99-12553. Regional Transmission Organizations; Notice of Proposed Rulemaking  

  • [Federal Register Volume 64, Number 111 (Thursday, June 10, 1999)]
    [Proposed Rules]
    [Pages 31390-31444]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 99-12553]
    
    
    
    [[Page 31389]]
    
    _______________________________________________________________________
    
    Part III
    
    
    
    
    
    Department of Energy
    
    
    
    
    
    _______________________________________________________________________
    
    
    
    Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
    
    
    
    _______________________________________________________________________
    
    
    
    18 CFR Part 35
    
    
    
    Regional Transmission Organizations; Proposed Rule
    
    Regional Transmission Organizations; Intent To Prepare and 
    Environmental Assessment for the Regional Transmission Organizations 
    Rulemaking, Request for Comments on Environmental Issues, and Public 
    Scoping Meeting; Notice
    
    Federal Register / Vol. 64, No. 111 / Thursday, June 10, 1999 / 
    Proposed Rules
    
    [[Page 31390]]
    
    
    
    DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
    
    Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
    
    18 CFR Part 35
    
    [Docket No. RM99-2-000]
    
    
    Regional Transmission Organizations; Notice of Proposed 
    Rulemaking
    
    May 13, 1999.
    AGENCY: Federal Energy Regulatory Commission.
    
    ACTION: Notice of proposed rulemaking.
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    SUMMARY: The Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (Commission) is 
    proposing to amend its regulations under the Federal Power Act (FPA) to 
    facilitate the formation of Regional Transmission Organizations (RTOs). 
    The Commission proposes to require that each public utility that owns, 
    operates, or controls facilities for the transmission of electric 
    energy in interstate commerce make certain filings with respect to 
    forming and participating in an RTO. The Commission also proposes 
    minimum characteristics and functions that a transmission entity must 
    satisfy in order to be considered to be an RTO.
    
    DATES: Initial comments are due August 16, 1999. Reply comments are due 
    September 15, 1999.
    
    ADDRESSES: Send comments to: Office of the Secretary, Federal Energy 
    Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street, NE., Washington, D.C. 20426.
    
    FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
    Alan Haymes (Technical Information), Office of Electric Power 
    Regulation, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street, 
    NE., Washington, D.C. 20426, (202) 219-2919.
    Wilbur C. Earley (Technical Information), Office of Economic Policy, 
    Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street, NE., 
    Washington, D.C. 20426, (202) 208-0100
    Brian R. Gish (Legal Information), Office of the General Counsel, 
    Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street, NE., 
    Washington, D.C. 20426, (202) 208-0996
    
    SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: In addition to publishing the full text of 
    this document in the Federal Register, the Commission also provides all 
    interested persons an opportunity to inspect or copy the contents of 
    this document during normal business hours in the Public Reference Room 
    at 888 First Street, N.E., Room 2A, Washington, D.C. 20426.
        The Commission Issuance Posting System (CIPS) provides access to 
    the texts of formal documents issued by the Commission from November 
    14, 1994, to the present. CIPS can be accessed via Internet through 
    FERC's Home page (http://www.ferc.fed.us) using the CIPS Link or the 
    Energy Information Online icon. Documents will be available on CIPS in 
    ASCII and WordPerfect 6.1. User assistance is available at 202-208-2474 
    or by E-mail to cips.master@ferc.fed.us.
        This document is also available through the Commission's Records 
    and Information Management System (RIMS), an electronic storage and 
    retrieval system of documents submitted to and issued by the Commission 
    after November 16, 1981. Documents from November 1995 to the present 
    can be viewed and printed. RIMS is available in the Public Reference 
    Room or remotely via Internet through FERC's Home page using the RIMS 
    link or the Energy Information Online icon. User assistance is 
    available at 202-208-2222, or by E-mail to rimsmaster@ferc.fed.us.
        Finally, the complete text on diskette in WordPerfect format may be 
    purchased from the Commission's copy contractor, RVJ International, 
    Inc. RVJ International, Inc. is located in the Public Reference Room at 
    888 First Street, N.E., Washington, D.C. 20426.
    
    Table of Contents
    
    I. Introduction and Summary
    II. Background
        A. The Foundation for Competitive Markets: Order Nos. 888 and 
    889
        B. Developments Since Order Nos. 888 and 889
        1. Industry Restructuring and New Stresses on the Transmission 
    Grid
        2. Successes, Failures and Haphazard Development of Regional 
    Transmission Entities
        3. The Commission's ISO and RTO Inquiries; Conferences with 
    Stakeholders and State Regulators
        C. Statutory Framework
    III. Discussion
        A. Barriers to Assuring an Abundant Supply of Electric Energy 
    throughout the U.S. with the Greatest Possible Economy
        1. Engineering and Economic Inefficiencies in the Operation, 
    Planning, and Expansion of Regional Transmission Grids
        2. Actual and Perceived Discriminatory Conduct by Transmission 
    Owners to Favor Their Own or Affiliated Merchant Operations
        B. Benefits That RTOs Can Offer
        1. An RTO Would Improve Efficiencies in the Management of the 
    Transmission Grid
        2. An RTO Would Improve Grid Reliability
        3. An RTO Would Remove Opportunities for Discriminatory 
    Transmission Practices
        4. An RTO Would Result in Improved Market Performance
        5. An RTO Would Facilitate Lighter-Handed Governmental 
    Regulation
        6. Conclusion
        C. Concerns Expressed by the State Commissions
        1. Federal Mandate
        2. Regional Flexibility
        3. Retail Markets
        4. Effect on States With Low Cost Generation
        5. Need for Independent Transmission Operation
        6. Transmission Cost Shifting
        7. Boundary Drawing
        8. Regional Approach to Reliability
        9. Pricing Reform
        10. Participation of Public Power
        11. State Role in RTO Governance
        12. Existing Regional Transmission Entities
        D. Minimum Characteristics and Functions for a Regional 
    Transmission Organization
        Minimum Characteristics
        1. Independence
        2. Scope and Regional Configuration
        3. Operational Authority
        4. Short-term Reliability
        Minimum Functions
        1. Tariff Administration and Design
        2. Congestion Management
        3. Parallel Path Flow
        4. Ancillary Services
        5. OASIS and TTC and ATC
        6. Market Monitoring
        7. Planning and Expansion
        E. Open Architecture
        F. Ratemaking for Transmission Facilities under RTO Control
        1. Single Transmission Access Rate for Capital Cost Recovery
        2. Congestion Pricing
        3. Performance Based Rate Regulation
        4. Consideration of Incentive Pricing Proposals
        G. Public Power Participation in RTOs
        H. Other Issues
        1. Pre-existing Transmission Contracts
        2. Treatment of Existing Regional Transmission Entities
        3. Participation by Canadian and Mexican Entities
        4. Providing Service to Transmission-owning Utilities That Do 
    Not Participate in an RTO
        5. RTO Filing Requirements
        6. Power Exchanges (PXs)
        I. Implementation of the Rule
        1. Collaborative Process
        2. Filing Requirements
    IV. Environmental Statement
    V. Regulatory Flexibility Act
    VI. Public Reporting Burden and Information Collection Statement
    VII. Public Comment Procedures
    Text of the Regulations
    Appendix A: Staff Summary of the FERC-Industry ISO Conferences
    Appendix B: Staff Summary of FERC Consultations With the States
    Appendix C: Existing Configurations
    
    I. Introduction and Summary
    
        In 1996 the Commission put in place the foundation necessary for
    
    [[Page 31391]]
    
    competitive wholesale power markets in this country--open access 
    transmission.1 Since that time, the industry has undergone 
    sweeping restructuring activity, including a movement by many states to 
    develop retail competition, the growing divestiture of generation 
    plants by traditional electric utilities, a significant increase in the 
    number of mergers among traditional electric utilities and among 
    electric utilities and gas pipeline companies, large increases in the 
    number of power marketers and independent generation facility 
    developers entering the marketplace, and the establishment of 
    independent system operators (ISOs) as managers of large parts of the 
    transmission system. Trade in bulk power markets has continued to 
    increase significantly and the Nation's transmission grid is being used 
    more heavily and in new ways.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \1\ See Promoting Wholesale Competition Through Open Access Non-
    discriminatory Transmission Services by Public Utilities and 
    Recovery of Stranded Costs by Public Utilities and Transmitting 
    Utilities, 61 FR 21540 (1996), FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 31,036 
    (1996) (Order No. 888), order on reh'g, Order No. 888-A, 62 FR 12274 
    (1997), FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 31,048 (1997), order on reh'g, 
    Order No. 888-B, 62 FR 64688, 81 FERC para. 61,248 (1997), order on 
    reh'g, Order No. 888-C, 82 FERC para. 61,046 (1998), appeal 
    docketed, Transmission Access Policy Study Group, et al. v. FERC, 
    Nos. 97-1715 et al. (D.C. Cir.).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As a result, the traditional means of grid management is showing 
    signs of strain and may be inadequate to support the efficient and 
    reliable operation that is needed for the continued development of 
    competitive electricity markets. In addition, there are indications 
    that continued discrimination in the provision of transmission services 
    by vertically integrated utilities may also be impeding fully 
    competitive electricity markets. These problems may be depriving the 
    Nation of the benefits of lower prices, more reliance on market 
    solutions, and lighter-handed regulation that competitive markets can 
    bring.
        If electricity consumers are to realize the full benefits that 
    competition can bring to wholesale markets, the Commission must address 
    the extent of these problems and appropriate ways of mitigating them. 
    Competition in wholesale electricity markets is the best way to protect 
    the public interest and ensure that electricity consumers pay the 
    lowest price possible for reliable service. We believe that further 
    steps may need to be taken to address grid management if we are to 
    achieve fully competitive power markets. We further believe that 
    regional approaches to the numerous issues affecting the industry may 
    be the best means to eliminate remaining impediments to properly 
    functioning competitive markets.
        Our objective is for all transmission owning entities in the 
    Nation, including non-public utility entities, to place their 
    transmission facilities under the control of appropriate regional 
    transmission institutions in a timely manner. We seek to accomplish our 
    objective by encouraging voluntary participation. We are therefore 
    proposing in this rulemaking minimum characteristics and functions for 
    appropriate regional transmission institutions; a collaborative process 
    by which public utilities and non-public utilities that own, operate or 
    control interstate transmission facilities, in consultation with the 
    state officials as appropriate, will consider and develop regional 
    transmission institutions; a willingness to consider incentive pricing 
    on a case-specific basis and an offer of non-monetary regulatory 
    benefits, such as deference in dispute resolution, reduced or 
    eliminated codes of conduct, and streamlined filing and approval 
    procedures; and a time line for public utilities to make appropriate 
    filings with the Commission and initiate operation of regional 
    transmission institutions. As a result, we expect jurisdictional 
    utilities to form Regional Transmission Organizations (RTOs).
        As discussed in detail herein, regional institutions can address 
    the operational and reliability issues now confronting the industry, 
    and any residual discrimination in transmission services that can occur 
    when the operation of the transmission system remains in the control of 
    a vertically integrated utility. Appropriate regional transmission 
    institutions could: (1) improve efficiencies in transmission grid 
    management 2; (2) improve grid reliability; (3) remove the 
    remaining opportunities for discriminatory transmission practices; (4) 
    improve market performance; and (5) facilitate lighter handed 
    regulation.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \2\ Appropriate regional institutions could improve efficiencies 
    in grid management through improved pricing, congestion management, 
    more accurate estimates of Available Transmission Capability, 
    improved parallel path flow management, more efficient planning, and 
    increased coordination between regulatory agencies.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Thus, we believe that appropriate regional transmission 
    institutions could successfully address the existing impediments to 
    efficient grid operation and competition and could consequently benefit 
    consumers through lower electricity rates resulting from a wider choice 
    of services and service providers. There are likely to be substantial 
    cost savings brought about by regional transmission institutions.
        In light of important questions regarding the complexity of grid 
    regionalization raised by state regulators and applicants in individual 
    cases, we are proposing a flexible approach. We are not proposing to 
    mandate that utilities participate in a regional transmission 
    institution by a date certain. Instead, we act now to ensure that they 
    consider doing so in good faith. Moreover, the Commission is not 
    proposing a ``cookie cutter'' organizational format for regional 
    transmission institutions or the establishment of fixed or specific 
    regional boundaries under section 202(a) of the FPA.
        Rather, the Commission is proposing to establish fundamental 
    characteristics and functions for appropriate regional transmission 
    institutions. We will designate institutions that satisfy all of the 
    minimum characteristics and functions as Regional Transmission 
    Organizations (RTOs). Hereinafter, the term Regional Transmission 
    Organization, or RTO, will refer to an organization that satisfies all 
    of the minimum characteristics and functions.
        Pursuant to our authority under section 205 of the FPA to ensure 
    that rates, terms and conditions of transmission and sales for resale 
    in interstate commerce by public utilities are just, reasonable and not 
    unduly discriminatory or preferential, and our authority under section 
    202(a) of the FPA to promote and encourage regional districts for the 
    voluntary interconnection and coordination of transmission facilities 
    by public utilities and non-public utilities for the purpose of 
    assuring an abundant supply of electric energy throughout the U.S. with 
    the greatest possible economy, we propose the following.3
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \3\ The Commission's legal authority is discussed in Section II.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        First, the Commission proposes minimum characteristics and 
    functions that an RTO must satisfy. Industry participants, however, 
    retain flexibility in structuring RTOs that satisfy these 
    characteristics and functions. For example, we do not propose to 
    require or prohibit any one form of organization for RTOs or require or 
    prohibit RTO ownership of transmission facilities. The characteristics 
    and functions could be satisfied by different organizational forms, 
    such as ISOs, transcos, combinations of the two, or even new 
    organizational forms not yet discussed in the industry or proposed to 
    the Commission.
        Second, we propose to adopt an ``open architecture'' policy 
    regarding RTOs, whereby all RTO proposals must
    
    [[Page 31392]]
    
    allow the RTO and its members the flexibility to improve their 
    organizations in the future in terms of structure, operations, market 
    support and geographic scope to meet market needs. In turn, the 
    Commission will provide the regulatory flexibility to accommodate such 
    improvement.
        Third, we propose guidance on flexible transmission ratemaking that 
    may be proposed by RTOs, including ratemaking treatments that will 
    address congestion pricing and performance based regulation. We also 
    propose to consider on a case-by-case basis incentive pricing that may 
    be appropriate for transmission facilities under RTO control.
        Finally, all public utilities (with the exception of those 
    participating in an approved regional transmission entity that conforms 
    to the Commission's ISO principles) that own, operate or control 
    interstate transmission facilities must file with the Commission by 
    October 15, 2000 a proposal for an RTO with the minimum characteristics 
    and functions adopted in the Final Rule,4 or, alternatively, 
    a description of efforts to participate in an RTO, any existing 
    obstacles to RTO participation, and any plans to work toward RTO 
    participation. Each proposed RTO must plan to be operational by 
    December 15, 2001. We expect that such proposals would include the 
    transmission facilities of public utilities as well as transmission 
    facilities of public power and other non-public utility entities to the 
    extent possible.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \4\ An RTO proposal includes a basic agreement filed under 
    section 205 of the FPA setting out the rules, practices and 
    procedures under which an RTO will be governed and operated, and 
    requests by the public utility members of the RTO under section 203 
    of the FPA to transfer control of their jurisdictional transmission 
    facilities from individual public utilities to the RTO. Most RTO 
    proposals by public utilities are likely to involve one or more 
    filings under FPA sections 203, 205, or 206, but the number and 
    types of filing may vary depending upon the type of RTO proposed, 
    and the number of public utilities involved in the proposal. Under 
    the proposed rule, a utility may file a petition for a declaratory 
    order asking whether a proposed transmission entity would qualify as 
    an RTO, to be followed by appropriate filings under sections 203, 
    205 and/or 206.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A public utility that is a member of an existing transmission 
    entity that has been approved by the Commission as in conformance with 
    the eleven ISO principles set forth in Order No. 888 must make a filing 
    no later than January 15, 2001 that explains the extent to which the 
    transmission entity in which it participates meets the minimum 
    characteristics and functions for an RTO, or proposes to modify the 
    existing institution to become an RTO. Alternatively, the public 
    utility must file an explanation of efforts, obstacles and plans with 
    respect to conforming to these characteristics and functions.
        Through the required filings, utilities will make known to the 
    public any plans for RTO participation so that other utilities and the 
    competitive market can respond accordingly. This proposal relies 
    primarily on the enlightened self-interest of stakeholders in each 
    region. Such public disclosure of plans for transmission facilities 
    will benefit the industry, the financial community, and public policy 
    makers as the electric industry restructuring continues.
        To facilitate RTO formation in all regions of the Nation, the 
    Commission proposes to sponsor and support a collaborative process 
    under section 202(a) to take place in the spring of 2000. Under this 
    process, we expect that public utilities and non-public utilities, in 
    coordination with state officials, Commission staff, and all affected 
    interest groups, will actively work toward the voluntary development of 
    specific RTOs.
        Prior to undertaking this proposed rulemaking, we held eight 
    technical conferences in 1998 with all industry stakeholders as well as 
    three technical conferences this year with state regulatory commissions 
    to obtain their views on the need for, and benefits of, regional 
    organizations. We gained valuable insight from the participants, 
    including many state commissions that have undertaken or are 
    considering state retail choice programs for the consumers in their 
    states. In light of the comments received, we wish to respond to 
    several concerns that were raised.
        First, we are not proposing to mandate RTOs, nor are we proposing 
    detailed specifications on a particular organizational form for RTOs. 
    The goal of this rulemaking is to get RTOs in place through voluntary 
    participation. While this Commission has specific authorities and 
    responsibilities under the FPA to protect against undue discrimination 
    and remove impediments to wholesale competition, we believe it is 
    preferable to meet these responsibilities in the first instance through 
    an open and collaborative process that allows for regional flexibility 
    and induces voluntary behavior.
        Second, the development of RTOs is not intended to interfere with 
    state prerogatives in setting retail competition policy. The Commission 
    believes that RTOs can successfully accommodate the transmission 
    systems of all states, whether or not a particular state has adopted 
    retail competition. However, for those states that have chosen to adopt 
    retail wheeling, RTOs can play a critical role in the realization of 
    full competition at the retail level as well as at the wholesale level. 
    In addition, the Commission believes that RTOs will not interfere with 
    a state's prerogative to keep the benefits of low-cost power for the 
    state's own retail consumers.
        Third, we propose to allow RTOs to prevent transmission cost 
    shifting by continuing our policy of flexibility with respect to 
    recovery of sunk transmission costs, such as the ``license plate'' 
    approach.
        Fourth, the existence of RTOs has not, and will not in the future, 
    interfere with traditional state and local regulatory responsibilities 
    such as transmission siting, local reliability matters, and regulation 
    of retail sales of generation and local distribution. In fact, RTOs 
    offer the potential to assist the states in their regulation of retail 
    markets and in resolving matters among states on a regional basis. They 
    also provide a vehicle for amicably resolving state and Federal 
    jurisdictional issues.
        Finally, we do not propose to establish regional boundaries in this 
    rulemaking. Our foremost concern is that a proposed RTO's regional 
    configuration is sufficient to ensure that the required RTO 
    characteristics and functions are satisfied. To this end, the 
    Commission proposes guidance regarding the scope and regional 
    configuration of RTOs.
        We now turn to the state of the electric utility industry in the 
    wake of Order No. 888 and how the development of RTOs achieves 
    efficient, reliable and competitive power markets.
    
    II. Background
    
        In April 1996, in Order Nos. 888 and 889, the Commission 
    established the foundation necessary to develop competitive bulk power 
    markets in the United States: non-discriminatory open access 
    transmission services by public utilities and stranded cost recovery 
    rules that would provide a fair transition to competitive markets. 
    Order Nos. 888 and 889 were very successful in accomplishing much of 
    what they set out to do. However, they were not intended to address all 
    problems that might arise in the development of competitive power 
    markets. Indeed, the nature of the emerging markets and the remaining 
    impediments to full competition have become apparent in the three years 
    since the issuance of our orders.
    
    A. The Foundation for Competitive Markets: Order Nos. 888 and 889
    
        In Order Nos. 888 and 889, the Commission found that unduly 
    discriminatory and anticompetitive
    
    [[Page 31393]]
    
    practices existed in the electric industry, and that transmission-
    owning utilities had discriminated against others seeking transmission 
    access.5 The Commission stated that its goal was to ensure 
    that customers have the benefits of competitively priced generation, 
    and determined that non-discriminatory open access transmission 
    services (including access to transmission information) and stranded 
    cost recovery were the most critical components of a successful 
    transition to competitive wholesale electricity markets.6
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \5\ Order No. 888, FERC Stats & Regs. at 31,682.
        \6\ Id. at 31,652.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Accordingly, Order No. 888 required all public utilities that own, 
    control or operate facilities used for transmitting electric energy in 
    interstate commerce to (1) file open access non-discriminatory 
    transmission tariffs containing, at a minimum, the non-price terms and 
    conditions set forth in the Order, and (2) functionally unbundle 
    wholesale power services. Under functional unbundling, the public 
    utility must: (a) take transmission services under the same tariff of 
    general applicability as do others; (b) state separate rates for 
    wholesale generation, transmission, and ancillary services; and (c) 
    rely on the same electronic information network that its transmission 
    customers rely on to obtain information about its transmission system 
    when buying or selling power.7 Order No. 889 required that 
    all public utilities establish or participate in an Open Access Same-
    Time Information System (OASIS) that meets certain specifications, and 
    comply with standards of conduct designed to prevent employees of a 
    public utility (or any employees of its affiliates) engaged in 
    wholesale power marketing functions from obtaining preferential access 
    to pertinent transmission system information.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \7\ Id. at 31,654-55.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        During the course of the Order No. 888 proceeding, the Commission 
    received comments urging it to require generation divestiture or 
    structural institutional arrangements such as regional independent 
    system operators (ISOs) to better assure non-discrimination. The 
    Commission responded that, while it believed that ISOs had the 
    potential to provide significant benefits, efforts to remedy undue 
    discrimination should begin by requiring the less intrusive functional 
    unbundling approach. Order No. 888 set forth eleven principles for 
    assessing ISO proposals submitted to the Commission. 8 Order 
    No. 888 also stated:
    
        \8\ Id. at 31,730.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        [W]e see many benefits in ISOs, and encourage utilities to 
    consider ISOs as a tool to meet the demands of the competitive 
    marketplace.
        As a further precaution against discriminatory behavior, we will 
    continue to monitor electricity markets to ensure that functional 
    unbundling adequately protects transmission customers. At the same 
    time, we will analyze all alternative proposals, including formation 
    of ISOs, and, if it becomes apparent that functional unbundling is 
    inadequate or unworkable in assuring non-discriminatory open access 
    transmission, we will reevaluate our position and decide whether 
    other mechanisms, such as ISOs, should be required. 9
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \9\ Id. at 31,655.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In section III.A.2 of this Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, we 
    discuss our experiences to date with functional unbundling. It has 
    become apparent that several types of regional transmission 
    institutions, in addition to the kinds of ISOs approved to date, may 
    also be able to provide the benefits attributed to ISOs in Order No. 
    888.
    
    B. Developments Since Order Nos. 888 and 889
    
        In the three years since Order Nos. 888 and 889 were issued, 
    numerous significant developments have occurred in the electric utility 
    industry. Some of these reflect changes in governmental policies; 
    others are strictly industry driven. These activities have resulted in 
    a considerably different industry landscape from the one faced at the 
    time the Commission was developing Order No. 888, resulting in new 
    regulatory and industry challenges.
        Order Nos. 888 and 889 required a significant change in the way 
    many public utilities have done business for most of this century, and 
    most public utilities accepted these changes and made substantial good 
    faith efforts to comply with the new requirements. Virtually all public 
    utilities have filed tariffs stating rates, terms and conditions for 
    third-party use of their transmission systems. In addition, improved 
    information about the transmission system is available to all 
    participants in the market at the same time that it is available to the 
    public utility as a result of utility compliance with the OASIS 
    regulations.
        The availability of tariffs and information about the transmission 
    system has fostered a rapid growth in dependence on wholesale markets 
    for acquisition of generation resources. Areas that have experienced 
    generation shortages have seen rapid development of new generation 
    resources. For example, New England, where there was deep concern about 
    adequacy of generation supply only three years ago, now has 
    approximately 30,000 MW of generation proposed. That response comes 
    almost entirely from independent generating plants that are able to 
    sell power into the bulk power market through open access to the 
    transmission system. Power resources are now acquired over increasingly 
    large regional areas, and interregional transfers of electricity have 
    increased.
        The very success of Order Nos. 888 and 889, and the initiative of 
    some utilities that have pursued voluntary restructuring beyond the 
    minimum open access requirements , have put new stresses on regional 
    transmission systems--stresses that call for regional solutions.
    1. Industry Restructuring and New Stresses on the Transmission Grid
        Open access transmission and the opening of wholesale competition 
    in the electric industry have brought an array of changes in the past 
    several years: divestiture by many integrated utilities of some or all 
    of their generating assets; significantly increased merger activity 
    both between electric utilities and between electric and natural gas 
    utilities; increases in the number of new participants in the industry 
    in the form of independent power marketers and generators; increases in 
    the volume of trade in the industry, particularly as marketers make 
    multiple sales; state efforts to create retail competition; and new and 
    different uses of the transmission grid.
        With respect to divestiture, since August 1997, approximately 
    50,000 MW of generating capacity have been sold (or are under contract 
    to be sold) by utilities, and an additional 30,000 MW is currently for 
    sale. In total, this represents more than 10 percent of U.S. generating 
    capacity. In all, according to publicly available data, 27 utilities 
    have sold all or some of their generating assets and 7 others have 
    assets for sale. Buyers of this generating capacity have included 
    traditional utilities with specified service territories as well as 
    independent power producers with no required service territory.
        Since Order No. 888 was issued, there have been more than 20 
    applications filed with us to approve proposed mergers involving public 
    utilities. Most of these mergers have been approved by various 
    regulatory authorities, including the Commission, although a few have 
    been rejected or withdrawn, and several mergers are pending regulatory 
    approval. Most of these merger proposals have been between electric 
    utilities with contiguous service areas, while some of the proposed 
    mergers have been between utilities with non-
    
    [[Page 31394]]
    
    contiguous service areas. The Commission has also been presented with 
    merger applications involving the combination of electric and natural 
    gas assets.
        There has been significant growth in the volume of trading in the 
    wholesale electricity market. In the first quarter of 1995, according 
    to power marketer quarterly filings, marketer sales totaled 1.8 million 
    MWh, but by the second quarter of 1998, such sales escalated to 513 
    million MWh.10 Many new competitors have entered the 
    industry. For example, in the first quarter of 1995, there were eight 
    power marketers (either independent or affiliated with traditional 
    utilities) actively trading in wholesale power markets, but by the 
    second quarter of 1998, there were 108 actively trading power 
    marketers. The Commission has granted market-based rate authority to 
    well over 500 wholesale power marketers, of which some are independent 
    of traditional investor-owned utilities, some are affiliated with 
    traditional utilities, and some are traditional utilities 
    themselves.11
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \10\ Power marketer quarterly filings, cited in Staff Report to 
    the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission on the Causes of Wholesale 
    Electric Pricing Abnormalities in the Midwest During June 1998, 
    (September 22, 1998) (Staff Price Spike Report) at 3-1 to 3-2. It 
    must be noted that a significant portion of the sales represent the 
    retrading of power by a number of different market participants. In 
    other words, there may be multiple resales of the same generation.
        \11\ Id. at 3-1.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        State commissions and legislatures have been active in the past few 
    years studying competitive options at the retail level, setting up 
    pilot retail access programs, and, in some states, implementing full 
    scale retail access programs. As of May 1, 1999, 18 states have enacted 
    electric restructuring legislation, 3 have issued comprehensive 
    regulatory orders, and 28 others have legislation or orders pending or 
    investigations underway.12 Fifteen states have implemented 
    full-scale or pilot retail competition programs that offer a choice of 
    suppliers to at least some retail customers. Eight states have set in 
    motion programs to offer access to retail customers by a date certain.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \12\ ``Status of Electric Utility Deregulation Activity as of 
    May 1, 1999,'' Energy Information Administration.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Because of the changes in the structure of the electric industry, 
    the transmission grid is now being used more intensively and in 
    different ways than in the past. The Commission is concerned that the 
    traditional approaches to operating the grid are showing signs of 
    strain. According to the North American Electric Reliability Council 
    (NERC), ``the adequacy of the bulk transmission system has been 
    challenged to support the movement of power in unprecedented amounts 
    and in unexpected directions.'' 13 These changes in the use 
    of the transmission system ``will test the electric industry's ability 
    to maintain system security in operating the transmission system under 
    conditions for which it was not planned or designed.'' 14 It 
    should be noted that, despite the increased transmission system 
    loadings, NERC believes that the ``procedures and processes to mitigate 
    potential reliability impacts appear to be working reliably for now,'' 
    and that even though the system was particularly stressed during the 
    summer of 1998, ``the system performed reliably and firm demand was not 
    interrupted due to transmission transfer limitations.'' 15
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \13\ Reliability Assessment 1998-2007, North American Electric 
    Reliability Council (September 1998), at 26.
        \14\ Id.
        \15\ Id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        An indication that the increased and different use of the 
    transmission system is stressing the grid is the increased use of 
    transmission line loading relief (TLR) procedures. 16 NERC's 
    TLR procedures were invoked 250 times between January 1 and September 
    1, 1998 to prevent facility or interface overloads on the Eastern 
    Interconnection. 17
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \16\  The TLR procedures are designed to remedy overloads that 
    result when a transmission line or other transmission equipment 
    carries or will carry more power than its rating, which could result 
    in either power outages or damage to property. The TLR procedures 
    are designed to bring overloaded transmission equipment to within 
    NERC's Operating Security Limits essentially by curtailing 
    transactions contributing to the overload. See North American 
    Electric Reliability Council, 85 FERC para. 61,353 (1998) (NERC).
        \17\  Reliability Assessment 1998-2007 at 27.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        It appears that the planning and construction of transmission and 
    transmission-related facilities may not be keeping up with increased 
    requirements. According to NERC, ``Business is increasing on the 
    transmission system, but very little is being done to increase the load 
    serving and transfer capability of the bulk transmission system.'' 
    18 The amount of new transmission capacity planned over the 
    next ten years is significantly lower than the additions that had been 
    planned five years ago, and most of the planned projects are for local 
    system support. 19 NERC states that, ``The close 
    coordination of generation and transmission planning is diminishing as 
    vertically integrated utilities divest their generation assets and most 
    new generation is being proposed and developed by independent power 
    producers.'' 20
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \18\  Id. at 26.
        \19\  Id. at 7.
        \20\  Id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The transition to new market structures has resulted in new 
    challenges and circumstances. For example, during the week of June 22-
    26, 1998, the wholesale electric market in the Midwest experienced 
    numerous events that led to unprecedented high spot market prices. Spot 
    wholesale market prices for energy briefly rose as high as $7,500 per 
    MWh, compared to an average price for the summer of approximately $40 
    per MWh in the Midwest if the price spikes are excluded. 21 
    This experience led to calls for price caps, allegations of market 
    power, and a questioning of the effectiveness of transmission open 
    access and wholesale electric competition.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \21\  Staff Price Spike Report at 3-8 to 3-11.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission staff undertook an investigation of the price spike 
    incident. Staff's report concluded that the unusually high price levels 
    were caused by a combination of factors, particularly above-average 
    generation outages, unseasonably hot temperatures, storm-related 
    transmission outages, transmission constraints, poor communication of 
    price signals, lowered confidence in the market due to a few contract 
    defaults, and inexperience in dealing with competitive markets. 
    22
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \22\  Id. at v.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission's staff found that the market institutions were not 
    adequately prepared to deal with such a dramatic series of events. 
    Regarding regional transmission entities, the staff report observed: 
    ``The necessity for cooperation in meeting reliability concerns and the 
    Commission's intent to foster competitive market conditions underscores 
    the importance of better regional coordination in areas such as 
    maintenance of transmission and generation systems and transmission 
    planning and operation.'' 23 Support for this view comes 
    from many sources. For example, the Public Utilities Commission of 
    Ohio, in its own report on the price spikes, recommended that policy 
    makers ``take unambiguous action to require coordination of 
    transmission system operations by regionwide Independent System 
    Operators.'' 24
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \23\  Id. at 5-8.
        \24\  Ohio's Electric Market, June 22-26, 1998, What Happened 
    and Why, A Report to the Ohio General Assembly, at iii.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        On September 29, 1998, the Secretary of Energy Advisory Board Task 
    Force on Electric System Reliability published its
    
    [[Page 31395]]
    
    final report. 25 The Task Force was convened in January 1997 
    to provide advice to the Department of Energy on critical 
    institutional, technical, and policy issues that need to be addressed 
    in order to maintain bulk power electric system reliability in a more 
    competitive industry. The Task Force found that ``the traditional 
    reliability institutions and processes that have served the Nation well 
    in the past need to be modified to ensure that reliability is 
    maintained in a competitively neutral fashion;'' that ``grid 
    reliability depends heavily on system operators who monitor and control 
    the grid in real time;'' and that ``because bulk power systems are 
    regional in nature, they can and should be operated more reliably and 
    efficiently when coordinated over large geographic areas.'' 
    26
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \25\  Maintaining Reliability in a Competitive U.S. Electricity 
    Industry; Final Report of the Task Force on Electric System 
    Reliability (Sept. 29, 1998) (Task Force Report). The Task Force was 
    comprised of 24 members representing all major segments of the 
    electric industry, including private and public suppliers, power 
    marketers, regulators, environmentalists, and academics.
        \26\  Task Force Report at x-xi.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The report noted that many regions of the United States are 
    developing ISOs as a way to maintain electric system reliability as 
    competitive markets develop. According to the Task Force, ISOs are 
    significant institutions to assure both electric system reliability and 
    competitive generation markets. The Task Force concluded that a large 
    ISO would: (1) be able to identify and address reliability issues most 
    effectively; (2) internalize much of the loop flow caused by the 
    growing number of transactions; (3) facilitate transmission access 
    across a larger portion of the network, consequently improving market 
    efficiencies and promoting greater competition; and (4) eliminate 
    ``pancaking'' of transmission rates, thus allowing a greater range of 
    economic energy trades across the network. 27
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \27\  Id. at 76.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    2. Successes, Failures, and Haphazard Development of Regional 
    Transmission Entities
        Since Order No. 888 was issued, there have been both successful and 
    unsuccessful efforts to establish ISOs, and other efforts to form 
    regional entities to operate the transmission facilities in various 
    parts of the country. While we are encouraged by the success of some of 
    these efforts, it is apparent that the results have been inconsistent, 
    and much of the country's transmission facilities remain outside of an 
    operational regional transmission institution.
        Proposals for the establishment of five ISOs have been submitted to 
    and approved, or conditionally approved, by the Commission. These are 
    the California ISO,28 the PJM ISO,29 ISO New 
    England ISO,30 the New York ISO,31 and the 
    Midwest ISO.32 In addition, the Texas Commission has ordered 
    an ISO for the Electric Reliability Council of Texas 
    (ERCOT).33 Moreover, our international neighbors in Canada 
    and Mexico are also pursuing electric restructuring efforts that 
    include various forms of regional transmission entities.34
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \28\ Pacific Gas & Electric Company, et al., 77 FERC para.61,204 
    (1996), order on reh'g, 81 FERC para.61,122 (1997) (Pacific Gas & 
    Electric).
        \29\ Pennsylvania-New Jersey-Maryland Interconnection, et al., 
    81 FERC para.61,257 (1997), reh'g pending (PJM).
        \30\ New England Power Pool, 79 FERC para.61,374 (1997), order 
    on reh'g, 85 FERC para.61,242 (1998) (order conditionally 
    authorizing ISO New England); New England Power Pool, 83 FERC 
    para.61,045 (1998), reh'g pending (order on NEPOOL tariff and 
    restructuring)(NEPOOL).
        \31\ Central Hudson Gas & Electric Corporation, et al., 83 FERC 
    para.61,352 (1998), order on reh'g, 87 FERC para.61,135 (1999) 
    (Central Hudson).
        \32\ Midwest Independent Transmission System Operator, et al., 
    84 FERC para.61,231, order on reconsideration, 85 FERC para.61,250, 
    order on reh'g, 85 FERC para.61,372 (1998) (Midwest ISO).
        \33\ See 16 Texas Administrative Code Sec. 23.67(p).
        \34\ See Policy Proposal for Structural Reform of the Mexican 
    Electricity Industry, Secretary of Energy, Mexico (February 1999); 
    Third Interim Report of the Ontario Market Design Committee (October 
    1998); TransAlta Enterprises Corporation, 75 FERC para.61,268 at 
    61,875 (1996) (recognition of the restructuring in the Province of 
    Alberta, Canada to create a Grid Company of Alberta).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The PJM, New England and New York ISOs were established on the 
    platform of existing tight power pools. It appears that the principal 
    motivation for creating ISOs in these situations was the Order No. 888 
    requirement that there be a single system wide transmission tariff for 
    tight pools. In contrast, the establishment of the California ISO and 
    the ERCOT ISO was the direct result of mandates by state governments. 
    The Midwest ISO, which is not yet operational, is unique. It began 
    through a consensual process and was not driven by a pre-existing 
    institution. Two states in the region subsequently required utilities 
    in their states to participate in either a Commission-approved ISO 
    (Illinois and Wisconsin), or sell their transmission assets to an 
    independent transmission company (Wisconsin).
        The approved ISOs have similarities as well as differences. All 
    five Commission-approved ISOs operate, or propose to operate, as non-
    profit organizations. All five ISOs include both public and non-public 
    utility members. However, among the five, there is considerable 
    variation in governance, operational responsibilities, geographic scope 
    and market operations. Four of the ISOs rely on a two-tier form of 
    governance with a non-stakeholder governing board on top that is 
    advised, either formally or informally, by one or more stakeholder 
    groups. In general, the final decision making authority rests with the 
    independent non-stakeholder board. One ISO, the California ISO, uses a 
    board consisting of stakeholders and non-stakeholders.
        Four of the five ISOs operate traditional control areas, but the 
    Midwest ISO does not currently plan to operate a traditional control 
    area. Three are multi-state ISOs (New England, PJM and Midwest), while 
    two ISOs (California and New York) currently operate within a single 
    state. The current Midwest ISO members do not encompass one contiguous 
    geographic area and there are holes in its coverage. The ISO New 
    England administers a separate NEPOOL tariff, while the other four 
    administer their own ISO transmission tariffs.
        Three ISOs operate or propose to operate centralized power markets 
    (New England, PJM and New York), and one ISO (California) relies on a 
    separate power exchange (PX) to operate such a market.35 The 
    Midwest ISO did not originally envision an ISO-related centralized 
    market for its region.36 In addition, at least one separate 
    PX has begun to do business in California apart from the PX established 
    through the restructuring legislation.37
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \35\ The California PX offers day-ahead and hour-ahead markets 
    and the ISO operates a real-time energy market. Participation in the 
    PX market is voluntary except that the three traditional investor-
    owned utilities in California must bid their generation sales and 
    purchases through the PX for the first five years. New York will 
    offer day-ahead and real-time energy markets that will be operated 
    by the ISO. PJM and New England offer only real-time energy markets, 
    although PJM has proposed to operate a day-ahead market. The ERCOT 
    ISO is the only other ISO that does not currently operate a PX.
        \36\ There are indications, however, that the Midwest ISO is 
    considering the formation of a power exchange. See Joint Committee 
    for the Development of a Midwest Independent Power Exchange, 
    ``Solicitation of Interest-Creation of an Independent Power Exchange 
    for the U.S. Midwest,'' February 5, 1999.
        \37\ See Automated Power Exchange, Inc., 82 FERC para. 61,287, 
    reh'g denied, 84 FERC para. 61,020 (1998), appeals docketed, No. 98-
    1415 (D.C. Cir. Sept. 14, 1998) and No. 98-1419 (D.C. Cir. Sept. 14, 
    1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Not all efforts to create ISOs have been successful. For example, 
    after more than two years of effort, the proponents of the IndeGO ISO 
    in the Pacific Northwest and Rocky Mountain regions ended their efforts 
    to create an ISO. More recently, members of MAPP, an existing power 
    pool that covers six U.S.
    
    [[Page 31396]]
    
    states and two Canadian provinces, failed to achieve consensus for 
    establishing a long-planned ISO. In the Southwest, proponents of the 
    Desert Star ISO have not been able to reach agreement on a formal 
    proposal after more than two years of discussion.
        Various reasons have been advanced to explain why it is difficult 
    to form a voluntary, multi-state ISO. These include cost shifting in 
    transmission capital costs; disagreements about sharing of ISO 
    transmission revenues among transmission owners; difficulties in 
    obtaining the participation of publicly-owned transmission facilities; 
    concerns about the loss of transmission rights and prices embedded in 
    existing transmission agreements; the likelihood of not being able to 
    maintain or gain a competitive advantage in power markets through the 
    use of transmission facilities; and the preference of certain 
    transmission owners to sell or transfer their transmission assets to a 
    for-profit transmission company in lieu of handing over control to a 
    non-profit ISO.
        Apart from these efforts to create ISOs, we have received proposals 
    for other types of transmission entities. For example, in October 1998 
    a group of Arizona entities filed a request with the Commission to 
    create an ``independent scheduling administrator'' (ISA) in 
    Arizona.38 Unlike an ISO, this entity would not administer 
    its own transmission tariff nor would it have any direct operational 
    responsibilities. Instead, it appears that its functions would be 
    limited to monitoring the scheduling decisions and OASIS site operation 
    of the Arizona utilities that operate transmission 
    facilities.39 In case of disputes, the ISA would provide a 
    type of expedited dispute resolution process. The applicants state that 
    the ISA would be a transitional organization that would ultimately 
    evolve or be merged into a stronger, multi-state ISO.40 In 
    other developments, one public utility has recently made a filing with 
    us to sell its transmission assets to a newly formed 
    affiliate.41 Another public utility recently filed a request 
    for declaratory order asking us to find that its proposal to transfer 
    its transmission assets (in the form of ownership or a lease) to a 
    ``transco'' in return for a passive ownership interest in the transco, 
    would satisfy the Commission's eleven ISO principles.42
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \38\ Arizona Independent Scheduling Administrator Association, 
    Docket No. ER99-388-000 (filed October 29, 1998).
        \39\ A proposal for a similar entity has been in the Pacific 
    Northwest. This entity, described as an independent grid scheduler, 
    would make actual scheduling decisions rather than simply monitoring 
    the decisions made by current transmission owners. See Regional ISO 
    Conference (Portland), transcript at 39-40.
        \40\ See Applicant's filing, Docket No. ER99-388-000, at 3.
        \41\ FirstEnergy, Inc., Docket No. EC99-53-000 (filed March 19, 
    1999).
        \42\ Entergy Services, Inc., Docket No. EL99-57-000 (filed April 
    5, 1999).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As part of general restructuring initiatives, several states now 
    require independent grid management organizations. For example, an 
    Illinois law requires that its utilities become members of a FERC-
    approved regional ISO by March 31, 1999, and Wisconsin law gives its 
    utilities the option of joining an ISO or selling their transmission 
    assets to an independent transmission company by June 30, 2000. In both 
    states, the backstop is a single-state organization if regional 
    organizations are not developed. Recently, Virginia and Arkansas have 
    also enacted legislation requiring their electric utilities to join or 
    establish regional transmission entities.
    3. The Commission's ISO and RTO Inquiries; Conferences with 
    Stakeholders and State Regulators
        In light of the various restructuring activities occurring 
    throughout the U.S., the Commission has, within the past year, held 11 
    public conferences in 9 different cities across the country to hear the 
    views of industry, consumers, and state regulators with respect to the 
    need for RTOs and their appropriate roles and responsibilities.
        The Commission initiated an inquiry in March 1998 pertaining to its 
    policies on ISOs. A notice establishing procedures for a conference 
    gave the following rationale:
    
        In Order Nos. 888 and 889 and their progeny, the Commission 
    established the fundamental principles of non-discriminatory open 
    access transmission services. Nevertheless, many issues remain to be 
    addressed if the Nation is to fully realize the benefits of open 
    access and more competitive electric markets.
    * * * * *
        Given the dramatic changes taking place in both wholesale and 
    retail electric markets and the many proposals under consideration 
    with respect to the creation of ISOs or other transmission entities, 
    such as transmission-only utilities, it is time for the Commission 
    to take stock of its policies in order to determine whether they 
    appropriately support our dual goals of eliminating undue 
    discrimination and promoting competition in electric power 
    markets.\43\
    
        \43\ Inquiry Concerning the Commission's Policy on Independent 
    System Operators, Notice of Conference, Docket No. PL98-5-000, at 1-
    2 (March 13, 1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Accordingly, the Commission held a series of eight conferences in 1998 
    to gain insight into participants' views on the formation and role of 
    ISOs in the electric utility industry. The first conference was held in 
    April 1998 at the Commission's offices in Washington, D.C. Between May 
    28 and June 8, 1998, the Commission held seven regional conferences in 
    Phoenix, Kansas City, New Orleans, Indianapolis, Portland, Richmond and 
    Orlando. As a result of these conferences, the Commission heard 
    approximately 145 oral presentations and received a large number of 
    written comments on the appropriate size, scope, organization and 
    functions of regional transmission institutions. A number of different 
    viewpoints were expressed. They will be discussed elsewhere in this 
    NOPR and are summarized in Appendix A hereto.
        On October 1, 1998, the Secretary of Energy delegated his authority 
    under section 202(a) of the FPA to the Commission. In doing so the 
    Secretary stated that section 202(a) ``provides DOE with sufficient 
    authority to establish boundaries for Independent System Operators 
    (ISOs) or other appropriate transmission entities.'' \44\ The Secretary 
    also stated,
    
        \44\ 63 FR 53889 (1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        FERC is also increasingly faced with reliability-related issues. 
    Providing FERC with the authority to establish boundaries for ISOs 
    or other appropriate transmission entities could aid in the orderly 
    formation of properly-sized transmission institutions and in 
    addressing reliability-related issues, thereby increasing the 
    reliability of the transmission system.
    
