97-17869. Competitive Bidding  

  • [Federal Register Volume 62, Number 131 (Wednesday, July 9, 1997)]
    [Proposed Rules]
    [Pages 36752-36756]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 97-17869]
    
    
    =======================================================================
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
    
    47 CFR CHAPTER I
    
    [WT Docket No. 97-150; FCC 97-232]
    
    
    Competitive Bidding
    
    AGENCY: Federal Communications Commission.
    
    ACTION: Request for comments.
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    SUMMARY: On July 2, 1997, the Federal Communications Commission 
    released a public notice requesting comment on the Commission's use of 
    competitive bidding to award licenses to provide wireless services as 
    part of its preparation of a report to Congress, as required by Section 
    309(j)(12) of the Communications Act, 47 U.S.C. 309(j)(2). The public 
    notice solicits comment from the public on a variety of issues relating 
    to the Commission's spectrum auction program to date, and announces 
    that comments are due on or before August 1, 1997.
    
    DATES: Comments are due on or before August 1, 1997.
    
    FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Mark Bollinger or Alice Elder, 
    Wireless Telecommunications Bureau, Federal Communications Commission, 
    (202) 418-0660.
    
    SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a summary of the public notice 
    released on July 2, 1997. The complete public notice is available for 
    inspection and copying during normal business hours in the FCC 
    Reference Center (Room 239), 1919 M Street, N.W., Washington, D.C., 
    20554, and also may be purchased from the Commission's copy contractor, 
    International Transcription Services, (202) 857-3800, 2100 M Street, 
    N.W., Washington, D.C. 20037. The complete public notice is also 
    available on the Commission's Internet home page (http://www.fcc.gov).
    
    Summary of the Public Notice
    
    Commission Opens Inquiry on Competitive Bidding Process for Report to 
    Congress
    
    Comment Due Date: August 1, 1997
    
    I. Introduction and Background
    
        The Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1993 (the ``Budget Act'') 
    added Section 309(j) to the Communications Act of 1934, as amended, 47 
    U.S.C. Secs. 151-713 (the ``Communications Act''). Section 309(j) 
    authorized the Commission to employ competitive bidding to choose from 
    among mutually exclusive applications for initial licenses in services 
    where the licensee receives compensation from subscribers. It requires 
    the Commission to promote the development and rapid deployment of new 
    technologies, products and services for the benefit of the public, 
    including those residing in rural areas, without administrative or 
    judicial delays. It further requires the Commission to promote 
    opportunity and competition by avoiding excessive concentration of 
    licenses and by disseminating licenses among a wide variety of 
    applicants, including small businesses, rural telephone companies, and 
    businesses owned by members of minority groups and women.
        In the four years since grant of auction authority, the Commission 
    has completed fourteen auctions. These auctions have resulted in the 
    assignment of over 4,300 licenses for spectrum-based services, which 
    include narrowband Personal Communications Service (PCS), broadband 
    PCS, Interactive Video Data Service (IVDS), Multipoint Distribution 
    Service (MDS), 900 MHz Specialized Mobile Radio Service (SMR), unserved 
    cellular areas, Direct Broadcast Satellite (DBS), Digital Audio Radio 
    Service (DARS) and Wireless Communications Service (WCS). Auctions to 
    date have raised a total of $23.1 billion for the U.S. Treasury. Future 
    auctions being planned include those for licenses to provide Local 
    Multipoint Distribution Service, paging, narrowband PCS, and the 800 
    MHz SMR and 220 MHz services.
        Section 309(j)(12) of the Communications Act requires that the 
    Commission conduct a public inquiry regarding the use of competitive 
    bidding to award licenses and submit a report to Congress by September 
    30, 1997. Pursuant to the statute, the report must:
        (1) Contain a statement of the revenues obtained, and a projection 
    of future revenues, from the use of competitive bidding systems;
        (2) Describe the competitive bidding methodologies established by 
    the Commission pursuant to Sections 309(j)(3) and (4) of the 
    Communications Act;
        (3) Compare the advantages and disadvantages of the competitive 
    bidding methodologies established by the Commission in terms of 
    attaining the objectives described in Sections 309(j)(3) and (4) of the 
    Communications Act;
        (4) Evaluate whether and to what extent:
        (i) Competitive bidding significantly improved the efficiency and 
    effectiveness of the process for granting radio spectrum licenses;
        (ii) Competitive bidding facilitated the introduction of new 
    spectrum-based technologies and the entry of new companies into the 
    telecommunications market;
        (iii) Competitive bidding methodologies have secured prompt 
    delivery of service to rural areas and have adequately addressed the 
    needs of rural spectrum users; and
    
