99-14699. Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service; Access Charge Reform  

  • [Federal Register Volume 64, Number 110 (Wednesday, June 9, 1999)]
    [Proposed Rules]
    [Pages 30949-30956]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 99-14699]
    
    
    =======================================================================
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
    
    47 CFR Part 36
    
    [CC Docket Nos. 96-45 and 96-262; FCC 99-119]
    
    
    Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service; Access Charge 
    Reform
    
    AGENCY: Federal Communications Commission.
    
    ACTION: Notice of proposed rulemaking.
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    SUMMARY: The Commission has adopted the principles of a federal support 
    mechanism that conforms to the Second Recommended Decision, however, 
    the Commission does not believe that an adequate record yet exists to 
    make determinations regarding some of the specific elements of the 
    support methodology. Accordingly, the Commission has issued this 
    document seeking comment on several specific implementation issues. In 
    conjunction with our actions to implement an explicit high-cost support 
    mechanism based on forward-looking costs, we also take action and seek 
    comment on additional issues to permit us to identify implicit support 
    remaining in interstate access charges by January 1, 2000.
    
    DATES: Comments are due on or before July 2, 1999 and reply comments 
    are due on or before July 16, 1999. Written comments by the public on 
    the proposed information collections are due on or before July 2, 1999 
    and reply comments are due on or before July 16, 1999. Written comments 
    must be submitted by the Office of Management and Budget (OMB) on the 
    proposed information collections on or before August 9, 1999.
    
    ADDRESSES: Parties who choose to file by paper must file an original 
    and four copies of each filing. All filings must be sent to the 
    Commission's Secretary, Magalie Roman Salas, Office of the Secretary, 
    Federal Communications Commission, 445 Twelfth Street, S.W., TW-A325, 
    Washington, D.C. 20554. In addition to filing comments with the 
    Secretary, a copy of any comments on the information collections 
    contained herein should be submitted to Judy Boley, Federal 
    Communications Commission, Room 1-C804, 445 Twelfth Street, S.W., 
    Washington, DC 20554, or via the Internet to jboley@fcc.gov, and to 
    Timothy Fain, OMB Desk Officer, 10236 NEOB, 725--17th Street, N.W., 
    Washington, DC 20503 or via the Internet to fain__t@al.eop.gov.
    
    FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Jack Zinman, Attorney, Common Carrier 
    Bureau, Accounting Policy Division, (202) 418-7400. For additional 
    information concerning the information collections contained in this 
    Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking contact Judy Boley at 202-418-
    0214, or via the Internet at jboley@fcc.gov.
    
    SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a summary of the Commission's 
    document released on May 28, 1999. The full text of this document is 
    available for public inspection during regular business hours in the 
    FCC Reference Center, Room CY-A257, 445 Twelfth Street, S.W., 
    Washington, D.C., 20554.
    
    Initial Paperwork Reduction Act Analysis
    
        1. This Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking contains a proposed 
    information collection. The Commission, as part of its continuing 
    effort to reduce paperwork burdens, invites the general public and the 
    Office of Management and Budget (OMB) to comment on the information 
    collections contained in this Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, as 
    required by the Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995, Public Law 104-13. 
    Public and agency comments are due at the same time as other comments 
    on this Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking; OMB notification of 
    action is due August 9, 1999. Comments should address: (a) whether the 
    proposed collection of information is necessary for the proper 
    performance of the functions of the Commission, including whether the 
    information shall have practical utility; (b) the accuracy of the 
    Commission's burden estimates; (c) ways to enhance the quality, 
    utility, and clarity of the information collected; and (d) ways to 
    minimize the burden of the collection of information on the 
    respondents, including the use of automated collection techniques or 
    other form of information technology.
        OMB Approval Number: None.
        Title: Notification to High Cost Subscriber Lines and Certification 
    Letter Accounting for Receipt of Federal Support (Proposals).
        Form No.: N/A.
        Type of Review: New collection.
        Respondents: Business or Other for Profit and State, Local or 
    Tribal Government.
    
    [[Page 30950]]
    
    
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                     Number of
                                    respondents          Estimate time per response            Total annual burden
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
    Notification to High Cost               30   3 hours (Quarterly)......................  1080 hours.
     subscriber Lines.
    Certification Letter                    51   3 hours..................................  153 hours.
     Accounting for Receipt of
     Federal Support.
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Total Annual Burden: 1233 hours.
        Estimated costs per respondent: $0.
        Needs and Uses: The Commission proposes that carriers should be 
    required to notify high-cost subscribers that their lines have been 
    identified as high-cost lines. This information will be used to show 
    that federal high-cost support is being provided to the carrier to 
    assist in keeping rates affordable in those subscribers' area. Further, 
    the proposed collection of information will be used to verify that the 
    carriers have accounted for its receipt of federal support in its rates 
    or otherwise used the support for the ``provision, maintenance, and 
    upgrading of facilities and services for which the support is 
    intended'' in accordance with section 254(e).
    