        On November 24, 1998, we gave notice in this docket of our intent 
    to initiate a consultation process with State commissions pursuant to 
    section 202(a).45 The purpose of the consultations was to 
    afford State commissions a reasonable opportunity to present their 
    views with respect to appropriate boundaries for regional transmission 
    institutions and other issues relating to RTOs. Conferences with State 
    commissioners were held in St. Louis, Missouri on February 11, 1999; in 
    Las Vegas, Nevada on February 12, 1999; and in Washington, D.C. on 
    February 17, 1999. In all, we heard oral presentations by 
    representatives of 41 state commissions during these consultations, 
    with others monitoring or providing written comments.46 
    During these sessions, we received much valuable advice. We have set 
    forth in Appendix B a summary of the comments received, and discuss in
    
    [[Page 31397]]
    
    Section III.B below our response to some of the major concerns 
    expressed.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \45\ Notice of Intent to Consult Under Section 202(a), 63 FR 
    66158 1998*), FERC Stats & Regs. para. 35,534 (1998).
        \46\ See Appendix B for a list of commenters.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    C. Statutory Framework
    
        The Commission is granted the authority and responsibility by FPA 
    sections 205 and 206, 16 U.S.C. 824d, 824e, to ensure that the rates, 
    charges, classifications, and service of public utilities (and any 
    rule, regulation, practice, or contract affecting any of these) are 
    just and reasonable and not unduly discriminatory, and to remedy undue 
    discrimination in the provision of such services. In fulfilling its 
    responsibilities under FPA sections 205 and 206, the Commission is 
    required to address, and has the authority to remedy, undue 
    discrimination and anticompetitive effects. The Commission has a 
    statutory mandate under these sections to ensure that transmission in 
    interstate commerce and rates, contracts, and practices affecting 
    transmission services, do not reflect an undue preference or advantage 
    (or undue prejudice or disadvantage) and are just, reasonable, and not 
    unduly discriminatory or preferential.47 Additionally, as 
    discussed in Order No. 888,48 there is a substantial body of 
    case law that holds that the Commission's regulatory authority under 
    the FPA ``clearly carries with it the responsibility to consider, in 
    appropriate circumstances, the anticompetitive effects of regulated 
    aspects of interstate utility operations pursuant to [FPA] Secs. 202 
    and 203, and under like directives contained in Secs. 205, 206, and 
    207.'' 49
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \47\ Once such a finding is made, the Commission is required to 
    remedy it. See, e.g., Southern California Edison Company, 40 FERC 
    para. 61,371 at 62,151-52 (1987), order on reh'g 50 FERC para. 
    61,275 at 61,873 (1990), modified sub nom., Cities of Anaheim v. 
    FERC, 941 F.2d 1234 (D.C. Cir. 1991); Delmarva Power and Light 
    Company, 24 FERC para. 61,199 at 61,466, order on reh'g 24 FERC 
    para. 61,380 (1983).
        \48\ Order No. 888, FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,669.
        \49\ Gulf States Utilities Co. v. FPC, 411 U.S. 747, 758-59, 
    reh'g denied, 412 U.S. 944 (1973) (Gulf States). See also City of 
    Huntingburg v. FPC, 498 F.2d 778, 783-84 (D.C. Cir. 1974) 
    (Commission has a duty to consider the potential anticompetitive 
    effects of a proposed Interconnection Agreement.)
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission also has the authority and responsibility under 
    section 203 of the FPA to review mergers and other transactions 
    involving public utilities, including dispositions of jurisdictional 
    facilities by public utilities. This includes public utilities' 
    transfers of control of jurisdictional transmission facilities to 
    entities such as RTOs. Under section 203, the Commission must approve a 
    proposed disposition of jurisdictional facilities if it is consistent 
    with the public interest. The Commission may grant an application under 
    section 203 upon such terms and conditions as it finds necessary to 
    secure the maintenance of adequate service and the coordination in the 
    public interest of jurisdictional facilities.
        Further, section 202(a) of the FPA, whose authority has recently 
    been delegated to the Commission by the Secretary of 
    Energy,50 authorizes and directs the Commission ``to divide 
    the country into regional districts for the voluntary interconnection 
    and coordination of facilities for the generation, transmission, and 
    sale of electric energy * * *.'' The purpose of this division into 
    regional districts is for ``assuring an abundant supply of electric 
    energy throughout the United States with the greatest possible economy 
    and with regard to the proper utilization and conservation of natural 
    resources * * *.'' Section 202(a) states that it is ``the duty of the 
    Commission to promote and encourage such interconnection and 
    coordination within each such district and between such districts.''
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \50\ 63 FR 53889 (1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    III. Discussion
    
    A. Barriers to Assuring an Abundant Supply of Electric Energy 
    Throughout the United States with the Greatest Possible Economy
    
        In light of our experiences with ISOs and other utility 
    restructuring activity in the aftermath of Order Nos. 888 and 889, and 
    after almost three years of experience with implementation of Order 
    Nos. 888 and 889, we believe that there remain important transmission-
    related impediments to a competitive wholesale electric market. We have 
    grouped these remaining impediments into two broad categories. The 
    first category of impediments consists of engineering and economic 
    inefficiencies inherent in the current operation and expansion of the 
    transmission grid--inefficiencies that, in and of themselves, are 
    hindering fully competitive power markets and imposing unnecessary 
    costs on electric consumers. The second category of impediments 
    consists of continuing opportunities for transmission owners to unduly 
    discriminate in the operation of their transmission systems so as to 
    favor their own or their affiliates' power marketing activities. Both 
    sets of impediments unnecessarily restrict the scope of bulk power 
    markets and inhibit the large-scale competition that we sought in 
    issuing Order Nos. 888 and 889.
        The situation of the electric industry is somewhat analogous to the 
    natural gas industry after the initial step of open access 
    transportation was taken. In 1985, the Commission issued Order No. 
    436,51 which instituted open-access, nondiscriminatory 
    transportation of natural gas with the goal of increasing competition 
    and permitting gas users to purchase gas directly from gas merchants. 
    However, the Commission subsequently found that open access alone was 
    not sufficient to remove all barriers to competition. 52 
    Because of the different structures of the electric and gas industries, 
    the specific remaining impediments to competition may not be the same, 
    but there are similarities in that open access, without sufficient 
    mechanisms for ensuring that such access is equal and efficient for all 
    participants, may not be enough to promote a fully competitive market. 
    53
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \51\ Regulation of Natural Gas Pipelines After Partial Wellhead 
    Decontrol, Order No. 436, 50 FR 42408 (Oct. 18, 1985), FERC Stats. & 
    Regs. [Regulations Preambles 1982-1985] para. 30,665 1985), vacated 
    and remanded, Associated Gas Distributors v. FERC, 824 F.2d 981 
    (D.C. Cir. 1987), cert. denied, 485 U.S. 1006 (1988), readopted on 
    an interim basis, Order No. 500, 52 FR 30334 (Aug. 14, 1987), FERC 
    Stats. & Regs. [Regulations Preambles, 1986-1990] para.30,761 
    (1987), remanded, American Gas Association v. FERC, 888 F.2d 136 
    (D.C. Cir. 1989), readopted, Order No. 500-H, 54 FR 52334 (Dec. 21, 
    1989), FERC Stats. & Regs. [Regulations Preambles 1986-1990] para. 
    30,867 (1989), reh'g granted in part and denied in part, Order No. 
    500-I, 55 FR 6605 (Feb. 26, 1990), FERC Stats. & Regs. [Regulations 
    Preambles 1986-1990] para. 30,880 (1990), aff'd in part and remanded 
    in part, American Gas Association v. FERC, 912 F.2d 1496 (D.C. Cir. 
    1990), cert. denied, 111 S. Ct. 957 (1991).
        \52\ In the case of natural gas, we found that the principal 
    remaining barrier was the continued existence of bundled city-gate 
    firm sales service that had a transportation component of higher 
    quality than available through open access. Hence, we issued Order 
    No. 636 to unbundle services and equalize the quality of service 
    offered. See Pipeline Service Obligations and Revisions to 
    Regulations Governing Self-Implementing Transportation and 
    Regulation of Natural Gas Pipelines After Partial Wellhead 
    Decontrol, 57 FR 13267 (April 16, 1992), III FERC Stats. & Regs. 
    para. 30,939 (April 8, 1992), reh'g granted and denied in part, 
    Order No. 636-A, 57 FR 36128 (August 12, 1992), III FERC Stats. & 
    Regs. para. 30,950 (August 3, 1992), order on reh'g Order No. 636-B, 
    57 FR 57911 (December 8, 1992), 61 FERC para. 61,272 (1992), Notice 
    of Denial of Rehearing (January 8, 1993), 62 FERC para. 61,007 
    (1993), aff'd in part and vacated and remanded in part, United Dist. 
    Companies v. FERC, 88 F.3d 1105 (D.C. Cir. July 16, 1996), order on 
    remand, Order No. 636-C, 78 FERC para. 61,186 (1997).
        \53\ For a discussion of the similarities and differences in the 
    structure and regulation of the natural gas and electric industries, 
    see generally Santa and Sikora, Open Access And Transition Costs: 
    Will The Electric Industry Transition Track The Natural Gas 
    Restructuring?, 15 Energy L.J. 273 (1994).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Our current understanding of industry conditions, as set forth 
    below, will be enhanced by future consultations with and analysis from 
    all industry stakeholders, including state commissions. The Commission 
    seeks comments in order to achieve a deeper
    
    [[Page 31398]]
    
    appreciation of any impediments to competition in the Nation's 
    electricity markets and how they should be addressed.
    1. Engineering and Economic Inefficiencies in the Operation, Planning 
    and Expansion of Regional Transmission Grids
        The transmission facilities of any one utility in a region are part 
    of a larger, integrated transmission system. From an electrical 
    engineering perspective, each of the three interconnections in the 
    United States (the Eastern, the Western and ERCOT) operates as a single 
    ``machine.'' 54 The Eastern Interconnection also extends 
    into Canada, and the Western Interconnection includes parts of Canada 
    and Mexico.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \54\ North American Electric Reliability Council, Electric 
    Reliability Panel, ``Reliable Power: Renewing the North American 
    Electric Reliability Oversight System,'' December 1997, at 9.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Problems have arisen over the last three years, in part, because we 
    have multiple operators of each of these machines. Each separate 
    operator usually makes independent decisions about the use, limitations 
    and expansion of its piece of the interconnected grid based on 
    incomplete information. This approach--separate operation of each 
    utility's own transmission facilities--would make engineering sense 
    only if each system operated independently of the others. But the 
    physical reality is that, within the three interconnected grids, any 
    action taken by one transmission provider can have major and 
    instantaneous effects on the transmission facilities of all other 
    transmission providers.55
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \55\ U.S. Congress, Office of Technology Assessment, ``Electric 
    Power Wheeling and Dealing, Technological Considerations for 
    Increasing Competition,'' May, 1989.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        This is not a new phenomenon. Since the very first transmission 
    interconnection between two neighboring utilities, interconnected 
    utilities have had to cope with the fact that electricity will flow 
    over others' lines. In the past, these effects were often small or 
    infrequent and the utility could generally pass any costs through to 
    captive customers. Today, with the increase in bulk power trade and the 
    large shifts in power flows, the effects may be large, frequent and not 
    recoverable by the utility bearing the cost.
        Another important change is that the structure of the industry that 
    exists today is very different from the industry that existed three 
    years ago when we issued Order No. 888. The industry is no longer 
    composed uniformly of vertically-integrated, self-sufficient public 
    utilities that do not compete with each other. Instead, it is an 
    increasingly de-integrated and decentralized industry with many new and 
    existing participants that actively compete against each 
    other.56
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \56\ For example, there are now about 550 Commission-approved 
    power marketers. Decentralization has also increased because of 
    divestiture of generating plants by traditionally vertically 
    integrated utilities. Such sales are frequently required by state 
    governments as one element of the structural reforms that accompany 
    the introduction of retail competition. During the last three years, 
    utilities have sold or have contracts to sell more than 50,000 MW of 
    existing generating capacity. About 30,000 MW of additional capacity 
    is currently being offered for sale.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As a consequence of these changes in trade patterns and industry 
    structure, certain operational problems have become more significant 
    and more difficult to resolve. These include: maintaining reliable grid 
    operations; determining available transmission capability (ATC); 
    57 managing transmission congestion; and planning and 
    investing in new transmission facilities. In addition, traditional 
    approaches to the pricing and provision of transmission service may be 
    hindering the further development of competitive and efficient bulk 
    power markets. These impediments include: pancaking of transmission 
    access charges; non-market approaches to managing congestion; the 
    absence of clear transmission rights; the absence of secondary markets 
    in transmission service; and the possible disincentives created by the 
    level and structure of transmission rates. The Commission believes that 
    properly structured RTOs can address both sets of problems and further 
    the development of competitive bulk power markets.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \57\ See definition of ATC infra.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    a. Reliable Grid Operations
        The United States has one of the most reliable power systems in the 
    world. For over thirty years, NERC and the regional reliability 
    councils have developed and implemented voluntary standards to maintain 
    the security of the transmission systems. There is no net public policy 
    benefit to promoting competition if reliability suffers as a 
    consequence.58 The promotion of competition must therefore 
    go hand-in-hand with the creation of new institutions to ensure that 
    reliability is maintained or improved in any new industry 
    structure.59 We fully agree with the findings of the DOE 
    Reliability Task Force:
    
        \58\ Unless otherwise noted, we use the term ``reliability'' to 
    refer to the reliable or secure operation of the bulk power grid. 
    This is one component of the broader NERC definition, which also 
    includes ``adequacy'' (i.e., sufficient generation and transmission 
    capacity) as a second component of overall reliability. See North 
    American Electric Reliability Council, ``Glossary of Terms,'' August 
    1996, at 21.
        \59\ See George C. Loehr, ``Ten Myths About Electric 
    Deregulation: Electrons May Seem Imaginary, But Reliability Is 
    Real,'' Public Utilities Fortnightly, April 15, 1998, at 28-31.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    * * * there is a critical need to be sure that reliability is not 
    taken for granted as the industry restructures, and thus does not 
    ``fall through the cracks.'' 60
    
        \60\ DOE Task Force Report, at xv.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The DOE Reliability Task Force also pointed out that with the entry 
    of many new participants, dramatic increases in unbundled power sales 
    and shifts in electrical flows, the nation's bulk power system is being 
    stressed in ways that have never been experienced before. A similar 
    conclusion was reached by NERC in its 1998 summer assessment of bulk 
    power reliability:
    
        Throughout the Regions, parallel path flows from increased 
    electricity transfers are stressing the transmission systems. These 
    flows are at magnitudes and in directions not anticipated at the 
    time the systems were designed.* * *The transmission system will be 
    required to operate under unprecedented, and sometimes unstudied, 
    conditions.61
    
        \61\ NERC, ``1998 Summer Assessment: Reliability of Bulk 
    Electricity Supply in North America,'' May 1998, at 2-3.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    These stresses have always existed but not in these magnitudes. 
    Moreover, they could be more readily accommodated through voluntary ad 
    hoc agreements when there were fewer industry participants who 
    generally did not compete against each other in any significant 
    way.62 But as we have noted, this traditional industry 
    structure is rapidly disappearing. Our concern is that the reliability 
    fault lines may become more prominent and dangerous.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \62\ In assessing the continued viability of the current system, 
    NERC's blue-ribbon Electric Reliability Panel concluded that: ``The 
    competitive dynamics among a much larger universe of players is not 
    at all conducive to a system of voluntary peer compliance.'' 
    Electric Reliability Panel Report, December 1997, at 28.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        It is well accepted that the operation of interconnected 
    transmission networks requires careful coordination and the exchange of 
    information between many individual systems. Any operational change on 
    one system in the network instantly affects other systems. For example, 
    the shipment of power from one location to another will divide among 
    all transmission paths from source to destination based on the laws of 
    physics.63 This is referred to as
    
    [[Page 31399]]
    
    parallel path or loop flow. Such flows will also affect a neighboring 
    system's ability to determine ATC accurately. In addition, if a 
    transmission facility is already loaded close to its operating limit, 
    the additional flow resulting from a transaction contracted for on a 
    neighboring system may overload the facility and threaten reliability. 
    In order to operate the system in a reliable manner, a single, 
    independent grid operator must know all sources and destinations for 
    each transaction. The Commission believes that an RTO, as the only 
    transmission provider and security coordinator in its region, would 
    have the information needed to identify the effects of parallel flows 
    and accommodate them in its operations.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \63\ The amount of power flowing on any path in an electrical 
    network is inversely proportional to that path's impedance. 
    Impedance will depend on the actual length of the line and its 
    voltage. See U.S. Congress, Office of Technology Assessment, 
    Electric Power Wheeling and Dealing: Technological Considerations 
    for Increasing Competition, OTA-E-409, May 1989, at 110-11.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        At present, the industry's ability to maintain reliable grid 
    operation is hindered by the existence of many separate organizations 
    that directly or indirectly affect the operation and expansion of the 
    grid. There are more than 100 owners of the Nation's grid who operate 
    about 140 separate control areas.64 In addition, there are 
    10 regional reliability councils, 23 security coordinators, 5 regional 
    transmission groups (RTGs) and 5 independent system operators. With so 
    many entities, the lines of authority and communication are not always 
    as clear as they should be.65 An additional complication is 
    that many of these entities also own generation or have a decision 
    making process that continues to be dominated by traditional vertically 
    integrated utilities.66 Therefore, their independence and 
    commercial neutrality as grid operators is subject to question.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \64\ A control area is an electrical system bounded by 
    interconnection (tie-line) metering and telemetry. Within a control 
    area, resources are balanced against load, and generation is 
    regulated to maintain interchange schedules with other control areas 
    and to achieve the target frequency (60 hz) for the entire 
    Interconnection. See NERC Operating Policies Manual (available on 
    the NERC website at www.nerc.com).
        \65\ See, e.g., Western Systems Coordinating Council, EL99-23-
    000, comments of Enron Power Marketing, Inc. at 4-5.
        \66\ See, e.g., New England Power Pool, 86 FERC para. 61,262 at 
    61,965 (1999).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        It appears that information that is critical for maintaining 
    reliability is not being shared as readily now as was generally the 
    case in the past. NERC recently observed that there is a growing 
    ``reluctance on the part of the market participants to share 
    operational real-time and operational planning data with TPs 
    [transmission providers].'' 67 This is not surprising 
    because, as we have noted before, information that is needed for 
    reliability purposes may also have a commercial value.68 If 
    market participants believe that the entity that receives operational 
    information for reliability reasons may use it for commercial 
    advantage, they will understandably be reluctant to supply the 
    information. After spending more than 18 months reviewing the current 
    reliability system, the DOE Reliability Task Force concluded that this 
    inherited system, with its patchwork of organizations, inadequate 
    information sharing and overlapping and sometimes unclear 
    responsibilities, is ``clearly unsustainable'' and that until new 
    policies and institutions are in place, ``substantial parts of North 
    America will be exposed to unacceptable risk.'' 69
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \67\ NERC, Reliability Assessment 1998-2007 at 39 (1998).
        \68\ Midwest ISO, 84 FERC at 62, 158-159.
        \69\ DOE Task Force Report at vii and xi.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        This is not just a theoretical concern. During last year's regional 
    ISO conferences, several industry participants described three 
    ``reliability near misses'' in the Midwest. The three incidents on July 
    22, 1993, August 7, 1996 and July 11, 1997 came very close to producing 
    major outages throughout the Midwest.70 While there has been 
    some improvement in coordination among different systems, we believe 
    that there are limits to the amount of coordination that can be 
    achieved between separate organizations, especially if they are 
    competing for the right to use the same limited transmission capacity 
    and sometimes competing for the same customers. While competition 
    requires decentralization, we think that reliable and efficient grid 
    operation requires more coordination. The Commission believes that a 
    beneficial platform for both competition and reliability is a single 
    independent grid operator that sees the ``big picture'' by having 
    access to real-time information on conditions and schedules for the 
    entire regional grid.71 Such an entity does not exist in 
    several regions of the country. As a consequence, there is, at present, 
    a disconnect between electrical flows and information flows that could 
    have major reliability consequences.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \70\ Regional ISO Conference (Indianapolis), transcript at 24-
    29.
        \71\ The importance of a single operator for reliability was 
    stressed in comments of AMEREN and Commonwealth Edison. See Regional 
    ISO Conference (Indianapolis), transcript at 19-29.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    b. Determining Available Transmission Capability (ATC)
        Any transportation service provider should know how much commodity 
    it can carry. For electric transmission service providers, the 
    calculations of total transmission capability (TTC) and ATC are needed 
    to make this determination. TTC and ATC are key elements of the OASIS 
    information system.72 Order No. 889 requires each 
    transmission provider to calculate and post TTC and ATC numbers to give 
    its transmission customers a reasonable estimate of how much power can 
    be carried between any two locations on the grid and how much capacity 
    is available to support additional trade at any given time.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \72\ ATC is a measure of transfer capability remaining in the 
    physical transmission network for further commercial activity over 
    and above already committed uses. TTC is the amount of electric 
    power that can be transferred over the interconnected transmission 
    network in a reliable manner based on certain specified conditions, 
    North American Reliability Council, Glossary of Terms (1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We have received many complaints about the accuracy and usefulness 
    of posted ATC numbers. There are several reasons why it is difficult to 
    determine available transmission capability accurately.
        First, ATC numbers are still calculated on an individual company 
    basis in many areas of the country. Separate calculations of ATC by 
    individual companies are fundamentally inconsistent with the physical 
    reality of an interconnected transmission system. An individual 
    transmission provider may post ATC numbers in good faith, and attempt 
    to provide transmission service based on these numbers, only to learn 
    later that the transfer capability that it thought was available no 
    longer exists because of decisions made by other transmission providers 
    that it did not know about at the time it made its calculations. 
    Accurate ATC numbers would require reliable and timely information 
    about load, generation, facility outages and transactions on 
    neighboring systems. Individual transmission operators will generally 
    not have this information. They also may apply differing assumptions 
    and criteria to ATC calculations, which may produce wide variations in 
    posted ATC values for the same transmission path.73 All 
    these considerations make it virtually impossible for an individual 
    transmission provider that operates one
    
    [[Page 31400]]
    
    part of a large interconnected grid to calculate ATC 
    accurately.74
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \73\ This, in turn, creates other problems. According to NERC, 
    the ``inconsistent calculation [of ATC] can increase the use of TLR 
    and other operational complexities, which has the potential to cause 
    reliability problems.'' NERC, Reliability Assessment, 1998-2007, 
    September, 1998, at 40. (See definition of TLR in section II.)
        \74\ In addition, it has been frequently alleged that individual 
    transmission may intentionally post inaccurate ATC numbers to favor 
    their own power marketing efforts. These allegations are discussed 
    in section III.A.2.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Second, requests for transmission service are usually based on 
    ``contract path'' scheduling. This is the practice of finding a 
    contiguous chain of utilities from the power supplier to the power 
    consumer and contracting with those utilities to transmit the power. 
    The implicit assumption is that all the power flows through the 
    utilities along this ``contract path.'' In fact, the power divides up 
    and flows along all paths from the supplier to the buyer. All utilities 
    in the region are affected. Contract path scheduling provides little or 
    no information about actual flows on the grid.75 In its 
    October 1997 report to the Commission, the Commercial Practices Working 
    Group commented that: ``Reserving and scheduling transmission on a 
    contract path basis does not even closely resemble the physical impact 
    on the system.'' 76 We note that NERC is encouraging 
    initiatives that would move the industry toward recognizing actual 
    flows in scheduling.77
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \75\ See Allegheny Power Service Corporation et al., 78 FERC 
    para. 61,314 at 62,339.
        \76\ October 31, 1997 report, at 39.
        \77\ See NERC, 85 FERC at 62,363.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    c. Managing Congestion
        Congestion occurs when requests for transmission service exceed the 
    capability of the grid. When transmission constraints limit the amount 
    of power that can be transmitted, the loads on the system may not be 
    able to be served by the least-cost mix of available generators. The 
    constraints may reflect voltage, temperature and dynamic limits. 
    Relieving congestion leads to a more costly pattern of generation 
    dispatch. The cost of congestion is the additional energy cost 
    associated with the new pattern of dispatch.
        We recognize that even optimally designed systems will normally 
    experience at least occasional congestion that at times can be 
    significant and costly. In general, congestion can be managed in two 
    ways: the construction of new transmission facilities that increase 
    grid capacity; or the redispatch of existing or new generators to 
    reduce flows or create counterflows on the constrained facility. The 
    complete elimination of congestion would typically require the 
    construction of new transmission facilities. While this may be a 
    physically effective solution, it may not always be cost effective. 
    Because of this, we believe that an efficiently operated transmission 
    system should have in place mechanisms for pricing congestion and then 
    managing congestion through changes in the pattern of dispatch. Without 
    mechanisms for determining the cost of congestion, it will be virtually 
    impossible to make rational, cost effective decisions to expand the 
    grid.
        The Commission believes that efficient congestion management is 
    best performed at the regional level. At present, outside of the 
    operational ISOs, transaction curtailment through transmission loading 
    relief (TLR) procedures is the dominant approach for dealing with 
    congestion in the Eastern Interconnection. NERC has reported that its 
    TLR procedures were invoked 329 times between July 1997 and October 
    1998 on the Eastern Interconnection.78 Current TLR 
    procedures are cumbersome, inefficient and disruptive to bulk power 
    markets because they rely exclusively on physical measures of flows 
    with no attempt to assess the relative costs of different congestion 
    management options. Moreover, TLR actions are typically taken by one 
    utility without assessing the costs imposed on other grid users. This 
    inevitably raises the suspicion that the TLR request could be motivated 
    by competitive rather than reliability concerns. For these reasons, the 
    Commission has encouraged NERC to develop regional market approaches to 
    managing congestion.79
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \78\ North American Electricity Reliability Council, Interim 
    Market Interface Committee, Minutes of Jan. 12 and 13, 1999 meeting, 
    Exhibit D.
        \79\ See NERC, 85 FERC at 62,364.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission recognizes, however, that NERC may not be able to 
    comply fully with this policy in the absence of regional organizations 
    that have the authority and ability to promote regional congestion 
    markets. There are three considerations that support this conclusion.
        First, a regional organization would have accurate and reliable 
    information about existing and possible future conditions on the grid. 
    Such information is generally not available to individual transmission 
    providers. RTOs would have this information because they would function 
    as both regional security coordinators and regional transmission 
    providers.
        Second, congestion management is best performed at a regional 
    level. This is shown in the largely unsuccessful efforts of 
    Commonwealth Edison to create congestion markets that would allow 
    transmission customers to ``buy-through'' (i.e., firm up) transmission 
    rights on congested flow gates. After six months of its one year 
    experiment, we note that Commonwealth concluded that it is ``difficult 
    for one transmission owner to identify and implement redispatch'' when 
    the physical limitations and cost effective options for relief exist on 
    other transmission systems that are beyond their reach.80
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \80\ Commonwealth Edison, Interim Report on Non-Firm Redispatch, 
    Docket No. ER98-2279, December 17, 1998, at 4, 10.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Third, RTOs will be able to establish and define rights to the use 
    of the grid. At present, with multiple and independent operators of the 
    grid, individual users and owners have unclear and conflicting rights 
    to the grid. This makes it difficult to establish congestion markets. A 
    congestion market, like any other market, cannot develop in the absence 
    of clear rights.\81\ Such rights, whether held by transmission users or 
    owners, are a necessary prerequisite for establishing congestion 
    markets. Without establishing such rights, the industry will continue 
    to grapple with the problem of incomplete markets. Thus, it is 
    difficult to achieve efficient and competitive regional bulk power 
    markets if congestion on the transmission grid is not accurately 
    priced.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \81\ Robert Cooter and Thomas Ulen, Law and Economics, Scott, 
    Foresman and Company, 1988, at 91 (``From a legal viewpoint, 
    property is a bundle of rights'').
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    d. Planning and Expanding Transmission Facilities
        Transmission planning and expansion are more difficult today than 
    three years ago. While uncertainty has always been a fact of life for 
    any transmission planning exercise, the level of uncertainty has 
    increased with the increasing number and distance of unbundled 
    transactions and the wider variation in generation dispatch patterns. 
    Uncertainty has also increased because:
    
        Generation developers are reluctant to disclose their plans for 
    future capacity additions. Similarly, utilities intending to 
    purchase from others are reluctant to speculate on whom or where 
    their suppliers might be, making modeling of such transactions for 
    transmission analysis virtually impossible.\82\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \82\ NERC, ``Reliability Assessment, 1998-2007,'' September 
    1998, at 39.
    
    One troubling consequence of this uncertainty has been a noticeable 
    decline in planned transmission investments. NERC recently reported 
    that the level of planned transmission
    
    [[Page 31401]]
    
    additions is significantly lower than five years ago despite an overall 
    increase in load growth and unbundled transmission service.\83\ While 
    this could simply reflect better utilization of the existing grid, the 
    Commission is concerned that it may also reflect an incompatibility of 
    existing planning institutions with the new market realities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \83\ Id. at 7.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We are also concerned that the existing approach to transmission 
    pricing may not sufficiently encourage the investments in transmission 
    facilities that are needed to improve the reliability and efficiency of 
    the grid. Inadequate investment could be a major impediment to the 
    development of regional bulk power markets and a possible source of 
    future reliability problems. There are at least three concerns about 
    the way transmission prices are set.
        First, although there are varying degrees of investment 
    coordination around the country, utilities ultimately make transmission 
    investment decisions individually rather than through joint decisions 
    that internalize commercial and reliability effects of the investment. 
    It may be unclear which utility should have the responsibility for 
    expanding capacity to relieve a transmission constraint. For example, 
    power flows scheduled by one utility with ample transmission capacity 
    on its own lines may overload a neighbor's lines. The first utility may 
    be unwilling to expand transmission capacity because it needs no extra 
    transmission capacity itself, and the second utility may be unwilling 
    to expand transmission capacity because it collects no revenues from 
    the power flows scheduled by others. In a multi-utility region, 
    decisions about where to site new facilities and who should pay for 
    capacity expansions can be even more complex unless a regional body 
    provides a forum for discussions and a method for resolving disputes.
        Second, the motivation for constructing new facilities is changing 
    as the industry changes. Formerly, a utility built transmission 
    primarily to deliver power from its generating plants to its customers. 
    Inadequate transmission would have hurt power sales, the principal 
    source of utility revenue. Today, facility expansion may be needed to 
    transmit power sold by others. As generation and transmission ownership 
    become increasingly separate and as many states implement or even 
    merely consider retail access, the transmission owner's traditional 
    incentive for making new transmission investment to support its power 
    sales erodes. Incentives for transmission investment need to be related 
    more to the power needs of the region than the generation stock of the 
    transmission owners.
        Third, the transmission owner that does invest in transmission to 
    overcome a constraint may be concerned about recovering its investment. 
    Under traditional ratemaking practices, it must recover its investment 
    over a long period of time, typically thirty years. But subsequent 
    generation construction on the power-poor side of the constraint may 
    obviate the need for the line and threaten recovery of its capital 
    cost. In addition, where there is higher risk, a higher return 
    commensurate with the higher risk may be appropriate. To support this, 
    customers and regulators would want assurance that the decision to 
    invest in transmission is made in the best interests of the region, 
    considering not only all the transmission options but also the 
    generation and demand management alternatives to transmission 
    construction. Therefore, as discussed below, we will consider concrete 
    proposals from regional transmission organizations for transmission 
    pricing reforms and the explicit use of pricing incentives to encourage 
    RTOs to make efficient investments in new transmission facilities.
    e. Pancaked Transmission Rates
        With the exception of power pools, open access under Order No. 888 
    focuses on individual, existing transmission providers. Order No. 888 
    does not require transmission pricing reforms that are needed to 
    support efficient and competitive bulk power markets. The ``missing'' 
    reforms include, among others, the elimination of pancaked transmission 
    access charges, the use of reservation-based (as opposed to load-based) 
    transmission tariffs and the availability of secondary markets in 
    transmission rights.84 In this section, we will focus on the 
    problems created by the widespread pancaking of transmission access 
    charges.85
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \84\ See, e.g., Capacity Reservation Open Access Transmission 
    Tariffs, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 
    32,519 (1996) and Inquiry Concerning the Commission's Pricing Policy 
    for Transmission Services Provided by Public Utilities Under the 
    Federal Power Act: Policy Statement, 69 FERC para. 61,086 (1994).
        \85\ We did, however, require non-pancaked rates for power pools 
    that offer non-pancaked rates to their own members in Order No. 888. 
    Order No. 888, FERC Stats, and Regs. at 31,727-28.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In most of the United States, a transmission customer pays 
    separate, additive access charges every time its contract path crosses 
    the boundary of a transmission owner. By raising the cost of 
    transmission, pancaking reduces the size of geographic power markets. 
    This, in turn, can result in concentrated electricity markets. 
    Balkanization of electricity markets hurts electricity consumers, in 
    general, by forcing them to pay higher prices than they would in a 
    larger, more competitive, bulk power market.86
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \86\ While it is difficult to estimate the exact impact on 
    consumers, we note that there have been studies of the deregulated 
    British power markets that have found excessive concentration in 
    generation has produced prices 20 to 40 percent above competitive 
    levels at certain times. Richard Green and David Newbery, 
    Competition in the British Electricity Spot Market, 100 J. Pol. 
    Econ., 929, 1992.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission has heard from many states about the negative 
    effects of pancaked rates in their efforts to introduce retail 
    competition. At this time, about 21 states have introduced or are 
    planning to introduce competition for retail loads under their 
    jurisdiction.87 Because the Commission has jurisdiction over 
    transmission service and rates for unbundled retail customers, we have 
    an obligation to address these concerns.88 A retail choice 
    initiative, no matter how well designed at the state level, may fail if 
    the pool of potential competitors is effectively limited to a few 
    nearby supply sources because of pancaked transmission charges.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \87\ ``Status of Electric Utility Deregulation as of May 1, 
    1999,'' Energy Information Administration.
        \88\ Order No. 888, FERC Stats. and Regs. at 31,651-52.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        This concern of pancaked rates was highlighted to us in the recent 
    consultations with our state commission colleagues. Several state 
    commissioners emphasized that the success of their retail competition 
    initiatives is related to the adoption of non-pancaked transmission 
    tariffs and other ISO policies.89 We believe that the 
    likelihood of success for existing and planned retail choice 
    initiatives is significantly enhanced if the Commission can ensure fair 
    and efficient access to a regional market without pancaked transmission 
    access charges, and that we need to take steps beyond Order No. 888 to 
    accomplish this.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \89\ See, e.g., Comments of Gerald Thorpe (Maryland) and 
    President Herbert Tate (New Jersey), RTO Conference (Washington, 
    DC), transcript at 37-39; 49-51.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    f. Conclusion
        We believe that the preferred solution to the engineering and 
    economic problems discussed in this section is a regional solution. 
    Notwithstanding it success, Order No. 888 has not been able to produce 
    a fully efficient and competitive outcome because it does not address 
    ATC calculations, congestion
    
    [[Page 31402]]
    
    management, reliability, pancaking of transmission access charges, and 
    grid planning and expansion. These are regional problems. Therefore, we 
    are proposing a rule to encourage the development of independent 
    regional transmission operators that can promote both electric system 
    reliability and competitive generation markets.
    2. Actual and Perceived Discriminatory Conduct by Transmission Owners 
    to Favor Their Own or Affiliated Merchant Operations
        In addition to operational inefficiencies impeding full 
    competition, there also exist questions about residual discrimination 
    in the provision of transmission services by public utilities. As 
    discussed below, many in the industry have expressed a fundamental 
    mistrust of transmission owners. In addition, there are allegations, 
    and in some circumstances findings, of actual discrimination by 
    transmission owners. We discuss below indications of discriminatory 
    conduct by vertically integrated utilities and seek further comment on 
    utility practices subsequent to Order No. 888.
        Utilities that control monopoly transmission facilities and also 
    have power marketing interests 90 have poor incentives to 
    provide equal quality transmission service to their power marketing 
    competitors. It is, in fact, in the economic self-interest of 
    transmission-owning utilities to favor their own power marketing 
    interests and frustrate their competitors. As the Commission stated in 
    Order No. 888:
    
        \90\ The term power marketing interests is used as shorthand 
    herein to include the utility's own wholesale merchant function as 
    well as any affiliates with wholesale merchant functions.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        It is in the economic self-interest of transmission monopolists, 
    particularly those with high-cost generation assets, to deny 
    transmission or to offer transmission on a basis that is inferior to 
    that which they provide themselves. The inherent characteristics of 
    monopolists make it inevitable that they will act in their own self-
    interest to the detriment of others by refusing transmission and/or 
    providing inferior transmission to competitors in the bulk power 
    markets to favor their own generation, and it is our duty to 
    eradicate unduly discriminatory practices.\91\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \91\ Order No. 888, FERC Stats. and Regs. at 31,682.
    
    The exercise of transmission market power allows transmission providers 
    with power marketing interests to benefit in the short-run by making 
    more power sales at higher prices, and benefit in the long-run by 
    deterring entry by other market participants. As a result, prices to 
    the Nation's electricity consumers will be higher than need be.
        It was to eliminate this inherent tendency of a vertically-
    integrated utility to favor its own power sales that Order Nos. 888 and 
    889 required utilities to functionally unbundle their transmission and 
    power merchant services. Generally, functional unbundling requires a 
    public utility to: separate its transmission system functions and staff 
    from wholesale generation marketing functions and staff; abide by a 
    standard of conduct to define impermissible contact between generation 
    and transmission personnel; take transmission services under the same 
    open access tariff of general applicability as do others; state 
    separate rates for wholesale generation, transmission, and ancillary 
    services; and rely on the same Open Access Same-Time Information System 
    (OASIS) that its transmission customers rely on to obtain information 
    about its transmission system when buying or selling 
    power.92 The Commission imposed these requirements to 
    establish a foundation for open grid access and competitive electricity 
    markets.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \92\ Id. at 31,654-55.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Functional unbundling did not change the incentives of vertically-
    integrated utilities to use their transmission assets to favor their 
    own generation, but instead attempted to reduce the ability of 
    utilities to act on those incentives. In Order No. 888, the Commission 
    received and considered numerous comments that functional unbundling 
    was unlikely to work, and that more drastic restructuring, such as 
    corporate unbundling, was needed.\93\ However, the Commission decided 
    at the time to adopt what it considered to be the less intrusive and 
    less costly remedy.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \93\ Id. at 31,653-54.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Clearly, Order No. 888 has resulted in wholesale power markets 
    becoming more competitive, more transmission services being made 
    available to more potential users than ever before, and generally lower 
    transaction costs.
        However, market participants increasingly have alleged that 
    numerous transmission service problems related to discriminatory 
    conduct remain, and that these problems are impeding competitive 
    wholesale power markets.\94\ Our information about alleged continued 
    discriminatory practices comes from several sources. These include 
    formal complaints filed with the Commission, informal complaints made 
    to the Commission's enforcement hotline, oral and written comments made 
    in conjunction with public conferences held by the Commission, and 
    pleadings filed with the Commission in various dockets.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \94\ See, e.g.,  of Roger Fontes on behalf of the Northern 
    California Power Agency, Regional ISO Conference (Phoenix), 
    Transcript at 136 (``In general, orders 888 and 889 have not fully 
    remedied undue discrimination in providing transmission service in 
    this country.'')
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Compared to the situation before Order No. 888, transmission-owning 
    utilities must now resort to more subtle means to frustrate their 
    marketing competitors and favor their own marketing interests. 
    Continued discrimination may be conscious and deliberate, but it may 
    also result from the failure to make sufficient efforts to change the 
    way integrated utilities have done business for many years. In either 
    case, the tendency of transmission owners to confer advantages, however 
    subtle, upon their own marketing interests is discriminatory as against 
    other marketers.
        In the sections that follow, we will outline the information 
    derived from filings and other sources about remaining impediments to 
    competition caused by continued discriminatory conduct by transmission 
    owners. We note, and we are well aware, that many allegations that have 
    been made in various forums are unproved, and perceived discrimination 
    may in fact turn out to have justifiable explanations. It is often hard 
    to determine, on an after-the-fact basis, whether an action was 
    motivated by an intent to favor affiliates or simply resulted from the 
    need to serve native load customers or the impartial application of 
    operating or technical requirements. Given our considerable difficulty 
    in determining whether there has been compliance with our regulations, 
    the question arises whether functional unbundling is an appropriate 
    long-term regulatory solution.
        We consider allegations of discrimination, even if not reduced to 
    formal findings, to be a serious concern for two reasons. First, we may 
    be seeing only the ``tip of the iceberg.'' We are aware that instances 
    of actual discriminatory conduct may be undetectable in a non-
    transparent market. In addition, there are significant disincentives to 
    filing and pursuing formal complaints that would result in definitive 
    findings. Transmission customers often tell the Commission's 
    enforcement staff that they are reluctant to make even informal 
    complaints because of concerns that the Commission will not take strong 
    action, and fear, perhaps most importantly, of retribution by their 
    transmission supplier.95 We also have been told that
    
    [[Page 31403]]
    
    the complaint process is costly and time-consuming,96 and 
    that the Commission's remedies for transmission violations do not 
    impose sufficient financial harms on the transmission provider to act 
    as a significant deterrent.97
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \95\ See Comments of Dan Jones on behalf of the Public Utilities 
    Commission of Texas, Regional ISO Conference (Kansas City), 
    Transcript at 1985 (``And we've also heard that these entities are 
    hesitant to bring those complaints forward because they have to deal 
    with both sides of that utility'').
        \96\ We note that we have recently issued a Final Rule regarding 
    complaint procedures designed to make them more efficient. See 
    Complaint Procedures, Final Rule, Docket No. RM98-13-000, 86 FERC 
    para. 61,324 (issued March 31, 1999).
        \97\ Comments of National Energy Marketers Association, Docket 
    No. RM98-5-000 (filed January 22, 1999).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Perhaps the most problematic aspect of relying on after-the-fact 
    enforcement in the fast-paced business of power marketing, however, is 
    that there may be no adequate remedy for lost short-term sale 
    opportunities. For example, the Electric Power Supply Association has 
    told us:
    
        Furthermore, even if the exercise of such discrimination could 
    be adequately documented and packaged in the form of a complaint 
    under Section 206 of the Federal Power Act under a more streamlined 
    complaint process contemplated by the Commission, it would still be 
    extremely costly and inefficient to deal with such complaints on a 
    case-by-case basis. More than likely, the potential power 
    transactions for which transmission principally was sought would 
    disappear by the time a Commission ruling was obtained.98
    
        \98\ Motion to Intervene and Comments of Electric Power Supply 
    Association in Support of Petition for Rulemaking, Docket No. RM98-
    5-000 (filed Sept. 21, 1998), at 3.
    