    [[Page 36753]]
    
        (iv) Small businesses, rural telephone companies, and businesses 
    owned by members of minority groups and women were able to participate 
    successfully in the competitive bidding process; and
        (5) Recommend any statutory changes that are needed to improve the 
    competitive bidding process.
        To date, the Commission has conducted numerous rule makings 
    implementing its auction authority. As a result, the agency has 
    obtained comments and information from potential and actual bidders, 
    industry groups and licensees concerning its auction process. By this 
    Public Notice, the Commission seeks additional information and comment 
    in order to assist in preparing its report to Congress. The Commission 
    encourages comment from participants in prior auctions, from persons or 
    entities who are planning to participate in upcoming auctions, and from 
    other interested parties, including small businesses, rural telephone 
    companies, and businesses owned by members of minority groups and 
    women. Analysis of the data and results of specific auctions already 
    conducted, as well as information helpful in evaluating future 
    auctions, is desirable. Further information about the Commission's 
    auctions can be found at the Commission's Internet Auctions site, 
    http://www.fcc.gov/wtb/auctions.html. Parties are asked to provide any 
    examples or detailed analyses, studies or statistics concerning the 
    issues to be addressed in our report.
    
    II. Request for Public Comment
    
    A. Projection of Revenues From the Use of Competitive Bidding Systems
    
        To date, the Commission has raised $23 billion for the U.S. 
    Treasury through fourteen spectrum auctions. Revenue to be derived from 
    future auctions will likely be affected by various factors, including 
    the nature and amount of spectrum auctioned, service-specific FCC 
    rules, market conditions, and auction methodology. Determining the 
    value of spectrum in advance of an auction is very difficult. The value 
    of spectrum depends on a number of factors, including its location, 
    technical characteristics, the amount of spectrum, the geographic area 
    covered, the availability of technology suitable for a given band, the 
    amount of spectrum already available for provision of similar services, 
    the number of incumbents presently occupying the spectrum, and whether 
    incumbents, if any, will remain licensed in that spectrum or will be 
    relocated to other spectrum. The Commission has not made estimates of 
    the value of auctionable spectrum in the past. Moreover, the 
    Commission's statutory authority specifically instructs the Commission 
    not to base its spectrum allocation decisions ``solely or 
    predominantly'' on the expectation of revenues that auctions may 
    generate. The Commission's primary mission in conducting auctions is 
    promoting competition by awarding licenses rapidly to those who value 
    them most highly.
        The Commission asks commenters to provide it with information that 
    will aid the Commission in estimating projected revenues for its report 
    to Congress. Specifically, the Commission asks:
         How have the Commission's auction rules affected revenues 
    in the first fourteen spectrum auctions? Please be specific.
         How and to what extent has the amount of spectrum being 
    offered for auction, size of the license areas, the timing of the 
    offerings, and the use for which the spectrum is allocated, affected 
    revenues?
         What other factors have affected the revenues derived from 
    the spectrum auctions conducted to date?
         What methodologies should the Commission use to project 
    future revenues? Please provide specific illustrations of how such 
    methodologies might be applied.
    