    I. Introduction
    
        2. Although we are adopting the principles of a federal support 
    mechanism that conform to the Second Recommended Decision, 63 FR 67837 
    (December 9, 1998), we do not believe that an adequate record yet 
    exists to make determinations regarding some of the specific elements 
    of the support methodology. Accordingly, we adopt this Further Notice 
    of Proposed Rulemaking (FNPRM) seeking comment on several specific 
    implementation issues. While we are resolving these implementation 
    issues, we also are continuing to verify the operation of the cost 
    model, including the input data elements. To complete this process, we 
    issue separately an additional FNPRM on the model input and operational 
    issues. We encourage commenters to consider both of these FNPRMs 
    together, and frame their comments to recognize the close relationship 
    between the issues discussed in each.
        3. We intend to resolve the remaining methodological issues 
    identified in this FNPRM and verify the operation of the cost model, 
    including the input data elements, on which comment is being sought in 
    the companion Inputs FNPRM. We anticipate adoption this fall of an 
    order resolving these remaining issues, so that support may be based on 
    forward-looking costs of providing supported services beginning January 
    1, 2000. In conjunction with our actions to implement an explicit high-
    cost support mechanism based on forward-looking costs, we also take 
    action today and seek comment on additional issues to permit us to 
    identify implicit support remaining in interstate access charges by 
    January 1, 2000.
    
    A. Methodology Issues
    
    National Benchmark
        4. In its Second Recommended Decision, the Joint Board supported 
    using a cost-based benchmark, as opposed to one based on revenues, in 
    evaluating rate comparability because state jurisdictions vary in how 
    they set local rates. The Joint Board explained that forward-looking 
    cost estimates for a given area could be compared against the single 
    national cost benchmark in order to determine whether the area has 
    costs that are significantly above the national average. We adopted the 
    Joint Board's recommendation to employ a cost-based benchmark.
        5. In setting the level of the national benchmark, the Joint Board 
    recommended that the Commission consider using a range between 115 and 
    150 percent of the national weighted average cost per line. Although 
    several commenters support the use of a national benchmark, many were 
    reluctant to comment on the range proposed by the Joint Board in the 
    absence of a finalized cost model. For that reason, we seek further 
    comment on the specific cost benchmark that we should adopt, and we 
    seek comment on whether the national benchmark should fall within the 
    Joint Board's recommended range.
        6. The current high-cost mechanism for large carriers provides 
    increasing amounts of support based on the amount by which a carrier's 
    loop costs exceed the national average, beginning with loop costs 
    between 115 percent and 160 percent of the national average. In 
    particular, the current federal support mechanism provides 10 percent 
    support (in addition to the 25 percent allocation of all loop costs to 
    the interstate jurisdiction) for large incumbent LECs with more than 
    200,000 working loops for book loop costs above 115 percent of the 
    national average, and provides gradually more support for the portion 
    of these carriers' book loop costs exceeding 160 percent of the 
    national average. The following chart summarizes the levels of support 
    provided by the current high-cost mechanism for large carriers:
    
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
     Loop cost as a percent of the national   Amount of intrastate loop cost
                    average                        supported (percent)
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    Greater than 115%, but not greater than                     10
                             160%
    Greater than 160%, but not greater than                     30
                             200%
    Greater than 200%, but not greater than                     60
                             250%
               Greater than 250%                                75
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        While the existing mechanism provides support for loop costs 
    beginning at 115 percent of the national average, it considers only 
    loop costs, while the forward-looking cost model estimates the forward-
    looking cost of all components of the network necessary to provide the 
    supported services.
        7. Although we have not yet completed our work verifying the 
    results of the forward-looking cost model, the cost model is now 
    operational and, in a Report and Order, we have adopted the framework 
    of our methodology for its use. The model currently suggests that, 
    using this methodology, a cost benchmark level near the center of the 
    range recommended by the Joint Board would provide support levels that 
    are sufficient to enable reasonably comparable rates, in light of 
    current levels of competition to preserve and advance the Commission's 
    universal service goals. In addition to general comments on the Joint 
    Board's recommended range for the cost benchmark, we also seek specific 
    comment on the level at which we should set the national benchmark, 
    including comment on what additional factors and considerations we 
    should take into account before selecting a final national benchmark 
    level. We encourage commenters to use updated model outputs in 
    formulating their comments.
        8. To ensure that there are no sudden withdrawals or reallocations 
    of federal support to cover costs between the cost benchmark range that 
    we ultimately adopt, we also seek comment today on the Joint Board's 
    recommendation that the new forward-looking mechanism incorporate a 
    hold-harmless provision. We seek comment on the specific operation of 
    such a provision. We encourage commenters to consider and discuss the 
    interaction between specific cost benchmark levels and the precise 
    operation of the hold-harmless provision.
    
    [[Page 30951]]
    
