94-15443. Expanded Interconnection With Local Telephone Company Facilities  

  • [Federal Register Volume 59, Number 122 (Monday, June 27, 1994)]
    [Unknown Section]
    [Page 0]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 94-15443]
    
    
    [[Page Unknown]]
    
    [Federal Register: June 27, 1994]
    
    
    =======================================================================
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
    
    47 CFR Parts 61, 64, and 69
    
    [CC Docket 91-141, FCC No. 94-118]
    
     
    
    Expanded Interconnection With Local Telephone Company Facilities
    
    AGENCY: Federal Communications Commission.
    
    ACTION: Final rule.
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    SUMMARY: The Commission required Tier 1 local exchange carriers (LECs) 
    (except members of the National Exchange Carrier Association (NECA)) to 
    provide to interested third parties, including competitive access 
    providers (CAPs), interexchange carriers, (IXCs), and end users, 
    signalling information necessary to provide tandem switching services. 
    These parties will thus, for the first time, be able to carry traffic 
    of multiple IXCs from LEC end offices to their own tandems, switch 
    traffic at that point, and deliver the traffic to the appropriate IXC. 
    LECs must offer signalling information from their equal access end 
    offices pursuant to tariff.
    
    EFFECTIVE DATE: September 15, 1994.
    
    FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
    Gary L. Phillips (202) 632-4048 or Linda L. Haller (202) 632-1298.
    
    SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a summary of the Commission's Third 
    Report and Order in CC Docket No. 91-141, adopted May 19, 1994, and 
    released May 27, 1994. The full text of this decision is available for 
    inspection and copying during normal business hours in the FCC 
    Reference Center (Room 239), 1919 M Street, NW., Washington, DC 20554. 
    The complete text of this decision also may be purchased from the 
    Commission's copy contractor, International Transcription Service, 
    Inc., 2100 M Street, NW., Suite 140, Washington, DC 20037, (202) 857-
    3800.
    
    Paperwork Reduction Act
    
        Public reporting burden for this collection of information is 
    estimated to average 37 hours per response, including the time for 
    reviewing instructions, searching existing data sources, gathering and 
    maintaining the data needed, and completing and reviewing the 
    collection of information. Send comments regarding this burden estimate 
    or any other aspect of this collection of information, including 
    suggestions for reducing the burden, to the Federal Communications 
    Commission, Records Management Division, Paperwork Reduction Project, 
    Washington, DC 20554 and to the Office of Management and Budget, 
    Paperwork Reduction Project, Washington, DC 20503.
    
    Summary of the Order
    
        1. The Commission found that this decision represents another step 
    in a series of efforts to remove barriers to competition in interstate 
    access services. It stated that while the Commission's earlier expanded 
    interconnection decisions opened the door to competition in special 
    access and switched transport transmission services, interconnectors, 
    however, had to rely on LECs to perform the switching functions 
    necessary to provide switched transport. The Commission concluded that 
    the Order will enable interconnectors, as well as other parties, to 
    provide tandem switching functions for switched transport services.
        2. The Commission concluded that LEC-provision of signalling 
    information will open the door to third parties to provide competitive 
    tandem switching services. By further reducing barriers to competition 
    in switched access services, this action will benefit all users of 
    tandem switching, especially small IXCs that tend to rely heavily on 
    tandem-switched transport, who will benefit from more competitively 
    priced tandem switching services. The Commission also found that its 
    action should promote more efficient use and deployment of the 
    country's telecommunications networks, encourage technological 
    innovation, and exert downward pressure on access charges and long-
    distance rates, all of which should contribute to economic growth and 
    the creation of new job opportunities. In addition, these measures 
    should increase access to diverse facilities, which could improve 
    network reliability.
        3. The Commission required Tier 1 LECs (except NECA pool members) 
    to provide signalling information necessary for tandem switching from 
    LEC equal access end offices to any interested third party (hereinafter 
    sometimes referred to as ``tandem switching providers'' or ``TSPs''). 
    (Tier 1 LECs are those with $100 million or more in annual regulated 
    revenues for a sustained period of time.) In end offices in which 
    common channel signalling (CCS or SS7) is available, TSPs shall have 
    the option of receiving signalling information via SS7 or multi-
    frequency (MF) signalling. The provision of this information will be 
    treated as a new service under the Commission's price caps regime. Tier 
    1 LECs must file tariff amendments to reflect the availability of 
    signalling information from LEC equal access end offices within ninety 
    days of the publication of the Order in the Federal Register. Based on 
    the record and in light of prior decisions on pricing flexibility in 
    the Switched Transport Expanded Interconnection Order and in the 
    Transport proceeding, the Commission did not grant LECs additional 
    pricing flexibility at this time. The Commission also found that the 
    transport interconnection charge is sufficient to protect support flows 
    potentially affected by the provision of signalling information.
    