    B. Comparison of Different Methodologies
    
        The introduction of competitive bidding into the license assignment 
    process promotes competition by awarding licenses quickly to those who 
    value them most highly, reduces wasteful private expenditures on 
    obtaining licenses in the secondary market, and raises revenue that 
    lessens taxpayer burdens. Before the grant of auction authority, the 
    Commission mainly relied upon comparative hearings and lotteries to 
    select a single licensee from a pool of mutually exclusive applicants 
    for a license. Under the comparative hearing process, the licensee was 
    selected from among a group of applicants on the basis of certain 
    criteria; under the lottery process, a licensee was selected at random. 
    The Commission has found that spectrum auctions more effectively assign 
    licenses than either comparative hearings or lotteries in most cases. 
    For example, using comparative hearings and lotteries, it generally 
    took the Commission at least two years or more to award licenses in 
    each of the top cellular markets. Lotteries also had the effect of 
    fueling speculation that resulted in the agency receiving nearly 
    400,000 applications for cellular licenses, and of allowing license 
    winners to reap large windfall profits by quickly selling their 
    licenses in a private auction to others. Notably, between 1983 and 1993 
    over 75 percent of all cellular licenses had been transferred at least 
    once. By using auctions, the Commission has reduced the average time 
    from license application to award to less than one year and the public 
    is now receiving the direct financial benefit from the award of 
    licenses.
        Additionally, the Commission auction methodology promotes efficient 
    spectrum use in several ways. First, it facilitates efficient spectrum 
    aggregation across geographic areas and spectrum blocks. Second, it 
    generates information about the value of spectrum for alternative uses. 
    Moreover, auctions, unlike comparative hearings, can be conducted at 
    modest cost relative to license value. The total cost of all Commission 
    auctions to date has been approximately $65 million, which represents 
    only about 0.28 percent of the total auction revenue raised to date.
        In conducting spectrum auctions, the Commission also has analyzed 
    and experimented with various auction methodologies. The Commission 
    pioneered the use of simultaneous multiple round auctions, the format 
    which we have used for most of our auctions. In contrast to other 
    bidding mechanisms, simultaneous multiple round bidding generates the 
    most information about license values during the course of the auction 
    and provides bidders with the most flexibility to pursue spectrum 
    aggregation strategies. Thus, this methodology effectively awards 
    interdependent licenses to the bidders who value them most highly. 
    Generally, the Commission has found that because of the superior 
    information and flexibility simultaneous multiple round bidding 
    provides, it is likely to yield more revenue than other auction 
    designs. The Commission also has used oral outcry and sequential 
    multiple round electronic auction designs, and is exploring other 
    bidding mechanisms, such as combinatorial bidding, for future auctions. 
    See Amendment of Part 1 of the Commission's Rules--Competitive Bidding 
    Proceeding, WT Docket No. 97-82, Order, Memorandum Opinion and Order 
    and Notice of Proposed Rule Making, FCC 97-60, 62 FR 13540 (March 21, 
    1997) (``Part 1 NPRM''). The Commission asks commenters to consider the 
    different methodologies used to date and offer any views or comparisons 
    of these mechanisms that would be helpful for the Commission's report 
    to Congress. In particular, the Commission asks:
    
    [[Page 36754]]
    
         Are there specific examples of where the simultaneous 
    multiple round auction methodology has facilitated efficient 
    aggregation of complementary licenses?
         What costs have been incurred in the preparation of bids? 
    Have these costs been significantly affected by the duration of the 
    auctions? How do these costs compare to the costs associated with 
    lotteries and comparative hearings?
         How has the use in connection with auctions of electronic 
    application filing, electronic bidding, and the distribution of 
    information via the Internet improved the efficiency and effectiveness 
    of granting spectrum licenses?
         Are there any other auction methodologies or improvements 
    to existing methodologies that might be explored?
    
    C. Evaluation of How Competitive Bidding Has Facilitated the 
    Introduction of New Technologies and the Entry of New Companies Into 
    the Telecommunications Market
    
