97-19082. Draft Report to Congress on the Costs and Benefits of Federal Regulations  

  • [Federal Register Volume 62, Number 140 (Tuesday, July 22, 1997)]
    [Notices]
    [Pages 39352-39383]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 97-19082]
    
    
    
    [[Page 39351]]
    
    _______________________________________________________________________
    
    Part IV
    
    
    
    
    
    Office of Management and Budget
    
    
    
    
    
    _______________________________________________________________________
    
    
    
    Draft Report to Congress on the Costs and Benefits of Federal 
    Regulations; Notice
    
    Federal Register / Vol. 62, No. 140 / Tuesday, July 22, 1997 / 
    Notices
    
    [[Page 39352]]
    
    
    =======================================================================
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    
    OFFICE OF MANAGEMENT AND BUDGET
    
    
    Draft Report to Congress on the Costs and Benefits of Federal 
    Regulations
    
    AGENCY: Office of Management and Budget, Executive Office of the 
    President.
    
    ACTION: Notice and request for comments.
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    SUMMARY: OMB requests comments on the attached Draft Report to Congress 
    on the Costs and Benefits of Federal Regulations. The draft report is 
    divided into four chapters. Chapter I sets the context and provides the 
    background for the next three chapters. Chapter II presents OMB's best 
    estimate of the total costs and benefits of Federal regulation. Chapter 
    III provides data on the costs and benefits of each of the economically 
    significant regulations reviewed by OMB under Executive Order 12866 in 
    the last year. Chapter IV provides recommendations aimed at further 
    developing the information, methodologies, and analyses necessary for 
    improving the efficiency, effectiveness and soundness of regulatory 
    programs and program elements.
    
    DATES: To ensure consideration of comments as OMB prepares this Draft 
    Report for submission to Congress on or before September 30, 1997, 
    comments must be in writing and received by OMB no later than September 
    1, 1997.
    
    ADDRESSES: Comments on this Draft Report should be addressed to John F. 
    Morrall III, Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs, Office of 
    Management and Budget, NEOB, Room 10235, 725 17th Street, N.W., 
    Washington, D.C. 20503.
        Comments may also be submitted by facsimile to (202) 395-6974, or 
    by electronic mail to [email protected] (please note that ``1'' in 
    ``A1'' is the number one and not the letter ``l''). Be sure to include 
    your name and complete postal mailing address in the comments sent by 
    electronic mail. If you submit comments by facsimile or electronic 
    mail, please do not also submit them by regular mail.
        Electronic availability and addresses: This Federal Register Notice 
    is available electronically from the OMB Homepage on the World Wide 
    Web: ``http://www.whitehouse.gov/WH/EOP/OMB/html/fedreg.html.''
    
    FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: John F. Morrall III, Office of 
    Information and Regulatory Affairs, Office of Management and Budget, 
    NEOB, Room 10235, 725 17th Street, N.W., Washington, D.C. 20503. 
    Telephone: (202) 395-7316.
    
    SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: Congress directed the Office of Management 
    and Budget (OMB) to prepare a Report to Congress on the Costs and 
    Benefits of Federal Regulations. Specifically, under Section 645 of the 
    Treasury, Postal Services and General Government Appropriations Act, 
    1997 (Pub. L. 104-208), the Director of OMB is to submit to Congress, 
    no later than September 30, 1997, a report that, in summary, provides 
    (1) estimates of the total annual costs and benefits of Federal 
    regulatory programs, (2) estimates of the costs and benefits of each 
    rule that is likely to have a gross annual effect on the economy of 
    $100,000,000 or more in increased costs, (3) an assessment of the 
    direct and indirect impacts of Federal rules, and (4) recommendations 
    from OMB and a description of significant public comments to reform or 
    eliminate any Federal regulatory program that is inefficient, 
    ineffective, or is not a sound use of the Nation's resources.
        The attached document is a draft of this report to Congress. OMB is 
    to provide public notice and an opportunity to comment on the report 
    before it is submitted to Congress no later than September 30, 1997.
    
    Issues for Comment
    
        Accordingly, OMB seeks comments on all aspects of the attached 
    draft report, but in particular is interested in comments and 
    suggestions pertaining to the following:
        1. The validity and reliability of the quantitative and qualitative 
    measures of the costs and benefits of regulations in the aggregate, as 
    well as of the individual regulations issued between April 1, 1996, and 
    March 31, 1997, discussed in the attached draft report;
        2. The discussion of the direct and indirect effects of regulation;
        3. Any additional studies that might provide reliable estimates or 
    assessments of the annual costs and benefits, or direct and indirect 
    effects, of regulation in the aggregate or of the individual 
    regulations that are discussed in the draft report; and
        4. Programs or program elements on which there is objective and 
    verifiable information that would lead to a conclusion that such 
    programs are inefficient or ineffective and should be eliminated or 
    reformed.
    Sally Katzen,
    Administrator, Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs.
    
    Draft Report to Congress on the Costs and Benefits of Federal 
    Regulations
    
    Introduction
    
        The Federal Government affects the lives of its citizens in a 
    variety of ways--through taxation, spending, grants, and loans, and 
    through regulation. Over time, regulation has become increasingly 
    prevalent in our society, and the importance of our regulatory 
    activities cannot now be overstated.
        Both proponents and opponents of regulation have resorted to grand 
    characterizations of either the benefits or the costs of regulation, 
    without much substantiation and very little agreement on the underlying 
    facts. In order to help further the debate on the nation's regulatory 
    system, Congress adopted Section 645 of the Treasury, Postal Services 
    and General Government Appropriations Act, 1997 (Pub. L. 104-208) on 
    September 30, 1996. Section 645(a) directs the Director of the Office 
    of Management and Budget to submit to Congress, no later than September 
    30, 1997, a report that provides--
        ``(1) estimates of the total annual costs and benefits of Federal 
    Regulatory programs, including quantitative and nonquantitative 
    measures of regulatory costs and benefits;
        ``(2) estimates of the costs and benefits (including quantitative 
    and nonquantitative measures) of each rule that is likely to have a 
    gross annual effect on the economy of $100,000,000 or more in increased 
    costs;
        ``(3) an assessment of the direct and indirect impacts of Federal 
    rules on the private sector, State and local government, and the 
    Federal Government; and
        ``(4) recommendations from the Director and a description of 
    significant public comments to reform or eliminate any Federal 
    regulatory program or program element that is inefficient, ineffective, 
    or is not a sound use of the Nation's resources.''
        The request for this report reflected a consensus that it could be 
    productive to assemble the information available, and acknowledge the 
    data gaps and the limits of the information at hand, all for the 
    purpose of improving the quality of the debate. The goals of this 
    statutory charge are worthwhile and important, but also very ambitious. 
    Having spent a considerable amount of time, we must acknowledge at the 
    outset that what we
    
    [[Page 39353]]
    
    present is neither a complete response to the mandate, nor in many 
    respects as much as we would have liked to have done had we had more 
    time and resources. But it is, we believe, a useful step in the process 
    and will enable, we hope, a more constructive dialogue on this issue.
        To be more specific, we found enormous data gaps in the information 
    available on regulatory benefits and costs. Accurate data is 
    particularly sparse on benefits, a fact that has been noted often by 
    commentators in the literature and analysts in the field. We were not 
    surprised by this finding. First, the limited quantified or monetized 
    data is partly a result of the obvious technical difficulties, many of 
    which we will discuss below (e.g., the problem of establishing 
    baselines or valuing qualities not generally traded in the 
    marketplace). Just as important, however, are the significant 
    ``cultural'' or ``philosophical'' barriers to reducing values, 
    equities, and a myriad of physical or emotional effects to dollars and 
    cents. There are few agreed upon conventions for doing this, and 
    agencies are understandably reluctant to spend scarce time and 
    resources on what may be perceived as a not very informative exercise. 
    This is compounded by the belief of some that it is morally or 
    politically difficult or wrong to engage in such seemingly uncaring 
    calculations. Some also fear a tyranny of numbers--that is, ``if it is 
    quantified, the decision will necessarily be determined solely by the 
    numbers.'' Their understandable response is not to quantify or 
    monetize.
        Nevertheless, the fact remains that explicitly quantifying and 
    monetizing benefits and costs significantly enhances the consideration 
    of alternative approaches to achieving regulatory goals, ultimately 
    producing more benefits with fewer costs. As explained more fully 
    below, President Clinton's Executive Order 12866, ``Regulatory Planning 
    and Review,'' recognizes and incorporates this principle, requiring 
    agencies to quantify both costs and benefits to the best of their 
    ability and to the extent permitted by law. This report takes up the 
    challenge of the Executive Order and Section 645 and candidly presents 
    the available information on both the total costs and benefits of 
    regulation and the costs and benefits of the recent major individual 
    regulations. We hope that this is just the beginning of an important 
    dialogue to improve our knowledge about the effects of regulation on 
    the public, the economy, and American society.
        This document is only a draft of our report. Section 645(b) 
    requires the Director of OMB to provide public notice and an 
    opportunity to comment on the report before it is submitted to Congress 
    at the end of September 1997. Accordingly we seek comments on all 
    aspects of this document, but in particular are interested in comments 
    and suggestions pertaining to the following:
         The validity and reliability of the quantitative and 
    qualitative measures of the costs and benefits of regulations in the 
    aggregate, as well as of the individual regulations discussed;
         Our discussion of the direct and indirect effects of 
    regulation;
         Any additional studies that might provide reliable 
    estimates or assessments of the annual costs and benefits, or direct 
    and indirect effects, of regulation in the aggregate or of the 
    individual regulations issued between April 1, 1996, and March 31, 
    1997, that we discuss; and;
         Programs or program elements on which there is objective 
    and verifiable information that would lead to a conclusion that such 
    programs are inefficient or ineffective and should be eliminated or 
    reformed.
        All comments received will be carefully considered in preparing the 
    final report that will be submitted to Congress.
        The draft report is divided into four chapters: chapter I sets the 
    context and provides the background for the next three chapters. It 
    discusses the development of our regulatory system and demonstrates the 
    breadth of activity that is called regulation, which ranges from 
    economic regulation such as price supports of agricultural products to 
    social regulation such as the protection of workers and the 
    environment. It tracks the use of benefit-cost analysis to evaluate 
    specific regulations, with the recognition of the limits of 
    quantification and its permitted use under the law. Chapter I concludes 
    by presenting the outline of the ``best practices'' guidance that the 
    current regulatory review program under Executive Order 12866 uses in 
    conducting economic analyses and estimating costs and benefits of 
    economically significant regulations.
        In accordance with Section 645(a)(1), chapter II presents our best 
    estimate of the total costs and benefits of Federal regulation. We use 
    a well recognized, peer reviewed study (Hahn and Hird 1991) for the 
    costs and benefits of regulations as of 1988, supplemented by an 
    Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) report to Congress (Cost of Clean 
    1990); we then add information about costs and benefits from agency 
    regulatory impact analyses (RIAs) for regulations that have been issued 
    since 1988. In almost all cases, the RIAs have gone through notice and 
    comment and been reviewed by OMB for accuracy and reliability. The 
    figures derived are approximately $200 billion in annual costs and $300 
    billion in annual benefits for environmental and social regulation and 
    about $90 billion in annual costs and nominal benefits for economic 
    regulation. While this information is useful, we cannot over emphasize 
    the limitations of these estimates for use in making recommendations 
    about reforming or eliminating regulatory programs. As discussed in 
    this chapter, aggregate estimates of the costs and benefits of 
    regulation offer little guidance on how to improve the efficiency, 
    effectiveness or soundness of the existing body of regulation. This 
    chapter also discusses the possible indirect effects of regulation on 
    the economy as directed by Section 645(a)(3) and concludes that the 
    effects are ambiguous theoretically, not well understood empirically, 
    and offer little content for making recommendations about regulatory 
    policy.
        In fulfillment of Section 645(a)(2), chapter III provides data on 
    the costs and benefits of each of the economically significant 
    regulations reviewed by OMB under Executive Order 12866 over the period 
    from April 1, 1996, to March 31, 1997. These data were developed by the 
    agencies as required by the Executive Order. For the most part, these 
    data were subject to notice and public comment and reviewed by OMB. We 
    conclude that although the agency analyses described in Chapter III 
    provide much useful information on Federal regulatory programs and 
    provisions of regulations, there should be further improvement in 
    providing high quality data and analyses before decisions about 
    modifying regulatory programs can be made.
        Chapter IV provides recommendations aimed at further developing the 
    information, methodologies, and analyses necessary for improving the 
    efficiency, effectiveness and soundness of regulatory programs and 
    program elements as required by Section 645(a)(4). We also propose 
    several ways for the agencies and OMB to work together to improve the 
    quality of the data and analysis found in the economic impact studies 
    submitted to OMB under Executive Order 12866, including ``best 
    practices'' training sessions and interagency peer reviews of selected 
    regulatory programs.
    
    [[Page 39354]]
    
    Chapter I. The Role of Economic Analysis in Regulatory Reform
    
    1. Federal Regulatory Programs
    
        The regulatory programs that exist today are the product of many 
    different forces, often operating independently of one another, but 
    with the support--over many decades--of both major political parties in 
    both the Legislative and Executive branches.
    The History of Major Regulatory Programs
        Federal regulation as we know it began in the late 19th century 
    with the creation of the Interstate Commerce Commission, which was 
    charged with protecting the public against excessive and discriminatory 
    railroad rates. The regulation was economic in nature, setting rates 
    and regulating the provision of railroad services. Having achieved some 
    success, this administrative model of an independent, bipartisan 
    commission, reaching decisions through an adjudicatory approach, was 
    used for the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) (1914), the Water Power 
    Commission (1920) (later the Federal Power Commission), and the Federal 
    Radio Commission (1927) (later the Federal Communications Commission). 
    In addition, during the early 20th century, Congress created several 
    other agencies to regulate commercial and financial systems--including 
    the Federal Reserve Board (1913), the Tariff Commission (1916), the 
    Packers and Stockyards Administration (1916), and the Commodities 
    Exchange Authority (1922)--and to ensure the purity of certain foods 
    and drugs, the Food and Drug Administration (1931).
        Federal regulation began in earnest in the 1930s with the 
    implementation of wide-ranging New Deal programs. Some of the New Deal 
    economic regulatory programs were implemented by the Federal Home Loan 
    Bank Board (1932), the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) 
    (1933), the Commodity Credit Corporation (1933), the Farm Credit 
    Administration (1933), the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) 
    (1934), and the National Labor Relations Board (1935). In addition, the 
    jurisdiction of both the Federal Communications Commission (FCC) and 
    the Interstate Commerce Commission were expanded to regulate other 
    forms of communications (e.g., telephone and telegraph) and other forms 
    of transport (e.g., trucking). In 1938, the role of the Food and Drug 
    Administration (FDA) was expanded to include prevention of harm to 
    consumers in addition to corrective action. The New Deal also called 
    for the establishment of an agency to enforce the Fair Labor Standards 
    Act of 1938 in the Department of Labor, which is now called the 
    Employment Standards Administration.
        A second burst of regulation began in the late 1960s with the 
    enactment of comprehensive, detailed legislation intended to protect 
    the consumer, improve environmental quality, enhance work place safety, 
    and assure adequate energy supplies. In contrast to the pattern of 
    economic regulation adopted before and during the New Deal, the new 
    social regulatory programs tended to cross many sectors of the economy 
    (rather than individual industries) and affect industrial processes, 
    product designs, and by-products (rather than entry, investment, and 
    pricing decisions).
        The consumer protection movement of that era led to creation in the 
    then newly formed Department of Transportation (DOT) of several 
    agencies designed to improve transportation safety. They included the 
    Federal Highway Administration (1966), which sets highway and heavy 
    truck safety standards; the Federal Railroad Administration (1966), 
    which sets rail safety standards; and the National Highway Traffic 
    Safety Administration (1970), which sets safety standards for 
    automobiles and light trucks. Regulations were also authorized pursuant 
    to the Truth in Lending Act, the Equal Credit Opportunity Act, the 
    Consumer Leasing Act, and the Fair Debt Collection Practices Act. The 
    National Credit Union Administration (1970) and the Consumer Product 
    Safety Commission (1972) were also created to protect consumer 
    interests.
        In 1970, the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) was created to 
    consolidate and expand environmental programs. Its regulatory authority 
    was expanded through the Clean Air Act (1970), the Clean Water Act 
    (1972), the Safe Drinking Water Act (1974), the Toxic Substances 
    Control Act (1976), and the Resource Conservation and Recovery Act 
    (1976). This effort to improve environmental protection also led to the 
    creation of the Materials Transportation Board (1975) (now part of the 
    Research and Special Programs Administration in the DOT) and the Office 
    of Surface Mining Reclamation and Enforcement (1977) in the Department 
    of the Interior (DOI).
        The Occupational Safety and Health Administration (1970) was 
    established in the Department of Labor (DOL) to enhance work place 
    safety. Major mine safety and health legislation had been passed in 
    1969, following prior statutes reaching back to 1910. Enforcement 
    responsibility now lies with the Mine Safety and Health Administration, 
    also in the DOL. The Pension Benefit Guaranty Corporation and the 
    Pension and Welfare Administration were established in 1974 to 
    administer and regulate pension plan insurance systems.
        Also in the 1970s, the Federal Government attempted to address the 
    problems of the dwindling supply and the rising costs of energy. In 
    1973, the Federal Energy Administration (FEA) was directed to manage 
    short-term fuel shortage. Less than a year later, the Atomic Energy 
    Commission was divided into the Energy Research and Development 
    Administration (ERDA) and an independent Nuclear Regulatory Commission 
    (NRC). In 1977, the FEA, ERDA, the Federal Power Commission, and a 
    number of other energy program responsibilities were merged into the 
    Department of Energy (DOE) and the independent Federal Energy 
    Regulatory Commission.
        Another significant regulatory agency, the Department of 
    Agriculture (USDA) (1862), has grown over time so that it now regulates 
    the price, production, import, and export of agricultural crops; the 
    safety of meat, poultry, and certain other food products; a wide 
    variety of other agricultural and farm-related activities; and broad-
    reaching welfare programs. Agriculture regulatory authorities have 
    changed over time, but now include the U.S. Forest Service (1905), the 
    Natural Resources Conservation Service (1935), the Farm Service Agency 
    (1961), the Food and Consumer Service (1969), the Agricultural 
    Marketing Service (1972), the Federal Grain Inspection Service (1976), 
    the Animal and Plant Health Inspection Service (1977), the Foreign 
    Agricultural Service (1974), the Food Safety and Inspection Service 
    (1981), and the Rural Development Administration (1990).
        In addition to the regulatory agencies listed above, most 
    Departments and agencies also issue regulations that affect the public 
    in a variety of ways such as:
         Eligibility standards and documentation requirements for 
    government benefit programs, i.e., USDA's Food and Nutrition Service, 
    Health and Human Services' (HHS) Health Care Financing Administration, 
    Housing and Urban Development's (HUD) Federal Housing Administration, 
    DOL's Employment and Training Administration, and DOI's Bureau of 
    Indian Affairs as well as Veterans Affairs, Education, the Department 
    of
    
