98-20998. Regulation of Short-Term Natural Gas Transportation Services  

  • [Federal Register Volume 63, Number 154 (Tuesday, August 11, 1998)]
    [Proposed Rules]
    [Pages 42982-43023]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 98-20998]
    
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
    
    Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
    
    18 CFR Parts 161, 250, and 284
    
    [Docket No. RM98-10-000]
    
    
    Regulation of Short-Term Natural Gas Transportation Services
    
    July 29, 1998.
    AGENCY: Federal Energy Regulatory Commission.
    
    ACTION: Notice of proposed rulemaking.
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    SUMMARY: The Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (Commission) is 
    proposing an integrated package of revisions to its regulations 
    governing interstate natural gas pipelines to reflect the changes in 
    the market for short-term transportation services on pipelines. Under 
    the proposed approach, cost-based regulation would be eliminated for 
    short-term transportation and replaced by regulatory policies intended 
    to maximize competition in the short-term transportation market, 
    mitigate the ability of firms to exercise residual monopoly power, and 
    provide opportunities for greater flexibility in the provision of 
    pipeline services. The proposed changes include initiatives to revise 
    pipeline scheduling procedures, receipt and delivery point policies, 
    and penalty policies, to require pipelines to auction short-term 
    capacity, to improve the Commission's reporting requirements, to permit 
    pipelines to negotiate rates and terms of services, and to revise 
    certain rate and certificate policies that affect competition.
    
    DATES: Comments are due November 9, 1998.
    
    
    [[Page 42983]]
    
    
    ADDRESSES: Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street, NE, 
    Washington DC, 20426.
    
    FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
    
    Michael Goldenberg, Office of the General Counsel, Federal Energy 
    Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street, NE, Washington, DC 20426. 
    (202) 208-2294
    Erica Yanoff, Office of the General Counsel, Federal Energy Regulatory 
    Commission, 888 First Street, NE, Washington, DC 20426. (202) 208-0708
    Ingrid Olson, Office of the General Counsel, Federal Energy Regulatory 
    Commission, 888 First Street, NE, Washington, DC 20426. (202) 208-2015.
    
    SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: In addition to publishing the full text of 
    this document in the Federal Register, the Commission also provides all 
    interested persons an opportunity to inspect or copy the contents of 
    this document during normal business hours in the Public Reference Room 
    at 888 First Street, NE, Room 2A, Washington, DC 20426.
        The Commission Issuance Posting System (CIPS) provides access to 
    the texts of formal documents issued by the Commission. CIPS can be 
    accessed via Internet through FERC's Homepage (http://www.ferc.fed.us) 
    using the CIPS Link or the Energy Information Online icon. The full 
    text of this document will be available on CIPS in ASCII and 
    WordPerfect 6.1 format. CIPS is also available through the Commission's 
    electronic bulletin board service at no charge to the user and may be 
    accessed using a personal computer with a modem by dialing 202-208-
    1397, if dialing locally, or 1-800-856-3920, if dialing long distance. 
    To access CIPS, set your communications software to 19200, 14400, 
    12000, 9600, 7200, 4800, 2400, or 1200 bps, full duplex, no parity, 8 
    data bits and 1 stop bit. User assistance is available at 202-208-2474 
    or by E-mail to [email protected]
        This document is also available through the Commission's Records 
    and Information Management System (RIMS), an electronic storage and 
    retrieval system of documents submitted to and issued by the Commission 
    after November 16, 1981. Documents from November 1995 to the present 
    can be viewed and printed. RIMS is available in the Public Reference 
    Room or remotely via Internet through FERC's Homepage using the RIMS 
    link or the Energy Information Online icon. User assistance is 
    available at 202-208-2222, or by E-mail to [email protected]
        Finally, the complete text on diskette in WordPerfect format may be 
    purchased from the Commission's copy contractor, La Dorn System 
    Corporation. La Dorn Systems Corporation is located in the Public 
    Reference Room at 888 First Street, NE, Washington, DC, 20426.
    
    Table of Contents
    
    I.  Reexamination of the Transportation Market
        A.  The Developing Short-term Market
        B.  Implications for Commission Regulatory Policies of the 
    Changing Nature of Short-term Markets
    II.  Proposed Change in Regulatory Approach
        A.  A Different Model for Regulating the Short-term Market
        B.  Legal Basis for the Proposed Regulatory Change
        C.  Interrelated Proposals for Regulatory Change
    III.  Creating Greater Competition Among Short-term Service 
    Offerings
        A.  Nomination Equality
        B.  Segmentation and Flexibility of Receipt and Delivery Points
        C.  Capacity Auctions
        D.  Information Reporting and Remedies for the Exercise of 
    Market Power
    IV.  Penalties and Operational Flow Orders
        A.  Pipelines Should Provide, on a Timely Basis, as Much 
    Imbalance and Overrun Information as Possible
        B.  Transportation Penalties Must Be Necessary and Appropriate 
    to Protect System Operations
        C.  Pipelines Must Provide Services, to the Extent Operationally 
    Feasible, That Facilitate Imbalance Management
        D.  Pipelines Must Adopt Incentives and Procedures That Minimize 
    the Use and Adverse Impact of OFOs
    V.  Negotiated Rates and Services
        A.  Guiding Principles
        B.  Implementation of the Negotiated Rates and Services Policy
    VI.  Long-term Services
        A.  The Interaction Between Long-term and Short-term Services
        B.  Specific Impediments to Long-term Contracts
        C.  New Capacity Certificate Issues
    VII.  Reorganization of Part 284 Regulations
    VIII.  Information Collection Statement
    IX.  Environmental Analysis
    X.  Regulatory Flexibility Act Certification
    XI.  Comment Procedures
    
    Notice of Proposed Rulemaking
    
        Five years have passed since Congress, in the Wellhead Decontrol 
    Act, completed the decontrol of natural gas prices. Six years ago the 
    Commission, in Order No. 636, unbundled the purchase of gas from the 
    purchase of gas transportation. Since then, the natural gas market has 
    changed from a largely regulated market to one increasingly driven by 
    market forces. In order to continue to fulfill its statutory duties to 
    ensure just and reasonable rates in the rapidly evolving gas market of 
    today, the Commission has engaged in a comprehensive, critical 
    examination of the regulatory assumptions and procedures that it has 
    been using to determine whether other regulatory approaches would 
    better fit the needs of this changing marketplace.
        Since Order No. 636, the natural gas marketplace has fundamentally 
    changed. Active short-term markets have begun to develop. Shippers are 
    trading gas at market centers on a daily or sometimes an intra-day 
    basis with prices varying from day-to-day. Prior to Order No. 636, the 
    majority of contracts were long-term with less price volatility. As 
    local distribution companies (LDCs) unbundle the gas commodity from 
    transportation, new players, such as electric cogenerators, industrial 
    end-users, and small businesses (such as restaurants) are entering the 
    gas marketplace with gas and transportation needs different from those 
    of the LDCs that previously transported and sold the majority of gas. 
    Increasingly, LDC unbundling is even bringing homeowners into the gas 
    marketplace. These new entrants often use marketers or other 
    facilitators to arrange for their gas supplies on a delivered basis.
        The use of transportation capacity also has changed. Before Order 
    No. 636, shippers could acquire transportation only from the pipeline. 
    They could buy gas from the pipeline at the city-gate either on a 
    short-term or long-term basis, acquire long-term firm capacity from the 
    pipelines, often with 20-year contracts, or purchase short-term 
    interruptible capacity. In today's market, shippers have additional 
    options. They can acquire capacity from other firm capacity holders 
    through the capacity release market. They also can obtain capacity 
    indirectly by purchasing gas bundled with transportation from 
    producers, marketers, or aggregators for one delivered price (often 
    called a gray market sale).
        The changes in the short-term market have caused the Commission to 
    closely examine its regulatory structure to see whether it provides a 
    good fit with the developing short-term market. The Commission has 
    received comments on the impact of these changes through a number of 
    proceedings, among them a prior Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (NOPR) on 
    the secondary market,\1\ a request for comments on whether pipelines 
    should be permitted to
    
    [[Page 42984]]
    
    negotiate terms of service,\2\ and an industry conference on issues and 
    priorities in the gas industry.\3\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \1\ Secondary Market Transactions on Interstate Natural Gas 
    Pipelines, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 61 FR 41046 (Aug. 7, 
    1996), IV FERC Stats. & Regs. Proposed Regulations para. 32,520 
    (Jul. 31, 1996).
        \2\ Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service Ratemaking for 
    Natural Gas Pipelines, and Regulation of Negotiated Transportation 
    Services of Natural Gas Pipelines, 61 FR 4633 (Feb. 7, 1996), 74 
    FERC para. 61,076, at 61,242 (1996).
        \3\ Issues and Priorities for the Natural Gas Industry, PL97-1-
    000 (conference held May 29-30, 1997).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Upon review of the changes in the market and the comments it has 
    received, the Commission is concerned that its current regulatory 
    approach, which relies on a constant maximum rate in the short-term 
    market, may not be the best approach in light of the variability in 
    pricing in the short-term market. Due to the variability in 
    transportation value, the current approach may not provide the best 
    protection against the exercise of market power during peak and off-
    peak periods. Or, the protection it does provide may come at the 
    expense of a more efficient capacity market during peak periods, when 
    shippers are most in need of a market that works efficiently.
        The Commission recognizes that despite all the competitive 
    improvements in the short-term market, the short-term market still may 
    not be fully competitive. Thus, the Commission must continue to have a 
    regulatory presence in the short-term market to protect against the 
    exercise of market power and undue discrimination.
        The Commission is, therefore, proposing in this NOPR a different 
    approach for regulating the short-term transportation market which is 
    designed to permit the market to function efficiently while continuing 
    to protect shippers against the exercise of market power. This approach 
    has a number of objectives. It is designed to improve competition in 
    short-term markets by facilitating the trading of capacity, so that 
    shippers will have a larger number of capacity alternatives from which 
    to choose. By expanding options, it seeks to help reduce the number of 
    captive customers. Additionally, it seeks to provide the opportunity 
    for greater flexibility in pipeline contracting practices so that 
    pipelines can design services that better meet the needs of existing 
    and new players in the gas marketplace.
        The proposal uses different regulatory structures for short-term 
    and long-term markets. Long-term transportation prices (i.e., 
    transportation of one-year or longer) would continue to be regulated 
    under a cost-based regulatory regime to protect against the exercise of 
    pipeline monopoly power. For short-term transportation services, 
    however, cost-based regulation would be eliminated. In its place, the 
    Commission proposes to regulate the short-term market through 
    regulatory policies that are intended to maximize competition in the 
    short-term transportation market, to mitigate the ability of firms to 
    exercise residual monopoly power, and to improve the ability of market 
    participants and the Commission to monitor the market for exercises of 
    monopoly power or undue discrimination. The goal of this approach to 
    the short-term market is to ensure that the Commission's regulatory 
    policy does not inhibit competitive market forces from creating 
    efficient capacity markets, while still providing captive customers and 
    others with protection against the exercise of market power in the 
    transportation market.
        Specifically, to maximize competition (which is the best protection 
    against the exercise of market power) the Commission is proposing in 
    this NOPR to revise pipeline nomination and scheduling procedures, and 
    flexible receipt and delivery point policies so that capacity release 
    can compete on a more equal footing with pipeline capacity. To further 
    mitigate the exercise of market power and the potential for undue 
    discrimination, the Commission is proposing to require that all short-
    term capacity be sold through capacity auctions. To improve shippers' 
    and the Commission's ability to monitor the marketplace the Commission 
    is proposing changes to its reporting requirements. To improve 
    competition across the pipeline grid, the Commission is making 
    proposals to change pipeline penalty procedures so that penalties, 
    although necessary to deter conduct inimical to system operations, do 
    not unnecessarily limit shippers' competitive alternatives.
        At the same time, the Commission recognizes that changes in the 
    short-term market also influence shippers' decisions in the long-term 
    market. For example, the value of long-term capacity lies in the 
    guarantee of capacity at a relatively stable price as compared with 
    buying capacity at the more volatile short-term price. Long-term 
    contracts, therefore, are a means by which shippers and pipelines can 
    manage the risks inherent in the short-term market.
        To foster greater innovation in pipeline services and to permit 
    pipelines and shippers to better allocate the risks of long-term 
    contracts, the Commission is proposing to allow pipelines' greater 
    flexibility in negotiating contracts with individual shippers, subject 
    to criteria that will protect captive customers against the risk of 
    undue discrimination. Further, to create a more efficient marketplace, 
    regulatory policies should not affect the allocation of risk between 
    acquiring short-term or long-term capacity. As part of this integrated 
    package, therefore, the Commission is proposing changes to some of its 
    policies governing long-term contracts to ensure that these policies do 
    not unfairly bias shippers' contracting decisions. The Commission also 
    is considering whether changes to its policies regarding authorization 
    for new construction are needed so that these policies do not 
    unnecessarily limit competition.
        The Commission recognizes that the impact on the long-term market 
    of the changes in the short-term market go beyond the proposals 
    outlined above. Therefore, in a Notice of Inquiry (NOI) issued 
    contemporaneously with this NOPR, the Commission asks for additional 
    comment on the future direction of its policies for pricing of long-
    term capacity.
    
    I. Reexamination of the Transportation Market
    
    A. The Developing Short-term Market
    
        Natural gas markets have developed rapidly since wellhead price 
    deregulation and unbundling of pipeline merchant and transportation 
    services. In many ways, the gas market performs very well, without the 
    loss of reliability that many feared when Order No. 636 was being 
    contemplated.\4\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \4\ See Pipeline Service Obligations and Revisions to 
    Regulations Governing Self-Implementing Transportation Under Part 
    284 and Regulation of Natural Gas Pipelines After Partial Wellhead 
    Decontrol, Order No. 636, 57 FR 13267, FERC Stats. & Regs. 
    Regulations Preambles [Jan. 1991-June 1996] para. 30,939, at 30,408 
    (Apr. 8, 1992), Order No. 636-A, 57 FR 36128 (Aug. 12, 1992), FERC 
    Stats. & Regs. Regulations Preambles [Jan. 1991-June 1996] para. 
    30,950, at 30,570 (Aug. 3, 1992) (concerns about providing 
    transportation service equal in reliability to bundled sales 
    service).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Gas commodity markets have arisen, along with market mechanisms to 
    enable consumers to manage price risk for the gas.\5\ There are monthly 
    and growing daily spot markets for gas supplies which enable shippers 
    not only to buy their own gas supplies at the wellhead, but to trade 
    gas among themselves on a daily or even more frequent basis. Many of 
    these spot markets are organized around market centers that facilitate 
    trading of gas across pipelines as well as providing a variety of new 
    services, such as storage, wheeling, parking, lending, electronic gas 
    trading, and tracking of gas title
    
    [[Page 42985]]
    
    transfers.\6\ Active forward markets also have developed to enable gas 
    consumers to hedge against price risk. The New York Mercantile Exchange 
    (NYMEX) launched its natural gas futures contract in 1992, and it is 
    very heavily traded.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \5\ See S. Walsh, A Hot (and Cold) New Investment Opportunity, 
    Washington Post, July 4, 1998, C12 (Business) (discussing 
    development of new weather derivative to enable companies to hedge 
    against abnormal weather patterns).
        \6\ Department of Energy/Energy Information Administration, Pub. 
    No. DOE/EIA-0560(96), Natural Gas 1996 Issues and Trends, Chapter, 
    The Emergence of Natural Gas Market Centers (1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Along with the development of a more liquid commodity market, 
    shippers' transportation options have expanded. In the past, shippers 
    could purchase capacity only from the pipeline and had, for the most 
    part, only two transportation choices: long-term firm capacity or 
    interruptible service. Pipeline offerings have expanded as well, with 
    pipelines offering short-term firm transportation service, pooling,\7\ 
    hub services,\8\ parking and loan services,\9\ and both short-term and 
    long-term storage services.\10\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \7\ See Standards For Business Practices Of Interstate Natural 
    Gas Pipelines, Order No. 587, 61 FR 39053 (Jul. 26, 1996), III FERC 
    Stats. & Regs. Regulations Preambles para. 31,038 (Jul. 17, 1996) 
    (requiring pipelines to provide pooling services).
        \8\ See Moss Bluff Hub Partners, 80 FERC para. 61,181 (1997) 
    (firm storage and interruptible hub services); Egan Hub Partners, 
    L.P., 77 FERC para. 61,016 (1996) firm storage and interruptible hub 
    services).
        \9\ See Mojave Pipeline Company, 79 FERC para. 61,347 (1997); 
    Colorado Interstate Gas Company, 83 FERC para. 61,273 (1998).
        \10\ See Koch Gateway Pipeline Company, 66 FERC para. 61,385 
    (1994) (firm and interruptible storage); New York State Electric Gas 
    Corporation, 81 FERC para. 61,020 (1997) (issuing certificate).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Non-traditional players also have entered the capacity market, so 
    that today firm shippers holding pipeline capacity include electric 
    utilities (21% of total pipeline firm capacity), industrial end-users 
    (5%), marketers (17%), pipelines (7%), and others, including producers 
    (6%) in addition to the traditional LDCs (44%). While many of these 
    shippers still hold pipeline contracts longer than a year, short-term 
    firm contracts are rising in significance. Among the shipper groups, 
    marketers are the largest users of short-term capacity, with over 
    three-quarters of the total.\11\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \11\ Department of Energy/Energy Information Administration, 
    Pub. No. DOE/EIA-0618(98), Deliverability on the Interstate Natural 
    Gas Pipeline System 88-89 (1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In today's market, shippers also have the added option of buying 
    firm capacity released by other shippers in a variety of ways (such as 
    on a fixed, or volumetric basis, or with other release conditions, 
    including provisions for handling capacity recalls). Since its 
    inception in 1992, capacity release transactions have been growing 
    dramatically.\12\ For instance, the amount of capacity held by 
    replacement shippers for the 12 month period ending March 1997, totaled 
    7.4 quadrillion Btu, a 22% percent increase over the previous 12 month 
    period and almost double the level for the 12 months ending March 
    1995.\13\ While the amount of capacity held by replacement shippers 
    declined during the heating season, EIA reports it still represents a 
    sizable amount.\14\ Despite the growing use of released capacity, 
    interruptible pipeline service also continues to be a viable service 
    option, maintaining a relatively constant share of throughput.\15\ As 
    in the case of released capacity, EIA reports that interruptible 
    service is available during the heating season.\16\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \12\ Id. at 82 (representing about 16% of the gas delivered for 
    market).
        \13\ Id. at 83.
        \14\  Id. at 85-86 (2,960 trillion Btu from November to March 
    1996-97).
        \15\ Id. at 85 (about 16% of total throughput for the 12 months 
    ending March 31, 1997).
        \16\ Id. at 87 (2,000 TBtu moved during heating season).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In addition to acquiring capacity from pipelines and releasing 
    shippers, purchasers in the short-term market have other capacity 
    options. Implicit in the Commission's decision to unbundle the gas 
    commodity from transportation was a recognition that the market would 
    develop so that customers who did not want to assume the responsibility 
    of purchasing or transporting their own gas could purchase delivered 
    gas from marketers or third parties with the marketer providing all or 
    a portion of the needed transportation, for example to a nearby market 
    center.\17\ Capacity rights holders can now sell gas as a commodity in 
    downstream markets at market-based prices.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \17\ See Order No. 636, FERC Stats. & Regs. Regulations 
    Preambles [Jan. 1991-June 1996] para. 30,939, at 30,410.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Further, as a result of Commission initiatives, the gas industry, 
    through the Gas Industry Standards Board (GISB), has developed 
    standards that make it easier to move and trade gas on individual 
    pipeline systems and across pipeline systems.\18\ These standards 
    establish a daily, along with an intra-day, nomination schedule which 
    permit shippers to adjust their nominations to conform to changes in 
    weather and other circumstances. The Commission recently adopted GISB 
    standards providing for three intra-day nomination opportunities.\19\ 
    These standards also significantly enhance shipper flexibility, for 
    example, by giving shippers the ability to aggregate gas supplies from 
    numerous sources in a pipeline pool for nomination purposes and by 
    allowing shippers to assign priority rankings to gas packages.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \18\ Standards For Business Practices Of Interstate Natural Gas 
    Pipelines, Order No. 587, 61 FR 39053 (Jul. 26, 1996), III FERC 
    Stats. & Regs. Regulations Preambles para. 31,038 (Jul. 17, 1996), 
    Order No. 587-B, 62 FR 5521 (Feb. 6, 1997), III FERC Stats. & Regs. 
    Regulations Preambles para. 31,046 (Jan. 30, 1997), Order No. 587-C, 
    62 FR 10684 (Mar. 10, 1997), III FERC Stats. & Regs. Regulations 
    Preambles para. 31,050 (Mar. 4, 1997), Order No. 587-G, 63 FR 20072 
    (Apr. 23, 1998), III FERC Stats. & Regs. Regulations Preambles para. 
    31,062 (Apr. 16, 1998).
        \19\ Standards For Business Practices Of Interstate Natural Gas 
    Pipelines, Order No. 587-H, 63 FR 39509 (Jul. 23, 1998), 84 FERC 
    para. 61,031 (July 15, 1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        These changes, operating together, have changed the character of 
    short-term markets. Five years ago, most gas was purchased during bid 
    week under monthly contracts and transportation was arranged at the 
    same time on a monthly basis. Transactions occurring outside of bid 
    week were unusual and were referred to as the aftermarket. Today, daily 
    markets for gas and capacity are developing rapidly. Shippers now trade 
    gas on a daily or even an intra-day basis at various market centers and 
    pipeline interconnect points or at pipeline pooling points. For 
    example, at pipeline interconnect points or at pools, there may be 
    repeated sales of the same gas between producers and marketers before 
    the gas is scheduled for transportation. As described in a recent 
    proceeding, shippers can use pooling to effectuate gas exchanges (pool 
    to pool transfers) as a means of enhancing supply and pricing options 
    and of market hedging.\20\ For example, a shipper may buy gas from a 
    pool as insurance against a change in its system requirements and then 
    sell that gas to another pool if the load does not develop in its 
    market.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \20\ El Paso Natural Gas Company, 81 FERC para. 61,174, at 
    61,760 (1997) (approving a limit on pool to pool transfers because 
    pipeline could not handle the volume of transactions under new 
    scheduling timeline).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Shippers also can take advantage of trading opportunities by making 
    daily or intra-day changes to their gas nominations to react quickly to 
    changing weather, changing prices or supply sources, or other 
    circumstances. For instance, a shipper that loses a supply source can 
    submit an intra-day nomination to change its receipt point for gas so 
    that it can purchase gas from an alternate supply source. The reports 
    in trade publications of daily gas prices at delivered markets are 
    further evidence of the increasing scope of the developing short-term 
    market.\21\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \21\ See, e.g., Gas Daily, March 2, 1998, at 1-2; Natural Gas 
    Intelligence, Jan. 5, 1998, at 4; Natural Gas Week, Jan. 12, 1998, 
    at 12, 17, 20-21.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The developing gas market, however, is in some respects still in 
    its infancy and there are still impediments, both regulatory and non-
    regulatory, to the
    
    [[Page 42986]]
    
    development of a well-functioning market. Price information, which is 
    crucial to a well-developed market, could be improved. While the 
    Commission requires the posting of information on capacity release 
    transactions, posting of pipeline discount transactions occurs well 
    after-the-fact and cannot be used by shippers to make daily market 
    decisions. Moreover, it is difficult for shippers to obtain accurate 
    information about delivered gas transactions or the value of 
    transportation inherent in such transactions. Shippers are left to 
    personal communication or trade publications to determine prices at 
    receipt and delivery points. Acquiring market information through 
    personal communication is time consuming and expensive, particularly 
    for small customers who would have difficulty canvassing a large enough 
    number of sources to obtain sufficient market information. Each trade 
    publication uses different reporting methods. Some mix long and short-
    term transactions and some report price ranges while others report 
    averages, and most do not report quantities traded.
        Also, capacity markets are fragmented. Different regulatory rules 
    apply to pipeline sales of interruptible and firm capacity, capacity 
    obtained through release transactions, and capacity used as part of 
    delivered gas transactions. For example, the nomination and scheduling 
    procedures and rate regulation differ among pipeline capacity, released 
    capacity, and delivered gas transactions. In addition, different rights 
    may apply depending on the type of capacity a shipper tries to acquire. 
    Shippers purchasing released capacity from certain firm shippers may 
    have to rely on alternate receipt or delivery points, and the use of 
    such points are sometimes restricted by pipelines' tariffs.
        All of these factors increase the shippers' transaction costs by 
    increasing the difficulty and risk of doing business in the short-term 
    market. Absent good price and capacity information, shippers cannot 
    easily compare capacity alternatives or obtain full, comparable 
    information about the alternatives available at any time. This inhibits 
    their ability to make informed decisions about acquiring gas and 
    capacity and prevents them from finding the best gas and capacity deals 
    available. These costs may be particularly meaningful for small 
    customers, who do not have the time and resources to unearth, through 
    personal contacts, the information they need to make informed choices.
        In the developing short-term market, market forces impact regulated 
    services. The growing emphasis on daily transactions means that 
    customers are more concerned with the daily price of transportation 
    capacity. For example, many short-term decisions are based on the 
    delivered price for gas (including transportation) on a daily basis. 
    Often narrow differences in delivered prices may affect shippers' 
    decisions.
        The existence of a market price for gas at all points along the 
    pipeline grid has created a market-driven value for transportation 
    between receipt and delivery points. In effect, the implicit value of 
    transportation between two such points is the spot price of gas at the 
    delivery point minus the spot price of gas at the receipt point.
        This market driven value can fluctuate widely on a daily basis. As 
    shown in the following example, many such valuations remain near zero 
    for long periods of time, only to rise during periods of peak demand. 
    On this illustration, the market-driven value of transportation 
    represents the difference between the spot price for gas at the 
    upstream hub in Louisiana and the delivered price for gas in the New 
    York downstream market. In other words, the price for delivered gas in 
    the downstream New York market reflects the spot price for gas at the 
    upstream hub plus the value of the transportation needed to deliver the 
    gas to the downstream market. The market value of transportation can 
    then be compared with the cost-based, regulated maximum interruptible 
    rates for the three pipelines transporting from Louisiana to New York 
    (represented by the dotted lines).\22\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \22\ The source for the spot price data is the Gas Daily Weekly 
    Weighted Average Prices ($/MMBtu). The source for the maximum 
    interruptible tariff rate is from PIPELINE Grid published by the 
    Petroleum Information Corporation Logistics Solution. The range of 
    tariff rates includes the interruptible rates from Columbia Gas 
    Transmission Corporation ($.45/MMBtu), Tennessee Gas Pipeline 
    Company ($.57/MMBtu), and Transcontinental Gas Pipe Line Corporation 
    ($.44/MMBtu).
    
