98-19266. Access Charge Reform for Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers Subject to Rate-of-Return Regulation  

  • [Federal Register Volume 63, Number 138 (Monday, July 20, 1998)]
    [Proposed Rules]
    [Pages 38774-38783]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 98-19266]
    
    
    =======================================================================
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
    
    47 CFR Part 69
    
    [CC Docket No. 98-77; FCC 98-101]
    
    
    Access Charge Reform for Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers 
    Subject to Rate-of-Return Regulation
    
    AGENCY: Federal Communications Commission.
    
    ACTION: Notice of proposed rulemaking.
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    SUMMARY: By this Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (NPRM), the Commission 
    commences a proceeding to reform access charge rules applicable to 
    incumbent local exchange carriers (LECs) subject to rate-of-return 
    regulation. The NPRM seeks comment on proposals to establish a 
    transition to access charges that more closely reflect economic costs, 
    with a goal of making our system of interstate access charges 
    compatible with a competitive paradigm. Specifically, the Commission 
    seeks comment on proposals to revise the switched access rate structure 
    for rate-of-return LECs. The Commission also solicits comments on some 
    additional issues relating to the regulation of interstate access 
    services of rate-of-return LECs.
    
    DATES: Comments are due on or before August 17, 1998, and reply 
    comments are due on or before September 17, 1998. Written comments and 
    reply comments by the public on the proposed information collections 
    are due August 17 and September 17, 1998, respectively.
    
    ADDRESSES: Federal Communications Commission, Secretary, Room 222, 1919 
    M Street N.W., Washington, DC 20554. In addition to filing comments 
    with the
    
    [[Page 38775]]
    
    Commission's Secretary, a copy of any comments on the proposed 
    information collections contained herein should be submitted to Judy 
    Boley, Federal Communications Commission, Room 234, 1919 M Street N.W., 
    Washington, DC 20554, or via the Internet to jboley@fcc.gov, and to 
    Timothy Fain, OMB Desk Officer, 10236 NEOB, 725 17th Street N.W., 
    Washington, DC 20503, or via the Internet to fain__t@al.eop.gov.
    
    FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Douglas L. Slotten, Common Carrier 
    Bureau, Competitive Pricing Division, at (202) 418-1572. For additional 
    information concerning information collections, contact Judy Boley at 
    (202) 418-0214, or via the Internet at jboley@fcc.gov.
    
    SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a summary of the Commission's NPRM 
    in the matter of Access Charge Reform for Incumbent Local Exchange 
    Carriers Subject to Rate-of-Return Regulation, CC Docket 98-77, adopted 
    May 26, 1998, and released June 4, 1998. The complete text of this NPRM 
    is available for inspection and copying during normal business hours in 
    the Commission's Reference Center, Room 239, 1919 M Street N.W., 
    Washington, DC. In addition, the NPRM is available through the Internet 
    at http://www.fcc.gov/Bureaus/Common__Carrier/Notices/1998/fcc98101.wp. 
    The complete text may be purchased from the Commission's duplicating 
    contractor, International Transcription Service, Inc. (ITS, Inc.), at 
    1231 20th Street N.W., Washington, DC 20036 (202-857-3800).
    
    Paperwork Reduction Act
    
        This NPRM contains either proposed or modified information 
    collections. As part of our continuing effort to reduce paperwork 
    burdens, we invite the general public and OMB to take this opportunity 
    to comment on any additional information collections contained in this 
    NPRM, not previously approved by OMB, as required by the Paperwork 
    Reduction Act of 1995, Pubic Law 104-13. Public and agency comments and 
    reply comments are due August 17 and September 17, 1998, respectively. 
    Written comments by the Office of Management and Budget on the proposed 
    information collections are due September 18, 1998. Comments should 
    address: (a) Whether the proposed collection of information is 
    necessary for the proper performance of the functions of the 
    Commission, including whether the information shall have practical 
    utility; (b) the accuracy of the Commission's burden estimates; (c) 
    ways to enhance the quality, utility, and clarity of the information 
    collected; and (d) ways to minimize the burden of the collection of 
    information on the respondents, including the use of automated 
    collection techniques or other forms of information technology.
        OMB Control No.: None.
        Title: Access Charge Reform for Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers 
    Subject to Rate-of-Return Regulation--CC Docket No. 98-77.
        Form No.: N/A.
        Respondents: Business or other for-profit entities.
        Type of Review: New collection.
    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                          Number of      Estimated time per response                                
            Proposed collection          respondents               (annual)                  Total annual burden    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
    Cost Study for Local Switching Port          155  400 Hours........................  62,000 Hours.              
     Costs.                                                                                                         
    Tariff Filing......................           51  200 Hours........................  10,200 Hours.              
    New Services Requirement...........           10  10 Hours.........................  100 Hours.                 
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Frequency of Response: One-time requirement, on occasion.
        Total Annual Burden: 72,300 Hours.
        Estimated Costs Per Respondent: $600 per respondent.
        Needs and Uses: The Commission commences a proceeding to reform 
    access charge rules applicable to incumbent local exchange carriers 
    (LECs) subject to rate-of-return regulation. We propose to require 
    rate-of-return LECs to conduct cost studies to determine the 
    geographically-averaged portion of local switching costs that is 
    attributable to the line-side ports and to dedicated trunk-side ports, 
    to be filed with the tariffs implementing these changes. The Commission 
    also proposes to allow rate-of-return carriers to file a petition for 
    new services based on a public interest standard. The information will 
    be used to determine whether the incumbent LECs should receive the 
    regulatory relief proposed in the NPRM. The information collections are 
    necessary to implement the Telecommunications Act of 1996.
    
    Synopsis of Notice of Proposed Rulemaking
    
        1. Access reform is one of a series of actions that collectively 
    are intended to foster and accelerate the introduction of efficient 
    competition in all telecommunications markets, pursuant to the mandate 
    of the 1996 Telecommunications Act (1996 Act). In the Access Charge 
    Reform Order, we set in motion the forces of competition and 
    deregulation in local telecommunications markets served by incumbent 
    LECs subject to price cap regulation. Access Charge Reform, CC Docket 
    No. 96-262, First Report and Order, 12 FCC Rcd 15982 (1997), 62 FR 
    31868 (June 11, 1997) (Access Charge Reform Order); Order on 
    Reconsideration, 12 FCC Rcd 10119 (1997), 62 FR 40460 (July 29, 1997); 
    appeal pending sub nom. Southwestern Bell Tel. Co. v. FCC, No. 97-2618 
    (and consolidated cases) (8th Cir. argued Jan. 15, 1998); Second Order 
    on Reconsideration, 12 FCC Rcd 16606 (1997), 62 FR 56121 (October 29, 
    1997) (Second Reconsideration Order). The 1996 Act, however, expressly 
    provides that ``Consumers in all regions of the Nation . . . should 
    have access to telecommunications and information services . . . that 
    are reasonably comparable to those services provided in urban areas and 
    that are available at rates that are reasonably comparable to rates 
    charged for similar services in urban areas.'' 47 U.S.C. 254(b)(3). 
    With this NPRM, we commence a further proceeding on access reform to 
    mobilize the same forces to serve the interests of consumers located in 
    those rural and suburban areas that are served by incumbent LECs 
    subject to rate-of-return regulation. The first step in this reform 
    process is to enable these rate-of-return LECs to assess interstate 
    access charges that are more consistent with principles of cost-
    causation and economic efficiency.
        2. With this NPRM, we continue the process of reforming the access 
    charge rate structure for rate-of-return LECs that was begun in the 
    Access Charge Reform Order with the modifications to the transport rate 
    structure, the reallocation of costs in the transport interconnection 
    charge (TIC), and the amendments reflecting the changes necessary to 
    implement universal service reform. In doing so, we intend to build on 
    the analysis of the access charge rate structure developed in the 
    Access Charge Reform Order. While rate-of-return LEC costs generally 
    may be higher than price cap LEC costs due to longer loops or lower 
    economies of
    
