all stranded costs associated 
    with retail wheeling customers can occur only through the vehicle of 
    Commission-jurisdictional transmission in interstate commerce, and 
    therefore, that the same nexus between FERC-jurisdictional transmission 
    and stranded costs that exists in the retail-turned-wholesale context 
    is present in the retail wheeling context. We also disagree that it is 
    legally immaterial whether stranded costs are caused by the 
    Commission's ordering the transmission or the states doing so, and that 
    the determining factor is who has the jurisdiction to make the rates 
    for the service, not who has the jurisdiction to order the service. The 
    opportunity for stranded cost recovery set forth in this Rule is based 
    on the causal link between stranded costs and the availability and use 
    of the Commission-required transmission tariff. It is true that in both 
    the retail-turned-wholesale context and the retail wheeling context 
    there is a limited nexus between stranded costs and Commission-
    jurisdictional access since, in both situations, the Commission has 
    jurisdiction over the rates, terms and conditions of the transmission 
    service and, therefore, the authority to permit stranded cost recovery 
    through the transmission rates. However, the causal nexus to FERC-
    jurisdictional transmission and stranded costs in the two contexts 
    (retail vs. retail-turned-wholesale) is different. In the retail 
    wheeling context, there is no causal nexus between stranded costs and 
    transmission that has been ordered by this Commission. In the retail-
    turned-wholesale context, in contrast, the opportunity for a utility to 
    seek recovery of stranded costs is grounded on the existence of a 
    direct causal nexus between stranded costs and transmission that has 
    been ordered by this Commission.
        We will reject the rehearing petitions that ask the Commission to 
    act on requests for stranded cost recovery associated with retail 
    wheeling customers not only when the state commission lacks authority, 
    but also when the state commission has authority but either has 
    declined to use it or has only allowed partial recovery. As explained 
    above, our decision to entertain requests to recover stranded costs 
    caused by retail wheeling in a limited circumstance (when the state 
    regulatory authority does not have authority under state law to address 
    stranded costs when the retail wheeling is required) is based on our 
    determination to fill any regulatory gap that arises in association 
    with interstate transmission.
        We will reject TX Com's request that the Commission clarify that 
    section 35.26(d) (dealing with recovery of retail stranded costs), 
    which refers only to public utilities, should also refer to 
    transmitting utilities. The Commission's decision to act as a limited 
    backstop in the case of stranded costs associated with retail wheeling 
    customers is based on our jurisdiction under sections 205 and 206 of 
    the FPA over the rates, terms, and conditions of retail transmission in 
    interstate commerce. As a result, our ability to allow the recovery of 
    such costs through a surcharge on a section 205 unbundled transmission 
    rate is necessarily limited to public utilities.721
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \721\ We note that the definition of ``retail stranded cost'' in 
    section 35.26(b)(5) mistakenly refers to ``a public utility or 
    transmitting utility'' (emphasis added). We will revise the 
    definition to remove the reference to ``transmitting utility.''
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests Opposing Commission Treatment of Stranded Costs 
    Associated With Retail Wheeling Customers in Holding Company Intra-
    System Agreement Cases
    
        A number of entities oppose the Commission's proposal to address on 
    a case-by-case basis whether jurisdictional intra-system agreements may 
    need to be amended in order to prevent inappropriate cost-shifting that 
    could occur if one state disallows stranded cost recovery associated 
    with retail wheeling customers. IN Com objects that the problem is not 
    the actions of one state or another, but rather the terms of the intra-
    system agreement.
        AR Com objects that Order No. 888 is factually in error because a 
    state's treatment of retail stranded costs under the Entergy System 
    Agreement cannot shift costs to other jurisdictions.722 It submits 
    that whenever retail load changes, whether due to retail wheeling or 
    any other factor, responsibility ratios under Entergy's reserve 
    equalization schedule, MSS-1, will change and costs will shift 
    irrespective of the regulator's treatment of retail stranded costs. AR 
    Com says that MSS-1 reveals no changes in calculations due to retail 
    treatment of stranded costs or any other retail ratemaking; only 
    ``excess'' capacity costs of intermediate gas- and oil-fired plant are 
    ``shifted'' under the Entergy System Agreement. Although the Commission 
    has the authority to amend intra-system agreements when
    
    [[Page 12415]]
    
    wholesale cost allocations have become unjust and unreasonable, AR Com 
    submits that the Commission does not have jurisdiction to reach to the 
    state level and dictate what retail ratepayers should pay to 
    shareholders. AR Com maintains that a FERC-jurisdictional intra-system 
    agreement extends only to sales for resale (transactions among 
    subsidiaries), and that if a holding company believes that an intra-
    system agreement is unduly discriminatory as a result of a state's 
    disallowance of costs, the holding company can propose to amend 
    it.723
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \722\ See also MO/KS Coms (the cost-shifting problem does not 
    arise because of a particular state treatment of stranded costs; it 
    arises because Entergy insists on recovering 100 percent of its 
    costs even when some portion of the costs are not economical).
        \723\ AR Com also objects to the Commission's description of the 
    issue as involving not only holding companies, but also other multi-
    state situations. AR Com says that ``[t]he mere fact that a 
    company's territory crosses state lines does not automatically mean 
    that all assets serve all customers, or that all customers are 
    required to bear the economic risk associated with all assets, or 
    that assets that at one time were solely state-jurisdictional can 
    somehow, by virtue of a company's decision to expand across state 
    lines, become FERC-jurisdictional.'' AR Com at 11.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        AR Com argues that retail stranded costs fall to state jurisdiction 
    regardless of whether the utility is a member of an interstate holding 
    company. AR Com says that because the costs at issue are in retail rate 
    base, any Commission influence over their recovery could occur only 
    through preemption, but preemption of a state disallowance from retail 
    rate base is possible only if there is a ``trapped cost.'' AR Com 
    submits that a disallowance of retail rate base cost cannot result in a 
    trapped cost because there is no inconsistency between two agencies 
    acting within their jurisdiction; the Commission has no jurisdiction to 
    act. AR Com maintains that, unlike the Grand Gulf situation, the 
    Commission has not mandated any Entergy generation costs into retail 
    rate base. It further says that different state decisions regarding 
    recovery of retail costs are not inconsistent decisions; they represent 
    each state applying its law to its facts. According to AR Com, 
    decisions by states leading to less than full recovery could be deemed 
    inconsistent decisions only if there were a federal guarantee of full 
    cost recovery of retail costs, which there is not.
        AR Com and MO/KS Coms assert that the Commission's proposal for 
    holding company situations cannot apply to future holding companies, 
    where there is no history of joint planning justifying cost 
    equalization, nor can it apply to future investments. They contend that 
    this would require an assumption that the utility subsidiaries of a 
    registered holding company have planned, and should plan, together 
    rather than separately (i.e., that interaffiliate transactions are 
    always more efficient than nonaffiliate transactions), and that such 
    assumption would be sound only if having the transaction occur between 
    affiliates is inherently more efficient than having the transaction 
    occur between an affiliate and a nonaffiliate.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The comments raised for the most part are either premature or 
    reflect a misunderstanding of the Commission's decision. Contrary to AR 
    Com's argument, the Commission in Order No. 888 in no way asserted 
    jurisdiction over state determinations of stranded costs associated 
    with retail wheeling customers. We agree with AR Com that our 
    jurisdiction extends only to sales for resale (and transmission in 
    interstate commerce) and that a holding company can seek to amend an 
    intra-system agreement if it believes the agreement is unduly 
    discriminatory as a result of a state's disallowance of costs. However, 
    a holding company also may seek to amend an agreement before any 
    potential disallowances can occur, to keep cost-shifting from 
    occurring. The fact is that intra-system agreements which involve 
    wholesale sales among affiliate companies in different states could, 
    through operation of their reserve equalization formulas, result in 
    customers in one or more states having to indirectly bear stranded 
    costs that are disallowed in another state, and the Commission has a 
    responsibility to prevent inappropriate cost-shifting. Such 
    determinations can be made only on a case-by-case basis. Again, as we 
    stated in Order No. 888, we encourage affected state commissions to 
    propose mutually agreeable solutions to this potential problem.
    8. Evidentiary Demonstration Necessary--Reasonable Expectation Standard
        In Order No. 888, the Commission concluded that a utility seeking 
    to recover stranded costs must demonstrate that it had a reasonable 
    expectation of continuing to serve a customer. We stated that whether a 
    utility had a reasonable expectation of continuing to serve a customer, 
    and for how long, will be determined on a case-by-case basis, and will 
    depend on all of the facts and circumstances. We also determined that 
    the existence of a notice provision in a contract would create a 
    rebuttable presumption that the utility had no reasonable expectation 
    of serving the customer beyond the specified period. We said that 
    whether or not a contract contains an ``evergreen'' or other automatic 
    renewal provision will be a factor to be considered in determining 
    whether the presumption of no reasonable expectation is rebutted in a 
    particular case.724
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \724\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,831; mimeo at 570-72.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We also said that we would apply the reasonable expectation 
    standard to retail-turned-wholesale customers. We explained that, 
    before the Commission will permit a utility to recover stranded costs, 
    the utility must demonstrate that it incurred such costs based on a 
    reasonable expectation that the retail-turned-wholesale customer would 
    continue to receive bundled retail service. Whether the state law 
    awards exclusive service territories and imposes a mandatory obligation 
    to serve would be among the factors to be considered in determining 
    whether the reasonable expectation test is met in a particular 
    case.725
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \725\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,831; mimeo at 572. We indicated 
    that the same procedures would apply to retail customers that obtain 
    retail wheeling.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We noted that Order No. 888 does not address who will bear the 
    stranded costs caused by a departing generation customer if the 
    Commission finds that the utility had no reasonable expectation of 
    continuing to serve that customer. We indicated that we anticipate 
    that, in such a case, a public utility will seek in subsequent 
    requirements rate cases to have the costs reallocated among the 
    remaining customers on its system. However, we stated that we were not 
    prejudging that issue in the Rule.726
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \726\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,831; mimeo at 572-73.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests Opposing or Seeking Modification of the Reasonable 
    Expectation Standard
    
        APPA challenges the reasonable expectation standard as being too 
    vague. It submits that the Commission has provided no guidance 
    concerning application of the reasonable expectation standard, other 
    than to state that it would decide the issue on a case-by-case basis. 
    APPA objects that public utilities can exploit the uncertainty created 
    by this standard, which will lead to costly and time-consuming 
    litigation. IL Com supports replacing the reasonable expectation 
    standard with a statutory, regulatory, contractual standard.
        Several entities contend that there is no basis to conclude that 
    the reasonable expectation test could ever be met. VT DPS and Valero 
    submit that, since 1973, utilities have known that a refusal to wheel 
    power could subject them to antitrust liability. They say that Order 
    No. 888 ignores the breadth of NRC
    
    [[Page 12416]]
    
    licensing conditions. LEPA similarly argues that the reasonable 
    expectation standard could not be met where NRC license conditions 
    required an explicit wheeling commitment and prohibited the utility 
    from including in the wheeling cost any amount attributable to the loss 
    of customers due to the wheeling. It objects that delaying a decision 
    on stranded cost recovery in such cases holds the threat of possible 
    stranded cost charges over the heads of bulk power purchasers and 
    thereby chills their ability to seek competitive sellers.
        TAPS asserts that there should be an irrefutable presumption that 
    no stranded costs are due from customers with pre-existing transmission 
    rights, including customers who were the beneficiaries of NRC license 
    conditions.727 TAPS submits that there can be no legitimate 
    ``reasonable expectation'' that such customers would continue to 
    purchase power if the price was higher than the market price.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \727\ AMP-Ohio submits that where transmission access and 
    competition have existed to varying extents for decades, there 
    should be an irrebuttable presumption of no reasonable expectation 
    of continued service.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Occidental Chemical asks the Commission to clarify that a utility 
    could have had no reasonable expectation of recovering stranded costs 
    from customers who, prior to the issuance of the NOPR, had the 
    opportunity to switch to an alternative electric supplier or had the 
    option of self-generating, obtaining on-site third-party generation, or 
    municipalizing. Occidental Chemical further argues that it defies 
    commercial expectations to allow a utility to argue that if a contract 
    is silent on the issue of renewal, the obligation to purchase does not 
    expire with the termination of the contract. It submits that the 
    Commission has not shown that it has the authority to force customers 
    to extend purchase agreements against their will in violation of 
    accepted commercial practice.
        A number of entities submit that the Commission erred in failing to 
    treat a notice of termination provision as conclusive evidence that the 
    utility had no reasonable expectation of continued service.728 
    Several object that the Commission has failed to explain why the 
    presence of a notice provision does not conclusively demonstrate the 
    lack of a reasonable expectation and ipso facto terminate the 
    obligation of the customer to purchase the product.729 APPA 
    objects that the Commission provided no evidence that it considered 
    comments supporting making the presumption conclusive and that it found 
    legally sufficient reasons to reject them.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \728\ E.g., APPA, American Forest & Paper, Central Montana EC, 
    NRECA, TDU Systems, Oglethorpe, IMPA, VT DPS, Valero, PA Munis.
        \729\ E.g., APPA, NRECA, TDU Systems. See also VT DPS and Valero 
    (by signing a contract with a termination date, the utility assumed 
    the risk that the customer will elect to leave when the contract 
    expires).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        PA Munis objects that the rebuttable presumption represents an 
    unjustified departure from the Commission's traditional policy of 
    enforcing the express terms of notice provisions without any inquiry 
    into the reasonable expectations of the party, provided that the 
    agreements were negotiated in good faith and approved by the 
    Commission.730 PA Munis contends that wholesale requirements 
    customers negotiated notice provisions with the knowledge that the 
    Commission would enforce the notice provisions according to their 
    terms, including the specific length of the term. 731 PA Munis 
    argues that it is arbitrary and capricious to provide utilities an 
    opportunity to seek to amend these contracts.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \730\ In support of its argument, PA Munis cites Boston Edison 
    Company, 56 FPC 3414 (1976). See also American Forest & Paper.
        \731\ Citing Kentucky Utilities Company, 23 FERC para. 61,317 
    (1983); Philadelphia Electric Company and Susquehanna Electric 
    Company, 65 FERC para. 61,303 (1993).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Several entities submit that the rebuttable presumption invites 
    litigation and promotes uncertainty for customers.732 APPA objects 
    that the Commission has failed to establish the showing that it would 
    require to overcome the presumption.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \732\ E.g., NRECA, IMPA, PA Munis.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Referring to the Commission's discussion of evergreen provisions, 
    Central Montana EC argues that it is wrong to infer from the existence 
    of an automatic renewal provision that the parties intended that the 
    contract might run longer than its initial term. Central Montana EC 
    asserts that the presence of an evergreen provision infers simply that 
    the parties agreed upon a mechanism to avoid the renegotiation of a 
    power supply contract if, at the conclusion of its initial term, the 
    parties were satisfied with the contract. It maintains that the 
    parties' obligations are defined by the term and termination provisions 
    of wholesale power contracts, and that the presence of a mechanism to 
    avoid contract renegotiation does not alter those termination rights.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We will reject the requests for rehearing of our decision to adopt 
    a reasonable expectation standard to be applied on a case-by-case basis 
    and to treat a notice provision in a contract as a rebuttable, not a 
    conclusive, presumption of no reasonable expectation. Contrary to the 
    claims of some entities, the Commission has explained the basis for its 
    finding that utilities may have had an implicit obligation to serve 
    their wholesale requirements customers and, therefore, that a utility 
    should be given an opportunity to demonstrate that it incurred costs to 
    provide service to a customer and that it had a reasonable expectation 
    that it would continue to serve the customer beyond the contract 
    termination date. The same factors that some petitioners contend 
    establish the absence of a reasonable expectation of continued service 
    may be offered as evidence to be considered in determining whether the 
    reasonable expectation test is met in a particular case.
        We believe that our decision to treat a notice of termination 
    provision in a contract as creating a rebuttable presumption that the 
    utility had no reasonable expectation of serving the customer beyond 
    the period provided for in the notice provision is a reasonable one. It 
    places evidentiary significance on the fact that a contract contains a 
    notice of termination provision. Moreover, while it gives the utility 
    an opportunity, based on the facts and circumstances of a particular 
    case, to rebut the presumption of no reasonable expectation, it firmly 
    places the burden of establishing reasonable expectation on the 
    utility. Although some entities support treating notice provisions as a 
    conclusive presumption of no reasonable expectation, as discussed 
    below, we decline to adopt such an inflexible approach. Nevertheless, 
    as we indicated in Order No. 888, when a utility is seeking a contract 
    amendment to permit stranded cost recovery based on expectations beyond 
    the stated term of the contract, we believe that the utility has a 
    heavy burden in demonstrating that the contract ought to be 
    modified.733
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \733\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,665, 31,813-14; mimeo at 87, 
    522.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Contrary to the position of PA Munis, the rebuttable presumption is 
    fully consistent with the Commission's past treatment of notice 
    provisions. For example, the Kentucky Utilities Company case cited by 
    PA Munis supports the proposition that, until a customer exercises a 
    notice of
    
    [[Page 12417]]
    
    termination provision, the utility is under an implicit obligation to 
    continue to serve and plan for the future needs of the 
    customer.734 Thus, the presence of a notice of termination 
    provision in a contract (particularly one not yet exercised by the 
    customer), in and of itself, may not necessarily support the conclusion 
    that the utility could never prove that it reasonably expected to 
    continue serving the customer beyond the notice period.735
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \734\ See Kentucky Utilities Company, 23 FERC at 61,679-80 
    (``Once it receives an effective notice of cancellation, Kentucky 
    can stop planning for the future needs of that customer. . . . To be 
    effective a notice of cancellation must contain a specification of 
    the source of supply, the date on which the source of supply will be 
    available, and an affidavit from the supplier that it will supply 
    the customer on the date the contract ends.'').
        \735\ See Potomac Electric Power Company, 43 FERC para. 61,189 
    (1988) (suspending a notice of termination for five months due to 
    questions about the impact of the proposed cancellation on service 
    reliability).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In response to APPA's objection that the Commission has failed to 
    establish the showing that it would require to overcome the 
    presumption, we note that the Commission cannot establish such a 
    showing upfront because whether there is sufficient evidence to rebut 
    the presumption of no reasonable expectation will depend on the facts 
    of each case.
        We appreciate the concerns expressed by some entities that the 
    rebuttable presumption may increase the customer's uncertainty by 
    inviting litigation. We have carefully weighed the pros and cons of 
    treating a notice provision as a rebuttable presumption of no 
    reasonable expectation versus the pros and cons of treating it as a 
    conclusive presumption of no reasonable expectation. It is true, as 
    some entities assert, that the rebuttable presumption approach presents 
    the potential for litigation between the parties as to whether, in a 
    particular case, the utility can rebut the presumption. The alternative 
    would be to treat all contracts with notice of termination provisions 
    as conclusive evidence that the utility could have had no reasonable 
    expectation that it would continue to serve the customer beyond the 
    specified notice period. While the latter approach presumably would 
    reduce the number of cases in which the issue of a utility's reasonable 
    expectation would have to be litigated, it would do so only by 
    prohibiting a utility from ever demonstrating that, notwithstanding the 
    existence of a notice provision, based on the facts of a particular 
    case, the utility reasonably expected to continue serving the customer. 
    While we do not prejudge the likelihood of a utility being able to 
    rebut the presumption in a particular case, we believe that it would 
    not be in the public interest for the Commission to absolutely preclude 
    a utility from being able to make such a showing. On this basis, we 
    conclude that treating a notice provision as a rebuttable, rather than 
    a conclusive, presumption that the utility did not have a reasonable 
    expectation of continuing service to the customer is, on balance, the 
    fairer and more equitable approach.
        Central Montana EC asserts that it is wrong to infer from the 
    existence of an automatic renewal provision that the parties intended 
    that the contract might run longer than its initial term. However, our 
    statement in Order No. 888 that the existence of an automatic renewal 
    provision will be a factor to be considered in determining whether the 
    presumption of no reasonable expectation is rebutted in a particular 
    case makes no such inference. Whether the utility can rebut the 
    presumption will depend on the facts of each case.
    
    Rehearing Requests Supporting Modification of Evidentiary Standard for 
    Retail Customers
    
        Several entities ask the Commission to consider adopting a 
    rebuttable presumption that utilities had a reasonable expectation of 
    continuing to serve any retail load for which they had a public utility 
    obligation to serve. They submit that the burden should be on the 
    former bundled retail customer to show that the utility's service 
    obligation was not binding and that the utility's expectation of 
    continuing service was unfounded.736 Florida Power Corp and 
    Utilities For Improved Transition suggest that the only exception to 
    such a rebuttable presumption should be for retail customers that gave 
    notice of termination before the effective date of the Rule. EEI 
    expresses concern that the issue may be wrongly decided on the 
    existence (or lack) of an exclusive franchise. It states that while 
    many states do award franchises delineating exclusive service 
    territories, some do not, even though long-established service 
    arrangements are in place. Puget submits that because there is a duty 
    to serve all retail customers, Order No. 888 should provide for 
    stranded cost recovery from all departing retail customers without 
    application of a reasonable expectation test.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \736\ E.g., EEI, Oklahoma G&E, Southern, Florida Power Corp, 
    Utilities For Improved Transition.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        NY Com, on the other hand, opposes application of the reasonable 
    expectation standard to stranded costs associated with retail-turned-
    wholesale customers. It argues that the reasonable expectation test 
    would ignore prudence, customer impact, financial viability and a 
    series of criteria traditionally analyzed by state regulatory agencies 
    in determining rate treatment of costs incurred with the intention of 
    providing service.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We will deny the requests for rehearing of the Commission's 
    decision to apply the reasonable expectation standard to retail-turned-
    wholesale and retail wheeling customers on a case-by-case basis without 
    adopting a rebuttable presumption that utilities had a reasonable 
    expectation of continuing to serve any retail load for which they had a 
    public utility obligation to serve. When a utility seeks to recover 
    stranded costs from former bundled retail customers, we think it is 
    appropriate that the utility bear the burden of proving reasonable 
    expectation (instead of requiring the customer to bear the burden of 
    disproving the utility's reasonable expectation). Placing the burden on 
    the utility is consistent with the requirement of sections 205 and 206 
    of the FPA that a public utility demonstrate the justness and 
    reasonableness of its proposed rates. The same factors that are offered 
    as support for the establishment of a rebuttable presumption of a 
    reasonable expectation (such as the utility's obligation to serve all 
    retail customers) may be offered by the utility as evidence to be 
    considered in determining whether the reasonable expectation test is 
    met in a particular case.
        We also will deny NY Com's request that the Commission not apply 
    the reasonable expectation standard to retail-turned-wholesale 
    customers. We believe it is appropriate to require the same evidentiary 
    demonstration for recovery of stranded costs from a retail-turned-
    wholesale customer as that required in the case of a wholesale 
    requirements customer. Moreover, as discussed in Section IV.J.7 above, 
    the reasonable expectation standard contemplates evidence as to what a 
    utility might reasonably expect to recover under state law, and we will 
    give great weight to a state's view of what might be recoverable.
    9. Calculation of Recoverable Stranded Costs
        In Order No. 888, the Commission considered various proposals 
    regarding how stranded costs should be calculated and who should pay. 
    With respect to the calculation of stranded costs, the Commission 
    rejected as overly complicated and costly an asset-by-asset
    
    [[Page 12418]]
    
    approach to determine the amount of stranded costs assigned to a 
    departing customer. Instead, the Commission determined that the 
    revenues lost approach was the fairest and most efficient way to make 
    this determination during the transition to a competitive wholesale 
    bulk power market. The Commission adopted the following revenues lost 
    formula for calculating the stranded cost for each departing customer: 
    SCO-(RSE--CMVE) x L. The Commission provided a precise definition for 
    each component of the formula,737 and made the application of the 
    formula, and collection of the resulting stranded costs, subject to a 
    number of conditions.738
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \737\ Briefly, SCO refers to the departing customer's stranded 
    cost obligation, which is determined by taking the average annual 
    revenues that the customer would have paid had it remained a 
    customer of the utility (RSE), and subtracting from it the 
    competitive market value of the power (on an average annual basis) 
    no longer taken by the departing customer (CMVE). The difference 
    represents the average annual stranded cost, which must be 
    multiplied by ``L'' (L represents the period over which the utility 
    reasonably could have expected to serve the departing customer 
    beyond the contract termination, but for the open access required 
    under Order No. 888) to produce the departing customer's total SCO.
        \738\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,839-40; mimeo at 595-99.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    RSE Issues
    
        Numerous petitioners oppose the use of present revenues in the 
    stranded cost formula.739 TDU Systems argues that the revenues 
    lost approach is arbitrary and capricious because its effect exceeds 
    its purpose. Specifically, TDU Systems contends that the revenues lost 
    approach can permit overrecovery because it provides recovery of any 
    difference between pre-Order No. 888 cost-plus rates and post-Order No. 
    888 competitive rates, regardless of the cause of the difference. TDU 
    Systems cites enhanced utilization and technological improvements as 
    two examples of pre-and post-Order No. 888 rate differences that are 
    not competition related, but for which recovery would be provided. TDU 
    Systems states that instead of using present revenues, RSE should be 
    calculated based on the most current, reliable estimate of future 
    revenues.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \739\ E.g., TDU Systems, APPA, Central Vermont, ELCON.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Multiple Intervenors argues that the revenues lost method assumes 
    that a utility's costs of operating its plants are per se reasonable, 
    yet the New York utilities' current rates include levels of O&M, 
    especially wages and benefits, expenses that may reflect inefficiencies 
    and thus are not stranded costs for which a utility's shareholders 
    should be compensated. Similarly, other petitioners oppose as backward-
    looking the use of present revenues for what should be a forward-
    looking remedy, consistent with the other elements in the 
    formula.740 TDU Systems argues that the use of past revenues is 
    inappropriate in a falling cost environment, and notes that new 
    capacity costs are less than the existing capacity costs embedded in a 
    utility's rate base.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \740\ E.g., TDU Systems, NRECA, Central Montana EC, SoCal 
    Edison.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        NYSEG states that the Commission should permit a utility to 
    reconcile initial stranded cost charges to actual stranded costs on a 
    periodic basis to account for changes in sales, energy purchases from 
    NUGs, and changes in market price. NYSEG supports development of 
    stranded cost charges based on three-year estimates. Under this 
    approach, a customer would pay locked-in charges for a series of three-
    year periods. At the end of each period, the stranded cost estimate 
    would be revised for the next three-year period. This process would 
    continue until all stranded costs are recovered.741 Other 
    petitioners support the use of a projected revenue stream or a true-up 
    mechanism.742 These petitioners argue that a true-up mechanism is 
    necessary to protect all parties against the inevitable risk of 
    inaccurate forecasts.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \741\ See also Coalition for Economic Competition at 47.
        \742\ E.g., Central Vermont, Texaco, Carolina P&L.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        ELCON argues that calculating RSE based upon customer usage over 
    the past three years results in an artificially high stranded cost 
    because it fails to take into account that the utility would have had 
    to reduce its prices in the future in response to competition. ELCON 
    states that wholesale customers have a reasonable expectation that 
    utility costs will be lower in the future, and thus that the annual 
    revenues contributed by a customer who remains with the utility would 
    be lower than RSE. ELCON further contends that the revenues lost 
    formula should not guarantee the profits the utility was allowed to 
    receive prior to the issuance of Order No. 888 because such revenues 
    included a risk factor (e.g., plant operating risk, or risk of customer 
    insolvency) that is absent under the direct assignment method of 
    allocating stranded costs. ELCON cites Town of Norwood v. FERC 743 
    as support for its position that the RSE should be reduced to reflect 
    the decreased risk associated with the direct assignment approach.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \743\ 80 F.3d 526 (D.C. Cir. 1996) (Town of Norwood).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        TDU Systems and NRECA also argue that the Commission should 
    eliminate from RSE the risk component of the return on equity contained 
    in present rates. They argue for this adjustment because the Commission 
    is eliminating the risk associated with non-recovery of plant costs by 
    providing full recovery of stranded costs. NRECA further contends that 
    if the Commission keeps the equity return in the calculation of 
    stranded costs, it should permit a consumer-owned system to include an 
    imputed equity component in its RSE if it needs to recover stranded 
    costs.
        APPA argues that the use of present revenues fails to reflect 
    future cost reductions expected from accumulated depreciation, load 
    growth, and declining capital costs. APPA further opposes the use of 
    present revenues because present revenues are the direct product of the 
    monopoly power that the utility exercised over transmission. APPA 
    states that RSE should be calculated based upon the price of wholesale 
    power in a competitive market.
        CCEM argues that only fixed costs should be eligible for recovery, 
    and that this amount should exclude any return on investment. CCEM 
    would exclude variable costs from the calculation of stranded costs 
    because allowing recovery of variable charges would encourage the 
    continued operation of facilities that are conceded to be uneconomic. 
    CCEM further contends that the Commission should provide less than full 
    recovery of stranded costs so that the utility has some incentive to 
    mitigate them.
        Central Vermont states that where the contract does not commit the 
    customer to a set amount of service, the utility's reasonable 
    expectation of the amount of continuing service will not necessarily be 
    reflected in the revenues of the three previous years. Central Vermont 
    urges the Commission to allow utilities the option of showing that 
    their actual reasonable expectation of continued service differs from 
    historical experience. Central Vermont maintains that any other 
    approach would be less than reasonable, and, in fact, would be 
    arbitrary and capricious.
        Numerous petitioners 744 would retain the use of present 
    revenues as the RSE; however, they support a limited exception that 
    would permit a utility to seek recovery of certain future cost 
    increases (primarily nuclear decommissioning costs, back-loaded PURPA 
    contract costs, and other deferred costs) if those costs are not in 
    rates now or are in rates but are being under-recovered at present. 
    These
    
    [[Page 12419]]
    
    petitioners argue that the majority of these costs were incurred as a 
    result of various regulatory mandates, with the reasonable expectation 
    of future recovery in rates. As a part of their proposal, Utilities For 
    Improved Transition and EEI (and others) support offsetting such cost 
    increases with any decreases in other costs reflected in present 
    revenues. Utilities For Improved Transition maintains that nuclear 
    decommissioning costs, in particular, should be revisited as they 
    become better defined. Similarly, Nuclear Energy Institute and others 
    request that the Commission allow a utility, on a case-by-case basis, 
    to propose its own recovery mechanism, as nuclear decommissioning costs 
    are significantly different from other future cost increases.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \744\ E.g., EEI, Utilities For Improved Transition, VEPCO, 
    Coalition for Economic Competition.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Lastly, TDU Systems and NRECA object to the manner by which the 
    formula deducts average transmission-related revenues (which would be 
    unbundled in the utility's new open access tariff) in the development 
    of RSE. TDU Systems and NRECA contend that the transmission credit, 
    because it is based on the revenues that would be generated under a 
    utility's new wholesale tariff, would not reflect that the cost of 
    transmission has been declining.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        In Order No. 888, the Commission stated that the use of ``present'' 
    annual revenues as the basis for the stranded cost calculation has 
    numerous advantages over other approaches advocated. The Commission 
    noted that the use of present revenues (1) eliminates disputes over 
    estimates of future revenues, providing certainty to the calculation; 
    and (2) eliminates the need for a detailed listing and litigation of 
    includable costs, relying instead on the presumption that present rates 
    include all just and reasonable costs of providing service. The 
    Commission further noted that the rates that produce present revenues 
    have been approved by regulators, which strongly suggests that the 
    costs included in them are prudent, legitimate and verifiable.
        The Commission continues to believe that the use of present 
    revenues as the basis for the stranded cost calculation is superior to 
    other proposed methods. Arguments that the use of present revenues 
    either over-or under-recovers ``true'' costs are not persuasive. Either 
    the customer or the utility may file for a change in rates before the 
    existing contract ends if it believes the existing rate is 
    inappropriate.
        In response to petitioners requesting an RSE based on estimates of 
    future revenues for the reasonable expectation period (L), we continue 
    to believe that an approach based on estimates of future revenue 
    streams would engender countless disputes over the RSE component in the 
    formula with little, if any, added accuracy. These would in effect be 
    rate cases that attempt to litigate not what costs were during a test 
    year based on audited accounting data, but what costs will be, based on 
    speculation about future fuel costs, employment levels, capital costs, 
    and so on. In contrast, we believe that the use of present revenues 
    will produce fair results and minimize litigation of RSE. This is 
    appropriate for a transition period cost recovery charge that needs to 
    be settled quickly for market participants to make business decisions 
    about future wholesale sales and purchases. Our approach minimizes 
    transaction costs and provides greater certainty with respect to the 
    RSE term in the formula.
        Some have argued that a method that periodically adjusts the 
    departing customer's stranded cost obligation in the future to reflect 
    actual future increases or decreases in a utility's future cost-based 
    rates would produce more accurate results. However, this ``true-up'' 
    approach has several difficulties. First, it assumes that the utility 
    will have wholesale cost-based rates in the future. Many utilities 
    already sell in the wholesale market at market-based rates, and this 
    trend is accelerating. Having a series of ongoing rate cases solely for 
    the purpose of trueing-up a stranded cost calculation would be 
    cumbersome and costly. It would eliminate much of the regulatory cost 
    savings that result from market-based rates. Further, even if ``cost-
    based'' rates were on file in the future, many such future wholesale 
    rates, as in the past, are likely to result from settlements among the 
    parties. Such settlements are agreements on prices that do not 
    necessarily spell out the cost components of the final agreed-upon 
    rate.
        These difficulties aside, the true-up approach would introduce a 
    great deal of ongoing uncertainty about the departing customer's 
    stranded cost obligation. This uncertainty would add unnecessary risk 
    for both the customer and the utility as they consider alternative 
    purchase or sales transactions. Customers would have no way of knowing 
    what their ultimate stranded cost charge would be, and therefore would 
    be unable to evaluate definitively whether changing suppliers would be 
    beneficial. Under a true-up approach, the eventual sum of the 
    customer's SCO and replacement power cost could be more or less than 
    the amount it would have paid had it simply stayed with its host 
    supplier. This possibility could discourage many customers from taking 
    advantage of the open access provided by Order No. 888. We believe that 
    any potential accuracy benefit of a true-up approach is greatly 
    outweighed by the cost, uncertainty, delay, and litigation such an 
    approach would cause.
        In summary, we believe that the use of present revenues as the 
    basis for calculating stranded cost appropriately balances precision 
    and efficiency 745 for what is fundamentally a transition period 
    policy.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \745\ The use of present revenues is reasonably workable from an 
    administrative standpoint.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In response to the other arguments raised, the Commission makes the 
    following findings. We disagree with ELCON that the use of present 
    revenues will result in an artificially high stranded cost because it 
    fails to account for the fact that a utility would have to lower its 
    prices to respond to new competition. ELCON's argument is circular in 
    that much of the new competition to which it refers results from our 
    issuance of Order No. 888. ELCON's approach would undo the goal of 
    providing recovery of stranded costs by eliminating the very difference 
    that the formula is intended to determine. 746 ELCON's argument is 
    rejected accordingly.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \746\ Our rationale here is equally applicable to APPA's 
    argument that RSE should be based upon the price of wholesale power 
    in a competitive market.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In addition, ELCON's reliance on Town of Norwood (for the 
    proposition that RSE should be reduced to reflect the reduced operating 
    risk and reduced risk of customer insolvency associated with direct 
    assignment of stranded costs) is misplaced. In Town of Norwood, the 
    Commission was faced with a request for recovery of plant costs. The 
    utility made a cost-effective proposal to shut down its single asset, a 
    small nuclear reactor. In that case, the Commission disallowed full 
    return on investment in part because the unit was no longer operating 
    and the utility had no operating risk.
        Elimination of the rate of return is inappropriate because, unlike 
    Town of Norwood, the departing customer's service is not tied to any 
    particular unit; rather, service is considered to be provided by the 
    entire system. Contrary to ELCON's assertion, operating risk is not 
    reduced because the utility must continue to operate its generating 
    facilities (by reselling the capacity) if it is to recover all its 
    costs. Accordingly,
    
    [[Page 12420]]
    
    there is not a reduced operating risk as argued by ELCON.
        With respect to ELCON's customer insolvency argument, this risk is 
    also present under the direct assignment approach. Because Order No. 
    888 permits a customer to pay its stranded cost obligation over a 
    number of years, during this period the customer could become 
    insolvent, thereby leaving the utility with uncollected stranded 
    costs.747
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \747\ In addition, Order No. 888 provides recovery of only the 
    difference between the average annual revenues that the customer 
    would have paid had it remained a customer (RSE) and the estimated 
    competitive market value (CMVE) of the released power (i.e., the 
    stranded cost). However, while the formula contemplates that the 
    utility can sell the released power at the estimated competitive 
    market value, the actual market value may be lower, increasing the 
    risk that the utility will not be able to recover its stranded 
    costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Also, unlike Town of Norwood, the utility is presently collecting 
    rates that compensate for traditional utility risks, but do not include 
    the risk of open access. Further, eliminating the rate of return would 
    engender considerable complication, speculation and expense as the 
    Commission would have to determine an appropriate rate of return that 
    included some risks (e.g., customer bankruptcy) but not others (e.g., 
    211 request or use of the open access tariff). Thus, eliminating the 
    rate of return (or a portion thereof) is inappropriate.
        Accordingly, ELCON's arguments that the revenue stream should be 
    reduced to reflect lower risk associated with direct assignment is 
    rejected. Instead, we continue to believe that the transmission 
    provider is entitled to recover all the costs, including return on 
    equity, that it incurred based on a reasonable expectation of having to 
    serve the departing customer. All these costs would have been 
    recoverable absent the action taken in Order No. 888.748
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \748\ In Order No. 888, the Commission rejected arguments that 
    return-related revenues be excluded from the revenue stream. The 
    Commission found that such exclusion would effectively require 
    shareholders to absorb stranded costs, which is contrary to the 
    Commission's finding that a utility is entitled to an opportunity to 
    fully recover legitimate, prudent and verifiable stranded costs. In 
    this order, we reaffirm our earlier finding.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission also rejects NRECA's proposal to include an imputed 
    equity component in the RSE when calculating stranded costs for a 
    consumer-owned system. Simply put, if a cost is not stranded, or if a 
    cost is not really a cost, recovery should not be granted.
        The Commission rejects APPA's contention that it is inappropriate 
    to use present revenues as the RSE because those revenues are the 
    direct product of the monopoly power that the utility exercised over 
    transmission. The Commission believes that the use of present revenues 
    is one of the strengths of the formula in that the rates that produce 
    present revenues have been approved by regulators as just and 
    reasonable, which strongly suggests that the costs included in them 
    have been shown to be prudent, legitimate and verifiable.
        In response to CCEM's argument that only fixed costs should be 
    eligible for recovery (because the inclusion of variable costs in the 
    RSE will encourage the continued operation of facilities that are 
    conceded to be uneconomic), we agree. The Commission notes that 
    condition 1, ``Cap on SCO'' 749 limits the recovery of stranded 
    costs to fixed costs. Accordingly, the formula, as designed, addresses 
    CCEM's concern.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \749\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,840; mimeo at 597.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We note that Central Vermont supports its opposition to the use of 
    present revenues differently from other petitioners, who argue (in 
    effect) that the price component of RSE is flawed.750 Central 
    Vermont, on the other hand, is concerned that the quantity component of 
    present revenues may not reflect the quantity that would have been 
    taken during L. It states that the Commission should permit the utility 
    to show that it had a reasonable expectation of continued customer 
    service that is not based on the customer's previous three years of 
    power consumption. The Commission does not believe that this is 
    appropriate. Central Vermont's approach would introduce forecasting 
    controversy, litigation cost, and uncertainty which are similar to the 
    disputes about cost discussed above. For example, a utility might argue 
    that the customer was expected to consume more than it has in the last 
    three years, based presumably on such factors as expected economic 
    development, changing demographics, appliance saturation rates, and 
    even changes in climate. Conversely, the departing customer might argue 
    that it would have increased electricity conservation efforts, used 
    more natural gas, relied more on self-generation, and so on, if open 
    access had not been made available by Order No. 888. The Commission has 
    stated above why it favors the use of present revenues, for both price 
    and quantity combined, and these reasons apply regardless of whether 
    the argument is directed toward the price or quantity component of 
    present revenues.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \750\ Present revenues depend, of course, on both price and 
    quantity. Most petitioners who dispute the use of present revenues 
    argue, in some fashion or another, that present revenues are 
    inappropriate because the costs included in present revenues may not 
    equate to the costs incurred by the utility during L. These 
    petitioners are arguing about price.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Finally, TDU Systems' and NRECA's argument regarding the 
    transmission revenue credit component of RSE is made on the same basis 
    as their argument that the revenue stream should be calculated on a 
    forward-looking basis. For the reasons discussed above, we reject this 
    argument also.
        Therefore, after consideration of the arguments on rehearing, and 
    reconsideration of our policy rationale supporting the use of present 
    revenues, we continue to support the use of present revenues, without 
    true-ups or adders, as the basis for the stranded cost formula. We find 
    that the use of present revenues fairly and efficiently balances the 
    competing interests of the affected parties.
    
    CMVE Issues
    
        Petitioners raised a number of CMVE related issues. We take them up 
    in the following two categories.
    
    Present Value Issues
    
        EEI agrees with the Commission that stranded costs should be 
    calculated on a present value basis. EEI states that with respect to 
    RSE, the formula appears to be stated on a present value basis, 
    although it believes that the language could be strengthened to read: 
    ``the present value of average annual revenues from the departing 
    customer over the three years prior * * * '' (new text emphasized).
        However, EEI maintains that the rule fails to define CMVE clearly 
    on a present value basis. Therefore, EEI suggests that the Commission 
    clarify the definition as follows: ``Option 1--the utility's estimate 
    of the net present value of the average annual revenues * * * or Option 
    2--the net present value of the average annual cost to the customer of 
    replacement capacity and associated energy * * * '' (new text 
    underlined). EEI states that this clarification could also be applied 
    to the ``Cap on SCO,'' to put it on a par with the other definitions in 
    terms of the time value component.
        TDU Systems and NRECA also express concerns regarding the 
    calculation of SCO on a present value basis. Specifically, they state 
    that the formula contains no component, factor, or other mechanism to 
    indicate how such present value is to be determined. They also state 
    that no discount rate is specified, and that the calculation should be 
    synchronized with the customer's chosen payment option. Central Vermont 
    maintains that the Commission should make it clear that a utility is 
    entitled to recovery of both
    
    [[Page 12421]]
    
    stranded costs and the time value of those costs from the date on which 
    they were experienced through the date of their recovery.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We believe that EEI misinterprets our intent with the three-year 
    average annual revenues for RSE. EEI is proposing to increase the 
    revenues of three years ago to current dollars, the revenues of two 
    years ago to current dollars (and so on) before finding the three-year 
    average. The Commission clarifies that our use of the term ``present 
    value'' does not require such an adjustment. If the utility thought its 
    rates on file did not adequately reflect rising costs, it should have 
    filed for a rate increase. If it did file for and receive a rate 
    increase, the formula does not use a three-year average, but rather 
    revenue based on the new rate.751 It would be inappropriate to 
    adjust the three years of revenue used to calculate RSE to a current 
    dollar value if these rates have been in effect for three years without 
    change. It is assumed that all costs, including inflationary and 
    deflationary changes in the underlying costs, have been recovered. We 
    do not have any time lag between the provision of service and the 
    recovery of the costs of providing that service. Accordingly, EEI's 
    proposed present value adjustment is neither necessary nor appropriate.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \751\ Condition 2 requires use of the most recent twelve months 
    of revenue if there has been a rate change. See FERC Stats. & Regs. 
    at 31,840; mimeo at 597.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        With respect to EEI's concern that CMVE is not determined on a 
    present value basis, we clarify that it should be calculated on a 
    present value basis. Both the revenues that would have been collected 
    if the customer had remained on the system and the revenues the utility 
    expects to collect by selling the power must be stated on a present 
    value basis so that the difference, RSE-CMVE, is at present 
    value.752 The ``Cap on SCO'' must also be stated on a present 
    value basis.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \752\ If RSE and CMVE are calculated on a present value basis, 
    and the difference between the two is multiplied by L, the result 
    constitutes the customer's SCO. This present value is the amount to 
    be paid under the lump-sum payment option. If the customer chooses 
    another payment option, additional time-value calculations would be 
    required to match the customer's stranded cost obligation with a 
    series of payments made over time.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In response to TDU Systems, NRECA and Central Vermont, we clarify 
    that a utility is entitled to recovery of stranded costs and the time-
    value of the revenues that would have been recovered.753 However, 
    we decline to specify the discount rate or the number of periods to be 
    used in the calculation. Although establishing a uniform discount rate 
    would serve to minimize disputes over the calculation, we prefer to 
    give the parties some flexibility on the use of a discount rate. 
    Similarly, we do not prescribe the number of periods to be used in the 
    present value calculation as this also should be determined on a case-
    by-case basis due to differences in ``L'' and billing payment cycles 
    for each departing customer.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \753\ The utility is entitled to recover no more than the 
    present value of the revenue stream (less the competitive market 
    value) it would have received had the customer remained on its 
    system.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    CMVE Option 2 Issues
    
        In Order No. 888, the Commission allows the departing customer to 
    set CMVE equal to the average annual revenues it would pay to its 
    alternative supplier. This option is referred to as CMVE Option 2.
        SoCal Edison and Central Vermont argue that CMVE Option 2 should be 
    eliminated because it will be administratively difficult to monitor and 
    enforce. In their view, Option 2 will allow customers the opportunity 
    to ``game'' the system, which will increase the utility's and the 
    Commission's administrative costs and place the utility at risk for 
    less than full recovery of stranded costs. In addition, SoCal Edison 
    maintains that it will be difficult to reflect in the calculation of 
    stranded costs any non-price benefits a customer may receive under the 
    contract. SoCal Edison further maintains that there is a possibility 
    that additional bargains may have been struck outside of the agreement 
    between the new supplier and the departing customer. These bargains may 
    have the effect of increasing the price of the alternative power, but 
    the terms of the bargains would not be known to the utility to use in 
    adjusting CMVE. As a result, the customer's contract price may not 
    accurately reflect the utility's CMVE, resulting in an inaccurate 
    estimate of stranded cost responsibility.
        EEI has requested that the Commission clarify that the conditions 
    placed on CMVE Option 2 were intended to prevent the customer from 
    unfairly avoiding its full stranded cost obligation (i.e., prevent 
    gaming of the stranded cost calculation). EEI also states that the 
    Commission should give the utility an opportunity to challenge the 
    validity of the replacement contract's price, terms and conditions on a 
    case-by-case basis or give the utility the right of first refusal to 
    provide power to the customer under the replacement contract's price, 
    terms and conditions. Carolina P&L requests that the Commission require 
    the departing customer to make a compliance filing containing 
    information regarding the replacement contract. Centerior maintains 
    that in order to guard against the customer overpaying for replacement 
    capacity (thereby lowering its SCO), the Commission should use the 
    revenues received by the host utility in the resale of the power to 
    determine the CMVE.
        NRECA and TDU Systems maintain that the formula fails to address 
    how the CMVE component will be adjusted when the customer's contractual 
    commitment for replacement capacity is for a period shorter than L.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The comments filed in response to our Open Access NOPR maintained 
    overwhelmingly that determining accurately the competitive market value 
    of the released capacity and energy is a difficult and subjective task. 
    Therefore, we did not prescribe a CMVE by formula as we did for RSE. 
    Instead, we provide options for determining it. Our requirement for the 
    utility to estimate it is CMVE Option 1. However, the customer may 
    contend that the utility will underestimate CMVE under this option so 
    as to increase the customer's stranded cost obligation. In response to 
    these concerns, the Commission adopted CMVE Option 2 because ``[t]he 
    customer will test the market and choose the best deal available. 
    Hence, the price the customer pays its alternative supplier is arguably 
    a more accurate measure of the competitive market value of the capacity 
    and associated energy not taken from the host utility.'' 754 The 
    Commission also believes that, because of the potential for disputes 
    over the CMVE component of the formula, many utilities and departing 
    customers would appreciate CMVE Option 2 because it would provide them 
    with a simple and reliable method for determining the CMVE.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \754\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,842; mimeo at 604.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        However, the Commission recognized the potential for gaming on the 
    part of the customer. To address this potential, the Commission placed 
    certain conditions on the use of Option 2. One of these conditions is 
    that the departing customer must demonstrate that the replacement 
    service is equivalent to that from the current supplier. This provides 
    the utility with the ability to investigate whether the new service is 
    essentially the same, in terms of contract duration, terms and 
    conditions, as that which it currently provides the customer. Any 
    unresolvable disputes over the value of
    
    [[Page 12422]]
    
    non-price benefits contained in the customer's replacement contract, 
    which is SoCal Edison's concern, can be developed during a stranded 
    cost hearing, and the Commission will decide the disputed issues based 
    on the record provided. SoCal Edison's concern with additional bargains 
    outside the contract, which increase the contract price and lower the 
    customer's SCO, is properly addressed through the discovery process. 
    The utility could ask for a copy of agreements between the new supplier 
    and the departing customer, and the customer would be obligated to 
    provide the requested information.
        Although we recognize that there may be difficulties in assuring 
    the ``equivalence'' of the customer's replacement contract, we believe 
    that CMVE Option 2 creates an incentive for the utility to estimate 
    CMVE as accurately as possible (in Option 1), and provides a quick and 
    simple alternative to protracted litigation of the utility's estimate 
    of CMVE. Accordingly, SoCal Edison's and Central Vermont's request for 
    elimination of CMVE Option 2 is rejected. Also, because a utility is 
    permitted to undertake discovery regarding the terms and conditions of 
    the replacement contract, and any contracts or considerations 
    associated with the replacement contract, we do not believe that it is 
    necessary to give the utility the right of first refusal to supply the 
    departing customer under the replacement contract's price, terms and 
    conditions. EEI's ``gaming'' concerns are best addressed through the 
    discovery process in a stranded cost hearing.
        Furthermore, we will not require the departing customer to make a 
    compliance filing containing information about its replacement 
    contract, as the utility can obtain this information through discovery 
    if it is needed and relevant, without automatically burdening the 
    Commission with additional filings or requiring the customer to 
    disclose confidential and irrelevant information. A customer must file 
    replacement contract information only if it chooses to assert that the 
    replacement contract price is relevant to the determination of 
    CMVE.755
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \755\ We note that in a section 206 proceeding initiated by a 
    customer, Order No. 888 requires that estimates of stranded cost 
    liability shall include the information necessary to allow the 
    utility to understand the basis of the estimate. (Mimeo at 610 
    referencing Implementation Procedure (2)). The implementation 
    requirements in Implementation Procedure (2) apply not only to a 
    utility making a stranded cost estimate, but also to a customer 
    filing under section 206. Therefore, in case Order No. 888 is 
    unclear, we clarify that a customer filing under section 206 and 
    choosing CMVE Option 2 must include a copy of its replacement 
    contract and any other information necessary to determine the 
    equivalence of its replacement contract.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In response to NRECA and TDU Systems, the Commission reiterates 
    that a customer cannot avail itself of CMVE Option 2 if its replacement 
    contract is for a period shorter than L. This restriction is necessary 
    to ensure equivalence of service.
    
    Marketing/Brokering Option Issues
    
        In Order No. 888, the Commission allows the departing customer to 
    market or broker the capacity that it would strand as a result of its 
    decision to purchase power from an alternative supplier. This option is 
    intended to protect a departing customer from a low utility estimate of 
    CMVE, which would result in a higher stranded cost charge to the 
    customer.
        ELCON maintains that the option to broker the released power in 
    response to a ``low balling'' of the CMVE by a utility places an unfair 
    burden on the customer by requiring it to engage in brokering.
        SoCal Edison and NIMO argue that a customer choosing the marketing 
    option should pay the utility's estimate of the market value of energy, 
    rather than the average system energy costs for the energy it 
    purchases. SoCal Edison and NIMO argue that the use of average system 
    energy costs is inconsistent with the use of estimated market value 
    used to calculate the customer's stranded cost responsibility and will 
    result in an under-recovery of stranded costs. Florida Power Corp is 
    also concerned that the payment provisions of the marketing option 
    could result in under-recovery of stranded costs. Specifically, Florida 
    Power Corp states that permitting customers to purchase the associated 
    energy at average system variable costs is appropriate if the stranded 
    capacity marketed by the customer is slice-of-system and if the energy 
    used is at the same load factor as the average load factor of the 
    utility's remaining requirements customers. If these conditions are not 
    met, Florida Power Corp states that under-recovery or over-recovery of 
    stranded costs could occur. To prevent this, Florida Power Corp would 
    require the customer to reimburse the utility for the marketed energy 
    at the utility's actual hourly average energy costs for the hours in 
    which the energy is resold.
        Occidental Chemical requests guidance as to when a stranded cost is 
    ``legitimate'' and how the utility will develop an estimate of the 
    capacity to be released. Occidental Chemical also requests 
    clarification regarding the obligations of a departing customer to the 
    replacement buyer and whether the departing customer can resell the 
    capacity under terms and conditions different from those under which it 
    bought it. Similarly, CCEM requests that the Commission clarify that 
    there can be no conditions attached to the former customer's use of the 
    capacity, except for conditions pertaining to safety and reliability. 
    CCEM also contends that the 60-day limit for finding a buyer under the 
    brokering option is too short and should be eliminated. CCEM states 
    that if the customer pays for the capacity in the stranded cost charge, 
    it should have flexibility in disposing of it.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Commission disagrees with ELCON that the brokering option 
    places an unfair burden on the departing customer. The Commission 
    believes that the marketing/brokering option is another effective 
    incentive for a utility to make a good faith estimate of CMVE. 
    Furthermore, we note that the marketing/brokering option is just that: 
    an option. A customer is not required to exercise the marketing/
    brokering option, just as it is not required to exercise CMVE Option 2. 
    Rather, the marketing/brokering option is available to a customer who 
    believes it can reduce its stranded cost obligation through marketing 
    or brokering the released power.756
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \756\ If the customer decides not to exercise either CMVE Option 
    2 or the marketing/brokering option, the customer still would be 
    permitted to challenge the reasonableness of the utility's CMVE 
    estimate (under CMVE Option 1) as well as the reasonableness of the 
    other aspects of the utility's stranded cost estimate.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In response to SoCal Edison, NIMO and Florida Power Corp, the 
    Commission believes that permitting a customer to purchase the 
    associated energy under the marketing option at average system variable 
    costs is appropriate in most instances for at least two reasons. First, 
    the capacity being marketed in all or almost all cases would not be 
    associated with a single asset or subset of assets. Instead, a customer 
    who chooses to exercise this option is purchasing a ``slice of the 
    system,'' i.e., a fraction of the production of all assets. 
    Accordingly, our requirement that the customer purchase the associated 
    energy at average system variable costs is consistent with the notion 
    that it is purchasing a slice-of-the-system. Furthermore, we believe 
    that the customer should have the opportunity to purchase the 
    associated energy at the price it currently pays, and for most 
    customers that price is based on average
    
    [[Page 12423]]
    
    system costs. It is not appropriate to require market value pricing of 
    associated energy when the customer's present payments are based on 
    average system variable costs. For SoCal Edison and NIMO, we further 
    clarify that, when the departing customer markets the released power at 
    a market-based rate and pays average system variable cost for the 
    energy component of the price, the difference between the market price 
    of the power and the average system variable cost determines the market 
    value of the released capacity. When we refer to ``purchasing energy at 
    average system variable cost,'' we refer to compensation for the 
    variable cost component of the sale (mostly fuel cost); we are not 
    referring to the total price of the power sale, which would include a 
    fixed cost recovery component.
        We agree with the argument of Florida Power Corp. The Commission 
    recognizes that there may be instances where the departing customer 
    does not purchase energy at average system variable costs. We also 
    recognize that the entity to which the departing customer sells the 
    released capacity may have a usage pattern that differs significantly 
    from that of the departing customer. In this circumstance, the utility 
    should be paid actual hourly average energy costs for the hours in 
    which the energy is resold by the departing customer. Parties should 
    address this issue in their marketing agreement.
        In addition, we clarify that the departing customer's capacity 
    charge is the utility's CMVE minus average system variable costs as 
    contained in its estimate of RSE.757 Hence, the capacity charge is 
    the fixed cost that the utility could recover if it sold the power at 
    market value. This approach assumes that the customer choosing the 
    marketing option is buying a slice of the system and buys the energy 
    associated with the released capacity on the same basis as under its 
    contract with the utility.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \757\ For estimation purposes the utility should still provide 
    its CMVE on a market value basis for both capacity (fixed) and 
    energy (variable) so that customers can better understand the basis 
    for the utility's estimate.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In response to Occidental Chemical, a stranded cost is legitimate 
    if it meets the criteria established in the Rule. With respect to the 
    obligations of a departing customer to a replacement customer, such 
    obligations will be governed in part by the individual contracts 
    between the parties. However, with respect to Occidental Chemical's 
    question as to whether the departing customer can resell the capacity 
    under terms and conditions different from those under which it bought 
    the capacity, the Commission finds that, at a minimum, the customer is 
    entitled to resell the capacity and energy under the terms and 
    conditions governing its purchase from the utility. However, customers 
    would not be precluded from negotiating different terms and conditions 
    with the utility.
        In response to CCEM's concerns, the Commission will not prohibit a 
    utility from attaching conditions to the former customer's use of the 
    system. There may be circumstances (which we have not contemplated) 
    where certain conditions may be necessary, and we do not wish to 
    foreclose such instances at this time. However, we caution utilities 
    against using this to restrict the customer's use of this option. We 
    reiterate our finding in Order No. 888 that the utility should allow 
    the customer to market/broker the released capacity under terms and 
    conditions comparable to a utility resale of the capacity to a third 
    party.
        The Commission disagrees with CCEM that the 60-day period for 
    finding a buyer under the brokering option is too short and should be 
    eliminated. The 60-day period protects both customers and utilities in 
    the event that an acceptable buyer for the power cannot be found. It 
    protects the utility from being stuck with the released capacity for an 
    extended period, during which time it can receive only minimal 
    compensation for it.758 Similarly, the 60-day limit protects the 
    customer by reverting back to the formula if its brokering attempt is 
    unsuccessful. CCEM's argument that the customer who pays for the 
    capacity in the stranded cost charge should have flexibility in 
    disposing of it ignores the fact that under the brokering option (as 
    opposed to the marketing option), the customer does not take title to 
    the released capacity. For these reasons, the Commission continues to 
    believe that a time limit is necessary, and that 60 days is adequate to 
    meet the dual goals described above.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \758\ This is so because, throughout the period that the 
    customer is trying to find a buyer, the utility can sell the 
    released capacity and energy only in the short-term market, most 
    likely at a lower price than it could receive in a longer-term 
    market. The utility is limited to the short-term market because the 
    capacity must be available when the customer finds a buyer.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Length of Reasonable Expectation Issues
    
        American Forest & Paper faults the Commission for failing to limit 
    the period of reasonable expectation to a discrete period, such as 
    three to five years. TDU Systems contends that the threat of stranded 
    costs extends well beyond a mere transition period, and therefore, is 
    inconsistent with the Commission's statement that stranded costs are a 
    transition issue. TDU Systems maintains that the period of reasonable 
    expectation should be defined as the shorter of either the term of the 
    terminating contract or the utility's planning horizon as of July 11, 
    1994. IL Com states that absent a statutory, regulatory or contractual 
    obligation to incur costs or provide service, the length of a utility's 
    expectation to serve a customer beyond its contract expiration should 
    be zero. However, IL Com states that if a statutory or regulatory 
    obligation to serve can be demonstrated by a public utility on a case-
    by-case basis, extra-contractual recovery may be appropriate but should 
    not exceed three years. IL Com proposes a formula for L that 
    incorporates a three-year cap.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We reiterate that our stranded cost procedure applies to wholesale 
    contracts only if they are entered into on or before July 11, 1994 (and 
    do not contain exit fees or other stranded cost provisions), so that as 
    these contracts end this stranded cost recovery procedure will cease to 
    apply. This fact alone shows that the policy is a transition issue and 
    not a permanent policy for wholesale requirements contracts. Further, 
    it should be remembered that a utility must demonstrate that it had a 
    reasonable expectation of continued service for a time certain (L) 
    before any stranded cost is recognized to exist or recovery permitted. 
    This is not an insignificant demonstration. Moreover, although we 
    decline to establish an outside limit for L, it is likely that the 
    longer the period claimed by the utility, the harder it will be for the 
    utility to demonstrate a reasonable expectation. In any event, to 
    provide recovery of the full stranded cost, it is necessary that the 
    reasonable expectation period not be limited to an arbitrary number, 
    such as three to five years, as suggested by American Forest & Paper.
        Regarding the time it takes to complete the transition to a market 
    unaffected by stranded cost considerations, the Commission 
    distinguishes the reasonable expectation period for determining the 
    amount of stranded costs attributable to a departing customer from the 
    period over which the customer pays for stranded costs. For example, a 
    utility may have incurred a cost under the expectation that the 
    customer would remain for another seven years (L). However, the 
    customer could pay that amount
    
    [[Page 12424]]
    
    immediately, over three years, over seven years, or over a longer 
    period. The period of reasonable expectation, L, is unrelated to the 
    repayment period. If all customers were to choose the lump-sum payment 
    option, the transition period to a market completely unaffected by 
    stranded cost recovery would be short.
        In response to TDU Systems, we note that its proposal to define the 
    period of reasonable expectation as the shorter of either the term of 
    the terminating contract or the utility's planning horizon as of July 
    11, 1994 is not foreclosed by our Rule. When faced with a claim for 
    stranded costs, TDU Systems may argue that either of these limit the 
    reasonable expectation period in that instance. However, it would be 
    inappropriate to limit generically the period of reasonable expectation 
    as suggested because the limitation may not fit all circumstances. We 
    reiterate that whether a utility had a reasonable expectation of 
    continued service, and for how long, will be determined on a case-by-
    case basis, and will depend on the facts and circumstances of each 
    individual case.
        With respect to IL Com's argument that absent a statutory, 
    regulatory or contractual obligation to incur costs, the length of a 
    utility's expectation to serve a customer beyond its contract 
    expiration should be zero, the Commission agrees that such obligations 
    are likely to be the principal reasons for a reasonable expectation in 
    most cases, but we would not preclude a utility from introducing other 
    relevant evidence. If a utility can demonstrate that costs were 
    incurred to serve a customer, based on a reasonable expectation of 
    continued service, and if that customer uses the open access provided 
    by Order No. 888 to reach an alternative supplier, leaving the utility 
    with unrecovered costs, the utility should be allowed to make its case 
    for recovery of those costs based on whatever evidence it chooses to 
    offer.
    