    BILLING CODE 6717-01-P
    
    [[Page 4*ERR58*2987]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP11AU98.000
    
    
    
    BILLING CODE 6717-01-C
        This illustrates that the value of transportation during the peak 
    winter period of 1995-1996 rose to $10/MMBtu (20 times the maximum 
    daily tariff rates of between $.44 and $.57/MMBtu) and during the 1996-
    1997 winter to over $1/MMBtu (2 times the maximum tariff rate). During 
    non-peak periods, the value of transportation was uniformly below the 
    maximum daily tariff rate. While the illustration may not portray 
    precise transportation values,\23\ it nonetheless does provide a 
    picture of the fluctuation in transportation values over time.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \23\ For instance, gas from markets other than Louisiana may 
    have affected delivered prices in New York, and the data contain 
    unexplained anomalies, such as transportation values of less than 0, 
    indicating that the price of gas was lower in New York than at the 
    receipt point in Louisiana. During that time, either no gas moved 
    from Louisiana to New York or, if gas did move, the markets were not 
    clearing properly or the price data were not accurate.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The fluctuation of transportation values raises questions about 
    whether the Commission's current rate policies are attuned to the 
    realities of the developing short-term market. The Commission currently 
    establishes a daily maximum rate for pipeline services and capacity 
    release by taking the pipelines' annual rate and converting it to a 
    daily rate (by dividing the yearly rate by 365). But this single rate 
    does not reflect the variability of daily pricing in the short-term 
    market. While the $10 value during the 1995-1996 may not be repeated, 
    transportation values during the next winter were double the maximum 
    rate.
        These data on delivered prices, and derived transportation values, 
    do not establish either the presence or absence of market power. 
    Delivered markets for gas can, and probably do, coexist with the 
    continued exercise of market power over transportation. Pricing by a 
    pipeline with market power would exhibit the same pricing variability 
    as shown in the illustration, with higher prices during periods when 
    demand is greatest. Also, even though prices during off-peak periods 
    are below the maximum rate, that does not guarantee that market power 
    cannot be exercised.
        The existence of a delivered market does not, in and of itself, 
    establish that the market is operating efficiently. Regulatory 
    impediments, such as poorly designed penalty structures or the maximum 
    rate cap, may create transaction costs, reducing market efficiency and 
    raising prices. The price
    
    [[Page 42988]]
    
    cap, for instance, can create a disincentive for firm capacity holders 
    to make capacity available for release during peak periods, because the 
    capacity holder is unable to realize the market value for its capacity. 
    This can create a less efficient market by depriving other shippers of 
    the ability to obtain capacity when they place a greater value on the 
    capacity than the shipper holding it.\24\ The buyer's alternative is to 
    try and purchase delivered gas. But the market for delivered gas may 
    not be as efficient as giving the buyer the added option of purchasing 
    transportation capacity in an open and transparent market in which the 
    buyer can decide for itself whether it obtains greater value by 
    purchasing delivered gas or using its own gas contracts and obtaining 
    transportation separately.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \24\ See Mary L. Barcella, How Commodity Markets Drive Gas 
    Pipeline Values, Public Utilities Fortnightly, Feb. 1, 1998, 24, 25 
    (price cap limits shippers' incentive to release capacity and can 
    result in shutting out other shippers needing capacity).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In sum, the short-term market is changing, with greater emphasis on 
    daily transactions and daily prices for the gas commodity both at 
    origin and delivered markets which vary with demand. The constant 
    maximum rate approach to regulation does not appear to fit well in this 
    new fast-paced market and may result in a less efficient market, with 
    increased transaction costs. Yet, market power over transportation 
    continues to exist and must be addressed.
    
    B. Implications for Commission Regulatory Policies of the Changing 
    Nature of Short-term Markets
    
        The development of active commodity markets at both ends of the 
    pipeline poses a significant challenge to the Commission's traditional 
    method of rate regulation. The current maximum rate provides some 
    regulatory protection for shippers during peak periods, because it 
    prevents pipelines from exercising monopoly power at least to the 
    extent that shippers cannot be charged prices above the maximum rate. 
    Even during off-peak periods, the maximum rate provides some protection 
    because it protects some shippers against discriminatory prices that 
    might otherwise exceed the cap. During off-peak periods, some shippers 
    still place a high value on moving gas, and the price cap limits the 
    price such shippers can be forced to pay. Moreover, the Commission 
    permits pipelines to price discriminate (at prices below the maximum 
    rate) during off-peak periods to provide benefits to captive customers 
    who hold long-term firm contracts. The added revenue the pipeline 
    generates by selectively discounting helps to reduce the reservation 
    charges owed by the captive firm shippers.\25\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \25\ During off-peak periods, the pipeline can price 
    discriminate by offering discounts to some customers that are 
    greater than those offered to other customers. This practice brings 
    in more revenue than the pipeline would earn if it could only charge 
    the same price to all customers. The additional revenue benefits the 
    firm capacity holders because, in the pipelines' rate case, the 
    increased revenue reduces the reservation charges firm shippers 
    might otherwise pay. See Associated Gas Distributors v. FERC (D.C. 
    Cir. 1987) (selective discounting by a monopolist justified on 
    equitable grounds because it would reduce captive customers' 
    contributions to fixed costs).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As the short-term market continues to grow, maximum rate regulation 
    in the short-term market may become an increasingly more ineffective 
    method of regulating the short-term market. Maximum rate regulation may 
    not provide shippers with the most effective protection against the 
    exercise of market power. Moreover, the protection it does provide may 
    come at too great a cost in efficiency.
        The rate cap may, for instance, result in misallocation of capacity 
    where those shippers placing the greatest value on the capacity are 
    unable to obtain it. During peak periods, pipelines can only sell 
    capacity which is not under contract or used by those shippers holding 
    firm capacity. Thus, a pipeline may have little capacity to sell on a 
    peak day. Even if the pipeline did have capacity to sell, a particular 
    shipper placing the highest value on the capacity may be unable to 
    obtain that capacity. Under current Commission rules, when demand for 
    capacity exceeds the supply available, and all shippers bid the maximum 
    rate, the pipeline awards its capacity using a queue based on contract 
    execution date or on a pro rata basis. In either case, the shipper 
    placing the greatest value on the capacity may not obtain capacity or 
    not obtain as much capacity as it needs and for which it is willing to 
    pay.
        The shipper's other alternative is to try to obtain capacity from 
    firm capacity holders, but in this market the price cap may not provide 
    much protection to the purchasing shipper. The price cap applies to 
    released capacity. But, the price cap has little effect on delivered 
    gas transactions, in which the transportation value may exceed the 
    maximum rate.
        There is little hard empiric evidence on how extensive the 
    delivered market is, but the existence of delivered gas transactions 
    during peak periods suggests that, due to the price cap, capacity 
    holders with available capacity will choose to use that capacity to 
    make delivered transactions, where the profit opportunity is greater, 
    rather than releasing the capacity, where the price is capped. In 
    addition, a pending proceeding raises the question whether shippers 
    have developed other methods for avoiding the maximum rate that are 
    difficult to detect and prevent on a systematic basis.26
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \26\ Consumers Energy Company, 82 FERC ] 61,284 (1997). See 
    Inside FERC's Gas Market Report, December 1, 1995, at 14 (discussing 
    various methods of avoiding the price cap).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Attempting to regulate the transportation component of delivered 
    gas transactions would be difficult. But even if this market could be 
    effectively regulated, it is not clear that such regulation would be 
    beneficial. If capacity transactions could not occur above the price 
    cap, then, as described above, capacity would not be allocated 
    efficiently; those customers most needing gas during peak periods would 
    be unable to obtain the gas they need and the market would not clear 
    efficiently.
        In addition, as described earlier, the price cap may reduce the 
    efficiency of the delivered gas market itself by raising transaction 
    costs, thus resulting in higher delivered prices. Because unbundled 
    sales of capacity by releasing shippers cannot be made above the 
    maximum rate, the market may not operate in as open, transparent, or 
    efficient a manner as is possible. Information for delivered gas is not 
    publicly posted and shippers relying on word of mouth may not be able 
    to easily locate all available sources of transportation. The 
    difficulty of locating potential sellers and obtaining accurate price 
    information may lead some customers to pay higher than necessary 
    prices. 27 For instance, during the winter of 1996 when gas 
    prices rose dramatically, while the market worked well to prevent 
    shortages and ensure that customers received gas, it could have worked 
    more efficiently. According to the trade press, the delivered prices 
    for gas in Chicago on the same day ranged from $20.50 to $46.00 per 
    MMBtu.28 In an efficient market, one would not expect such a 
    wide differential in prices, but would expect transactions in the same 
    market to clear at roughly similar prices. The Commission seeks input 
    from the industry on whether the price cap creates transaction costs 
    and prevents
    
    [[Page 42989]]
    
    the development of an efficient short-term market.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \27\ For example, in the automobile market, the time and expense 
    of comparison shopping may result in some customers paying higher 
    prices than others.
        \28\ See Gas Daily, February 2, 1996, at 1.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Maximum rate regulation may have an unintended effect by reducing 
    the capacity available during peak periods, the time at which the 
    industry would most benefit from having as much pipeline capacity 
    available as is possible. As a result of the maximum rate cap, firm 
    capacity holders may not find it sufficiently profitable to make their 
    capacity available. It may be that due to state restrictions not all 
    local distribution companies (LDCs) may be able to make delivered gas 
    transactions off-system. Thus, they may not make capacity available 
    during peak periods if they cannot receive the market price for their 
    capacity.
        For instance, an LDC might have a peak shaving capability (storage 
    or liquified natural gas (LNG)) that costs more to operate than the 
    maximum transportation rate. The LDC might be willing to release its 
    transportation capacity and use the peak shaving device instead if the 
    price it could receive for pipeline transportation exceeded its cost to 
    operate the peak shaving device. By using its peak shaving device 
    instead of transportation, the shipper would be expanding the amount of 
    transportation capacity available for resale during a peak period. But 
    if the price cap prevented the shipper from obtaining a price higher 
    than the cost of turning on the peak shaving device, and the shipper 
    could not sell the gas on a delivered basis, the shipper would use its 
    transportation capacity, thus depriving other shippers (without peak 
    shaving) of the opportunity to acquire needed transportation capacity. 
    Thus, maximum rate regulation may actually reduce the amount of 
    pipeline capacity available for sale during peak periods. A restriction 
    on the amount of available capacity would cause peak period prices to 
    be higher than they would be without the cap. Comments should address 
    whether the price cap has these effects and whether it does 
    significantly limit the amount of capacity available in the short-term 
    market.
        Maximum rate regulation during peak periods also may increase 
    shipper imbalances and penalties. During peak periods, penalties affect 
    the value of transportation.29 In a cold snap, a shipper may 
    be willing to pay a penalty for overrunning its contract demand to 
    obtain the gas it needs. If that shipper faced a $100/MMBtu penalty, it 
    might be willing to pay any amount for capacity up to $100 to avoid the 
    penalty. For example, if the value of capacity in an efficient market 
    were $80, the shipper willing to pay a $100 penalty would be better off 
    by $20 if it obtained capacity instead. But, as described above, the 
    price cap may reduce the efficiency of the marketplace, limiting the 
    shipper's ability to obtain the capacity it needs. The shipper, 
    therefore, may choose to overrun its contract demand and pay the 
    penalty. In this situation, the price cap may result in increasing 
    shipper imbalances, thereby increasing the penalty revenue paid to 
    pipelines, and perhaps decreasing the reliability of the system.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \29\ See Industry Surveys the Damage as Winter's Strength Runs 
    Out, Natural Gas Intelligence, April 22, 1996, at 1, 4 (penalties 
    started to be a real factor in determining the price of gas in the 
    Midwest).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        During off-peak periods, the maximum rate cap does not affect the 
    efficiency of the market because market values do not appear to reach 
    the maximum rate ceiling. The rate cap, however, may not provide 
    sufficient protection against the exercise of market power. During off-
    peak periods, pipelines and releasing shippers are not required to sell 
    available capacity at prices less than the maximum rate.30 
    By limiting the supply of capacity during off-peak periods, pipelines 
    or releasing shippers may be able to charge monopoly prices because 
    even a monopoly price may be less than the daily maximum rate. Since 
    pipelines are permitted to price discriminate at rates below the 
    maximum rate, they may charge shippers, at least those without other 
    choices, higher prices than would prevail in an efficient competitive 
    market. Although the Commission has permitted pipelines to price 
    discriminate by discounting below the maximum rate, it may be that the 
    benefits for captive customers holding long-term transportation 
    contracts come at too great a cost to other shippers or that the 
    benefits even to captive customers no longer warrant continuation of 
    this policy.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \30\ See El Paso Natural Gas Company, 83 FERC para. 61,286 
    (1998) (pipeline not required to discount below the maximum rate); 
    Southern California Edison Company v. Southern California Gas 
    Company, 79 FERC para. 61,157 (1997), reh'g denied, 80 FERC para. 
    61,390 (1997) (no requirement that pipelines or shippers offer 
    discounts below the maximum rate).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In summary, the interface between the regulated and unregulated 
    sectors of the gas industry has become much more complicated in the 
    last five years. Regulatory policies that worked well in one market 
    setting may not work as well today. For this reason, the Commission is 
    reassessing its current policies and proposing changes.
    
    II. Proposed Change in Regulatory Approach
    
        The Commission's regulatory policies must be attuned to the 
    realities of the market it is regulating. As became clear during the 
    period when wellhead prices were regulated, consumers receive little 
    benefit from artificially low regulated prices if such prices distort 
    the market and create shortages so consumers cannot acquire gas when 
    they most need it.31 Moreover, in fashioning regulatory 
    policies, it must be recognized that market power varies over a 
    continuum between perfect competition at one end of the continuum and a 
    single firm monopoly with impenetrable entry barriers at the other. 
    Thus, a regulatory approach appropriate for pure monopoly markets may 
    not be the best method for regulating the markets where market power, 
    while not absent, may be partially disciplined by market forces.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \31\ See Transcontinental Gas Pipe Line Corporation v. State Oil 
    and Gas Board, 474 U.S. 409, 420 (1986) (Natural Gas Act's 
    artificial pricing scheme is a major cause of imbalance between 
    supply and demand); Atlantic Refining Company v. Public Service 
    Commission of N.Y., 360 U.S. 378, 388 (1959) (rate regulation should 
    ensure reasonable rates consistent with the maintenance of adequate 
    service).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The changes to the short-term market raise the question of whether 
    the Commission needs to change its regulatory philosophy. Prior to 
    unbundling, maximum rate regulation in the short-term market was more 
    effective, because the short-term market essentially was limited to the 
    pipelines' interruptible transportation service.
        However, as the short-term market continues to develop, the 
    continuation of maximum rate regulation in the short-term market may 
    become increasingly troublesome. First, maximum rate regulation, by its 
    very nature, inefficiently allocates capacity because those shippers 
    placing the greatest value on capacity may not be able to obtain it. 
    Therefore, during peak periods, when the market is under the most 
    stress, the rate cap may result in a less efficient and more opaque 
    market in which shippers cannot acquire capacity they need or must pay 
    higher prices for delivered gas than would have prevailed in a more 
    efficient short-term market. Second, maximum rate regulation may not be 
    the most effective tool for preventing the exercise of market power, 
    particularly for transactions during off-peak periods. Thus, while the 
    ostensible goal of Commission regulatory policy is to protect shippers 
    against the exercise of monopoly power by the pipelines, the current 
    system of maximum rate regulation may no longer be the best method for 
    meeting this goal.
    
    [[Page 42990]]
    
    A. A Different Model for Regulating the Short-term Market
    
        To respond to the emerging short-term market, the Commission is 
    proposing in this NOPR a change in regulatory focus to better reflect 
    the way in which short-term gas markets function and to do a better job 
    of protecting against the exercise of market power and helping to 
    foster a more competitive commodity market. The Commission, however, 
    recognizes that the ability to exercise market power still exists in 
    the short-term market and, therefore, any regulatory approach it adopts 
    must continue to provide effective protection against the exercise of 
    market power.
        To do this, there are several criteria that a regulatory approach 
    must satisfy. It should maximize efficient competition among releasing 
    shippers and between releasing shippers and the pipelines, because 
    competition and efficient markets are the best overall protection 
    against the exercise of market power. It should include policies that 
    will mitigate any residual market power and monitor for its continued 
    exercise. It should fairly balance the interests of those customers 
    that purchase long-term capacity and those who choose to acquire 
    transportation in the short-term market. And, it should promote 
    innovation in service offerings to attract new customers.
        The Commission believes its statutory objectives can better be met 
    by a regulatory model that recognizes the distinction between short-
    term and long-term markets. Therefore, in the short-term transportation 
    market, the Commission proposes to replace the reliance on maximum rate 
    regulation 32 with a regulatory approach focusing on 
    creating competitive alternatives for shippers, developing policies to 
    mitigate residual market power, and monitoring the marketplace for the 
    exercise of market power. In the long-term transportation market, the 
    Commission proposes to continue to rely upon regulated cost-based rates 
    to protect against the exercise of monopoly power by the pipelines. 
    Price regulation for the long-term transportation market will ensure 
    continued protection for captive customers with long-term contracts 
    with the pipeline. It will also help discipline the potential exercise 
    of market power in the short-term market by enabling shippers to 
    purchase long-term capacity at regulated rates.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \32\ Minimum rates would be retained.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission fully recognizes that pipelines still possess 
    monopoly power in the transportation market as a result of economies of 
    scale and barriers to entry. This is particularly true in the long-term 
    market where the pipeline may be the only source of capacity. The 
    Commission also recognizes that simply because competition exists for 
    the gas commodity at receipt and delivery points on the grid does not 
    mean that the transportation between all points is necessarily fully 
    competitive.
        On the other hand, in the short-term market, the Commission's 
    capacity release and flexible receipt and delivery point policies, 
    together with other market changes such as pooling, hub and market 
    center services, and storage services, have increased the competitive 
    alternatives available to buyers of capacity. While these measures have 
    not resulted in effective competition everywhere throughout the 
    pipeline grid, it cannot be disputed that they have increased the level 
    of competition and reduced the ability of pipelines to exercise 
    monopoly power. Thus, while a regulatory presence is still needed in 
    the short-term transportation market, the Commission may not need to 
    continue to regulate this market as if each pipeline was still a single 
    firm monopoly.
        At the same time the Commission is proposing to eliminate maximum 
    rate regulation in the short-term market, it is proposing several 
    initiatives in this NOPR to maximize competition in the short-term 
    market, minimize the potential for the exercise of market power, and 
    monitor the marketplace for the continuing exercise of market power. To 
    maximize the extent of competition, the Commission is proposing a 
    number of measures to create more efficient competition among capacity 
    offerings so that shippers will have more choice in obtaining capacity. 
    The Commission is proposing to create more uniform nominating 
    procedures for released capacity so that it can better compete with 
    capacity from the pipelines and delivered gas transactions. The 
    Commission further is requesting comment on whether changes in 
    regulatory policy are needed to maximize shippers' ability to segment 
    their capacity to provide greater competitive alternatives. To further 
    improve competition in the short-term market across the pipeline grid, 
    the Commission is suggesting potential methods of reforming penalty 
    procedures to ensure that different penalty processes across pipelines 
    do not limit shippers' flexibility in using capacity or otherwise 
    distort shippers' decisions about how best to use capacity.
        As an additional measure to mitigate potential market power, the 
    Commission is proposing the use of capacity auctions for all short-term 
    capacity. A properly designed capacity auction can protect against the 
    exercise of market power by limiting the ability to withhold capacity 
    and to engage in price discrimination.
        To monitor the marketplace, the Commission is proposing to 
    establish reporting requirements to provide capacity and pricing 
    information to all shippers. This information will have the further 
    benefit of making competition more efficient by providing the pricing 
    information that a competitive market needs for shippers to make 
    informed decisions about their capacity purchases. All of these 
    proposals are addressed in more detail in Parts III and IV of this 
    NOPR.
        In addition to these proposals for monitoring the short-term 
    market, the Commission proposes to conduct a generic review of the 
    operation of the short-term market without a price cap after two winter 
    heating seasons.
        Because the proposed regulatory approach differs between short-term 
    and long-term services, there is a need to define the period 
    encompassed by each. The Commission is proposing to define short-term 
    transactions as all transactions of less than one year. The Commission 
    has traditionally drawn the line between long-term and short-term 
    transactions at one year.\33\ A term of one year corresponds with 
    naturally repeating weather and planning cycles for production, 
    transportation, and storage. A term of one year also corresponds with 
    the period used to calculate long-term rates.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \33\ 18 CFR 284.221(d)(2) (right of first refusal applies to 
    contracts with a term of one year or more); Pipeline Service 
    Obligations and Revisions to Regulations Governing Self-Implementing 
    Transportation Under Part 284 of the Commission's Regulations, Order 
    No. 636-A, 57 FR 36128 (Aug. 12, 1992), FERC Stats. & Regs. 
    Regulations Preambles [Jan. 1991-June 1996] para. 30,950, at 30,627 
    (Aug. 3, 1992).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission, however, requests comment on whether a shorter 
    period, such as five months, should be used. If a period of less than 
    one year were chosen, it could either be a discrete period (e.g., 
    November through March) or could refer to any transaction with a term 
    of less than the chosen period. A five month period, for instance, 
    would generally correspond to the length of time of the heating 
    season.\34\ The use of a period of less than one year could reduce the 
    outlay that any shipper would have to make in order to buy
    
    [[Page 42991]]
    
    capacity at cost-based rates to avoid the potential exercise of market 
    power. \35\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \34\ In defining short-term for the purposes of capacity release 
    transactions, the industry, through the Gas Industry Standards 
    Board, defined short-term releases as releases of less than five 
    months. 18 CFR 284.10(b)(1)(v), Capacity Release Related Standards 
    5.3.2.
        \35\ For instance, under a five month definition, the maximum 
    charge a shipper would have to incur to purchase long-term capacity 
    would be the current monthly rate times five.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    B. Legal Basis for the Proposed Regulatory Change
    
        The Commission's statutory responsibility under the Natural Gas Act 
    (NGA) is to establish rates that are just and reasonable and that 
    protect consumers of natural gas from the exercise of monopoly power by 
    pipelines.\36\ In addition, the Commission has the obligation, under 
    the Wellhead Decontrol Act, to structure its regulatory framework to 
    ``improve [the] competitive structure [of the natural gas industry] in 
    order to maximize the benefits of [wellhead] decontrol.'' \37\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \36\ FPC v. Hope Natural Gas Co., 320 U.S. 591, 610 (1944); 
    Associated Gas Distributors v. FERC, 824 F.2d 981, 995 (D.C. Cir. 
    1987), cert. denied, 485 U.S. 1006 (1988) (``The Natural Gas Act has 
    the fundamental purpose of protecting interstate gas consumers from 
    pipelines' monopoly power.'').
        \37\ Natural Gas Decontrol Act of 1989, H.R. Rep. No. 101-29, 
    101st Cong., 1st Sess., at 6 (1989); Pipeline Service Obligations 
    and Revisions to Regulations Governing Self-Implementing 
    Transportation Under Part 284 of the Commission's Regulations, Order 
    No. 636, 57 FR 13267 (Apr. 16, 1992), FERC Stats. & Regs. 
    Regulations Preambles [Jan. 1991-June 1996] para. 30,939, at 30,932 
    (Apr. 8, 1992).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The courts have recognized that the Commission needs to be able to 
    develop flexible pricing programs that accommodate its regulation to 
    the needs of the marketplace. The Commission is not bound to ``use any 
    single pricing formula'' in determining just and reasonable rates,\38\ 
    and cost-based regulation can be relaxed when the overall ``regulatory 
    scheme'' ensures that rates are within a zone of reasonableness.\39\ 
    The case law makes clear that flexible rate regulation is permissible 
    as long as, on balance, the benefits of the program outweigh the 
    potential risks, and the Commission takes reasonable measures to 
    protect against the exercise of market power, even though not every 
    transaction would be free of market power.\40\ In Environmental Action 
    v. FERC, the court approved a flexible pricing program, which fostered 
    efficient trading of energy and transmission service, even though the 
    program created a risk that market power could be exercised over 
    captive customers. Given the benefits of effective trading and the 
    protections adopted by the Commission to limit the potential exercise 
    of market power, the court concluded that the Commission acted 
    reasonably in approving the program despite the potential risks.\41\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \38\ Elizabethtown Gas Company v. FERC, 10 F.3d 866, 870 (D.C. 
    Cir. 1993) (approving market-based rates).
        \39\ See Farmers Union Central Exchange v. FERC, 734 F.2d 1486, 
    1509-10 (D.C. Cir. 1984).
        \40\ Environmental Action v. FERC, 996 F.2d 401, 408, 411 (D.C. 
    Cir. 1993) (approving flexible pricing program to permit efficient 
    trading of electric power).
        \41\ As the court stated:
        We acknowledge that the flexible pricing that fosters trading 
    among members of the Pool also permits price discrimination 
    especially against captive utilities. Yet, given the benefits of 
    this trading, the limited number of captive members, and the 
    provisions for monitoring transactions and remedying any abuses of 
    market power, we do not find that the Commission acted arbitrarily 
    when it approved the use of flexible prices despite their admitted 
    risk.
         996 F.2d at 411.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission believes the model it is proposing satisfies the 
    Commission's statutory obligations by achieving the appropriate balance 
    between the benefits to be garnered from efficient trading in the 
    short-term market and the protection needed against the exercise of 
    market power. As discussed earlier, removing maximum rate regulation 
    from the short-term market provides significant benefits by allowing 
    markets to efficiently allocate capacity in an environment in which 
    cost-based solutions do not accommodate the volatile price changes in 
    the industry.
        The potential risk of this approach is that it could give pipelines 
    or shippers greater latitude to exercise market power during peak 
    periods. Although competition clearly has increased in the short-term 
    market, the Commission is not making a finding that the short-term 
    market is sufficiently competitive to satisfy its traditional market 
    power analysis. Nor is the Commission making a finding that the 
    proposals in this NOPR will necessarily create a fully competitive 
    market. Rather, as discussed below, the proposed approach in this NOPR 
    is intended to place effective limits on the ability of pipelines and 
    shippers to exercise market power by enhancing competitive options in 
    the short-term market, mitigating market power by limiting the ability 
    to withhold capacity and price discriminate, and monitoring the 
    marketplace.
        The proposed approach should provide benefits to all shippers--both 
    those holding long-term capacity, and those purchasing short-term 
    capacity. Long-term capacity holders would still be protected by the 
    cost-based rate in the long-term market and would benefit by being able 
    to realize the value of their long-term capacity. Shippers relying on 
    the short-term market would not be unreasonably harmed since the 
    proposals in the NOPR are designed to protect them against the 
    withholding of capacity and price discrimination, both during peak and 
    off-peak periods. At the same time, short-term shippers would benefit 
    because the proposals would help to create a more efficient marketplace 
    during peak periods, with capacity allocated to those valuing it most, 
    prices undistorted by regulatory allocation priorities, clearer price 
    signals, and more open, transparent, and efficient capacity 
    allocations. These benefits are fully described below.
        The approach proposed here also appears better suited than other 
    potential approaches for responding to the changing dynamics of the 
    short-term market. The Commission, however, requests comment on whether 
    this proposal is the best approach for protecting against market power 
    given the realities of the short-term market. Commenters should address 
    whether the Commission should seek evidence to determine whether it can 
    make a finding that the market is competitive or pursue other 
    regulatory approaches.
    1. Protection Against the Exercise of Market Power by Pipelines and 
    Shippers
        The Commission's primary responsibility is to protect against the 
    exercise of monopoly power by pipelines. Even under the current maximum 
    rate approach, such protection is not absolute. Pipelines are able to 
    price discriminate below the existing price cap.
        The approach proposed here seeks to control the pipelines' exercise 
    of monopoly power in a different way, by enhancing the competition from 
    firm shippers releasing capacity, by requiring pipeline capacity to be 
    sold through an auction that limits the ability to withhold capacity, 
    and by monitoring the marketplace for evidence of the exercise of 
    monopoly power. Moreover, the proposed approach would reduce the 
    ability of pipelines to withhold future capacity (by not expanding 
    their systems) in order to increase price and earn a supra-competitive 
    rate of return. If pipelines sought to limit capacity in order to earn 
    high returns on short-term transactions, shippers could purchase long-
    term capacity at cost-based rates and capture the profit opportunities 
    in the short-term market for themselves by releasing the capacity. 
    Further, any revenues from short-term sales would be accounted for in 
    the pipeline's next rate case ensuring that the long-term benefits of 
    increased revenue from sales of short-term capacity go to the long-term 
    firm capacity holders. The Commission also could act under section 5 of 
    the NGA in cases where monitoring revealed that
    
