96-19592. Waterous Company, Inc.; Proposed Consent Agreement With Analysis To Aid Public Comment  

  • [Federal Register Volume 61, Number 149 (Thursday, August 1, 1996)]
    [Notices]
    [Pages 40229-40234]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 96-19592]
    
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION
    [File No. 901-0061]
    
    
    Waterous Company, Inc.; Proposed Consent Agreement With Analysis 
    To Aid Public Comment
    
    AGENCY: Federal Trade Commission.
    
    ACTION: Proposed consent agreement.
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    SUMMARY: In settlement of alleged violations of federal law prohibiting 
    unfair or deceptive acts or practices and unfair methods of 
    competition, this consent agreement, accepted subject to final 
    Commission approval, would prohibit, among other things, the St. Paul-
    based manufacturer of fire pumps for fire trucks from entering into, 
    continuing, or enforcing any requirement that fire truck manufacturers 
    refrain from purchasing mid-ship mounted fire pumps from any company, 
    or that they purchase or sell only Waterous's pumps. The consent 
    agreement settles allegations that Waterous and Hale Products, Inc., 
    which together account for 90 percent of the market, sold their pumps 
    on an exclusive basis to fire truck manufacturers and that this 
    arrangement allowed the two companies to allocate the customers each 
    would serve and made it more difficult for other pump makers to enter 
    the market.
    
    DATES: Comments must be received on or before September 30, 1996.
    
    ADDRESSES: Comments should be directed to: FTC/Office of the Secretary, 
    Room 159, 6th St. and Pa. Ave., N.W., Washington, D.C. 20580.
    
    FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: William Baer, Federal Trade 
    Commission, 6th and Pennsylvania Avenue, NW, H-374, Washington, DC 
    20850. (202) 326-2932. Mark Whitener, Federal Trade Commission, 6th and 
    Pennsylvania Avenue, NW, H-374, Washington, DC 20850. (202) 326-2845.
    
    SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: Pursuant to Section 6(f) of the Federal 
    Trade Commission Act, 38 Stat. 721, 15 U.S.C. 46 and section 2.34 of 
    the Commission's Rules of Practice (16 CFR 2.34), notice is hereby 
    given that the following consent agreement containing a consent order 
    to cease and desist, having been filed with and accepted, subject to 
    final approval, by the Commission, has been placed on the public record 
    for a period of sixty (60) days. Public comment is
    
    [[Page 40230]]
    
    invited. Such comments or views will be considered by the Commission 
    and will be available for inspection and copying at its principal 
    office in accordance with section 4.9(b) (6) (ii) of the Commission's 
    Rules of Practice (16 CFR 4.9(b) (6) (ii)).
    