    Background
    
        4. The Commission stated that it has taken several initiatives to 
    increase competition in the long-distance market. First, in 1992, in 
    the Special Access Expanded Interconnection Order, the Commission 
    required Tier 1 LECs, except NECA pool members, to provide expanded 
    interconnection for interstate special access to all interested 
    parties.\1\ The Commission also stated that in 1993, it adopted the 
    Switched Transport Expanded Interconnection Order, in which the 
    Commission required LECs providing expanded interconnection for special 
    access to provide expanded interconnection for switched transport 
    service as well.\2\ In that order, the Commission opened the 
    opportunity for interconnectors to provide alternative transmission 
    services to LEC-provided direct-trunked transport and entrance 
    facilities by collocating transmission facilities in LEC end offices, 
    tandems, serving wire centers (SWCs), and certain remote nodes. The 
    Commission stated that as a result of those two actions, 
    interconnectors are now able to provide special access and switched 
    transport transmission services in competition with the LECs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \1\Expanded Interconnection with Local Telephone Company 
    Facilities, Report and Order and Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 7 
    FCC Rcd 7369 (1992), 57 FR 54323 (November 18, 1992), vacated in 
    part and remanded in part, Bell Atlantic v. FCC, No. 92-1619 (D.C. 
    Cir. June 10, 1994), recon., 8 FCC Rcd 127 (1992), recon., 8 FCC Rcd 
    7341 (1991).
        \2\Expanded Interconnection with Local Telephone Company 
    Facilities, Second Report and Order and Third Notice of Proposed 
    Rulemaking, 8 FCC Rcd 7374 (1993), 58 FR 48756 (September 17, 1993), 
    appeal pending sub nom. Bell Atlantic v. FCC, No. 93-1743 (D.C. 
    Cir., filed November 12, 1993).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        5. The Commission stated that only LECs, however, currently can 
    provide tandem switching functions. Third parties cannot now provide 
    such functions because they generally do not have access to the 
    signalling information necessary to switch and route traffic to IXCs. 
    Thus, virtually all tandem-switched transport currently must be routed 
    through LEC tandems and switched by the LECs at that point; 
    interconnectors can provide only the link between the LEC tandem and 
    the IXC point-of-presence (POP).
        6. The Commission stated that in a Second Notice of Proposed 
    Rulemaking (Notice),\3\ which is the subject of this proceeding, it 
    proposed to broaden the scope of its access initiatives to address this 
    limitation. Specifically, the Commission proposed to require LECs to 
    provide other parties to offer tandem switching functions. Under this 
    proposal, interconnectors would be able to offer tandem-switched 
    transport, using their own tandems, in competition with the LECs. In 
    addition, third parties, such as IXCs, could obtain economies by 
    aggregating their traffic from end offices on a single direct trunk, 
    routing that traffic to a third-party tandem, and switching it at that 
    point.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \3\Expanded Interconnection with Local Telephone Company 
    Facilities, Second Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 7 FCC Rcd 7740 
    (1991), 56 FR 52496 (October 21, 1991).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Technical Requirements and Network Modifications
    
        7. The Commission stated that the record identifies four types of 
    signalling information used to provide switched transport: (1) The 
    Carrier Identification Code (CIC), which identifies the caller's 
    selected IXC; (2) the OZZ, which indicates the specific IXC trunk group 
    that is to carry the call; (3) the Automatic Number Identification 
    (ANI), which identifies the billed number; and (4) the Called Number 
    Identification (CNI), which identifies the called telephone number. 
    IXCs may use different trunk groups to carry different classes of 
    calls. For example, 0+ calls may be carried on a different trunk group 
    than direct-dialed domestic calls. The OZZ digits indicate the call 
    type, and thus the trunk group, onto which a particular call should be 
    routed.
    