    Area Over Which Costs Should Be Averaged
        9. After further consultation with the Joint Board, we seek further 
    comment on whether the federal support mechanism should calculate 
    support levels by comparing the forward-looking costs of providing 
    supported services to the benchmark at either (1) the wire center 
    level; (2) the unbundled network element (UNE) cost zone level; or (3) 
    the study area level.
        10. A number of commenters have expressed support for calculating 
    costs at the wire center level. As we strive to bring competition to 
    local telephone markets while keeping rates for local service 
    affordable and reasonably comparable in all regions of the country, we 
    recognize two major benefits of such explicit deaveraged high-cost 
    support. As competition places downward pressure on rates charged to 
    urban, business, and other low-cost subscribers, we believe that 
    support deaveraged to the wire center level or below may ensure that 
    adequate support is provided specifically to the subscribers most in 
    need of support, because the support reflects the costs of specific 
    areas. In addition, deaveraged explicit support that is portable among 
    all eligible telecommunications carriers and targeted in a granular 
    manner to support high-cost subscribers could encourage efficient 
    competitive entry in all areas, not just in urban or other low-cost 
    areas. By permitting the incumbent's rates to reflect actual costs in 
    all areas, subject to explicit support assessments or portable support 
    payments, explicit deaveraged support may provide incentives to 
    competitors to expand service beyond urban areas and business centers 
    into all areas of the country and to all Americans, as envisioned by 
    the 1996 Act. We seek comment on this analysis.
        11. As an alternative to computing costs at the wire center level, 
    we seek comment on whether we should compare costs to the benchmark at 
    the level of UNE cost zones instead. Under this proposal, each wire 
    center within a UNE cost zone would receive the same amount of support. 
    Thus, support would still be targeted to the general areas that need it 
    most, but upward pressure on the size of the federal fund would be 
    lessened compared to the wire center approach. This approach would also 
    coincide with the rules on the pricing of UNEs. Under our deaveraging 
    rules, state commissions must establish different rates for elements in 
    at least three defined geographical areas within the state to reflect 
    geographic cost differences, and may use existing density-related zone 
    pricing plans, or other cost-related zone plans established pursuant to 
    state law. Using UNE zones may avoid opportunities for arbitrage, and 
    because states are responsible for developing UNE zones, states will be 
    able to develop zone boundaries based upon local conditions, including 
    cost characteristics and the status of competition. We generally do not 
    foresee any difficulty using the cost model to mirror state UNE zones, 
    provided that state UNE zones correspond to wire center boundaries. We 
    seek comment, however, on how state UNE zones that potentially do not 
    correspond to wire center boundaries can be effectively used in the 
    cost model. We encourage commenters to use updated model outputs in 
    formulating their comments on this proposal. Finally, we ask commenters 
    to propose any other cost zones, other than UNE zones, that may be an 
    appropriate basis for computing costs.
        12. We also seek comment on whether we should calculate costs at 
    the study area level. In recommending that the federal support 
    mechanism calculate costs at the study area level, the Joint Board 
    suggested that the level of competition today has not eroded implicit 
    support flows to such an extent as to threaten universal service. In 
    addition, compared to calculating costs at the level of wire centers or 
    UNE zones, calculating costs at the larger study area level may be more 
    likely to prevent substantial increases in the size of the high-cost 
    support mechanism because high-cost areas within the study area are 
    averaged with lower-cost areas within the study area. In addition, we 
    seek comment on whether comparing costs to the benchmark at the study 
    area level is more consistent with a vision of a federal mechanism for 
    reasonable rate comparability that focuses on support flows among 
    states rather than within states, and whether such a vision is more 
    consistent with the Joint Board's Second Recommended Decision. We seek 
    specific comment, however, on the extent to which competition is likely 
    to place steadily increasing pressure on implicit support flows from 
    low-cost areas and the extent to which this pressure suggests that we 
    should deaverage support in the implementation of our new mechanism. We 
    urge commenters to use updated model outputs when responding to this 
    analysis.
        13. We seek specific comment on the impact of using study-area 
    averaged costs in a study area where UNEs are available. In the Local 
    Competition Order, the Commission determined that UNEs would be priced 
    in a minimum of three rate zones within a state. If high-cost support 
    is provided using study-area averaged costs, then all lines within the 
    study area would be eligible for the same amount of support even though 
    the UNE rates for those same lines would vary among rate zones within 
    the state. We seek comment on whether this disparity between support 
    amounts and UNE rates among different rate zones may create incentives 
    for carriers to engage in arbitrage or other uneconomic activities 
    unrelated to the purpose of high-cost support.
        14. In recommending that costs be calculated at the study area 
    level, the Joint Board was driven by concerns that the amount of 
    federal high-cost universal service support be ``properly measured'' in 
    light of the current state of local competition. Comparing costs to a 
    benchmark when averaged over a smaller area is bound to produce higher 
    support calculations, however, because high costs in one area are less 
    likely to be diluted by low costs in another area when the area under 
    consideration is smaller. As discussed, we agree with the Joint Board 
    that federal support to enable reasonably comparable local rates for 
    non-rural carriers should not increase significantly from current 
    levels. We seek comment, however, on ways to resolve the tension 
    between the goal of preventing the fund from increasing significantly 
    above current levels, and the goal of ensuring that support is, to the 
    extent possible, directly targeted to high-cost areas within study 
    areas. In addition, we seek specific comment on four proposals to 
    resolve this tension.
        15. First, we propose, if we were to determine total support 
    amounts in each study area by running the model to estimate costs at 
    the study area level, to distribute support by running the model again 
    at the wire center level in order to target support to high-cost wire 
    centers within the study area. This approach would not significantly 
    increase the size of the fund, but would ensure that support is 
    distributed to areas that need it most. As a second alternative, we 
    could determine support based on costs averaged at a level more 
    granular than the study area, such as UNE zones or wire centers, but 
    provide only a uniform percentage of the support so indicated. Such an 
    approach would be consistent with the Joint Board's findings that rates 
    are presently affordable and that competition has not yet eroded 
    support to high-cost customers.
        16. As a third alternative, we could determine support based on 
    costs averaged at a level more granular than the study area, such as 
    UNE zones or wire centers, but cap the amount of
    