        The PCS spectrum auctions resulted in the creation of many new 
    wireless telecommunications companies. Counted among these companies 
    are many small entrepreneurial firms. Indeed, 54 percent of the 
    licenses thus far awarded by auctions have gone to small businesses, 
    many of which are new entrants in the telecommunications market. Also, 
    several of the largest telecommunications enterprises in the world, 
    such as Sprint Telecommunications and the Bell Operating Companies, 
    have formed alliances to establish nationwide PCS networks. For 
    subscribers, these new firms represent new choices for increasingly 
    improving wireless service at lower prices. A recent report identifies 
    over 40 markets that now have three wireless competitors and 10 markets 
    with four competitors. There have been some reports that pricing in 
    competitive markets with at least one PCS operator averages 18 percent 
    lower than in markets with no PCS competitors. Competition is also 
    increasing consumers' choice of products by advancing the development 
    of three digital standards. In monetary terms, the most important 
    effect to the economy is that these firms are now investing in 
    infrastructure that will permit them to offer telecommunications 
    services in competition with each other and with other providers such 
    as cable and telephone companies. The wireless investment is expected 
    to be in the area of $50 billion over the next five years--the largest 
    single non-military investment in a new technology in history.
        By substantially lessening the length of the license assignment 
    process, auctions have resulted in speeding new technologies and 
    services to the wireless communications marketplace. For example, the 
    Commission recently completed the Digital Audio Radio Service auction, 
    which will bring a new digital radio service to American listeners 
    nationwide. Other services that have been rapidly developed through 
    auctions include narrowband PCS, Direct Broadcast Satellite, Multipoint 
    Distribution Service, and Specialized Mobile Radio. For its report, the 
    Commission asks:
         How do spectrum auctions compare with previous assignment 
    methods in attracting new entities to the communications market? How 
    successful have new entrants been in winning licenses at auction? What 
    effect are new entities having on the availability to the public of 
    competitive communications offerings?
         What are specific examples of new and innovative service 
    offerings or technologies that have been made available to the public 
    rapidly because of auctions?
         Has the auction process or the timing of auctions 
    adversely affected the introduction of new technologies in any way? If 
    so, what changes could we make in our auctions process to better 
    facilitate new technologies?
    
    D. Evaluation of How Competitive Bidding Methodologies Have Secured 
    Prompt Delivery of Service to Rural Areas
    
        For broadband PCS, the Commission adopted measures that would 
    facilitate the delivery of new services to rural and underserved areas. 
    In that proceeding, rural telephone companies were concerned that they 
    effectively would be barred from entering the broadband PCS industry if 
    they were required to bid on an entire Basic Trading Area (BTA) or 
    Major Trading Area (MTA) license to obtain the license which covered 
    their wireline service areas. They believed that partitioning would 
    allow them to serve areas in which they already provide service, 
    encouraging them to take advantage of existing infrastructure in 
    providing PCS services and thereby speeding service to rural areas. In 
    response to their concerns, the Commission adopted measures allowing 
    rural telephone companies to obtain broadband PCS licenses that are 
    geographically partitioned from larger PCS service areas, as well as to 
    obtain disaggregation of a portion of the spectrum assigned to the 
    licensee. In the Partitioning and Disaggregation Order, the Commission 
    extended its PCS partitioning and disaggregation rules to allow 
    entities other than rural telephone companies to obtain partitioned or 
    disaggregated licenses in order to speed service to unserved or 
    underserved areas. Partitioning is the assignment of geographic 
    portions of a spectrum license along geopolitical or other boundaries. 
    Disaggregation is the assignment of discrete portions or ``blocks'' of 
    spectrum licenses to another qualifying entity. See Geographic 
    Partitioning and Spectrum Disaggregation by Commercial Mobile Radio 
    Licensees, WT Docket No. 96-148, FCC 96-474, Report and Order and 
    Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 62 FR 696 (January 6, 1997). The 
    benefits of these rules are demonstrated in a partitioning agreement 
    recently approved in which a large licensee partitioned a geographic 
    portion of its MTA to a rural telephone company, thereby increasing the 
    rural telephone company's footprint and giving it access to several key 
    interstate arteries.
        The Commission has adopted or proposed partitioning and 
    disaggregation rules for other services, such as narrowband PCS, 220 
    MHz, paging, and LMDS. To identify other ways its rules have 
    facilitated delivery to underserved areas, the Commission asks 
    commenters to address the following questions:
         How have the Commission's competitive bidding rules 
    facilitated delivery of new and competitive telecommunications services 
    to rural and/or underserved areas?
         What effect have the Commission's rules on geographic 
    service area size and the size of spectrum blocks had on delivery of 
    new technologies and services to rural and/or underserved areas?
         How well have service-specific performance requirements, 
    including build out requirements, ensured the prompt delivery of new 
    and competitive service to rural and/or underserved areas?
         What effect have the Commission's policies on geographic 
    partitioning and spectrum disaggregation had on improving opportunities 
    for delivery of new technologies and services to rural and/or 
    underserved areas?
    