    [[Page 39355]]
    
    Defense, and the Social Security Administration;
         Use and leasing requirements for Federal lands and 
    resources, i.e., USDA's Forest Service and DOI's Bureau of Land 
    Management and National Park Service; and
         Revenue collection requirements, i.e., Treasury's Internal 
    Revenue Service, Customs Service, and Bureau of Alcohol, Tobacco and 
    Firearms.
        The consequence of the long history of regulatory activities is 
    that Federal regulations now affect virtually all individuals, 
    businesses, State, local, and tribal governments, and other 
    organizations in virtually every aspect of their lives or operations. 
    Some rules are based on old statutes; others on relatively new ones. 
    Some regulations are critically important (such as the safety criteria 
    for airlines or nuclear power plants); some are relatively trivial 
    (such as setting the times that a draw bridge may be raised or 
    lowered). But each has the force and effect of law and each must be 
    taken seriously.
    The Nature of Regulation
        It is conventional wisdom that competition in the marketplace is 
    the most effective regulator of economic activity. Why then is there so 
    much regulation? The answer is that markets are not always perfect and 
    when they are not, society's resources may be imperfectly or 
    inefficiently used. The advantage of regulation is that it can improve 
    resource allocation or help obtain other societal benefits. For 
    example, consider the following situations:
    
    --Certain markets may not be sufficiently competitive, thus potentially 
    subjecting consumers to the harmful exercise of market power (such as 
    higher prices or artificially limited supplies). Regulation can be used 
    to protect consumers by regulating prices charged by natural monopolies 
    or preventing firms from restricting competition through mergers, 
    collusion or creating entry barriers.
    --In an unregulated market, firms and individuals may impose costs on 
    others--including future generations--that are not reflected in the 
    prices of the products they buy and sell. They may pollute streams, 
    cause health hazards, or endanger the safety of their workers or 
    customers. Regulation can be used to reduce these harmful effects by 
    prohibiting certain activities or imposing the societal costs of the 
    activity in question on those causing the harm. One goal of regulation 
    is to induce private parties to act as they would if they had to bear 
    the full costs that they impose on others.
    --Similarly, in an unregulated market, firms and individuals may not 
    have incentives to provide individuals with accurate or sufficient 
    information needed to make intelligent choices. Firms may mislead 
    consumers or take advantage of consumer ignorance to market unsafe or 
    risky products. Regulation may be needed to require disclosure of 
    information, such as the possible side effects of a drug, the contents 
    of a food or packaged good, the energy efficiency of an appliance, or 
    the full cost of a home mortgage.
    --Even when consumers have full information, the Government may wish to 
    protect individuals, especially children, from their own actions. 
    Regulation may thus be used to restrict certain unacceptable or harmful 
    practices such as substance abuse.
    --Regulation can also be beneficial in achieving goals that reflect our 
    national values, such as equal opportunity and universal education, or 
    a respect for individual privacy.
    
        There are also many potential disadvantages of regulating--to the 
    Government, to those regulated, and to society at large--that can give 
    rise to significant costs.
    
    --The direct costs of administering, enforcing, and complying with 
    regulations may be substantial. Some of these costs may be borne by the 
    Government, while others are paid for by firms and individuals, 
    eventually being reflected in the form of higher prices, lower wages, 
    and foregone investment, research, and output.
    --There are also disadvantages of regulation that are difficult to 
    measure, such as adverse effects on flexibility and innovation, which 
    may impair productivity and competitiveness in the global marketplace, 
    and counterproductive private incentives, which may distort investment 
    or reduce needed supporting activities.
    
        In short, regulations (like other instruments of government policy) 
    have enormous potential for both good and harm. Well-chosen and 
    carefully crafted regulations can protect consumers from dangerous 
    products and ensure they have information to make informed choices. 
    Such regulations can limit pollution, increase worker safety, 
    discourage unfair business practices, and contribute in many other ways 
    to a safer, healthier, more productive, and more equitable society. 
    Excessive or poorly designed regulations, by contrast, can cause 
    confusion and delay, give rise to unreasonable compliance costs in the 
    form of capital investments, labor and ongoing paperwork, retard 
    innovation, reduce productivity, and accidentally distort private 
    incentives.
        The only way we know to distinguish between the regulations that do 
    good and those that cause harm is through careful assessment and 
    evaluation of their benefits and costs. Such analysis can also often be 
    used to redesign harmful regulations so they produce more good than 
    harm and redesign good regulations so they produce even more net 
    benefits. The next section describes how regulatory analysis has 
    evolved to do just that.
    
    2. Development of the U.S. Regulatory Analysis Program
    
        As discussed above, the late 1960's and early 1970's marked a 
    period in U.S. history of major expansion of health, safety and 
    environmental regulation. Numerous new government agencies were set up 
    to protect the American workplace, the environment, highway travelers, 
    and consumers. As with almost every political development, the 
    significant growth in the amount and kinds of regulation created a 
    counter political development that ultimately produced a companion 
    program to evaluate the regulatory system.
    The Nixon and Ford Review Programs
        The Nixon Administration established in 1971 a little known review 
    group in the White House called the ``Quality of Life Review'' program. 
    The program focused solely on environmental regulations to minimize 
    burdens on business. These reviews did not utilize analysis of the 
    benefits and costs to society. The controversy that resulted from the 
    program began a debate about both Presidential review of regulations 
    and the use of benefit-cost analysis that would continue for two 
    decades and to some extent continues today.
        Soon after Gerald Ford became President in 1974, he held an 
    economic summit that included top industry leaders and economists to 
    seek solutions to the stagflation and slow growth that the nation was 
    then facing. Out of that summit came proposals to establish a new 
    government agency in the Executive Office of the President, called the 
    Council on Wage and Price Stability (CWPS), to monitor the inflationary 
    actions of both the government and private sectors of the economy. It 
    also led President Ford to issue Executive Order 11821, requiring 
    government agencies to prepare inflation impact statements before they 
    issued costly new regulations. The innovative aspect
    
    [[Page 39356]]
    
    of the Ford program was the creation of a specific White House agency 
    to review the inflationary actions, mainly regulations, of other 
    government agencies. CWPS was staffed primarily by economists drawn 
    from academia and had little authority beyond the influence of public 
    criticism.
        The economists at CWPS quickly concluded that a regulation would 
    not be truly inflationary unless its costs to society exceeded the 
    benefits it produced. Thus the economists turned the inflation impact 
    statement into a benefit-cost analysis. This requirement, that agencies 
    do an analysis of the benefits and costs of their ``major'' proposed 
    regulations--generally defined as having an annual impact on the 
    economy of over $100 million--was adopted in modified form by each of 
    the four next Presidents.
        The Administrative Procedure Act requires agencies to give the 
    public and interested parties a chance to comment on proposed 
    regulations before they are adopted in final form. The agency issuing 
    the regulation must respond to the comments and demonstrate that what 
    it is intending to do is within its scope of authority and is not 
    ``arbitrary or capricious.'' CWPS used this formal comment process to 
    file its critiques of the agencies' economic analyses of the benefits 
    and costs of proposed regulations. CWPS would also issue a press 
    release summarizing its filing in non-technical terms. The CWPS 
    analyses attracted considerable publicity. But while this system was 
    effective in preventing some unsupportable regulations from becoming 
    law, it had little success in preventing the issuance of poorly thought 
    out regulations that had strong interest group support.
        Nevertheless, one of the legacies of this approach was that it 
    slowly built an economic case against poorly conceived regulations, 
    raising interest particularly among academics and students who began to 
    use the publicly available analyses in their textbooks and courses. 
    When benefit-cost analysis was first introduced, it was not welcomed by 
    the political establishment, especially the lawyers and other non-
    economists who comprised many agencies and congressional staffs. But 
    over time, as these analyses became standard fare in textbooks, the 
    value and legitimacy of benefit-cost analysis became evident, and it 
    slowly gained acceptance among the public.
    The Carter Review Program
        After President Carter came to office in 1977, the regulating 
    agencies argued that the Executive Office of the President should not 
    have a role in reviewing their regulations. On the other hand, the 
    President's chief economic advisers argued that a centralized review 
    program based on careful economic analysis was necessary to assure that 
    regulatory burdens on the economy were properly considered and that the 
    regulations that were issued were cost effective. Rapidly escalating 
    inflation in 1978 convinced President Carter of the need to act. In 
    March of 1978, he issued Executive Order 12044, ``Improving Government 
    Regulations.'' It established general principles for agencies to follow 
    when regulating and required regulatory analysis to be done for rules 
    that ``may have major economic consequences for the general economy, 
    for individual industries, geographical regions or levels of 
    government.''
        President Carter also set up a new group, called the Regulatory 
    Analysis Review Group (RARG), with instructions to review up to ten of 
    the most important regulations each year. The RARG was chaired by the 
    Council of Economic Advisors (CEA) and was composed of representatives 
    of OMB and the economic and regulatory agencies. It relied on the staff 
    of CWPS and the CEA to develop evaluations of agency regulations and 
    the associated economic analyses and to place these analyses in the 
    public record of the agency proposing to issue the regulation. The 
    analyses were reviewed by the RARG members and reflected the views of 
    the member agencies, including the agency that proposed the regulation.
        In this way, the Carter Administration helped to institutionalize 
    both regulatory review by the Executive Office of the President and the 
    utility of benefit-cost analysis for regulatory decision makers. Also, 
    in an important legal ruling, the U.S. Court of Appeals for the 
    District of Columbia in Sierra Club v. Costle (657 F. 2d 298 (1981)) 
    found that a part of the President's administrative oversight 
    responsibilities was to review regulations issued by his subordinates.
    The Reagan/Bush Reform Effort
        During the Presidential campaign of 1980, the issue was not whether 
    to continue a regulatory review oversight program, but whether to 
    strengthen it. President Reagan had made regulatory relief one of his 
    four pillars for economic growth--in addition to reducing government 
    spending, tax cuts, and steady monetary growth. He specifically used 
    the term ``regulatory relief'' rather than ``regulatory reform'' to 
    emphasize his desire to cut back regulations, not just make them more 
    cost effective. One of his first acts as President was to issue 
    Executive Order 12291, ``Federal Regulation'' (February 17, 1981).
        The Reagan regulatory oversight program differed from the Carter 
    Program in a number of important respects. First, it required that 
    agencies not only prepare cost-benefit analyses for major rules, but 
    also that they issue only regulations that maximize net benefits 
    (social benefits minus social costs). Second, OMB, and within OMB the 
    Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs (OIRA), replaced CWPS as 
    the agency responsible for centralized review. Third, agencies were 
    required to send their proposed regulations and cost-benefit analyses 
    in draft form to OMB for review before they were issued. Fourth, it 
    required agencies to review their existing regulations to see which 
    ones could be withdrawn or scaled back. Finally, President Reagan 
    created The Task Force on Regulatory Relief, chaired by then-Vice 
    President Bush, to oversee the process and serve as an appeal mechanism 
    if the agencies disagreed with OMB's recommendations. Together these 
    steps established a more formal and comprehensive centralized 
    regulatory oversight program.
        In 1985, President Reagan issued Executive Order 12498, 
    ``Regulatory Planning Process,'' that further strengthened OMB's 
    oversight role by extending it earlier into the regulatory development 
    process. The Order required that agencies annually send OMB a detailed 
    plan on all the significant rules that they had under development. OMB 
    coordinated the plans with other interested agencies and could 
    recommend modifications. It also compiled these detailed descriptions 
    of the agencies' most important rules--usually about 500--in one large 
    volume called the Regulatory Program of the U.S. Government.
        The Bush Administration continued the regulatory review program of 
    the Reagan Presidency. Nonetheless, the pace of new health, safety, and 
    environmental regulations that had begun to increase at the end of the 
    Reagan Administration continued during the first two years of the Bush 
    Administration. In 1990, President Bush responded to expressions of 
    concern about increasing regulatory burdens by returning to the 
    approach used by the Reagan Task Force on Regulatory Relief. Vice 
    President Quayle was placed in charge of a task force--now called the 
    Competitiveness Council--whose mission was to provide regulatory 
    relief.
    
    [[Page 39357]]
    
    The Clinton Review Program
        On September 30, 1993, President Clinton issued Executive Order 
    12866, ``Regulatory Planning and Review.'' The Order reaffirmed the 
    legitimacy of centralized review but reestablished the primacy of the 
    agencies in regulatory decision making. It retained the requirement for 
    analysis of benefits and costs, quantified to the maximum extent 
    possible, and the general principle that the benefits of intended 
    regulations should justify the costs. In addition, while continuing the 
    basic framework of regulatory review established in 1981, it made 
    several changes in response to criticisms that had been voiced against 
    the Reagan/Bush programs.
        One of the changes was to focus OMB's resources on the most 
    significant rules, allowing agencies to issue less important 
    regulations without OMB review. OMB had been reviewing about 2,200 
    regulations per year with a staff of less than 40 professionals. This 
    change enabled OMB to add greater value to its review by focusing on 
    the most important rules.
        A second change was the establishment of a 90-day period for OMB 
    review of proposed rules. Executive Order 12291 contained no strict 
    limit on the length of review, and some reviews had dragged on for 
    several years before resolution. The Clinton Executive Order also set 
    up a mechanism for a timely resolution of any disputes between OMB and 
    agency heads.
        A third change was to increase the openness and accountability of 
    the review process. All documents exchanged between OIRA and the agency 
    during the review are made available to the public at the conclusion of 
    the rulemaking. The Executive Order also requires that records be kept 
    of any meetings with people outside of the Executive branch on 
    regulations under review by OMB, that agency representatives be invited 
    to attend the meetings, and that all written communications be placed 
    in the public docket and given to the agency.
        OMB has produced three reports on its implementation of this 
    Executive Order. On May 1, 1994, OMB published a six month assessment 
    of the Executive Order that the President had requested when he issued 
    the Order (Report to the President On Executive Order No. 12866, 1994). 
    The report concluded that many initial improvements in the regulatory 
    review system had been made, but that in some areas it was taking 
    longer to show results than expected. Among other things, the report 
    documented that the new Executive Order was resulting in increased 
    selectivity. The 578 rules reviewed by OMB over the six-month period 
    was about one half the rate of review under the previous Executive 
    Order. Freeing up limited staff resources to concentrate on the more 
    significant rules resulted in a higher percentage of changes to the 
    rules reviewed. Second, the new time limits for OMB review were for the 
    most part being met. Of the 578 reviews completed in the first six 
    months of the Executive Order, only three had gone beyond 90 days and 
    those delays were requested by the agencies. Third, the report 
    concluded that the new requirements for openness and accountability 
    were being met. During the six-month period, 36 meetings were held with 
    outsiders about specific rules under review. These meetings were 
    disclosed to the public and agency representatives were always invited.
        In October 1994, OIRA produced a second report entitled, The First 
    Year of Executive Order No. 12866, that basically confirmed the 
    findings of the first report. The number of significant rules that OIRA 
    was reviewing fell to a rate of about 900 per year, 60 percent lower 
    than the 2200 per year average reviewed under the previous Executive 
    Order, and the number of rules that were changed continued to increase. 
    About 15 percent of the rules were ``economically significant''--
    meaning in general that the regulation was expected to have an effect 
    on the economy of more that $100 million per year. The 90-day review 
    period was generally observed, and there were about 70 meetings during 
    the first year, to which agency representatives were invited. The 
    report concluded that the new openness and transparency policy had 
    served to defuse, if not eliminate, the criticism of OIRA's regulatory 
    impact analysis and review program.
        The third report, More Benefits Fewer Burdens: Creating a 
    Regulatory System that Works for the American People, was issued in 
    December 1996. The report provided a series of examples of how the 
    agencies and OMB had worked together to produce regulations that 
    adhered to the principles of Executive Order 12866. The examples were 
    organized around six broad themes, several of which emphasize economic 
    analysis and efficiency:
         Properly identifying problems and risks to be addressed, 
    and tailoring the regulatory approach narrowly to address them;
         Developing alternative approaches to traditional command-
    and-control regulation, such as using performance standards (telling 
    people what goals to meet, not how to meet them), relying on market 
    incentives, or issuing nonbinding guidance in lieu of rules;
         Developing rules that, according to sound analysis, are 
    cost-effective and have benefits that justify their costs.
         Consulting with those affected by the regulation, 
    especially State, local, and tribal governments;
         Ensuring that agency rules are well coordinated with rules 
    or policies of other agencies; and
         Streamlining, simplifying, and reducing burden of Federal 
    regulation.
        The report included examples of incremental improvements in the 
    regulatory systems across the government. Although few major 
    eliminations or reforms of regulatory programs were listed, the sum of 
    the improvements indicated that significant benefits were attained with 
    lower costs. A key recommendation of this report was the continued use 
    by the agencies, and vigorous promotion by OMB, of the principles of 
    the Executive Order.
        An appendix to More Benefits Fewer Burdens contained information on 
    the costs of regulations issued between 1987 and 1996, which we use 
    below to estimate the aggregate costs of regulation. Another appendix 
    included a discussion of regulatory reform legislation that President 
    Clinton had supported and was passed by Congress during the three-year 
    period, including three statutes that require agencies to follow 
    certain procedures and/or consider various economic impacts before 
    taking regulatory action: the Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995, the 
    Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995, and the Small Business Regulatory 
    Enforcement Fairness Act of 1996.
    