    Accordingly, actual problems with functional unbundling may be more 
    pervasive than formally adjudicated complaints would suggest, and the 
    informal allegations we hear provide valuable insight.
        Second, we consider the allegations of discrimination to be serious 
    because, if nothing else, they represent a perception by market 
    participants that the market is not working fairly because such 
    participants know that integrated utilities have the incentive and 
    opportunity to discriminate. Mistrust in the market can itself be a 
    serious impediment to competition. If market participants perceive that 
    other participants have an unfair advantage through the affiliation 
    with the transmission provider, it can inhibit their willingness to 
    participate in the market, including, for example, building new 
    generating units, thus thwarting the development of robust competition. 
    Such mistrust can also harm reliability. As stated by NERC, there is a 
    reluctance on the part of market participants to share operational 
    real-time and planning data with transmission providers because of the 
    suspicion that they could be providing an advantage to their affiliated 
    marketing groups.99
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \99\ NERC Reliability Assessment 1998-2007, at 39.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The functional unbundling policy underlying Order No. 888 was an 
    attempt to regulate the behavior of transmission owners. There are 
    growing indications, however, that the conflicting incentives that 
    vertically integrated utilities have regarding transmission access may 
    be too difficult to police. Many have asserted that it is not realistic 
    even to expect functional unbundling to eliminate attempts by 
    transmission owners to gain economic advantage. Companies have an 
    obligation to maximize value for shareholders, and it should be no 
    surprise that they will be aggressive in doing so. For example, in 
    comments to the Commission in the Order No. 888 proceeding, the Federal 
    Trade Commission advised the Commission that a functional unbundling 
    approach ``* * * would leave in place the incentive and opportunity for 
    some utilities to exercise market power in the regulated system. 
    Preventing them from doing so by enforcing regulations to control their 
    behavior may prove difficult.'' A representative of Lafayette Utilities 
    told us at the New Orleans ISO Conference:
    
        Notwithstanding functional separation and the requirement not to 
    discriminate, transmission personnel are well aware of the interests 
    of their company's generation function, and can find a way to give 
    preferential treatment. * * * 100
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \100\ Comments of Frank Ledoux on behalf of Lafayette Utilities 
    System, Regional ISO Conference (New Orleans), Transcript at 180.
    
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
        A representative of a Wisconsin public utility told us:
    
        Administration of the tariff entails a myriad of decisions that 
    require discretion, as well as ``technical'' judgments (like 
    [available transmission capability] and [capacity benefit margin]) 
    that have significant competitive ramifications. It is inevitable 
    that these decisions and judgments will be made with competitive 
    concerns in mind. Functional separation does not solve this 
    problem.101
    
        \101\ Statement of Roy Thilly on behalf of Wisconsin Public 
    Power, Inc. at 2, Docket No. PL98-5-000 (filed April 15, 1998).
    
    Similarly, at our regional ISO conference in Indianapolis, we were 
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    told:
    
        In a capital intensive industry where a high percentage of the 
    investment is in generation assets, it is inconceivable that a 
    utility, which in some cases has very high generation cost, would 
    somehow manage its transmission system so as not to give its 
    generation a competitive advantage. I think this is self-
    evident.102
    
        \102\ Comments of Kenneth Hegemann on behalf of American 
    Municipal Power, Ohio, Regional ISO Conference (Indianapolis), 
    Transcript at 174.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    While it should not be assumed that such problems exist in every 
    circumstance, clearly many market participants do not believe the 
    market can yet be trusted with respect to their commercial interests, 
    at least in some areas. We now turn to some of the areas that have 
    produced the most complaints about continuing discrimination.
    a. Calculation and Posting of Available Transmission Capability in a 
    Manner Favorable to the Transmission Provider
        Perhaps the most significant complaint with respect to alleged 
    discriminatory conduct under functional unbundling concerns the 
    important function of calculating and posting the amount of 
    transmission capability that is available on a transmission provider's 
    system. The transmission provider is required to calculate and post on 
    its OASIS the TTC and ATC for each posted transmission 
    path.103 ATC is the capacity that is stated to be available 
    for transmission service requests. As we discussed above in Section 
    III.A.1, it is not possible to calculate accurately the transmission 
    capability of one system without knowing the flows scheduled by all 
    other interconnected transmission providers in the region. Given this 
    technical problem, it may be impossible to distinguish an inaccurate 
    ATC presented in good faith from an inaccurate ATC presented for the 
    purpose of favoring the transmission provider's marketing interests.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \103\ See 18 CFR 37.6(b) (1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Transmission providers with power marketing interests have 
    incentives to understate ATC on those paths valuable to its marketing 
    competitors, or to divert transmission capacity so that it is available 
    for use by its own marketing interests. If there is insufficient ATC, 
    competitors may be forced to forego power sale transactions or use a 
    less desirable alternative path if one is available.
        The Commission has found violations of ATC postings in three cases. 
    In Washington Water Power Company,104 the transmission 
    owning utility showed that it had no firm ATC, which would have 
    discouraged any potential marketers who needed firm transmission 
    service to make a sale. However, the utility then offered its power 
    marketing affiliate, Avista
    
    [[Page 31404]]
    
    Energy, an ``interruptible firm'' transmission service that was not 
    available to competitors. As the Commission explained in finding a 
    violation of Order No. 888:
    
        \104\ 83 FERC para. 61,097 (1998), further order, 83 FERC para. 
    61,282 (1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Avista received a preference from Washington Water Power that 
    was not available to any of its competitors. Simply stated, Avista's 
    customer was deprived of the benefit of choosing among all potential 
    power suppliers.
    
        The case of Wisconsin Public Power Inc. SYSTEM v. Wisconsin Public 
    Service Corporation, et al. (Wisconsin Public) 105 
    demonstrates both the difficulties and suspicions of discrimination 
    resulting from when a transmission customer requests transmission 
    service from an integrated utility. WPPI was seeking additional network 
    transmission service from both Wisconsin Public Service Corporation 
    (WPSC) and Wisconsin Power & Light Company (WP&L). In both cases, the 
    requests were denied because of claims that the transmission owners 
    were using all available capacity. In the case of WPSC, the Commission 
    initially found that the utility had not properly reserved capacity for 
    its merchant function and directed that it recompute its ATC without 
    that reservation. After WPSC submitted additional documentation, the 
    Commission accepted some of WPSC's merchant priority, but still found 
    that it had violated its obligations under its tariff, and that its 
    actions raised serious concerns about the functional separation of its 
    staff. With respect to WP&L, the Commission found that it provided 
    unduly preferential treatment to its merchant function, had been 
    changing its ATC without posting those changes on OASIS, and had been 
    computing ATC where none exists.106
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \105\ 83 FERC para. 61,198 (1998), order on reh'g, 84 FERC para. 
    61,120 (1998).
        \106\ 83 FERC at 61,860.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Wisconsin Public cases demonstrate, if nothing else, the 
    difficulty of achieving, and enforcing, functional separation of a 
    utility's transmission and merchant functions. These types of cases 
    require substantial Commission investigative and adjudicative 
    resources, not to mention the resources of the parties involved. The 
    Commission recognized in Wisconsin Public how RTOs could help eliminate 
    these problems. The Commission stated:
    
        As we recently explained in Louisville Gas & Electric Company, 
    et al., 82 FERC para. 61,308 at 62,222 & n. 39 (1998), a properly 
    structured ISO, or other transmission entity can eliminate the 
    potential for the strategic use of a transmission owner's priority 
    to use internal system capacity for native load. The ISO or other 
    transmission entity can also eliminate the incentive to engage in 
    strategic curtailments of generation that a transmission operator's 
    generation service competitors own and can remove any incentive to 
    game OASIS operations. This will promote generation entry and 
    competition, since a properly structured ISO or other transmission 
    entity would have no economic stake in favoring certain market 
    participants over others and potential entrants would likely see the 
    transmission market as fair. An ISO, therefore, could help to solve 
    the problems established in the instant complaints.107
    
        \107\ Id. at 61,859.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The case of Morgan Stanley Capital Group v. Illinois Power Company 
    108 also demonstrated problems associated with ATC and a 
    transmission provider's use of its system for its own purposes. Morgan 
    Stanley complained that Illinois Power failed to accurately post ATC, 
    failed to award transmission capacity in a non-discriminatory manner, 
    and allocated transmission in favor of its own bulk power marketing 
    arm. Illinois Power admitted the ATC posting error, and the Commission 
    found other violations of its tariff in responding to Morgan Stanley's 
    request for service. Although the Commission initially also found that 
    Illinois Power did not designate its own network resources in the same 
    manner as network customers are required to designate them, Illinois 
    Power disputed this, and after showing that its network resource was 
    legitimate, the Commission dismissed its rehearing as moot. 
    Nevertheless, this case demonstrates that a combination of ATC errors 
    and unclear procedures feeds the mistrust in the marketplace with 
    respect to a transmission owner's ability to use its system to favor 
    itself.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \108\ 83 FERC para. 61,204, order granting clarification and 
    dismissing reh'g, 83 FERC para. 61,299 (1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We also have currently pending before us several formal complaints 
    alleging that a transmission provider is improperly keeping its 
    transmission capability for its merchant function. In one case, a power 
    marketer asserts that a transmission provider has refused service over 
    an interconnection on the basis that the transmission provider needs 
    all the ATC for native load. The marketer has alleged that the 
    transmission provider's claims of reliability concerns are a mask to 
    block competitors from importing power into the transmission provider's 
    system when the transmission provider has higher cost generation 
    available.109 In another recent formal complaint filing, it 
    is alleged that a transmission provider denied transmission service and 
    then improperly provided it to its merchant group.110
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \109\ Aquila Power Corporation v. Entergy Services, Inc., Docket 
    No. EL98-36-000, Amended and Restated Complaint at 6 (filed June 23, 
    1998).
        \110\ Arizona Public Service Company v. Idaho Power Company, 
    Docket No. EL99-44-000 (filed March 3, 1999).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Aside from these cases involving formal complaints, there have been 
    a number of other complaints with respect to ATC calculation. For 
    example, our enforcement staff receives hotline complaints concerning 
    ATC posting problems. The enforcement staff has confirmed a number of 
    such ATC errors. In most cases, these errors were corrected within 
    several months of having them pointed out, and the utilities often 
    offered explanations based on hardware or software problems. We make no 
    judgment whether such identified errors were an intentional attempt to 
    thwart competition; however, they had the potential to have that 
    effect.
        In July 1997, the Commission held a technical conference concerning 
    how well the OASIS system was working. Several commenters suggested 
    that erroneous ATC calculation and posting was hurting competition. A 
    representative from Electric Clearinghouse told us that there is a 
    pervasive problem of incorrect or stale information on the OASIS sites, 
    and that ``competition is blocked when this occurs.'' That same 
    representative stated that very little firm ATC is offered due to the 
    utility's caution or strategy, and that some providers will not offer 
    firm ATC because they do not want to curtail their own 
    transactions.111 At the same conference, a representative 
    from the American Public Power Association told us:
    
        \111\  Open Access Same Time Information Technical Conference, 
    Docket No. RM95-9-003 (July 18, 1997), transcript at 23.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        ATC is often understated and inconsistently posted on adjacent 
    OASIS nodes. Inter-regional coordination is lacking. This fact 
    limits the usefulness of the system for commercial 
    purposes.112
    
        \112\ Id. at 28.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In March 1998, a group referring to themselves as power industry 
    stakeholders 113 filed a petition for rulemaking on electric 
    power industry structure.114 Although we are not addressing 
    here the specific relief they are requesting in that Petition, the
    
    [[Page 31405]]
    
    Petition does contain a number of fairly specific allegations 
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    indicating problems in the market. For example, the Petition asserts:
    
        \113\ The group consists of a number of power marketers and 
    users, including, for example, Coalition for a Competitive Electric 
    Market, ELCON, Electric Clearinghouse, Inc., and Enron Power 
    Marketing, Inc.
        \114\ Petition for a Rulemaking on Electric Power Industry 
    Structure and Commercial Practices and Motion to Clarify or 
    Reconsider Certain Open-Access Commercial Practices, Docket No. 
    RM98-5-000.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Concepts such as ATC and the OASIS have become vehicles for 
    obstructing and curtailing, rather than accommodating, transactions. 
    Incumbents are able to deny new entrants access to critical, 
    accurate information across control areas. This can take the form of 
    out-of-date or incorrect postings of ATC or, in some instances, 
    intentional withholding of actual ATC. Regardless of the cause, more 
    transmission capability is physically available than is being 
    released for sale.115
    
        \115\ Petition at 7-8.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Petition alleges the existence of ``ATC exclusions, 
    inaccuracies and misuses that deny new entrants the ability to evaluate 
    market opportunities, and therefore, prevent reasonable access to the 
    grid.'' 116 The Petition cited specific instances of 
    inconsistent ATC calculations for the same interconnection by the 
    systems on either side; an OASIS showing ATC that was not in fact made 
    available for scheduling; and an OASIS showing no ATC but the utility 
    then using that path for a sale.117
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \116\ Id. at 15.
        \117\ Id. at Appendix D.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        EPSA, the trade association representing certain power suppliers, 
    filed comments in support of the Petition and echoed many of the same 
    experiences:
    
        EPSA agrees that this discriminatory conduct persists 
    principally because of the continuing incentives and opportunity for 
    transmission owning public utilities covertly to discriminate 
    against other transmission customers, by, for example, minimizing 
    reported available transmission capability (ATC), delaying or 
    inaccurately posting ATC on the OASIS, or otherwise manipulating 
    market operations.118
    
        \118\ EPSA Comments, Docket No. RM98-5-000, at 2 (filed 
    September 21, 1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        EPSA further stated that, ``The manipulation of ATC--whether with 
    the intent to deceive or as the result of poor OASIS management--is a 
    serious entrance barrier for competitive power suppliers.'' 
    119
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \119\ Id. at 8.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        At our regional ISO conference in New Orleans, we were told by a 
    representative from the Public Service Commission of Yazoo City, 
    Mississippi, of a specific instance of what it considered to be 
    discriminatory treatment:
    
        Yazoo City, as a participant, has experienced first hand an 
    individual [transmission] owner's continued ability to use its 
    ownership and control [of] transmission to disadvantage competitors, 
    notwithstanding Order 888's mandate of non-discriminatory 
    transmission access.
    
        The representative then went on to describe an instance where a 
    marketer could not complete a 10 MW power sale because of transmission 
    restrictions, but then the transmission provider offered to supply the 
    capacity itself.120 The representative concluded that Orders 
    Nos. 888 and 889 have not fully eliminated undue discrimination and 
    this will not be achieved ``as long as transmission owners are allowed 
    to fence in transmission-dependent utilities and others located on 
    their transmission system to enhance the value of their generation 
    assets at increased cost to competitors.''
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \120\ Comments of Rebert D. Priest on behalf of the Public 
    Service Commission of Yazoo City, Regional ISO Conference (New 
    Orleans), Transcript at 201-03. After hearing this assertion, 
    Entergy Services, Inc. filed a letter in which it stated that it was 
    unable to identify any Entergy-imposed restrictions that would have 
    prevented the power purchase. See Letter in Docket No. PL98-5-000 
    (filed July 1, 1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        One specific area where there have been allegations that 
    transmission owners are using ATC to favor their own merchant 
    operations concerns the calculation and use of Capacity Benefit Margin 
    (CBM). Although there is no single accepted definition, CBM is 
    generally used to mean an amount of transmission transfer capability 
    reserved by load serving entities to ensure access to generation from 
    interconnected systems to meet their generation reliability 
    requirements.121 Some utilities subtract CBM from their 
    total transmission capability to arrive at ATC. There is no uniform 
    method for calculating CBM. The ability to withhold CBM to ensure 
    reliability not only confers a reliability advantage for the 
    transmission provider, but may give the transmission provider the 
    opportunity to selectively withhold ATC over paths and interconnections 
    useful to its generation competitors.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \121\ NERC, Available Transfer Capability Definitions and 
    Determinations (June 1996), at 14.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The use of CBM is an issue that is currently being considered in 
    several cases pending before the Commission.122 For example, 
    with respect to the formation of the PJM ISO, the Commission noted that 
    it was not demonstrated that the PJM Pool's historical practice of 
    withholding firm transmission interface capacity as a substitute for 
    installed generating reserves is consistent with our open access 
    policies. The Commission observed that the load serving entities that 
    own generating capacity within the PJM control area appeared to benefit 
    from this practice as suppliers in addition to benefitting as load 
    serving entities.123 The Commission set the issue for 
    further briefing and it remains pending. In another pending proceeding 
    concerning WPSC's CBM calculation, two of the parties assert that CBM 
    ``removes firm transmission capacity from open access offerings, 
    thereby raising an unnecessary and unjustifiable barrier to 
    competition,'' and ``fosters discrimination by giving merchant 
    functions gatekeeping control over CBM-related transmission access and 
    by giving individual interface transmission owners broad discretion 
    over where and how much CBM is withdrawn from ATC.'' 124 In 
    the same proceeding, Electric Clearinghouse, Inc. asserts that ``the 
    CBM set-aside embodies undue discrimination in access to the monopoly 
    owned transmission wires because it ensures certain users a priority 
    over the reserved transmission interface capacity to the exclusion of 
    other firm transmission users.'' 125
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \122\ The Commission recently noticed a technical conference, to 
    be held May 20 and 21, 1999, on the issue of CBM. See Capacity 
    Benefit Margin in Computing Available Transmission Capacity, Notice 
    of Technical Conference, Docket No. EL99-46-000.
        \123\ PJM, 81 FERC at 62,277.
        \124\ Protest of Madison Gas & Electric Company and Wisconsin 
    Public Power Inc., Docket No. EL98-2-003 at 3 (filed August 21, 
    1998).
        \125\ Protest of Electric Clearinghouse, Inc., Docket No. EL98-
    2-003, at 3 (filed Ausust 21, 1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As we stated above, we fully recognize that these are assertions 
    made in pending cases in which we have not yet made findings. They are 
    referenced here as illustrative of the suspicions in the industry of 
    continuing opportunities for discriminatory treatment that may 
    disadvantage certain competitors where generation owners continue to 
    operate transmission.
    b. Standards of Conduct Violations
        To ensure the functional separation of a transmission provider's 
    transmission and merchant functions, the Commission adopted standards 
    of conduct that prohibit the transmission provider's marketing interest 
    employees from having any more access to transmission system 
    information than is available on OASIS, and requires the transmission 
    provider's transmission employees to provide impartial service to all 
    transmission customers.126 If a transmission provider's 
    marketing interests have favorable access to transmission system 
    information or receive more favorable treatment of their transmission 
    requests, this obviously creates a disadvantage for marketing 
    competitors.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \126\ See 18 CFR Part 37 (1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In spite of the standards of conduct, there continues to be a 
    perception by
    
    [[Page 31406]]
    
    many market participants that the transmission provider's marketing and 
    transmission interests are not fully functionally separated. In cases 
    in which the Commission has issued formal orders, we have found serious 
    concerns with functional separation and improper information sharing 
    with respect to at least four public utilities.127 In 
    addition, our enforcement staff receives numerous telephone calls about 
    standards of conduct issues; some of these are simply questions about 
    what is permissible conduct, but others are complaints of a violation. 
    In a number of cases, our staff has verified non-compliance with the 
    standards of conduct.128
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \127\ See Wisconsin Public, 83 FERC at 61,855, 61,860 (WPSC's 
    actions raised ``serious concerns'' as to functional separation; 
    WP&L's actions demonstrated that it provided unduly preferential 
    treatment to its merchant function); Washington Water Power, 83 FERC 
    at 61,463 (utility found to have violated standards in connection 
    with its marketing affiliate); Utah Associated Municipal Power 
    Systems v. PacifiCorp, 87 FERC para. 61,044 (1999) (finding that 
    PacifiCorp had failed to maintain functional separation between 
    merchant and transmission functions).
        \128\ See, e.g., Communications of Market Information Between 
    Affiliates, Docket No. IN99-2-000, 87 FERC para. 61,012 (1999) 
    (Commission issued declaratory order based on hotline complaint 
    clarifying that it is an undue preference in violation of section 
    205 for a public utility to tell an affiliate to look for a 
    marketing offer prior to posting the offer publicly).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The petitioners for rulemaking in Docket No. RM98-5-000 allege that 
    there are common instances of ``unauthorized exchanges of competitively 
    valuable information on reservations and schedules between transmission 
    system operators and their own or affiliated merchant operation 
    employees.'' 129 They also cite OASIS data showing an 
    instance where a transmission provider quickly confirmed requests for 
    firm transmission service by an affiliate, while service requests from 
    independent marketers took much longer to approve.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \129\ Petition at 15.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We believe that some of the identified standards of conduct 
    violations are transitional issues resulting from a new way of doing 
    business, and we acknowledge that many utilities are making good-faith 
    efforts to properly implement standards of conduct. However, we also 
    believe that there is great potential for standards of conduct 
    violations that will never even be reported or detected. The use of 
    standards of conduct is not the optimal procedure for ensuring a fair 
    marketplace, and may be unnecessary in a properly structured and 
    operated market.
        We are increasingly concerned about the extensive regulatory 
    oversight and administrative burdens that have resulted from policing 
    compliance with standards of conduct. We have discussed above some of 
    the cases in which the Commission had to address potential violations 
    of the standards of conduct. In addition, transmission providers were 
    required to file their standards of conduct for Commission review. In 
    response, the Commission initially issued 8 orders concerning 126 
    public utilities' standards of conduct.130 Generally, these 
    orders required the utilities to revise their standards of conduct and 
    post, on the OASIS, organizational charts and job descriptions for 
    transmission/reliability and wholesale merchant function employees. The 
    Commission subsequently issued 13 more orders requiring the public 
    utilities to further revise their standards of conduct and/or 
    organizational charts and job descriptions.131 The 
    Commission has also issued three orders on rehearing of the standards 
    of conduct orders.132
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \130\ The citations for these orders are: 81 FERC para. 61,332 
    (1997), 81 FERC para. 61,338 (1997), 81 FERC para. 61,339 (1997), 82 
    FERC para. 61,028 (1998), 82 FERC para. 61,073 (1998), 82 FERC para. 
    61,132 (1998), 82 FERC para. 61,193 (1998) and 82 FERC para. 61,246 
    (1998).
        \131\ The citations for these orders are: 84 FERC para. 61,131 
    (1998), 84 FERC para. 61,255 (1998), 84 FERC para. 61,320 (1998), 84 
    FERC para. 61,327 (1998), 85 FERC para. 61,068 (1998), 85 FERC para. 
    61,145 (1998), 85 FERC para. 61,227 (1998), 85 FERC para. 61,390 
    (1998), 86 FERC para. 61,044 (1999), 86 FERC para. 61,079 (1999), 86 
    FERC para. 61,146 (1999), 86 FERC para. 61,185 (1999) and 86 FERC 
    para. 61,246
        \132\ The citations for these orders are: 82 FERC para. 61,131 
    (1998), 83 FERC para. 61,357 (1998), and 85 FERC para. 61,382 
    (1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As of April 1, 1999, 51 utilities' standards of conduct and 
    organizational charts and job descriptions have been accepted and 75 
    utilities' standards of conduct and/or organizational charts and job 
    descriptions have not been accepted and are pending review. This is an 
    indication of the significant regulatory effort required by both public 
    utilities and the Commission to make the standards of conduct approach 
    workable--a regulatory effort that could be greatly reduced through 
    more distinct organizational separation.
    c. Line Loading Relief and Congestion Management
        A number of complaints have been made alleging that transmission 
    providers are acting in a discriminatory manner in implementing line 
    loading relief, which is required when a transmission line is in danger 
    of being overloaded. Such complaints allege that the transmission 
    providers are not providing redispatch service, are favoring their own 
    transactions, and are failing to follow curtailment priorities 
    established in Order No. 888.133 All of these actions by 
    transmission providers may provide subtle competitive advantages in 
    wholesale markets. For example, for those purchasers for whom service 
    reliability is particularly important, purchasing power from a 
    transmission provider may be viewed as offering enhanced reliability.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \133\ We set for evidentiary hearing a formal complaint by 
    Wisconsin Electric Power Company making these types of allegations. 
    Wisconsin Electric Power Company v. Northern States Power Company 
    (Minnesota) and Northern States Power Company (Wisconsin), 86 FERC 
    para. 61,121 (1999). The parties subsequently filed a settlement 
    agreement.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Like the issue of calculating ATC, the fact that curtailment of 
    service in times of congestion is in the control of the transmission 
    provider, who also has power transactions on the affected transmission 
    lines, leads to suspicions of discriminatory behavior that are 
    difficult to verify. For example, a representative of Blue Ridge Power 
    Agency told us at one of our ISO conferences:
    
        There simply is no shaking the notion that integrated generation 
    and transmission-owning utilities have strategic and competitive 
    interests to consider when addressing transmission constraints. 
    Functional unbundling and enforcement of [standard of] conduct 
    standards require herculean policing efforts, and they are not 
    practical. 134
    
        \134\ Regional ISO Conference (Richmond), Transcript at 20.
    
        Likewise, we were told at another ISO conference that operators 
    with reliability responsibility possess actual controlling authority 
    over transactions, ``thereby giving them a tremendous advantage over 
    competitors.'' 135
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \135\ Comments of Marvin Carraway on behalf of Clarksdale Public 
    Utilities Commission, Regional ISO Conference (Kansas City), 
    Transcript at 107.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    d. OASIS Sites That Are Difficult To Use
        Aside from the problems alleged with respect to posting inaccurate 
    ATC calculations on OASIS sites, there have been complaints that some 
    transmission providers have implemented their OASIS sites as a tool to 
    impede competition rather than as it was intended--as a tool to foster 
    competition. It has been alleged that transmission providers have no 
    incentive to make the sites easier to use, because it is primarily the 
    transmission providers' marketing competitors who would benefit from 
    better OASIS sites. 136 The petitioners in Docket No. RM98-
    5-000 asserted:
    
        \136\ See, e.g., Comments of representative from Enron Power 
    Marketing speaking at Commission's July 1997 OASIS Technical 
    Conference, transcript at 43-44.
    
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [[Page 31407]]
    
        Indeed, to gain a competitive advantage over those who are 
    dependent on the timeliness and accuracy of OASIS, vertically 
    integrated transmission owners have an incentive to make OASIS as 
    slow and uninformative as possible.137
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \137\ Petition at 37.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Similarly, EPSA has told us that ``the present transmission regime 
    gives existing transmission-distribution utilities an inherent 
    advantage to reserve capacity for their own native load use, and 
    provides them with no incentive to maintain a properly functioning 
    OASIS.'' 138
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \138\ EPSA Comments, Docket No. RM98-5-000. at 8 (filed 
    September 21, 1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As we stated above with respect to ATC calculation, we are not in a 
    position to make a judgment that transmission providers are 
    deliberately making their OASIS sites difficult to use in order to 
    disadvantage marketing competitors. In fact, we are aware that some 
    OASIS sites are well run and engender few complaints from users, and 
    that there may be legitimate technical and transitional difficulties 
    responsible for some of the problems complained of. However, this is 
    another example of the situation where market participants perceive 
    discriminatory intent, whether or not one exists, because of the 
    apparent opportunity and incentive to discriminate.
    e. Other Issues Related to Functional Unbundling and Dealing With 
    Remaining Undue Discrimination
        While the Commission here has not attempted to provide an 
    exhaustive compilation of the remaining opportunities for 
    discriminatory practices by transmission operators who are also in the 
    power business,139 it believes that the potential for such 
    problems increases in a competitive environment unless the market can 
    be made structurally efficient and transparent with respect to 
    information, and equitable in its treatment of competing participants. 
    We invite public comments on the extent to which there remains undue 
    discrimination in transmission services, and if it remains, in what 
    forms. Those comments should address both the areas of alleged 
    discrimination we have discussed above, as well as any other areas that 
    commenters may have experienced. In addition, we are asking for 
    comments about what remedies we should impose in an effort to eliminate 
    any remaining discriminatory conduct. For example, should we require 
    mandatory participation in an RTO, or are there other possible 
    remedies? Could a performance-based rate system be designed to realign 
    economic interests to remove the motive for discrimination?
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \139\ There have been other violations alleged. For example, 
    many relate to pricing and discounting.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        One thing that seems apparent is that a system that attempts to 
    control behavior that is motivated by economic self-interest through 
    the use of standards of conduct will require constant and extensive 
    policing. This kind of regulation goes beyond traditional price 
    regulation and forces us to regulate very detailed aspects of internal 
    company policy and communication. For functional unbundling to be 
    successful, we have to be concerned, in some sense, about ``who spoke 
    to whom'' in the company cafeteria. Functional unbundling does not 
    necessarily promote light-handed regulation. It also undoubtedly 
    imposes a cost on those entities that have to comply with the standards 
    of conduct who face additional training and rules that create 
    rigidities in their internal management activities.
        It appears, based upon our experience thus far, that no matter how 
    detailed the standards of conduct and how intensive our enforcement, 
    competitors will continue to be suspicious that the wall between 
    transmission operations and power sales is being breached in subtle and 
    hard to detect ways. The perception that many entities that operate the 
    transmission system cannot be trusted is not a good foundation on which 
    to build a competitive power market. It creates needless uncertainty 
    and risk for new investments in generation.
        In section III.B below, we will address how the use of independent 
    RTOs can help eliminate the opportunity for unduly discriminatory 
    practices by transmission providers, restore the trust among 
    competitors that all are playing by the same rules, and reduce the need 
    for overly intrusive regulatory oversight.
    B. Benefits That Regional Transmission Organizations Can Offer
        In the preceding sections, we have set forth what we consider to be 
    at least some of the remaining transmission related impediments to full 
    competition in the electricity markets. These impediments include 
    engineering and economic inefficiencies in the operation and structure 
    of the existing transmission grid that inhibit the development of 
    broad-based markets for electric power, and remaining opportunities for 
    discriminatory practices by transmission owners with power marketing 
    interests.
        We now believe that the establishment of properly structured RTOs 
    throughout the U.S. can effectively remove the remaining impediments to 
    competition in the power markets. As discussed elsewhere in this NOPR, 
    a properly structured RTO will be an entity that is independent from 
    all generation and power marketing interests, and has the exclusive 
    responsibility for grid operations, short-term reliability, and 
    transmission service within a region. Such an entity would not only 
    confer benefits related to removing impediments to competition, but 
    would also enhance reliability and allow for less intrusive government 
    regulation of transmission providers.
        We note that the Commission's recognition of the benefits of 
    regional transmission organizations is not new. The Commission has 
    encouraged the industry to create such institutions for more than six 
    years. In 1993, the Commission issued a policy statement encouraging 
    the formation of RTGs, which were defined as voluntary organizations of 
    transmission owners, users, and other entities interested in 
    coordinating transmission planning (and expansion), operation and use 
    on a regional and inter-regional basis. 140 The Commission 
    summarized the benefits of such entities as enabling the market for 
    electric power to operate in a more competitive, and thus more 
    efficient manner; providing coordinated regional planning of the 
    transmission system to assure that system capabilities are adequate to 
    meet system demands; decreasing the delays that are inherent in the 
    regulatory process, resulting in a more market-responsive industry; and 
    resolving technical transmission issues (e.g., loop 
    flow).141
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \140\ Policy Statement Regarding Regional Transmission Groups, 
    FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 30,976 at 30,870 and n.4 (1993) (RTG 
    Policy Statement).
        \141\ RTG Policy Statement, FERC Stats. & Regs. at 30,871.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        One year later, the Commission issued a transmission pricing policy 
    statement which encouraged RTGs to address transmission pricing and 
    offered to provide more latitude to RTGs than to individual utilities 
    for innovative pricing proposals, recognizing that issues such as loop 
    flow required a regional approach.142 Then, two years after 
    that in Order No. 888, the Commission encouraged the industry to 
    consider ISOs, and gave specific guidance on characteristics and 
    functions in the form of 11 principles.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \142\ Inquiry Concerning the Commission's Pricing Policy for 
    Transmission Services Provided by Public Utilities Under the Federal 
    Power Act, 59 FR 55031 (November 3, 1994), FERC Stats. & Regs., 
    Regulations Preambles para. 31,005, at 31,140, 31,145 (Transmission 
    Pricing Policy Statement.)
    
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [[Page 31408]]
    
        The Commission has not been alone in recognizing the benefits of 
    RTOs. In fact, there is surprising unanimity about the benefits of 
    regional transmission solutions to grid management. For example, the 
    Edison Electric Institute adopted a resolution that ``recognizes the 
    potential benefits of voluntary grid regionalization in addressing 
    pancaked transmission rates, congestion management and reliability, 
    transmission planning, and market power * * *'' and supported 
    ``flexible, voluntary, market-based approaches'' toward grid 
    regionalization.143 The American Public Power Association 
    has stated that ``mandating RTOs will prevent further inequities in the 
    provision of wholesale transmission service, provide guidance to the 
    states, advance regional solutions to reliability issues to head off 
    future crisis situations such as the 1998 Midwest Price Spikes, and 
    partially mitigate serious market power concerns that have arisen due 
    to the high number of recent mergers in the electric utility 
    industry.'' 144 The National Energy Marketers Association 
    urges the Commission to ``take bold steps necessary to create larger 
    regional transmission organizations (RTOs) and to force maximum 
    participation into (sic) these organizations.'' 145 Other 
    industry groups representing very different interests have reached 
    similar conclusions.146
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \143\ Edison Electric Institute, Resolution Regarding Grid 
    Regionalization, adopted by the Board of Directors, January 7, 1999.
        \144\ Motion of American Public Power Association For Leave To 
    Lodge, Docket No. RM99-2-000, filed March 17, 1999, at 2.
        \145\ NEA, ``National Guidelines For Restructuring The Electric 
    Generation Transmission and Distribution Industries,'' January 1999, 
    at 6.
        \146\ The Electric Power Supply Association recommends that 
    ``ISOs Must be Regional in Scope.'' (EPSA Position Statement on 
    Independent System Operators, January 1997, at 1.) The Electricity 
    Consumers Resource Council (ELCON) states that ``a competitive 
    electricity marketplace requires the formation of large, regional 
    independent system operators.'' (ELCON, ``Independent System 
    Operators,'' Profiles On Electricity Issues, No. 18, March 1997, at 
    2.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        States are also recognizing the need for regional approaches to 
    grid operation. At least five states have passed laws or issued 
    regulations requiring transmission owning utilities in their states to 
    participate in regional transmission entities.147 Other 
    state regulators have highly praised the new regional transmission 
    entities that are functioning in their regions.148
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \147\ Laws to encourage participation in regional ISOs or 
    transcos have been passed in Wisconsin, Illinois, Virginia, and 
    Arkansas. Regulations to encourage this outcome have been issued by 
    the Nevada commission.
        \148\ See, e.g., Comments of Commissioner Marlene Johnson, RTO 
    Conference (District of Columbia), transcript at 23-24; Commissioner 
    Gerald Thorpe (Maryland), transcript at 39-40; President Herbert 
    Tate (New Jersey), transcript at 47-50; and Commissioner Nora Mead 
    Brownell (Pennsylvania), transcript at 54.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        While these industry groups and state regulators may not agree on 
    the form of such regional organizations and how aggressive the 
    Commission should be in encouraging their development, they do 
    generally agree that such entities would provide substantial benefits.
        We note, additionally, that this same conclusion has also been 
    reached in other countries. In almost every country that has chosen to 
    introduce competition in its power sector, a single regional or 
    national grid management organization has or will be created as the 
    necessary platform for achieving fair and efficient bulk power 
    competition.149
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \149\ Government of Mexico, Secretaria de Energia, Policy 
    proposal for structural reform of the Mexican electricity sector, 
    1999; World Bank, Reforms and Private Participation in the Power 
    Sector of Selected Latin American and Caribbean and Industrialized 
    Countries, 1994; National Regulatory Research Institute, Electric 
    Power industry Restructuring in Australia: Lessons From Down Under, 
    Occasional Paper #20, Ohio State University, January 1997; World 
    Bank (Industry and Energy Department), Central and Eastern Europe: 
    Power Sector Reform in Selected Countries 1997; Ontario (Canada) 
    Market Design Committee, The Fourth and Final Report, January, 1999; 
    Alberta (Canada) Department of Energy, Moving To Competition, A 
    Guide to Alberta's New Electricity Structure, 1994; Jan Moen, A 
    Common Electricity Market in Norway and Sweden: Prerequisites, 
    Development and Results So Far, Norwegian Water Resources and Energy 
    Administration, May, 1996; National Grid Company, Grid System 
    Management, Coventry, England; and J. Culy, E. Read and B. Wright, 
    ``The Evolution of New Zealand's Electricity Supply Structure,'' in 
    International Comparisons of Electricity Regulation, Gilbert and 
    Kahn, editors, Cambridge University Press, 1996.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In the following discussion, we address the significant benefits of 
    establishing RTOs.
    1. An RTO Would Improve Efficiencies in the Management of the 
    Transmission Grid
        As discussed in section III.A above, numerous inefficiencies in the 
    current operation and structure of the transmission grid may be 
    impeding full competition. Establishing RTOs could help remove most, if 
    not all, of those inefficiencies in a number of ways.
        First, an RTO would improve efficiency through regional 
    transmission pricing. The Commission has long recognized that 
    transmission pricing reform is most effectively accomplished on a 
    regional basis.150 An RTO would have the geographic scope 
    needed to eliminate pancaked transmission rates within its region. This 
    would broaden the generation market and could result in more potential 
    suppliers and less concentrated generation markets, thereby fostering 
    more competitive markets and lower prices to consumers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \150\ Transmission Pricing Policy Statement, FERC Stats. & Regs. 
    at 31,145.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Second, regional scope would improve congestion management on the 
    grid. An RTO would improve the way congestion is managed over a large 
    area, thus expanding the number of potential transactions over existing 
    facilities while reducing the number of curtailments.
        The scheduling of power by multiple utilities over a regional grid 
    can lead to unexpected overloads on constrained facilities. This can be 
    a serious barrier to competitive power trading because some power sale 
    transactions may have to be curtailed. With a regional scope, an RTO 
    would be better able to manage congestion. An RTO would be in a better 
    position to prevent congestion or control it through application of 
    appropriate regionwide congestion pricing to ration use of the grid if 
    necessary. An RTO would also more readily identify schedules that could 
    lead to congestion, and relieve congestion through regional redispatch 
    authority. A pricing approach to capacity allocation would improve 
    efficiency by ensuring that the most highly valued transactions remain 
    on the grid and possibly result in less curtailment than under the 
    present approach.
        Third, an RTO would improve efficiency by providing more accurate 
    estimates of ATC than those currently provided by individual systems. 
    Conditions on all parts of the regional grid affect ATC on individual 
    utility systems. Factors such as load estimates, generation and 
    transmission outages, generation dispatch orders and transactions on 
    individual systems can affect the determination of ATC. An individual 
    utility may not have complete or timely information regarding such 
    factors and may apply assumptions and criteria in its ATC estimates 
    that are different from those of neighboring transmission operators, 
    leading to wide variations in ATC values for the same transmission 
    path. The information needed may be considered confidential, and market 
    participants would be more willing to share it with an independent 
    body.
        An RTO would produce better ATC estimates because it would have 
    access to complete regional usage information, would have current 
    information because the RTO will be the security coordinator as well as 
    the OASIS site administrator, and would calculate ATC values on a 
    consistent region-wide basis using a regional flow model. An RTO would 
    also resolve most, and perhaps all, of the complaints of inaccurate ATC
    
    [[Page 31409]]
    
    postings. Problems are likely to remain only to the extent that 
    scheduling reservations across several RTOs continue to be made on a 
    contract path basis.
        Fourth, an RTO also would more effectively manage parallel path 
    flows. With an RTO in place, the geographic scope for scheduling and 
    pricing transmission would be widened and parallel path flows would be 
    internalized within the RTO. This should result in more accurate ATC 
    calculations, improve reliability, and, with appropriate transmission 
    pricing, eliminate or reduce disputes among transmission owners 
    regarding uncompensated uses of facilities.
        Fifth, an RTO would promote more efficient planning for 
    transmission or generation investments needed to increase transmission 
    capacity. One advantage of an RTO that is helpful in planning is that 
    it will be able to see the ``big picture.'' Planning and expansion of 
    grid facilities will no longer be done on a piecemeal basis. An RTO 
    would help identify the best place on the grid to locate new 
    generation.151 An RTO also will have more options available 
    to it because of its size and configuration. It has the potential to 
    select and implement the most efficient investment or operating option 
    within the region for relieving a bottleneck. This is in marked 
    contrast to the current situation in many regions where individual 
    transmission owners are generally limited to investment options in 
    their particular service areas even though better (i.e., less costly) 
    options may be available elsewhere in the region.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \151\ One of the benefits of the ERCOT (Texas) ISO has been, due 
    to the ISO's comprehensive view of the grid, the ability to identify 
    the most effective spots on the grid to locate new generation 
    facilities. See Chairman Patrick Wood (Texas), transcript at 205-06.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Sixth, an RTO would increase coordination between separate state 
    regulatory agencies by providing a single point of focus for 
    transmission expansion review, possibly even encouraging multi-state 
    agreements to review and approve new transmission 
    facilities.152 As RTOs develop viable regional planning 
    processes, there may be a growing willingness on the part of individual 
    states to accommodate regional regulatory review on either a formal or 
    informal basis.153
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \152\ The Commission recognizes that there may be legal 
    impediments to such a shift. For example, most state siting laws 
    typically require that the proposed facility must be assessed in 
    terms of its benefits for the state rather than the region. See 
    Ileana Elsa Garcia, ``State Electric Facility Siting Practices,'' 
    background paper prepared for the Harvard Electric Policy Group, 
    April 10, 1997.
        \153\ To encourage this movement, we propose requiring that the 
    RTO's planning and expansion process must '' accommodate efforts by 
    state regulatory commissions to create multi-state agreements to 
    review and approve new transmission facilities.'' See section III.E.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Seventh, transactions costs would also be reduced with an RTO in 
    place. For example, the consolidation of transmission control 
    operations would cut general and administrative costs over the long 
    term. In addition, an RTO would administer a single regional 
    transmission tariff, thereby permitting ``one stop shopping'' for 
    regional transmission service and resulting in simpler and more 
    efficient procedures for transmission users to transmit power over 
    greater distances.
        Eighth, through regional standardization of transmission services 
    and the terms and conditions under which they are transacted, an RTO 
    would facilitate establishing transmission rights and the 
    ``tradeability'' of transmission rights. The early experience suggests 
    that independent regional transmission organizations are in the best 
    position to establish well-defined rights to the use of the 
    grid.154 Such rights are essential to establishing 
    congestion markets. Clear rights are also needed for the ability to 
    trade transmission rights between customers that place different values 
    on capacity. Such trade helps ensure an efficient allocation of current 
    capacity and helps ensure that new capacity is built only when and 
    where necessary. 155
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \154\ See Central Hudson Gas & Electric Corporation, et al., 86 
    FERC para. 61, 062 at 61, 228-33 (1999); PJM, 81 FERC at 62,240.
        \155\ Capacity Reservation Open-Access Transmission Tariffs, 
    Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 61 FR 21847 (May 10, 1996), FERC 
    Stats. & Regs. para. 32, 519 (CRT NOPR).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Ninth, an RTO would facilitate the success of state retail access 
    programs by providing greater confidence in the markets and a larger 
    regional market with access to more potential suppliers.
    2. An RTO Would Improve Grid Reliability
        With the improved transmission access that has resulted from 
    industry compliance with Order No. 888, the volume of wholesale 
    electricity transactions has significantly increased along with the 
    number of market participants. This has led to industry concerns that 
    traditional reliability rules may not guarantee that the bulk power 
    system remains secure. Many transmission owners in a region make 
    independent decisions about use of a common regional transmission grid. 
    A reliability problem on one utility's transmission system may threaten 
    the reliability of its neighbor's system. A regional body that operates 
    the regional grid and enforces reliability rules for the entire region 
    could prove helpful to current efforts and should be considered. An RTO 
    would enhance reliability by (1) operating the system for a large 
    region, (2) ensuring coordination during system emergencies and 
    restorations, (3) conducting comprehensive and objective reliability 
    studies, (4) coordinating generation and transmission outage schedules, 
    and (5) sharing of ancillary services responsibilities.
    3. An RTO Would Remove Opportunities for Discriminatory Transmission 
    Practices
        In an RTO, the control of transmission operation is cleanly 
    separated from power market participants. An RTO would have no 
    financial interests in any power market participant, and no power 
    market participant would be able to control an RTO. This separation 
    will eliminate the economic incentive and ability for the transmission 
    provider to act in a way that favors or disfavors any market 
    participant in the provision of transmission service.156 
    Accordingly, ATC calculations can be made in an unquestionably 
    objective manner, OASIS sites can be equally relied upon by all 
    transmission users, and line loading relief should be free from 
    preferences for certain market participants.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \156\ Appropriate price regulation of RTOs would still be 
    needed.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In addition, the separation of transmission operation from power 
    marketing activities also would reduce opportunities for intentional or 
    inadvertent communication of commercially valuable information from the 
    transmission provider to any market participant, and should eliminate 
    any advantage that market participants may now have with respect to 
    arranging transmission service with an affiliated transmission 
    provider.
        Finally, removing the opportunity for discriminatory transmission 
    practices will help ensure the openness and integrity of the commercial 
    process. We have been told repeatedly of the importance of transparency 
    and fairness in the relationship between transmission users and 
    transmission providers. This was a prominent topic at our ISO 
    conferences last year. Fairness, impartiality and market confidence are 
    also important to reliability. If the operator orders certain actions 
    to be taken for system reliability purposes that might harm the 
    interests of some users, those users must know that the action being 
    ordered has been made
    