    [[Page 36755]]
    
    E. Evaluation of How the Commission's Competitive Bidding Rules Ensure 
    that Small Businesses, Rural Telephone Companies and Businesses Owned 
    by Women and Members of Minority Groups were able to Participate 
    Successfully in the Competitive Bidding Process
    
        In prescribing competitive bidding regulations, Congress directed 
    the Commission to ensure that small businesses, rural telephone 
    companies, and businesses owned by members of minority groups and women 
    are given the opportunity to participate in the provision of spectrum-
    based services. 47 U.S.C. Sec. 309(j)(4)(D). To promote these 
    objectives, Section 309(j)(4)(A) requires the Commission ``to consider 
    . . . alternative payment schedules and methods of calculation, 
    including lump sums or guaranteed installment payments, with or without 
    royalty payments, or other schedules or methods.'' 47 U.S.C. 
    Sec. 309(j)(4)(A). The Commission has adopted a number of measures, 
    including entrepreneurs' blocks, bidding credits, reduced upfront 
    payments and down payments, and installment payments, to ensure the 
    participation of rural telephone companies and small businesses, 
    including those owned by women and minorities.
        Since the 1993 mandate to ensure that designated entities are given 
    the opportunity to participate in the provision of spectrum-based 
    services, Congressional and Supreme Court actions have narrowed our 
    options for fulfilling this mandate. In 1994, Congress repealed Section 
    1071 of the Communications Act, voiding the Commission's tax 
    certificate program. In 1995, the Supreme Court held in Adarand 
    Constructors, Inc. v. Pena, 115 S. Ct. 2097, 2113 (1995), that ``all 
    racial classifications . . . must be analyzed by a reviewing court 
    under strict scrutiny.'' The Court ruled that any federal program that 
    makes distinctions on the basis of race must serve a compelling 
    governmental interest and must be narrowly tailored to serve that 
    interest. In 1996, the Supreme Court held in United States v. Virginia, 
    116 S. Ct. 2264, 2274-76 (1996), that a state program that makes 
    distinctions on the basis of gender must be supported by an ``exceeding 
    persuasive justification'' in order to withstand constitutional 
    scrutiny. Because the record developed in promulgating rules to promote 
    Section 309(j)'s objectives did not assume application of a ``strict 
    scrutiny test,'' the Commission narrowed the provisions for minority- 
    and women-owned businesses to provisions benefiting small businesses. 
    Id. The Commission believes that these measures have allowed small 
    businesses, including those owned by women and minorities, to overcome 
    barriers that have impeded these groups' participation in the 
    telecommunications arena, including barriers related to access to 
    capital. The Commission continues to encourage the participation of a 
    variety of entrepreneurs in the provision of wireless services, 
    believing that innovation by small businesses will result in a 
    diversity of service offerings that will increase customer choice and 
    promote competition. Additionally, the Commission has initiated a 
    proceeding to consider other ways to improve the access of small 
    businesses, minority- and women-owned firms to the telecommunications 
    markets. See Section 257 Proceeding to Identify and Eliminate Market 
    Entry Barriers for Small Businesses, Report, GN Docket No. 96-113, FCC 
    97-164, 62 FR 34648 (June 27, 1997). The Commission recently issued a 
    report pursuant to this proceeding which discusses the numerous 
    measures the Commission has implemented to benefit small businesses, 
    such as the use of service-specific definitions of small businesses, 
    the outreach efforts by the FCC Office of Public Affairs and Office of 
    Communications Business Opportunities, and the establishment of the 
    Telecommunications Development Fund (TDF). The Commission also is 
    commencing a comprehensive study to further examine the role of small 
    businesses and businesses owned by minorities or women in the 
    telecommunications industry and the impact of our policies on access to 
    the industry for such businesses. This study will assist the Commission 
    in determining whether there are constitutionally-sound bases for 
    adopting licensing provisions to promote opportunities for women and 
    minorities.
        The Commission's experience in conducting auctions has demonstrated 
    that small businesses, as well as minority- and women-owned businesses, 
    have benefited from its competitive bidding procedures. Of the over 
    4,300 licenses awarded thus far by auctions, 54 percent were awarded to 
    small businesses; 11 percent to minority-owned businesses; 11 percent 
    to women-owned businesses; 10 percent to women-owned small businesses; 
    4 percent to minority women-owned businesses; and 5 percent to rural 
    telephone companies. (Note that a licensee may fall into more than one 
    category.)
        The Commission requests that commenters assess the provisions the 
    Commission has adopted to meet its statutory directive. Specifically, 
    the Commission asks:
         How have the Commission's ownership policies (e.g., 
    attribution rules and spectrum caps), eligibility restrictions (e.g., 
    entrepreneurs' blocks) and favorable payment terms (e.g., bidding 
    credits, reduced upfront and down payments, and installment payment 
    plans) affected the ability of small businesses, rural telephone 
    companies and businesses owned by women and members of minority groups 
    (``designated entities'') to participate successfully in the 
    competitive bidding process? In particular, have these provisions 
    provided significant opportunities for rural telephone companies?
         What specific financial incentives have been beneficial to 
    small businesses? Should these provisions be altered in any manner? 
    What, if any, policies could the Commission adopt to guard against 
    defaults by bidders and licensees? Are installment payment plans 
    essential to attracting new entrants to participate in the auctions? Do 
    the problems presented by the administration of such plans and by the 
    potential for licensee default detract from the efficient award of 
    licenses?
         What should be the Commission's role in the management of 
    the Commission's installment loan portfolio? Should post-licensing 
    issues relating to the satisfaction of installment obligations be 
    transferred to another government agency with the appropriate 
    expertise?
         Have designated entity provisions and other rules (e.g., 
    spectrum caps) served the statutory objective of wide dissemination of 
    licenses?
         Following the Supreme Court's decision in Adarand, the 
    Commission revised its auction rules to make them race- and gender-
    neutral. What has been the impact of this on the opportunities of 
    businesses owned by women and minorities to participate in the 
    provision of spectrum-based services?
    