    Implementation Issues
    
        SoCal Edison is concerned that, under the framework established in 
    Order No. 888, a customer could request numerous estimates of stranded 
    costs based on different alternative supply scenarios and departure 
    dates, to which the utility would have to respond in a 30-day period. 
    SoCal Edison states that the Commission should reasonably limit the 
    number and types of requests. SoCal Edison maintains that if the number 
    and type of a customer's requests are unduly burdensome or unreasonable 
    in the utility's view, the utility should be permitted to refuse the 
    requests. Under SoCal Edison's approach, the customer would have the 
    right to petition the Commission to demand that such studies be 
    undertaken.
        SoCal Edison also argues that the Commission should allow a utility 
    to assess a reasonable charge to cover administrative costs associated 
    with developing the studies required to produce estimates of stranded 
    cost responsibility.
        TDU Systems states that the 30-day period allowed for a customer to 
    respond to a utility's notice of alleged stranded costs is too little 
    time to perform an adequate analysis. In addition, TDU Systems and 
    NRECA maintain that a customer should not be bound by its estimate of 
    stranded cost obligation as filed in a petition for declaratory order 
    or a section 205 or 206 proceeding. They contend that certain elements 
    of the formula depend heavily on data in the public utility's 
    possession, and that the Rule, as written, will encourage the customer 
    to present a low-end estimate of stranded cost liability. TDU Systems 
    and NRECA maintain that the Commission should instead require the 
    customer to state its binding estimate at the close of the discovery 
    period when it presumably would be in possession of the data necessary 
    to make a realistic estimate of the stranded cost floor.
        PSE&G argues that a utility should be able to begin recovering 
    stranded costs right away, subject to refund pending the outcome of the 
    proceeding, to eliminate any incentive a customer would have to delay 
    proceedings so as to delay payment of stranded costs.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Regarding SoCal Edison's concern about numerous requests for 
    estimates of stranded costs, we do not believe that the number of 
    requests will rise to the level of ``unduly burdensome'' or 
    ``unreasonable'' in most instances. However, if this problem occurs, a 
    utility can petition the Commission for relief, and we will consider 
    each petition on a case-by-case basis.
        The Commission does not agree with SoCal Edison that a utility 
    should be permitted a special charge to cover the cost associated with 
    providing a stranded cost estimate. Such costs are likely to be de 
    minimis. Given that Order No. 888 provides an opportunity for full 
    recovery of stranded costs, we do not believe it is appropriate for a 
    utility to charge a customer an additional fee for asking whether it 
    can expect a stranded cost claim.
        The Commission also disagrees with TDU Systems that the 30-day 
    customer response period is too short. No utility has argued on 
    rehearing that the 30-day utility response to a request for an estimate 
    is too short, and only TDU Systems argues that the 30-day customer 
    response to the utility's estimate is too short. The 30-day period is 
    intended to speed the negotiation process, with the goal of settling 
    stranded costs disputes without Commission involvement. Order No. 888 
    requires a utility to provide an estimate of stranded cost 
    responsibility within 30 days of the customer's request for an 
    estimate. We do not believe it is unreasonable to require the customer 
    to respond in like time. Accordingly, we will not modify the 30-day 
    response requirement.
        Furthermore, the Commission is unpersuaded by TDU Systems' and 
    NRECA's argument that a customer should be bound by its estimate of 
    stranded cost obligation only after the close of the discovery period. 
    Order No. 888 requires the utility to provide detailed support for its 
    stranded cost estimates, and this information should be adequate to 
    allow the customer to develop its own estimate of any stranded cost 
    obligation.
        In response to PSE&G, we clarify that recovery of stranded cost 
    claims filed under section 205, 206, or 211/212 will be governed by 
    these sections and the Commission's promulgating regulations thereto.
    
    Net Benefit Issues
    
        EGA and IMPA argue that the revenues lost approach does not capture 
    the net utility benefits that result from open access. EGA states that 
    no stranded costs should be imposed on any one ``lost'' customer if the 
    utility is a ``net winner,'' that is, where the benefits from the new 
    competitive regime outweigh the utility's stranded costs. EGA states 
    that the formula is unclear as to how the revenues lost approach will 
    take into account the following three potentially beneficial effects of 
    competition: (1) an expanded customer base as a result of enhanced 
    transmission access; (2) reductions in the cost of purchased power, 
    which is resold by a utility; and (3) a utility's ability to obtain 
    higher than cost of service rates for electricity. Freedom Energy 
    argues that the potential future benefit should be factored into the 
    revenues lost calculation.
        IMPA maintains that a mechanism should be provided for recovery of 
    the benefits of open access, particularly if a utility does not seek 
    stranded cost recovery. IMPA states that it is economically inefficient 
    for consumers of generation and transmission services to pay stranded 
    costs to those suppliers that have higher than average cost generation, 
    while the benefits from
    
    [[Page 12425]]
    
    increases in asset value are not shared with the consumers or used to 
    pay for other utilities' stranded costs. IMPA further contends that if 
    the customer's departure as a power customer frees up the generating 
    capacity for remarketing through the use of the transmission system, 
    section 212 of the FPA, as modified by the Energy Policy Act, supports 
    recognition of such benefits in the price paid by the customer for its 
    continued usage. Finally, IMPA maintains that if a transmission 
    provider seeks stranded cost recovery for an asset that appears ``high 
    cost'' due to its relative youth, the asset's future lower cost as an 
    older unit must also be included in the calculation; otherwise the 
    departing customer will be denied the long-term average benefit of the 
    generating asset.
        Multiple Intervenors contend that there should be consistent 
    treatment of all assets that deviate from fair market value. For 
    example, if a utility is allowed to recover the difference between the 
    book value of an asset and its lower market value, then that amount 
    should be offset by the appreciated value of any assets that have a 
    market value higher than book value. Similarly, ELCON and Freedom 
    Energy are concerned that the revenues lost approach may overcompensate 
    a utility for stranded costs because it fails to account for the fact 
    that uneconomic assets may be offset by the increased economic value of 
    other assets in a deregulated environment.759 Freedom Energy 
    states that losses may occur in the short run, but in the long run the 
    utility may be better off.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \759\ Freedom Energy and ELCON reference a study conducted under 
    the aegis of the Massachusetts Attorney General to support their 
    position that the future benefits of deregulating sales of energy 
    and capacity will produce a net gain for utilities that is often 
    sufficient to offset the full amount of any potential stranded 
    costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Commission believes that the suggestion by EGA and others that 
    a long-run comprehensive analysis be undertaken every time a customer 
    departs, in order to determine whether the utility would eventually be 
    a net winner, is unworkable. Identifying the competitive market value 
    for power during the reasonable expectation period (L) is hard enough; 
    EGA would have us also find the market value of the power for an 
    indefinite time after the expectation period ends. Further, attempts to 
    define which benefits are the result of Order No. 888 would, at the 
    very least, be unwieldy and highly subjective. The Commission's 
    approach, on the other hand, is far less subjective and more likely to 
    produce a reasonable result.
        With respect to the specific ``potentially'' beneficial effects of 
    competition during the period L, which EGA states should be used to 
    offset stranded costs, the Commission finds these benefits to be 
    questionable at best. However, if these potential benefits occur, the 
    Rule's stranded cost approach accommodates them. For example, our 
    clarification (infra) that the formula addresses load growth responds 
    to EGA's first concern that the formula should take into account the 
    expanded customer base that results from open access. EGA's second 
    concern, i.e., that the formula should reflect reductions in the cost 
    of purchased power, is misplaced. If, in a future market-based pricing 
    world, a utility can purchase power at a lower cost, it must either 
    pass this lower cost through to customers in its cost-based rates or 
    sell power at similarly low market-based rates to other customers. In 
    either case, except for possible timing considerations, it is unable to 
    profit by buying low and selling high. If a utility has such a 
    hypothetical benefit before the customer departs, the customer may file 
    a section 206 complaint prior to the termination of the existing 
    contract, so that the resulting rates, reflecting the reduction in the 
    cost of purchased power, could be used to calculate RSE. Lastly, if a 
    utility can sell at market-based rates that are higher than cost-based 
    rates (other than in the speculative long run), it would not qualify to 
    recover stranded costs.
        In addition, ELCON's and Freedom Energy's concern that utilities 
    may be overcompensated under the revenues lost approach is based on a 
    study that assumes a fully deregulated environment. There is no basis 
    for this assumption over the next several years. Furthermore, it is 
    highly speculative whether a particular utility will necessarily be 
    better off in future markets as the study predicts. This is especially 
    so because Freedom Energy's argument that future benefits should be 
    used to offset stranded costs appears to assume a short reasonable 
    expectation period, L. We do not find merit in Freedom Energy's 
    suggestion that events beyond the reasonable expectation period should 
    be factored into the stranded cost calculation.
        The Commission also believes that IMPA's benefit reallocation 
    proposal is inappropriate and unworkable. It would require a utility 
    not requesting stranded cost recovery to share with its wholesale 
    customers any future benefits that would accrue to it as a result of 
    Order No. 888. Customers have purchased power from utilities at cost-
    based rates that have been found to be just and reasonable by this 
    Commission. Such purchases in no way convey an ownership interest in 
    the facilities used to provide service. The rationale for stranded cost 
    recovery, i.e., payment for investments made to serve a customer under 
    the utility's reasonable expectation of continuing to serve, cannot be 
    converted into what would be in effect an ownership interest with the 
    right to receive a share of profits from future sales. Moreover, IMPA's 
    argument assumes that utilities whose assets have a book value less 
    than market value will be able to charge market-based rates for their 
    capacity. This assumption is unrealistic for many utilities, and 
    therefore cannot be relied upon as basis for a generic policy. However, 
    even if all utilities could charge market-based rates, economic 
    efficiency would argue strongly against such utility payments to 
    departing customers. Specifically, there would be little or no 
    incentive for an efficient, low cost utility to seek the best deal in 
    the power market if the profits must be credited back to its former 
    customers, or other utilities' customers, as IMPA suggests. Therefore, 
    while IMPA's symmetry argument (i.e., customers must pay stranded costs 
    so equity requires utilities to pay customers any benefits that result 
    from open access) may have surface appeal, it would serve to undo the 
    goal of Order No. 888--that is, to promote competition and economic 
    efficiency in bulk power markets. The Commission considered carefully 
    the issue of symmetry in Order No. 888 and provided the appropriate 
    utility-customer symmetry: a utility is entitled to make the case that 
    it expected the customer to remain a customer longer than the term of 
    the contract and the customer is entitled to make the case that the 
    term of an existing contract should be shortened.
        We also reject IMPA's argument that section 212 of the FPA requires 
    recognition in transmission rates of any generation benefits that 
    accrue to a utility as a result of Order No. 888. Section 212 requires 
    the Commission to consider all costs incurred by the transmission 
    provider in providing the service, ``including taking into account any 
    benefits to the transmission system of providing the transmission 
    service.'' 760 We do not interpret this to refer to the resale of 
    a utility's generation freed-up as a result of Order No. 888.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \760\ 16 U.S.C. Sec. 824(a).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        IMPA's argument that if a transmission provider seeks stranded cost 
    recovery for an asset that appears
    
    [[Page 12426]]
    
    ``high cost'' due to its relative youth, the asset's projected future 
    lower (depreciated) cost as an older unit must also be included in the 
    calculation, improperly focusses on an individual asset. As we 
    explained above, the revenues lost approach is not an asset-by-asset 
    approach, but an approach that looks at a utility's current rates which 
    are based on all the utility's assets, including typically a mix of 
    facilities of various ages.
        Lastly, the revenues lost approach automatically includes an offset 
    of the type described by Multiple Intervenors, ELCON and Freedom 
    Energy. The revenue stream is based on present rates, which are based 
    on the net book value of all of the underlying assets used to provide 
    the service. If present rates include some assets that have a market 
    value that exceeds net book value (for example, plants that are almost 
    fully depreciated), the formula automatically captures the described 
    offset because the revenue stream is based on the lower book value of 
    the utility's assets rather than their higher market value.
    
    Miscellaneous Formula Issues
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        American Forest & Paper argues that the definition of wholesale 
    stranded costs in section 35.26(b)(1) is overly inclusive; rather than 
    using a gross measure of stranded costs, it believes the regulations 
    should adopt a net measure that accounts for a utility redeploying its 
    assets in a competitive market at market price. American Forest & Paper 
    also maintains that the formula fails to reward efficient utilities or 
    those that already have borne the pain of restructuring. On the 
    contrary, it argues that the Commission's definition artificially and 
    unjustifiably improves the competitive position of the inefficient 
    utilities. American Forest & Paper further contends that the formula 
    fails to allocate the risk of non-mitigation to utilities, the entities 
    that are in the best position to mitigate such costs, but rather places 
    the risk on customers by requiring customers to challenge the utility's 
    CMVE.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        In response to American Forest & Paper, we note that the definition 
    of wholesale stranded cost in section 35.26(b)(1) should not be looked 
    at in isolation. Although that definition does not specifically mention 
    the subtraction of the competitive market value of the released power 
    from RSE, the revenues lost formula, which is set forth in section 
    35.26(c)(2)(iii), does. The formula explicitly provides that a 
    customer's stranded cost obligation is to be calculated by subtracting 
    the estimated competitive market value (of the released power) from the 
    revenue stream estimate.
        In response to the argument that the formula fails to reward the 
    efficient utility that has already borne the pain of restructuring, we 
    note that our intention in providing stranded cost recovery was not to 
    review or reward utility business decisions that preceded this Rule. 
    Our decision was, at bottom, based on equity for a utility that chooses 
    to make a case to regulators for recovery of costs stranded by 
    transmission access. Furthermore, we disagree that the definition of 
    stranded costs artificially and unjustifiably improves the competitive 
    position of an inefficient utility. Instead, the Commission believes 
    that to deny stranded cost recovery would violate the pre-existing 
    regulatory compact and would unjustifiably place certain utilities with 
    stranded costs at a financial disadvantage.
        With respect to American Forest & Paper's concern about mitigation 
    risk, the Commission requires the utility to mitigate, or reduce, its 
    stranded cost by reselling the released capacity at a price as high as 
    the market allows. In addition, Order No. 888 contains several other 
    incentives (e.g., the marketing/brokering option) to protect the 
    departing customer from paying an excessive stranded cost charge. These 
    incentives serve to mitigate stranded costs. Regarding the customer's 
    ``requirement'' to challenge the utility's CMVE, we view this as the 
    customer's right to challenge the utility's stranded cost estimate, 
    which is like its right to challenge a cost item in any rate case.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        NRECA and TDU Systems maintain that the formula fails to account 
    for any savings or reductions in fuel costs attributable to a 
    customer's departure. NRECA and TDU Systems contend that the utility's 
    fuel costs will decrease equivalent to the incremental fuel costs 
    associated with the energy not taken. They maintain that if the 
    customer's associated revenues are based on average fuel cost energy 
    charges, stranded costs should be offset by the reduction in average 
    system fuel costs directly related to the incremental fuel costs 
    savings. They argue that any stranded cost recovery mechanism should 
    properly reflect such offsetting savings.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Commission disagrees with NRECA and TDU Systems that the 
    formula fails to account for any savings or reductions in fuel costs 
    attributable to a departing customer. The formula automatically 
    accounts for fuel costs by assuming that the utility will be reselling 
    the same capacity and energy to another buyer, presumably at a lower 
    price. The lower price can be viewed as contributing less to capital 
    cost and purchased power cost recovery, but containing the same fuel 
    cost component. Under this approach, any decrease in fuel cost caused 
    by no longer serving the departing customer is offset by the increased 
    fuel cost of serving the new customer. Hence, there is no fuel costs 
    savings to reflect.
    
    Rehearing Requests--Divestiture
    
        CCEM continues to support divestiture of generating assets as a 
    precondition to a utility's authority to recover stranded costs. CCEM 
    maintains that divestiture is the only way to obtain an accurate 
    determination of CMVE on a net asset basis.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Commission disagrees that divestiture is the only way to obtain 
    an accurate measure of CMVE and we continue to believe that mandatory 
    asset divestiture does not need to be a requirement for stranded cost 
    recovery. However, the Rule (Section IV.J.10) states that we are 
    willing to consider case-specific proposals for dealing with stranded 
    costs in the context of any voluntary restructuring proceeding 
    instituted by an individual utility.
    
    Rehearing Requests--Load Growth and Excess Capacity
    
        TDU Systems and NRECA argue that the formula fails to take into 
    account the effect of load growth on the recovering utility's revenues. 
    They maintain that if the recovering utility is able to sell the 
    released capacity to new or existing customers, the rationale for 
    stranded cost recovery would be eliminated. Similarly, Arkansas Cities 
    argues that the formula is an imperfect indicator of a utility's 
    stranded costs because it does not explicitly take into account the 
    role played by the utility's having (or not having) excess capacity. PA 
    Munis maintains that as a prerequisite to stranded cost recovery, a 
    utility should be required to prove that the customer's use of open 
    access transmission actually resulted (or could result) in excess 
    capacity on its system. 761
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \761\ See also Wisconsin Municipals.
    
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [[Page 12427]]
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We clarify that our stranded cost policy does take into account the 
    effects of load growth and excess capacity. The formula is used to 
    calculate the value of stranded costs only if the Commission determines 
    that the utility has proved it has legitimate, prudent, and verifiable 
    stranded costs. For example, it must pass our reasonable expectation 
    test before the formula applies. However, costs may be stranded only if 
    they are not fully recovered from another customer; that is, the 
    released capacity may be either left unsold or resold at a price below 
    full embedded cost.
        The resale may be either to a new third-party customer or to 
    remaining native load. If the released capacity is resold to a third-
    party customer at full embedded cost-based rates, then no costs would 
    be stranded and the formula would not have to be used. Released 
    capacity would also be considered ``resold'' if its cost is 
    subsequently (and without delay) included in the rate base of the 
    utility's retail and wholesale native load. It may be included if it is 
    needed, in the judgment of the appropriate state or federal regulatory 
    body, for native load growth plus reliability reserve. In this case the 
    cost is not stranded if it is fully recovered in the cost-based rates 
    paid by native load. If the full embedded cost rate is paid by the new 
    purchaser for the capacity released by the departing customer, the 
    parties may argue either that there is no stranded cost or that the 
    formula produces a stranded cost obligation of zero because CMVE equals 
    the embedded-cost rate that the utility charges its wholesale and 
    retail native load customers; hence RSE equals CMVE.
        In response to Arkansas Cities, if the released capacity was 
    included in the Commission-approved cost-based rates paid by the 
    departing customer, we presume that such capacity is not ``excess'' 
    capacity. The departing customer's rate (which produces annual 
    revenues, RSE) for the released capacity includes capacity that 
    regulators have approved as needed to meet the needs of requirements 
    customers, including capacity needed for reliability reserve. The only 
    excess capacity issue is whether the released capacity becomes 
    ``excess'' because of the customer's departure, that is, whether the 
    departure strands costs because the utility cannot find a buyer for the 
    capacity. If the released capacity is ``excess'' capacity that is 
    excluded from subsequent native load rates because it is not needed for 
    native load, its cost may be eligible for stranded cost recovery under 
    the formula. Thus, contrary to the arguments made by TDU Systems, 
    NRECA, Arkansas Cities, Pa Munis and others, the revenues lost formula 
    does take load growth and excess capacity into account appropriately in 
    determining the departing customer's stranded cost obligation. For this 
    reason, we reject the arguments made by commenters that the formula is 
    flawed.
    
    Rehearing Requests--Tax Treatment of Nuclear Decommissioning Costs
    
        EEI and Nuclear Energy Institute request clarification that the 
    Commission did not intend Order No. 888 to change the IRS's tax 
    treatment of nuclear decommissioning costs. To be tax deductible, 
    nuclear decommissioning costs must be part of a utility's regulated 
    cost of service. EEI and Nuclear Energy Institute seek clarification 
    that costs included in a utility's stranded cost calculation continue 
    to be considered by the Commission as included in the utility's cost of 
    service.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The requested clarification is granted. We clarify that costs 
    included in a utility's stranded cost calculation continue to be 
    considered by the Commission as included in the utility's cost of 
    service.
    
    Rehearing Requests--Application of Formula to Stranded Costs Associated 
    With Retail-Turned-Wholesale Customers and Retail Wheeling Customers
    
        OH Com, MO Com and KS Com maintain that the Commission's formula is 
    inappropriate for calculating stranded costs associated with retail 
    wheeling customers and/or retail-turned wholesale customers. They 
    contend that the formula would be impractical to administer and would 
    produce inaccurate results given the enormity of the calculations and 
    assumptions involved. Suffolk County argues that the formula is flawed 
    for retail-related stranded costs because the Commission cannot 
    guarantee any retail rates into the future because it has no basis for 
    even speculating about how retail rates may be changed by subsequent 
    state action.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        With respect to stranded costs caused by retail wheeling, the 
    Commission determined in Order No. 888 that the formula was 
    inappropriate, and that if the Commission had to determine stranded 
    costs associated with retail wheeling it would do so on a case-by-case 
    basis. 762 However, the formula does work for stranded costs 
    associated with retail-turned-wholesale customers because the newly 
    formed municipal utility would have the resources to engage in 
    marketing or brokering and would have a marketable product. This stands 
    in contrast to individual retail customers, most of whom are unlikely 
    to have the resources to engage in marketing or brokering and would 
    have very small amounts of energy for sale. Although the calculations 
    necessary to estimate stranded costs associated with retail-turned-
    wholesale customers are somewhat more involved than stranded costs 
    associated with wholesale contracts, they are not impossible or overly 
    burdensome. Accordingly, we affirm our finding in Order No. 888 that 
    the formula is appropriate in the retail-turned-wholesale context.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \762\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,840; mimeo at 598.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Allegheny Power states that stranded cost recovery should not be 
    permitted if a utility recovers large amounts through exit fees, then 
    uses the freed capacity to make sales in the market at anything over 
    variable costs. Allegheny Power argues that a utility with nuclear 
    generation, which has a low variable cost, can dump power on the market 
    because its fixed costs are subsidized by stranded cost recovery. 
    Allegheny Power requests that the Commission recognize that this 
    distortion of the competitive market should not be facilitated by 
    stranded cost recovery.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Allegheny Power's concern that a utility recovering stranded costs 
    will use those revenues to subsidize sales in the market at anything 
    above variable costs is misplaced. In the power market, power pricing 
    decisions are based on whether the utility can recover its variable 
    cost, plus earn some contribution to capital costs. Stranded cost 
    revenues are not relevant. This fact is demonstrated by considering the 
    situation where no stranded cost revenues are provided to a utility 
    with nuclear generation as described by Allegheny Power. The utility, 
    in pricing power for off-system sales, would still face the same 
    choice, i.e., make the sale and earn some minimal contribution to 
    capital, or forego the sale and earn nothing. The Commission's decision 
    to provide recovery of stranded costs does not change the economics 
    involved in utility power pricing decisions, and does not lead to the 
    type of market distortion that concerns Allegheny Power.
    
    [[Page 12428]]
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        SBA asserts that determining the proper amount of stranded cost 
    recovery is an integral step in the deregulation process.763 It 
    expresses concern that the revenues lost formula can be abused through 
    the manipulation of the necessary financial statements of the parties 
    and that such abuse could be harmful to small businesses. SBA requests 
    that the Commission solicit its input, as well as the input of the 
    small business community and small business organizations, when 
    determining whether the proposed stranded cost recovery amount in a 
    particular case is fundamentally fair in terms of maintaining a viable 
    environment for small businesses.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \763\ As discussed in Section VI., we will treat SBA's request 
    as a motion for reconsideration.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        In response to SBA's request, we note that SBA, or any interested 
    small business organization, has the opportunity to provide input to 
    the Commission in a particular stranded cost proceeding by filing a 
    motion to intervene in that proceeding.764
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \764\ 18 CFR 385.214 (1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    10. Stranded Costs in the Context of Voluntary Restructuring
        No rehearing requests were filed on this issue. The Commission 
    reaffirms that we are willing to consider case-specific proposals for 
    dealing with stranded costs in the context of any restructuring 
    proceedings that may be instituted by individual utilities.765
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \765\ See FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,845-46; mimeo at 614-15.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    11. Accounting Treatment for Stranded Costs
        No rehearing requests were filed on this issue. The Commission 
    reaffirms Order No. 888's treatment of this issue.766
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \766\ See FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,846-47; mimeo at 615-18.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    12. Definitions, Application, and Summary
        In Order No. 888, we defined ``wholesale stranded cost'' in section 
    35.26(b)(1) as follows:
    
        (1) Wholesale stranded cost means any legitimate, prudent and 
    verifiable cost incurred by a public utility or a transmitting 
    utility to provide service to:
        (i) a wholesale requirements customer that subsequently becomes, 
    in whole or in part, an unbundled wholesale transmission services 
    customer of such public utility or transmitting utility; or
        (ii) a retail customer, or a newly created wholesale power sales 
    customer, that subsequently becomes, in whole or in part, an 
    unbundled wholesale transmission services customer of such public 
    utility or transmitting utility. [767]
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \767\ Mimeo at 768.
    
    We rejected requests by commenters in this proceeding to expand the 
    definition to include the situation where a wholesale requirements 
    customer or a retail-turned-wholesale customer ceases to purchase power 
    from the utility without using the transmission services of that 
    utility.768 We explained that any costs that the utility might 
    incur as a result of the loss of the requirements customer in this 
    scenario would be outside the scope of this Rule. We noted that the 
    premise of this Rule is that, where a customer uses Commission-mandated 
    transmission access of its former power supplier to obtain power from a 
    new generation supplier, the customer must pay the costs that were 
    incurred to provide service to the customer under the prior regulatory 
    regime. We indicated that if a customer leaves its utility supplier by 
    exercising power supply options (such as access to another utility's 
    transmission system or self-generation) that do not rely on access to 
    the former seller's transmission, there is no nexus to the new open 
    access rules.769
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \768\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,849-50; mimeo at 624-26. The 
    definition of ``retail stranded cost'' contains a similar 
    requirement that the retail customer must become, in whole or in 
    part, an unbundled retail transmission services customer of the 
    public utility from which the customer previously received bundled 
    retail services. We said that we would retain it for the same 
    reasons discussed above.
        \769\ As we clarify in this Order, there is not a sufficient 
    nexus to Commission-required transmission access in such 
    circumstances. The Commission's decision not to allow utilities to 
    seek recovery of stranded costs under the provisions of Order No. 
    888 if the customer leaves its historical power supplier by 
    exercising power supply options that do not rely on access to the 
    former supplier's transmission is based on the absence of a direct 
    causal nexus between stranded costs and the availability and use of 
    Commission-required transmission access. Self-generation and access 
    to another utility's transmission system would have been options 
    prior to the Rule.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We also decided to retain the requirement that stranded costs be 
    ``legitimate, prudent and verifiable,'' rejecting requests by some 
    commenters to eliminate the term ``prudent'' from the definition of 
    stranded costs.770 We explained that a determination that a 
    utility had a reasonable expectation of continuing to serve a customer 
    would not, in all circumstances, mean that costs incurred by the 
    utility were prudent. We said that prudence of costs, depending upon 
    the facts in a specific case, may include different things: e.g., 
    prudence in operation and maintenance of a plant; prudence in 
    continuing to own a plant when cheaper alternatives become available; 
    prudence in entering into purchased power contracts, or continuing such 
    contracts when buy-outs or buy-downs of the contracts would result in 
    savings. We concluded that the Commission cannot make a blanket 
    assumption that all claimed stranded costs will have been prudently 
    incurred, but we clarified that we do not intend to relitigate the 
    prudence of costs previously recovered.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \770\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,850; mimeo at 626-27.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests--Definitions of ``Wholesale Stranded Cost'' and 
    ``Wholesale Requirements Contract''
    
        As discussed in Sections IV.J.1 and IV.J.6, supra, a number of 
    entities ask the Commission to expand the scope of stranded cost 
    recovery allowed under the Rule to include ``bypass'' situations (i.e., 
    situations in which a departing customer does not use its former 
    supplier's transmission system to reach another supplier). Coalition 
    for Economic Competition asks the Commission to revise the definition 
    of ``wholesale stranded cost'' to accomplish that result. It notes, for 
    example, that the reference in the definition to ``newly created 
    wholesale power sales customer'' creates an ambiguity and may provide a 
    loophole to evade stranded costs through municipal annexation.
        El Paso expresses concern that a retail-turned-wholesale customer 
    could attempt to avoid its stranded cost responsibility simply by 
    having its outside power supplier be the ``wholesale transmission 
    customer'' (i.e., the entity that formally requests transmission 
    service from the transmitting utility). El Paso asks the Commission to 
    clarify that a retail-turned-wholesale customer is responsible to the 
    transmitting utility for stranded costs regardless of whether it or its 
    outside power supplier is the ``transmission customer'' of the 
    transmitting utility. El Paso asks the Commission to revise section 
    35.26(c)(1)(vii) (which presently provides for recovery from retail-
    turned-wholesale customers through section 205-206 or 211-212 wholesale 
    transmission rates) to provide for the recovery of stranded costs 
    directly from retail-turned-wholesale customers (through an exit fee or 
    lump sum payment).
        Utilities For Improved Transition asks the Commission to expand the 
    definition to include costs incurred to provide service to ``a 
    wholesale requirements customer that loses retail load because of 
    retail wheeling,
    
    [[Page 12429]]
    
    municipalization of retail load, the creation of a new customer, or 
    because retail customers have bypassed its system through transmission 
    or distribution taps to other suppliers or by other means.'' 771 
    Utilities For Improved Transition argues that, in the case of retail 
    wheeling and municipalization, these costs are incurred because of open 
    access tariffs. It further submits that the Commission also should 
    include costs incurred because of taps (interconnections) to other 
    systems to avoid encouraging uneconomic bypass as a way to avoid 
    stranded cost charges.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \771\ Utilities For Improved Transition at 17.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        APPA expresses concern that the definition in section 35.26(b)(4) 
    of ``wholesale requirements contract'' as ``a contract under which a 
    public utility or transmitting utility provides any portion of a 
    customer's bundled wholesale power requirements'' could be read as 
    including a bundled sale of capacity regardless of whether the seller 
    undertook to meet the customer's load growth. As a result, APPA submits 
    that the definition could include coordination arrangements. It is 
    APPA's position that the Commission could not, or should not, have 
    intended to allow stranded cost recovery for such contracts. APPA asks 
    the Commission to specify on rehearing that a ``wholesale requirements 
    contract'' is a bundled power and transmission arrangement that 
    includes the obligation to meet some or all of the customer's load 
    growth, and that all other services are coordination arrangements to 
    which the stranded cost recovery rules do not apply.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We will reject the requests for rehearing that ask the Commission 
    to expand the scope of stranded cost recovery allowed under the Rule to 
    include situations in which a wholesale requirements customer (or a 
    retail-turned-wholesale customer) ceases to purchase power from the 
    utility without using the transmission services of that utility. As we 
    explain in Sections IV.J.1 and IV.J.6, supra, any costs that the 
    utility might incur as a result of the loss of the customer in these 
    scenarios would be outside the scope of Order No. 888. However, as 
    discussed in Section IV.J.6, we grant rehearing on the municipal 
    annexation issue.
        We share El Paso's concern that a retail-turned-wholesale customer 
    should not be able to avoid its stranded cost responsibility simply by 
    having its outside power supplier be the entity that formally requests 
    unbundled transmission service from the utility. As we explain in 
    Section IV.J.6, supra, in response to a similar concern expressed by 
    Puget, we have revised the definition of ``wholesale stranded cost'' in 
    section 35.26(b)(1)(ii) to cover this situation. As revised, that 
    section provides that ``[w]holesale stranded cost means any legitimate, 
    prudent and verifiable cost incurred by a public utility or a 
    transmitting utility to provide service to: * * *. (ii) a retail 
    customer that subsequently becomes, either directly or through another 
    wholesale transmission purchaser, an unbundled wholesale transmission 
    services customer of such public utility or transmitting utility.
        We will deny Utilities For Improved Transition's request that the 
    Commission expand the definition to include costs incurred to provide 
    service to ``a wholesale requirements customer that loses retail load 
    because of retail wheeling, municipalization of retail load, the 
    creation of a new customer, or because retail customers have bypassed 
    its system through transmission or distribution taps to other suppliers 
    or by other means.'' Utilities For Improved Transition, in effect, is 
    asking that the Commission allow the recovery of costs that may be 
    stranded due to the loss of an indirect customer and to expand the 
    scope of the ``wholesale stranded costs'' for which Order No. 888 
    provides an opportunity for recovery. As we discuss in Section IV.J.1, 
    supra, the Commission does not believe it is appropriate to expand the 
    scope of the stranded cost recovery opportunity provided under this 
    Rule to include costs that may be stranded due to the loss of an 
    indirect customer (i.e., a customer of a wholesale requirements 
    customer of the utility). The reasonable expectation analysis would 
    apply only to the direct wholesale requirements customer of the 
    utility, not to the indirect customer. A utility may seek to recover 
    stranded costs from a direct wholesale customer (subject to the 
    requirements of the Rule), but it is up to the direct wholesale 
    customer, through its contracts with its customers or through the 
    appropriate regulatory authority, to seek to recover stranded costs 
    from its customers.
        In response to APPA's argument that the definition of ``wholesale 
    requirements contract'' in new section 35.26(b)(4) of the Commission's 
    regulations could be read as including coordination arrangements, we 
    clarify that it does not. The opportunity to recover stranded costs 
    applies only to bundled power contracts where the utility can 
    demonstrate that it incurred costs to provide service to a customer 
    based on a reasonable expectation of continuing service to the customer 
    beyond the contract term. Coordination arrangements could not meet the 
    cost incurrence and reasonable expectation prerequisites of Order No. 
    888, and therefore a customer served under such an arrangement would 
    not be subject to stranded cost charges.
    
    Rehearing Requests--Relitigation of Prudence
    
        A number of entities express concern that, notwithstanding the 
    Commission's stated preference not to relitigate prudence, Order No. 
    888 leaves the door open for subsequent litigation of prudence issues. 
    Centerior asks the Commission either to remove ``prudent'' from the 
    definition or to clarify that ``prudent'' means all costs found 
    prudently incurred by the state commissions. Centerior asks the 
    Commission not to relitigate prudence in the operation and maintenance 
    of a plant or the prudence of continuing to own a plant when cheaper 
    alternatives become available. Other entities (including EEI, PSE&G, 
    and Nuclear Energy Institute) similarly ask the Commission to clarify 
    that it does not intend to relitigate costs that are already in rates 
    when calculating the revenue stream estimate. Nuclear Energy Institute 
    states that, in the case of nuclear plants, significant prudence 
    proceedings have already been conducted and, by definition, the 
    embedded capital costs included in current rates to customers are 
    prudent.
        PSE&G recommends that if costs that form the basis for a utility's 
    claimed stranded costs are already included in filed rates and are no 
    longer subject to refund, those costs should be treated as per se 
    prudent. Southern states that if the Commission does not strike the 
    word ``prudent'' from the definition of stranded costs, at a minimum it 
    should modify the Rule to establish a rebuttable presumption of 
    prudence that must be overcome by the departing customer.
        PSE&G and Carolina P&L submit that if prudence challenges under the 
    Rule are retained on rehearing, they should be subject to the same 
    standards as any other prudence challenge, namely the ``reasonable 
    person test'' under which prudent costs are those ``which a reasonable 
    utility management * * * would have made, in good faith, under the same 
    circumstances, and at the relevant point in time.'' 772 PSE&G and 
    Carolina P&L ask the Commission to limit the prudence review to the 
    reasonableness of the costs that were incurred to provide wholesale 
    requirements service based on the
    
    [[Page 12430]]
    
    utility's reasonable expectation of continued service. They ask the 
    Commission to clarify that it will not permit prudence proceedings to 
    devolve into collateral attacks on stranded cost recovery and unfocused 
    debates on the sufficiency of the utility's efforts to adapt to changes 
    in the industry, such as its decisions on staffing reductions and asset 
    write-offs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \772\ Both note that this is the prudence standard that the 
    Commission applied in Order No. 636.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        In Order No. 888, we specifically stated that we do not intend to 
    relitigate the prudence of costs previously recovered but that we would 
    not preclude parties from raising prudence in stranded cost 
    proceedings. Because we believe that this approach adequately ensures 
    that the prudence of costs previously recovered at this Commission or a 
    state commission will not be relitigated for stranded cost purposes, we 
    will reject the rehearing requests that seek elimination of the term 
    ``prudent'' from the definition of stranded costs.773 However, we 
    make certain clarifications below in response to the rehearing 
    petitions.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \773\ For the same reason, we will reject Southern's request 
    that we establish a rebuttable presumption of prudence that must be 
    overcome by the departing customer.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As an initial matter, we clarify that the Commission's 
    determination in Order No. 888, which is reaffirmed here, is the same 
    approach the Commission traditionally has followed regarding prudence 
    matters.774 Costs are assumed prudent unless a party or the 
    Commission raises a serious doubt as to prudence; then the burden is on 
    the utility to prove that costs were prudently incurred.775 If 
    costs have previously been recovered in rates (either following an 
    explicit prudence determination or based on an implicit assumption of 
    prudence because no one raised prudence), they cannot be relitigated. 
    However, if prudence has not previously been litigated or if certain 
    costs or activities have become imprudent,776 a party may raise 
    the issue as it pertains to future cost recovery.777 The 
    Commission intends to apply the same prudence standards with regard to 
    future cost recovery, including stranded costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \774\ See Minnesota Power & Light Company, Opinion No. 86, 11 
    FERC para. 61,312 at 61,644-45 (1980).
        \775\ Id. at 61,644; Anaheim Riverside, et al. v. FERC, 669 F.2d 
    799, 809 (D.C. Cir. 1981).
        \776\ A utility has an ongoing prudence obligation. As pointed 
    out in Order No. 888, although an investment or a contract may have 
    been prudently incurred, it may become imprudent at a later point in 
    time not to dispose of assets or not to buy-out contracts that have 
    become uneconomic, assuming this results in net benefits to 
    customers.
        \777\ See Canal Electric Company, 47 FERC para. 61,044 at 
    61,127, reh'g denied, 49 FERC para. 61,069 (1989) (if a party raises 
    prudence issues in a later proceeding, any future finding concerning 
    prudence will have no effect on past rates).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We further clarify that we do not intend to relitigate, for 
    purposes of stranded cost determinations involving retail-turned-
    wholesale customers or unbundled retail customers, the prudence of 
    costs for which rate recovery has been allowed by state commissions. 
    Similarly, in calculating the revenue stream estimate, we do not intend 
    to relitigate the prudence of any costs for which rate recovery has 
    been allowed by this Commission or a state commission.778
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \778\ Although we will not go so far as to characterize these 
    costs as ``per se prudent'' (as requested by PSE&G), in effect, the 
    result is the same because we will not allow the prudence of such 
    costs to be relitigated.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In response to PSE&G and Carolina P&L, we also clarify that, in 
    cases in which we do entertain stranded cost claims, the standard to be 
    used for reviewing the prudence of a utility's costs is the 
    ``reasonable person'' test that we apply in other contexts.779 
    This test gives utility managers ``broad discretion in conducting their 
    business affairs and in incurring costs necessary to provide services 
    to their customers.'' 780 It asks whether the costs are those 
    ``which a reasonable utility management * * * would have made, in good 
    faith, under the same circumstances, and at the relevant point in 
    time.'' 781 We clarify that we do not intend to permit prudence 
    proceedings to become an opportunity for collateral attacks on stranded 
    cost recovery.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \779\ See New England Power Company, 31 FERC para. 61,047 at 
    61,081-84 (1985), aff'd sub nom., Violet v. FERC, 800 F.2d 280, 282-
    83 (1st Cir. 1986). We note that this is the same standard that the 
    Commission has used for reviewing the prudence of a pipeline's Order 
    No. 636 gas supply realignment costs. See Texas Eastern Transmission 
    Corporation, 65 FERC para. 61,363 (1993).
        \780\ New England Power Company, 31 FERC at 61,084.
        \781\ Id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    K. Other
    
    1. Information Reporting Requirements for Public Utilities
        In the Final Rule, the Commission indicated that it will not now 
    eliminate the public disclosure of allegedly competitively sensitive, 
    proprietary, or otherwise confidential data submitted to the Commission 
    on Form No. 1, as well as on other Commission forms. 782 It 
    explained that the information it collects from public utilities is 
    necessary to carry out its jurisdictional responsibilities and is used, 
    among other things, to evaluate the reasonableness of cost-based rates 
    subject to the Commission's jurisdiction and the operation of power 
    markets.783 Moreover, the Commission noted its explanation in 
    ConEd:
    
        \782\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,851-52; mimeo at 631-32.
        \783\ See, e.g., Consolidated Edison Company of New York, Inc. 
    and Central Hudson Gas & Electric Corp., 72 FERC para. 61,184 at 
    61,891 (1995) (ConEd).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [r]eports required to be submitted by Commission rule and necessary 
    for the Commission's jurisdictional activities are considered public 
    information. 18 C.F.R. Sec. 388.106. In addition, the Commission has 
    long required jurisdictional utilities to submit Form 1 data on a 
    form that states on its cover that the Commission does not consider 
    the material to be confidential. [784]
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \784\ 72 FERC at 61,891.
    
        The Commission expressed sensitivity to the lack of symmetry in the 
    generation information we require from traditional public utilities, 
    particularly those that have market-based rate authority, and the 
    generation information required from other public utilities (e.g., 
    public utility marketers) authorized to sell at market-based rates, but 
    explained that the record in the proceeding is insufficiently developed 
    to make and support a well-informed decision requiring a different 
    reporting scheme, particularly given the industry's current rapid pace 
    of change. Also, the Commission indicated that it was not persuaded 
    that the burdens borne by traditional public utilities (primarily 
    annual reports submitted months after-the-fact) are impairing the 
    competitiveness of these utilities so much that we must act hastily 
    now, instead of deferring a decision to a more appropriate proceeding.
        However, the Commission stated that it will monitor its reporting 
    requirements to make sure that they are needed, fair to all segments of 
    the industry, and consistent with the workings of a competitive 
    environment.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Allegheny asserts that this proceeding is the proper forum to 
    evaluate the public disclosure of information required from public 
    utilities because it is necessary to avoid disparate treatment of 
    market participants that violates the comparability standard and leads 
    to market distortions. It argues that the Commission should eliminate 
    the requirement to file data on Form No. 1 and other informational 
    filings, or alternatively the Commission should protect the information 
    as proprietary and confidential.
        Centerior argues that the Commission should eliminate the public 
    disclosure of the cost-based generation rates and provide for symmetry 
    between the information provided by public utilities
    
    [[Page 12431]]
    
    and power marketers by eliminating the reporting requirements.
        EEI indicates that it intends to petition the Commission for 
    further action on information reporting requirements in the near 
    future. It adds that it seeks to work with the Commission in 
    streamlining the reporting process and in creating a level playing 
    field.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We are not persuaded that the information reporting requirements 
    for public utilities need to be changed at this time. Very simply, it 
    is premature to take such a step at a time when much of the industry is 
    still under cost-based rate regulation for sales of electric energy and 
    when corporate restructuring, including utility mergers, is occurring 
    at a rapid pace. On rehearing, entities have merely reiterated the 
    arguments that we previously addressed in the Final Rule and have 
    presented no evidence that the competitiveness of traditional public 
    utilities is being impaired by their having to submit primarily annual 
    reports that are filed months after the fact. Accordingly, we will 
    continue to require public utilities to submit the information required 
    by our rules and regulations and we will monitor our reporting 
    requirements as the industry environment continues to change.
    2. Small Utilities
        The Commission noted that it was sympathetic to the array of 
    concerns raised by small public utilities and small transmission 
    customers and explained that the regulations it was adopting include 
    waiver provisions under which public utilities and transmission 
    customers, and non-public utility entities seeking exemption from the 
    reciprocity condition, may file requests for waivers from all or part 
    of the Commission's regulations or for special treatment.785 
    However, the Commission explained, it is difficult to imagine any 
    circumstance that would justify waiving the requirements of this Rule 
    for any public utility that is also a control area operator.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \785\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,853-54; mimeo at 636-38. The 
    Commission also noted that non-public utility entities could request 
    that the Commission find that they can satisfy the reciprocity 
    condition without meeting all or some of the requirements that 
    public utilities must meet.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission recognized that it might be a financial burden on 
    small public utilities to unbundle generation from transmission, follow 
    standards of conduct that separate transmission personnel from 
    wholesale marketing personnel, and maintain an OASIS. In addition, the 
    Commission explained that for small public utilities that own no 
    generation and buy at wholesale on a radial transmission line from 
    another utility's grid or if their service territory is part of another 
    utility's control area, the small public utility should be permitted to 
    make a showing that it should be exempt from all or some of the Rule.
        The Commission further explained that because the possible 
    scenarios under which small entities may seek waivers from the Final 
    Rule are diverse, they are not susceptible to resolution on a generic 
    basis and the Commission will require applications and fact-specific 
    determinations in each instance.
        In addition, the Commission indicated that it will apply the same 
    standards to any entity seeking a waiver. The Commission explained that 
    this includes public utilities seeking waiver of some or all of the 
    requirements of the Rule, as well as non-public utilities seeking 
    waiver of the reciprocity provisions contained in the pro forma open 
    access tariff. The Commission concluded that it would not apply the 
    open access reciprocity provision to small non-public utilities that 
    are not control area operators and either do not own or control 
    transmission or have transmission that no one is likely to ask to use. 
    However, the Commission explained that they will have to apply for this 
    waiver and demonstrate that they qualify for the waiver.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        APPA asserts that absent a finding that a non-public utility has 
    market power or has exhibited undue discrimination, the non-public 
    utility should be granted a waiver.
        Michigan Systems asks that the Commission modify the Rule to 
    provide a blanket waiver for systems that by their nature cannot have 
    market power over transmission and do not have the personnel to 
    separate functions. It also asserts that the Final Rule waiver 
    procedure is cumbersome and time consuming.
        Tallahassee asks the Commission to clarify that it will liberally 
    apply its waiver policy to small public utilities even if they run a 
    control area. It asserts that the proper focus of concerns over 
    competition are a utility's size, its ability to manipulate the market, 
    and how it operates its control room.
        CAMU asks the Commission to clarify that the small utilities waiver 
    will be generally available to those entities lacking market power 
    because only utilities with market power are capable of subverting the 
    transmission market.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The issues raised with respect to waivers for small utilities are 
    more appropriately addressed in individual fact-specific proceedings. 
    As we explained in the Final Rule,
    
    [b]ecause the possible scenarios under which small entities may seek 
    waivers from the Final Rule are diverse, they are not susceptible to 
    resolution on a generic basis and we will require applications and 
    fact-specific determinations in each instance. We note here that any 
    waivers that we may grant depend upon the facts presented in each 
    case.[786]
    
        \786\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,854; mimeo at 637-38.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Indeed, we have granted a variety of waiver requests by small utilities 
    since issuance of the Final Rule.787
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \787\ Black Creek Hydro, Inc. (Black Creek), 77 FERC para. 
    61,232 (1996); Midwest Energy, Inc., 77 FERC para. 61,208 (1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    3. Regional Transmission Groups
    a. Incentives for RTGs To Form and Resolve Regional Transmission Issues
        In the Final Rule, the Commission expressed its continued support 
    for the development of RTGs and encouraged regional tariffs.788 To 
    further encourage the development of RTGs, the Commission stated that 
    it will accept regional open access transmission tariffs developed by 
    RTGs that are consistent with the objectives of this Rule.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \788\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,854-55; mimeo at 640.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    b. Deference To RTGs to Develop Regional Tariffs and Prices
        In the Final Rule, the Commission indicated its intent to give 
    deference to the planning, dispute resolution, and decisionmaking 
    processes of an RTG. 789 With respect to pricing proposals 
    submitted by RTGs, the Commission stated that RTGs may be able to 
    develop solutions to such problems as loop flows through innovative 
    flow-based pricing methodologies.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \789\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,855; mimeo at 642.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        No requests for rehearing addressed this matter.
    4. Pacific Northwest
        In the Final Rule, the Commission encouraged the filing of regional 
    open access transmission tariffs.790 It also explained that the 
    Final Rule pro forma tariff contains provisions allowing utilities to 
    modify tariff terms to reflect prevailing regional practices. The 
    Commission concluded that this should permit entities in the Pacific 
    Northwest
    
    [[Page 12432]]
    
    to address unique circumstances that exist in the Pacific Northwest and 
    to incorporate prevailing regional practices (e.g., treatment of 
    hydropower generation in the priority of dispatch) into their open 
    access transmission tariffs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \790\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,856; mimeo at 644-45.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        No requests for rehearing addressed this matter.
    5. Power Marketing Agencies
    a. Bonneville Power Administration (BPA)
        In the Final Rule, the Commission stated that BPA is not a public 
    utility under section 201(e) of the FPA and, thus, is not subject to 
    the requirements of this Rule to put the Final Rule pro forma tariff 
    into effect.791 However, the Commission indicated three 
    circumstances under which the Commission may review BPA's transmission 
    access and pricing policies.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \791\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,857-58; mimeo at 648-49.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        With respect to stranded costs, the Commission clarified that the 
    Rule addresses only stranded costs recovered by public utilities under 
    the FPA and transmitting utilities (including BPA) that are subject to 
    mandatory transmission requests under FPA section 211. It explained 
    that the Rule does not address stranded cost recovery by BPA under the 
    Northwest Power Act.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        BPA asks the Commission to clarify that it did not intend to 
    address stranded cost recovery by BPA under either the Northwest Power 
    Act or section 212(i) of the FPA. If Order No. 888 is intended to 
    govern stranded cost recovery by BPA in the case of Commission-ordered 
    transmission under section 211, BPA asks the Commission for an 
    opportunity to brief the issue on rehearing.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We clarify that our review of stranded cost recovery by BPA would 
    take into account the statutory requirements of the Northwest Power Act 
    and the other authorities under which we regulate BPA (e.g., DOE 
    delegation for interim rate approval) and/or section 212(i), as 
    appropriate.
    b. Other Power Marketing Agencies
        In the Final Rule, the Commission explained that Federal power 
    marketing agencies (PMAs) are not public utilities as defined under 
    section 201(e) of the FPA and, thus, are not required by this Rule to 
    file non-discriminatory open access transmission tariffs.792 
    However, the Commission did state that to the extent a PMA receives 
    open access transmission service from a public utility, it is subject 
    to the reciprocity provisions in the utility's pro forma 
    tariff.793
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \792\ The Commission noted, however, that PMAs are transmitting 
    utilities subject to requests for mandatory transmission services 
    under section 211 of the FPA.
        \793\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,858; mimeo at 650-51.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        With respect to SEPA's concern that the proposed point-to-point 
    tariff has a one MW minimum scheduling requirement, but many of its 
    customers have loads of less than one MW, the Commission clarified that 
    the Final Rule pro forma tariff will allow SEPA to continue to schedule 
    service for these customers. The Commission also clarified that SEPA, 
    as a seller of power to multiple purchasers inside several control 
    areas, is eligible to receive network service.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Entergy asks the Commission to clarify that SEPA can obtain network 
    service only in the same manner as any other customer and that there 
    was no intent in the Rule to create a special type of network service 
    for SEPA.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We will clarify that for purposes of obtaining network service SEPA 
    is to be treated as any other customer.
    6. Tennessee Valley Authority
        In the Final Rule, the Commission stated that TVA is not a public 
    utility under section 201(e) of the FPA and, thus, is not required to 
    file a non-discriminatory open access transmission tariff under this 
    Rule.794 However, the Commission explained, if TVA receives open 
    access transmission service from a public utility, it is subject to the 
    reciprocity provision in the utility's pro forma tariff.795
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \794\ The Commission noted, however, that TVA is a transmitting 
    utility subject to requests for mandatory transmission services 
    under section 211 of the FPA.
        \795\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,858-59; mimeo at 651-52.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        No requests for rehearing addressed this matter.
    7. Hydroelectric Power
    Non-Firm Transactions
        In the Final Rule, the Commission explained that it will permit 
    entities to incorporate prevailing regional practices (e.g., treatment 
    of hydropower generation in the priority of dispatch) into regional 
    open access transmission tariffs.796 This, the Commission 
    indicated, should permit entities in a region to resolve concerns over 
    the scheduling of non-firm hydropower.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \796\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,859; mimeo at 654-55.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission's Licensing Practices
    
        The Commission explained that the issues raised by National 
    Hydropower with respect to the Commission's hydroelectric licensing 
    practices are beyond the scope of this rulemaking. The Commission also 
    noted that these issues were raised in a petition to the Commission to 
    revise hydroelectric licensing procedures, filed on July 10, 1995. That 
    is the proper proceeding, the Commission explained, in which to address 
    the Commission's hydroelectric licensing practices.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        No requests for rehearing addressed this matter.
    8. Residential Customers
        In the Final Rule, the Commission stated that it was convinced that 
    the proposed changes for wholesale markets will benefit residential 
    consumers. 797 Moreover, the Commission explained that the Rule 
    does not require retail transmission access for retail customers of any 
    size and does not require any changes in programs such as assistance to 
    low-income and elderly consumers and weatherization and energy 
    conservation, which are, and will remain, under the jurisdiction of the 
    individual states. The Commission further noted that the Rule contains 
    several safeguards to maintain the ability of states to impose 
    conditions on retail access, such as conditions that help to protect 
    residential customers from becoming the residual payer of stranded 
    costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \797\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,860; mimeo at 656.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        No requests for rehearing addressed this matter.
    9. Miscellaneous Issues
    Unconstitutional Taking of Property
        Union Electric declares that the imposition of an onerous regime of 
    mandates governing what utilities must and must not do with their own 
    property constitutes an unconstitutional taking of their property in 
    violation of the takings clause.
    