    [[Page 30952]]
    
    support available to any particular state to a fixed percentage of the 
    overall fund. As a fourth alternative, if we were to determine support 
    based on costs averaged at the UNE zone or wire center level, we could 
    limit the size of the fund either by raising the cost benchmark 
    appropriately or adopting incremental funding levels for costs above 
    the selected benchmark similar to the existing high-cost loop support 
    mechanism. As an example of incremental funding levels, were we to 
    adopt a cost benchmark of 135 percent of the national weighted average 
    cost per line, we could fund 10 percent of the costs that are between 
    135 percent and 160 percent of the national average, 30 percent of the 
    costs that are between 160 percent and 200 percent of the national 
    average, and so forth. We seek comment on each of these proposals, 
    including comment on how each meets the statutory requirement that 
    support should be ``sufficient.'' We also ask commenters to suggest 
    additional methods for preventing the size of the fund from growing 
    significantly.
    Determining a State's Ability To Support High-Cost Areas
        17. As discussed, we agree with the Joint Board that federal 
    support to enable reasonably comparable local rates for non-rural 
    carriers should be determined based, in part, on a state's ability to 
    support its universal service needs internally and that such federal 
    support should be available to the extent the state is unable to 
    achieve reasonably comparable rates using its own resources. We 
    concluded that a fixed dollar amount per line is a reasonably certain 
    and specific means of assessing a state's ability to enable reasonable 
    comparability of rates using its own resources.
        18. In this FNPRM, we now seek comment on the fixed per-line dollar 
    amount that should be set to estimate a state's ability to internally 
    support its high-cost areas, and how the amount should be determined. 
    As one option, we observe that in the First Report and Order, 62 FR 
    32862 (June 17, 1997), the Commission suggested a revenue benchmark of 
    approximately $31. In the Second Recommended Decision, the Joint Board 
    considered establishing a state's responsibility based on a percentage 
    of revenues, specifically, a range between three and six percent of 
    intrastate telecommunications revenues. We seek comment on whether the 
    per-line amount should be set so that it amounts to between three and 
    six percent of this original $31 revenue benchmark, in order to roughly 
    equal, in absolute dollar terms, the amount that a state could 
    reasonably have anticipated if measured on a revenue percentage basis. 
    For example, a $2.00 per line figure would reflect roughly six percent 
    of $31. Under this fixed dollar amount per line approach, the perceived 
    need for support in the state is first calculated by comparing costs to 
    the benchmark. The state's ability to enable reasonably comparable 
    rates in the face of this perceived need would then be estimated by 
    multiplying the per-line figure by the total number of non-rural 
    carrier lines in the state. If the perceived support need exceeds this 
    estimate of the state's own resources, federal support would support 
    the difference in accordance with the benchmark methodology described. 
    We seek comment on this proposal.
        19. We also seek comment on whether wireless lines should be 
    included in the calculation of a state's ability to support universal 
    service. If commenters believe that wireless lines should be included, 
    we seek comment on whether there should be a distinction between 
    wireless lines of an ETC and wireless lines of a non-ETC. Finally, we 
    emphasize that the use of a fixed per-line dollar value assessment to 
    estimate states' abilities to support their universal service needs 
    internally does not mandate the creation of state universal service 
    funds for this purpose.
    
    B. Distribution and Application of Support
    
        20. As discussed, we have concluded that, consistent with section 
    254, carriers should be required to use support ``only for the 
    provision, maintenance, and upgrading of facilities and services for 
    which the support is intended.'' We seek comment on what specific 
    restrictions, if any, are necessary to achieve this statutory 
    requirement. Specifically, in the event that the Commission ultimately 
    decides to average costs over an area larger than the wire center in 
    determining support levels, we seek comment on how this application of 
    support should be accomplished given our tentative conclusion to 
    require carriers to apply federal high-cost support to the wire centers 
    that triggered the need for support.
        21. Although the Commission has the responsibility to ensure that 
    support is sufficient to enable reasonable comparability of rates, the 
    states establish specific rate levels. Therefore, we seek comment on 
    whether making federal support available as carrier revenue, to be 
    accounted for by the state in the rate setting process, will 
    sufficiently fulfill the section 254(e)'s requirement that federal 
    support shall be used ``only for the provision, maintenance, or 
    upgrading of facilities and services for which the support was 
    intended.'' We tentatively conclude that making support available as 
    part of the state rate-setting process would empower state regulators 
    to achieve reasonable comparability of rates within their states. For 
    example, we expect that states that have adopted price cap regulation 
    could require exogenous price cap adjustments to reflect the increased 
    support for high-cost areas and that states that retain rate of return 
    regulation would count the new support towards carriers' revenue 
    requirements. In either case, the state would be able to use federal 
    support targeted to high-cost wire centers to enable reasonable 
    comparability of local rates, if it so chose. We seek comment on this 
    proposal. Specifically, we seek comment on whether all state 
    commissions possess the jurisdiction and resources to take the actions 
    this approach would require. We also seek comment on whether, under 
    this proposal, carriers should be required to notify high-cost 
    subscribers that their lines have been identified as high-cost lines 
    and that federal high-cost support is being provided to the carrier to 
    assist in keeping rates affordable in those subscribers' area.
        22. In addition, we seek comment on what further restrictions, if 
    any, we should impose on the use of federal support to ensure that 
    recipient carriers use the support in a manner consistent with section 
    254. The Joint Board recommended that the Commission require carriers 
    to certify that they will apply federal high-cost support in accordance 
    with the statute. The Joint Board also recommended that the Commission 
    should not require states to provide any certification as a 
    ``condition'' for carriers in the state to receive high cost support, 
    but the Commission should instead permit states to certify that, in 
    order to receive federal universal service support, a carrier must use 
    such funds in a manner consistent with section 254. We seek comment on 
    whether state authority over local rates in a manner cognizant of 
    federal support levels will adequately enforce the requirements of 
    section 254(e), making additional federal regulation unnecessary. 
    Because some states may lack either the authority or the desire to 
    impose conditions on the use of high-cost support, we tentatively 
    conclude that such state oversight, while valuable and potentially 
    sufficient, may not in every case ensure that section 254(e)'s goals 
    are met. Therefore, we seek comment on whether
    