    III. Recommendation of any Policy and Statutory Changes
    
        The Commission also invites commenters to recommend specific 
    actions the Commission should take to improve the competitive bidding 
    rules and procedures in order to fulfill the objectives of Section 
    309(j). The Commission notes that it is currently considering proposals 
    to revise and improve the general competitive bidding rules and 
    procedures contained in subpart Q of part 1 of the
    
    [[Page 36756]]
    
    Commission's Rules. See part 1 NPRM. Commenters are further requested 
    to offer recommendations on any statutory or procedural changes that 
    would improve the licensing processes following an auction.
    
    IV. Procedural Matters
    
        Comments must be submitted by August 1, 1997. All comments should 
    be filed with the Acting Secretary, Federal Communications Commission, 
    1919 M Street, N.W., Washington, D.C. 20554. Copies must be provided to 
    Kathleen O'Brien Ham, Chief, Auctions Division, Wireless 
    Telecommunications Bureau, Federal Communications Commission, 2025 M 
    Street, N.W., Room 5322, Washington, D.C. 20554. Comments should 
    reference Docket No. WT 97-150.
        Copies of the comments may be obtained from the Commission's 
    duplicating contractor: International Transcription Service, Inc., 2100 
    M Street, N.W., Suite 140, Washington, D.C. 20037, (202) 857-3500. 
    Copies will also be available for public inspection during regular 
    business hours in the FCC Reference Center, Room 239, 1919 M Street, 
    N.W., Washington, D.C.
        For further information, please contact Mark Bollinger or Alice 
    Elder, Auctions Division, Wireless Telecommunications Bureau, Federal 
    Communications Commission at (202) 418-0660.
    
    Federal Communications Commission.
    William F. Caton,
    Acting Secretary.
    [FR Doc. 97-17869 Filed 7-8-97; 8:45 am]
    BILLING CODE 6712-01-P
    
    
    

Document Information

Published:
07/09/1997
Department:
Federal Communications Commission
Entry Type:
Proposed Rule
Action:
Request for comments.
Document Number:
97-17869
Dates:
Comments are due on or before August 1, 1997.
Pages:
36752-36756 (5 pages)
Docket Numbers:
WT Docket No. 97-150, FCC 97-232
PDF File:
97-17869.pdf