    3. Basic Principles for Assessing Benefits and Costs
    
        In order to help agencies prepare the economic analyses required by 
    Executive Order 12866 or the various statutes enacted by the Congress 
    in the last few years, OMB developed, through an interagency process, a 
    ``Best Practices'' manual that was issued on January 11, 1996. Best 
    Practices sets the standard for high quality economic analysis of 
    regulation--whether in the form of a prospective regulatory impact 
    analysis of a proposed regulation, or in the form of a retrospective 
    evaluation of a regulatory program. The principles that are described 
    in detail in Best Practices are summarized here because they can serve 
    as an introduction to how we have evaluated the studies on the costs 
    and benefits of regulation discussed in the following chapters. We 
    discuss those principles in Best
    
    [[Page 39358]]
    
    Practices that are general in nature, then those that pertain to 
    benefits, and then those that pertain to costs.
    General Principles
        Costs and benefits must be measured relative to a baseline. 
    Typically, this baseline is constructed to reflect policy in the 
    absence of the regulation being evaluated, consistent with pending 
    government actions, and applied equally to benefits and costs. In some 
    instances where the likelihood of government actions is uncertain, 
    analysis with multiple baselines is appropriate.
        Costs and benefits should be presented in a way to maximize their 
    consistency or comparability. Costs and benefits can be monetized, 
    quantified but not monetized, or presented in qualitative terms. A 
    monetized estimate is one that either occurs naturally in dollars 
    (e.g., increased costs by a business to purchase equipment needed to 
    comply with a regulation) or has been converted into dollars using some 
    specified methodology (e.g., the number of avoided health effects 
    multiplied by individuals' estimated willingness-to-pay to avoid them). 
    A quantitative estimate is one which is expressed in metric units other 
    than dollars (e.g., tons of pollution controlled, number of endangered 
    species protected from extinction). Finally, a qualitative estimate is 
    one which is expressed in ordinal or nominal units or is purely 
    descriptive. Presentation of monetized benefits and costs is preferred 
    where acceptable estimates are possible. However, monetization of some 
    of the effects of regulations is often difficult, if not impossible, 
    and even the quantification of some effects may not be easy. As 
    discussed below, aggregating costs and benefits is particularly 
    difficult, if not impossible, where they are not presented in 
    consistent or comparable units.
        An economic analysis cannot reach a conclusion about whether net 
    benefits are maximized--the key economic goal for good regulation--
    without consideration of a broad range of alternative regulatory 
    options. To help decision-makers understand the full effects of 
    alternative actions, the analysis should present available physical or 
    other quantitative measures of the effects of the alternative actions 
    where it is not possible to present monetized benefits and costs, and 
    also present qualitative information to characterize effects that 
    cannot be quantified. Information should include the magnitude, timing, 
    and likelihood of impacts, plus other relevant dimensions (e.g., 
    irreversibility and uniqueness). Where benefit or cost estimates are 
    heavily dependent on certain assumptions, it is essential to make those 
    assumptions explicit, and where alternative assumptions are plausible, 
    to carry out sensitivity analyses based on the alternative assumptions.
        The large uncertainties implicit in many estimates of risks to 
    public health, safety or the environment make treatment of risk and 
    uncertainty especially important. In general, the analysis should fully 
    describe the range of risk reductions, including an identification of 
    the central tendency in the distribution; risk estimates should not 
    present either the upper-bound or the lower-bound estimate alone.
        Those who bear the costs of a regulation and those who enjoy its 
    benefits often are not the same people. The term ``distributional 
    effects'' refers to the distribution of the net effects of a regulatory 
    alternative across the population and economy, divided in various ways 
    (e.g., income groups, race, sex, industrial sector). Where distributive 
    effects are thought to be important, the effects of various regulatory 
    alternatives should be described quantitatively to the extent possible, 
    including their magnitude, likelihood, and incidence of effects on 
    particular groups. There are no generally accepted principles for 
    determining when one distribution of net benefits is more equitable 
    than another. Thus, the analysis should be careful to describe 
    distributional effects without judging their fairness.
    Benefits
        The analysis should state the beneficial effects of the proposed 
    regulatory change and its principal alternatives. In each case, there 
    should be an explanation of the mechanism by which the proposed action 
    is expected to yield the anticipated benefits. As noted above, an 
    attempt should be made to quantify all potential real benefits to 
    society in monetary terms to the maximum extent possible, by type and 
    time period. Any benefits that cannot be monetized, such as an increase 
    in the rate of introducing more productive new technology or a decrease 
    in the risk of extinction of endangered species, should also be 
    presented and explained.
        The concept of ``opportunity cost'' is the appropriate construct 
    for valuing both benefits and costs. The principle of ``willingness-to-
    pay'' captures the notion of opportunity cost by providing an aggregate 
    measure of what individuals are willing to forgo to enjoy a particular 
    benefit. Market transactions provide the richest data base for 
    estimating benefits based on willingness-to-pay, as long as the goods 
    and services affected by a potential regulation are traded in markets.
        Where market transactions are difficult to monitor or markets do 
    not exist, analysts should use appropriate proxies that simulate 
    willingness-to-pay based on market exchange. A variety of methods have 
    been developed for estimating indirectly traded benefits. Generally, 
    these methods apply statistical techniques to distill from observable 
    market transactions the portion of willingness-to-pay that can be 
    attributed to the benefit in question. Contingent-valuation methods 
    have become increasingly common for estimating indirectly traded 
    benefits, but the reliance of these methods on hypothetical scenarios 
    and the complexities of the goods being valued by this technique raise 
    issues about its accuracy in estimating willingness to pay compared to 
    methods based on (indirect) revealed preferences.
        Health and safety benefits are a major category of benefits that 
    are indirectly traded in the market. The willingness-to-pay approach is 
    conceptually superior, but measurement difficulties may cause agencies 
    to prefer valuations of reductions in risks of nonfatal illness or 
    injury based on the expected direct costs avoided by such risk 
    reductions. The primary components of the direct-cost approach are 
    medical and other costs of offsetting illness or injury; costs for 
    averting illness or injury (e.g., expenses for goods such as bottled 
    water or job safety equipment that would not be incurred in the absence 
    of the health or safety risk); and the value of lost production.
        Values of fatality risk reduction often figure prominently in 
    assessments of government action. Reductions in fatality risks as a 
    result of government action are best monetized according to the 
    willingness-to-pay approach for small reductions in mortality risk, 
    usually presented in terms of the value of a ``statistical life'' or of 
    ``statistical life-years'' extended.
        It is important to keep in mind the larger objective of 
    consistency--subject to statutory limitations--in the estimates of 
    benefits applied across regulations and agencies for comparable risks. 
    Failure to maintain such consistency prevents achievement of the most 
    risk reduction from a given level of resources spent on risk reduction.
    Costs
        The preferred measure of cost is the ``opportunity cost'' of the 
    resources used or the benefits forgone as a result of the regulatory 
    action. Opportunity costs include, but are not limited to, private-
    
    [[Page 39359]]
    
    sector compliance costs and government administrative costs. 
    Opportunity costs also include losses in consumers' or producers' 
    surpluses, discomfort or inconvenience, and loss of time. The 
    opportunity cost of an alternative also incorporates the value of the 
    benefits forgone as a consequence of that alternative. For example, the 
    opportunity cost of banning a product (e.g., a drug, food additive, or 
    hazardous chemical) is the forgone net benefit of that product, taking 
    into account the mitigating effects of potential substitutes. All costs 
    calculated should be incremental--that is, they should represent 
    changes in costs that would occur if the regulatory option is chosen 
    compared to costs in the base case (ordinarily no regulation or the 
    existing regulation) or under a less stringent alternative. As with 
    benefit estimates, the calculation of costs should reflect the full 
    probability distribution of potential consequences.
        An important, but sometimes difficult, problem in cost estimation 
    is to distinguish between real costs and transfer payments. As 
    discussed below, transfer payments are not social costs but rather are 
    payments that reflect a redistribution of wealth. While transfers 
    should not be included in the estimates of the benefits and costs of a 
    regulation, they may be important for describing the distributional 
    effects of a regulation.
    
    Chapter II. Estimates of the Total Annual Costs and Benefits of Federal 
    Regulatory Programs
    
    1. Overview
    
        This chapter discusses the total annual costs and benefits of 
    existing Federal regulatory programs called for by Section 645(a)(1). 
    Before doing so, however, it is important to place the subject in 
    perspective. First, we need to keep in mind the discussion in chapter I 
    on best practices for estimating costs and benefits. Second, it is 
    important to ask: What public policy purposes do aggregate estimates 
    serve? And, in particular: In what ways can these estimates help 
    support the recommendations to reform the regulatory system required of 
    the Director by Section 645(a)(4)? Clearly, knowing the costs and 
    benefits of proposed regulatory actions and their alternatives, 
    including the alternative of no action, enables policy officials to 
    make decisions that improve society's well being. But for reasons 
    discussed below, knowing the total costs and total benefits of all of 
    the many and diverse regulations that the Federal government has issued 
    provides little specific guidance for regulatory decisions.
        For example, four possible outcomes can result from totaling up the 
    costs and benefits of all existing Federal regulations:
        (1) High costs and high benefits.
        (2) High costs and low benefits.
        (3) Low costs and high benefits.
        (4) Low costs and low benefits.
        Given the intensity of the debate over regulatory reform, 
    categories (3) and (4) are not likely outcomes of careful and fair 
    accounting. A priori, it is not clear which of the remaining two 
    categories is most likely. But does it matter? In each case, the policy 
    guidance would be the same. Real economic improvement comes from 
    expanding those significant regulatory programs that provide benefits 
    that are greater than costs and contracting those programs that provide 
    benefits that are less than costs. The substance is in the details, not 
    in the total.
        The implication of this discussion is that an excessive amount of 
    resources should not be devoted to estimating the total costs and 
    benefits of all Federal regulations. To the extent that the costs and 
    benefits of specific regulatory programs can easily be combined, some 
    indication of the importance of regulatory reform can be inferred by 
    the magnitude of these estimates, but knowing the exact amounts of 
    total costs and benefits, even if that were possible, adds little of 
    value.
        This proposition is important because it is extremely difficult, if 
    not impossible, to estimate the actual total costs and benefits of all 
    existing Federal regulations with any degree of precision. There are at 
    least two types of intractable problems that make this so.
    The Baseline Problem
        In order to estimate the impact of regulations on society and the 
    economy, one has to determine the counterfactual--that is, how things 
    would have been if the regulation had not been issued. In other words, 
    what is the baseline against which costs and benefits should be 
    measured? With respect to estimating total costs and benefits of all 
    Federal regulations, the baseline problem has several dimensions.
        First, it is impossible to determine the true counterfactual, since 
    it never happened. What would have happened in the absence of 
    regulation can only be an educated guess. Furthermore, the greater the 
    hypothesized difference between reality and the counterfactual, the 
    more problematic the exercise. For example, some estimates of the total 
    cost of regulation include the cost of compliance with our tax system. 
    But to twist a phrase, one can no more easily imagine a world without 
    taxes than one can imagine a world without death. It is also difficult 
    to imagine a world without health, safety, and environmental 
    regulation. Could a civil society even exist without regulation? In 
    other words, what do we use as the baseline for a world without any 
    regulation?
        Second, even disregarding the problem of modeling large changes, 
    there are significant difficulties in determining the counterfactual 
    for individual regulations that one could begin to aggregate. One can 
    survey firms and other regulated entities on their expected compliance 
    costs either ex ante, before the regulation is implemented, or ex post, 
    after the regulation has gone into effect. For both types of studies, 
    the problem of potential bias must be kept in mind. It is often alleged 
    that strategic behavior may color both regulators' and the regulated's 
    estimates of the cost of regulation (Hahn and Hird 1991, Hopkins 1991, 
    and Hahn 1996). Agencies are generally advocates of their programs and 
    businesses generally are not in favor of regulation. In the ordinary 
    course, therefore, the best studies are ex post studies done by 
    individuals who do not have vested interests, but do have reputations 
    as objective analysts to uphold.
        Often only ex ante cost estimates are available, but even if firms' 
    or agencies' estimates are unbiased at the time, technological change 
    or ``learning-by-doing'' may result in those estimates overstating 
    compliance costs (Hahn and Hird 1991 and Hahn 1996). In fact, there is 
    much evidence that competition among regulated firms often reduces 
    expected compliance costs once real time and effort is directed at the 
    problem (Office of Technology Assessment 1995).
        While ex post studies are likely to be more accurate than ex ante 
    studies because firms should by then have had experience with actual 
    regulatory compliance costs, ex post cost estimates have their own 
    problems. Properly done they are likely to be resource and time 
    intensive. Firms do not usually keep their cost accounting estimates 
    according to what regulations are driving them. Thus, when surveyed, 
    firms have to reconstruct causality. A recent General Accounting Office 
    (GAO) report details the difficulties the GAO had in trying to 
    determine the total cost of Federal regulation by surveying a sample of 
    firms. The firms reported great difficulty in estimating their own 
    costs of compliance because they could not easily separate Federal from 
    State and local regulation and because they
    
    [[Page 39360]]
    
    did not keep records on incremental costs of regulation (See GAO 1996, 
    pp. 49-51). Some studies have attempted to address this problem 
    reasonably successfully by comparing the results of different degrees 
    of regulation in different localities or time periods.
        Moreover, virtually all of the studies of the costs of regulation 
    produced to date are measuring the expenditures of firms required (ex 
    ante or ex post) by regulation, whereas the cost to society of 
    regulation should be measured by the change in consumer and producer 
    surplus associated with the regulation and with any price and/or income 
    changes that may result (Cropper and Oates 1992). At one extreme, 
    ignoring the consumer surplus loss produced by a ban understates costs 
    to society because although no compliance expenditures are required, 
    consumers can no longer buy the product. At the other extreme, 
    calculating compliance expenditures based on pre-regulation output 
    overstates costs because if the firm raises prices to cover compliance 
    costs, consumers will shift to other products, which reduces their 
    welfare losses (Cropper and Oats 1992, p. 722).
        A third problem relates to the economy and the appropriateness of 
    the baseline for the purpose for which it is expected to be used. If 
    the objective is to reduce the burden of existing regulation, even ex 
    post evaluation surveys may be inadequate for they would reflect the 
    cost of gearing up to comply, not the cost saving of no longer having 
    to comply with a given regulatory program. While the former is relevant 
    for deciding whether to regulate, the latter would be the relevant 
    concept if one is considering reducing regulation. There is also the 
    dynamic nature of the economy, whereby technological advances over time 
    are likely to reduce the start-up cost of compliance the firm 
    originally faced. In addition, sunk costs, such as specialized capital 
    costs and the cost of changing procedures already in place, make the 
    cost savings from eliminating regulation less than the cost of 
    complying with those regulations. Very few studies exist, especially 
    for health, safety and environmental regulation, that attempt to 
    determine the cost savings that would result from reducing or 
    eliminating existing regulation.
        It is important to note that this dynamic nature of the economy may 
    affect the estimation of benefits as well as costs. Technological 
    improvements could reduce predicted benefits. For example, medical 
    progress can reduce the future benefits estimated for health, safety 
    and environmental regulations, just as productivity improvements in 
    manufacturing reduces the costs of compliance of some regulations. New 
    drugs or medical procedures can reduce the benefits of regulations 
    aimed at reducing exposure to certain harmful agents such as an 
    infectious disease or even sunlight. Regulations aimed at increasing 
    the energy efficiency of consumer products or buildings may see their 
    expected benefits reduced by new technology that reduces the cost of 
    producing energy. Furthermore, productivity improvements lead directly 
    to higher incomes, which lead people to demand better health and more 
    safety. Business responds to these demands by providing safer products 
    and workplaces, even in the absence of regulation. Individuals with 
    rising incomes may also purchase or donate land to nature conservancies 
    to provide ecological benefits. Yet as on the cost side, the baseline 
    that is used is almost always the status quo, not what is likely to be 
    true in the future.
        Fourth, the construction of a baseline may be complicated where, as 
    frequently occurs, there are several causes of the change in behavior 
    attributed to a Federal regulation. State and local regulations may 
    also require some level of compliance. The tort system, voluntary 
    standards organizations, and public pressure also cause firms to 
    provide a certain degree of public protection in the absence of Federal 
    regulation. As GAO points out, determining how much of the costs and 
    benefits of these activities to attribute solely to Federal regulation 
    is a difficult undertaking (GAO 1996). Adding to the complexity, the 
    degree to which these other factors cause firms and other regulated 
    entities to provide safe and healthful products and workplaces and 
    engage in environmentally sound practices changes over time, generally 
    increasing with increasing per capita incomes and knowledge about cause 
    and effect.
        Thus, although the National Highway Traffic Safety Administration 
    has significantly increased the safety of automobiles, it is not likely 
    that if the agency's regulations were eliminated the automobile 
    companies would discontinue the safety features that had been mandated. 
    Consumers demand safer cars than they used to and automobile companies 
    are concerned about product liability. This same phenomenon exists with 
    the environment, although probably to a lesser extent. Environmentally 
    responsible behavior has become good for the bottom line. One paper 
    company interviewed by GAO said that it would have incurred a 
    substantial amount of its compliance costs even if there were no 
    regulations, simply as good business practices (GAO 1996, p. 51). Over 
    time, this ``rising baseline'' phenomenon reduces the true costs of 
    health, safety, and environmental regulations. Estimates of the 
    aggregate costs of regulations that include the unadjusted cost 
    estimates from aging studies are thus likely to be overestimates of the 
    real costs of those regulations.
    The Apples and Oranges Problem
        The studies that have attempted to tote up the total costs and 
    benefits of Federal regulations have basically added together a diverse 
    set of individual studies. Unfortunately, these individual studies vary 
    in quality, methodology, and type of regulatory costs included. Thus we 
    have an apples and oranges problem, or, more aptly, an apples, oranges, 
    kiwis, grapefruit, etc., problem.
        Part of the problem arises because of the nature of regulation 
    itself. There are over 130,000 pages of regulations in the Code of 
    Federal Regulations, with about 60 Federal agencies issuing regulations 
    at the rate of over 1,800 per year. For our purposes, a ``regulation'' 
    or ``rule'' means an agency statement of general applicability and 
    future effect, which the agency intends to have the force and effect of 
    law, that is designed to implement, interpret, or prescribe law or 
    policy or to describe the procedure or practice of an agency. Clearly, 
    ``regulation'' encompasses a lot of territory. The Hopkins series of 
    studies (1991, 1992, 1995, 1996), which are the latest attempts to 
    aggregate the costs of all regulations for which estimates are 
    available and which we discuss in detail later, include five major 
    categories of regulation:
        Environmental. As the EPA points out, the true social cost of 
    regulations aimed at improving the quality of the environment are 
    represented by the total value that society places on the goods and 
    services foregone as a result of resources being diverted to 
    environmental protection. (Cost of a Clean Environment, pp. 1-2 to 1-
    3.) These costs include the direct compliance costs of the capital 
    equipment and labor needed to meet the standard, as well as the more 
    indirect consumer and producer surplus losses that result from lost or 
    delayed consumption and production opportunities resulting from the 
    higher prices and reduced output needed to pay for the direct 
    compliance costs. In the case of a product ban or prohibitive 
    compliance costs, almost all of the costs represent consumer and 
    producer surplus losses. Most of the cost estimates used in this report 
    do not
    