    [[Page 12433]]
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Union Electric has provided no valid legal or factual basis to 
    support its arguments that our final orders result in an 
    unconstitutional taking of property in violation of the takings clause. 
    We have a statutory obligation under the FPA to remedy undue 
    discrimination in the transmission or sale of electric energy subject 
    to our jurisdiction. In Order No. 888, we concluded that unduly 
    discriminatory and anticompetitive practices exist today in the 
    electric industry and that such practices will increase as competitive 
    pressures continue to grow in the industry.798 Accordingly, we 
    exercised our remedial authority by issuing Order Nos. 888 and 889 to 
    ensure that unduly discriminatory practices can no longer 
    occur.799
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \798\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,682-84; mimeo at 136-142.
        \799\ Union Electric argues that
        [t]he dramatic changes in the regulatory scheme set forth in the 
    final rules impose extensive constraints on Union Electric's use of 
    its own property, forcing Union Electric to throw open its 
    transmission system to use by third parties, dictating the terms and 
    conditions of that usage and, in the process, providing for the 
    physical occupation of Union Electric's transmission system by third 
    parties' facilities and power. (Union Electric at 59).
        However, as Union Electric's own words demonstrate, these so-
    called dramatic changes are no more than a summary of the 
    Commission's current authority and the Commission's current 
    regulation of public utilities. Under the FPA, Union Electric can 
    only provide non-unduly-discriminatory jurisdictional services to 
    third parties and must obtain Commission approval of the rates, 
    terms and conditions pursuant to which it provides such service. 
    Moreover, under Order No. 888, third parties may ``physically 
    occupy'' Union Electric's transmission system only pursuant to the 
    terms of Union Electric's tariff and contracts entered into with 
    Union Electric, just as third parties previously had the right to 
    ``physically occupy'' its transmission system.
        Finally, we are confused about Union Electric's argument in that 
    in the pending merger proceeding involving its proposed merger with 
    Central Illinois, it argues that the open access tariff of the 
    merged company will be used to mitigate market power. See El Paso 
    Electric Company and Central and South West Services Inc., 68 FERC 
    para. 61,181 at 61,914 (1994), dismissed, 72 FERC para. 61,292 
    (1995). Union Electric cannot argue that the tariff mitigates market 
    power at the same time it argues that the requirement to have the 
    tariff is prohibited as an unconstitutional taking of property.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In exercising our remedial authority, we did not alter the 
    traditional principle that a utility is entitled to a reasonable 
    opportunity to recover its prudently incurred costs.800 Union 
    Electric has provided no evidence that it will not be adequately 
    compensated for whatever services it may provide on its system 
    following the effectiveness of Order Nos. 888 and 889. To the extent a 
    third party uses Union Electric's transmission system, it must still 
    compensate Union Electric for that usage, as has happened in the past. 
    There simply cannot be an unconstitutional taking of property when 
    public utilities continue to have the right to file for and receive 
    rates that provide them a reasonable opportunity to recover their 
    prudently incurred costs. Indeed, as the Supreme Court has explained, 
    ``[a]ll that is protected against, in a constitutional sense, is that 
    the rates fixed by the Commission be higher than a confiscatory 
    level.'' 801 Union Electric has made no showing that Order Nos. 
    888 and 889 will result in its rates being set at a confiscatory level. 
    Furthermore, the rate that Union Electric may charge for transmission 
    service is currently before the Commission in Docket No. OA96-50-000 
    and Union Electric should make arguments regarding the reasonableness 
    of its transmission rate in that proceeding. 802 Moreover, Union 
    Electric is free to propose changes to the rate it charges for 
    transmission from time to time to ensure that it is being fairly 
    compensated for its investment in its transmission system, as well as 
    any expenses it incurs in providing such service.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \800\ See, e.g., FPC v. Hope Natural Gas Company, 320 U.S. 591 
    (1944). Moreover, to the extent Union Electric's facilities are used 
    for public service, Union Electric is entitled to recover all 
    prudently invested capital in the public utility enterprise. We have 
    not changed that principle.
        \801\ FPC v. Texaco, 417 U.S. 380, 391-92 (1974); see also FPC 
    v. Natural Gas Pipeline Co., 315 U.S. 575, 585 (1942).
        \802\ All public utilities subject to Commission jurisdiction 
    were required to file open access compliance tariffs, including the 
    rate to be charged for various types of transmission service, by 
    July 9, 1996.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Section 206 Complaints
    
        Cleveland states that, unfortunately, it has suffered significantly 
    because of denied transmission access and the inefficacy of long-
    delayed enforcement relief under section 206 of the FPA. Thus, 
    Cleveland states that the Commission must announce its intention to 
    enforce transmission and related obligations and, having made that 
    pronouncement, take whatever steps are necessary to do so.
        TAPS states that throughout the Final Rule the Commission points to 
    complaint procedures to redress complaints against transmission 
    providers' open access tariffs and argues that the Commission must 
    clarify that these complaints will receive expedited treatment.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Commission has a statutory obligation to act if it finds, upon 
    its own motion or upon complaint, that any rate, charges, or 
    classification demanded, observed, charged, or collected by any public 
    utility, or that any rule, regulation, practice, or contract affecting 
    such rate, charge, or classification is unjust, unreasonable, unduly 
    discriminatory or preferential, and to determine the just and 
    reasonable rate, charge, classification, rule, regulation, practice, or 
    contract to be thereafter observed. Moreover, section 206(b) of the FPA 
    requires that whenever the Commission institutes a proceeding under 
    this section it must establish a refund effective date. In carrying out 
    its obligations under section 206 of the FPA, the Commission acts as 
    expeditiously as is possible, given the complexities of the issues at 
    hand, its other workload and its level of staffing. The Commission will 
    continue to work as expeditiously as possible in resolving section 206 
    proceedings, as well as in resolving all of the other matters that come 
    before it. Given the critical importance of timely, comparable 
    transmission access in fostering competitive wholesale power markets, 
    the Commission intends to vigorously enforce utilities' open access 
    obligations. 803
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \803\ With specific regard to Cleveland and CEI, we note that 
    the Commission has expended considerable resources over the years 
    dealing with and resolving a significant number of section 205 and 
    206 proceedings in which these companies contested a plethora of 
    issues. As the D.C. Circuit noted, these two entities have a 
    particularly hostile relationship. City of Cleveland v. FERC, 773 
    F.2d 1368, 1371 (1985). This has led to a situation where these 
    contentious entities are more likely to contest issues before the 
    Commission than to resolve them. Since 1993 alone, the Commission 
    has addressed and resolved at least 9 proceedings involving disputes 
    between Cleveland and CEI. Indeed, at this time, the Commission has 
    only several ongoing proceedings involving disputes between these 
    entities. In addition, the parties are in disagreement over 
    transmission issues in the pending merger application involving CEI 
    and Ohio Edison.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We would emphasize that filing complaints with the Commission is 
    not the only avenue that transmission customers (or potential 
    customers) can pursue to raise their concerns. Under the Open Access 
    Transmission Tariff, parties can and should avail themselves of the 
    Dispute Resolution Procedures set forth in section 12 of the pro forma 
    tariff. This section provides that an arbitrator must render a decision 
    and notify the parties within ninety days of appointment.
    
    NRC Remedial Orders
    
        Cleveland asks that the Commission clarify that directives 
    requiring non-discriminatory treatment of transmission customers are 
    not intended to override, but are expected to accommodate, valid 
    remedial orders of the NRC imposed in the form of nuclear license 
    conditions.
    
    [[Page 12434]]
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We will deny Cleveland's requested clarification because it is 
    overly broad. However, we do clarify that we view our jurisdiction 
    under the FPA and the NRC's jurisdiction as complementary. In that 
    regard, a utility subject to the Commission's jurisdiction and to the 
    NRC's jurisdiction would have to comply with the orders of both 
    commissions. Moreover, just as the NRC cannot and does not enforce this 
    Commission's orders, it is not within our jurisdiction to enforce 
    orders of the NRC. In the event that an entity believes that it must, 
    but cannot, comply with separate orders issued by this Commission and 
    the NRC, it should present evidence to this Commission and/or the NRC 
    of such a conflict. To the extent necessary and appropriate, we would 
    attempt to resolve any such conflicts subject to our jurisdiction under 
    the FPA.
    
    Retail Customers' Future Access to Transmission Capacity
    
        IL Industrials states that the Commission should fashion safeguards 
    to prevent monopolization of transmission capacity by wholesale 
    customers before retail customers are entitled to engage in direct 
    access. Alternatively, IL Industrials states that the Commission should 
    specify that this issue will be addressed in the CRT NOPR proceeding 
    and that contracts or other arrangements affecting available 
    transmission capacity will be subject to safeguards to protect retail 
    customer transmission access.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        This matter is beyond the scope of this proceeding. We have no way 
    of ascertaining the transmission capacity that a retail customer may 
    require in the future should it become entitled to engage in direct 
    access through a state-approved program or voluntary action by its 
    current transmission provider. We cannot require a transmission 
    provider to keep transmission capacity available for all possible 
    transactions that a retail customer may possibly enter into in the 
    future. Just as transmission customers must take the system as it 
    exists at the time of a request, so must future potential transmission 
    customers take the system as it exists at the time of their request.
    
    Transaction Accommodation Arrangements
    
        NCMPA argues that the Commission failed to address the problem of 
    market power arising from a transmission provider's control over 
    transaction accommodation arrangements, which it states are 
    arrangements needed by transmission dependent utilities to accommodate 
    third-party transactions within an existing power supply relationship 
    between the TDU and the transmission provider. NCMPA explains that this 
    problem is most apparent where there is a comprehensive power supply 
    relationship that purports to establish most or all of the TDU's bulk 
    power needs. For example, NCMPA points out that because of Duke Power 
    Company's control over transaction accommodation arrangements, NCMPA 
    has been frustrated in its attempts to pursue beneficial bulk power 
    transactions with parties other than Duke. NCMPA asks that the 
    Commission require transmission providers to provide these arrangements 
    on a comparable basis, state that it will take prompt action to remedy 
    a denial of comparable arrangements, and require that any utility 
    seeking specific permission for any action premised on the mitigation 
    of market power to demonstrate that it has offered comparable 
    transaction accommodation arrangements to any TDU that requires such 
    arrangements.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        NCMPA's concerns appear to be related to its existing power supply 
    arrangements, not with new service under the pro forma tariff. These 
    concerns are more appropriately addressed in a case-specific section 
    206 complaint proceeding before the Commission.
    
    Ohio Valley--Power to Uranium Enrichment Facility
    
        Ohio Valley asks the Commission to clarify that the orders do not 
    apply to Ohio Valley so that Ohio Valley can continue to provide the 
    lowest possible cost, and most reliable, service to the Piketon, Ohio 
    uranium enrichment facility owned by the United States.804 
    Otherwise, Ohio Valley argues, compliance could result in increased 
    costs to the United States and to the customers of the utilities 
    participating in providing power to the enrichment facility. Ohio 
    Valley seeks to avoid unnecessary interference with its ability to 
    carry out its obligations under the existing agreements, but is 
    amenable to reasonable and prudent use of its transmission system in 
    accordance with sections 211 and 212.805
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \804\ Ohio Valley states that the facility is now leased by the 
    United States to the United States Enrichment Corporation.
        \805\ Dayton filed a motion to reject Ohio Valley's request for 
    rehearing, arguing that it was really an application for waiver. 
    (Dayton Motion to Reject).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Ohio Valley's rehearing request is essentially an application for 
    waiver that is not properly addressed in this proceeding. By order 
    issued July 2, 1996, we explained that because of the fact-specific 
    nature of waiver requests the Commission will not address such requests 
    in a generic rulemaking proceeding, but will require entities seeking 
    waiver to submit separate, fact-specific requests that will be docketed 
    in separate OA proceedings.806 Subsequently, Ohio Valley filed a 
    separate petition for waiver in Docket No. OA96-126-000 that 
    effectively reiterated the arguments made in its rehearing request. The 
    Commission will address Ohio Valley's fact-specific arguments in Docket 
    No. OA96-126-000.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \806\ Order Clarifying Order Nos. 888 and 889 Compliance 
    Matters, 76 FERC para. 61,009 (1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Exchanges
    
        Several entities argue that exchanges should be permitted without a 
    requirement that customers book capacity for each direction the power 
    will flow and parties should not each have to pay the full reservation 
    charge.807 Because point-to-point customers can change receipt 
    points without payment of additional charges, they argue that the same 
    logic applies to exchanges.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \807\ E.g., VT DPS, Valero, APPA.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        An exchange between two utilities has traditionally been viewed as 
    two separate transactions (two one-way services) from the transmitting 
    utility's planning and reservation perspective and has been priced as 
    two separate services. Consistent with this approach, the pro forma 
    tariff only allows changes to points of receipt and delivery for point-
    to-point service on a non-firm basis at no extra charge. Any changes to 
    points of receipt and delivery on a firm basis must be submitted to the 
    Commission as new applications. However, we note that comparability is 
    achieved if the transmission provider charges itself and its 
    transmission customers for point-to-point service on a consistent 
    basis, whether that be separately for both directions or on a 
    bidirectional basis.
    
    Various Rate Matters
    
        VT DPS and Valero argue that rates ``should be based on a 
    definition and quantification of a core of transmission function lines 
    and substations for use in wholesale wheeling rather than on the basis 
    of a rolled-in rate for the entire
    
    [[Page 12435]]
    
    transmission network.'' VT DPS states that ``[i]n order to insure 
    against cross subsidization, the tariffs should provide for the 
    imposition of a Local Transmission System Access Charge to recover the 
    costs of the facilities used to provide service to customers in this 
    category.'' (VT DPS at 23-24; Valero at 8-10).
        American Forest & Paper argues that
    
    the Commission's proposal includes as part of the transmission 
    revenue requirement amounts attributable to the utility's use of its 
    own transmission system to effectuate off-system sales and revenues 
    received from transmission customers taking service under existing 
    contracts and tariffs but not under the new transmission tariffs. By 
    failing to subtract such revenues from the revenue requirement used 
    to determine rates for services rendered under the new tariffs, the 
    utility effectively recovers these amounts twice: once from its off-
    system sales and transmission customers not taking service under the 
    new tariffs and a second time from its customers taking service 
    under the proposed new tariffs.''[808]
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \808\ American Forest & Paper at 24.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        American Forest & Paper asserts that to eliminate this double-
    recovery, the Commission should adopt PacifiCorp's proposal in Docket 
    No. ER95-1240. American Forest & Paper further declares that the 
    Commission must demonstrate that the charges imposed on customers of 
    network wheeling service are commensurate with the benefits that they 
    receive.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We are not prepared to mandate in a generic proceeding such as this 
    that all transmission rates must be established by function or that a 
    specific pricing methodology should be used. Our rate policy, as set 
    forth in the Transmission Pricing Policy Statement, is to encourage 
    flexible and innovative rate approaches by the electric industry. 
    Mandating a single methodology for the entire industry would certainly 
    defeat that goal. While the Commission welcomes new and innovative 
    proposals, we will not impose a generic change in this proceeding. As 
    always, utilities are free to propose the use of a functional pricing 
    method in their compliance filings or in any section 205 filing it may 
    submit to the Commission.
    
    Federal Government Contract Clauses
    
        ConEd asserts that the Commission must modify the pro forma tariff 
    to include certain Federal government required anti-discrimination 
    clauses. According to ConEd, these clauses require that all of Con 
    Edison's transmission providers agree to be bound by certain provisions 
    of the federal subcontractor regulations. ConEd suggests that the 
    ``Commission state that Con Edison and similarly-situated utilities be 
    permitted to comply with the federal subcontracting requirements by 
    inserting such clauses in their service agreements for transmission 
    services.'' (ConEd at 17-18).
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Commission disagrees with ConEd's assertion that the Commission 
    must modify the pro forma tariff to include certain Federal government 
    anti-discrimination clauses. The Commission does not dispute that 
    certain parties must comply with provisions of the federal 
    subcontractor regulations for particular transactions that may involve 
    the provision of transmission service. However, we do not agree that 
    these provisions must be incorporated into the pro forma tariff. The 
    contracting obligation raised by ConEd is independent of the pro forma 
    tariff and more appropriately addressed in a separate contract between 
    the parties to the purchase or the service agreements for transmission 
    services. The Commission notes that this is apparently how the issue 
    has been handled in the past by ConEd because its tariffs previously 
    filed with the Commission (pre-NOPR) did not include such anti-
    discrimination clauses.
    
    V. Environmental Statement
    
    Summary
    
        The Commission prepared an environmental impact statement (EIS) to 
    evaluate the environmental consequences that could result from adopting 
    the Rule. We did so largely in response to the claims of several 
    commenters who charge that the Rule will have significant adverse 
    environmental effects. As described in Order No. 888:
    
        Although a number of issues were raised, by far the most 
    prominent concern arises from the theory that competitive market 
    conditions created by the rule will provide an advantage to power 
    suppliers who produce power from coal-fired facilities that are not 
    subject to stringent controls on nitrogen oxides (NOX) 
    emissions. Under this theory, these facilities, located primarily in 
    the Midwest and South, will, as a result of the rule, generate more 
    power and emit more NOX, which will contribute to ozone 
    formation. The ozone could add to pollution both in those regions 
    and more significantly in the Northeast, to which area such 
    pollutants could be transported. Those who propound this theory 
    argue that it is the responsibility of the Commission, using its 
    authority under the Federal Power Act, to effect environmental 
    controls that will mitigate what they predict will be significant 
    increases in NOX emissions associated with this rule.[809]
    
        \809\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,860; mimeo at 657-58 (footnote 
    omitted).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The EIS recognizes that the electric industry will contribute to 
    air emissions regardless of whether the Rule is adopted. The purpose of 
    the EIS is to analyze to what extent the Rule is likely to affect those 
    emissions.
        Many variables can influence the impacts of the Rule and the EIS 
    uses a modeling framework that incorporates a range of assumptions 
    about these variables. The most significant variable is likely to be 
    the future prices of the two primary fuels used to generate 
    electricity--coal and natural gas. Government and industry price 
    forecasts were used to construct two alternative fuel price 
    assumptions: (1) that the price of natural gas will increase relative 
    to the price of coal; and (2) that the relative price of coal and 
    natural gas will remain constant. These assumptions form the basis for 
    two base cases that project the environmental impacts of developments 
    in the electric industry without the Rule. The EIS then makes 
    assumptions about the effects of the Rule to create three scenarios 
    that project a range of possible results. It compares the environmental 
    impacts projected in the scenarios with those projected in the base 
    cases to determine the effect of the Rule.810 The analysis set 
    forth in the EIS demonstrates that the Rule will not in any significant 
    respect affect overall trends in NOX emissions.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \810\ The EIS also conducts sensitivity analyses of how 
    projected air emissions might change if key assumptions in the 
    analysis are changed. These analyses include two frozen efficiency 
    reference cases which represent a world in which: (1) the Commission 
    reverses current pro-competitive transmission policy (inconsistent 
    with congressional mandates under EPAct); (2) states cease to adopt 
    programs to improve industry efficiency; and (3) electric companies 
    cease to improve operations or to enter into mutually beneficial 
    transactions.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Subsequent to the issuance of Order No. 888, the Environmental 
    Protection Agency (EPA) conducted a review of the Commission's FEIS in 
    which EPA employed alternative assumptions for a number of model 
    inputs. In doing so, EPA stressed that ``[n]aturally there can be 
    differences among reasonable analysts concerning the assumptions used 
    in such an analysis'' and that ``EPA believes the assumptions used by 
    the FERC and those used by EPA both lie within the reasonable range.'' 
    811 EPA has concluded that the Rule is unlikely to have any 
    significant adverse environmental impact in the immediate
    
    [[Page 12436]]
    
    future, and that implementation of the Rule should go forward without 
    delay. In reaching these conclusions, EPA concurred that the Commission 
    conducted an adequate NEPA analysis of the environmental impacts of the 
    Rule under a range of possible scenarios. EPA also agreed that the 
    Commission made a reasonable choice of models with which to conduct the 
    analysis and, as noted above, made assumptions for various factors 
    input into the model that lie within the range of reasonable 
    assumptions.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \811\ Letter of May 22, 1996 from Mary Nichols, Assistant 
    Administrator for Air and Radiation, EPA, to Kathleen McGinty, 
    Chair, CEQ.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        EPA also concurred with the Commission that NOX emissions 
    increases associated with the Rule, if any, should be addressed as part 
    of a comprehensive NOX emissions control program developed by EPA 
    and the states pursuant to the Clean Air Act. EPA committed to use its 
    Clean Air Act authority to support successful completion of this 
    program, and stated that it will establish a NOX cap-and-trade 
    program through Federal Implementation Plans if some states are 
    unwilling or unable to act in a timely manner.
        In a letter dated May 13, 1996, the EPA Administrator referred 
    Order No. 888 to CEQ.812 In doing so, EPA suggests that if the 
    Ozone Transport Assessment Group (OTAG) and Clean Air Act processes 
    fail to produce the necessary pollution limitations in a timely manner, 
    EPA will call upon all other interested federal agencies to assist in 
    solving the problem. EPA would ask the Commission to contribute by 
    examining, through a Notice of Inquiry, possible strategies for 
    mitigating NOX emissions increases associated with the Rule.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \812\ Letter of May 13, 1996, from Carol Browner, Administrator, 
    EPA to Kathleen McGinty, Chair, CEQ.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission subsequently responded by issuing an order stating 
    that if EPA concludes that the OTAG process has not succeeded in 
    meeting its objectives in a timely manner, the Commission would 
    initiate a Notice of Inquiry to further examine what mitigation might 
    be permissible and appropriate under the Federal Power Act. Such an 
    inquiry would solicit public comment on how to assess appropriately the 
    air pollution impacts attributable to the Rule, suitable ways in which 
    to address such impacts, if any, and the scope of the Commission's 
    authority to address such impacts. The Commission also stated that, 
    under the extraordinary circumstances in which EPA would undertake a 
    Federal Implementation Plan, the Commission would agree to initiate 
    contemporaneously a rulemaking to propose possible mitigation that 
    could be undertaken by the Commission under the FPA. Such a rulemaking 
    would be undertaken on the basis of the Notice of Inquiry discussed 
    above and would be appropriate only if environmental harm attributable 
    to the Rule that warranted mitigation is demonstrated.813 On June 
    14, 1996, CEQ concluded that the Commission's order was fully 
    responsive to EPA's concerns and requests and that the referral process 
    and corresponding responses to the referral from the Commission and 
    other agencies have successfully resolved the disagreements between EPA 
    and the Commission.814
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \813\ Order Responding to Referral to Council on Environmental 
    Quality, 75 FERC para. 61,208 at 61,691-92 (1996).
        \814\ Letter of June 14, 1996 from Kathleen McGinty, Chair, CEQ, 
    to Carol Browner, Administrator, EPA and Elizabeth Moler, Chair, 
    FERC.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As discussed below, EPA is currently taking steps to implement a 
    comprehensive NOX emissions control program to ensure that 
    emissions reductions are achieved to prevent significant transport of 
    ozone pollution across state boundaries in the Eastern United States. 
    OTAG is continuing to work in conjunction with EPA on this issue and 
    intends to complete its process in the near future.
        Rehearing is sought on eight categories of issues relating to the 
    Commission's analysis of environmental issues: selection of the 
    appropriate no-action alternative; challenges to modeling assumptions; 
    need for mitigation; emissions standards disparity; the short-term 
    consequences of the Rule; cost benefit analysis; socioeconomic impacts; 
    and compliance with the Coastal Zone Management Act. For the reasons 
    discussed below, rehearing is denied.
    
    A. The Appropriate No-Action Alternative
    
        The FEIS discusses several alternatives, including the alternative 
    of instituting open access pursuant to section 211 of the FPA. The FEIS 
    states in this regard that:
    
        Actions taken pursuant to section 211 and pursuant to sections 
    203 and 205 in merger and market-rate cases, respectively, represent 
    a case-by-case approach to establishing open access. Absent action 
    on the proposed rule, the Commission would continue using these 
    authorities to require utilities to file open access tariffs and 
    provide case-specific service, as necessary or appropriate. In 
    addition, sections 205 and 206 charge the Commission with ensuring 
    that purely voluntary transmission tariffs are not unduly 
    discriminatory. Thus, if the proposed rule were not adopted, the 
    Commission would continue to require that voluntary tariffs be 
    upgraded to offer the Commission's current standards for non-
    discriminatory open access transmission services. The result of 
    continuing the Commission's policies without the proposed rule is 
    that the Commission would effectuate a more open transmission grid, 
    but in a patchwork manner and at a slower pace.
        The case-by-case approach to achieving open access currently in 
    use is slower and more costly, and thereby less desirable, than the 
    generic approach set forth in the proposed rule. Thus, the no-action 
    alternative is not a reasonable alternative to the proposed 
    rule.815
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \815\ FEIS at 2-1 and 2-2.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        The PA Com contends that the FEIS does not adequately consider the 
    alternative of instituting open access pursuant to section 211 of the 
    FPA. It states that section 211 provides a means for wholesale power 
    sellers and buyers to obtain transmission services necessary to compete 
    in, or to reach competitive markets, and that the FEIS ignores the 
    steady, if slow, progression to open access taking place under section 
    211.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The FEIS notes that there are significant reasons for implementing 
    open access through a rulemaking rather than the case-by-case approach 
    of section 211. In the absence of a Commission rulemaking, the 
    development of open access pursuant to section 211 would occur as 
    potential transmission users file requests for such services and the 
    Commission approves them as appropriate. Such proceedings are likely to 
    be contested by competitors and the Commission would decide each 
    application individually. Given the number of potential transmission 
    users who are likely to file requests for such services, it is 
    conceivable that this approach may require the Commission to decide a 
    large number of such applications. 816 Thus, the case-by-case 
    approach is likely to be much slower and more costly to implement than 
    action by rule.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \816\ To date, the Commission has issued six proposed orders and 
    four final section 211 orders. Id. at 2-1.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Case-by-case implementation of open access is also more likely to 
    result in patchwork development as the policy evolves over time. It is 
    important to develop uniform national standards to facilitate the move 
    to open access. This approach adds certainty and facilitates 
    development and implementation of open access in a way that would be 
    difficult to achieve on a case-by-case basis. The development of 
    national
    
    [[Page 12437]]
    
    standards is best done through a mechanism whereby all interested 
    parties can participate in shaping the policy through notice and 
    comment rulemaking. The piecemeal implementation of open access on a 
    case-by-case basis over time, no matter how carefully conducted, is 
    likely to result in inconsistencies and difficulty in application. 
    Given the national nature of the electric grid and the developing open 
    access market, case-by-case implementation is not practical nor 
    desirable and will limit the anticipated benefits of open access.
        The PA Com does not specify how the Commission fails to adequately 
    consider the alternative of instituting open access pursuant to section 
    211. It is insufficient for a party to complain that an analysis is 
    inadequate without providing specific support for its claim. As the 
    court noted in Northside Sanitary Landfill, Inc. v. Thomas, 849 F.2d 
    1516, 1519-20 (D.C. Cir. 1988), cert. denied, 489 U.S. 1078 (1989):
    
        In Vermont Yankee Nuclear Power Corp. v. Natural Resources 
    Defense Council, Inc., 435 U.S. 519, 98 S.Ct. 1197, 55 L.Ed.2d 460 
    (1978), then-Justice Rehnquist expressed the unanimous opinion of 
    seven members of the Supreme Court that a party * * * has the burden 
    of clarifying its position for the [agency]. Even though the 
    [agency] has the statutory obligation to consider fully significant 
    comments, ``it is still incumbent upon intervenors who wish to 
    participate * * * to structure their participation so that it is 
    meaningful, so that it alerts the agency to the intervenors' 
    position and contentions.'' 435 U.S. at 553, 98 S.Ct. at 1216. 
    Justice Rehnquist, then quoted with approval Judge Leventhal's 
    remarks in Portland Cement, id., and concluded that administrative 
    proceedings should not be a game or a forum to engage in unjustified 
    obstructionism by making cryptic and obscure references to matters 
    that ``ought to be'' considered and then, after failing to do more 
    to bring the matter to the agency's attention, seeking to have that 
    agency determination vacated on the ground that the agency failed to 
    consider matters forcefully presented.''
    
    Id., at 533-54, 98 S.Ct. at 1217.
    
        We also note that the PA Com's quarrel does not appear to be with 
    the Commission's analysis of the section 211 alternative in any event, 
    but rather with the underlying policy decision to implement open access 
    through a rulemaking rather than more slowly on a case-by-case basis.
        The Administrative Procedure Act authorizes agencies to establish 
    policies by rulemaking or on a case-by-case basis. Here, the Commission 
    has properly exercised its discretion to establish open access by 
    rulemaking rather than in individual proceedings. The PA Com does not 
    contest this authority or the Commission's exercise of it. Rather, its 
    complaint goes to the underlying policy choices guiding that decision. 
    Disagreement with an agency's policy choice is not a proper basis for a 
    NEPA-based challenge to agency action. As the Circuit Court of Appeals 
    for the District of Columbia (D.C. Circuit) stated in Foundation on 
    Economic Trends v. Lyng, 817 F.2d 882, 886 (D.C. Cir. 1987) (footnote 
    omitted) (brackets in original):
    
    NEPA was not intended to resolve fundamental policy disputes. As the 
    Supreme Court recently admonished, ``[t]he political process, and 
    not NEPA, provides the appropriate forum in which to air policy 
    disagreements.'' Metropolitan Edison Co. v. People Against Nuclear 
    Energy, 460 U.S. 766, 777, 103 S.Ct. 1556, 1563, 75 L.Ed.2d 534 
    (1983) (citation omitted). A policy disagreement, at bottom, is the 
    gravamen of appellants' complaint. In our view, ``[t]ime and 
    resources are simply too limited for us to believe that Congress 
    intended to extend NEPA as far as [appellant would take] it.'' Id. 
    at 776, 103 S.Ct. at 1562. [817]]
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \817\ See also Northwest Coalition for Alternatives to 
    Pesticides v. Lyng, 844 F.2d 588, 591 (9th Cir. 1988).
    
        Contrary to the PA Com's assertion, and regardless of the basis for 
    that assertion, the discussion of the section 211 alternative in the 
    FEIS satisfies the requirements of NEPA. The Supreme Court has stated 
    that ``[t]o make an impact statement something more than an exercise in 
    frivolous boilerplate the concept of alternatives must be bounded by 
    some notion of feasibility.'' 818 ``Central to evaluating 
    practicable alternatives is the determination of a project's purpose.'' 
    819 ``The range of alternatives that must be considered in the EIS 
    need not extend beyond those reasonably related to the purposes of the 
    project.'' 820 The purpose of the Rule is to implement open access 
    in order to remedy undue discrimination and to do so on a timely basis 
    and in a uniform manner; the Commission has determined that case-by-
    case implementation of open access will not satisfy that purpose.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \818\ Vermont Yankee Nuclear Power Corp. v. Natural Resources 
    Defense Council, Inc., 435 U.S. 519, 551 (1978); Laguna Greenbelt, 
    Inc. v. U.S. Department of Transportation, 42 F.3d 517, 524 (9th 
    Cir. 1994).
        \819\ National Wildlife Federation v. Whistler, 27 F.3d 1341, 
    1345 (8th Cir. 1994).
        \820\ Laguna Greenbelt, supra, 42 F.2d at 524. In that case, 
    involving construction of a tollroad, Laguna contended that the EIS 
    ignored a smaller, four-lane alternative. The EIS addressed this 
    proposal, explaining that it was rejected because a four lane 
    highway would not meet the project's goal of reducing traffic 
    congestion. The court found that the proposal was thus properly 
    rejected as not reasonably related to the purposes of the project. 
    Id. at 524-25.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The PA Com has proffered no reasons why the examination in the FEIS 
    of the section 211 alternative is insufficient. We conclude that the 
    FEIS adequately considers the alternative of instituting open access 
    pursuant to section 211. Rehearing on this issue is denied.
    
    B. Challenges to Modeling Assumptions
    
        Several rehearing requests challenge the modeling assumptions used 
    in the FEIS. These challenges are raised in support of the claim that 
    the Commission's analysis understates the environmental impacts of the 
    Rule. The most fundamental challenge is the PA Com's claim that 
    computer modeling is insufficient to examine the impacts of the Rule. 
    The PA Com and Joint Commenters suggest that the model fails to use the 
    appropriate base case. Questions are also raised regarding specific 
    assumptions used in the model.
        In discussing these issues below, we note that although EPA raised 
    many similar points with respect to the Commission's modeling approach 
    in comments on the DEIS, EPA ultimately concluded that ``the FERC has 
    conducted an adequate analysis under the National Environmental Policy 
    Act of the environmental impacts of the open access rule under a range 
    of possible scenarios'' and that ``[t]he FERC made a reasonable choice 
    of models (CEUM) and made assumptions for various factors input into 
    the model that lie within the range of reasonable assumptions.'' EPA 
    also notes that the Commission performed the specific additional 
    analyses that were requested in comments on the draft EIS.
        As EPA points out, ``[n]aturally, there can be differences among 
    reasonable analysts concerning the assumptions used in such an 
    analysis.'' EPA then reiterates that it believes that assumptions used 
    by the Commission ``lie within the reasonable range.'' It concludes 
    that ``the FEIS provides a credible basis for understanding the 
    possible environmental impacts of the open access rule.''
    1. Appropriate Base Case
        Selection of the appropriate base case was contested in the DEIS on 
    grounds similar to those presented here. Certain commenters argued that 
    the Commission should compare the impacts of the Rule to a no-action 
    alternative that assumes that the Commission abandons all open access 
    policies, not just the Rule. Some commenters went even further, 
    suggesting that the Commission compare emission levels projected to 
    result from the Rule against a frozen efficiency case in which other 
    major
    
    [[Page 12438]]
    
    factors--factors that would increase industry efficiency independent of 
    the Rule--do not occur. Such factors include adoption of pro-
    competitive state polices and actions by utilities to undertake 
    mutually beneficial voluntary transactions that do not require the use 
    of open access tariffs mandated under the Rule. Commenters who 
    advocated either a different no-action alternative or the frozen 
    efficiency case posited that studies using those assumptions would show 
    that the Rule will cause significantly greater NOX emissions than 
    those shown in the DEIS. We concluded in Order No. 888 that:
    
    [S]taff has selected the appropriate ``no-action'' alternative. An 
    alternative that requires the Commission to reverse all its other 
    open access policies is simply not a ``no-action'' alternative. To 
    the contrary, it would require decisive action running counter to 
    the direction from the Congress in the Energy Policy Act and the 
    needs of the marketplace and electricity consumers.
        However, to ensure that the effects of the rule were analyzed 
    fully, the FEIS did study a reference case based on the ``frozen 
    efficiency'' case * * * Although, as described below, we believe 
    this case to be highly unlikely, the results show that, even under 
    this scenario, the impacts of the rule are not great and do not vary 
    significantly from those projected by staff under the other 
    assumptions. [821]]
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \821\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,863; mimeo at 665-66 (footnote 
    omitted).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Pennsylvania PUC. The PA Com asserts that the Commission did not 
    compare emissions levels associated with the Rule against the 
    appropriate base case. It claims that the Commission should have used 
    continued case-by-case evolution of open access and increased wholesale 
    competition under FPA sections 211 and 212 as the base case instead of 
    generic, simultaneous, nationwide open access as mandated by Order No. 
    888. Put differently, the PA Com claims that the appropriate base case 
    is the evolution of competition and open access without the 
    intervention of Order No. 888. The PA Com concludes that by using the 
    improper base case the FEIS ignores evidence of significant NOX 
    increases resulting from the Rule, which affects the ability of 
    Pennsylvania to meet the mandates of the Clean Air Act.
        Joint Commenters. The Joint Commenters maintain that the FEIS uses 
    an inappropriate no-action alternative as a basis for analysis. 
    822 The gist of its argument is that the Commission must 
    acknowledge the policy initiative of which it contends Order No. 888 is 
    only one part. It claims that the Commission ignores the fact that, 
    whether competition is pursued through Order No. 888 or on a case-by-
    case basis, implementation of open access is a major programmatic 
    policy choice the environmental impacts of which must be addressed. It 
    contends that by using case-by-case implementation as the no-action 
    alternative, the Commission effectively defines away most of the 
    impacts of the Rule.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \822\ Although cast as use of an inappropriate ``no action 
    alternative'', the Joint Commenters' point goes to the 
    appropriateness of the base case used in the analysis.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In short, the Joint Commenters claim that by defining the no-action 
    alternative as implementation of the open access program over a longer 
    period of time through case-by-case action, the Commission did not 
    fully examine the potential impacts of Order No. 888. It states that if 
    the effects of Order No. 888 are defined to include only those that 
    result from the timing difference between implementation of open access 
    through case-by-case decisions and open access pursuant to a generic 
    rule, it is virtually a foregone conclusion that most of the 
    potentially adverse environmental effects of the Commission's open 
    access policies will not be identified.
        The Joint Commenters concur that the frozen efficiency case 
    analyzed in the FEIS is a proper starting place for an acceptable NEPA 
    review. It faults the discussion of the frozen efficiency case, 
    however, as failing to provide important information needed to allow 
    parties to evaluate the analysis. The Joint Commenters complain that 
    the analysis does not include the model outputs which demonstrate the 
    most severe environmental effects; this, they claim, makes it 
    impossible to verify the results or analyze the factors contributing to 
    the effects shown.
        The Joint Commenters state that in addition to omitting the 
    modeling outputs for the most environmentally relevant cases, the FEIS 
    does not contain air quality modeling of the scenarios that show the 
    greatest emissions increases. It claims that the Urban Airshed Model 
    (UAM-V) examines only the incremental impacts of the Competition-
    Favors-Coal Scenario as compared with the High-Price-Differential Base 
    Case, the same analysis presented in the DEIS. The Joint Commenters 
    stress that EPA in its comments on the DEIS noted that the results 
    shown for this case (an emissions decrease) is illogical and should be 
    explained. It states that without modeling the emissions changes 
    associated with the Competition-Favors-Coal Scenario over the frozen 
    efficiency base case, the FEIS provides no indication of the 
    seriousness of the environmental harm from potential emissions 
    increases caused by FERC's initiatives. The Joint Commenters also claim 
    that the expanded transmission analysis used in the FEIS is unduly 
    conservative.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Commission continues to believe that the base cases and 
    scenarios used in the DEIS are most appropriate for studying the 
    effects of the Rule. Nonetheless, to ensure that the effects of the 
    Rule were analyzed fully, the FEIS also examined a frozen efficiency 
    case that uses a combination of assumptions most likely to show 
    significant increases in emissions.
        We did this despite our belief that it is inaccurate to attribute 
    all efficiency improvements in the industry to Order No. 888 or even to 
    federal actions of all kinds. In fact, as noted in the FEIS, the frozen 
    efficiency case is far more extreme in its assumptions than would be 
    reasonable for a no-further-Commission-action case because it presumes 
    that industry and state regulators also cease all changes toward a more 
    competitive industry. However, the frozen efficiency case is useful as 
    a sensitivity analysis because it reflects an extreme bound on any 
    separate no-further-Commission-action case. 823 A fortiori the 
    impact actually to be expected from the Rule must be less than that 
    determined using the frozen efficiency case.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \823\ This analysis is described as a sensitivity analysis 
    because it examines how projected air emissions might change if key 
    assumptions in the analysis are altered.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We believe that the frozen efficiency analysis is highly 
    implausible because its represents a world in which: (1) the Commission 
    reverses current pro-competitive transmission policies (inconsistent 
    with congressional mandates under EPAct); (2) states cease to adopt 
    programs to improve industry efficiency; and (3) electric companies 
    cease to improve operation or to enter into mutually beneficial 
    transactions.
        The Joint Commenters agree that the frozen efficiency analysis 
    constitutes a valid NEPA review. That issue, therefore, is not in 
    dispute. It objects that the FEIS does not include the model outputs 
    for the sensitivity cases which demonstrate the most severe 
    environmental effects, and that it is therefore impossible to verify 
    the results or analyze the factors contributing to the effects shown.
        The Joint Commenters' assertion is incorrect. Appendix K of the 
    FEIS sets forth tables demonstrating the results of
    
    [[Page 12439]]
    
    the model runs for the sensitivity analysis. These tables provide 
    adequate documentation to analyze and verify the conclusions reached in 
    the FEIS. We note also that the Joint Commenters have not requested 
    specific model outputs that it claims are lacking. The Commission will 
    make available information used in the study that Joint Commenters or 
    anyone else identifies as not being provided.
        As to the claim raised by the PA Com, it appears to be mistaken 
    regarding the base case actually used in the FEIS. Contrary to what the 
    PA Com states, the base cases do include continuing case-by-case 
    actions under section 211 and the Commission's open access policy.
    2. Challenge to the Use of Computer Modeling
        The Commission's intent to use computer modeling in the 
    identification and evaluation of the impacts of the Rule has been clear 
    since the Commission decided to prepare an EIS. The DEIS and FEIS 
    explain the computer modeling techniques used in the analysis in great 
    detail.
        For example, the DEIS and FEIS explain that the Coal and Electric 
    Utilities Model (CEUM) was selected for the analysis because it is the 
    best tested, most widely used national-level model available. 824 
    CEUM is a forecasting model that incorporates virtually all coal and 
    electric utility market activities--ranging from mining, 
    transportation, and blending of coal to power plant and system 
    dispatching, transmission, and new capacity construction. It also 
    examines the impact of changes in factors such as plant availabilities, 
    heat rates, planning reserve margins, and transmission costs. CEUM has 
    been used extensively by, among others, EPA and DOE.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \824\ DEIS at 3-2 through 3-5; FEIS at 3-2 through 3-5.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        CEUM models the contiguous United States as 45 separate demand 
    regions. It possesses a supply component which models key coal supply 
    regions and coal transportation networks in great detail. It also 
    incorporates constraints on long-term coal supplies, power plant 
    emission limitations, national emission caps (e.g., acid rain 
    requirements of Title IV of the Clean Air Act Amendments of 1990), coal 
    transportation capacity, electric transmission capacity, and power 
    plant construction plans.
        The DEIS and FEIS explain that to analyze the Rule, assumptions as 
    to factors such as electricity demand growth rates, oil and gas prices, 
    and planning reserve margins were developed and incorporated into the 
    model. Factors such as existing patterns of transmission capacity and 
    costs were also analyzed and incorporated into the model.
        Once the necessary information and assumptions were incorporated 
    into CEUM, model runs were conducted to ensure that the projections 
    closely match actual experience for a selected year, in this case 1993. 
    These runs used the information prepared for the base cases together 
    with other inputs (e.g., electricity demand) for the historical year. 
    The purpose of this calibration process was to ensure that the model 
    replicates historical experience. After the model was calibrated, it 
    was run for each of the base cases, and then for each of the Rule 
    scenarios for selected time periods.
        To examine the impact of the Rule on regional attainment of ozone 
    standards, additional air quality modeling was conducted using the UAM-
    V. UAM-V is a three-dimensional photochemical grid model that simulates 
    the physical and chemical processes in the atmosphere that affect 
    pollutant concentrations. It tracks emissions both geographically 
    according to preset weather patterns and chemically over time. The UAM-
    V was used to create detailed air quality analyses for cases that might 
    potentially create additional impacts from NOX transport and ozone 
    in the Northeast.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        The PA Com challenges the ability of computer modeling to simulate 
    the effects of the Rule. It states that computer modeling is an attempt 
    to reflect an approximation of reality that uses systems of linear 
    equations, and that the airborne transport of pollutants in the 
    atmosphere and the North American electric transmission grid are 
    extremely large, complex nonlinear systems.825
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \825\ The PUC appears to base its rehearing comments on the 
    DEIS; the points it asserts on rehearing ignore extensive responses 
    to these comments in the FEIS. For example, the FEIS responds to the 
    following specific points that are now raised by the PUC on 
    rehearing: Impact of the rule on Pennsylvania coal production (FEIS 
    at J-22); impact on reliability (FEIS at J-26); impact on stranded 
    benefits (FEIS at J-30); impact of assumed increased volume of 
    transmission transactions (FEIS at J-39); claim that the analysis 
    must consider impact of Group II boiler rule and Phase III of the 
    MOU (FEIS at J-49); claim that FEIS makes conclusory statements 
    (FEIS at J-60); claim that heat rate assumptions are optimistic 
    (FEIS at J-63); claim that transmission usage prices are circular 
    (FEIS at J-65); claim that availabilities are speculative (FEIS at 
    J-67); claim that reserve margins are unlikely to fall as far as the 
    FEIS assumes (FEIS at J-68); concerns about choice of linear 
    modeling (FEIS at J-73); concerns about differing emission standards 
    in Pennsylvania and West Virginia (FEIS at J-92); claim that the 
    Rule is inconsistent with Title I of the Clean Air Act (FEIS at J-
    97).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The PA Com's challenge to the use of computer modeling also turns 
    on the observation that models produce results that are dependent on 
    the inputs and assumptions used in the models. The specific challenges 
    to the inputs and assumptions used in the model are discussed 
    separately below.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        We note first that computer models are the only available means of 
    analysis that incorporate the range of factors that influence 
    engineering and economic choices in the electric power industry, and 
    the atmospheric chemistry and weather patterns that influence 
    downstream air quality. We are mindful of the limitations of models, 
    but the alternative of using no model at all--and hence making no 
    analytic attempt to capture the complex economic and environmental 
    factors--did not appear reasonable.
        The PA Com does not explain how the Commission should otherwise 
    simulate the effects of the Rule. Computer modeling may not be a 
    perfect tool, but it is the best existing mode of analysis for this 
    type of effort. The PA Com cannot merely assert that such modeling is 
    inadequate. As the court noted in a similar context in City of Los 
    Angeles v. National Highway Traffic Safety Administration, 912 F.2d 
    478, 488 (D.C. Cir. 1990), overruled in part on other grounds, Florida 
    Audubon Society v. Bentsen, 94 F.3d 658 (D.C. Cir. 1996):
    
        Petitioners call for more ``analysis,'' but do not specify what 
    they see as lacking or how ``analysis'' could supply the want. At 
    some point--here after a seemingly full treatment--the agency must 
    make a judgment. We discern no more from petitioners' argument than 
    that they disagree with that judgment. Even were we to share their 
    view of the matter, that would not be a sufficient basis for 
    overturning the agency's decision.
    
    Quoting Portland Cement Ass'n v. Ruckelshaus, 486 F.2d 375, 394 (D.C. 
    Cir. 1973), cert. denied sub nom. Portland Cement Ass'n v. 
    Administrator, EPA, 417 U.S. 921, 94 S.Ct. 2628, 41 L.Ed.2d 226 (1974), 
    the court in Northside Sanitary Landfill, Inc. v. Thomas, 849 F.2d 
    1516, 1519 (D.C. Cir. 1988), cert. denied, 489 U.S. 1078 (1989), stated 
    in like manner that:
    
        [C]omments must be significant enough to step over a threshold 
    requirement of materiality before any lack of agency response or 
    consideration becomes of concern. The comment cannot merely state 
    that a particular mistake was made * * *; it must show why the 
    mistake was of possible
    
    [[Page 12440]]
    
    significance in the results [the agency reaches]. (Emphasis in 
    original).
    
        The FEIS explains the Commission's conclusion that the 
    environmental analysis of Order No. 888 is best conducted using the 
    CEUM and UAM-V computer models. The PA Com cannot merely state that the 
    use of such models is inappropriate. It must explain why this is so and 
    what alternative method of analysis should be used. This it has not 
    done. The request for rehearing is denied.
    3. Transmission Assumptions
        The FEIS recognizes the interdependence of interregional electric 
    transmission transactions; accordingly, non-simultaneous interregional 
    transfer capabilities estimated by the North American Electricity 
    Reliability Council (NERC) were reduced for use in the model (see FEIS 
    section 3.4.2). The analysis also considers the impact of the Rule on 
    interregional transfers (see FEIS Tables 5-13 and 5-14), and the impact 
    of changes in transmission capacity through sensitivity 
    analysis.826
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \826\ FEIS at 3-8 through 3-11.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        The PA Com asserts that transmission usage in the FEIS is based on 
    assumptions which are indeterminate to some degree. It states that 
    historical interregional power transfers are used to estimate future 
    transmission capabilities and capacity, and that while historical 
    interregional electric transmission transactions have been large and 
    complex, under the Rule the level of transactions will increase 
    enormously. The PA Com claims that almost every time a new major 
    interregional electric transmission transaction has occurred, there 
    have been unpredictable flows of electricity in other regions that 
    might be a thousand miles away. It concludes that relatively small 
    changes in transmission flows can and have produced large harmonic 
    transients and instabilities on the power grid.
        The PA Com also contends that the relationship between the 
    transmission usage price and the price of transmission service is 
    unclear. It states that the development of the usage price seems 
    circular, at least in part. It notes that model inputs were changed 
    until the usage price coincided with an estimate of historical costs. 
    The PA Com requests clarification of the development of the usage price 
    assumption.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The PA Com does not appear to understand the way the transmission 
    usage price functioned in the analysis.827 As explained in the 
    FEIS, the CEUM model is annual and regional: it models a single year at 
    a time using regions approximately the size of a state or large regions 
    within a state.828 Transmission in the model is represented as 
    movement of power from one region to another. The model attempts to 
    satisfy the demand for electricity at lowest cost--if there were no 
    limitations on the movement of power from one region to another, the 
    model would always generate power at the cheapest source and move that 
    power to meet the demand. This result would clearly be unrealistic, 
    since sources of power are limited in their ability to reach demand by 
    limitations in the intervening transmission network. The transmission 
    network in CEUM is represented primarily by the limitations that the 
    transmission grid places on the ability of power to move freely to meet 
    demand.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \827\ As explained in the FEIS at 3-13 through 3-15 and as 
    discussed below, the movement of power from low cost sources is 
    limited not only by the physical constraints of the transmission 
    system, but also by institutional impediments such as lack of access 
    to needed transmission. As a result, in a model like that used in 
    the EIS, where flows are based on minimizing costs subject to 
    physical constraints, the model will typically overestimate the 
    amount of power flowing from low-cost sources of generation. The 
    Commission chose to address this by developing a ``usage price'' to 
    raise the variable cost to simulate the effect of observed barriers 
    to power flows between regions. The usage price is a proxy for 
    transmission barriers, not an attempt to estimate or model an actual 
    transmission price. The usage price was calibrated to produce actual 
    historical flows of electricity, not costs of transmission. As such 
    it has almost no relationship with actual transmission prices.
        \828\ Id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        To use CEUM to provide a reasonable representation of transmission 
    requires balancing the different ways in which the transmission system 
    imposes limits on the movement of power. Flows on links between regions 
    are limited by three general parameters in the model: losses, variable 
    costs, and constraints on the quantity of capacity or energy that can 
    be transferred. Losses are generally small, and are typically kept 
    fixed from one model run to the next. Simulating transmission limits is 
    largely a matter of balancing variable costs and quantity limits. True 
    variable costs are usually assumed to be small, reflecting the low 
    variable cost of operating the transmission system. Basic quantity 
    limits are usually developed from NERC sources or other studies of the 
    limits imposed by the physical operation of the transmission system.
        However, such limits do not always provide an adequate picture of 
    current patterns of generation and transmission in the electric utility 
    system. Movement of power from low cost sources is limited not only by 
    the physical constraints of the transmission system, but also by 
    institutional impediments such as lack of access to needed 
    transmission. As a result, in a model like CEUM, where flows are based 
    on minimizing costs subject to physical constraints, the amount of 
    power flowing from lost-cost sources of generation is typically 
    overestimated.
        The FEIS explains that there are two primary ways to address this 
    difficulty when calibrating the model to represent historical power 
    flows. One is to impose further limits on the quantity of power 
    transferred within the model. The other is to raise the variable cost 
    to simulate the effect of observed barriers to power flows between 
    regions. The second approach was used by developing a ``usage price'' 
    to raise the variable cost barriers in CEUM and supplement basic 
    quantity limits derived from NERC estimates. This approach was taken 
    because of its nexus to the primary effect of the Rule on transmission 
    activities. The primary effect of the Rule on transmission will be to 
    increase the ability of transmission users to gain access to 
    transmission service and to permit users to develop flexible ways for 
    buyers and sellers to use the transmission system efficiently. The 
    primary effect is thus to remove institutional barriers to the use of 
    the transmission system--in effect to reduce the transaction costs, or 
    usage price, faced by those seeking access to transmission. Thus, the 
    model was calibrated by selecting an initial set of usage prices and 
    adjusting those prices until the model provided an accurate 
    representation of historical generation and transmission patterns.
        Usage prices (in mills per kWh) were developed by running CEUM for 
    a historical period (1993). Starting from initial estimates of usage 
    prices between CEUM regions, the model was run using historical inputs 
    for 1993; the outputs from these runs were compared with the historical 
    pattern of generation and transmission for that year. Usage prices were 
    then adjusted until the pattern projected by the model was consistent 
    with the observed historical pattern. The final adjusted prices were 
    then used as the current usage prices.
        Two rules were used to set the initial usage price estimates:
    
        (1) For closely coordinated (i.e., tight) pools, no separate 
    usage price was assumed. This is consistent with the principle 
    embodied in many pools that transmission
    
    [[Page 12441]]
    
    assets are to be treated as one system and used to minimize variable 
    costs. Any allocation of the cost of service associated with 
    transmission assets is typically treated as a fixed cost.
        (2) Separate transmission costs are commonly applied in loosely 
    configured pools. In many cases, these separate costs are derived on 
    a MW-mile basis. Because the number of systems that have to be 
    traversed within a loosely configured pool is generally small, the 
    transmission usage price for areas with loosely configured pools 
    were set to a small initial value (1 to 2 mills/kWh). Transmission 
    across NERC regions may require traversing many utility systems, and 
    for modeling purposes a charge of about 3 mills/kWh was assumed.
    
        Applying this method required several runs of CEUM. Usage price 
    changes were typically downward in areas where the initial prices were 
    set at 3 mills per kWh, and prices after adjustment remained within the 
    range of the initial usage prices. As a result, estimates of the 
    current usage price varied from region to region after calibration, but 
    generally fell within the range of 1 to 3 mills per kWh.
        Thus, the concerns expressed by the PA Com were either considered 
    in the FEIS, or are based on a misunderstanding of the method used.
    4. Plant Availabilities and Heat Rates
        The FEIS explains that power plant availability is the percentage 
    of time that a generating unit is available to provide electricity to 
    the grid, and that availability estimates for coal plants have an 
    important effect on projected base case emissions because those 
    estimates determine the amount of future generation expected from 
    existing power plants.829
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \829\ Id. at 3-18.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The base cases assume that average fossil-fuel plant availability 
    rises to 85 percent by 2005 and then remains constant through 2010. 
    This assumption reflects continuing efforts by utilities to improve 
    plant availability. Between 1984 and 1993, coal plant availability 
    increased five percent to nearly 81 percent. This trend is projected to 
    continue through 2005 as electric generators respond to competitive 
    pressures and opportunities extant without the Rule.
        The FEIS explains that in the Competition-Favors-Coal Scenario, 
    plant availabilities are assumed to reach 90 percent (as opposed to 85 
    percent in the base cases and other Rule scenarios) because competition 
    is projected to lead to greater operational efficiency in generation 
    markets. It notes that some older coal plants are not likely to reach 
    this level without substantial capital investment. However, since 90 
    percent availability is achievable for many plants, this figure was 
    selected as an upper bound to illustrate how much existing plants may 
    be able to run if generation owners focus on meeting competition 
    through greater use of coal plants.
        The FEIS also explains that the base cases assume some 
    deterioration in heat rates between life extension programs. In the 
    Competition-Favors-Coal Scenario, existing generating plants are 
    assumed to be better maintained so that there is no deterioration of 
    heat rates between life extension programs. Except in the Competition-
    Favors-Gas Scenario, it is assumed that new combined cycle natural gas 
    plants sustain existing heat rates (rather than improving as the next 
    generation of gas technology comes on line). These assumptions reflect 
    the fact that industry has put more effort into making better use of 
    existing (disproportionately coal) plants rather than into improving 
    the performance of new (almost entirely gas) plants.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        The PA Com challenges the plant availability assumptions used in 
    the FEIS. It notes that the analysis assumes that generation plant 
    availability will rise to 85 percent and that the Competition-Favors-
    Coal Scenario assumes that generation plant availability will rise to 
    90 percent by the year 2005. The PA Com states that although historical 
    trends indicate that plant availability might increase, in reality as 
    availability goes up it becomes increasingly difficult to obtain 
    further improvements.
        The PA Com contends that increasing availability to 85 percent 
    would be surprising; an increase to 90 percent would be astonishing. It 
    states that such increases would require a number of simultaneous 
    technical advances, the likelihood of which are speculative. The PA Com 
    argues that utilities in competition with each other may be less 
    willing to fund and participate in cooperative research that leads to 
    technical advances. The PA Com notes that maintenance staffs are being 
    reduced as a result of cost reduction programs and that plant 
    availability might decline as maintenance is deferred.
        The PA Com also contends that the assumption in the Competition-
    Favors-Coal Scenario that heat rates do not degrade (go up) over time 
    may be optimistic. It concedes that technological advances have 
    produced dramatic improvements in heat rates, but states that it is 
    unclear if this improvement is sufficient to overcome losses caused by 
    backfitting emission control equipment. The PA Com notes that coal-
    fired generating stations in Pennsylvania have been required to install 
    emission control equipment and that efficiency has been reduced in some 
    cases, degrading the heat rate. It states that some coal stations have 
    installed sulfur dioxide (SO2) scrubbers which can reduce 
    efficiency by five percent, and that other stations may be required to 
    install selective catalytic reduction systems for NOx or SO2 
    scrubbers.
        The PA Com contends that an additional limit on heat rate 
    improvements is the age of generating stations and the fact that heat 
    rates decline as stations age. It posits that this decline may be 
    greater than the improvements that can be gained through technological 
    advances.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The PA Com's argument fails to consider the discussion of this 
    issue in the FEIS.830 Briefly, higher availabilities for coal 
    plants were assumed in order to provide a scenario that was extremely 
    favorable to the use of coal in existing facilities and hence a 
    scenario that was most likely to have a larger environmental impact. 
    The fact that some coal plants are able to maintain 90 percent 
    availability is sufficient grounds for considering such a case, 
    especially where the purpose of the assumption is to establish a 
    reasonable range of potential environmental outcomes from the Rule.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \830\ Id. at J-63 and J-67.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        With regard to the heat rate assumptions, the PA Com does not 
    appear to understand how the assumptions functioned in the analysis. 
    First, the factors it mentions (e.g., efficiency reductions resulting 
    from the addition of scrubber technology) are already considered in the 
    CEUM model. Second, the CEUM does assume that heat rates degrade over 
    time in the base cases. The assumption that they do not degrade in the 
    Competition-Favors-Coal Scenario was made to simulate the relative 
    improvement that might be achieved through potential effects of the 
    Rule when competition is favorable to coal. As with certain other 
    modeling assumptions challenged by the PA Com on rehearing, the heat 
    rate assumptions used by the Commission are more conservative than 
    those urged by the PA Com and thus demonstrate greater impacts from the 
    Rule than would be the case using the assumptions urged by the PA Com.
    