    [[Page 30953]]
    
    it would be appropriate to condition the receipt of federal universal 
    service high-cost support on any state action, including adjustments to 
    local rate schedules reflecting federal support. We believe that 
    denying support to states that lack the regulatory authority to ensure 
    that federal funds are used appropriately would penalize those states 
    and would not be consistent with section 254's mandates. We tentatively 
    conclude, however, that even states that lack this authority would be 
    able to certify to the Commission that a carrier within the state had 
    accounted for its receipt of federal support in its rates or otherwise 
    used the support for the ``provision, maintenance, and upgrading of 
    facilities and services for which the support is intended'' in 
    accordance with section 254(e). Conversely, if the state were unable or 
    unwilling to take action to achieve the goals of section 254(e), we 
    could allow such states to refuse federal high-cost support. We seek 
    comment on these approaches, including comment on whether 
    implementation of multiple options might best achieve the goals of 
    section 254(e), and comment on whether any carrier-initiated action 
    would be necessary in states with limited authority. Finally, we seek 
    comment on what carrier or state commission action, if any, may be 
    necessary to prevent double-recovery of universal service support at 
    both the federal and state level.
        23. Under the approach discussed, we recognize that we may need to 
    allocate federal support among high-cost wire centers within a 
    carrier's study area. If the federal support amount based on forward-
    looking cost provides only a portion of the support for a given wire 
    center, or if we choose to fund only a portion of the support otherwise 
    indicated by the model, we seek comment on means by which to perform 
    this allocation. If a carrier does not receive support equal to the 
    full amount of the difference between the forward-looking cost estimate 
    for the wire center and the threshold level for federal support, we 
    tentatively conclude that it should allocate the support among all 
    lines in these high-cost wire centers in a pro rata manner, based upon 
    the difference between the federal benchmark, plus state supported 
    levels, and the wire center's forward-looking cost of providing 
    service. We believe this approach has the potential to foster 
    competition because the amount of the support available to competing 
    eligible telecommunications carriers would be clearly identified, and 
    thus competing carriers would be able to assess more accurately whether 
    competitive entry is viable in a particular high-cost area. In 
    addition, high-cost support would be distributed in such a manner that 
    support levels in each high-cost wire center would be proportionate to 
    costs. We seek comment on these proposals and tentative conclusions.
    
    C. Hold-Harmless and Portability of Support
    
        24. As discussed, we agree with the Joint Board that the federal 
    high-cost support mechanism should have a hold-harmless provision to 
    prevent immediate and substantial reductions of federal support and 
    potentially significant rate increases. Under such a hold-harmless 
    provision, the amount of support provided would be the greater of the 
    amount generated under the forward-looking mechanism or the explicit 
    amount presently received. We seek comment on how we should implement 
    such a hold-harmless provision to best accomplish this goal. 
    Specifically, we seek comment on whether the hold-harmless provision 
    should be implemented on a state-by-state basis or on a carrier-by-
    carrier basis.
        25. Under a state-by-state approach, the total amount of federal 
    support provided in each state would be the greater of the total amount 
    indicated by the forward-looking mechanism or the total amount 
    presently received by carriers in the particular state. For example, 
    assume a state has two carriers, Carrier A and Carrier B, each 
    presently receiving $100 in federal high-cost intrastate support. 
    Assume further that under the forward-looking mechanism, Carrier A is 
    entitled to $100 and Carrier B is entitled to $95. The total amount of 
    support indicated by the forward-looking mechanism ($195) is less than 
    the total amount of support under the present mechanism ($200). 
    Therefore, the hold-harmless provision would supply an additional $5 of 
    support. Assume, however, that under the forward-looking mechanism, 
    Carrier A is entitled to $120 and Carrier B is entitled to $90. The 
    total amount of support indicated by the forward-looking mechanism 
    ($210) is greater than the total amount of support under the present 
    mechanism ($200). Although Carrier B would receive less support under 
    the forward-looking mechanism, the state, as a whole, would receive 
    more support under the forward-looking mechanism. Therefore, the hold-
    harmless provision does not supply any additional support. We believe 
    that such a state-by-state hold-harmless is likely to prevent 
    substantial increases in the size of the high-cost support mechanism 
    because an increase in support for one carrier can be offset by a 
    decrease in support for another carrier when determining the total 
    amount of hold-harmless support provided in a particular state. On the 
    other hand, the state-by-state approach may not prevent a decrease in 
    support for certain carriers within a particular state. Redistribution 
    of federal support within the state, however, may be accomplished by 
    state commission action.
        26. In contrast, under a carrier-by-carrier hold-harmless approach, 
    the amount of federal support provided to each carrier in a state would 
    be the greater of the amount indicated by the forward-looking mechanism 
    or the explicit amount presently received by the carrier. For example, 
    assume a state has two carriers, Carrier A and Carrier B, each 
    presently receiving $100 in support. Assume further that, under the 
    forward-looking mechanism, Carrier A is entitled to $125 and Carrier B 
    is entitled to $75. Under a carrier-by-carrier hold-harmless provision, 
    Carrier A would receive $125 pursuant to the forward-looking model, and 
    Carrier B would receive $100 pursuant to the hold-harmless provision. 
    Thus, the total amount of federal support provided in that state would 
    increase to $225. A carrier-by-carrier approach ensures that no carrier 
    receives less support under the forward-looking mechanism than it 
    receives under the present mechanism. We believe, however, that the 
    carrier-by-carrier approach, as opposed to the state-by-state approach, 
    is more likely to inflate the size of the high-cost support mechanism 
    because the amount of support provided to each carrier can only 
    increase under this approach. Using updated model outputs, we ask 
    commenters to comment on whether a state-by-state or a carrier-by-
    carrier hold-harmless approach is more consistent with universal 
    service principles set forth in the Act and the role of the federal 
    mechanism in providing high-cost support.
        27. In addition, in the event that the Commission adopts a state-
    by-state hold-harmless provision, we seek comment on how such a 
    provision should allocate support among carriers in the event that the 
    total amount of hold-harmless support provided in a particular state is 
    insufficient to fully hold each carrier harmless. Specifically, in the 
    event the Commission adopts a state-by-state hold-harmless approach, we 
    propose allocating the total amount of support pro rata among such 
    carriers based on their relative reductions in support. For example, 
    assume that a state has three carriers, Carrier A,
    