    Agreement Containing Consent Order To Cease and Desist
    
        The Federal Trade Commission (``Commission'') having initiated an 
    investigation of certain acts and practices of Waterous Company, Inc., 
    (sometimes referred to as ``Proposed Respondent'' or ``Waterous''), and 
    it now appearing that Proposed Respondent is willing to enter into an 
    Agreement containing an Order to Cease and Desist from the use of the 
    acts and practices being investigated,
        It is hereby agreed by and between Proposed Respondent, by its duly 
    authorized officers, and their attorneys, and counsel for the 
    Commission that:
        1. Proposed Respondent Waterous Company, Inc., is a corporation 
    organized, existing, and doing business under and by virtue of the laws 
    of the State of Minnesota. Its principal place of business is 300 John 
    E. Carroll Avenue East, South Saint Paul, Minnesota 55075.
        2. Proposed Respondent admits all the jurisdictional facts set 
    forth in the draft of complaint.
        3. Proposed Respondent waives:
        (a) Any further procedural steps;
        (b) The requirement that the Commission's decision contain a 
    statement of findings of fact and conclusions of law;
        (c) All rights to seek judicial review or otherwise to challenge or 
    contest the validity of the order entered pursuant to this agreement; 
    and
        (d) Any claim under the Equal Access to Justice Act.
        4. This agreement shall not become part of the public record of the 
    proceeding unless and until it is accepted by the Commission. If this 
    agreement is accepted by the Commission it, together with the draft of 
    complaint contemplated thereby, will be placed on the public record for 
    a period of sixty (60) days and information in respect thereto publicly 
    released. The Commission thereafter may either withdraw its acceptance 
    of this agreement and so notify the Proposed Respondent, in which event 
    it will take such action as it may consider appropriate, or issue and 
    serve its complaint (in such form as the circumstances may require) and 
    decision, in disposition of the proceeding.
        5. This agreement is for settlement purposes only and does not 
    constitute an admission by Proposed Respondent that the law has been 
    violated as alleged in the draft of complaint, or that the facts as 
    alleged in the draft complaint, other than jurisdictional facts, are 
    true.
        6. This agreement contemplates that, if it is accepted by the 
    Commission, and if such acceptance is not subsequently withdrawn by the 
    Commission pursuant to the provisions of Sec. 2.34 of the Commission's 
    Rules, the Commission may, without further notice to Proposed 
    Respondent, (1) issue its complaint corresponding in form and substance 
    with the draft of complaint and its decision containing the following 
    order to cease and desist in disposition of the proceeding and (2) make 
    information public in respect thereto. When so entered, the order to 
    cease and desist shall have the same force and effect and may be 
    altered, modified or set aside in the same manner and within the same 
    time provided by statute for other orders. The order shall become final 
    upon service. Delivery by the U.S. Postal Service of the complaint and 
    decision containing the agreed-to order to Proposed Respondent's 
    addresses as stated in this agreement shall constitute service. 
    Proposed Respondent waives any right it may have to any other manner of 
    service. The complaint may be used in construing the terms of the 
    order, and no agreement, understanding, representation or 
    interpretation not contained in the order or the agreement may be used 
    to vary or contradict the terms of the order.
        7. Proposed Respondent has read the proposed complaint and order 
    contemplated hereby. Proposed Respondent understands that once the 
    order has been issued, it will be required to file one or more 
    compliance reports showing that it has fully complied with the order. 
    Proposed Respondent further understands that it may be liable for civil 
    penalties in the amount provided by law for each violation of the order 
    after it becomes final.
    
    Order
    
    I
    
        It Is Ordered that, as used in this Order, the following 
    definitions shall apply:
        (a) ``Respondent Waterous'' means (1) Waterous Company, Inc.; (2) 
    its predecessors, subsidiaries, divisions, and groups and affiliates 
    controlled by Waterous Company, Inc., and their successors and assigns; 
    (3) all companies or entities that any parent of Waterous Company, 
    Inc., creates in the future and that engage in the manufacture or sale 
    of Mid-Ship Mounted Fire Pumps, or Waterous' parent if it engages in 
    the manufacture or sale of Mid-Ship Mounted Fire Pumps; (4) the 
    respective directors, officers, employees, agents and representatives 
    of any of the entities described in subparagraphs (1), (2) and (3) 
    above.
        (b) ``Mid-Ship Mounted Fire Pumps'' are truck mounted fire pumps 
    that meet the National Fire Protection Association Standard for Pumper 
    Fire Apparatus known as ``NFPA 1901.''
        (c) ``Commission'' means the Federal Trade Commission.
        (d) ``OEM's'' are original equipment manufacturers who buy and 
    install Mid- Ship Mounted Fire Pumps, as well as many other components, 
    into a final fire truck. OEM's then sell the trucks to fire departments 
    in the United States.
    
    II
    
        It Is Further Ordered that Respondent Waterous, directly or through 
    any corporation, subsidiary, division, or other device, including 
    franchisees or licensees, in connection with the offering for sale or 
    sale of any Mid-Ship Mounted Fire Pump in or affecting commerce, as 
    ``commerce'' is defined in the Federal Trade Commission Act, does 
    forthwith cease and desist from entering into, continuing, or enforcing 
    any condition, agreement or understanding with any OEM that such OEM 
    will refrain from the purchase or sale of Mid-Ship Mounted Fire Pumps 
    of any manufacturer, or will purchase or sell Mid-Ship Mounted Fire 
    Pumps of only Respondent Waterous; provided however, that nothing in 
    this Order shall prohibit any price differentials that make only due 
    allowance for differences in the cost of manufacture, sale, or delivery 
    resulting from the differing methods or quantities in which Mid-Ship 
    Mounted Fire Pumps are sold or delivered, or that are otherwise lawful 
    under the provisions of the Robinson-Patman Act, 15 U.S.C. Sec. 13.
    