    [[Page 42992]]
    
    the market rate is not just and reasonable.\42\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \42\ See Elizabethtown, 10 F.3d at 870 (Commission can use its 
    section 5 authority to assure that market-based rates are just and 
    reasonable); Environmental Action, 996 F.2d at 411 (emphasizing 
    provisions for monitoring market-based rates to protect against 
    exercise of market power).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The approach proposed here also can be expected to limit the 
    exercise of market power by firm capacity holders. Releasing shippers 
    face competition from other releasing shippers and from the sale of 
    pipeline firm and interruptible service. Firm capacity holders should 
    not be able to withhold capacity to raise price, because if they do not 
    use their capacity it then becomes available either as interruptible or 
    short-term firm capacity from the pipeline. The proposed auction would 
    then require the pipeline to sell that capacity at a market-determined 
    price. The auction also would limit the ability of firm capacity 
    holders to unduly discriminate. Moreover, the pipelines' ability to 
    build additional capacity is a final protection against releasing 
    shippers' exercise of market power. If the pipeline observes shippers 
    earning high returns from constrained capacity, the pipelines have 
    every incentive to try to capture those returns by building additional 
    capacity to satisfy that demand.
        2. Protection for Shippers Relying on Long-term and Short-term 
    Capacity
        While the Commission has an obligation to consider the interests of 
    all shippers, its paramount obligation is to protect long-term firm 
    capacity holders that cannot risk going without long-term 
    capacity.43 Interruptible or short-term shippers, by 
    definition, take the risk that they may be unable to acquire 
    capacity.44 The proposed regulatory model would protect 
    those shippers holding long-term capacity, while at the same time not 
    putting short-term shippers at unreasonable risk and perhaps even 
    providing them with benefits.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \43\ See Maryland People's Counsel v. FERC, 761 F.2d 768 (D.C. 
    Cir. 1985); Maryland People's Counsel v. FERC, 761 F.2d 780 (D.C. 
    Cir. 1985) (remanding special marketing program because it excluded 
    core captive customers); Environmental Action, 761 F.2d at 411 
    (permitting flexible pricing program even though there was some 
    possibility of discrimination against captive utilities).
        \44\ See American Gas Association v. FERC, 912 F.2d 1496, 1518 
    (D.C. Cir. 1990). The court remanded the Commission's decision to 
    permit pre-granted abandonment of all long-term contracts, because 
    of a concern about the pipeline's ability to exercise monopoly 
    market power over long-term capacity holders. The court, however, 
    found that holders of interruptible and short-term services did not 
    need similar protection against the exercise of pipeline monopoly 
    power.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Under the proposed approach, shippers holding long-term capacity 
    would continue to receive the traditional protection accorded them 
    because long-term capacity would still be subject to cost-based 
    regulation. Indeed, removal of the price cap for short-term 
    transactions should benefit long-term capacity holders, because it 
    would permit them to recover more of their reservation charges during 
    peak periods. For those shippers holding long-term contracts that are 
    unable to sell delivered gas, the price cap currently limits their 
    ability to recover their reservation charges by releasing capacity 
    during peak periods when capacity is valuable. On the other hand, 
    during off-peak periods, competition from other releasers or the 
    pipeline may limit a shipper's ability to recover its reservation 
    charges. At the same time, interruptible or short-term shippers benefit 
    from the competition during off-peak periods because they pay prices 
    lower than what the pipeline charged when it was the sole supplier of 
    capacity. Thus, removal of the rate cap would permit long-term firm 
    capacity holders to realize the full value of their transportation 
    capacity during both peak and off-peak periods.
        Even if a long-term firm capacity holder is unable to release its 
    own capacity during a peak period, it may benefit if the pipeline can 
    charge competitive rates for peak period capacity. In the pipeline's 
    next rate case, the revenue received from such sales would be used to 
    reduce the reservation charges for firm customers.
        Nonetheless, the Commission expects that the proposed regulatory 
    model would not put shippers in the short-term market at unreasonable 
    risk and may even benefit them. These shippers would have the option of 
    buying long-term capacity at regulated cost-based rates, which should 
    help to limit the potential exercise of market power in the short-term 
    market. Pipelines would continue to be required to sell long-term 
    capacity to anyone offering the maximum rate regardless of the rates 
    bid for short-term capacity. Further, to ensure that long-term capacity 
    is available, the Commission would examine closely pipeline refusals to 
    construct taps requested by customers as well as pipeline refusals to 
    construct new capacity when demand for new construction exists.
        This model also should work to the benefit of short-term customers 
    during both off-peak and peak periods. During peak periods, the price 
    cap offers only limited protection against the exercise of market 
    power, and may actually create inefficiency which reduces short-term 
    shippers' ability to obtain capacity when they need it. During peak 
    periods, when capacity is constrained, short-term customers currently 
    run a significant risk that they may be unable to obtain capacity from 
    the pipeline even if they place the highest value on that capacity. If 
    they instead seek to acquire capacity through a delivered gas 
    transaction, they receive little protection against the exercise of 
    market power and the price for such gas may be higher than it would be 
    in a more efficient market. By removing the price cap, but at the same 
    time offering initiatives for enhancing competition among capacity 
    alternatives, the approach proposed in this NOPR should be more 
    effective than the current system in creating a transparent and 
    efficient short-term market in which shippers, even on peak, can 
    acquire gas and capacity at efficient market-clearing prices.
        During off-peak periods, the rate cap provides little protection 
    against the exercise of market power, because pipelines and shippers 
    are not required to sell capacity at rates below the maximum rate. The 
    proposals for increasing competition and the auction ought to limit the 
    pipelines' ability to exercise market power or price discriminate so 
    all short-term shippers would be paying prices closer to a competitive 
    level.
    3. Alternative Approaches for Regulating the Short-Term Transportation 
    Market
        The approach proposed in this NOPR appears better suited than other 
    possible methods of dealing with the dynamics of the short-term 
    transportation market.
        An alternative approach would be to continue the current maximum 
    rate system, but allow pipelines and firm capacity holders to seek 
    removal of the cap in the short-term market upon a demonstration that 
    they cannot exercise market power. In effect, this approach presumes 
    market power is present and requires the parties to try to predict, 
    through market concentration data or other approaches, whether market 
    power will be exercised if the rate cap is removed. This is essentially 
    the approach the Commission uses with respect to market power in its 
    Alternative Rate Design policy, which focuses on the exercise of market 
    power in the long-term market for pipeline capacity.45
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \45\ Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service Ratemaking for 
    Natural Gas Pipelines, and Regulation of Negotiated Transportation 
    Services of Natural Gas Pipelines, 61 FR 4633 (Feb. 7, 1996), 74 
    FERC para. 61,076 (1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The approach of screening for market power is certainly a possible 
    alternative, but it would move the Commission in a direction very 
    different from the one
    
    [[Page 42993]]
    
    proposed here. The approach proposed here does not rely on a finding of 
    a lack of market power, relying instead on regulatory measures to 
    reduce or limit the exercise of market power.
        The market power screen, in contrast, would require the Commission 
    to make a finding of lack of market power in each relevant market. This 
    not only could be a time consuming and daunting task to undertake on an 
    industry-wide basis, but it might have to be repeated periodically as 
    contracts expire or the competitive circumstances on individual 
    pipelines change. The market power screen approach also was developed 
    to isolate market power in circumstances in which the pipeline is the 
    sole source of capacity, and it, therefore, imposes a relatively heavy 
    evidentiary burden on pipelines seeking market-based rates. Such a 
    screen may not be discriminating enough or the most appropriate means 
    of dealing with market power in the short-term market where more 
    competition is clearly present. The use of the traditional market power 
    screen, therefore, might suggest the presence of market power in areas 
    that ought to be found reasonably competitive.
        Moreover, in cases where the concentration data do not satisfy the 
    market power screen, the market analysis approach would continue to 
    rely on maximum rate regulation which, as discussed earlier, may not be 
    very effective in protecting against market power in the short-term 
    market and also promotes more inefficient short-term markets. The 
    Commission, however, requests comment on whether a modified version of 
    the market power screen could and should be developed for the short-
    term market that would be easier to administer and could determine 
    whether market power is a significant problem.
        Another cost-of-service option would be to attempt to develop a 
    cost-based, seasonal rate design that would better approximate pricing 
    activity that would occur during peak and off-peak periods. But price 
    swings can be very large on a daily, weekly, or monthly basis, making 
    the development of a rate structure that would accurately reflect 
    competitive market conditions particularly difficult. Moreover, if the 
    price cap is raised high enough to accommodate peak period competitive 
    prices, this approach is little different than simply removing the rate 
    cap, since it would afford firms with market power substantial latitude 
    to exercise that power at prices below the price cap.46
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \46\ See Environmental Action, 996 F.2d 401 (approving a 
    flexible pricing program for an electric power pool with a rate 
    ceiling based on the most valuable and expensive transportation 
    service).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Of the regulatory options available, the proposed regulatory model 
    appears to create the best balance between achieving the Commission's 
    objectives of preventing the exercise of market power and creating a 
    regulatory environment that fosters a competitive, efficient commodity 
    market that is fair to all shippers. This approach would free the 
    short-term market from regulatory impediments that prevent the market 
    from responding to the competitive supply and demand forces that may 
    result in competitive prices exceeding the price cap. At the same time, 
    the proposals to increase competition in the short-term market should 
    help to keep the prices for most transactions within reasonable levels. 
    Because firm shippers would be better able to release capacity in 
    competition with the pipelines, the pipelines' ability to exercise 
    market power would be limited. At the same time, firm shippers' ability 
    to exercise market power would be restrained because, if they tried to 
    withhold capacity to raise prices, the pipelines would be required to 
    sell that capacity at market clearing prices. The proposed auction also 
    would restrain the ability of both pipelines and firm shippers to 
    exercise market power and to unduly discriminate in the allocation of 
    capacity. Further, the overall scheme of the proposal limits the 
    pipelines' ability to charge monopoly prices because shippers can 
    discipline the pipelines' exercise of market power by purchasing long-
    term capacity at cost-based levels.
    
    C. Interrelated Proposals for Regulatory Change
    
        The principal focus of the regulatory changes proposed in this NOPR 
    is on improving efficiency and competition in the short-term 
    transportation market. Yet, the regulation of long-term transportation 
    service is an integral part of the Commission's proposal because 
    continued regulation of long-term services is an important back-stop to 
    protect against the pipelines' exercise of market power. Long-term and 
    short-term transportation services are linked in other ways since the 
    value of purchasing long-term capacity lies in its ability to insure 
    shippers against the risk of price swings in the short-term market. 
    Thus, the changing nature of short-term markets has a concomitant 
    effect on how shippers use the long-term market and, likewise, actions 
    affecting long-term contracts can affect the short-term market. For 
    example, if a pipeline can attract more shippers to its system, the 
    long-term rate will be reduced, which, in turn, would limit the ability 
    of pipelines to raise price in the short-term market. On the other 
    hand, policies discouraging shippers from entering long-term contracts 
    could reduce the extent of competition in the short-term market. 
    Because of the relationship between short-term and long-term services, 
    the Commission also is proposing in this NOPR initiatives to improve 
    competition and innovation in the market for long-term services and to 
    ensure that its regulatory policies in the long-term market do not bias 
    shippers' purchasing decisions.
        The Commission is proposing to give pipelines more flexibility in 
    negotiating rates and terms of service with individual shippers. 
    Allowing greater flexibility in contract terms for long-term service 
    can be an important element in the allocation of risk between pipelines 
    and potential customers. Permitting negotiation of services will 
    provide an incentive for pipelines to innovate and create additional 
    value in transportation service.\47\ Also, negotiated rates and 
    services may permit the pipelines to attract new customers, which would 
    reduce reservation charges for existing customers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \47\ In unregulated and even in regulated industries, sellers 
    often create innovative service options for individual customers 
    while still providing a basic service to all. For instance, 
    telecommunication firms provide specialized services for small and 
    large businesses while still providing standard service to the 
    public.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        On the other hand, allowing the pipelines to negotiate individual 
    terms of service creates the possibility of discrimination against 
    captive customers as well as a risk that such terms could degrade 
    competition in the short-term market by limiting the range of capacity 
    alternatives available to shippers. To fully realize the benefits from 
    negotiated services while reducing the risks, the Commission is 
    proposing to permit pipelines and shippers to enter into contracts for 
    negotiated services, while also proposing criteria to protect against 
    the risks of undue discrimination or impairment of the competitiveness 
    of the short-term market.
        Further, to ensure that contracting decisions are made efficiently, 
    regulatory policies should not unfairly bias shippers' contracting 
    decisions. Some Commission policies, like the right of first refusal, 
    may well create an asymmetry in the risks facing pipelines and capacity 
    purchasers and bias shippers towards shorter term contracts. The 
    Commission, therefore, is proposing certain changes in regulatory 
    policy to
    
    [[Page 42994]]
    
    eliminate provisions that may tilt shipper decisions towards the 
    purchase of short-term capacity.
        The construction of new capacity also affects competition in the 
    short-term market. For instance, the ability of shippers to purchase 
    long-term capacity at cost-based rates is a protection against the 
    exercise of market power in the short-term market. The Commission is, 
    therefore, considering changes in certificate policy so that these 
    policies do not unnecessarily inhibit competition.
        In addition, to better reflect the changing nature of services in 
    the short-term market and to consolidate pipeline reporting 
    requirements under Part 284, the Commission is proposing to reorganize 
    Part 284 to put the regulations into a more logical order.\48\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \48\ The references in this NOPR to proposed regulatory changes 
    are to the new regulatory sections. References to existing 
    regulations are to the existing regulatory framework.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    III. Creating Greater Competition Among Short-Term Service 
    Offerings
    
        Increasing competition is the best antidote to market power. As 
    long as buyers have good alternative sources of capacity, no seller can 
    exercise market power, because any attempt to raise price above the 
    competitive level will result in the buyer moving to another 
    seller.\49\ Prior to Order No. 636, the pipeline was the only source of 
    both long-term and short-term capacity. The Commission's establishment, 
    in Order No. 636, of the capacity release mechanism has significantly 
    increased competition on most pipelines both between the pipeline and 
    shippers and among shippers themselves.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \49\ Market power can be exercised in two ways. A holder of 
    capacity may withhold capacity from the market to drive up the price 
    that all shippers pay for the remaining capacity, or it can price 
    discriminate by charging captive customers more than those customers 
    with more alternatives. In either case, however, competition will 
    prevent the exercise of market power.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        But there remain means of enhancing competition and improving the 
    substitutability of capacity alternatives. Three such improvements are 
    to make nomination and scheduling procedures more uniform for all 
    short-term services; provide shippers with a greater ability to segment 
    capacity and use alternate receipt and delivery points so 
    transportation alternatives are more comparable; and employ auctions 
    for all capacity to limit the ability of pipelines or shippers to 
    withhold capacity or discriminate. In addition, the Commission is 
    proposing changes to its reporting requirements to ensure that 
    comparable information about pipeline and release transactions is 
    provided. Improved information enables shippers to make more informed 
    capacity choices while it also permits the Commission and the industry 
    to monitor transactions for the potential exercise of market power in 
    the event the Commission's efforts to mitigate market power are not 
    successful. The Commission is committed to take appropriate and timely 
    action in individual cases to deal with the exercise of market power. 
    To this end, the Commission is in the process of considering 
    improvements to its procedures for handling complaints.\50\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \50\ See Compliant Procedures, Docket No. RM98-13-000 (issued 
    contemporaneously with this NOPR).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    A. Nomination Equality
    
        In order to foster a more competitive short-term market, all forms 
    of transportation--pipeline interruptible and short-term firm capacity, 
    released capacity, and delivered sales transactions--must be able to 
    compete on as equal a basis as possible. While there are obviously 
    differences in rights associated with the different types of capacity, 
    the Commission is concerned that differences in nomination and 
    scheduling procedures for capacity release inhibit the ability of 
    capacity release transactions to compete with pipeline capacity. The 
    Commission, however, requests comment on whether the existing 
    differences in nomination and scheduling procedures for capacity 
    release transactions reflect important differences in the nature of the 
    services that should be preserved.
        Under current regulations, pipelines can sell their interruptible 
    and short-term services at any time and shippers can schedule such 
    services at the earliest available nomination opportunity. Similarly, 
    capacity holders making delivered sales can nominate and schedule at 
    every available opportunity. In contrast, nomination and scheduling 
    opportunities under capacity release transactions currently are 
    significantly circumscribed.
        Under Commission regulations, shippers currently submit their daily 
    nominations at 11:30 a.m. to take effect at 9 a.m. the next gas day. 
    Pipelines presently are required to provide shippers at least one 
    intra-day nomination change after the 11:30 a.m. nomination, although 
    many pipelines provide additional intra-day nomination opportunities. 
    While a pipeline may sell interruptible or short-term firm service and 
    permit the recipient of that service to submit a nomination at the 
    earliest available nomination opportunity, shippers consummating a 
    release transaction must do so prior to 9 a.m. and can only submit a 
    nomination at 11:30 a.m. for the next gas day. They cannot consummate a 
    release transaction later than 9 a.m., nor can the replacement shipper 
    utilize an intra-day nomination opportunity to submit a nomination for 
    the current gas day.
        The disparate treatment of capacity release transactions, if left 
    uncorrected, promises to become even more severe as a result of the 
    industry's agreement to enhance intra-day nomination opportunities. In 
    a final rule issued on July 15, 1998,51 the Commission 
    adopted the consensus agreement of the Gas Industry Standards Board 
    (GISB) to expand shippers' intra-day nomination opportunities by 
    establishing three synchronized intra-day nomination periods across the 
    grid. Under the industry's schedule, the three synchronization times 
    are 6 p.m. (for the next gas day), 10 a.m. and 5 p.m. (for the current 
    gas day). A shipper obtaining short-term firm or interruptible capacity 
    from the pipeline, or making a delivered sales transaction, will be 
    able to submit a nomination at any of these intra-day nomination 
    opportunities. Significantly, however, a replacement shipper cannot 
    acquire released capacity immediately prior to these intra-day 
    nomination times and nominate at these times. The replacement shipper 
    must consummate a capacity release deal by 9 a.m. and must wait a full 
    day before it can flow gas under the release transaction.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \51\ Standards For Business Practices Of Interstate Natural Gas 
    Pipelines, Final Rule, 63 FR 39509 (July 23, 1998), 84 FERC para. 
    61,031 (Jul. 15, 1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In order to place capacity release transactions on a more equal 
    footing with pipeline services, the Commission is proposing, in 
    proposed section 284.13(c)(1)(ii), that pipelines provide purchasers of 
    released capacity, like shippers purchasing capacity from the pipeline, 
    with the opportunity to submit a nomination at the first available 
    opportunity after consummation of the deal. This will enable shippers, 
    for instance, to acquire released capacity at any of the nomination or 
    intra-day nomination synchronization times and nominate gas coincident 
    with their acquisition of capacity.
        In some cases, pipelines currently require replacement shippers to 
    pass a credit-worthiness check and execute contracts prior to 
    nominating. Under the proposed regulation, such requirements could not 
    prevent a replacement shipper from nominating when it completes the 
    release transaction. Proposed section 284.13(c)(1)(ii) would provide 
    that a pipeline that requires the replacement shipper to enter into a 
    contract must
    
    [[Page 42995]]
    
    issue the contract within one hour of submission of the transaction 
    52 and that the requirement for contracting must not inhibit 
    the ability to submit a nomination at the time the transaction is 
    complete.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \52\ The current regulations require pipelines to issue 
    contracts within one hour. 18 CFR 284.10(b)(1)(v), Capacity Release 
    Related Standards 5.3.2.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Pipelines have available several procedures which they can use to 
    protect themselves against the credit risk of the replacement shipper. 
    The pipelines can institute procedures under which replacement shippers 
    receive pre-approval of their credit-worthiness or receive a master 
    contract, like those used for interruptible shippers, permitting the 
    replacement shipper to nominate under that contract at any 
    time.53 For replacement shippers that do not have a master 
    contract, the pipeline could provide a contract number for nominating 
    as soon as the pipeline is notified of the release transaction. For 
    replacement shippers that have not received pre-approved credit, the 
    releasing shipper may agree to be liable for any usage charges incurred 
    by the replacement shipper while the pipeline conducts the credit-
    worthiness check.54
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \53\ The Commission previously issued a proposed rule suggesting 
    that pipelines use pre-approved credit-worthiness procedures for 
    replacement shippers. Secondary Market Transactions on Interstate 
    Natural Gas Pipelines, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 61 FR 41046 
    (Aug. 7, 1996), IV FERC Stats. & Regs. Proposed Regulations para. 
    32,520 (Jul. 31, 1996). In the comments on the proposal, the 
    pipelines, in general, did not object to the use of pre-approval for 
    credit-worthiness or master contracts. Tenneco Energy objected only 
    to the use of master contracts, arguing that because capacity 
    release is a firm service, the pipeline needs prior notice of the 
    specific terms of the release including the firm transportation 
    quantity, the zones of the release, and the rights to primary and 
    secondary points.
        \54\ Releasing shippers already are responsible for all 
    reservation charges under the Commission's capacity release 
    regulations. 18 CFR 284.243(f).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    B. Segmentation and Flexibility of Receipt and Delivery Points
    
    1. Background
        In Order No. 636, the Commission established two principles that 
    are important to creating efficient competition between holders of 
    capacity and the pipelines: segmentation of capacity and the ability of 
    shippers to use alternative receipt and delivery points. Segmentation 
    refers to the ability of firm capacity holders to subdivide their 
    capacity into segments to enhance the value of the capacity and the 
    capacity holders' ability to compete with the pipeline. In the example 
    used in Order No. 636, a shipper holding firm capacity from a primary 
    receipt point in the Gulf of Mexico to primary delivery points in New 
    York could release that capacity to a replacement shipper moving gas 
    from the Gulf to Atlanta while the New York releasing shipper could 
    inject gas downstream of Atlanta and use the remainder of the capacity 
    to deliver the gas to New York. In order for such a transaction to 
    work, both the releasing and replacement shippers need the right to 
    change their receipt and delivery points from the primary points in 
    their contract to use other available points.
        Without the ability to segment and use alternate points, the New 
    York releasing shipper in the example would not be an effective 
    competitor to another shipper holding firm primary point capacity at 
    Atlanta. The ability to segment capacity and use alternate points, 
    therefore, provides a potential replacement shipper who wants to ship 
    to Atlanta with additional capacity options. It can buy from the 
    releasing shipper holding primary point capacity in Atlanta or from the 
    New York releasing shipper or any other shipper holding capacity 
    downstream of Atlanta.
        However, under current Commission policies, the ability of the 
    releasing shipper in New York to compete with the pipeline or with the 
    shipper in Atlanta may be limited. Under the Commission's current 
    policies, the releasing shipper in New York only has a secondary 
    delivery point right at Atlanta, which is inferior to the primary point 
    right of the releasing shipper holding primary point rights at Atlanta. 
    In other words, if the pipeline is unable to make both deliveries to 
    Atlanta, the shipper with the primary right at Atlanta will be given 
    delivery priority over the releasing shipper in New York or the 
    replacement shipper buying capacity from the New York shipper, each of 
    which only has secondary point rights at Atlanta. To the extent that 
    this is a possibility, capacity from the releasing shipper in New York 
    is not equal in quality or fully competitive with the capacity from the 
    shipper holding primary point rights at Atlanta.
        Receipt and delivery point flexibility is not applied consistently 
    across pipelines, and pipelines do not treat different types of 
    segmentation similarly. During the restructuring proceedings mandated 
    by Order No. 636, the Commission permitted certain pipelines to adopt 
    tariff provisions under which releasing shippers would lose their 
    rights to primary receipt or delivery points if replacement shippers 
    changed primary points under the release.55 The Commission 
    permitted such restrictions where the pipelines had pre-existing tariff 
    provisions that did not permit shippers' primary receipt and delivery 
    point CD rights to exceed their mainline rights. To prevent the 
    possible loss of primary point rights, the releasing shipper would have 
    to include a condition in the release prohibiting the replacement 
    shipper from changing primary points. The Commission, however, sought 
    to minimize the effect of this restriction on segmented releases by 
    adopting a policy for segmented releases under which:
    
        \55\ See Transwestern Pipeline Company, 62 FERC at 61,659, 63 
    FERC at 61,911-12 (1993); El Paso Natural Gas Company, 62 FERC para. 
    61,311, at 62,982-83 (1993).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        the releasing and replacement shippers must be treated as 
    separate shippers with separate contract demands. Thus, the 
    releasing shipper may reserve primary points on the unreleased 
    segment up to its capacity entitlement on that segment, while the 
    replacement shipper simultaneously reserves primary points on the 
    released segment up to its capacity on that segment.56
    
        \56\ Texas Eastern Transmission Corporation, 63 FERC para. 
    61,100, at 61,452 (1993). El Paso Natural Gas Company, 62 FERC para. 
    63,311, at 62,991. See also Transwestern Pipeline Company, 61 FERC 
    para. 61,332, at 62,232 (1992).
    
        Under this policy [hereinafter referred to as the Texas Eastern/El 
    Paso policy], the releasing shipper could protect its delivery point 
    rights by choosing Atlanta as its primary receipt point and New York as 
    its primary delivery point, while the replacement shipper designate its 
    primary receipt point as the Gulf and Atlanta as its primary delivery 
    point. However, it is not clear whether all pipelines adhere to this 
    policy.57
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \57\ See Colorado Interstate Gas Company FERC Gas Tariff, First 
    Revised Volume No. 1, Third Revised Sheet No. 254 (replacement 
    shippers are not permitted to change primary points and can nominate 
    only the original primary or at secondary points).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Even on those pipelines following the Texas Eastern/El Paso policy, 
    replacement shippers face limitations on their ability to change 
    primary receipt and delivery points.58 However, even at the 
    time the Commission permitted those pipelines with pre-existing tariff 
    restrictions on receipt and delivery point rights to continue such 
    restrictions, it was skeptical about the justifications for imposing 
    such limits.59 In fact, the Commission rejected applications 
    to impose similar
    
    [[Page 42996]]
    
    restrictions by pipelines without pre-existing 
    restrictions.60 In these cases, the Commission required 
    pipelines to permit replacement shippers to change primary points 
    without releasing shippers losing their right to return to their 
    original primary point at the end of the release. As the Commission 
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    explained in Northwest:
    
        \58\ For example, if the replacement shipper seeks to change its 
    primary receipt point right from the Gulf to another point, then the 
    releasing New York shipper might lose the ability to return to its 
    primary Gulf receipt point at the end of the release.
        \59\ See Transwestern Pipeline Company, 62 FERC at 61,659, 63 
    FERC at 61,911-12 (1993); El Paso Natural Gas Company, 62 FERC para. 
    61,311, at 62,982-83 (1993).
    
        \60\ See Northwest Pipeline Company, 63 FERC para. 61,124, at 
    61,806-08 n.72 (1993).
    
        Northwest's restriction on replacement shippers' ability to 
    designate primary receipt or delivery points different from those of 
    the releasing shipper unless the releasing shipper agrees to 
    relinquish the original primary point could operate to limit or 
    impair capacity release transactions. A releasing shipper may be 
    unwilling to enter into a short term release if, in so doing, it 
    loses priority to its primary receipt and delivery points for the 
    remainder of a 20 year contract. Replacement shippers may be 
    reluctant to bid on mainline capacity if they cannot be assured of 
    receipt and delivery point capacity at available points (not subject 
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    to bumping by shippers coming later in time).61
    
        \61\ Northwest Pipeline Company, 63 FERC para. 61,124, at 61,807 
    (1993). See also Questar Pipeline Company, 62 FERC para. 61,192, at 
    62,306 (1993).
    