    [[Page 12442]]
    
    5. Reserve Margins
        The FEIS discusses the assumptions regarding planning reserve 
    margins and their use in the model.831 It states that planning 
    reserve margins influence the amount of new capacity built and the mix 
    of gas versus coal fired generation projected in CEUM. In particular, 
    lower reserve margins tend to result in the construction of less 
    capacity (typically, fewer gas-fired turbines and combined cycle units) 
    and a somewhat greater utilization of existing coal units.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \831\ Id. at 3-16 and 3-17. Table 3-4 is found on page 3-17.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Generally, individual utilities set their reserve margins to comply 
    with a technical standard established by the NERC sub-region. 
    Typically, the NERC sub-region might determine that a one day in 10 
    years loss of load probability (LOLP) is the appropriate standard. 
    Individual utilities within the sub-region would determine their 
    reserve planning margin to be consistent with this standard after 
    accounting for tie capabilities. NERC sub-regional studies are 
    performed periodically to determine whether the reliability standard is 
    being satisfied for the planning horizon given planned capacity 
    additions. The tie capability between the sub-region and other regions 
    is accounted for in reliability studies at the NERC sub-regional level.
        The FEIS notes that in recent years, reserve margins typically have 
    been revised downwards, although the planning standard itself (most 
    commonly the one day in 10 years LOLP) has not been changed. Three 
    reasons support the downward revision in reserve margins: (1) An 
    expected improvement in unit availability; (2) anticipated shifts in 
    utility load shape towards a lower load factor; and (3) an increase in 
    the number of generating units.
        FEIS Table 3-4 summarizes the reserve criteria and associated 
    planning reserve margins that have been derived from the most recent 
    annual planning documents prepared by the reliability councils. It 
    states that a review of current planning documents shows that utilities 
    expect planning reserve margins to decline over time. One factor 
    identified as contributing to this decline is the expectation that 
    availability will improve appreciably as utilities are subject to 
    performance-based regulation and experience greater competition.
        Additionally, some utilities have revised their planning reserve 
    margins to account for ties in other regions. In some cases, utilities 
    have updated their planning reserve margin calculation to reflect 
    current estimates of customer willingness to pay for increase 
    reliability.
        Based upon a review of utility expectations, the FEIS concludes 
    that an appropriate base case assumption is for planning reserve 
    margins to decline by 2005 to the lower end of the applicable ranges 
    set forth in FEIS Table 3-4.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        The PA Com challenges the reserve margin assumptions used in the 
    model. It asserts that the assumption that reserve margins will fall to 
    fifteen percent by 2000 and (in one scenario) to thirteen percent by 
    2005 is based in part upon the assumption of increased generation plant 
    availability across the board. The PA Com notes that this increase in 
    availability might not occur. It states that as wholesale transactions 
    increase under open access, some, but not most, utilities will be able 
    to reduce reserve margins and still maintain reliability. The PA Com 
    asserts that many utilities cannot reduce reserve margins because 
    available transmission capacity between regions is already being 
    utilized to the maximum extent possible. It concludes that reserve 
    margins for certain individual utilities could decline, but this alone 
    would not reduce required reserve margins for all utilities to the 
    levels that are assumed in the model.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The reserve margins used in the base cases were set using current 
    utility plans and trends in the industry. Reserve margins for the 
    competition scenarios were set slightly lower, reflecting the potential 
    for decline in a more open competitive environment. The PA Com 
    acknowledges the potential decline, but claims that not all utilities 
    will be able to reduce reserve margins to the levels assumed. However, 
    the FEIS addresses such differences by using different regional 
    assumptions about reserve margins and different reserve margins in each 
    region. The PA Com's concern is therefore without basis.
    6. Northeast MOU
        The FEIS assumes that power plants in the Northeast Ozone Transport 
    Region (OTR) will comply with Phase II of the Northeast Memorandum of 
    Understanding (MOU). The MOU establishes NOX tonnage limits during 
    the five-month ozone season (May-September) for electric generating and 
    large industrial services and allows for emissions trading.832 The 
    FEIS states that compliance with Phase III of the MOU was not assumed 
    since its implementation is optional, depending on final attainment 
    status with regard to Clean Air Act requirements.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \832\ Id. at 3-25.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        The PA Com states that the base cases and scenarios assume that no 
    NOX controls will be required for Title IV group II boilers, that 
    phase II of the MOU will be implemented, and that no additional 
    requirements will be imposed. The PA Com contends that phase III of the 
    MOU might be implemented, and that if this occurs and upwind generation 
    is not required to control ozone precursors, cleaner generation in the 
    Northeast may be displaced by increased generation from outside the 
    OTR.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        In essence, the PA Com appears to be raising an emissions disparity 
    argument rather than posing a challenge to the modeling assumptions 
    used in the FEIS. The emissions disparity argument is addressed below.
    7. Natural Gas Prices
        Average wellhead natural gas prices for the High-Price-Differential 
    Base Case were based on a recent forecast of natural gas acquisition 
    prices by Wharton Econometric Forecasting Associates (WEFA).833 
    This forecast projected at that time that natural gas prices would 
    increase in real terms (1994 dollars) to $1.83 per MMBtu by 2000, and 
    rise to $2.42 per MMBtu by 2010. The forecast was selected as 
    representative of a number of natural gas price forecasts that were 
    made during that time.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \833\ Id. at 3-5 through 3-8.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        CEUM requires delivered, not wellhead or acquisition, prices as an 
    input. Delivered natural gas prices for each Census region were derived 
    from the weighted average transportation mark-ups reported by the 
    Energy Information Administration (EIA) in Natural Gas Monthly for each 
    Census region. The Natural Gas Monthly provides a consistent historical 
    series of wellhead and delivered prices for calculating historical 
    transportation margins. These margins were assumed to remain constant 
    throughout the forecast period.
        In the Constant-Price-Differential Base Case, delivered gas prices 
    were assumed to equal current delivered spot prices in each region. To 
    maintain a constant gas price relative to coal, these prices were 
    assumed to decline from current levels
    
    [[Page 12443]]
    
    at the same rate as coal prices decline in CEUM.834
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \834\ Id. at 3-7 through 3-8.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        The Joint Commenters assert that the fuel-price assumptions used in 
    the model unduly favor the use of natural gas as a fuel and appear to 
    understate adverse effects.
        In particular, the Joint Commenters claim that the two alternative 
    fuel-price cases use the same coal price assumptions. It states that 
    the Competition-Favors-Coal Scenario is supposed to demonstrate the 
    effects of economic assumptions that favor coal, but that this case 
    actually uses price assumptions that reflect the lowest natural gas 
    price of the projections cited in the FEIS. It states that the FEIS 
    should have used projections less favorable to natural gas: for 
    example, $2.51 per MMBtu in 2000 (Gas Research Institute) and $3.37 per 
    MMBtu in 2010 (Energy Information Administration). Put differently, a 
    more appropriate Competition-Favors-Coal Scenario would have used the 
    projected highest reasonable natural gas prices relied on in the FEIS.
        The Joint Commenters then claim that the Constant-Price-
    Differential Base Case is based on gas price assumptions that are far 
    below the projected prices cited in the FEIS.835 According to the 
    Joint Commenters, this case assumes natural gas prices of $1.67 per 
    MMBtu in 2000 and $1.57 per MMBtu in 2010. It asserts that these 
    estimates are approximately 10 and 54 percent lower in years 2005 and 
    2010, respectively, than the lowest forecasts cited. A more appropriate 
    Competition-Favors-Gas Scenario would have used the WEFA forecasts that 
    contain the lowest reasonable projected gas prices.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \835\ The Joint Commenters claims as to the Constant-Price-
    Differential Base Case are probably meant as a reference to the 
    Competition-Favors-Gas Scenario.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The claim that the assumptions unduly favor natural gas prices is 
    incorrect. First, the assumption that lower gas prices will reflect 
    favorably the environmental effects of the Rule is not valid. The 
    impact of the Rule when gas prices are constant relative to coal is 
    very close to the impact when gas prices are high relative to 
    coal.836 For example, the impact on total NOX emissions in 
    2005 is higher when gas prices are constant relative to coal than when 
    gas prices are high relative to coal (88,000 tons for the Constant-
    Price-Differential Base Case versus 55,000 tons for the High-Price-
    Differential Base Case).837
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \836\ FEIS Chapter 6.
        \837\ Id. at Table 6-19 (page 6-23) and Table 5-18 (page 5-16), 
    respectively.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Second, the two price series were selected to give a range of 
    variation in emissions that reflect differences in the price of gas 
    relative to coal, rather than to project a ``correct'' natural gas 
    price. As discussed in the FEIS, the Constant-Price-Differential Base 
    Case reflects a continuation of the historical relationship between gas 
    and coal prices over the past 10 years. Appendix G shows how forecasts 
    over this period have consistently overestimated the price of gas 
    relative to coal. It is therefore reasonable to consider the Constant-
    Price-Differential Base Case as one side of a reasonable range.
        The prices selected for the other side of the reasonable range of 
    gas prices relative to coal (the High-Price-Differential Base Case) 
    were based on current forecasts at the time of the analysis. There were 
    two primary reasons for selecting a lower gas price from the range of 
    existing forecasts. First, the CEUM coal price forecast is determined 
    within the model and could not be changed as an input. This coal price 
    forecast was lower than the coal prices assumed in other forecasts. By 
    picking a gas price forecast at the lower end of the range of current 
    forecasts, and combining this forecast with the lower coal prices 
    forecasts in CEUM, the analysis assumed a typical price of natural gas 
    relative to coal.
        Second, at the time the analysis was conducted, all major 
    forecasting organizations stated that they expected their gas price 
    forecasts to be lower. However, these organizations did not complete 
    their forecasts for several months. Since the available forecasts were 
    up to a year old, there was reason to believe the forecasts overstated 
    the current thinking among forecasters regarding future natural gas 
    prices. This reason was confirmed by the forecasts that appeared around 
    the time the analysis was completed. For example, the forecast for the 
    wellhead price of natural gas in the year 2010 from the EIA published 
    in January 1996 was $2.10 per million Btu, 15 percent below the 
    forecast of $2.42 assumed for the High-Price-Differential Base Case in 
    the FEIS.
    8. Expanded Transmission Analysis
        Several commenters on the DEIS expressed concern that increases in 
    transmission capacity resulting from open access might increase 
    generation levels and thus air pollution. In response, the FEIS 
    examined scenarios that increased transmission capacity substantially 
    beyond current levels--including increases that the Commission believed 
    would far exceed any transmission capacity increases that might occur 
    as a result of the Rule. This analysis found that postulated increases 
    in transmission do not affect emissions attributable to the Rule. The 
    Commission also found that issues regarding enhancement of existing 
    lines are more complex, and that this is due in part to the fact that 
    state-level siting issues, the principal barrier to major increases in 
    the transmission grid, are unaffected by the Rule. While competition 
    will lead to improved efficiencies in generation, transmission will 
    remain a regulated monopoly function. The Rule will reduce barriers to 
    access, but will not open the transmission system to direct 
    competition. Thus, the Commission concluded that the competitive 
    effects of the Rule on transmission will be relatively small.838
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \838\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,872 n.974; mimeo at 691-92 
    n.974.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        The Joint Commenters claim that the expanded transmission analysis 
    is unduly conservative. It states that the Commission increased peak 
    transmission usage from 75 percent of first contingency total transfer 
    capability (FCTTC) to 105 percent of FCTTC, and that this expanded 
    transmission analysis represent minimal actual expansions, the most 
    extreme of which barely increases FCTTC above current levels by the 
    year 2010. The Joint Commenters claim that the Commission should have 
    examined additional expansion potential in those analyses that more 
    accurately demonstrate the effects of transmission expansion.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Joint Commenters' claim that the expanded transmission analysis 
    is inadequate is based on the premise that the FEIS used the wrong 
    assumptions in developing transmission capacity. Joint Commenters 
    contend that 100 percent of the FCTTC should have been used in CEUM. We 
    believe that the use of 75 percent of this capacity to reflect annual 
    capability is the appropriate level for modeling purposes. This 
    reduction factor is necessary because the capability must be 
    simultaneous systemwide capability and it must be sustainable. The 
    FCTTC is a non-simultaneous ``snapshot'' transmission capability. The 
    total simultaneous transfer capability is not accurately represented by 
    adding together the
    
    [[Page 12444]]
    
    maximum transfer capability of each line in the system. The 
    transmission system is a system. Loading on one line affects loading 
    capability on all other lines in the system. This is especially true if 
    the calculation is for capability over an extended period of time, as 
    is the case with the FEIS, which uses transfer capability over one 
    year. ``Derating'' as it has been called, is a reasonable way to 
    represent the fact that a transmission system is capable of carrying 
    less than the sum of the capabilities of the individual lines. Further, 
    when modeling, if the model is calibrated so that the system is 
    carrying actual historical flows--no matter what factor is used--the 
    system will be carrying at or near its maximum capacity at constrained 
    points which are the only points on the system where increased capacity 
    would produce increased flows. As a result, increasing the transfer 
    capability factor by up to 40 percent, as is done in the sensitivity 
    analyses in Chapter 6 of the FEIS, represents a large change in the 
    capability and use of the transmission system. Moreover, we note that 
    this methodology has been used in previous CEUM analysis, where it was 
    subject to review by electric utility experts.839 For these 
    reasons, the Joint Commenters' criticisms are invalid.840
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \839\ Edison Electric Institute, Assessment of Greenhouse Gas 
    Emissions Policies on the Electric Utility Industry: Costs, Impacts 
    and Opportunities, prepared by ICF Resources, January 1992.
        \840\ See also FEIS Sections 3.4.2.1 and J.7.1.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Joint Commenters challenge the assumptions used in the 
    Commission's expanded transmission analysis as ``unduly conservative'' 
    and ``represent[ing] minimal actual expansions.'' Joint Commenters fail 
    to explain in what respect they deem the expanded transmission analysis 
    to be inadequate. They fail even to respond to the matters discussed by 
    the Commission with regard to this issue in Order No. 888.
        As we noted above in the discussion of the PA Com's argument that 
    the Commission failed adequately to consider the alternative of 
    instituting open access pursuant to section 211 of the FPA, it is 
    insufficient for a party to complain that an analysis is inadequate 
    without providing specifics.
    
    C. Mitigation
    
        The FEIS and Order No. 888 extensively assess the need for 
    mitigation and discuss potential mitigation measures, including 
    proposals advanced by commenters.841 This discussion is perhaps 
    best summarized by the conclusion to Chapter 7 of the FEIS, which 
    states that:
    
        \841\ The EIS and Order No. 888 examine the specific mitigation 
    proposals advanced by the Center for Clean Air Policy, the EPA, the 
    Joint Commenters, the Project for Sustainable FERC Energy Policy, 
    and the Department of Energy. FEIS at 7-28 through 7-43; FERC Stats. 
    & Regs. at 31,877-82; mimeo at 705-17. The Commission concluded that 
    the mitigation measures urged by the commenters are unwarranted, and 
    that mitigation of the Rule is not required. Of the commenters 
    advancing specific mitigation proposals in comments on the draft 
    EIS, only the Joint Commenters seek rehearing of Order No. 888 on 
    environmental issues. The Joint Commenters do not take issue on 
    rehearing with the Commission's rejection of its mitigation 
    proposal, but rather mounts a broad attack in which it asserts that 
    the Commission has failed to properly consider and disclose the 
    potential environmental effects of the Rule, and that the 
    Commission's decision that it lacks authority to implement 
    mitigation is contrary to law.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        This FEIS shows that the proposed rule is expected to slightly 
    increase or slightly decrease total future NOX emissions, 
    depending on whether competitive conditions in the electric industry 
    favor natural gas or coal. The insistence of commenters that the 
    Commission adopt and implement mitigation measures is based on 
    significantly overstated assumptions regarding the contribution of 
    the proposed rule to the existing environmental problems. The 
    analysis presented in Chapter 6 establishes that overstated 
    assumptions about the impact of the proposed rule are simply wrong.
        Nonetheless, in light of the importance of this issue, we have 
    examined potential mitigation measures in detail, including those 
    proposed by commenters, to ensure that environmental consequences of 
    the rule have been fully and fairly evaluated. We do not believe 
    mitigation should be undertaken in this rule because:
        Any mitigation measures the Commission might undertake are not 
    justified by the small impacts of the rule, which impacts are as 
    likely to be beneficial as they are to be harmful;
        The impacts of the proposed rule are dwarfed by the far larger 
    ozone and NOX emission issues that either have nothing to do 
    with the electric industry or will be unchanged by the rule or the 
    larger open access program. We believe that it would be ineffective 
    to address the NOX and ozone issues in a piecemeal way;
        The NOX issue is part of a long-standing, difficult set of 
    inter-regional environmental issues. Representatives of many 
    interests in both the Northeast and the Midwest have invested 
    substantial efforts towards finding acceptable solutions through the 
    OTAG process. Any mitigation the Commission might undertake could 
    usurp EPA's mandate under the Clean Air Act and undermine progress 
    towards comprehensive solutions sought by OTAG. This is not 
    justified by impacts that are small and just as likely to be 
    positive.
        We do not agree that the frozen efficiency reference case should 
    be substituted for the EIS base cases or that competitive forces 
    will favor coal over the next 15 years. But even accepting those 
    assumptions, emissions attributable to the rule are relatively small 
    until well after the turn of the century. So, even accepting such 
    assumptions, the staff believes it would be unreasonable for the 
    Commission to adopt mitigation requirements as part of the final 
    rule; to do so would be tantamount to assuming that EPA and OTAG 
    will not implement reasonable control measures in the next ten to 15 
    years;
        The Federal Power Act and NEPA, either singly or conjointly, do 
    not authorize the Commission to adopt and implement the proposed 
    mitigation measures. The Commission does not possess (and has no 
    mandate to possess) expertise on the extremely difficult issues 
    involved in atmospheric chemistry and transport. It is fundamentally 
    a economic regulatory agency. As a result, any mitigation measures 
    the Commission undertook would be based on less-than-ideal 
    information and analysis. It is unreasonable for the Commission to 
    attempt such mitigation given the impacts found in this FEIS. This 
    is especially true in light of the substantial additional research 
    that EPA and OTAG are undertaking on the basic nature of the 
    problem;
        Some suggested mitigation measures that might work at the 
    transaction level would undermine the purpose of the rule. There is 
    no justification for endangering the substantial benefits projected 
    from the rule to mitigate a problem that might not exist and that 
    is, in any case, likely to be small.[842]
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \842\ FEIS at 7-47 and 7-48.
    
        The FEIS goes on to note that the long-term existence of a 
    significant ozone nonattainment problem in parts of the country has led 
    to the development of mechanisms to address this issue. It states that 
    any incremental increases in NOX emissions that may result from 
    the Rule can be addressed within this existing framework. In 
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    particular:
    
        The Clean Air Act authorizes EPA to establish transport regions 
    that are charged with assessing the degree of interstate transport 
    of pollutants, assessing mitigation strategies, and recommending 
    revisions to State Implementation Plans to correct the problem. The 
    Clean Air Act specifically establishes an ozone transport region for 
    the Northeast. The jurisdictions that comprise the OTR have 
    developed a coordinated approach to this problem that includes 
    adopting a regional cap on NOX emissions.
        Although the OTR process is achieving its purpose, the problem 
    is larger than the OTR can address. As a consequence, the Ozone 
    Transport Assessment Group has been formed which encompasses the OTR 
    and upwind states that contribute to nonattainment. OTAG is 
    performing extensive photochemical grid modeling of the eastern U.S. 
    to determine ozone transport patterns and to evaluate the efficiency 
    of various control strategies. OTAG is considering imposing a cap 
    and trade system for NOX emissions in a 37-state area comprised 
    of the Northeast OTR and upwind states. If the cap and trading 
    system becomes
    
    [[Page 12445]]
    
    effective it should fully mitigate NOX emission increases, if 
    any, attributable to open access transmission within the 37-state 
    area. A cap and trade program is also likely to mitigate CO2 
    and mercury emissions.
        We believe that the cap and trading system under consideration 
    in the OTAG process is the preferred approach to the overall 
    NOX emissions problem. The OTAG process brings to the table the 
    parties that must participate in making the difficult decisions to 
    fully resolve this problem. The OTAG process possesses the technical 
    resources and expertise to address the difficult scientific and 
    technical issues that must be resolved to remedy this problem. More 
    limited approaches cannot render a satisfactory solution. We respect 
    the expertise and the goals of the OTAG process and do not believe 
    we can or should substitute for them in addressing this long-term 
    national problem.[843]
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \843\ Id. at 7-49.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Pennsylvania PUC. The PA Com claims that the Commission has 
    inappropriately declined to assume any responsibility for mitigating 
    environmental impacts associated with the Rule. It states that the 
    Commission has authority to take mitigation measures related to its 
    regulatory actions and that the Commission can reasonably add 
    environmental impacts to the list of factors to be weighed under the 
    FPA's public interest standard. In this regard, it contends that the 
    FPA grants FERC authority to place conditions on the regulation of 
    rates and conditions of wholesale power sales and the interstate 
    transmission of electric power as well as to order wholesale wheeling 
    under certain circumstances.
        The PA Com states that the Commission should act to minimize the 
    likelihood of significant additional NOX emissions by developing a 
    mitigation plan to be implemented in conjunction with the Rule, and 
    that FERC should use the results of the OTAG process to provide 
    information to develop this strategy. The PA Com concludes that FERC 
    should not require open access generically.
        Vermont Department of Public Service. The Vermont Department of 
    Public Service (VT DPS) contends that the Commission erred in failing 
    to establish a monitoring program and a periodic reopener provision to 
    address environmental considerations. VT DPS submits that the 
    Commission has given inadequate consideration to the possibility that 
    the Rule may unnecessarily exacerbate environmental impacts. It notes 
    EPA's claim in its referral letter to the Council on Environmental 
    Quality (CEQ) that any future NOX increases resulting from open 
    access would exacerbate the difficulty of accomplishing reductions in 
    NOX emissions.
        VT DPS claims that the environmental review process has not 
    facilitated the ability of affected parties to review all modeling 
    assumptions. It also claims that other environmental reviews suggests 
    more serious NOX emission consequences of the Rule than 
    acknowledged by the Commission.
        VT DPS states that given the possibility that the FEIS conclusions 
    may prove wrong, the Commission should take steps to permit timely 
    reevaluation of its program. VT DPS recommends that the Commission 
    establish an ongoing monitoring program to determine if the Rule poses 
    an unacceptable risk to air quality. It states that a monitoring 
    program would allow the Commission to take timely action to mitigate 
    any unintended consequences of the Rule. The Commission should also 
    provide for periodic reevaluation of the Rule's open access provisions 
    and should commit to a comprehensive reevaluation of the Rule's 
    environmental impacts every five years over the next 20 years.
        New York Attorney General. The New York Attorney General (Attorney 
    General) states that the federal government should ensure that New York 
    and other Northeast states do not bear the burden of any increased air 
    pollution resulting from deregulation.844
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \844\ The New York Attorney General wrote to the Commission on 
    May 13, 1996 expressing concern about the potential environmental 
    effects of the Rule. Its filing does not appear to constitute a 
    request for rehearing, but it is treated here as such.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Attorney General asserts that utilities in upwind states have a 
    competitive advantage relative to Northeast utilities because they are 
    subject to less extensive environmental controls. The Attorney General 
    contends that deregulation may result in these plants increasing 
    generation, thus increasing emissions that will contribute to the 
    inability of New York and the Northeast to meet the federal ozone 
    standard. The Attorney General claims that, regardless of the effects 
    of the Rule, studies show that a 50 percent reduction in NOX 
    emissions from all sources east of the Mississippi will be necessary 
    for New York and other Northeast states to achieve the ozone standard.
        The Attorney General states that Congress has placed limits on 
    EPA's authority to protect New York from upwind emissions, and that it 
    is therefore essential that FERC exercise any authority it may have to 
    mitigate the environmental effects of the Rule.
        The Attorney General claims that EPA's proposal in its February 20, 
    1996 comments to place a cap on NOX emissions would mitigate the 
    effects of the Rule; it suggests basing this system on the MOU pursuant 
    to authority residing in EPA and/or FERC. Under this proposal, a 
    utility would be permitted to take advantage of deregulation if it 
    simultaneously takes steps to prevent emission increases.
        Joint Commenters--Overview. The Joint Commenters state that FERC 
    has failed to consider and disclose the potential environmental effects 
    of the Rule, and that FERC's decision that it lacks authority to 
    implement mitigation is contrary to law.
        The Joint Commenters' premise is that, despite deficiencies in the 
    Commission's analysis which understate the effects of the Rule, the 
    FEIS nonetheless presents data confirming that open access will have 
    significant adverse environmental impacts. Joint Commenters posit that 
    increased emissions from open access could seriously threaten 
    achievement of Clean Air Act requirements and other environmental 
    commitments. It reasons that the Commission therefore must develop and 
    implement environmental mitigation.
        The Joint Commenters begin with the assertion that the data 
    presented in the FEIS do not support the conclusion that the effect of 
    the Rule on air pollution will be insignificant. It claims that the 
    Commission relied on cases that show small impacts. Joint Commenters 
    note in this regard that EPA has determined that any increase in 
    NOX emissions from restructuring is unacceptable and should be 
    remedied.
        Joint Commenters then assert that FPA sections 205 and 206 require 
    the Commission to adopt mitigation. It claims that case law supports 
    the proposition that both NEPA and the FPA authorize FERC to mitigate 
    the adverse environmental impacts arising from its action. Even 
    assuming arguendo that it was reasonable for the Commission to reject 
    specific proposed mitigation measures, it is unreasonable the deny the 
    existence of authority to mitigate. The Commission should remedy this 
    by adopting mitigation concurrent with implementation of Order No. 888.
        According to Joint Commenters, the FEIS establishes that 
    competitive electric markets will likely result in higher utilization 
    of heavily polluting coal-fired generation. Thus, in view of EPA's 
    statement in its referral to CEQ that any increase in NOX 
    emissions could seriously undermine attainment of health based 
    standards, the FEIS
    
    [[Page 12446]]
    
    finding that emission increases that may be as large as 315,000 tons 
    per year are insignificant is not supported by the record.
        Joint Commenters then argue that not only does the decision not to 
    implement mitigation measures risk nonattainment of public health 
    goals, it will fail to achieve the regulatory objective of fair and 
    efficient bulk power competition. It contends that without concurrent 
    environmental mitigation, the Commission will put in place a market 
    structure that is inherently discriminatory and that arbitrarily shifts 
    costs. It states that Order No. 888, in effect, provides a class of 
    competitors with an undue preference subsidy. This undue preference 
    results from the fact that the owners of coal-fired generation that are 
    not subject to emissions regulation will be able to shift financial 
    responsibility for their pollution to competitors in downwind regions. 
    This discriminatory situation will distort the bulk power market and 
    produce inefficiencies that the Commission has not addressed.845
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \845\ This aspect of the Joint Commenters' argument is addressed 
    below.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Open Access Will Have Significant Adverse Impacts. The Joint 
    Commenters state that some FEIS scenarios show that restructuring is 
    likely to have significant adverse environmental effects. It claims 
    that the sensitivity analyses confirm that low-cost, high-emission coal 
    plants may increase their capacity utilization from an average of 62 
    percent in 1993 to 81.5 percent by 2010 and that this increase is 
    associated with an additional 515 billion kWh of coal generation per 
    year by 2010 above 1993 levels, assuming expanding transmission. FEIS 
    data further indicate that 110 billion kWh of this annual increase by 
    the year 2010 will be attributable to competition under the open access 
    policy compared to the frozen efficiency case.
        The Joint Commenters assert that the FEIS also confirms that this 
    increase in coal-based generation will increase NOX emissions 
    across the 37-state OTAG region by 250,000 tons per year by 2010 
    (315,000 tons for the entire U.S.) and result in a cumulative NOX 
    emissions increase across the U.S. of 530,000 tons by 2000 and 2.7 
    million tons by 2010.
        The Joint Commenters assert that the impacts of a 250,000 ton 
    NOX increase across the OTAG region are extremely significant, 
    particularly in downwind nonattainment areas, and fly in the face of 
    EPA's determination that any increase is unacceptable.
        The Joint Commenters contend that the Commission understates the 
    significance of these numbers by emphasizing percentages and using 
    national figures. According to Joint Commenters, the FEIS demonstrates 
    that regional increases in NOX include a seven percent increase in 
    the East North Central region, 10 percent in the Mountain region and 26 
    percent in the Pacific regions. These references are to emissions in 
    2005. The percentages in the year 2010 are approximately five percent 
    nationally, rather than the three percent discussed in Order No. 888.
        The Joint Commenters state that the FEIS also shows that increased 
    utilization of coal plants could significantly add to utility carbon 
    dioxide (CO2) emissions, which would conflict with the Clinton 
    Administration's commitment to stabilize greenhouse gas emissions at 
    1990 levels by the year 2000. It states that the Competition-Favors-
    Coal Scenario projects that annual utility CO2 emissions will 
    increase by 285 million tons by 2000 and by 737 million tons by 2010; 
    and that the FEIS attributes about 10 percent of the increase to the 
    Rule. It argues that this increase will threaten international 
    commitments of the U.S. Government. The Joint Commenters assert that 
    utility CO2 emissions are not currently on track to fulfill 
    national and international climate protection objectives and open 
    access competition, to the extent it favors existing coal plants, will 
    exacerbate these trends.
        The Joint Commenters then claim that in addition to the emissions 
    impacts that are identified in the FEIS, EPA's technical analysis 
    indicates that the Rule has the potential to cause much larger impacts 
    than the FEIS estimates for the Competition-Favors-Coal Scenario. EPA's 
    evaluation, which Joint Commenters claim does not incorporate worst 
    case scenario assumptions, indicates that the potential increases in 
    NOX emissions from open access could be more than twice the 
    increases projected in the FEIS Competition-Favors-Coal Scenario in 
    years 2000, 2005 and 2010. The potential that FERC's highest polluting 
    case understates emissions increases to this extent illustrates the 
    uncertainty surrounding the impacts of open access, particularly the 
    uncertainties surrounding the accuracy of the Commission's estimates, 
    and the critical importance of developing mitigation programs.
        Authority to Mitigate. The Joint Commenters assert that the 
    Commission's rejection of authority to mitigate environmental impacts 
    is contrary to law and arbitrary and capricious. It states that the 
    Commission's rejection is inconsistent with Commission claims about its 
    sections 205 and 206 authority, and that both NEPA and the FPA permit 
    FERC to mitigate adverse environmental impacts. Thus, while it may be 
    reasonable for the Commission to reject specific mitigation measures, 
    the Commission's decision that it lacks authority to implement 
    mitigation constitutes an arbitrary and capricious exercise of agency 
    authority.
        The Joint Commenters argue that NEPA authorizes agencies to 
    consider and address environmental impacts so long as any actions 
    undertaken do not conflict with the agency's authorizing statute. It 
    states that a number of cases support the proposition that FERC's FPA 
    authority is broadened by NEPA--that NEPA policies and goals inform and 
    expand the FPA's definition of public interest. In effect, NEPA 
    establishes a legal nexus between the Commission's primary regulatory 
    duties and environmental protection. Thus, courts have upheld agency 
    mitigation actions under NEPA even when the agencies have no explicit 
    environmental protection mandate. The Joint Commenters assert that the 
    Commission did not address these cases in concluding that it lacks 
    authority to mitigate adverse environmental impacts under sections 205 
    and 206 and the FPA's general public interest standard.
        The Joint Commenters assert that if NEPA is to be given practical 
    effect, agencies must have authority to do more than study the 
    potential environmental impacts of proposed actions. To interpret and 
    administer federal laws in accordance with NEPA policies, agencies must 
    have the authority to use their statutory powers in ways that implement 
    NEPA policies. The arena of permissible environmental action is 
    constrained only by the limits of the agency's jurisdictional authority 
    under its enabling statutes. Thus, the only limits on FERC's ability to 
    implement environmental mitigation are those defined by the FPA. 
    Therefore, the question is whether mitigation falls within the 
    regulatory powers of FERC.
        The Joint Commenters argue that the FPA authorizes the Commission 
    to mitigate the environmental effects of its actions, stating that the 
    public interest standard of FPA section 201 encompasses the 
    environmental and other competitive concerns discussed in its request 
    for rehearing. The Joint Commenters state that NAACP v. FPC, 425 U.S. 
    662 (1976) and similar cases establish that FERC has jurisdiction to 
    address environmental concerns since such concerns are directly related 
    to FERC's regulation of economic interests in the electric industry.
        The Joint Commenters assert that FERC's duty to ensure just and
    
    [[Page 12447]]
    
    reasonable rates that are not unduly discriminatory or preferential 
    also encompasses non-economic factors in appropriate circumstances. It 
    argues that the Commission's reliance on Office of Consumers' Counsel 
    v. FERC, 655 F.2d 1132 (D.C. Cir. 1980), to support its narrow reading 
    of the FPA's public interest standard is misplaced.
        The Joint Commenters then take issue with the position that the 
    Commission lacks authority to implement mitigation because it has 
    insufficient expertise in air pollution control and because Congress 
    gave EPA authority to address such issues. It states that the record 
    does not support a conclusion that FERC lacks the expertise necessary 
    to provide for mitigation of the Rule's impacts. Moreover, nothing 
    would prevent the Commission from acting in concert with EPA to take 
    advantage of EPA's expertise.
        The Joint Commenters state that, unlike the situation in Office of 
    Consumers' Counsel, Congress has given FERC, along with EPA and other 
    federal agencies, the responsibility to address the environmental 
    effects of its actions. In this case, Joint Commenters are asking the 
    Commission to mitigate the environmental impacts of its Rule, not to 
    assert jurisdiction proactively over air pollution matters or to usurp 
    EPA's role. Under Order No. 888's logic, no federal agency would have 
    authority to mitigate the environmental impacts of its proposed actions 
    because EPA is the primary agency with environmental expertise and 
    responsibility.
        The Joint Commenters then argue that the Commission's jurisdiction 
    to consider environmental issues also derives from a traditional 
    analysis of FERC's jurisdiction over wholesale power rates. It states 
    that if the Commission does not allocate environmental responsibility 
    to high-emission utilities, environmental compliance costs will be 
    transferred to downwind utilities and their customers. These utilities 
    will be required to incur costs to reduce emissions and must increase 
    rates to recapture these costs. Thus, Order No. 888 will directly 
    affect the costs that are included in electric rates, which the 
    Commission has authority to review under sections 205 and 206.
        The Joint Commenters conclude their discussion by noting that, 
    while it may have been reasonable for the Commission to reject specific 
    mitigation proposals, the Commission should reexamine the position that 
    it has no authority in this area and instead acknowledge that the 
    exercise of that authority is not warranted here given the conclusions 
    in the FEIS. The Joint Commenters go on to note that EPA proposed in 
    its referral to CEQ a mitigation approach that seeks the Commission's 
    commitment to future actions and outlines immediate actions EPA will 
    take to address the potential NOX emission increases identified in 
    the FEIS. The Joint Commenters state that although it believes EPA's 
    proposal is reasonable and strongly support the tracking system 
    recommended, the Commission should develop a backup NOX mitigation 
    mechanism by the end of 1996 to assure that Order No. 888 will be 
    implemented without adverse environmental impacts.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Need for Mitigation. The FEIS examines fully claims that the Rule 
    will have significant environmental impacts requiring mitigation. As 
    stated in Order No. 888:
    
        First, the findings show that, without the rule, NOX 
    emissions are expected to decline until at least the year 2000. 
    Thereafter, again without the rule, NOX emissions are expected 
    to increase steadily through the year 2010 (the end of the FEIS 
    study period). The extent of the decrease and the increase will be 
    largely determined by the relative prices of natural gas and coal, 
    the two main fuels used to generate electric power in most regions.
        In reaching this conclusion, the FEIS used two ``base'' cases. 
    In one (the ``High-Price-Differential Base Case''), natural gas was 
    assumed to become substantially more expensive compared with coal 
    than it is today. In the other (the ``Constant-Price-Differential 
    Base Case''), natural gas was assumed to maintain essentially the 
    same price relative to coal that has existed for the last ten years. 
    The two cases describe the range of emissions due to fuel price 
    uncertainty without the rule and demonstrate the overall trends of 
    decreases until 2000 and increases thereafter.
        Second, the FEIS finds that the rule will not in any significant 
    respect affect these overall trends.
        The potential impact of the rule was studied initially under two 
    scenarios. In one (the ``Competition-Favors-Gas Scenario''), the 
    rule is assumed to result in efficiency gains in the electric 
    industry that would tend to favor natural gas as a fuel. In this 
    scenario the effect of the rule is slightly beneficial. Total 
    NOX emissions are reduced overall by about two percent 
    nationwide from the base cases. In the other (the ``Competition-
    Favors-Coal Scenario''), the rule is assumed to result in efficiency 
    gains in the electric industry that would tend to favor coal as a 
    fuel. In this scenario the effect is again slight, showing 
    approximately a one percent increase in NOX emissions 
    nationwide from the base cases. In both scenarios, however, the rule 
    does not have an overall effect on NOX emission trends.
        Stated differently, under any case studied, with or without the 
    rule, there will be an overall net decrease in NOX emissions 
    through the year 2000. Thereafter, NOx emissions begin to increase. 
    The rule does not materially affect either the decline prior to 2000 
    or the increase thereafter.
        Based on these findings the Commission concludes that a 
    comprehensive, Commission-imposed mitigation scheme to address the 
    environmental consequences of the rule is not appropriate. If 
    competition favors gas, the effects are beneficial and mitigation is 
    unnecessary. If competitive conditions favor coal through the year 
    2010, and NOX emissions increase slightly as a result of the 
    rule, these minor effects would be effectively mitigated as a part 
    of a comprehensive NOX cap and trading allowance scheme 
    developed by EPA in cooperation with the Ozone Transport Assessment 
    Group (OTAG) and administered by EPA and state environmental 
    regulators under the clearly established authority of the Clean Air 
    Act. [846]
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \846\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,862-63; mimeo at 663-65 
    (footnotes omitted).
    
        The Commission went on to note that it believes the appropriate no-
    action alternative was used to conduct this analysis. ``An alternative 
    that requires the Commission to reverse all its other open access 
    policies is simply not a 'no-action' alternative. To the contrary, it 
    would require decisive action running counter to the direction from the 
    Congress in the Energy Policy Act and the needs of the marketplace and 
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    electricity consumers.'' 847 The Commission then explained:
    
        \847\ Id. at 31,863; mimeo at 665.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        However, to ensure that the effects of the rule were analyzed 
    fully, the FEIS did study a reference case based on the ``frozen 
    efficiency'' case proffered by EPA and the Department of Energy 
    (DOE). Although, as described below, we believe this case to be 
    highly unlikely, the results show that, even under this scenario, 
    the impacts of the rule are not great and do not vary significantly 
    from those projected by staff under the other assumptions.
        In one case requested by EPA, staff studied a combination of 
    assumptions most likely to show significant increases in emissions 
    associated with the rule; the case included EPA's frozen efficiency 
    scenario, coupled with the ``Competition-Favors-Coal'' assumptions. 
    Other cases requested by EPA posit dramatic increases in 
    transmission capacity (that we find highly unlikely). Even this 
    combination of assumptions--geared to demonstrate the greatest 
    impact the rule might have on increased NOX emissions--produced 
    little in the way of environmental consequences associated with the 
    rule. Under these extreme (and unlikely) conditions, there would 
    still be a net decrease in NOX emissions until at least the 
    year 2000, albeit a smaller decrease than in the base cases. 
    Comparing projections of emissions for the same years, emissions 
    would be higher than the base cases only by two percent in 2000 and 
    three percent in 2005. It is only in the year 2010, assuming these 
    improbable scenarios, that NOX emissions associated with the 
    rule would be higher than the base case by even five percent.
    
    [[Page 12448]]
    
        Based on these studies, including the EPA reference case, the 
    Commission endorses the staff findings that the rule will affect air 
    quality slightly, if at all, and that the environmental impacts are 
    as likely to be beneficial as negative. This is true even under 
    scenarios contrived to maximize emissions associated with the rule 
    under circumstances that this Commission believes to be highly 
    unlikely.
        Importantly, this is also true in the near-to mid-term. Until 
    the year 2010, even the worst case (the frozen efficiency case) 
    produces results very similar to those produced using assumptions 
    the Commission believes to be reasonable. In short, the rule will 
    not produce an ``ozone cloud'' coming across the Appalachians to 
    threaten the Northeast on the day the rule goes into effect. 
    Assuming that any environmental impacts occur, they are years in the 
    future and may well be beneficial. As a result, calls for Commission 
    mitigation, and in particular for interim mitigation to ``fill the 
    gap'' until programs under the Clean Air Act can be adopted, are 
    unnecessary and disproportionate to the possible effects of the 
    rule. [ 848]
    
        \848\ Id. at 31,863-64; mimeo at 665-67 (footnotes omitted).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Thus, there is no basis for claims that the Rule will result in 
    large increases in pollution from generating plants operating under 
    less stringent environmental controls. This negates arguments calling 
    for the imposition of mitigation measures to ensure that all entities 
    compete under an identical regulatory regime.
        We note in this regard that the Joint Commenters' claim that the 
    Rule may result in emissions increases as large as 315,000 tons per 
    year by the year 2010, and cumulative NOX increases across the 
    United States of 530,000 tons by 2000 and 2.7 million tons by 2010, is 
    incorrect. The Joint Commenters derive this result by selectively 
    choosing numbers from the FEIS, comparing sensitivity cases designed to 
    be unrealistically low and high extremes. The low emissions case 
    selected is the frozen efficiency case that represents a complete 
    reversal of current industry and regulatory trends that are occurring 
    without the Rule. The high emissions case represents an increase in 
    transmission capacity that cannot reasonably be ascribed to the Rule. 
    The FEIS indicates that these cases were used to examine the 
    sensitivity of findings to certain extreme assumptions maintained by 
    commenters and are not the appropriate cases to use for considering 
    potential environmental impacts from the Rule.
        Moreover, the Joint Commenters reference increases from the Rule 
    without noting equally likely decreases. Even with the lower emissions 
    resulting from the unrealistic frozen efficiency case, the FEIS finds 
    decreases in emissions from the Rule when competitive forces lead to 
    greater efficiency for natural gas generation compared to coal.
        Actions to Mitigate NOX Emissions. Moreover, EPA and the 
    Commission have committed to undertake the actions sought by those 
    seeking rehearing on this issue. EPA in its referral to the CEQ 
    concurred with the Commission ``that the open access rule is unlikely 
    to have any significant adverse environmental impact in the immediate 
    future, and that in light of its anticipated economic benefits, 
    implementation of the Rule should go forward without delay.'' EPA also 
    ``concludes that the FERC has conducted an adequate analysis under the 
    National Environmental Policy Act of the environmental impacts of the 
    open access rule under a range of possible scenarios.'' In particular, 
    EPA concurs that the ``FERC made a reasonable choice of models (CEUM) 
    and made assumptions for various factors input into the model that lie 
    within the range of reasonable assumptions.''
        EPA also concurred with the Commission that NOX emissions 
    increases associated with the Rule, if any, should be addressed as part 
    of a comprehensive NOX emissions control program developed by EPA 
    and the states under mechanisms available under the Clean Air Act. This 
    includes support for the efforts of OTAG to develop standards for 
    measuring the scope of the ozone transport problem and developing 
    emissions reduction strategies.
        More significantly, EPA committed to use its authority under the 
    Clean Air Act to support successful completion of the OTAG process. EPA 
    will establish a NOX cap-and-trade program for the OTAG region 
    through Federal Implementation Plans ``if some States are unable or 
    unwilling to act in a timely manner.'' 849
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \849\ The FEIS at page 7-8 discusses EPA's authority under the 
    Clean Air Act to remedy the interstate transport of air pollution. 
    Section 176A provides that whenever EPA has reason to believe that 
    the interstate transport of air pollutants from one or more states 
    contributes significantly to a violation of national ambient air 
    quality standards in one or more other states, it may establish a 
    transport region for such pollutant. The transport commission is 
    charged statutorily with assessing the degree of interstate 
    transport of the pollutant or precursors to the pollutant throughout 
    the transport region, assessing strategies for mitigating the 
    interstate pollution, and recommending to the EPA Administrator 
    measures to ensure that the relevant State Implementation Plans 
    (which every state is required to have in place to address air 
    pollution) meet the requirements of the Clean Air Act.
        A transport commission may request the Administrator to issue a 
    finding under section 110(k)(5) that the SIP for one or more of the 
    states in the transport region is substantially inadequate to meet 
    the requirements of section 110. The Administrator must approve or 
    disapprove such a request within 18 months of its receipt.
        Upon approval of recommendations submitted by the transport 
    commission, the Administrator must issue to each state in the OTR to 
    which a requirement of the approved plan applies, a finding under 
    section 110(k)(5) that the implementation plan for such state is 
    inadequate to meet the requirements of section 110. Such finding 
    shall require each such state to revise its SIP to include the 
    approved additional control measures within one year after the 
    finding is issued.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        EPA also states that if ``the OTAG and Clean Air Act processes fail 
    to produce the necessary pollution limitations in a timely manner, EPA 
    will call upon all other interested Federal agencies to assist in 
    solving the problem.'' In this context EPA would ask the Commission to 
    contribute by further examining, through a Notice of Inquiry, possible 
    strategies for mitigating NOX emissions increases associated with 
    the Rule. EPA also suggested that if it determines that the problem 
    must be addressed through EPA initiation of Federal Implementation 
    Plans, FERC could then initiate a rulemaking to propose ``suitable 
    means under the Federal Power Act'' for mitigating impacts attributable 
    to the Rule.
        The Commission, on May 29, 1996, issued an order responding to 
    EPA's referral. The Commission stated that:
    
        Given EPA's commitment to address air pollution issues, it is 
    appropriate for EPA to seek assurances that if its best efforts are 
    not successful, other agencies will examine their abilities to 
    address the problem within the scope of their respective statutory 
    authorities. Given the broad powers vested in EPA by the Clean Air 
    Act, we fully expect EPA to succeed. We also note that if EPA is 
    unable ultimately to address the issue, either through the voluntary 
    OTAG process or by means of its authority under the Clean Air Act, 
    we doubt that other agencies will be able to resolve the NOX 
    emissions problem under more limited authority. In such 
    circumstances, action by the Congress may be necessary.
        Nevertheless, we believe that the Commission should be willing, 
    if called upon under the circumstances EPA describes, to consider 
    whether, under the Federal Power Act, it can and should attempt to 
    address NOX emissions issues attributable to the Rule. 
    Therefore, if EPA concludes that the OTAG process has not succeeded 
    in meeting its objectives in a timely manner, we will initiate a 
    Notice of Inquiry to further examine what mitigation might be 
    permissible and appropriate under the Federal Power Act. Such an 
    inquiry would solicit public comment on how to assess appropriately 
    the air pollution impacts attributable to the Final Rule, suitable 
    ways in which to address such impacts, if any, and the scope of the 
    Commission's authority to address such impacts.
    
    [[Page 12449]]
    
        Additionally, under the extraordinary circumstances in which EPA 
    would undertake a Federal Implementation Plan, the Commission would 
    agree to initiate contemporaneously a rulemaking to propose possible 
    mitigation that could be undertaken by the Commission under the 
    Federal Power Act. Such a rulemaking would be undertaken on the 
    basis of the NOI mentioned above and would be appropriate only if 
    environmental harm attributable to the rule that warranted 
    mitigation is demonstrated. The Commission would rely upon 
    information gleaned in the NOI in proposing possible mitigation 
    strategies that are workable, tailored to address consequences 
    attributable to the Rule, and consistent with our statutory 
    authority. In no event would the Commission propose a mitigation 
    strategy that would undermine the purposes of the rule to provide 
    open transmission access on a non-discriminatory basis. We emphasize 
    that neither the NOI nor the rulemaking, if they occur, will affect 
    the implementation of the rule as required under Orders of the 
    Commission. [850]
    
        \850\ Order Responding to Referral to Council on Environmental 
    Quality, 75 FERC para. 61,208 at 61,691-92 (1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Thus, EPA has concluded that the Commission conducted an adequate 
    analysis of the impacts of the Rule and agrees that the Rule is 
    unlikely to have any significant adverse environmental impact in the 
    near future. EPA also concurs that NOX emissions increases 
    associated with the Rule, if any, should be addressed as part of a 
    comprehensive NOX emissions control program developed by EPA and 
    the states under mechanisms available under the Clean Air Act. This 
    includes support for the efforts of OTAG to develop emissions 
    reductions strategies. EPA will use its Clean Air Act authority to 
    support completion of the OTAG process. EPA is prepared to establish a 
    NOX cap-and-trade program for the OTAG region through Federal 
    Implementation Plans if states are unable or unwilling to act in a 
    timely manner.
        This commitment by EPA puts to rest the concerns expressed by those 
    seeking rehearing on the issues of mitigation and disparate emissions 
    standards. As stated in the FEIS:
    
        The Ozone Transport Assessment Group (OTAG) represents [a] 
    broad[] effort to deal with the interstate transport of pollutants 
    that form ozone. OTAG is a voluntary organization that consists of 
    37 eastern states, the District of Columbia, and the EPA; industry 
    and environmental groups also participate in the OTAG process. It 
    was organized by the Environmental Council of States to study the 
    transport of ozone and its precursors in the eastern U.S. and to 
    develop mitigation strategies. OTAG is performing extensive 
    photochemical grid modeling to determine ozone transport patterns 
    and to evaluate the efficiency of various control strategies. OTAG 
    intends to submit its findings regarding transport patterns and its 
    recommendations for mitigation of ozone transport to EPA by January 
    1997.
        OTAG is considering a number of strategies to mitigate the 
    problem of ozone nonattainment. One strategy is the imposition of a 
    cap and trading system for NOX emissions in a 37-state area 
    compromising the Northeast OTR and upwind states. If the cap and 
    trading system becomes effective, it will fully mitigate any 
    NOX emissions increases attributable to open access 
    transmission within the 37-state area, because increases within this 
    area would have to be offset by a corresponding emission reduction.
        The OTAG cap and trade program may not deal directly with 
    emissions of pollutants other than NOX. However, a cap on 
    NOX is likely to mitigate CO2 and mercury increases, 
    because internalizing costs of NOX controls on coal-fired units 
    is likely to dampen increases in capacity utilization of such 
    units.[851]
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \851\ FEIS at 7-10 through 7-11.
    
        The OTAG process includes the players of concern here--both the 
    states from which alleged pollution increases would originate and the 
    states that would be affected by the increased pollution. OTAG has a 
    process underway to determine transport patterns and to evaluate 
    control strategies. One strategy that is being considered is the 
    imposition of a cap and trade system for NOX emissions like that 
    sought on rehearing here.852 OTAG originally intended to submit 
    its findings regarding transport patterns and recommendations for 
    mitigation to EPA by January 1997. As a result of its decision to 
    conduct additional modeling to determine the appropriate geographic 
    applicability of emission reduction strategies, OTAG has extended its 
    January timeframe by a few months, and now intends to complete its 
    process by April or May 1997.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \852\ We note in this regard that in a recently completed 
    rulemaking promulgating standards for the second phase of the 
    Nitrogen Oxides Reduction Program under Title IV of the Clean Air 
    Act, EPA authorized states to adopt a NOX cap and trading 
    program under certain circumstances. ``Acid Rain Program; Nitrogen 
    Oxides Emission Reduction Program'', 61 FR 67112, 67163 (1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        While OTAG is continuing its efforts, EPA is moving rapidly forward 
    to remedy in a comprehensive fashion the interstate transport of air 
    pollution. On January 10, 1997, EPA issued a notice of intent to use 
    the authority granted it by sections 110(k)(5) and 110(a)(2)(D) of the 
    Clean Air Act to require states to submit state implementation plan 
    (SIP) measures to ensure that emission reductions are achieved as 
    needed to prevent significant transport of ozone pollution across state 
    boundaries in the Eastern United States. This notice ``announces EPA's 
    intention to conduct the formal process for implementing the regional 
    reductions in ozone precursors that are necessary for areas in the 
    Eastern United States to reach attainment.'' 853 EPA states that 
    it intends to publish a Notice of Proposed Rulemaking in March 1997 
    that ``will propose overall amounts or ranges of NOX and/or VOC 
    emission reductions that each State would need to achieve to reduce the 
    boundary condition concentrations of ozone and its precursors within a 
    specified timeframe and require the submission of SIP controls to 
    achieve these reductions.'' 854 The notice of inquiry also states 
    that the SIP revision must contain a schedule for adoption and 
    implementation of these measures. It notes that while EPA could allow 
    up to 18 months for SIP submittals under section 110(k)(5), ``EPA is 
    considering a more accelerated schedule for submittals under this SIP 
    call to attain air quality benefits sooner and to facilitate area 
    specific SIP planning.'' 855 EPA notes that as it goes through the 
    process of developing an implementation program for the new standard, 
    it will be able to take advantage of the information gathered by OTAG 
    and account for emission reductions that result from the recommended 
    strategy. EPA intends to publish the final SIP call notice in summer 
    1997.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \853\ 62 FR 1420 (1997).
        \854\ Id. at 1423.
        \855\ Id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Thus, actions to address the concerns with regard to mitigation and 
    emissions standards disparity are taking place at this time and should 
    be in place in the near future. This lays to rest as well concerns that 
    any near-term impacts of the Rule have not been taken into account.
        The Commission's Authority to Mitigate. The PA Com makes an 
    unsupported assertion that the FPA's public interest standard 
    authorizes the Commission to take mitigation measures related to its 
    regulatory actions, and that the Commission should use the results of 
    the OTAG process to develop a mitigation strategy.
        The Joint Commenters argue that the Commission has broad authority 
    under NEPA to mitigate the environmental consequences of its proposed 
    actions. It contends that NEPA broadens the Commission's FPA 
    authority--that NEPA policies and goals inform and expand the FPA's 
    definition of the public interest. It also argues that the Commission's 
    duty to ensure just and reasonable rates that are not unduly 
    discriminatory or preferential also
    
    [[Page 12450]]
    
    encompasses non-economic factors in appropriate circumstances.
        The Joint Commenters conclude that, while it may be reasonable for 
    the Commission to reject specific proposed mitigation measures, the 
    Commission should, at a minimum, acknowledge that the FEIS demonstrates 
    that the exercise of that authority is not warranted in this case. The 
    Joint Commenters add that the Commission should initiate a rulemaking 
    proceeding that considers mitigation options and evaluates the 
    effectiveness of alternative strategies and proposals. The Joint 
    Commenters concur that EPA's commitment to address air pollution issues 
    is reasonable, but would have the Commission develop a backup NOX 
    mitigation mechanism by the end of 1996.
        Thus, the PA Com and the Joint Commenters would have the Commission 
    revisit in this order, by means of a generalized reexamination of the 
    Commission's authority to impose mitigation, the conclusion in Order 
    No. 888 that the mitigation measures recommended by commenters are 
    beyond our authority to implement.
        Order No. 888 and the FEIS fully examine the need for mitigation 
    and the Commission's legal authority to impose mitigation measures. 
    That examination led to the conclusion that: (1) the insistence of 
    certain commenters that the Commission adopt and implement mitigation 
    measures is based on significantly overstated assumptions regarding the 
    contribution of the Rule to existing environmental problems, and that 
    these assumptions about the impact of the Rule are wrong; (2) the 
    existence for many years of a significant ozone nonattainment problem 
    in part of the U.S. has led to the development of mechanisms to address 
    this issue; (3) the mitigation recommendations suggested by commenters 
    suffer from serious legal and practical shortcomings; and (4) the 
    mitigation measures recommended by commenters are beyond the 
    Commission's authority to implement and strong policy considerations 
    militate against their adoption.
        The PA Com and Joint Commenters have not raised any arguments that 
    warrant revisiting the Commission's exhaustive examination of this 
    issue in Order No. 888 and the FEIS, and we hereby reaffirm those 
    decisions. We note in this regard that the PA Com did not advance a 
    specific mitigation proposal in comments on the EIS and does not 
    challenge the Commission's rejection in Order No. 888 of specific 
    mitigation proposals advanced by other commenters. The Joint Commenters 
    did propose a specific mitigation strategy which the Commission 
    rejected because, among other things, it would have the Commission 
    impose a revenue collection measure. The Joint Commenters do not 
    challenge the Commission's analysis of its proposal or seek rehearing 
    of its rejection. Instead, the Joint Commenters seek an acknowledgement 
    from the Commission that, given the conclusions in the FEIS, the 
    exercise of authority to mitigate is not warranted in this case. As we 
    stated in Order No. 888 and the FEIS, mitigation is not warranted given 
    the conclusions reached in the FEIS. The Commission also notes that we 
    have thoroughly examined our legal authority in Order No. 888 and we 
    find nothing in the arguments on rehearing that persuade us now to a 
    different result. We have agreed to further examine our authority to 
    engage in environmental mitigation through a Notice of Inquiry if EPA 
    determines that the OTAG efforts are not successful. Therefore, it is 
    unnecessary in this context to opine further in the abstract as to the 
    scope of the Commission's mitigation authority.
        Because the PA Com and the Joint Commenters have raised no new 
    arguments that were not thoroughly addressed in Order No. 888 and the 
    FEIS, it is unnecessary to repeat here the thorough analysis of this 
    issue set forth in those documents. The Commission declines to grant 
    rehearing on this issue.
        Other Mitigation-Related Issues. VT DPS states that the Commission 
    has given inadequate consideration to the possibility that the Rule may 
    unnecessarily exacerbate environmental impacts and that the Commission, 
    therefore, should adopt mitigation.
        This statement, which VT DPS fails to substantiate, is incorrect. 
    The FEIS and the process which led to the conclusions contained therein 
    fully consider the environmental impact of the Rule. VT DPS fails to 
    identify any particulars in which the FEIS is deficient. VT DPS's 
    disagreement appears to be a generalized dissatisfaction with the 
    substantive conclusion reached by the FEIS that the Rule will not have 
    significant environmental impacts.
        VT DPS next claims that the Commission's environmental review 
    process has not facilitated the ability of affected parties to review 
    all of the modeling assumptions. It also claims that other 
    environmental reviews suggest that the Rule will have more serious 
    NOX emissions consequences than acknowledged by the Commission.
        VT DPS again attacks the FEIS with a broad brush, but fails to 
    identify ways in which the ability of parties to review modeling 
    assumptions has been impeded. Likewise, it does not identify areas in 
    which modeling assumptions have not been identified or any way in which 
    its understanding of the FEIS has been hampered by the alleged 
    unavailability of certain modeling assumptions. VT DPS is very late in 
    raising such claims. The time to raise such issues is during the 
    scoping process or in comments on the DEIS.
        It is unclear what other environmental reviews VT DPS is referring 
    to or the ways in which those reviews allegedly suggest that the Rule 
    will have more serious NOX emissions consequences than 
    acknowledged by the Commission. Even if the unidentified studies reach 
    different results than the FEIS this does not invalidate the 
    conclusions contained in the FEIS. The mere fact of disagreement, even 
    disagreement among experts in a given area, does not invalidate a 
    study. 856
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \856\ See, e.g., Marsh v. Oregon Natural Resources Council, 490 
    U.S. 360 (1989); Sierra Club v. Marita, 46 F.3d 606, 623-24 (7th 
    Cir. 1995); Inland Empire Public Lands Council v. Schultz, 992 F.2d 
    977, 981 (9th Cir. 1993).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        VT DPS next recommends that the Commission establish an ongoing 
    monitoring program in consultation with environmental agencies. It 
    states that a monitoring program would allow the Commission to take 
    timely action to mitigate any unintended consequences of the Rule.
        An EIS is required to be prepared, when appropriate, prior to 
    agency action. As the Supreme Court has stated, the moment at which an 
    agency must have a final statement ready is the time at which it makes 
    a recommendation or report on a proposal for federal action. 857 
    There is no requirement that an agency continue to evaluate the 
    environmental impacts of a project after it is implemented, 
    particularly where, as here, the agency has determined that the 
    proposal is not likely to have adverse environmental impacts.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \857\ Kleppe v. Sierra Club, 427 U.S. 390 (1976).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Moreover, as discussed extensively above, EPA's commitment to take 
    action with regard to the underlying problems of the interstate 
    transport of air pollutants provides a fuller measure of relief than 
    that sought by VT DPS.
        The New York Attorney General claims that it is essential that FERC 
    exercise any authority it may have to mitigate the environmental 
    effects of the Rule because Congress has limited EPA's authority in 
    this regard. The Attorney General also claims that EPA's proposal in 
    its comments of February 20, 1996 on the DEIS to place a cap on 
    NOX emissions would mitigate the effects of the Rule; it suggests 
    basing
    
    [[Page 12451]]
    
    this system on the MOU. The Attorney General urges implementation of 
    this system on the federal level pursuant to authority residing in EPA 
    and/or FERC.
        We note first that Congress has made a full grant of authority to 
    EPA to address the issue of the interstate transport of air pollution. 
    As discussed extensively above, EPA has committed to address this 
    issue, and to use its authority pursuant to the Clean Air Act if states 
    are unwilling to address this issue cooperatively through the MOU 
    process. Thus, EPA has committed to undertake the relief sought by the 
    Attorney General. If EPA is unsuccessful, the Commission has pledged to 
    assist in this effort as discussed above.
    