    III
    
        It Is Further Ordered that Respondent Waterous shall provide a copy 
    of this Order with the complaint, and a copy of the notice set out in 
    Appendix A:
        (a) within thirty (30) days after the date this Order becomes 
    final, one notice to each OEM to whom it sold a Mid-Ship Mounted Fire 
    Pump at any time during the two (2) years prior to the date this order 
    becomes final; and
        (b) for a period of three (3) years after the date this Order 
    becomes final, to each OEM not covered by sub-paragraph (a) above to 
    whom it provides a price
    
    [[Page 40231]]
    
    list for or a price quotation on a Mid-Ship Mounted Fire Pump. Such 
    notice shall accompany the price list or price quotation, or in the 
    case of telephone quotations shall be delivered as soon as practical 
    after such quotation, and need only be provided once to each OEM not 
    covered by sub-paragraph (a) above.
    
    IV
    
        It Is Further Ordered that Respondent Waterous shall file with the 
    Commission within sixty (60) days after the date this order becomes 
    final, and annually on the anniversary of the date this order becomes 
    final for each of the three (3) years thereafter, a report, in writing, 
    signed by the Respondent, setting forth in detail the manner and form 
    in which it has complied and is complying with this order.
    
    V
    
        It Is Further Ordered that Respondent shall notify the Commission 
    at least thirty (30) days prior to any proposed change in the corporate 
    respondent, such as dissolution, assignment or sale resulting in the 
    emergence of a successor corporation, or the creation or dissolution of 
    subsidiaries or any other change in the corporation that may affect 
    compliance obligations arising out of this order. Such notification 
    shall be at least thirty (30) days in cases not subject to the 
    notification provisions of the Hart-Scott-Rodino Antitrust Improvements 
    Act of 1976, 15 U.S.C. Sec. 18a, and at least ten (10) days in the case 
    of transactions subject to the notification provisions of the Hart-
    Scott-Rodino Act.
    
    VI
    
        It Is Further Ordered that this order shall terminate twenty (20) 
    years from the date this order becomes final.
    
    Appendix A
    
    [Waterous' Letterhead]
    PLEASE READ THIS
        Enclosed with this notice is a copy of a Consent Order agreed to 
    between the Federal Trade Commission and Waterous Company, Inc. In the 
    Order, Waterous has agreed that it will not refuse to sell, or refuse 
    to contract to sell, Mid-Ship Mounted Fire Pumps on the grounds that an 
    OEM refuses to sell Waterous pumps exclusively. The Order does not 
    prohibit OEMs from purchasing only Waterous Mid-Ship Mounted Fire Pumps 
    if, in the OEM's sole discretion, it deems it advisable. Moreover, 
    Waterous retains the right to refuse to sell Mid-Ship Mounted Fire 
    Pumps to any OEM for lawful reasons. THE TYPE OF PUMP YOU USE IS YOUR 
    BUSINESS, AND YOU ARE FREE TO OFFER AND INSTALL COMPETING PUMPS AS 
    ALTERNATIVES TO WATEROUS PUMPS.
    
    Analysis of Proposed Consent Order To Aid Public Comment
    
        The Federal Trade Commission has accepted an agreement to a 
    proposed consent order, subject to final approval, from Waterous 
    Company, Inc.
        The proposed consent order has been placed on the public record for 
    sixty (60) days for reception of comments by interested persons. 
    Comments received during this period will become part of the public 
    record. After sixty (60) days, the Commission will decide whether it 
    should withdraw from the agreement or make final the agreement's 
    proposed order.
    