    [[Page 39361]]
    
    include consumer and producer surplus losses because it is difficult to 
    estimate the demand and supply curves needed to do this type of 
    analysis.
        Further indirect effects on productivity and efficiency result from 
    these price and output changes as they filter through other sectors of 
    the economy. According to EPA in the Cost of Clean report, recent 
    research indicates that compliance cost estimates may understate 
    substantially the true long-term costs of pollution control (p. 1-3). 
    The estimates used in this report do not include these indirect and 
    general equilibrium effects.
        The benefits of environmental protection are represented by the 
    value that society places on improved health, recreational 
    opportunities, quality of life, visibility, preservation of ecosystems, 
    biodiversity, and other attributes of protecting or enhancing our 
    environment. As discussed in chapter 1, the value is best measured by 
    society's willingness to pay for these attributes. Because most types 
    of improvements in environmental quality are not traded in markets, 
    benefits must be estimated by indirect means using sophisticated 
    statistical techniques that generally make benefit estimation more 
    problematic than cost estimation.
        Although the EPA issues the great majority of environmental 
    regulations, DOI, DOT, and the DOE, among others, also issue rules 
    aimed at improving the environment.
        Other Social. This category of regulation includes rules designed 
    to advance the health and safety of consumers and workers, as well as 
    regulations aimed at promoting social goals such as equal opportunity 
    and equal access to facilities. They are often lumped together with 
    environmental regulation in the category of ``Social Regulation.'' 
    Social regulation is mainly concerned with controlling the harmful or 
    unintended consequences of market transactions, such as air pollution, 
    occupationally induced illness, or automobile accidents. These 
    consequences are commonly called ``negative externalities'' and 
    regulation designed to deal with them attempts to ``internalize'' the 
    externalities. This can be done by regulating the amount of the 
    externality, e.g., banning a pollutant or limiting it to a ``safe'' 
    level, or by regulating how a product is produced or used. The 
    techniques and methodological concerns involved in the estimation of 
    the social costs and benefits generated by these rules are similar to 
    those involved in the estimation of costs and benefits of environmental 
    regulation discussed above.
        Economic. Economic regulation is so-called because it directly 
    restricts firms' primary economic activities, e.g., its pricing and 
    output decisions. It may also limit the entry or exit of firms into or 
    out of certain specific types of businesses. The regulations are 
    usually applied on an industry basis such as banking, trucking, or 
    securities. In the United States, much of this type of regulation at 
    the Federal level is administered by what are referred to as 
    ``independent'' commissions, e.g., the FCC or the SEC, whose members 
    are appointed but not removable without good cause by the President. 
    The economic loss caused by this type of regulation results from the 
    higher prices and inefficient operations that often result when 
    competition is prevented from developing.
        The costs of such regulation are usually measured by modeling or 
    comparing specific regulated sectors with less regulated sectors, 
    estimating the consumer and producer surplus losses that result from 
    higher prices and lack of service, and estimating the excess costs that 
    may result from the lack of competition. In contrast to social 
    regulatory cost estimates, these estimates are mainly indirect costs.
        Economic regulation, including antitrust, may produce social 
    benefits when natural monopolies are regulated to simulate competition 
    or when firms are prevented from anticompetitive collusion and mergers. 
    In a dynamic economy, however, the dollar amount of such economic 
    efficiency benefits are thought to be small (Hahn and Hird 1991). Much 
    of the motivation for economic regulation is based on equity and 
    fairness considerations, but often it is based on enhancing one group 
    at the expense of another. These considerations are not social costs or 
    benefits, but do need to be factored into regulatory decisions.
        Transfer. As discussed in chapter 1, transfers are payments from 
    one group in society to another and therefore are not real costs to 
    society as a whole. One person's loss is another person's gain. 
    Examples of transfers include payments to Social Security recipients 
    from taxpayers and the higher profits that farmers receive as a result 
    of the higher prices consumers must pay for farm products limited by 
    production quotas. Nevertheless, Hopkins (1991) includes transfer costs 
    in the total cost of regulations. He does place them in a separate 
    category and points out that they are different from the real social 
    costs that result from economic efficiency losses. As discussed in 
    Chapter 1, OMB's guidance states that transfers should not be added to 
    the cost and benefit totals included in regulatory assessments but 
    should be discussed and noted for policymakers.
        Process. Process costs, according to Hopkins, are the 
    administrative or paperwork costs of filling out government forms such 
    as income tax, immigration, social security, etc. Although there are 
    benefits to the services that these government programs provide and 
    some minimum amount of process cost is necessary to deliver these 
    services, it makes little sense to try to place a separate value on 
    administration. Rather, process costs should be viewed as a ``cost of 
    doing business'' that should be minimized for a given level or quality 
    of service.
        Adding these various categories together, as Hopkins and others 
    have done, does two things. It produces large numbers and it creates 
    confusion. It produces large numbers by including ``costs'' that are 
    not normally considered as part of the regulatory reform debate. For 
    example, costs such as the burden of filling out income tax forms or 
    doing the paperwork needed to get visas, passports, small business 
    loans, and veterans benefits are not what one usually thinks about when 
    worrying about the cost of regulation. Nor do we usually think that the 
    income gained by farmers from price support programs or the increased 
    sales by domestic businesses as a result of trade protection are costs 
    of regulation. Congress did not seek oversight of these types of costs 
    when, in the last Congress, it debated legislative proposals for 
    comprehensive regulatory reform, such as S. 343 and H.R. 9, or when it 
    passed the Unfunded Mandate Reform Act of 1995 or the Small Business 
    Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act of 1996.
        Adding these categories of regulation together with health, safety 
    and environmental regulation also creates confusion because the 
    appropriate policies to reduce any adverse effects from these programs 
    are very different. To reduce price supports, modify international 
    trade protectionism, and minimize non-cost-effective health, safety, 
    and environmental regulation would take very different paths. Lumping 
    them together does not enlighten the search for appropriate reforms.
        In sum, adding up the costs and benefits of the various regulatory 
    programs may give us a rough estimate of the magnitude of the impact of 
    regulatory activities on the economy and make it clear that regulation 
    plays an important role in our economy. Indeed, we can use the total 
    cost figures to begin to track the extent of this activity relative to 
    other aggregate data.
    
    [[Page 39362]]
    
    For example, our calculations indicate that regulatory costs are about 
    4% (3.8%) of GDP in 1997. We have also looked at 1988, and found that 
    regulatory costs were then roughly the same percentage. From this 
    comparison, we can say that there has been no material growth in the 
    cost of regulation relative to the size of the economy in the last 
    decade.
        However, these data provide little useful information about what to 
    do next. If what is intended is to make regulation more efficient, one 
    needs to estimate the incremental costs and benefits of individual 
    regulations, or specific provisions of individual regulations, on a 
    case-by-case basis. If what is intended is to reduce the burden of 
    existing, health, safety and environmental regulation, one needs to 
    estimate how firms would react to the removal of requirements, not how 
    they acted when the requirements were originally imposed. If what is 
    intended is to improve the cost-effectiveness of new regulations, one 
    needs to know what factors are preventing future regulations from being 
    more cost-effective. But none of this information is found in the 
    aggregate estimates of the costs and benefits of regulation done to 
    date.
    
    2. Our Estimates of the Costs and Benefits of Existing Regulations
    
        To meet the requirements of Section 645(a)(1), we surveyed the 
    existing literature on the total costs and benefits of regulation, 
    supplementing it with information we have obtained from reviewing 
    regulatory impact analyses over the last ten years under Executive 
    Orders 12291 and 12866. Our review of the literature revealed only one 
    comprehensive study that attempted to estimate the total costs and 
    benefits of all Federal regulations (Hahn and Hird 1991). Hahn and 
    Hird's estimates were peer reviewed and published in one of the top 
    economics/legal journals specializing in regulatory issues, the Yale 
    Journal on Regulation. In addition, EPA issued a report to Congress at 
    about the same time known as the Cost of Clean report (EPA 1990). The 
    Cost of Clean report is recognized as the most thorough and careful 
    attempt to estimate the compliance cost of environmental regulation 
    published to date.
        The Hahn and Hird study compiled cost and benefit estimates from 
    over 25 studies published mostly by academics in peer reviewed 
    journals, e.g., Hufbauer (1986) for international trade, Wenders (1987) 
    for telecommunications, Gardner (1987) for agricultural price supports, 
    Morrison and Winston (1986 and 1989) for airlines, Crandall (1986) for 
    highway safety, and Crandall (1988), Denison, (1979), and Viscusi 
    (1983) for Occupational Safety and Health. It should be noted that 
    although all of these studies are generally recognized as the best 
    available, they are not without shortcomings. For example, the Crandall 
    (1988) and Denison (1979) studies relied upon for the cost of OSHA 
    regulations used survey data that included expenditures that firms 
    would have made on safety in the absence of OSHA regulation.
        The Cost of Clean report's estimates of costs are based on annual 
    survey data from the Department of Commerce's ``Pollution Abatement and 
    Control Expenditures'' (PACE) reports, regulatory impact analyses of 
    major EPA regulations, and special analyses by EPA program offices or 
    contractors. The PACE report surveys, which were conducted through 
    1994, but discontinued thereafter, cannot be used without careful 
    adjustments because they contain pollution control expenditures that 
    are not Federally mandated. EPA is continuing efforts to review the 
    costs and benefits of certain of its regulatory programs. It has 
    completed reports on drinking water (EPA 1993) and surface water (EPA 
    1995) and is presently working on a report required by the Clean Air 
    Act Amendments of 1990 on the costs and benefits of the Clean Air Act, 
    which it plans to submit to Congress in October of 1997. A draft of 
    this report indicates that some of the numbers we report below may be 
    understated (EPA 1997).
        In addition, we used information about the costs of major 
    regulations reviewed by OMB under Executive Order 12291 and 12866, 
    which were recently published by OMB in More Benefits Fewer Burdens 
    (1996). (We include the cost of rules published in 1987 and 1988 to 
    allow for a lag between publication of the rule and the expenditure of 
    funds for compliance.) The rules included are generally all final rules 
    with annual costs of $100 million or more issued by Executive Branch 
    agencies, which we believe capture at least 90 percent of the costs 
    added by all rules. The cost estimates themselves are agency estimates 
    that have gone through OMB review and the Administrative Procedure Act 
    requirements for notice and comment by the public.
    Total Costs
        Using the estimates for Federally mandated regulatory costs from 
    the Cost of Clean report (1990, Table 8-9D) for environmental 
    regulation and Hahn and Hird's estimates for other social regulation 
    for a 1988 base, we added the cost of all major regulations reviewed by 
    OMB under Executive Orders 12291 and 12866 and issued by the agencies 
    between 1987 and 1996. The following table shows our calculations for 
    the costs of social regulations:
    
                          Table 1.--Estimates of the Annual Cost of Social Regulation for 1997                      
                                               [Billions of 1996 dollars]                                           
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                                                       Environmental   Other social    Total social 
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
    1988 Baseline:                                                                                                  
        (EPA, Hahn and Hird)........................................             101              35             136
        Cost of rules 1987-96 (OMB).................................              43              19              62
                                                                     -----------------------------------------------
          Total for 1997............................................             144              54             198
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        While our estimates do not include the costs of regulations with 
    costs below $100 million and there is a possibility that agencies 
    understate the costs of proposed rules (Hopkins, 1992, p. 13), we 
    believe that, if anything, the estimates overstate actual direct costs 
    because of the rising baseline phenomenon discussed above. For example, 
    as a sensitivity analysis, it does not seem implausible that, for 
    environmental and other social regulations over ten years old, no more 
    than half of compliance costs would likely be saved if these Federal 
    regulations magically disappeared over night. The automobile companies 
    are not likely to make their cars less safe or less fuel efficient. 
    Similarly, the great majority of firms are not likely to stop 
    controlling asbestos and cotton dust
    
    [[Page 39363]]
    
    fibers or lead dust and benzene emissions in the workplace if these 
    regulations were abolished. Nor would the judicial tort system likely 
    tolerate increased levels of harmful pollution or harmful products. If 
    this scenario is correct, then the cost of social regulation in 1997 
    would fall to $130 billion (136/2+62=130), or $93 billion for 
    environmental regulations and $37 billion for other social regulation.
        To the cost estimates for environmental and other social 
    regulation, we must add the costs of the other types of regulation, 
    i.e., economic and process regulation. We use the Hahn and Hird 
    estimate for the efficiency cost of economic regulation for 1988. 
    Because the great majority of these regulations are issued by 
    independent regulatory agencies (e.g., the FCC, the FTC, the SEC, the 
    FDIC and the NRC that were not required under Executive Orders 12291 or 
    12866 to submit information on benefits and costs of regulations to 
    OMB, we did not have our own data to update the 1988 baseline. Instead, 
    we relied on a study by Hopkins (1992) who derived an estimate of $81 
    billion for the efficiency costs of economic regulation for 1997.
        Hopkins made several additions to Hahn and Hird to update economic 
    regulation costs to 1997: $10 billion for surface transportation costs, 
    $5 billion for the Jones Act, and $5 billion for banking regulations 
    (p. 27). We have no basis to question these estimates and therefore 
    have included them. On the other hand, we do not include Hopkins' 
    estimate of the transfer costs of economic regulation, because, as 
    noted above, we do not believe that transfers are costs that should be 
    included in total cost of regulation estimates. In addition, we do not 
    include the process or paperwork cost estimated by Hopkins and others 
    (Hopkins 1991 and 1992 and Weidenbaum and DeFina 1978) because these 
    costs are for the most part already included in cost estimates supplied 
    by the agencies and reviewed by OMB. However, there are costs of 
    paperwork imposed by the independent agencies that should be added. 
    According to OMB's latest Information Collection Budget, the burden 
    hours of paperwork imposed by the independent agencies was about 390 
    million hours (or about $10 billion in costs using a $26.50 per hour 
    estimate to take into account the fact that these agencies' paperwork 
    often require some professional expertise to fill them out). Since 
    these costs are mostly for economic regulation (the NRC paperwork is 
    only two percent of the total), we add the $10 billion to the $81 
    billion estimate for the cost of economic regulation.
        Our best estimate of the total cost of regulation for 1997 is thus 
    the following:
    