    D. Emissions Standards Disparity
    
        Order No. 888 addresses claims that the Commission should ``level 
    the playing field'' as to environmental standards. The argument was 
    that unless the Commission imposes mitigation, competitors with 
    ``dirty'' generation will be favored over ``clean'' competitors. Those 
    urging the adoption of measures to level the playing field argue that 
    mitigation of environmental impacts has a direct relationship to 
    ensuring that open access is implemented under terms of economic 
    fairness for all utilities, and not merely those with current low-cost 
    regulatory advantages.
        We responded to those arguments in Order No. 888 by noting that:
    
        [A]ll power generation technologies have different costs. For 
    example, hydroelectric facilities which, like coal-fired facilities, 
    may have environmental mitigation conditions imposed on them, may be 
    quite expensive to build compared to gas or oil-fired generation, 
    but their operating costs may be significantly lower. These cost 
    differences may reflect the different costs of complying with 
    mandated environmental requirements; the prudent costs of complying 
    with such mandates may be reflected in rates.
        Indeed, sellers come to the power markets with a variety of 
    advantages and disadvantages, many of which are the result of 
    federal laws--for example, tax preferences, labor standards, and 
    similar matters. In empowering the Commission to remedy undue 
    discrimination and promote competition, Congress has not authorized 
    the Commission to equalize the environmental costs of electricity 
    production in order to ensure ``economic fairness.'' Such 
    homogenization of competitors, or their costs, has never been a goal 
    of the FPA.
    * * * * *
        In short, the ``economic nexus'' urged by commenters advocating 
    that the Commission undertake to regulate air emissions is 
    inconsistent with the ``charge to promote the orderly production of 
    plentiful supplies of electric energy'' envisioned by the FPA.
        We have exercised conditioning authority in the past only where 
    necessary to ensure that jurisdictional transactions and rates do 
    not result in anti-competitive effects, or are not unjust, 
    unreasonable or unduly discriminatory or preferential. Thus, the 
    conditions we have imposed have involved economic regulatory matters 
    within our purview under the FPA. Any exercise of conditioning 
    authority must, as the Supreme Court noted in NAACP, be directly 
    related to our economic regulation responsibilities; EPA and the 
    other commenters have not demonstrated such a nexus.
        This distinction is more evident when one considers the way in 
    which we are authorized to treat the costs of environmental 
    compliance. There are legitimate costs of environmental compliance 
    that should be reflected in jurisdictional rates to the extent 
    prudently incurred, just as the prudent costs of complying with, for 
    example, occupational health and safety requirements designed to 
    protect utility employees should be reflected in jurisdictional 
    rates. This we are authorized to do and we routinely review and 
    allow such costs. However, the fact that the costs of providing 
    utility workers with a safe workplace are properly reflected in 
    utilities' jurisdictional rates does not mean that we have authority 
    to condition sellers' rates or customers' use of jurisdictional 
    services on meeting safety regulations that are in the public 
    interest. The same rationale applies to environmental matters 
    related to the rule. [858]
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \858\ FERC Stats. & Reg. at 31,890-91; mimeo at 740-43 
    (footnotes omitted). The FEIS noted in this regard at page J-93 
    that:
        Many factors cause generation sources to have differing costs. 
    Some states impose taxes on generators that others do not. Some 
    fuels are taxed differently than others (e.g., renewable generators 
    such as wind power receive tax incentives that fossil generators do 
    not while fossil fuels receive other tax advantages that renewables 
    do not.) Such differences cannot be said to be unduly 
    discriminatory, especially when they are sanctioned, or even 
    required, by the actions of the Congress or state authorities. If 
    the Commission attempted to ``level'' all of the ``playing fields'' 
    it would be unable to judge any rate to be just and reasonable. 
    Further, traditional rates are not determined through competitive 
    processes but on a cost of service basis. Not all rates have to be 
    determined to be competitive in order to be judged just and 
    reasonable. * * *
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        Pennsylvania PUC. The PA Com asserts that the FEIS does not 
    adequately address challenges posed by the Clean Air Act Amendments of 
    1990. The PA Com contends that the Rule may shift power production from 
    Pennsylvania plants with strong environmental controls to upwind plants 
    with less stringent controls, and that prevailing climatic patterns may 
    transport the increased pollution downwind. It states that mitigation 
    is needed to prevent degradation of downwind air quality and the 
    imposition of further costs and limits on downwind generation.
        The PA Com states that the Clean Air Act Amendments imposed 
    stringent emission standards on Pennsylvania generation, but did not 
    impose similar standards on neighboring states such as Ohio and West 
    Virginia. It claims that the FEIS does not sufficiently consider these 
    requirements. The PA Com concludes that implementing open access 
    without mitigation will place Pennsylvania utilities at a competitive 
    disadvantage, and that this result is inconsistent with the public 
    policy goals of the Clean Air Act and the Federal Power Act. The PA Com 
    also asserts that the Rule may discriminate against Pennsylvania 
    utilities and the Pennsylvania coal industry, and that the combination 
    of the Clean Air Act and Order No. 888 places Pennsylvania at a 
    disadvantage in the competition for new industry and jobs.
        The PA Com claims that Order No. 888 may push states in the 
    Northeast Ozone Transport Commission into repudiating the existing MOU. 
    It claims that it is inconsistent for one federal purpose which is 
    statutorily clear (i.e., clean air mandates established by the Clean 
    Air Act Amendments) to be prejudiced by another federal purpose with 
    only inferential statutory authority (i.e., open access under sections 
    205 and 206 of the FPA).
        The PA Com asserts in this regard that Phase II of the MOU will 
    require by 1999 a 55 percent reduction in NOX emissions in most of 
    Pennsylvania and 65 percent (0.2 lbs/mmBTU) in the Philadelphia area. 
    Title I of the Clean Air Act requires that the Northeast make 
    reasonable progress towards attainment. If the inner zone of states 
    comprising the Ozone Transport Commission do not achieve attainment, 
    Phase III of the MOU will be implemented in 2003. Phase III requires a 
    75 percent reduction in emissions (0.15 lbs/mmBTU) for the entire 
    state. According to the PA Com, to meet Phase III requirements most 
    Pennsylvania coal-fired stations will have to install Selective 
    Catalytic Reduction technology at a capital cost of $2.3 to $3.5 
    billion. It states that other Northeast states will be required to make 
    expenditures that are much lower, and that states such as West Virginia 
    and Ohio will not be subject to these requirements at all.
        New Jersey BPU. The NJ BPU poses a similar concern. It states that 
    upwind power plants are designed to meet NOX emission standards 
    which are substantially less restrictive than those required in New 
    Jersey. The NJ BPU claims that this will have a two-fold impact--New 
    Jersey air quality will be degraded through air transport and New 
    Jersey utilities will be placed at a
    
    [[Page 12452]]
    
    significant cost disadvantage. The NJ BPU states that it is 
    inconsistent to assert substantial incremental benefits associated with 
    competition brought about by the Rule, while asserting that the Rule 
    will not result in any change in the utilization of existing power 
    plants.
        NJ BPU asserts that there are disparities in the electric industry 
    among suppliers with regard to environmental impacts and costs, and 
    that the Commission did not take this into account in determining the 
    total economic benefit of a competitive wholesale generation market. It 
    notes that the Commission may consider that it produced an economic 
    benefit if the Rule enables a buyer in the Southeast to displace self-
    generated 4-cent power with 3-cent power from the Midwest. The NJ BPU 
    contends, however, that if emissions from the plants producing the 
    electricity result in 1.5 cents worth of mitigation costs on a downwind 
    state, an appropriate economic analysis would conclude that the 
    transaction actually increases total costs. NJ BPU asserts that it was 
    inappropriate for the Commission to focus on economic gains while 
    leaving cost issues to be dealt with by other entities.
        NJ BPU recommends that the Commission adopt an integrated 
    environmental, economic and energy policy approach which embraces the 
    underlying principles in EPA's acid rain program. It states that the 
    Commission should call for specific, significant and enforceable 
    reductions in NOX emissions coupled with a market based trading 
    program of emissions. It asserts that this approach would ensure a fair 
    and competitive playing field at a fraction of the expected cost 
    savings from the Rule.
        Joint Commenters. The Joint Commenters assert that the Commission 
    has a duty under the FPA to mitigate undue preferences that affect 
    competition in the wholesale power market. It concludes that this 
    mandate must be applied here where implementation of open access 
    policies without concurrent environmental mitigation will cause 
    generation-owning utilities to face a discriminatory competitive 
    situation.
        The Joint Commenters note that the Northeast is an ozone 
    nonattainment area because of high levels of ambient ozone pollution, 
    and is therefore subject to strict NOX reduction requirements. It 
    states that regional utilities have invested significant sums in 
    pollution reduction facilities and cleaner generation to meet legal 
    requirements to reduce emissions. It contends that these utilities will 
    be subject to additional NOX reduction requirements, thus 
    increasing generation costs, if ambient ozone levels increase as a 
    result of competition.
        The Joint Commenters contend that if open access increases 
    emissions, utilities in the Northeast that have increased their 
    generation costs to reduce air pollution will be required to bear 
    additional costs to offset the impacts of increased upwind emissions. 
    It states that the cost to Northeast utilities to offset additional 
    NOX emissions will likely be substantially higher than the costs 
    would be to upwind competitors to mitigate emissions at the source. It 
    claims that offsetting the impacts of a 250,000 ton NOX increase 
    in downwind nonattainment areas, where marginal NOX and volatile 
    organic compound (VOC) control costs average about $3,800 per ton, 
    could total $1 billion. On the other hand, mitigating the pollution 
    increases at generation sources which currently operate with minimal 
    environmental controls would cost about $500 per ton, or $130 million. 
    The Joint Commenters assert that this cost differential will be hidden 
    from the competitive market because Northeast generators will bear the 
    cost.
        The Joint Commenters assert that this demonstrates that the 
    wholesale bulk power market in the eastern United States is suffused 
    with an existing undue preference that inordinately favors one category 
    of competitors by allowing them to produce and sell power at a lower 
    marginal cost. This preference exists today as a result of costs 
    incurred in the past to meet Clean Air Act obligations; the FEIS 
    demonstrates that Order No. 888 could worsen this situation as a result 
    of increased sales from older, higher-emitting upwind coal generators.
        The Joint Commenters add that, aside from the competitive 
    unfairness of this situation, the undue preferences will produce 
    inefficiencies which distort investment decisions and increase the 
    overall cost to produce electricity--the antithesis of what Order No. 
    888 is meant to achieve. It asserts that these inefficiencies will 
    occur in four ways:
    
        Sources in downwind nonattainment areas could have to spend 
    hundreds of millions of dollars to address increased air pollution 
    resulting from open access if polluting plants do not mitigate at 
    the source. Thus, less efficient investments will be made to reduce 
    air pollution and the overall cost of generating electricity will be 
    higher than in a competitive market that is not distorted by 
    discrimination.
        Order No. 888 could adversely impact the economic dispatch of 
    generating sources under competitive conditions. In the absence of 
    mitigation, generation from higher polluting upwind plants could 
    displace generation from plants in the Northeast that operate more 
    efficiently at the margin. As utilities in the Northeast are 
    required to add more costly emission controls in response to 
    interregional migration of air pollution, their operating costs will 
    be driven up and may exceed the costs of less efficient plants which 
    have avoided such controls. Thus, in the absence of mitigation, 
    Order No. 888 may foster less efficient utilization of generating 
    resources.
        Implementation of Order No. 888 without mitigation may distort 
    the market for future generation capacity. If older, more highly-
    polluting plants can shift the environmental cost of production to 
    other wholesale generators, they are likely to expand their output 
    to address market needs, thus reducing the demand for more 
    efficient, clean-burning generating facilities.
        Transmission from the Midwest to the East is often heavily 
    constrained. Consequently, a distorted price signal to increase 
    generation in the Midwest would exacerbate existing constraints and 
    improperly stimulate the construction of new transmission capacity 
    to support additional interregional transactions.
    
    The Joint Commenters conclude that the Commission has an obligation to 
    exercise its authority in non-arbitrary manner, particularly when 
    acting to prevent undue discrimination.
        Finally, the Joint Commenters disagree with the Commission's 
    response to this issue in Order No. 888. It asserts that the Commission 
    and the courts have found in the ``price squeeze'' context that the 
    Commission has authority to remedy anti-competitive discrimination, 
    even when it is caused by regulatory practices of others over which it 
    and its regulated public utilities have no control. Second, the 
    Commission has the authority and responsibility to address 
    environmental issues that directly affect and have a nexus to its 
    section 205 and 206 responsibilities. Third, if the competitive market 
    that the Commission wishes to create will not operate fairly or 
    efficiently, the Commission has a duty to consider whether it should go 
    forward at all if it believes it does not have the power to remedy 
    important adverse competitive consequences.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        Congress has empowered the Commission to remedy undue 
    discrimination and promote competition; it has not authorized the 
    Commission to equalize the environmental costs of electricity 
    production in order to ensure ``economic fairness.'' Homogenization of 
    competitors, or their costs, has never been a goal of the FPA.
        Action in Order No. 888 to remedy undue discrimination in access to 
    the monopoly owned transmission wires
    
    [[Page 12453]]
    
    that control whether and to whom electricity can be transported in 
    interstate commerce does not require action by the Commission to cure 
    all competitive differences between participants in the utility 
    marketplace. This is particularly true where the disparities arise 
    because Congress has established policies with regard to competing 
    issues of national significance and charged other agencies of the 
    federal government with implementing those policies. The assertion that 
    the Commission must eliminate any competitive disadvantage arising from 
    congressionally mandated policies, including the vital national 
    policies set forth in the Clean Air Act, before it can act to remedy 
    undue discrimination and encourage competition in the electric utility 
    industry is in error.
        Furthermore, as noted above, the analysis reflected in the FEIS 
    refutes the claim that the Rule will result in significant 
    environmental impacts. Thus, there is no basis in any event to support 
    requests that the Commission ``level'' the playing field.
        Recounted briefly, those findings show that, without the Rule, 
    NOX emissions are expected to decline until at least the year 
    2000. Thereafter, again without the Rule, NOX emissions are 
    expected to increase steadily through the year 2010. The extent of the 
    decrease and increase will be largely determined by the relative prices 
    of natural gas and coal.
        The analysis also demonstrates that the Rule will not in any 
    significant respect affect these overall trends. The analysis shows 
    that if the Rule results in efficiency gains in the electric industry 
    that favors the use of natural gas as a fuel, the effect will be 
    slightly beneficial; total NOX emissions will be reduced overall 
    by about two percent nationwide below what would otherwise be expected 
    to occur. If the Rule results in efficiency gains that favor the use of 
    coal as a fuel, the Rule is expected to increase NOX emissions 
    approximately one percent above what would otherwise be expected to 
    occur.
        Even analyzing the highly unlikely frozen efficiency case, the 
    analysis demonstrates that the impacts of the Rule will not be great 
    and will not vary significantly from those projected by staff under the 
    assumptions discussed above. This study, utilizing a combination of 
    assumptions geared to demonstrate the greatest impact the Rule might 
    have on increased NOX emissions, produced little in the way of 
    environmental consequences associated with the Rule. Under these 
    extreme (and unlikely) conditions, there would still be a net decrease 
    in NOX emissions until at least the year 2000, albeit a smaller 
    decrease than in the base cases. Comparing projections of emissions for 
    the same years, emissions would be higher than the base cases only by 
    two percent in 2000 and three percent in 2005. It is only in the year 
    2010, assuming these improbable scenarios, that NOX emissions 
    associated with the Rule would be higher than the base case by even 
    five percent.
        All told, this analysis demonstrates that the Rule will affect air 
    quality slightly, if at all, and that the environmental impacts are as 
    likely to be beneficial as negative. This is true under scenarios 
    contrived to maximize emissions under circumstances that the Commission 
    believes to be highly unlikely. This is also true in the near to mid-
    term. Assuming that any environmental impacts occur, they are years in 
    the future and may well be beneficial.
        Thus, contrary to the position taken by those seeking to have the 
    Commission impose mitigation, the Rule will not result in impacts 
    requiring mitigation to level the playing field.
        Moreover, as also noted above, EPA has committed to address the 
    existing NOX transport issue, including the contribution of the 
    Rule, if any, to those impacts. It must be emphasized in this regard 
    that the Northeast has experienced significant air pollution problems 
    for many, many years. Much of this pollution is generated by activities 
    within the affected states and within the affected region; the problem 
    is exacerbated somewhat by the airborne transport of pollutants from 
    upwind areas, including pollutants resulting from the generation of 
    electricity that will occur regardless of any future increase in 
    generation that might result from implementation of the Rule.
        Put differently, the pollution problems in the individual states 
    and in the Northeast in general result primarily from economic 
    activities within those states. The airborne transport of pollutants, 
    including pollution resulting from existing electric generation, adds 
    to the existing problem to some degree. The analysis in the FEIS 
    demonstrates that open access may increase the amount of upwind 
    generation by some small increment, and thus increase the downwind 
    NOX levels by an even smaller incremental amount. On the other 
    hand, depending on the future competitive position of natural gas 
    versus coal, a situation over which the Commission has no control, the 
    Rule may decrease the amount of pollution that would otherwise exist 
    and thus decrease downwind pollution. In any event, the Rule will 
    affect existing trends slightly, if at all.
        In recognition of the situation described above, which again is 
    likely to be affected only very slightly, if at all, by the Rule, EPA 
    has committed to address the overall issue of NOX emissions as 
    part of a comprehensive program developed by EPA and the states. EPA 
    has committed to use its authority under the Clean Air Act to 
    successfully complete the OTAG process. EPA states that it will, if 
    necessary, establish a NOX cap-and-trade program for the OTAG 
    region through Federal Implementation Plans if some states are unable 
    or unwilling to act in a timely manner.
        As discussed in the FEIS, and as noted above, OTAG has efforts 
    underway to develop responses to this problem. For example, OTAG 
    intends to submit its findings regarding ozone transport patterns and 
    its recommendations for mitigation of ozone transport to EPA by April 
    or May 1997. If this process is less than fully successful, the Clean 
    Air Act authorizes EPA to act in a relatively short time-frame to 
    address this problem. EPA has committed to exercise this authority to 
    address the problem.
        It must be emphasized that EPA has stated its intent to address the 
    problem regardless of the effects of the Rule. Even if the Rule results 
    in environmental impacts, those incremental impacts will be addressed 
    as part of the comprehensive NOX regulatory developed by EPA in 
    conjunction with the states.
        Thus, EPA has committed to undertake the mitigation sought by the 
    PA Com, NJ BPU and Joint Commenters. The Commission has stated its 
    intent to participate in this process as discussed above. This result 
    negates claims that implementing open access without mitigation will 
    place downwind utilities and the Pennsylvania coal industry at a 
    competitive disadvantage. Accordingly, the requests that the Commission 
    impose mitigation measures to ``level'' the environmental playing field 
    are denied.
    
    E. Short-Term Consequences of the Rule
    
        The FEIS projects future electric powerplant emissions under a 
    range of assumptions without the Rule (base cases). These results are 
    then compared to what electric powerplant emissions are likely to be 
    under corresponding assumptions with the Rule in place (Rule 
    scenarios). The study utilizes three reporting years: 2000, 2005, and 
    2010. These reporting years were chosen because they cover a reasonable 
    time frame for the study. Beyond 2010, the
    
    [[Page 12454]]
    
    projections are dependent on too many unforeseeable factors to be 
    meaningful.859
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \859\ FEIS at ES-9, 3-1.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Although the effects of the Rule will begin to occur when the final 
    Rule is issued, the effects should develop gradually over time. 
    Measurable effects are expected to be clearly observable by the year 
    2000, though not necessarily fully complete.860
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \860\ Id. at 3-1.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The FEIS analysis of the Rule scenarios shows that NOX 
    emissions are expected to decrease significantly between 1993 and 2000. 
    The Competition-Favors-Gas Scenario demonstrates that the Rule will 
    reinforce decreases already present in the base case. Thus, the Rule 
    will enhance underlying environmental improvements. While the 
    Competition-Favors-Coal Scenario demonstrates small emissions 
    increases, NOX emissions nonetheless continue to decrease from 
    1993 to 2000. A similar trend is also seen on a regional basis. The 
    Rule does not alter the basic pattern of environmental 
    improvement.861
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \861\ Id. at 5-15.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        New Jersey BPU. The NJ BPU claims that the FEIS fails to recognize 
    possible short-term effects the Rule may have on existing ozone 
    problems in the Northeast, and that the failure to address short-term 
    consequences is of particular importance to nonattainment states who 
    must meet Clean Air Act attainment dates in 1996 and 1999.
        Joint Commenters. The Joint Commenters claim that by examining the 
    period between 2000 and 2010, the FEIS fails to analyze near-term 
    impacts and the need for a short-term mitigation strategy. Joint 
    Commenters note that the Rule will be implemented almost immediately, 
    and that changes in generation plant utilization that give rise to the 
    greatest environmental concerns may occur very quickly.
        The Joint Commenters are concerned that the FEIS does not consider 
    how projected environmental effects prior to 2000 would impact air 
    quality and Clean Air Act attainment deadlines. The Joint Commenters 
    contest the conclusion that utility NOX emissions will decline 
    between 1993 and 2000. It states that emissions will increase each year 
    between 1993 and 2000 except in 1996 and 2000, when large NOX 
    reductions will be implemented pursuant to the Clean Air Act. The Joint 
    Commenters also contend that it is irrelevant whether clean air 
    programs will cause overall emissions to be lower in 2000 than they 
    were in 1993; the relevant question is whether emissions will be higher 
    with Order No. 888 than without it.
        The Joint Commenters contend that the data presented in the FEIS 
    for the year 2000 suggest that, if the Rule is considered in isolation, 
    there will be potentially significant short-term emissions increases in 
    the period 1996-2000. It states that the FEIS indicates that 
    implementation of the Rule under the Competition-Favors-Coal Scenario 
    with expanded transmission will lead to an additional 132,000 tons of 
    NOX emissions in 2000 compared with the frozen efficiency 
    reference case. It contends, assuming a linear increase, that this 
    means there could be an additional 75,000, 94,000 and 113,000 tons of 
    NOX emissions as a result of the Rule in 1997, 1998, and 1999, 
    respectively.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The Joint Commenters' claims that implementation of the Rule will 
    lead to an additional 132,000 tons of NOX emissions in the year 
    2000 in incorrect. As is the case with regard to its assertion above 
    that the Rule will result an additional 315,000 tons of NOX 
    emissions in 2010, this impact was derived by selectively choosing 
    numbers from the FEIS, comparing two sensitivity cases designed to be 
    unrealistically low and high extremes. The low emissions case is the 
    frozen efficiency case that represents a complete reversal of current 
    industry and regulatory trends that are occurring without the Rule. The 
    high emissions case represents an increase in transmission capacity 
    that cannot reasonably be ascribed to the Rule. As stated in the FEIS, 
    these cases were selected to examine the sensitivity of FEIS findings 
    to certain extreme assumptions maintained by commenters and are not the 
    appropriate cases for determining potential environmental impacts from 
    the Rule.
        Moreover, we note that the Joint Commenters reference increases 
    from the Rule without noting equally likely decreases. Even with the 
    lower emissions resulting from the unrealistic frozen efficiency case, 
    the FEIS finds decreases in emissions from the Rule when competitive 
    forces lead to greater efficiency for natural gas generation compared 
    to coal.
        The Commission has analyzed the Rule and found that its impacts 
    will be insignificant. We also note that even if the Rule were to 
    result in short-term emission increases, EPA has signaled its 
    willingness to address the transport of pollutants in a timely fashion. 
    As discussed above, EPA has concluded that any emissions increases 
    associated with the Rule should be addressed as part of a comprehensive 
    NOX emissions control program developed by EPA and the states 
    under mechanisms available under the Clean Air Act. This approach 
    includes support for OTAG efforts to develop emissions reduction 
    strategies. OTAG plans to submit its findings and mitigation 
    recommendations to EPA by April or May 1997. As discussed above, EPA 
    has issued a notice of intent to adopt by summer 1997 a rule that would 
    require state implementation plan measures to ensure that emission 
    reductions are achieved as needed to prevent significant transport of 
    ozone pollution across state boundaries in the Eastern United States. 
    EPA is contemplating establishing deadlines for state implementation 
    plan submittals ranging from six months to 18 months following the date 
    of publication of its notice of final rulemaking.
        The instant Rule will affect the existing NOX transport issue 
    very little, if at all. As stated in Order No. 888, the Rule is not the 
    appropriate vehicle for resolving this debate. The appropriate 
    regulatory mechanism for addressing the overall NOX problem, 
    including emissions from electric utility generating plants, is a 
    NOX emissions cap and allowance trading scheme along the lines of 
    that developed by the Congress under the Clean Air Act for SO2 
    emissions. As noted, EPA has committed to implement this approach. Even 
    if there are slight environmental impacts associated with the Rule, 
    they are better and more effectively addressed as part of a 
    comprehensive NOX regulatory program.
    
    G. Cost Benefit Analysis
    
        ``The legal and policy cornerstone'' of Order No. 888 ``is to 
    remedy undue discrimination in access to the monopoly owned 
    transmission wires that control whether and to whom electricity can be 
    transported in interstate commerce.'' 862 As reiterated in the 
    FEIS, the purpose of the Rule is to increase access to non-
    discriminatory transmission services and thereby increase competition 
    in wholesale electric markets.863
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \862\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,634; mimeo at 1.
        \863\ FEIS at ES-13 through ES-16.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The FEIS states that the Rule will give wholesale power customers a 
    greater opportunity to obtain competitively priced electricity. 
    Competition will create benefits through better use of existing assets 
    and institutions, new market mechanisms, technical innovation, and less 
    rate distortion.
    
    [[Page 12455]]
    
    Only the first--better use of existing assets and institutions--was 
    estimated quantitatively: approximately $3.8 to $5.4 billion per year. 
    The FEIS also discusses other benefits that cannot be quantified but 
    may be large. Based on the experience of, for example, the natural gas 
    and telecommunications industries, the Commission opined that the other 
    three are likely to increase industry efficiency--and benefits--
    substantially.864
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \864\ The discussion of the economic benefits of the Rule in 
    found in the FEIS at ES-13 through ES-16 and 5-64 through 5-75.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As described elsewhere in this order, the FEIS also discusses 
    extensively possible environmental effects (i.e., costs) of the Rule. 
    It concludes that the Rule could raise or lower national emissions 
    slightly, but will not have a significant effect on the environment.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        The Joint Commenters contend that the analysis of projected 
    benefits from the Rule appears to be inadequately substantiated and 
    uses assumptions that are inconsistent with those used to reach a 
    finding of no significant impact on environmental issues. Although 
    Joint Commenters do not challenge the conclusion that Order No. 888 
    will result in economic benefits, it states that the benefits 
    identified in the FEIS are inadequately substantiated and do not 
    reflect a balanced analysis. It claims that courts have held that when 
    economic development is the selling point or raison d'etre of an action 
    NEPA requires the agency to provide a specific comparison of economic 
    benefits versus environmental costs. It concludes that the analysis of 
    the economic benefits of Order No. 888 is tipped in favor of benefits, 
    especially when contrasted with the analysis of projected environmental 
    impacts.
        Joint Commenters state that the conclusion that benefits will range 
    from $3.76 to $5.37 billion per year is not properly documented and 
    cannot be relied upon as justification for implementing the Rule 
    without mitigation. It contends that the Commission is counting 
    benefits from changes that are unrelated to the Rule, such as benefits 
    resulting from higher plant availability factors. Joint Commenters 
    claim that this assertion appears to be inconsistent with industry 
    reactions to competition to date. The same is true of planning reserve 
    margins. It states that key assumptions used to define the operating 
    savings, particularly fuel price assumptions, are unreasonable. It adds 
    that these savings are the ones that give rise to adverse environmental 
    effects due to increased utilization of existing low-cost coal 
    generation. Therefore, it is inappropriate to count these economic 
    benefits without examining the offsetting environmental costs, which 
    increase as the level of the asserted benefits increase.
        Finally, Joint Commenters assert that the FEIS does not address 
    potential costs associated with implementing the Rule. These include 
    costs to the Northeast and other regions of additional environmental 
    compliance and the impact on public health of additional pollution; 
    socioeconomic costs associated with utility downsizing; potential 
    adverse effects on nuclear power plant operations from competition; or 
    potential regulatory costs associated with compliance with Order No. 
    888. Thus, Joint Commenters conclude that the FEIS does not provide a 
    basis for calculating the net benefits of Order No. 888. It also states 
    that the FEIS does not provide a basis for concluding that the 
    potential savings will exceed the additional costs associated with 
    increased use of coal generation without mitigation.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The fulcrum of Joint Commenters' challenge is its claim that when 
    economic development is the selling point of a proposed action, NEPA 
    requires the agency to provide a specific comparison of economic 
    benefits versus environmental costs. The Joint Commenters do not 
    challenge the conclusion that the Rule will result in economic 
    benefits. Rather, it claims that the benefits identified in the FEIS 
    are not adequately substantiated and do not reflect a balanced analysis 
    of benefits versus costs. This argument is made to further the claim, 
    asserted by Joint Commenters in various forms, that the Commission must 
    impose mitigation to ``level'' the playing field.
        The Joint Commenters' argument misapprehends the purpose of Order 
    No. 888, the role a cost-benefit analysis plays in an EIS, and the 
    reasons for the Commission's discussion of the economic benefits of the 
    Rule.
        The purpose of the Rule is not to foster economic development, 
    although the Commission anticipates that this will be a salutary effect 
    of open access. The purpose of the Rule is to promote competition in 
    the wholesale bulk power markets by remedying undue discrimination in 
    access. The fact that the Rule will create benefits through better use 
    of existing assets and institutions, new market mechanisms, technical 
    innovation, and less rate distortion is a consequence rather than the 
    purpose of the Rule.
        The Joint Commenters also mistake the role a cost-benefit analysis 
    plays in an EIS. The CEQ regulations implementing NEPA set forth the 
    requirements pertaining to a cost-benefit analysis at 40 CFR 1502.23 
    (1996):
    
        If a cost-benefit analysis relevant to the choice among 
    environmentally different alternatives is being considered for the 
    proposed action, it shall be incorporated by reference or appended 
    to the statement as an aid in evaluating the environmental 
    consequences. To assess the adequacy of compliance with section 
    102(2)(B) of the Act the statement shall, when a cost-benefit 
    analysis is prepared, discuss the relationship between that analysis 
    and any analyses of unquantified environmental impacts, values, and 
    amenities. For purposes of complying with the Act, the weighing of 
    the merits and drawback of the various alternatives need not be 
    displayed in a monetary cost-benefit analysis and should not be when 
    there are important qualitative considerations. In any event, an 
    environmental impact statement should at least indicate those 
    considerations, including factors not related to environmental 
    quality, which are likely to be relevant and important to a 
    decision.
    
    Thus, the function of a cost-benefit analysis is to assist in the 
    choice among environmentally different alternatives. As discussed 
    above, the Commission's recitation in the FEIS of the anticipated 
    economic benefits of the Rule is not undertaken to assist in the choice 
    among environmental different alternatives. The FEIS discusses the 
    expected economic benefits of the Rule in a broader context, noting 
    that ``[t]he most important socioeconomic effect of the proposed rule 
    is expected to be potentially large benefits to ratepayers and to the 
    economy as a whole.'' 865
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \865\ FEIS at 5-64.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The authorities cited by the Joint Commenters do not alter this 
    conclusion. The Commission is not using the benefits of the Rule as a 
    selling point to go forward with the action while ignoring 
    disadvantages that might flow from it. The FEIS fully examines the 
    impacts of the Rule and concludes that implementation of the Rule will 
    not result in adverse environmental consequences. The Joint Commenters 
    disagreement is with this substantive conclusion, not with the alleged 
    failure to conduct a cost-benefit analysis. Their disagreement does not 
    mean, however, that the Commission has ignored the disadvantages that 
    Joint Commenters assert would flow from the Rule. In brief, as 
    discussed throughout the FEIS, Order No. 888, and this order on 
    rehearing, the Commission has examined the impacts of the Rule and
    
    [[Page 12456]]
    
    concluded that it will not result in environmental harms.
        Thus, even under the broadest possible interpretation of the cost-
    benefit analysis requirement, the Commission has evaluated the benefits 
    of the Rule against its impacts and concluded that the benefits are 
    likely to be significant and that the impacts are likely to be 
    insignificant.866
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \866\ In point of fact, the overall thrust of the FEIS is to 
    analyze and discuss the projected costs of the Rule. The discussion 
    of the projected benefits of the Rule comprise a tiny fraction of 
    that discussion. The Joint Commenters dissatisfaction with the 
    results of the analysis does not mean that the projected impacts of 
    the Rule were not discussed in full.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The D.C. Circuit rejected the underlying argument advanced here by 
    the Joint Commenters in Public Utilities Commission of the State of 
    California v. FERC, 900 F.2d 269 (D.C. Cir. 1990). There, California 
    contended that the Commission did not comply with NEPA in granting an 
    Optional Expedited Certificate (OEC) permitting construction of a 
    natural gas pipeline. California argued that the Commission could not 
    have balanced the adverse environmental effects against the need for 
    the project because under the OEC procedures it made no particularized 
    inquiry into the economic benefits of the pipeline. The court responded 
    that:
    
        Two of our cases speak of a NEPA requirement that ``responsible 
    decisionmakers *  *  * fully advert[] to the environmental 
    consequences'' of a proposed action and ``decide[] that the public 
    benefits *  *  * outweigh[] the[] environmental costs.'' Illinois 
    Commerce Comm'n v. ICC, 848 F.2d 1246, 1259 (D.C.Cir.1988); Jones v. 
    District of Columbia Redevelopment Land Agency, 499 F.2d 502, 512 
    (D.C.Cir.1974). Though the Commission engaged in an ``individualized 
    consideration and balancing of environmental factors,'' as required 
    by Calvert Cliffs' Coord. Comm. v. United States Atomic Energy 
    Comm'n, 449 F.2d 1109, 1115 (D.C.Cir.1971), its evaluation of the 
    nonenvironmental aspects of the pipeline was not individualized. As 
    to them the Commission stated that ``the interests of the public 
    articulated in our adoption of the optional certificate process 
    [i.e., Order No. 436] outweigh, on balance, the relatively 
    insubstantial environmental harm which will result from a properly 
    mitigated WyCal Pipeline.'' Mojave Pipeline Co., 46 FERC at 61,168 
    (emphasis added).
        California's insistence on a particularized assessment of non-
    environmental features finds no support in the statutory language. 
    See NEPA Sec. 102, 42 U.S.C. Sec. 4332 (requiring the agency to 
    consider a variety of environmental, not economic, factors). Its 
    theory would disable any number of efforts at streamlining the 
    resolution of regulatory issues that have nothing to do with the 
    environment. An agency's primary duty under the NEPA is to ``take[] 
    a 'hard look' at environmental consequences.'' Kleppe v. Sierra 
    Club, 427 U.S. 390, 410 n. 21, 96 S.Ct. 2718, 2730 n. 21, 49 L.Ed.2d 
    576 (1976). We will not extend that statute well beyond its realm so 
    as to create unnecessary conflicts with others. [867]
    
        \867\ Public Utilities Commission, 900 F.2d at 282 (brackets, 
    ellipses, and emphasis in original).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Thus, an agency need not conduct a particularized assessment of the 
    nonenvironmental features of a proposal, in particular its economic 
    benefits or costs. The Commission nonetheless examined the potential 
    costs of the Rule and determined that those costs will be very small 
    and may be positive instead of negative in any event. The Commission 
    has also examined the benefits of the project and concluded that it 
    will have substantial benefits. Accordingly, the request for rehearing 
    is denied.
    
    H. Socioeconomic Impacts
    
        The FEIS examines the socioeconomic impacts of the Rule, including 
    whether the Rule will result in regional shifts in economic activity 
    (especially electric generation and coal mining).868 The analysis 
    demonstrates that an effect of a more competitive industry may be 
    increased use of existing electric generating facilities. Consequently, 
    it seems likely that those who supply fuel to existing plants could see 
    a higher demand for their output as a result of the Rule. The FEIS 
    notes that this might not be true in all places, however, if factors 
    such as changes in environmental standards work in the opposite 
    direction. The FEIS does not attempt to measure local or site-specific 
    impacts given the speculative nature of such impacts.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \868\ FEIS at 5-64 and 5-75 through 5-76.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The FEIS also notes that open access could lead to changes in 
    employment patterns, but concludes that it is highly uncertain, 
    however, which changes are likely to result from restructuring.869 
    The FEIS notes that some changes should lead to cost reductions that 
    will tend to increase jobs in other industries, as well as lower rates 
    for other consumers. Lower power bills can make other industries more 
    competitive and lead them to increase employment.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \869\ Id. at 5-75 through 5-76.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The FEIS also notes that the Rule is only part of the restructuring 
    currently affecting the industry. Employment in traditional utilities 
    has fallen in recent years. Developments at the state and federal 
    levels will increase competition in the industry even without the Rule. 
    Given the highly uncertain nature of future developments in the 
    electric industry and the complex, dynamic economic issues involved, 
    the FEIS concludes that any quantitative estimate of changes in 
    employment (or even the direction of change) would be highly 
    speculative.
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        The PA Com claims that socioeconomic impacts that may result from 
    regional economic shifts occurring as a result of the Rule are not 
    adequately discussed in the FEIS. It states that Order No. 888 
    contemplates a reduction in the amount of coal-fired generation, and 
    that if Pennsylvania generation is shut-down or dispatched less often 
    in favor of generation that is not subject to the same environmental 
    costs and requirements, less Pennsylvania coal will be mined.
        The PA Com states that Pennsylvania produces 60 million tons of 
    coal a year, most of which is purchased by Pennsylvania electric 
    utilities. It alleges that the Pennsylvania coal industry provides 
    9,200 direct mining jobs and 9,500 support service jobs. Coal sales 
    contribute $1.5 billion to the Pennsylvania economy each year and 
    provide an annual payroll of $600 million. The PA Com adds that if coal 
    production declines, the state may curtail efforts to reclaim abandoned 
    mines and coal refuse piles.
        The PA Com also contends that social obligations now borne by 
    transmission owning utilities--demand side management programs, 
    integrated resource planning, low-income assistance programs, and 
    federal environmental mandates--have an impact upon price and the 
    market for power, and that utilities might view these obligations as an 
    impediment to competition. It claims that third parties who wish to use 
    the transmission system may balk if they are required to contribute to 
    those social goals.
        Finally, the PA Com claims that functional unbundling, open access 
    on a comparability basis, and increased competition may impact 
    reliability of service. It states that it is concerned that reliability 
    is subordinate to economic concerns, and that if reliability is not an 
    articulated foundation of FERC actions, system reliability may suffer. 
    It concludes that the FEIS assumes that reliability will be enhanced by 
    open access, but that this assumption is not adequately explained.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        The PA Com's concerns as to the alleged socioeconomic impacts of 
    the Rule are based on a series of tenuous economic ``what-ifs.'' It 
    assumes that the Rule will result in a reduction in Pennsylvania 
    generation. It assumes from this that less coal will be mined in
    
    [[Page 12457]]
    
    Pennsylvania and that Pennsylvania will suffer adverse economic 
    consequences. It then assumes that this might lead Pennsylvania to 
    curtail efforts to reclaim abandoned surface and strip mines. No basis 
    has been shown to support the elements in this chain of assumptions. 
    The effects Pennsylvania fears are simply too speculative to assess at 
    this time.
        Moreover, the PA Com's concerns stem from the postulated economic 
    impacts of the Rule rather than from the alleged impact of the Rule on 
    the physical environment. Thus, its concerns are not proper for 
    consideration in an EIS. The CEQ states that socioeconomic impacts 
    alone do not warrant study in an EIS.870 The CEQ also states that 
    an agency must make reasonable efforts in preparing an EIS to acquire 
    relevant information concerning socioeconomic impacts when economic or 
    social and natural or physical environmental effects are 
    interrelated.871 If such effects are not interrelated, they need 
    not be considered. In this case, the PA Com's concerns stem from what 
    it anticipates will be the economic impact of the Rule on Pennsylvania, 
    and not from the natural or physical environmental impacts of the Rule. 
    Thus, these concerns are not proper for consideration in an 
    EIS.872
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \870\ The CEQ regulations, 40 CFR 1508.14 (1996), state that 
    ``economic or social effects are not intended by themselves to 
    require preparation of an environmental impact statement.'' See also 
    Panhandle Producers & Royalty Owners Association v. Economic 
    Regulatory Administration, 847 F.2d 1168, 1179 (5th Cir. 1988); 
    Olmstead Citizens for a Better Community v. United States, 793 F.2d 
    201, 205 (8th Cir. 1986).
        \871\ The CEQ regulations, 40 CFR 1508.14 (1996), provide that 
    ``[w]hen an environmental impact statement is prepared and economic 
    or social and natural or physical environmental effects are 
    interrelated, then the environmental impact statement will discuss 
    all of these effects on the human environment.'' This limitation has 
    been read very strictly. In Stauber v. Shalala, 895 F.Supp. 1178, 
    1194 (W.D.Wis.1995), for example, the court responded to a claim 
    that a proposed action would cause both environmental and 
    socioeconomic harms and that for this reason an EIS was necessary. 
    The court found that:
        This assertion is insufficient to satisfy the 
    ``interrelatedness'' requirement of Sec. 1508.14. I read 40 C.F.R. 
    Sec. 1508.14 to mean that it is only after an agency determines that 
    the socioeconomic impact of the proposed agency action is likely to 
    cause environmental harms itself that the agency needs to discuss 
    the socioeconomic effects in the environmental impact statement. See 
    Breckinridge v. Rumsfield, 537 F.2d 864, 866 (6th Cir.1976) 
    (accord), cert. denied, 429 U.S. 1061, 97 S.Ct. 785, 50 L.Ed.2d 777 
    (1977). This reading fully comports with the plain language of the 
    regulation. * * *
        \872\ It is interesting to note in this regard that Pennsylvania 
    recently adopted electric restructuring legislation of its own 
    establishing retail wheeling. It thus became the fourth state in the 
    Northeast to do so; the others are Massachusetts, Rhode Island, and 
    New Hampshire. The legislation was described by the Governor of 
    Pennsylvania as creating a ``critical competitive advantage'' for 
    Pennsylvania. The Energy Daily, December 4, 1996.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The approach to such issues is perhaps best symbolized by the 
    Supreme Court's decision in Metropolitan Edison Co. v. People Against 
    Nuclear Energy, 460 U.S. 766 (1983). In that case, People Against 
    Nuclear Energy (PANE) contended that NEPA required the Nuclear 
    Regulatory Commission to consider whether restarting the Three Mile 
    Island-1 nuclear reactor after the accident at the Three Mile Island-2 
    reactor would ``cause both severe psychological health damage to 
    persons living in the vicinity, and serious damage to the stability, 
    cohesiveness, and well-being of the neighboring communities.'' 873 
    The court rejected this argument:
    
        \873\ Metropolitan Edison Co., 460 U.S. at 769. PANE also 
    asserted that NEPA required consideration of ``[t]he perception, 
    created by the accident, that the communities near Three Mile Island 
    are undesirable locations for business or industry, or for the 
    establishment of law or medical practice, or homes compounds the 
    damage to the viability of the communities.'' Id. at 770 n.2.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The theme of Sec. 102 is sounded by the adjective 
    ``environmental'': NEPA does not require the agency to assess every 
    impact or effect of its proposed action, but only the impact or 
    effect on the environment. If we were to seize the word 
    ``environmental'' out of its context and give it the broadest 
    possible definition, the words ``adverse environmental effects'' 
    might embrace virtually any consequence of a governmental action 
    that someone thought ``adverse.'' But we think the context of the 
    statute shows that Congress was talking about the physical 
    environment--the world around us, so to speak. NEPA was designed to 
    promote human welfare by alerting governmental actors to the effect 
    of their proposed actions on the physical environment.
    
    * * * Thus, although NEPA states its goals in sweeping terms of 
    human health and welfare, those goals are ends that Congress has 
    chosen to pursue by means of protecting the physical environment. 
    [874]
    
        \874\ Id. at 772-73 (emphasis in original) (footnote omitted). 
    The continuing validity of the argument that socioeconomic effects 
    are to be considered in an EIS if the federal action has a primary 
    impact on the natural environment is doubtful. The court in Olmsted 
    Citizens for a Better Community v. United States, 793 F.2d 201, 206 
    (8th Cir. 1986) stated that:
        [I]t is unlikely that such a distinction survives the recent 
    Supreme Court holding in Metropolitan Edison. That decision, as 
    discussed above, was based on congressional intent, and there is no 
    suggestion that Congress contemplated that the process it designed 
    to make agencies aware of the consequences of their actions with 
    regard to the physical environment would be converted into a process 
    for airing general policy objections anytime the physical 
    environment was implicated. Such a rule would divert agency 
    resources away from the primary statutory goal of protecting the 
    physical environment and natural resources. * * *
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Even though it was not incumbent upon it to do so, the Commission 
    analyzed the concerns raised by the PA Com to the extent it was 
    practicable to do so. The impacts of the Rule on future levels of coal-
    fired generation in Pennsylvania or on employment in a specific 
    geographic area or in a specific economic sector are influenced by a 
    virtually unlimited roster of other factors, and thus are too 
    speculative to be useful.
    
    I. Coastal Zone Management Act
    
        Order No. 888 found that the Rule does not constitute a federal 
    activity subject to compliance with the Coastal Zone Management Act, 16 
    U.S.C. Sec. 1451 et seq. (CZMA). 875 Order No. 888 concluded that:
    
        \875\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,895; mimeo at 754.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Connecticut has in any event waived its right to request a 
    consistency determination for the Commission's rulemaking. 
    Connecticut's coastal management program's list of federal agency 
    activities likely to require a consistency determination does not 
    (for good reason) describe rulemakings of this kind, and the rule 
    will not ``result in a significant change in air or water quality 
    within the management area'' (the program's catch-all category). In 
    addition, Connecticut did not notify the Commission of its 
    conclusion that the Rule requires a consistency determination until 
    well after 45 days from receipt of several notices of the rulemaking 
    proceeding. Consequently, pursuant to 15 CFR 930.35(b), Connecticut 
    has in any event waived its right to request a consistency 
    determination for this rulemaking. [ 876]
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \876\ Id. at 31,895-96; mimeo at 755-56 (footnote omitted).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Rehearing Requests
    
        The Connecticut Department of Environmental Protection (Connecticut 
    DEP) requests that the Commission determine whether Order No. 888 is a 
    federal activity requiring a coastal consistency determination, 
    determine whether the Rule is consistent with Connecticut's coastal 
    management plan (CMP), and consider the impacts that promoting 
    competition and altering transmission and generation patterns may have 
    on water quality in the Long Island Sound. The Connecticut DEP also 
    requests that the Commission mitigate potential increases in nitrogen 
    and sulphur oxide emissions occurring as a result of the Rule.
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
        On August 20, 1996, the Commission responded to the Connecticut 
    DEP, issuing a consistency determination and a negative determination. 
    The response notes that the FEIS focuses on the concerns raised by the 
    Connecticut DEP and concludes that the most important factor 
    determining changes in future emissions is the relative competitive
    
    [[Page 12458]]
    
    position (e.g., price) of coal and natural gas. Depending on the 
    relative prices of these fuels, emissions from electric generating 
    facilities may increase slightly or decrease slightly. Regional 
    effects, including those for the region encompassing Connecticut, are 
    projected to be similar. The response also notes that these estimates 
    fall within the ``noise'' level of the model. That is, they are smaller 
    than the uncertainties in the science underlying the model.
        Thus, the response concludes that the Rule will not have an effect 
    on the land and water uses or natural resources of Connecticut. 
    Accordingly, the Commission issued a negative determination pursuant to 
    the regulations implementing the CZMA, 15 CFR 930.35(d). 877
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \877\ In issuing a negative determination, the Commission noted 
    that it questioned whether the CZMA applies to economic regulatory 
    activities involving interstate electric rates and service. The 
    Commission also noted that Connecticut had waived its right to 
    request a consistency determination or negative determination by 
    failing to notify the Commission of its request within 45 days from 
    receipt of the notice of the federal activity. The Commission 
    concluded that it did not waive those arguments by providing 
    Connecticut with a consistency determination and negative 
    determination.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The response also notes that even if the Rule were to have a 
    minimal effect on Connecticut's coastal zone, the Rule is consistent to 
    the maximum extent practicable with the enforceable policies of the 
    Connecticut Coastal Management Plan (Connecticut Plan). The Connecticut 
    Coastal Management Act and supporting policies which provide the basis 
    for the Connecticut Plan require that activities be consistent with the 
    Clean Air Act. The Connecticut Plan provides that activities are not 
    assumed to directly affect Connecticut, and thus do not require a 
    consistency determination, unless they ``would result in a significant 
    change in air or water quality.''
        The August 20, 1996 response concludes that the Rule is consistent 
    with the requirements of the Clean Air Act and will not result in a 
    significant change in air or water quality in Connecticut. In fact, 
    depending on the future prices of fuel, the Rule is equally likely to 
    improve air quality over Connecticut and decrease emissions deposition 
    in the waters of the Long Island Sound. Thus, the Rule is consistent 
    with the Connecticut Plan regardless of any slight effects it may have.
        Finally, the response notes that the action sought by Connecticut 
    DEP to ensure consistency with the Connecticut Plan has already been 
    taken in any event. Following issuance of the Rule, EPA, the federal 
    agency charged with implementing the Clean Air Act, stated that it 
    would use its authority to comprehensively address NOX emissions, 
    including any potential incremental increases in emissions that might 
    result from implementation of the Rule, in the 37-state region that 
    makes up the Ozone Transport Assessment Group. This region includes 
    Connecticut. In an Order issued May 29, 1996, the Commission agreed to 
    examine the issue of mitigation of the impacts, if any, of the Rule in 
    the event that EPA and the OTAG states are unsuccessful in addressing 
    the NOX problem.
        Thus, the FEIS demonstrates that the Rule will not have an effect 
    on any land or water use or natural resource of Connecticut's coastal 
    zone. Moreover, the Rule is consistent with Connecticut's CMP. Finally, 
    EPA and the Commission have taken the action sought by Connecticut DEP 
    to ensure consistency with Connecticut's CMP. These actions fully 
    address Connecticut DEP's coastal zone concerns.
    
    VI. Regulatory Flexibility Act Certification
    
        The Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA) 878 requires rulemakings 
    to either contain a description and analysis of the effect that the 
    proposed or final rule will have on small entities or to contain a 
    certification that the rule will not have a significant economic impact 
    on a substantial number of small entities. In the Open Access and 
    Stranded Cost Final Rules, the Commission certified that the final 
    rules would not impose a significant economic impact on a substantial 
    number of small entities.879
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \878\ 5 U.S.C. Sec. 601-612.
        \879\ Open Access Rule, 61 FR 21540 at 21691 (May 10, 1996), 
    FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 31,036 at 31,898 (1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        NRECA and SBA question this certification.880 According to 
    NRECA there are about 1,000 rural electric cooperatives and 2,000 
    municipal electric systems, most of which meet the RFA definition of 
    small electric entity. NRECA states that the Commission has imposed 
    open access, OASIS and code of conduct requirements on non-public 
    utilities. NRECA maintains that if non-public utilities do not meet 
    these requirements, ``they will not retain access over the long-term to 
    the nation's bulk power transmission grid--access they must have if 
    they wish to stay in business.'' 881
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \880\ The SBA filed its Request for Rehearing on June 10, 1996, 
    after the statutory deadline for the filing of such a pleading. 
    Accordingly, we will not accept its pleading as a request for 
    rehearing but will, instead, treat it as a motion for 
    reconsideration.
        On November 1, 1996, NRECA filed a supplement to its Requests 
    for Rehearing and Clarifications. We will reject the supplement to 
    the request for rehearing as barred by the 30 day time limit for 
    filing petitions for reconsideration. Neither the Commission nor the 
    courts can waive a failure to comply with the statute. See Platte 
    River Whooping Crane Critical Habitat Maintenance Trust v. FERC, 876 
    F.2d 109, 113 (D.C. Cir. 1989); Tennessee Gas Pipeline Company v. 
    FERC, 871 F. 2d 1099, 1107 (D.C. Cir. 1989); Boston Gas Company v. 
    FERC, 575 F.2d 975 (1st Cir. 1978). Accord Commonwealth Electric 
    Company v. Boston Edison Company, 46 FERC para. 61,253 at 61,757, 
    reh'g denied, 47 FERC para. 61,118 (1989). We will accept NRECA's 
    supplemental request for clarifications.
        \881\ NRECA at 42-43.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        NRECA also contends that the stranded cost issue will affect small 
    non-public utilities ``any time a non-public utility is required to 
    render reciprocal transmission service, and loses a customer as a 
    result of rendering that service, or a TDU [transmission dependent 
    utility] loses a customer to an open access public utility transmission 
    provider.'' 882 NRECA asserts that both the OASIS Final Rule and 
    the Capacity Reservation Tariff NOPR 883 will substantially burden 
    small non-public utilities.884 NRECA further maintains that the 
    Commission's waiver provisions will not alleviate the burden on small 
    utilities. It states that filing a waiver request with the Commission 
    is burdensome for small utilities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \882\ NRECA at 44.
        \883\ Capacity Reservation Open Access Transmission Tariffs, 
    Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, IV FERC Stats. & Regs Proposed 
    Regulations para. 32,519 (1996), 61 FR 21847 (May 10, 1996) 
    (Capacity Reservation).
        \884\ We will discuss NRECA's arguments concerning the OASIS 
    Final Rule in our order on rehearing in that proceeding. We reject 
    NRECA's reference to the Capacity Tariff Reservation NOPR as 
    inapposite to this proceeding. We have invited comments on the 
    proposed Capacity Reservation Open Access Transmission Tariffs 
    (Capacity Reservation, IV FERC Stats. & Regs. Proposed Regulations 
    at 33,235, 61 FR 21847 at 21853) and will discuss those comments in 
    the appropriate proceeding.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        SBA states that 30 percent (50 of 166) of public utilities are 
    small under the SBA's definition of a small public electric 
    utility.885 SBA contends that if, as the Commission has found, 11 
    percent of public utilities are small, the Final Rules will still 
    affect a significant number of small public utilities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \885\ SBA Request for Reconsideration at 5. The SBA defines a 
    small public electric utility as one that disposes of 4 Million MWh 
    per year. 13 CFR 121.201.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        SBA challenges the Commission's reliance on Mid-Tex Electric 
    Cooperative, Inc. v. FERC.886 It contends that the Commission 
    should have analyzed the probable effect of the Final Rules on small 
    businesses by projecting, perhaps on the model of the deregulated
    
    [[Page 12459]]
    
    telecommunications industry, how many small electric utilities, as the 
    SBA defines that term, would enter the deregulated electric utility 
    market.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \886\ 773 F.2d 327 (D.C. Cir. 1985) (Mid-Tex).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Commission Conclusion
    
    A. Docket No. RM95-8-000 (Open Access Final Rule)
    
    1. Public Utilities
        In the Open Access Final Rule we determined that the Rule applies:
    
    to public utilities that own, control or operate interstate 
    transmission facilities, not to electric utilities per se. The total 
    number of public utilities that, absent waiver, would have to have 
    open access tariffs on file is 166. Of these, only 50 public 
    utilities dispose of 4 million MWh or less per year. Eliminating 
    those utilities that are affiliates of other utilities whose sales 
    exceed 4 million MWh or less per year, or are not independently 
    owned, the total number of public utilities affected by the Open 
    Access Final Rule that qualify under the SBA's definition of small 
    electric utility is 19 or 11 percent of the total number of public 
    utilities that would have to have on file open access 
    tariffs.887
    
        \887\ FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,897 (1996)(footnotes omitted); 
    mimeo at 758-59.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We do not agree with the SBA that 11 percent of all of the public 
    utilities that would have to file open access tariffs with us is a 
    significant number. Also, the SBA has overlooked several of the other 
    findings we made as to the possible effect of the Open Access Final 
    Rule on small public utilities. As we noted, of the 19 public utilities 
    that would come within the SBA's definition of small electric utility, 
    five have already filed open access tariffs with the Commission, so 
    that the effect of the Open Access Rule on these utilities should not 
    be significant.888
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \888\ Id. at n.1078.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Further, the Commission is specifying the non-rate terms and 
    conditions of the tariffs that public utilities must file, so all 
    public utilities need to do is file a rate, and the small public 
    utilities with open access tariffs already on file with us need not 
    even do that. They may elect to continue service under the Open Access 
    Final Rule's non-rate terms and conditions at their existing rates. In 
    our Final Rule we estimated that the cost for filing a rate would not, 
    on average, exceed one half of one percent of total annual sales for 
    small electric utilities,889 which is not a significant economic 
    impact.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \889\ Id. at n.1081.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We disagree with SBA that our reliance on Mid-Tex is misplaced. In 
    Mid-Tex, the court accepted the Commission's conclusion that virtually 
    all of the public utilities that the Commission regulates do not fall 
    within the RFA's meaning of the term ``small entities.'' Mid-Tex 
    involved a rule that applies to all public utilities. The Open Access 
    Final Rule applies to only those public utilities that own, control or 
    operate interstate transmission facilities, which are a subset of the 
    group of public utilities for which Mid-Tex did not require the 
    preparation of a regulatory flexibility analysis.890
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \890\ Mid-Tex, 773 F. 2d at 340-43.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        SBA attempts to distinguish Mid-Tex by postulating that the 
    Commission should have attempted to predict how many new entrants into 
    a deregulated market would be small electric utilities, within the 
    SBA's meaning of that term. Mid-Tex held just the opposite, deciding 
    squarely that an agency need only consider the businesses that a 
    regulation directly affects.891 There is no precedent for SBA's 
    suggestion that the Commission must engage in a hypothetical projection 
    of how many entrants likely to enter a deregulated market may be small 
    electric utilities, and we know of no satisfactory way of making such a 
    projection. Entry into the telecommunications industry, which the SBA 
    offers as a model, involves very different costs, distribution and 
    marketing patterns and entirely different technology. There is no way, 
    from looking at what has happened in the telecommunications industry, 
    that the Commission could project, with any degree of accuracy, how 
    many small electric utilities, if any, will enter the market following 
    the effective date of the Final Open Access Rule.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \891\ Id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Finally, SBA overlooks, and NRECA unreasonably discounts, the 
    effect that the Commission's waiver rules have on relieving the burden 
    of the Open Access Final Rule on small entities.892 The Commission 
    has recently issued a number of orders waiving the requirements of the 
    Open Access Final Rule for a number of small electric 
    utilities.893 As these cases show, the Commission is carefully 
    evaluating the effect of the Open Access Final Rule on small electric 
    utilities and is granting waivers where appropriate, thus mitigating 
    the economic effect of that rule on small entities. Indeed, as we noted 
    in Order No. 888, 5 small public utilities previously had filed open 
    access tariffs, and we have since, in the cases cited above, granted 
    waivers to approximately 17 small public utilities.894
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \892\ The Commission's waiver policy follows the SBA definition 
    of small electric utility. See 5 U.S.C. Sec. 601(3) and 601(6) and 
    15 U.S.C. Sec. 632(a). The RFA defines a small entity as one that is 
    independently owned and not dominant in its field of operation. See 
    15 U.S.C. Sec. 632(a). The SBA defines a small electric utility as 
    one that disposes of 4 million MWh or less of electric energy in a 
    given year. See 13 CFR 121.601 (Major Group 49-Electric, Gas and 
    Sanitary Services) (1995).
        \893\ Northern States Power Company, 76 FERC para. 61,250 
    (1996); Central Electric Cooperative, et al., 77 FERC para. 61,076 
    (1996); Black Creek Hydro, et al., 77 FERC 61,232 (1996); Dakota 
    Electric Association, et al., 78 FERC para. 61,117 (1997); Soyland 
    Power Cooperative, Inc., et al., 78 FERC para. 61,095 (1997); 
    Niobrara Valley Electric Membership Cooperation, Docket Nos. OA96-
    146-001 and ER97-1412-000, Letter Order issued February 26, 1997.
        \894\ These total more that the 19 small public utilities we 
    referenced in Order No. 888 because, since the issuance of that 
    order, several entities have repaid their RUS-financed debt and 
    become public utilities subject to our jurisdiction and several new 
    public utilities have been created as the result of the construction 
    of new facilities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    2. Non-Public Utilities
        We disagree with NRECA's argument that Order No. 888 imposes 
    burdens upon non-public utilities. As we noted in the Final Rule, we do 
    not have jurisdiction to regulate non-public utilities' rates, terms 
    and conditions of transmission service under sections 205 and 206 of 
    the FPA, and there is no requirement in Order No. 888 that non-public 
    utilities file open access tariffs.895
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \895\ See United Distribution Companies v. FERC, 88 F.3d 1105, 
    1170 (July 16, 1996) (``FERC had no obligation to conduct a small 
    entity impact analysis of effects on entities which it does not 
    regulate.'').
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In addition, under the waiver provisions of the Open Access Final 
    Rule, small non-public utilities may seek waiver from the reciprocity 
    provision. As reflected in the cases cited above, the Commission has 
    granted waivers of the reciprocity provision to 10 small non-public 
    electric utilities and issued disclaimers of jurisdiction with respect 
    to 19 small electric utilities, thus mitigating the effect of the Open 
    Access Final Rule on small non-public electric utilities.
    