        Under both the Texas Eastern/El Paso and Northwest policies, 
    replacement shippers can change primary points only if the new point is 
    available and is not fully subscribed. In addition, shippers can only 
    change to available points that are within the capacity path for which 
    they paid. Pipelines, therefore, are not required to permit shippers to 
    change primary points if doing so would mean that the pipeline's 
    mainline capacity would be oversubscribed.
        During the restructuring proceedings, the Commission addressed 
    segmentation only in the context of release transactions. It did not 
    address whether a shipper could segment capacity, for instance, by 
    delivering gas to Atlanta and then shipping to New York for its own 
    use. It is not clear whether pipelines permit such transactions. Even 
    if pipelines do permit the segmented transaction, the shipper may be 
    unable to designate both Atlanta and New York as primary delivery 
    points.
        In the Commission's NOPR on secondary market transactions 
    (Secondary Market NOPR),62 the Commission requested comment 
    on whether it needed to provide more flexibility for shippers and 
    replacement shippers to change primary points. Most shippers supported 
    providing more flexibility, arguing that a shipper using capacity on a 
    secondary basis within the primary path has the same rights afforded 
    transportation between primary points. The pipelines, however, opposed 
    increased flexibility, arguing that allowing releasing shippers to 
    return to previously vacated points would require the pipeline to hold 
    otherwise available capacity in reserve for shippers without collecting 
    reservation charges for that capacity.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \62\ Secondary Market Transactions on Interstate Natural Gas 
    Pipelines, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 61 FR 41046 (Aug. 7, 
    1996), IV FERC Stats. & Regs. Proposed Regulations para. 32,520 
    (Jul. 31, 1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    2. Is There a Need To Revise Policies To Improve Competition Between 
    Primary and Alternate Point Capacity?
        Shippers' rights to segment and use receipt and delivery points 
    clearly differ across pipelines. In today's gas market, shippers are 
    acquiring capacity from multiple sources and need the ability to use 
    their capacity more flexibly. The issue is whether, in operation, the 
    current system fairly allocates capacity so no changes need to be made 
    to the policies or whether changes are necessary to maximize the extent 
    of competition in the short-term market. The concerns involve two 
    interrelated areas: segmentation policy, including priorities for 
    primary and secondary points, and the confirmation process between 
    pipelines and between pipelines and other entities, such as LDCs.
        The first concern, as discussed above, is whether on some 
    pipelines, replacement shippers may be unable to use certain receipt or 
    delivery points as primary points under segmented release transactions 
    and whether this significantly limits shippers' flexibility or raises 
    transaction costs. These limitations would be more severe on pipelines 
    that do not follow the Texas Eastern/El Paso policy by permitting both 
    releasing shippers and replacement shippers on segmented releases to 
    hold primary point capacity equal to their contract demand.
        On some pipelines, delivery or receipt point priorities may be used 
    to determine priorities over constrained mainline capacity even if both 
    shippers have equal firm rights over the constrained mainline. For 
    example, if pipelines are unable to schedule competing firm 
    nominations, the pipelines may give higher priority to shippers moving 
    between primary firm points over shippers moving to secondary points 
    even if both sets of shippers have equal firm rights past the area that 
    has become constrained.63 It is not clear how frequently 
    pipelines use receipt or delivery point priority to allocate mainline 
    capacity in the event of constraints or whether the use of such an 
    allocation policy significantly limits shippers' flexibility.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \63\ See El Paso Natural Gas Company, 81 FERC para. 61,174 
    (1997) (because the pipeline does not assign receipt point rights, 
    it effectively allocates constrained mainline capacity based on 
    whether customers are nominating to primary or secondary delivery 
    points).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Second, confirmation practices may affect the allocation of primary 
    and secondary capacity at interconnects between two pipelines (which 
    includes interconnects between interstate and intrastate pipelines and 
    interstate pipelines and local distribution companies). Suppose there 
    are two shippers with firm capacity on pipeline A that covers an 
    interconnect with pipeline B, but shipper 1 holds the interconnect as a 
    primary delivery point and shipper 2 as a secondary delivery point. 
    Further, suppose there is insufficient capacity to effect both 
    deliveries and shipper 1 holds only interruptible capacity on pipeline 
    B, while shipper 2 holds firm capacity on pipeline B.
    
    BILLING CODE 6717-01-P
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP11AU98.001
    
    
    
    [[Page 42997]]
    
    
    BILLING CODE 6717-01-C
    Shipper 1: Pipeline A--Firm Primary at Delivery Point; Pipeline B--
    Interruptible at Receipt Point
    Shipper 2: Pipeline A--Firm Secondary at Delivery Point; Pipeline B--
    Firm Secondary at Receipt Point
    
    If both pipelines independently allocate capacity according to their 
    tariff-based priorities before seeking confirmation, neither shipper 
    would be able to flow, even though shipper 2 has firm capacity on both 
    pipelines.64
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \64\ Pipeline A would allocate the delivery point right to 
    shipper 1, whose primary firm right has priority over shipper 2's 
    secondary firm right. Pipeline B would allocate the receipt point 
    right to shipper 2, whose firm capacity right has priority over 
    shipper 1's interruptible capacity. Thus, the capacity allocations 
    would not match and neither would be confirmed.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In some contexts, however, gas flows may be determined by the 
    decision of the downstream party as to which gas it will 
    accept.65 If that were the case in the above example, 
    shipper 2 would flow gas because it had the priority right on 
    downstream pipeline B.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \65\ See, e.g., Southwest Gas Corporation v. El Paso Natural Gas 
    Company, 63 FERC para. 61,111 (1993) (finding that allocation of 
    delivery point rights had not abrogated Southwest's delivery point 
    priority since Southwest controlled the capacity to take gas away 
    from the delivery point). This case would seem to suggest that the 
    confirmation by the LDC takes precedence over upstream primary or 
    secondary delivery point rights.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The confirmation practices of pipelines in this situation are not 
    specified in Commission regulations or pipeline tariffs. Thus, the 
    result in this situation is not predictable, which may raise the costs 
    of doing business.
        The Commission is seeking comment on whether the current system 
    works efficiently or whether changes to the current practices are 
    needed. The comments should focus on: (1) How the current system works, 
    particularly with respect to any differences between interconnections 
    between pipelines and interconnections between pipelines and LDCs; (2) 
    whether the current system impedes efficient competition and 
    flexibility or raises transaction costs, and if so, whether the problem 
    results from current Commission policies, from a failure to understand 
    and adhere to those policies, or from a lack of uniform application of 
    Commission policies; and (3) whether changes in policies would help to 
    enhance competition and reduce the ability of pipelines or shippers to 
    exercise market power. To help focus comments, the Commission will lay 
    out below some options which commenters can consider. The first set of 
    options deal with segmentation and receipt and delivery point priority 
    issues, while the second deals with issues relating to pipeline 
    confirmation procedures.
        First, the current system under which receipt and delivery point 
    priorities are determined on a pipeline-by-pipeline basis could 
    continue. This option would be appropriate if current policies do not 
    unfairly restrict competition or if non-uniform rules are necessary due 
    to pipelines' differing operational capabilities.
        Second, all pipelines could be required to conform to the Texas 
    Eastern/El Paso requirement that, in a segmented release, both 
    releasing shippers and replacement shippers can designate available 
    primary receipt and delivery point capacity rights equal to their 
    contract demand. This would help to increase efficient competition by 
    giving buyers a better opportunity to substitute capacity acquired 
    through segmented releases for pipeline capacity or capacity provided 
    by a shipper with primary point capacity.
        Third, to further expand the extent of efficient competition, all 
    pipelines could be required to adhere to the Northwest approach under 
    which replacement shippers could change primary point rights to any 
    available point without the releasing shippers losing their right to 
    return to their initial primary point at the end of the release. The 
    pipeline could still sell the vacated point to another shipper during 
    the term of the release. The Northwest policy also could be extended 
    beyond release situations to permit a shipper to segment its own 
    capacity. As described earlier, a shipper with firm capacity with a 
    primary receipt point in the Gulf of Mexico and a primary delivery 
    point to New York would be able to deliver gas to Atlanta as a primary 
    delivery point, while choosing a receipt point downstream of Atlanta as 
    a primary receipt point for making a delivery to New York as a primary 
    delivery point.
        Fourth, pipelines could be required to provide all shippers with 
    firm capacity rights over the mainline with equal rights to flow gas 
    past a mainline constraint point.66 This would increase 
    shipper capacity options by giving released capacity flowing to 
    secondary points priority at a mainline constraint point along the 
    shipper's path equal to pipeline capacity or released capacity flowing 
    to primary points.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \66\ See, e.g., Northwest Pipeline Company, 67 FERC para. 61,095 
    (1994) (mainline constraints allocated according to path rights 
    rather than point rights). As this case illustrates, even on web or 
    displacement systems, capacity path rights may be defined.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        This principle could be expanded so that all shippers with firm 
    capacity would have equal rights to receive or deliver gas at all 
    points along their path. This would provide a shipper moving to a 
    secondary delivery point along its path rights to deliver at that point 
    equal to shippers buying pipeline capacity or shippers buying released 
    capacity which have that point as a primary delivery point. Such an 
    approach would ensure that all capacity along the mainline path would 
    compete equally, giving shippers seeking capacity more capacity 
    alternatives from which to choose. A possible conflict might arise if 
    the receipt or delivery point could not accommodate all the receipts or 
    deliveries sought by the shippers. It is not clear how frequently such 
    a problem would occur.
        Fifth, a monetary value could be developed for all receipt and 
    delivery points so that shippers could choose to pay for additional 
    primary point rights, especially those outside their contract path. 
    Under this approach, shippers would be able to buy unsubscribed primary 
    receipt and delivery point rights independent of mainline 
    transportation. One issue under this approach would be to determine a 
    value for additional receipt and delivery point rights. One option is 
    to take a strictly cost-based approach in which the pipelines would 
    have to establish the cost of making or receiving deliveries. Another 
    might be to conduct an auction for all available points.
        The previous options deal with ways of enhancing the ability of 
    shippers with mainline capacity at secondary points to compete with 
    capacity from the pipeline or other shippers at primary points, but do 
    not address confirmation practices across interconnect points. One 
    possible approach would be for the pipelines to seek to confirm all 
    transactions before they apply tariff-based priority rules, and to 
    require that, in the confirmation process, pipelines must seek to 
    maximize the flow of firm transportation across an interconnect. Thus, 
    in the example given above, shipper 2 holding firm capacity on both the 
    upstream and downstream pipeline would get priority over shipper 1, 
    since shipper 1 holds only interruptible transportation on the 
    downstream pipeline.67/ Another potential option would be 
    for priority through pipeline interconnect points to be determined 
    based on which shipper has the take-away capacity on the downstream 
    pipeline. The Commission requests comment on these options as well as 
    the submission of other proposals for handling confirmations that would 
    create greater substitutability between primary and secondary releases 
    and lower the associated transactions costs
    
    [[Page 42998]]
    
    while still fairly allocating capacity among shippers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \67\ See text accompanying note 64, supra.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    C. Capacity Auctions
    
        Auctions are often used as effective methods of selling goods and 
    services. A well-structured auction can assure that pipeline capacity 
    is allocated to the party placing the greatest value on the capacity 
    and can assure fairness in the allocation process by preventing price 
    discrimination or favoritism by the capacity seller. An auction 
    provides customers with equal opportunities to acquire capacity, 
    preventing the pipeline or releasing shipper from treating different 
    bidders differently. Auctions also have value because they provide the 
    market with accurate information on the value of capacity.
        If a market is perfectly competitive with a sufficiently large 
    number of capacity holders, and equal access to market information, an 
    auction would not be necessary to limit the exercise of market power, 
    because market power would not be present. But, even in that case, an 
    auction may help reduce the transaction costs of trading capacity. Any 
    attempt to charge more than a competitive price would result in the 
    potential buyer looking elsewhere for capacity.
        The current regulations seek to protect against pipeline exercise 
    of market power by requiring pipelines to sell capacity when they have 
    received an offer at the maximum tariff rate. This requirement prevents 
    the pipelines from withholding capacity at the maximum rate in order to 
    raise prices. The current regulations, however, do not require 
    pipelines to sell capacity at a discounted rate. Thus, pipelines may be 
    able to exercise market power at rates below the maximum rate because 
    the pipeline is not obligated to sell capacity (can withhold capacity) 
    at less than the maximum rate.
        In markets where market power is present, an auction that limits 
    capacity withholding can be an effective method of limiting the 
    exercise of market power and creating a more efficient market. In 
    today's market, during peak periods, the price cap may restrict 
    shippers' ability to obtain capacity from the pipelines or may result 
    in shippers paying a higher price than necessary for delivered gas 
    either because releasing shippers exercise market power or because the 
    market simply is not transparent enough for potential buyers to be able 
    to locate and negotiate with alternative capacity sources. During off-
    peak periods, shippers similarly may have to pay more than necessary to 
    obtain capacity if pipelines or releasing shippers can withhold 
    capacity or price discriminate. Placing all available capacity in an 
    auction would help ensure that shippers will pay lower prices both 
    during peak and off-peak periods, because the auction process helps to 
    ensure that prices reflect competitive market forces rather than 
    resulting from the exercise of market power or shippers' inability to 
    obtain accurate market information.
    1. Proposed Auction Requirement
        To help prevent the exercise of market power, the Commission is 
    proposing, in revised Sec. 284.10(c)(5), to require all available 
    short-term pipeline firm and interruptible capacity and released 
    capacity to be allocated through an auction process. The proposed 
    auction requirement applies to all sales of short-term pipeline 
    capacity, both interruptible and firm, and released capacity. Thus, all 
    capacity sold for a term of less than a year (or whatever other time 
    period is chosen to define short-term capacity) would be sold through 
    an auction process. Using an auction process for all capacity, during 
    both peak and off-peak periods, is necessary to limit the exercise of 
    market power and to allow the market to determine the value of 
    capacity.
        The Commission is proposing that pipelines adhere to the following 
    principles in designing an auction:
         all available short-term capacity must be sold through an 
    auction;
         daily capacity from the pipeline must be allocated based 
    on the auction without the establishment of a reserve or minimum bid 
    price;
         all eligible shippers must be permitted to bid with no 
    favoritism shown to pipeline affiliates or other shippers;
         the procedures and rules for each auction, including the 
    auction schedule, must be disclosed in the pipeline's tariff in advance 
    of the auction and must be applied in each auction;
         capacity must be allocated based on established criteria 
    and parameters known in advance to all bidders and the same criteria 
    and parameters must apply to pipeline and released capacity; 
    68 and
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \68\ See 18 CFR 284.10(b)(1)(v), Capacity Release Related 
    Standards 5.3.3 and 7.3.14 (three methods for valuing bids, highest 
    rate, net revenue, and net present value).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
         shippers must be able to validate that the auction was run 
    properly either through the posting of information sufficient to permit 
    them to validate that the winners were selected appropriately or 
    through the use of other mechanisms, such as an independent third-
    party, which will validate the results.
        The requirement of an auction for short-term capacity still leaves 
    the question of whether to retain the current bidding procedure for 
    long-term capacity release transactions.69 Pipelines are not 
    subject to any auction or bidding requirements in selling long-term 
    capacity. To ensure comparability, the Commission, therefore, proposes 
    to permit shippers to release capacity on a long-term basis without 
    going through a bidding process. As is the case for the pipelines, no 
    sales of long-term capacity can exceed the pipeline's maximum rate.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \69\ See CFR 284.243(e).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The proposal for auctions of capacity raises issues about auction 
    design that will be discussed below. The first issue is whether to 
    permit pipelines or releasing shippers to establish a reserve or 
    minimum price below which they are not obligated to sell capacity. The 
    second is how to design the auction to work most efficiently.
    2. Reserve Prices
        The Commission is proposing two different auction methodologies for 
    pipeline capacity. For capacity sold for one day, the Commission is 
    proposing a daily auction in which pipelines cannot establish a reserve 
    price. Pipelines would not be required to sell below the minimum rate 
    (variable cost) in their tariffs. For auctions of longer than one day, 
    pipelines would be permitted to establish reserve prices.
        Prohibiting pipelines from establishing a reserve price would limit 
    their ability to withhold capacity. Requiring pipelines to auction 
    their daily capacity, without a reserve price, should be sufficient to 
    prevent them from withholding capacity for longer short-term 
    transactions, for instance, a deal for three months' worth of capacity. 
    The pipeline should not be able to demand a monopoly price for three 
    months' worth of capacity because shippers would not pay that price. A 
    shipper would pay only the amount that it would expect to have to pay 
    if it purchased the capacity in the daily auction plus a premium for 
    the insurance value of locking-in the capacity and price for a set 
    period of time.
        For capacity available for periods of longer than one day, 
    pipelines could establish reserve prices. Pipelines may have a 
    legitimate basis for believing that the market value for their capacity 
    on a single day is less than what the capacity will be worth at a later 
    date or if the capacity ultimately was sold on a longer-term basis.
        The auctions of pipeline capacity would work in the following 
    manner. When a pipeline has firm capacity
    
    [[Page 42999]]
    
    available for more than one day, for instance six months beginning on 
    July 1, the pipeline could establish a reserve price for the six month 
    block of capacity. If that capacity was not sold by June 30, the 
    pipeline would have to sell the capacity for July 1 through the auction 
    process for that day. The pipeline, however, could continue the reserve 
    price for shippers willing to bid on the six month (less one day) block 
    of capacity. This process would continue until the capacity is sold.
        The daily auction also would apply to available pipeline storage 
    capacity. But comments should address whether a daily auction for 
    storage capacity is practical, whether different rules should apply to 
    storage capacity, and whether storage capacity needs to be included in 
    the daily auction to prevent capacity withholding.
        The Commission is proposing that all short-term releases of 
    capacity by firm shippers take place through the auction to ensure that 
    capacity is allocated on a non-discriminatory basis to the purchaser 
    placing the greatest value on the capacity. Releasing shippers would be 
    permitted to place reserve prices on their capacity, because they have 
    a legitimate basis for retaining capacity for their own use. For 
    instance, firm shippers may need to reserve capacity to meet 
    unanticipated weather changes, to replace depleted storage, or to 
    change to a substitute supply to ensure reliable service. Moreover, 
    firm capacity holders should not be able to withhold capacity because, 
    under the proposal, if a firm capacity holder does not nominate (use) 
    its capacity, the pipeline would be required to sell the unnominated 
    capacity as interruptible or short-term firm capacity through the 
    auction.
        The Commission, however, requests comment on a number of aspects of 
    its proposed approach to reserve prices. Commenters should address 
    whether requiring pipelines to sell capacity at the bid price for only 
    one day is sufficient to limit the pipeline's ability to withhold 
    capacity. Commenters should address the question of the price at which 
    capacity should be sold. For example, should all shippers pay the 
    market-clearing price (lowest price necessary to get capacity) 
    70 or should each shipper pay the price it bids?
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \70\ The market clearing price is the price at which all 
    available capacity is sold and no shipper bidding that price or 
    higher would be denied capacity.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commenters also should address whether the proposed requirement to 
    sell pipeline daily capacity without a reserve price could cause cost-
    recovery problems for some pipelines. If shippers on a pipeline where 
    capacity is not sufficiently constrained relied exclusively on the 
    daily auction, the revenue received may be insufficient to cover the 
    pipeline's costs allocated to interruptible and short-term firm 
    capacity.71 The daily auction without a reserve price also 
    may affect the ability of pipelines to resubscribe firm capacity at 
    maximum rates as contracts expire, which could cause cost recovery 
    problems. If the pipeline is expected to be uncongested, shippers may 
    prefer to rely on the daily auction rather than resubscribing to firm 
    capacity.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \71\ Pipelines are generally considered to be natural monopolies 
    because they have very large fixed costs, with significant economies 
    of scale. Thus, it is less expensive to have one pipeline provide 
    service than to have two or more pipelines compete over the same 
    route. However, when a natural monopolist is at the efficient size, 
    where the cost of producing one additional unit (marginal cost) 
    equals the price that a customer is willing to pay (demand), that 
    price is not sufficient to cover the average costs of the firm. See 
    R. Posner, Economic Analysis of the Law, 251-264 (2d ed. 1977).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        On the other hand, it may be that most pipelines are sufficiently 
    constrained so that the daily auction requirement will not limit their 
    ability to recover their costs.72 The proposal to limit the 
    requirement to sell capacity without a reserve price to one day may 
    itself reduce the risk to pipeline cost recovery. Some shippers may be 
    unwilling to take the risk of not having firm capacity.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \72\ Many pipelines, however, may be at less than efficient size 
    and, therefore, be sufficiently congested that they will be able to 
    recover their costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In addition, on some pipelines, the requirement for a daily auction 
    may give large customers greater leverage over pipelines in negotiating 
    renewal contracts. When a large customer's firm contract expires, it 
    may well decide not to renew that contract and to submit low bids for 
    capacity in the daily auction. If the purchaser is the principal, if 
    not the only, shipper for a large block of pipeline capacity, it could 
    be reasonably confident that it would not be outbid by other shippers.
        There are potential approaches to address these kinds of cost 
    recovery problems if they materialize, without rejecting the benefits 
    of an auction process. One set of possibilities is for pipelines to 
    charge a fixed access charge to all customers using its system to 
    recover fixed costs or a volumetric usage charge designed to recover 
    the fixed costs of the system. These are similar to methods that are 
    being considered in connection with congestion pricing in the electric 
    industry.73
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \73\ These options are discussed in the NOI on long-term 
    services which is being issued contemporaneously with this NOPR.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Another alternative is to allow the pipeline to set a reserve price 
    in the daily auction that is above variable costs, but below the 
    current maximum rate. In effect, this would be a minimum price floor 
    below which the pipeline would not have to sell. The price floor could 
    be established by using the dollar amounts associated with specified 
    cost-of-service elements, such as rate of return, or could be 
    established at a percentage of the maximum rate. This approach would 
    still provide shippers with protection against the exercise of market 
    power and would prevent the pipeline from discriminating in the prices 
    it charges to specific customers while permitting the pipeline a 
    reasonable opportunity to recover its fixed costs. However, preventing 
    the pipelines from price discriminating may still result in cost 
    recovery problems.
        Another approach would be to limit the auction only to transactions 
    above the maximum rate (as converted to a daily rate). The current 
    regulations require a pipeline to sell capacity at the maximum rate to 
    all shippers, thus preventing the pipeline from withholding capacity at 
    the maximum rate to derive a higher price. A requirement that pipelines 
    must auction capacity at the market clearing price, whenever such 
    prices exceed the maximum rate, would continue the protection in the 
    current regulations. It would protect against the pipelines' 
    withholding capacity to raise price and would prevent them from price 
    discriminating between shippers, because all shippers would pay the 
    market clearing price. It also would help to ensure that the pipelines' 
    opportunity to recover their cost-of-service is not impaired. However, 
    such an approach would not help to constrain the pipelines' ability to 
    exercise market power at prices below the existing cap.
        Commenters should address the merits of the potential methods for 
    dealing with situations in which the requirement to sell capacity 
    without a reserve price would result in cost recovery problems for 
    pipelines. Commenters also should address whether solutions should be 
    determined on a pipeline by pipeline basis or whether there needs to be 
    a uniform approach applicable to all pipelines.
    3. Auction Design
        The Commission recognizes the need for the auction to work quickly 
    and efficiently.74 Shippers buying capacity
    
    [[Page 43000]]
    
    not only want the ability to consummate deals quickly, they also want 
    the assurance they can acquire capacity in sufficient time to finalize 
    their gas supply arrangements. The current system, which takes four 
    hours, and must be completed the day prior to nominations,75 
    is inadequate to meet the needs of the market.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \74\ Shippers have complained that the Commission's current 
    bidding process for capacity release is too cumbersome and slow. See 
    Secondary Market NOPR, IV FERC Stats. & Regs. Proposed Regulations 
    at 33,244.
        \75\ 18 CFR 284.10(b)(1)(v) (1997), Capacity Release Related 
    Standards 5.3.2.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        An electronic auction, designed properly, can be efficient and can 
    operate faster than the current process of sending facsimiles and using 
    telephones to arrange deals. Electronic auctions used for trading 
    stocks and other commodities demonstrate this efficiency.
        There are a variety of auction formats that would meet the 
    Commission's criteria as well as provide the speed the market requires. 
    The Commission ultimately would decide on the proper auction format. It 
    could do so either through this rulemaking, through a subsequent 
    proceeding, or by reviewing proposals on a pipeline-by-pipeline basis, 
    and it requests comment on which approach would be preferable. To 
    assist the Commission in evaluating potential auction formats, comments 
    should focus on the details of how the auction or multiple auctions 
    should be conducted and on whether a uniform auction format should be 
    applied to all pipelines.
        For example, different auction formats could be used for intra-day, 
    daily, monthly, and longer auctions.76 Auctions for capacity 
    of one day or less could be held as part of each intra-day nomination 
    opportunity or could be held continuously, every hour during the 
    business day. Consideration also should be given to establishing 
    standardized parameters for recall or other conditions in order to 
    facilitate trading for daily or intra-day capacity. To further expedite 
    the daily auction, it could be integrated with the nomination process 
    using a computerized auction process.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \76\ The Commission's current regulations, for instance, provide 
    for longer posting and bidding periods for transactions of five 
    months or longer than for shorter-term transactions. 18 CFR 
    284.10(b)(1)(v), Capacity Release Related Standards 5.3.2.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        To accomplish such integration, releasing shippers could submit 
    nominations establishing the minimum or reserve price or prices at 
    which they would be willing to sell some or all of their capacity. For 
    capacity the shipper wanted to use, it could establish a very high 
    reserve price while for capacity it clearly wanted to release it could 
    establish a zero reserve price. Bidders would submit nominations with 
    the price they are willing to pay. Pipelines would be required to offer 
    the released capacity along with their own available capacity. The 
    pipeline would then apply Commission-approved procedures to determine a 
    market clearing price and all bidders submitting bids above this price 
    would be automatically scheduled.
        Auctions for periods longer than a day could use a different 
    format, while auctions of monthly capacity could employ posting and 
    bidding periods that would coincide with the industry's monthly gas 
    purchasing cycle. Longer posting and bidding times might be needed for 
    auctions of greater than one month.
        The Commission also requests comment on whether alternatives to the 
    comprehensive auction described above would be sufficient to protect 
    against the exercise of market power. One possibility would be only to 
    require pipelines to sell available interruptible capacity to the 
    highest bidder. While such an approach would not cover capacity 
    releases or sales of pipeline firm capacity, it may be sufficient to 
    ensure that capacity is not withheld from the market to raise price. 
    For instance, it would protect against the incentives present in a 
    duopoly or oligopolistic market in which firm shippers and the pipeline 
    recognize a mutual interest in withholding capacity. If the releasing 
    shipper tried to withhold capacity by not releasing it, the pipeline, 
    under this option, would be forced to sell the resulting interruptible 
    capacity to the highest bidder. Pipelines already are generally 
    required to allocate interruptible capacity based on price when they 
    are unable to satisfy all nominations for interruptible service at the 
    maximum rate.\77\ While this proposal would expand the requirement to 
    all transactions, it could be implemented using the same process.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \77\ See Sea Robin Pipeline Company, 81 FERC para. 61,041, at 
    61,225 (1997); Pacific Gas Transmission Company, 76 FERC para.61,258 
    (1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The information the Commission is proposing to require pipelines to 
    provide is intended to enable the market to effectively monitor 
    transactions. Indeed, the knowledge that information will be provided 
    to the market should itself act as a check against anticompetitive 
    transactions.
    
    D. Information Reporting and Remedies for the Exercise of Market 
    Power
    
    1. Reporting Requirements
        In creating a competitive marketplace, information plays a crucial 
    role. Equal access to relevant information is necessary for shippers to 
    make informed decisions about capacity purchases and for markets to 
    perform efficiently. Market information also is needed so that the 
    Commission and shippers can monitor transactions to determine if market 
    power is being exercised.
        The information needed by the market, both for decision-making and 
    monitoring purposes, falls into three general categories: information 
    on capacity availability, information on the structure of the market, 
    and information on capacity transactions, such as rates, contract 
    duration, and contract terms. Information on the amount of capacity 
    available at receipt and delivery points and on mainline segments as 
    well as on the daily amount of capacity that pipelines schedule at 
    these points will help shippers structure gas transactions and cast 
    light on whether shippers or the pipeline may be withholding capacity. 
    To assess market structure, shippers and the Commission need to know 
    who holds or controls capacity on each portion of the pipeline system 
    so they can determine the number of potential sources of capacity. 
    Transactional information provides price transparency so shippers can 
    make informed purchasing decisions as well as permitting both shippers 
    and the Commission to monitor actual transactions for evidence of the 
    possible exercise of market power.
        The current regulations already require the posting of much of the 
    needed information. The proposals here would require expansion of these 
    current reporting requirements, but such expansion appears justified to 
    give shippers the information they need both for competitive and 
    monitoring purposes. Moreover, in some cases, the proposals are 
    designed to ensure that the same information is provided for competing 
    types of capacity. For instance, detailed information on capacity 
    release transactions, including the releasing and replacement shipper 
    names, the rate paid, and points covered by the release are already 
    being posted at the time of the transaction.78 In contrast, 
    pipelines are only required to file limited information on their 
    discount transactions well after the transaction has taken 
    place.79
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \78\ 18 CFR 284.10(b) (1)(v), Capacity Release Related Standards 
    5.4.1, 5.4.3.
        \79\ 18 CFR 284.7(c) (6).
    