       Table 2.--Estimate of the Annual Total Cost of Regulation for 1997   
                           [Billions of 1996 dollars]                       
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                                                            
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    Environmental..............................................          144
    Other Social...............................................           54
    Economic...................................................           91
                                                                ------------
        Total..................................................          289
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Total Benefits
        Aggregating benefits from individual regulations poses special 
    problems even beyond those discussed above for aggregating costs. There 
    are several important limits to such an exercise. First among these is 
    uncertainty. Because so much of the uncertainty in possible benefit 
    estimation is unknown, and so little is known about the relationships 
    among benefit estimates of different regulations, analysts have 
    virtually no basis for aggregating benefits in a manner that might 
    preserve information about the likely distribution of aggregate 
    benefits.
        Second, as noted above, benefits, like costs, may be presented as 
    monetized, quantified, or in narrative forms. For a variety of reasons, 
    many of them understandable, if not legitimate, agencies often do not 
    express beneficial effects in monetizable terms that can easily be 
    aggregated. What is being described may not be readily amenable to 
    quantification or monetization (e.g., the value of greater national 
    security or of increased individual privacy), or the agency may have 
    chosen not to develop monetized estimates because of resource or time 
    constraints. Moreover, while some of the effects are present as 
    quantified estimates, these cannot be summed if they are not expressed 
    in common units. Of course, when effects are not expressed in 
    quantitative terms, this aggregation problem is even more acute. We can 
    only conclude that estimates of the total benefits of regulation will 
    be understated by an unknown amount until all significant benefits are 
    monetized.
        Because of the difficulty of estimating benefits, there are very 
    few studies that attempt to estimate the total benefits as well as 
    costs of regulation. Indeed the only study that has attempted to 
    estimate the total benefits of all regulations is the study by Hahn and 
    Hird that we relied upon for the 1988 cost baseline. Hahn and Hird 
    present the following broad range of estimates of the annual benefits 
    of regulation in billions as of 1988, which we have converted to 1996 
    dollars using the CPI:
    
                Table 3.--Hahn and Hird's 1988 Benefit Estimates            
                           [Billions of 1996 dollars]                       
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                                       Low          High    
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    Environmental...............................          21.8         179.3
    Other Social................................          33.5          60.3
    Economic....................................           0             0  
                                                 ---------------------------
        Total...................................          55.3         239.6
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Note that while Hahn and Hird do not include any benefits from economic 
    regulation (on the grounds that they are negligible in most cases), 
    they state that the regulation of natural monopolies and antitrust can 
    theoretically produce efficiency gains (p. 253). When Hahn and Hird 
    take the midpoints of their benefit and cost estimates, they find net 
    benefits of regulation of about $2 billion, which leads them to 
    conclude that ``* * * net benefits of social regulation are positive 
    but small.'' (p. 253, f. 74).
        Since the Hahn and Hird study, the only systematic study of the 
    benefits together with the costs of major social regulations, of which 
    we are aware, is a study by Hahn, published jointly by Oxford 
    University Press and the AEI Press in 1996. In that study, Hahn 
    reviewed the regulatory impact statements required by Executive Orders 
    12291 and 12866 for major regulations produced by agencies between 1990 
    and mid-1995. Hahn accepted the agency estimates of benefits at face 
    value, used consensus estimates from the academic literature to value 
    the benefits (e.g., the Viscusi 1992, estimate for a ``statistical 
    life'') and used consistent assumptions across agencies to produce 
    monetized benefit estimates (pp. 214-217). He found that 54 regulations 
    had produced almost $500 billion in benefits in present value 
    (discounting at 5 percent and using his middle value consensus 
    estimates) (p. 218). Hahn also calculated that these regulations 
    produced $220 billion in net costs (gross costs minus any costs savings 
    produced by regulation).
        Unfortunately, we do not have enough information to convert Hahn's 
    present value estimates to annual estimates so that we could compare 
    them to our annual cost estimates presented above. However, we can use 
    Hahn's benefit/cost ratio ($500b/$220b) or 2.5, assume that it holds 
    for the full period since 1988, and calculate an aggregate benefit 
    estimate. It should be noted , however, that Hahn believes his 
    aggregate net benefit estimates `` * * * are likely to
    
    [[Page 39364]]
    
    substantially overstate actual net benefits'' (p. 224). Both our 
    estimates and Hahn's estimates would most likely include almost the 
    same set of regulations issued between 1990 and 1995 because we both 
    attempted to be exhaustive in our cost collection effort. According to 
    our sample, about 80% of the costs of social regulation issued between 
    1989 and 1996 were issued between 1990 and 1995. Assuming that in 1988, 
    social regulation produced net benefits of $2 billion as Hahn and Hird 
    suggest, and using Hahn's benefit-cost ratios for environmental (1.4) 
    and other social regulation (5.3), we calculate that the benefits of 
    regulation in 1996 were as follows, and we present our cost estimates 
    for comparison:
    
    Table 4.--Estimates of the Total Annual Benefits and Costs of Regulation
                                    for 1997                                
                           [Billions of 1996 dollars]                       
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                                      Benefits      Costs   
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    Environmental.................................          162          144
    Other Social..................................          136           54
    Economic......................................            0           91
                                                   -------------------------
        Total.....................................          298          289
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As explained above, these are very rough estimates, probably 
    overstating both the benefits and costs, and viewed alone not very 
    informative. The total numbers on costs and benefits indicate that 
    regulation has produced about as much in benefits as in costs, but this 
    is because economic regulation produces negligible benefits. 
    Disaggregating the totals a little reveals that ``Other Social'' 
    regulation produces very large net benefits, but if one digs into both 
    the Hahn and Hird, and Hahn studies in greater detail, it becomes clear 
    that most of the benefits of this category are produced by highway 
    safety regulation. Hahn and Hird state that they found very little 
    ``credible evidence'' that as of 1988, OSHA regulations had produced 
    any significant benefits (275-276), although Hahn's 1996 study found 
    that OSHA regulations had produced over $50 billion (present value) in 
    net benefits by 1995.
        Hahn makes clear that even though his study found that the 53 
    regulations issued between 1990 and 1995 produce very large net 
    benefits, only 23 would ``pass'' a cost-benefit test. He also points 
    out that if the rules that had not passed the test had not been issued, 
    net benefits would have been $115 billion, or about 40 percent greater 
    (p. 221). He also finds that all safety regulations have benefits 
    greater than costs, and that regulations based on the Clean Air Act and 
    the Safe Drinking Water Act had positive net benefits (p. 221) (which 
    is corroborated by the EPA Drinking Water study (1993)). An analysis of 
    the costs and benefits of regulations based on other regulatory 
    programs produced mixed results. The message is clear: the policy 
    content is in the details.
    
    3. Other Estimates of the Total Costs of Regulation
    
        As noted, the estimates of total costs and benefits that we have 
    provided overstates, we believe, both the benefits and most certainly 
    the costs of regulation. Nonetheless, our cost estimates are 
    substantially less than other numbers that are often cited and have 
    gained a certain credibility in the debate. We would note that, apart 
    from the Hahn and Hird study we used, all other estimates of total 
    costs do not present benefit estimates. We believe that presenting 
    costs without benefits is not very informative and potentially 
    misleading. In any event, some explanation of the difference between 
    our numbers and other numbers that have been cited is appropriate.
        According to a 1995 report to Congress by the Small Business 
    Administration's (SBA) Office of Advocacy, there are estimates of the 
    total cost of regulation generated by the Heritage Foundation as high 
    as $810 billion to $1.7 trillion for 1992 with benefits reportedly 
    netted out. We cite this study because it is the largest estimate of 
    the costs of regulation that we are aware of. Our reference to it 
    should not be construed as any endorsement of it; indeed, it has not 
    been peer reviewed, it has not been published in a reputable journal, 
    and most importantly, the basis for the estimate has not been made 
    publicly available. Our own view is that the numbers are either wrong 
    or are measuring something other than what we are talking about.
        On the other hand, there is a series of Hopkins studies of the 
    total cost of regulation (1991, 1992, 1995, and 1996), which is both 
    well known and better documented. The Hopkins estimates have also 
    received attention from the Congress. A recent GAO study, Regulatory 
    Reform: Information on Costs, Cost-Effectiveness, and Mandated 
    Deadlines for Regulation (1995), was asked to focus on the Hopkins 
    study because of its prominence and the fact that it was the only game 
    in town.
        Hopkins relied on the paper by Hahn and Hird (1991) that provided 
    estimates of the costs and benefits of economic and social regulation 
    for 1988, on the 1990 study by the EPA, The Cost of a Clean, and 
    various reports from OMB: The Information Collection Budget (various 
    years)--that is, the same materials that we used for our 1988 cost 
    baseline. Hopkins also reviewed two earlier attempts at adding up the 
    total costs of regulation as of 1976-77 by Weidenbaum and DeFina (1978) 
    and Litan and Nordhaus (1983) to make estimates of the trend in total 
    regulatory costs over this decade. He also projected cost to the year 
    2000, based on estimates from the Cost of Clean, extrapolations of past 
    trends, and some educated guess work about the future costs of 
    compliance with regulations required by statutes such as the Clean Air 
    Act Amendments of 1990 and the Americans with Disabilities Act of 1990. 
    Because we focus our attention on the state of regulation as of 1997, 
    we do not directly critique the earlier studies by Weidenbaum and 
    DeFina or Litan and Nordhaus, nor do we discuss Hopkins' extrapolations 
    beyond 1997.
        Hopkins' cost estimate for 1997 (presented by us in 1996 dollars 
    using the CPI), is as follows:
    
          Table 5.--Hopkins' Estimate of the Annual Costs of Regulation     
                           [Billions of 1996 dollars]                       
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                                                            
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    Environmental..............................................          185
    Other Social...............................................           62
    Economic: Efficiency Costs.................................           81
    Economic: Transfer Costs...................................          148
    Process....................................................          232
                                                                ------------
        Total..................................................          708
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        One important problem with these estimates is that, with the 
    exception of the Process estimate, they are based on individual studies 
    that were published, for the most part, between 1975 and 1990 and then, 
    as mentioned above, extrapolated to 1997 based on the Cost of Clean 
    cost projections for future years for environmental regulation and his 
    own ad hoc ``guesstimates'' (his words ( 1991, p. 11)) for other social 
    and economic regulation. Note that although we also use data from 1988 
    and earlier, his approach differs significantly from ours. Rather than 
    extrapolation, we used timely information supplied by the agencies over 
    the period 1987 to 1996 that was subject to notice and public comment 
    and OMB review to update the estimates on benefits and costs to 1997. 
    Ideally, to get a realistic picture of the total costs of regulation, 
    one needs to do a comprehensive study of all regulatory costs facing 
    the economy at a given point in time. But that would be prohibitively 
    expensive and, as pointed out above, ex post surveys of the costs of 
    existing regulations have their own problems.
    
    [[Page 39365]]
    
        A second problem relates to the appropriateness of Hopkins' 
    adjustments. Specifically, Hopkins' adds to EPA's Cost of Clean report 
    (the 1988 base), $10 billion for the Clean Air Act Amendments, $8 
    billion for Superfund/RCRA, and $1 billion for several DOT 
    environmental regulations. It is not clear, however, how these figures 
    are derived. Similarly, Hopkins' estimate for ``other'' social 
    regulation costs starts with Hahn and Hird (as we did), but adds an 
    additional $1 billion and an assumed rise of 5% percent per year for 
    OSHA regulations, and adds $4 billion for the new universal 
    accessibility standards, $500 million for food labeling regulations, 
    $200 million for energy conservation standards, and $1.6 billion for 
    clinical lab regulations. These amounts are taken from a combination of 
    agency and industry sources, although again it is not clear how the 
    specific numbers were derived.
        As noted above, we used Hopkins' updates for the changes in 
    economic costs to 1997. Moreover, we added $10 billion to his estimate 
    of the cost of economic regulation to account for the paperwork costs 
    imposed by the independent agencies. But we did not include Hopkins' 
    estimate of transfer costs. Hopkins acknowledges that transfers are 
    exchanges of funds from one group to another, but he argues that the 
    existence of transfers creates real social costs because they give rise 
    to ``rent-seeking behavior.'' (``Rent seeking behavior'' is behavior 
    that attempts to capture or create excess profits usually by 
    influencing government actions, such as regulations.) He states that 
    the existence of transfers creates real costs that exhausts the amount 
    of the transfer as interest groups and their lobbyists, lawyers and 
    experts campaign for those funds (p. 29). We believe that Hopkins has 
    the causality wrong. Rather than the existence of a transfer program 
    causing rent-seeking behavior, rent-seeking behavior causes the 
    transfer. It is the possibility that rent-seeking behavior may result 
    in a gain that causes special interests to form and campaign for 
    special treatment. The transfer program does not have to exist, just 
    the possibility that one could be set up. Thus to the extent that rent-
    seeking behavior imposes real costs on society, those costs would be 
    more appropriately attributable to our democratic political system than 
    to a particular regulation.
        We also believe that Hopkins' has overstated the costs of process 
    regulation, which for the most part either represents double counting 
    or more appropriately belongs elsewhere. Most of Hopkins' estimate is 
    based on the burden hour estimates reported in OMB's annual Information 
    Collection Budgets (various years ) of the time it takes the public to 
    comply with information requests made or generated by the Federal 
    government. He multiplies burden hours by $26.50 per hour (in 1996 
    dollars), an estimate of the public's opportunity cost for filling out 
    forms and gathering information. While average private nonagricultural 
    hourly earnings was $11.82 in 1996 (less than 45 percent of the number 
    he used), Hopkins argues that his time cost estimate is not too high 
    because about 85 percent of the burden hour estimate is from the 
    Treasury Department, much of which represents the time it takes high 
    priced tax accountants to fill out income and corporate tax forms.
        We believe the paperwork costs of the tax code should not be 
    included in an estimate of the total cost of regulation. First, filling 
    out tax forms is not the result of ``regulations'' but rather of the 
    tax code itself, with most regulations merely providing interpretations 
    and clarifications of tax law. Second, Hopkins assumes a zero 
    baseline--that is, he implicitly assumes that replacing the revenue 
    generated by the present tax code could be done with no record keeping 
    or reporting costs. The implicit baseline is a world without taxes. 
    Third, reforming the tax code is an entirely different public policy 
    area than regulation, and lumping the two together, especially when the 
    tax numbers are so large relative to social and economic regulatory 
    costs, just confuses the issue.
        Hopkins has removed the cost of procurement paperwork, such as that 
    imposed by DOD and GSA, based on an OMB estimate that in 1990 the 
    procurement paperwork burden was about 30 percent of the total non-tax-
    related paperwork. He correctly points out that those costs are mostly 
    paid by taxpayers through higher procurement costs, and thus it would 
    be double counting to include them as private sector regulatory costs. 
    However, most of the remaining paperwork costs also represent double 
    counting, because the estimates of regulatory costs for individual 
    social and economic regulations that he uses already include these 
    costs as a cost of compliance. Specifically, the compliance cost 
    estimates submitted to OMB and included in our estimate for the cost of 
    social regulation include associated paperwork costs. Although Hopkins 
    admits the likelihood of double counting, he dismisses it because ``the 
    dominance in this category of tax-related paperwork suggests this is 
    not likely a serious problem'' (1991, p. 14). But once tax-related 
    paperwork is removed, it becomes a serious problem.
        Hopkins also adds to his process costs estimates $10 billion in 
    1997 as the amount that State and local government spent to comply with 
    Federal mandates. However, we cannot determine a clear basis for his 
    estimate. Because our approach of adding the costs of all social 
    regulations issued since 1987 should capture State and local regulatory 
    costs, there should not be a special provision for State and local 
    mandates.
        The final piece of Hopkins' process cost estimate is an estimate of 
    how much more overhead the U.S. multi-payer health care system 
    generates than Canada's single-government-payer system. His argument 
    here is that because the United States has less regulation, it has 
    higher regulatory costs. It is certainly true that regulation can 
    improve efficiency, but it seems disingenuous to argue that because 
    regulations have not mandated a single payer system or restricted 
    private payment systems, etc., regulatory costs are increased. These 
    increased cost estimates (Woolhandler and Himmelstein, 1991), if they 
    are true (they are controversial), are more properly treated as 
    benefits of regulation (or of a government program), not as costs of 
    not regulating. Additionally, as discussed above, including these costs 
    confuses the regulatory reform debate.
        In sum, in our view, Hopkins' total cost estimate is about 240% 
    greater than ours because he includes inappropriate transfers and 
    process costs and less accurate estimates of the growth of social 
    regulation since 1988.
    