    Requirement to Provide Signalling Information
    
        8. The Commission stated that currently, LECs transmit ANI and CNI 
    to their access customers on originating Feature Group D trunks from 
    LEC end offices and tandems. They do not, however, transmit the CIC and 
    OZZ codes to third parties because IXCs do not need this information to 
    route and bill calls. Thus, these latter codes are dropped by the LECs 
    from the signalling data stream after trunk selection has taken place. 
    In the case of direct-trunked traffic, the CIC and OZZ codes are 
    dropped at the originating end office; in the case of tandem-switched 
    traffic, they are dropped at the tandem. Because the CIC and OZZ codes 
    are needed for tandem switching and are not currently provided to third 
    parties, these data are the focus of this proceeding.
        9. The Commission affirmed its tentative conclusion that broader 
    interconnection requirements to facilitate access competition are in 
    the public interest. In accordance with this finding, the Commission 
    required Tier 1 LECs (except NECA pool members) to provide signalling 
    information from equal access end offices so that third parties may 
    install their own tandems to provide tandem-switching services. Third 
    parties may collocate at LEC end offices and provide their own tandem-
    switched transport between those end offices and their tandems, or they 
    may purchase LEC transport to their tandems. We do not require LECs to 
    provide signalling information for tandem-switching from their tandems 
    since we find that the record does not support the establishment of 
    such a requirement at this time.
        10. The Commission concluded that the availability to third parties 
    of signalling information needed for tandem switching could provide 
    significant public benefits. It would facilitate broader access 
    competition by enabling interconnectors to offer competitive interstate 
    tandem-switching and transport services. In addition, it would increase 
    opportunities for small IXCs to gain economies of scale by sharing 
    direct-routed transport facilities and providing their own tandem-
    switching. The Commission found that as it stated in the Notice, 
    broader access competition should exert downward pressure on tandem-
    switched transport rates, while fostering more efficient provisioning 
    of these services by new competitors and LECs. The Commission also 
    concluded that in addition, competition should encourage innovation and 
    investment in new technologies and could offer increased network 
    reliability through route diversity and redundancy. IXCs would benefit 
    from greater competition in the tandem-switched service market. Small 
    IXCs would especially benefit because they tend to rely more heavily on 
    tandem-switched transport than larger IXCs. The Commission also stated 
    that in addition, by promoting competition in tandem-switched transport 
    services and facilitating the use of direct-trunked transport by small 
    IXCs, these measures should help ensure more rational cost-based 
    pricing relationships between direct-trunked and tandem-switching 
    transport services, thereby lessening the need for regulatory controls 
    and fostering more efficient use of these services. All of these 
    benefits should contribute to economic growth--by enabling IXCs to use 
    more efficient transport arrangements, by fostering better, more 
    reliable, and more rationally priced access services, as well as by 
    creating new market opportunities for interconnectors.
        11. The Commission also concluded that LECs can make signalling 
    information available from their end offices at very little cost. 
    Indeed, the record indicates that the costs to LECs of providing such 
    information from end offices may well be de minimis, involving only a 
    simple change in the end office routing table. The Commission stated 
    that while a few LECs baldly assert that the costs of providing 
    signalling could be significant, these LECs do not substantiate their 
    allegations with cost estimates or data. Nor do they distinguish 
    between end-office generated and tandem-generated signalling 
    information. The Commission found that moreover, no party has shown 
    that the necessary modifications to LEC billing systems would be 
    unreasonably costly or burdensome, or that the asserted need to change 
    industry standards to accommodate the passage of CIC and OZZ codes over 
    Feature Group D represents a significant barrier to the implementation 
    of this proposal. The Commission concluded that any such measures could 
    be accomplished without undue burden or cost.
        12. The Commission stated that it was not persuaded that 
    competitive tandem switching services would require assignment of CICs 
    to IXCs. The record fails to indicate that any entity would actually 
    seek to offer or use that kind of routing dynamic. Even without 
    additional CIC assignments, IXCs would be able to designate a primary 
    route and an overflow route for their traffic, thereby securing the 
    benefits of both route and carrier diversity. Moreover, IXCs could vary 
    routing between a LEC and third party tandem on an end-office-by-end-
    office basis or, perhaps, based on OZZ codes--thereby designating one 