    [[Page 30954]]
    
    Carrier B, and Carrier C. Assume further that, under the present 
    mechanism, Carrier A receives $150, Carrier B receives $125, and 
    Carrier C receives $100. Also assume that, under the forward looking 
    mechanism, Carrier A is entitled to $175, Carrier B is entitled to 
    $100, and Carrier C is entitled to $75. The total amount of support 
    indicated by the forward-looking mechanism ($350) is less than the 
    total amount of support under the present mechanism ($375). Therefore, 
    a state-by-state hold-harmless provision would provide an additional 
    $25 of support. Because Carrier B and Carrier C have experienced a 
    combined reduction in support of $50 and Carrier A has experienced no 
    reduction in support, the $25 of hold-harmless support must be 
    allocated between Carrier B and Carrier C. Under our proposal, the 
    hold-harmless support would first be allocated to the carrier 
    experiencing the greater relative reduction in support. Here, Carrier B 
    received 80 percent ($100/$125) of its previous support amount, and 
    Carrier C received 75 percent ($75/$100) of its previous support 
    amount. In order to place Carrier B and Carrier C on equal footing, 
    therefore, the first $5 of the total hold-harmless amount would be 
    allocated to Carrier C, resulting in both Carrier B and Carrier C 
    receiving 80 percent of their previous amount of support. The remaining 
    $20 of support would be allocated pro rata between Carrier B and 
    Carrier C so that both carriers receive the same total percentage of 
    the support provided under the present mechanism. Carrier B would 
    receive an additional $11.11 ($125/$225  x  $20), for a total of 89 
    percent ($111.11/$125) of its support under the present mechanism, and 
    Carrier C would receive an additional $8.88 ($100/$225  x  $20), for a 
    total of 89 percent ($88.88/$100) of its support under the present 
    mechanism. We believe that this method of allocation allows for an 
    equitable distribution of support in the event that the total state-by-
    state amount is insufficient to fully hold each carrier harmless. We 
    seek comment on this proposal.
        28. In the alternative, we seek specific comment on whether, if we 
    eventually adopt a state-by-state rather than a carrier-by-carrier 
    hold-harmless approach, we should distribute universal service high-
    cost support directly to the state commissions, rather than to 
    carriers. The Joint Board considered and rejected distributing federal 
    support to the states, rather than directly to carriers, because of the 
    long-standing practice of distributing federal support directly to 
    carriers and the absence of any affirmative evidence in the Act or its 
    legislative history that Congress intended to alter this method of 
    distribution. In addition, commenters that addressed this issue oppose 
    a mechanism that would distribute support to the states. We seek 
    additional comment, however, on whether support should be distributed 
    to the state commissions for allocation among carriers in each state 
    instead of through a federal allocation mechanism, in the event one or 
    more carriers in the state experienced a reduction in support as a 
    result of a state-by-state hold-harmless mechanism.
        29. We also seek comment on the relationship between the hold-
    harmless approaches suggested, and the portability of federal high-cost 
    support. As discussed, we concluded that, consistent with the Joint 
    Board's recommendations and the policy we established in the First 
    Report and Order, federal high-cost support should be portable, and 
    available to all eligible telecommunications carriers, regardless of 
    the technology used to provide the supported services. To implement 
    portability, however, we must first determine the amount of support to 
    be ported. Specifically, in the event a competitor wins a customer from 
    an incumbent receiving hold-harmless support, we seek comment on 
    whether the competitor should receive the incumbent's hold-harmless 
    support, or whether the competitor should receive the amount of support 
    determined on a forward-looking basis. Making the hold-harmless amount 
    available to the competitor appears to be more competitively neutral, 
    because both carriers would receive the same amount. However, given 
    that the purpose of the hold-harmless provision is to prevent sudden 
    rate increases by carriers that have grown dependent on current support 
    in designing their rate structures, the hold-harmless amount could 
    represent a windfall to an efficient competitor. While making the 
    forward-looking amount available to the competitor and providing the 
    hold-harmless amount to the incumbent may not be as competitively 
    neutral, it would appear to approximate more closely the amount 
    necessary to support high-cost service in the area. We seek comment on 
    this issue. We encourage commenters to use updated model outputs in 
    framing their comments on the issue of portability.
    