    B. Docket No. RM94-7-000 (Stranded Cost Final Rule)
    
    1. Public Utilities
        No rehearing requests addressed this matter.
    2. Non-Public Utilities
        In Order No. 888, the Commission indicated that the Stranded Cost 
    Final Rule will not impose a significant economic impact on a 
    substantial number of non-public utility small entities because the 
    stranded cost issue would only arise in a proceeding under sections 211 
    and 212 of the FPA when, in directing transmission, the Commission 
    addresses the stranded cost issue in determining a just and reasonable 
    rate. NRECA counters that the stranded cost issue will ``arise: any 
    time a non-public utility is required to
    
    [[Page 12460]]
    
    render reciprocal transmission service, and loses a customer as a 
    result of rendering that service, or a TDU loses a customer to an open 
    access public utility transmission provider.'' 896 NRECA submits 
    that the adverse economic impact on small non-public utilities will 
    ``arise'' from the stranding of costs, not from the utilities' 
    participation in proceedings at the Commission, and that the Commission 
    ``cannot in good conscience fail at least to probe the potential 
    adverse economic impact on small non-public utilities of the stranded 
    costs they incur as a direct result of Order No. 888.''
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \896\ NRECA at 44.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Notwithstanding NRECA's argument that small non-public utilities 
    may experience stranded costs outside of a section 211/212 proceeding, 
    as we explain in Section IV.J.1, supra, our jurisdiction over the 
    recovery of stranded costs by non-public utilities, and thus our 
    ability to permit an opportunity for recovery of such costs, is limited 
    by statute. With the exception of our section 210 interconnection and 
    sections 211-212 transmission rate jurisdiction, we do not have 
    jurisdiction over the rates of non-public utilities. Because the 
    stranded cost issue would primarily arise as to non-public utilities 
    over which the Commission has jurisdiction in a proceeding under 
    sections 211 and 212 of the FPA when, in directing transmission, the 
    Commission addresses the stranded cost issue in determining a just and 
    reasonable rate,897 we concluded that the Stranded Cost Final Rule 
    will not impose a significant economic impact on a substantial number 
    of non-public utility small entities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \897\ Stranded costs could also conceivably arise as a result of 
    an ordered interconnection under section 210. However, the rates for 
    such an interconnection would be established pursuant to section 212 
    and could therefore also include stranded costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Because the Commission does not have rate jurisdiction over non-
    public utilities other than through sections 210, 211 and 212, the 
    Commission does not have the authority to allow them to recover 
    stranded costs other than through rates set under section 212. However, 
    we clarify that nothing in the Final Rule was intended to preclude non-
    public utilities from including stranded cost provisions in voluntary 
    reciprocity tariffs or from otherwise recovering stranded costs under 
    applicable law. Thus, a non-public utility that chooses voluntarily to 
    offer an open access tariff for purposes of demonstrating that it meets 
    the reciprocity provision can include a stranded cost provision in its 
    tariff. However, adjudication of any stranded cost claims under that 
    tariff is not subject to the Commission's jurisdiction.898 If a 
    non-public utility wishes to recover stranded costs pursuant to a 
    tariff or otherwise, it can seek to do so subject to the review of the 
    appropriate regulatory or judicial authority.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \898\ Although the Commission would not determine the rate, 
    including the stranded cost component of the rate, of a non-public 
    utility, we would review a public utility's claim that it is 
    entitled to deny service to a non-public utility because the 
    stranded cost component of the non-public utility's transmission 
    rate is being applied in a way that violates the principle of 
    comparability.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    VII. Information Collection Statement
    
        Order No. 888 contained an information collection statement for 
    which the Commission obtained approval from the Office of Management 
    and Budget (OMB).899 Given that this order on rehearing makes only 
    minor revisions to Order No. 888, none of which is substantive, OMB 
    approval for this order will not be necessary. However, the Commission 
    will send a copy of this order to OMB, for informational purposes only.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \899\ One need not respond to a collection of information unless 
    it displays a valid OMB control number. The OMB control number for 
    this collection of information is 1902-0096.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The information reporting requirements under this order are 
    virtually unchanged from those contained in Order No. 888. Interested 
    persons may obtain information on the reporting requirements by 
    contacting the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street, 
    N.E., Washington, D.C. 20426 [Attention Michael Miller, Information 
    Services Division, (202) 208-1415], and the Office of Management and 
    Budget [Attention: Desk Officer for the Federal Energy Regulatory 
    Commission (202) 395-3087].
    
    VIII. Effective Date
    
        Changes to Order No. 888 made in this order on rehearing will 
    become effective on May 13, 1997.
    
    List of Subjects 18 CFR Part 35
    
        Electric power rates, Electric utilities, Reporting and 
    recordkeeping requirements.
    
        By the Commission. Commissioners Hoecker and Massey dissented in 
    part with separate statements attached.
    Lois D. Cashell,
    Secretary.
    
        In consideration of the foregoing, the Commission amends part 35, 
    chapter I, title 18 of the Code of Federal Regulations, as set forth 
    below.
    
    PART 35--FILING OF RATE SCHEDULES
    
        1. The authority citation for part 35 continues to read as follows:
    
        Authority: 16 U.S.C. 791a-825r, 2601-2645; 31 U.S.C. 9701; 42 
    U.S.C. 7101-7352.
    
        2. Part 35 is amended by revising Sec. 35.26 to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 35.26  Recovery of stranded costs by public utilities and 
    transmitting utilities.
    
        (a) Purpose. This section establishes the standards that a public 
    utility or transmitting utility must satisfy in order to recover 
    stranded costs.
        (b) Definitions.--(1) Wholesale stranded cost means any legitimate, 
    prudent and verifiable cost incurred by a public utility or a 
    transmitting utility to provide service to:
        (i) A wholesale requirements customer that subsequently becomes, in 
    whole or in part, an unbundled wholesale transmission services customer 
    of such public utility or transmitting utility; or
        (ii) A retail customer that subsequently becomes, either directly 
    or through another wholesale transmission purchaser, an unbundled 
    wholesale transmission services customer of such public utility or 
    transmitting utility.
        (2) Wholesale requirements customer means a customer for whom a 
    public utility or transmitting utility provides by contract any portion 
    of its bundled wholesale power requirements.
        (3) Wholesale transmission services means the transmission of 
    electric energy sold, or to be sold, at wholesale in interstate 
    commerce or ordered pursuant to section 211 of the Federal Power Act 
    (FPA).
        (4) Wholesale requirements contract means a contract under which a 
    public utility or transmitting utility provides any portion of a 
    customer's bundled wholesale power requirements.
        (5) Retail stranded cost means any legitimate, prudent and 
    verifiable cost incurred by a public utility to provide service to a 
    retail customer that subsequently becomes, in whole or in part, an 
    unbundled retail transmission services customer of that public utility.
        (6) Retail transmission services means the transmission of electric 
    energy sold, or to be sold, in interstate commerce directly to a retail 
    customer.
        (7) New wholesale requirements contract means any wholesale 
    requirements contract executed after July 11, 1994, or extended or 
    renegotiated to be effective after July 11, 1994.
        (8) Existing wholesale requirements contract means any wholesale
    
    [[Page 12461]]
    
    requirements contract executed on or before July 11, 1994.
        (c) Recovery of wholesale stranded costs.--(1) General requirement. 
    A public utility or transmitting utility will be allowed to seek 
    recovery of wholesale stranded costs only as follows:
        (i) No public utility or transmitting utility may seek recovery of 
    wholesale stranded costs if such recovery is explicitly prohibited by a 
    contract or settlement agreement, or by any power sales or transmission 
    rate schedule or tariff.
        (ii) No public utility or transmitting utility may seek recovery of 
    stranded costs associated with a new wholesale requirements contract if 
    such contract does not contain an exit fee or other explicit stranded 
    cost provision.
        (iii) If wholesale stranded costs are associated with a new 
    wholesale requirements contract containing an exit fee or other 
    explicit stranded cost provision, and the seller under the contract is 
    a public utility, the public utility may seek recovery of such costs, 
    in accordance with the contract, through rates for electric energy 
    under sections 205-206 of the FPA. The public utility may not seek 
    recovery of such costs through any transmission rate for FPA section 
    205 or 211 transmission services.
        (iv) If wholesale stranded costs are associated with a new 
    wholesale requirements contract, and the seller under the contract is a 
    transmitting utility but not also a public utility, the transmitting 
    utility may not seek an order from the Commission allowing recovery of 
    such costs.
        (v) If wholesale stranded costs are associated with an existing 
    wholesale requirements contract, if the seller under such contract is a 
    public utility, and if the contract does not contain an exit fee or 
    other explicit stranded cost provision, the public utility may seek 
    recovery of stranded costs only as follows:
        (A) If either party to the contract seeks a stranded cost amendment 
    pursuant to a section 205 or section 206 filing under the FPA made 
    prior to the expiration of the contract, and the Commission accepts or 
    approves an amendment permitting recovery of stranded costs, the public 
    utility may seek recovery of such costs through FPA section 205-206 
    rates for electric energy.
        (B) If the contract is not amended to permit recovery of stranded 
    costs as described in paragraph (c)(1)(v)(A) of this section, the 
    public utility may file a proposal, prior to the expiration of the 
    contract, to recover stranded costs through FPA section 205-206 or 
    section 211-212 rates for wholesale transmission services to the 
    customer.
        (vi) If wholesale stranded costs are associated with an existing 
    wholesale requirements contract, if the seller under such contract is a 
    transmitting utility but not also a public utility, and if the contract 
    does not contain an exit fee or other explicit stranded cost provision, 
    the transmitting utility may seek recovery of stranded costs through 
    FPA section 211-212 transmission rates.
        (vii) If a retail customer becomes a legitimate wholesale 
    transmission customer of a public utility or transmitting utility, 
    e.g., through municipalization, and costs are stranded as a result of 
    the retail-turned-wholesale customer's access to wholesale 
    transmission, the utility may seek recovery of such costs through FPA 
    section 205-206 or section 211-212 rates for wholesale transmission 
    services to that customer.
        (2) Evidentiary demonstration for wholesale stranded cost recovery. 
    A public utility or transmitting utility seeking to recover wholesale 
    stranded costs in accordance with paragraphs (c)(1) (v) through (vii) 
    of this section must demonstrate that:
        (i) It incurred costs to provide service to a wholesale 
    requirements customer or retail customer based on a reasonable 
    expectation that the utility would continue to serve the customer;
        (ii) The stranded costs are not more than the customer would have 
    contributed to the utility had the customer remained a wholesale 
    requirements customer of the utility, or, in the case of a retail-
    turned-wholesale customer, had the customer remained a retail customer 
    of the utility; and
        (iii) The stranded costs are derived using the following formula: 
    Stranded Cost Obligation = (Revenue Stream Estimate--Competitive Market 
    Value Estimate)  x  Length of Obligation (reasonable expectation 
    period).
        (3) Rebuttable presumption. If a public utility or transmitting 
    utility seeks recovery of wholesale stranded costs associated with an 
    existing wholesale requirements contract, as permitted in paragraph 
    (c)(1) of this section, and the existing wholesale requirements 
    contract contains a notice provision, there will be a rebuttable 
    presumption that the utility had no reasonable expectation of 
    continuing to serve the customer beyond the term of the notice 
    provision.
        (4) Procedure for customer to obtain stranded cost estimate. A 
    customer under an existing wholesale requirements contract with a 
    public utility seller may obtain from the seller an estimate of the 
    customer's stranded cost obligation if it were to leave the public 
    utility's generation supply system by filing with the public utility a 
    request for an estimate at any time prior to the termination date 
    specified in its contract.
        (i) The public utility must provide a response within 30 days of 
    receiving the request. The response must include:
        (A) An estimate of the customer's stranded cost obligation based on 
    the formula in paragraph (c)(2)(iii) of this section;
        (B) Supporting detail indicating how each element in the formula 
    was derived;
        (C) A detailed rationale justifying the basis for the utility's 
    reasonable expectation of continuing to serve the customer beyond the 
    termination date in the contract;
        (D) An estimate of the amount of released capacity and associated 
    energy that would result from the customer's departure; and
        (E) The utility's proposal for any contract amendment needed to 
    implement the customer's payment of stranded costs.
        (ii) If the customer disagrees with the utility's response, it must 
    respond to the utility within 30 days explaining why it disagrees. If 
    the parties cannot work out a mutually agreeable resolution, they may 
    exercise their rights to Commission resolution under the FPA.
        (5) A customer must be given the option to market or broker a 
    portion or all of the capacity and energy associated with any stranded 
    costs claimed by the public utility.
        (i) To exercise the option, the customer must so notify the utility 
    in writing no later than 30 days after the public utility files its 
    estimate of stranded costs for the customer with the Commission.
        (A) Before marketing or brokering can begin, the utility and 
    customer must execute an agreement identifying, at a minimum, the 
    amount and the price of capacity and associated energy the customer is 
    entitled to schedule, and the duration of the customer's marketing or 
    brokering of such capacity and energy.
        (ii) If agreement over marketing or brokering cannot be reached, 
    and the parties seek Commission resolution of disputed issues, upon 
    issuance of a Commission order resolving the disputed issues, the 
    customer may reevaluate its decision in paragraph (c)(5)(i) of this 
    section to exercise the marketing or brokering option. The customer 
    must notify the utility in writing within 30 days of issuance of the 
    Commission's order resolving the disputed issues whether the customer 
    will market or broker a portion or all of
    
    [[Page 12462]]
    
    the capacity and energy associated with stranded costs allowed by the 
    Commission.
        (iii) If a customer undertakes the brokering option, and the 
    customer's brokering efforts fail to produce a buyer within 60 days of 
    the date of the brokering agreement entered into between the customer 
    and the utility, the customer shall relinquish all rights to broker the 
    released capacity and associated energy and will pay stranded costs as 
    determined by the formula in paragraph (c)(2)(iii) of this section.
        (d) Recovery of retail stranded costs--(1) General requirement. A 
    public utility may seek to recover retail stranded costs through rates 
    for retail transmission services only if the state regulatory authority 
    does not have authority under state law to address stranded costs at 
    the time the retail wheeling is required.
        (2) Evidentiary demonstration necessary for retail stranded cost 
    recovery. A public utility seeking to recover retail stranded costs in 
    accordance with paragraph (d)(1) of this section must demonstrate that:
        (i) It incurred costs to provide service to a retail customer that 
    obtains retail wheeling based on a reasonable expectation that the 
    utility would continue to serve the customer; and
        (ii) The stranded costs are not more than the customer would have 
    contributed to the utility had the customer remained a retail customer 
    of the utility.
    
        Note: Appendices A and B and statements of Commissioners Hoecker 
    and Massey will not be published in the Code of Federal Regulations.
    
    Appendix A--List of Petitioners
    
    Docket Nos. RM95-8-001 and RM94-7-002
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
                  Abbreviation                                              Petitioner                              
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
    1. AEC & SMEPA.........................  Alabama Electric Cooperative, Inc. and South Mississippi Electric Power
                                              Association.                                                          
    2. AEP.................................  Operating Companies of the American Electric Power System.             
    3. AL Com..............................  Alabama Public Service Commission.                                     
    4. Allegheny...........................  Allegheny Power Service Corporation.                                   
    5. AL Municipal........................  Alabama Municipal Electric Authority.                                  
    6. American Forest & Paper.............  American Forest & Paper Association.                                   
    7. AMP-Ohio............................  American Municipal Power-Ohio, Inc. and Indiana Municipal Power Agency.
    8. Anaheim.............................  Cities of Anaheim, Azusa, Banning, Colton and Riverside, California.   
    9. APPA................................  American Public Power Association.                                     
    10. AR Com.............................  Arkansas Public Service Commission.                                    
    11. Arkansas Cities....................  Arkansas Cities and Farmers Electric Cooperative.                      
    12. Associated EC......................  Associated Electric Cooperative, Inc.                                  
    13. Atlantic City......................  Atlantic City Electric Company.                                        
    14. Basin EC...........................  Basin Electric Power Cooperative.                                      
    15. Blue Ridge.........................  Blue Ridge Power Agency, Northeast Texas Electric Cooperative, Inc.,   
                                              Sam Rayburn G&T Electric Cooperative, Inc., and Tex-La Electric       
                                              Cooperative of Texas, Inc.                                            
    16. BPA................................  Bonneville Power Administration.                                       
    17. Cajun..............................  Ralph R. Mabey, Chapter II Trustee for Cajun Electric Power            
                                              Cooperative, Inc.                                                     
    18. California DWR.....................  California Department of Water Resources.                              
    19. Carolina P&L.......................  Carolina Power & Light Company.                                        
    20. CCEM...............................  Coalition for a Competitive Electric Market (consisting of Coastal     
                                              Electric Services Company, Destec Power Services, Inc., Electric      
                                              Clearinghouse, Inc., Enron Power Marketing, Inc., Equitable Power     
                                              Services Company, KCS Power Marketing, Inc., MidCon Power Services    
                                              Corp. and Vitol Gas & Electric Services, Inc).                        
    21. Centerior..........................  Centerior Energy Corporation.                                          
    22. Central Illinois Light.............  Central Illinois Light Company.                                        
    23. Central Minnesota Municipal........  Central Minnesota Municipal Power Agency.                              
    24. Central Montana EC.................  Central Montana Electric Power Cooperative, Inc.                       
    25. Cleveland..........................  Cleveland Public Power.                                                
    26. CO Consumers Counsel...............  Colorado Office of Consumer Counsel.                                   
    27. Coalition for Economic Competition.  Coalition for Economic Competition Consisting of Consolidated Edison   
                                              Company of New York, Inc., General Public Utilities Corporation,      
                                              Illinois Power Company, Long Island Lighting Company, New York State  
                                              Electric & Gas Corporation, Niagara Mohawk Power Corporation,         
                                              Northeast Utilities, and Rochester Gas and Electric Corporation.      
    28. ConEd..............................  Consolidated Edison Company of New York, Inc.                          
    29. Connecticut DEP....................  State of Connecticut Department of Environmental Protection.           
    30. Consumers Power....................  Consumers Power Company.                                               
    31. Cooperative Power..................  Cooperative Power.                                                     
    32. CSW Operating Companies............  Central Power and Light, West Texas Utilities Company, Public Service  
                                              Company of Oklahoma and Southwestern Electric Power Company.          
    33. CVPSC..............................  Central Vermont Public Service Corporation.                            
    34. Dairyland..........................  Dairyland Power Cooperative.                                           
    35. Dalton.............................  City of Dalton, Georgia.                                               
    36. Detroit Edison.....................  Detroit Edison Company.                                                
    37. Dispute Resolution.................  Communications and Energy Dispute Resolution Associates.               
    38. Duquesne...........................  Duquesne Light Company.                                                
    39. EEI................................  Edison Electric Institute.                                             
    40. EGA................................  Electric Generation Association.                                       
    41. El Paso............................  El Paso Electric Company.                                              
    42. ELCON..............................  Electricity Consumers Resource Council, American Iron and Steel        
                                              Institute, Chemical Manufacturers Association and Council of          
                                              Industrial Boiler Owners.                                             
    43. Entergy............................  Entergy Services, Inc.                                                 
    44. EPRI...............................  Electric Power Research Institute.                                     
    45. FL Com.............................  Florida Public Service Commission.                                     
    46. Florida Power Corp.................  Florida Power Corporation.                                             
    47. FMPA...............................  Florida Municipal Power Agency.                                        
    
    [[Page 12463]]
    
                                                                                                                    
    48. FPL................................  Florida Power & Light Company.                                         
    49. Freedom Energy Co..................  Freedom Energy Corporation, LLC.                                       
    50. Hoosier EC.........................  Hoosier Energy Rural Electric Cooperative.                             
    51. IA Com.............................  Iowa Utilities Board.                                                  
    52. IL Com.............................  Illinois Commerce Commission.                                          
    53. IL Industrials.....................  Illinois Industrial Energy Consumers.                                  
    54. Illinois Power.....................  Illinois Power Company.                                                
    55. IMPA...............................  Indiana Municipal Power Agency.                                        
    56. IN Com.............................  Indiana Utility Regulatory Commission.                                 
    57. IN Consumer........................  Indiana Office of Utility Consumer Counselor.                          
    58. Indianapolis POL...................  Indianapolis Power & Light Company.                                    
    59. IN Industrials.....................  Citizens Action Coalition of Indiana, Inc., Indiana Industrial Energy  
                                              Consumers, Inc. and Indianapolis Power & Light Company.               
    60. Joint Commenters...................  Joint Commenters Supporting Clear Air and Fair Corporation.            
    61. KCPL...............................  Kansas City Power & Light Company.                                     
    62. LEPA...............................  Louisiana Energy and Power Authority.                                  
    63. Local Furnishing Utilities.........  Local Furnishing Utilities (Long Island Lighting Company, Nevada Power 
                                              Company, San Diego Gas & Electric Company and Tuscon Electric Power   
                                              Company).                                                             
    64. MA Municipals......................  Twenty Four Massachusetts Municipals.                                  
    65. Maine Public Service...............  Maine Public Service Company.                                          
    66. MI Com.............................  Michigan Public Service Commission and New Hampshire Public Utilities  
                                              Commission.                                                           
    67. Michigan Systems...................  Michigan Public Power Agency, Michigan South Central Power Agency, and 
                                              Wolverine Power Supply Cooperative, Inc.                              
    68. Minnesota P&L......................  Minnesota Power & Light Company.                                       
    69. MN DPS.............................  Minnesota Department of Public Service and Minnesota Public Utilities  
                                              Commission.                                                           
    70. MO/KS Coms.........................  Missouri Public Service Commission and Kansas Corporation Commission.  
    71. Montana Power......................  Montana Power Company.                                                 
    72. Montana-Dakota Utilities...........  Montana-Dakota Utilities Company.                                      
    73. Multiple Intervenors...............  Multiple Intervenors.                                                  
    74. NARUC..............................  National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners.              
    75. NASUCA.............................  National Association of State Utility Consumer Advocates.              
    76. NCMPA..............................  North Carolina Municipal Power Agency Number 1.                        
    77. NE Public Power District...........  Nebraska Public Power District.                                        
    78. NIMO...............................  Niagara Mohawk Power Corporation.                                      
    79. NJ BPU.............................  New Jersey Board of Public Utilities.                                  
    80. North Jersey.......................  North Jersey Energy Associates.                                        
    81. NRECA..............................  National Rural Electric Cooperative Association.                       
    82. NU.................................  Northeast Utilities Service Company.                                   
    83. Nuclear Energy Institute...........  Nuclear Energy Institute.                                              
    84. Nucor..............................  Nucor Corporation.                                                     
    85. NWRTA..............................  Northwest Regional Transmission Association.                           
    86. NY AG..............................  New York State Attorney General.                                       
    87. NY Com.............................  Public Service Commission of the State of New York.                    
    88. NY Municipals......................  Municipal Electric Utilities Association of New York States.           
    89. NY Utilities.......................  Consolidated Edison Company of New York, Inc., Long Island Lighting    
                                              Company, New York State Electric & Gas Corporation, and Rochester Gas 
                                              and Electric Corporation.                                             
    90. NYPP...............................  New York Power Pool.                                                   
    91. NYSEG..............................  New York State Electric & Gas Corporation.                             
    92. Occidental Chemical................  Occidental Chemical Corporation.                                       
    93. Oglethorpe.........................  Oglethorpe Power Corporation.                                          
    94. OH Com.............................  Public Utilities Commission of Ohio.                                   
    95. OH Consumers' Counsel..............  Ohio Office of Consumers' Counsel.                                     
    96. Ohio Valley........................  Ohio Valley Electric Corporation and Indiana-Kentucky Electric         
                                              Corporation.                                                          
    97. Oklahoma G&E.......................  Oklahoma Gas and Electric Company Inc.                                 
    98. Ontario Hydro......................  Ontario Hydro.                                                         
    99. PA Com.............................  Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission.                                
    100. PA Coops..........................  Pennsylvania Rural Electric Association and Allegheny Electric         
                                              Cooperative, Inc.                                                     
    101. PA Munis..........................  Pennsylvania Municipal Electric Association.                           
    102. PacifiCorp........................  PacifiCorp.                                                            
    103. PSE&G.............................  Public Service Electric and Gas Company.                               
    104. PSNM..............................  Public Service Company of New Mexico.                                  
    105. Public Service Co of CO...........  Public Service Company of Colorado.                                    
    106. Puget.............................  Puget Sound Power & Light Company.                                     
    107. Redding...........................  City of Redding, California.                                           
    108. San Francisco.....................  City and County of San Francisco.                                      
    109. Santa Clara.......................  City of Santa Clara, California.                                       
    110. SBA...............................  United States Small Business Administration, Office of Advocacy.       
    111. SC Public Service Authority.......  South Carolina Public Service Authority.                               
    112. SoCal Edison......................  Southern California Edison Company.                                    
    113. Southern..........................  Southern Company Services, Inc.                                        
    114. Southwestern......................  Southwestern Public Service Company.                                   
    115. Speciality Steel..................  Speciality Steel Industry of North America.                            
    116. Suffolk County....................  Suffolk County (New York) Electric Agency.                             
    117. SWRTA.............................  Southwest Regional Transmission Association.                           
    
    [[Page 12464]]
    
                                                                                                                    
    118. Tallahassee.......................  City of Tallahassee, Florida.                                          
    119. TANC..............................  Transmission Agency of Northern California.                            
    120. TAPS..............................  Transmission Access Policy Study Group.                                
    121. TDU Systems.......................  Transmission Dependent Utility Systems.                                
    122. Texaco............................  Texaco Inc.                                                            
    123. Tucson Power......................  Tucson Electric Power Company.                                         
    124. Turlock...........................  Turlock Irrigation District.                                           
    125. TX Com............................  Public Utility Commission of Texas.                                    
    126. Umatilla EC.......................  Umatilla Electric Cooperative.                                         
    127. Union Electric....................  Union Electric Company.                                                
    128. Utilities For Improved transition.  Utilities For an Improved Transition (consisting of Associated Electric
                                              Cooperative, Inc., Boston Edison Company, Central Vermont Public      
                                              Service Corporation, Montaup Electric Company, Wisconsin Electric     
                                              Power Company, and Wisconsin Public Service Corporation).             
    129. VA Com............................  Staff of the Virginia State Corporation Commission.                    
    130. Valero............................  Valero Power Services Company.                                         
    131. VEPCO.............................  Virginia Electric and Power Company.                                   
    132. VT DPS............................  Vermont Department of Public Service.                                  
    133. Wabash............................  Wabash Valley Power Association, Inc.                                  
    134. Washington Water Power............  Washington Water Power Company.                                        
    135. WI Com............................  Public Service Commission of Wisconsin.                                
    136. Wisconsin Municipals..............  Municipal Electric Utilities of Wisconsin.                             
    137. WY Com............................  Public Service Commission of Wyoming.                                  
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Appendix B--Pro Forma Open Access Transmission Tariff
    
    Table of Contents
    
    I  Common Service Provisions
    
    1  Definitions
    
    1.1  Ancillary Services
    1.2  Annual Transmission Costs
    1.3  Application
    1.4  Commission
    1.5  Completed Application
    1.6  Control Area
    1.7  Curtailment
    1.8  Delivering Party
    1.9  Designated Agent
    1.10  Direct Assignment Facilities
    1.11  Eligible Customer
    1.12  Facilities Study
    1.13  Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service
    1.14  Good Utility Practice
    1.15  Interruption
    1.16  Load Ratio Share
    1.17  Load Shedding
    1.18  Long-Term Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service
    1.19  Native Load Customers
    1.20  Network Customer
    1.21  Network Integration Transmission Service
    1.22  Network Load
    1.23  Network Operating Agreement
    1.24  Network Operating Committee
    1.25  Network Resource
    1.26  Network Upgrades
    1.27  Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service
    1.28  Open Access Same-Time Information System (OASIS)
    1.29  Part I
    1.30  Part II
    1.31  Part III
    1.32  Parties
    1.33  Point(s) of Delivery
    1.34  Point(s) of Receipt
    1.35  Point-To-Point Transmission Service
    1.36  Power Purchaser
    1.37  Receiving Party
    1.38  Regional Transmission Group (RTG)
    1.39  Reserved Capacity
    1.40  Service Agreement
    1.41  Service Commencement Date
    1.42  Short-Term Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service
    1.43  System Impact Study
    1.44  Third-Party Sale
    1.45  Transmission Customer
    1.46  Transmission Provider
    1.47  Transmission Provider's Monthly Transmission System Peak
    1.48  Transmission Service
    1.49  Transmission System
    
    2  Initial Allocation and Renewal Procedures
    
    2.1  Initial Allocation of Available Transmission Capability
    2.2  Reservation Priority For Existing Firm Service Customers
    
    3  Ancillary Services
    
    3.1  Scheduling, System Control and Dispatch Service
    3.2  Reactive Supply and Voltage Control from Generation Sources 
    Service
    3.3  Regulation and Frequency Response Service
    3.4  Energy Imbalance Service
    3.5  Operating Reserve--Spinning Reserve Service
    3.6  Operating Reserve--Supplemental Reserve Service
    
    4  Open Access Same-Time Information System (OASIS)
    
    5  Local Furnishing Bonds
    
    5.1  Transmission Providers That Own Facilities Financed by Local 
    Furnishing Bonds
    5.2  Alternative Procedures for Requesting Transmission Service
    
    6  Reciprocity
    
    7  Billing and Payment
    
    7.1  Billing Procedure
    7.2  Interest on Unpaid Balances
    7.3  Customer Default
    
    8  Accounting for the Transmission Provider's Use of the Tariff
    
    8.1  Transmission Revenues
    8.2  Study Costs and Revenues
    
    9  Regulatory Filings
    
    10  Force Majeure and Indemnification
    
    10.1 Force Majeure
    10.2  Indemnification
    
    11  Creditworthiness
    
    12  Dispute Resolution Procedures
    
    12.1  Internal Dispute Resolution Procedures
    12.2  External Arbitration Procedures
    12.3  Arbitration Decisions
    12.4  Costs
    12.5  Rights Under The Federal Power Act
    
    II. Point-to-Point Transmission Service
    
    Preamble
    
    13  Nature of Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service
    
    13.1  Term
    13.2  Reservation Priority
    13.3  Use of Firm Transmission Service by the Transmission Provider
    13.4  Service Agreements
    13.5  Transmission Customer Obligations for Facility Additions or 
    Redispatch Costs
    13.6  Curtailment of Firm Transmission Service
    13.7  Classification of Firm Transmission Service
    13.8  Scheduling of Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service
    
    14  Nature of Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service
    
    14.1  Term
    14.2  Reservation Priority
    14.3  Use of Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service by the 
    Transmission Provider
    14.4  Service Agreements
    14.5  Classification of Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service
    
    [[Page 12465]]
    
    14.6  Scheduling of Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service
    14.7  Curtailment or Interruption of Service
    
    15  Service Availability
    
    15.1  General Conditions
    15.2  Determination of Available Transmission Capability
    15.3  Initiating Service in the Absence of an Executed Service 
    Agreement
    15.4  Obligation to Provide Transmission Service that Requires 
    Expansion or Modification of the Transmission System
    15.5  Deferral of Service
    15.6  Other Transmission Service Schedules
    15.7  Real Power Losses
    
    16  Transmission Customer Responsibilities
    
    16.1  Conditions Required of Transmission Customers
    16.2  Transmission Customer Responsibility for Third-Party 
    Arrangements
    
    17  Procedures for Arranging Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service
    
    17.1  Application
    17.2  Completed Application
    17.3  Deposit
    17.4  Notice of Deficient Application
    17.5  Response to a Completed Application
    17.6  Execution of Service Agreement
    17.7  Extensions for Commencement of Service
    
    18  Procedures for Arranging Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service
    
    18.1  Application
    18.2  Completed Application
    18.3  Reservation of Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service
    18.4  Determination of Available Transmission Capability
    
    19  Additional Study Procedures For Firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service Requests
    
    19.1  Notice of Need for System Impact Study
    19.2  System Impact Study Agreement and Cost Reimbursement
    19.3  System Impact Study Procedures
    19.4  Facilities Study Procedures
    19.5  Facilities Study Modifications
    19.6  Due Diligence in Completing New Facilities
    19.7  Partial Interim Service
    19.8  Expedited Procedures for New Facilities
    
    20  Procedures if the Transmission Provider is Unable to Complete New 
    Transmission Facilities for Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service
    
    20.1  Delays in Construction of New Facilities
    20.2  Alternatives to the Original Facility Additions
    20.3  Refund Obligation for Unfinished Facility Additions
    
    21  Provisions Relating to Transmission Construction and Services on 
    the Systems of Other Utilities
    
    21.1  Responsibility for Third-Party System Additions
    21.2  Coordination of Third-Party System Additions
    
    22  Changes in Service Specifications
    
    22.1  Modifications On a Non-Firm Basis
    22.2  Modification On a Firm Basis
    23  Sale or Assignment of Transmission Service
    23.1  Procedures for Assignment or Transfer of Service
    23.2  Limitations on Assignment or Transfer of Service
    23.3  Information on Assignment or Transfer of Service
    
    24  Metering and Power Factor Correction at Receipt and Delivery 
    Points(s)
    
    24.1  Transmission Customer Obligations
    24.2  Transmission Provider Access to Metering Data
    24.3  Power Factor
    
    25  Compensation for Transmission Service
    
    26  Stranded Cost Recovery
    
    27  Compensation for New Facilities and Redispatch Costs
    
    III. Network Integration Transmission Service
    
    Preamble
    
    28  Nature of Network Integration Transmission Service
    
    28.1  Scope of Service
    28.2  Transmission Provider Responsibilities
    28.3  Network Integration Transmission Service
    28.4  Secondary Service
    28.5  Real Power Losses
    28.6  Restrictions on Use of Service
    
    29  Initiating Service
    
    29.1  Condition Precedent for Receiving Service
    29.2  Application Procedures
    29.3  Technical Arrangements to be Completed Prior to Commencement 
    of Service
    29.4  Network Customer Facilities
    29.5  Filing of Service Agreement
    
    30  Network Resources
    
    30.1  Designation of Network Resources
    30.2  Designation of New Network Resources
    30.3  Termination of Network Resources
    30.4  Operation of Network Resources
    30.5  Network Customer Redispatch Obligation
    30.6  Transmission Arrangements for Network Resources Not Physically 
    Interconnected With The Transmission Provider
    30.7  Limitation on Designation of Network Resources
    30.8  Use of Interface Capacity by the Network Customer
    30.9  Network Customer Owned Transmission Facilities
    31  Designation of Network Load
    31.1  Network Load
    31.2  New Network Loads Connected With the Transmission Provider
    31.3  Network Load Not Physically Interconnected with the 
    Transmission Provider
    31.4  New Interconnection Points
    31.5  Changes in Service Requests
    31.6  Annual Load and Resource Information Updates
    
    32  Additional Study Procedures for Network Integration Transmission 
    Service Requests
    
    32.1  Notice of Need for System Impact Study
    32.2  System Impact Study Agreement and Cost Reimbursement
    32.3  System Impact Study Procedures
    32.4  Facilities Study Procedures
    
    33  Load Shedding and Curtailments
    
    33.1  Procedures
    33.2  Transmission Constraints
    33.3  Cost Responsibility for Relieving Transmission Constraints
    33.4  Curtailments of Scheduled Deliveries
    33.5  Allocation of Curtailments
    33.6  Load Shedding
    33.7  System Reliability
    
    34  Rates and Charges
    
    34.1  Monthly Demand Charge
    34.2  Determination of Network Customer's Monthly Network Load
    34.3  Determination of Transmission Provider's Monthly Transmission 
    System Load
    34.4  Redispatch Charge
    34.5  Stranded Cost Recovery
    
    35  Operating Arrangements
    
    35.1  Operation under The Network Operating Agreement
    35.2  Network Operating Agreement
    35.3  Network Operating Committee
    Schedule 1
        Scheduling, System Control and Dispatch Service
    Schedule 2
        Reactive Supply and Voltage Control from Generation Sources 
    Service
    Schedule 3
        Regulation and Frequency Response Service
    Schedule 4
        Energy Imbalance Service
    Schedule 5
        Operating Reserve--Spinning Reserve Service
    Schedule 6
        Operating Reserve--Supplemental Reserve Service
    Schedule 7
        Long-Term Firm and Short-Term Firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service
    Schedule 8
        Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service
        Attachment A
        Form Of Service Agreement For Firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service
        Attachment B
        Form Of Service Agreement For Non-Firm Point-To-Point 
    Transmission Service
        Attachment C
        Methodology To Assess Available Transmission Capability
        Attachment D
        Methodology for Completing a System Impact Study
        Attachment E
        Index Of Point-To-Point Transmission Service Customers
        Attachment F
        Service Agreement For Network Integration Transmission Service
        Attachment G
    
    [[Page 12466]]
    
        Network Operating Agreement
        Attachment H
        Annual Transmission Revenue Requirement For Network Integration 
    Transmission Service
        Attachment I
        Index Of Network Integration Transmission Service Customers
    
    I. Common Service Provisions
    
    1  Definitions
    
        1.1  Ancillary Services: Those services that are necessary to 
    support the transmission of capacity and energy from resources to 
    loads while maintaining reliable operation of the Transmission 
    Provider's Transmission System in accordance with Good Utility 
    Practice.
        1.2  Annual Transmission Costs: The total annual cost of the 
    Transmission System for purposes of Network Integration Transmission 
    Service shall be the amount specified in Attachment until amended by 
    the Transmission Provider or modified by the Commission.
        1.3  Application: A request by an Eligible Customer for 
    transmission service pursuant to the provisions of the Tariff.
        1.4  Commission: The Federal Energy Regulatory Commission.
        1.5  Completed Application: An Application that satisfies all of 
    the information and other requirements of the Tariff, including any 
    required deposit.
        1.6  Control Area: An electric power system or combination of 
    electric power systems to which a common automatic generation 
    control scheme is applied in order to:
        (1) Match, at all times, the power output of the generators 
    within the electric power system(s) and capacity and energy 
    purchased from entities outside the electric power system(s), with 
    the load within the electric power system(s);
        (2) Maintain scheduled interchange with other Control Areas, 
    within the limits of Good Utility Practice;
        (3) Maintain the frequency of the electric power system(s) 
    within reasonable limits in accordance with Good Utility Practice; 
    and
        (4) Provide sufficient generating capacity to maintain operating 
    reserves in accordance with Good Utility Practice.
        1.7  Curtailment: A reduction in firm or non-firm transmission 
    service in response to a transmission capacity shortage as a result 
    of system reliability conditions.
        1.8  Delivering Party: The entity supplying capacity and energy 
    to be transmitted at Point(s) of Receipt.
        1.9  Designated Agent: Any entity that performs actions or 
    functions on behalf of the Transmission Provider, an Eligible 
    Customer, or the Transmission Customer required under the Tariff.
        1.10  Direct Assignment Facilities: Facilities or portions of 
    facilities that are constructed by the Transmission Provider for the 
    sole use/benefit of a particular Transmission Customer requesting 
    service under the Tariff. Direct Assignment Facilities shall be 
    specified in the Service Agreement that governs service to the 
    Transmission Customer and shall be subject to Commission approval.
        1.11  Eligible Customer: (i) Any electric utility (including the 
    Transmission Provider and any power marketer), Federal power 
    marketing agency, or any person generating electric energy for sale 
    for resale is an Eligible Customer under the Tariff. Electric energy 
    sold or produced by such entity may be electric energy produced in 
    the United States, Canada or Mexico. However, with respect to 
    transmission service that the Commission is prohibited from ordering 
    by Section 212(h) of the Federal Power Act, such entity is eligible 
    only if the service is provided pursuant to a state requirement that 
    the Transmission Provider offer the unbundled transmission service, 
    or pursuant to a voluntary offer of such service by the Transmission 
    Provider. (ii) Any retail customer taking unbundled transmission 
    service pursuant to a state requirement that the Transmission 
    Provider offer the transmission service, or pursuant to a voluntary 
    offer of such service by the Transmission Provider, is an Eligible 
    Customer under the Tariff.
        1.12  Facilities Study: An engineering study conducted by the 
    Transmission Provider to determine the required modifications to the 
    Transmission Provider's Transmission System, including the cost and 
    scheduled completion date for such modifications, that will be 
    required to provide the requested transmission service.
        1.13  Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service: Transmission 
    Service under this Tariff that is reserved and/or scheduled between 
    specified Points of Receipt and Delivery pursuant to Part II of this 
    Tariff.
        1.14  Good Utility Practice: Any of the practices, methods and 
    acts engaged in or approved by a significant portion of the electric 
    utility industry during the relevant time period, or any of the 
    practices, methods and acts which, in the exercise of reasonable 
    judgment in light of the facts known at the time the decision was 
    made, could have been expected to accomplish the desired result at a 
    reasonable cost consistent with good business practices, 
    reliability, safety and expedition. Good Utility Practice is not 
    intended to be limited to the optimum practice, method, or act to 
    the exclusion of all others, but rather to be acceptable practices, 
    methods, or acts generally accepted in the region.
        1.15  Interruption: A reduction in non-firm transmission service 
    due to economic reasons pursuant to Section 14.7.
        1.16  Load Ratio Share: Ratio of a Transmission Customer's 
    Network Load to the Transmission Provider's total load computed in 
    accordance with Sections 34.2 and 34.3 of the Network Integration 
    Transmission Service under Part III the Tariff and calculated on a 
    rolling twelve month basis.
        1.17  Load Shedding: The systematic reduction of system demand 
    by temporarily decreasing load in response to transmission system or 
    area capacity shortages, system instability, or voltage control 
    considerations under Part III of the Tariff.
        1.18  Long-Term Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service: Firm 
    Point-To-Point Transmission Service under Part II of the Tariff with 
    a term of one year or more.
        1.19  Native Load Customers: The wholesale and retail power 
    customers of the Transmission Provider on whose behalf the 
    Transmission Provider, by statute, franchise, regulatory 
    requirement, or contract, has undertaken an obligation to construct 
    and operate the Transmission Provider's system to meet the reliable 
    electric needs of such customers.
        1.20  Network Customer: An entity receiving transmission service 
    pursuant to the terms of the Transmission Provider's Network 
    Integration Transmission Service under Part III of the Tariff.
        1.21  Network Integration Transmission Service: The transmission 
    service provided under Part III of the Tariff.
        1.22  Network Load: The load that a Network Customer designates 
    for Network Integration Transmission Service under Part III of the 
    Tariff. The Network Customer's Network Load shall include all load 
    served by the output of any Network Resources designated by the 
    Network Customer. A Network Customer may elect to designate less 
    than its total load as Network Load but may not designate only part 
    of the load at a discrete Point of Delivery. Where a Eligible 
    Customer has elected not to designate a particular load at discrete 
    points of delivery as Network Load, the Eligible Customer is 
    responsible for making separate arrangements under Part II of the 
    Tariff for any Point-To-Point Transmission Service that may be 
    necessary for such non-designated load.
        1.23  Network Operating Agreement: An executed agreement that 
    contains the terms and conditions under which the Network Customer 
    shall operate its facilities and the technical and operational 
    matters associated with the implementation of Network Integration 
    Transmission Service under Part III of the Tariff.
        1.24  Network Operating Committee: A group made up of 
    representatives from the Network Customer(s) and the Transmission 
    Provider established to coordinate operating criteria and other 
    technical considerations required for implementation of Network 
    Integration Transmission Service under Part III of this Tariff.
        1.25  Network Resource: Any designated generating resource 
    owned, purchased or leased by a Network Customer under the Network 
    Integration Transmission Service Tariff. Network Resources do not 
    include any resource, or any portion thereof, that is committed for 
    sale to third parties or otherwise cannot be called upon to meet the 
    Network Customer's Network Load on a non-interruptible basis.
        1.26  Network Upgrades: Modifications or additions to 
    transmission-related facilities that are integrated with and support 
    the Transmission Provider's overall Transmission System for the 
    general benefit of all users of such Transmission System.
        1.27  Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service: Point-To-
    Point Transmission Service under the Tariff that is reserved and 
    scheduled on an as-available basis and is subject to Curtailment or 
    Interruption as set forth in Section 14.7 under Part II of this 
    Tariff. Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service is available on 
    a stand-alone basis for periods ranging from one hour to one month.
    
    [[Page 12467]]
    
        1.28  Open Access Same-Time Information System (OASIS): The 
    information system and standards of conduct contained in Part 37 of 
    the Commission's regulations and all additional requirements 
    implemented by subsequent Commission orders dealing with OASIS.
        1.29  Part I: Tariff Definitions and Common Service Provisions 
    contained in Sections 2 through 12.
        1.30  Part II: Tariff Sections 13 through 27 pertaining to 
    Point-To-Point Transmission Service in conjunction with the 
    applicable Common Service Provisions of Part I and appropriate 
    Schedules and Attachments.
        1.31  Part III: Tariff Sections 28 through 35 pertaining to 
    Network Integration Transmission Service in conjunction with the 
    applicable Common Service Provisions of Part I and appropriate 
    Schedules and Attachments.
        1.32  Parties: The Transmission Provider and the Transmission 
    Customer receiving service under the Tariff.
        1.33  Point(s) of Delivery: Point(s) on the Transmission 
    Provider's Transmission System where capacity and energy transmitted 
    by the Transmission Provider will be made available to the Receiving 
    Party under Part II of the Tariff. The Point(s) of Delivery shall be 
    specified in the Service Agreement for Long-Term Firm Point-To-Point 
    Transmission Service.
        1.34  Point(s) of Receipt: Point(s) of interconnection on the 
    Transmission Provider's Transmission System where capacity and 
    energy will be made available to the Transmission Provider by the 
    Delivering Party under Part II of the Tariff. The Point(s) of 
    Receipt shall be specified in the Service Agreement for Long-Term 
    Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service.
        1.35  Point-To-Point Transmission Service: The reservation and 
    transmission of capacity and energy on either a firm or non-firm 
    basis from the Point(s) of Receipt to the Point(s) of Delivery under 
    Part II of the Tariff.
        1.36  Power Purchaser: The entity that is purchasing the 
    capacity and energy to be transmitted under the Tariff.
        1.37  Receiving Party: The entity receiving the capacity and 
    energy transmitted by the Transmission Provider to Point(s) of 
    Delivery.
        1.38  Regional Transmission Group (RTG): A voluntary 
    organization of transmission owners, transmission users and other 
    entities approved by the Commission to efficiently coordinate 
    transmission planning (and expansion), operation and use on a 
    regional (and interregional) basis.
        1.39  Reserved Capacity: The maximum amount of capacity and 
    energy that the Transmission Provider agrees to transmit for the 
    Transmission Customer over the Transmission Provider's Transmission 
    System between the Point(s) of Receipt and the Point(s) of Delivery 
    under Part II of the Tariff. Reserved Capacity shall be expressed in 
    terms of whole megawatts on a sixty (60) minute interval (commencing 
    on the clock hour) basis.
        1.40  Service Agreement: The initial agreement and any 
    amendments or supplements thereto entered into by the Transmission 
    Customer and the Transmission Provider for service under the Tariff.
        1.41  Service Commencement Date: The date the Transmission 
    Provider begins to provide service pursuant to the terms of an 
    executed Service Agreement, or the date the Transmission Provider 
    begins to provide service in accordance with Section 15.3 or Section 
    29.1 under the Tariff.
        1.42  Short-Term Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service: Firm 
    Point-To-Point Transmission Service under Part II of the Tariff with 
    a term of less than one year.
        1.43  System Impact Study: An assessment by the Transmission 
    Provider of (i) the adequacy of the Transmission System to 
    accommodate a request for either Firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service or Network Integration Transmission Service and (ii) whether 
    any additional costs may be incurred in order to provide 
    transmission service.
        1.44  Third-Party Sale: Any sale for resale in interstate 
    commerce to a Power Purchaser that is not designated as part of 
    Network Load under the Network Integration Transmission Service.
        1.45  Transmission Customer: Any Eligible Customer (or its 
    Designated Agent) that (i) executes a Service Agreement, or (ii) 
    requests in writing that the Transmission Provider file with the 
    Commission, a proposed unexecuted Service Agreement to receive 
    transmission service under Part II of the Tariff. This term is used 
    in the Part I Common Service Provisions to include customers 
    receiving transmission service under Part II and Part III of this 
    Tariff.
        1.46  Transmission Provider: The public utility (or its 
    Designated Agent) that owns, controls, or operates facilities used 
    for the transmission of electric energy in interstate commerce and 
    provides transmission service under the Tariff.
        1.47  Transmission Provider's Monthly Transmission System Peak: 
    The maximum firm usage of the Transmission Provider's Transmission 
    System in a calendar month.
        1.48  Transmission Service: Point-To-Point Transmission Service 
    provided under Part II of the Tariff on a firm and non-firm basis.
        1.49  Transmission System: The facilities owned, controlled or 
    operated by the Transmission Provider that are used to provide 
    transmission service under Part II and Part III of the Tariff.
    
    2.  Initial Allocation and Renewal Procedures
    
        2.1  Initial Allocation of Available Transmission Capability: 
    For purposes of determining whether existing capability on the 
    Transmission Provider's Transmission System is adequate to 
    accommodate a request for firm service under this Tariff, all 
    Completed Applications for new firm transmission service received 
    during the initial sixty (60) day period commencing with the 
    effective date of the Tariff will be deemed to have been filed 
    simultaneously. A lottery system conducted by an independent party 
    shall be used to assign priorities for Completed Applications filed 
    simultaneously. All Completed Applications for firm transmission 
    service received after the initial sixty (60) day period shall be 
    assigned a priority pursuant to Section 13.2.
        2.2  Reservation Priority For Existing Firm Service Customers: 
    Existing firm service customers (wholesale requirements and 
    transmission-only, with a contract term of one-year or more), have 
    the right to continue to take transmission service from the 
    Transmission Provider when the contract expires, rolls over or is 
    renewed. This transmission reservation priority is independent of 
    whether the existing customer continues to purchase capacity and 
    energy from the Transmission Provider or elects to purchase capacity 
    and energy from another supplier. If at the end of the contract 
    term, the Transmission Provider's Transmission System cannot 
    accommodate all of the requests for transmission service the 
    existing firm service customer must agree to accept a contract term 
    at least equal to a competing request by any new Eligible Customer 
    and to pay the current just and reasonable rate, as approved by the 
    Commission, for such service. This transmission reservation priority 
    for existing firm service customers is an ongoing right that may be 
    exercised at the end of all firm contract terms of one-year or 
    longer.
    
    3.  Ancillary Services
    
        Ancillary Services are needed with transmission service to 
    maintain reliability within and among the Control Areas affected by 
    the transmission service. The Transmission Provider is required to 
    provide (or offer to arrange with the local Control Area operator as 
    discussed below), and the Transmission Customer is required to 
    purchase, the following Ancillary Services (i) Scheduling, System 
    Control and Dispatch, and (ii) Reactive Supply and Voltage Control 
    from Generation Sources.
        The Transmission Provider is required to offer to provide (or 
    offer to arrange with the local Control Area operator as discussed 
    below) the following Ancillary Services only to the Transmission 
    Customer serving load within the Transmission Provider's Control 
    Area (i) Regulation and Frequency Response, (ii) Energy Imbalance, 
    (iii) Operating Reserve--Spinning, and (iv) Operating Reserve--
    Supplemental. The Transmission Customer serving load within the 
    Transmission Provider's Control Area is required to acquire these 
    Ancillary Services, whether from the Transmission Provider, from a 
    third party, or by self-supply. The Transmission Customer may not 
    decline the Transmission Provider's offer of Ancillary Services 
    unless it demonstrates that it has acquired the Ancillary Services 
    from another source. The Transmission Customer must list in its 
    Application which Ancillary Services it will purchase from the 
    Transmission Provider.
        If the Transmission Provider is a public utility providing 
    transmission service but is not a Control Area operator, it may be 
    unable to provide some or all of the Ancillary Services. In this 
    case, the Transmission Provider can fulfill its obligation to 
    provide Ancillary Services by acting as the Transmission Customer's 
    agent to secure these Ancillary Services from the Control Area 
    operator. The Transmission Customer
    
    [[Page 12468]]
    
    may elect to (i) have the Transmission Provider act as its agent, 
    (ii) secure the Ancillary Services directly from the Control Area 
    operator, or (iii) secure the Ancillary Services (discussed in 
    Schedules 3, 4, 5 and 6) from a third party or by self-supply when 
    technically feasible.
        The Transmission Provider shall specify the rate treatment and 
    all related terms and conditions in the event of an unauthorized use 
    of Ancillary Services by the Transmission Customer.
        The specific Ancillary Services, prices and/or compensation 
    methods are described on the Schedules that are attached to and made 
    a part of the Tariff. Three principal requirements apply to 
    discounts for Ancillary Services provided by the Transmission 
    Provider in conjunction with its provision of transmission service 
    as follows: (1) any offer of a discount made by the Transmission 
    Provider must be announced to all Eligible Customers solely by 
    posting on the OASIS, (2) any customer-initiated requests for 
    discounts (including requests for use by one's wholesale merchant or 
    an affiliate's use) must occur solely by posting on the OASIS, and 
    (3) once a discount is negotiated, details must be immediately 
    posted on the OASIS. A discount agreed upon for an Ancillary Service 
    must be offered for the same period to all Eligible Customers on the 
    Transmission Provider's system. Sections 3.1 through 3.6 below list 
    the six Ancillary Services.
        3.1  Scheduling, System Control and Dispatch Service: The rates 
    and/or methodology are described in Schedule 1.
        3.2  Reactive Supply and Voltage Control from Generation Sources 
    Service: The rates and/or methodology are described in Schedule 2.
        3.3  Regulation and Frequency Response Service: Where applicable 
    the rates and/or methodology are described in Schedule 3.
        3.4  Energy Imbalance Service: Where applicable the rates and/or 
    methodology are described in Schedule 4.
        3.5  Operating Reserve--Spinning Reserve Service: Where 
    applicable the rates and/or methodology are described in Schedule 5.
        3.6  Operating Reserve--Supplemental Reserve Service: Where 
    applicable the rates and/or methodology are described in Schedule 6.
    
    4  Open Access Same-Time Information System (OASIS)
    
        Terms and conditions regarding Open Access Same-Time Information 
    System and standards of conduct are set forth in 18 CFR Sec. 37 of 
    the Commission's regulations (Open Access Same-Time Information 
    System and Standards of Conduct for Public Utilities). In the event 
    available transmission capability as posted on the OASIS is 
    insufficient to accommodate a request for firm transmission service, 
    additional studies may be required as provided by this Tariff 
    pursuant to Sections 19 and 32.
    
    5  Local Furnishing Bonds
    
        5.1  Transmission Providers That Own Facilities Financed by 
    Local Furnishing Bonds: This provision is applicable only to 
    Transmission Providers that have financed facilities for the local 
    furnishing of electric energy with tax-exempt bonds, as described in 
    Section 142(f) of the Internal Revenue Code (``local furnishing 
    bonds''). Notwithstanding any other provision of this Tariff, the 
    Transmission Provider shall not be required to provide transmission 
    service to any Eligible Customer pursuant to this Tariff if the 
    provision of such transmission service would jeopardize the tax-
    exempt status of any local furnishing bond(s) used to finance the 
    Transmission Provider's facilities that would be used in providing 
    such transmission service.
        5.2  Alternative Procedures for Requesting Transmission Service:
        (i) If the Transmission Provider determines that the provision 
    of transmission service requested by an Eligible Customer would 
    jeopardize the tax-exempt status of any local furnishing bond(s) 
    used to finance its facilities that would be used in providing such 
    transmission service, it shall advise the Eligible Customer within 
    thirty (30) days of receipt of the Completed Application.
        (ii) If the Eligible Customer thereafter renews its request for 
    the same transmission service referred to in (i) by tendering an 
    application under Section 211 of the Federal Power Act, the 
    Transmission Provider, within ten (10) days of receiving a copy of 
    the Section 211 application, will waive its rights to a request for 
    service under Section 213(a) of the Federal Power Act and to the 
    issuance of a proposed order under Section 212(c) of the Federal 
    Power Act. The Commission, upon receipt of the Transmission 
    Provider's waiver of its rights to a request for service under 
    Section 213(a) of the Federal Power Act and to the issuance of a 
    proposed order under Section 212(c) of the Federal Power Act, shall 
    issue an order under Section 211 of the Federal Power Act. Upon 
    issuance of the order under Section 211 of the Federal Power Act, 
    the Transmission Provider shall be required to provide the requested 
    transmission service in accordance with the terms and conditions of 
    this Tariff.
    