    as primary for a particular type of traffic and another for a different 
    type of traffic. No IXC indicates that these options are insufficient, 
    at least for now. Therefore, the Commission found, no additional CIC 
    code assignments would have to be made to accommodate competitive 
    tandem-switched networks.
        13. The Commission also found that the record belies any contention 
    that third parties do not really want signalling information and that 
    IXCs do not really want to use competitively-provided tandem-switching 
    services. The Commission found that the vast majority of parties, 
    including IXCs, CAPs, users, and some LECs, argue that unbundled 
    signalling information would allow development of alternatives to LEC 
    tandem-switched transport services and they urge us to make such 
    information available. The Commission stated that even if the measures 
    that it now takes do not produce an immediate change in the access 
    market, they will be beneficial in the long-term. By eliminating 
    barriers to competition in the provision of tandem-switched services, 
    this action will pave the way to a more competitive access market in 
    the future. The Commission also stated that the availability of 
    signalling information to third parties could, in itself and even 
    without actual entry into the market by competitive tandem-switching 
    providers, subject LEC pricing to some additional competitive 
    pressures. Since the costs of providing signalling information from 
    equal access end offices are so small, the Commission concluded, these 
    benefits are well worth the costs. The Commission also stated that LECs 
    should be required to offer signalling information from equal access 
    end offices is not based on application of the test that governs LEC 
    BSE offerings since signalling information is not a BSE, but that, 
    nevertheless, its conclusion was based on the same type of cost/benefit 
    considerations.
        14. The Commission stated that it appears that providing signalling 
    information from LEC tandems would require software upgrades to those 
    tandems. In addition, the record indicates that tandem-provided 
    signalling may be of less utility to TSPs than end office-provided 
    signalling. Although some parties claim generally that tandem-provided 
    signalling could provide a useful adjunct to other forms of 
    interconnection, they do not explain with any specificity how they 
    could use such an architecture, or how a two-tandem architecture could 
    actually be competitively viable, either from a service quality or 
    pricing standpoint. Therefore, based on the current record, the 
    Commission did not require LECs to provide this service at this time.
        15. The Commission clarified that in proposing access to LEC 
    signalling information from LEC end offices and tandems, it did not 
    intend to require LECs to reconfigure their SS7 networks. Thus, the 
    Commission held that LECs may provide end-office-generated signalling 
    information through STPs, and they may require TSPs that are 
    terminating traffic to transmit signalling formation to LEC end offices 
    through LEC STPs. The Commission recognized that STPs perform important 
    network screening functions and did not require LECs to decentralize 
    those functions by deploying them in every switch. Moreover, the record 
    does not indicate that TSPs would seek to interconnect via SS7 at end 
    offices, rather than at STPs. Rather, as some parties pointed out, it 
    would be far more efficient for them to interconnect at STPs.
        16. Regarding billing of terminating traffic, the Commission stated 
    that, consistent with its earlier expanded interconnection measures, 
    the customer of record of the terminating LEC should be billed by the 
    terminating LEC for services provided by that LEC. If the TSP is the 
    customer of record, the LEC should bill the TSP directly. If the TSP's 
    customer is the customer of record, then the TSP must provide the LEC 
    with billing tapes so that the LEC may properly count and bill access 
    minutes. The Commission rejected the suggestion of some LECs that all 
    discrepancies between TSP-provided billing tapes and LEC billing 
    records be resolved in favor of the LECs. The Commission stated that 
    TSPs and LECs can and should establish fair and reasonable procedures 
    to resolve billing discrepancies.
        17. The Commission stated that it does not base its decision that 
    LECs must, in some instances, accept billing tapes from TSPs on a co-
    carrier model. It required LECs to make signalling information 
    available to any third party, not just providers of competitive tandem-
    switched transport services. Thus, small IXCs may use signalling 
    information as a way to aggregate their traffic on direct-trunked 
    transport facilities purchased from a LEC so that they can enjoy the 
    same scale economies as larger IXCs. In that situation, the IXC 
    ordering the signalling and transport would be a reseller or 
    aggregator, not a co-carrier. Indeed, if the meet-point billing model 
    applied, TSPs would not be able to purchase direct-trunked transport 
    from a LEC, since LEC tandem-switched transport rates to the ``meet-
    point'' would apply.
    