    The Complaint
    
        The complaint prepared for issuance along with the proposed order 
    alleges that the proposed respondent violated Section 5 of the Federal 
    Trade Commission Act by maintaining exclusive dealing arrangements with 
    its customers--manufacturers of municipal fire trucks.
        The complaint alleges that respondent Waterous and Hale Products 
    are the two largest manufacturers of mid-ship mounted fire pumps 
    (``fire pumps'') sold in the United States. Together, respondent 
    Waterous and Hale Products account for close to or more than ninety 
    (90) percent of the fire pump market in the United States. Except to 
    the extent that competition has been restrained as alleged in the 
    complaint, respondent Waterous and Hale Products have been and are now 
    in competition among themselves and with other fire pump manufacturers 
    in the United States.
        The complaint alleges that, for over fifty (50) years and until 
    approximately 1991, both respondent Waterous and Hale Products 
    maintained exclusive dealing arrangements. Each sold fire pumps to its 
    customers on the condition or understanding that such customers would 
    deal in its pumps exclusively, or that such customers would refrain 
    from buying and selling pumps made by the other. The complaint, and a 
    companion complaint against Hale Products, further allege that both 
    companies believed that continued exclusive dealing by the two 
    companies would tend to exclude competitors from the market, and that 
    continued exclusive dealing, if maintained by both companies, would 
    tend to reduce competition between them over price and over non-price 
    terms, such as quality differences and delivery times. Consequently, 
    both continued to maintain and to enforce exclusive dealing policies.
        The complaint alleges that, under these circumstances, respondent's 
    exclusive dealing agreements violated Section 5 of the Federal Trade 
    Commission Act. Specifically, the complaint alleges that exclusive 
    dealing substantially reduced competition in the sale and marketing of 
    fire pumps by facilitating an allocation of customers between 
    respondent Waterous and Hale Products, and by excluding or tending to 
    exclude other actual or potential manufacturers of fire pumps from the 
    market. Facilitating coordinated interaction, and raising entry 
    barriers that exclude competition, are two ways that exclusive dealing 
    restraints can be anticompetitive. See Beltone Electronics Corp., 100 
    F.T.C. 68, 207 (1982).
    
    The Proposed Consent Order
    
        The proposed consent order would prohibit respondent Waterous from 
    entering into, continuing, or enforcing any condition, agreement, or 
    understanding with any fire truck manufacturer that such manufacturer 
    will refrain from the purchase or sale of any other manufacturer's fire 
    pumps. The proposed order, however, would allow certain lawful 
    discounts such as volume discounts that do not run afoul of the 
    provisions of the Robinson-Patman Act.
        The proposed consent order would also require respondent Waterous 
    to notify its customers of the terms of the order. Specifically, the 
    proposed consent would require respondent Waterous to send a copy of 
    the order to each fire truck manufacturer it sold a pump to during the 
    two (2) years prior to the entry of the order; for three (3) years 
    after the order is entered, respondent Waterous must send a copy of the 
    order to each new customer to whom it provides a price list or a price 
    quotation. The order would also requre notification to such customers 
    that respondent will not restrict the brand of pumps they may use.
        The proposed consent order would also require respondent Waterous 
    to file with the Commission compliance reports setting forth the manner 
    in which it has complied and is complying with the terms of the order. 
    Such reports are due within sixty (60) days after the order becomes 
    final, and for three (3) years annually on the anniversary of the date 
    the order becomes final. Respondent Waterous must also notify the 
    Commission at least thirty (30) days prior to any proposed change in 
    the corporate respondent, such as dissolution, assignment, or sale 
    resulting in the emergence of a
    
    [[Page 40232]]
    
    successor corporation. In cases subject to the provisions of the Hart-
    Scott-Rodino Act, however, such prior notification may be made at least 
    ten (10) days prior to the proposed change. Finally, the proposed 
    consent provides that the order will terminate automatically twenty 
    (20) years after the date it becomes final.
        The purpose of this analysis is to facilitate public comment on the 
    proposed order, and it is not intended to constitute an official 
    interpretation of the agreement and proposed order or to modify in any 
    way their terms.
    Donald S. Clark,
    Secretary.
    