    D. Adjusting Interstate Access Charges To Account for Explicit Support
    
        30. As discussed, we agree with the Joint Board that we have the 
    jurisdiction and statutory obligation to identify any universal service 
    support that is implicit in interstate access charges and, as far as 
    possible, make that support explicit. In this section we seek comment 
    on how we should adjust interstate access charges to offset universal 
    service support that we subsequently identify in interstate access 
    charges and allow carriers to recover through increased support from 
    the new federal mechanism. Because of the role access charges have 
    played in supporting universal service, it is critical to implement 
    changes in the interstate access charge system together with the 
    complementary changes in the federal universal service support 
    mechanism we adopt today. We seek comment on how we should adjust 
    interstate access charges to reflect any increases in federal explicit 
    support provided to non-rural carriers under the new federal mechanism 
    and methodology.
        31. The Commission determined in the First Report and Order that 
    non-rural carriers would begin to receive high-cost support on July 1, 
    1999, based on forward-looking costs, and delayed the implementation of 
    support based on forward-looking costs for rural carriers until at 
    least January 1, 2001. As discussed, more time is needed to verify the 
    models that will determine the forward-looking costs on which the 
    intrastate high-cost support for non-rural carriers will be based. 
    Thus, we are postponing the July 1, 1999, implementation of intrastate 
    high-cost support for non-rural carriers until January 1, 2000. Because 
    these models may also be used to determine levels of implicit support 
    in interstate access charges and the amount of federal support a 
    carrier should receive, this will also delay determination of the 
    interstate high-cost support for non-rural carriers. This section 
    addresses only the question of how to reduce interstate access charges 
    to reflect increased explicit federal support for non-rural carriers 
    that currently flows within the interstate jurisdiction. We will 
    address any necessary interstate access charge reductions for rural 
    carriers at a later date.
        32. We tentatively conclude that we should require price cap LECs 
    to reduce their interstate access rates to reflect any increased 
    explicit federal high-cost support they receive. To do otherwise would 
    give these carriers a windfall by allowing them to maintain rates that 
    include implicit high-cost support even after the support has been made 
    explicit. We tentatively conclude that the carriers should make an 
    exogenous downward adjustment to the common line basket. In the short 
    run, this will reduce the CCLC and multi-line PICCs.
    
    [[Page 30955]]
    
    In the longer run, this adjustment will keep down scheduled increases 
    for the primary residential and single-line business PICC. The PICC is 
    often passed on to the end user by the IXC that pays it. This approach 
    will serve the dual purpose of eliminating implicit support and holding 
    down per-line rates associated with primary residential and single-line 
    business lines. This will, therefore, help keep basic telephone service 
    affordable and comparable.
        33. We seek comment on whether we should require price cap LECs to 
    reflect explicit high-cost support by making the downward exogenous 
    adjustment to their common line basket's price cap indexes (PCIs). 
    Alternatively, we seek comment on whether we should instead permit 
    incumbent LECs to reduce their access rates to offset the explicit 
    support by lowering their common line charges on a geographically 
    deaveraged basis. For example, we could reduce implicit support 
    resulting from geographic averaging by permitting carriers to lower 
    their SLCs on a deaveraged basis, reducing SLCs in low-cost areas, 
    while maintaining the SLC caps in our rules for high-cost areas. We 
    seek comment on whether we should allow carriers to determine where 
    they lower their rates under such an approach. Alternatively, we seek 
    comment on whether we or the state commissions should delineate the 
    permissible areas for deaveraged reductions, and how those areas should 
    be determined. We could, for example, require the deaveraging to occur 
    based on the same rate zones that some states have already identified 
    pursuant to our deaveraging requirement for the pricing of unbundled 
    network elements and interconnection. We also seek comment on which 
    common line rate elements should be deaveraged.
        34. We also seek comment on whether price cap carriers should also 
    reduce their base factor portion (BFP). For carriers that calculate 
    their SLC based on the BFP, this would result in reductions to the SLC 
    for multi-line business and non-primary residential lines, which would 
    be offset by smaller reductions in CCL and multi-line PICC rates. We 
    also seek comment on whether a downward adjustment to the incumbent 
    LECs' PCIs should be across-the-board instead of targeted to the common 
    line basket.
        35. We also seek comment on whether we should reduce the SLC on 
    primary residential and single-line business lines. Although such a 
    reduction is an option, it would not further the goal of reducing 
    implicit interstate support, unless it was targeted to low-cost wire 
    centers within a study area. The current SLC cap of $3.50 per month on 
    primary residential and single-line business lines already creates 
    interstate implicit support for most of those lines. A general 
    reduction in the SLC would increase the need for such support and would 
    not reduce support implicit in the CCLC and the multi-line PICC. 
    Although, at the end of the transition initiated by our Access Charge 
    Reform Order, 62 FR 31040 (June 6, 1997), the combination of the SLC 
    and PICC assessed to each line will permit carriers to recover the full 
    interstate-allocated portion of their common line costs from the line 
    that caused those costs to be incurred, any reduction in the SLC would 
    delay this transitional process and result in a higher PICC on primary 
    residential and single-line business lines. We do not expect any 
    reductions to the common line basket to reduce common-line recovery 
    below $3.50 per month, per line, but we seek comment on whether we 
    should limit any reductions to the common line basket to the amount 
    needed to reduce common line revenues per line to $3.50. We seek 
    comment on how the remainder of the adjustment should be applied if 
    that were to occur.
        36. We tentatively conclude that non-rural rate-of-return LECs 
    should apply additional interstate explicit high-cost support revenues 
    to the CCL element, thus reducing CCL charges. We seek comment on this 
    tentative conclusion. We also seek comment on whether these revenues 
    should instead be deducted from the BFP, which would reduce the SLC for 
    multi-line business lines and diminish the reduction to the CCLC. 
    Furthermore, as noted, the Joint Board set forth certain guidelines 
    that the Commission should follow when taking action to remove implicit 
    support from interstate access rates, including: (1) there should be a 
    corresponding dollar-for-dollar reduction in interstate access charges 
    as implicit support in interstate access rates is replaced with 
    explicit support; (2) any reductions in interstate access rates should 
    benefit consumers; (3) universal service should bear no more than a 
    reasonable share of joint and common costs; and (4) reasonable 
    comparability should not be jeopardized, and neither consumers in 
    general nor particular classes of consumers should be harmed. We seek 
    comment on whether our proposals in this section conform to the Joint 
    Board's guidelines.
        37. Finally, we recognize that some proposals for access reform may 
    have the added benefit of directing more federal support to high-cost 
    areas, relative to low-cost areas. For example, some parties have 
    suggested using the cost proxy model as the basis for converting the 
    excess of access rates above the forward-looking cost of access from 
    implicit support to geographically deaveraged support amounts. These 
    support amounts would be both explicit and portable to competing LECs 
    that serve the lines to which these support amounts would be assigned. 
    It would appear that these proposals could potentially serve to direct 
    more federal support to high-cost areas, relative to low-cost areas, 
    much like we believe the use of the cost model in conjunction with an 
    appropriate benchmark could direct such additional support to high-cost 
    areas. We seek comment on whether and how adoption of an access reform 
    proposal that would direct more federal support to high-cost areas, 
    relative to low-cost areas, should affect our calculation of high-cost 
    universal service support, if at all. To the extent possible, parties 
    commenting on this issue should address specific access reform 
    proposals that could be used in this manner to reform both high-cost 
    universal service and access charges simultaneously.
    