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [[Page 43001]]
    
        a. Information on Available Capacity. For capacity availability, 
    the current regulations require posting of information about the amount 
    of operationally available capacity at points and on the 
    mainline.80 But, in order to effectively determine whether 
    capacity is being withheld, information also is needed to show the 
    total design capacity of the point or segment and the amount scheduled 
    on a daily basis. The Commission proposes in proposed section 284.14(d) 
    to add this information to the posting requirements.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \80\ 18 CFR 284.8(b) (3); 18 CFR 284.10(b) (1) (iv) (1997), 
    Electronic Delivery Mechanism Related Standards 4.3.6; 18 CFR 
    284.10(b) (1) (v), Capacity Release Related Standards 5.4.13.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission also proposes, in proposed Sec. 284.14(d) to require 
    pipelines to post information on planned and actual maintenance or 
    system outages that would reduce the amount of capacity available. 
    While some pipelines currently post such information, it is not 
    currently a Commission requirement. Shippers can better make decisions 
    about their use of capacity if they know whether the available capacity 
    will be reduced on a particular day. Such information will also help in 
    monitoring capacity withholding by revealing reasons for reductions in 
    scheduled quantities.
        b. Information on Market Structure. With respect to the structure 
    of the marketplace, pipelines currently file with the Commission, and 
    post on their Internet web sites, an Index of Customers, which (under 
    Sec. 284.106(c)(3) of the regulations, new Sec. 284.14(b)) provides 
    information on the names of shippers holding firm capacity, the amount 
    of capacity they hold, and the duration of their contracts. But the 
    Index of Customers does not provide information on the capacity path 
    held by the shipper, so the data cannot be used to determine which 
    shippers can compete in providing capacity on segments of the pipeline. 
    The Commission, therefore, proposes to add a requirement, in proposed 
    section 284.14(b), to include in the Index of Customers the receipt and 
    delivery points held under the contract, the zones or segments in which 
    the capacity is held, and the shipper's contract number. The contract 
    number is needed on the Index of Customers as well as on the report of 
    capacity release transactions so capacity can be traced through release 
    transactions to reveal how much total capacity each shipper holds. 
    Since the current capacity release requirements do not include the 
    contract number, the Commission is proposing to require that the number 
    be provided.
        In addition, to permit effective monitoring of the capacity held on 
    pipelines, it is necessary to know affiliate relationships, which may 
    affect the amount of capacity held by a single parent entity. The 
    Commission, therefore, proposes to add a requirement in proposed 
    section 284.14(b) that pipelines disclose in the Index of Customers any 
    affiliate relationship between the pipeline and the holder of capacity 
    and any affiliate relationship between holders of capacity. 
    Additionally, the Commission would require disclosure of affiliate 
    transactions in capacity release transactions.81
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \81\ Some pipelines now require disclosure of affiliate 
    transactions for capacity release transactions. 18 CFR 284.10(b) (1) 
    (v), Capacity Release Related Standards 5.4.3. This requirement 
    would become mandatory for all pipelines under this proposal.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission also is proposing to expand its affiliate 
    regulations to provide more information to permit monitoring and self-
    policing of affiliate transactions. The Commission is proposing to add 
    a new section 161.3(i) and revise section 284.286(c) to require 
    pipelines to post on their web sites organizational charts, and job 
    descriptions, including the names of senior employees,82 for 
    the pipeline, its marketing affiliates, and gas sales operating 
    units.83 The pipeline would not be required to include 
    employees whose duties are purely clerical or those who do not have 
    access to information concerning the processing or administration of 
    requests for service (such as employees who operate or repair the 
    pipeline facilities). The Commission also is proposing to include in 
    the Internet posting the list of the operating personnel and facilities 
    shared by the interstate pipeline and its marketing affiliate or gas 
    sales operating unit. The pipelines currently provide this information 
    in their tariffs, under Sec. 250.16(b)(1), and this requirement will 
    make all affiliate information easily available on the Internet. The 
    Commission has adopted a similar requirement in the electric industry 
    to help monitor, and protect against, improper communications between 
    transmission and wholesale merchant function employees.84/
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \82\ Senior employee would be defined as an employee who 
    supervises non-clerical employees engaged in transmission/
    reliability or gas marketing functions.
        \83\ Contemporaneously with this NOPR, the Commission is issuing 
    a final rule adding a requirement to 18 CFR 161.3 requiring 
    pipelines to post the names and addresses of their marketing 
    affiliates on their web sites. Reporting Interstate Natural Gas 
    Pipleline Marketing Affiliates on the Internet, Docket No. RM98-7-
    000. For the NOPR, see Reporting Interstate Natural Gas Pipeline 
    Marketing Affiliates on the Internet, Notice of Proposed Rulemaing, 
    63 FR 27526 (May 19, 1998), IV FERC Stats. & Regs. Proposed 
    Regulations para. 32,530 (May 13, 1998). Should the Commission adopt 
    the regulations proposed in this NOPR, the changes could be 
    consolidated with the requirement for posting affiliate names and 
    addresses.
        \84\ American Electric Power Service Corporation, 83 FERC para. 
    61,357 (1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In addition, in the current market, shippers may be using agents or 
    asset managers to manage their capacity and such managers may be given 
    wide latitude over the way in which capacity is used. The Commission, 
    therefore, is proposing to add a requirement in Sec. 284.14(b) that 
    pipelines disclose such agents or asset managers when they control 20% 
    or more of capacity in a pipeline rate zone, as well as the rights of 
    the agent or asset manager with respect to managing the transportation 
    service. This information would help to show the degree of control over 
    pipeline capacity that an agent or asset manager may exercise.
        c. Transactional Information. Pipelines already provide 
    transactional information for their own capacity transactions and for 
    capacity release transactions, although the type of information and the 
    manner of accessing it differ. For capacity release transactions, 
    pipelines provide via the Internet the names of the releasing and 
    acquiring shippers, the price, the receipt and delivery points under 
    the deal, the quantity of capacity traded, and the duration of the 
    deal.\85\ This information is posted immediately upon consummation of 
    the transaction. The information provided about pipeline transactions 
    is not as complete, nor is it as timely or as easy to access. Pipeline 
    discount reports are filed, but not posted, 15 days after the close of 
    the billing period applicable to the transaction and include only the 
    rate paid and the maximum rate, but do not include any information on 
    volumes, the receipt and delivery points under the transaction, or the 
    duration of the deal.\86\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \85\ 18 CFR 284.10(b)(1)(v), Capacity Release Related Standards 
    5.4.1, 5.4.3.
        \86\ 18 CFR 284.7(c)(6).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        To assure parity of transactional information, the Commission 
    proposes, as described, to require the pipelines to provide the same 
    information about their transactions as is currently provided about 
    capacity release transactions. The Commission recognizes that some 
    pipelines and shippers have previously expressed concern about posting 
    information on shipper names to preserve
    
    [[Page 43002]]
    
    confidentiality. However, shipper names currently are posted for 
    capacity release transactions and the Commission is unable to see how 
    other shippers can effectively monitor transactions for favoritism if 
    names are not provided.
        In many cases, much of the transactional information would be 
    provided in a properly designed, transparent short-term capacity 
    auction. To ensure that the information is provided, the Commission is 
    proposing to add a new section, 284.14(c), that would require pipelines 
    to post on their Internet web site, and provide downloadable files of, 
    transactional information about their own capacity transactions and 
    released capacity transactions. For firm service, the Commission 
    proposes that the pipelines provide contemporaneously with the 
    execution of the contract, the same information already posted for 
    capacity release transactions: the parties to the contract; the 
    contract number for the shipper receiving service and for the releasing 
    shipper; the rate charged under each contract; the duration of the 
    contract; the receipt and delivery points and mainline segments covered 
    by the contract; the contract quantity; any special terms and 
    conditions applicable to the contract; and any affiliate relationship 
    between the pipeline and the shipper or between the releasing and 
    replacement shipper. For interruptible transportation, the following 
    information on a daily basis would be required: the name of the 
    shipper; the rate charged; the receipt and delivery points and mainline 
    segments over which the shipper is entitled to nominate gas; the 
    quantity of gas the shipper is entitled to nominate; and any affiliate 
    relationship between the shipper and the pipeline.
    2. Remedies if the Exercise of Market Power Is Found
        While the Commission's proposals should enhance efficient 
    competition and mitigate market power, the Commission is committed to 
    take remedial action when pipelines or shippers exercise market power. 
    Because the facts of each such case would be different, it is difficult 
    to describe in advance the type of remedy the Commission would impose 
    if market power is being exercised, and not all remedies would be 
    appropriate in every case. As a general matter, the Commission's 
    preference would be to use a structural remedy that would enhance 
    efficient competition. Examples of such remedies would include revising 
    contractual provisions that inhibit competition, strengthening the 
    capacity auction requirement, requiring pipelines to build taps to 
    increase access to capacity, or conducting auctions to determine 
    whether sufficient demand exists for additional construction. Another 
    potential remedy would be to use a benchmark for regulating price 
    increases based on price changes in comparable competitive markets.\87\ 
    Reimposition of some form of price cap also would be a possible option 
    if other available remedies are not adequate. Commenters should address 
    the potential remedies suggested here as well as suggest other possible 
    remedies.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \87\ See Buckeye Pipe Line Company, 53 FERC para. 61,473, at 
    62,683 (1991) (basing price changes in non-competitive markets on 
    the changes in competitive markets).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    IV. Penalties and Operational Flow Orders
    
        A major goal of the changes proposed in this NOPR is to improve 
    competition in the short-term market both to improve the efficiency of 
    the market and to protect against the potential exercise of market 
    power. To improve efficiency and competition across the pipeline grid, 
    the Commission previously has adopted standards, promulgated by GISB, 
    as well as the Commission's own standards governing business practices 
    and electronic communication. But these standards have only partially 
    addressed the effect that pipeline operational flow orders, tolerances, 
    and penalties have on competition across the pipeline grid.
        Penalties and operational flow orders (OFOs) are necessary tools to 
    deter shipper behavior that threaten the integrity of the pipeline 
    system. At the same time, they have a significant effect on efficiency 
    and competition by restricting shippers' abilities to effectively use 
    their transportation capacity. As just one example of the interrelation 
    between penalties and the short-term market, penalty levels can affect 
    the value of capacity in the short-term market; shippers needing gas 
    might be willing to buy transportation capacity at any rate less than 
    the penalty they would have to pay if, for instance, they overran their 
    contract entitlement. In this section, the Commission considers reforms 
    to its policies for regulating OFOs and transportation penalties to 
    ensure that they can continue in their legitimate role of protecting 
    pipeline integrity, while not unnecessarily limiting or restricting 
    competition in the marketplace.
        These policies have their origin in the regulatory reforms 
    instituted by the Commission in Order No. 636. To promote competition 
    in the sales and transportation markets, Order No. 636 required that 
    pipelines unbundle sales and transportation services. The bundled sales 
    service provided considerable flexibility for the pipeline in how it 
    would meet the requirements of its customers, particularly on peak 
    days. In the implementation of Order No. 636, the Commission was 
    particularly concerned that the unbundled transportation services be as 
    reliable as the bundled sales service the pipelines previously 
    provided.
        To address that concern, the Commission accorded each pipeline 
    considerable discretion and authority to operate its system to ensure 
    its reliability, particularly during peak and emergency times. One 
    important tool the Commission has sanctioned is the use by pipelines of 
    OFOs that can restrict service or require shippers to take particular 
    actions. As examples, Commission-sanctioned OFOs can: reduce or 
    eliminate tolerances for imbalances or contract overruns; institute 
    severe penalties; restrict intra-day nominations; restrict or eliminate 
    the use of secondary receipt and delivery points; and restrict firm 
    storage withdrawals and eliminate interruptible storage withdrawals.
        Another means the Commission has provided pipelines to protect 
    system reliability is the approval of tariff penalties designed to 
    deter shippers from creating imbalances or from overrunning contract 
    entitlements. The Commission has approved particularly high penalties, 
    with little or no tolerance for imbalances or overruns, applicable 
    during peak or emergency periods to protect pipeline reliability. The 
    Commission also has approved penalties, usually at lower dollar levels 
    and greater tolerances, applicable during non-peak times to help ensure 
    that shipper imbalances or overruns do not create emergency conditions 
    on a pipeline that could have been prevented or minimized.
        The Commission believes that a review of present policies and 
    pipeline practices in these areas is appropriate as part of the new 
    approach to pipeline regulation proposed in this NOPR-- and 
    particularly its objective of promoting competition in the short-term 
    market.
        On initial review, it appears that some pipeline practices and 
    Commission policies regarding penalties can inhibit competition not 
    only with respect to transportation, but also in the sale of natural 
    gas. For example, an OFO that eliminates a secondary receipt point for 
    a shipper may eliminate the shipper's access to alternate suppliers 
    with the lowest priced gas or force the shipper to
    
    [[Page 43003]]
    
    points where it has no purchase or sales agreements. An OFO that limits 
    or eliminates a shipper's storage withdrawals may require the shipper 
    to purchase more costly gas on the spot market if the OFO allows the 
    shipper to shift to new points. The longer OFOs are in effect, the more 
    restrictive they become. Across all customers, OFOs may fragment 
    markets by making it impossible for many potential sales of gas or 
    transportation services to take place.
        High penalties on contract overruns or imbalances as well as low or 
    no tolerances during peak periods may also operate to limit and distort 
    market forces. For example, not all shippers have immediate access to 
    metering information on their imbalances or even the volumes of gas 
    they receive at their delivery points. This lack of information may 
    adversely affect shippers in several ways. For example, to avoid 
    overrun and/or imbalance penalties, shippers may not maximize use of 
    pipeline transportation, and shippers may contract for more 
    transportation capacity than they need. Also, the lack of information 
    on imbalances and delivered volumes may inhibit shippers from trading 
    imbalances or transportation capacity that could alleviate or prevent 
    system operational problems.
        The presence of severe penalties/tolerances during peak or 
    emergency periods also may preclude other uses of market forces that 
    could alleviate or prevent system operational problems. For example, a 
    shipper that delivers more gas than nominated into a pipeline when the 
    pipeline is short of gas would help to maintain system integrity. Yet, 
    under most currently approved tariff provisions, the shipper could be 
    penalized for doing so.
        Moreover, Commission-authorized penalties may provide an 
    opportunity for shippers to engage in a form of penalty arbitrage. For 
    example, during the 1995-96 winter there was a shortage of natural gas 
    to serve Chicago markets. Shippers reacted by intentionally overrunning 
    contract entitlements on those pipelines and LDCs that had the lowest 
    penalties for contract overruns. 88 In that situation, 
    penalties appeared to have skewed choices shippers might otherwise have 
    made. The consequence was that pipelines in the Chicago area appear to 
    have entered into bidding wars for the highest overrun/imbalance 
    penalties, with penalties for large variances running as high as $200/
    dth.89
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \88\ See Industry Surveys the Damage as Winter's Strength Runs 
    Out, Natural Gas Intelligence, April 22, 1996, at 1; Freezer Burn, 
    Gas Daily's NG, April 1996, at 30.
        \89\ See Panhandle Eastern Pipeline Company, 78 FERC para. 
    61,202, at 61,876 (1997)(penalties ranging from $25 per Dth for 
    variances of 5-10% to $200 for variances over 50%).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The fluctuation of transportation values also supports a 
    reexamination of Commission policies on OFOs and penalties. As 
    discussed earlier, the value of transportation varies widely. For 
    example, as shown on the earlier graph, during the winter of 1996-1997, 
    the value of capacity was double the maximum rate, while during the 
    winter of 1995-1996, spikes occurred on several occasions to much 
    higher levels, with the highest value reaching $10/MMBtu.90
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \90\ See text accompanying note 22, infra.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The fluctuation in short-term transportation values during peak 
    periods suggests the need to increase opportunities, as much as 
    practicable, for shippers to obtain transportation services at the 
    lowest competitive price during such times. Yet, the pipelines' current 
    OFO and penalty structures may restrict shippers' options more than is 
    necessary.
        Current pipeline tariff provisions for remedying monthly imbalances 
    of a shipper--often described as ``cash-outs''-- also appear to inhibit 
    market forces and may be otherwise unfair. Under these provisions, 
    shippers are allowed to cash-out net monthly imbalances using an 
    average monthly price. That procedure invites shippers to game the 
    system within the month. For example, a shipper may take more than it 
    delivers when gas prices are high and deliver more than it takes when 
    gas prices are low. At peak, such behavior may imperil system-wide 
    reliability and unnecessarily trigger OFOs and emergency penalties that 
    restrict or eliminate market forces. Such gaming also promotes 
    inefficient use of pipeline capacity. For example, to the extent gaming 
    is substantial on a pipeline, the pipeline is likely to react by 
    imposing stricter imbalance tolerances and higher penalties. Moreover, 
    gaming by some shippers is subsidized by other shippers. A pipeline's 
    tolerance and penalty levels are often a function of the amount of 
    storage it has retained; a pipeline with more storage can tolerate 
    greater imbalances. But all shippers pay for storage in their firm 
    rates. Accordingly, if a pipeline reduces tolerances and raises 
    penalties due to the behavior of some shippers, the firm shippers lose 
    the flexibility for which they are paying.
        The apparent problems associated with current OFO and penalty 
    tariff provisions suggest the need to reorient policy away from 
    penalties and towards promoting the opportunities for shippers to avoid 
    penalties and to prevent penalty situations, particularly by allowing 
    shippers to avail themselves of remedies that the marketplace can 
    provide. Such remedies would include the trading of imbalances, the 
    provision of timely information about system imbalances so shippers can 
    better anticipate adverse operational conditions and avoid possible 
    penalties, and no harm no foul rules under which shippers will not be 
    penalized for actions that help maintain the operational integrity of 
    the pipeline system. Stated in other terms, while there may always be a 
    need for penalties and OFOs, the adoption of policies that promote the 
    opportunity for shippers to avoid penalties and prevent penalty 
    situations, particularly by reliance on market forces, may be the most 
    efficient means of ensuring the reliability of a pipeline's system 
    operations. Towards this end, the Commission, in Order No. 587-G, 
    recently required pipelines to permit shippers to offset imbalances 
    across their own contracts and to trade imbalances with other 
    shippers.91
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \91\ Standards For Business Practices Of Interstate Natural Gas 
    Pipelines, Order No. 587-G, 63 FR 20072 (Apr. 23, 1998), III FERC 
    Stats. & Regs. Regulations Preambles para. 31,062 (Apr. 16, 1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Accordingly, the Commission proposes to revise section 284.13 of 
    its regulations to establish the following policies. First, the 
    Commission proposes to require each pipeline to provide, on a timely 
    basis, as much information as possible about the imbalance and overrun 
    status of each shipper and the imbalance of its system as a whole. The 
    adoption of this policy is a critical first step to enhancing the 
    opportunities of a shipper to avoid penalties and help prevent penalty 
    situations. Second, to ensure greater shipper flexibility, the 
    Commission proposes to require that pipelines have in place only those 
    transportation penalties that are necessary and appropriate to protect 
    system operations. Third, the Commission proposes to require that 
    pipelines provide services, to the extent operationally feasible, that 
    facilitate a shipper's ability to manage imbalances, which will also 
    help the shipper avoid penalties and prevent penalty situations. 
    Finally, the Commission proposes to require pipelines to adopt 
    incentives and procedures that will minimize the use and potential 
    negative impact of OFOs.
        As discussed below, the Commission solicits comments on these 
    proposed policies. The Commission also invites
    
    [[Page 43004]]
    
    comments on its assessment, set forth above, of current OFO and penalty 
    tariff provisions on which the proposed policies are based. 
    Specifically, the Commission solicits comments on how well these 
    current tariff provisions protect the integrity of system operations, 
    the extent to which such provisions have created the problems discussed 
    above, and whether changes to such tariff provisions are warranted.
    
    A. Pipelines Should Provide, on a Timely Basis, as Much Imbalance and 
    Overrun Information as Possible
    
        The Commission proposes to require each pipeline to provide, on a 
    timely basis, as much information as possible about the imbalance and 
    overrun status of each shipper and the imbalance of its system as a 
    whole. Providing such information is a critical first step to a new 
    Commission approach to penalties. To begin with, such information, by 
    itself, would help shippers avoid overruns and imbalances. Moreover, 
    providing each shipper with information on the precise level of its 
    deliveries and imbalances would help the shipper maximize the use of 
    its transportation rights on the pipeline system. Such information 
    could also allow the pipelines to reduce the level of penalty-free 
    tolerances and so reduce system costs (e.g., storage capacity to 
    provide such tolerances). Finally, such information together with 
    information on system imbalances would facilitate trading of imbalances 
    and capacity or other self-help measures that in turn could alleviate 
    or prevent conditions that imperil system integrity.
        Under the proposed regulation, Sec. 284.13(c)(2)(iv), the pipeline 
    would not be required to install real time meters. The burden on the 
    pipeline would be limited to distributing on a timely basis--i.e., so 
    that the shipper has a reasonable opportunity to avoid penalties--the 
    information the pipeline currently has on deliveries and imbalances at 
    each shipper's delivery point as well as system imbalances. The 
    pipeline would be required to establish a system that notifies each 
    shipper individually of the imbalance/delivery information that the 
    pipeline possesses or to give shippers access to such information via 
    the Internet. The pipeline could post relevant system imbalance 
    information more generally. The obligation that such information be 
    provided on a timely basis would vary from pipeline to pipeline, 
    depending on the pipeline's penalties. For example, a pipeline that 
    imposes imbalance penalties only on a monthly basis would have a 
    different obligation to provide imbalance information to its shippers 
    than a pipeline that imposes daily imbalance penalties.
        During technical conferences in individual cases, relating to 
    proposals by pipelines to institute or increase penalties, many 
    pipelines have provided assurances that they were moving toward better 
    metering on their system. On the other hand, customers have complained 
    of the imposition of penalties because existing metering equipment was 
    insufficient to provide them with timely information on deliveries and 
    imbalances. An important question raised by the proposed policy is the 
    manner in which, if at all, the Commission should address the situation 
    in which a shipper has receipt or delivery points at which there is not 
    the type of metering and related equipment that would provide the 
    shipper with timely information on its deliveries and imbalances. The 
    Commission sets forth below two options and solicits comment on them.
        One option, which would be a departure from the proposed policy set 
    forth above, is to require the pipeline to install the equipment that 
    would provide all shippers with timely information on imbalances and 
    deliveries. Important questions that should be addressed when 
    considering this option are, first, the extent to which such equipment 
    is not in place today and, second, the extent to which the shippers 
    without such equipment desire the information that would be provided. 
    For example, the Commission is aware that marketers and producers have 
    voiced complaints about the lack of timely information on deliveries 
    and imbalances. Those complaints suggest that there may be more of a 
    problem in obtaining timely information at receipt points than at 
    delivery points.
        A closely related and critical question is the cost of purchasing 
    and installing the equipment that will provide timely information. 
    Those costs must be compared in some manner to the benefits of 
    providing the equipment. The question of costs raises a host of other 
    related questions. For example, who should pay for the equipment--the 
    pipeline (who could recover the costs in generally applicable rates) or 
    the shipper? Is it appropriate to require all shippers to have access 
    to such information? For example, it may be cost effective only for 
    large shippers. Should the Commission require the metering needed to 
    provide timely information only at those receipt/delivery points where 
    the gas volumes are large enough to cover the equipment costs, and 
    exempt the remaining receipt/delivery points? If so, what alternatives 
    are appropriate for receipt/delivery points of small shippers to 
    provide some parity of treatment?
        A second option would be to forbid a pipeline from imposing a 
    penalty for an overrun/imbalance that does not threaten system 
    reliability unless the pipeline has metering equipment to measure the 
    imbalance/overrun and notifies the shipper in a timely manner of the 
    imbalance/overrun. The intent of this option is to give a pipeline an 
    incentive to install only the metering equipment associated with 
    imbalances or overruns that may imperil system integrity. The option 
    also would prevent penalties that a shipper would have been in a better 
    position to avoid with timely information.
        This option also raises the question of who should bear the costs 
    of the enhanced metering and related facilities. Another relevant 
    concern is the extent to which the option could be implemented--is 
    there an objective basis to determine which penalties are required, and 
    in what situations, to prevent realistic threats to a pipeline's system 
    integrity?
        The Commission solicits comments on its proposal, the alternative 
    options, and the related questions. The Commission also solicits other 
    alternative proposals that commenters believe merit consideration.
    
    B. Transportation Penalties Must Be Necessary and Appropriate to 
    Protect System Operations
    
        The Commission proposes to require that pipelines have in place 
    only those transportation penalties that are necessary and appropriate 
    to protect system operations. The Commission has authorized extremely 
    high overrun and imbalance penalties for several pipelines on the basis 
    that doing so was required to protect system integrity.92 
    The Commission questions whether there is necessarily a connection 
    between the high level of penalties that have been authorized and the 
    level that is necessary to ensure system reliability. Also, the 
    Commission is aware that some pipelines have penalties that are at the 
    same level during peak and non-peak periods and may be imposed 
    regardless of whether the pipeline is faced with emergency 
    conditions.93 In light of these considerations, the 
    Commission solicits comments on
    
    [[Page 43005]]
    
    whether currently effective penalties are the most appropriate and 
    effective penalties to protect system operations. The Commission also 
    solicits comments on the specific criteria the Commission should rely 
    on in determining what penalty provisions would be the most appropriate 
    and effective.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \92\ See Northern Natural Gas Company, 77 FERC para. 61,282, at 
    62,236 (1997); Panhandle Eastern Pipeline Company, 78 FERC para. 
    61,202, at 61,876-77 (1997), reh'g denied, 82 FERC para. 61,163 
    (1998).
        \93\ See Tennessee Gas Pipeline Company, 81 FERC para. 61,266, 
    at 62,312; reh'g denied, 83 FERC para. 61,063, at 61,335 (1998) 
    (contrasting a penalty based on spot pricing which varies penalty 
    levels in response to market conditions with other pipelines with 
    fixed penalty levels).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        There are many specific options the Commission may pursue in this 
    area on which comments are requested. One option would be to require, 
    on an industry-wide basis, penalties that are not set at specific 
    dollar levels, but instead reflect the varying gas commodity prices 
    that are available to the shipper--for example, a regional index plus 
    an adder. The use of such indices could allow a more effective 
    deterrence based on current market conditions. For example, a penalty 
    based on commodity prices might eliminate a recurrence of the situation 
    during the 1995-96 winter in the Chicago market where shippers sought 
    to overrun contract entitlements on the pipeline system with the lowest 
    stated dollar penalty.
        A related option is for the Commission to establish procedures that 
    would allow all segments of the natural gas industry to form a 
    consensus, to the extent practicable, on penalty tariff provisions that 
    could be uniform either on a national or regional basis. Such 
    provisions could:
         define the particular penalties and to whom they would 
    apply;
         implement cash-out provisions on all pipelines;
         set tolerance levels;
         determine the time periods when the penalties would be 
    applicable;
         define the time periods to notify shippers of penalties; 
    and
         allow make-up and/or trading of imbalances.
        A prominent concern underlying this option is to eliminate the 
    gaming where a shipper shifts capacity use among pipelines to overrun 
    its rights on the pipeline that has the lowest level of penalties. 
    Setting uniform standards for penalty provisions should reduce this 
    gaming problem and the incentive for a pipeline to adopt ever more 
    onerous penalty provisions to avoid having the least onerous penalties 
    in an area or region.
        Another objective underlying this option is to eliminate the 
    adverse effects on competition that are caused by the fact that penalty 
    provisions vary from pipeline to pipeline. Such variation gives rise to 
    administrative costs and uncertainty and acts as a disincentive for 
    shippers seeking alternative suppliers of gas and transportation 
    services.
        The Commission has successfully prompted, by adopting 
    recommendations of GISB, the standardization of many of the operating 
    rules of interstate pipelines to enhance competition. In that regard, 
    the Commission stresses that the intent of this option is not to 
    determine standardized penalty provisions as part of the rulemaking, 
    but rather to initiate a process in which a consensus may be achieved. 
    The Commission solicits comment on whether the industry could develop 
    such standards through GISB or whether the Commission would need to 
    establish its own process for developing the standards.
        A variant of the last option is to establish procedures that would 
    also include state representatives that could facilitate the 
    coordination of (a) penalty provisions used by interstate pipelines 
    with (b) penalty provisions that are used by state regulated entities--
    LDCs, Hinshaw and intrastate pipelines. The Commission believes that 
    such coordination would better address the problem of gaming as well as 
    enhance competition in both the sales and transportation of natural 
    gas. State regulators are particularly invited to comment on the 
    desirability of this option as well as to suggest procedures to 
    implement it.
        In addressing the proposals to develop a consensus process, 
    commenters should provide their views on the practical extent to which 
    certain types of penalty provisions can be standardized. For example, 
    it may be impractical to adopt particular levels of penalties or 
    tolerances on a national or even regional basis, given the different 
    operational characteristics of each pipeline. The Commission also seeks 
    alternative proposals to developing a consensus process that would 
    address the goals, described above, of eliminating gaming and the 
    administrative costs and uncertainty that arise due to the fact that 
    penalty provisions vary from pipeline to pipeline.
        Another option would be to provide an automatic credit to shippers 
    for a significant portion of the imbalance or contract overrun penalty 
    revenues a pipeline collects. Such a credit would not be provided to 
    those shippers that incurred the imbalance or overrun penalty. Current 
    Commission policy is not to provide an automatic credit, but to take 
    such penalty revenues into account in a rate case to develop a 
    pipeline's revenue requirement. Customers of pipelines have often 
    complained that such an approach is inappropriate when pipelines are no 
    longer required to file rate cases on a periodic basis. Those customers 
    argue that to the extent the penalty revenues are not reflected in 
    rates, penalty provisions act as a profit center for pipelines. 
    Crediting penalty revenues would eliminate an incentive for pipelines 
    to propose unnecessarily high levels of penalties or provisions that 
    unduly restrict the transportation rights of a shipper.
        The Commission invites comments on the extent to which there is a 
    need to provide an automatic credit of penalty revenues. The Commission 
    is particularly interested in comments on the extent to which penalties 
    are, or are not, a significant source of pipeline revenues. The 
    Commission is also concerned that the crediting of penalty revenues to 
    specific non-offending shippers may be difficult to implement. The 
    Commission seeks comments on whether such crediting can be implemented 
    without substantial administrative cost. The Commission also solicits 
    proposals for a specific mechanism for crediting penalty revenues.
        Another option on which the Commission solicits comments is the 
    desirability of revising the manner in which a shipper's cash-out 
    payment is determined. As discussed, current cash-out procedures 
    establish a payment based on the average price of gas for a given 
    month, which has induced shippers in some instances to game the 
    pipeline system to take advantage of changes in the price of natural 
    gas. A revision that could eliminate such gaming would be to require 
    the pipeline to provide a running imbalance of each shipper for each 
    day of the month. The imbalance would be defined not in volumes, but in 
    imbalance revenues, which would be the product of the shipper's volumes 
    of imbalance that particular day times that day's gas index price. One 
    concern this option raises is whether it would require pipelines to 
    install additional or enhanced meters and, if so, whether the costs of 
    doing so would outweigh the benefits of resolving the problems 
    associated with the gaming of the system.
        The Commission solicits comments on its proposal, the alternative 
    options, and the related questions. The Commission also solicits other 
    alternative proposals that commenters believe merit consideration.
    