    Separate Statement of Chairman Pitofsky, and Commissioners Varney and 
    Steiger
    
        In the Matter of Waterous Company, Inc./Hale Products, Inc., 
    File No. 901-0061
    
        We write separately to respond to some of the concerns raised in 
    Commissioner Starek's dissent.
        First, we cannot concur with Commissioner Starek's suggestion that, 
    for customer allocation of a component product to work, the 
    participants must be able to allocate the ultimate customers of the 
    finished product (p.1). There will be situations where downstream 
    competition will undermine a customer allocation scheme of a component 
    of a final good. For example, that might be the case where the 
    component is a significant part of the cost of the final product, or 
    where the ultimate consumers have a much stronger preference for the 
    component than the ultimate good.
        None of those conditions was present in this case. Fire truck 
    buyers make purchase decisions primarily on the basis of truck brand, 
    the pump price is only a small part of the final purchase price, and 
    pump features are only a small part of the entire truck package. 
    Evidence of relatively high profits at the component level supports 
    this interpretation.
        Second, Commissioner Starek suggests that these exclusive dealing 
    arrangements would not increase the likelihood of successful collusion 
    because of the difficulty of detecting cheating. (p.2) We agree that 
    maintaining collusion requires the ability to detect and discipline 
    cheating. But here that methodology was simple: if a fire engine 
    manufacturer used an alternative pump it would be readily identified. 
    Moreover, the fact that the customer allocation through exclusive 
    dealing was maintained over almost five decades suggests that there was 
    an effective method for enforcing the exclusive dealing arrangements.
        Third, Commissioner Starek observes that instability at the truck 
    manufacturing stage (i.e., changes in market share) may lead to the 
    demise of any customer allocation agreement with respect to a 
    component. We agree that might be the case where a very large portion 
    of a pump manufacturer's sales were tied to a single truck 
    manufacturer. Here, however, the arrangements were durable; the fact is 
    that instability among truck manufacturers did not deter the 
    effectiveness of these agreements.
        Finally, Commissioner Starek suggests that the arrangements did not 
    foreclose new entry because they were not really exclusive. He relies 
    on the fact that some OEMs were willing to install the pumps of a third 
    manufacturer at customers' request. (p. 3) The fact that the exclusive 
    policy was not perfect and that some truck manufacturers may have 
    offered the pumps of a third pump manufacturer, accounting for a very 
    small share of pump sales, did not have a significant effect on 
    competition at the pump level. The key to competition in this market 
    was the competitive positions of Hale and Waterous, which together 
    account for more than 90% of the market. The evidence establishes that 
    Hale and Waterous understood that as long as both firms maintained the 
    exclusive dealing arrangements, competition between them would be 
    diminished, prices would be higher and entry would be more difficult. 
    That is in fact how things worked in this industry for several decades, 
    and those are the anticompetitive effects that the Commission's orders 
    are intended to address.
    
    Dissenting Statement of Commissioner Mary L. Azcuenaga
    
        In the matter of Waterous Company, Inc./Hale Products, Inc. File 
    No. 901-0061.
    
        I generally endorse the views expressed by Commissioner Starek in 
    his dissenting statement. The evidence does not in my view suggest a 
    market in which competition has been unlawfully restrained, and I do 
    not find reason to believe that the law has been violated.
    
    Dissenting Statement of Commissioner Roscoe B. Starek, III
    
        In the matter of Waterous Company, Inc./Hale Products, Inc. File 
    No. 901 0061.
    