    [[Page 38776]]
    
    scale, the two groups of carriers incur costs in the same manner, and 
    similar economic principles should apply. Subject to receiving evidence 
    showing that differences exist between price cap LECs and rate-of-
    return LECs that require different rules to achieve the goal of 
    fostering an efficient, competitive marketplace, we propose to amend 
    the access charge rules for rate-of-return LECs in a manner similar to 
    that adopted for price cap LECs.
        3. We recognize that differences in the circumstances of rate-of-
    return and price cap LECs may require different approaches to reform, 
    including a different transition to more economically efficient, cost-
    based interstate access charges. We seek to ensure that, at the end of 
    the transition, all Americans enjoy the benefits of competition. By 
    varying the transitional mechanisms, we can ensure that the process of 
    getting to those benefits is as smooth as possible.
        In this NPRM we propose to reform the access charge rate structure 
    of rate-of-return LECs. We address many of the most fundamental 
    economic inefficiencies in the current structure and will lay a 
    foundation on which to develop further initiatives for rate-of-return 
    LECs, including the rural LECs, most of whom are subject to rate-of-
    return regulation. In a subsequent phase of this proceeding, we intend 
    to address the very difficult question of when, and how much, 
    additional pricing flexibility should be afforded to rate-of-return 
    LECs. We also intend to address, in a future proceeding, alternative 
    forms of regulation for LECs currently subject to rate-of-return 
    regulation. Such alternative regulatory structures could offer 
    incentives to rate-of-return LECs that are able to become more 
    efficient.
        5. The Access Charge Reform Order, including subsequent 
    reconsideration and waiver orders, and the Universal Service Order, 
    made the modifications necessary to implement the revisions to the 
    universal service support mechanisms adopted in the Universal Service 
    Order. Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, CC Docket No. 
    96-45, First Report and Order, 12 FCC Rcd 8776 (1997), 62 FR 32862 
    (June 17, 1997) (Universal Service Order). This NPRM is not intended to 
    address contentions that some additional costs or services should 
    receive universal service support; those matters will be resolved in 
    the Universal Service proceeding. We note that the Commission has 
    determined that there shall be no change in the existing high cost 
    support mechanisms for rural LECs until January 1, 2001, at the 
    earliest. This means that, in the interim, the amount of universal 
    service support for rural LECs will be maintained initially at existing 
    levels and should increase in accordance with specified factors, such 
    as inflation, that have historically guided changes in such support.
        6. Common Line Costs. Currently, rate-of-return LECs' subscriber 
    line charges (SLCs) are limited to recovering the lesser of the actual 
    cost of the interstate portion of the local loop, or $3.50 per month 
    for residential and single line business customers, or $6.00 per month 
    for multi-line business customers. Any remaining common line costs are 
    recovered through carrier common line (CCL) charges, which are per-
    minute charges imposed on interexchange carriers (IXCs).
        7. We tentatively conclude that we should adopt rate structure 
    modifications for rate-of-return LECs that are similar to those that 
    were adopted for price cap LECs in the Access Charge Reform Order. We 
    seek comment on the applicability of the rate structure modifications 
    adopted for price cap LECs to rate-of-return LECs. Specifically, the 
    Commission proposes to permit rate-of-return LECs to adjust their SLC 
    ceilings on non-primary residential and multi-line business lines to 
    the level necessary to recover their average per-line interstate-
    allocated common line costs, subject to an inflation-adjusted $9.00 
    ceiling, while leaving the existing SLC ceiling of $3.50 for primary 
    residential and single-line business lines at its current level.
        8. To ameliorate possible adverse impacts of an immediate SLC 
    adjustment for non-primary residential lines, the Commission proposes 
    to adjust the SLC ceilings for these lines gradually. The Commission 
    seeks comment on adjusting the monthly SLC ceiling initially to the 
    LEC's average per-line interstate-allocated costs, but not exceeding 
    $1.50 more than the current SLC ceiling. Annually thereafter, rate-of-
    return LECs could adjust the monthly SLC ceiling for these lines for 
    inflation and could increase the ceiling by $1.00 per line, until the 
    SLC ceiling for non-primary residential lines is equal to the SLC 
    ceiling permitted for multi-line business lines.
        9. To the extent that SLC ceilings prevent rate-of-return LECs from 
    recovering their allowed common line revenues from end users, the 
    Commission proposes to permit these LECs to recover the shortfall, 
    subject to a maximum charge, through a presubscribed interexchange 
    carrier charge (PICC), a flat, per-line charge assessed on the end-
    user's presubscribed interexchange carrier. For the first year, the 
    proposed ceiling on the PICC will be $1.50 per month for non-primary 
    residential lines and $2.75 per month for multi-line business lines. 
    The Commission proposes adjusting the PICC for price cap non-primary 
    residential and multi-line business lines annually for inflation and 
    increasing the PICCs for non-primary residential and multi-line 
    business lines by a maximum of $1.00 and $1.50 per year, respectively, 
    until price cap LECs recover all their permitted common line revenues 
    through a combination of flat-rated SLC and PICCs. The Commission also 
    invites comment on whether the PICC for primary residential and single-
    line business lines should be capped at $0.53 per month for the first 
    year, and adjusted annually thereafter for inflation, and increase by 
    $0.50 per year, until it equals one twelfth of the sum of the annual 
    per-line common line cost and residual interconnection charge cost 
    permitted under our rate-of-return rules, divided by the projected 
    average number of local exchange service subscriber lines in use during 
    such annual period, less the maximum primary residential and single-
    line business lines SLC computed pursuant to our rules. If a customer 
    does not designate a presubscribed interexchange carrier, the 
    Commission proposes to permit rate-of-return LECs to collect directly 
    from the customer the PICC that could otherwise be assessed against the 
    presubscribed interexchange carrier.
        10. To the extent that the SLC ceilings on all lines and the PICC 
    ceilings on primary residential and single-line business lines prevent 
    recovery of the full common line revenues permitted by the rate-of-
    return rules, the Commission proposes to permit rate-of-return LECs to 
    recover the shortfall through a per-minute residual CCL charge. The 
    Commission proposes that rate-of-return LECs should assess the residual 
    CCL charge initially on originating minutes, subject to a rate cap, 
    with any residual being collected through a per-minute terminating CCL 
    charge. Rate-of-return LECs would, under the Commission's proposal, be 
    allowed to assess an originating CCL charge that, when added to the sum 
    of local switching charges, the per-minute residual TIC, and any per-
    minute charges related to marketing expenses, does not exceed the sum 
    of local switching charges, the per-minute CCL charge, and TIC assessed 
    on originating minutes on December 31, 1997. A per-minute residual TIC 
    could also be assessed on IXCs by rate-of-return LECs to recover any 
    TIC costs not recovered through facility-based charges. The originating 
    residual TIC charge would be subject to the same
    