    6  Reciprocity
    
        A Transmission Customer receiving transmission service under 
    this Tariff agrees to provide comparable transmission service that 
    it is capable of providing to the Transmission Provider on similar 
    terms and conditions over facilities used for the transmission of 
    electric energy owned, controlled or operated by the Transmission 
    Customer and over facilities used for the transmission of electric 
    energy owned, controlled or operated by the Transmission Customer's 
    corporate affiliates. A Transmission Customer that is a member of a 
    power pool or Regional Transmission Group also agrees to provide 
    comparable transmission service to the members of such power pool 
    and Regional Transmission Group on similar terms and conditions over 
    facilities used for the transmission of electric energy owned, 
    controlled or operated by the Transmission Customer and over 
    facilities used for the transmission of electric energy owned, 
    controlled or operated by the Transmission Customer's corporate 
    affiliates.
        This reciprocity requirement applies not only to the 
    Transmission Customer that obtains transmission service under the 
    Tariff, but also to all parties to a transaction that involves the 
    use of transmission service under the Tariff, including the power 
    seller, buyer and any intermediary, such as a power marketer. This 
    reciprocity requirement also applies to any Eligible Customer that 
    owns, controls or operates transmission facilities that uses an 
    intermediary, such as a power marketer, to request transmission 
    service under the Tariff. If the Transmission Customer does not own, 
    control or operate transmission facilities, it must include in its 
    Application a sworn statement of one of its duly authorized officers 
    or other representatives that the purpose of its Application is not 
    to assist an Eligible Customer to avoid the requirements of this 
    provision.
    
    7  Billing and Payment
    
        7.1  Billing Procedure: Within a reasonable time after the first 
    day of each month, the Transmission Provider shall submit an invoice 
    to the Transmission Customer for the charges for all services 
    furnished under the Tariff during the preceding month. The invoice 
    shall be paid by the Transmission Customer within twenty (20) days 
    of receipt. All payments shall be made in immediately available 
    funds payable to the Transmission Provider, or by wire transfer to a 
    bank named by the Transmission Provider.
        7.2  Interest on Unpaid Balances: Interest on any unpaid amounts 
    (including amounts placed in escrow) shall be calculated in 
    accordance with the methodology specified for interest on refunds in 
    the Commission's regulations at 18 C.F.R. Sec. 35.19a(a)(2)(iii). 
    Interest on delinquent amounts shall be calculated from the due date 
    of the bill to the date of payment. When payments are made by mail, 
    bills shall be considered as having been paid on the date of receipt 
    by the Transmission Provider.
        7.3  Customer Default: In the event the Transmission Customer 
    fails, for any reason other than a billing dispute as described 
    below, to make payment to the Transmission Provider on or before the 
    due date as described above, and such failure of payment is not 
    corrected within thirty (30) calendar days after the Transmission 
    Provider notifies the Transmission Customer to cure such failure, a 
    default by the Transmission Customer shall be deemed to exist. Upon 
    the occurrence of a default, the Transmission Provider may initiate 
    a proceeding with the Commission to terminate service but shall not 
    terminate service until the Commission so approves any such request. 
    In the event of a billing dispute between the Transmission Provider 
    and the Transmission Customer, the Transmission Provider will 
    continue to provide service under the Service Agreement as long as 
    the Transmission Customer (i) continues to make all payments not in 
    dispute, and (ii) pays into an independent escrow account the 
    portion of the invoice in dispute, pending resolution of such 
    dispute. If the Transmission Customer fails to meet these two 
    requirements for continuation of service, then the Transmission 
    Provider may provide notice to the Transmission Customer of its 
    intention to suspend service in sixty
    
    [[Page 12469]]
    
    (60) days, in accordance with Commission policy.
    
    8   Accounting for the Transmission Provider's Use of the Tariff
    
        The Transmission Provider shall record the following amounts, as 
    outlined below.
        8.1  Transmission Revenues: Include in a separate operating 
    revenue account or subaccount the revenues it receives from 
    Transmission Service when making Third-Party Sales under Part II of 
    the Tariff.
        8.2  Study Costs and Revenues: Include in a separate 
    transmission operating expense account or subaccount, costs properly 
    chargeable to expense that are incurred to perform any System Impact 
    Studies or Facilities Studies which the Transmission Provider 
    conducts to determine if it must construct new transmission 
    facilities or upgrades necessary for its own uses, including making 
    Third-Party Sales under the Tariff; and include in a separate 
    operating revenue account or subaccount the revenues received for 
    System Impact Studies or Facilities Studies performed when such 
    amounts are separately stated and identified in the Transmission 
    Customer's billing under the Tariff.
    
    9  Regulatory Filings
    
        Nothing contained in the Tariff or any Service Agreement shall 
    be construed as affecting in any way the right of the Transmission 
    Provider to unilaterally make application to the Commission for a 
    change in rates, terms and conditions, charges, classification of 
    service, Service Agreement, rule or regulation under Section 205 of 
    the Federal Power Act and pursuant to the Commission's rules and 
    regulations promulgated thereunder.
        Nothing contained in the Tariff or any Service Agreement shall 
    be construed as affecting in any way the ability of any Party 
    receiving service under the Tariff to exercise its rights under the 
    Federal Power Act and pursuant to the Commission's rules and 
    regulations promulgated thereunder.
    
    10  Force Majeure and Indemnification
    
        10.1  Force Majeure: An event of Force Majeure means any act of 
    God, labor disturbance, act of the public enemy, war, insurrection, 
    riot, fire, storm or flood, explosion, breakage or accident to 
    machinery or equipment, any Curtailment, order, regulation or 
    restriction imposed by governmental military or lawfully established 
    civilian authorities, or any other cause beyond a Party's control. A 
    Force Majeure event does not include an act of negligence or 
    intentional wrongdoing. Neither the Transmission Provider nor the 
    Transmission Customer will be considered in default as to any 
    obligation under this Tariff if prevented from fulfilling the 
    obligation due to an event of Force Majeure. However, a Party whose 
    performance under this Tariff is hindered by an event of Force 
    Majeure shall make all reasonable efforts to perform its obligations 
    under this Tariff.
        10.2  Indemnification: The Transmission Customer shall at all 
    times indemnify, defend, and save the Transmission Provider harmless 
    from, any and all damages, losses, claims, including claims and 
    actions relating to injury to or death of any person or damage to 
    property, demands, suits, recoveries, costs and expenses, court 
    costs, attorney fees, and all other obligations by or to third 
    parties, arising out of or resulting from the Transmission 
    Provider's performance of its obligations under this Tariff on 
    behalf of the Transmission Customer, except in cases of negligence 
    or intentional wrongdoing by the Transmission Provider.
    
    11  Creditworthiness
    
        For the purpose of determining the ability of the Transmission 
    Customer to meet its obligations related to service hereunder, the 
    Transmission Provider may require reasonable credit review 
    procedures. This review shall be made in accordance with standard 
    commercial practices. In addition, the Transmission Provider may 
    require the Transmission Customer to provide and maintain in effect 
    during the term of the Service Agreement, an unconditional and 
    irrevocable letter of credit as security to meet its 
    responsibilities and obligations under the Tariff, or an alternative 
    form of security proposed by the Transmission Customer and 
    acceptable to the Transmission Provider and consistent with 
    commercial practices established by the Uniform Commercial Code that 
    protects the Transmission Provider against the risk of non-payment.
    
    12  Dispute Resolution Procedures
    
        12.1  Internal Dispute Resolution Procedures: Any dispute 
    between a Transmission Customer and the Transmission Provider 
    involving transmission service under the Tariff (excluding 
    applications for rate changes or other changes to the Tariff, or to 
    any Service Agreement entered into under the Tariff, which shall be 
    presented directly to the Commission for resolution) shall be 
    referred to a designated senior representative of the Transmission 
    Provider and a senior representative of the Transmission Customer 
    for resolution on an informal basis as promptly as practicable. In 
    the event the designated representatives are unable to resolve the 
    dispute within thirty (30) days [or such other period as the Parties 
    may agree upon] by mutual agreement, such dispute may be submitted 
    to arbitration and resolved in accordance with the arbitration 
    procedures set forth below.
        12.2  External Arbitration Procedures: Any arbitration initiated 
    under the Tariff shall be conducted before a single neutral 
    arbitrator appointed by the Parties. If the Parties fail to agree 
    upon a single arbitrator within ten (10) days of the referral of the 
    dispute to arbitration, each Party shall choose one arbitrator who 
    shall sit on a three-member arbitration panel. The two arbitrators 
    so chosen shall within twenty (20) days select a third arbitrator to 
    chair the arbitration panel. In either case, the arbitrators shall 
    be knowledgeable in electric utility matters, including electric 
    transmission and bulk power issues, and shall not have any current 
    or past substantial business or financial relationships with any 
    party to the arbitration (except prior arbitration). The 
    arbitrator(s) shall provide each of the Parties an opportunity to be 
    heard and, except as otherwise provided herein, shall generally 
    conduct the arbitration in accordance with the Commercial 
    Arbitration Rules of the American Arbitration Association and any 
    applicable Commission regulations or Regional Transmission Group 
    rules.
        12.3  Arbitration Decisions: Unless otherwise agreed, the 
    arbitrator(s) shall render a decision within ninety (90) days of 
    appointment and shall notify the Parties in writing of such decision 
    and the reasons therefor. The arbitrator(s) shall be authorized only 
    to interpret and apply the provisions of the Tariff and any Service 
    Agreement entered into under the Tariff and shall have no power to 
    modify or change any of the above in any manner. The decision of the 
    arbitrator(s) shall be final and binding upon the Parties, and 
    judgment on the award may be entered in any court having 
    jurisdiction. The decision of the arbitrator(s) may be appealed 
    solely on the grounds that the conduct of the arbitrator(s), or the 
    decision itself, violated the standards set forth in the Federal 
    Arbitration Act and/or the Administrative Dispute Resolution Act. 
    The final decision of the arbitrator must also be filed with the 
    Commission if it affects jurisdictional rates, terms and conditions 
    of service or facilities.
        12.4  Costs: Each Party shall be responsible for its own costs 
    incurred during the arbitration process and for the following costs, 
    if applicable:
        (A) The cost of the arbitrator chosen by the Party to sit on the 
    three member panel and one half of the cost of the third arbitrator 
    chosen; or
        (B) One half the cost of the single arbitrator jointly chosen by 
    the Parties.
        12.5  Rights Under The Federal Power Act: Nothing in this 
    section shall restrict the rights of any party to file a Complaint 
    with the Commission under relevant provisions of the Federal Power 
    Act.
    
    II. Point-to-Point Transmission Service
    
    Preamble
    
        The Transmission Provider will provide Firm and Non-Firm Point-
    To-Point Transmission Service pursuant to the applicable terms and 
    conditions of this Tariff. Point-To-Point Transmission Service is 
    for the receipt of capacity and energy at designated Point(s) of 
    Receipt and the transmission of such capacity and energy to 
    designated Point(s) of Delivery.
    
    13  Nature of Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service
    
        13.1  Term: The minimum term of Firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service shall be one day and the maximum term shall be specified in 
    the Service Agreement.
        13.2  Reservation Priority: Long-Term Firm Point-To-Point 
    Transmission Service shall be available on a first-come, first-
    served basis i.e., in the chronological sequence in which each 
    Transmission Customer has reserved service. Reservations for Short-
    Term Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service will be conditional 
    based upon the length of the requested transaction. If the 
    Transmission System becomes oversubscribed, requests for longer term 
    service may preempt requests for shorter term service up to the 
    following
    
    [[Page 12470]]
    
    deadlines: one day before the commencement of daily service, one 
    week before the commencement of weekly service, and one month before 
    the commencement of monthly service. Before the conditional 
    reservation deadline, if available transmission capability is 
    insufficient to satisfy all Applications, an Eligible Customer with 
    a reservation for shorter term service has the right of first 
    refusal to match any longer term reservation before losing its 
    reservation priority. A longer term competing request for Short-Term 
    Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service will be granted if the 
    Eligible Customer with the right of first refusal does not agree to 
    match the competing request within 24 hours (or earlier if necessary 
    to comply with the scheduling deadlines provided in section 13.8) 
    from being notified by the Transmission Provider of a longer-term 
    competing request for Short-Term Firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service. After the conditional reservation deadline, service will 
    commence pursuant to the terms of Part II of the Tariff. Firm Point-
    To-Point Transmission Service will always have a reservation 
    priority over Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service under the 
    Tariff. All Long-Term Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service will 
    have equal reservation priority with Native Load Customers and 
    Network Customers. Reservation priorities for existing firm service 
    customers are provided in Section 2.2.
        13.3  Use of Firm Transmission Service by the Transmission 
    Provider: The Transmission Provider will be subject to the rates, 
    terms and conditions of Part II of the Tariff when making Third-
    Party Sales under (i) agreements executed on or after [insert date 
    sixty (60) days after publication in Federal Register] or (ii) 
    agreements executed prior to the aforementioned date that the 
    Commission requires to be unbundled, by the date specified by the 
    Commission. The Transmission Provider will maintain separate 
    accounting, pursuant to Section 8 , for any use of the Point-To-
    Point Transmission Service to make Third-Party Sales.
        13.4  Service Agreements: The Transmission Provider shall offer 
    a standard form Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service Agreement 
    (Attachment A) to an Eligible Customer when it submits a Completed 
    Application for Long-Term Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service. 
    The Transmission Provider shall offer a standard form Firm Point-To-
    Point Transmission Service Agreement (Attachment A) to an Eligible 
    Customer when it first submits a Completed Application for Short-
    Term Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service pursuant to the 
    Tariff. Executed Service Agreements that contain the information 
    required under the Tariff shall be filed with the Commission in 
    compliance with applicable Commission regulations.
        13.5  Transmission Customer Obligations for Facility Additions 
    or Redispatch Costs: In cases where the Transmission Provider 
    determines that the Transmission System is not capable of providing 
    Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service without (1) degrading or 
    impairing the reliability of service to Native Load Customers, 
    Network Customers and other Transmission Customers taking Firm 
    Point-To-Point Transmission Service, or (2) interfering with the 
    Transmission Provider's ability to meet prior firm contractual 
    commitments to others, the Transmission Provider will be obligated 
    to expand or upgrade its Transmission System pursuant to the terms 
    of Section 15.4. The Transmission Customer must agree to compensate 
    the Transmission Provider for any necessary transmission facility 
    additions pursuant to the terms of Section 27. To the extent the 
    Transmission Provider can relieve any system constraint more 
    economically by redispatching the Transmission Provider's resources 
    than through constructing Network Upgrades, it shall do so, provided 
    that the Eligible Customer agrees to compensate the Transmission 
    Provider pursuant to the terms of Section 27 . Any redispatch, 
    Network Upgrade or Direct Assignment Facilities costs to be charged 
    to the Transmission Customer on an incremental basis under the 
    Tariff will be specified in the Service Agreement prior to 
    initiating service.
        13.6  Curtailment of Firm Transmission Service: In the event 
    that a Curtailment on the Transmission Provider's Transmission 
    System, or a portion thereof, is required to maintain reliable 
    operation of such system, Curtailments will be made on a non-
    discriminatory basis to the transaction(s) that effectively relieve 
    the constraint. If multiple transactions require Curtailment, to the 
    extent practicable and consistent with Good Utility Practice, the 
    Transmission Provider will curtail service to Network Customers and 
    Transmission Customers taking Firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service on a basis comparable to the curtailment of service to the 
    Transmission Provider's Native Load Customers. All Curtailments will 
    be made on a non-discriminatory basis, however, Non-Firm Point-To-
    Point Transmission Service shall be subordinate to Firm Transmission 
    Service. When the Transmission Provider determines that an 
    electrical emergency exists on its Transmission System and 
    implements emergency procedures to Curtail Firm Transmission 
    Service, the Transmission Customer shall make the required 
    reductions upon request of the Transmission Provider. However, the 
    Transmission Provider reserves the right to Curtail, in whole or in 
    part, any Firm Transmission Service provided under the Tariff when, 
    in the Transmission Provider's sole discretion, an emergency or 
    other unforeseen condition impairs or degrades the reliability of 
    its Transmission System. The Transmission Provider will notify all 
    affected Transmission Customers in a timely manner of any scheduled 
    Curtailments.
        13.7  Classification of Firm Transmission Service:
        (a) The Transmission Customer taking Firm Point-To-Point 
    Transmission Service may (1) change its Receipt and Delivery Points 
    to obtain service on a non-firm basis consistent with the terms of 
    Section 22.1 or (2) request a modification of the Points of Receipt 
    or Delivery on a firm basis pursuant to the terms of Section 22.2.
        (b) The Transmission Customer may purchase transmission service 
    to make sales of capacity and energy from multiple generating units 
    that are on the Transmission Provider's Transmission System. For 
    such a purchase of transmission service, the resources will be 
    designated as multiple Points of Receipt, unless the multiple 
    generating units are at the same generating plant in which case the 
    units would be treated as a single Point of Receipt.
        (c) The Transmission Provider shall provide firm deliveries of 
    capacity and energy from the Point(s) of Receipt to the Point(s) of 
    Delivery. Each Point of Receipt at which firm transmission capacity 
    is reserved by the Transmission Customer shall be set forth in the 
    Firm Point-To-Point Service Agreement for Long-Term Firm 
    Transmission Service along with a corresponding capacity reservation 
    associated with each Point of Receipt. Points of Receipt and 
    corresponding capacity reservations shall be as mutually agreed upon 
    by the Parties for Short-Term Firm Transmission. Each Point of 
    Delivery at which firm transmission capacity is reserved by the 
    Transmission Customer shall be set forth in the Firm Point-To-Point 
    Service Agreement for Long-Term Firm Transmission Service along with 
    a corresponding capacity reservation associated with each Point of 
    Delivery. Points of Delivery and corresponding capacity reservations 
    shall be as mutually agreed upon by the Parties for Short-Term Firm 
    Transmission. The greater of either (1) the sum of the capacity 
    reservations at the Point(s) of Receipt, or (2) the sum of the 
    capacity reservations at the Point(s) of Delivery shall be the 
    Transmission Customer's Reserved Capacity. The Transmission Customer 
    will be billed for its Reserved Capacity under the terms of Schedule 
    7. The Transmission Customer may not exceed its firm capacity 
    reserved at each Point of Receipt and each Point of Delivery except 
    as otherwise specified in Section 22. The Transmission Provider 
    shall specify the rate treatment and all related terms and 
    conditions applicable in the event that a Transmission Customer 
    (including Third-Party Sales by the Transmission Provider) exceeds 
    its firm reserved capacity at any Point of Receipt or Point of 
    Delivery.
        13.8  Scheduling of Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service: 
    Schedules for the Transmission Customer's Firm Point-To-Point 
    Transmission Service must be submitted to the Transmission Provider 
    no later than 10:00 a.m. [or a reasonable time that is generally 
    accepted in the region and is consistently adhered to by the 
    Transmission Provider] of the day prior to commencement of such 
    service. Schedules submitted after 10:00 a.m. will be accommodated, 
    if practicable. Hour-to-hour schedules of any capacity and energy 
    that is to be delivered must be stated in increments of 1,000 kW per 
    hour [or a reasonable increment that is generally accepted in the 
    region and is consistently adhered to by the Transmission Provider]. 
    Transmission Customers within the Transmission Provider's service 
    area with multiple requests for Transmission Service at a Point of 
    Receipt, each of which is under 1,000 kW per hour, may consolidate 
    their service requests at a common point of receipt into units of 
    1,000 kW per hour for scheduling and billing purposes. Scheduling 
    changes will be
    
    [[Page 12471]]
    
    permitted up to twenty (20) minutes [or a reasonable time that is 
    generally accepted in the region and is consistently adhered to by 
    the Transmission Provider] before the start of the next clock hour 
    provided that the Delivering Party and Receiving Party also agree to 
    the schedule modification. The Transmission Provider will furnish to 
    the Delivering Party's system operator, hour-to-hour schedules equal 
    to those furnished by the Receiving Party (unless reduced for 
    losses) and shall deliver the capacity and energy provided by such 
    schedules. Should the Transmission Customer, Delivering Party or 
    Receiving Party revise or terminate any schedule, such party shall 
    immediately notify the Transmission Provider, and the Transmission 
    Provider shall have the right to adjust accordingly the schedule for 
    capacity and energy to be received and to be delivered.
    
    14  Nature of Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service
    
        14.1  Term: Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service will be 
    available for periods ranging from one (1) hour to one (1) month. 
    However, a Purchaser of Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service 
    will be entitled to reserve a sequential term of service (such as a 
    sequential monthly term without having to wait for the initial term 
    to expire before requesting another monthly term) so that the total 
    time period for which the reservation applies is greater than one 
    month, subject to the requirements of Section 18.3.
        14.2  Reservation Priority: Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service shall be available from transmission capability in excess of 
    that needed for reliable service to Native Load Customers, Network 
    Customers and other Transmission Customers taking Long-Term and 
    Short-Term Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service. A higher 
    priority will be assigned to reservations with a longer duration of 
    service. In the event the Transmission System is constrained, 
    competing requests of equal duration will be prioritized based on 
    the highest price offered by the Eligible Customer for the 
    Transmission Service. Eligible Customers that have already reserved 
    shorter term service have the right of first refusal to match any 
    longer term reservation before being preempted. A longer term 
    competing request for Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service 
    will be granted if the Eligible Customer with the right of first 
    refusal does not agree to match the competing request: (a) 
    immediately for hourly Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service 
    after notification by the Transmission Provider; and, (b) within 24 
    hours (or earlier if necessary to comply with the scheduling 
    deadlines provided in section 14.6) for Non-Firm Point-To-Point 
    Transmission Service other than hourly transactions after 
    notification by the Transmission Provider. Transmission service for 
    Network Customers from resources other than designated Network 
    Resources will have a higher priority than any Non-Firm Point-To-
    Point Transmission Service. Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service over secondary Point(s) of Receipt and Point(s) of Delivery 
    will have the lowest reservation priority under the Tariff.
        14.3  Use of Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service by the 
    Transmission Provider: The Transmission Provider will be subject to 
    the rates, terms and conditions of Part II of the Tariff when making 
    Third-Party Sales under (i) agreements executed on or after [insert 
    date sixty (60) days after publication in Federal Register] or (ii) 
    agreements executed prior to the aforementioned date that the 
    Commission requires to be unbundled, by the date specified by the 
    Commission. The Transmission Provider will maintain separate 
    accounting, pursuant to Section 8 , for any use of Non-Firm Point-
    To-Point Transmission Service to make Third-Party Sales.
        14.4  Service Agreements: The Transmission Provider shall offer 
    a standard form Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service 
    Agreement (Attachment B) to an Eligible Customer when it first 
    submits a Completed Application for Non-Firm Point-To-Point 
    Transmission Service pursuant to the Tariff. Executed Service 
    Agreements that contain the information required under the Tariff 
    shall be filed with the Commission in compliance with applicable 
    Commission regulations.
        14.5  Classification of Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service: Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service shall be 
    offered under terms and conditions contained in Part II of the 
    Tariff. The Transmission Provider undertakes no obligation under the 
    Tariff to plan its Transmission System in order to have sufficient 
    capacity for Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service. Parties 
    requesting Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service for the 
    transmission of firm power do so with the full realization that such 
    service is subject to availability and to Curtailment or 
    Interruption under the terms of the Tariff. The Transmission 
    Provider shall specify the rate treatment and all related terms and 
    conditions applicable in the event that a Transmission Customer 
    (including Third-Party Sales by the Transmission Provider) exceeds 
    its non-firm capacity reservation. Non-Firm Point-To-Point 
    Transmission Service shall include transmission of energy on an 
    hourly basis and transmission of scheduled short-term capacity and 
    energy on a daily, weekly or monthly basis, but not to exceed one 
    month's reservation for any one Application, under Schedule 8.
        14.6  Scheduling of Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service: Schedules for Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service 
    must be submitted to the Transmission Provider no later than 2:00 
    p.m. [or a reasonable time that is generally accepted in the region 
    and is consistently adhered to by the Transmission Provider] of the 
    day prior to commencement of such service. Schedules submitted after 
    2:00 p.m. will be accommodated, if practicable. Hour-to-hour 
    schedules of energy that is to be delivered must be stated in 
    increments of 1,000 kW per hour [or a reasonable increment that is 
    generally accepted in the region and is consistently adhered to by 
    the Transmission Provider]. Transmission Customers within the 
    Transmission Provider's service area with multiple requests for 
    Transmission Service at a Point of Receipt, each of which is under 
    1,000 kW per hour, may consolidate their schedules at a common Point 
    of Receipt into units of 1,000 kW per hour. Scheduling changes will 
    be permitted up to twenty (20) minutes [or a reasonable time that is 
    generally accepted in the region and is consistently adhered to by 
    the Transmission Provider] before the start of the next clock hour 
    provided that the Delivering Party and Receiving Party also agree to 
    the schedule modification. The Transmission Provider will furnish to 
    the Delivering Party's system operator, hour-to-hour schedules equal 
    to those furnished by the Receiving Party (unless reduced for 
    losses) and shall deliver the capacity and energy provided by such 
    schedules. Should the Transmission Customer, Delivering Party or 
    Receiving Party revise or terminate any schedule, such party shall 
    immediately notify the Transmission Provider, and the Transmission 
    Provider shall have the right to adjust accordingly the schedule for 
    capacity and energy to be received and to be delivered.
        14.7  Curtailment or Interruption of Service: The Transmission 
    Provider reserves the right to Curtail, in whole or in part, Non-
    Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service provided under the Tariff 
    for reliability reasons when, an emergency or other unforeseen 
    condition threatens to impair or degrade the reliability of its 
    Transmission System. The Transmission Provider reserves the right to 
    Interrupt, in whole or in part, Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service provided under the Tariff for economic reasons in order to 
    accommodate (1) a request for Firm Transmission Service, (2) a 
    request for Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service of greater 
    duration, (3) a request for Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service of equal duration with a higher price, or (4) transmission 
    service for Network Customers from non-designated resources. The 
    Transmission Provider also will discontinue or reduce service to the 
    Transmission Customer to the extent that deliveries for transmission 
    are discontinued or reduced at the Point(s) of Receipt. Where 
    required, Curtailments or Interruptions will be made on a non-
    discriminatory basis to the transaction(s) that effectively relieve 
    the constraint, however, Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service shall be subordinate to Firm Transmission Service. If 
    multiple transactions require Curtailment or Interruption, to the 
    extent practicable and consistent with Good Utility Practice, 
    Curtailments or Interruptions will be made to transactions of the 
    shortest term (e.g., hourly non-firm transactions will be Curtailed 
    or Interrupted before daily non-firm transactions and daily non-firm 
    transactions will be Curtailed or Interrupted before weekly non-firm 
    transactions). Transmission service for Network Customers from 
    resources other than designated Network Resources will have a higher 
    priority than any Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service under 
    the Tariff. Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service over 
    secondary Point(s) of Receipt and Point(s) of Delivery will have a 
    lower priority than any Non-Firm
    
    [[Page 12472]]
    
    Point-To-Point Transmission Service under the Tariff. The 
    Transmission Provider will provide advance notice of Curtailment or 
    Interruption where such notice can be provided consistent with Good 
    Utility Practice.
    
    15  Service Availability
    
        15.1  General Conditions: The Transmission Provider will provide 
    Firm and Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service over, on or 
    across its Transmission System to any Transmission Customer that has 
    met the requirements of Section 16.
        15.2  Determination of Available Transmission Capability: A 
    description of the Transmission Provider's specific methodology for 
    assessing available transmission capability posted on the 
    Transmission Provider's OASIS (Section ) is contained in Attachment 
    of the Tariff. In the event sufficient transmission capability may 
    not exist to accommodate a service request, the Transmission 
    Provider will respond by performing a System Impact Study.
        15.3  Initiating Service in the Absence of an Executed Service 
    Agreement: If the Transmission Provider and the Transmission 
    Customer requesting Firm or Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service cannot agree on all the terms and conditions of the Point-
    To-Point Service Agreement, the Transmission Provider shall file 
    with the Commission, within thirty (30) days after the date the 
    Transmission Customer provides written notification directing the 
    Transmission Provider to file, an unexecuted Point-To-Point Service 
    Agreement containing terms and conditions deemed appropriate by the 
    Transmission Provider for such requested Transmission Service. The 
    Transmission Provider shall commence providing Transmission Service 
    subject to the Transmission Customer agreeing to (i) compensate the 
    Transmission Provider at whatever rate the Commission ultimately 
    determines to be just and reasonable, and (ii) comply with the terms 
    and conditions of the Tariff including posting appropriate security 
    deposits in accordance with the terms of Section 17.3.
        15.4  Obligation to Provide Transmission Service that Requires 
    Expansion or Modification of the Transmission System: If the 
    Transmission Provider determines that it cannot accommodate a 
    Completed Application for Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service 
    because of insufficient capability on its Transmission System, the 
    Transmission Provider will use due diligence to expand or modify its 
    Transmission System to provide the requested Firm Transmission 
    Service, provided the Transmission Customer agrees to compensate the 
    Transmission Provider for such costs pursuant to the terms of 
    Section 27. The Transmission Provider will conform to Good Utility 
    Practice in determining the need for new facilities and in the 
    design and construction of such facilities. The obligation applies 
    only to those facilities that the Transmission Provider has the 
    right to expand or modify.
        15.5  Deferral of Service: The Transmission Provider may defer 
    providing service until it completes construction of new 
    transmission facilities or upgrades needed to provide Firm Point-To-
    Point Transmission Service whenever the Transmission Provider 
    determines that providing the requested service would, without such 
    new facilities or upgrades, impair or degrade reliability to any 
    existing firm services.
        15.6  Other Transmission Service Schedules: Eligible Customers 
    receiving transmission service under other agreements on file with 
    the Commission may continue to receive transmission service under 
    those agreements until such time as those agreements may be modified 
    by the Commission.
        15.7  Real Power Losses: Real Power Losses are associated with 
    all transmission service. The Transmission Provider is not obligated 
    to provide Real Power Losses. The Transmission Customer is 
    responsible for replacing losses associated with all transmission 
    service as calculated by the Transmission Provider. The applicable 
    Real Power Loss factors are as follows: [To be completed by the 
    Transmission Provider].
    
    16  Transmission Customer Responsibilities
    
        16.1  Conditions Required of Transmission Customers: Point-To-
    Point Transmission Service shall be provided by the Transmission 
    Provider only if the following conditions are satisfied by the 
    Transmission Customer:
        a. The Transmission Customer has pending a Completed Application 
    for service;
        b. The Transmission Customer meets the creditworthiness criteria 
    set forth in Section 11;
        c. The Transmission Customer will have arrangements in place for 
    any other transmission service necessary to effect the delivery from 
    the generating source to the Transmission Provider prior to the time 
    service under Part II of the Tariff commences;
        d. The Transmission Customer agrees to pay for any facilities 
    constructed and chargeable to such Transmission Customer under Part 
    II of the Tariff, whether or not the Transmission Customer takes 
    service for the full term of its reservation; and
        e. The Transmission Customer has executed a Point-To-Point 
    Service Agreement or has agreed to receive service pursuant to 
    Section 15.3.
        16.2  Transmission Customer Responsibility for Third-Party 
    Arrangements: Any scheduling arrangements that may be required by 
    other electric systems shall be the responsibility of the 
    Transmission Customer requesting service. The Transmission Customer 
    shall provide, unless waived by the Transmission Provider, 
    notification to the Transmission Provider identifying such systems 
    and authorizing them to schedule the capacity and energy to be 
    transmitted by the Transmission Provider pursuant to Part II of the 
    Tariff on behalf of the Receiving Party at the Point of Delivery or 
    the Delivering Party at the Point of Receipt. However, the 
    Transmission Provider will undertake reasonable efforts to assist 
    the Transmission Customer in making such arrangements, including 
    without limitation, providing any information or data required by 
    such other electric system pursuant to Good Utility Practice.
    
    17  Procedures for Arranging Firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service
    
        17.1  Application: A request for Firm Point-To-Point 
    Transmission Service for periods of one year or longer must contain 
    a written Application to: [Transmission Provider Name and Address], 
    at least sixty (60) days in advance of the calendar month in which 
    service is to commence. The Transmission Provider will consider 
    requests for such firm service on shorter notice when feasible. 
    Requests for firm service for periods of less than one year shall be 
    subject to expedited procedures that shall be negotiated between the 
    Parties within the time constraints provided in Section 17.5. All 
    Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service requests should be 
    submitted by entering the information listed below on the 
    Transmission Provider's OASIS. Prior to implementation of the 
    Transmission Provider's OASIS, a Completed Application may be 
    submitted by (i) transmitting the required information to the 
    Transmission Provider by telefax, or (ii) providing the information 
    by telephone over the Transmission Provider's time recorded 
    telephone line. Each of these methods will provide a time-stamped 
    record for establishing the priority of the Application.
        17.2  Completed Application: A Completed Application shall 
    provide all of the information included in 18 CFR Sec. 2.20 
    including but not limited to the following:
        (i) The identity, address, telephone number and facsimile number 
    of the entity requesting service;
        (ii) A statement that the entity requesting service is, or will 
    be upon commencement of service, an Eligible Customer under the 
    Tariff;
        (iii) The location of the Point(s) of Receipt and Point(s) of 
    Delivery and the identities of the Delivering Parties and the 
    Receiving Parties;
        (iv) The location of the generating facility(ies) supplying the 
    capacity and energy and the location of the load ultimately served 
    by the capacity and energy transmitted. The Transmission Provider 
    will treat this information as confidential except to the extent 
    that disclosure of this information is required by this Tariff, by 
    regulatory or judicial order, for reliability purposes pursuant to 
    Good Utility Practice or pursuant to RTG transmission information 
    sharing agreements. The Transmission Provider shall treat this 
    information consistent with the standards of conduct contained in 
    Part 37 of the Commission's regulations;
        (v) A description of the supply characteristics of the capacity 
    and energy to be delivered;
        (vi) An estimate of the capacity and energy expected to be 
    delivered to the Receiving Party;
        (vii) The Service Commencement Date and the term of the 
    requested Transmission Service; and
        (viii) The transmission capacity requested for each Point of 
    Receipt and each Point of Delivery on the Transmission Provider's 
    Transmission System; customers may combine their requests for 
    service in order to satisfy the minimum transmission capacity 
    requirement.
    
    [[Page 12473]]
    
        The Transmission Provider shall treat this information 
    consistent with the standards of conduct contained in Part 37 of the 
    Commission's regulations.
        17.3  Deposit: A Completed Application for Firm Point-To-Point 
    Transmission Service also shall include a deposit of either one 
    month's charge for Reserved Capacity or the full charge for Reserved 
    Capacity for service requests of less than one month. If the 
    Application is rejected by the Transmission Provider because it does 
    not meet the conditions for service as set forth herein, or in the 
    case of requests for service arising in connection with losing 
    bidders in a Request For Proposals (RFP), said deposit shall be 
    returned with interest less any reasonable costs incurred by the 
    Transmission Provider in connection with the review of the losing 
    bidder's Application. The deposit also will be returned with 
    interest less any reasonable costs incurred by the Transmission 
    Provider if the Transmission Provider is unable to complete new 
    facilities needed to provide the service. If an Application is 
    withdrawn or the Eligible Customer decides not to enter into a 
    Service Agreement for Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service, the 
    deposit shall be refunded in full, with interest, less reasonable 
    costs incurred by the Transmission Provider to the extent such costs 
    have not already been recovered by the Transmission Provider from 
    the Eligible Customer. The Transmission Provider will provide to the 
    Eligible Customer a complete accounting of all costs deducted from 
    the refunded deposit, which the Eligible Customer may contest if 
    there is a dispute concerning the deducted costs. Deposits 
    associated with construction of new facilities are subject to the 
    provisions of Section 19. If a Service Agreement for Firm Point-To-
    Point Transmission Service is executed, the deposit, with interest, 
    will be returned to the Transmission Customer upon expiration or 
    termination of the Service Agreement for Firm Point-To-Point 
    Transmission Service. Applicable interest shall be computed in 
    accordance with the Commission's regulations at 18 CFR 
    Sec. 35.19a(a)(2)(iii), and shall be calculated from the day the 
    deposit check is credited to the Transmission Provider's account.
        17.4  Notice of Deficient Application: If an Application fails 
    to meet the requirements of the Tariff, the Transmission Provider 
    shall notify the entity requesting service within fifteen (15) days 
    of receipt of the reasons for such failure. The Transmission 
    Provider will attempt to remedy minor deficiencies in the 
    Application through informal communications with the Eligible 
    Customer. If such efforts are unsuccessful, the Transmission 
    Provider shall return the Application, along with any deposit, with 
    interest. Upon receipt of a new or revised Application that fully 
    complies with the requirements of Part II of the Tariff, the 
    Eligible Customer shall be assigned a new priority consistent with 
    the date of the new or revised Application.
        17.5  Response to a Completed Application: Following receipt of 
    a Completed Application for Firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service, the Transmission Provider shall make a determination of 
    available transmission capability as required in Section 15.2. The 
    Transmission Provider shall notify the Eligible Customer as soon as 
    practicable, but not later than thirty (30) days after the date of 
    receipt of a Completed Application either (i) if it will be able to 
    provide service without performing a System Impact Study or (ii) if 
    such a study is needed to evaluate the impact of the Application 
    pursuant to Section 19.1. Responses by the Transmission Provider 
    must be made as soon as practicable to all completed applications 
    (including applications by its own merchant function) and the timing 
    of such responses must be made on a non-discriminatory basis.
        17.6  Execution of Service Agreement: Whenever the Transmission 
    Provider determines that a System Impact Study is not required and 
    that the service can be provided, it shall notify the Eligible 
    Customer as soon as practicable but no later than thirty (30) days 
    after receipt of the Completed Application. Where a System Impact 
    Study is required, the provisions of Section 19 will govern the 
    execution of a Service Agreement. Failure of an Eligible Customer to 
    execute and return the Service Agreement or request the filing of an 
    unexecuted service agreement pursuant to Section , within fifteen 
    (15) days after it is tendered by the Transmission Provider will be 
    deemed a withdrawal and termination of the Application and any 
    deposit submitted shall be refunded with interest. Nothing herein 
    limits the right of an Eligible Customer to file another Application 
    after such withdrawal and termination.
        17.7  Extensions for Commencement of Service: The Transmission 
    Customer can obtain up to five (5) one-year extensions for the 
    commencement of service. The Transmission Customer may postpone 
    service by paying a non-refundable annual reservation fee equal to 
    one-month's charge for Firm Transmission Service for each year or 
    fraction thereof. If during any extension for the commencement of 
    service an Eligible Customer submits a Completed Application for 
    Firm Transmission Service, and such request can be satisfied only by 
    releasing all or part of the Transmission Customer's Reserved 
    Capacity, the original Reserved Capacity will be released unless the 
    following condition is satisfied. Within thirty (30) days, the 
    original Transmission Customer agrees to pay the Firm Point-To-Point 
    transmission rate for its Reserved Capacity concurrent with the new 
    Service Commencement Date. In the event the Transmission Customer 
    elects to release the Reserved Capacity, the reservation fees or 
    portions thereof previously paid will be forfeited.
    
    18  Procedures for Arranging Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service
    
        18.1  Application: Eligible Customers seeking Non-Firm Point-To-
    Point Transmission Service must submit a Completed Application to 
    the Transmission Provider. Applications should be submitted by 
    entering the information listed below on the Transmission Provider's 
    OASIS. Prior to implementation of the Transmission Provider's OASIS, 
    a Completed Application may be submitted by (i) transmitting the 
    required information to the Transmission Provider by telefax, or 
    (ii) providing the information by telephone over the Transmission 
    Provider's time recorded telephone line. Each of these methods will 
    provide a time-stamped record for establishing the service priority 
    of the Application.
        18.2  Completed Application: A Completed Application shall 
    provide all of the information included in 18 CFR Sec. 2.20 
    including but not limited to the following:
        (i) The identity, address, telephone number and facsimile number 
    of the entity requesting service;
        (ii) A statement that the entity requesting service is, or will 
    be upon commencement of service, an Eligible Customer under the 
    Tariff;
        (iii) The Point(s) of Receipt and the Point(s) of Delivery;
        (iv) The maximum amount of capacity requested at each Point of 
    Receipt and Point of Delivery; and
        (v) The proposed dates and hours for initiating and terminating 
    transmission service hereunder.
    
    In addition to the information specified above, when required to 
    properly evaluate system conditions, the Transmission Provider also 
    may ask the Transmission Customer to provide the following:
        (vi) The electrical location of the initial source of the power 
    to be transmitted pursuant to the Transmission Customer's request 
    for service; and
        (vii) The electrical location of the ultimate load.
        The Transmission Provider will treat this information in (vi) 
    and (vii) as confidential at the request of the Transmission 
    Customer except to the extent that disclosure of this information is 
    required by this Tariff, by regulatory or judicial order, for 
    reliability purposes pursuant to Good Utility Practice, or pursuant 
    to RTG transmission information sharing agreements. The Transmission 
    Provider shall treat this information consistent with the standards 
    of conduct contained in Part 37 of the Commission's regulations.
        18.3  Reservation of Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service: Requests for monthly service shall be submitted no earlier 
    than sixty (60) days before service is to commence; requests for 
    weekly service shall be submitted no earlier than fourteen (14) days 
    before service is to commence, requests for daily service shall be 
    submitted no earlier than two (2) days before service is to 
    commence, and requests for hourly service shall be submitted no 
    earlier than noon the day before service is to commence. Requests 
    for service received later than 2:00 p.m. prior to the day service 
    is scheduled to commence will be accommodated if practicable [or 
    such reasonable times that are generally accepted in the region and 
    are consistently adhered to by the Transmission Provider].
        18.4  Determination of Available Transmission Capability: 
    Following receipt of a tendered schedule the Transmission Provider 
    will make a determination on a non-discriminatory basis of available 
    transmission capability pursuant to Section
    
    [[Page 12474]]
    
    15.2. Such determination shall be made as soon as reasonably 
    practicable after receipt, but not later than the following time 
    periods for the following terms of service (i) thirty (30) minutes 
    for hourly service, (ii) thirty (30) minutes for daily service, 
    (iii) four (4) hours for weekly service, and (iv) two (2) days for 
    monthly service. [Or such reasonable times that are generally 
    accepted in the region and are consistently adhered to by the 
    Transmission Provider].
    
    19  Additional Study Procedures For Firm Point-To-Point 
    Transmission Service Requests
    
          Notice of Need for System Impact Study: After receiving a 
    request for service, the Transmission Provider shall determine on a 
    non-discriminatory basis whether a System Impact Study is needed. A 
    description of the Transmission Provider's methodology for 
    completing a System Impact Study is provided in Attachment D. If the 
    Transmission Provider determines that a System Impact Study is 
    necessary to accommodate the requested service, it shall so inform 
    the Eligible Customer, as soon as practicable. In such cases, the 
    Transmission Provider shall within thirty (30) days of receipt of a 
    Completed Application, tender a System Impact Study Agreement 
    pursuant to which the Eligible Customer shall agree to reimburse the 
    Transmission Provider for performing the required System Impact 
    Study. For a service request to remain a Completed Application, the 
    Eligible Customer shall execute the System Impact Study Agreement 
    and return it to the Transmission Provider within fifteen (15) days. 
    If the Eligible Customer elects not to execute the System Impact 
    Study Agreement, its application shall be deemed withdrawn and its 
    deposit, pursuant to Section 17.3 , shall be returned with interest.
        19.2 System Impact Study Agreement and Cost Reimbursement:
        (i) The System Impact Study Agreement will clearly specify the 
    Transmission Provider's estimate of the actual cost, and time for 
    completion of the System Impact Study. The charge shall not exceed 
    the actual cost of the study. In performing the System Impact Study, 
    the Transmission Provider shall rely, to the extent reasonably 
    practicable, on existing transmission planning studies. The Eligible 
    Customer will not be assessed a charge for such existing studies; 
    however, the Eligible Customer will be responsible for charges 
    associated with any modifications to existing planning studies that 
    are reasonably necessary to evaluate the impact of the Eligible 
    Customer's request for service on the Transmission System.
        (ii) If in response to multiple Eligible Customers requesting 
    service in relation to the same competitive solicitation, a single 
    System Impact Study is sufficient for the Transmission Provider to 
    accommodate the requests for service, the costs of that study shall 
    be pro-rated among the Eligible Customers.
        (iii) For System Impact Studies that the Transmission Provider 
    conducts on its own behalf, the Transmission Provider shall record 
    the cost of the System Impact Studies pursuant to Section 20.
        19.3 System Impact Study Procedures: Upon receipt of an executed 
    System Impact Study Agreement, the Transmission Provider will use 
    due diligence to complete the required System Impact Study within a 
    sixty (60) day period. The System Impact Study shall identify any 
    system constraints and redispatch options, additional Direct 
    Assignment Facilities or Network Upgrades required to provide the 
    requested service. In the event that the Transmission Provider is 
    unable to complete the required System Impact Study within such time 
    period, it shall so notify the Eligible Customer and provide an 
    estimated completion date along with an explanation of the reasons 
    why additional time is required to complete the required studies. A 
    copy of the completed System Impact Study and related work papers 
    shall be made available to the Eligible Customer. The Transmission 
    Provider will use the same due diligence in completing the System 
    Impact Study for an Eligible Customer as it uses when completing 
    studies for itself. The Transmission Provider shall notify the 
    Eligible Customer immediately upon completion of the System Impact 
    Study if the Transmission System will be adequate to accommodate all 
    or part of a request for service or that no costs are likely to be 
    incurred for new transmission facilities or upgrades. In order for a 
    request to remain a Completed Application, within fifteen (15) days 
    of completion of the System Impact Study the Eligible Customer must 
    execute a Service Agreement or request the filing of an unexecuted 
    Service Agreement pursuant to Section 15.3, or the Application shall 
    be deemed terminated and withdrawn.
        19.4  Facilities Study Procedures: If a System Impact Study 
    indicates that additions or upgrades to the Transmission System are 
    needed to supply the Eligible Customer's service request, the 
    Transmission Provider, within thirty (30) days of the completion of 
    the System Impact Study, shall tender to the Eligible Customer a 
    Facilities Study Agreement pursuant to which the Eligible Customer 
    shall agree to reimburse the Transmission Provider for performing 
    the required Facilities Study. For a service request to remain a 
    Completed Application, the Eligible Customer shall execute the 
    Facilities Study Agreement and return it to the Transmission 
    Provider within fifteen (15) days. If the Eligible Customer elects 
    not to execute the Facilities Study Agreement, its application shall 
    be deemed withdrawn and its deposit, pursuant to Section 17.3, shall 
    be returned with interest. Upon receipt of an executed Facilities 
    Study Agreement, the Transmission Provider will use due diligence to 
    complete the required Facilities Study within a sixty (60) day 
    period. If the Transmission Provider is unable to complete the 
    Facilities Study in the allotted time period, the Transmission 
    Provider shall notify the Transmission Customer and provide an 
    estimate of the time needed to reach a final determination along 
    with an explanation of the reasons that additional time is required 
    to complete the study. When completed, the Facilities Study will 
    include a good faith estimate of (i) the cost of Direct Assignment 
    Facilities to be charged to the Transmission Customer, (ii) the 
    Transmission Customer's appropriate share of the cost of any 
    required Network Upgrades as determined pursuant to the provisions 
    of Part II of the Tariff, and (iii) the time required to complete 
    such construction and initiate the requested service. The 
    Transmission Customer shall provide the Transmission Provider with a 
    letter of credit or other reasonable form of security acceptable to 
    the Transmission Provider equivalent to the costs of new facilities 
    or upgrades consistent with commercial practices as established by 
    the Uniform Commercial Code. The Transmission Customer shall have 
    thirty (30) days to execute a Service Agreement or request the 
    filing of an unexecuted Service Agreement and provide the required 
    letter of credit or other form of security or the request will no 
    longer be a Completed Application and shall be deemed terminated and 
    withdrawn.
        19.5  Facilities Study Modifications: Any change in design 
    arising from inability to site or construct facilities as proposed 
    will require development of a revised good faith estimate. New good 
    faith estimates also will be required in the event of new statutory 
    or regulatory requirements that are effective before the completion 
    of construction or other circumstances beyond the control of the 
    Transmission Provider that significantly affect the final cost of 
    new facilities or upgrades to be charged to the Transmission 
    Customer pursuant to the provisions of Part II of the Tariff.
        19.6  Due Diligence in Completing New Facilities: The 
    Transmission Provider shall use due diligence to add necessary 
    facilities or upgrade its Transmission System within a reasonable 
    time. The Transmission Provider will not upgrade its existing or 
    planned Transmission System in order to provide the requested Firm 
    Point-To-Point Transmission Service if doing so would impair system 
    reliability or otherwise impair or degrade existing firm service.
        19.7  Partial Interim Service: If the Transmission Provider 
    determines that it will not have adequate transmission capability to 
    satisfy the full amount of a Completed Application for Firm Point-
    To-Point Transmission Service, the Transmission Provider nonetheless 
    shall be obligated to offer and provide the portion of the requested 
    Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service that can be accommodated 
    without addition of any facilities and through redispatch. However, 
    the Transmission Provider shall not be obligated to provide the 
    incremental amount of requested Firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service that requires the addition of facilities or upgrades to the 
    Transmission System until such facilities or upgrades have been 
    placed in service.
        19.8  Expedited Procedures for New Facilities: In lieu of the 
    procedures set forth above, the Eligible Customer shall have the 
    option to expedite the process by requesting the Transmission 
    Provider to tender at one time, together with the results of 
    required studies, an ``Expedited Service Agreement'' pursuant to 
    which the Eligible Customer would agree to compensate the 
    Transmission Provider for all costs incurred pursuant to the terms 
    of the Tariff. In order to exercise this option, the Eligible 
    Customer shall request in
    
    [[Page 12475]]
    
    writing an expedited Service Agreement covering all of the above-
    specified items within thirty (30) days of receiving the results of 
    the System Impact Study identifying needed facility additions or 
    upgrades or costs incurred in providing the requested service. While 
    the Transmission Provider agrees to provide the Eligible Customer 
    with its best estimate of the new facility costs and other charges 
    that may be incurred, such estimate shall not be binding and the 
    Eligible Customer must agree in writing to compensate the 
    Transmission Provider for all costs incurred pursuant to the 
    provisions of the Tariff. The Eligible Customer shall execute and 
    return such an Expedited Service Agreement within fifteen (15) days 
    of its receipt or the Eligible Customer's request for service will 
    cease to be a Completed Application and will be deemed terminated 
    and withdrawn.
    
    20  Procedures if The Transmission Provider is Unable to Complete 
    New Transmission Facilities for Firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service
    
        20.1  Delays in Construction of New Facilities: If any event 
    occurs that will materially affect the time for completion of new 
    facilities, or the ability to complete them, the Transmission 
    Provider shall promptly notify the Transmission Customer. In such 
    circumstances, the Transmission Provider shall within thirty (30) 
    days of notifying the Transmission Customer of such delays, convene 
    a technical meeting with the Transmission Customer to evaluate the 
    alternatives available to the Transmission Customer. The 
    Transmission Provider also shall make available to the Transmission 
    Customer studies and work papers related to the delay, including all 
    information that is in the possession of the Transmission Provider 
    that is reasonably needed by the Transmission Customer to evaluate 
    any alternatives.
        20.2  Alternatives to the Original Facility Additions: When the 
    review process of Section determines that one or more alternatives 
    exist to the originally planned construction project, the 
    Transmission Provider shall present such alternatives for 
    consideration by the Transmission Customer. If, upon review of any 
    alternatives, the Transmission Customer desires to maintain its 
    Completed Application subject to construction of the alternative 
    facilities, it may request the Transmission Provider to submit a 
    revised Service Agreement for Firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service. If the alternative approach solely involves Non-Firm Point-
    To-Point Transmission Service, the Transmission Provider shall 
    promptly tender a Service Agreement for Non-Firm Point-To-Point 
    Transmission Service providing for the service. In the event the 
    Transmission Provider concludes that no reasonable alternative 
    exists and the Transmission Customer disagrees, the Transmission 
    Customer may seek relief under the dispute resolution procedures 
    pursuant to Section or it may refer the dispute to the Commission 
    for resolution.
        20.3  Refund Obligation for Unfinished Facility Additions: If 
    the Transmission Provider and the Transmission Customer mutually 
    agree that no other reasonable alternatives exist and the requested 
    service cannot be provided out of existing capability under the 
    conditions of Part II of the Tariff, the obligation to provide the 
    requested Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service shall terminate 
    and any deposit made by the Transmission Customer shall be returned 
    with interest pursuant to Commission regulations 35.19a(a)(2)(iii). 
    However, the Transmission Customer shall be responsible for all 
    prudently incurred costs by the Transmission Provider through the 
    time construction was suspended.
    
    21  Provisions Relating to Transmission Construction and Services 
    on the Systems of Other Utilities
    
        21.1  Responsibility for Third-Party System Additions: The 
    Transmission Provider shall not be responsible for making 
    arrangements for any necessary engineering, permitting, and 
    construction of transmission or distribution facilities on the 
    system(s) of any other entity or for obtaining any regulatory 
    approval for such facilities. The Transmission Provider will 
    undertake reasonable efforts to assist the Transmission Customer in 
    obtaining such arrangements, including without limitation, providing 
    any information or data required by such other electric system 
    pursuant to Good Utility Practice.
        21.2  Coordination of Third-Party System Additions: In 
    circumstances where the need for transmission facilities or upgrades 
    is identified pursuant to the provisions of Part II of the Tariff, 
    and if such upgrades further require the addition of transmission 
    facilities on other systems, the Transmission Provider shall have 
    the right to coordinate construction on its own system with the 
    construction required by others. The Transmission Provider, after 
    consultation with the Transmission Customer and representatives of 
    such other systems, may defer construction of its new transmission 
    facilities, if the new transmission facilities on another system 
    cannot be completed in a timely manner. The Transmission Provider 
    shall notify the Transmission Customer in writing of the basis for 
    any decision to defer construction and the specific problems which 
    must be resolved before it will initiate or resume construction of 
    new facilities. Within sixty (60) days of receiving written 
    notification by the Transmission Provider of its intent to defer 
    construction pursuant to this section, the Transmission Customer may 
    challenge the decision in accordance with the dispute resolution 
    procedures pursuant to Section 12 or it may refer the dispute to the 
    Commission for resolution.
    
    22  Changes in Service Specifications
    
        22.1  Modifications On a Non-Firm Basis: The Transmission 
    Customer taking Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service may request 
    the Transmission Provider to provide transmission service on a non-
    firm basis over Receipt and Delivery Points other than those 
    specified in the Service Agreement (``Secondary Receipt and Delivery 
    Points''), in amounts not to exceed its firm capacity reservation, 
    without incurring an additional Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service charge or executing a new Service Agreement, subject to the 
    following conditions.
        (a) Service provided over Secondary Receipt and Delivery Points 
    will be non-firm only, on an as-available basis and will not 
    displace any firm or non-firm service reserved or scheduled by third 
    parties under the Tariff or by the Transmission Provider on behalf 
    of its Native Load Customers.
        (b) The sum of all Firm and non-firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service provided to the Transmission Customer at any time pursuant 
    to this section shall not exceed the Reserved Capacity in the 
    relevant Service Agreement under which such services are provided.
        (c) The Transmission Customer shall retain its right to schedule 
    Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service at the Receipt and Delivery 
    Points specified in the relevant Service Agreement in the amount of 
    its original capacity reservation.
        (d) Service over Secondary Receipt and Delivery Points on a non-
    firm basis shall not require the filing of an Application for Non-
    Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service under the Tariff. However, 
    all other requirements of Part II of the Tariff (except as to 
    transmission rates) shall apply to transmission service on a non-
    firm basis over Secondary Receipt and Delivery Points.
        22.2  Modification On a Firm Basis: Any request by a 
    Transmission Customer to modify Receipt and Delivery Points on a 
    firm basis shall be treated as a new request for service in 
    accordance with Section 17 hereof, except that such Transmission 
    Customer shall not be obligated to pay any additional deposit if the 
    capacity reservation does not exceed the amount reserved in the 
    existing Service Agreement. While such new request is pending, the 
    Transmission Customer shall retain its priority for service at the 
    existing firm Receipt and Delivery Points specified in its Service 
    Agreement.
    
    23  Sale or Assignment of Transmission Service
    
        23.1  Procedures for Assignment or Transfer of Service: Subject 
    to Commission approval of any necessary filings, a Transmission 
    Customer may sell, assign, or transfer all or a portion of its 
    rights under its Service Agreement, but only to another Eligible 
    Customer (the Assignee). The Transmission Customer that sells, 
    assigns or transfers its rights under its Service Agreement is 
    hereafter referred to as the Reseller. Compensation to the Reseller 
    shall not exceed the higher of (i) the original rate paid by the 
    Reseller, (ii) the Transmission Provider's maximum rate on file at 
    the time of the assignment, or (iii) the Reseller's opportunity cost 
    capped at the Transmission Provider's cost of expansion. If the 
    Assignee does not request any change in the Point(s) of Receipt or 
    the Point(s) of Delivery, or a change in any other term or condition 
    set forth in the original Service Agreement, the Assignee will 
    receive the same services as did the Reseller and the priority of 
    service for the Assignee will be the same as that of the Reseller. A 
    Reseller should notify the Transmission Provider as soon as possible 
    after any assignment or transfer of service
    
    [[Page 12476]]
    
    occurs but in any event, notification must be provided prior to any 
    provision of service to the Assignee. The Assignee will be subject 
    to all terms and conditions of this Tariff. If the Assignee requests 
    a change in service, the reservation priority of service will be 
    determined by the Transmission Provider pursuant to Section 13.2.
        23.2  Limitations on Assignment or Transfer of Service: If the 
    Assignee requests a change in the Point(s) of Receipt or Point(s) of 
    Delivery, or a change in any other specifications set forth in the 
    original Service Agreement, the Transmission Provider will consent 
    to such change subject to the provisions of the Tariff, provided 
    that the change will not impair the operation and reliability of the 
    Transmission Provider's generation, transmission, or distribution 
    systems. The Assignee shall compensate the Transmission Provider for 
    performing any System Impact Study needed to evaluate the capability 
    of the Transmission System to accommodate the proposed change and 
    any additional costs resulting from such change. The Reseller shall 
    remain liable for the performance of all obligations under the 
    Service Agreement, except as specifically agreed to by the Parties 
    through an amendment to the Service Agreement.
        23.3  Information on Assignment or Transfer of Service: In 
    accordance with Section 4, Resellers may use the Transmission 
    Provider's OASIS to post transmission capacity available for resale.
    
    24  Metering and Power Factor Correction at Receipt and Delivery 
    Point(s)
    
        24.1  Transmission Customer Obligations: Unless otherwise 
    agreed, the Transmission Customer shall be responsible for 
    installing and maintaining compatible metering and communications 
    equipment to accurately account for the capacity and energy being 
    transmitted under Part II of the Tariff and to communicate the 
    information to the Transmission Provider. Such equipment shall 
    remain the property of the Transmission Customer.
        24.2  Transmission Provider Access to Metering Data: The 
    Transmission Provider shall have access to metering data, which may 
    reasonably be required to facilitate measurements and billing under 
    the Service Agreement.
        24.3  Power Factor: Unless otherwise agreed, the Transmission 
    Customer is required to maintain a power factor within the same 
    range as the Transmission Provider pursuant to Good Utility 
    Practices. The power factor requirements are specified in the 
    Service Agreement where applicable.
    