        I respectfully dissent from the Commission's decision to accept 
    consent agreements with Waterous Company, Inc., and Hale Products, 
    Inc., two producers of midship-mounted pumps for fire trucks. The 
    proposed complaints claim anticompetitive effects arising from alleged 
    exclusive dealing arrangements between each proposed respondent and its 
    direct customers, the original equipment manufacturers of fire trucks 
    (``OEMs''), in violation of Section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission 
    Act, 15 U.S.C. Sec. 45. I am unpersuaded that the arrangements between 
    proposed respondents and their customers can be characterized 
    accurately as ``exclusive.'' More important, however, there is no sound 
    theoretical or empirical basis for believing that these relationships, 
    even if exclusive, harmed competition; in fact, there are good reasons 
    to believe the contrary. In any event, even if one assumes arguendo the 
    validity of the theories of anticompetitive effects, the proposed 
    orders are unlikely to remedy those alleged effects.
        The complaints allege, inter alia, that the arrangements between 
    Waterous, Hale, and their OEM customers reduce competition in two 
    ways--by facilitating an allocation of customers between Waterous and 
    Hale, and by creating a barrier to the entry of new pump manufacturers. 
    The first theory posits that Waterous and Hale wish to set the prices 
    of their fire pumps collusively but find themselves unable to reach and 
    maintain a direct agreement on price. Under this hypothesis, in order 
    to achieve collusive pricing without a direct agreement on prices, 
    Waterous and Hale have entered into a de facto agreement to allocate 
    fire truck OEMs between themselves. That agreement, combined with an 
    agreement not to bid for each other's OEM business, makes each pump 
    maker a monopolist with respect to its OEMs. As monopolists, it is 
    argued, the pump manufacturers are able to set supracompetitive prices.
        This theory is fatally flawed. For a customer allocation scheme to 
    allow Waterous and Hale to set supracompetitive prices, it necessarily 
    must entail the allocation of the final customers--the fire 
    departments--between the two pump makers. Absent such an allocation, an 
    exclusive dealing contract between a pump maker and one or more OEMs--
    or even outright vertical integration between the pump producer and one 
    or more OEMs--does not allow the pump producer to raise prices 
    anticompetitively. Under the Commission's theory of competitive harm, 
    Waterous and Hale ``allocate customers'' in lieu of trying to enter 
    into direct pump price agreements that presumably would break down 
    under each party's incentives to undercut the collusive price. In other 
    words, the pump makers'' ``customer allocation''
    
    [[Page 40233]]
    