    Collocation
    
        18. The Commission affirmed its tentative conclusion that physical 
    collocation of switching equipment should not be required. Virtually 
    every commenter that addressed this issue supported the tentative 
    conclusion and the reasoning behind it. Thus, the parties agreed that 
    there is no competitive or technical benefit to locating switching 
    equipment in LEC offices; that switching equipment is too large and too 
    heavy to be collocated in LEC space; and that interconnectors would 
    prefer to place their switching equipment on their own premises for 
    monitoring purposes. The Commission found that the arguments offered in 
    support of mandatory collocation were not convincing. It stated that no 
    one has shown why the line-drawing process between switching and 
    transmission equipment would be unmanageable or that collocation is 
    necessary to ensure fair and nondiscriminatory treatment of 
    interconnectors by LECs. The Commission's tariffing and general 
    nondiscrimination requirements should provide sufficient protection 
    against unfair or unreasonably discriminatory LEC rates and practices.
    
    Pricing
    
        19. The Commission concluded that LEC provision of CIC and OZZ data 
    to TSPs from LEC end offices will constitute a new service under the 
    price caps regime, which covers all Tier 1 LECs. New services add to 
    the range of options already available to customers. While LECs 
    currently transmit CIC and OZZ codes to their own access tandems, they 
    do not provide this information to their customers. Therefore, these 
    data add to the range of options of LEC customers and hence represent a 
    new service. While LECs appear to be able to provide this new service 
    without implementing new technology, the need--or absence of need--for 
    new technology does not dictate the categorization of the service under 
    price caps. Rather, this factor affects the costs and thus the price 
    that LECs may charge for a new service.
        20. LECs will be required to make a cost-based showing under the 
    price caps new services test. This showing will enable the Commission 
    to ensure that signalling services are reasonably priced. The 
    Commission will not use the net revenue test in reviewing LEC tariff 
    filings. The Commission stated that this is consistent with its 
    decision to eliminate the net revenue test for new service offerings 
    under price caps. That test is unnecessary, both because of the 
    Commission's requirement that LECs submit cost support for new 
    services, and because LECs clearly lack incentives to underprice 
    signalling services provided to competitive tandem-switching providers.
        21. The Commission concluded further that LECs must establish new 
    rate elements for CIC and OZZ signalling data as a separate service 
    category within the trunking basket. This category will be subject to 
    an upper pricing band of 2%. The Commission stated that because LECs 
    have no incentive to price signalling services at predatory levels, it 
    saw no need for a lower band and therefore did not impose one. The 
    Commission believes that these measures are necessary to prevent LECs 
    from offsetting increases in the price of signalling information 
    provided to TSPs with price reductions in the LECs' own tandem-switched 
    transport rates.
        22. The Commission found that the co-carrier model does not aptly 
    define the LEC/TSP relationship. It found that even though the 
    Commission has stated in the past that cellular service providers are 
    like co-carriers, it has never held that cellular interconnection 
    charges should be imposed on all LEC customers or on all cellular 
    users, rather than on the providers taking interconnection. Thus, a co-
    carrier model does not necessarily dictate that the costs unique to 
    providing a joint service should always be directly imposed on the 
    LEC's customers or on all customers of the service in question. The 
    Commission also stated that a cost recovery mechanism that would have 
    all purchasers of switched transport or tandem-switched transport bear 
    the costs of making signalling information available to TSPs, is 
    inappropriate and that instead, TSPs should pay for such costs. The 
    Commission found that this is consistent with its long-held view that 
    costs should be paid by the cost causer.
    
    Recovery of Support Flows
    
        23. The Commission stated that it appears from the record that 
    there is no need for additional support mechanisms in conjunction with 
    adoption of this Order. The transport interconnection charge is 
    sufficient to protect support flows potentially affected by this 
    decision.
    