    II. Procedural Matters
    
    A. Regulatory Flexibility Act
    
        38. The Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA) requires a Regulatory 
    Flexibility Act analysis whenever an agency publishes a notice of 
    proposed rulemaking, or promulgates a final rule, unless the agency 
    certifies that the proposed or final rule will not have ``a significant 
    economic impact on a substantial number of small entities,'' and 
    includes the factual basis for such certification. The RFA generally 
    defines ``small entity'' as having the same meaning as the term ``small 
    business concern'' under the Small Business Act, 15 U.S.C. 632. The 
    Small Business Administration (SBA) defines a ``small business 
    concern'' as an enterprise that (1) is independently owned and 
    operated; (2) is not dominant in its field of operation; and (3) meets 
    any additional criteria established by the SBA.
        39. We conclude that neither an Initial Regulatory Flexibility 
    Analysis nor a Final Regulatory Flexibility Analysis are required here 
    because the foregoing FNPRM seeks comment only on the mechanisms that 
    the Commission should use to provide high-cost support to non-rural 
    LECs. Non-rural LECs generally do not fall within the SBA's definition 
    of a small business concern because they are usually large 
    corporations, affiliates of such corporations, or dominant in their 
    field of operations. Therefore, we certify, pursuant to the RFA, 5 
    U.S.C. 605(b),
    
    [[Page 30956]]
    
    that the proposals contained in the FNPRM, will not have a significant 
    economic impact on a substantial number of small entities. The Office 
    of Public Affairs, Reference Operation Division, will send a copy of 
    this certification, along with this FNPRM, to the Chief Counsel for 
    Advocacy of the SBA in accordance with the RFA, see 5 U.S.C. 605(b), 
    and to Congress pursuant to the Small Business Regulatory Enforcement 
    Fairness Act of 1996, see 5 U.S.C. 801(a)(1)(A). In addition, this 
    certification, as well as this FNPRM (or summaries thereof), will be 
    published in the Federal Register.
    
    B. Filing Comments
    
        40. Pursuant to Sections 1.415 and 1.419 of the Commission's rules, 
    47 CFR 1.415, 1.419, interested parties may file comments on or before 
    July 2, 1999, and reply comments on or before July 16, 1999. Comments 
    may be filed using the Commission's Electronic Comment Filing System 
    (ECFS) or by filing paper copies. See Electronic Filing of Documents in 
    Rulemaking Proceedings, 63 FR 24,121 (1998).
        41. Comments filed through the ECFS can be sent as an electronic 
    file via the Internet to http://www.fcc.gov/e-file/ecfs.html>. 
    Generally, only one copy of an electronic submission must be filed. If 
    multiple docket or rulemaking numbers appear in the caption of this 
    proceeding, however, commenters must transmit one electronic copy of 
    the comments to each docket or rulemaking number referenced in the 
    caption. In completing the transmittal screen, commenters should 
    include their full name, Postal Service mailing address, and the 
    applicable docket or rulemaking number. Parties may also submit an 
    electronic comment by Internet e-mail. To get filing instructions for 
    e-mail comments, commenters should send an e-mail to ecfs@fcc.gov, and 
    should include the following words in the body of the message, ``get 
    form 

Document Information

Published:
06/09/1999
Department:
Federal Communications Commission
Entry Type:
Proposed Rule
Action:
Notice of proposed rulemaking.
Document Number:
99-14699
Dates:
Comments are due on or before July 2, 1999 and reply comments are due on or before July 16, 1999. Written comments by the public on the proposed information collections are due on or before July 2, 1999 and reply comments are due on or before July 16, 1999. Written comments must be submitted by the Office of Management and Budget (OMB) on the proposed information collections on or before August 9, 1999.
Pages:
30949-30956 (8 pages)
Docket Numbers:
CC Docket Nos. 96-45 and 96-262, FCC 99-119
PDF File:
99-14699.pdf
CFR: (1)
47 CFR 36