    [[Page 31410]]
    
    fairly and with only technical factors in mind.
        One important benefit of an RTO is that it could help eliminate the 
    suspicions about, or remaining actual discriminatory practices by, grid 
    operators. The DOE Reliability Task Force concluded that regional 
    reliability entities such as RTOs must be ``truly independent of 
    commercial interests so that their reliability actions are--and are 
    seen to be--unbiased and untainted * * *'' [emphasis added] 
    157 The same conclusion was reached by the blue-ribbon 
    Electric Reliability Panel convened by NERC to recommend reforms in the 
    current U.S. reliability system. The panel concluded that: ``(t)o 
    dispel suspicions that the system operator favors one participant over 
    another * * *, the operator must be independent from market 
    participants.'' 158
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \157\ See Secretary of Energy Advisory Board, U.S. Department of 
    Energy, ``Maintaining Reliability in a Competitive U.S. Electricity 
    Industry,'' September 29, 1998 at xv.
        \158\ Electric Reliability Panel of the North American 
    Reliability Council, ``Reliable Power: Renewing the North American 
    Electric Reliability Oversight System,'' December 1997, at 17.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    4. An RTO Would Result in Improved Market Performance
        By improving efficiencies in the management of the grid, improving 
    grid reliability, and removing any remaining opportunities for 
    discriminatory transmission practices, the widespread development of 
    RTOs would also improve the performance of electricity markets in 
    several ways and consequently lower prices to the Nation's electricity 
    consumers.
        The RTO benefits discussed so far in this section would result in 
    improving the competitiveness of wholesale electricity markets. To the 
    extent that RTOs foster fully competitive wholesale markets, the 
    incentives to operate generating plants efficiently are bolstered. 
    Suppliers will continuously seek to avoid being made uncompetitive by 
    rivals. We have now had close to two decades of experience with 
    generating plants being operated in at least partially competitive 
    markets. Non-traditional generators have had the opportunity to realize 
    increased profits through reduced costs and improved operating 
    performance. For years, the growing presence of independent power 
    generators has led to highly efficient new capacity coming on line. The 
    evidence is clear that market incentives can lead to highly efficient 
    plant operations.
        The incentives for more efficient plant operation can also affect 
    existing generation facilities. Especially noteworthy is the recent 
    experience that indicates improvements in the generation sector in 
    regions with RTOs. Regions which have ISOs in place are undergoing 
    dramatic shifts in the ownership of generating facilities. Large-scale 
    divestiture and high levels of new entry in California and the 
    Northeast are changing the ownership structure of these regions' 
    generators. Availability of customers, and the presence of competing 
    suppliers, are creating the incentives for better-performing plants. 
    All plants are coming under pressure to improve their availabilities 
    and operating efficiencies. Individual firms have made strategic 
    decisions to seek to become more competitive, or to prepare themselves 
    for future competition.159
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \159\ Examples include: Virginia Power, which has made more than 
    $1 billion in capital improvements and other investments (without 
    raising rates) between 1992 and 1998, including $921 million in 
    generating plant and approximately $125 million in transmission line 
    upgrades. See Virginia Power, Virginia Power Statement on SCC 
    Report, May 24, 1998. This document is available on Virginia Power's 
    website at http://www.vapower.com/news/archive/releases980324.html; 
    Entergy, which has achieved high performance at its nuclear units in 
    terms of capacity factors, outage times and refueling periods, See 
    Entergy Operation Services, Inc., Entergy Nuclear Units Have 
    Outstanding Year as Entergy Forges Ahead with National Nuclear 
    Company, January 26, 1999, press release. This document is available 
    on Entergy's website at http://www.entergy.com/news/1999/
    nr012699.htm.; New York Power Authority, which has lowered operating 
    and maintenance budgets, refinanced debt, and invested $181 million 
    in capital improvements. See New York Power Authority, NYPA Exceeds 
    Performance Goals in 1998, February 12, 1999, press release. This 
    document is available on NYPA's website at http://www.nypa.gov/
    press/0212a.htm.; Green Mountain Power, which reduced operations and 
    maintenance expenditures by 50% between 1998 and 1995. See Green 
    Mountain Power Corporation, Sales and Expenditures, 1995 Annual 
    Report. This document is available on Green Mountain Power 
    Corporation's website at http://www.gmpvt.com/annrpt95/salesex2.htm; 
    and the Tennessee Valley Athority, which realized cost savings of 
    22% on fossil-fueled and hydroelectric plant outage projects which 
    were subject to a continuous improvement process. See Hans E. Picard 
    and C. Robert Seay, Jr., Competitive Advantage Through Continous 
    Outage Improvement, Electric Power Research Institute Fossil Plant 
    Maintenance Conference, July 29, 1996. This document is avialable at 
    website http://www.iac.net/pconsult/epri.html..
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        By improving competition, RTOs will also reduce the potential for 
    market power abuse. As discussed earlier, eliminating pancaked 
    transmission prices will expand the scope of markets and bring more 
    players into the markets.160 By eliminating the mistrust in 
    the current grid management, entry by new generation into the market 
    will become more likely as new entrants will perceive the market as 
    more fair and attractive for investment. And with more players, the 
    market becomes deeper and more fluid, allowing for more sophisticated 
    forms of transacting and smoother matching of buyers and sellers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \160\ Evidence from the UK and strategic behavior studies, 
    however, indicates that such market power can lead to ongoing cost 
    impacts as well as outright efficiency losses. See Richard Green and 
    David Newbery, Competition in the British Electricity Spot Market, 
    100 J. POL. ECON., 929, 1992.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The full value of the benefits of RTOs to improve market 
    performance cannot be known with precision before their development, 
    and we do not yet have a long enough track record with existing 
    institutions with which to measure. The Commission will estimate the 
    potential cost savings from RTOs as part of its National Environmental 
    Protection Act analysis. At this time, we foresee several billion 
    dollars annually in efficiency gains to the economy.161
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \161\ The benefits are likely to come substantially from lower 
    generation operation and maintenance costs that result from new 
    plants, improved performance of existing plants, and improved 
    congestion management.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission seeks comment on the effect of RTOs on electricity 
    market performance, including any data or other information that could 
    shed light on quantifying the extent of those benefits.
    5. An RTO Would Facilitate Lighter-Handed Governmental Regulation
        There are several ways that the existence of a properly structured 
    RTO would reduce the need for Commission oversight and scrutiny, which 
    would benefit both the Commission and the industry.
        A number of regulatory benefits depend critically on the RTO being 
    truly independent of power marketing interests. For example, to the 
    extent an RTO is independent of power marketing interests, there would 
    be no need for this Commission to monitor and attempt to enforce 
    compliance with the standards of conduct designed to unbundle a 
    utility's transmission and generation functions.
        An independent RTO with an impartial dispute resolution mechanism 
    would resolve disputes without resort to the Commission complaint 
    process. The Commission has demonstrated its willingness to defer to 
    such mechanisms.162 It is generally more efficient for these 
    organizations to resolve many disputes internally rather than bringing 
    every dispute to the Commission. We seek comment on what types of 
    disputes or other matters would be appropriate for the Commission to 
    defer to the decisions of the RTO? In granting deference to decisions 
    that result from an acceptable ADR process,
    
    [[Page 31411]]
    
    would there be a need to distinguish between RTOs that are ISOs and 
    RTOs that are transcos?
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \162\ See PJM, 81 FERC at 62,269.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission could also consider adopting streamlined filing and 
    approval procedures. The Commission could consider different filing 
    requirements for established RTOS. For example, should we lower the 
    threshold for the types of changes to operations or practices that 
    would not require a filing with the Commission? Should such a policy be 
    applied equally for non-profit and for-profit RTOs?
        Another regulatory benefit is that an RTO could result in more 
    streamlined transmission rate proceedings. The Commission has indicated 
    its willingness to grant more latitude to transmission pricing 
    proposals from appropriately constituted regional groups, and RTOs 
    would be such groups.163
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \163\ See Transmission Pricing Policy Statement, FERC Stats. & 
    Regs. at 31,145, 31,148.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        To the extent that RTOs increase market size and decrease market 
    concentration, the competitive consequences of proposed mergers would 
    become less problematic and thereby help further streamline the 
    Commission's utility merger decision making process.
    6. Conclusion
        The Commission believes that the widespread formation of RTOs can 
    provide substantial benefits. The Commission invites comment on the 
    benefits of RTOs and the magnitude of these benefits.
    
    C. Concerns Expressed by the State Commissions
    
        Our Notice of Intent to Consult with State Commissions in this 
    proceeding initiated our commitment to take into account the advice and 
    concerns of the states in formulating an RTO policy. Through written 
    and oral comments made during the consultations in February 1999, and 
    in response to a series of follow-up questions, state commissioners 
    raised a number of concerns regarding RTO policy. The Commission 
    appreciates the state commissioners' serious consideration and their 
    comments have helped shape our proposal. We take the opportunity to 
    summarize the principal concerns and how our proposal addresses those 
    concerns.
    1. Federal Mandate
        Most states oppose a FERC mandate to form RTOs.164 The 
    proposed rule would not generically require public utilities to 
    transfer control of their transmission facilities to an RTO; however, 
    we do seek comment on the issue. We are proposing to provide the 
    impetus needed to help form RTOs by engaging the industry and the 
    states in a national dialogue regarding RTO characteristics, setting 
    minimum characteristics and functions for RTOs, providing flexibility 
    for innovative transmission rate proposals, including a willingness to 
    consider incentive pricing proposals, and establishing regional 
    processes with Commission staff participation after a Final Rule is 
    issued for fostering RTO formation. Thus, the proposed rule stops short 
    of generically ordering utilities into RTOs but instead, as WUTC 
    expresses it, we are at this time adopting: `` * * * a policy of 
    encouraging voluntary RTO participation and filings * * * '' 
    165 The Commission is, however, concerned that the current 
    transmission grid management framework may be preventing electricity 
    markets from reaching their full competitive potential. We will 
    evaluate the comments received in response to our proposals to 
    determine if additional action is needed.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \164\ See, e.g, Comments in Docket No. RM99-2-000 of North 
    Carolina Utilities Commission (NCUC) at 1; Washington Utilities and 
    Transportation Commission at (WUTC) at 4; Georgia Public Service 
    Commission (GPSC) at 10; Mississippi Public Service Commission 
    (MPSC) at 3; and South Carolina Public Service Commission (SCPSC) at 
    1.
        \165\ WUTC at 4-5.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    2. Regional Flexibility
        At all three consultations with the state commissions and in 
    written comments, we were urged by almost every state commission not to 
    impose a ``one size fits all'' approach to RTO design.166 
    The vast majority of the respondents to the Commission's follow-up 
    questions were unwilling to designate a particular type of RTO 
    organization as superior in all cases. The Commission agrees and does 
    not propose to establish a mandatory national template for RTOs. Such a 
    policy would be ill advised at this time. Neither this Commission, nor, 
    we suspect, anyone else in the industry knows now what is the best 
    combination of ownership and control to achieve an optimal RTO. Given 
    the lack of experience to date, the Commission believes that the best 
    policy is to encourage regional experimentation. Thus, as discussed 
    below, the proposed rule would establish only minimum characteristics 
    and functions needed for Commission approval as an appropriate RTO. We 
    also propose to initiate collaborative regional processes in which each 
    region would be encouraged to design an RTO that best meets its needs. 
    This collaborative process is discussed below.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \166\ See, e.g., comments of Florida Public Service Commission 
    (FPSC) at 3.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Our proposed policy of regional flexibility should also help some 
    states' concerns with the cost of an RTO. As discussed above, we 
    believe RTO development will result in substantial benefits for the 
    Nation. However, some states are concerned that the costs of an RTO 
    will exceed its benefits. The cost of meeting the minimum RTO 
    characteristics need not be large, but it is not always easy to measure 
    the long-term RTO benefits that would offset these costs. By permitting 
    regional flexibility, subject to our minimum characteristics and 
    functions, the proposed rule allows each region to design an RTO that 
    has costs commensurate with the regional benefits expected.
    3. Retail Markets
        States that have not adopted a retail access policy are concerned 
    that an RTO in their state might interfere with their prerogatives 
    regarding adopting, or not adopting, retail access. The comments and 
    responses of some state commissions reiterate the concern that RTO 
    formation will lead to retail access where it does not yet 
    exist.167 The proposed rule does not require retail access. 
    The Commission agrees with FPSC that, ``FERC should not pursue any 
    policy that would interfere with or contravene a state's authority to 
    adopt or refrain from adopting direct retail access.'' 168 
    Having an RTO in a state does nothing to interfere with the state's 
    authority to decide retail access policy. Some states whose utilities 
    are in RTOs can have retail access while others can choose not to have 
    retail access. This is demonstrated today by the presence of ISOs in 
    the Middle Atlantic and New England regions, but not all of the states 
    in those regions have yet adopted retail competition. Some states with 
    retail access believe that an RTO is needed to support their customer 
    choice plan because the RTO allows customers, aggregators and marketers 
    to reach supplies over a larger area. Those states that do not have 
    retail access can nevertheless benefit from an RTO as their utilities 
    enjoy the benefits of the RTO to lower native load generation rates by 
    buying and selling power over a larger market area.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \167\ See, e.g. response of Kentucky Public Service Commission 
    (KPSC) at 1.
        \168\ FPSC comments at 4.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Some states are also concerned that having a Commission-regulated 
    RTO provide transmission service for retail
    
    [[Page 31412]]
    
    customers would lead to some loss of control over retail market 
    services, such as the ability to assure reliability. A primary purpose 
    of an RTO is to ensure transmission reliability. Whether there is any 
    decrease in state control over any aspects of retail market services 
    would depend on the design of the particular RTO. Under any RTO design, 
    the states would retain full control over the generation adequacy of 
    franchised power suppliers, transmission siting and local distribution 
    reliability. Further, the proposed rule would encourage state 
    involvement both in RTO design and ongoing oversight, providing states 
    a vehicle to protect all aspects of transmission reliability on behalf 
    of retail customers.
    4. Effect on States with Low Cost Generation
        States with relatively low cost power are concerned that an RTO 
    would result in local utilities selling their low cost power to other 
    states. However, the vast majority of the respondents to a follow-up 
    question on this issue stated that this is not a likely 
    problem.169 Similarly, we do not believe RTOs will cause 
    such a result. The presence or absence of retail access is the 
    principal factor affecting potential out-of-state sales of low-cost 
    power, and this is in the hands of state policy makers. Arguably, 
    retail access could lead to low cost power being sold out of state if 
    incumbent utilities no longer have an obligation to serve retail 
    customers. However, this could happen with or without an RTO. Where 
    there is no retail access, state authorities can continue to ensure 
    that a utility with a monopoly franchise sells its lowest cost power to 
    local native load, even if the utility's transmission is operated by an 
    RTO. Indeed, an RTO could actually lower retail rates by expanding the 
    market region for the utility to sell the higher cost power not sold to 
    native load and sharing in the benefits of regionwide resource planning 
    and congestion management.170 And finally, utilities that 
    now have low cost generation will help assure access to future low cost 
    generation plants by participating in an RTO. New low-cost generation 
    plants are more likely to be attracted to regions with a well-
    functioning regional market governed by an RTO.171 In other 
    words, a state that is low-cost today may not be low-cost tomorrow 
    without an RTO in its area.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \169\ See, e.g., responses of Virginia State Corporation 
    Commission (VSCC) at 1; WUTC comments at 2; Wisconsin Public Service 
    Commission (WPSC) comments at 1; and Florida Public Service 
    Commission (FPSC) comments at 1. But see, e.g., response of Alabama 
    Public Service Commission (APSC) at 1, and response of District of 
    Columbia Public Service Commission (DCPSC) at 1.
        \170\ See response of Indian Utility Regulatory Commission 
    (IURC) at 1.
        \171\ According to data in a recent survey, about 64% of 
    announced merchant power plants will be located in California, 
    Texas, New York, New England, and the middle Atlantic area, while 
    such states account for only about 30% of total electricity load in 
    the U.S. See Announced Merchant Plants, survey prepared by the 
    Electric Power Supply Association, Appril 13, 1999.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We seek comment from state commissions regarding how an RTO in 
    their state would affect power costs.
    5. Need for Independent Transmission Operation
        Many states believe that transmission operators should be 
    structurally independent of other market participants. Responses to 
    follow-up questions indicated that independence of the transmission 
    operator is a basic assumption for an effective RTO.172 As 
    the Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission (PaPUC) states, ``It is 
    therefore the case that RTOs must have sufficient independence from 
    direct control by any single entity or interest group to perform these 
    functions well and honestly.'' 173 As discussed below, our 
    proposed rule would require strict independence of transmission 
    operation from market participants for approval of an RTO application.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \172\ See e.g., responses of KPSC at 2 and Missouri Public 
    Service Commission (MoPSC) at 1.
        \173\ Supplemental comments at 7.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    6. Transmission Cost Shifting
        There is a concern by some states with utilities with relatively 
    low cost transmission facilities that, by joining an RTO, their 
    utilities' transmission costs will be averaged with the higher cost 
    facilities of utilities in other states in determining RTO transmission 
    rates.174 As a result, these states are concerned that 
    joining an RTO will increase local transmission rates. This is known as 
    transmission cost shifting. It has been an issue in every ISO the 
    Commission has approved to date. That is why, in each of those ISO 
    cases, we have allowed a transition period in which access fees are 
    based on some form of ``license plate'' pricing: access fees are paid 
    by load serving entities based on the fixed transmission costs of the 
    local utility. As discussed below, we propose to continue and perhaps 
    expand such flexibility in allowing the license plate approach or other 
    approaches to recover current sunk transmission costs during a 
    transition period.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \174\ See, e.g., comments of WUTC at 6.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    7. Boundary Drawing
        Many states expressed opposition to the Commission drawing regional 
    or RTO boundaries in a rulemaking.175 The proposed rule does 
    not set boundaries. Instead, we propose factors for assessing whether a 
    proposed RTO's geographic configuration will ensure that the required 
    RTO functions, such as assuring reliability, internalizing loop flow, 
    managing congestion, and eliminating pancaked rates, are satisfied. In 
    other words, we are proposing that the boundaries and other factors 
    affecting scope and regional configuration will depend on the functions 
    that an RTO performs. We note, however, that some RTO functions are 
    likely to be carried out more effectively in a large region.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \175\ See, e.g., comments of NCUC at 1 and WUTC at 3.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    8. Regional Approach to Reliability
        Many states believe that regional operation of transmission is 
    needed to assure the continued reliability of the transmission 
    system.176 The proposed rule would require regional 
    operation of transmission by an RTO with primary responsibility for 
    short-term reliability as a condition for approval of an RTO 
    application. This is discussed below.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \176\ See, e.g., comments of NCUC at 3.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    9. Pricing Reform
        Many states want regional approaches to transmission pricing 
    reform. In particular, they would like to decrease the incidence of 
    pancaked transmission rates. Our proposal is aimed at developing RTOs 
    that would provide the forum and have the geographic scope for a 
    regional approach to transmission pricing reform. The proposed rule 
    would also permit flexibility for experimenting with innovative forms 
    of congestion management, which would mean fewer TLR curtailments and 
    more assurance that native load is served.
    10. Participation of Public Power
        In some regions of the Nation, substantial portions of the 
    transmission grid are owned by pubic agencies. The states in these 
    regions have expressed a concern that our RTO initiative must address 
    how to assure that such public agencies join the RTO. Some of the 
    responses to follow-up questions reiterated the need to include public 
    power agencies in any RTO formation.177
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \177\ See, e.g., responses of Iowa Utilities Board (IUB) at 1 
    and New Mexico Public Regulation Commission (NMPRC) at 1.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The proposed rule would not require RTO formation and so does not 
    address
    
    [[Page 31413]]
    
    how to require public agency transmission owners to join RTOs. As 
    suggested by KPSC,178 we will allow flexibility in RTO 
    formation in order to meet, where possible, the requirements of public 
    agencies. Nevertheless, the Commission's objective is to encourage the 
    placement of all transmission facilities under the control of an RTO. 
    In section III-G of this notice, we have requested comments on ways the 
    Commission can facilitate public power participation in RTOs. We are 
    also proposing regional processes to help facilitate RTO formation 
    under section 202(a) of the Federal Power Act. Because section 202(a) 
    applies to public power as well as public utilities, the regional 
    processes will include publicly owned transmission entities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \178\ Response at 1.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    11. State Role in RTO Governance
        States want a role in the governance of any RTOs for their states, 
    and the Commission proposes to be as flexible as possible in 
    accommodating their needs. The state commission responses to follow-up 
    questions show that some states want to be closely involved in RTO 
    operation 179 while others believe it better to remain 
    independent of the RTO in order to engage in better 
    oversight.180 Practically all respondents see siting 
    authority remaining with the states.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \179\ See, e.g., responses of WUTC at 4 and Arizona Corporation 
    Commission (ACC) at 2.
        \180\ See, e.g., response of Wisconsin Public Service Commission 
    (WPSC) at 3.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As discussed below, the proposed rule encourages RTO design to 
    accommodate appropriate state oversight, especially with regard to 
    planning and siting new multi-state transmission facilities. We request 
    comments on the appropriate state role in RTO governance. For example, 
    should state government officials participate as voting members of an 
    RTO?
    12. Existing Regional Transmission Entities
        During our consultations, many of the state commissioners from the 
    northeastern region and a representative from California, where 
    transmission facilities are already, or soon will be, under the control 
    of Commission-approved ISOs, asked that the Commission not require 
    major changes to these ISOs during their implementation 
    periods.181 The commissioners observed that their states' 
    ISOs were still undergoing an implementation and learning period and, 
    in some instances, are important to retail choice program 
    implementation.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \181\ See, e.g., Comments at the Washington, DC conference of 
    New England Conference of Public Utilities Commissioners, Inc. 
    (NECPUC) at 4 and remarks of California Senator Peace, RTO 
    Conference (Las Vegas), transcript at 3-4.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission respects the investment of time and other resources 
    made in the existing ISOs. We understand the importance of avoiding 
    change during the critical implementation periods. Due to these 
    considerations, and our proposed policy of regional flexibility, the 
    proposed rule does not require major changes to the existing 
    transmission entities that the Commission has found in conformance with 
    the ISO principles of Order No. 888 at this time, absent compelling 
    circumstances. However, any entity must meet our minimum RTO 
    characteristics and functions to receive any of the benefits to be 
    accorded RTOs. Our objective is to have all of the Nation's 
    transmission grid under the control of RTOs that have the minimum 
    characteristics and functions adopted in the Final Rule. That is why we 
    propose to require the public utility members of existing transmission 
    entities that have been found in conformance with the Commission's ISO 
    principles to make a filing, individually or jointly, with the 
    Commission no later than October 15, 2000, that explains the extent to 
    which the entity in which it or they participate meets the minimum RTO 
    characteristics and functions. The Commission is also concerned about 
    impediments to transactions between existing ISOs (as well as any 
    future RTOs). We therefore encourage existing ISOs to consider ways to 
    reduce any impediments to transactions among them.
        The Commission invites further comments from the state commissions 
    on all aspects of the proposed rule.
    
    D. Minimum Characteristics and Functions for a Regional Transmission 
    Organization
    
        In this section, we propose minimum characteristics and functions 
    for a transmission entity to qualify as an RTO. These characteristics 
    and functions are designed to ensure that any RTO will be independent 
    and able to provide reliable, non-discriminatory and efficiently priced 
    transmission service to support competitive regional bulk power 
    markets. There are four minimum characteristics for an RTO:
        (1) Independence from market participants;
        (2) Appropriate scope and regional configuration;
        (3) Possession of operational authority for all transmission 
    facilities under the RTO's control; and
        (4) Exclusive authority to maintain short-term reliability.
        In addition, there are seven minimum functions that an RTO must 
    perform. An RTO must:
        (1) Administer its own tariff and employ a transmission pricing 
    system that will promote efficient use and expansion of transmission 
    and generation facilities;
        (2) Create market mechanisms to manage transmission congestion;
        (3) Develop and implement procedures to address parallel path flow 
    issues;
        (4) Serve as a supplier of last resort for all ancillary services 
    required in Order No. 888 and subsequent orders;
        (5) Operate a single OASIS site for all transmission facilities 
    under its control with responsibility for independently calculating TTC 
    and ATC;
        (6) Monitor markets to identify design flaws and market power; and
        (7) Plan and coordinate necessary transmission additions and 
    upgrades.
        The Commission seeks comment on the following questions: (1) 
    whether the Commission's enumeration of minimum criteria omits a 
    necessary minimum characteristic or function, or includes an 
    unnecessary characteristic or function; (2) whether there is a need to 
    distinguish between minimum characteristics and minimum functions 
    (i.e., adopt separate categories for the minimum requirements); and (3) 
    if so, whether any of the minimum characteristics should be re-
    characterized as minimum functions, and vice versa. Comments on these 
    questions should take into account the Commission's objective in this 
    rulemaking of encouraging the formation of RTOs that promote 
    competitive markets and non-discriminatory access to, and reliable 
    operation of, the electric grid.
        Under this proposal, all RTOs must satisfy the four minimum 
    characteristics on their first day of operation as approved RTOs. The 
    Commission also proposes that all RTOs be prepared to perform at least 
    four of the seven minimum functions on their first day of operation as 
    approved RTOs. Recognizing that more time may be needed to perform 
    certain functions, we are proposing that for the other three of the 
    functions--establishing procedures for addressing parallel path flows 
    with neighboring systems, managing congestion, and planning 
    transmission expansion--additional time ranging from one to three years 
    after initial operation will be allowed.
        The Commission seeks comments on whether we should grant RTO status 
    to entities that are not able to perform immediately these three 
    functions. The Commission also seeks comments on
    
    [[Page 31414]]
    
    whether we should grant RTO status to entities that may not be able to 
    perform on the first day of operation certain other (i.e., any of the 
    remaining four) of the minimum functions. Should we differentiate, for 
    purposes of initial implementation, between any of the seven minimum 
    functions? If so, has the Commission appropriately identified those 
    minimum functions that are most likely to require additional time to 
    perform?
        We propose to give transmission entities flexibility in deciding 
    how to meet these seven minimum functions. For five of the functions 
    (tariff administration, congestion management, ancillary services, 
    market monitoring and planning and expansion), we propose to establish 
    standards for how the function is performed, but an RTO will have the 
    option of demonstrating that an alternative proposal is consistent with 
    or superior to the standards in the proposed rule.182 The 
    Commission seeks comment on whether this flexibility--i.e., the option 
    of demonstrating that an alternative proposal is consistent with or 
    superior to the proposed rulemaking standards--should apply to any or 
    all of the minimum characteristics.183
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \182\ We use the term ``standard'' to refer to the required sub-
    elements under each characteristic and function.
        \183\ Alternative proposals may include requests for appropriate 
    transition periods. We will consider such proposals on a case-by-
    case basis, based on an assessment of their effect on regional power 
    markets.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We also propose that the RTOs would have flexibility in designing 
    their organizational structures. We are receptive to all types of RTO 
    proposals as long as they satisfy the specified minimum characteristics 
    and functions. For example, we will consider proposals for non-profit 
    or for-profit organizations. An RTO can be an operator of the grid that 
    it controls, an operator and owner of the grid that it controls, or a 
    combination of the two.184 The minimum characteristics and 
    functions provide a wide range of implementation flexibility and 
    discretion. They represent a floor, not a ceiling. To encourage further 
    evolution, the Commission is proposing an ``open architecture'' 
    requirement. Under this requirement, the RTO must permit further 
    improvements that will enhance the efficient operation of regional bulk 
    power markets.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \184\ One example of an arrangement that combines these two 
    approaches would be a transmission entity that owns and operates 
    some transmission facilities and operates other facilities under 
    long-term leases or other agreements with existing or new 
    transmission owners.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Minimum Characteristics
    
    1. Characteristic 1: Independence. The RTO Must be Independent of 
    Market Participants. (Proposed Sec. 35.34(i)(1))
        Market participants must be assured that the RTO will provide 
    transmission access to all market participants on a fair and non-
    discriminatory basis. The Commission believes that it is a prerequisite 
    for achieving fair, open and competitive power markets. An RTO needs to 
    be independent in both reality and perception.185 As we have 
    said before in the context of ISOs, we think that ``the principle of 
    independence is the bedrock upon which the ISO must be built * * 
    *''186 It is the Commission's view that independence can be 
    achieved if the RTO satisfies three conditions. First, the RTO, its 
    non-stakeholder governing board members and its employees must have no 
    financial interests in market participants.187 Second, the 
    RTO's decision making must not be controlled by any market 
    participants. Third, the RTO must have independent authority to file 
    changes to its transmission tariff. We now discuss these conditions.
    
        \185\ This is also the conclusion of almost every one of the 
    state commission representatives who attended our recent 
    consultatons with the state regulatory community. See, e.g., 
    Comments of Commissioners Marlene Johnson and Herbert Tate, Regional 
    ISO Conference (Washington, D.C.), transcript at 66-67, 95; Comments 
    of Judy Sheldrew, RTO Conference (Las Vegas), transcript at 58.
        \186\ Atlantic City Electric Company, et al., 77 FERC para. 
    61,148 at 61,574 (1996). The same conclusion was reached by the DOE 
    Reliability Task Force and the NERC Reliability Panel. The DOE Task 
    Force concluded that regional reliability entities must be ``truly 
    independent of commercial interests so that their reliability 
    actions are--and are seen to be--unbiased and untainted * * *'' Task 
    Force Report at xv. The Electric Reliability Panel concluded that 
    ``(t)o dispel suspicions that the system operator favors one 
    particular over another * * * the operator must be independent from 
    market participants.'' North American Electric Reliability Council, 
    Electric Reliability Panel, Reliability Power: Renewing the North 
    American Electric Reliability Oversight System, December 22, 1997, 
    at 17.
        \187\ We use the terms ``stakeholder'' and ``market 
    participant'' interchangeably. They mean any entity that buys or 
    sells electric energy in the RTO's region or in any neghboring 
    region that might be affected by the RTO's actions, or any affiliate 
    of such entity.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
     a. The RTO, its employees and any non-stakeholder directors must not 
    have financial interests in any electricity market participants. 
    (Proposed Sec. 35.34(i)(1)(i))
    
        We propose that the RTO, the non-stakeholder members of its 
    governing board and all employees be prohibited from having financial 
    interests in any market participants. The prohibition clearly applies 
    to current financial interests. It does not preclude past financial 
    ties with market participants. Nor does it require a total or permanent 
    prohibition on all future financial ties with market participants in 
    the region. Such a prohibition would make it difficult for the RTO to 
    hire experienced and knowledgeable employees. Therefore, we will employ 
    a rule of reason standard in deciding what financial ties with market 
    participants would be acceptable after an individual leaves the RTO. As 
    has been the case in our review of conflict of interest standards for 
    ISOs, the Commission would establish these standards on a case-by-case 
    basis.188
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \188\ See, e.g. Midwest ISO, 84 FERC at 62,152-53, order on 
    reh'g 85 FERC at 62,036; NEPOOL, 79 FERC at 62,586-87.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission requests commenters to address some or all of the 
    following issues related to the proposed requirements. Do we need to 
    define the financial independence requirement in more specific terms or 
    is it sufficient to enunciate the general principle and then apply it 
    on a case-by-case basis? Should the definition of stakeholders or 
    market participants be expanded to include entities that operate 
    distribution-only facilities (i.e., entities that perform the ``wires'' 
    function at lower voltages) and transmission entities in neighboring 
    regions? Should this definition be broadened to include sellers and 
    buyers of ancillary services? Are there any circumstances in which the 
    definition should be expanded to include entities that do not 
    participate in power markets in the region but that provide 
    transmission services to the RTO or buy transmission service from the 
    RTO? Do we need to add more specificity to the requirement that RTOs 
    have conflict of interest standards? Are there lessons to be learned 
    from the experience of ISOs with conflict of interest standards that 
    can now be applied more generally to RTOs?
    
    b. An RTO must have a decisionmaking process that is independent of 
    control by any market participant or class of participants. (Proposed 
    Sec. 35.34(i)(1)(ii))
    
        This requirement would be satisfied, for example, by an RTO with 
    (a) a non-stakeholder governing board and (b) a prohibition on market 
    participants having more than a de minimis (one percent) ownership 
    interest in the RTO.189 The Commission seeks
    
    [[Page 31415]]
    
    comments on whether this kind of RTO should be deemed to satisfy 
    automatically this element of the independence requirement. We also 
    request comments on whether there should be a single standard for 
    independent decision making for all RTOs regardless of whether they are 
    for-profit or non-profit entities. The Commission recognizes that there 
    may be other ways to satisfy the independent decision making 
    requirement. Therefore, we propose to consider other governance and 
    ownership proposals, which will be judged on a case-by-case basis 
    against the general requirement of independent decisionmaking.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \189\ It is our understanding that a similar standard was 
    established by the British government when it created the National 
    Grid Company (NGC), the largest, for profit transmission company in 
    the world. The company's basic corporate documents prohibit market 
    participants from serving on NGC's board and from owning more than 
    one percent of the shares in its voting equity. A similar 
    prohibition appears to exist in the Wisconsin state law that 
    mandates Wisconsin utilities to join either an ISO or an independent 
    transmission company by a specific date. See 1997 Wisconsin Act 204, 
    Section 30.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        With regard to the RTO governing board, we propose to define a non-
    stakeholder governing board as a governing board of individuals without 
    any financial ties to market participants or their affiliates. 
    Individuals on such a board are independent, rather than 
    representative, of market participants. Board members usually have 
    experience in a variety of fields related to the RTO's operations. 
    These could include, among others, transmission operations and 
    planning, law, electricity regulation, business management, market 
    analysis, and risk management. The non-stakeholder board would be the 
    ultimate decision making authority, though it could choose to delegate 
    decisions to its staff or committees of stakeholders.190 The 
    board would be advised by the RTO staff and perhaps by a committee of 
    stakeholders. In recent proceedings, we have accepted this two tier 
    approach because it represents a middle ground in that it attempts to 
    balance independence with expertise.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \190\ An ISO governing board's delegation of decisions to a 
    stakeholder committee would be contingent on this committee not 
    being dominated by one segment of the industry. We recently found 
    that the existing tiered governance arrangements of the New York and 
    New England ISOs failed to meet this standard and we ordered both 
    ISOs to reduce the voting power of dominant utilities in the lower 
    tier of stakeholders charged with advising the non-stakeholder 
    governing boards. See Central Hudson, 87 FERC at __, slip. op. at 
    12-13; New England Power Pool, 86 FERC para. 61,262 at 61,965.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In the case of a non-stakeholder board, how can we ensure that the 
    concerns of market participants are communicated effectively to the 
    board? We request comments on what, if any, additional requirements 
    should apply to a governing board that is not a stakeholder board or to 
    a governing board with both stakeholders and non-stakeholders. For 
    either stakeholder or non-stakeholder boards, should we impose an upper 
    limit on the size of the board? How should the Commission consider 
    proposals for state regulatory or other governmental officials to 
    select board members for either stakeholders or non-stakeholder boards? 
    How should the Commission view proposals for state government officials 
    to serve as voting members of RTO boards?
        With regard to market participants having no more than a de minimis 
    interest in the ownership of the RTO, we propose to consider a de 
    minimis interest as having no more than a one percent interest in the 
    ownership of an RTO. We seek comment on whether one percent is an 
    appropriate de minimis ownership interest and, if not, what would 
    constitute appropriate de minimis ownership for purposes of 
    establishing independence. We also request comment on whether there are 
    conditions under which market participants should be allowed to have 
    more than a de minimis ownership interest in an RTO. Should the 
    Commission have a different standard for passive interests? How should 
    the Commission treat preferred equity shares?
        There are several reasons why we are proposing that the independent 
    decision making standard can be satisfied by an RTO with (a) a non-
    stakeholder governing board and (b) a prohibition on market 
    participants having more than a de minimis (one percent) ownership 
    interest in the RTO. First, affiliated transmission companies (i.e., 
    transmission companies in which one or more market participants have 
    more than a de minimis ownership interest) may not be trusted by market 
    participants even with elaborate protections (e.g., voting trusts, 
    independent trustees and corporate boards not chosen by the owners). We 
    believe that market participants are likely to suspect that the 
    safeguards will be gamed. This, in turn, could affect investment 
    behavior. In particular, market participants may be reluctant to make 
    needed investments in generation or marketing of electricity if they 
    believe that the RTO is likely to give favored treatment to its 
    affiliates.
        Second, affiliated transmission entities that are not independent 
    of market participants would continue the regulatory need for detailed 
    and hard to enforce codes of conduct. If we permit RTOs to be 
    affiliated with one or more market participants, we believe that the 
    Commission may have to devote considerable regulatory resources to 
    ``chasing after conduct'' (i.e., allegations of favoritism). If our 
    experience with functional unbundling as well as with affiliated 
    natural gas pipelines provides any lessons, we will probably find it 
    necessary to issue detailed rules that deal with internal corporate 
    matters relating to organizational responsibilities, corporate 
    communications, etc.191 For this reason, the existence of 
    affiliated transmission entities also could make it difficult to pursue 
    light-handed regulation.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \191\ Natural gas pipelines that transport gas for others and 
    are affiliated with gas marketers or brokers must conform to the 
    standards of conduct outlined in Section 161.3 of the Commission's 
    regulations. Further, such pipelines, pursuant to Section 250.16 of 
    the Commission's regulations must maintain: (a) provisions in their 
    effective tariffs that divulge operating employees and facilities 
    shared by the pipeline and its affiliate(s) and the procedures used 
    to address complaints; (b) a data log showing, by customer 
    (affiliate and non-affiliate), how capacity on the pipeline was 
    allocated; and (c) information concerning shippers receiving 
    discounted rates. Within the natural gas pipeline industry, these 
    requirements are sometimes viewed as overly intrusive regulation. 
    See ``FERC Clarifies Affiliate Etiquette For Gas Pipelines,'' The 
    Energy Daily, November 17, 1998, at 1.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commenters are asked to address whether these are reasonable 
    assessments of the effects of allowing market participants to have more 
    than a de minimis ownership interest in RTOs. Is there relevant 
    experience from other regulated industries? If we were to allow market 
    participants to have more than a de minimis ownership interest for a 
    transition period, how long should the transition period be? Would any 
    additional safeguards be required during such a transition period? In 
    general, which type of institution would better serve the goal of 
    independence: a transco with de minimis ownership and a non-stakeholder 
    board or an ISO with a non-stakeholder board?
    
    c. The RTO Must Have Exclusive and Independent Authority To File 
    Changes to Its Transmission Tariff with the Commission under Section 
    205 of the Federal Power Act. (Proposed Sec. 35.34(i)(1)(iii)
    
        We believe that independence requires that the RTO provide service 
    under its own open access transmission tariff and that it has the right 
    to file changes to its tariff with the Commission on its own authority. 
    In other words, the RTO should not be required to get the prior 
    approval of transmission customers, transmission owners or any other 
    entities to make Section 205 filings with the Commission. The rationale 
    is that if the RTO is taking over the open access transmission service 
    obligation from current transmission providers, the RTO
    
    [[Page 31416]]
    
    must be able to independently and unilaterally propose changes in its 
    tariff.192 While this is not likely to be a concern for 
    transcos, our recent experience suggests that it is an important issue 
    for ISOs that seek to become RTOs. We have approved ISOs that appear 
    not to meet this standard. For example, the New England ISO provides 
    transmission service under the tariff of the NEPOOL RTG rather than its 
    own tariff.193 In our order approving the Midwest ISO, we 
    stated that: ``We believe that any problems that may arise can be 
    addressed by the Midwest ISO's authority to file changes unilaterally 
    to the congestion management procedures.'' 194 However, our 
    order also accepted a requirement that the ISO get the prior approval 
    of existing transmission owners before filing certain types of changes 
    in its tariff with us.195 Separately, we have a pending 
    request for clarification on this issue from the PJM ISO.196 
    Can an RTO be truly independent if it does not have the authority to 
    file changes in its tariff without the approval of other entities such 
    as transmission owners? Should the ISO's unilateral filing authority be 
    limited to transmission rate design and terms and conditions that 
    directly affect access but not to changes that would affect 
    transmission owners' ability to collect their overall revenue 
    requirements? In practice, is this a viable distinction? If an RTO's 
    filed rate schedule also includes market design rules, should the RTO 
    have Section 205 filing authority to make changes in these rules?
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \192\ The Commission has previously stated that the 
    ``[a]uthority to act unilaterally . . . is a crucial element of a 
    truly independent ISO.'' 79 FERC para. 61,374 at 62,585 (1997).
        \193\ This has been protested by the New England Conference of 
    Public Utility Commissioners. See ``Motion For Leave To Submit 
    Answer. . . .,'' Docket Nos. OA97-237 and ER97-1079, April 8, 1997.
        \194\ See Midwest ISO, 84 FERC at 62,163.
        \195\ Id. at 62,151.
        \196\ ``PJM Interconnection, LLC's Request For Clarification, Or 
    In The Alternative, Rehearing,'' Docket No. OA97-261, December 27, 
    1997.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    2. Characteristic 2: Scope and Regional Configuration. The RTO must 
    serve an appropriate region. The region must be of sufficient scope and 
    configuration to permit the RTO to effectively perform its required 
    functions and to support efficient and nondiscriminatory power markets. 
    (Proposed Sec. 35.34(i)(2))
        We propose that all RTO proposals filed with us identify a region 
    of appropriate scope and configuration. The scope and configuration of 
    the regions in which RTOs are to operate, and the extent to which RTOs 
    control the transmission facilities within a region, will significantly 
    affect how well they will be able to achieve the desired regulatory, 
    reliability, operational, and competitive benefits. Accordingly, we set 
    forth below what we consider to be relevant factors that may affect the 
    appropriate scope and configuration for a region that an RTO will 
    serve.197 If the formation of RTOs is undertaken without 
    considering the goals that large regions can best achieve, it is 
    unlikely that RTOs will be configured to provide maximum benefits. 
    Transmission owners could seek to gain strategic advantage by the way 
    an RTO is formed. For example, an RTO could be placed to act as a toll 
    collector on a critical corridor.198 Alternatively, an RTO 
    could propose configurations that interfere with the formation of a 
    larger, more appropriately configured RTO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \197\ We note that a number of parties have asked the Commission 
    to take the initiative to make the RTO formation process more 
    orderly. For example, 11 state commissions filed a petition with 
    FERC in February 1998 (which was noticed in both the Midwest ISO 
    proceeding and in the generic ISO inquiry) asking FERC to take 
    action on the geographic configuration of ISOs, arguing that 
    inappropriate borders for ISOs could result in reduced customer 
    benefits, economic inefficiencies, unnecessary complication of 
    coordinated operations, and detrimental impacts on planning. 
    However, in our three RTO conferences, representatives of several 
    other state commissions expressed concern about the Commission 
    playing too strong a role in RTO formation, arguing, for example, 
    that we should not define RTO geographic boundaries but should leave 
    this to the parties in each area of the country to determine.
        \198\ See Statement of Ohio Commission Chairman Craig Glazer, 
    RTO Conference (St. Louis), transcript at 85-87.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission is aware that there is likely no one ``right'' 
    configuration of regions. One particular boundary may satisfy one 
    desirable RTO objective and conflict with another. The industry will 
    continue to evolve, and the appropriate regional configurations will 
    likely change over time with technological and market developments. The 
    Commission is also mindful of the interests of individual states 
    regarding RTO boundaries. Given all these considerations, the 
    Commission believes that the public interest will best be served if we 
    establish at the time of the Final Rule a set of factors that encourage 
    appropriate regional configuration, without actually prescribing 
    boundaries.
        In the discussion that follows, the Commission sets forth, and 
    solicits comments on, the factors that it believes are important for an 
    appropriately configured region in which an RTO would operate.
    a. Factors Affecting The Appropriate Scope And Regional Configuration 
    Of An Acceptable Region
        The Commission has grouped the factors that it believes are 
    significant to developing appropriate regions into regional 
    configuration factors and factors for evaluating boundaries.
    i. Regional Configuration Factors
        The Commission believes that the most important consideration in 
    evaluating the geographic configuration of an RTO is that such 
    configuration permit the RTO to perform its functions effectively. We 
    believe that many of the characteristics and functions for an RTO 
    proposed in this section suggest that the regional configuration of a 
    proposed RTO should be large in scope.199 For example:
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \199\ This reiterates the conclusion we reached in the eleven 
    ISO principles in Order No. 888, where we stated that ``[t]he 
    portion of the transmission grid operated by a single ISO should be 
    as large as possible.'' Order No. 888, FERC Stats. & Regs. at 
    31,731.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
         Making accurate and reliable ATC determinations: An RTO of 
    sufficient regional scope can make more accurate determinations of ATC 
    across a larger portion of the grid using consistent assumptions and 
    criteria.
         Resolving loop flow issues: An RTO of sufficient regional 
    scope would internalize loop flow and address loop flow problems over a 
    larger region.
         Managing transmission congestion: A single transmission 
    operator over a large area can more effectively prevent and manage 
    transmission congestion.
         Offering transmission service at non-pancaked rates: 
    Competitive benefits result from eliminating pancaked transmission 
    rates within the broadest possible energy trading area.
         Operations: A single OASIS operator over an area of 
    sufficient regional scope will better allocate scarcity as regional 
    transmission demand is assessed; promote simplicity and ``one-stop 
    shopping'' by reserving and scheduling transmission use over a larger 
    area; and lower costs by reducing the number of OASIS sites.
         Planning and coordinating transmission expansion: 
    Necessary transmission expansion would be more efficient when planned 
    and coordinated over a larger region.
        The Commission recognizes, however, that there may be other factors 
    that limit how large a region may be, for example, the requirement that 
    an RTO be the grid operator. There may be a limitation on how many 
    facilities or transactions can be reliably overseen by a single 
    operator, imposed either by hardware
    