    ONA Framework
    
        24. The Commission concluded that unbundled CIC and OZZ data are 
    not BSEs as defined in its ONA orders and that there is no public 
    policy reason to treat them equivalently. BSEs are ``optional unbundled 
    features . . . that an ESP may require or find useful in configuring an 
    enhanced service.''\4\ The Commission found that there has been no 
    showing that the CIC and OZZ data that are the subject of the Order 
    will be used by ESPs to provide enhanced services. Rather, these data 
    will be used by TSPs to provide basic network services. Thus, these 
    data do not fall within the Commission's definition of a BSE.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \4\Filing and Review of Open Network Architecture Plans, 4 FCC 
    Rcd 1, 36 (1988(, 54 FR 3453 (January 24, 1989).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        25. The Commission also found that no party demonstrated that it 
    would be in the public interest to treat CIC and OZZ codes as BSEs. The 
    Commission stated that while some parties argued that the four-part 
    test that LECs use in determining whether to offer an ESP-requested BSE 
    should apply, it has relied on similar considerations in assessing the 
    relative costs and benefits of LEC-provided signalling information. The 
    Commission also stated that the ``flagging'' requirements associated 
    with BSEs, under which BOCs must identify BSEs that they intend to use 
    themselves, are irrelevant: There is no dispute that LECs use CIC and 
    OZZ data for tandem-switched transport service. The Commission also 
    found that there would be no added benefit from a pricing standpoint in 
    treating CIC and OZZ data as BSEs, since it has already held that the 
    new services test applies to their initial rates.
    
    Tariffing and Implementation
    
        26. The Commission required Tier 1 LECs (except NECA members) to 
    file tariffs, with requisite cost support, for the provision of CIC and 
    OZZ codes within ninety days from publication of this Order in the 
    Federal Register, to be effective on forty-five days' notice. The 
    Commission found that the record in this proceeding shows that LECs can 
    provide CIC and OZZ codes to third parties from equal access end 
    offices simply by modifying their end office routing tables, without 
    purchasing new end office software and without making other costly and 
    time-consuming modifications. The Commission concluded that under the 
    circumstances, there is no reason why the LECs cannot tariff this 
    offering for all of their equal access end offices within ninety days 
    of publication of this Order in the Federal Register.
    
    LEC Pricing Flexibility
    
        27. The Commission did not grant LECs additional pricing 
    flexibility but stated that it will continue to examine these issues in 
    a broader context in future consideration of pending access reform 
    petitions. The Commission also stated that it has already addressed 
    virtually all of the specific proposals suggested by LECs in the 
    Switched Transport Expanded Interconnection Order and the First 
    Transport Reconsideration. Thus, LECs may offer density zone pricing 
    and volume and term discounts under certain conditions. In addition, 
    they may price transport between their tandems and SWCs on a flat-rate 
    basis. The Commission also stated that it had considered and rejected 
    in the Switched Transport Expanded Interconnection Order various other 
    requests for flexibility. For example, the Commission rejected the 
    suggestion that LECs receive the same pricing flexibility as their 
    competitors, noting that giving LECs too much flexibility could stifle 
    competitive entry and harm customers of less competitive services. The 
    Commission also declined to eliminate service category pricing bands, 
    stating that these bands serve important public policy goals. The 
    Commission found that no party had shown that providing signalling 
    information to TSPs warrants a different outcome. Nor had any party set 
    forth any other specific pricing flexibility request related to 
    providing signalling information. The Commission also found that no 
    party had demonstrated that the availability of signalling information 
    warrants authorization of LEC contract tariffs. The Commission has 
    limited contract carriage to services found to be ``substantially 
    competitive.'' The Commission concluded that while the measures it now 
    takes should permit alternatives to LEC tandem-switched access services 
    to develop, it could not conclude that these services are now subject 
    to substantial competition.
        28. The Commission concluded that for these reasons, it would not 
    to grant LECs additional pricing flexibility in conjunction with its 
    decision to make tandem signalling information available. The 
    Commission stated, however, that this decision is not intended to 
    prejudge broader questions regarding the possible need for access 
    charge reform. The Commission stated that by opening the door to 
    greater competition in the provision of tandem-switched services, it is 
    continuing the process of removing barriers to the development of a 
    more competitive access market in which CAPs and other entities can 
    participate.
    
    Other Issues
    
    Reciprocity
    
        29. The Commission declined to impose reciprocal signalling 
    obligations on interconnectors at this time. It found, first, that 
    requests for reciprocal obligations are beyond the scope of this 
    proceeding. The Notice proposed that LECs provide signalling 
    information to third parties. The Commission stated that it did not 
    propose to impose reciprocal requirements on these third parties, and 
    that it declined to broaden this proceeding to consider such 
    requirements here. The Commission stated that second, LEC requests for 
    reciprocity seem to assume that only CAPs will purchase signalling 
    information. As noted, this information must be made available to any 
    interested party, including IXCs. LECs requesting reciprocity fail to 
    address the implications of their proposal with respect to these other 
    types of TSPs. The Commission stated that third, except in the few 
    instances where CAPs have end offices, interconnectors simply do not 
    have the signalling information to provide to the LECs, and the LECs 
    have not demonstrated specific, present needs for such information. The 
    Commission found furthermore, that TSPs do not possess market power. It 
    stated, for example, that the Commission had previously declined to 
    impose reciprocal obligations on interconnectors, noting, inter alia, 
    that CAPs and other interconnectors do not control bottleneck 
    facilities.
    