    [[Page 38777]]
    
    ceiling mechanism as the residual CCL charge.
        11. Under the Commission's proposal, the per-minute residual CCL 
    and residual TIC charges will be eliminated as the PICC ceilings 
    increase. After the residual CCL and the residual TIC charges are 
    eliminated, increases in the PICC for primary residential and single-
    line business lines will reduce the PICCs on non-primary residential 
    and multi-line business lines by an amount that corresponds to the 
    total increases in PICCs for primary residential and single-line 
    business lines. Reductions will be targeted to the PICCs on multi-line 
    business lines until the PICCs for those lines are equal to the PICCs 
    for non-primary residential lines. Thereafter, reductions will be 
    applied to both classes of customers equally until the combined SLCs 
    and PICCs for primary residential and single-line business lines 
    recover the full average per-line common line costs permitted under our 
    rules, and the additional PICCs on non-primary residential and multi-
    line business lines no longer recover common line costs. Under the 
    proposal, certain TIC costs and marketing expenses, in addition to 
    common line costs, will be recovered through non-primary residential 
    line and multi-line business PICCs, even though SLCs and PICCs for 
    primary residential and single-line business lines only recover the 
    average per-line common line costs permitted under our rules.
        12. We conclude that modifications similar to those we made for 
    price cap LECs are needed to remove implicit subsidies and ensure that 
    charges more accurately reflect the manner in which the costs are 
    incurred, thereby promoting competition. We acknowledge that certain 
    rate-of-return LECs, especially those in rural and insular areas, face 
    different market conditions and incur higher costs than do many price 
    cap LECs due to the lack of economies of scale that result from low 
    subscriber density and small exchanges that characterize rural areas. 
    Smaller LECs serving more costly areas, however, will receive universal 
    service support based on their embedded costs until the Commission, 
    with the Universal Service Joint Board's assistance, develops an 
    appropriate model to ensure that rural carriers receive support at a 
    level that will enable them to provide supported services at affordable 
    rates. Adopting the same rate structure approach for rate-of return 
    LECs, therefore, most likely will not align rates with costs as quickly 
    as it will for price cap LECs. For many rate-of-return companies, 
    especially those located in rural and insular areas, longer loops and 
    difficult terrain result in average loop costs that significantly 
    exceed the average loop costs of price cap LECs. The cost recovery 
    mechanism for price cap LECs contemplates that price cap LECs will be 
    able to recover all of their interstate-allocated common line costs 
    through a combination of SLCs and PICCs, reducing the CCL charge to 
    zero in a relatively short amount of time.
        13. If rate-of-return LECs were to implement the revised common 
    line rate structure applied to price cap LECs, multi-line business 
    PICCs and CCL charges would often go to their respective ceilings and 
    remain higher than those of price cap LECs for the foreseeable future, 
    because rate-of-return LEC common line costs are significantly higher 
    than those of price cap LECs. If we direct rate-of-return LECs to 
    recover certain switching, marketing, and residual TIC costs through 
    the common line SLCs and PICCs, per-line common line costs will 
    increase further. Under this scenario, the SLCs and/or PICCs for many 
    rate-of-return LECs would have to be adjusted to a level that would be 
    higher than the ceilings we adopted for price cap LECs if significant 
    reductions in the CCL rate were desired. We solicit comment on this 
    analysis.
        14. We ask interested parties to discuss how we should determine 
    appropriate SLC ceilings. Several entities have expressed concern that 
    the immediate SLC increases to $9.00 for non-primary or multi-line 
    business lines will create a large disparity between SLCs charged by 
    rate-of-return LECs and neighboring price cap LECs, and that under the 
    1996 Act and applicable state laws, the lower-cost price cap carriers 
    will be able to ``cherry pick'' the high volume business customers of 
    the higher priced rate-of-return LECs. These entities urge the 
    Commission to grant them pricing flexibility and propose that SLCs be 
    set based on the national average or on the neighboring price cap LEC's 
    average SLC.
        15. We invite comment on establishing a ceiling that is based on 
    the neighboring price cap LEC's average multi-line business SLC, or on 
    the national average. In addition, in some cases, as the non-primary 
    SLC cap increases, the disparity between the $3.50 SLC for primary 
    residential lines and the SLC for non-primary residential lines will 
    most likely be greater for rate-of-return carriers than it is for price 
    cap companies. Would this disparity warrant a different approach for 
    rate-of-return carriers' non-primary residential lines than we adopted 
    for price cap LECs?
        16. Interested parties should discuss whether the PICC is an 
    effective cost recovery mechanism for rate-of-return LECs' common line 
    costs and, if so, to what extent the PICCs and CCL charges for rate-of-
    return LECs should be comparable to those of price cap LECs. If 
    commenters believe that the plan we adopted in the Access Charge Reform 
    Order would not produce the expected economic benefits for rate-of-
    return LECs and their customers, interested parties should submit 
    alternative plans. For example, should we prescribe higher ceilings for 
    PICCs that would permit rate-of-return LECs to reduce their CCL rates 
    to levels comparable to those of price cap LECs? Alternatively, should 
    we prescribe a maximum CCL charge and eliminate the PICC ceiling to 
    allow rate-of-return LECs to recover the shortfall through flat-rated 
    charges? In addition, in light of the higher common line costs incurred 
    by many rate-of-return LECs, and because, if adopted, other 
    modifications proposed in this NPRM will require rate-of-return LECs to 
    recover certain switching, marketing, and TIC costs through the common 
    line recovery mechanism, we invite parties to discuss whether we should 
    permit these carriers to recover relatively more of the common line 
    revenue requirement through terminating minutes. Given that local 
    switching per-minute rates will be reduced significantly by the 
    inclusion of dial equipment minutes (DEM) weighing in universal service 
    support, we ask interested parties to discuss whether a higher per-
    minute CCL charge in the short run is unsatisfactory.
        17. Interested parties should also discuss the extent to which, for 
    purposes of assessing SLCs and PICCs, residential and business lines 
    should be treated differently. For example, should non-primary 
    residential lines be assessed lower PICCs than multi-line business 
    lines and phased in over time, as we did for price cap LECs, or should 
    we permit the SLCs for non-primary residential lines to increase more 
    rapidly for rate-of-return LECs than for price cap LECs, in order to 
    allow carriers in high-cost areas to reduce their CCL charge more 
    rapidly than would otherwise be possible with graduated increases in 
    the SLC? Alternatively, should a uniform PICC be applied to all non-
    primary residential and business lines to spread the revenue 
    requirement evenly across these classes of customers?
        18. In the Second Reconsideration Order in the Access Charge Reform 
    proceeding, we concluded that with
    
    [[Page 38778]]
    