    25  Compensation for Transmission Service
    
        Rates for Firm and Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service 
    are provided in the Schedules appended to the Tariff: Firm Point-To-
    Point Transmission Service (Schedule 7); and Non-Firm Point-To-Point 
    Transmission Service (Schedule 8). The Transmission Provider shall 
    use Part II of the Tariff to make its Third-Party Sales. The 
    Transmission Provider shall account for such use at the applicable 
    Tariff rates, pursuant to Section 8.
    
    26  Stranded Cost Recovery
    
        The Transmission Provider may seek to recover stranded costs 
    from the Transmission Customer pursuant to this Tariff in accordance 
    with the terms, conditions and procedures set forth in FERC Order 
    No. 888. However, the Transmission Provider must separately file any 
    specific proposed stranded cost charge under Section 205 of the 
    Federal Power Act.
    
    27  Compensation for New Facilities and Redispatch Costs
    
        Whenever a System Impact Study performed by the Transmission 
    Provider in connection with the provision of Firm Point-To-Point 
    Transmission Service identifies the need for new facilities, the 
    Transmission Customer shall be responsible for such costs to the 
    extent consistent with Commission policy. Whenever a System Impact 
    Study performed by the Transmission Provider identifies capacity 
    constraints that may be relieved more economically by redispatching 
    the Transmission Provider's resources than by building new 
    facilities or upgrading existing facilities to eliminate such 
    constraints, the Transmission Customer shall be responsible for the 
    redispatch costs to the extent consistent with Commission policy.
    
    III. Network Integration Transmission Service
    
    Preamble
    
        The Transmission Provider will provide Network Integration 
    Transmission Service pursuant to the applicable terms and conditions 
    contained in the Tariff and Service Agreement. Network Integration 
    Transmission Service allows the Network Customer to integrate, 
    economically dispatch and regulate its current and planned Network 
    Resources to serve its Network Load in a manner comparable to that 
    in which the Transmission Provider utilizes its Transmission System 
    to serve its Native Load Customers. Network Integration Transmission 
    Service also may be used by the Network Customer to deliver economy 
    energy purchases to its Network Load from non-designated resources 
    on an as-available basis without additional charge. Transmission 
    service for sales to non-designated loads will be provided pursuant 
    to the applicable terms and conditions of Part II of the Tariff.
    
    28  Nature of Network Integration Transmission Service
    
        28.1  Scope of Service: Network Integration Transmission Service 
    is a transmission service that allows Network Customers to 
    efficiently and economically utilize their Network Resources (as 
    well as other non-designated generation resources) to serve their 
    Network Load located in the Transmission Provider's Control Area and 
    any additional load that may be designated pursuant to Section 31.3 
    of the Tariff. The Network Customer taking Network Integration 
    Transmission Service must obtain or provide Ancillary Services 
    pursuant to Section 3.
        28.2  Transmission Provider Responsibilities: The Transmission 
    Provider will plan, construct, operate and maintain its Transmission 
    System in accordance with Good Utility Practice in order to provide 
    the Network Customer with Network Integration Transmission Service 
    over the Transmission Provider's Transmission System. The 
    Transmission Provider, on behalf of its Native Load Customers, shall 
    be required to designate resources and loads in the same manner as 
    any Network Customer under Part III of this Tariff. This information 
    must be consistent with the information used by the Transmission 
    Provider to calculate available transmission capability. The 
    Transmission Provider shall include the Network Customer's Network 
    Load in its Transmission System planning and shall, consistent with 
    Good Utility Practice, endeavor to construct and place into service 
    sufficient transmission capacity to deliver the Network Customer's 
    Network Resources to serve its Network Load on a basis comparable to 
    the Transmission Provider's delivery of its own generating and 
    purchased resources to its Native Load Customers.
        28.3  Network Integration Transmission Service: The Transmission 
    Provider will provide firm transmission service over its 
    Transmission System to the Network Customer for the delivery of 
    capacity and energy from its designated Network Resources to service 
    its Network Loads on a basis that is comparable to the Transmission 
    Provider's use of the Transmission System to reliably serve its 
    Native Load Customers.
        28.4  Secondary Service: The Network Customer may use the 
    Transmission Provider's Transmission System to deliver energy to its 
    Network Loads from resources that have not been designated as 
    Network Resources. Such energy shall be transmitted, on an as-
    available basis, at no additional charge. Deliveries from resources 
    other than Network Resources will have a higher priority than any 
    Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service under Part II of the 
    Tariff.
        28.5  Real Power Losses: Real Power Losses are associated with 
    all transmission service. The Transmission Provider is not obligated 
    to provide Real Power Losses. The Network Customer is responsible 
    for replacing losses associated with all transmission service as 
    calculated by the Transmission Provider. The applicable Real Power 
    Loss factors are as follows: [To be completed by the Transmission 
    Provider].
        28.6  Restrictions on Use of Service: The Network Customer shall 
    not use Network Integration Transmission Service for (i) sales of 
    capacity and energy to non-designated loads, or (ii) direct or 
    indirect provision of transmission service by the Network Customer 
    to third parties. All Network Customers taking Network Integration 
    Transmission Service shall use Point-To-Point Transmission Service 
    under Part II of the Tariff for any Third-Party Sale which requires 
    use of the Transmission Provider's Transmission System.
    
    29  Initiating Service
    
        29.1  Condition Precedent for Receiving Service: Subject to the 
    terms and conditions of Part III of the Tariff, the Transmission 
    Provider will provide Network Integration Transmission Service to 
    any Eligible
    
    [[Page 12477]]
    
    Customer, provided that (i) the Eligible Customer completes an 
    Application for service as provided under Part III of the Tariff, 
    (ii) the Eligible Customer and the Transmission Provider complete 
    the technical arrangements set forth in Sections 29.3 and 29.4, 
    (iii) the Eligible Customer executes a Service Agreement pursuant to 
    Attachment F for service under Part III of the Tariff or requests in 
    writing that the Transmission Provider file a proposed unexecuted 
    Service Agreement with the Commission, and (iv) the Eligible 
    Customer executes a Network Operating Agreement with the 
    Transmission Provider pursuant to Attachment G.
        29.2  Application Procedures: An Eligible Customer requesting 
    service under Part III of the Tariff must submit an Application, 
    with a deposit approximating the charge for one month of service, to 
    the Transmission Provider as far as possible in advance of the month 
    in which service is to commence. Unless subject to the procedures in 
    Section 2, Completed Applications for Network Integration 
    Transmission Service will be assigned a priority according to the 
    date and time the Application is received, with the earliest 
    Application receiving the highest priority. Applications should be 
    submitted by entering the information listed below on the 
    Transmission Provider's OASIS. Prior to implementation of the 
    Transmission Provider's OASIS, a Completed Application may be 
    submitted by (i) transmitting the required information to the 
    Transmission Provider by telefax, or (ii) providing the information 
    by telephone over the Transmission Provider's time recorded 
    telephone line. Each of these methods will provide a time-stamped 
    record for establishing the service priority of the Application. A 
    Completed Application shall provide all of the information included 
    in 18 CFR Sec. 2.20 including but not limited to the following:
        (i) The identity, address, telephone number and facsimile number 
    of the party requesting service;
        (ii) A statement that the party requesting service is, or will 
    be upon commencement of service, an Eligible Customer under the 
    Tariff;
        (iii) A description of the Network Load at each delivery point. 
    This description should separately identify and provide the Eligible 
    Customer's best estimate of the total loads to be served at each 
    transmission voltage level, and the loads to be served from each 
    Transmission Provider substation at the same transmission voltage 
    level. The description should include a ten (10) year forecast of 
    summer and winter load and resource requirements beginning with the 
    first year after the service is scheduled to commence;
        (iv) The amount and location of any interruptible loads included 
    in the Network Load. This shall include the summer and winter 
    capacity requirements for each interruptible load (had such load not 
    been interruptible), that portion of the load subject to 
    interruption, the conditions under which an interruption can be 
    implemented and any limitations on the amount and frequency of 
    interruptions. An Eligible Customer should identify the amount of 
    interruptible customer load (if any) included in the 10 year load 
    forecast provided in response to (iii) above;
        (v) A description of Network Resources (current and 10-year 
    projection), which shall include, for each Network Resource:
    
    --Unit size and amount of capacity from that unit to be designated 
    as Network Resource
    --VAR capability (both leading and lagging) of all generators
    --Operating restrictions
    --Any periods of restricted operations throughout the year
    --Maintenance schedules
    --Minimum loading level of unit
    --Normal operating level of unit
    --Any must-run unit designations required for system reliability or 
    contract reasons
    --Approximate variable generating cost ($/MWH) for redispatch 
    computations
    --Arrangements governing sale and delivery of power to third parties 
    from generating facilities located in the Transmission Provider 
    Control Area, where only a portion of unit output is designated as a 
    Network Resource
    --Description of purchased power designated as a Network Resource 
    including source of supply, Control Area location, transmission 
    arrangements and delivery point(s) to the Transmission Provider's 
    Transmission System;
    
        (vi) Description of Eligible Customer's transmission system:
    
    --Load flow and stability data, such as real and reactive parts of 
    the load, lines, transformers, reactive devices and load type, 
    including normal and emergency ratings of all transmission equipment 
    in a load flow format compatible with that used by the Transmission 
    Provider
    --Operating restrictions needed for reliability
    --Operating guides employed by system operators
    --Contractual restrictions or committed uses of the Eligible 
    Customer's transmission system, other than the Eligible Customer's 
    Network Loads and Resources
    --Location of Network Resources described in subsection (v) above
    --10 year projection of system expansions or upgrades
    --Transmission System maps that include any proposed expansions or 
    upgrades
    --Thermal ratings of Eligible Customer's Control Area ties with 
    other Control Areas; and
    
        (vii) Service Commencement Date and the term of the requested 
    Network Integration Transmission Service. The minimum term for 
    Network Integration Transmission Service is one year.
        Unless the Parties agree to a different time frame, the 
    Transmission Provider must acknowledge the request within ten (10) 
    days of receipt. The acknowledgement must include a date by which a 
    response, including a Service Agreement, will be sent to the 
    Eligible Customer. If an Application fails to meet the requirements 
    of this section, the Transmission Provider shall notify the Eligible 
    Customer requesting service within fifteen (15) days of receipt and 
    specify the reasons for such failure. Wherever possible, the 
    Transmission Provider will attempt to remedy deficiencies in the 
    Application through informal communications with the Eligible 
    Customer. If such efforts are unsuccessful, the Transmission 
    Provider shall return the Application without prejudice to the 
    Eligible Customer filing a new or revised Application that fully 
    complies with the requirements of this section. The Eligible 
    Customer will be assigned a new priority consistent with the date of 
    the new or revised Application. The Transmission Provider shall 
    treat this information consistent with the standards of conduct 
    contained in Part 37 of the Commission's regulations.
        29.3  Technical Arrangements to be Completed Prior to 
    Commencement of Service: Network Integration Transmission Service 
    shall not commence until the Transmission Provider and the Network 
    Customer, or a third party, have completed installation of all 
    equipment specified under the Network Operating Agreement consistent 
    with Good Utility Practice and any additional requirements 
    reasonably and consistently imposed to ensure the reliable operation 
    of the Transmission System. The Transmission Provider shall exercise 
    reasonable efforts, in coordination with the Network Customer, to 
    complete such arrangements as soon as practicable taking into 
    consideration the Service Commencement Date.
        29.4  Network Customer Facilities: The provision of Network 
    Integration Transmission Service shall be conditioned upon the 
    Network Customer's constructing, maintaining and operating the 
    facilities on its side of each delivery point or interconnection 
    necessary to reliably deliver capacity and energy from the 
    Transmission Provider's Transmission System to the Network Customer. 
    The Network Customer shall be solely responsible for constructing or 
    installing all facilities on the Network Customer's side of each 
    such delivery point or interconnection.
        29.5  Filing of Service Agreement: The Transmission Provider 
    will file Service Agreements with the Commission in compliance with 
    applicable Commission regulations.
    
    30  Network Resources
    
        30.1  Designation of Network Resources: Network Resources shall 
    include all generation owned, purchased or leased by the Network 
    Customer designated to serve Network Load under the Tariff. Network 
    Resources may not include resources, or any portion thereof, that 
    are committed for sale to non-designated third party load or 
    otherwise cannot be called upon to meet the Network Customer's 
    Network Load on a non-interruptible basis. Any owned or purchased 
    resources that were serving the Network Customer's loads under firm 
    agreements entered into on or before the Service Commencement Date 
    shall initially be designated as Network Resources until the Network 
    Customer terminates the designation of such resources.
        30.2  Designation of New Network Resources: The Network Customer 
    may designate a new Network Resource by providing the Transmission 
    Provider with as much advance notice as practicable. A designation 
    of a new Network Resource must
    
    [[Page 12478]]
    
    be made by a request for modification of service pursuant to an 
    Application under Section 29.
        30.3  Termination of Network Resources: The Network Customer may 
    terminate the designation of all or part of a generating resource as 
    a Network Resource at any time but should provide notification to 
    the Transmission Provider as soon as reasonably practicable.
        30.4  Operation of Network Resources: The Network Customer shall 
    not operate its designated Network Resources located in the Network 
    Customer's or Transmission Provider's Control Area such that the 
    output of those facilities exceeds its designated Network Load, plus 
    non-firm sales delivered pursuant to Part II of the Tariff, plus 
    losses. This limitation shall not apply to changes in the operation 
    of a Transmission Customer's Network Resources at the request of the 
    Transmission Provider to respond to an emergency or other unforeseen 
    condition which may impair or degrade the reliability of the 
    Transmission System.
        30.5  Network Customer Redispatch Obligation: As a condition to 
    receiving Network Integration Transmission Service, the Network 
    Customer agrees to redispatch its Network Resources as requested by 
    the Transmission Provider pursuant to Section 33.2. To the extent 
    practical, the redispatch of resources pursuant to this section 
    shall be on a least cost, non-discriminatory basis between all 
    Network Customers, and the Transmission Provider.
        30.6  Transmission Arrangements for Network Resources Not 
    Physically Interconnected With The Transmission Provider: The 
    Network Customer shall be responsible for any arrangements necessary 
    to deliver capacity and energy from a Network Resource not 
    physically interconnected with the Transmission Provider's 
    Transmission System. The Transmission Provider will undertake 
    reasonable efforts to assist the Network Customer in obtaining such 
    arrangements, including without limitation, providing any 
    information or data required by such other entity pursuant to Good 
    Utility Practice.
        30.7  Limitation on Designation of Network Resources: The 
    Network Customer must demonstrate that it owns or has committed to 
    purchase generation pursuant to an executed contract in order to 
    designate a generating resource as a Network Resource. 
    Alternatively, the Network Customer may establish that execution of 
    a contract is contingent upon the availability of transmission 
    service under Part III of the Tariff.
        30.8  Use of Interface Capacity by the Network Customer: There 
    is no limitation upon a Network Customer's use of the Transmission 
    Provider's Transmission System at any particular interface to 
    integrate the Network Customer's Network Resources (or substitute 
    economy purchases) with its Network Loads. However, a Network 
    Customer's use of the Transmission Provider's total interface 
    capacity with other transmission systems may not exceed the Network 
    Customer's Load.
        30.9  Network Customer Owned Transmission Facilities: The 
    Network Customer that owns existing transmission facilities that are 
    integrated with the Transmission Provider's Transmission System may 
    be eligible to receive consideration either through a billing credit 
    or some other mechanism. In order to receive such consideration the 
    Network Customer must demonstrate that its transmission facilities 
    are integrated into the plans or operations of the Transmission 
    Provider to serve its power and transmission customers. For 
    facilities constructed by the Network Customer subsequent to the 
    Service Commencement Date under Part III of the Tariff, the Network 
    Customer shall receive credit where such facilities are jointly 
    planned and installed in coordination with the Transmission 
    Provider. Calculation of the credit shall be addressed in either the 
    Network Customer's Service Agreement or any other agreement between 
    the Parties.
    
    31  Designation of Network Load
    
        31.1  Network Load: The Network Customer must designate the 
    individual Network Loads on whose behalf the Transmission Provider 
    will provide Network Integration Transmission Service. The Network 
    Loads shall be specified in the Service Agreement.
        31.2  New Network Loads Connected With the Transmission 
    Provider: The Network Customer shall provide the Transmission 
    Provider with as much advance notice as reasonably practicable of 
    the designation of new Network Load that will be added to its 
    Transmission System. A designation of new Network Load must be made 
    through a modification of service pursuant to a new Application. The 
    Transmission Provider will use due diligence to install any 
    transmission facilities required to interconnect a new Network Load 
    designated by the Network Customer. The costs of new facilities 
    required to interconnect a new Network Load shall be determined in 
    accordance with the procedures provided in Section and shall be 
    charged to the Network Customer in accordance with Commission 
    policies.
        31.3  Network Load Not Physically Interconnected with the 
    Transmission Provider: This section applies to both initial 
    designation pursuant to Section and the subsequent addition of new 
    Network Load not physically interconnected with the Transmission 
    Provider. To the extent that the Network Customer desires to obtain 
    transmission service for a load outside the Transmission Provider's 
    Transmission System, the Network Customer shall have the option of 
    (1) electing to include the entire load as Network Load for all 
    purposes under Part III of the Tariff and designating Network 
    Resources in connection with such additional Network Load, or (2) 
    excluding that entire load from its Network Load and purchasing 
    Point-To-Point Transmission Service under Part II of the Tariff. To 
    the extent that the Network Customer gives notice of its intent to 
    add a new Network Load as part of its Network Load pursuant to this 
    section the request must be made through a modification of service 
    pursuant to a new Application.
        31.4  New Interconnection Points: To the extent the Network 
    Customer desires to add a new Delivery Point or interconnection 
    point between the Transmission Provider's Transmission System and a 
    Network Load, the Network Customer shall provide the Transmission 
    Provider with as much advance notice as reasonably practicable.
        31.5  Changes in Service Requests: Under no circumstances shall 
    the Network Customer's decision to cancel or delay a requested 
    change in Network Integration Transmission Service (e.g. the 
    addition of a new Network Resource or designation of a new Network 
    Load) in any way relieve the Network Customer of its obligation to 
    pay the costs of transmission facilities constructed by the 
    Transmission Provider and charged to the Network Customer as 
    reflected in the Service Agreement. However, the Transmission 
    Provider must treat any requested change in Network Integration 
    Transmission Service in a non-discriminatory manner.
        31.6  Annual Load and Resource Information Updates: The Network 
    Customer shall provide the Transmission Provider with annual updates 
    of Network Load and Network Resource forecasts consistent with those 
    included in its Application for Network Integration Transmission 
    Service under Part III of the Tariff. The Network Customer also 
    shall provide the Transmission Provider with timely written notice 
    of material changes in any other information provided in its 
    Application relating to the Network Customer's Network Load, Network 
    Resources, its transmission system or other aspects of its 
    facilities or operations affecting the Transmission Provider's 
    ability to provide reliable service.
    
    32  Additional Study Procedures For Network Integration 
    Transmission Service Requests
    
        32.1  Notice of Need for System Impact Study: After receiving a 
    request for service, the Transmission Provider shall determine on a 
    non-discriminatory basis whether a System Impact Study is needed. A 
    description of the Transmission Provider's methodology for 
    completing a System Impact Study is provided in Attachment . If the 
    Transmission Provider determines that a System Impact Study is 
    necessary to accommodate the requested service, it shall so inform 
    the Eligible Customer, as soon as practicable. In such cases, the 
    Transmission Provider shall within thirty (30) days of receipt of a 
    Completed Application, tender a System Impact Study Agreement 
    pursuant to which the Eligible Customer shall agree to reimburse the 
    Transmission Provider for performing the required System Impact 
    Study. For a service request to remain a Completed Application, the 
    Eligible Customer shall execute the System Impact Study Agreement 
    and return it to the Transmission Provider within fifteen (15) days. 
    If the Eligible Customer elects not to execute the System Impact 
    Study Agreement, its Application shall be deemed withdrawn and its 
    deposit shall be returned with interest.
        32.2  System Impact Study Agreement and Cost Reimbursement:
        (i) The System Impact Study Agreement will clearly specify the 
    Transmission Provider's estimate of the actual cost, and
    
    [[Page 12479]]
    
    time for completion of the System Impact Study. The charge shall not 
    exceed the actual cost of the study. In performing the System Impact 
    Study, the Transmission Provider shall rely, to the extent 
    reasonably practicable, on existing transmission planning studies. 
    The Eligible Customer will not be assessed a charge for such 
    existing studies; however, the Eligible Customer will be responsible 
    for charges associated with any modifications to existing planning 
    studies that are reasonably necessary to evaluate the impact of the 
    Eligible Customer's request for service on the Transmission System.
        (ii) If in response to multiple Eligible Customers requesting 
    service in relation to the same competitive solicitation, a single 
    System Impact Study is sufficient for the Transmission Provider to 
    accommodate the service requests, the costs of that study shall be 
    pro-rated among the Eligible Customers.
        (iii) For System Impact Studies that the Transmission Provider 
    conducts on its own behalf, the Transmission Provider shall record 
    the cost of the System Impact Studies pursuant to Section 8.
        32.3  System Impact Study Procedures: Upon receipt of an 
    executed System Impact Study Agreement, the Transmission Provider 
    will use due diligence to complete the required System Impact Study 
    within a sixty (60) day period. The System Impact Study shall 
    identify any system constraints and redispatch options, additional 
    Direct Assignment Facilities or Network Upgrades required to provide 
    the requested service. In the event that the Transmission Provider 
    is unable to complete the required System Impact Study within such 
    time period, it shall so notify the Eligible Customer and provide an 
    estimated completion date along with an explanation of the reasons 
    why additional time is required to complete the required studies. A 
    copy of the completed System Impact Study and related work papers 
    shall be made available to the Eligible Customer. The Transmission 
    Provider will use the same due diligence in completing the System 
    Impact Study for an Eligible Customer as it uses when completing 
    studies for itself. The Transmission Provider shall notify the 
    Eligible Customer immediately upon completion of the System Impact 
    Study if the Transmission System will be adequate to accommodate all 
    or part of a request for service or that no costs are likely to be 
    incurred for new transmission facilities or upgrades. In order for a 
    request to remain a Completed Application, within fifteen (15) days 
    of completion of the System Impact Study the Eligible Customer must 
    execute a Service Agreement or request the filing of an unexecuted 
    Service Agreement, or the Application shall be deemed terminated and 
    withdrawn.
        32.4  Facilities Study Procedures: If a System Impact Study 
    indicates that additions or upgrades to the Transmission System are 
    needed to supply the Eligible Customer's service request, the 
    Transmission Provider, within thirty (30) days of the completion of 
    the System Impact Study, shall tender to the Eligible Customer a 
    Facilities Study Agreement pursuant to which the Eligible Customer 
    shall agree to reimburse the Transmission Provider for performing 
    the required Facilities Study. For a service request to remain a 
    Completed Application, the Eligible Customer shall execute the 
    Facilities Study Agreement and return it to the Transmission 
    Provider within fifteen (15) days. If the Eligible Customer elects 
    not to execute the Facilities Study Agreement, its Application shall 
    be deemed withdrawn and its deposit shall be returned with interest. 
    Upon receipt of an executed Facilities Study Agreement, the 
    Transmission Provider will use due diligence to complete the 
    required Facilities Study within a sixty (60) day period. If the 
    Transmission Provider is unable to complete the Facilities Study in 
    the allotted time period, the Transmission Provider shall notify the 
    Eligible Customer and provide an estimate of the time needed to 
    reach a final determination along with an explanation of the reasons 
    that additional time is required to complete the study. When 
    completed, the Facilities Study will include a good faith estimate 
    of (i) the cost of Direct Assignment Facilities to be charged to the 
    Eligible Customer, (ii) the Eligible Customer's appropriate share of 
    the cost of any required Network Upgrades, and (iii) the time 
    required to complete such construction and initiate the requested 
    service. The Eligible Customer shall provide the Transmission 
    Provider with a letter of credit or other reasonable form of 
    security acceptable to the Transmission Provider equivalent to the 
    costs of new facilities or upgrades consistent with commercial 
    practices as established by the Uniform Commercial Code. The 
    Eligible Customer shall have thirty (30) days to execute a Service 
    Agreement or request the filing of an unexecuted Service Agreement 
    and provide the required letter of credit or other form of security 
    or the request no longer will be a Completed Application and shall 
    be deemed terminated and withdrawn.
    
    33  Load Shedding and Curtailments
    
        33.1  Procedures: Prior to the Service Commencement Date, the 
    Transmission Provider and the Network Customer shall establish Load 
    Shedding and Curtailment procedures pursuant to the Network 
    Operating Agreement with the objective of responding to 
    contingencies on the Transmission System. The Parties will implement 
    such programs during any period when the Transmission Provider 
    determines that a system contingency exists and such procedures are 
    necessary to alleviate such contingency. The Transmission Provider 
    will notify all affected Network Customers in a timely manner of any 
    scheduled Curtailment.
        33.2  Transmission Constraints: During any period when the 
    Transmission Provider determines that a transmission constraint 
    exists on the Transmission System, and such constraint may impair 
    the reliability of the Transmission Provider's system, the 
    Transmission Provider will take whatever actions, consistent with 
    Good Utility Practice, that are reasonably necessary to maintain the 
    reliability of the Transmission Provider's system. To the extent the 
    Transmission Provider determines that the reliability of the 
    Transmission System can be maintained by redispatching resources, 
    the Transmission Provider will initiate procedures pursuant to the 
    Network Operating Agreement to redispatch all Network Resources and 
    the Transmission Provider's own resources on a least-cost basis 
    without regard to the ownership of such resources. Any redispatch 
    under this section may not unduly discriminate between the 
    Transmission Provider's use of the Transmission System on behalf of 
    its Native Load Customers and any Network Customer's use of the 
    Transmission System to serve its designated Network Load.
        33.3  Cost Responsibility for Relieving Transmission 
    Constraints: Whenever the Transmission Provider implements least-
    cost redispatch procedures in response to a transmission constraint, 
    the Transmission Provider and Network Customers will each bear a 
    proportionate share of the total redispatch cost based on their 
    respective Load Ratio Shares.
        33.4  Curtailments of Scheduled Deliveries: If a transmission 
    constraint on the Transmission Provider's Transmission System cannot 
    be relieved through the implementation of least-cost redispatch 
    procedures and the Transmission Provider determines that it is 
    necessary to Curtail scheduled deliveries, the Parties shall Curtail 
    such schedules in accordance with the Network Operating Agreement.
        33.5  Allocation of Curtailments: The Transmission Provider 
    shall, on a non-discriminatory basis, Curtail the transaction(s) 
    that effectively relieve the constraint. However, to the extent 
    practicable and consistent with Good Utility Practice, any 
    Curtailment will be shared by the Transmission Provider and Network 
    Customer in proportion to their respective Load Ratio Shares. The 
    Transmission Provider shall not direct the Network Customer to 
    Curtail schedules to an extent greater than the Transmission 
    Provider would Curtail the Transmission Provider's schedules under 
    similar circumstances.
        33.6  Load Shedding: To the extent that a system contingency 
    exists on the Transmission Provider's Transmission System and the 
    Transmission Provider determines that it is necessary for the 
    Transmission Provider and the Network Customer to shed load, the 
    Parties shall shed load in accordance with previously established 
    procedures under the Network Operating Agreement.
        33.7  System Reliability: Notwithstanding any other provisions 
    of this Tariff, the Transmission Provider reserves the right, 
    consistent with Good Utility Practice and on a not unduly 
    discriminatory basis, to Curtail Network Integration Transmission 
    Service without liability on the Transmission Provider's part for 
    the purpose of making necessary adjustments to, changes in, or 
    repairs on its lines, substations and facilities, and in cases where 
    the continuance of Network Integration Transmission Service would 
    endanger persons or property. In the event of any adverse 
    condition(s) or disturbance(s) on the Transmission Provider's 
    Transmission System or on any other system(s) directly or indirectly 
    interconnected with the Transmission Provider's Transmission System, 
    the Transmission Provider, consistent with Good
    
    [[Page 12480]]
    
    Utility Practice, also may Curtail Network Integration Transmission 
    Service in order to (i) limit the extent or damage of the adverse 
    condition(s) or disturbance(s), (ii) prevent damage to generating or 
    transmission facilities, or (iii) expedite restoration of service. 
    The Transmission Provider will give the Network Customer as much 
    advance notice as is practicable in the event of such Curtailment. 
    Any Curtailment of Network Integration Transmission Service will be 
    not unduly discriminatory relative to the Transmission Provider's 
    use of the Transmission System on behalf of its Native Load 
    Customers. The Transmission Provider shall specify the rate 
    treatment and all related terms and conditions applicable in the 
    event that the Network Customer fails to respond to established Load 
    Shedding and Curtailment procedures.
    
    34  Rates and Charges
    
        The Network Customer shall pay the Transmission Provider for any 
    Direct Assignment Facilities, Ancillary Services, and applicable 
    study costs, consistent with Commission policy, along with the 
    following:
        34.1  Monthly Demand Charge: The Network Customer shall pay a 
    monthly Demand Charge, which shall be determined by multiplying its 
    Load Ratio Share times one twelfth (\1/12\) of the Transmission 
    Provider's Annual Transmission Revenue Requirement specified in 
    Schedule H.
        34.2  Determination of Network Customer's Monthly Network Load: 
    The Network Customer's monthly Network Load is its hourly load 
    (including its designated Network Load not physically interconnected 
    with the Transmission Provider under Section 31.3) coincident with 
    the Transmission Provider's Monthly Transmission System Peak.
        34.3  Determination of Transmission Provider's Monthly 
    Transmission System Load: The Transmission Provider's monthly 
    Transmission System load is the Transmission Provider's Monthly 
    Transmission System Peak minus the coincident peak usage of all Firm 
    Point-To-Point Transmission Service customers pursuant to Part II of 
    this Tariff plus the Reserved Capacity of all Firm Point-To-Point 
    Transmission Service customers.
        34.4  Redispatch Charge: The Network Customer shall pay a Load 
    Ratio Share of any redispatch costs allocated between the Network 
    Customer and the Transmission Provider pursuant to Section 33. To 
    the extent that the Transmission Provider incurs an obligation to 
    the Network Customer for redispatch costs in accordance with Section 
    33, such amounts shall be credited against the Network Customer's 
    bill for the applicable month.
        34.5  Stranded Cost Recovery: The Transmission Provider may seek 
    to recover stranded costs from the Network Customer pursuant to this 
    Tariff in accordance with the terms, conditions and procedures set 
    forth in FERC Order No. 888. However, the Transmission Provider must 
    separately file any proposal to recover stranded costs under Section 
    205 of the Federal Power Act.
    
    35  Operating Arrangements
    
        35.1  Operation under The Network Operating Agreement: The 
    Network Customer shall plan, construct, operate and maintain its 
    facilities in accordance with Good Utility Practice and in 
    conformance with the Network Operating Agreement.
        35.2  Network Operating Agreement: The terms and conditions 
    under which the Network Customer shall operate its facilities and 
    the technical and operational matters associated with the 
    implementation of Part III of the Tariff shall be specified in the 
    Network Operating Agreement. The Network Operating Agreement shall 
    provide for the Parties to (i) operate and maintain equipment 
    necessary for integrating the Network Customer within the 
    Transmission Provider's Transmission System (including, but not 
    limited to, remote terminal units, metering, communications 
    equipment and relaying equipment), (ii) transfer data between the 
    Transmission Provider and the Network Customer (including, but not 
    limited to, heat rates and operational characteristics of Network 
    Resources, generation schedules for units outside the Transmission 
    Provider's Transmission System, interchange schedules, unit outputs 
    for redispatch required under Section 33, voltage schedules, loss 
    factors and other real time data), (iii) use software programs 
    required for data links and constraint dispatching, (iv) exchange 
    data on forecasted loads and resources necessary for long-term 
    planning, and (v) address any other technical and operational 
    considerations required for implementation of Part III of the 
    Tariff, including scheduling protocols. The Network Operating 
    Agreement will recognize that the Network Customer shall either (i) 
    operate as a Control Area under applicable guidelines of the North 
    American Electric Reliability Council (NERC) and the [applicable 
    regional reliability council], (ii) satisfy its Control Area 
    requirements, including all necessary Ancillary Services, by 
    contracting with the Transmission Provider, or (iii) satisfy its 
    Control Area requirements, including all necessary Ancillary 
    Services, by contracting with another entity, consistent with Good 
    Utility Practice, which satisfies NERC and the [applicable regional 
    reliability council] requirements. The Transmission Provider shall 
    not unreasonably refuse to accept contractual arrangements with 
    another entity for Ancillary Services. The Network Operating 
    Agreement is included in Attachment G.
        35.3  Network Operating Committee: A Network Operating Committee 
    (Committee) shall be established to coordinate operating criteria 
    for the Parties' respective responsibilities under the Network 
    Operating Agreement. Each Network Customer shall be entitled to have 
    at least one representative on the Committee. The Committee shall 
    meet from time to time as need requires, but no less than once each 
    calendar year.
    
    Schedule 1--Scheduling, System Control and Dispatch Service
    
        This service is required to schedule the movement of power 
    through, out of, within, or into a Control Area. This service can be 
    provided only by the operator of the Control Area in which the 
    transmission facilities used for transmission service are located. 
    Scheduling, System Control and Dispatch Service is to be provided 
    directly by the Transmission Provider (if the Transmission Provider 
    is the Control Area operator) or indirectly by the Transmission 
    Provider making arrangements with the Control Area operator that 
    performs this service for the Transmission Provider's Transmission 
    System. The Transmission Customer must purchase this service from 
    the Transmission Provider or the Control Area operator. The charges 
    for Scheduling, System Control and Dispatch Service are to be based 
    on the rates set forth below. To the extent the Control Area 
    operator performs this service for the Transmission Provider, 
    charges to the Transmission Customer are to reflect only a pass-
    through of the costs charged to the Transmission Provider by that 
    Control Area operator.
    
    Schedule 2--Reactive Supply and Voltage Control from Generation Sources 
    Service
    
        In order to maintain transmission voltages on the Transmission 
    Provider's transmission facilities within acceptable limits, 
    generation facilities under the control of the control area operator 
    are operated to produce (or absorb) reactive power. Thus, Reactive 
    Supply and Voltage Control from Generation Sources Service must be 
    provided for each transaction on the Transmission Provider's 
    transmission facilities. The amount of Reactive Supply and Voltage 
    Control from Generation Sources Service that must be supplied with 
    respect to the Transmission Customer's transaction will be 
    determined based on the reactive power support necessary to maintain 
    transmission voltages within limits that are generally accepted in 
    the region and consistently adhered to by the Transmission Provider.
        Reactive Supply and Voltage Control from Generation Sources 
    Service is to be provided directly by the Transmission Provider (if 
    the Transmission Provider is the Control Area operator) or 
    indirectly by the Transmission Provider making arrangements with the 
    Control Area operator that performs this service for the 
    Transmission Provider's Transmission System. The Transmission 
    Customer must purchase this service from the Transmission Provider 
    or the Control Area operator. The charges for such service will be 
    based on the rates set forth below. To the extent the Control Area 
    operator performs this service for the Transmission Provider, 
    charges to the Transmission Customer are to reflect only a pass-
    through of the costs charged to the Transmission Provider by the 
    Control Area operator.
    
    Schedule 3--Regulation and Frequency Response Service
    
        Regulation and Frequency Response Service is necessary to 
    provide for the continuous balancing of resources (generation and 
    interchange) with load and for maintaining scheduled Interconnection 
    frequency at sixty cycles per second (60 Hz). Regulation and 
    Frequency Response Service is accomplished by committing on-line 
    generation whose output is raised or lowered (predominantly through 
    the use of automatic generating control equipment) as necessary to
    
    [[Page 12481]]
    
    follow the moment-by-moment changes in load. The obligation to 
    maintain this balance between resources and load lies with the 
    Transmission Provider (or the Control Area operator that performs 
    this function for the Transmission Provider). The Transmission 
    Provider must offer this service when the transmission service is 
    used to serve load within its Control Area. The Transmission 
    Customer must either purchase this service from the Transmission 
    Provider or make alternative comparable arrangements to satisfy its 
    Regulation and Frequency Response Service obligation. The amount of 
    and charges for Regulation and Frequency Response Service are set 
    forth below. To the extent the Control Area operator performs this 
    service for the Transmission Provider, charges to the Transmission 
    Customer are to reflect only a pass-through of the costs charged to 
    the Transmission Provider by that Control Area operator.
    
    Schedule 4--Energy Imbalance Service
    
        Energy Imbalance Service is provided when a difference occurs 
    between the scheduled and the actual delivery of energy to a load 
    located within a Control Area over a single hour. The Transmission 
    Provider must offer this service when the transmission service is 
    used to serve load within its Control Area. The Transmission 
    Customer must either purchase this service from the Transmission 
    Provider or make alternative comparable arrangements to satisfy its 
    Energy Imbalance Service obligation. To the extent the Control Area 
    operator performs this service for the Transmission Provider, 
    charges to the Transmission Customer are to reflect only a pass-
    through of the costs charged to the Transmission Provider by that 
    Control Area operator.
        The Transmission Provider shall establish a deviation band of +/
    -1.5 percent (with a minimum of 2 MW) of the scheduled transaction 
    to be applied hourly to any energy imbalance that occurs as a result 
    of the Transmission Customer's scheduled transaction(s). Parties 
    should attempt to eliminate energy imbalances within the limits of 
    the deviation band within thirty (30) days or within such other 
    reasonable period of time as is generally accepted in the region and 
    consistently adhered to by the Transmission Provider. If an energy 
    imbalance is not corrected within thirty (30) days or a reasonable 
    period of time that is generally accepted in the region and 
    consistently adhered to by the Transmission Provider, the 
    Transmission Customer will compensate the Transmission Provider for 
    such service. Energy imbalances outside the deviation band will be 
    subject to charges to be specified by the Transmission Provider. The 
    charges for Energy Imbalance Service are set forth below.
    
    Schedule 5--Operating Reserve--Spinning Reserve Service
    
        Spinning Reserve Service is needed to serve load immediately in 
    the event of a system contingency. Spinning Reserve Service may be 
    provided by generating units that are on-line and loaded at less 
    than maximum output. The Transmission Provider must offer this 
    service when the transmission service is used to serve load within 
    its Control Area. The Transmission Customer must either purchase 
    this service from the Transmission Provider or make alternative 
    comparable arrangements to satisfy its Spinning Reserve Service 
    obligation. The amount of and charges for Spinning Reserve Service 
    are set forth below. To the extent the Control Area operator 
    performs this service for the Transmission Provider, charges to the 
    Transmission Customer are to reflect only a pass-through of the 
    costs charged to the Transmission Provider by that Control Area 
    operator.
    
    Schedule 6--Operating Reserve--Supplemental Reserve Service
    
        Supplemental Reserve Service is needed to serve load in the 
    event of a system contingency; however, it is not available 
    immediately to serve load but rather within a short period of time. 
    Supplemental Reserve Service may be provided by generating units 
    that are on-line but unloaded, by quick-start generation or by 
    interruptible load. The Transmission Provider must offer this 
    service when the transmission service is used to serve load within 
    its Control Area. The Transmission Customer must either purchase 
    this service from the Transmission Provider or make alternative 
    comparable arrangements to satisfy its Supplemental Reserve Service 
    obligation. The amount of and charges for Supplemental Reserve 
    Service are set forth below. To the extent the Control Area operator 
    performs this service for the Transmission Provider, charges to the 
    Transmission Customer are to reflect only a pass-through of the 
    costs charged to the Transmission Provider by that Control Area 
    operator.
    
    Schedule 7--Long-Term Firm and Short-Term Firm Point-To-Point 
    Transmission Service
    
        The Transmission Customer shall compensate the Transmission 
    Provider each month for Reserved Capacity at the sum of the 
    applicable charges set forth below:
        (1) Yearly delivery: one-twelfth of the demand charge of 
    $________________/KW of Reserved Capacity per year.
        (2) Monthly delivery: $________________/KW of Reserved Capacity 
    per month.
        (3) Weekly delivery: $________________/KW of Reserved Capacity 
    per week.
        (4) Daily delivery: $________________/KW of Reserved Capacity per 
    day.
        The total demand charge in any week, pursuant to a reservation 
    for Daily delivery, shall not exceed the rate specified in section 
    (3) above times the highest amount in kilowatts of Reserved Capacity 
    in any day during such week.
        (5) Discounts: Three principal requirements apply to discounts 
    for transmission service as follows (1) any offer of a discount made 
    by the Transmission Provider must be announced to all Eligible 
    Customers solely by posting on the OASIS, (2) any customer-initiated 
    requests for discounts (including requests for use by one's 
    wholesale merchant or an affiliate's use) must occur solely by 
    posting on the OASIS, and (3) once a discount is negotiated, details 
    must be immediately posted on the OASIS. For any discount agreed 
    upon for service on a path, from point(s) of receipt to point(s) of 
    delivery, the Transmission Provider must offer the same discounted 
    transmission service rate for the same time period to all Eligible 
    Customers on all unconstrained transmission paths that go to the 
    same point(s) of delivery on the Transmission System.
    
    Schedule 8--Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service
    
        The Transmission Customer shall compensate the Transmission 
    Provider for Non-Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service up to the 
    sum of the applicable charges set forth below:
        (1) Monthly delivery: $________________/KW of Reserved Capacity 
    per month.
        (2) Weekly delivery: $________________/KW of Reserved Capacity 
    per week.
        (3) Daily delivery: $________________/KW of Reserved Capacity 
    per day.
        The total demand charge in any week, pursuant to a reservation 
    for Daily delivery, shall not exceed the rate specified in section 
    (2) above times the highest amount in kilowatts of Reserved Capacity 
    in any day during such week.
        (4) Hourly delivery: The basic charge shall be that agreed upon 
    by the Parties at the time this service is reserved and in no event 
    shall exceed $________________/MWH. The total demand charge in any 
    day, pursuant to a reservation for Hourly delivery, shall not exceed 
    the rate specified in section (3) above times the highest amount in 
    kilowatts of Reserved Capacity in any hour during such day. In 
    addition, the total demand charge in any week, pursuant to a 
    reservation for Hourly or Daily delivery, shall not exceed the rate 
    specified in section (2) above times the highest amount in kilowatts 
    of Reserved Capacity in any hour during such week.
        (5) Discounts: Three principal requirements apply to discounts 
    for transmission service as follows (1) any offer of a discount made 
    by the Transmission Provider must be announced to all Eligible 
    Customers solely by posting on the OASIS, (2) any customer-initiated 
    requests for discounts (including requests for use by one's 
    wholesale merchant or an affiliate's use) must occur solely by 
    posting on the OASIS, and (3) once a discount is negotiated, details 
    must be immediately posted on the OASIS. For any discount agreed 
    upon for service on a path, from point(s) of receipt to point(s) of 
    delivery, the Transmission Provider must offer the same discounted 
    transmission service rate for the same time period to all Eligible 
    Customers on all unconstrained transmission paths that go to the 
    same point(s) of delivery on the Transmission System.
    
    Attachment A--Form of Service Agreement for Firm Point-To-Point 
    Transmission Service
    
        1.0  This Service Agreement, dated as of____________________, is 
    entered into, by and between ____________________ (the Transmission 
    Provider), and ____________________ (``Transmission Customer'').
        2.0  The Transmission Customer has been determined by the 
    Transmission Provider to
    
    [[Page 12482]]
    
    have a Completed Application for Firm Point-To-Point Transmission 
    Service under the Tariff.
        3.0  The Transmission Customer has provided to the Transmission 
    Provider an Application deposit in accordance with the provisions of 
    Section 17.3 of the Tariff.
        4.0  Service under this agreement shall commence on the later of 
    (1) the requested service commencement date, or (2) the date on 
    which construction of any Direct Assignment Facilities and/or 
    Network Upgrades are completed, or (3) such other date as it is 
    permitted to become effective by the Commission. Service under this 
    agreement shall terminate on such date as mutually agreed upon by 
    the parties.
        5.0   The Transmission Provider agrees to provide and the 
    Transmission Customer agrees to take and pay for Firm Point-To-Point 
    Transmission Service in accordance with the provisions of Part II of 
    the Tariff and this Service Agreement.
        6.0  Any notice or request made to or by either Party regarding 
    this Service Agreement shall be made to the representative of the 
    other Party as indicated below.
    
    Transmission Provider
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Transmission Customer
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        7.0  The Tariff is incorporated herein and made a part hereof.
        IN WITNESS WHEREOF, the Parties have caused this Service 
    Agreement to be executed by their respective authorized officials.
    
    Transmission Provider
    
    By:--------------------------------------------------------------------
    Name
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    Title
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    Date
    
    Transmission Customer
    
    By:--------------------------------------------------------------------
    Name
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    Title
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    Date
    
    Specifications for Long-Term Firm Point-To-Point Transmission Service
    
        1.0  Term of Transaction: ______________________________
    
      Start Date:----------------------------------------------------------
    
      Termination Date:----------------------------------------------------
    
        2.0  Description of capacity and energy to be transmitted by 
    Transmission Provider including the electric Control Area in which 
    the transaction originates.
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        3.0  Point(s) of Receipt: ______________________________
    
      Delivering Party: ______________________________---------------------
    
        4.0  Point(s) of Delivery: ______________________________
    
      Receiving Party: ______________________________----------------------
    
        5.0  Maximum amount of capacity and energy to be transmitted 
    (Reserved Capacity):
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        6.0 Designation of party(ies) subject to reciprocal service 
    obligation:
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        7.0  Name(s) of any Intervening Systems providing transmission 
    service:
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        8.0  Service under this Agreement may be subject to some 
    combination of the charges detailed below. (The appropriate charges 
    for individual transactions will be determined in accordance with 
    the terms and conditions of the Tariff.)
        8.1  Transmission Charge:
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        8.2  System Impact and/or Facilities Study Charge(s):
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        8.3  Direct Assignment Facilities Charge:
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        8.4  Ancillary Services Charges:
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Attachment B--Form of Service Agreement For Non-Firm Point-To-Point 
    Transmission Service
    
        1.0  This Service Agreement, dated as of ____________________, 
    is entered into, by and between ____________________(the 
    Transmission Provider), and ____________________ (Transmission 
    Customer).
        2.0  The Transmission Customer has been determined by the 
    Transmission Provider to be a Transmission Customer under Part II of 
    the Tariff and has filed a Completed Application for Non-Firm Point-
    To-Point Transmission Service in accordance with Section 18.2 of the 
    Tariff.
        3.0  Service under this Agreement shall be provided by the 
    Transmission Provider upon request by an authorized representative 
    of the Transmission Customer.
        4.0  The Transmission Customer agrees to supply information the 
    Transmission Provider deems reasonably necessary in accordance with 
    Good Utility Practice in order for it to provide the requested 
    service.
        5.0 The Transmission Provider agrees to provide and the 
    Transmission Customer agrees to take and pay for Non-Firm Point-To-
    Point Transmission Service in accordance with the provisions of Part 
    II of the Tariff and this Service Agreement.
        6.0 Any notice or request made to or by either Party regarding 
    this Service Agreement shall be made to the representative of the 
    other Party as indicated below.
    
    Transmission Provider
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Transmission Customer
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        7.0  The Tariff is incorporated herein and made a part hereof.
        IN WITNESS WHEREOF, the Parties have caused this Service 
    Agreement to be executed by their respective authorized officials.
    
    Transmission Provider
    
    By:--------------------------------------------------------------------
    Name
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    Title
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    Date
    
    Transmission Customer
    
    By:--------------------------------------------------------------------
    Name
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    Title
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    Date
    
    Attachment C--Methodology To Assess Available Transmission Capability
    
        To be filed by the Transmission Provider.
    
    Attachment D--Methodology for Completing a System Impact Study
    
        To be filed by the Transmission Provider.
    
    Attachment E--Index of Point-To-Point Transmission Service Customers
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Customer
    
    Date of Service Agreement
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Attachment F--Service Agreement for Network Integration Transmission 
    Service
    
        To be filed by the Transmission Provider.
    
    Attachment G--Network Operating Agreement
    
        To be filed by the Transmission Provider.
    
    Attachment H--Annual Transmission Revenue Requirement for Network 
    Integration Transmission Service
    
        1. The Annual Transmission Revenue Requirement for purposes of 
    the Network Integration Transmission Service shall be 
    ____________________.
        2. The amount in (1) shall be effective until amended by the 
    Transmission Provider or modified by the Commission.
    
    [[Page 12483]]
    
    Attachment I--Index of Network Integration Transmission Service 
    Customers
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
    Customer
    
        Date of Service Agreement
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------
        Promoting Wholesale Competition Through Open Access Non-
    discriminatory Transmission Services by Public Utilities. Docket No. 
    RM95-8-001.
        Recovery of Stranded Costs by Public Utilities and Transmitting 
    Utilities. Docket No. RM94-7-002.
    
    (Issued March 4, 1997)
    
    HOECKER, Commissioner, dissenting in part:
    
    I. General Observations
    
        Today's rehearing order makes Order No. 888 ripe for judicial 
    review and largely concludes the most ambitious generic rulemaking 
    effort in this agency's history. The scores of specific policy calls 
    embodied in Order No. 888-A represent reasoned decisionmaking that, 
    in its sheer level of detail, takes us to the outer limits of our 
    ability to predict or control the proper future operation of the 
    market. Still, the timeliness of this order ought to be welcomed. 
    Having satisfactorily demonstrated that the fundamental rules 
    governing a network as complex and important as the Nation's 
    transmission grid can be changed and made to work, the Commission 
    will henceforth be engaged in implementing open access tariffs and 
    dealing with the direct and indirect consequences of bulk power 
    competition. The mantle of major policymaking now shifts to the 
    states and to the U.S. Congress.
        During this proceeding, the industry has continued to evolve. In 
    ten short months, merger and acquisition activity has increased 
    dramatically and may foretell a more significant reconfiguration in 
    the future. The concept of an independent system operator has 
    attained significant credibility as a possible way to throttle 
    market power, ensure system reliability, and rationalize the bulk 
    power market. Retail access and customer choice suddenly dominate 
    the restructuring debate, although the future competitive retail 
    power market still defies prediction. The demarcation between state 
    and federal jurisdiction is actively being tested. And, as the 
    implications of full stranded cost recovery are being thought 
    through within the industry, companies are also trying to diagnose 
    and address their other competitive vulnerabilities. These 
    remarkable and largely unforeseeable changes counsel against the 
    temptation among public policymakers to over-plan and over-prescribe 
    the future of power markets.
    
    II. Partial Dissent
    
        In Order No. 888, the Commission announced that it would be the 
    ``primary forum'' for stranded cost claims in those instances where 
    a retail power customer turns wholesale wheeling customer, usually 
    through a municipalization. I dissented from that portion of the 
    Final Rule because I concluded that the Commission's decision to 
    take responsibility for stranded costs arising from municipalization 
    was insupportable as a matter of either policy or law. As the 
    ``primary forum'' for recovery of these costs, the Commission will 
    be required to second-guess certain state retail stranded cost 
    determinations, even when state regulators and state statutes 
    address the issue sufficiently. This would, in my estimation, 
    encourage forum shopping and fundamentally contradict our approach 
    in the retail wheeling situation, where retail stranded costs are 
    subject to Commission action only if the state regulatory body lacks 
    authority to deal with this important transitional issue. I continue 
    to hold these views.
        The majority has bolstered its position today with additional 
    arguments connecting the Commission's actions in Order No. 888 to 
    the wholesale status of new municipal power customers. While 
    inventive, the majority rests its theory of jurisdiction on a 
    tenuous theory of cause and effect. Briefly, the rehearing order 
    distinguishes wholesale stranded costs from retail stranded costs 
    not by the nature of the costs, but by the status of the customer 
    (i.e., a wholesale transmission services customer versus a retail 
    transmission services customer) with whom the costs are associated. 
    It further contends that jurisdiction over stranded costs depends on 
    ``whether the transmission tariffs used by the customer to escape 
    its former power supplier * * * were required by this Commission or 
    by a state commission''. The majority states that this Commission 
    will serve as the ``primary forum'' for stranded cost recovery only 
    where there exists a direct nexus between the availability and use 
    of FERC's open access transmission tariffs and the stranding of 
    costs.
        I am not persuaded by the rationale supplied by my colleagues. I 
    continue to believe that municipalization, like retail wheeling, 
    would be unavailable to retail customers as a competitive supply 
    alternative but for state action. In both instances, it is state law 
    that provides the legal means for retail customers to gain access to 
    FERC-jurisdictional transmission tariffs. In the final analysis, I 
    am not persuaded that the public interest is served by the 
    majority's intrusion into an area potentially policed under state 
    law, notwithstanding the Commission's strong commitment to full cost 
    recovery.
        In today's order, the Commission also broadens its ``primary 
    forum'' approach to include situations involving the expansion of 
    existing municipal utility systems, for example through annexation 
    of retail customer load or additional service territory. I contend, 
    however, that the ``primary forum'' approach is no more appropriate 
    for municipal annexations than it is for new municipalizations.
        The discussion of this issue in Order No. 888-A heightens my 
    previous concerns in a number of ways. First, the majority's 
    position is based on the alleged similarities between the creation 
    of a new municipal utility system and the expansion of an existing 
    municipal utility system. In both cases, they argue, a nexus exists 
    between the municipalization and Commission-required transmission 
    access; the salient connection is the use that the new wholesale 
    customer makes of the former supplying utility's transmission 
    system. If one were to assume the correctness of the majority's 
    municipalization approach, it would make sense to limit its stranded 
    cost recovery provisions to such circumstances only. But, there are 
    two more compelling factors that determine the legitimacy of any 
    stranded cost approach. First, like retail wheeling, all 
    municipalizations, whether new or annexations, occur pursuant to 
    state law. As already discussed, state action allows retail 
    customers to aggregate load and, through municipalization, gain 
    access to FERC-jurisdictional transmission tariffs. Second, the risk 
    of annexation (and with it the loss of retail load) existed long 
    before enactment of the Energy Policy Act or implementation of Order 
    No. 888. I believe these factors argue for treatment of all costs 
    incurred to serve retail load and stranded pursuant to state 
    action--whether by retail wheeling, new municipalization, or 
    annexation--by the same state regulatory body. I do not dispute, 
    however, that the Commission should step in when states fail to 
    ensure some level of stranded cost recovery, thereby creating a 
    regulatory gap.
        The rehearing order has an additional problem. It states that 
    the Commission will not necessarily be the ``primary forum'' for 
    stranded cost recovery in all cases of municipal annexation. The 
    majority's new willingness to decide stranded costs arising from the 
    annexation of new load will therefore require a finding that the 
    existing municipality will use the transmission system of the 
    annexed retail customers' former supplier to provide service to the 
    annexed load. This approach is necessitated by the ``nexus'' theory 
    of jurisdiction over the underlying stranded costs, and it 
    represents a novel theory of law. Moreover, the administrative 
    difficulties associated with this particular fact-finding will be 
    extensive. An existing municipality already has transmission and 
    generation service arrangements in place. With access to additional 
    generation resources now available in the newly competitive 
    wholesale power market, a municipality ultimately may be served by a 
    number of suppliers, possibly in addition to its own resources. In 
    such circumstances, the difficulty in determining which generation 
    resources, and hence which transmission services, are being used to 
    supply service to the annexed customers in particular may be 
    virtually insurmountable. Under the nexus test, the Commission must 
    settle that matter preliminarily just to decide whether it is the 
    proper forum for addressing the costs stranded by an annexation.
        To compound this practical problem, the majority's commitment to 
    give ``great weight to a state's view'' of what stranded costs are 
    recoverable under state law in these circumstances, and to deduct 
    the amount of state stranded cost awards from the amount that a 
    utility may seek to recover from this Commission, is likely to prove 
    a hollow promise. Such deference would require a prior stranded cost 
    determination on the merits by state regulators, despite the 
    majority's instruction to the parties to raise all stranded cost 
    claims under the municipalization scenario before this Commission 
    ``in the first instance.''
    
    [[Page 12484]]
    
    Deference in this context is a slippery proposition for other 
    reasons, too. Naturally, states may perceive equity considerations, 
    cost causation principles, 1 and market risk factors2 
    differently than the Commission, and consequently they may not share 
    the Commission's view that utilities are entitled to full recovery 
    of stranded costs here. Because of this potential difference of 
    opinion, I suspect that the amount of deference that the Commission 
    provides to the states may be directly proportional to the level of 
    stranded cost recovery that states grant the utilities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \1\ Pipeline Service Obligations and Revisions to Regulations 
    Governing Self-Implementing Transportation Under Part 284 of the 
    Commission's Regulations and Regulation of Natural Gas Pipelines 
    After Partial Wellhead Decontrol, Order No. 636-C, 78 FERC para. 
    61,186 (1997).
        \2\ Mechanisms for Passthrough of Pipeline Take-or-Pay Buyout 
    and Buydown Costs, Order No. 528-A, 54 FERC para. 61,095 (1991).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In sum, the majority's ingenious attempt to federalize stranded 
    cost claims arising from municipalization, while admirable in terms 
    of the need to resolve transition cost issues expeditiously, is more 
    likely to cause greater uncertainty and more argument about the 
    appropriate standard to apply than it is to promote settlement of 
    the matter.
        I therefore respectfully dissent in small part to Order No. 888-
    A.
    James J. Hoecker,
    Commissioner.
        Promoting Wholesale Competition Through Open Access Non-
    Discriminatory Transmission Services by Public Utilities. Docket No. 
    RM95-8-001.
        Recovery of Stranded Costs by Public Utilities and Transmitting 
    Utilities. Docket No. RM94-7-002.
    
    Order No. 888-A
    
    (Issued March 4, 1997)
    
    MASSEY, Commissioner, dissenting in part:
    
        I dissent in part, from this otherwise excellent rule, on a 
    single issue. I continue to believe, as I stated in my dissent to 
    Order No. 888, that the Commission should treat stranded costs 
    arising from retail competition and municipalizations similarly.
        Municipalization occurs under state rather than federal law. The 
    majority's decision in Order No. 888 that FERC should be the primary 
    forum for addressing the recovery of stranded costs caused by 
    municipalization boldly and unnecessarily preempts legitimate state 
    authority. Today's order perpetuates and compounds this error by 
    extending federal preemption to stranded costs arising from 
    municipal annexations as well.
        Many state commissions have express legislative authority to 
    address these issues and should not be prohibited from doing so by 
    federal regulators. It is only when a state commission does not have 
    the authority, or has the authority and fails to use it, that the 
    Commission should be available as a stranded cost recovery forum of 
    last resort.
        On this one issue, I respectfully dissent.
    William L. Massey,
    Commissioner.
    [FR Doc. 97-5767 Filed 3-13-97; 8:45 am]
    BILLING CODE 6717-01-P
    
    
    

Document Information

Effective Date:
5/13/1997
Published:
03/14/1997
Department:
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
Entry Type:
Rule
Action:
Final rule; order on rehearing.
Document Number:
97-5767
Dates:
This rule is effective on May 13, 1997.
Pages:
12274-12484 (211 pages)
Docket Numbers:
Docket Nos. RM95-8-001 and RM94-7-002, Order No. 888-A
PDF File:
97-5767.pdf
CFR: (2)
18 CFR 35.19a(a)(2)(iii)
18 CFR 35.26