    C. Pipelines Must Provide Services, to the Extent Operationally 
    Feasible, That Facilitate Imbalance Management
    
        An expansion of the number of imbalance management services would 
    reduce the need for penalties and the imposition of unnecessary 
    penalties.
    
    [[Page 43006]]
    
    The Commission has recently taken a first step in this direction in 
    Order No. 587-G 94 when it required pipelines, inter alia, 
    to
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \94\ Standards For Business Practices Of Interstate Natural Gas 
    Pipelines, Order No. 587-G, 63 FR 20072 (Apr. 23, 1998), III FERC 
    Stats. & Regs. Regulations Preambles para. 31,062 (Apr. 16, 1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
         allow firm shippers to revise nominations during the day 
    (thereby reducing the probability of imbalances caused by inaccurate 
    nominations);
         enter into operational balancing agreements at all 
    pipeline to pipeline interconnections;
         permit shippers to offset imbalances across contracts and 
    trade imbalances amongst themselves when such imbalances have similar 
    operational impact on the pipeline's system; and
         provide notice of OFOs and other critical notices by 
    posting the notice on their Internet web sites, which would be 
    accessible to shippers nationwide and by notifying the affected 
    customers directly.
        In this section the Commission proposes to require pipelines to 
    revise their tariffs to expand the number of imbalance management 
    services and opportunities available to shippers. Parking (temporary 
    storage) and lending (temporary loan of gas) are currently offered by 
    several, but not all, pipelines and allow shippers to avoid imbalances. 
    Under the proposal, a pipeline would be required to provide such 
    services if operationally practicable. In addition, a pipeline would be 
    required to revise or eliminate any tariff provision that gives undue 
    preference to its storage or balancing services over such services that 
    are provided by a third party. In response to the tariff filing, 
    parties could protest the proposals and propose alternatives for 
    Commission consideration.
        The Commission solicits comments on whether more specific 
    requirements or additional initiatives would be appropriate. One 
    prominent area of inquiry is the manner and extent to which the 
    Commission should encourage the availability of parking and lending as 
    well as alternative services. Some incentives are already provided for 
    in this NOPR. For example, because parking and lending are short-term 
    services, providers of such services would not be subject to a rate 
    cap. The Commission could also facilitate the use of third-party 
    storage by specifically requiring that a pipeline's transportation 
    charges for long-term services related to injection and withdrawal of 
    gas that comes from third party storage must be the same as the charges 
    that apply for long-term services when the gas comes from the 
    pipeline's own storage facilities.
        The Commission could also adopt policies that promote individual 
    shipper actions that alleviate system imbalances or operational 
    constraints. For example, the Commission has recently established a 
    ``no harm, no foul'' policy that would permit beneficial imbalances to 
    escape penalties.95 Such a policy is especially important in 
    emergency or peak periods, when a shipper's imbalance can run in the 
    opposite direction from the conditions adversely affecting the 
    pipeline. A shipper with such a beneficial imbalance (one that runs in 
    the opposite direction of the imbalance that adversely affects the 
    pipeline system) is aiding rather than adversely affecting the system 
    at a critical time. For example, a shipper might be taking less than it 
    nominated on a pipeline that was suffering from significant overtakes 
    of gas. This policy prohibits a pipeline from penalizing a shipper to 
    the extent that such ``good'' behavior can be tracked.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \95\ Panhandle Pipe Line Co., 82 FERC para. 61,163, at 61,600-
    601
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A variation of a ``no harm, no foul'' policy would be to go beyond 
    immunizing a shipper running a beneficial imbalance from penalties, and 
    to reward such shippers especially during emergency time periods. On 
    the other hand, in Order No. 587-G the Commission has required 
    pipelines to permit shippers to net imbalances across contracts and 
    trade imbalances with other shippers. In light of these requirements, 
    would rewarding shippers running beneficial imbalances provide 
    significant additional benefit?
        The Commission solicits comments on its proposal, the alternative 
    options, and the related questions. The Commission also solicits other 
    alternative proposals that commenters believe merit consideration.
    
    D. Pipelines Must Adopt Incentives and Procedures That Minimize the Use 
    and Adverse Impact of OFOs
    
        Finally, the Commission proposes to require each pipeline to adopt 
    incentives and procedures that minimize the use and adverse impact of 
    OFOs. The imposition of OFOs may severely restrict the purchase and 
    transportation alternatives available to a customer during peak 
    periods, precisely when such alternatives are critically needed to 
    enhance the opportunities of a shipper to purchase such services at the 
    lowest competitive prices. Under current practice, pipelines have 
    incentives to favor OFOs as the first option, not the last resort. The 
    pipeline is likely to err on the side of using an OFO, because it bears 
    the risk that if it does not, curtailment of load may result that could 
    in turn precipitate strong public disapproval and law suits from firm 
    customers. In contrast, shippers--not pipelines--bear the costs that 
    result from imposition of OFOs. A pipeline could also prefer OFOs 
    because it would limit or eliminate a shipper's option to purchase 
    transportation that would be in lieu of transportation services 
    provided by that pipeline. In technical conferences, shippers have 
    complained that OFOs have been issued too frequently, for too long, and 
    were larger in scope than required to protect the integrity of system 
    operations.96
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \96\ See, e.g., NorAm Gas Transmission Company, 79 FERC para. 
    61,126, at 61,546-47 (1997); Southern Natural Gas Company, 80 FERC 
    para. 61,233, at 61,890 (1997) Northern Natural Gas Company, 77 FERC 
    para. 61,282 (1997); Panhandle Eastern Pipeline Company, 78 FERC 
    para. 61,202 (1997); Northwest Pipeline Company, 71 FERC para. 
    61,315 (1995).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In light of these considerations, it is appropriate to review 
    existing pipeline tariffs to ensure that the resort to, and adverse 
    impact of, OFOs are reduced to the maximum extent practicable. The 
    Commission therefore proposes to require each pipeline to revise its 
    tariff to the extent necessary to:
         state clear standards, based on objective operational 
    conditions, for when OFOs begin and end; 97
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \97\ For example, if a pipeline anticipates an OFO will be in 
    effect until weather conditions change, it would aid shippers' 
    planning to so advise them.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
         require the pipeline to post, as soon as available, 
    information about the status of operational variables that determine 
    when an OFO will begin and end; 98
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \98\ For example, if an OFO will remain in effect until repairs 
    are completed on a compressor, the pipeline should be required to 
    update shippers on the status of the repairs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
         state the steps and order of operational remedies that 
    will be followed before an OFO is issued to assure that the OFO has the 
    most limited application practicable and to limit the consequences of 
    its imposition; 99
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \99\ For example, one requirement would be that a pipeline 
    provide as much advance warning as possible of the conditions that 
    may create an OFO and the specific OFO itself that would allow 
    customers to respond to such conditions and/or prepare alternative 
    arrangements in the event the OFO is implemented.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
         set standards for different levels or degrees of severity 
    of OFOs to correspond to different degrees of system emergencies the 
    pipeline may confront; 100 and
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \100\ For example, a $100 OFO penalty may be appropriated in 
    severe cases, whereas a $25 OFO penalty may be appropriate in 
    others.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
         establish reporting requirements that provide information 
    after OFOs are
    
    [[Page 43007]]
    
    issued on the factors that caused the OFO to be issued and then lifted.
        In response to the tariff filing, parties could protest the 
    proposals and propose alternatives for Commission consideration.
        The Commission requests comments on the proposal set forth above. 
    The Commission is particularly interested in comments on the extent to 
    which current OFOs have created significant problems and, if so, the 
    specific problems that were created.
        The Commission also solicits comments on additional or alternative 
    options. One such option would be to use financial incentives based on 
    the past OFO experiences of a pipeline to minimize future imposition of 
    OFOs. For example, a pipeline that never issues OFOs could be allowed 
    to retain a portion of cash-out penalties, which under current 
    Commission policy would be automatically credited to its customers. 
    Conversely, a pipeline that frequently issues OFOs could be required to 
    rebate a portion of the customer's reservation charges if it does not 
    fix within a reasonable time the operational problems that give rise to 
    frequent OFOs. The Commission solicits comments on the adequacy of such 
    incentives and also solicits alternative incentives.
        Another option would be to require automatic crediting of OFO 
    penalties, even if the Commission retains its current policy of not 
    requiring pipelines to credit most penalty revenues. As discussed, 
    currently pipelines have incentive to impose OFOs as a first reaction 
    to a system operational problem. Requiring the automatic crediting of 
    OFO penalties would at least eliminate one potential incentive.
        Another option is for the Commission to institute a program that 
    monitors on a periodic basis the frequency of impositions by each 
    regulated pipeline of OFOs. If the Commission determines that an 
    individual pipeline frequently issues OFOs, the Commission could audit 
    the pipeline's operations or establish a proceeding to determine if 
    changes should be made to the pipeline's tariff.
        The Commission solicits comments on its proposal, the alternative 
    options, and the related questions. The Commission also solicits other 
    alternative proposals that commenters believe merit consideration.
    
    V. Negotiated Rates and Services
    
        Two of the objectives of the regulatory changes proposed in this 
    NOPR are to promote greater innovation in service offerings, and to 
    increase the value of long-term capacity as protection against price 
    swings in the short-term market. As explained below, allowing the 
    negotiation of rates and services can provide the flexibility necessary 
    to foster service innovation. The negotiation of rates and services 
    also has the ability to increase the attractiveness of long-term 
    capacity, so that biases toward short-term capacity are weakened. In 
    this manner, negotiated rates and services can help achieve the 
    Commission's goal of creating a more neutral regulatory policy with 
    respect to short-term and long-term capacity.
        Permitting pipelines to negotiate the terms and conditions of 
    service with their customers can have several beneficial effects. 
    First, permitting negotiated terms and conditions of service may spur 
    innovation and creativity in the services provided, and keep natural 
    gas transportation service from becoming stagnant. Traditional 
    regulation does not always allow for innovation and gives regulated 
    companies little incentive to be creative or to innovate. For example, 
    conventional tariff procedures may inhibit the development of 
    innovative services, since the need for such services may be immediate 
    and may arise quickly. Therefore, presently, neither pipelines, 
    customers, nor regulators know with certainty what innovations are 
    feasible, or would be worth their cost.
        A policy that permits pipelines to negotiate rates and terms of 
    services together may give pipelines more incentive to innovate by 
    allowing pipelines to charge more for innovations that customers value 
    more. Also, the ability to negotiate rates and services may stimulate 
    pipelines to offer service innovations that are relatively costless to 
    provide, something they may have had little incentive to do under cost-
    based rates. These innovations should ultimately improve the quality of 
    the pipelines' other tariff services, if pipelines are given incentives 
    to maintain and upgrade these services, as well.
        Second, while the negotiation of service may be useful for short-
    term services, its most significant use may be as a valuable risk 
    management tool for pipelines and customers with respect to long-term 
    contracts.
        When a customer enters into a long-term contract, it must undertake 
    a number of risks. It must bear the general market risk that the value 
    of capacity may decrease in time, so that the customer could have 
    acquired the capacity for a lower rate later, or the risk that the 
    pipeline will experience a decrease in system throughput, which would 
    drive the maximum regulated rate up. The customer must bear the 
    regulatory risk that the rates for the capacity that it has committed 
    to under the firm contract will increase due to, for example, the 
    rolling-in of the costs of new capacity construction, or other general 
    rate increases. The customer must also bear the customer-specific risk 
    that its own need for capacity might fluctuate or disappear.
        When these risks are too high for a customer, at the given rates 
    for long-term and short-term capacity, the customer may be unwilling to 
    hold long-term capacity contracts. In the past, shippers accepted some 
    regulatory price risk in return for little or no gas supply risk. Now, 
    however, shippers appear less willing to shoulder the price risks 
    associated with long-term contracts as a result of the increased 
    attractiveness of short-term contracts, the presence of regulatory 
    disincentives to long-term contracts, such as the right of first 
    refusal, and the uncertainty of potential business impacts of state 
    retail open-access programs. The movement away from long-term contracts 
    increases the pipeline's risk that it will not earn enough revenues 
    during the pipeline's useful life to cover its total cost and an 
    acceptable return on the investment in the pipeline.
        Allowing pipelines and shippers to negotiate terms and conditions 
    of service, as well as rates, may permit greater flexibility in the 
    allocation of the shipper's risk inherent in long-term capacity 
    contracts. Such negotiation of rates and services could permit the 
    parties to negotiate more flexible contracts for higher rates. Other 
    options for negotiation could include lower rates for longer contract 
    terms, differing rates for the right to reopen the contract in 
    specified contingencies, or varying rates for different payment 
    schedules.
        Thus, a negotiated rates and services policy may give parties the 
    ability to negotiate terms that will reduce the shipper's risk in 
    entering into a long-term contract, thereby increasing a shipper's 
    willingness to execute long-term contracts and encouraging greater 
    long-term contracting, generally. This, in turn, raises a third benefit 
    of allowing negotiated terms and conditions of service. As the value of 
    long-term contracts increases, and more long-term contracts are 
    executed, problems of capacity turnback may be alleviated. Negotiated 
    rates and services may give pipelines the ability to attract new 
    customers and keep existing customers as long-term contracts expire, 
    helping to ensure that pipelines are able to recover their long-term 
    investment costs. Such negotiation is especially important as
    
    [[Page 43008]]
    
    markets increasingly define the value of capacity.
        Further, certain additional, indirect benefits can result from 
    permitting negotiated services. A policy favorable to negotiated 
    services may facilitate the unbundling of LDC services at the state 
    level, thereby extending customer choice to more retail markets 
    nationwide. It may also position the gas industry to be a viable 
    competitor of the increasingly competitive electric industry for end 
    use customers.
        While the Commission recognizes the important benefits that would 
    result from a negotiated rates and services policy, the Commission is 
    also mindful that significant, although probably manageable, concerns 
    exist in permitting negotiated services. Pipelines will exercise market 
    power if they can. The concept of negotiated rates and services--under 
    which shippers and pipelines would be able to negotiate rates or 
    service terms and conditions that deviate from those in the pipeline's 
    otherwise applicable tariff--relies on the theory that shippers would 
    be able to choose a ``recourse'' rate or service from the pipeline's 
    tariff as an alternative to negotiating with the pipeline. In this way, 
    the recourse service would act as a check on the exercise of the 
    pipeline's market power. Nevertheless, the negotiation of rates and 
    services, by its nature, gives pipelines the ability to treat customers 
    differently, and thereby could facilitate a pipeline's ability to 
    segregate customers and exercise market power.
        A pipeline with market power might be able to force captive 
    customers to pay for unwanted terms or conditions of service by 
    bundling them with desired services, or to pay for basic services at 
    premium prices. The Commission is concerned that permitting the 
    negotiation of service could give pipelines an incentive to degrade the 
    quality of recourse services in order to sell other services on a 
    negotiated basis.
        Another way pipelines could exercise their market power with 
    negotiated services is by unduly discriminating against certain 
    customers. Some level of discrimination, or differentiation, among 
    customers is inherent to the concept of negotiating differing rates and 
    terms of service. However, the Commission is concerned that pipelines 
    could give undue preference to affiliates or other customers in the 
    offering of negotiated services.
        Further, the Commission is keenly aware of the natural tension that 
    exists between allowing negotiated rates and services, on the one hand, 
    and ensuring the tradability of capacity, on the other hand. The 
    negotiation of terms and conditions of service could make capacity less 
    tradable and deter the Commission's goal of promoting competition in 
    capacity markets.
        Many of these concerns were raised in response to the Commission's 
    ``Request for Comments on Alternative Pricing Methods'' in Docket No. 
    RM95-6-000.101/ These concerns were part of the reason that 
    the Commission was reluctant, in its subsequent ``Statement of Policy 
    and Request for Comments'' in Docket Nos. RM95-6-000 and RM95-7-000, to 
    allow the full range of negotiation, and therefore, declined to permit 
    the negotiation of terms and conditions of service as part of its 
    negotiated rates policy at that time.102/ However, since 
    then, the Commission has had the benefit of the additional industry 
    comments filed in Docket No. RM95-7-000, and has undertaken a thorough 
    review of its natural gas policies. The Commission now recognizes that 
    the concept of negotiated rates and services, taken together with the 
    other proposals in this document, has the potential to improve the 
    Commission's regulatory framework for natural gas pipelines.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \101\ / Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service Ratemaking 
    for Natural Gas Pipelines, 60 FR 8356 (Feb. 14, 1995), 70 FERC ] 
    61,139 (1995).
        \102\ / Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service Ratemaking 
    for Natural Gas Pipelines, and Regulation of Negotiated 
    Transportation Services of Natural Gas Pipelines, 61 FR 4633 (Feb. 
    7, 1996), 74 FERC para. 61,076 (1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Given the above concerns, the Commission concludes that the 
    benefits to increased service innovation and long-term contracting that 
    can result from the negotiation of terms and conditions of service, 
    together with rates, are valuable, but only if they do not come at the 
    expense of the interests of recourse ratepayers, or hinder the 
    development of competitive markets.
        Accordingly, the Commission proposes to implement a policy 
    permitting the negotiation of rates, terms, and conditions of service 
    for transportation services that will be governed by a set of guiding 
    principles designed to protect recourse and captive customers from the 
    exercise of market power, prevent undue discrimination and preference, 
    and foster competition in the interstate capacity 
    markets.103 These proposed guiding principles, as described 
    below, will provide limits and conditions on the negotiation of rates 
    and services that should minimize the risk of potential harm to 
    recourse shippers and capacity markets, and thereby help ensure that 
    the benefits of the negotiated rates and services policy outweigh such 
    risks.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \103\ See Sec. 284.11 of the proposed regulations.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission is seeking comment on whether to permit the 
    negotiation of services in the short-term market. As the short-term 
    market develops, it can be argued that the benefits of negotiated 
    services are especially important to the short-term market, provided 
    that such negotiation does not impair the tradability of short-term 
    capacity. A number of expected benefits to the market may flow from 
    allowing the negotiation of short-term services. Short-term peak market 
    conditions arguably require a maximum amount of flexibility and 
    customization for shippers. On the other hand, the Commission has not 
    resolved how the negotiation of short-term rates and services could be 
    coordinated with the capacity auction process proposed in this NOPR. 
    Typically, auctions involve the trading of standardized products and 
    services, whereas negotiated services may not be sufficiently tradable.
        The Commission proposes to address this issue in the final rule, 
    and seeks analysis and comment on the alternatives of whether to permit 
    or prohibit the negotiation of terms and conditions of service in the 
    short-term market. Should the negotiation of services be reserved for 
    the long-term market? Can negotiation of services be accomplished in 
    combination with the auction process? What effect would the negotiation 
    of short-term services have on the tradability of short-term capacity? 
    What are the benefits to the marketplace of permitting negotiation in 
    the short-term market?
        In addition, while the Commission is proposing in this NOPR to 
    permit negotiated rates, terms, and conditions of service under the 
    principles below, the Commission also proposes to conduct a generic 
    review of the negotiated services after they have been in effect for 
    two winter heating seasons.
    
    A. Guiding Principles
    
        The Commission is proposing to permit the negotiation of any rate, 
    or term or condition of service for transportation services to the 
    extent :
         It does not result in undue discrimination or preference;
         It does not degrade the quality of existing services;
         It does not hinder the release of capacity, or otherwise 
    significantly reduce competition;
         Pipelines do not require customers to take negotiated 
    transportation services tied with any unwanted sales, storage, or 
    gathering services provided
    
    [[Page 43009]]
    
    by the pipeline, its affiliates, or upstream or downstream entities; 
    and
         The terms of the negotiated transactions are made publicly 
    available.
        These general guiding principles will provide the boundaries within 
    which the industry may conduct negotiations of rates and services, and 
    will be applied on a case-by-case basis. They will also give the 
    Commission, and the industry, a basic foundation for evaluating future 
    negotiated deals that cannot be envisioned currently. Establishing more 
    specific or restrictive guidelines could limit, in the future, the 
    degree of innovation that potentially could be achieved.
        Further, the Commission proposes that if a pipeline violates any of 
    these proposed guiding principles, the Commission would revoke that 
    pipeline's authority to negotiate rates and services. Establishment of 
    this penalty up-front for violating the guidelines of the negotiated 
    rates and services policy should serve as an incentive for compliance. 
    In addition, the traditional remedies available under the NGA would 
    also be available to the Commission to use.
        Each of the proposed guiding principles is discussed more fully 
    below.
    1. No Undue Discrimination or Preference
        The Commission is particularly concerned that the negotiation of 
    rates and services does not violate the statutory prohibition against 
    undue discrimination and preference in the NGA.104 The very 
    nature of negotiated rates and services is to provide some customers 
    rates and services that differ from those provided to others. However, 
    the negotiation of rates and services under the proposed policy cannot 
    be unduly discriminatory or preferential. Practically speaking, under 
    existing undue discrimination standards, this would require that 
    ``similarly situated'' shippers have rights to the same negotiated 
    deal. The cases in which the Commission has applied the ``similarly 
    situated'' standard in the past provide some guidance on the meaning of 
    ``similarly situated'' shippers.105
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \104\ See Section 4(b) of the NGA. 15 U.S. C. 717c (1994).
        \105\ See Tennessee Gas Pipeline Company, 77 FERC para. 61,877 
    (1996) (requiring the pipeline to file specific information to 
    enable shippers to determine if they are similarly situated to 
    particular negotiated rate customers, including the type of service, 
    the receipt and delivery points applicable to the service, and the 
    volume of gas to be transported); and Standards of Conduct and 
    Reporting Requirements for Transportation and Affiliate 
    Transactions, 59 FR 32885 (June 27, 1994), FERC Stats. & Regs. para. 
    30,997 at 31,067-68 (1994) (Order No. 566) (requiring pipelines to 
    post particular information on their EBBs regarding affiliate 
    discounts, including quantity and point data, to enable non-
    affiliates to determine if they are entitled to a similar discount). 
    See also, Iroquois Gas Transmission System, L.P., 79 FERC para. 
    61,394 (1997), reh'g denied, 82 FERC para. 61,086 (1998) (holding 
    that the pipeline may not charge new expansion shippers and existing 
    shippers different rates, based on findings that differences between 
    each shipper group stemming from the time when each group came on 
    the system, such as differences in receipt and delivery points or 
    available competitive alternatives, were insufficient to justify 
    disparate treatment); and El Paso Natural Gas Company, 62 FERC para. 
    61,311 at 62,990-91 (1993), followed in ANR Pipeline Company, 66 
    FERC para. 61,340 at 62,130-31 (1994) and Questar Pipeline Company 
    v. PacifiCorp, 70 FERC para. 61,328 at 62,009 (1995) (shippers 
    holding discounted rate contracts between certain primary points do 
    not have the right to use alternate points at the discounted rate, 
    since the market conditions may not be the same at the primary and 
    alternate points).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Nevertheless, the Commission recognizes that clear guidelines, or 
    standards, on what constitutes undue discrimination or preference in 
    negotiating rates and services may need to be established before any 
    negotiation takes place so that the industry can abide by this 
    principle. Such up-front standards could provide guidance to pipelines 
    and shippers about acceptable negotiation practices, eliminating 
    confusion about what does and does not constitute permissible conduct, 
    and could minimize the risk of discrimination occurring before 
    standards emerge from a case-by-case complaint and review process. The 
    standards may also be critical to effective monitoring and enforcement.
        While the Commission is considering developing such generic undue 
    discrimination guidelines, such standards could prove difficult to 
    craft, since undue discrimination findings usually depend on specific 
    facts and often are subject to widely varied and subjective 
    interpretation. Thus, the Commission seeks comment on the need for, and 
    feasibility of, its developing clear standards on what constitutes 
    undue discrimination or preference before negotiations are permitted to 
    occur. The Commission further requests commenters to discuss what 
    should be the standards for undue discrimination, including whether the 
    ``similarly situated'' standard should continue to be used, and if so, 
    how that term should be defined.
    2. No Degradation of the Quality of Existing Services
        A core concern of captive customers, shared by the Commission, is 
    the effect a negotiated rates and services policy could have on the 
    quality of service that recourse shippers receive. Permitting the 
    negotiation of particular terms and conditions of service might, in a 
    direct way, adversely affect the quality of one or many recourse 
    shippers' service. For example, negotiations to loosen a pipeline's 
    imbalance provision for some shippers may force the tightening of 
    allowed tolerances for others.
        Therefore, the Commission proposes to permit the negotiation of 
    rates and services as long as the quality of service for recourse 
    shippers is not diminished or degraded. The Commission's objective in 
    proposing this principle is to prevent pipelines from negotiating 
    services at the expense of service quality for recourse shippers.
    3. No Impairment of the Tradability of Capacity
        The negotiation of terms and conditions of service could impair or 
    reduce competition in capacity markets. This may happen either because 
    service may become defined so differently that capacity is no longer 
    fungible, or because customers voluntarily give up the rights that make 
    trading possible in exchange for a rate reduction. This, in turn, could 
    diminish the degree of competition in capacity markets generally, or in 
    some specific markets.
        Therefore, to guard against this, the Commission proposes to permit 
    the negotiation of rates and services as long as such negotiation does 
    not impair tradability of capacity, result in a significantly greater 
    concentration of sellers in capacity markets, or otherwise 
    significantly reduce existing competition. Since the full range of 
    innovation that might occur under the negotiated rates and services 
    policy cannot be known at this time, it may be that shippers will be 
    able to develop negotiated services that do not impair the tradability 
    of capacity. To help enable shippers to release negotiated services, 
    mechanisms may be developed which allow negotiated service to revert to 
    standard service at the releasing shipper's option when released to 
    another shipper.106
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \106\ This is discussed more fully below.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    4. No Unwanted Tying Arrangements
        One of the Commission's objectives in Order No. 636 was to prevent 
    the exercise of market power over transportation from being extended to 
    the sale of natural gas, through the tying of the two different 
    services. The negotiation of terms and conditions of service can raise 
    new issues in this regard. Permitting pipelines to negotiate 
    individualized services may prompt pipelines to require customers to 
    take packages of service, either from the pipeline, its affiliate, or 
    another entity,
    
    [[Page 43010]]
    
    that include both transportation and sales services that are currently 
    available separately. Similar concerns arise from attempts to bundle 
    transportation with unwanted storage or gathering services. Allowing 
    pipelines to force customers to take tied services could adversely 
    affect commodity markets that are currently competitive, or competition 
    between sellers of capacity, and could lead to increased preferences 
    for affiliates.
        Therefore, the Commission proposes that a pipeline may not require 
    that a negotiated transportation service be tied with any unwanted 
    sales service or other services provided by the pipeline, its 
    affiliate, or by any upstream or downstream entity, unless that service 
    is necessary to the provision of the negotiated transportation service. 
    While the Commission does not envision that the tying of gathering or 
    sales service to the transportation service would be necessary to the 
    transportation service, there may be instances where storage service 
    could be a prerequisite for the pipeline's ability to provide the 
    negotiated transportation service.
    5. Transparency of Negotiated Transactions
        The Commission proposes to require that the essential elements of 
    negotiated transactions, including price, be transparent to the public 
    and the Commission. The full disclosure of the terms of the negotiated 
    transactions is critical to the ability of shippers and the Commission 
    to detect, and deter, the exercise of market power and undue 
    discrimination and preference. The transparency of negotiated 
    arrangements also enables shippers to make informed purchasing 
    decisions.
        The need for transparency has guided the Commission's development 
    of the proposed procedures for implementing a negotiated rates and 
    services policy. Thus, as discussed infra, the Commission is proposing 
    to require pipelines to file with the Commission and serve on firm 
    shippers, written notice of all essential information about a 
    negotiated transaction prior to the transaction taking effect. The 
    Commission is also proposing to increase its existing reporting 
    requirements.
    