    respect to the PICC, Centrex customers should be treated similarly to 
    PBX customers, because the two arrangements are functionally 
    equivalent. Accordingly, we determined that Centrex lines should be 
    assessed PICCs using a 9:1 line-to-trunk equivalency ratio, except 
    where the multi-line business SLC ceiling does not permit the recovery 
    of all interstate-allocated loop costs from the end user. In those 
    instances, a PICC that includes the difference between the per-line 
    loop cost and the multi-line business SLC cap, subject to the multi-
    line business PICC ceiling, will be assessed on Centrex lines. We seek 
    comment on the applicability of this approach and of the 9:1 ratio to 
    rate-of-return LECs. Parties proposing different ratios should submit 
    data supporting the ratio they propose.
        19. We also seek comment on how the 1996 Act will affect the 
    development of competition in areas served by small and rural rate-of-
    return LECs. While the entry of competitors in many rate-of-return LEC 
    service areas may be delayed due to the provisions of 47 CFR 251(f), 
    entry in these areas will likely occur in time. Specifically, section 
    251(f)(1) provides an exemption for certain rural telephone companies 
    from the duties of local exchange carriers enumerated in section 
    251(c), including but not limited to the duties to interconnect, to 
    provide access to network elements on an unbundled basis, and to resell 
    telecommunications services. Section 251(f)(2) provides a mechanism by 
    which local exchange carriers with fewer than two percent of the 
    nation's subscriber lines may petition the state for suspension or 
    modification of some of the duties imposed by the Act on local exchange 
    carriers. We ask interested parties to discuss the impact of these 
    statute sections and the development of competition as they relate to 
    the rate structure and transition mechanism we are proposing in this 
    NPRM.
        20. We also seek comment on whether we should adopt one approach 
    for all rate-of-return LECs or whether our approach should vary 
    depending on size, population density, topography, or other factors 
    that may vary among rate-of-return LECs. Are there concerns that are 
    specific to National Exchange Carrier Association (NECA) pooling 
    companies that warrant separate treatment? Interested parties should 
    address the specific issues raised and submit proposals for 
    modifications that are consistent with the goals of the 1996 Act. 
    Interested parties should also propose a time frame for adopting 
    modifications to the rate structure. Should modifications adopted 
    become effective immediately or should they be phased in over time? 
    Finally, parties should address the extent to which options proposed 
    affect small business entities, including small incumbent LECs and new 
    entrants.
        21. Assessment of SLCs and PICCs on Derived Channels. We propose to 
    adopt similar SLCs and PICCs for integrated services digital network 
    (ISDN) service offered by rate-of-return LECs. Specifically, we propose 
    to permit rate-of-return LECs to charge SLC and PICC rates for Primary 
    Rate Interface (PRI) ISDN service equal to five times the rate-of-
    return LEC's multi-line business SLC and PICC, and SLC and PICC rates 
    for Basic Rate Interface (BRI) ISDN service equal to the rate-of-return 
    LEC's non-primary residential line SLC and PICC. We seek comment on 
    these conclusions and invite parties to comment on the impact that 
    assessing SLCs and PICCs on ISDN lines will have on rate-of-return 
    carriers and their customers. Parties should address whether the cost 
    relationship between ISDN and analog service provided by rate-of-return 
    LECs is similar to that of price cap LECs; if they believe it is not, 
    they should submit specific data supporting their position. We also 
    invite parties to discuss the relationship between proposed 
    modifications to the common line rate structure and our tentative 
    conclusion to treat rate-of-return LECs' ISDN lines in the manner 
    discussed above.
        22. Local Switching Dedicated Facilities. The interstate portion of 
    local switching costs is currently recovered through per-minute local 
    switching charges levied on IXCs, even though a significant portion of 
    local switching costs is associated with ports and appears to be driven 
    by the number of lines or trunks connected to the switch, not by the 
    number of minutes of traffic routed by the switch. We propose to 
    require rate-of-return LECs to reassign all costs for line-side ports, 
    including the line card, protector, and main distribution frame, from 
    the local switching category to the common line category, for recovery 
    through the common line rate structure. We seek comment on this 
    proposal. We ask if there are any specific factors for rate-of-return 
    LECs that would preclude our adoption of this rate structure change at 
    this time.
        23. We propose to require rate-of-return LECs to conduct cost 
    studies to determine the geographically-averaged portion of local 
    switching costs that is attributable to the line-side ports and to 
    dedicated trunk-side ports, to be filed with the tariffs implementing 
    these changes. We solicit comment on this cost study proposal. In the 
    alternative, commenters are requested to suggest a substitute mechanism 
    to identify and assign costs to line-side ports or to trunk-side ports.
        24. We also propose to require rate-of-return LECs to recover 
    dedicated trunk port costs through a flat-rated trunk port charge 
    assessed on the purchaser of the dedicated trunk terminating at the 
    port. Analog switches require a voice-grade interface on the trunk-side 
    of the end office switch, thereby requiring DS1 transport trunks to be 
    demultiplexed into individual voice-grade circuits before being 
    switched at analog end office switches. DS1/voice-grade multiplexers 
    perform this function. A digital switch port includes the DS1/voice-
    grade multiplexing function. In addition, we propose to establish a 
    separate rate element through which rate-of-return LECs can recover on 
    a flat-rated basis the additional costs of DS1/voice grade multiplexers 
    required in conjunction with terminating dedicated trunks at analog 
    switches that were reassigned from the TIC. We ask whether the benefits 
    to be gained from a more efficient, cost-causative rate structure 
    outweigh the burden on rate-of-return LECs of establishing these new 
    rate elements. In addition, we solicit suggestions as to what specific 
    modifications of the part 69 cost allocation rules we should make to 
    implement any rate structure changes for dedicated local switching 
    facilities.
        25. Common line charges will recover the cost of a line port used 
    to provide basic, analog service, even when the end user has another 
    form of service. For some services, such as ISDN, the cost of a line 
    port is significantly more than the cost of a line port associated with 
    a basic, analog line. We propose to permit rate-of-return LECs to 
    assess a separate, monthly, flat-rated charge directly on end users of 
    such services, to recover the amount by which the cost of a line port 
    for ISDN, or the cost of a line port associated with other services, 
    exceeds the cost of a line port for basic, analog service. We request 
    comment on this proposal.
        26. Local Switching Shared Facilities. We seek comment on our 
    tentative conclusion that rate-of-return LECs adhere to a per-minute 
    rate structure for shared local switching facilities, including the 
    central processing unit, switching matrix, and shared trunk ports. 
    Under this approach, the shared trunk ports and any associated DS1/
    voice grade multiplexers required at analog local switches will be 
    assessed on a per-minute basis, separate from the charge for the switch 
    itself. We ask whether there are any factors inherent to
    
    [[Page 38779]]
    