    scheme solves this instability problem. However, unless Waterous and 
    Hale also agree not to compete against one another for the patronage of 
    the fire departments--i.e., unless they collusively allocate fire 
    departments between themselves--each pump maker retains its incentive 
    to take business from its rival through price cuts. Absent allocation 
    of fire department customers, one should expect the same sort of 
    ``cheating,'' with the equivalent competitive result, that the 
    Commission believes frustrated direct collusion between Waterous and 
    Hale.1
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
         1  The majority's assertion that pump prices and pump brands 
    are relatively unimportant to final consumers (i.e., fire 
    departments) is inconsistent with the events that triggered this 
    investigation--namely, complaints from OEMs that they suffered 
    significant competitive harm from their alleged inability to offer 
    multiple pump brands. It is hard to reconcile those complaints with 
    the majority's claimed end-user indifference to pump brands.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Thus, it is implausible that ``exclusive dealing'' arrangements 
    between the proposed respondents and their OEMs increase the likelihood 
    of successful collusion between Waterous and Hale. Indeed, there are 
    compelling reasons why such an arrangement might actually reduce this 
    likelihood. Maintaining collusion requires the reasonably accurate 
    identification and punishment of cheating.2 If Waterous and Hale 
    bid directly and repeatedly for OEM business, cheating might be 
    inferable from one firm's loss of a pump sale to its rival. On the 
    other hand, when Waterous and Hale compete indirectly--i.e., when, as 
    here, their affiliated OEMs submit bids to a fire department 
    incorporating not merely the pump price but rather the prices of all of 
    the truck's components--it will be more difficult for a pump maker to 
    determine whether a loss of business is attributable to price-cutting 
    by the rival pump maker or to reductions in the prices of other 
    components.3
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
         2  See, e.g., Stigler, ``A Theory of Oligopoly,'' 72 J. Pol. 
    Econ. 44 (1964), reprinted in THE ORGANIZATION OF INDUSTRY, ch. 5 
    (1968).
         3  The majority appears to have misunderstood my point 
    with regard to the detection of cheating. By ``cheating,'' I am not 
    referring to an effort by, say, Hale to sell to Waterous OEMs (or 
    vice-versa). Rather, I refer to Hale's hidden reduction in pump 
    prices to its own customers, which consequently allows those 
    customers to take business from OEMs affiliated with the rival pump 
    brand. This form of cheating is extremely difficult to detect, 
    because an OEM's capture of sales from a rival OEM could be 
    attributable to many reasons other than a reduced pump price.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The difficulty of maintaining coordination is exacerbated if there 
    is substantial market share volatility among the affiliated customers 
    for reasons unrelated to the pumps. Such volatility makes it difficult 
    for a pump maker to infer whether a sales loss stems from secret pump 
    price concessions or from some other cause. Moreover, if the fortunes 
    of buyers (here, fire truck OEMs) are expected to differ over time--
    some flagging, others flourishing--the utility of customer allocation 
    as a long-run aid to collusion appears questionable. The pump producer 
    with the misfortune to have affiliated with unsuccessful buyers will 
    have still greater incentives to depart from the collusive scheme. In 
    this regard, the fire truck OEM market witnessed substantial turnover 
    during the period in which the allegedly exclusive agreements were in 
    force.4 Thus, even if one could overcome the defect in the 
    Commission's collusive theory, these other factors would continue to 
    cast substantial doubt upon this theory's applicability.5
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
         4 For example, just since 1990, at least four major OEMs--
    Grumman, Mack, FMC, and Beck--have exited the market. This period 
    also witnessed entry by such OEMs as Firewolf and Becker. As 
    discussed below, substantial entry into and exit from the OEM market 
    also bear on the applicability of the proposed complaints' second 
    theory of competitive harm (entry deterrence).
         5 With regard to the pump makers' ostensibly high 
    accounting profits, antitrust economists no longer consider 
    accounting profits as a reliable indicator of high economic profits 
    (which can themselves be as consistent with superior efficiency as 
    with collusion). Fisher and McGowan, ``On the Misuse of Accounting 
    Rates of Return to Infer Monopoly Profits,'' 73 Am. Econ. Rev. 82 
    (1983). Moreover, concerning the longevity of the arrangements 
    between pump makers and OEMs, that factor testifies only to their 
    profitability; it does not distinguish between anticompetitive and 
    procompetitive (or competitively neutral) explanations for their 
    use. Indeed, the asserted instability of OEMs' market shares lends 
    greater credence to an efficiency explanation: one would not expect 
    the parties to an efficient exclusive dealing arrangement to abandon 
    it simply because a customer loses market share, while (as I have 
    explained above) the same cannot be said of an anticompetitive 
    arrangement.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission's second theory of harm alleges that exclusive 
    arrangements between pump makers and OEMs have created a barrier to the 
    entry of new pump manufacturers, thereby allowing the incumbent pump 
    sellers to set and maintain supracompetitive prices. Although the 
    vertical section of the 1984 Merger Guidelines 6 is not cited 
    explicitly, the theory here appears to have been drawn from those 
    Guidelines. That analysis focuses on a market in which, but for ease of 
    entry, conditions are favorable to the exercise of market power, and 
    asks whether a vertical merger (or, in the current case, vertical 
    integration through contract) might reduce entry so that market power 
    could be exercised.7
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \6\ U.S. Department of Justice, Merger Guidelines, Sec. 4.2 
    (1984), 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) para. 13,103.
        \7\ The 1984 Merger Guidelines (Sec. 4.21) identify three 
    necessary but not sufficient conditions for this problem to exist. 
    First, the market in which power would be exercised (the ``primary'' 
    market) must be sufficiently conducive to anticompetitive behavior 
    that the impact of vertical integration in reducing entry would 
    allow such behavior to occur. Second, the degree of vertical 
    integration subsequent to the merger must be so extensive that an 
    entrant into the primary market would also have to enter the other 
    market (the ``secondary'' market). If substantial unintegrated 
    capacity remains in the secondary market after the vertical merger, 
    it is less likely that the merger will facilitate an anticompetitive 
    outcome. Third, the requirement that a firm enter both the primary 
    and secondary markets--rather than just the primary market--must 
    make entry into the primary market significantly more difficult and 
    therefore less likely to occur. 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) para. 13,103 
    at 20,565-66; see also Blair and Kaserman, LAW AND ECONOMICS OF 
    VERTICAL INTEGRATION AND CONTROL 152 (1983).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Although this effect might occur in some settings, in this case I 
    find the evidence to support invoking this theory tenuous at best. The 
    Commission's complaints apparently rest on the difficulty allegedly 
    experienced by another pump maker in obtaining the patronage of 
    OEMs.8 An alternative explanation for that firm's failure to 
    achieve a larger market share is that fire departments find its pumps 
    significantly less attractive than those of Hale and Waterous for 
    reasons unrelated to the pump makers' distribution policies. The 
    evidence adduced by the staff is far from sufficient to establish that 
    this firm, or any other actual or potential competitor, was 
    anticompetitively excluded from selling pumps to OEMs.9
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \8\ The evidence supporting the Commission's entry-deterrence 
    theory appears to consist of that producer's experience in trying to 
    erode OEMs' preferences for Waterous and Hale pumps.
        \9\ The majority's assertion with respect to the entry-deterring 
    effects of the arrangements is simply that--an assertion. All of the 
    evidence gathered in this investigation is easily reconciled with an 
    efficiency rationale for the challenged arrangements between pump 
    makers and OEMs. In this market, as in any other, superior 
    efficiency on the part of incumbents is a powerful entry deterrent. 
    It is not an antitrust violation.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In addition to the weaknesses in the anticompetitive theories 
    outlined above, a factual problem plagues this case: evidence gathered 
    in the investigation calls into question whether Waterous's and Hale's 
    relationships with their respective OEM customers can even be 
    characterized as ``exclusive.'' Although many OEMs have tended to deal 
    principally with only one pump maker--a fact, I note in passing, that 
    is as consistent with an efficiency rationale for exclusivity as it is 
    with an anticompetitive theory--several larger OEMs affiliated with 
    Waterous and Hale have expressed a willingness to install another 
    manufacturer's pumps at customers' request. Indeed, several OEMs--
    including at least one of the largest ones affiliated with Hale--have 
    installed another competitor's pumps, and this investigation produced 
    no
    