    4. Assessment of the Direct and Indirect Impact of Federal Rules
    
        A proper assessment of the costs and benefits of regulation would 
    have to take into account both the direct and indirect impact of 
    regulation on the economy. As reported above, our estimate of the 
    direct effect is that, in the aggregate, the net benefits of regulation 
    issued to date is positive. The few studies that have attempted to 
    determine the indirect effects of regulation on productively and 
    welfare have found significant indirect effects, implying that the 
    direct effects reported above are significant understatements of the 
    full costs of regulation (Hazilla and Kopp 1990 and Jorgenson and 
    Wilcoxen 1990). However, as Hahn and Hird (1991) point out, it is not 
    clear how to evaluate these studies and others like them, which are 
    based on huge, complex and often proprietary models of the U.S. 
    economy. This makes it almost impossible to validate the
    
    [[Page 39366]]
    
    models or to view the assumptions on which they are based.
        These studies have another major problem because they only take 
    into account indirect cost effects and do not include the indirect 
    beneficial effects that may result from better health and safer lives. 
    Yet it is generally agreed that healthier people tend to work harder 
    and longer and save and invest more, thereby increasing the growth of 
    the economy. Therefore, without knowing what the indirect and general 
    equilibrium benefits of regulation are, one should not draw conclusions 
    by only looking at the indirect costs. Models that take into account 
    the indirect benefits and general equilibrium effects of longer life 
    spans, higher levels of environmental quality, and more equal 
    opportunities remain to be developed.
        The best survey of what we know about the full range of indirect 
    costs and benefits of social regulation was recently published in one 
    of the leading economic journals: the Journal of Economic Literature 
    (Jaffe, Peterson, Portney, and Stavins 1995). Although concentrating on 
    environmental regulation, their discussion should apply to health and 
    safety regulation as well because they are similar in their economic 
    effects and the direct costs of health and safety regulation are only 
    about one third the amount of environmental regulation. The authors 
    conclude from a survey of the literature that environmental regulation 
    has little impact on ``competitiveness as measured by net exports, 
    overall trade flows, and plant location decisions (p. 157), `` modest 
    adverse impacts on productivity'' (p. 151) and ``significant dynamic 
    impacts * * * in the form of costs associated with reduced investment'' 
    based on computable general equilibrium models (p. 151). However, they 
    also point out that, for the most part, these estimates do not take 
    into account the feedback effect from improvements in the environment 
    (p. 153).
        Jaffe et al. also examine the contention that environmental and 
    other social regulation may actually enhance economic growth and 
    competitiveness by stimulating improvements in productivity as firms 
    compete among themselves to comply with regulations in the least cost 
    way. We discussed this proposition above as a reason why the actual 
    costs of compliance ex post often turns out to be less than predicted 
    ex ante. Several authors have extended this proposition beyond the ad 
    hoc to include the economy as a whole (Porter 1991 and Gardiner 1994). 
    This line of reasoning claims that the country that leads in 
    environmental protection will gain a lasting comparative advantage in 
    international trade in the supplier industries because of having been 
    the ``first mover'' into an area that other countries must follow.
        We are cautious about extending such claims to the economy as a 
    whole. To be sure, certain sectors benefit and we may even develop a 
    comparative advantage in them, but other sectors must invariably lose 
    their comparative advantage because resources are drawn from them and 
    comparative advantage is by definition a relative phenomenon. Jaffe, et 
    al., (p. 157) conclude:
    
        Thus, overall, the literature on the ``Porter hypothesis'' 
    remains one with a high ratio of speculation and anecdote to 
    systematic evidence. While economists have good reason to be 
    skeptical of arguments based on nonoptimizing behavior where the 
    only support is anecdotal, it is also important to recognize that if 
    we wish to persuade others of the validity of our analysis we must 
    go beyond tautological arguments that rest solely on the postulate 
    of profit-maximization. Systematic empirical analysis in this area 
    is only beginning, and it is too soon to tell if it will ultimately 
    provide a clear answer.
    
        We agree with this statement and hope that this report stimulates 
    ``systematic empirical analysis'' in this area, as well as work on as 
    the broader issue of how to improve the estimation of the costs and 
    benefits of regulatory programs discussed in this report.
    
    Chapter III. Estimates of Benefits and Costs of ``Economically 
    Significant'' Rules
    
    1. Scope
    
        In this chapter, we examine the benefits and costs of ``each rule 
    that is likely to have a gross annual effect on the economy of 
    $100,000,000 or more in increased costs,'' as required by Section 
    645(a)(2). We have included in our review those final regulations on 
    which OIRA concluded review during the 12-month period April 1, 1996, 
    through March 31, 1997. We chose this time period to ensure that we 
    covered a full year's regulatory actions as close as practicable to the 
    date our report is due, given the need to compile and analyze data and 
    publish the report for public comment. In addition, we thought it would 
    be useful to adopt a time period close to that used for the annual OMB 
    report required by the Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995.
        The statutory language categorizing the rules we are to consider 
    for this report is somewhat different from the definition of 
    ``economically significant'' rules in Executive Order 12866 (Section 
    3(f)(1)). It also differs from similar statutory definitions in the 
    Unfunded Mandates Reform Act and Subtitle E of the Small Business 
    Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act of 1996--Congressional Review of 
    Agency Rulemaking. Given these varying definitions, we interpreted 
    Section 645(a)(2) broadly to include all final rules promulgated by an 
    Executive branch agency that meet any one of the following three 
    measures:
         Rules designated as ``economically significant'' under 
    Section 3(f)(1) of Executive Order 12866;
         Rules designated as ``major'' under 5 U.S.C. 804(2) 
    (Congressional Review Act);
         Rules designated as meeting the threshold under Title II 
    of the Unfunded Mandates Reform Act (2 U.S.C. 1531-1538).
        We did not include rules issued by independent regulatory agencies 
    because we do not review their rules under Executive Order 12866. In 
    any case, we believe that few of their individual regulations meet the 
    statutory criteria of Section 645(a)(2).
        During the time period selected, OIRA reviewed 41 final rules that 
    met these criteria. (Table 6.) For 9 of these 41 final rules, OIRA also 
    reviewed a proposed rule during the time period. (OIRA reviewed 13 
    additional proposed rules that met one or more of the three criteria 
    listed above.) 1 Of the 41 final rules, USDA submitted 12; 
    HHS submitted 8; EPA submitted 7; and the remainder were from the 
    Departments of the Commerce (1), Housing and Urban Development (2), 
    Interior (2), Justice (1), Labor (2), and Transportation (3), and the 
    Social Security Administration (2). Also included is one multi-agency 
    rule from HHS, DOL, and Treasury. These 41 rules represent about 15% of 
    the final rules reviewed by OIRA during this period, and less than 1% 
    of all final rules published in the Federal Register between April 1, 
    1996, and March 31, 1997. Nevertheless, because of their greater scale 
    and scope, we believe that they represent the vast majority of the 
    costs and benefits of new Federal regulations during this period.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \1\ These proposals include several particularly significant 
    proposals reviewed by OIRA: EPA's two proposals in November 1996 to 
    revise the National Ambient Air Quality Standards for Particulate 
    Matter and Ozone; EPA's proposal in the summer of 1996 expanding the 
    industries covered by the Toxic Release Inventory; and FDA's January 
    1997 proposal regarding Animal Proteins Prohibited in Ruminant Feed. 
    These proposals are not discussed because they were not yet final 
    during the time frame on which we are reporting.
    
    [[Page 39367]]
    
    
    
                 Table 6.--Economically Significant Final Rules             
                                [4/1/96-3/31/97]                            
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                                                            
    -------------------------------------------------------------------------
                            Department of Agriculture                       
                                                                            
    Foreign Agriculture Service:                                            
        CCC Supplier Credit Guarantee Program                               
        Dairy Tariff-Rate Import Quota Licensing                            
    Farm Service Agency:                                                    
        1995-Crop Sugarcane and Sugar Beet Price-Support Loan Rates         
        Farm Program Provisions of the 1996 Farm Bill                       
        Peanut Poundage Quota Regulations--7 CFR Part 729 (Interim Final)   
        Conservation Reserve Program--Long Term Policy                      
    Federal Crop Insurance Corp.:                                           
        Catastrophic Risk Protection Endorsement                            
        General Administrative Regulations--Subpart T                       
    Animal and Plant Health Inspection Service: Karnal Bunt                 
    Food Safety and Inspection Service: Hazard Analysis and Critical Control
     Points                                                                 
    Food and Consumer Service:                                              
        Certification Provisions (Mickey Leland Childhood Hunger Relief     
         Act), Food Stamp Program                                           
        Child and Adult Care Food Program: Targeting of Day Care Home       
         Reimbursements (Interim Final)                                     
                                                                            
                             Department of Commerce                         
                                                                            
    Bureau of Export Administration: Encryption Items Transferred from the  
     U.S. Munitions List to the Commerce Control List                       
                                                                            
                     Department of Health and Human Services                
                                                                            
    Health Care Financing Administration:                                   
        Limits on Aggregate Payments to Disproportionate Share Hospitals    
        Hospital Inpatient Prospective Payment Systems FY 1997 Rates        
        Medicare Revisions to Policies Under Physician Fee Schedule 1997    
        Requirements for Physician Incentive Plans in Prepaid HCOs          
        Individual Market Health Insurance Reform (Interim Final)           
    Food and Drug Administration:                                           
        Food Labeling Nutrition Labeling, Small Business Exemption          
        Medical Devices: CGMP Quality Systems Regulation                    
        Sale and Distribution of Tobacco                                    
                                                                            
                   Department of Housing and Urban Development              
                                                                            
    Office of Housing:                                                      
        Single-Family Mortgage Insurance (Interim Final)                    
        Sale of HUD-Held Single-Family Mortgages                            
                                                                            
                             Department of Interior                         
                                                                            
    Fish and Wildlife Service:                                              
        Migratory Bird Hunting--Final Frameworks Early Season               
        Migratory Bird Hunting--Final Frameworks Late Season                
                                                                            
                              Department of Justice                         
                                                                            
    Immigration and Naturalization Service: Inspection and Expedited Removal
     of Aliens (Interim Final)                                              
                                                                            
                               Department of Labor                          
                                                                            
    Employment Standards Administration: Service Contract Act Standards for 
     Federal Service Contracts                                              
    Occupational Safety and Health Administration: Methylene Chloride       
                                                                            
                          Department of Transportation                      
                                                                            
    National Highway Traffic Safety Administration:                         
        Occupant Crash Protection (Airbag Depowering)                       
        Light Truck Corporate Average Fuel Economy MY 1999                  
    Federal Railroad Administration: Roadway Worker Protection              
                                                                            
                         Environmental Protection Agency                    
                                                                            
    Office of Solid Waste and Emergency Response:                           
        Accidental Release Prevention--112(r)                               
        Financial Assurance for Local Gov't. Owners of MSW Landfills        
    Office of Air and Radiation:                                            
        Deposit Control Gasoline                                            
        Acid Rain Phase II NOX                                              
        Federal Test Procedure Revisions                                    
        Voluntary Standards for Light Duty                                  
        Vehicles (49-State)                                                 
    Office of Prevention, Pesticides, and Toxic Substances: Lead-Based Paint
     Activities in Target Housing                                           
                                                                            
                         Social Security Administration                     
                                                                            
    Cycling Payment of Social Security Benefits                             
    Determining Disability for Individuals Under Age 18 (Interim Final)     
    Common Rule--Health and Human Services/Labor/Treasury: Health Insurance 
     Portability of Group Health Plans (Interim Final)                      
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    
    [[Page 39368]]
    
    2. Overview
    
        As noted in chapter I, Executive Order 12866 ``reaffirms] the 
    primacy of Federal agencies in the regulatory decision-making process'' 
    because agencies are given the legal authority and responsibility for 
    rulemaking under both their organic statutes and certain process-
    oriented statutes, such as the Administrative Procedure Act, the 
    Unfunded Mandates Reform Act, and the Small Business Regulatory 
    Enforcement Fairness Act. The Executive Order also reaffirms the 
    legitimacy of centralized review generally and in particular review of 
    the agencies' benefit-cost analyses that are to accompany their 
    proposals. The Executive Order recognizes that in some instances the 
    consideration of benefits or costs is precluded by law. For example, 
    the National Ambient Air Quality Standards under the Clean Air Act are 
    to be health-based standards set by EPA solely on the basis of the 
    scientific evidence. In addition, under the Clean Water Act, 
    technology-based standards must be established without regard to 
    benefits. A variation is the Occupational Safety and Health Act, where 
    health standards must be based on significant risks to the extent they 
    are economically and technologically feasible. However, the Executive 
    Order requires agencies to prepare and submit benefit-cost analysis 
    even if those considerations are not a factor in the decision-making 
    process. Again, it is the agencies that have the responsibility to 
    prepare these analyses, and it is expected that OIRA will review (but 
    not redo) this work.
        Reviewing for this report the benefit-cost analyses accompanying 
    the 41 final rules listed in Table 6, we found a wide variety in the 
    type, form, and format of the data generated and used by the agencies. 
    For example, agencies developed estimates of benefits, costs, and 
    transfers that were sometimes monetized, sometimes quantified but not 
    monetized, sometimes qualitative, and, most often, some combination of 
    the three. Generally, the boundaries between these types of estimates 
    are relatively well-defined.
        As discussed above, all monetized estimates are, by definition, 
    given in dollars and permit ready comparison and aggregation. Monetized 
    estimates of effects are what is most generally thought of as the basis 
    of benefit-cost analysis. Even when such figures are available, 
    however, care must be taken when interpreting them because they depend 
    for comparability on a number of distinct elements. Specifically, 
    monetized estimates consist of: (1) the dollar value itself; (2) the 
    base year of the dollar used; (3) the initial year in which the effects 
    occur; (4) the final year after which the effects disappear; (5) the 
    discount rate used (whether explicitly or implicitly) to convert future 
    into current values (or vice versa); and (6) the format in which the 
    monetized value is represented.
        Format means the characterization of the monetized or quantified 
    effects over time. In the rules on which we are reporting, we found 
    that agencies used a variety of formats:
        1. Annualized values, which spread out variable effects into yearly 
    sums that are financially equivalent to the actual temporal schedule, 
    regardless of how ``lumpy'' it might be;
        2. Present values, which convert over time into an immediate lump-
    sum;
        3. Constant annual values, in which effects have been estimated (or 
    are assumed) to be fixed each year over the time horizon in which the 
    regulation applies;
        4. Other formats, such as varying annual values or values reported 
    only for selected years, which can be converted into annualized or 
    present value format under certain specified conditions and 
    assumptions; and
        5. Unknown formats, which cannot be interpreted without additional 
    information.
        From the perspective of benefit-cost analysis, annualized and 
    present value formats are always preferred because they permit 
    aggregation and comparisons within and across regulatory actions. 
    Constant annual values are slightly less desirable insofar as they 
    require the additional step of discounting to permit such aggregation 
    and comparison. Constant annual values are typically found in monetized 
    cost estimates involving federal budget outlays, and in quantified 
    benefit estimates where agencies have chosen not to discount; 
    aggregation and comparison within and across regulations generally 
    cannot be performed without a common discounting methodology. Where an 
    agency's estimation methodology follows an unknown format, further 
    research needs to be performed to ascertain how to convert or 
    reconstruct annualized or present value estimates.
        Quantified estimates may take the form of a variety of different 
    units, but they share in common a numeric measure. Generally, 
    quantified estimates of benefits, costs, and transfers must be 
    interpreted with the same elements noted above in mind. The most 
    important difference, of course, is that quantified estimates are 
    expressed in units other than dollars. Such estimates may be aggregated 
    only if they are presented in the same or similar units. Also, a 
    quantified estimate should identify the applicable time period (e.g., 
    tons of pollution controlled per year, number of endangered species 
    protected from extinction per decade). Quantified estimates that lack 
    reference to the time periods to which they apply may be highly 
    misleading, and should be converted to similar time periods to be 
    comparable. Indeed, even when estimates of similar type include 
    explicit reference to their underlying time periods, care must be taken 
    when aggregating or comparing them because of the risk of summing 
    estimates based on different time periods or inconsistent base years.
        In contrast, qualitative estimates may not have any units at all, 
    or they may be expressed in units that do not lend themselves to simple 
    comparisons. As has often been observed, it is more frequently the case 
    that costs are monetized and benefits are more often quantified or 
    presented in qualitative form. Qualitative effects should be evaluated 
    in terms of their uniqueness, reversibility, timing, and geographic 
    scope and severity. These effects are the most difficult to interpret, 
    and this may lead some to give them short shrift. The fact that an 
    effect has not been monetized or quantified does not, however, 
    necessarily mean that it is small or unimportant. In discussing 
    agencies' descriptions of qualitative effects, we use the first year in 
    which such effects are expected to occur where it can be determined.
        Qualitative effects must be used with care for other reasons as 
    well. Because they tend to be general and descriptive, they may be 
    broader than the incremental effects of the particular regulation being 
    analyzed. For example, in developing a rule designed to address a 
    particular safety problem, an agency may describe the extent of the 
    problem--that is, so many persons injured per year from this particular 
    cause. While important in estimating the benefits of the rule, this 
    figure itself is not a benefit estimate unless and until it is linked 
    to the likely effectiveness of the proposed rule. Finally, qualitative 
    estimates cannot be aggregated at all because they do not contain units 
    that permit arithmetic operations. In addition, not infrequently they 
    fail to contain relevant information about the period of time during 
    which they apply.
        Cost-effectiveness measures and break-even analyses, which are 
    frequently used in regulatory analyses, are not equivalent to either 
    monetized or quantified estimates. Unlike benefits and costs, which are 
    expressed with
    
    [[Page 39369]]
    
    time as the explicit or implicit denominator, cost-effectiveness 
    estimates (e.g., dollars per ton of pollution controlled) are expressed 
    in terms of cost per unit of benefit--that is, as ratios in which 
    ``cost'' is the numerator and ``benefit'' is the denominator. 
    Frequently, such estimates are quite useful, particularly when 
    comparing alternative methods of achieving a predetermined objective. 
    Nevertheless, cost-effectiveness estimates cannot be compared with 
    either cost or benefit estimates, nor can they themselves be aggregated 
    in any manner.
        Similarly, break-even analyses reveal the minimum level of benefits 
    necessary for net benefits to be positive. For example, if a regulation 
    is estimated to prolong one ``statistical life'' at a cost of $X 
    million, break-even analysis reveals that if society's willingness-to-
    pay to prolong one statistical life is greater than $X million, then 
    the benefit of the regulation exceeds its cost. Likewise, if we know 
    that society's willingness-to-pay to prolong one statistical life is $X 
    million, and that the regulation will cost $X million then break-even 
    analysis reveals that benefits exceed costs if more than one 
    statistical life is saved. While this form of analysis is often useful 
    to decision makers, it does not address either the absolute or marginal 
    magnitude of benefits and costs.
    