    rate-of-return LECs that should lead us to change this tentative 
    conclusion.
        27. Call Setup Charge. We propose to permit, but not require, rate-
    of-return LECs to establish a charge for call setup, the process of 
    establishing a transmission path over which a phone call will be 
    routed. Costs for call setup using SS7 are incurred primarily on a per-
    call rather than a per-minute basis. Under this proposed revision to 47 
    CFR 69.106, a rate-of-return LEC could elect to establish a separate 
    per-call setup charge assessed on IXCs for all originating interstate 
    calls handed off to the IXC's point of presence (POP), and on all 
    terminating interstate calls that are received from an IXC's POP, 
    whether or not a call is completed. We invite comment on this proposal 
    for an optional call setup charge, including specific language to 
    modify our part 69 cost allocation rules to implement this rate 
    structure change. Moreover, if a rate-of-return LEC elects to recover 
    revenue requirements through a call setup charge, we tentatively 
    conclude that this charge cannot overlap with any other local switching 
    charges, with charges for dedicated SS7 facilities, or with other 
    signalling charges. We request comment on our tentative conclusion 
    prohibiting double recovery for call setup charges by rate-of-return 
    LECs. Commenters also should suggest mechanisms that would prevent any 
    double recovery for rate-of-return LECs.
        28. It would be extremely difficult to segregate the costs of the 
    switch central processing unit and other traffic-sensitive costs into 
    per-message and per-minute portions and to verify that the allocation 
    has been done properly. Therefore, we propose to limit the costs that a 
    rate-of-return LEC may recover through call setup charges to those 
    associated with signalling. We request comment on this proposal. We 
    seek comment on how call setup costs are affected by whether 
    multifrequency (MF) signalling or SS7 signalling is employed. We also 
    request estimates of the percentage of the total costs of a typical 
    call that are represented by call setup costs. To facilitate our 
    comparison of the estimates submitted, we request that commenters use 
    an average call duration of 3.86 minutes, which we used as the call 
    duration in our analysis in the Access Charge Reform Order.
        29. Tandem-Switched Transport Issues. We request comment on our 
    analysis that we should require rate-of-return LECs to recover the 
    costs of trunk ports used to terminate dedicated trunks on the serving 
    wire center (SWC) side of the tandem switch through flat-rated charges 
    assessed on the purchaser of the dedicated trunk terminated at the 
    trunk port on the SWC side of the tandem switch. To ease the burdens of 
    implementing this unbundling, we propose to permit rate-of-return LECs 
    to use the dedicated trunk port rates at the local switch to establish 
    this unbundled charge. We ask for comment on this proposal. With regard 
    to shared facilities at the tandem switch, we solicit comment on our 
    tentative conclusion that there is no need to create a separate charge 
    for shared trunk ports on the end-office-side of the tandem switch 
    because this trunk port cost is included in the charge for the tandem 
    switch and there is no reason to charge separately for shared trunk 
    ports in the tandem switching context.
        30. We also propose to require rate-of-return LECs to establish 
    separate rate elements to recover the costs of multiplexing equipment 
    on each side of the tandem switch that were reassigned to tandem 
    switching from the TIC in the Access Charge Reform First 
    Reconsideration Order. The rates for multiplexers on the SWC side of 
    the tandem switch would be flat rated because they are dedicated to a 
    single IXC. The rates for the multiplexers on the end office side of 
    the tandem switch would be per-minute charges because these 
    multiplexers are shared among all users of common transport. To 
    simplify the implementation process for rate-of-return LECs, we propose 
    to permit them to use multiplexer rates already established in their 
    special access tariff for similar multiplexers. We request comment on 
    these proposals. These provisions cover DS1/voice grade multiplexers 
    used with analog tandem switches, as well as other multiplexers that 
    are not included in transport rates.
        31. Outstanding Transport Interconnection Charge Issues for Rate-
    of-Return LECs. Although the Commission in the Access Charge Reform 
    Order directed rate-of-return LECs to make specified cost reallocations 
    from the TIC to other facilities-based rate elements, thereby reducing 
    the amount in the TIC, the reallocation of costs from the TIC to other 
    rate elements will not remove all of the costs from the TIC, leaving a 
    residual TIC. We propose to incorporate the residual TIC in the common 
    line pricing structure of rate-of-return LECs, just as we did for price 
    cap LECs. This will put in place a mechanism that will, at different 
    times for different rate-of-return LECs, begin the process of 
    transferring TIC costs to other rate elements. We ask for comment on 
    this analysis and on our proposal to adopt a similar rate structure to 
    that we employed for price cap LECs.
        32. The Access Charge Reform Order reduces the TIC for price cap 
    LECs by targeting certain price cap index (PCI) reductions to reducing 
    the TIC. Price cap LECs will target price cap productivity (X-factor) 
    adjustments to the trunking basket's PCI, and therein to the TIC 
    service band index (SBI), thus reducing the amounts recovered through 
    the residual TIC and effectively spreading those residual TIC revenues 
    among the universe of access services. We ask whether any comparable 
    mechanism exists for rate-of-return LECs that would eliminate the 
    residual TIC in a reasonable time. We ask commenters whether it would 
    be practical to spread the residual TIC proportionately over the other 
    access elements in a manner comparable to that of targeting price cap 
    productivity reductions to the TIC. We seek comment on what would be a 
    reasonable time in which to accomplish such a reallocation. We ask 
    parties supporting such an approach to propose cost allocation rules to 
    implement their approach. Parties presenting data to quantify amounts 
    in the residual TIC should include sufficient detail to permit the 
    Commission and interested parties to evaluate the procedures used and 
    to adjust the results, if necessary, to address concerns raised by the 
    record. We seek comment on how these approaches affect small business 
    entities, including small incumbent LECs and new entrants.
        33. We ask parties to address whether there are additional causes 
    of costs remaining in the residual TIC for rate-of-return LECs that 
    have not been identified previously that would justify further 
    reallocations of costs from the TIC. Parties identifying such costs 
    should indicate the other element(s) to which these additional costs 
    should be reallocated. We invite parties to comment on whether any 
    public policy reasons would support retaining some costs of rate-of-
    return LECs in the residual TIC indefinitely. We ask parties to address 
    the competitive implications of waiting for completion of a Joint Board 
    review of separations procedures to determine which, if any, of the 
    costs in the TIC reflect the higher cost of providing transport 
    services in less densely populated areas, as compared with the costs 
    underlying transport rates that were derived from special access rates. 
    See Jurisdictional Separations Reform and Referral to the Federal-State 
    Joint Board, CC Docket No. 80-286, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 12 
    FCC Rcd 22120 (1997), 62 FR 59842 (November 5, 1997).
        34. Signalling System Seven (SS7). SS7 is the international 
    standard
    
    [[Page 38780]]
    
    network protocol currently used to establish and close transmission 
    paths over which telephone calls are carried. Once the reallocation of 
    SS7 costs included in the TIC is completed, most, if not all, of SS7 
    costs presumably will be recovered through the local switching charge. 
    We invite comment on our proposal to continue the existing rate 
    structure for SS7 cost recovery by rate-of-return LECs, and to permit 
    these LECs to adopt the rate structure for SS7 services that we 
    approved in Ameritech Operating Companies Petition for Waiver of Part 
    69 of the Commission's Rules to Establish Unbundled Rate Elements for 
    SS7 Signalling, Order, 11 FCC Rcd 3839, 3841 (Com. Car. Bur. 1996). The 
    rate structure established by Ameritech pursuant to that waiver 
    recovers costs through four unbundled charges for the various functions 
    performed by SS7 networks: (1) Signal link; (2) STP port termination; 
    (3) signal transport; and (4) signal switching. We also solicit 
    additional, alternative SS7 rate structure proposals for rate-of-return 
    LECs. Any comments on this issue should include an assessment of the 
    expense of requiring rate-of-return LECs to install equipment in their 
    networks for metering SS7 traffic. Would the streamlined waiver 
    petition procedure we propose pursuant to section 69.4(g) be preferable 
    as a means to address alternative SS7 rate structures proposed by rate-
    of-return LECs?
        35. We recognize that some call setup is still performed using in-
    band, MF signalling, rather than out-of-band signalling systems such as 
    SS7. SS7 signalling may be less prevalent for rate-of-return LECs than 
    for price cap LECs. Any determination we make concerning a SS7 rate 
    structure for rate-of-return LECs could be affected by the extent that 
    rate-of-return LEC networks use SS7. We also ask parties to comment on 
    the need for revisions to the cost allocation rules in part 69 to 
    accommodate the provision of SS7 signalling in accordance with the 
    provisions of the Ameritech SS7 waiver.
        36. General Support Facilities Costs. To the extent that rate-of-
    return LECs' costs are underallocated to the billing and collection 
    category, rate-of-return LECs' regulated services are recovering costs 
    associated with unregulated services through interstate access charges. 
    We solicit comment on our tentative conclusion that we should modify 47 
    CFR 69.307 for rate-of-return LECs to allocate general support 
    facilities (GSF) costs related to billing and collection services to 
    the billing and collection category. For rate-of-return LECs that 
    maintain accounts below the summary account level, we propose the use 
    of a general expense allocator to apportion the interstate share of 
    Accounts 2111 (Land), 2121 (Buildings), 2123 (Office Equipment), and 
    2124 (General Purpose Computers) between: (1) The billing and 
    collection category and (2) all other elements and categories. To 
    determine the amount to be assigned to the billing and collection 
    category, we propose to apply a modified ``Big Three Expense Factor'' 
    allocator to the interstate investment recorded in these four accounts. 
    The interstate portion of Account 6120 (General Support Expenses) will 
    continue to be apportioned among all elements and categories, including 
    billing and collection, based upon the allocation rules contained in 47 
    CFR 69.401(a)(2). Access Charge Reform, Third Report and Order, CC 
    Docket No. 96-262, 12 FCC Rcd 22430 (1997) (Third Report and Order), 62 
    FR 65619 (December 15, 1997). Because certain small rate-of-return LECs 
    do not maintain accounts below the summary account level, we seek 
    comment on what adjustments, if any, we should make to the allocation 
    procedures to reflect this difference. It would be helpful if parties 
    would comment on how many rate-of-return LECs use general purpose 
    computers to provide billing and collection services. We also invite 
    parties to identify any changes that should be made to other access 
    elements as a result of any changes we may make to the GSF allocation 
    procedures. Finally, parties should also address the extent to which 
    these approaches affect large and small rate-of-return LECs differently 
    and how small business entities, including small incumbent LECs and new 
    entrants, will be affected.
        37. Marketing Expenses. The Commission concluded in the Access 
    Charge Reform Order that price cap LECs' marketing costs that are not 
    related to the sale or advertising of interstate switched access 
    services are not appropriately recovered from IXCs through per-minute 
    interstate switched access charges. We seek comment on our tentative 
    conclusion that rate-of-return LECs' marketing expenses allocated to 
    the interstate jurisdiction should be recovered through the common line 
    recovery mechanism from end users on a per-line basis. Specifically, we 
    propose that rate-of-return LECs recover the revenues related to the 
    Account 6610 marketing expenses by increasing the SLCs for multi-line 
    business and non-primary residential lines, subject to the SLC 
    ceilings. To the extent the SLC ceilings prevent full recovery of these 
    amounts, rate-of-return LECs would be required to recover marketing 
    costs through equal increases on the PICCs for non-primary residential 
    and multi-line business lines, subject to the PICC ceilings. In the 
    event the PICC ceilings prevent full recovery of these expenses, any 
    residual marketing expenses may be recovered through per-minute charges 
    on originating access service, subject to the ceiling placed on 
    originating minutes. If rate-of-return LECs cannot recover their 
    remaining marketing expenses through per-minute charges on originating 
    access, any residual may be recovered through per-minute charges on 
    terminating access service. To the extent marketing expenses will be 
    recovered through the SLC, they shall not be included in the base 
    factor portion or considered common line revenues.
        38. We also ask parties to propose a mechanism comparable to the 
    separate basket created for price cap LECs that will remove marketing 
    expenses from access charges assessed by rate-of-return LECs. We invite 
    parties to provide language for the amendment of our part 69 cost 
    allocation rules that affect the recovery of these marketing expenses 
    through the common line cost recovery mechanism.
        39. Special Access. In light of the most recent changes to the 
    charges incurred by multi-line businesses, including the higher SLC and 
    the new multi-line business PICC, it may be cost effective for some 
    multi-line businesses to substitute the purchase of special access 
    lines for the use of switched access. We have already tentatively 
    concluded that we should permit price cap LECs to assess a PICC on 
    special access lines to recover revenues for the common line basket. 
    Access Charge Reform, CC Docket No. 96-262, Further Notice of Proposed 
    Rulemaking, 12 FCC Rcd 15982, 16154 para. 401 (1997), 62 FR 31868 (June 
    11, 1997) (Further Notice). The special access PICC would be no higher 
    than the PICC that a price cap LEC could charge for a multi-line 
    business line, would not recover TIC or marketing expenses, and would 
    be gradually eliminated as the single-line PICC is gradually 
    implemented for price cap LECs. We tentatively concluded that allowing 
    price cap LECs to impose such special access PICCs would be necessary 
    to facilitate the transition from current per minute CCL charges to the 
    flat-rate PICC.
        40. We invite parties to comment on whether, if we apply a PICC to 
    special access services offered by price cap LECs, we should apply a 
    PICC to special access services offered by rate-of-return LECs. Parties 
    should comment on the
    