    Jurisdictional Measurement and Reporting
    
        30. The Commission found that most parties agree that the customer 
    of record should be responsible for reporting the PIU factor for 
    terminating traffic when the LEC cannot itself measure jurisdiction. 
    The Commission stated that this is consistent with existing reporting 
    arrangements that have worked satisfactorily. If the customer of record 
    is a TSP, it shall be the responsibility of that TSP to compile PIU 
    reports based on data from those to whom it provides tandem-switching. 
    If the customer of record is an IXC or other purchaser of access, that 
    entity shall continue to provide PIU reports directly to the LEC 
    providing terminating access.
    
    Separations Issues
    
        31. The Commission concluded that the signalling information 
    requirement does not raise separations issues that should be referred 
    to a Joint Board. The record does not show that providing signalling 
    information will raise any significant issues beyond those already 
    referred to the Joint Board in the Switched Transport Expanded 
    Interconnection Order. As noted, the costs associated with LEC 
    provision of CIC and OZZ codes from equal access end offices should be 
    minimal. The Commission found that therefore, these costs or the 
    revenues derived from providing signalling information do not require 
    Joint Board consideration. The Notice stated that the Commission did 
    not intend to refer to the Joint Board broader separations issues. The 
    Commission stated that these matters would be more properly addressed 
    in the context of a comprehensive separations review proceeding.
    
    Conclusion
    
        32. The Commission concluded that in this Order, it took another 
    step in its ongoing effort to promote competition in the interstate 
    access market. Tier 1 LECs (except NECA members) are required to 
    provide signalling information from equal access end offices to 
    interested third parties. This measure will allow third parties to 
    provide tandem switching and thereby promote development of 
    alternatives to LEC-provided tandem-switched transport service. CAPs 
    may develop their own tandem-switching networks; other TSPs may use 
    tandem-switching to achieve scale economics attending the aggregation 
    of traffic. The Commission found that by promoting access to diverse 
    facilities and providers, this action should permit more efficient use 
    and deployment of interstate access services, increase network 
    reliability and redundancy, encourage innovation, and exert downward 
    pressure on access charges and long-distance rates. These benefits 
    should, in turn, contribute to economic growth and the creation of new 
    job opportunities.
    
    Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
    
        33. The Commission stated that in the Notice, it certified that the 
    proposed rule changes would not have a significant economic impact on a 
    substantial number of small business entities, as defined by 
    Sec. 601(3) of the Regulatory Flexibility Act.\5\ It also stated that 
    the Notice provided that to the extent that a PIU reporting requirement 
    would apply to small entities, it would not have a significant economic 
    impact on a substantial number of small business entities. The 
    Commission found that no commenting party disagreed with its analysis. 
    The Secretary shall send a copy of this Report and Order, including the 
    certification, to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the Small Business 
    Administration in accordance with Sec. 605(b) of the Regulatory 
    Flexibility Act, Public Law 96-354, 94 Stat. 1164, 5 U.S.C. Secs.  601 
    et seq.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \5\Notice, 7 FCC Rcd at 7749, 57.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Ordering Clauses
    
        34. Accordingly, it is ORDERED, pursuant to authority contained in 
    Sections 1, 4(i), 201-205, and 214(d) of the Communications Act of 
    1934, as amended, 47 U.S.C. 151(i), 154, 201-205, and 214(d), that 
    Parts 61 & 69 of the Commission's rules, 47 CFR Secs. 61, 64, and 69, 
    are AMENDED as set forth below.
        35. IT IS FURTHER ORDERED that the policies, rules, and 
    requirements set forth herein ARE ADOPTED, effective eighty days after 
    publication in the Federal Register.
        36. IT IS FURTHER ORDERED that the all LECs subject to this order 
    shall file tariff amendments as specified herein within ninety days of 
    publication of this order in the Federal Register, to be effective on 
    forty-five days' notice.
    