    [[Page 40234]]
    
    evidence to suggest that any dealer was terminated for selling that 
    firm's pumps. In any case, however, even if OEM exclusivity could be 
    convincingly demonstrated, it should be clear from the discussion above 
    that a great deal more is required to prove that the exclusive 
    arrangements had anticompetitive effects.10 The evidence on the 
    competitive effects of existing arrangements between pump makers and 
    OEMs is as consistent with the view that the arrangements induce 
    greater efficiency in the production and marketing of pumps as it is 
    with a market power theory.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
         10  Cf. Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 
    U.S. 36, 58-59 (1977) (plaintiff must demonstrate anticompetitive 
    effects and defendant's market power when challenging vertical 
    restraints).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        I am therefore unpersuaded that respondents' distribution policies 
    have harmed competition in any relevant market. Even had I concluded 
    otherwise, however, I would not endorse the proposed consent orders, 
    which require each respondent to cease and desist from requiring OEM 
    exclusivity as a condition of sale. As I have noted elsewhere,11 
    the problems with remedies of this sort are significant.12 A 
    formal ban on exclusive dealing accomplishes little if respondents have 
    alternative means available to achieve the same end. One readily 
    available method in this case, fully consistent with the terms of the 
    proposed orders, would be to establish a set of quantity discounts 
    providing a customer with substantial financial incentives to procure 
    all of its pumps from a single seller. Moreover, nothing in the orders 
    would prevent a pump manufacturer from unilaterally refusing to sell to 
    an OEM so long as the refusal was not conditioned on a promise of 
    exclusivity. Another possible method would be to give exclusive OEMs 
    better service (e.g., faster delivery times) than their non-exclusive 
    rivals receive.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \11\ Dissenting Statement of Commissioner Roscoe B. Starek, III, 
    in Silicon Graphics, Inc., Docket No. C-3626.
        \12\ For a discussion of why nondiscrimination remedies are 
    problematic, see Brennan, ``Why regulated firms should be kept out 
    of unregulated markets: understanding the divestiture in United 
    States v. AT&T,'' 32 Antitrust Bull. 741 (1987).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        I cannot endorse an ineffective remedy for a nonexistent harm.
    
    [FR Doc. 96-19592 Filed 7-31-96; 8:45 am]
    BILLING CODE 6750-01-P
    
    
    

Document Information

Published:
08/01/1996
Department:
Federal Trade Commission
Entry Type:
Notice
Action:
Proposed consent agreement.
Document Number:
96-19592
Dates:
Comments must be received on or before September 30, 1996.
Pages:
40229-40234 (6 pages)
Docket Numbers:
File No. 901-0061
PDF File:
96-19592.pdf