    B. Implementation of the Negotiated Rates and Services Policy
    
    1. Procedural Mechanism
        The American Gas Association (AGA), on behalf of itself and the 
    Interstate Natural Gas Association of America (INGAA), proposed to the 
    Commission, by letter dated May 4, 1998, a method for implementing a 
    negotiated services policy. AGA/INGAA's proposed method would entail 
    each pipeline making an initial ``benchmark'' filing, prior to its 
    first negotiation of service, that would (a) set forth certain terms or 
    conditions of service that could not be negotiated absent 30 days prior 
    notice, and (b) establish a high standard for quality and reliability 
    of recourse service, as well as better define essential elements of the 
    pipeline's tariff. Then, after Commission approval of the initial 
    benchmark filing, the pipeline would be able to implement, after 10 
    days prior notice, negotiated deals containing items not identified in 
    the initial filing as requiring 30 days prior notice. The Pipeline 
    Transportation Customer Coalition (Coalition), comprised of end users, 
    marketers, producers, and municipal distributors, filed with the 
    Commission a letter opposing AGA/INGAA's negotiated services proposal 
    and more broadly, the concept of negotiated services.\107\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \107\ See June 17, 1998 letter of the Pipeline Transportation 
    Customer Coalitation filed in Docket No. PL97-1-000.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As discussed above, the negotiation of rates and services can serve 
    a valuable role in the Commission's proposed new regulatory approach. 
    While the Commission acknowledges the potential risk of harm to 
    competitive markets and recourse shippers, that risk appears to be 
    manageable. Therefore, the Commission is proposing a method for 
    implementing negotiated services that has some similarity to aspects of 
    AGA/INGAA's proposed method.
        The Commission is proposing to require a pipeline interested in 
    negotiating terms and conditions of service to make an initial filing 
    requesting authority to negotiate rates and services on its system. 
    This initial filing would accomplish two equally important functions. 
    First, it would define and establish a high quality recourse 
    service.\108\ Second, the initial filing would establish the parameters 
    of permissible and impermissible negotiation for that pipeline in 
    advance of any negotiation of service or implementation of negotiated 
    services. This would be accomplished by the pipeline identifying 
    categories of non-negotiable, negotiable, and potentially negotiable 
    terms or conditions of service, as described in more detail below. The 
    Commission would closely scrutinize the proposed categories of terms 
    and conditions of service, particularly the terms and conditions of 
    service included within the negotiable category, to ensure consistency 
    with the proposed guiding principles. For example, the Commission would 
    analyze whether the negotiation of the negotiable items could adversely 
    affect the quality of other services or the tradability of capacity, 
    and whether additional terms and conditions should be included in the 
    non-negotiable category. Interested parties would have the opportunity 
    to comment on and protest any aspect of the initial filing, and the 
    Commission would carefully consider all such comments and protests. 
    Only after such review, and Commission approval of the initial filing, 
    would the pipeline be permitted to begin negotiations and implement 
    negotiated services. In addition, after the Commission approved the 
    initial filing, the pipeline would be required to include the 
    categories of terms and conditions of service in its tariff.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \108\ Further discussion of this aspect of the proposal is 
    included in the discussion below on the establishment of initial 
    recourse service.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The non-negotiable category of terms and conditions of service 
    would include certain terms and conditions of service that could never 
    be negotiated, and thus, would be per se non-negotiable. A pipeline 
    might include in this category terms or conditions that, by their 
    nature, would directly affect the services of other shippers (e.g., 
    force majeure, higher curtailment, or generic OFOs provisions).
        The negotiable category of terms and conditions of service would 
    include particular items that the pipeline would be permitted to 
    negotiate, at its and its customers' discretion. A pipeline could 
    include permissible ranges of flexibility for each negotiable area of 
    service. These negotiable deals would be permitted to be implemented 
    after 10 days prior written notice to firm shippers and the 
    Commission.\109\ The Commission is proposing to permit these negotiable 
    services to go into effect at the end of the 10 day notice period, 
    without action on the notice filing by the Commission, since the 
    Commission would have already generically approved the negotiation of 
    these items by that pipeline with its action on the initial filing. 
    Similarly, other shippers would have had the opportunity to comment on 
    or oppose the pipeline's proposed negotiation of a particular term or 
    condition of service at the initial filing stage.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \109\ See 18 CFR 385.2007 (1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission, however, seeks comment on whether a shorter advance 
    notice period, or any advance notice at all, is necessary for contracts 
    containing the items identified by the initial filing as negotiable. 
    Parties should comment on whether such negotiated contracts could be 
    self-implementing, becoming
    
    [[Page 43011]]
    
    effective upon the agreement of the pipeline and the shipper, subject 
    only to the pipeline filing and posting a transactional report of the 
    negotiated deal contemporaneous with the execution of the contract.
        The potentially negotiable category of terms and conditions of 
    service would not need to be specifically identified, but would 
    encompass all other terms and conditions of service not identified in 
    the non-negotiable or negotiable categories. Items would fall into this 
    category if they had the potential to have an impact on the service of 
    other shippers, or had the potential to violate one of the other 
    guiding principles. Thus, any negotiation of these unspecified terms 
    and conditions of service would require prior notice, an opportunity 
    for other shippers to comment, and Commission review of the particular 
    negotiated transaction before taking effect. Specifically, the pipeline 
    would be required to make a filing under Sections 4(d) and (e) of the 
    NGA before the negotiated deal could take effect.\110\ The 30 days 
    prior written notice to the Commission and firm shippers provided by 
    the Section 4 filing would give all other shippers the opportunity to 
    protest the negotiated transaction before it takes effect, and the 
    Commission would have the ability, as usual, to accept, reject, or 
    suspend the pipeline's filing.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \110\ 15 U.S.C. 717c (1994).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The pipeline's Section 4 filing would need to contain the essential 
    aspects of the negotiated agreement, including: the name of the 
    shipper, any affiliation with the pipeline, the contract quantity, the 
    applicable rate(s), the receipt and delivery points, and a brief 
    description of the negotiated term or condition of service with 
    reference to the modified provision of the recourse tariff or rate 
    schedule. The filing would also contain a statement, with any 
    supporting information, that no material adverse effects on the 
    benchmark service will result from the negotiated term or condition. 
    This statement and supporting information would create a rebuttable 
    presumption that the negotiated transaction will not have any material 
    adverse effect on the recourse service. If the presumption is overcome, 
    the ultimate burden of persuasion would be on the pipeline to show that 
    no degradation of the recourse service would result.
        Finally, the Commission is also proposing to continue the current 
    practice of allowing pipelines to negotiate unique services in 
    individual rate schedules that are then made available to all 
    customers, since this method already serves the industry well.
        Although the Commission is proposing the method for implementing 
    negotiated services described above, the Commission would also consider 
    variations on this method, including the specific proposal advanced by 
    AGA/INGAA. In this regard, the Commission requests comment on whether 
    pipelines could be given an option of implementing negotiated terms and 
    conditions of service without having to initially file general tariff 
    provisions defining the scope of permissible or impermissible 
    negotiation. That is, could pipelines also be permitted to negotiate 
    unique deals with individual shippers that include terms and conditions 
    that deviate from those in its existing tariff, by filing each 
    negotiated contract with 30 days advance notice, and bypassing the 
    initial tariff filing? The Commission invites comments discussing the 
    pros and cons of the proposed implementation method, including whether 
    that method adequately addresses concerns which have been expressed 
    about the pipelines' potential exercise of market power. Commenters are 
    also invited to suggest alternative procedures for implementing 
    negotiated rates and services.
    2. Recourse Service
        The recourse service, which would be available to all shippers, 
    serves as an alternative to negotiating with the pipeline, and an 
    important check on the pipeline's potential exercise of market power. 
    Therefore, the Commission must ensure that the recourse service is 
    initially, and remains over time, a high quality service, so that it 
    stays a viable alternative to negotiated rates and services. Below, the 
    Commission presents proposals for initially establishing a good quality 
    recourse service, and for maintaining the vitality of that recourse 
    service in the future.
        a. Establishment of Initial Recourse Service. The Commission 
    proposes to require that each pipeline's initial voluntary filing to 
    implement negotiated terms and conditions of service define the 
    components of that pipeline's recourse service. Pipelines would be 
    required to design a recourse service that is of a high quality and 
    reliability, and maintains at least the level of service being offered 
    by the pipeline in its currently effective tariff. Core elements of the 
    pipeline's recourse service that are not adequately defined in the 
    tariff, including standard operating practices, would be identified by 
    the pipeline or its customers in conjunction with the filing.
        Essentially, this method of establishing initial recourse service 
    would require that any pipeline choosing to implement negotiated terms 
    and conditions of service submit its tariff services for review and 
    modification to establish adequate recourse service in exchange for the 
    authorization to negotiate terms and conditions of service. This 
    proposal would provide a procedure to address shippers' dissatisfaction 
    with some pipelines' existing service offerings, and their concerns 
    that the literal language of the existing tariffs might permit 
    pipelines to reduce the quality of recourse service from that enjoyed 
    under current operating practice. Thus, the review and modification of 
    individual pipelines' existing tariff services will help ensure that 
    recourse service is adequate before any negotiation of rates or 
    services takes place.
        However, the Commission also seeks comments on whether using 
    pipelines' existing tariffs as the initial recourse service, without 
    requiring new filings, might be less burdensome on the industry and the 
    Commission, and thereby permit pipelines and shippers to begin 
    negotiating rates and services sooner than if initial filings to 
    establish recourse service were required. Parties should also comment 
    on whether the existing rates, terms, and conditions in pipelines' 
    current tariffs could be acceptable as initial recourse services, since 
    they have already been found by the Commission to be just and 
    reasonable. In commenting, parties should evaluate the need for 
    establishing adequate recourse services against the ability to 
    implement the negotiated rates and services policy without undue delay.
        Another option for establishing initial recourse service would be 
    to have GISB generically identify basic elements of service that could 
    not be subject to negotiation. Designating particular terms or 
    conditions as non-negotiable would have the effect of defining some of 
    the basic terms and conditions of service that comprise recourse 
    service. Some commenters have requested that the Commission generically 
    specify particular terms or conditions as non-negotiable. However, GISB 
    is the one forum where all segments of the industry are brought 
    together, making across-the-board consensus on this issue a 
    possibility. The Commission requests comments on the feasibility and 
    value of having GISB define initial recourse service.
        b. Maintaining Vitality of Recourse Service Over Time. For recourse 
    service to remain a viable option to negotiated
    
    [[Page 43012]]
    
    service, the overall quality of the recourse service must continue to 
    meet shippers' needs. The Commission is concerned that over time the 
    quality of recourse service may deteriorate. By not updating recourse 
    service to keep pace with changing markets, technology, and customer 
    needs, or by maintaining a low-quality or inferior recourse service, 
    pipelines could force captive customers into negotiating the basic 
    services they need, at premium rates.
        Thus, the Commission finds that a mechanism needs to be established 
    to review recourse services to ensure they remain viable alternatives 
    to negotiated services. Accordingly, the Commission proposes to 
    implement periodic reviews of the rates, terms, and conditions of 
    recourse service.\111\ As discussed in more detail below, the 
    Commission proposes that these periodic reviews take place on a three-
    to-five year cycle, although comment is invited on proposals for 
    alternative review cycles. These periodic reviews would provide the 
    Commission with the opportunity to examine the range of terms and 
    conditions included in the recourse service, and to assess the quality 
    of the recourse service as a whole.\112\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \111\ See proposed Sec. 284.10(c).
        \112\ The Commission may need, at some point in the future, to 
    adopt standards that define recourse service quality.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The periodic reviews would provide a forum for the Commission to 
    determine if certain negotiated services offered by some pipelines 
    should be offered as recourse services after some reasonable time. This 
    would allow captive customers to obtain the benefits of service 
    innovation, while at the same time giving pipelines a reasonable period 
    of time to profit from their innovative service offerings before having 
    to offer the service at a cost-based rate. The periodic reviews of 
    recourse services would also enable proposed additions or changes to 
    recourse service to be considered comprehensively, to help ensure that 
    the new package of recourse services is both operationally feasible and 
    cost effective.
        There are several different ways that the Commission could 
    implement the periodic reviews of recourse service. The periodic review 
    could be undertaken on an individual pipeline basis, on a regional 
    basis, or on a national, or generic, basis. The Commission proposes to 
    establish recourse services, through the periodic reviews, for each 
    individual pipeline. This approach is likely to provide the best match 
    of customers' service needs with the operational capabilities of 
    individual pipelines. Establishing recourse services individually, for 
    each pipeline, would also allow rate issues to be treated 
    simultaneously with service issues.
        The Commission proposes that pipelines offering negotiated terms 
    and conditions of service file information with the Commission every 
    three to five years that will ensure the viability of the pipeline's 
    recourse service. The information proposed to be filed is intended to 
    give the Commission adequate information to determine whether and how 
    to modify the pipeline's recourse rates and service to keep pace with 
    market conditions.
        The information would need to be filed for each type of negotiated 
    service--the negotiated services that take effect on shortened notice 
    and the transactions subject to 30 days notice. The filing would 
    include data on the names and types of shippers negotiating the 
    contracts, the terms negotiated, the contract demand, and volumes moved 
    under the contracts.
        In addition, to permit a comparison to the pipeline's current 
    recourse service, the pipeline would have to provide aggregate data for 
    each category of negotiated service, and for the recourse service. The 
    aggregate data would include information on total contract demand, 
    aggregate volumes, and revenues for the negotiated contracts and the 
    recourse service.
        Commenters are requested to address the adequacy of the information 
    required in the proposal, including whether more detailed information 
    is necessary, and are encouraged to suggest other information that 
    might better permit the Commission to review negotiated rates and 
    services.
        The Commission is still considering, as an alternative to the 
    pipeline-specific review of recourse service, requiring the periodic 
    recourse service reviews to be made on a regional basis, before any 
    individual pipeline-specific adjustments are made. On the one hand, the 
    establishment of recourse services on a regional basis, so that the 
    recourse services offered by all pipelines in a given region would be 
    as nearly equivalent as possible given operational differences among 
    pipelines, could result in greater standardization of pipeline services 
    and practices, thereby enhancing competition and tradability of 
    capacity. It could also lower transaction costs for customers. In 
    addition, a regional approach may be less burdensome on shippers 
    because they would need to participate in fewer proceedings. On the 
    other hand, it may be difficult to develop recourse services for all 
    pipelines in a region, since a regional approach would not facilitate 
    the tailoring of services to the operational capabilities of specific 
    pipelines.
        The Commission seeks comment on the different ways that the 
    Commission could implement the periodic reviews of recourse service, 
    including comment on the merits of establishing recourse service on a 
    regional basis through regional reviews. Parties may discuss the 
    advantages and disadvantages of each approach, and how a regional 
    approach might be performed.
    3. The Release of Negotiated Capacity
        To enhance the tradability of capacity under negotiated service 
    contracts, the Commission is contemplating requiring pipelines to 
    include in their tariffs a provision that allows, but does not require, 
    a negotiated service to revert to a standard form of service when it is 
    offered for release. This should make it easier for the customer under 
    a negotiated service contract to release its capacity. This is because 
    a negotiated service agreement may contain provisions tailored to a 
    customer's needs which render the service undesirable to other shippers 
    with different needs. This provision could apply either to all 
    negotiated services, or only to those that represent an enhancement 
    over the standard service. The provision could also be structured such 
    that any negotiated term or condition of service which the replacement 
    shipper desires would remain in the contract.
        In the case where a releasing shipper negotiates enhanced, more 
    flexible, or ``better'' services than the standard service, the 
    releasing shipper presumably would be compensated for reselling 
    capacity as if it was standard service, regardless of what it paid for 
    the capacity. If negotiated services are below the standard level 
    included in the tariff provision, the releasing shipper might be 
    required to pay the difference between the negotiated rate and the 
    standard rate before reselling its service as standard service. In both 
    cases, reversion of a negotiated service to a standard form of service 
    would be allowed only when operationally feasible, and only when 
    requested by the releasing shipper.
        The Commission requests comment on this potential method for 
    helping ensure that negotiated capacity remains tradable, particularly 
    on the feasibility of implementing such a requirement. Commenters 
    should address how critical establishing this reversion requirement is 
    to permitting the release of capacity under a negotiated contract, how 
    difficult it would be to define what
    
    [[Page 43013]]
    
    service is of a higher or lower quality than the standard level of 
    service, and to what extent operational difficulties in permitting the 
    reversion to a standard form of service might limit the overall value 
    of this approach.
    4. Negotiation of Rates and Services With Affiliates
        As stated previously, the Commission proposes to permit the 
    negotiation of rates and services where similarly situated shippers 
    have rights to the same negotiated deal. The Commission is considering 
    whether additional protections are required to protect against unduly 
    preferential treatment in favor of pipeline marketing affiliates or 
    whether the Commission's existing marketing affiliate rules provide 
    adequate protections. Therefore, the Commission proposes to permit 
    pipelines to negotiate terms and conditions of service with their 
    marketing affiliates so long as all other similarly situated shippers 
    are offered the same rates and services. Consistent with prior 
    precedent, the Commission proposes to establish a rebuttable 
    presumption that all shippers receiving the same type of service, using 
    the same pipeline facilities, are similarly situated.\113\ The pipeline 
    could rebut the presumption by showing that a particular shipper or 
    group of shippers is not similarly situated with its affiliate in order 
    to justify not offering the same negotiated deal to non-affiliated 
    shippers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \113\ See Tennessee Gas Pipeline Company, 77 FERC at 61,877 
    (requiring the pipeline to file specific information to enable 
    shippers to determine if they are similarly situated to particular 
    negotiated rate customers), see also, Iroquois Gas Transmission 
    System, L.P. CP96-687-000, 79 FERC para. 61,394 at 62.693 (1997), 
    reh'g denied, 82 FERC para. 61,086 (1998) (rejecting proposal to 
    discount service to expansion shippers as unduly discriminatory 
    against existing shippers).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission seeks comments on whether the above proposal 
    provides adequate protection against undue discrimination. For example, 
    should the Commission consider stronger protections, such as precluding 
    the negotiation of rates and services with marketing affiliates as 
    unduly preferential unless all other shippers are offered the same 
    rates and services? Alternatively, could robust monitoring be adequate 
    to discourage and prevent pipelines from giving undue preference to 
    their affiliates eliminating the need for stronger protections? If so, 
    what types of information would the Commission need to gather to meet 
    its monitoring objectives, and how burdensome would it be to provide 
    this information? Is some other form of protection better suited to the 
    Commission's purpose of ensuring against undue discrimination? 
    Commenters are invited to respond to these issues and may raise any 
    related issues not presented here.
    5. Negotiation of Capacity Release and Flexible Point Rights
        The Commission is considering whether the rights to release 
    capacity and to flexible receipt and delivery points should be included 
    among the terms or conditions of service that could not be changed by 
    negotiation. Capacity release is a fundamental element of the 
    increasingly competitive natural gas capacity market. It creates 
    competition between firm capacity holders and the pipeline in what 
    otherwise may be a monopoly capacity market.
        Under a negotiated rates and services policy, both pipelines and 
    shippers may find it easy and advantageous to negotiate the 
    relinquishment of such rights. Pipelines may find it in their interest 
    to negotiate services without capacity release rights to reduce 
    competition for their interruptible and short-term firm services. 
    Shippers, also, may wish to relinquish capacity release rights for a 
    price break, particularly if they do not plan to utilize their release 
    rights. Shippers who give up capacity release rights will no longer be 
    potential sellers of capacity. Those who give up flexible receipt and 
    delivery points may severely limit their participation in the secondary 
    market. Thus, surrender of these rights could have a clear and direct 
    impact upon competition from the release market and the pipeline's 
    ability to exercise market power.
        The Commission requests comment on whether precluding the 
    negotiation of rights to capacity release and flexible points is 
    necessary to ensure that firm shippers can continue to release capacity 
    and trade with others behind secondary points, and thereby remain 
    competitors in the short-term capacity market. Commenters should 
    address the likelihood, and extent to which, they expect these rights 
    to be a primary subject of negotiations between pipelines and shippers, 
    and the extent to which restricting the negotiation of such rights 
    might limit the range of possible negotiated deals. Commenters also 
    should consider whether the Commission should implement this 
    restriction as an initial protection that could be relaxed in the 
    future as more experience is gained with the negotiated rates and 
    services policy.
    6. Future Cost Allocation Issues
        The Commission shares concerns, voiced by potential recourse 
    shippers in the comments filed in Docket No. RM95-7-000, regarding the 
    effect that the negotiation of rates and services might have on 
    recourse shippers' rates. The main concern is that pipelines entering 
    into negotiated deals that result in reduced revenue streams might seek 
    to recover the revenue shortfall by raising recourse rates in future 
    rate cases. Such cost-shifting could cross-subsidize negotiated 
    services, and pipelines could try to keep revenues that exceed recourse 
    rate caps, while shifting revenue shortfalls to recourse ratepayers.
        The rates of recourse shippers should not be adversely affected by 
    the pipelines' negotiations of service with other parties. Only the 
    negotiating parties should bear the risks and rewards of their 
    negotiated contracts. In fact, the Commission has previously addressed 
    this issue in the negotiated rates context by prohibiting a pipeline 
    from making any adjustment to its recourse rates to account for its 
    failure to recover costs from a negotiated rate shipper,\114\ absent 
    some showing of benefit to recourse shippers.\115\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \114\ NorAm Gas Transmission Company, 75 FERC para. 61,091, 
    order on reh'g, 77 FERC para. 61,011 (1996) (NorAm).
        \115\ Northwest Pipeline Corporation, 79 FERC para. 61,416, 
    62,754 (1997).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        At the same time, the Commission is concerned that if discount-type 
    adjustments for negotiated services are similarly prohibited in future 
    rate cases, pipelines might be deterred from negotiating rates and 
    services. Pipelines might favor the discounting of service fees over 
    the negotiation of creative alternatives, since the Commission's 
    discounting policies permit the recovery of revenue shortfalls. These 
    lost negotiated agreements may have resulted in the pipeline obtaining 
    a higher total revenue stream than it would have by entering into a 
    discounted deal, and may have mitigated the losses associated with the 
    level of discounting reflected in current rates. All customers may 
    benefit to the extent that some shippers stay on the system or take 
    longer term contracts as a result of the ability to negotiate rates and 
    services.
        Therefore, the Commission is considering examining all rate issues 
    associated with negotiated rates and services in future rate cases, 
    including the treatment of revenue shortfalls and excess revenues, and 
    whether corresponding rate adjustments are appropriate. This would be a 
    change from the policy stated in NorAm of prohibiting, per se, 
    discount-type adjustments for negotiated rate agreements as a means of 
    ensuring costs
    
    [[Page 43014]]
    
    are not shifted to recourse rate customers. This approach may also 
    permit the Commission to consider any additional cost allocation issues 
    that might arise from any new facilities that may have been built to 
    provide the negotiated service. However, the burden of justifying the 
    benefit of specific negotiated deals would be on the pipeline. In this 
    respect, the Commission seeks comment on what type of showing pipelines 
    would have to make in order to show that specific negotiated deals 
    merited an adjustment to recourse rates.
        Finally, the examination of all rate issues associated with 
    negotiated terms and conditions in future rate cases may also provide 
    the Commission with the opportunity to fully explore the benefits and/
    or harm to the recourse shippers from the negotiated rates and services 
    policy. To the extent that these are unknowns at this point, the 
    Commission needs to have a fair amount of flexibility to decide how 
    revenues and costs associated with negotiated services should be 
    treated in future rate cases. The Commission solicits comment on the 
    above proposal, including comment on the extent to which this approach 
    may lead pipelines to attempt to shift risks to captive ratepayers, and 
    the proposal's potential impact on the ratemaking process.
        An alternative would be to prohibit any adjustments to recourse 
    rates due to revenue shortfalls resulting from negotiated rates and 
    services. This approach would prevent pipelines from shifting the risks 
    of negotiated deals to recourse ratepayers. On the other hand, if the 
    pipeline were required to absorb any revenue shortfalls from negotiated 
    deals, the pipeline should probably have a corresponding right to 
    retain any excess revenues resulting from negotiated rates, thus 
    eliminating the possibility that recourse shippers would benefit from 
    negotiated deals other than through improved recourse service.
        The Commission seeks comment on the advantages and disadvantages of 
    this alternative proposal to prohibit rate adjustments to recourse 
    rates for revenue shortfalls. Commenters should include discussion on 
    the extent to which prohibiting rate adjustments might discourage 
    pipelines from entering into negotiated deals, and whether, and/or to 
    what extent, prohibiting rate adjustments is inconsistent with the 
    Commission's existing discount policy.
    7. Reporting, Monitoring, and Complaint Procedures
        The implementation of stringent reporting requirements and active 
    monitoring will be necessary to ensure the success of a negotiated 
    rates and services policy. Such reporting and monitoring will be 
    critical for the Commission to be able to detect and deter the exercise 
    of market power, for customers to identify undue discrimination in the 
    provision of services and to support their legitimate complaints, and 
    for the Commission to ensure compliance with the guiding principles of 
    the negotiated rates and services policy.
        The Commission is proposing to add to the data that pipelines 
    currently are required to report under the Index of Customers. Such 
    additional information will be aimed at capturing the existence of 
    similarly situated customers and any affiliate relationship between the 
    capacity holder and the customer in a negotiated transaction.
        Specifically, the Commission proposes to require pipelines to 
    identify, in the Index of Customers, each contract that contains 
    negotiated rates and services. Pipelines would only be required to flag 
    contracts with negotiated rates and services through a ``yes/no'' 
    indicator and contract number for each customer and contract. The 
    Commission is not proposing to require pipelines to delineate the terms 
    of specific contracts in the Index of Customers. Such delineation might 
    pose a significant burden on the pipelines, without a substantial 
    countervailing benefit.
        In addition, the Commission is proposing to require other 
    information in the Index of Customers and/or the proposed monthly 
    transaction reports to assist in monitoring a pipeline's market power. 
    This includes information on receipt points, delivery points, segments, 
    affiliate relationships, and contract numbers. Such information will 
    enable shippers and the Commission to evaluate whether specific 
    shippers or transactions are ``similarly situated'' for purposes of 
    assessing undue discrimination or preference under a negotiated 
    contract.
        Further, the Commission proposes to conduct compliance audits or 
    studies of specific pipelines' compliance with the principles. 
    Compliance audits or studies may provide the necessary detail about 
    specific services offered, and their effects on the customers in 
    individual cases, to allow case-by-case review of complaints, the early 
    detection of problems, and sua sponte Commission action. Such audits 
    also could provide constructive feedback to both the industry and the 
    Commission, and may improve overall compliance. The Commission seeks 
    comments on the utility of compliance audits.
        Finally, an effective complaint procedure is necessary to resolve 
    and discourage abuses of the negotiated rates and services policy. To 
    this end, the Commission recently held a public conference in Docket 
    No. PL98-4-000, to aid in the process of evaluating and improving its 
    complaint procedures,\116\ and is contemporaneously issuing a separate 
    NOPR to revise the complaint process in Docket No. RM98-13-000.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \116\ Symposium on Process and Reform: Commission Complaint 
    Procedures. See Notice of Conference issued March 10, 1998 in Docket 
    No. PL98-4-000, 63 FR 12800 (March 16, 1998).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        AGA/INGAA's negotiated terms and conditions proposal recommends 
    that an expedited and effective complaint procedure allow for the 
    remedy of retroactive relief in the event a customer proves that the 
    pipeline willfully and knowingly made a material misrepresentation in 
    its initial filing of a negotiated term or condition, which resulted in 
    material harm to the customer. Such relief would only be available in 
    the context of the negotiated terms and conditions policy, and would 
    not be permitted to be used as precedent for any other matter under any 
    statute administered by the Commission. Parties may also comment on 
    this proposal in the separate rulemaking proceeding in Docket No. RM98-
    13-000.
    