    [[Page 38781]]
    
    impact of PICCs on special access lines if the PICCs on rate-of-return 
    LECs' multi-line business lines remain in place for a considerably 
    longer time than they do for price cap LECs. To the extent parties 
    advocate assessing PICCs on special access lines, we seek comment on 
    how special access connections should be counted for purposes of 
    assessing a ``per line'' PICC. Parties should also address the extent 
    to which our proposal affects large and small LECs differently and how 
    small business entities, including small incumbent LECs and new 
    entrants, will be affected.
        41. Part 69 Cost Allocation Rules. Under the Commission's 
    separations rules at 47 CFR part 36, certain costs of the incumbent LEC 
    network are assigned to the interstate jurisdiction. For rate-of-return 
    LECs, the Commission's cost allocation rules at 47 CFR part 69 allocate 
    these interstate costs among the various access and interexchange 
    services. In addition to the comment requested previously in this NPRM 
    on the need for changes to our cost allocation rules in conjunction 
    with specific proposals to revise certain rate structure provisions of 
    the part 69 rules, we ask whether we should make any other 
    modifications at this time to our cost allocation rules for rate-of-
    return LECs to accommodate any of those changes, or to update the rules 
    in other respects. Parties making such suggestions should be specific 
    about the reasons the change is needed and include proposed language 
    for revising the cost allocation rules.
        42. Modification of New Services Requirement. Rate-of-return LECs 
    currently must file a petition pursuant to 47 CFR 1.3 to request a part 
    69 waiver for the establishment of one or more new switched access rate 
    elements to accommodate a new service offering to switched access 
    customers. In order to streamline the part 69 waiver process for a 
    rate-of-return LEC wishing to offer a new service, we request comment 
    on our proposal to adopt for rate-of-return LECs the streamlined 
    petition provisions of section 69.4(g), which currently requires a 
    price cap LEC in similar circumstances to file a petition that 
    demonstrates one of two criteria: (1) That another LEC has previously 
    obtained approval to establish identical rate elements and that the 
    original petition did not rely upon a competitive showing as part of 
    its public interest justification, or (2) that the new rate elements 
    would serve the public interest. In addition, we request suggestions as 
    to any manner in which the procedures or standards of section 69.4(g) 
    should be modified for rate-of-return LECs. Parties should comment, for 
    instance, on whether a showing of prior approval should be limited to 
    petitions granted to other rate-of-return LECs.
    
    Ex Parte Presentations
    
        43. This Notice of Proposed Rulemaking is a permit-but-disclose 
    proceeding and is subject to the permit-but-disclose requirements under 
    47 CFR 1206(b), as revised. Persons making oral ex parte presentations 
    are reminded that memoranda summarizing the presentation must contain a 
    summary of the substance of the presentation and not merely a listing 
    of the subjects discussed. More than a one or two sentence description 
    of the views and arguments presented is generally required. Other rules 
    pertaining to oral and written presentations are set forth in section 
    1.1206(b), as well.
    
    Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
    
        44. As required by the Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA), the 
    Commission has prepared this Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis 
    (IRFA) of the possible significant economic impact on small entities of 
    the proposals suggested in this NPRM. See 5 U.S.C. 603. The RFA, 5 
    U.S.C. 601 et seq., has been amended by the Contract With America 
    Advancement Act of 1996, Public Law 104-121, 110 Stat. 847 (1996) 
    (CWAAA). Title II of the CWAAA is the Small Business Regulatory 
    Enforcement Fairness Act of 1996 (SBREFA).
        45. Written public comments are requested on the IRFA. Comments and 
    reply comments must be identified by a separate and distinct heading as 
    responses to the IRFA and must be filed on or before August 17 or 
    September 17, 1998 respectively. Parties should address the extent to 
    which our proposals affect large and small incumbent rate-of-return 
    local exchange carriers (LECs) differently and how small business 
    entities, including small incumbent LECs and new entrants, will be 
    affected. The Commission's Office of Public Affairs, Reference 
    Operations Division, will send a copy of this NPRM, including this 
    IRFA, to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the Small Business 
    Administration, in accordance with 5 USC 603(a). In addition, the NPRM 
    and IRFA (or summaries thereof) will be published in the Federal 
    Register.
        46. Need for, and Objectives of, the Proposed Rules. The 
    Commission's access charge rules for rate-of-return LECs were adopted 
    at a time when interstate access and local exchange services were 
    offered on a monopoly basis. We seek to revise the Commission's access 
    charge rules for local exchange carriers (LECs) subject to rate-of-
    return regulation to make the rules consistent with the pro-
    competitive, deregulatory policies contemplated by the 
    Telecommunications Act of 1996. In the 1997 Access Charge Reform Order, 
    we focused on setting in motion the forces of competition and 
    deregulation in local markets served by incumbent local exchange 
    carriers subject to price cap regulation. In this NPRM, we propose to 
    modify our rate structure requirements, to the extent possible, to 
    permit rate-of-return LECs to recover costs in a manner that more 
    accurately reflects the way those costs are incurred, identify implicit 
    subsidies, and reduce subsidies by recovering more costs from the cost 
    causer, thereby sending more accurate pricing signals to both consumers 
    and competitors, and facilitating the transformation from a regulated 
    to a competitive marketplace. Specifically, we propose to reduce usage-
    sensitive interstate access charges by diminishing local loop and other 
    non-traffic sensitive costs and directing rate-of-return LECs to 
    recover those non-traffic sensitive costs through more economically 
    efficient, flat-rated charges.
        47. Legal Basis. The proposed action is authorized by sections 1-4, 
    201-205, 251, 254, 303(r) and 403 of the Communications Act of 1934, as 
    amended, 47 U.S.C. 151-154, 201-205, 251, 254, 303(r) and 403.
        48. Description and Estimate of the Number of Small Entities To 
    Which the Proposed Rules Will Apply. The Regulatory Flexibility Act 
    directs agencies to provide a description of and an estimate, where 
    feasible, of the number of small entities that may be affected by 
    proposed rules, if adopted. 5 U.S.C. 603(b)(3). The Regulatory 
    Flexibility Act generally defines the term ``small entity'' as having 
    the same meaning as the term ``small business.'' 5 U.S.C. 601(6). The 
    term ``small business'' has the same meaning as the term ``small 
    business concern'' under the Small Business Act. See 5 U.S.C. 601(3). 
    Under the Small Business Act, a ``small business concern'' is one that: 
    (1) Is independently owned and operated; (2) is not dominant in its 
    field of operation; and (3) meets any additional criteria established 
    by the Small Business Administration (SBA). 15 USC 632. See, e.g., 
    Brown Transport Truckload, Inc. v. Southern Wipers, Inc., 176 B.R. 82 
    (N.D. Ga. 1994).
        49. Because the small rate-of-return LECs that would be subject to 
    these rules are either dominant in their field of operations or are not 
    independently owned and operated, consistent with
    