    [[Page 31417]]
    
    design or costs, or imposed by human limitations to process the 
    required amount of information.
        The Commission is not proposing that the RTO must be a control area 
    operator, although four of the five ISOs approved so far by the 
    Commission are each a single control area.200 If those 
    forming an RTO decide that the RTO should be a control area operator, 
    this too may limit the RTO's size. However, control area functions 
    might be performed over a large area by a master-satellite (or other 
    hierarchical) structure. The Commission solicits comments on the 
    technical limitations or cost limitations on how large an RTO can be if 
    it is to have control area responsibilities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \200\ The Midwest ISO is the only Commission-approved ISO that 
    has not proposed a single control area.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The difficulty and cost of transferring operational control over 
    many transmission systems to one RTO may also affect regional 
    configuration. The larger the number of transmission systems, the more 
    complex the task may be and the longer it may take to accomplish. The 
    Commission solicits comments on how the number of transmission systems 
    to be combined would affect the cost and time required to form an RTO.
        A third factor that may limit size is rate treatment. As regions 
    get larger and involve more existing owners of transmission, reaching 
    consensus on an appropriate transmission rate design for the region may 
    prove challenging. Also, a uniform transmission rate treatment which 
    averages the costs of existing transmission assets across the region 
    could subject some RTO participants to higher transmission rates. 
    Moreover, sharing the costs of future transmission improvements may 
    raise issues regarding whether the transmission improvements provide 
    benefits to the entire region and who should pay those costs. These 
    issues are discussed further below with respect to cost shifting 
    concerns.
        Are there other factors that may limit the geographic scope of an 
    RTO? The Commission solicits comments on this issue.
    ii. Factors for Evaluating Boundaries
        In addition to the factors affecting the size of a region, other 
    factors may affect the location of regional boundaries. The Commission 
    believes that RTO boundaries should be drawn so as to facilitate and 
    optimize the competitive, reliability, efficiency, and other benefits 
    that RTOs are intended to achieve, as well as to avoid unnecessary 
    disruption to existing institutions. The Commission proposes below a 
    list of factors it would consider in evaluating the configuration for a 
    proposed RTO. Various factors may indicate different configurations, 
    and assessing the appropriateness of a region's configuration will 
    require a balancing of factors.
        Given this qualification, the Commission proposes that the 
    following factors should be considered in evaluating an RTO's 
    boundaries:
        Facilitate performing essential RTO functions and achieving RTO 
    goals, as discussed elsewhere in this proposed rule: The regions should 
    be configured so that an RTO operating therein can ensure non-
    discrimination and enhance efficiency in the provision of transmission 
    and ancillary services, maintain and enhance reliability, encourage 
    competitive energy markets, promote overall operating efficiency, and 
    facilitate efficient expansion of the transmission grid. For example, 
    we understand that there have been instances where transmission system 
    reliability was jeopardized due to the lack of adequate real-time 
    communication between separate transmission operators in times of 
    system emergencies. To the extent possible, RTO boundaries should 
    encompass areas for which real-time communication is critical, and 
    unified operation is preferred.
        Recognize trading patterns: Given that a goal of this initiative is 
    to promote competition in electricity markets, regions should be 
    configured so as to recognize trading patterns, and be capable of 
    supporting trade over a large area, and not perpetuate unnecessary 
    barriers between energy buyers and sellers. There may exist today some 
    infrastructure or institutional barriers inhibiting trade between 
    regions that could be mitigated economically. It would be desirable 
    that RTO boundaries not perpetuate these barriers.
        Not facilitate the exercise of market power. While the industry 
    should work toward a goal of virtually seamless trade between RTOs, it 
    may be that initially a significant amount of trade may be contained 
    within RTOs. Thus, it is important to avoid creating an RTO region that 
    is dominated by a only a few buyers or sellers of energy, or a region 
    where an RTO of inappropriate scope and configuration can exercise 
    transmission market power by acting as an unnecessary toll collector on 
    a critical corridor.
        Encompass existing control areas: Existing control areas have 
    established systems for load balancing within their area. Most existing 
    control areas are relatively small. For the sake of efficiency, it may 
    be advisable not to divide them. However, the affected parties would 
    not be precluded from proposing to divide control areas if they found 
    it otherwise advantageous.
        Encompass existing regional transmission entities: Because existing 
    ISOs, and any other regional transmission entities we may hereafter 
    approve, already integrate transmission systems, it may not be 
    efficient to divide them into different regions. This is not to say, 
    however, that RTO boundaries must coincide with existing regional 
    transmission entities. An appropriate region may well be larger, and 
    there may be circumstances that support combining or reconfiguring 
    existing entities.
        Encompass one contiguous geographic area: The competitive, 
    efficiency, reliability, and other benefits of RTOs can be best 
    achieved if there is one transmission operator in a region. To be most 
    effective, that operator should have control over all transmission 
    facilities within a large geographic area, including the transmission 
    facilities of non-public utility entities. This consideration could 
    preclude a noncontiguous region, or a region with ``holes.''
        Encompass a highly interconnected portion of the grid: To promote 
    reliability and efficiency, portions of the transmission grid that are 
    highly integrated and interdependent should not be divided into 
    separate RTOs. One RTO operating the integrated facilities can better 
    manage the grid. This is not to say, however, that every weak 
    interconnection belongs on a regional boundary. Where a weak interface 
    is frequently constrained and acts as a barrier to trade, it may be 
    appropriate to place that interface within an RTO region. It may be 
    more difficult to expand a weak interface on the boundary between two 
    regions; this may act as a barrier to trade between the two regions. 
    The Commission welcomes comments on the relative merits of 
    internalizing constraints within a region versus having constraints act 
    as natural boundaries between regions.
        Take into account existing regional boundaries (e.g. North American 
    Electric Reliability Council (NERC) regions) to the extent consistent 
    with the Commission's goals for RTOs: An RTO's configuration should, to 
    the extent possible, not disrupt existing useful institutions. The 
    Commission recognizes that utilities have been working together 
    regionally in different contexts for some time. There is value in 
    keeping together parties that have been working together.
        Take into account international boundaries: The Commission 
    recognizes
    
    [[Page 31418]]
    
    that natural transmission boundaries do not necessarily coincide with 
    international boundaries. Indeed, a large part of Canada's transmission 
    system, and a small part of Mexico's, is interconnected on a 
    synchronous basis with that of the U.S. Accordingly, an appropriate 
    region need not stop at the international boundary. However, this 
    Commission does not have, and does not seek, jurisdiction over the 
    facilities in a foreign country. We will ask our international 
    neighbors to participate in discussion of these issues. Perhaps what 
    may be thought of as a ``dotted line'' boundary at the international 
    border could be used to indicate that a natural transmission region 
    does not necessarily stop at the border, while this Commission's 
    jurisdiction does.
        The Commission seeks comments on the appropriateness of these 
    factors to determine an appropriate configuration for the regions in 
    which RTOs would operate, and also asks if any additional factors may 
    be appropriate.
    b. Potential Geographic Configurations
        Any number of RTO configurations could be appropriate regions. One 
    approach to establishing RTO regions is to use existing configurations. 
    These include the three electric interconnections within the 
    continental United States, the ten NERC reliability councils, and the 
    twenty-three NERC security coordinator areas. (See Appendix C to this 
    NOPR for depictions of these configurations 201). These 
    configurations are offered only for the purposes of having three 
    examples for assessing how well selected regions can satisfy the 
    minimum RTO characteristics and functions and for focusing commenters 
    on the trade-offs involved in determining an RTO configuration. The 
    Commission has not concluded that the example sets of boundaries are 
    acceptable configurations. The Commission seeks comments on how well 
    the regions served by existing institutions would satisfy the factors 
    enunciated above, and specifically how well they would be able to 
    satisfy the minimum RTO characteristics and functions outlined in this 
    section, and the advantages and disadvantages of these three examples. 
    The Commission also welcomes presentation and evaluation of other 
    methods to define appropriate regions.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \201\ While the maps in Appendix C accurately depict the 
    existing configurations extending into Canada, this is not intended 
    to suggest that our jurisdiction under this proposed rule reaches 
    there.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    c. Control of Facilities within a Region
        In addition to the scope and configuration of the region, effective 
    performance also requires that most or all of the transmission 
    facilities in a region be included in the RTO. Any RTO proposal filed 
    with us should plan to operate all transmission facilities within its 
    proposed region. We recognize, however, that there may be cases where 
    the proponents of an RTO may not be able to obtain agreement by all 
    transmission owners within a region of appropriate scope and 
    configuration to transfer operating control of their facilities to the 
    RTO. This may occur, for example, because certain facilities may be 
    owned by governmental entities that have restrictions on transfer of 
    control that may require time to resolve. We do not believe that it 
    would be desirable to deny RTO status or delay RTO start-up where the 
    transmission owners representing a significant portion of the 
    facilities within a region are ready to move forward, while a few 
    others are not. On the other hand, we do not believe it would be 
    desirable to approve an RTO proposal for a proposed region if the 
    proponents represent only a small portion of the facilities in that 
    region.
        We therefore propose to accept as RTOs only those proposals for 
    which a region of appropriate scope and configuration is identified and 
    the proponents represent a sufficient portion of the transmission 
    facilities within the identified region. Where the proponents do not 
    represent all the facilities within a region, they should identify the 
    reasons why all facilities are not represented, any efforts that will 
    be made to eventually include all facilities, and any interim 
    arrangements that could be made with the non-represented facility 
    owners to maximize coordination within the region.
        We solicit comments on how best to balance our goal of having RTOs 
    in place that operate all transmission facilities within an 
    appropriately sized and configured region against the reality that 
    there may be difficulties in obtaining 100 percent participation in all 
    regions in the near term. Should we deny RTO status for any proposal 
    that does not include all transmission facilities within an appropriate 
    region? If we do not deny RTO status for less than 100 percent 
    participation, is there some guideline that we should use for 
    determining when the proponents represent an appropriate ``critical 
    mass'' for the region? Should we require that the RTO at least 
    negotiate certain agreements with any non-participants within its 
    region to ensure maximum coordination? If so, what should be the terms 
    of such agreements?
        Finally, we seek comment on the question of how much deference, if 
    any, we should give to the proposed scope and regional configuration of 
    a proposed RTO. How readily, if at all, after balancing all appropriate 
    factors, should the Commission be willing to substitute its vision of 
    an appropriate RTO configuration for that of its proponents? To what 
    extent should the Commission take into account the degree of support in 
    assessing a proposed RTO configuration? Should approval or disapproval 
    by affected state commissions of the scope or configuration of a 
    proposed RTO affect the level of deference the Commission should afford 
    such a proposal?
    3. Characteristic 3: Operational Authority. The RTO must have 
    operational responsibility for all transmission facilities under its 
    control.202 (Proposed Sec. 35.34(i)(3))
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \202\ Transmission facilities will be distinguished from local 
    distribution facilities using the criteria that were established in 
    Order No. 888. Order No. 888, FERC Stats. and Regs. para. 31,036 at 
    31,770-71.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        a. The Regional Transmission Organization May Choose to Directly 
    Operate Facilities (Direct control), delegate certain tasks to other 
    entities (Functional Control) or Use a Combination of the Two 
    Approaches. (Proposed Sec. 35.34(i)(3)(i))
    
        Operational control raises two basic questions: What functions 
    should be performed by an RTO? How should an RTO perform the functions 
    that it has reserved for itself? With respect to the first question, 
    there is a concern that some splits of functions between an RTO that is 
    an ISO and existing control area operators could compromise reliability 
    and allow the control area operators to continue to favor their own 
    power marketing efforts.203
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \203\ Midwest ISO, 84 FERC at 62,156-60, 62,181.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        One solution would be for all RTOs to operate a single control 
    area. We have decided not to propose this as a requirement or two 
    reasons. First, the recent experience with the California ISO suggests 
    that the cost of investing in new control centers and 
    telecommunications systems and developing new operating systems can be 
    very high.204 Second, there is some uncertainty as to 
    whether it is technically feasible to establish a single traditional 
    control area over a large
    
    [[Page 31419]]
    
    geographic area. In light of these considerations, we do not propose to 
    require that an RTO must operate a single control area. However, the 
    RTO must have ultimate responsibility for providing non-discriminatory 
    transmission service for all market participants and for ensuring the 
    short-term reliability of the grid.205 We propose to give an 
    RTO considerable flexibility in deciding on the particular division of 
    operational responsibilities with existing control areas that will 
    allow it to achieve this outcome.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \204\ A recent report commissioned by the California ISO found 
    that the higher costs of the California ISO relative to other ISOs 
    could be explained, in part, by the decisions ``to build a privately 
    dedicated communications network, to have a hot standby backup 
    center half a state away, to not rely on existing infrastructure 
    more than necessary, to attempt full functionality on day one, to 
    accomplish the job in about one year. . .'' See ``A Comparative 
    Analysis Of Operating Independent System Operators In The United 
    States,'' prepared by James H. Caldwell Jr. (TGAL, Inc.) For the 
    California ISO, October 15, 1998, at 13.
        \205\ In our order approving the Midwest ISO, we stated that our 
    approval of the ISO was based on the applicants' commitment that the 
    ISO would be able to ``take all actions necessary to provide 
    nondiscriminatory transmission service, promote and maintain 
    reliability.'' Midwest ISO, 84 FERC at 62,159.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We will also grant an RTO considerable flexibility in deciding how 
    best to perform the functions that it has reserved for itself. The RTO 
    may choose to operate the grid through direct physical operation by RTO 
    employees, contractual agreements with other entities (e.g., 
    transmission owners and control area operators) or combinations of the 
    two. For example, an RTO could lease some control equipment from the 
    owners of existing control centers or convert some employees at these 
    control centers into RTO employees. Or alternatively, the RTO could 
    establish a system of hierarchical control in which it operates a 
    master control center and existing control centers become satellites of 
    the RTO control center for certain specified functions. 206 
    Under this arrangement, the personnel of the existing control centers 
    might become employees of the RTO or remain as employees of the control 
    center owner but supervised by RTO personnel. We will leave it to the 
    discretion of the RTO to decide on the combination of direct and 
    functional control that works best for its circumstances.207 
    Our only requirement is that the system of operational control chosen 
    by the RTO must ensure reliable operation of the grid and non-
    discriminatory access to the grid by all market participants. In 
    addition, to ensure that the RTO does not become locked into an 
    operational system that is unsatisfactory, the Commission will require 
    an RTO to prepare a public report that assesses the efficacy of its 
    operational arrangements no later than two years after it begins 
    operations.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \206\ See, e.g., Marija Ilic and Shell Liu, Hierarchical Power 
    System Control: Its Value in a Changing Industry, Springer-Verlag, 
    1996. It appears that certain types of hierarchical arrangements 
    have operated successfully in the PJM and NEPOOL pools for many 
    years.
        \207\ This topic is also addressed in our discussion of the 
    RTO's role as a provider of ancillary services. See the discussion 
    of Function 4.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission requests commenters to address the following 
    questions. What has been the experience of existing tight power pools 
    with master-satellite and hierarchical forms of control? Was there a 
    need to modify these operational arrangements when the pool was 
    replaced by an ISO? Outside of tight power pools, has the functional 
    unbundling requirement in Order No. 888 led to any divisions of 
    previously integrated internal operational systems? If so, have these 
    new divisions of operational responsibilities created any reliability 
    problems?
    
        b. The RTO must be the security coordinator for the transmission 
    facilities that it controls. (Proposed Sec. 35.34(i)(3)(ii))
    
        The Commission will also require that any qualifying RTO be the 
    NERC approved security coordinator for its region. A security 
    coordinator is a new type of grid entity that typically coordinates 
    reliability between multiple control areas across a region. It has been 
    promoted by NERC since 1995 to improve coordination and communication 
    across control areas. At present, there are more than 20 security 
    coordinators.208
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \208\See NERC, Operating Policy 9--Security Coordinator 
    Procedures. The current version of this document is available on the 
    NERC website at http://www.nerc.com/oc/opermanl.html. 
    See also, NERC TLR Order, 85 FERC para. 61,353 at 62,360-62.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Up to now, the job of a security coordinator has been to anticipate 
    reliability problems and to take actions to correct these problems if 
    they arise. Among the key functions of a security coordinator are to: 
    (1) perform load-flow and stability studies of the transmission system 
    to identify and address security problems; (2) exchange necessary 
    security information with control area operators, ISOs and regional 
    reliability councils; (3) monitor real-time operating characteristics 
    (e.g., availability of operating reserves, interchange schedules, 
    system frequency, actual flows versus limits, generation capacity 
    deficiencies) that could affect reliability; (4) take appropriate 
    action including, if necessary, the shedding of load in the event of a 
    reliability problem.209
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \209\ Midwest ISO, 84 FERC at 62, 155-56.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In our Midwest ISO order, we required that the proposed ISO must be 
    the security coordinator for its region. Our justification for this 
    requirement was that:
    
        This role [the role of a security coordinator] is central to 
    maintaining grid reliability and non-discriminatory access. Under 
    proposed NERC policies, security coordinators would be required to 
    anticipate problems that could jeopardize the reliability of the 
    interconnected grid. In the course of performing these reliability 
    functions, the Security Coordinator would receive considerable 
    information which is commercially sensitive. Therefore, it is 
    important that the proposed Midwest ISO Security Coordinator be 
    performed by an entity that is independent of market participants.
    
        The same logic applies to any RTO proposal. Therefore, we will 
    require that a qualifying RTO must be the security coordinator for its 
    region. 210
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \210\ We note that this was also the conclusion of the blue-
    ribbon Electric Reliability Panel of NERC. In its final report, the 
    panel concluded that ``it is essential that the security 
    coordinators perform their functions independent of any market 
    influences.'' The panel recommended that security coordinators 
    should be ``structured as independent entities, or their role 
    subsumed into independent system operator-type organizations.'' 
    NERC, Electric Reliability Panel, ``Reliable Power: Renewing the 
    North American Electric Reliability Oversight System,'' December 
    1997, at 35.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    4. Characteristic 4: Short-term Reliability. The RTO must have 
    exclusive authority for maintaining the short-term reliability of the 
    grid that it operates. (Proposed Sec. 35.34(i)(4))
        a. The RTO must have exclusive authority for receiving, 
    confirming and implementing all interchange schedules. (Proposed 
    Sec. 35.34(i)(4)(i))
    
        Historically, interchange schedules have referred to the scheduling 
    actions between adjacent control areas. These schedules could be 
    triggered by the sale or exchange of electricity or the wheeling of 
    electricity between the two control areas. The first type of action, 
    the sale or exchange of electricity between control areas, usually has 
    not been accompanied by a separate transmission transaction. Instead, 
    the transmission service was implicit in the overall transaction and, 
    therefore, its cost was not quoted separately. With the growth of 
    unbundled transmission service, triggered in part by our Order No. 888 
    requirements, bundled interchange transactions will become rarer. This 
    means that in the future, interchange schedules will generally be 
    accompanied by, and coincide with, transmission schedules.
        We are proposing that an RTO ``must receive and evaluate all 
    requests for transmission service under its own FERC approved tariff.'' 
    211 If the RTO operates a control area, this implies that 
    the RTO will also be receiving, confirming and implementing interchange 
    schedules. Therefore, the three actions should go hand-in-hand for an 
    RTO that operates a control area.
    
    [[Page 31420]]
    
    However, this may not be the case for RTOs that do not operate control 
    areas. As we stated in our Midwest ISO order, our basic concern is that 
    non-RTO control area operators who are also competitors in power 
    markets may be ``able to know their competitors' schedules or 
    transactions* * *'' 212 If this is true, such knowledge 
    would give the control area operators an unfair competitive advantage. 
    The Commission directed the ISO to monitor for this potential problem 
    and report to us immediately if the problem arises. We recognize, 
    however, that it may be difficult to detect this discrimination. In 
    addition to our current code of conduct standards, are there any 
    actions that the Commission should require to reduce the likelihood of 
    this problem that do not require the consolidation of all existing 
    control areas within the region? Is it feasible for a non-RTO control 
    area operator, operating within an RTO region, to perform its functions 
    without having access to commercially sensitive information involving 
    its competitors? For example, could an RTO provide control area 
    operators with information about scheduled net interchanges between 
    control areas without disclosing the individual transactions making up 
    the new interchanges? 213
    
        \211\ See the discussion of Function 1 (Tariff Administration 
    and Design), infra.
        \212\ See Midwest ISO, 84 FERC at 62,154-55.
        \213\ See Id. at 62,160.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        b. The RTO must have the right to order redispatch of any 
    generator connected to transmission facilities it operates if 
    necessary for the reliable operation of these facilities. (Proposed 
    Sec. 35.34(i)(4)(ii))
    
        As we have stated before, the dividing line ``between transmission 
    control and generation control is not always clear because both sets of 
    functions are ultimately required for reliable operation of the overall 
    system.'' 214 The entity that controls the transmission 
    system must have some degree of control over some 
    generation.215 In general, we do not think that this 
    authority should extend to initial unit commitment and dispatch 
    decisions of generators. However, the Commission believes that it is 
    necessary and appropriate that the RTO have authority to order 
    redispatch of any generating unit when necessary for the reliability of 
    the grid.
    
        \214\ Id. at 62,151.
        \215\ This seems to be generally recognized in the industry. For 
    example, the participants in the Midwest ISO proposed that the ISO 
    ``will possess authority over generation to the extent that 
    generation affects transmission.'' See ER98-1438-000, Applicants' 
    Response at 3.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        c. When the RTO operates transmission facilities owned by other 
    entities, the RTO must have authority to approve and disapprove all 
    requests for scheduled outages of transmission facilities to ensure 
    that the outages can be accommodated within established reliability 
    standards. (Proposed Sec. 35.34(i)(4)(iii))
    
        Control over transmission maintenance is a necessary RTO function 
    because planned and unplanned outages of individual transmission 
    facilities affect the overall transfer capability of the grid. If a 
    facility is removed from service for any reason, the power flows on all 
    regional facilities are affected. These shifting power flows may cause 
    other facilities to become overloaded, and so adversely affect system 
    reliability. The availability or unavailability of specific 
    transmission facilities can also have major effects on electricity 
    market prices.216
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \216\ See ``Staff Report to the FERC on the Causes of Wholesale 
    Electric Pricing Abnormalities in the Midwest During June 1998,'' 
    September 22, 1998, at 4-3.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Under this proposed requirement, the RTO would determine whether 
    the proposed maintenance of transmission facilities could be 
    accommodated within established state, regional and national 
    reliability standards. The RTO's regional perspective will allow it to 
    coordinate individual maintenance schedules with each other as well as 
    with expected seasonal system demand variations. Since the RTO will 
    have access to extensive information, it will see the ``big picture'' 
    and be able to make more accurate assessments of the reliability effect 
    of proposed maintenance schedules than individual, sub-regional 
    transmission owners.
        If the RTO is a transmission company that owns and operates 
    transmission facilities, these assessments would be an internal company 
    matter. If the RTO is an ISO, it would need to review transmission 
    requests made by various transmission owners (TOs) of its 
    region.217 In this latter case, we would expect the RTO to: 
    receive requests for authorization of preferred maintenance outage 
    schedules; review and test these schedules against reliability 
    criteria; approve specific requests for scheduled outages; require 
    changes to maintenance schedules when they fail to meet reliability 
    standards; and update and publish maintenance schedules on a regular 
    basis.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \217\ Since some of these transmission owners may also own 
    generation, they may have an incentive to schedule transmission 
    maintenance at times that would increase the prices received from 
    their power sales. A transmission company, not affiliated with any 
    generators, would not have these same incentives.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission requests commenters to address a number of questions 
    related to this proposed requirement. Does it cede too much or too 
    little authority to the RTO? If the RTO requires a transmission owner 
    to reschedule its planned maintenance, should the transmission owner be 
    compensated for any costs created by the required rescheduling? Would 
    it be feasible to create a market mechanism to induce transmission 
    owners to plan their maintenance so as to minimize reliability effects? 
    Should an RTO that is an ISO have any authority to require rescheduling 
    of maintenance if it anticipates that the planned maintenance schedule 
    will adversely affect power markets? If the RTO is a transco, can it 
    manipulate its transmission maintenance schedules in a manner that 
    harms competition?
        The proposed requirement does not give the RTO any authority over 
    proposed generation maintenance schedules. However, in our order 
    approving the Midwest ISO, we observed that ``the dividing line between 
    transmission control and generation control is not always clear because 
    both sets of functions are ultimately required for reliable operation 
    of the overall system.'' 218 Should the RTO have some 
    authority over generation maintenance schedules? If so, how much 
    authority should it have?
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \218\ Midwest ISO, 84 FERC at 62,180.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We also anticipate that the RTO will need to establish performance 
    standards for transmission facilities under its direct or contractual 
    control. Such standards could take the form of targets for planned and 
    unplanned outages. The rationale for this requirement is that two 
    transmission owners should not receive equal compensation if one owner 
    operates a reliable transmission facility while the other operates an 
    unreliable facility. For RTOs that are transcos, we would anticipate 
    that such quality standards would be implicit or explicit in any 
    performance based regulatory proposal. 219/ Is it possible 
    for a non-profit ISO to establish similar incentive schemes for the 
    transmission owners whose facilities it operates?
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \219\ We note that the National Grid Company in England and 
    Wales reports annually on quality of service in certain dimensions 
    (systems availability, interconnector availability, system security 
    and quality of supply) to the Director General of Electricity 
    Supply. See National Grid Company ``Report of the Director General 
    of Electricity Supply, Financial Year 1997-98.'' A copy of this 
    report will be placed in the public record.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Facility ratings. It is widely recognized that reliable operation 
    of the transmission system in the short-term requires both continuous 
    monitoring of equipment availability and loading, and actions to 
    maintain loading levels within the established operating ranges
    
    [[Page 31421]]
    
    and equipment ratings. If a transmission line or other facility becomes 
    overloaded or experiences a forced outage, the short-term reliability 
    of the power system may be threatened. Therefore, we anticipate that 
    the RTO will need to monitor equipment availability and loading so that 
    it can determine which control actions or redispatch options are 
    necessary. The options open to the RTO for ensuring short-term 
    reliability, such as direct control of transmission facilities, 
    initiating transmission loading relief procedures or pursuing 
    redispatch options and bids, are discussed in other sections.
        To determine whether existing or scheduled power flows will 
    threaten short-term system reliability, flow levels must be compared to 
    ratings established in power flow reliability studies. The entity that 
    establishes these ratings and operating ranges will have a major 
    influence on the reliable operation of the power system. Its 
    determinations will not only affect system reliability but also ATC. 
    The Commission believes that RTOs are best situated to establish 
    ratings and operating ranges for two reasons. First, they will have the 
    most complete information about expected and real-time operating 
    conditions. Second, RTOs will be trusted since they will be independent 
    in two ways: they will not have any economic interests in electricity 
    market outcomes and they will not be owned or controlled by any market 
    participants.
        The Commission recognizes that an RTO that is an ISO may initially 
    need to rely upon existing values for equipment ratings and operating 
    ranges so as not to disrupt reliable system operation. The RTO will 
    then have the ongoing task of validating and updating these existing 
    values, focusing initially on those identified as critical to the 
    development of a competitive electricity market.
        The Commission understands that transmission owners may be 
    concerned that changes in existing equipment ratings may lead to 
    problems of equipment safety and possible damage. These concerns could 
    trigger disputes over the values established by the RTO. We propose 
    that if there is a dispute over values established for equipment 
    ratings, the RTO values will prevail until the outcome of the dispute 
    resolution process. It is the intent of the Commission to promote RTOs 
    that have the expertise and personnel capable of determining both 
    equipment ratings and operating ranges necessary to maintain system 
    reliability. In addition, since RTOs will be independent of all 
    stakeholders in the electricity market, they will not have an incentive 
    to distort the operation of electricity markets by manipulating 
    equipment ratings and reliability assumptions. And most significantly, 
    since the RTO is ultimately responsible for system reliability, it will 
    be careful not to harm system equipment. Therefore, to avoid an impasse 
    over equipment ratings that are determined by one market participant 
    and contested by a second, we believe that the RTO's values should 
    prevail when there is disagreement, until resolution is reached through 
    an ADR process approved by the Commission.220
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \220\ This is the same policy that we adopted in approving the 
    Midwest ISO. See Midwest ISO, 84 FERC at 62,165-66.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission asks commenters to address the following issues. 
    Given that an RTO has responsibility for system reliability, what 
    should be the extent of its liability for its actions? Would this 
    differ depending on whether the RTO owns the facilities?
    
        d. If the RTO operates under reliability standards established 
    by another entity (e.g., a regional reliability council), the RTO 
    must report to the Commission if these standards hinder it from 
    providing reliable, non-discriminatory and efficiently priced 
    transmission service. (Proposed Sec. 35.30(i)(4)(iv))
    
        RTOs may be new organizations. However, they will be sharing some 
    of their responsibilities with existing organizations. For example, the 
    New England ISO shares its responsibilities with the NEPOOL 
    RTG.221 The New York ISO shares its reliability 
    responsibilities with the New York State Reliability Council. We 
    anticipate that, in the near future, RTOs will be implementing 
    reliability standards that are established by a separate regional 
    reliability council.222 We believe this is necessary to 
    maintain the reliable operation of the grid, but it also raises 
    concerns because almost every reliability standard will have a 
    commercial consequence, and regional or sub-regional reliability groups 
    may not be as independent of market participants as RTOs.223 
    As a consequence, an RTO could be required to implement a reliability 
    standard that may favor the commercial interests of certain types of 
    market participants when an equally effective, but more commercially 
    neutral, variant of the standard might be feasible. Therefore, it is 
    important that the RTO notify us immediately if implementation of 
    externally established reliability standards will prevent it from 
    meeting its obligation to provide reliable, non-discriminatory 
    transmission service.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \221\ Commissioner Malachowski, representing the New England 
    Conference of Public Utility Commissions (NECPUC), stated that the 
    current sharing of power between the New England ISO and NEPOOL is 
    unsatisfactory. He said that the New England commissions believe 
    that more decision making authority must be transferred to the ISO. 
    As a specific example, the mentioned the need for the ISO to have 
    more direct authority over market design. RTO Conference 
    (Washington, D.C.), transcript at 123.
        \222\ In Order 888, we required that any ISO should ``comply 
    with their applicable standards set by NERC and the regional 
    reliability council.'' (ISO Principle No. 4)
        \223\ See Central Hudson, 83 FERC at 62,411 for a discussion of 
    our concerns about the relationship between the New York ISO and the 
    New York State Reliability Council. In this instance, we were 
    willing to accept the fact that the NYSRC will establish rules that 
    the ISO would implement because any new rule or revisions to 
    existing rules would be ``subject to immediate suspension by the 
    NYSRC if requested to do so by the New York ISO.'' Id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Minimum Functions
    
    1. Function 1: Tariff Administration and Design. The RTO must 
    administer its own transmission tariff and employ a transmission 
    pricing system that will promote efficient use and expansion of 
    transmission and generation facilities. (Proposed Sec. 35.30(j)(1))
        The pro forma open access transmission tariff that accompanied 
    Order No. 888's functional unbundling is based on a traditional 
    approach to transmission service: it relies on embedded cost 
    ratemaking, contract path scheduling and physical rights to service. We 
    recognized that it did not break new ground on transmission pricing 
    because it was based ``on the practices and procedures'' that were 
    traditionally used by public utilities that owned transmission 
    facilities. Instead, the focus of the pro forma tariff is on the non-
    price terms and conditions of transmission service needed to get non-
    discriminatory transmission service. Our intent was to ``initiate open 
    access'' for individual transmission providers. We stated that our 
    issuance of the pro forma tariff was ``* * * not intended to signal a 
    preference for contract path/embedded cost pricing for the future.'' 
    224 In the Capacity Reservation Tariff (CRT) NOPR that was 
    issued at the same time, we emphasized that: ``* * * the Commission is 
    not committed to traditional tariff design.'' 225 Since the 
    issuance of Order No. 888, the Commission has encouraged transmission 
    providers to come forward with other open access transmission tariffs 
    that they believe have pricing
    
    [[Page 31422]]
    
    provisions that are equal or superior to the mandated tariff that was 
    part of the Order No. 888 initiative.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \224\ Order No. 888, FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,666-67.
        \225\ CRT NOPR, FERC Statutes and Regulations at 33,228 (1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        To date, the most significant innovations in transmission access 
    and pricing have been brought to us by ISOs. This is not surprising. 
    Given the interconnectedness of the grid, it is necessary to introduce 
    regional pricing innovations through some kind of regional 
    organization. This cannot be done by individual transmission providers 
    acting alone. We anticipated that regional organizations would be the 
    likely innovators in our Transmission Pricing Policy Statement. Among 
    the innovations that have been proposed since the issuance of Order No. 
    888 are: locational pricing; fixed transmission rights (FTRs) and 
    transmission congestion contracts (TCCs) that give defined financial 
    rights to grid users (i.e., financial rather than physical rights to 
    the grid); and explicit market-based pricing of congestion and 
    ancillary services.226 In almost every instance, we have 
    approved these proposals because they offer the promise of promoting 
    overall operating efficiency and encouraging fair, open and competitive 
    energy markets.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \226\ See, e.g., Pacific Gas & Electric, 81 FERC para. 61,122 
    (1997), Central Hudson, 83 FERC para. 61,352 (1998), NEPOOL, 85 FERC 
    para. 61,242 (1998); PJM; 81 FERC para. 61,257 (1997).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Therefore, we take this opportunity to reaffirm the importance of 
    such reform by establishing it as an explicit obligation for qualifying 
    RTOs. The wording of this requirement is general and this is 
    intentional. The Commission believes that RTOs are in the best position 
    at this time to develop innovative transmission access and pricing 
    regimes that will promote competition and meet the needs of their 
    region. The Commission invites commenters to address whether more 
    specific guidance is required.
        In carrying out Function 1, the RTO must satisfy each standard 
    discussed below, or demonstrate that an alternative proposal is 
    consistent with or superior to satisfying the standard.
    
    a. The Regional Transmission Organization must be the only provider of 
    transmission service over the facilities under its control, and must be 
    the sole administrator of its own Commission-approved open access 
    transmission tariff. The Regional Transmission Organization must have 
    the sole authority to receive, evaluate, and approve or deny all 
    requests for transmission service. The Regional Transmission 
    Organization must have the authority to review and approve requests for 
    new interconnections.227 (Proposed Sec. 35.30(j)(1)(i))
    
        \227\ The Commission, of course, retains ultimate authority to 
    order transmission services and interconnections pursuant to the 
    FPA.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The rationale for this standard is straightforward. The RTO cannot 
    ensure nondiscriminatory transmission service to all market 
    participants unless it is the sole provider of transmission service 
    over facilities that it owns or controls. If it is to be an effective 
    ``provider'', it must be the only entity that receives, evaluates and 
    approves or denies requests for transmission service. However, it 
    cannot make informed decisions unless it has accurate and unbiased 
    information about pending transmission requests and current system 
    conditions. This, in turn, implies that in addition to being the 
    transmission service provider, the RTO must be the operator of the 
    OASIS site as well as the regional security coordinator (see the 
    discussion of function 5 and characteristic 3).
        An organization like an independent scheduling administrator that 
    simply monitors the scheduling decisions of current transmission owners 
    and offers dispute resolution services in case of a dispute would not 
    qualify as an RTO. Similarly, a transmission organization that offers 
    service under another entity's tariff would not meet this standard.
        An RTO's obligation to provide nondiscriminatory transmission 
    service is not limited just to existing users. It is important that the 
    RTO ensures nondiscriminatory access to transmission service for new 
    entrants such as new generators. This requires that the RTO, rather 
    than existing transmission owners, have the authority to review and 
    approve requests for interconnections. The Commission believes that the 
    RTO cannot be an effective provider of transmission service if it lacks 
    the authority to ensure that new customers are interconnected to the 
    grid. This standard should be relatively easy to implement for an RTO 
    that owns transmission facilities. However, it may be more difficult 
    for an RTO that does not own transmission facilities because actual 
    physical construction of the interconnection facilities will usually be 
    made by an existing transmission owner who may also be a competitor of 
    the new generator. Therefore, the Commission invites comments on how 
    this standard can be made effective for RTOs that are ISOs. Are there 
    lessons to be learned from the experience of qualifying facilities 
    (QFs) under PURPA in getting interconnections to the grid that would be 
    applicable to ISOs? Should this standard be expanded to give the RTO 
    the authority to review and approve all new interconnections (e.g., to 
    connect new generators, to improve reliability, to increase trading 
    opportunities with neighboring regions) or all transmission investments 
    above some threshold dollar amount?
    
    b. The RTO tariff must not result in transmission customers paying 
    multiple access charges to recover capital costs over facilities that 
    it controls (i.e., no pancaking of transmission access charges). 
    (Proposed Sec. 35.34(j)(1)(ii))
    
        The elimination of transmission rate pancaking for large regions is 
    a central goal of the Commission's RTO policy. Therefore, the offering 
    of non-pancaked transmission access charges is a requirement for a 
    conforming RTO. In the existing world of many individual transmission 
    service providers, transmission customers have generally been required 
    to pay an access charge to each transmission provider along the 
    contract path (and pay nothing to providers off the contract path). 
    This is a form of distance-based transmission pricing, but the charge 
    is a function of corporate boundaries crossed on the contract path 
    rather than distance traveled on actual flow paths. Such pancaked 
    transmission charges have led to multiple transmission charges across 
    several transmission systems and make it difficult to create region-
    wide power markets. Competition is clearly enhanced when customers are 
    able to access larger numbers of generators over a wide geographic 
    region when they pay a single transmission access charge. In Order No. 
    888, we required tight power pools and holding companies to offer a 
    system-wide tariff with non-pancaked rates.228 To date, non-
    pancaked transmission access charges have been a feature of all five 
    ISOs that we have approved. In this NOPR, we are proposing to extend 
    that requirement to RTOs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \228\Order No. 888, FERC Stats. & Regs. at 31,727-29, 31,731.
    