    List of Subjects in 47 CFR Parts 61, 64, and 69
    
        Communication Common carriers, Reporting and recordkeeping 
    requirements, Telephone.
    
    Federal Communications Commission.
    William F. Caton,
    Acting Secretary.
    
    Amendatory Text
    
        Parts 61, 64, and 69 of Title 47 of the Code of Federal Regulations 
    are amended as follows:
    
    PART 61--TARIFFS
    
        1. The authority citation for Part 61 continues to read as follows:
    
        Authority: Sec. 4, 48 Stat. 1066, as amended; 47 U.S.C. 154. 
    Interpret or apply sec. 203, 48 Stat. 1070; 47 U.S.C. 203.
    
        2. Section 61.42 is amended by adding paragraph (e)(2)(vii) to read 
    as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 61.42  Price cap baskets and service categories.
    
    * * * * *
        (e) * * *
        (2) * * *
        (vii) Signalling for tandem switching, as described in Sec. 69.129 
    of this chapter.
    * * * * *
        3. Section 61.47 is amended by adding paragraph (g)(5) as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 61.47  Adjustments to the SBI; pricing bands.
    
    * * * * *
        (g) * * *
        (5) The upper pricing band for the ``Signalling for tandem 
    switching'' service category shall limit the upward pricing flexibility 
    for this service category, as reflected in its SBI, to two percent, 
    relative to the percentage change in the PCI for the trunking basket, 
    measured from the levels in effect on the last day of the preceding 
    tariff year. There shall be no lower pricing band for this service 
    category.
    * * * * *
    
    PART 64--MISCELLANEOUS RULES RELATING TO COMMON CARRIERS
    
        1. The authority citation for Part 64 continues to read as follows:
    
        Authority: Section 4, 48 Stat. 1066, as amended; 47 U.S.C. 154, 
    unless otherwise noted. Interpret or apply secs. 201, 218, 225, 48 
    Stat. 1070, as amended, 1077; 47 U.S.C. 201, 218, 225, unless 
    otherwise noted.
    
        2. Section 64.1401 is amended by adding paragraph (i) to read as 
    follows:
    
    
    Sec. 64.1401  Expanded interconnection.
    
    * * * * *
        (i) The local exchange carriers specified in paragraph (a) of this 
    section shall offer signalling for tandem switching, as defined in 
    Sec. 69.2(vv) of this chapter, at central offices that are classified 
    as equal office end offices or serving wire centers, or at signal 
    transfer points if such information is offered via common channel 
    signalling.
    
    PART 69--ACCESS CHARGES
    
        1. The authority citation for Part 69 continues to read as follows:
    
        Authority: Secs. 4, 201, 202, 203, 205, 218, 403, 48 Stat. 1066, 
    1070, 1072, 1077, 1094, as amended, 47 U.S.C. 154, 201, 202, 203, 
    205, 218, 403.
    
        2. Section 69.2 is amended by adding paragraph (vv) to read as 
    follows:
    
    
    Sec. 69.2  Definitions.
    
    * * * * *
        (vv) Signalling for tandem switching means the carrier 
    identification code (CIC) and the OZZ code, or equivalent information 
    needed to perform tandem switching functions. The CIC identifies the 
    interexchange carrier and the OZZ identifies the interexchange carrier 
    trunk to which traffic should be routed.
    
        3. Section 69.129 is added to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 69.129  Signalling for tandem switching.
    
        A charge that is expressed in dollars and cents shall be assessed 
    upon the purchasing entity by a local telephone company for provision 
    of signalling for tandem switching.
    
    [FR Doc. 94-15443 Filed 6-24-94; 8:45 am]
    BILLING CODE 6712-01-M
    
    
    

Document Information

Published:
06/27/1994
Department:
Federal Communications Commission
Entry Type:
Uncategorized Document
Action:
Final rule.
Document Number:
94-15443
Dates:
September 15, 1994.
Pages:
0-0 (1 pages)
Docket Numbers:
Federal Register: June 27, 1994, CC Docket 91-141, FCC No. 94-118
CFR: (6)
47 CFR 69.2(vv)
47 CFR 61.42
47 CFR 61.47
47 CFR 64.1401
47 CFR 69.2
More ...