    [[Page 38782]]
    
    our prior practice, they are excluded from the definition of ``small 
    entity'' and ``small business concerns.'' See Implementation of the 
    Local Competition Provisions of the Telecommunications Act of 1996, CC 
    Docket No. 96-98, First Report and Order, 11 FCC Rcd 15499, 16144-45 
    Paras. 1327-30 (1996) (Local Competition Order), 61 FR 45476 (August 
    29, 1996), Order on Reconsideration, 11 FCC Rcd 13042 (1996), 61 FR 
    52706 (October 8, 1996), vacated in part sub nom. Iowa Utils. Bd. v. 
    FCC, 120 F.3d 753 (8th Cir. 1997), cert. granted sub nom. AT&T Corp. v. 
    Iowa Utils. Bd., 118 S.Ct. 879 (1998). Accordingly, our use of the 
    terms ``small entities'' and ``small businesses'' does not encompass 
    small rate-of-return LECs. Out of an abundance of caution, however, for 
    regulatory flexibility analysis purposes, we will consider small rate-
    of-return LECs within this analysis and use the term ``small incumbent 
    rate-of-return LECs'' to refer to any rate-of-return LECs that arguably 
    might be defined by SBA as ``small business concerns,'' including 
    consideration of any adverse impact of the rules we adopt and 
    consideration of alternatives that may reduce adverse impacts on such 
    entities. Since the time of the Commission's 1996 decision in the Local 
    Competition Order, 11 FCC Rcd at 16144-45, 61 FR 45476 (August 29, 
    1996), the Commission has consistently addressed in its regulatory 
    flexibility analyses the impact of its rules on incumbent LECs. See 13 
    CFR 121.210 (SIC 4813). See also Executive Office of the President, 
    Office of Management and Budget, Standard Industrial Classification 
    Manual (1987).
        50. The SBA has defined a small business for Standard Industrial 
    Classification (SIC) category 4813 (Telephone Communications, Except 
    Radiotelephone) to be small telecommunications entities when they have 
    no more than 1,500 employees at the holding company level. 13 CFR 
    121.201. We invite interested parties to discuss the number of 
    telecommunications providers, if any, that can be considered ``small 
    entities'' within the meaning of the Regulatory Flexibility Act, and 
    whether there is any reason to establish different requirements for 
    small telecommunication providers. Below, we discuss the total 
    estimated number of telephone companies falling within these categories 
    and the number of small businesses in each category, and we then 
    attempt to refine further those estimates to correspond with the 
    categories of telephone companies that are commonly used under our 
    rules.
        51. The most reliable source of information regarding the total 
    numbers of certain common carriers nationwide appears to be data the 
    Commission publishes annually in its Telecommunications Industry 
    Revenue report, regarding the Telecommunications Relay Service (TRS). 
    FCC, Telecommunications Industry Revenue: TRS Fund Worksheet Data, 
    Figure 2 (Number of Carriers Paying Into the TRS Fund by Type of 
    Carrier) (Nov. 1997) (Telecommunications Industry Revenue). According 
    to data in the most recent report, there are 3,459 interstate carriers. 
    These carriers include, inter alia, local exchange carriers, wireline 
    carriers and service providers, interexchange carriers, competitive 
    access providers, operator service providers, pay telephone operators, 
    providers of telephone toll service, providers of telephone exchange 
    service, and resellers. See 13 CFR 121.201, SIC code 4813.
        52. Telephone Companies Affected. The United States Bureau of the 
    Census (Census Bureau) reports that, at the end of 1992, there were 
    3,497 firms engaged in providing telephone service, as defined therein, 
    for at least one year. United States Department of Commerce, Bureau of 
    the Census, 1992 Census of Transportation, Communications, and 
    Utilities, Establishment and Firm Size, at Firm Size 1-123 (1995) (1992 
    Census). This number contains a variety of different categories of 
    carriers, including incumbent LECs, interexchange carriers (IXCs), 
    competitive access providers, cellular carriers, mobile service 
    carriers, operator service providers, pay telephone operators, personal 
    communication service (PCS) providers, covered specialized mobile radio 
    (SMR) providers, and resellers. It seems certain that some of those 
    3,497 telephone service firms may not qualify as small entities or 
    small rate-of-return incumbent LECs because they are not independently 
    owned or operated. See generally 15 U.S.C. 632(a)(1). For example, a 
    PCS provider that is affiliated with an IXC having more than 1,500 
    employees would not meet the definition of a small business. It seems 
    reasonable to conclude that fewer than 3,497 telephone service firms 
    are small entity telephone service firms or small incumbent rate-of-
    return LECs because some of them are not independently owned or 
    operated.
        53. Wireline Carriers and Service Providers Affected. The SBA has 
    developed a definition of small entities for telephone communications 
    companies other than radiotelephone (wireless) companies. According to 
    the SBA's definition, a small business telephone company other than a 
    radiotelephone company is one employing no more than 1,500 persons. 13 
    CFR 121.201, SIC Code 4812. The Census Bureau reports that there were 
    2,321 such telephone companies in operation for at least one year at 
    the end of 1992. 1992 Census, supra, at Firm Size 1-123. All but 26 of 
    the 2,321 non-radiotelephone companies listed by the Census Bureau were 
    reported to have fewer than 1,000 employees. Thus, even if all 26 of 
    those companies had more than 1,500 employees, there would still be 
    2,295 non-radiotelephone companies that might qualify as small entities 
    or small rate-of-return LECs. We do not have data on the number of 
    carriers that are not independently owned and operated, and thus are 
    unable at this time to estimate with greater precision the number of 
    wireline carriers and service providers that would qualify as small 
    business concerns under the SBA's definition. Consequently, we estimate 
    that there are fewer than 2,295 small telephone communications 
    companies other than radiotelephone companies that may be affected by 
    the proposed rules, if adopted.
        54. Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers Affected. Neither the 
    Commission nor the SBA has developed a definition of small providers of 
    local exchange service. The closest applicable definition under SBA 
    rules is for telephone telecommunications companies other than 
    radiotelephone (wireless) companies. Standard Industrial Classification 
    (SIC) Code 4813. The most reliable source of information regarding the 
    number of incumbent LECs nationwide appears to be the report that we 
    compiled from the 1997 Telecommunications Relay Service (TRS) Fund 
    worksheets and the Universal Service Fund (USF) worksheets of 
    September, 1997. According to our most recent data, 1,376 companies 
    that provided interstate telecommunications service as of June 30, 1997 
    reported that they were engaged in the provision of local exchange 
    service. Federal Communications Commission, Common Carrier Bureau, 
    Industry Analysis Division, Carrier Locator: Interstate Service 
    Providers, Figure 1 (Nov. 1997). Although it seems certain that some of 
    these carriers are not independently owned or operated, have more than 
    1,500 employees, or are subject to price cap regulation, we are unable 
    at this time to estimate with greater precision the number of rate-of-
    return LECs that would qualify as small business
    