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [[Page 31423]]
    
        Would the requirement for a tariff with non-pancaked rates make the 
    voluntary formation of RTOs more difficult because it might result in 
    the potential for sudden and unacceptable transmission rate charges? Is 
    the severity of any such problem related to the scope and regional 
    configuration of the proposed RTO? Does the use of so-called license 
    plate design allow the RTO to meet this requirement without cost 
    shifting? Would the provision for a reasonable transition period help?
        Waiving of access charges. While the Commission wishes to encourage 
    more efficient intra-regional trade, it also would like to encourage 
    inter-regional trade. Boundaries are always a potential impediment to 
    trade, whether between states, RTOs or countries. Therefore, we 
    encourage RTOs to negotiate the mutual waiving of transmission access 
    charges to increase the size of effective trading areas. In the Midwest 
    ISO proceeding, we were told that this was difficult to 
    implement.229 Therefore, commenters are requested to 
    recommend actions that the Commission could take to facilitate 
    reciprocal waiving of access charges. Even if there is mutual waiving 
    of access charges, are there other pricing impediments to inter-
    regional trade (e.g., differences in scheduling and curtailment 
    conventions between regions) that are likely to impede trade?
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \229\ See Response of Midwest ISO Participants, May 1, 1998, at 
    11-13.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    2. Function 2: Congestion Management. The RTO must ensure the 
    development and operation of market mechanisms to manage transmission 
    congestion. (Proposed Sec. 35.34(j)(2)).
        In carrying out Function 2, the RTO must satisfy each standard 
    discussed below, or demonstrate that an alternative proposal is 
    consistent with or superior to satisfying the standard.
    
    a. The market mechanisms must accommodate broad participation by all 
    market participants, and must provide all transmission customers with 
    efficient price signals regarding the consequences of their 
    transmission usage decisions. The RTO must either operate such markets 
    itself or ensure that the task is performed by another entity that is 
    not affiliated with any market participant. (Proposed 
    Sec. 35.34(j)(2)(i))
    
        As we stated in our recent order addressing NERC's transmission 
    loading relief (TLR) procedures, the traditional approaches to 
    congestion management may no longer be acceptable in a competitive, 
    vertically de-integrated industry.230 For example, the use 
    of administrative curtailment procedures has important economic 
    consequences for market participants, yet such procedures are usually 
    invoked without regard to the relative value of transactions that are 
    curtailed. This can lead to a considerable disruption of power markets 
    and can be financially damaging for market participants. The Commission 
    has concluded that efficient congestion management requires a greater 
    reliance on market mechanisms.231 Recent experience suggests 
    that only a large regional organization like an RTO will be able to 
    create a workable and effective congestion management 
    market.232
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \230\ See NERC, 85 FERC at 62,364.
        \231\ Id.
        \232\ The recent experience of Commonwealth Edison suggests that 
    redispatch markets operated by individual utilities will not be able 
    to elicit an adequate response by generators. After six months of an 
    experimental program, Commonwealth concluded that it is ``difficult 
    for one transmission owner to identify and implement redispatch'' 
    when the physical limitations and cost effective options for relief 
    are on other transmission systems. According to Commonwealth, the 
    only viable solution would be for the redispatch market to be 
    operated by a regional transmission system operator. See 
    Commonwealth Edison, Interim Report on Non-Firm Redispatch, Docket 
    No. ER98-2279, December 17, 1998, at 4 and 10.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As we noted in our order approving the PJM ISO, markets that are 
    based on locational marginal pricing and financial rights for firm 
    transmission service provide a sound framework for efficient congestion 
    management.233 However, just as we do not intend to mandate 
    a single corporate form for RTOs, we will not require one specific 
    market approach to congestion management. It is our intent to give RTOs 
    considerable flexibility in experimenting with different market 
    approaches to managing congestion. However, we believe that a workable 
    market approach to congestion management should generally establish 
    clear and tradeable rights for transmission usage, promote efficient 
    regional dispatch, support the emergence of secondary markets for 
    transmission rights, and provide market participants with the 
    opportunity to hedge locational differences in energy prices.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \233\ See, e.g., PJM, FERC 62,252-53.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A market approach to congestion management should lead to more 
    efficient transmission prices. As we explained in our Transmission 
    Pricing Policy Statement, an efficient pricing policy must meet certain 
    objectives.234 Of the four objectives set forth in the 
    Policy Statement, two are particularly relevant for congestion 
    management. First, the generators that are dispatched in the presence 
    of transmission constraints should be those that can serve system loads 
    at least cost, given the constraints. Second, given that the demand for 
    transmission services during periods of congestion exceeds the system's 
    ability to supply them, the limited transmission capacity should be 
    used by market participants that value that use most highly.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \234\ Transmission Pricing Policy Statement, FERC Stats. & Regs. 
    at 31,140-44.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In designing market mechanisms for congestion management, the 
    Commission recognizes that it is important to consider the time frame 
    in which decisions must be made and actions must be taken. It is the 
    nature of electric systems that operating conditions, including those 
    that lead to the presence or absence of congestion, are constantly 
    changing. Thus, to manage congestion efficiently while ensuring safety 
    and reliability, system operators must be able to take decisive action 
    quickly.
        One possible implication of this need for quick, decisive action is 
    that markets that directly support congestion management may have to be 
    subject to some coordination by the RTO. For example, a congestion 
    market that is not coordinated by the RTO might require transmission 
    customers to negotiate individually with generators to pre-arrange an 
    alternative dispatch that would allow the transmission customer's 
    transaction to proceed (or to be efficiently altered) if and when 
    congestion arises. However, because congestion can occur suddenly and 
    unexpectedly, time may not permit the operator to (1) identify 
    impending transmission constraints, (2) inform customers whose 
    transactions are affected, (3) allow customers to contact generators, 
    and (4) receive instructions from customers as to what actions they 
    wish the operator to take with respect to their pending transactions. 
    We have expressed concerns that such a process may be unwieldy and even 
    unworkable in the limited time in which operators must 
    act.235 Although the process could be simplified by 
    completing some of these activities in advance, such simplifications 
    may come at the cost of eliminating some potentially efficient options.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \235\ We expressed similar concerns in our order authorizing the 
    formation of the Midwest ISO. See Midwest ISO, 84 FERC at 62,165-66. 
    Nevertheless, we opted to allow the Midwest ISO to go forward with 
    its proposal in order to gain actual operating experience.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission invites comments on our requirement that RTOs must 
    be responsible for managing congestion with a market mechanism. Can
    
    [[Page 31424]]
    
    decentralized markets for congestion management be made to work 
    effectively and quickly? Can the RTO's role be limited to that of a 
    facilitator that simply brings together market participants for the 
    purpose of engaging in bilateral transactions to relieve congestion? If 
    not, will these markets require centralized operation by the RTO or 
    some other independent entity? How can an RTO ensure that enough 
    generators will participate in the congestion management market to make 
    possible a least-cost dispatch? Are there any special considerations in 
    evaluating market power in a congestion market operated or facilitated 
    by an RTO?
        We propose that the congestion management function need not 
    necessarily be in place on the first day of RTO operation, and propose 
    to allow up to one year after start-up for this function to be 
    implemented. We recognize that the new approaches to congestion 
    management called for by newly competitive markets may take additional 
    time to work out. We seek comment on whether such an additional 
    implementation time period is warranted, and whether one year is an 
    appropriate additional time period.
    3. Function 3: Parallel Path Flow. The RTO must develop and implement 
    procedures to address parallel path flow issues within its region and 
    with other regions. The RTO must satisfy this requirement with respect 
    to coordination with other regions no later than three years after it 
    commences initial operation. (Proposed Sec. 35.34(j)(3))
        Many power sales and transmission service contracts are written 
    under the assumption that the power delivered will flow on a particular 
    contract path. This relatively straightforward and easy to administer 
    ``contract path'' approach assumes that it is possible to determine and 
    fix the path through the transmission network along which power will 
    flow from source to sink. However, this assumption often does not 
    accurately reflect what actually occurs because the scheduled power 
    transfer will flow across the interconnected electrical path between 
    source and destination according to laws of physics, which means that 
    some power may flow over the lines of adjoining transmission systems. 
    This power flow effect is commonly referred to as ``parallel path 
    flow'' or ``loop flow.''
        Parallel path flows have the potential to create, and have in the 
    past created, disputes among transmission system owners. There are 
    efficiency and economic equity issues involved when a scheduled 
    transaction in fact causes power flows over the facilities of an entity 
    that is not compensated, or when the costs of mitigating parallel flows 
    are allocated to various transmission owners.236 There are 
    also reliability issues involved when parallel path flows overload a 
    transmission line, and decisions must be made as to what actions to 
    take, and who should bear responsibility for taking necessary steps to 
    unload that line.237 The interdependent nature of 
    electricity flow implies that one party's ability to transmit energy 
    will depend upon the actions of others, and, for scheduling and pricing 
    purposes, the capacity of the entire network and not just individual 
    systems is the most important factor.238
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \236\ See Indiana Michigan Power Company and Ohio Power Company, 
    64 FERC para. 61,184 (1993) (Indiana Michigan) (complaint that 95% 
    of a power sale flowed over transmission system that was not 
    compensated); Southern California Edison Company, et al., 73 FERC 
    para. 61,219 (1995) (Southern California) (Commission approved plan 
    for mitigating loop flows within the WSSC).
        \237\ See NERC, 85 FERC para. 61,353 (1998).
        \238\ The Order No. 888 pro forma open access tariff does not 
    explicitly recognize the effect of parallel path/loop flow.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission has previously expressed its view that the issues 
    surrounding parallel path flow are best resolved by mutual arrangements 
    between the utilities that have chosen to interconnect.239 
    More recently, the Commission directed all public utilities in the 
    Eastern Interconnection to file an interim redispatch plan if they are 
    not currently participating in a regional congestion management program 
    through a power pool.240
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \239\ See Indiana Michigan, 64 FERC at 62,554.
        \240\ NERC, 85 FERC at 62,363-64.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission believes that the formation of RTOs, with their 
    widened geographic scope of transmission scheduling and expanded 
    coverage of uniform transmission pricing structures provides an 
    opportunity to ``internalize'' most, if not all, of the effect of 
    parallel path/loop flow in their scheduling and pricing processes 
    within a region. In particular, we believe that RTO access to region-
    wide information on network conditions and power transactions, coupled 
    with efficient congestion management and well specified physical and 
    financial transmission usage rights, could help RTOs, as regional grid 
    managers, in taking preemptive action against curtailment incidents 
    that would otherwise be induced by parallel path/loop flow loading of 
    critical transmission facilities. We anticipate that parallel path/loop 
    flow related disputes will diminish to the extent that RTOs are 
    relatively large and able to implement more realistic scheduling and 
    pricing procedures that subsume the effect of parallel path/loop flow 
    within their regions.
        We propose that measures to address parallel path flow may not 
    necessarily be in place on the first day of RTO operation, and propose 
    to allow up to three years after start-up for this function to be 
    implemented. We seek comment on whether such an additional 
    implementation time period is warranted, and whether three years is an 
    appropriate additional time period.
    4. Function 4: Ancillary Services. An RTO must serve as the supplier of 
    last resort of all ancillary services required by Order No. 888, FERC 
    Stats. & Regs. para.31,038 (Final Rule on Open Access and Stranded 
    Costs), and subsequent orders. (Proposed Sec. 35.34(j)(4))
        In carrying out Function 4, the RTO must satisfy each standard 
    discussed below, or demonstrate that an alternative proposal is 
    consistent with or superior to satisfying the standard.
    
    a. All market participants must have the option of self-supplying or 
    acquiring ancillary services from third parties subject to any general 
    restrictions imposed by the Commissions's ancillary services 
    regulations in Order No. 888, FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 31,038 (Final 
    Rule on Open Access and Stranded Costs), and subsequent orders. 
    (Proposed Sec. 35.34(j)(4)(i))
    
        An RTO is a transmission provider and therefore is subject to the 
    general requirements established by the Commission for the provision of 
    ancillary services under Order Nos. 888 and 889 and succeeding orders. 
    Specifically, these require that the transmission provider must provide 
    or cause to be provided six ancillary services on an unbundled 
    basis.241 Of the six ancillary services, a transmission 
    customer is obligated to purchase two of the services from the 
    transmission provider (the RTO)--scheduling, system control and 
    dispatch service and reactive supply and voltage control from 
    generation. For the remaining four services, a transmission customer 
    has the option of self-providing these services, either by acquiring 
    them from
    
    [[Page 31425]]
    
    a third party or providing them from the customer's own resources.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \241\ The six ancillary services are: (1) Scheduling, System 
    Control and Dispatching Service; (2) Reactive Supply and Voltage 
    Control from Generation Sources Service; (3) Regulation and 
    Frequency Response Service; (4) Energy Imbalance Service; (5) 
    Operating Reserve-Spinning Reservice; and (6) Operating Reserve-
    Supplemental Reserve Service. Order No. 888, FERC Stats. & Regs. at 
    31,706-17; Order No. 888-A, FERC Stats. & Regs. at 30,227-34.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Our rationale for imposing the ultimate supply obligation on the 
    RTO is that not all transmission customers may be equally able to self-
    supply (some own generation, others do not) and that in many 
    circumstances it may be more efficient (i.e., less costly) for the RTO 
    to provide the service for all transmission users on an aggregated 
    basis. Our rationale for allowing self-supply is that it provides a 
    possible competitive check on the RTO to ensure that it acquires the 
    services at lowest cost. In addition, the Commission believes, as a 
    matter of policy, that legal monopolies should not be granted (i.e., 
    serving as the sole provider of ancillary services) unless they are 
    natural monopolies.
        The ancillary services policies in Order Nos. 888 and 889 were 
    developed for transmission providers that were generally vertically 
    integrated utilities. There was an expectation that they would be able 
    to provide many of the generation based ancillary services from their 
    own generating resources. An RTO by definition will not own any 
    generating resources. Does this difference necessitate a different set 
    of ancillary service requirements for RTOs? Are there other ancillary 
    services, in addition to scheduling, system control and dispatch, and 
    reactive supply and voltage control from generation sources, for which 
    the self-supply option should be eliminated? Under what circumstances 
    can the RTO's obligation as the ancillary services supplier of last 
    resort be eliminated?
    
    b. The RTO must have the authority to decide the minimum required 
    amounts of each ancillary service and, if necessary, the locations at 
    which these services must be provided. All ancillary service providers 
    must be subject to direct or indirect operational control by the RTO. 
    The RTO must promote the development of competitive markets for 
    ancillary services whenever feasible. (Proposed Sec. 35.34(j)(4)(ii))
    
        This policy would, in effect, grant RTOs the exclusive right, 
    subject to national and regional reliability norms, to determine the 
    quantities and, in some instances, the locations at which certain 
    ancillary services must be provided. It would also require that the RTO 
    be able to exercise complete operational control, either directly or 
    indirectly, over any supplier of ancillary services.
        Direct control (sometimes referred to as hands-on control or actual 
    physical operation) would require, for example, that RTO employees 
    ``push the button'' or that RTO computers send instructions directly to 
    generating units or other facilities to take certain physical actions. 
    Automatic generation control (AGC) might be one example of direct 
    control. If the RTO has direct control, it would have authority, by 
    contract or other means, to send direct electronic signals to those 
    generators who have offered, in return for a payment, to increase or 
    decrease the output of their units in response to the RTO's signals. 
    Indirect control (sometimes referred to as functional control, directed 
    control or contractual control) requires that the RTO send instructions 
    to the owner of the facility who then, in turn, performs the actual 
    physical actions to implement these instructions. Indirect control 
    usually requires that there be a contractual agreement between the RTO 
    and the owner of the facilities that has agreed to provide ancillary 
    services.
        The Commission requests commenters to address whether these are 
    minimum requirements needed to ensure that the RTO can satisfy its 
    obligation to maintain targeted levels of reliability. Would it be 
    feasible for the RTO to maintain reliability with less authority?
        In our Midwest ISO order, we stated that the ISO ``* * * should use 
    competitive procurement for all services needed to operate the 
    system.'' 242 This general requirement would apply to 
    ancillary services since they are clearly needed to operate a reliable 
    bulk power system. One prerequisite for competitive procurement is a 
    competitive market.243 The Commission would anticipate that 
    many of the generation-based ancillary services (e.g., balancing and 
    reserves) could be acquired in short-term markets that would operate in 
    parallel to basic energy markets.244 This has been the 
    approach taken by most of the ISOs that we have approved and we see no 
    reason why this would be different for transcos or other types of RTO 
    entities. Other services such as black start capability and voltage 
    support are probably best acquired in long-term markets where potential 
    suppliers would compete for the right to enter into a long-term 
    contract with the RTO. Apart from establishing the general requirement 
    to use competitive markets, the Commission believes that it is best to 
    leave many of the detailed market design questions to the individual 
    RTOs with case-by-case review by us.245 As we noted earlier, 
    we intend to permit regional flexibility and encourage experimentation. 
    Such experimentation would be discouraged if we issued regulations that 
    are too detailed.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \242\ See Midwest ISO, 84 FERC para. 61,231 at 62,164 (1998).
        \243\ However, we recognize that the existence of a competitive 
    supply market for ancillary services is no guarantee that the RTO 
    will automatically buy efficiently. Therefore, since the RTO may be 
    the de facto buyer of many of these services, the Commission is 
    receptive to performance-based regulatory proposals that would give 
    RTOs explicit incentives to be efficient buyers of ancillary 
    services. See section III.F.
        \244\ See Eric Hirst and Brendan Kirby, Unbundling Generation 
    and Transmission Services for Competitive Electricity Markets, a 
    report prepared for the National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI 
    98-05), January 1998.
        \245\ These would include design issues such as: Are ancillary 
    service bids received before, after or at the same time as energy 
    market bids? Do ancillary service markets clear simultaneously or 
    sequentially? Must the RTO publicly announce the amount of each 
    ancillary service that it needs prior to bidding? What do generators 
    bid (capacity, energy or both)? If there are multiple bid 
    components, are they evaluated together or separately? Should the 
    RTO acquire ancillary services from outside its region? These are 
    some of the design issues that have arisen in the operation of 
    ancillary markets by the California ISO. We expect that there will 
    be other design issues as other ancillary market proposals are 
    presented to us.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission believes that, whenever it is economically feasible, 
    it is important for the RTO to provide accurate price signals that 
    reflect the costs of supplying ancillary services to particular 
    customers. Accurate price signals are especially important because some 
    of the RTO's customers may be competing against each other in other 
    power sales markets. It is important that the RTO's actions not distort 
    regional power market competition by charging potential competitors 
    inaccurate prices for ancillary services that they purchase from the 
    RTO.
    
    c. The RTO must ensure that its transmission customers have access to a 
    real-time balancing market. The RTO must either develop and operate 
    such markets itself or ensure that this task is performed by another 
    entity that is not affiliated with any market participant. (Proposed 
    Sec. 35.34(j)(4)(iii))
    
        Real-time balancing refers to the moment-to-moment matching of 
    loads and generation on a system-wide basis. It is a function that 
    control area operators must perform to maintain frequency at 60 hz. 
    Real-time balancing is usually achieved through the direct control of 
    select generators (and, in some cases, loads) who increase or decrease 
    their output (or consumption in the case of loads) in response to 
    instructions from the system operator. Over the last two years, the 
    Commission has seen an increasing use by system operators of market 
    mechanisms that rely on bids from generators to achieve
    
    [[Page 31426]]
    
    overall, real-time balancing.246 Since system-wide balancing 
    is a critical element of reliable short-term grid operation, we will 
    require that it be a responsibility of the RTO. The Commission would 
    expect that an RTO will perform the overall system balancing function 
    directly if it operates a control area or indirectly if it supervises 
    the operation of sub-regional control areas.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \246\ See Pacific Gas & Electric, 81 FERC para. 61,122 (1997), 
    Central Hudson, 83 FERC para. 61,352 (1998), NEPOOL, 85 FERC para. 
    61,242 (1998); PJM, 81 FERC para. 61,257 (1997).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A separate, but related, issue is balancing by individual grid 
    users. The fact that the overall system must be in balance to maintain 
    frequency does not necessarily require that there be a moment-to-moment 
    balance between the individual loads and resources of bilateral traders 
    and load-serving entities and the schedules and actual production of 
    individual generators. Imbalances are inevitable since generators do 
    not exactly meet their schedules and loads always vary from moment-to-
    moment.
        As we noted in the Midwest ISO order, unequal access to balancing 
    options for individual customers can lead to unequal access in the 
    quality of transmission service available to different customers. This 
    could be a significant problem for RTOs that serve some customers who 
    operate control areas and other customers who do not. Under current 
    NERC regulations, control area operators have access to inadvertent 
    energy accounts so they can pay back imbalances in kind and thereby 
    avoid any penalties.247 In contrast, non-control area 
    transmission customers do not have access to such accounts. Instead, 
    under the pro forma tariff, load serving entities are subject to a 
    deadband and then penalties if the magnitude of their imbalances fall 
    outside the deadband. Our concern, as we stated in our Midwest ISO 
    order, is that ``nondiscriminatory access would suffer'' under such a 
    system.248 Therefore, the Commission proposes to require 
    that RTOs operate a real-time balancing market that would be available 
    to all transmission customers, or ensure that this task is performed by 
    another entity not affiliated with market participants.249
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \247\ NERC Operating Manual, at P1-9.
        \248\ Midwest ISO, 84 FERC at 62,155.
        \249\ We have already approved such markets for four ISOs. See 
    e.g., PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., Order Accepting In Part and 
    Rejecting In Part Proposed Revisions To Rate Schedules, September 
    16, 1998 and New England Power Pool, ``Order Conditionally Accepting 
    Market Rules and Conditionally Approving Market Based Rates, 85 FERC 
    para. 61,379 (1998). These markets generally allow all transmission 
    customers to settle their imbalances at real time energy market 
    prices. We note that participants in the Midwest ISO have issued a 
    request for proposals that could lead to the establishment of such a 
    market in their region. See Solicitation of Interest, Creation of an 
    Independent Power Exchange for the U.S. Midwest, Joint Committee for 
    the Development of a Midwest Independent Power Exchange (Feb. 5, 
    1999).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission believes that it is important to give RTOs 
    considerable discretion in how such a market would be operated. An RTO 
    may choose to operate the market itself or assign the task to another 
    entity (e.g., a for-profit exchange) that would operate the market 
    under the RTO's supervision. In addition, the Commission would expect 
    that the design of such a market will necessarily vary between RTOs 
    that operate control areas and those that do not. However, in those 
    instances where RTO does not operate a control area, the RTO must be 
    especially vigilant that transmission customers who continue to operate 
    control areas cannot use that functional responsibility to the 
    disadvantage of non-control area customers.\250\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \250\ See Midwest ISO, 84 FERC at 62,159-160.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission invites comments on the use of market mechanisms to 
    support overall system balancing and imbalances of individual 
    transmission users. Is it feasible to rely on markets to support a 
    function that is so time-sensitive? Can such markets be made to 
    function efficiently if the RTO is not a control area operator? For the 
    imbalances of individual transmission customers, should a distinction 
    be made between loads and generators? Should customers have the option 
    of paying for all imbalances in such a market or only imbalances within 
    a specified band?
    5. Function 5: OASIS and TTC and ATC. The RTO must be the single OASIS 
    site administrator for all transmission facilities under its control 
    and independently calculate TTC and ATC. (Proposed Sec. 35.34(j)(5))
        The operation of an OASIS site has many dimensions. For example, it 
    includes specific practices and terminology. In response to a consensus 
    request from the industry, we recently issued a NOPR that proposes to 
    standardize various practices and terms. The focus of that NOPR is on 
    standardization of protocols for posting, naming and responding to 
    posted information.251 Apart from these practices, the 
    central and probably most controversial aspect of OASIS operation is 
    the calculation and posting of ATC numbers. The calculation of ATC 
    depends, in turn, on the calculation of TTC.252 These 
    calculations are different from business practices in that the focus is 
    on content rather than procedures and practices. There is widespread 
    dissatisfaction with the reliability of posted ATC numbers. The 
    Commission has received formal and informal complaints from 
    transmission customers stating that they cannot rely on posted ATC 
    numbers. Criticisms of posted ATC numbers have also been the subject of 
    a widely publicized report issued by a major industry 
    group.253 It is been alleged that transmission providers who 
    also compete in power markets against their competitors have both the 
    incentive and ability to post unreliable ATC numbers.254
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \251\ Open Access Same-Time Information System, Notice of 
    Proposed Rulemaking, FERC Statutes and Regulations para. 32,531 
    (1998).
        \252\ See section III.A.1 for definitions of these terms.
        \253\ Commercial Practices Working Group and the OASIS How 
    Working Group, ``Industry Report to the Federal Energy Regulatory 
    Commission on the Future of OASIS, October 31, 1997.
        \254\ This is discussed more fully in Section III.A.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We recognize that an individual transmission provider may post ATC 
    numbers on OASIS in good faith only to find that the projected 
    capability does not exist because of scheduling decisions taken by 
    other transmission providers elsewhere on the grid. In such 
    circumstances, transmission providers are not acting unscrupulously. 
    Instead, the problem is simply a mismatch between information flows and 
    electrical flows. Regional transmission organizations that perform ATC 
    calculations based on complete and timely information would tend to 
    eliminate this problem. This seems to be supported by fact that the 
    Commission has received very few complaints about ATC calculations made 
    by ISOs.
        The essential feature of our proposed requirement is that the RTO 
    become the administrator of a single OASIS site for all transmission 
    facilities over which it is the transmission provider. This is 
    consistent with earlier orders.255 Moreover, every ISO that 
    we have approved so far has become the OASIS site administrator for the 
    customers that it serves. However, we recognize that this generally 
    stated requirement inevitably raises questions as to the level of RTO 
    involvement in ATC calculations. An RTO could be involved in ATC 
    calculations at three general levels. At Level 1, the RTO's role would 
    be limited to receiving and posting ATC numbers received from 
    transmission owners. At Level 2, the RTO would receive raw data from 
    transmission
    
    [[Page 31427]]
    
    owners and centrally calculate ATC values. At Level 3, the RTO would 
    centrally calculate ATC values on data partially or totally developed 
    by the RTO. The proposed requirement that the RTO be the OASIS site 
    administrator is based on the expectation that the RTO will operate at 
    Level 3.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \255\ In the Primergy merger order, we required that the 
    proposed ISO should be ``responsible for calculating ATC.'' See 
    Primergy, 79 FERC para. 61,158, May 14, 1997.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The RTO must eventually operate at Level 3 to ensure that ATC 
    values are based on accurate information that is based on consistent 
    assumptions and to minimize the opportunities for conscious 
    manipulation. In general, the RTO must perform all the calculations and 
    studies necessary to develop the underlying data. When data are 
    supplied by others, the RTO must create a system for regularly 
    validating the data for accuracy and assumptions. If there is a dispute 
    over ATC values, the RTO's values should be used pending the outcome of 
    the dispute resolution process.256 The RTO must also 
    establish the operating standards (subject to regional and national 
    reliability requirements) underlying the ATC calculations.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \256\ This is the same requirement that the Commission imposed 
    on the Midwest ISO. See Midwest ISO, 84 FERC at 62,154.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    6. Function 6: Market Monitoring. The RTO must monitor markets for 
    transmission services, ancillary services and bulk power to identify 
    design flaws and market power and propose appropriate remedial actions. 
    (Proposed Sec. 35.34(j)(6))
        In carrying out Function No. 6, the RTO must satisfy each standard 
    discussed below, or demonstrate that an alternative proposal is 
    consistent with or superior to satisfying the standard.
    
        a. The RTO must monitor markets for transmission service and the 
    behavior of transmission owners, if any, to determine if their 
    actions hinder the RTO in providing reliable, efficient and 
    nondiscriminatory transmission service. (Proposed 
    Sec. 35.34(j)(6)(i))
        b. The RTO must monitor markets for ancillary services and bulk 
    power. This obligation is limited to markets that the RTO operates. 
    (Proposed Sec. 35.34(j)(6)(ii))
        c. The RTO must periodically assess how behavior in markets 
    operated by others (e.g., bilateral power sales markets and power 
    markets operated by unaffiliated power exchanges) affects RTO 
    operations and conversely how RTO operations affect the performance 
    of power markets operated by others. (Proposed 
    Sec. 35.34(j)(6)(iii))
    
        The RTO's role as market monitor. To date, the Commission has found 
    monitoring to be essential in helping to ensure non-discrimination and 
    efficiency in the provision of transmission and ancillary services; 
    encourage fair, open, and competitive energy markets; and promote 
    overall operating efficiency. 257 As we stated in the New 
    England ISO order, ``markets are likely to evolve in ways that may not 
    be totally anticipated. To ensure that the markets operate 
    competitively and efficiently, it is important that any problems 
    involving market power or market design are quickly identified so that 
    appropriate solutions can be crafted.'' 258 To date, we have 
    been willing to use ISOs, or their independent monitoring 
    organizations, as a ``first line of defense'' in detecting both market 
    power abuses and market design flaws.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \257\ Pacific Gas & Electric, 81 FERC at 61,552; PJM, 81 FERC at 
    62,282; NEPOOL, 85 FERC at 62,479-480; Midwest ISO, 84 FERC at 
    62,180-181.
        \258\ New England ISO, 85 FERC para. 62,379 at 62,479-480 
    (1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The proposed requirements are arguably based on the presumption 
    that an RTO will be a non-profit, system operator that does not own any 
    facilities. The requirements may not be appropriate for a for-profit 
    transco that owns the facilities that it operates.259 
    Therefore, a threshold question is: what should be the market 
    monitoring role, if any, of an independent, for-profit transco? Is it 
    reasonable to expect that such an RTO could be objective in its 
    assessments? If the RTO is an ISO, do its monitoring activities need to 
    be further insulated to ensure independence and objectivity? For 
    example, should monitoring be performed by one or more individuals or 
    organizations that are funded by the RTO but that have the right to 
    issue reports without the RTO's approval?
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \259\ We note that at least one entity that is contemplating the 
    creation of a for-profit transmission company has proposed that this 
    company would perform a market monitoring function. See Statement of 
    Mr. Frank Gallaher on behalf of Entergy Corporation, Regional ISO 
    Conference (New Orleans), transcript at 18.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission believes that RTOs that are ISOs have a significant 
    comparative advantage over other entities in monitoring 
    markets.260 First, RTOs have access to considerable 
    information about market conduct and performance. For example, we would 
    expect that an RTO, in the normal course of business, will develop or 
    receive information on quantities of bulk power and transmission 
    services bought and sold by different market participants, expected and 
    real time transmission system conditions, planned maintenance of both 
    generation and transmission facilities and anticipated and real time 
    patterns of load and generation. Second, RTOs will be completely 
    independent of all market participants. For these reasons, the 
    Commission believes that we and our colleagues in state commissions can 
    have great confidence in the RTO market assessments.261 Our 
    early experience with market assessments performed by the New England 
    and California ISOs has been encouraging. The assessments have been 
    comprehensive and objective even to the point of criticizing past 
    actions by the ISOs themselves.262
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \260\ See Midwest ISO, 84 FERC at 62,181.
        \261\ The early experience with market assessments in California 
    and New England seems to support this conclusion. See AES Redondo 
    Beach, et al., 85 FERC para. 61,123 at 61,462 (1998).
        \262\ See Peter Cramton and Robert Wilson, A Review of ISO New 
    England's Proposed Market Rules, Docket No. ER97-1079, September 9, 
    1998, and the California ISO Market Surveillance Committee's 
    Preliminary Report On the Operation of the Ancillary Services 
    Markets., Docket No. ER98-2843, August 19, 1998 Markets.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Despite the advantages of better information and incentives, the 
    Commission believes that it is neither fair nor feasible to impose a 
    monitoring obligation on RTOs for markets that they do not operate. Our 
    preliminary assessment is that it would be difficult for an RTO to 
    monitor a market in which it does not have information on prices, 
    bidding patterns and marginal costs. However, our experience with ISOs 
    has shown that markets for power, ancillary services and transmission 
    service are inextricably intertwined regardless of how they are 
    organized or who operates them.263 Therefore, we are 
    proposing a middle ground for monitoring regional markets not operated 
    by the RTO. The RTO's monitoring of markets operated by others will be 
    limited to assessing how behavior in these markets affects RTO markets 
    and operations and conversely how RTO markets and operations affect 
    these other markets.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \263\ See AES Redondo Beach, et al., 85 FERC para. 61,123 at 
    61,453 and 61,459-460 (1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission also recognizes that any markets, whether operated 
    by the RTO or others, will inevitably be affected by basic structural 
    characteristics such as the existing pattern of ownership and control 
    of generation and transmission facilities. Such characteristics are 
    often beyond the control of the RTO. Since our overarching goal in 
    promoting RTOs is to promote fair, open and competitive electricity 
    markets, we and our state commission colleagues need to understand how 
    these structural features affect the potential for competition. 
    Therefore, we propose to require RTOs to provide periodic assessments 
    as to the effect of existing structural conditions on the 
    competitiveness of their region's
    
    [[Page 31428]]
    
    electricity markets. Of all the industry organizations that may exist 
    in a region, we think that an RTO is best suited to make this 
    assessment because of its first hand knowledge of day-to-day grid and 
    generation operations and its independence.
        The Commission requests comments on several threshold issues 
    related to these proposed market monitoring requirements. Some argue 
    that RTOs should not be charged with any monitoring responsibilities 
    particularly with respect to market power abuses.264 They 
    argue that the antitrust laws and the Commission offer sufficient 
    protection against competitive abuses. Others have argued that RTOS are 
    somewhat akin to organized stock exchanges and that the Commission 
    should follow the SEC precedent of requiring extensive and 
    sophisticated market monitoring by all of the organized exchanges. Are 
    there features of electricity and transmission markets that argue for 
    imposing similar market monitoring responsibilities on RTOs?
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \264\ See, e.g., David B. Raskin, ISOs; The New Antitrust 
    Regulators? The Electricity Journal (April 1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        If the Commission decides to require RTOs to provide some form of 
    market monitoring, there are several other questions that arise. Should 
    the Commission rely on RTOs as the ``first line of defense'' for 
    detecting both design flaws and market power abuses? If this were our 
    approach, what would be an appropriate role for the Commission in 
    market monitoring? If the RTO is operating one or more markets (e.g., 
    ancillary services), is it reasonable to expect that it can perform an 
    objective self-assessment? Is there a difference in the market 
    monitoring that the Commission can expect from RTOs? For example, if 
    the RTO proposes to take a market position in secondary transmission 
    rights, is it plausible to expect that the RTO can perform an objective 
    assessment of this market? Since the success of retail competition will 
    often depend critically on the actions of RTOs, what should be the role 
    of state commissions in market monitoring?
        Scope of monitoring activities: design flaws. In observing the 
    experience of ISOs over the last year, we have learned that new market 
    designs almost inevitably include design flaws that become apparent 
    only after the markets begin operation.265 Often these 
    problems arise because of unexpected interactions between different 
    related markets and unanticipated incentives for buyers and sellers. 
    Electricity market restructuring in other countries has also 
    experienced the need to make many revisions to market designs and 
    rules.266 These experiences indicate that monitoring is 
    essential to ensure that the markets and structures evolve to ensure 
    just and reasonable rates to consumers. The Commission recognizes that 
    market monitoring can be expensive. We would welcome estimates of the 
    amount of money spent by ISOs to monitor markets and their assessments 
    as to whether they will need to spend more or less money in the future.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \265\ For example, the ancillary services markets in the summer 
    of 1998 in California behaved at odds with what one would expect in 
    an efficient market. The California ISO market surveillance 
    committee produced an extensive evaluation of this problem which led 
    to discussions of possible solutions.
        \266\ See, e.g., James Barker, Jr., Bernard Tenenbaum, and Fiona 
    Wolfe, ``Governance and Regulation of Power Pools and System 
    Operators: An International Comparison,'' Energy Law Journal, Volume 
    18, 1997, at 308-309.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Scope of monitoring activities: market power abuses. As we have 
    noted before, it is often difficult to predict whether certain entities 
    will have market power in the future. This is especially true in new 
    markets which operate with new participants and new transmission flow 
    patterns. In situations like this, the past is often not a very good 
    predictor of the future. As a consequence, the Commission has found 
    that in certain situations the better approach is to institute an 
    effective monitoring plan rather than to debate numerous assumptions 
    and projections that inevitably underlie competing market power 
    analyses.267 For abuses that arise from market power, should 
    the RTO's role be limited to detecting and describing the abuses? In 
    the case of localized market power (e.g., generating units that must 
    run for reliability reasons), should the RTO have the authority to take 
    corrective actions? If the market power has structural causes, what 
    role should the RTO have in developing structural solutions? Should 
    RTOs that are ISOs be required to make regular assessments as to 
    whether they have sufficient operational authority?
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \267\ Pacific Gas & Electric, 77 FERC para. 61,265 (1996). 
    NEPOOL, 85 FERC para. 61,379 (1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Sanctions and penalties. The Commission seeks comment on whether 
    RTOs should be allowed to impose penalties and sanctions. Should the 
    penalties be limited to violations of RTO rules and procedures? Should 
    the RTO be allowed to impose penalties for the exercise of market 
    power? How much discretion should the RTO have in setting penalties? 
    For example, should the RTO's penalty authority be limited to 
    collecting liquidated damages?
    
        d. The RTO must provide reports on market power abuses and 
    market design flaws to the Commission and affected regulatory 
    authorities. The reports must contain specific recommendations about 
    how observed market power abuses and market flaws can be corrected. 
    (Proposed Sec. 35.34(j)(6)(iv)).
    
        In order for regulatory agencies, interested parties and the 
    general public to benefit from monitoring activities, regular reporting 
    of findings is critical. Other than this general requirement, we do not 
    propose at this time to establish detailed standards on the format, 
    length and content of monitoring reports. We think that these decisions 
    are best left to the RTO.
        Should this reporting requirement be limited to producing reports 
    only when a specific problem is encountered? Or should RTOs be required 
    to make periodic reports that assess the state of competition and 
    transmission access even in the absence of specific problems? We note 
    that the California and New England ISOs have committed to producing 
    annual public reports. Arguably such reports give market participants 
    and others a regular opportunity to say whether they agree or disagree 
    with the RTO assessment. Also, it is conceivable that such reports 
    would be helpful to any market monitoring activities that this 
    Commission and state commissions may wish to pursue in the future.
    7. Function 7: Planning and Expansion. The RTO must be responsible for 
    planning necessary transmission additions and upgrades that will enable 
    it to provide efficient, reliable and non-discriminatory transmission 
    service and coordinate such efforts with the appropriate state 
    authorities. (Proposed Sec. 35.34(j)(7))
        In carrying out Function 7, the RTO must satisfy each standard 
    discussed below, or demonstrate that an alternative proposal is 
    consistent with or superior to satisfying the standard.
    
        a. The RTO planning and expansion process must encourage market-
    driven operating and investment actions for preventing and relieving 
    congestion. (Proposed Sec. 35.34(j)(7)(i))
    
        RTOs should be designed to promote efficient usage and efficient 
    expansion of their regional grids. The former requires efficient price 
    signals, such as congestion pricing; the latter requires control over 
    planning and expansion. Our specific proposal is that the RTO should 
    have ultimate responsibility for both transmission planning and 
    expansion within its region.268 This
    
    [[Page 31429]]
    
    requirement is motivated by the fact that investments in new 
    transmission facilities must be coordinated to ensure a least cost 
    outcome that maintains or improves existing reliability levels. In the 
    absence of a single entity with overall responsibility, there would be 
    danger that transmission investments would work at cross-purposes and 
    possibly even hurt reliability. We recognize that the RTO's 
    implementation of this general requirement will require addressing many 
    specific design issues.269 Once again, we propose to give 
    RTOs considerable flexibility in designing a planning and expansion 
    process that works best for its region. We recognize that the specific 
    features of this process must take account of and accommodate existing 
    institutions and physical characteristics of the region.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \268\ Investments in new transmission facilities might be needed 
    for a variety of reasons such as interconnecting new generation or 
    load, protecting or enhancing system reliability, improving system 
    operating efficiency and flexibility, reducing or eliminating 
    congestion and minimizing the need for ``must-run'' contracts with 
    one or more generators.
        \269\ Our experience with regional transmission groups suggests 
    that the following issues, among others, will need to be addressed: 
    Who establishes the planning criteria? Who sets the design criteria? 
    Should they be uniform across the system or vary with location? Who 
    can initiate studies for transmission investments? Who evaluates and 
    publishes different options? Who recommends which projects should be 
    built and how the costs and benefits of the project should be 
    allocated?
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Within these constraints, the Commission has a clear preference for 
    market-driven operating and investment actions for preventing and 
    relieving congestion.270 However, we understand that the 
    feasibility of obtaining market driven solutions requires satisfying 
    other prerequisites. For example, transmission prices must accurately 
    reflect existing patterns of congestion. Accurate congestion prices are 
    the link between current usage and future expansion. Therefore, we 
    place considerable emphasis on the need for RTOs to establish a system 
    of congestion management that establishes clear rights for existing and 
    new transmission facilities and price signals that reflect congestion. 
    (See section III.F) Independent governance is also a necessary 
    condition for efficient expansion. While accurate price signals can 
    signal the need for expansion, such expansion may never be achieved if 
    the RTO operates under a faulty governance system (e.g., a governance 
    system that allows market participants to block expansions that will 
    hurt their commercial interests).
    
        \270\ This is a topic that has been discussed widely within the 
    industry. See, e.g., the papers of Steven L. Walton, Indego 
    Transmission Expansion Strategy, Steven Stoft, Five Things You 
    Should Know About Grid Investment and Ray Coxe, New Paradigms for 
    Siting Transmission in Competitive Electric Markets. These papers 
    are available through the Harvard Electric Policy Group website 
    http://ksgwww.harvard.edu/hepg.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    b. The RTO's planning and expansion process must accommodate efforts by 
    state regulatory commissions to create multi-state agreements to review 
    and approve new transmission facilities. The RTO's planning and 
    expansion process must be coordinated with programs of existing 
    Regional Transmission Groups (RTGs) where necessary. (Proposed 
    Sec. 35.34(j)(7)(ii))
    
        At present, certification and siting of new transmission facilities 
    is almost always performed by a state agency, typically the public 
    utilities commission, in the state in which the facility will be 
    located.271 While there have been discussions about the need 
    for regional certification and siting since most new transmission lines 
    are integral elements of a regional grid system, such proposals have 
    met with little success.272 With the growth of RTOs, this 
    could conceivably change. The emergence of a single regional 
    transmission organization on the industry side may encourage the 
    development of regional organizations or agreements that deal with 
    transmission siting and certification on the regulatory side. The 
    Commission believes that this would be a positive development if it is 
    a voluntary decision of the affected states and replaces existing 
    state-by-state determinations that often lack a regional perspective. 
    To facilitate any voluntary actions taken by our state colleagues, we 
    will require that the RTO planning and coordination system must be able 
    to accommodate the possible future emergence of a regional regulatory 
    system.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \271\ See Ileana Elsa Garcia, State Electric Facility Siting 
    Practices, prepared for the Harvard Electric Policy Group (HEPG), 
    April 10, 1997. Available through the HEPG website at http://
    ksgwww.harvard.edu/hepg.
        \272\ See NARUC, ``Options for Jurisdiction over Transmission 
    Facility Siting,'' a resource document for the NARUC Committee on 
    Electricity, 1991 and Charles D. Gray, NARUC Assistant General 
    Counsel, Memorandum, January 1995. Available through the HEPG/
    website at http://ksgwww.harvard.edu/hepg.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission recognizes that regional transmission planning in 
    some areas is being performed to varying degrees by RTGs.273 
    It would be inefficient for RTOs initially to replicate the efforts of 
    RTGs. Therefore, we require that RTOs discuss their planning and 
    expansion with existing RTGs. However, over time, we would expect that 
    the RTG's planning process would become an RTO function and the need 
    for such coordination would be reduced or eliminated.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \273\ The Commission has approved RTGs for the New England Power 
    Pool, et al., 83 FERC para. 61,045 (1998), Mid-Continent Area Power 
    Pool, 76 FERC para. 61,261 (1996), Northwest Regional Transmission 
    Association, 71 FERC para. 61,397 (1995), Western Regional 
    Transmission Association, 71 FERC para. 651,158 (1995), and 
    Southwest Regional Transmission Association, 69 FERC para. 61,100 
    (1994).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    c. If the Regional Transmission Organization is unable to satisfy this 
    requirement when it commences operation, it must file a plan with the 
    Commission with specified milestones that will ensure that it meets 
    this requirement no later than three years after initial operation. 
    (Proposed Sec. 35.34(j)(7)(iii))
    
        We recognize that establishing an efficient procedure for 
    transmission planning and expansion may require coordination and 
    agreements among multiple parties and regulatory jurisdictions, and 
    that this may take some time to accomplish. Accordingly, we do not 
    propose that an RTO be capable of performing this function on its first 
    day of operation. We do expect, however, that RTO proposals contain at 
    least a plan explaining how the RTO intends to work toward implementing 
    this function. Such a plan should set forth milestones that will result 
    in this function being performed within three years after initial 
    operation. We seek comment on whether three years is an appropriate 
    amount of time for implementation of this function.
    
    E. Open Architecture
    
        The Commission believes that RTOs hold great promise in 
    accomplishing our goal of promoting competition in regional wholesale 
    electricity markets. That is why we want to accelerate their 
    development. We understand that there are many difficult 
    organizational, technical, and policy issues that must be addressed in 
    realizing proposals, and that markets are evolving quickly and possibly 
    in ways that cannot be foreseen at the time of RTO organization. 
    Further, the nature of the institutions supporting the markets may 
    change over time as well.
        For these reasons, the Commission will require that RTO design have 
    the ability to evolve over time. The Commission is committed to a 
    policy of ``open architecture.'' Simply put, open architecture requires 
    that there be no provision in any RTO proposal that precludes the RTO 
    and its members from improving their organizations to meet market 
    needs. The Commission will provide the regulatory flexibility to allow 
    such evolution.
        Under open architecture, an RTO should be able to evolve in several 
    ways, as long as it continues to satisfy the minimum RTO 
    characteristics and
    
    [[Page 31430]]
    
    functions. For example, open architecture would allow basic changes in 
    the organizational form of the RTO. An RTO that initially does not own 
    any transmission facilities might acquire ownership of some or all of 
    those facilities. The RTO's enabling agreements should at best 
    anticipate and facilitate such a change, but at minimum should not 
    prevent it or make it more difficult than necessary.
        Market trading patterns, technological change, and changes in 
    corporate strategies will make changes in RTO membership inevitable and 
    desirable. Accommodating change will require flexibility and 
    adaptability in the RTO organization and open architecture will permit 
    this.
        Market support and operations is another RTO dimension that could 
    benefit from open architecture. For example, an RTO may not initially 
    operate a PX to support a regional spot market, but if RTO members 
    later find that a PX would help the region, the RTO could propose to 
    add the PX function as well as a PX market monitoring function. It is 
    important that the basic RTO agreement not close off such development. 
    Our proposed open architecture policy will ensure that such future 
    development is not foreclosed.
        The Commission is interested in receiving comments regarding an 
    open architecture policy to ensure that initial RTOs can develop. What 
    flexibility needs to be built into RTO contracts? What regulatory 
    flexibility is needed from the Commission as part of an open 
    architecture policy? In which areas of RTO organization or operations 
    is it especially important for the Commission to expect improvement?
    