    3. Benefits and Costs of Economically Significant Final Rules
    
    A. Social Regulation
        Of the 41 rules reviewed by OIRA, 22 represent major new regulatory 
    initiatives requiring substantial additional private expenditures and/
    or providing new social benefits. (See Table 7). EPA issued 7 of these 
    rules; USDA issued 4; HHS and DOT each issued 3; and the remaining 5 
    were spread among DOC, DOI, DOJ, and DOL. Agency estimates and 
    discussion are presented in a variety of ways, ranging from an 
    extensive qualitative discussion of benefits, e.g., USDA's rules 
    implementing the 1996 Farm Bill, to a more complete benefit-cost 
    analysis, e.g., the HHS rule on the Sale and Distribution of Tobacco.
        Benefits Analysis. Of the 22 rules listed in Table 7, agencies 
    provided monetized benefit estimates in 8 cases. Monetized benefit 
    estimates included items such as: (1) FDA's estimated $275 to $360 
    million per year in annualized cost savings from its deregulatory food 
    labeling rule (these are savings in the costs associated with 
    compliance with labeling requirements on low-volume products that FDA 
    estimated would be enjoyed by small businesses); (2) FDA's estimated 
    $9.2 to $10.4 billion per year reduced incidence of morbidity and 
    mortality from its rule restricting cigarette sales and marketing; (3) 
    EPA's estimated $174 million per year in reduced damage to chemical and 
    other facilities from its accidental release prevention rule; and (4) 
    USDA's estimated $2 billion per year in the value of improved soil 
    productivity, water quality, and wildlife from rules implementing its 
    Conservation Reserve Program.
    
    BILLING CODE 3110-01-P
    
    [[Page 39370]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN22JY97.000
    
    
    
    [[Page 39371]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN22JY97.001
    
    
    
    [[Page 39372]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN22JY97.002
    
    
    
    [[Page 39373]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN22JY97.003
    
    
    
    [[Page 39374]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN22JY97.004
    
    
    
    [[Page 39375]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN22JY97.005
    
    
    
    [[Page 39376]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN22JY97.006
    
    
    
    [[Page 39377]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN22JY97.007
    
    
    
    BILLING CODE 3110-01-C
    
    [[Page 39378]]
    
        An innovative feature of FDA's estimate for monetized benefits from 
    the tobacco rule is explicit recognition of the increases in longevity, 
    the timing of these increases, and their value. In part of its benefits 
    analysis, FDA estimated more than 900,000 years of life would be gained 
    by each cohort (about 4 years per would-be smoker). FDA discounted 
    these life-years to account for the delay associated with smoking 
    related health effects, and then monetized the life-years gained at 
    $117,000 per life-year, an estimate derived from academic literature.
        In 6 cases, agencies provided benefit estimates that were 
    quantified but not monetized. These included: (1) OSHA's estimated 31 
    cancer cases per year avoided and 3 deaths per year avoided from acute 
    central nervous system effects and carboxyhemoglobinemia from its 
    methylene chloride rule; (2) NHTSA's estimated 83 to 101 fatalities 
    prevented and 5,100 to 8,800 fewer serious injuries (primarily to 
    children) over the lifetime of one model year's vehicles from its 
    airbag depowering rule; and (3) EPA's estimated number of tons of 
    hydrocarbons, carbon monoxide, and nitrogen oxide emissions which it 
    expected would be reduced annually from several of its rules. In one 
    case, the medical device rule, FDA provided some of its benefit 
    estimates in monetized form; other benefits were quantified.
        In a number of cases where agencies reported monetized or 
    quantified benefit estimates, they also provided a qualitative 
    description of unquantified effects. For example, DOT discussed the 
    possibility that its railroad worker protection rule could increase the 
    carrying capacity of the nation's railroads and boost railroad employee 
    morale. OSHA reported that its methylene chloride rule would lower 
    exposure for as many as 30,000 to 54,000 workers, reducing the risk of 
    adverse central nervous system effects (other than death) of 
    carboxyhemoglobinemia every year. FDA reported that its medical device 
    rule would yield additional benefits in the form of fewer injuries in 
    other less severe categories (that were not quantified by the FDA), 
    reduced inconvenience to users and/or patients, and reduced burden on 
    medical personnel in terms of having to repeat treatments, replace 
    devices, and complete the paperwork and reporting associated with 
    medical device failures. EPA reported that the accidental release 
    prevention rule would result in efficiency gains by providing the 
    public with additional information on accident prevention plans for 
    manufacturing facilities and by improving the transfer and adoption of 
    new technologies between industries.
        Finally, in 8 cases, agencies reported neither monetized nor 
    quantified benefit estimates. In some (but not all) of these cases, the 
    agency provided a qualitative description of benefits. For example, 
    USDA's analysis of the 1996 Farm Bill program rules included a 
    qualitative discussion of the benefits of increased efficiency due to 
    the additional flexibility the rule provided for farmers to decide 
    which crops to plant. In its rule establishing training requirements 
    for lead abatement contractors, workers, etc., EPA discussed in 
    qualitative terms the value to consumers of being able to purchase 
    abatement services of reliable quality.
        Cost Analysis. In 17 of the 22 cases, agencies provided monetized 
    cost estimates. These include such items as: (1) USDA's estimated $900 
    million per year in consumer ``deadweight'' losses from restrictions on 
    farm output under its Conservation Reserve Program; (2) EPA's estimated 
    $138 million per year for gasoline detergent additives under its 
    deposit control gasoline rule; and (3) OSHA's estimated $101 million 
    per year to reduce occupational exposures to methylene chloride. For 2 
    deregulatory rules--FDA's food labeling rule and EPA's municipal solid 
    waste landfill financial assurance rule--agencies' monetized cost 
    estimates were very small or zero.
        In 4 of the 22 cases, agencies provided estimates of non-monetized, 
    quantitative effects that were intended to better inform decision 
    makers, but which were not identified as benefit or cost estimates per 
    se. For example, NHTSA estimated that its airbag depowering rule would 
    result in 50 to 431 more fatalities and an increase of 171 to 553 
    serious chest injuries (primarily to adults not wearing seatbelts) over 
    the lifetime of one full model-year of vehicles, and DOI estimated that 
    duck hunters spend over $400 million per year on duck-hunting 
    activities.
        Seven (7) of these 22 rules have positive net monetized benefits--
    that is, the estimated monetized benefits exceed the estimated 
    monetized costs of the rules. For example, FDA estimated its tobacco 
    rule would result in $9 to 10.2 billion per year in net benefits 
    (benefits minus costs). EPA estimated its Accidental Release Prevention 
    rule would generate $77 million per year in net benefits. For the 
    remaining 15 rules, agency analysis did not provide enough information 
    to allow an estimate of net benefits. Five (5) of the rules provided 
    quantified estimates of the expected benefits in terms of tons of 
    emissions reduced or injuries avoided; but in those cases, the agencies 
    did not assign values to these effects. Five (5) additional rules 
    identified qualitative benefits associated with the rule; but in these 
    cases, the agencies did not develop any quantified estimates of the 
    likely magnitude of these effects. Finally, in 5 cases, we classified a 
    rule as economically significant although little economic data on the 
    effects of the rule existed. These deserve comment.
        USDA Karnal Bunt: Karnal bunt is a fungal disease that infects 
    wheat, and during the past year was closely controlled to prevent 
    potential losses in wheat exports. Fear of widespread Karnal bunt 
    infestation led USDA's Animal and Plant Health Inspection Service 
    (APHIS) to take several emergency quarantine actions beginning in March 
    1996. The quarantine severely restricted the movement of wheat grown in 
    Arizona, two counties in Southern California, New Mexico, and portions 
    of west Texas. It also directed the plowing under of several thousand 
    acres of wheat and instituted mandatory disinfection procedures for 
    combines and wheat handling equipment. APHIS instituted these 
    procedures on an emergency basis to prevent the spread of the disease. 
    These restrictions were known to be expensive, but estimates of how 
    expensive were not developed at the time the actions were taken.
        In October 1996, APHIS issued the rule included on Table 7, which 
    continued the quarantine and its restrictions, and established 
    provisions for compensating wheat farmers and handlers who suffered 
    losses. The rule was designated economically significant because, 
    although economic data were not then available, both agency and OIRA 
    staff agreed that the impacts associated with the rule were 
    significant. For the same reason, it was designated ``major'' under 
    SBREFA. While needing to issue this rule promptly APHIS agreed that it 
    would conduct a Regulatory Flexibility Analysis and an economic 
    analysis. In an analysis developed after the time period of our report, 
    USDA estimated one-year costs totaling about $42 million. The Federal 
    government paid $24 million to affected parties to compensate for these 
    losses. However, the Department acknowledged that other potentially 
    significant costs had not been formally estimated. The Department 
    estimated the benefits of the rule to be approximately $2 billion--
    based upon the potential loss of export markets if our trading partners 
    chose not to buy U.S. wheat--clearly making it an economically 
    significant rule.
    
    [[Page 39379]]
    
        DOI Migratory Bird Hunting (2 rules): These are unusual rules in 
    that they are permissive rather than restrictive--that is, migratory 
    bird hunting is prohibited absent these annual regulations which allow 
    hunting, setting bag limits and other controls on both early and late 
    season hunts. Thus the rules permit spending rather than requiring the 
    expenditure of private resources. DOI reports that the National Survey 
    of Fishing, Hunting, and Wildlife Associated Recreation indicated that 
    expenditures by migratory bird hunters (exclusive of licenses, tags, 
    permits, etc.) totaled $686 million in 1991. Based on this estimate, 
    DOI estimated expenditures by duck hunters would be over $400 million 
    per year in 1995. However, this figure is not a social benefit in the 
    commonly used sense of the term.
        DOT Light Truck CAFE: Each year DOT must establish a Corporate 
    Average Fuel Economy (CAFE) standard for light trucks, including sport-
    utility vehicles and minivans, (DOT also sets a separate standard for 
    passenger cars). For the past two years, however, appropriations 
    language has prohibited NHTSA from spending any funds to change the 
    standards. In effect, Congress has frozen the light truck standard at 
    its existing level of 20.7 miles per gallon (mpg) and has prohibited 
    NHTSA from analyzing effects at either 20.7 mpg or alternative levels. 
    Although benefits and costs are not estimated, DOT's experience in 
    previous years indicates that they may be substantial. Over 5 million 
    new light trucks are subject to these standards each year, and the 
    standard, at 20.7mpg, is binding on several manufacturers; some are 
    just above the standard and at least one is currently below 20.7 mpg. 
    Because of these likely substantial effects, the rule was designated as 
    economically significant even though analysis of the effects was 
    prohibited by law.
        DOC Encryption: Commerce's encryption rule allows the exportation 
    of more effective encryption products, subject to certain conditions 
    such as the development of a key management infrastructure. Although 
    quantitative estimates are not available, the rule is economically 
    significant, because, as commerce's analysis notes,
    
        The initiative addresses important foreign policy and national 
    security concerns identified by the President. Export controls on 
    cryptographic items are essential to controlling the spread abroad 
    of powerful encryption products which could be harmful to critical 
    U.S. national security, foreign policy and law enforcement 
    interests. This initiative will preserve such controls and foster 
    the development of a key management infrastructure necessary to 
    protect important national security, foreign policy and law 
    enforcement concerns.
    
    (61 FR 68573).
        Aggregate Effects. As noted above in chapter II, the substantial 
    limitations of the available data on the benefits and costs of this set 
    of rules make it virtually impossible to develop an aggregate estimate 
    of benefits and costs for even a single year's regulation. First, there 
    are no quantified or monetized estimates for 6 of the rules. In 
    addition, since many effects are not expressed in monetized terms, 
    there is a problem of apples and oranges in aggregating estimates. 
    Eight (8) of the rules listed in Table 7 have quantified estimates of 
    significant effects. Some of the quantified effects--premature deaths 
    and serious injuries avoided--are not unique to these rules but rather 
    are frequently identified in the RIAs for a variety of rules, and other 
    agencies have assigned monetized estimates to these outcomes. In any 
    event, the different quantitative effects cannot be summed because they 
    are not expressed in common units. Finally, when effects are only 
    described in a qualitative way, the aggregation problem becomes all the 
    more problematic.
        Because of the substantial variation in the presentation of agency 
    estimates and the differences in their discussion of benefits and 
    costs, Table 8 takes some initial steps in presenting agency estimates 
    in a more consistent way. This presentation re-formats the monetized 
    benefit and cost information on a rule-by-rule basis to enhance their 
    comparability. One key factor involves discounting where the timing of 
    effects matters. In order to make the agency estimates more consistent, 
    we performed some basic adjustments to agency estimates. For example, 
    the FRA presented monetized benefit and cost numbers in the form of a 
    present value over 10 years ($240 million in benefits and $229 million 
    in costs). We converted these to equal annual payments of $33 million 
    and $32 million respectively, using the 7 percent discount rate FRA 
    used to generate the present value estimates. We performed a similar 
    procedure for EPA's Lead-Based Paint rule, using the 3 percent discount 
    rate the agency used in calculating the rule's $1.114 billion present 
    value cost over 50 years. In the case of EPA's Federal Test Procedure 
    rule, the agency reported emission reductions for only four specific 
    years (2005, 2010, 2015, and 2010); in order to facilitate comparisons 
    with other emission-reducing rules, we used a linear interpolation 
    procedure to infer emission reductions in the interim years, and then 
    generated an equivalent annual stream of emission reductions.
    
                                  Table 8.--Summary of Agency Estimates for Final Rules                             
                                                    [4/1/96-3/31/97]                                                
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                                                                               Other quantitative   
                Agency/rule                  Benefit estimate           Cost estimate               effects         
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
    USDA:                                                                                                           
        1996 Farm Bill                                                                                              
        Farm Program Conservation.....  $2 Billion/Yr.............  $900 Million/Yr                                 
        Reserve Program...............  (1997-2002)...............  (1997-2002)..........                           
        Karnal Bunt...................   (\1\)                                                                      
        Hazard Analysis and Critical    $.065-2.43 Billion/Yr.....  $88-106 Million/Yr                              
         Control Points.                                                                                            
    Commerce:                                                                                                       
        Encryption Items Transferred    ..........................  $1.4 Million/Yr                                 
         from the U.S. Munitions List                                                                               
         to the Commerce Control List.                                                                              
    Health and Human Services:                                                                                      
        Food Labeling/Nutrition         $275-360 Million/Yr.......  $4 Million/Yr \2\                               
         Labeling: Small Business                                                                                   
         Exemption.                                                                                                 
        Medical Devices: Quality        $29 Million/Yr; 44 deaths   $82 Million/Yr                                  
         Systems Regulation.             and 484-677 serious                                                        
                                         injuries avoided/Yr.                                                       
    
    [[Page 39380]]
    
                                                                                                                    
        Restriction on Sale and         $9.2-10.4 Billion/Yr \3\..  $180 Million/Yr......  $160 Million/Yr in       
         Distribution of Tobacco.                                                           reduced house fire      
                                                                                            damage.                 
    Interior:                                                                                                       
        Migratory Bird Hunting (Early                                                                               
         Season Frameworks).                                                                                        
        Migratory Bird Hunting (Late                                                                                
         Season Frameworks).                                                                                        
    Justice:                                                                                                        
        Inspection and Expedited        ..........................  $235 Million/Yr                                 
         Removal of Aliens.                                                                                         
    Labor:                                                                                                          
        Methylene Chloride............  31 Cancer Cases/Yr; 3       $101 Million/Yr......  30,000 to 54,000 workers 
                                         Deaths/Yr from acute                               protected from central  
                                         central nervous system                             nervous system effects  
                                         effects.                                           and episodes of         
                                                                                            carboxyhemoglobinemia.  
    Transportation:                                                                                                 
        Airbag Depowering.............  83-101 fatalities and       $0...................  Increases of 50-431      
                                         5,100-8,800 serious                                fatalities and 261-842  
                                         injuries prevented over                            serious chest injuries  
                                         lifetime of one full                               over lifetime of one    
                                         model year's vehicles.                             full model year's       
                                                                                            vehicles.               
        Light Truck CAFE Model Year                                                                                 
         1999.                                                                                                      
        Roadway Worker Protection.....  $33 Million/Yr............  $32 Million/Yr                                  
    EPA:                                                                                                            
        Accidental Release Prevention.  $174Million/Yr............  $97 Million/Yr                                  
        Financial Assurance for         $105 Million/Yr...........  $0                                              
         Municipal Solid Waste                                                                                      
         Landfills.                                                                                                 
        Deposit Control Gasoline......  25,000 tons hydrocarbons;   $138 Million/Yr        Average savings of 64    
                                         474,000 tons carbon         average (1997-2000).   million gallons of      
                                         monoxide; 95,000 tons                              gasoline/Yr (1995-2001).
                                         nitrogen oxides average                                                    
                                         annual emission                                                            
                                         reductions (1997-2001).                                                    
        Acid Rain Phase II NOX          890,000 tons nitrogen       $204 Million/Yr                                 
         Controls.                       oxide annual emission                                                      
                                         reduction.                                                                 
        Federal Test Procedure          41,280 tons hydrocarbons;   $199-245 Million/Yr..  $202 Million/Yr in       
         Revisions.                      2,580,000 tons carbon                              potential fuel savings. 
                                         monoxide; 218,582 tons                                                     
                                         nitrogen oxides                                                            
                                         annualized emission                                                        
                                         reductions.                                                                
        Voluntary Standards for Light-  279 tons hydrocarbons;      $600 Million/Yr                                 
         Duty Vehicles.                  3,756 tons carbon                                                          
                                         monoxide; 400 tons                                                         
                                         nitrogen oxides DAILY                                                      
                                         emission reductions in                                                     
                                         2005.                                                                      
        Lead-Based Paint Activities in  ..........................  $33 Million/Yr \4\                              
         Target Housing.                                                                                            
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
    \1\ Agency performed analysis after the fact and released it after 3/31/97.                                     
    \2\ Maximum first-year cost; expected to decline thereafter.                                                    
    \3\ Benefits and cost at 7% discount rate. FDA also provided estimates at 3%.                                   
    \4\ Using EPA's 3% discount rate.                                                                               
    
        Any comparison or aggregation across rules must also consider a 
    number of factors which the presentation in Table 8 does not address. 
    First, for example, these rules may use different baselines in terms of 
    the regulations and controls already in place, the initial year for the 
    rule, and the time period over which the rule was considered to be 
    effective. In addition, these rules may well treat uncertainty in 
    different ways. In some cases, agencies may have developed alternative 
    estimates reflecting upper and lower bound estimates. In other cases, 
    the agencies may offer a mid-point estimate of benefits and costs, and 
    in some cases the agency estimates may reflect only upper bound 
    estimates of the likely benefits and costs. Also, in order for 
    comparisons or aggregation to be meaningful, benefit and cost estimates 
    should correctly account for all substantial effects of regulatory 
    actions, including potentially offsetting effects, which may or may not 
    be reflected in the available data.
        A final reason that any regulatory accounting effort has limits is 
    the treatment of the effects of regulations on distribution or equity. 
    None of the analyses addressed in this report provide quantitative 
    information on the distribution of benefits or costs by income 
    category, region, or any other factor. As a result, there is no basis 
    for quantifying distributional or equity impacts.
    Transfer Regulations
        Of the 41 rules listed in Table 6, 19 were rules necessary to 
    implement Federal budgetary programs. (See Table 9.) The budget outlays 
    associated with these rules generally provided ``transfers'' or reduced 
    transfers to program beneficiaries. Of the 19, 8 are USDA rules that 
    implement federal appropriations regarding agricultural and food stamp 
    policies; 7 are HHS and SSA rules that implement Medicare, Medicaid, 
    and Social Security policy; 2 are HUD rules associated with Federal 
    mortgage protections; 1 is a DOL rule
    
    [[Page 39381]]
    
    associated with Federal service contracts; and 1 is a joint HHS, 
    Treasury, and DOL action setting standards for health insurance 
    portability group health plans.
    