    [[Page 38783]]
    
    concerns under the SBA's definition. Consequently, we estimate that 
    there are fewer than 1,376 small rate-of-return LECs that may be 
    affected by the proposals in this NPRM, if adopted. We seek comment on 
    this estimate.
        55. Interexchange Carriers. Neither the Commission nor the SBA has 
    developed a definition of small entities specifically applicable to 
    providers of interexchange services. The closest applicable definition 
    under the SBA rules is for telephone communications companies other 
    than radiotelephone (wireless) companies. 13 CFR 121.201, SIC code 
    4813. According to the most recent Telecommunications Industry Revenue 
    data, 143 carriers reported that they were engaged in the provision of 
    interexchange services. Telecommunications Industry Revenue, Figure 2. 
    We do not have data specifying the number of these carriers that are 
    not independently owned and operated or have more than 1,500 employees, 
    and thus are unable at this time to estimate with greater precision the 
    number of interexchange carriers (IXCs) that would qualify as small 
    business concerns under the SBA's definition. Consequently, we estimate 
    that there are fewer than 143 small entity IXCs that may be affected by 
    the proposed rules, if adopted.
        56. Description of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping, and Other 
    Compliance Requirements. It is not clear whether, on balance, proposals 
    in this NPRM would increase or decrease incumbent rate-of-return LECs' 
    administrative burdens. With respect to rate-of-return LECs, we believe 
    that the rate structure reforms that we propose in Sections II and III 
    would require at least one, and possibly several, additional filings, 
    and may reduce some administrative burdens. For example, if we adopt 
    the streamlined petition provisions of 47 CFR 69.4(g) for introduction 
    of new services by rate-of-return LECs, we expect that this would 
    decrease some administrative burdens of rate-of-return LECs.
        57. If the rule revisions we propose are adopted, we estimate that 
    these rate-of-return LECs would make one tariff filing to bring their 
    access charges into compliance with the revised rules. We are unable to 
    estimate how extensive each tariff filing would be, on average. We 
    estimate that, on average, it would take approximately two hours per 
    page for the rate-of-return LEC to prepare each tariff filing, at a 
    cost of $35 per hour in professional level and support staff salaries. 
    If we decide to require the filing of a cost study for determining 
    local switching costs attributable to line-side ports and to trunk-side 
    ports, these rate-of-return LECs would file one cost study. We estimate 
    that, on average, it would take approximately 400 hours for the rate-
    of-return LEC to prepare a cost study, at a cost of $30 per hour in 
    professional level and support staff salaries. Compliance with these 
    tariff and cost study requirements may compel the use of engineering, 
    technical, operational, accounting, billing, and legal skills.
        58. Steps Taken to Minimize Significant Economic Impact on Small 
    Entities, and Significant Alternatives Considered. In Sections II and 
    III, for the subscriber line charge, the carrier common line charge, 
    non-traffic sensitive switching costs, the transport interconnection 
    charge, a special access PICC, and general purpose computer costs, we 
    have sought comment on how a number of proposals would affect small 
    entities. These proposals could have varying positive or negative 
    impacts on small entities, including small rate-of-return LECs and new 
    entrants. We seek comment on these proposals and urge that parties 
    support their comments with specific evidence and analysis.
        59. Federal Rules that May Duplicate, Overlap, or Conflict with the 
    Proposed Rules. None.
    
    Additional NPRM Filing Procedures
    
        60. Pursuant to applicable procedures set forth in 47 CFR 1.399 and 
    1.411 et seq., interested parties may file comments with the Secretary, 
    Federal Communications Commission, Washington D.C. 20554, no later than 
    August 17, 1998. Interested parties may file replies no later than 
    September 17, 1998. To file formally in this proceeding, participants 
    must file an original and twelve copies of all comments, reply 
    comments, and supporting comments. If participants want each 
    Commissioner to receive a personal copy of their comments, an original 
    plus 16 copies must be filed. In addition, parties must file two copies 
    of any such pleading with the Competitive Pricing Division, Common 
    Carrier Bureau, Room 518, 1919 M Street, N.W., Washington, D.C. 20554.
        61. Parties submitting diskettes should submit them along with 
    their formal filings to the Commission's Office of the Secretary. 
    Submissions should be on a 3.5 inch diskette formatted in an DOS PC 
    compatible form. The document should be saved into WordPerfect 5.1 for 
    Windows format. The diskette should be submitted in ``read only'' mode. 
    The diskette should be clearly labelled with the party's name, 
    proceeding, type of pleading (comment or reply comment), docket number, 
    and date of submission.
        62. Parties may also file informal comments electronically via e-
    mail rateofreturn@fcc.gov>. Only one copy of electronically-filed 
    comments must be submitted. The docket number of this proceeding must 
    appear in the subject line, CC Docket No. 98-77. The subject line must 
    also disclose whether an electronic submission is an exact copy of 
    formal comments. Your full name and U.S. Postal Service mailing address 
    must be included in your submission.
        63. Comments and replies must comply with 47 CFR 1.49 and all other 
    applicable sections of the Commission's Rules. We also direct all 
    interested parties to include the name of the filing party and the date 
    of the filing on each page of their comments and replies. Comments and 
    replies must also clearly identify the specific portion of the NPRM to 
    which a particular comment or set of comments is responsive. If a 
    portion of a party's comments does not fall under a particular topic 
    listed in the Table of Contents of this NPRM, such comments must be 
    included in a clearly labelled section at the beginning or end of the 
    submission.
    
    Ordering Clauses
    
        64. Accordingly, it is ordered, pursuant to sections 1-4, 201-205, 
    251, 254, 303(r) and 403 of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended, 
    47 U.S.C. 151-154, 201-205, 251, 254, 303(r) and 403, that notice is 
    hereby given of the rulemaking described above and that comment is 
    sought on these issues.
        65. It is further ordered that the Commission's Office of Public 
    Affairs, Reference Operations Division, shall send a copy of this 
    Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, including the Initial Regulatory 
    Flexibility Analysis, to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the Small 
    Business Administration.
    
    List of Subjects in 47 CFR Part 69
    
        Access charges, Communications common carriers.
    
    Federal Communications Commission.
    Magalie Roman Salas,
    Secretary.
    [FR Doc. 98-19266 Filed 7-17-98; 8:45 am]
    BILLING CODE 6712-01-U
    
    
    

Document Information

Published:
07/20/1998
Department:
Federal Communications Commission
Entry Type:
Proposed Rule
Action:
Notice of proposed rulemaking.
Document Number:
98-19266
Dates:
Comments are due on or before August 17, 1998, and reply comments are due on or before September 17, 1998. Written comments and reply comments by the public on the proposed information collections are due August 17 and September 17, 1998, respectively.
Pages:
38774-38783 (10 pages)
Docket Numbers:
CC Docket No. 98-77, FCC 98-101
PDF File:
98-19266.pdf
CFR: (1)
47 CFR 69