    F. Ratemaking for Transmission Facilities Under RTO Control
    
        The Commission expects RTOs to reform transmission pricing, and in 
    return we propose to allow RTOs greater flexibility in designing 
    pricing proposals. In 1994, the Commission issued its Transmission 
    Pricing Policy Statement encouraging transmission pricing reform and 
    setting out standards to be used to evaluate innovative transmission 
    pricing proposals.274 In the Transmission Pricing Policy 
    Statement the Commission allowed ``substantial flexibility'' to be 
    given to RTGs in justifying non-conforming proposals. The Commission 
    allowed this because RTGs represent the combined interests of 
    transmission owners, users and state authorities and because pricing 
    proposals for treating loop flow problems work better if all utilities 
    in the region use the same method.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \274\ The Policy Statement sets out five principles that 
    transmission pricing proposals should conform to: meet the 
    traditional revenue requirement; reflect comparability (open access 
    tariff); promote economic efficiency; promote fairness; and be 
    practical. The Policy Statement requires non-conforming proposals to 
    satisfy additional factors: promote competitive markets and produce 
    greater overall consumer benefits. Overall consumer benefits are 
    measured principally by greater access and customer choice, 
    projected price decreases to power customers, and service 
    flexibility and products to meet customer needs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In this section, we discuss a number of areas in which we expect 
    RTOs to provide innovative pricing and in which the Commission may be 
    expected to allow flexibility. We seek comments on the issues discussed 
    and other RTO pricing issues.
    1. Single Transmission Access Rate for Capital Cost Recovery
        One issue in ISO proposals that have come before the Commission is 
    the recovery of transmission capital costs through a single access 
    rate. Under such a rate, the capital costs of all RTO members would be 
    averaged, resulting in a rate that is higher than the individual system 
    rate for relatively low-cost transmission systems and lower than the 
    rate for high-cost transmission systems. This can cause two kinds of 
    ``cost-shifting'' concerns: high-cost transmission providers are 
    concerned about cost recovery, and customers of the low-cost providers 
    are concerned about increased rates.
        Transmission cost shifting has been an issue in every ISO the 
    Commission has approved to date, and we have allowed a flexible 
    approach to resolving the issue. In each of those cases, we have 
    allowed a transition period of between five and ten years during which 
    access fees are based on some form of ``license plate'' pricing: access 
    fees are paid by load serving entities based on the fixed transmission 
    costs of the local utility.275
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \275\ See, e.g., Order Directing Amendments to Proposals to 
    Restructure the Pennsylvania-New Jersey-Maryland Interconnection and 
    Providing Guidance, 77 FERC para. 61,148 at 61,577 (addressing 
    concerns about cost-shifting between high- and low-cost transmission 
    providers).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We propose to continue our flexibility in allowing the recovery of 
    current sunk transmission costs as transition mechanisms to single 
    rates if proposed by RTOs, including the license plate approach as well 
    as others. We request comment regarding whether the license plate 
    approach to fixed cost recovery is an appropriate long-term measure.
    2. Congestion Pricing
        As discussed in prior sections, managing regional congestion is one 
    of the problems that an RTO can help solve. We believe that efficient 
    congestion management requires a greater reliance on market mechanisms 
    276 and this can be effectively accomplished with price 
    signals. We propose to allow RTOs considerable flexibility in 
    experimenting with different market approaches to managing congestion 
    through pricing. 277 Proposals should, however, ensure that 
    the generators that are dispatched in the presence of transmission 
    constraints must be those that can serve system loads at least cost, 
    and limited transmission capacity should be used by market participants 
    that value that use most highly.278
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \276\ See NERC, 85 FERC at 62,364.
        \277\ This is consistent with our Transmission Pricing Policy 
    Statement's allowance of substantial flexibility to pricing 
    proposals from RTGs because RTGs are comprised of broad membership 
    to facilitate transmission access, develop a comprehensive regional 
    plan for transmission expansion, share transmission information and 
    provide for dispute resolution. 64 FERC 61,138 (1993). RTOs possess 
    these same characteristics.
        \278\ Transmission Pricing Policy Statement, FERC Stats. & Regs. 
    at 31,140-44.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission intends to be flexible in reviewing pricing 
    innovations, and we ask for comments as to what specific requirements, 
    if any, may best suit our RTO goals.
    3. Performance Based Rate Regulation
        Once RTOs are formed, the Commission is interested in finding ways 
    to ensure their satisfactory performance. One way to induce good grid 
    operation by an RTO is through performance-based regulation, or PBR. 
    PBR may consist of price/revenue caps, price incentives, or performance 
    standards.279 Performance-based regulation identifies 
    factors of good performance such as efficient congestion management, 
    lowering operator costs, and meeting reliability targets. Great care 
    must be taken in selecting the performance factors. RTOs should have a 
    reasonable chance of meeting or exceeding the performance targets, but 
    the targets must not be too easy to meet. We would reward only 
    performance that is truly superior to that which individual 
    transmission owners could achieve outside an RTO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \279\ See Incentive Ratemaking for Interstate Natural Gas 
    Pipelines, Oil Pipelines, and Electric Utilities, Policy Statement 
    on Incentive Regulation, 61 FERC para. 61,168 at 61,590-92 (1992), 
    and L. Brown, Michael Einhorn, and Ingo Vogelsang, Incentive 
    Regulation: A Research Report (1989).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission seeks comments on applying PBR to RTOs. Should PBR 
    be voluntary or applied to all RTOs? What degree of regulatory scrutiny 
    would a PBR regime require? In addition, the Commission seeks comment 
    on the specifics of how PBR would be applied
    
    [[Page 31431]]
    
    effectively to an RTO. For productivity incentives, what productivity 
    objectives should be adopted and how should productivity be measured? 
    How would a revenue cap or a price cap be set? What intermediate 
    adjustments to the cap should be allowed? How often should base costs 
    be examined?
    4. Consideration of Incentive Pricing Proposals
        RTOs would bring extensive benefits to North American electricity 
    markets and would further the objectives of sections 202(a), 205 and 
    206 of the FPA. We would be willing to consider, on a case by case 
    basis, allowing the transmission owners that bring about those benefits 
    to share in them through incentive pricing for public utility 
    transmission owners that turn over control of their transmission 
    facilities to an RTO.280 RTOs would be expected to propose 
    and justify specific proposals on a case-by-case basis.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \280\ As discussed above in section III-B, there are also a 
    number of non-pricing regulatory benefits that could be offered to 
    RTO members, such as deference in dispute resolution, reduced or 
    eliminated codes of conduct, and streamlined filing and approval 
    procedures.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        One potential treatment that could be considered is allowing 
    transmission owners that participate in RTOs to receive a higher return 
    on equity (ROE) on transmission plant than under current policy because 
    a transmission owner participating in an RTO puts its grid to a higher 
    valued use than one operating individually. This relates the incentive 
    to the benefit produced by the RTO. The simplest way to create a higher 
    ROE is to share the benefits of an RTO between transmission owners and 
    customers. Alternatively, a higher ROE could be implemented by either 
    allowing an ROE at the high end of the zone of reasonable returns for 
    RTO participants and an ROE in the current range for non-participants. 
    Is it appropriate to allow a higher ROE as a means of sharing the 
    benefits created by RTOs or should higher ROEs be limited only to 
    increases in risk? Is the risk of transmission capital recovery 
    increased or decreased by transferring transmission facilities to an 
    RTO from a vertically integrated firm?
        With improved grid operation and investment in new facilities to 
    relieve constraints, RTOs may lower grid operating costs. Another 
    incentive that could be considered would be to keep transmission rates 
    at current levels and allow participating RTO transmission owners to 
    keep the benefits from cost savings over time or to lower transmission 
    rates partly while owners keep part of the benefits. Would such 
    treatment encourage better performance?
        The Commission could also consider flexibility in cost recovery for 
    RTO participation. The capital cost of transmission plant is normally 
    recovered over a relatively long time period. RTO participants could be 
    allowed accelerated recovery for the costs of transmission expansion. 
    Similarly, the recovery of capital start-up costs of RTO participation 
    could be accelerated as well. Is it appropriate to allow such 
    accelerated recovery as an incentive to transfer transmission 
    facilities to an RTO or should capital recovery periods continue to be 
    based on the useful life of transmission facilities? Is industry 
    restructuring and the potential introduction of distributed generation 
    technology likely to affect the risk associated with transmission 
    investment recovery periods?
        The Commission may also be willing to consider non-traditional 
    methods for valuing transmission assets that are under the control of a 
    RTO. The Commission's traditional ratemaking policy values assets at 
    original cost, less depreciation. One alternative may be for rate base 
    to reflect a higher valuation through some measure of replacement cost. 
    Where an RTO or other independent owner purchases transmission assets 
    and pay a price that reflects such an enhanced valuation of assets, the 
    Commission may want to consider allowing the RTO to include in its 
    rates an acquisition premium that reflects the enhanced value.
        The Commission might also consider flexibility in allowing 
    levelized or non-levelized rate methods. Both methods can produce 
    reasonable results in particular circumstances, especially when one 
    method is used consistently throughout the life of a utility's 
    facilities. The Commission has, however, been reluctant to allow 
    switching from a non-levelized to a levelized rate design during the 
    life of a facility. The Commission's current policy is that a utility 
    must prove that switching methods is reasonable in light of its past 
    recovery of capital.281 The Commission could consider 
    granting some latitude for RTO pricing proposals for levelized rate 
    cost recovery.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \281\ See Consumers Energy Company, 85 FERC para. 61,100, at 
    61,366-367, 1998); Kentucky Utilities Company, 85 FERC para. 61,274, 
    at 62,103-105 (1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission seeks comments on whether to entertain case-by-case 
    proposals of rate incentive treatments for RTO participants. Will 
    transmission owners respond to incentives, and will incentives be 
    sufficient to achieve our objective of RTO formation? Which incentives 
    are most likely to be successful in so doing? Are there specific forms 
    of incentive pricing that are inappropriate and problematic? Are 
    safeguards needed if the Commission decides to allow incentive 
    treatments? In justifying a proposed rate treatment, should an RTO be 
    required to demonstrate that its benefits are likely to outweigh the 
    pecuniary ``costs'' of the proposal? Would certain incentive pricing 
    encourage RTOs to favor capital-based resource decisions (at the 
    expense of more efficient alternatives) or to favor transmission 
    solutions over alternative ways of relieving particular transmission 
    constraints? We also seek comment on whether and how public power 
    transmission owners that participate in RTOs could benefit from 
    flexible ratemaking and incentive pricing treatments.
        Finally, our willingness to consider incentive pricing proposals is 
    conditioned on an RTO meeting all of the proposed minimum 
    characteristics and functions. Allowing any incentive pricing to RTO 
    participants is based on a sharing of the extensive benefits that an 
    RTO brings to electricity markets. Only an RTO that meets the minimum 
    characteristics and functions can produce such extensive benefits, and 
    it would be inappropriate for the Commission to consider incentive 
    pricing to members of an RTO that falls short. We would, however, be 
    open to considering other innovative transmission rate treatments, such 
    as providing service at non-pancaked rates and regional congestion 
    management proposals, for an organization that does not meet all of the 
    minimum RTO characteristics and functions.
    
    G. Public Power Participation in RTOs
    
        The Commission's objective of encouraging all transmission owning 
    entities in the Nation to place their transmission facilities under the 
    control of an RTO includes transmission owned or controlled by public 
    power entities [e.g., municipals, cooperatives, Federal Power Marketing 
    Agencies (PMAs), Tennessee Valley Authority (TVA), and other state and 
    local entities]. We are aware that some public power entities have 
    filed open access tariffs with the Commission and others are 
    participating in ISOs and other regional institutions. We also are 
    aware, however, that many public power entities may face several 
    difficult issues regarding RTO participation. The Commission is 
    concerned about any obstacle to public power participation in the 
    formation and successful operation of any form of RTO. Accordingly, we 
    request comments that identify issues that
    
    [[Page 31432]]
    
    public power entities and others face regarding RTO participation and 
    that suggest ways the Commission might facilitate their resolution. We 
    expect public power entities to fully participate in the proposed 
    collaborative process for forming RTOs after our Final Rule is issued, 
    as discussed in section III-I below.
        One issue is the Internal Revenue Service (IRS) Code ``private 
    use'' restrictions on the transmission facilities of public power 
    entities financed by tax-exempt bonds. IRS temporary regulations may 
    allow facilities financed by outstanding tax-exempt bonds to be used to 
    wheel power in accordance with Order No. 888, but they may not allow 
    the issuance of additional tax-exempt bonds for expanded transmission 
    or permit transfer of operational control of existing transmission 
    facilities financed by tax-exempt bonds to a for-profit 
    transco.282 In addition, there is uncertainty regarding what 
    may happen after the temporary regulations expire on January 22, 2001.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \282\ See Uncrossing the Wires, Transmission in a Restructured 
    Market, a report by The Large Public Power Council, December 1998, 
    at 10.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We solicit comments on the extent to which IRS Code restrictions 
    may limit the transfer of operational control or other forms of 
    control, or ownership, of public power transmission facilities to a 
    for-profit transco. What impact would IRS Code restrictions have on 
    public power participation in other forms of an RTO? While IRS Code 
    restrictions might prevent issue of additional tax-exempt bonds for 
    transmission expansions made in accordance with RTO participation, are 
    non-tax exempt forms of financing a viable option for public power 
    participation in selected transmission additions?
        In addition to private use restrictions, are there other 
    restrictions on public power institutions that may limit their 
    participation in RTOs? For example, to what extent would state or local 
    charter limitations, prohibitions on participating in stock-owning 
    entities, or the current policies of various local regulatory entities 
    affect or impede full public power participation in RTOs? Are there 
    some forms of associate membership or participation in RTOs, or other 
    special accommodations, that the Commission should consider to make it 
    more feasible for public power entities to overcome obstacles to 
    participation in RTOs?
        The Commission seeks comment on legal restrictions or other 
    considerations regarding the PMAs that prevent their participation in 
    RTOs. For example, Bonneville Power Administration and other entities 
    in the Pacific Northwest may face unique circumstances that may affect 
    RTO formation in that area. These include the design of the power and 
    transmission system for the production of hydroelectric energy 
    involving the 1961 Columbia River Treaty, the Bonneville Project Act, 
    the Federal Columbia River Transmission System Act, the Pacific 
    Northwest Electric Power Planning and Conservation Act of 1980, and the 
    Northwest Preference Act. There may also be obstacles to TVA 
    participation in an RTO. How can the Commission help overcome any such 
    limiting factors to full RTO formation?
    
    H. Other Issues
    
        The Commission seeks comment on a number of other issues regarding 
    RTO participation. These issues are presented in this section.
    1. Pre-existing Transmission Contracts
        What is the appropriate treatment of existing transmission 
    agreements when an RTO is formed? In Order Nos. 888 and 888-A, we 
    specifically chose not to abrogate existing requirements and 
    transmission contracts when the utility filed an open access 
    tariff.283 However, an RTO represents an entirely different 
    context. We must balance the need for a uniform approach for 
    transmission pricing and the elimination of pancaked rates--one of the 
    principal benefits of an RTO--with the need to recognize the equities 
    inherent in existing transmission contracts. The potential financial 
    impact of giving up an advantageous transmission arrangement may act as 
    a disincentive to joining an RTO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \283\ See Order No. 888 at 31,664-65; Order No. 88-A at 30,181, 
    30,199; clarified, 76 FERC at 61,027; Order No. 888-B, 81 FERC at 
    62,072, 62, 090, 62,100.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In the ISO filings that we have acted on to date, we have evaluated 
    various ``transition plans'' regarding existing contracts on a case-by-
    case basis.\284\ At this juncture, we do not intend to resolve this 
    issue generically but instead propose to confine our policy to 
    addressing this issue on an RTO-by-RTO basis. We solicit comments on 
    this approach. How critical is this concern to transmission owners' and 
    others' decisions on whether to support RTO formation? Is the financial 
    impact of giving up an advantageous transmission arrangement 
    significant enough to act as a disincentive to RTO membership?
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \284\ See PJM, 81 FERC at 62,280-81; Midwest ISO, 84 FERC at 
    62,169-70 and order on reh'g, 85 FERC at 62,418-20 (1998); Pacific 
    Gas & Electric, 777 FERC at 61,821, 81 FERC at 61,470-71; NEPOOL, 83 
    FERC at 61,241-42; Central Hudson Gas & Electric Co. et al., 86 FERC 
    at 61,218-19.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    2. Treatment of Existing Regional Transmission Entities
        We propose to adopt in the Final Rule certain characteristics and 
    functions to be required of RTOs. It could turn out that the ISOs and 
    any other regional transmission entities that conform to the 
    Commission's ISO principles that we have approved to date do not meet 
    all of these characteristics and functions. It is our expectation that, 
    to the extent this is the case, the existing regional transmission 
    entities will over time evolve to be consistent with the 
    characteristics and functions adopted in the Final Rule. The Commission 
    recognizes that a number of operational, financial and political issues 
    will need to be addressed in the course of such an evolution and that 
    it cannot be accomplished overnight. We also respect the investment of 
    time and other resources made in the existing transmission entities, 
    and understand the importance of avoiding change during the critical 
    implementation period these institutions are now undergoing. Given 
    these considerations, and our policy of regional flexibility, the 
    proposed rule does not require major changes to the existing 
    transmission entities. However, our objective is to encourage all of 
    the Nation's transmission grid to be under the control of RTOs that 
    have the minimum characteristics and functions adopted in the Final 
    Rule. We therefore propose to require each public utility that is a 
    member of an existing regional transmission entity that has been 
    approved by the Commission as in conformance with the eleven ISO 
    principles set forth in Order No. 888 to make a filing no later than 
    January 15, 2001 that explains the extent to which the transmission 
    entity in which it participates meets the minimum characteristics and 
    functions for an RTO, or proposes to modify the existing institution to 
    become an RTO. Alternatively, the public utility may file an 
    explanation of efforts, obstacles and plans with respect to conforming 
    to these characteristics and functions. 285 The Commission 
    is also concerned about impediments to transactions between existing 
    transmission entities, as well as any future RTOs. We therefore 
    encourage existing transmission entities to consider ways to reduce any 
    impediments to transactions among them and direct
    
    [[Page 31433]]
    
    them to provide the Commission with a progress report by January 15, 
    2001.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \285\ Of course, there is nothing to prevent an existing 
    transmission entity from making an RTO filing prior to this date if 
    it so chooses.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission seeks comment on this issue.
    3. Participation by Canadian and Mexican Entities
        Canadian and Mexican involvement in RTO formation would be 
    beneficial to both, as well as to the United States. In certain areas, 
    ``natural'' electricity trading regions already cross national borders. 
    Expansion of electricity trade in the North American bulk power market 
    requires that regional institutions include all market participants so 
    that they may enjoy direct access to market information and the 
    benefits of non-pancaked transmission rates. In addition, any 
    reliability standards implemented by RTOs must be acceptable to the 
    affected nations and consider all resources to avoid wasteful 
    duplication of grid facilities.\286\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \286\ Historically, Canada and Mexico have participated in North 
    American utility organizations such as NERC and Western Systems 
    Coordinating Council (WSCC). Maintaining Reliability in a 
    Competitive U.S. Electricity Industry, Final Report of the Task 
    Force on Electric System Reliability, Secretary of Energy Advisory 
    Board, DOE, September 29, 1998 at 9, 58.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We encourage electric utilities in Canada and Mexico, and their 
    regulatory authorities, to participate in the discussions of the 
    rulemaking. Perhaps what may be thought of as a ``dotted line'' RTO 
    boundary could be used at international borders to indicate an 
    unwillingness to artificially limit an RTO's scope while recognizing 
    jurisdictional limits. The Commission emphasizes that Canadian and 
    Mexican authorities would be responsible for approving prices and other 
    terms and conditions of transmission service provided over any RTO 
    transmission facilities located in their countries. We invite the 
    comments of Canadian and Mexican authorities on these and other issues.
    4. Providing Service to Transmission-owning Utilities that do not 
    Participate in an RTO
        The transmission owners that turn control of transmission 
    facilities over to an RTO will help bring significant operational and 
    commercial benefits to a region. To what extent should transmission 
    owners who do not participate in their region's RTO share in those 
    benefits? Would it be appropriate to allow RTO members to provide 
    transmission service at individual system rates to non-participating 
    transmission owners located in the RTO region, thereby denying non-
    participants the benefits of non-pancaked transmission rates? The 
    Commission seeks comment on the treatment by an RTO of non-
    participating transmission owners in the RTO region.
    5. RTO Filing Requirements
        Any transfer of control of jurisdictional transmission facilities 
    owned, operated, or controlled by public utilities required by RTO 
    formation must be approved by the Commission pursuant to its Section 
    203 authority under the FPA. The RTO transmission rates, terms, and 
    conditions of service must also be approved pursuant to Section 205 of 
    the FPA. We request comments on whether the Commission should provide 
    for expedited or streamlined processing procedures for Section 203 
    transfers of jurisdictional facilities to RTOs that meet the 
    characteristics and functions of the Final Rule, and for the related 
    Section 205 transmission rates, terms, and conditions. We also welcome 
    specific suggestions regarding how we can further expedite or 
    streamline our procedures.
    6. Power Exchanges (PXs)
        Another important issue is the relationship between RTOs and power 
    exchanges. Of the five ISOs approved to date, only the Midwest ISO 
    chose not to include a power exchange in the design submitted to 
    us.287 However, after the Commission approved this proposal, 
    several ISO participants joined with other Midwestern power entities in 
    issuing a public request for proposals that would create an independent 
    power exchange that would operate in conjunction with the 
    ISO.288 This recent Midwest initiative appears to have been 
    motivated, at least in part, by the large price spikes that were 
    experienced last summer. Our staff's report concluded that one of 
    probable causes of the price spikes was the lack of price transparency 
    and that ``centralized trading institutions such as power exchanges 
    could have provided better price signals in the market and helped to 
    reduce price volatility.'' 289
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \287\ In California, PXs are operated by separate organizations 
    that coordinate with the ISO.
        \288\ See Joint Committee for the Development of a Midwest 
    Independent Power Exchange, ``Solicitation of Interest-Creation of 
    an Independent Power Exchange for the U.S. Midwest,'' February 5, 
    1999.
        \289\ Staff Report to the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission 
    on the Causes of Wholesale Electric Pricing Abnormalities in the 
    Midwest During June 1998, September 1998, at 4-4. Centralized power 
    exchanges appear to have other benefits. Since most power exchanges 
    establish credit and security standards as a condition for 
    participation and reserve funds to cover defaults, they create a 
    type of insurance by spreading counterparty risks among all 
    participants and thereby reducing the likelihood of cascading 
    transaction defaults such as those that occurred in the Midwest. In 
    addition, it is generally accepted that an organized and transparent 
    spot market is a prerequisite for a viable futures market which 
    would allow market participants to hedge the risk of future price 
    fluctuations. Finally, we note that during our recent consultations 
    with state commissions, several state commissioners informed us that 
    organized and open spot markets were critical to the success of 
    their efforts to introduce retail competition in their respective 
    states.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Regions may want to consider establishing a PX that is operated by 
    an RTO. However, some oppose RTO-operated PXs, contending that the two 
    principal functions of PXs, market making and price discovery, are not 
    natural monopoly functions.290 They also contend that power 
    exchanges force market participants to buy and sell electricity using 
    standardized contracts that may not meet their particular needs. They 
    argue that the full benefits of electricity competition can be achieved 
    only if there is competition for the market as well as in the market. 
    Finally, they assert that if power exchanges are introduced, an RTO 
    should be specifically prohibited from operating the exchange because 
    this would compromise the RTO's independence in fulfilling its 
    principal responsibilities as a transmission service provider and 
    system operator.291
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \290\ See, e.g., comments of Enron in PL98-5, Washington, D.C., 
    transcript at 211.
        \291\ See, e.g., comments of Automated Power Exchange, Inc., in 
    PL98-5 at 3.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In contrast, those who recommend that an RTO should operate a PX 
    contend that the two functions of short-term forward or spot market 
    operations and system operations are difficult to 
    separate.292 It is their view that there will be significant 
    inefficiencies unless the two functions are performed simultaneously by 
    a single entity.293 In addition, they contend that there is 
    no inherent conflict between the RTO as a transmission service provider 
    and a spot market operator as long as the RTO has no commercial 
    interest in whether prices are high or low in the markets that it 
    operates.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \292\ See Professor William W. Hogan, ``Enabling The Power Of 
    Markets,'' presentation at the EEI Chief Executive Conference, 
    Scottsdale, Arizona, January 7, 1999, at 8. A copy of this 
    presentation is available on Professor Hogan's website 
    (www.ksg.harvard.edu/people.whogan).
        \293\ See Dr. Larry Ruff, ``Competition in Electricity: Where Do 
    We Go From Here?'', lecture at the Institute of Economic Affairs, 
    London Business School, October 13, 1998. Available through the 
    website of the Harvard Electric Policy Group (http://
    ksgwww.harvard.edu/hepg/FPpapers.html).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        We leave it to each region to decide whether there is a need for a 
    PX and whether the RTO should operate the PX. The Commission will 
    accept an RTO
    
    [[Page 31434]]
    
    proposal that includes a PX in its design as long as its operation of 
    the PX does not compromise its independence as a transmission service 
    provider. We request comments on the following questions. Given that a 
    power exchange is useful, should it be part of an RTO or otherwise 
    associated with an RTO? If an area has more than one PX, should the PXs 
    have equal standing before the RTO? Is an organized PX necessary for 
    successful retail competition? If an RTO operates congestion markets 
    and balancing markets, are there efficiencies to be gained by allowing 
    or encouraging the RTO to operate day ahead or hour ahead energy 
    markets? Is it feasible for an RTO to operate a spot energy market 
    without compromising its ability to provide non-discriminatory 
    transmission service to all market participants? If a PX is operated by 
    a non-RTO entity, is there a need to require certain specified forms of 
    coordination between the two organizations?
    
    I. Implementation of the Rule
    
        The Commission seeks to support timely RTO formation in every 
    region of the country. To that end, the Commission envisions regional 
    collaborations soon after issuance of the Final Rule, building on 
    progress made to that date. Further, pursuant to our expectation that 
    utilities and other participants in the electric industry form RTOs, 
    the Commission proposes to require that certain filings be made by 
    October 15, 2000 concerning RTO formation. The collaborative process 
    and filing requirements are discussed in more detail below.
    1. Collaborative Process
        During our consultations with the state commissions, many said that 
    Commission leadership is needed to facilitate RTO formation and that 
    only we could facilitate broad regional participation. To facilitate 
    RTO formation in all regions of the Nation, the Commission proposes a 
    collaborative process under section 202(a) to take place in the spring 
    of 2000, after adoption of a Final Rule. The Commission expects public 
    utilities and non-public utilities, in coordination with appropriate 
    state officials, and affected interest groups in a region to fully 
    participate in working to develop an RTO.
        To assist in structuring the regional collaborations and to further 
    inform the Commission on activities in each region, we propose that 
    regional workshops be held throughout the Nation after the Final Rule 
    is issued. The goal of these workshops would be to share information 
    about the status of RTOs or RTO proposals in the region, to identify 
    any impediments to RTO formation in the area, to explore what process 
    could most expeditiously advance agreements on RTO formation, and to 
    determine what role, if any, Commission staff should play in advancing 
    discussions in the region. These regional workshops would be convened 
    by Commission staff in cooperation with the affected state officials. 
    The Commission would specifically invite each entity in the Nation that 
    owns or operates transmission facilities, and representatives from 
    Canada and Mexico as appropriate, to the public workshops. The 
    Commission proposes to make staff resources, including settlement 
    judges, available through our Dispute Resolution Service to assist in 
    designing and possibly facilitating regional collaborations following 
    the workshops. Commission technical staff will be made available for 
    participation in the regional collaborations.
        Would regional workshops advance RTO formation? Under whose 
    auspices should regional workshops be held? Would it be beneficial to 
    have the Commission's Dispute Resolution Service staff facilitate 
    discussions regarding RTO formation? Should the Commission staff 
    convene the regional workshops or should Commission staff be made 
    available to attend meetings convened by others? If the Commission 
    staff convenes workshops, in how many cities should meetings be 
    convened and how should the cities be chosen? Would the three U.S. 
    interconnections be appropriate starting points? Would participation of 
    Commission staff aid or stifle negotiations on RTO development?
    2. Filing Requirement
        The Commission is hopeful that the direction provided by this 
    rulemaking, the regional collaborations described above, and the 
    possibility of incentive rate treatments will lead to the prompt 
    development of RTO proposals. Thus, we propose that all public 
    utilities that own, operate or control interstate transmission 
    facilities (except those already participating in a regional 
    transmission entity in conformance with our eleven ISO principles) must 
    file with the Commission by October 15, 2000, either (1) a proposal to 
    participate in an RTO that will be operational no later than December 
    15, 2001, or (2) an alternative filing describing efforts to 
    participate in an RTO, obstacles to RTO participation, and any plans 
    and timetables for future efforts (see proposed 
    Sec. 35.34(c)).294 To the extent possible, RTO proposals 
    should include the transmission facilities of public power and other 
    non-public utility entities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \294\ A proposal to form a transmission institution that does 
    not meet all of the minimum RTO characteristics and functions will 
    not be approved as an RTO. This does not necessarily mean that the 
    proposal will not otherwise be approved as consistent with the FPA. 
    However, the proposal will not qualify as an RTO. For transmission 
    organizations that do not meet all of the minimum RTO 
    characteristics and functions, however, we would still be open to 
    considering, and indeed encourage, regional filings for providing 
    service at non-pancaked rates and regional congestion management 
    proposals.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The number and type of filings necessary to effectuate an RTO 
    proposal necessarily will vary depending upon the type of RTO being 
    proposed and the circumstances of each individual public utility 
    participant. At a minimum, an RTO proposal must include a basic 
    agreement filed under section 205 of the FPA setting out the rules, 
    practices and procedures under which an RTO will be governed and 
    operated, and requests by the public utility members of the RTO for 
    approval under section 203 of the FPA to transfer control of their 
    jurisdictional transmission facilities. However, depending upon the 
    circumstances, there may need to be additional section 205 or 206 
    amendments to existing public utility contracts or rate schedules in 
    order to effectuate an RTO proposal.
        For those public utilities that file an RTO proposal on or before 
    October 15, 2000, we will permit them to file a petition for 
    declaratory order asking whether a proposed transmission entity would 
    qualify as an RTO, with a description of the organizational and 
    operational structure and the intended participants of the institution, 
    an explanation of how the institution would satisfy each of the RTO 
    minimum characteristics and functions, and a commitment to submit 
    necessary section 203, 205 and 206 filing promptly after receiving the 
    Commission's determination on the declaratory order petition (see 
    proposed Sec. 35.34(d)(3)). This declaratory order petition option thus 
    is to be used only in conjunction with the filing of a proposal for an 
    RTO that is to begin operation no later than December 15, 2001.
        If a public utility is not able to file an RTO proposal on or 
    before October 15, 2000, it must alternatively file by that date a 
    description of any efforts made by the public utility to participate in 
    an RTO, the reasons it has not participated in an RTO, including 
    identifying specific obstacles to RTO participation, and any plans and 
    timetables the public
    
    [[Page 31435]]
    
    utility has for further work toward RTO participation (see proposed 
    Sec. 35.34(f)). If a public utility makes such an alternative filing, 
    the Commission at that time will determine what steps, if any, need to 
    be taken.
        The above requirements, however, do not apply to a public utility 
    that is a member of an existing transmission entity that the Commission 
    has found to be in conformance with the Order No. 888 ISO principles. 
    Rather, each such public utility must make a filing no later than 
    January 15, 2001 that (1) explains the extent to which the transmission 
    entity in which it participates meets the minimum characteristics and 
    functions for an RTO, (2) proposes to modify the existing institution 
    to become an RTO, or (3) explains efforts, obstacles and plans with 
    respect to conforming to these characteristics and functions (see 
    proposed Sec. 35.34(g)).295
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \295\ Of course, there is nothing to prevent an existing entity 
    from making an RTO filing prior to this date if it so chooses.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission does not propose to mandate RTO participation by 
    rule, and instead proposes to induce voluntary participation through a 
    combination of guidance on the minimum characteristics and functions of 
    an RTO, possible rate incentives, a collaborative process for 
    structuring regional dialogues, and filing requirements. The Commission 
    seeks comment on whether the filing requirements discussed above are 
    inconsistent with or otherwise would inhibit voluntary participation in 
    RTOs. The Commission also seeks comment on whether it needs to 
    generically mandate RTO participation by all public utilities to remedy 
    undue discrimination under sections 205 and 206 of the FPA. We also 
    seek comment on whether a performance based system could be designed to 
    realign economic interests to remove the motive for discrimination.
        In considering what actions might be appropriate if a utility fails 
    to voluntarily join an RTO, the Commission seeks comment on whether 
    market-based rates for generation services could continue to be 
    justified for a public utility that does not participate in an RTO, 
    whether a merger involving a public utility that is not a member of an 
    RTO would be consistent with the public interest, whether non-
    participants that own transmission facilities should be allowed to use 
    the non-pancaked transmission rates of the RTO participants in that 
    region, whether transmission services provided by a transmitting 
    utility need to be under RTO control to satisfy the discrimination 
    standards of sections 211 and 212 of the FPA, and whether a public 
    utility's lack of participation would otherwise be in violation of the 
    FPA. Does the possibility of any of these remedial actions for RTO non-
    participation undermine or otherwise inhibit voluntary participation in 
    RTOs? How should the Commission consider the efficiency, reliability, 
    and discrimination implications of RTO non-participation? How should 
    the Commission consider non-participation by utilities that constitute 
    ``holes'' in an RTO region?
        The Commission anticipates that public utilities will file 
    proposals for ISOs, transcos, or other types of regional transmission 
    institutions prior to the effective date of the Final Rule. We clarify 
    that the Commission will continue to apply to these proposals the ISO 
    principles contained in Order No. 888 and the case precedent 
    established for ISOs. However, a public utility that files such a 
    proposal prior to the effective date of the Final Rule would still be 
    subject to the October 15, 2000 or January 15, 2001 filing requirement, 
    as appropriate, in the Final Rule.
    
    IV. Environmental Statement
    
        In furtherance of the National Environmental Policy Act of 1969, 
    the staff of the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission will prepare an 
    environmental assessment (EA) that will consider the environmental 
    impacts of the proposed rule. A notice of intent to prepare the EA, 
    request comments on the scope of the EA, and notice of a public scoping 
    meeting is published elsewhere in this issue of the Federal Register.
    
    V. Regulatory Flexibility Act
    
        The Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA), 5 U.S.C. Secs. 601-612, 
    requires rulemakings to contain either a description and analysis of 
    the effect that the proposed rule will have on small entities or a 
    certification that the rule will not have a significant economic impact 
    on a substantial number of small entities. If this proposed rule goes 
    into effect, it will establish minimum characteristics and functions 
    for RTOs, none of which is likely to meet the SBA's definition of a 
    small electric utility, i.e., one that disposes of 4,000,000 MWh per 
    year or less. 13 C.F.R. Sec. 121.201. Furthermore, the rule will not 
    have the requisite impact upon transmission owners.
        In Mid-Tex Elec. Coop. v. FERC, 773 F.2d 327 (D.C. Cir. 1985), the 
    court found that Congress, in passing the RFA, intended agencies to 
    limit their consideration ``to small entities that would be directly 
    regulated'' by proposed rules. Id. at 342. The court further concluded 
    that ``the relevant `economic impact' was the impact of compliance with 
    the proposed rule on regulated small entities.'' Id. at 342.
        The proposed rule will not regulate any small entities, nor will it 
    impose upon them any significant costs of compliance. Small entities 
    will be free to determine for themselves whether to participate in an 
    RTO and whether any costs associated with joining an RTO will be 
    adequately offset by attendant benefits. The only requirement the rule 
    would impose upon a small entity would be the need to file a statement 
    explaining its efforts to join an RTO, any barriers it encountered, and 
    any future plans to seek to join an RTO. The Commission believes that 
    the costs associated with preparing and filing such a statement will be 
    minimal. Consequently, the Commission certifies that this proposed rule 
    will not have a significant economic impact upon a substantial number 
    of small entities.
    
    VI. Public Reporting Burden and Information Collection Statement
    
        The following collections of information contained in this proposed 
    rule are being submitted to the Office of Management and Budget (OMB) 
    for review under Section 3507(d) of the Paperwork Reduction Act of 
    1995. FERC identifies the information provided under Part 35 as FERC-
    516 and under Part 33 as FERC-519.
        Comments are solicited on the Commission's need for this 
    information, whether the information will have practical utility, the 
    accuracy of the provided burden estimates, ways to enhance the quality, 
    utility, and clarity of the information to be collected, and any 
    suggested methods for minimizing respondents' burden, including the use 
    of automated information techniques. The burden estimates for complying 
    with this proposed rule are as follows:
        Public Reporting Burden: Estimated Annual Burden:
    
    [[Page 31436]]
    
    
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                                         Number of       Number of       Hours per     Total annual
                     Data collection                    respondents      responses       response          hours
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
    FERC-516........................................              12               1             300           3,600
    FERC-519........................................          \1\ 50               1              80           4,000
                                                     ---------------------------------------------------------------
        Totals......................................  ..............  ..............  ..............           7,600
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
    \1\ Includes respondents who make application to form an RTO and the responses of utilities who choose not to
      participate.
    
        Total Annual Hours for Collection (reporting+record keeping, (if 
    appropriate))=7,600.
        Information Collection Costs: The Commission seeks comments on the 
    costs to comply with these requirements. It has projected the average 
    annualized cost for all respondents to be:
        Annualized Capital/Startup Costs--Annualized Costs (Operations & 
    Maintenance) -$401,518 (7,600 hours  2080 hours per year  x  
    $109,889 =$401,518). The cost per respondent is equal to $8,030 
    (participants and non-participants).
        The OMB regulations require OMB to approve certain information 
    collection requirements imposed by agency rule. (Footnote 5 CFR 
    1320.11)
        Accordingly, pursuant to OMB regulations, the Commission is 
    providing notice of its proposed information collections to OMB.
        Title: FERC-516, Electric Rate Schedule Filings; FERC-519 
    Application for Sale, Lease, or Other Disposition, Merger or 
    Consolidation of Facilities or for the Purchase or Acquisition of 
    Securities of a Public Utility.
        Action: Proposed Data Collections.
        OMB Control No.: 1902-0096 and 1902-0082.
        The applicant shall not be penalized for failure to respond to this 
    collection of information unless the collection of information displays 
    a valid OMB control number.
        Respondents: Business or other for profit, including small 
    businesses.
        Frequency of Responses: One time.
        Necessity of Information: The proposed rule revises the 
    requirements contained in 18 CFR part 35. The Commission is seeking to 
    establish RTOs nationwide by December 2001. In particular, the 
    Commission will establish in this proposed rule characteristics and 
    functions which applicants must meet to become Commission approved 
    RTOs. The Commission will engage in a collaborative process with state 
    officials and others to facilitate RTO development. The proposed rule 
    will require that each public utility that owns, operates or controls 
    transmission facilities participate in one-time filings proposing an 
    RTO or make a filing explaining why they are not participating in an 
    RTO proposal.
        Internal Review: The Commission has assured itself, by means of 
    internal review, that there is specific, objective support for the 
    burden estimates associated with the information requirements. The 
    Commission's Offices of Electric Power Regulation and Economic Policy 
    will use the data included in filings under Section 203 and 205 of the 
    Federal Power Act to evaluate efforts for the interconnection and 
    coordination of the U.S. electric transmission system and to ensure the 
    orderly formation of RTOs as well as for general industry oversight. 
    These information requirements conform to the Commission's plan for 
    efficient information collection, communication, and management within 
    the electric power industry.
        Interested persons may obtain information on the reporting 
    requirements by contacting the following: Federal Energy Regulatory 
    Commission, 888 First Street, NE, Washington, DC 20426 [Attention: 
    Michael Miller, Capital Planning and Policy Group, Phone: (202) 208-
    1415, fax: (202) 208-2425, E-mail: mike.miller@ferc.fed.us].
        For submitting comments concerning the collection of information(s) 
    and the associated burden estimate(s), please send your comments to the 
    contact listed above and to the Office of Management and Budget, Office 
    of Information and Regulatory Affairs, Washington, DC 20503, 
    [Attention: Desk Officer for the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 
    phone: (202) 395-3087, fax: (202) 395-7285].
    
    VII. Public Comment Procedures
    
        The Commission invites interested persons to submit written 
    comments on the matters and issues proposed in this notice to be 
    adopted, including any related matters or alternative proposals that 
    commenters may wish to discuss. Initial comments should not exceed 100 
    double-spaced pages and should include an executive summary. The 
    original and 14 copies of such comments must be received by the 
    Commission before 5:00 p.m. on August 16, 1999.
        The Commission will also permit interested persons to submit reply 
    comments in response to the initial comments filed in this proceeding. 
    Reply comments should not exceed 50 double-spaced pages and should 
    include an executive summary. The original and 14 copies of the reply 
    comments must be received by the Commission before 5:00 p.m. on 
    September 15, 1999.
        Comments should be submitted to the Office of the Secretary, 
    Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street, N.E., 
    Washington D.C. 20426 and should refer to Docket No. RM99-2-000.
        In addition to filing paper copies, the Commission encourages the 
    filing of comments either on computer diskette or via Internet E-Mail. 
    Comments may be filed in the following formats: WordPerfect 8.0 or 
    lower version, MS Word Office 97 or lower version, or ASCII format.
        For diskette filing, include the following information on the 
    diskette label: Docket No. RM99-2-000; the name of the filing entity; 
    the software and version used to create the file; and the name and 
    telephone number of a contact person.
        For Internet E-Mail submittal, comments should be submitted to 
    comment.rm@ferc.fed.us'' in the following format. On the subject 
    line, specify Docket No. RM99-2-000. In the body of the E-Mail message, 
    include the name of the filing entity; the software and version used to 
    create the file, and the name and telephone number of the contact 
    person. Attach the comments to the E-Mail in one of the formats 
    specified above. The Commission will send an automatic acknowledgment 
    to the sender's E-Mail address upon receipt. Questions on electronic 
    filing should be directed to Brooks Carter at 202-501-8145, E-Mail 
    address brooks.carter@ferc.fed.us.
        Commenters should take note that, until the Commission amends its 
    rules and regulations, the paper copy of the filing remains the 
    official copy of the document submitted. Therefore, any discrepancies 
    between the paper filing and the electronic filing or the diskette will 
    be resolved by reference to the paper filing.
    
    [[Page 31437]]
    
        All written comments will be placed in the Commission's public 
    files and will be available for inspection in the Commission's Public 
    Reference room at 888 First Street, N.E., Washington D.C. 20426, during 
    regular business hours. Additionally, comments may be viewed, printed 
    or downloaded remotely via the Internet through FERC's Homepage using 
    the RIMS or CIPS link. RIMS contains all comments but only those 
    comments submitted in electronic format are available on CIPS. User 
    assistance is available at 202-208-2222, or by E-Mail to 
    rimsmaster@ferc.fed.us.
    
    List of Subjects in 18 CFR Part 35
    
        Electric power rates, Electric utilities, Reporting and 
    recordkeeping requirements.
    
        By direction of the Commission.
    David P. Boergers,
    Secretary.
        In consideration of the foregoing, the Commission proposes to amend 
    Part 35, Chapter I, Title 18 of the Code of Federal Regulations, as set 
    forth below.
    
    PART 35--FILING OF RATE SCHEDULES
    
        1. The authority citation for part 35 continues to read as follows:
    
        Authority: 16 U.S.C. 791a-825r, 2601-2645; 31 U.S.C. 9701; 42 
    U.S.C. 7101-7352.
    
        2. Part 35 is amended by adding a new Subpart F consisting of 
    Sec. 35.34 to read as follows:
    
    Subpart F--Procedures and Requirements Regarding Regional 
    Transmission Organizations
    
    
    Sec. 35.34  Regional Transmission Organizations.
    
        (a) Purpose. This section establishes required characteristics and 
    functions for Regional Transmission Organizations for the purpose of 
    promoting efficiency and reliability in the operation and planning of 
    the electric transmission grid and ensuring nondiscrimination in the 
    provision of electric transmission services. This section further 
    directs each public utility that owns, operates, or controls facilities 
    used for the transmission of electric energy in interstate commerce to 
    make certain filings with respect to forming and participating in a 
    Regional Transmission Organization.
        (b) Definitions.
        (1) Regional Transmission Organization means an entity that 
    satisfies the minimum characteristics set forth in paragraph (i) of 
    this section, performs the functions set forth in paragraph (j) of this 
    section, and accommodates the open architecture conditions set forth in 
    paragraph (k) of this section.
        (2) Market participant means any entity that buys or sells electric 
    energy in the Regional Transmission Organization's region or in any 
    neighboring region that might be affected by the Regional Transmission 
    Organization's actions, or any affiliate of such an entity.
        (c) General rule. Except for those public utilities subject to the 
    requirements of paragraph (g) of this section, every public utility 
    that owns, operates or controls facilities used for the transmission of 
    electric energy in interstate commerce as of [effective date of the 
    final regulation] must file with the Commission, no later than October 
    15, 2000, one of the following:
        (1) A proposal to participate in a Regional Transmission 
    Organization consisting of one of the types of submittals set forth in 
    paragraph (d) of this section; or
        (2) A submittal consistent with paragraph (f) of this section.
        (d) Proposal to participate in a Regional Transmission 
    Organization. For purposes of this section, a proposal to participate 
    in a Regional Transmission Organization means:
        (1) Necessary filings, made individually or jointly with other 
    entities, pursuant to sections 203, 205 and/or 206 of the Federal Power 
    Act (16 U.S.C. 824b, 824d, and 824c), as appropriate, to create a new 
    Regional Transmission Organization;
        (2) Necessary filings, made individually or jointly with other 
    entities, pursuant to sections 203, 205 and/or 206 of the Federal Power 
    Act, as appropriate, to join a Regional Transmission Organization 
    approved by the Commission on or before the date of the filing; or
        (3) A petition for declaratory order, filed individually or jointly 
    with other entities, asking whether a proposed transmission entity 
    would qualify as a Regional Transmission Organization and containing at 
    least the following:
        (i) A detailed description of the proposed transmission entity, 
    including a description of the organizational and operational structure 
    and the intended participants;
        (ii) A discussion of how the transmission entity would satisfy each 
    of the characteristics and functions of a Regional Transmission 
    Organization specified in paragraphs (i), (j) and (k) of this section;
        (iii) A detailed description of the section 205 rates that will be 
    filed for the transmission entity; and
        (iv) A commitment to make necessary filings pursuant to sections 
    203, 205 and/or 206 of the Federal Power Act, as appropriate, promptly 
    after the Commission issues an order in response to the petition.
    
        Note to paragraph (d): Under this paragraph (d), the Commission 
    would consider a request for incentive rate treatment or another 
    form of innovative transmission pricing, such as performance based 
    rates. Such a filing must include a detailed explanation of how the 
    proposed rate treatment would help achieve each of the minimum 
    characteristics and functions and would result in benefits to 
    consumers.
    
        (e) Transfer of operational control. Any public utility's proposal 
    to participate in a Regional Transmission Organization filed pursuant 
    to paragraph (c)(1) of this section must propose that operational 
    control of that public utility's transmission facilities will be 
    transferred to the Regional Transmission Organization on a schedule 
    that will allow the Regional Transmission Organization to commence 
    operating the facilities no later than December 15, 2001.
    
        Note to paragraph (e): The requirement in this paragraph (e) may be 
    satisfied by proposing to transfer to the Regional Transmission 
    Organization ownership of the facilities in addition to operational 
    control.
    