                            Table 9.--Transfer Rules                        
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                                                            
    -------------------------------------------------------------------------
    Department of Agriculture:                                              
        Commodity Credit Corporation Supplier Credit Guarantee Program      
        Dairy Tariff-Rate Import Quota Licensing                            
        1995-Crop Sugar Cane and Sugar Beet Price-Support Loan Program      
        Peanut Poundage Quota Regulations                                   
        Catastrophic Risk Protection Endorsement                            
        General Administrative Regulations * * * Subpart T                  
        Food Stamp Program Certification Provisions                         
        Child and Adult Care Food Program: Day Care Home Reimbursements     
    Housing and Urban Development:                                          
        Single-Family Mortgage Insurance                                    
        Sale of HUD-Held Single-Family Mortgages                            
    Labor:                                                                  
        Service Contract Act Standards for Federal Service Contracts        
    Health and Human Services:                                              
        Limits on Aggregate Payment to Disproportionate Share Hospitals     
        Hospital Inpatient Prospective Payment Systems (FY 1997)            
        Medicare Revisions to Policies Under Physician Fee schedule 1997    
        Requirements for Physician Incentive Plans in Prepaid Health Care   
         Organizations                                                      
        Individual Market Health Insurance Reform: Portability from Group to
         Individual Coverage                                                
    Social Security Administration:                                         
        Cycling Payment of Social Security Benefits                         
        Determining Disability for Individuals Under Age 18                 
    Multi-Agency Common Rule--HHS/Treasury/Labor: Interim Rules for Health  
     Insurance Portability for Group Health Plans                           
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The transfers arising from these programs represent payments from 
    one group to another (often from the Federal government to program 
    beneficiaries, but also within beneficiary groups and from recipients 
    back to taxpayers) that redistribute wealth; they are not social costs 
    (or social benefits) and do not directly reflect the ``opportunity 
    cost'' of resources used or benefits foregone. Social costs may arise 
    indirectly from these transfers, however, because they must be financed 
    through mechanisms--for example, income and payroll taxes--that affect 
    the use of real resources. Similarly, social benefits may arise from 
    these transfers if the beneficiaries realize marginal benefits from the 
    payments that are greater than the loss for those who finance the 
    payments (i.e., taxpayers).
        Estimates of the magnitude of the social costs and benefits 
    associated with these rules are typically not available. As a practical 
    matter, the transfers arising form these rules are a product of the 
    Federal program authorization and budget appropriations processes, and 
    the social costs involved are generally viewed as subsidiary to the 
    transfers involved. For these reasons, the Best Practices document 
    specifically notes that instead of a complete benefit-cost analysis, a 
    different form of regulatory analysis may be appropriate for 
    regulations implementing these Federal programs.
    
    Chapter IV. Recommendations
    
        This report is to include ``recommendations from the Director of 
    OMB and a description of significant public comments to reform or 
    eliminate any Federal regulatory program or program element that is 
    inefficient, ineffective, or is not a sound use of the Nation's 
    resources'' (Section 645 (a)(4)). As indicated in the Introduction, we 
    are soliciting comment on a wide range of issues related to our 
    discussions of the methodology we use in evaluating total annual 
    benefits and costs of Federal regulatory programs; estimates of the 
    benefits and costs of ``economically significant'' or ``major'' rules; 
    and direct and indirect impacts of Federal rules on the private sector 
    and governmental bodies. We are also seeking comment on regulatory 
    programs or program elements that are ``inefficient, ineffective, or * 
    * * not a sound use of the Nation's resources.''
        As we indicated in chapter II, the current state of knowledge of 
    benefits and costs of Federal regulatory programs is limited, although 
    growing. While some aggregate estimates of the benefits and costs of 
    Federal regulations have been made based on adding the results from 
    various studies, these aggregate estimates are best viewed as valiant 
    first attempts to summarize existing knowledge. They may be viewed as 
    general indicators of the importance of regulation to the American 
    people and to the economy, but not as guides to specific regulatory 
    reforms.
        Although many difficult methodological problems have yet to be 
    solved, we presented in chapter II our own aggregate estimates of the 
    costs and benefits of regulation to further the discussion and generate 
    comments that we hope will lead to better estimates. Except for the 
    consensus among economists that there appear to be little long run 
    economic benefits from most economic, as opposed to environmental and 
    other social, regulation, we do not believe that the existing evidence 
    on aggregate costs and benefits rises to the level that would support a 
    recommendation to eliminate any regulatory programs. Virtually all of 
    the evidence discussed above is based either on estimates for proposed 
    regulations or on dated studies of existing regulations. These data are 
    not appropriate for determining whether existing regulations should be 
    repealed or significantly modified because of the sunk cost and rising 
    baseline problems discussed above. Before supportable recommendations 
    are made to eliminate existing regulatory programs or elements of 
    programs, empirical evidence based on analytical techniques designed to 
    solve the methodological problems discussed above must be developed. We 
    are interested in receiving studies and suggestions for methodological 
    approaches appropriate for evaluating existing regulations in
    
    [[Page 39382]]
    
    order to develop the strong empirical evidence necessary to propose 
    supportable recommendations for eliminating or reforming regulatory 
    programs.
        Chapter III points out that we also need better evidence for 
    determining whether proposed regulations are cost-effective and produce 
    the greatest net benefits. Agencies have had difficulties generating 
    sufficient data to make these determinations for individual 
    regulations. In some instances, there are significant technical 
    problems to assessing costs and, in particular, benefits. In other 
    instances, the ability of the government to conduct analysis is limited 
    by factors that direct use of limited agency resources--for example, 
    statutory and judicial deadlines--forcing agency action within time 
    frames that preclude adequate analysis. In some other instances, it is 
    not at all clear that given limited financial and human resources, 
    additional analysis would be useful. Finally, there are occasionally 
    emergencies that demand swift federal action, where the public expect 
    their elected officials to respond as best they can without the delay 
    that careful analysis would entail.
        In summary, based on our discussion and findings in chapters I, II 
    and III above, we see three major themes:
         Our estimates of the total costs and benefits of 
    regulation in the $300 billion (4 % of GDP) range clearly indicate that 
    regulation is important in providing both health, safety, and 
    environmental benefits and a well functioning economy.
         It is very difficult to draw strong conclusions about how 
    to improve regulatory policy from macro data on benefits and costs. 
    Micro data on individual regulations are needed.
         Although considerable progress has been made in providing 
    micro data in advance of regulatory proposals and in developing best 
    practice guidance, further progress is needed to continue improving 
    regulatory decisions. Specifically, we need to ensure that the quality 
    of data and analysis used by the agencies improves, that standardized 
    assumptions and methodologies are applied more uniformly across 
    regulatory programs and agencies, and that data and methodologies 
    designed to determine whether existing regulations need to be reformed 
    is developed and used appropriately.
        Consequently, at this stage, we do not believe substantial economic 
    evidence exits on which to base proposals for major reforms or 
    eliminations of social regulatory programs or their elements. We 
    specifically solicit comment on such programs or program elements on 
    which members of the public may have information that would lead to a 
    conclusion that such programs are inefficient or ineffective and should 
    be eliminated or reformed. In particular, we solicit studies or 
    comments on studies that provide strong, objective and verifiable 
    evidence on the true social benefits and costs of eliminating or 
    reforming specific regulatory programs or their elements using 
    appropriate methodology.
        We are proposing for comment the following recommendations designed 
    to improve the quality of data and analysis on individual regulations 
    and on regulatory programs and program elements as a first step toward 
    developing the evidence needed to propose major changes in regulatory 
    programs.
         OIRA should lead an effort among the agencies to raise the 
    quality of agency analyses used in developing new regulations by 
    promoting greater use of the Best Practice guidelines and offering 
    technical outreach programs and training sessions on the guidelines.
         An interagency group should subject a selected number of 
    agency regulatory analyses to ex post disinterested peer review in 
    order to identify areas that need improvement and stimulate the 
    development of better estimation techniques useful for reforming 
    existing regulations.
         OIRA should continue to develop a data base on benefits 
    and costs of major rules by using consistent assumptions and better 
    estimation techniques to refine agency estimates of incremental costs 
    and benefits of regulatory programs and elements.
         OIRA should continue to work on developing methodologies 
    appropriate for evaluating whether existing regulatory programs or 
    their elements should be reformed or eliminated using its Best 
    Practices manual as the starting point.
         OIRA should work toward a system to track the net benefits 
    (benefits minus costs) provided by new regulations and reforms of 
    existing regulations for use in determining the specific regulatory 
    reforms or eliminations, if any, to recommend.
        Regulation and regulatory reform have the potential to do much good 
    for society or much harm. The key to doing the former is having the 
    information and analysis necessary for wise decision-making. The steps 
    outlined above are aimed at continuing our efforts to improve our 
    ability to make better regulatory decisions.
    
    Bibliography
    
    Crandall, Robert W., Howard Gruenspecht, Ted Keeler and Lester Lave. 
    Regulating the Automobile (Washington D.C.: Brookings Institution, 
    1986).
    Crandall, Robert W. ``What Ever Happened to Deregulation?'' in David 
    Boaz (ed.) Assessing the Reagan Years (Washington D.C.: Cato 
    Institution, 1988).
    Cropper, Maureen L. and Wallace E. Oates. ``Environmental Economics: 
    A Survey,'' Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 30, No. 2 (June 
    1992).
    Denison, Edward F. Accounting for Slower Economic Growth: The U.S. 
    in the 1970's (Washington D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1979).
    Eads, George C. And Michael Fix. Relief or Reform? Reagan's 
    Regulatory Dilemma (Washington, DC: The Urban Institute Press, 
    1984).
    Gardner, Bruce L. Protection of U.S. Agriculture: Why, How, and Who 
    Loses? (University of Maryland Dept. Agriculture and Resource 
    Economics Working Paper No. 87-15).
    Gray, W. B. ``The Cost of Regulation: OSHA, EPA, and the 
    Productivity Slowdown,'' American Economic Review, (December 1987).
    Hahn, Robert W. and John A. Hird. ``The Costs and Benefits of 
    Regulation: Review and Synthesis,'' Yale Journal on Regulation, 
    (Vol. 8, No. 1, Winter 1991).
    Hahn, Robert W. ``Regulatory Reform: What do the Numbers Tell Us?,'' 
    in Hahn, Robert W., ed., Risks, Costs, and Lives Saved: Getting 
    Better Results From Regulation, (New York: Oxford University Press 
    and AEI Press, 1996).
    Hazilla, Michael and Raymond Kopp. ``Social Cost of Environmental 
    Quality Regulations: A General Equilibrium Analysis,'' Journal of 
    Political Economy, ( Vol. 98, No. 4, 1990).
    Himmelstein, David U. And Steffie Woolhandler. ``Cost Without 
    Benefit: Administrative Waste in U.S. Health Care,'' The New England 
    Journal of Medicine, (Vol. 314, No. 7, February 13, 1986).
    Hopkins, Thomas D. ``Cost of Regulation,'' Report Prepared for the 
    Regulatory Information Service Center, Washington DC, (August 1991).
    Hopkins, Thomas D. ``Cost of Regulation: Filling the Gaps,'' Report 
    Prepared for the Regulatory Information Service Center, Washington 
    DC, (August 1992).
    Hopkins, Thomas D. ``Profiles of Regulatory Costs,'' Report to U.S. 
    Small Business Administration, (November 1995).
    Hopkins, Thomas D. ``Regulatory Costs in Profile,'' Policy Study No. 
    132, Center for the Study of American Business, (August 1996).
    Hufbauer, Gary C., Diane T. Berliner and Kimberly Ann Elliot. Trade 
    Protection in the United States (Washington, D.C.: Institute for 
    International Economics, 1986).
    
    [[Page 39383]]
    
    Jaffe, Adam B., Steven R. Peterson, Paul R. Portney and Robert 
    Stavins. ``Environmental Regulation and the Competitiveness of U.S. 
    Manufacturing,'' Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 33, No. 1 
    (March 1995).
    James Jr., Harvey S. Estimating OSHA Compliance Costs, Center for 
    the Study of American Business (October 1996).
    Jorgenson, Dale W. and Peter J. Wilcoxen. ``Environmental Regulation 
    and U.S. Economic Growth,'' Rand Journal of Economics (Vol. 21, No. 
    2, Summer 1990).
    Litan, Robert E. and William D. Nordhaus. Reforming Federal 
    Regulation (New Haven, Ct.: Yale University Press, 1983).
    Morrison, Steven A. and Clifford Winston. The Economic Effects of 
    Airline Deregulation (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 
    1986).
    Morrison, Steven A. and Clifford Winston. ``Enhancing Performance of 
    the Deregulated Air Transportation System,'' Brookings Papers on 
    Economic Activity: Microeconomics, 1989.
    U.S., Council of Economic Advisers. Economic Report of the President 
    (February 1997).
    U.S., Environmental Protection Agency. Environmental Investments: 
    The Cost of a Clean Environment (December 1990).
    U.S., Environmental Protection Agency. Technical and Economic 
    Capacity of States and Public Water Systems to Implement Drinking 
    Water Regulations--Report to Congress (1993).
    U.S., Environmental Protection Agency. 1972-1992 Retrospective 
    Analysis: Impacts of Municipal Treatment Improvement for Inland 
    Waterways (1995).
    U.S., Environmental Protection Agency. The Benefits and Costs of the 
    Clean Air Act, 1970-1992--Draft Report for Congress (April 1997).
    U.S., General Accounting Office. Regulatory Burden: Measurement 
    Challenges Raised by Selected Companies (November 1996).
    U.S., General Accounting Office. Regulatory Reform: Information on 
    Costs, Cost-Effectiveness, and Mandated Deadlines for Regulations 
    (March 1995).
    U.S., Office of Management and Budget. More Benefits Fewer Burdens: 
    Creating a Regulatory System that Works for the American People 
    (December 1996).
    U.S., Office of Management and Budget. Information Collection Budget 
    of The United States Government (Various Years).
    U.S., Office of Technology Assessment. Gauging Control Technology 
    and Regulatory Impacts in Occupational Safety and Health (September 
    1995).
    U.S. Small Business Administration. The Changing Burden of 
    Regulation, Paperwork, and Tax Compliance on Small Business: A 
    Report to Congress (October 1995).
    Viscusi, W. Kip. Fatal Tradeoffs: Public and Private 
    Responsibilities for Risk (New York: Oxford University Press, 1992).
    Viscusi, W. Kip. Risk by Choice: Regulating Health and Safety in the 
    Workplace (Cambridge Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1983).
    Weidenbaum, Murray L. and Robert DeFina. ``The Cost of Federal 
    Regulation of Economic Activity,'' American Enterprise Institute, 
    Washington, D.C.
    Wenders, J. The Economics of Telecommunications: Theory and 
    Practice, 83 (1987).
    
    [FR Doc. 97-19082 Filed 7-21-97; 8:45 am]
    BILLING CODE 3110-01-P
    
    
    

Document Information

Published:
07/22/1997
Department:
Management and Budget Office
Entry Type:
Notice
Action:
Notice and request for comments.
Document Number:
97-19082
Dates:
To ensure consideration of comments as OMB prepares this Draft Report for submission to Congress on or before September 30, 1997, comments must be in writing and received by OMB no later than September 1, 1997.
Pages:
39352-39383 (32 pages)
PDF File:
97-19082.pdf