        (f) Alternative filing. The submittal referred to in paragraph 
    (c)(2) of this section must contain a description of any efforts made 
    by that public utility to participate in a Regional Transmission 
    Organization; the reasons it has not, to date, participated in a 
    Regional Transmission Organization, including identification of any 
    existing obstacles to participation in a Regional Transmission 
    Organization; and any plans the public utility has for further work 
    toward participation in a Regional Transmission Organization.
        (g) Public utilities participating in approved transmission 
    entities. Every public utility that owns, operates or controls 
    facilities used for the transmission of electric energy in interstate 
    commerce as of [effective date of the final regulation], and that has 
    filed with the Commission to transfer operational control of its 
    facilities to a transmission entity that has been approved or 
    conditionally approved by the Commission as being in conformance with 
    the eleven ISO principles set forth in Order No. 888, FERC Stats. & 
    Regs. para.31,036 (Final Rule on Open Access and Stranded Costs) on or 
    before [effective date of the final regulation], must, individually or 
    jointly with other entities, file with the Commission, no later than 
    January 15, 2001:
    
    [[Page 31438]]
    
        (1) A statement that it is participating in a transmission entity 
    that has been so approved;
        (2) A detailed explanation of the extent to which the transmission 
    entity in which it participates has the characteristics and performs 
    the functions of a Regional Transmission Organization specified in 
    paragraphs (i) and (j) of this section and accommodates the open 
    architecture conditions in paragraph (k) of this section; and
        (3) To the extent the transmission entity in which the public 
    utility participates does not meet all the requirements of a Regional 
    Transmission Organization specified in paragraphs (i), (j), and (k) of 
    this section, the public utility must file either a proposal to 
    participate in a Regional Transmission Organization that meets such 
    requirements in accordance with paragraph (d) of this section, a 
    proposal to modify the existing transmission entity so that it conforms 
    to the requirements of a Regional Transmission Organization, or a 
    filing containing the information specified in paragraph (f) of this 
    section addressing any efforts, obstacles, and plans with respect to 
    conformance with those requirements.
        (h) Entities that become public utilities with transmission 
    facilities. An entity that is not a public utility that owns, operates 
    or controls facilities used for the transmission of electric energy in 
    interstate commerce as of [effective date of the final regulation], but 
    later becomes such a public utility, must file a proposal to 
    participate in a Regional Transmission Organization in accordance with 
    paragraph (d) of this section, or an alternative filing in accordance 
    with paragraph (f) of this section, by October 15, 2000 or 60 days 
    prior to the date on which the public utility engages in any 
    transmission of electric energy in interstate commerce, whichever comes 
    later. If a proposal to participate in accordance with paragraph (d) of 
    this section is filed, it must propose that operational control of the 
    applicant's transmission system will be transferred to the Regional 
    Transmission Organization within 6 months of filing the proposal.
        (i) Required characteristics for a Regional Transmission 
    Organization. A Regional Transmission Organization must satisfy the 
    following characteristics when it commences operation:
        (1) Independence. The Regional Transmission Organization must be 
    independent of market participants.
        (i) The Regional Transmission Organization, its employees, and any 
    non-stakeholder directors must not have financial interests in any 
    market participants.
        (ii) A Regional Transmission Organization must have a decision 
    making process that is independent of control by any market participant 
    or class of participants.
        (iii) The Regional Transmission Organization must have exclusive 
    and independent authority to file changes to its transmission tariff 
    with the Commission under Section 205 of the Federal Power Act.
        (2) Scope and regional configuration. The Regional Transmission 
    Organization must serve an appropriate region. The region must be of 
    sufficient scope and configuration to permit the Regional Transmission 
    Organization to effectively perform its required functions and to 
    support efficient and non-discriminatory power markets.
        (3) Operational authority. The Regional Transmission Organization 
    must have operational responsibility for all transmission facilities 
    under its control.
        (i) The Regional Transmission Organization may choose to directly 
    operate facilities (direct control), delegate certain tasks to other 
    entities (functional control) or use a combination of the two 
    approaches. If certain operational functions are delegated to, or 
    shared with, entities other than the Regional Transmission 
    Organization, the Regional Transmission Organization must ensure that 
    this sharing of operational responsibility will not adversely affect 
    reliability or provide some market participants with an unfair 
    competitive advantage. Within two years after initial operation as a 
    Regional Transmission Organization, the Regional Transmission 
    Organization must prepare a public report that assesses whether any 
    division of operational responsibilities hinders the Regional 
    Transmission Organization in providing reliable, non-discriminatory and 
    efficiently priced transmission service.
        (ii) The Regional Transmission Organization must be the security 
    coordinator for the facilities that it controls.
    
        Note to paragraph (i)(3)(ii): The provision in this paragraph 
    (i)(3)(ii) requires that the Regional Transmission Organization 
    undertake the functions in its region currently assigned to security 
    coordinators by NERC in ``NERC Operating Policy 9--Security 
    Coordinator Procedures.'' It is recognized that NERC ``security 
    coordinators'' are relatively new and that they may not necessarily 
    be permanent institutions. However, the functions NERC currently 
    assigns to security coordinators are critical ones that should be 
    performed by the entity with operational authority for transmission 
    facilities within the region.
    
        (4) Short-term Reliability. The Regional Transmission Organization 
    must have exclusive authority for maintaining the short-term 
    reliability of the grid that it operates.
        (i) The Regional Transmission Organization must have exclusive 
    authority for receiving, confirming and implementing all interchange 
    schedules.
        (ii) The Regional Transmission Organization must have the right to 
    order redispatch of any generator connected to transmission facilities 
    it operates if necessary for the reliable operation of these 
    facilities.
        (iii) When the Regional Transmission Organization operates 
    transmission facilities owned by other entities, the Regional 
    Transmission Organization must have authority to approve or disapprove 
    all requests for scheduled outages of transmission facilities to ensure 
    that the outages can be accommodated within established reliability 
    standards.
        (iv) If the Regional Transmission Organization operates under 
    reliability standards established by another entity (e.g., a regional 
    reliability council), the Regional Transmission Organization must 
    report to the Commission if these standards hinder it from providing 
    reliable, non-discriminatory and efficiently priced transmission 
    service.
        (j) Required functions of a Regional Transmission Organization. The 
    Regional Transmission Organization must perform the following 
    functions. Unless otherwise noted, the Regional Transmission 
    Organization must satisfy these obligations when it commences 
    operations.
        (1) Tariff administration and design. The Regional Transmission 
    Organization must administer its own transmission tariff and employ a 
    transmission pricing system that will promote efficient use and 
    expansion of transmission and generation facilities. The Regional 
    Transmission Organization must carry out this function by satisfying 
    the standards listed in paragraphs (j)(1)(i) and (ii) of this section, 
    or by demonstrating that an alternative proposal is consistent with or 
    superior to satisfying such standards.
        (i) The Regional Transmission Organization must be the only 
    provider of transmission service over the facilities under its control, 
    and must be the sole administrator of its own Commission-approved open 
    access transmission tariff. The Regional Transmission Organization must 
    have the sole authority to receive, evaluate, and approve or deny all 
    requests for
    
    [[Page 31439]]
    
    transmission service. The Regional Transmission Organization must have 
    the authority to review and approve requests for new interconnections.
        (ii) The Regional Transmission Organization tariff must not result 
    in transmission customers paying multiple access charges to recover 
    capital costs for transmission service over facilities that the 
    Regional Transmission Organization controls (i.e, no pancaking of 
    transmission access charges).
        (2) Congestion management. The Regional Transmission Organization 
    must ensure the development and operation of market mechanisms to 
    manage transmission congestion. The Regional Transmission Organization 
    must carry out this function by satisfying the standards listed in 
    paragraph (j)(2)(i) of this section, or by demonstrating that an 
    alternative proposal is consistent with or superior to satisfying such 
    standards.
        (i) The market mechanisms must accommodate broad participation by 
    all market participants, and must provide all transmission customers 
    with efficient price signals that show the consequences of their 
    transmission usage decisions. The Regional Transmission Organization 
    must either operate such markets itself or ensure that the task is 
    performed by another entity that is not affiliated with any market 
    participant.
        (ii) The Regional Transmission Organization must satisfy this 
    requirement no later than one year after it commences initial 
    operation.
        (3) Parallel path flow. The Regional Transmission Organization must 
    develop and implement procedures to address parallel path flow issues 
    within its region and with other regions. The Regional Transmission 
    Organization must satisfy this requirement with respect to coordination 
    with other regions no later than three years after it commences initial 
    operation.
        (4) Ancillary services. The Regional Transmission Organization must 
    serve as a supplier of last resort of all ancillary services required 
    by Order No. 888, FERC Stats. & Regs. para.31,036 (Final Rule on Open 
    Access and Stranded Costs), and subsequent orders. The Regional 
    Transmission Organization must carry out this function by satisfying 
    the standards listed in paragraphs (j)(4)(i)-(iii) of this section, or 
    by demonstrating that an alternative proposal is consistent with or 
    superior to satisfying such standards.
        (i) All market participants must have the option of self-supplying 
    or acquiring ancillary services from third parties subject to any 
    restrictions imposed by the Commission in Order No. 888, FERC Stats. & 
    Regs. para.31,036 (Final Rule on Open Access and Stranded Costs), and 
    subsequent orders.
        (ii) The Regional Transmission Organization must have the authority 
    to decide the minimum required amounts of each ancillary service and, 
    if necessary, the locations at which these services must be provided. 
    All ancillary service providers must be subject to direct or indirect 
    operational control by the Regional Transmission Organization. The 
    Regional Transmission Organization must promote the development of 
    competitive markets for ancillary services whenever feasible.
        (iii) The Regional Transmission Organization must ensure that its 
    transmission customers have access to a real-time balancing market. The 
    Regional Transmission Organization must either develop and operate such 
    markets itself or ensure that this task is performed by another entity 
    that is not affiliated with any market participant.
        (5) OASIS and Total Transmission Capability (TTC) and Available 
    Transmission Capability (ATC). The Regional Transmission Organization 
    must be the single OASIS site administrator for all transmission 
    facilities under its control and independently calculate TTC and ATC.
        (6) Market monitoring. The Regional Transmission Organization must 
    monitor markets for transmission services, ancillary services and bulk 
    power to identify design flaws and market power and propose appropriate 
    remedial actions. The Regional Transmission Organization must carry out 
    this function by satisfying the standards listed in paragraphs 
    (j)(6)(i)-(iv) of this section, or by demonstrating that an alternative 
    proposal is consistent with or superior to satisfying such standards.
        (i) The Regional Transmission Organization must monitor markets for 
    transmission service and the behavior of transmission owners, if any, 
    to determine if their actions hinder the Regional Transmission 
    Organization in providing reliable, efficient and nondiscriminatory 
    transmission service.
        (ii) The Regional Transmission Organization must monitor markets 
    for ancillary services and bulk power. This obligation is limited to 
    markets that the Regional Transmission Organization operates.
        (iii) The Regional Transmission Organization must periodically 
    assess how behavior in markets operated by others (e.g., bilateral 
    power sales markets and power markets operated by unaffiliated power 
    exchanges) affects Regional Transmission Organization operations and 
    conversely how Regional Transmission Organization operations affect the 
    performance of power markets operated by others.
        (iv) The Regional Transmission Organization must provide reports on 
    market power abuses and market design flaws to the Commission and 
    affected regulatory authorities. The reports must contain specific 
    recommendations about how observed market power abuses and market flaws 
    can be corrected.
        (7) Planning and expansion. The Regional Transmission Organization 
    must be responsible for planning necessary transmission additions and 
    upgrades that will enable it to provide efficient, reliable and non-
    discriminatory transmission service and coordinate such efforts with 
    the appropriate state authorities. The Regional Transmission 
    Organization must carry out this function by satisfying the standards 
    listed in paragraphs (j)(7)(i) and (ii) of this section, or by 
    demonstrating that an alternative proposal is consistent with or 
    superior to satisfying such standards.
        (i) The Regional Transmission Organization planning and expansion 
    process must encourage market-driven operating and investment actions 
    for preventing and relieving congestion.
        (ii) The Regional Transmission Organization's planning and 
    expansion process must accommodate efforts by state regulatory 
    commissions to create multi-state agreements to review and approve new 
    transmission facilities. The Regional Transmission Organization's 
    planning and expansion process must be coordinated with programs of 
    existing RTGs where necessary.
        (iii) If the Regional Transmission Organization is unable to 
    satisfy this requirement when it commences operation, it must file a 
    plan with the Commission with specified milestones that will ensure 
    that it meets this requirement no later than three years after initial 
    operation.
        (k) Open architecture. (1) Any proposal to participate in a 
    Regional Transmission Organization must not contain any provision that 
    would limit the capability of the Regional Transmission Organization to 
    evolve in ways that would improve its efficiency, consistent with the 
    requirements in paragraphs (i) and (j) of this section.
        (2) Nothing in this regulation precludes an approved Regional 
    Transmission Organization from seeking to evolve with respect to its 
    organizational design, market design, geographic scope, ownership 
    arrangements, methods of operational control and other appropriate ways 
    if the changes are consistent with the
    
    [[Page 31440]]
    
    requirements of this section. Any future filing seeking approval of 
    such changes must demonstrate that the proposed changes will meet the 
    requirements of paragraphs (i) and (j) of this section and this 
    paragraph (k).
    
        Note: The following appendixes will not appear in the Code of 
    Federal Regulations.
    
    Appendix A--Staff Summary of FERC-Industry ISO Conferences
    
    [Docket No. PL98-5-000]
    
        During 1998, the Commission conducted a series of eight public 
    conferences with the electric power industry for the purpose of 
    examining its ISO policies. The Commission wanted to learn whether 
    any changes to its policies that affect the development of ISOs and 
    other forms of regional grid management structures are appropriate 
    to further promote competition and reliability in bulk power 
    markets. The Commission also wanted to learn whether it should also 
    be more prescriptive in this area. The Commission also focused on 
    the future of ISOs in administering the electric transmission grid 
    on a regional basis. 1
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \1\ See Inquiry Concerning the Commission's Policy on 
    Independent System Operators, Notice of Conference (dated March 13, 
    1998), and Notice of Panels for Conference (dated April 7, 1998). 
    See also, Inquiry Concerning the Commission's Policy on Independent 
    System Operators, Notice of Regional Conferences (dated April 27, 
    1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    ISO Trust, Flexibility and Mandate
    
        Participants largely agreed on the need for improved regional 
    organizations to operate the grid and implement reliability rules. 
    They emphasized the need for transmission operations to be 
    structurally independent, trustworthy, and fair in order for 
    competitive generation markets to flourish. There seemed to be a 
    consensus that any Commission ISO policy should be flexible to meet 
    the needs and characteristics of each region and its state 
    commissions, and that the Commission should avoid any one-size-fits-
    all approach to ISO structure and functions that might stifle 
    innovation. Participants differed, however, on whether the 
    Commission should require or merely encourage ISOs.
        Reasons offered as to why the voluntary approach to ISO 
    formation has not worked uniformly across the Nation included: (1) 
    some states that have not yet decided on retail access believe that 
    an ISO inevitably will lead to retail access; (2) some low-cost 
    states are concerned that ISOs and retail access will increase their 
    electric rates because utilities will be able to use ISOs to sell 
    their low-cost power elsewhere; (3) some see ISOs as overly 
    expensive, burdensome, and bureaucratic; and (4) some see 
    transmission access as having improved enough through the on-going 
    implementation of Order Nos. 888 and 889.
        Recommendations on what the Commission should do next ranged 
    from wait and see, to act decisively now. Some in the first camp 
    claimed that the Commission lacks the authority to mandate 
    participation in ISOs. Some counseled that the Commission should 
    continue to just nurture the formation of ISOs and allow development 
    of organizations that best fit the local needs of a particular 
    region and avoid stifling innovation by continuing the case-by-case 
    approval of voluntary ISO submittals. Some suggested that the 
    Commission merely define its basic objective as the availability of 
    efficient and reliable transmission service on a non-discriminatory 
    basis, and to encourage hold-outs to join.
        Those conference participants favoring stronger action contended 
    that functional unbundling has not worked well enough and that it is 
    unrealistic to expect it to do so. Many claimed that some vertically 
    integrated utilities are employing preferential reliability 
    practices or manipulating postings of ATC and capacity benefit 
    margin values to favor their own wholesale merchant functions. They 
    further claimed that there is a reluctance to lodge complaints out 
    of concern that the Commission may not take strong action or there 
    might be reprisals by the utilities. Others contended that some 
    utilities are impeding ISO formation by refusing to participate, and 
    that, as long as ISO boundaries are drawn by the voluntary decisions 
    of the transmission owners to pick and choose the ISO which most 
    advances their individual corporate and competitive objectives, the 
    result is likely to be ISOs whose shape and composition impede its 
    ability to create a true competitive market. Strong action advocates 
    also seemed to be looking for clear guidance on transmission 
    pricing, operation of energy markets, and the phase-in of certain 
    ISO responsibilities.
        Many of those concerned about a patchwork of ISO grid coverage 
    suggested that now is the time for the Commission to mandate ISOs 
    (possibly tempered with incentives), or at least mandate 
    participation in negotiations on ISO formation. Several suggested 
    that the Commission work with the states to develop specific 
    directives and guidelines as a way to assure that enough momentum on 
    ISO formation is achieved. One guideline that was suggested would 
    incorporate a standardized ISO tariff and a standardized set of 
    rules governing reciprocity among ISOs. It would be coupled with a 
    flexible ISO design that could accommodate varying regional needs. 
    Others variously recommended (1) specification of minimum ISO 
    functions as a basic model and letting the regions justify any 
    departure therefrom; (2) ordering the formation of ISOs and allowing 
    enough time for each region to develop a proposal that best suits 
    its local needs; and (3) exercising all Commission authority to 
    monitor and manage comprehensive ISO formation.
    
    ISO Purposes and Functions
    
        The many notions about what the proper functions of an ISO 
    should be seemed to reflect what each participant saw as the 
    critical regional objectives (e.g., promotion of retail access; more 
    efficient grid operation, planning and expansion; enhanced system 
    reliability; elimination of loop flow issues; solution of ``seams'' 
    problems between control areas; elimination of rate pancaking; 
    improved congestion management; enhanced reserve sharing; 
    establishment of one-stop shopping through creation of a regional 
    OASIS; enhanced market monitoring, and improved real-time 
    communication among all transmission entities). Accordingly, 
    suggested ISO functions included: control area responsibilities; 
    numerous security coordinator and reliability duties; impartial 
    operation of a regional OASIS to improve ATC postings; 
    administration of an ISO-wide tariff; generation redispatch duties 
    to relieve congestion; and ancillary services markets coordination 
    responsibilities.
        Some participants argued, however, that certain functions should 
    not be foisted upon ISOs. Some contended that it would be 
    detrimental to the markets and the administration of ISOs if ISOs 
    become involved with functions that are not natural monopolies such 
    as power exchange activities because this would compromise the ISO's 
    independence in fulfilling its primary transmission 
    responsibilities. Many cautioned that an ISO should not be involved 
    in market monitoring beyond data gathering tasks, due to the 
    attendant administrative burden and cost, and because enforcement 
    should be the sole prerogative of regulatory authorities.
    
    ISO Size
    
        Most participants agreed that, as a general proposition, bigger 
    ISOs can be more effective than smaller ISOs, given the growth in 
    unbundled power sales and the lessening of traditional cooperation 
    among utilities that have now become competitors. For example, with 
    regard to the connection between size and effective reliability 
    management, it was pointed out that an excessive number of control 
    areas in the Midwest has inhibited communication and coordination, 
    and contributed to several of the Midwest's recent reliability 
    ``near misses.''
        Basically, participants saw the ``proper'' size as depending 
    upon a number of factors: (1) The purposes and functions of the ISO 
    (such as enhancing reliability or accommodating regional power 
    markets); (2) the operating characteristics and make-up of the local 
    regional transmission system; (3) being large enough to capture 
    scale economies yet not too big to operate without difficulty and 
    handle large volumes of next-hour transactions; (4) recognizing 
    historic coordination arrangements, trading patterns, and load 
    patterns; and (5) remaining responsive to local transmission 
    concerns and conventions on such matters as how wide an area over 
    which costs associated with transmission construction and generation 
    redispatch should be spread.
    
    Alternatives to ISOs
    
        A number of participants counseled that the Commission should 
    seriously consider alternatives to ISOs such as investor-owned 
    transcos, and independent grid administrators or schedulers (IGA or 
    ISA).
        IGA/ISA supporters were concerned about what could be quickly 
    implemented that would avoid the high costs that seem to be 
    associated with comprehensive ISO initiatives, yet would provide 
    immediate control over the more egregious actions of some 
    transmission providers. IGA/ISA structures were described to include 
    any of the following: (1) One-stop shopping through an OASIS that 
    uniformly calculates ATC
    
    [[Page 31441]]
    
    values; (2) independent coordination of reservations and power flow 
    scheduling; and (3) fast-track dispute resolution. It was claimed 
    that such structures would avoid cost-shifting controversies and 
    congestion management complications because the IGA/ISA members 
    would continue to operate their own transmission and set their own 
    individual rates. While there was some support for IGA/ISA 
    structures as an interim step toward full ISO formation, many 
    participants expressed concern about the Commission approving 
    ``watered-down'' versions of an ISO that fail to address pressing 
    needs for grid expansion and pricing reform.
        Transco supporters argued that a transco can offer everything 
    that a full ISO can provide, plus the additional efficiency that is 
    inherent in combining operation and ownership of transmission assets 
    driven by the same corporate and market incentives. Transcos were 
    also said to provide more opportunity for shareholders to benefit 
    from the strong performance of any facilities placed under an ISO. 
    As such, transcos were touted as the natural end-state of 
    transmission restructuring. ISO supporters countered that the ISO 
    structure need not foreclose passing incentive-rate revenues on to 
    transmission owners. They also claimed that, unlike a transco, an 
    ISO is not dependent upon the successful transfer of all of the 
    transmission assets within a region and, if an ISO is sized wrong, 
    it can be more readily corrected than a transco for the same reason.
        Finally, some participants suggested that ISOs and transcos are 
    actually complementary forms. Others claimed that who owns the 
    transmission is irrelevant as long as the regional grid operator is 
    independent; it is big enough to internalize loop flows; it directs 
    region-wide transmission planning; and it allows for competitive 
    bidding on the installation of new facilities to expand the grid.
    
    ISO Pricing and Cost-shifting Concerns
    
        Some participants supported differing forms of ISO rate 
    structures: flow-based rates, distance-based pricing, average-cost 
    based rates, and locational marginal cost-based pricing. Many 
    cautioned that a Commission mandate on the use of any particular 
    tariff structure would be a major obstacle to the voluntary 
    formation of ISOs; therefore, they recommended that the Commission 
    provide great deference to the needs of each region as to what 
    locally is seen to be fair and reasonable pricing.
        In particular, many participants raised concerns about cost-
    shifting within an ISO that might result from membership with 
    significantly disparate embedded transmission costs and imposition 
    of an ISO-wide access tariff that reflects some composite of such 
    costs. These participants counseled that the Commission should allow 
    ``license plate'' access rates that reflect only the cost of the 
    transmission zone within the ISO in which the load to be served is 
    located. One participant suggested, however, that even license plate 
    rates can raise cost-shifting concerns, if the cost of an upgrade 
    that is used primarily for the benefit of external loads is included 
    in the cost basis for the affected zone.
    
    Non-jurisdictional Transmission Participation
    
        Most participants expressed the view that government-owned and 
    other regional non-jurisdictional transmission owners need to fully 
    participate in an ISO in order for it to be completely successful. 
    It was suggested that this is especially true for the West, where 
    large amounts of non-jurisdictional transmission is controlled by 
    Bonneville Power Administration, Western Area Power Administration, 
    Southwestern Power Administration, large municipals, cooperatives, 
    public power districts, British Columbia Hydro, and the Alberta 
    grid. Some participants wanted the Commission to provide guidance on 
    how to bring public power and other non-jurisdictional transmission 
    owners into an ISO. In this regard, some suggested that the 
    Department of Energy needs to issue guidance to the federal power 
    marketing agencies on their active support of any ISO initiatives. 
    Public power participants, who strongly supported ISOs, expressed 
    concern that any ISO participation on their part could adversely 
    affect the financing of their facilities due to Internal Revenue 
    Code ``private-use'' restrictions.
    
    Existing Transmission Contracts
    
        Some participants emphasized the need for ISOs to honor 
    (grandfather) existing transmission contract arrangements to 
    maintain any benefits that were bargained. Others emphasized the 
    need for ISOs to abrogate any existing transmission contracts to 
    eliminate any preferential transmission treatment. Those favoring 
    grandfathering, however, acknowledged that it could become a very 
    complicated administrative matter in the event that there is 
    insufficient transmission capacity to serve everyone.
    
    Panelists
    
        The Commission held conferences in Washington, D.C. and in seven 
    cities in different regions of the country.
    
    Washington, D.C.
    
        In the lead-off two-day conference held on April 15-16, 1998, in 
    Washington, D.C., approximately 400 individuals attended each day. 
    Panelists represented:
    
    American Electric Power Company
    American Public Power Association
    California Independent System Operator
    California Independent System Operator, Market Surveillance 
    Committee (by Stanford University)
    California Public Utilities Commission
    Cameron McKenna LLP
    Cinergy Energy Services, Inc.
    Commonwealth Edison Company
    Coalition For A Competitive Electric Market (by Enron Corporation)
    Economic Analysis Group
    Edison Electric Institute
    Edison Electric Institute (by NERA)
    Electric Power Supply Association.
    Entergy Services, Inc.
    Harvard University (John F. Kennedy School of Government)
    Industrial Consumers (by Electricity Consumers Resource Council)
    ISO New England
    Members Systems of the New York Power Pool (by Putnam, Hayes & 
    Bartlette, Inc.)
    Mid-Continent Area Power Pool (by Morgan, Lewis & Bockius)
    Montana Power Company
    National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (by Iowa 
    Utilities Board)
    National Rural Electric Cooperative Association
    NGC Corporation
    Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission
    PJM Interconnection, L.L.C.
    Public Utilities Commission of Ohio
    Public Service Commission of the State of New York
    Rhode Island Public Utilities Commission
    Secretary of Energy's Task Force on Electric System Reliability
    Sithe Energies, Inc. (By Economics Resource Group)
    Transmission Access Study Group (by Wisconsin Public Power, Inc.)
    Transmission Alliance (by Merrill Lynch)
    Transmission Dependent Utility Systems (by Arkansas Electric 
    Corporation
    U.S. Department of Justice
    U.S. Generating Company and PJM Supporting Companies (by Steptoe & 
    Johnson LLP)
    Wabash Valley Power Association, Inc.
    Wisconsin Electric Power Company
    
    Phoenix
    
        Almost 90 people attended the May 28, 1998, Phoenix conference. 
    Panelists represented:
    
    Arizona Corporation Commission
    Arizona Public Service Company
    Automated Power Exchange, Inc.
    California ISO
    Desert STAR
    K.R. Saline & Associates
    Colorado Springs Utilities
    Cyprus Climax Metals, BHP Copper, Phelps Dodge, ASARCO and Motorola 
    (by Energy Strategies, Inc.)
    Goldman Sachs & Co.
    Northern California Power Agency.
    Salt River Project Agricultural Improvement and Power District
    Southwest Power Trading Council (by Enron Corp.)
    Tri-State Generation and Transmission Cooperative, Inc.
    
    Kansas City
    
        About 90 people attended the May 29, 1998, Kansas City 
    conference. Panelists represented:
    
    City Utilities of Springfield, Missouri
    Clarksdale Public Utilities Commission
    Cooperative Power Association
    Iowa Utilities Board
    Kansas Corporation Commission
    Mid-America Regulatory Conference (by Kansas Corporation Commission)
    Midwest Coalition for Effective Competition (by MCES and 
    Environmental Law and Policy Center)
    Midwest ISO Participants (by Wisconsin Electric Power Company and 
    Ameren Services)
    Minnesota Department of Public Service
    
    [[Page 31442]]
    
    Missouri Office of Public Counsel
    Missouri Public Service Commission
    Nebraska Public Power District
    Northern States Power Company
    Public Utility Commission of Texas
    Shook, Hardy, Bacon, LLP
    Southwest Power Pool
    
    New Orleans
    
        The June 1, 1998, New Orleans conference panelists represented:
    
    Arkansas Electric Cooperative
    Entergy Corporation
    Gulf Coast Power Marketers Coalition
    Houston Industries Power Corporation, Inc.
    Lafayette Utilities System
    Louisiana Energy Users Group
    Public Service Commission of Yazoo City, Mississippi
    Southern Company Services, Inc.
    Southwest Power Pool
    Southwestern Public Service Company
    
    Indianapolis
    
        About two hundred people attended the June 4, 1998, Indianapolis 
    conference. Among the panelists represented:
    
    AMEREN
    American Municipal Power of Ohio
    Cinergy Services Inc.
    Citizens Action Coalition of Indiana
    Consumers Energy Company
    Detroit Edison Company
    Energy Michigan
    FirstEnergy Corporation
    Illinois Industrial Energy Consumers
    Indiana Municipal Power Agency
    Indiana Utility Regulatory Commission
    Kentucky Public Service Commission
    Madison Gas and Electric Company
    Mid-America Regulatory Commissioners (by Michigan Public Service 
    Commission)
    Midwest Coalition for Effective Competition
    Midwest ISO Participants
    Michigan Public Power Agency
    Minnesota Public Utilities Commission
    Public Utilities Commission of Ohio
    Wisconsin Electric Power Company
    
    Portland
    
        About 160 people attended the June 5, 1998, Portland conference. 
    Panelists represented:
    
    Automated Power Exchange
    Bonneville Power Administration
    California ISO
    California Municipal Utilities Association
    California Public Utilities Commission
    Chelen County PUD (on behalf of Independent Grid Scheduler)
    CIBC Oppenheimer Corp.
    Columbia Falls Aluminum Company, et al.
    Idaho Power Company
    Idaho Public Utilities Commission
    Industrial Customers of Northwest Utilities
    Land and Water Fund of the Rockies Energy Project
    Montana Department of Environmental Quality
    Montana Power Company
    Northern California Power Agency.
    Oregon Public Utilities Commission
    Pacific Northwest Generating Cooperative
    PacifiCorp
    Platte River Power Authority
    Public Power Council
    Public Service Company of Colorado
    Puget Sound Energy, Inc.
    Transmission Agency of Northern California
    Turlock Irrigation District
    University of California
    Washington Utilities and Transportation Commission
    Western Power Trading Forum
    Western Regional Transmission Association
    
    Richmond
    
        About 55 people attended the June 8, 1998, Richmond conference. 
    Panelists represented:
    
    Blue Ridge Power Agency
    LG&E Energy (on behalf of Midwest ISO Participants)
    Mid-Atlantic Power Association
    North Carolina Electric Membership Corporation
    Old Dominion Electric Cooperative
    TransEnergie U.S., Ltd.
    Virginia State Corporation Commission
    Virginia Committee for Fair Utility Rates and Old Dominion Committee 
    for Fair Utility Rates
    Virginia Electric & Power Company
    
    Orlando
    
        The June 8, 1998, Orlando conference was attended by about 100 
    people. Panelists represented:
    
    Dynergy
    Enron Power Marketing (by Basford & Associates)
    Florida Municipal Power Agency
    Florida Power & Light Company
    Florida Power Corporation
    Florida Public Service Commission
    Florida Reliability Coordinating Council, Inc.
    Morgan Stanley & Company
    Municipal Electric Authority of Georgia
    National Grid Company of England and Wales
    Seminole Electric Cooperative, Inc.
    
    Other Commenters
    
    Alabama Electric Cooperative, Inc.
    Allegheny Power, et al.
    Barbara R. Barkovich
    California Department of Water Resources
    California Electricity Oversight Board
    California Independent Energy Producers Association
    Central Illinois Light Company
    Citizens Group Responsible Use of Rural & Agricultural Land
    Commonwealth of Pennsylvania Utility Commission
    Commonwealth of Virginia, Division of Energy Regulations
    Commonwealth of Virginia State Corporation Commission
    Consumer Counsel Office of the Attorney General of Virginia
    Consumers Energy Company
    Cooperative Power Association
    CSW Operating Companies
    CSX Transportation
    D. Basford & Associates, Inc.
    Dairyland Power Cooperative
    Department of Energy, Bonneville Power Administration
    Desert Southwest Power Trading Council
    Dominion Resources Inc.
    Economic Resources Group, Inc.
    Electricities of North Carolina, Inc.
    Electricity Consumers Resource Council, et al.
    Energy Strategies, Inc.
    Fiona Woolf
    Georgia System Operations Corporation, et al.
    Goldman, Sachs & Company
    Gregory J. Werden
    Gridco Commenters
    Houston Industries, Inc.
    IES Utilities Inc., et al.
    Illinois Commerce Commission
    Independent Grid Scheduler Organizing Group
    Independent Power Producers of New York, Inc.
    Indiana Energy Michigan
    Indiana Office of Utility Consumer Counsel
    Kentucky Utilities Company
    Kentucky Public Service Commission
    Large Public Power Council
    Marija D. Ilic
    Mid-Atlantic Public Service Commissions
    Midwest Independent Transmission System Operator, Inc.
    Midwest Municipal Intervenors, et al.
    Minnesota Power Company
    Minnesota Public Utilities Commission
    Mississippi Office of Public Counsel
    Montana Public Service Commission
    Multiple Public Interest Organizations
    New York Mercantile Exchange
    New Mexico Industrial Energy Consumers
    Northern Indiana Public Service Company
    Northwest Power Plant Planning Council
    Oak Ridge National Laboratory
    Office of Ohio Consumers' Counsel
    Oklahoma Corporation Commission
    Oklahoma Gas and Electric Company
    Orange & Rockland Utilities
    Oregon Public Utilities Commission
    Otter Tail Power Company
    Pacific Gas & Electric Company
    PECO Energy Company
    Pennsylvania Office of Consumers Advocate
    PJM Supporting Companies
    Portland General Electric Company
    Powersmiths International, Inc.
    Project For Sustainable FERC Policy
    ProLiance Energy, LLC
    Public Service Commission of Wisconsin
    Public Service Electric & Gas Company
    Public Utilities Board of the City of Brownsville, Texas
    Public Utility District No. 1 of Chelan County, Washington
    Selkirk Cogen Partners, L.P.
    Sierra Pacific Power
    Southern California Gas Company, et al.
    Southwest Transmission Dependent Utility Group
    Staff of Bureau of Economics of the Federal Trade Commission
    State of California Public Utilities Commission
    State of Florida Public Service Commission
    State of Idaho & Idaho Public Utilities Commission
    State of Kansas Citizens' Utility Ratepayer Board's
    State of Minnesota Public Utilities Commission
    State of Montana Department of Environmental Quality
    State of New York Public Service Commission
    State of Rhode Island and Province Plantations
    
    [[Page 31443]]
    
    The Williams Companies Inc.
    Transmission Operators of Public Service Company of Colorado
    Tucson Electric Power Company
    University of Arizona
    Virginia Committee for Fair Utility Rates, et al.
    Washington Department of Community, Trade and Economic Development 
    Energy Policy Group
    Western Area Power Administration
    Wisconsin Intervenors
    Wisconsin Public Power, Inc.
    Wisconsin Public Service Corporation
    
    Appendix B--Staff Summary of FERC Consultations With the States
    
    [Docket No. RM99-2-000]
    
        In Docket No. RM99-2-000, as part of a broader inquiry into its 
    RTO policies, the Commission held a series of three regional 
    conferences to elicit the views and recommendations of state 
    regulatory authorities with respect to the development of 
    independent RTOs and whether and how it should use its authority 
    under section 202(a) of the Federal Power Act.\1\ The Commission 
    also wanted to learn whether the goals of full competition and non-
    discriminatory transmission access can be achieved in the absence of 
    broad participation by transmission-owning utilities in RTOs. 
    Conferences were held in St. Louis, Las Vegas, and Washington, D.C. 
    in February 1999.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \1\ See Regional Transmission Organizations, Notice Of Intent To 
    Consult Under Section 202(a) dated November 24, 1998, and Notice Of 
    Dates And Locations For Consultation Sessions With State Commissions 
    (dated January 13, 1999).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Need for Commission Mandate
    
        There was little real dispute by participants over the need for 
    independent and impartial regional grid management, whether it be 
    for improved grid operation, increased reliability, identifying 
    promising new generation locations, broadening markets by reducing 
    rate pancaking, or all of these. Most of the states also recognized 
    that the Commission is the necessary and appropriate facilitator for 
    forming RTOs, due to its broad jurisdiction. However, comments as to 
    how best the Commission should proceed next were mixed.
        One state wondered whether the Commission has the authority to 
    mandate RTOs. Several Northeastern and Mid-Atlantic states that 
    already have strong ISOs were concerned that the Commission might 
    disturb their ISOs before an adequate period of time has elapsed to 
    reveal their strengths and weaknesses. One state suggested that the 
    Commission should look into setting up a joint board of state and 
    federal regulators on RTO issues. Some Southeastern states saw no 
    need for a Federal policy on RTOs right now. They felt that the grid 
    is operated adequately and preferred to let the market sort RTO 
    developments.
        States west of the Appalachians generally recognized the need 
    for structural independence of transmission through RTOs beyond 
    functional unbundling sooner rather than later and saw a need for 
    strong Commission leadership on RTO formation. They differed on the 
    urgency and the necessary extent of Commission involvement. Many of 
    the states advocating a more aggressive role were located in the 
    Midwest, which had experienced price spikes during the summer of 
    1998.
        One state insisted that Commission action is needed to quicken 
    the pace of RTO formation so that development of competitive 
    electricity markets is not delayed. One vigorously complained about 
    the persistent lack of fuller RTO participation in the Midwest and 
    the possible strategic advantage to vertically integrated utilities 
    not participating. To counter the fragmentation in the Midwest, it 
    recommended that the Commission mandate utility participation or, at 
    a minimum, eliminate pancaked transmission rates within each 
    regional reliability council. Another suggested that the Commission 
    interpret any utility's refusal to join an RTO as an indicator of 
    undue discrimination. One recommended that the Commission strongly 
    promote fuller participation in RTOs by using a combination of 
    ``carrots'' and ``sticks'' as incentives.
    
    Flexibility
    
        A pervasive theme was the need for the Commission to avoid 
    taking a one-size-fits-all approach to RTOs. Many states recommended 
    that, if the Commission wants to establish RTO policy pursuant to 
    its section 202(a) authority, the policy must be implemented in a 
    way that adequately recognizes any regional differences in industry 
    structures. One Midwestern state counseled that the Commission 
    should partner with the states to develop a memorandum of 
    understanding (MOU) on regional transmission matters. The MOU would 
    outline common desires and objectives, describe the regulatory tools 
    to get there, and the circumstances under which the tools would be 
    used.
        Other states suggested that the Commission, before it considers 
    taking any stronger action, issue guidelines and allow enough time 
    for each state to determine which are appropriate for it in forming 
    regional RTOs. The guidelines would reflect determinations on such 
    issues as how to encourage participation by and otherwise deal with 
    non-jurisdictional transmission entities; whether to allow a state 
    to opt out of a mandatory RTO policy; and how to ensure that no 
    state's economy is harmed by an RTO. Several states suggested that 
    cost/benefit analyses be done for each region. Finally, numerous 
    states recommended that the Commission not mingle retail competition 
    issues with RTO issues, contending that retail choice is a state 
    prerogative.
    
    RTO Size
    
        Several states were concerned about how large is large enough 
    for an RTO, and how the Commission expects to set the proper 
    regional boundaries. In the East, states served by established ISOs 
    expressed concern that their ISOs might have to incur additional 
    costs for modifications that might be required to meet a potential 
    Commission size criterion before market forces have had the chance 
    to suggest an appropriate size. Some suggested that because the 
    existing ISOs are so crucial to promoting retail competition in 
    states that have already adopted retail choice, the Commission 
    should carefully consider any order that would expand, merge, or 
    restructure an existing ISO. Some states cautioned that expanding 
    their existing ISOs beyond a certain point might also lead to 
    reliability problems or inheriting problems from adjacent regions.
        One state recommended that only minimum size criteria be 
    established rather than the specific locations of boundaries. Other 
    states recommended that, if the Commission insists on establishing 
    regional boundaries, that it consider the relative costs and 
    benefits of an RTO sized according to each regional boundary set. 
    One state suggested that the Commission rely on the existing NERC 
    regional councils as the starting point for determining proper RTO 
    boundaries. Another state suggested that the Mid-Continent Area 
    Power Pool (MAPP) and Mid-American Interconnected Network (MAIN) 
    interfaces should be placed within a single RTO. Some western states 
    contended that, while only one regional reliability council serves 
    the West, many non-jurisdictional cooperative and government 
    utilities control such a substantial amount of transmission that 
    creating RTOs in the West will be difficult absent clear direction 
    from the Commission.
    
    Alternative Forms of RTOs
    
        While several states argued that competing ISO and transco 
    structures could lead to further fragmentation and limited RTO 
    operations, others argued that mandating specific forms of RTOs now 
    would impede the ability of the states and regions to adopt models 
    that are best suited for their particular needs and that the 
    Commission should not lock in particular RTO structures but should 
    instead retain flexibility to address changing future needs. One 
    state favored a non-profit ISO structure, because it doubted that 
    the industry would lend itself to the development of any transco 
    with sufficient geographic coverage and adequate independence from 
    generation interests. It noted, however, that if a for-profit 
    transco could meet the size and independence criteria, the transco 
    would have advantages over an ISO in the form of a stronger business 
    orientation and superior access to capital for grid expansion.
    
    Transmission Cost Shifting and Low Power Cost States
    
        Many states counseled that the Commission should allow a region 
    to opt-out of an average cost based RTO-wide rate, if such a rate 
    would shift highly disparate embedded transmission costs among its 
    RTO customers and force some to suffer transmission rate increases. 
    Many western states suggested that concern over the enhanced ability 
    of utilities to export their low cost power to other regions through 
    an RTO, as well as concerns about transmission cost shifting, not 
    only led to the demise of the IndeGo ISO but has thwarted further 
    RTO development in the West.
    
    [[Page 31444]]
    
    Panelists
    
    St. Louis
    
        About 120 people attended the February 11, 1999, conference in 
    St. Louis. Panelists represented commissions in:
    
        Arkansas
        Florida
        Illinois
        Indiana
        Iowa
        Kansas
        Kentucky
        Michigan
        Minnesota
        Missouri
        Nebraska
        North Dakota
        Ohio
        Oklahoma
        South Dakota
        Tennessee
        Texas
        Wisconsin
    
    Las Vegas
    
        About 96 people attended the February 12, 1999, conference held 
    in Las Vegas. Panelists represented commissions in:
        Arizona
        California
        Colorado
        Idaho
        Montana
        Nevada
        New Mexico
        Oregon
        Utah
        Washington
        Wyoming
    
    Washington, D.C.
    
        The panelists at the February 17, 1999, conference in 
    Washington, D.C. represented commissions in:
    
        Alabama
        Connecticut
        District of Columbia
        Georgia
        Maryland
        Massachusetts
        Mississippi
        New Jersey
        New York
        North Carolina
        Pennsylvania
        Rhode Island
        West Virginia
    
    Other Commenters
    
    Canadian Electricity Association
    ISO New England
    Mid-American Regulatory Commissioners
    National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners
    New England Conference of Public Utilities Commissioners, Inc.
    Regional Electric Power Cooperation
    Virginia State Corporation Commission
    Western Interstate Energy Board
    
    Appendix C--Existing Configurations
    
        This Appendix depicts the three existing configurations 
    discussed in Section III.D.2: the three electric interconnections 
    within the continental United States, the ten NERC reliability 
    councils, and the twenty-three NERC security coordinator areas.
    
    [The attachments to this Appendix are available for public 
    inspection and copying during normal business hours in the Public 
    Reference Room at 888 First Street, N.E., Room 2A, Washington, D.C. 
    20426, and through the Commission's Records and Information 
    Management System (RIMS). RIMS is available remotely via Internet 
    through FERC's Home page using the RIMS link or the Energy 
    Information Online icon.]
    
    [FR Doc. 99-12553 Filed 6-9-99; 8:45 am]
    BILLING CODE 6717-01-P
    
    
    

Document Information

Published:
06/10/1999
Department:
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
Entry Type:
Proposed Rule
Action:
Notice of proposed rulemaking.
Document Number:
99-12553
Dates:
Initial comments are due August 16, 1999. Reply comments are due September 15, 1999.
Pages:
31390-31444 (55 pages)
Docket Numbers:
Docket No. RM99-2-000
PDF File:
99-12553.pdf
CFR: (11)
18 CFR 35.34(f))
18 CFR 35.34(i)(4)(i))
18 CFR 35.34(i)(4)(ii))
18 CFR 35.34(i)(1)(ii))
18 CFR 35.34(j)(2)(i))
More ...