    VI. Long-Term Services
    
        The proposals made in this NOPR for the short-term capacity market 
    will necessarily impact the long-term market. Further, without a 
    vibrant market for long-term capacity, the benefits of the short-term 
    market proposals cannot be realized. If the Commission adopts a new 
    regulatory approach for short-term transportation, there must be 
    viable, regulated long-term services available to mitigate any market 
    power of capacity sellers. The Commission is issuing a companion Notice 
    of Inquiry \117\ to consider whether changes should be made in its 
    policies with regard to long-term markets. However, the Commission is 
    concerned that some of its current regulatory policies may result in a 
    bias toward short-term contracts, which could weaken the long-term 
    market and undermine the proposals set forth in this NOPR.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \117\ Regulation of Interstate Natural Gas Transportation 
    Services, Docket No. RM98-12-000.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Therefore, the Commission is addressing in this NOPR, several long-
    term transportation rate and certificate issues that have a direct and 
    significant impact on the short-term transportation policy proposals 
    contained in this NOPR. Specifically, the Commission is
    
    [[Page 43015]]
    
    proposing to modify the right of first refusal by eliminating the term 
    matching cap. Further, the Commission is considering changes to its 
    policies with regard to term-differentiated rates and negotiated terms 
    and conditions in long-term contracts. In addition, the Commission is 
    seeking comments on its policies for certification of new capacity.
    
    A. The Interaction Between Long-Term and Short-Term Services
    
        Long-term contracts provide important benefits to pipelines and 
    customers. Long-term contracts provide stability, and can reduce 
    financial risks to the pipeline, lowering their capital costs, to the 
    benefit of all the pipeline's customers. In addition, encouraging long-
    term contracts ensures that there will be sufficient capacity available 
    for release in the secondary market in order to maintain the vibrant 
    competition between sales of capacity in the primary and secondary 
    market which exists today.
        The Commission has proposed that the removal of the price cap in 
    the short-term transportation market, coupled with other changes 
    proposed for the short-term market, would be consistent with the 
    Commission's statutory responsibilities. These proposals, in 
    combination with one another, should foster a more competitive 
    environment, while at the same time, providing a check against any 
    monopoly power abuses. The rationale for modifying the approach to 
    short-term markets does not apply to the long-term market, however. In 
    the long-term market, there are no effective substitutes for long-term 
    pipeline service, unlike the short-term capacity products of 
    interruptible, short-term firm, and capacity release. Therefore, even 
    if the Commission decides to adopt a different regulatory approach for 
    short-term transactions, there will continue to be a need for the 
    Commission to regulate the terms and conditions of service for long-
    term transportation to protect shippers against the exercise of 
    monopoly power by pipelines. The Commission's regulation, however, 
    should not provide artificial disincentives for long-term contracts, 
    but should be neutral with regard to long-term and short-term 
    contracts.
        The Commission is concerned that some of its current regulatory 
    policies result in a bias toward short-term contracts. These policies 
    include the term matching cap in the right of first refusal and the use 
    of the same maximum rate for service under short-term and long-term 
    contracts. Under these conditions, financial risks and rewards are not 
    linked, i.e., there is risk asymmetry, favoring short-term contracts, 
    and there is little incentive for a shipper to enter into a long-term 
    contract with the pipeline. If a shipper enters into a long-term 
    contract, it runs the risk that its rates will increase during the term 
    of that contract. It can avoid this risk, and still be guaranteed that 
    it can receive service indefinitely by entering into a short-term 
    contract with a right of first refusal. The customer knows that it need 
    never pay more than the regulated cost-of-service maximum rate to buy 
    service from the pipeline, regardless of whether it is pursuant to a 
    long-term or a short-term contract. If market conditions are relatively 
    weak at the end of the current contract, the customer may be able to 
    bargain with the pipeline to get a discount or to obtain service more 
    cheaply through the secondary market or on another pipeline. Where 
    capacity holders have firm rights to capacity that is valued above the 
    cost-of-service rate, they will likely hold onto that capacity. Current 
    contract holders will exercise their right of first refusal when market 
    conditions are weak. Other things being equal, the customer should want 
    a shorter-term contract.
        The pipeline faces the other side of the bargain. The bias toward 
    short-term contracts and the current asymmetry of risk may have 
    negative economic consequences to the pipelines, and for example, may 
    be a factor in causing capacity turn-back and the discounting of rates 
    for long-term contracts. Customers may take only relatively short-term 
    contracts and only when the value meets or exceeds the rate. The 
    proposed removal of the price cap in the short-term market could move 
    some customers toward longer-term contracts to avoid price 
    uncertainties and potential jumps in the short-term prices. On the 
    other hand, however, removal of the price cap could move other 
    customers toward the short-term market because they could always count 
    on being able to secure capacity there at some price. Cost recovery 
    problems resulting from a weak long-term transportation market could be 
    a possibility for pipelines, even if the price cap were removed, given 
    the biases toward short-term contracts. Without changes in the 
    Commission policies that contribute to this bias, the Commission's 
    goals for the short-term market could be undermined because pipelines 
    would have an incentive to undermine short-term markets in order to be 
    more confident of their ability to recover their costs over the long 
    term.
        A pipeline with cost recovery problems could try to alleviate the 
    problem in one of several ways, each of which would have adverse 
    consequences on the short-term market. First, to try to recover their 
    revenues, pipelines could attempt to raise the charges to remaining 
    long-term customers. They are unlikely to be able to recover their 
    costs in this manner. Even if successful in raising rates to remaining 
    customers,\118\ this action could cause additional customers to leave 
    the pipeline, leaving the pipeline and the remaining customers in an 
    even worse financial situation.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \118\ The Commission would not necessarily approve a request for 
    increased rates. See, e.g., El Paso Natural Gas Company, 72 FERC 
    para. 61,083 at 61,441-42 (1995); and Natural Gas Pipeline Co., 73 
    FERC para. 61,050 at 61,128-30 (1995).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In addition, a pipeline with a cost recovery problem would feel 
    pressure to eliminate alternatives that enable shippers to turn back 
    capacity.\119\ If pipelines can make the secondary market less viable, 
    by withholding capacity and/or price discrimination, they would have 
    more captive customers from whom to recover their costs. This would 
    undermine short-term markets and reduce efficiency because shippers' 
    capacity could not be reallocated to those who value it more. It would 
    also give pipelines greater opportunity to exercise market power, 
    further decreasing efficiency, and making it easier for a pipeline to 
    maintain a policy of discrimination between customers. Thus, by having 
    a negative impact on the pipeline's financial stability, the bias in 
    favor of short-term markets would provide incentives for the pipelines 
    to undermine the short-term market.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \119\ Pipelines might also try to increase their sale of 
    interruptible transportation as another means of recovering their 
    costs of service. Shippers, however, would only take this capacity 
    when they need it, and not year round in most cases.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    B. Specific Impediments to Long-term Contracts
    
        There are a number of artificial impediments to long-term contracts 
    on existing pipelines. These result in lower risks to shippers for 
    short-term contracts available for the same maximum rates as the long-
    term contracts, thereby artificially discouraging long-term contracts. 
    One way to help restore balance is to remove these artificial 
    impediments to long-term contracts.
    1. The Right of First Refusal
        In Order No. 636, the Commission authorized pre-granted abandonment 
    of long-term firm contracts, subject to the right of first refusal for 
    the existing
    
    [[Page 43016]]
    
    shipper.\120\ Pursuant to the right of first refusal, the existing 
    shipper can retain service by matching the rate and length of service 
    of a competing bid. The rate is capped by the pipeline's maximum tariff 
    rate, and, in Order No. 636-C, the Commission limited the requirement 
    that the existing shipper must match the length of the contract term of 
    a competing bid to a contract length of five years.\121\ On rehearing 
    of Order No. 636-C, the pipelines argued that this five-year matching 
    cap interferes with market forces; and, because of the five-year cap, 
    it is unlikely that any existing shipper will renew its contract for 
    more than five years. While the Commission concluded that the record in 
    the Order No. 636 proceeding supported the five-year cap, the 
    Commission recognized there are legitimate concerns about the practical 
    effects of the five-year matching cap on the restructured market as it 
    continues to evolve.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \120\ 18 CFR 284.221(d).
        \121\ Order No. 636 capped the matching term at 20 years.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The right of first refusal with the five-year matching cap provides 
    a disincentive for an existing shipper to enter into a contract of more 
    than five years, and results in a bias toward short-term contracts. As 
    a practical matter, the right of first refusal with the five-year cap 
    gives current customers the incentive to opt for as short a contract 
    term as possible so that, at contract expiration, they can reassess the 
    value of the capacity and decide if it is in their interest to keep it. 
    If pipeline capacity is relatively valuable, there are likely to be 
    other shippers interested in long-term contracts, but the existing 
    shipper will exercise its right of first refusal and retain the 
    capacity for a five-year term. On the other hand, if the market value 
    of long term capacity is low, the existing shipper can terminate the 
    contract with no obligation to the pipeline. In these circumstances, 
    there is no reason for a shipper with a right of first refusal to enter 
    into a long-term contract because it can use a series of short-term 
    contracts to obtain long-term service, and wait and see how the market 
    develops.
        This results in an imbalance of risks between pipelines and 
    existing shippers. The pipeline is obligated to provide service for the 
    shipper indefinitely, as long as it exercises its right of first 
    refusal, while the shipper has no corresponding long-term obligation to 
    the pipeline. Elimination of the five-year cap from the right of first 
    refusal would remove a significant factor in the risk asymmetry 
    discussed above. Without a limitation on the contract length that must 
    be matched by the existing shipper, an existing shipper who wants to be 
    assured of access to capacity for the long term would have to match the 
    highest rate bid up to the maximum cost-based, for the capacity for the 
    duration of the contract bid, and thus share with the pipeline some of 
    the risks associated with the long-term commitment.
        Elimination of the cap limiting the contract length that the 
    existing shipper must match also would foster efficient competition, as 
    encouraged by Order No. 636. This cap tends to protect existing 
    shippers from competition and give them control over pipeline capacity. 
    Without the cap, the term of a contract will be determined by market 
    forces, rather than by the limitation established by the Commission.
        In UDC v. FERC,\122\ the Court stated that for a finding of public 
    convenience and necessity for pre-granted abandonment, the Commission 
    must make appropriate findings that existing market conditions and 
    regulatory structures protect customers from pipelines' market power. 
    The Court found that the right of first refusal mechanism with a cap on 
    contract length was one adequate means of protecting customers from 
    pipeline market power. In response to the Court's concern that the 
    Commission had failed to justify a twenty-year cap, the Commission 
    adopted the five-year cap in Order No. 636-C. However, conditions in 
    the market have changed substantially since the issuance of Order No. 
    636, and the five-year cap has not worked well in the restructured 
    market. As discussed above, it has led to asymmetry of risk and a bias 
    toward short-term contracts. Therefore, the Commission is proposing to 
    eliminate the term matching cap from the right of first refusal and is 
    seeking comments on this proposal.\123\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \122\ 88 F.3d 1105, 1139 (D.C. Cir. 1996), cert. denied, 117 S. 
    Ct. 1723 (1997).
        \123\ The term matching cap is not set forth in the regulations, 
    and, therefore, no revision to 18 CFR 284.221(d) is necessary.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Commission is also considering whether, in view of the changed 
    market conditions, the right of first refusal should be eliminated 
    entirely. Since restructuring, increased competition in both the 
    commodity and capacity markets now affords customers greater 
    protections from market power. Small LDCs no longer have to hold 
    capacity on the pipeline in order to receive gas, and can buy gas 
    delivered from marketers or can obtain capacity in the secondary 
    market. In fact, many LDCs have chosen not to hold capacity on 
    pipelines. Therefore, changed conditions suggest that the right of 
    first refusal may no longer be needed to protect the customers it was 
    originally intended to protect. The Commission is seeking comments on 
    eliminating the right of first refusal, as well as other options, such 
    as changing the length of the term matching cap or permitting the 
    pipelines and the customers to negotiate for a right of first refusal.
    2. Term-Differentiated Maximum Rates
        Another method of reducing risk asymmetry and strengthening the 
    long-term market would be to encourage contracts that contain lower 
    maximum rates for longer-term service than for short-term service in 
    recognition of the value of long-term contracts in limiting the 
    pipeline's risk. As explained above, a short-term contract is riskier 
    for the pipeline, and a higher short-term contract rate would 
    compensate pipelines for the additional risk they take when entering 
    short-term contracts. Conversely, a short-term contract provides 
    greater flexibility and less risk to the shipper, and the higher short-
    term rate would recognize, and require payment for, these benefits.
        The Commission is seeking comments on whether and how term-
    differentiated maximum rates should be encouraged, and, if so, how the 
    rate differential should vary with contract term. For example, should 
    there be only two contract length categories, or should there be more? 
    How would the appropriate contract length categories be determined? How 
    should the rate differentials between term categories be set? Could a 
    market mechanism be developed for determining the appropriate 
    differentials?
        Negotiation may be a primary way of addressing the sharing of risk 
    between the parties, to ensure that parties can contract to minimize 
    the total cost of that risk. Negotiation of rates and services is a 
    possible solution to some of the problems discussed above. The 
    limitations discussed in the preceding section\124\ should keep 
    negotiations from hurting the fungibility of the capacity in the short-
    term market, increasing the pipelines' (or their affiliates'') ability 
    to exercise market power, and otherwise hurting third parties.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \124\ The proceding section of this NOPR discusses the role of 
    negotiated terms and conditions in the short-term market.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    C. New Capacity Certificate Issues
    
        The Commission's proposed changes in the short-term market also 
    create a need to review its policies for
    
    [[Page 43017]]
    
    certificating new capacity and services. As explained above, the 
    removal of the price cap in the short-term market requires that viable 
    regulated services be available in the long-term market to mitigate any 
    market power of capacity sellers. The Commission's certificate policies 
    are critical to assuring that pipelines construct the optimal amount of 
    capacity to meet demand in the long-term market. Therefore, the 
    Commission is reviewing its certificate policies to determine whether 
    these policies should be modified to meet current market conditions and 
    needs, particularly in light of the proposed changes in the short-term 
    market.
        The Commission's objective in this review is to assure that its 
    policy is well-balanced so that facilities are constructed where demand 
    warrants construction, while at the same time guarding against 
    additional construction that is not necessary to meet any increase in 
    demand for capacity and that could result in excess capacity and the 
    problems of unsubscribed capacity. The Commission also seeks to assure 
    that its policies will not result in building new capacity in markets 
    where existing facilities are not fully subscribed because this could 
    create false price signals and weaken the long-term transportation 
    market.\125\
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \125\ In the NOI, the Commission discusses price distortions in 
    the California and Chicago markets, where several pipelines were 
    facing significant turnback of long-term capacity, while other 
    pipelines were constructing additional capacity to serve those 
    markets.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Under the policy set forth in Kansas Pipe Line & Gas Company 
    (Kansas Pipe Line),126 the Commission required an applicant 
    seeking an NGA section 7 certificate for authority to construct and 
    operate new facilities to show customer commitments sufficient to 
    justify the proposed project. In order to demonstrate the need for a 
    new project, an applicant was required to submit market studies of the 
    customers and area to be served, and contracts showing long-term 
    commitments for 100 percent of the proposed facility's capacity. This 
    approach made it unlikely that too much capacity would be built.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \126\ 2 FPC 29 (1939).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Under the current policy, an applicant for a traditional section 7 
    certificate must submit precedent agreements for long-term firm service 
    \127\ for a substantial amount of the new facility's capacity.\128\ 
    Where an applicant is not able to provide evidence of long-term 
    commitments for firm service for at least 25 percent of a proposed 
    facility's capacity, the Commission will typically place the applicant 
    at risk for unrecovered costs attributable to the unsubscribed 
    capacity.\129\ This at-risk condition is intended to discourage 
    overbuilding and assure that the pipeline's other customers are not 
    compelled to pay for costs associated with unused capacity.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \127\ For purposes of evaluating applications for new 
    construction, a long term is a term of at least 10 years. See e.g., 
    Texas Eastern Transmission Corp., 82 FERC para.61,238 (March 11, 
    1998).
        \128\ ``Generally, as it has evolved, the minimum level of firm 
    commitment that the Commission has determined to be sufficient for a 
    new onshore facility has been 25 percent of the proposed project's 
    capacity.'' Id. at 61,916.
        \129\ But see 18 CFR 157.100-157.106 (Applicants for an optional 
    expedited certificate under Subpart E of Part 157 may receive a 
    certificate to construct for others for new service without any 
    requirement to show specific market demand; however, the rates for 
    service provided through such facilities will be designed to impose 
    the economic risks of the project entirely on the applicant).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In considering evidence of market demand, the Commission gives 
    equal weight to precedent agreements between an applicant and its 
    affiliates and an applicant and unrelated third parties. Further, the 
    Commission has not sought to assess whether these customer commitments 
    indicate a genuine growth in market demand necessitating additional gas 
    supplies, or reflect a desire to access separate supply sources for 
    unchanging quantities of gas, or represent efforts to obtain reduced 
    transportation charges for shipping identical gas volumes. Before Order 
    No. 636, new projects were typically intended to bring gas to unserved 
    or clearly under-served markets. Increasingly, new projects are 
    designed to compete for market share by offering alternatives to 
    customers in established markets.
        The Commission seeks to assure that its policies strike the proper 
    balance between the enhancement of competitive alternatives and the 
    possibility of over building. The Commission wants to assure that its 
    policies serve to maximize competitive alternatives, while at the same 
    time protect against overbuilding, unnecessary disruption of the 
    environment, and unneeded exercise of eminent domain over private 
    property. Specifically, the Commission seeks comments on whether 
    proposed projects that will establish a new right-of-way in order to 
    compete for existing market share should be subject to the same 
    considerations as projects that will cut a new right-of-way in order to 
    extend gas service to a frontier market area. In conjunction with this 
    reassessment of project need, the Commission is considering how best to 
    balance demonstrated market demand against potential adverse 
    environmental impacts and private property rights in weighing whether a 
    project is required by the public convenience and 
    necessity.130
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \130\ See, e.g., Granite State Gas Transmission, 83 FERC 
    para.61,194 (1998). The Commission authorized a new liquefied 
    natural gas (LNG) facility after comparing services to be provided 
    by the proposed facility with similar services that might be offered 
    by employing alternative facilities. Although employing existing 
    facilities could result in diminished adverse environmental impacts, 
    the Commission authorized the proposed project, finding the service 
    made available by the new LNG facility would provide specific 
    advantages over the alternatives.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        One option would be for the Commission to authorize all 
    applications that at a minimum meet the regulatory requirements, then 
    let the market pick winners and losers. Another would be for the 
    Commission to select a single project to serve a given market and 
    exclude all other competitors. Another possible option would be for the 
    Commission to approve an environmentally acceptable right-of-way and 
    let potential builders compete for a certificate.
        The Commission requests comments on these three options, as well as 
    comments on the following questions: (1) Should the Commission look 
    behind the precedent agreement or contracts presented as evidence of 
    market demand to assess independently the market's need for additional 
    gas service? (2) Should the Commission apply a different standard to 
    precedent agreements or contracts with affiliates than with non-
    affiliates? For example, should a proposal supported by affiliate 
    agreements have to show a higher percentage of contracted-for capacity 
    than a proposal supported by non-affiliate agreements, or, should all 
    proposed projects be required to show a minimum percent of non-
    affiliate support? (3) Are precedent agreements primarily with 
    affiliates sufficient to meet the statutory requirement that 
    construction must be required by the public convenience and necessity, 
    and, if so, (4) Should the Commission permit rolled-in rate treatment 
    for facilities built to serve a pipeline affiliate? 131 (5) 
    Should the Commission, in an effort to check overbuilding and capacity 
    turnback, take a harder look at proposals that are designed to compete 
    for existing market share rather than bring service to a new customer 
    base, and what particular criteria should be applied in
    
    [[Page 43018]]
    
    looking at competitive applications versus new market applications? (6) 
    Should the Commission encourage pre-filing resolution of landowner 
    issues by subjecting proposed projects to a diminished degree of 
    scrutiny where the project sponsor is able to demonstrate it has 
    obtained all necessary right-of-way authority? (7) Should a different 
    standard be applied to project sponsors who do not plan to use either 
    federal or state-granted rights of eminent domain to acquire right-of-
    way?
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \131\As discussed in the NOI, in the Pricing Policy for New and 
    Existing Facilities Constructed by Interstate Natural Gas Pipelines, 
    71 FERC para.61,241 (1995), the Commission adopted a presumption in 
    favor of rolled-in rates when the rate increase to existing 
    customers from rolling in the new facilities in 5 percent or less, 
    and the pipeline makes a showing of system benefits.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The parties may also address other questions concerning 
    certification issues in general, including: (1) What should the 
    Commission do to provide for the infrastructure to serve future 
    increased demand for capacity? (2) How can pipelines deal with the 
    potential for not recovering new construction costs? Should the 
    Commission address, at the certificate issuance stage, the issue of a 
    pipeline's responsibility for future cost under-recovery once its 
    initial contracts expire? Assuming no adverse environmental impacts, 
    should a pipeline be allowed to build if it does not accept the 
    responsibility for all of the cost not covered by its initial 
    contracts? What, if anything, should the Commission do to ensure rate 
    certainty for customers and pipelines? Can or should this include 
    guarantees against future rolling-in of costly expansions, future 
    changes in O&M expenses, or any other future changes? (3) Should the 
    Commission reassess the balance between risk and return? Is there 
    really more risk for a pipeline with short-term contracts, or will 
    shippers continue to make short-term deals for the life of the pipeline 
    that cover the pipeline's cost-of-service? Is any of the risk 
    unnecessary, and can it be eliminated without imposing additional 
    costs? How should rates be determined after contracts expire? Should 
    the Commission establish different pricing based on contract term? (4) 
    What are the advantages (or disadvantages) of allowing pipelines and 
    customers to negotiate pre-construction risk and return-sharing 
    agreements, and what actions should the Commission take if pipelines 
    and customers do not agree on the allocation of risk and return? (5) To 
    what extent should the policies on new construction and existing 
    pipelines match? (6) How does retail unbundling and open access affect 
    all of these issues?
    
    VII. Reorganization of Part 284 Regulations
    
        Commission proposes to reorganize certain portions of its Part 284 
    regulations to better reflect the nature of services in the short-term 
    market and to consolidate its Part 284 reporting and filing 
    requirements in a single section. Because capacity release has become 
    an integral part of the short-term market, the Commission is proposing 
    to move its capacity release regulations from subpart H of Part 284 to 
    the same location in its regulations as pipeline firm and interruptible 
    service (newly designated sections 284.7 (firm service), 284.8 (release 
    of firm service), and 284.9 (interruptible service)).
        In addition, reporting and filing requirements for pipeline Part 
    284 services are presently scattered throughout Part 284. For example, 
    the Index of Customers and storage reports are presently located in 
    subpart B, section 284.106, which deals with interstate pipelines 
    performing transportation service under the Natural Gas Policy Act 
    (NGPA). But these regulations are then applied to interstate pipelines 
    performing open access services in subpart G, section 284.223. Other 
    reporting requirements are located throughout various substantive 
    provisions of Part 284.132 The Commission is proposing to 
    collect these requirements into one new section (proposed Sec. 284.14) 
    applicable to interstate pipelines transporting gas under Subpart B 
    (transportation under section 311 of the NGPA) and Subpart G (open 
    access transportation under the NGA). Reporting requirements specific 
    to Subpart B pipelines (by-pass reports) remain in Subpart B.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \132\ See, e.g., 18 CFR 284.8 (b) (3) and 284.9 (b) (3) 
    (requirements to provide information on available capacity); 284.7 
    (c) (6) (discount reports); 18 CFR 284.12 (filing of capacity).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        To aid commenters' review of the new regulatory format, the 
    following would be the new outline for subpart A of Part 284.
    
    284.1  Definitions.
    284.2  Refunds and interest.
    284.3  Jurisdiction under the Natural Gas Act.
    284.4  Reporting.
    284.5  Further terms and conditions.
    284.6  Rate interpretations.
    284.7  Firm transportation service.
    284.8  Release of firm transportation service.
    284.9  Interruptible transportation service.
    284.10  Rates.
    284.11  Negotiated rates and services.
    284.12  Environmental compliance.
    284.13  Standards for pipeline business operations and 
    communications.
    284.14  Reporting requirements for interstate pipelines.
    
        The Commission recognizes that such changes may occasion the need 
    for cross-reference changes in other sections of Part 284 as well as 
    other parts of the regulations. The Commission would make such non-
    substantive changes in the final rule, and commenters should point out 
    regulatory sections where such changes are needed.
    
    VIII. Information Collection Statement
    
        The following collections of information would be affected by this 
    proposed rule and have been submitted to the Office of Management and 
    Budget (OMB) for review under Section 3507(d) of the Paperwork 
    Reduction Act of 1995, 44 U.S.C. 3507(d). The Commission solicits 
    comments on the Commission's need for this information, whether the 
    information will have practical utility, the accuracy of the provided 
    burden estimates, ways to enhance the quality, utility, and clarity of 
    the information to be collected, and any suggested methods for 
    minimizing respondents's burden, including the use of automated 
    information techniques. The burden estimate in this proposed rule 
    includes the cost for pipelines to comply with the Commission's 
    proposed regulations concerning short-term natural gas transportation 
    services. The following burden estimates reflect only the incremental 
    costs of complying with the proposed new and revised standards intended 
    to implement the Commission's regulations. The burden estimates include 
    start up and on-going costs.
        Estimated Annual Burden: The estimated annual burden associated 
    with this NOPR is shown below.
    
    --------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                                                          Number of        Number of responses  per    Estimated burden      Total annual   
                        Affected data collection                         respondents              respondent          hours per response     burden hours   
    --------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
    FERC-545.......................................................                 100                          2.0              97.800              19,560
    FERC-549B......................................................                 100                        446.5               1.526              68,136
    FERC-592.......................................................                  74                          1.0               7.000                 518
                                                                    ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
        Total......................................................  ..................  ...........................  ..................              88,214
    --------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
    --------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    
    [[Page 43019]]
    
        The estimated number of reporting hours attributable to the 
    requirements proposed herein are expected to total
    88,214 hours and are included in the
    above annual burden estimates.
        Information Collection Costs: The Commission seeks comments on the 
    estimated cost to comply with these requirements. It has projected 
    average annualized costs for all respondents to be the following:
    
                                                      [In dollars]                                                  
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
             Estimated data collection costs             FERC-545        FERC-549B       FERC-592          Total    
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
    Annualized Capital/Startup Costs................         842,061         168,412               0       1,010,473
    Annualized Costs (Operations & Maintenance).....         187,359       3,417,506          27,262       3,632,127
                                                     ---------------------------------------------------------------
        Total Annualized Costs......................      $1,029,420       3,585,918          27,262       4,642,600
    ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The OMB regulations require OMB to approve certain information 
    collection requirements imposed by agency rule.\133\ Accordingly, 
    pursuant to OMB regulations, the Commission is providing notice of its 
    proposed information collections to OMB.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \133\ 5 CFR 1320.11.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Titles: FERC-545, Gas Pipeline Rates: Rate Change (Non-Formal); 
    FERC-549B, Gas Pipeline Rates: Capacity Information (a proposed new 
    title); and FERC-592, Marketing Affiliates of Interstate Pipelines.
    
        Action: Proposed Data Collections.
        OMB Control Numbers: 1902-0154; 1902-0169; and 1902-0157, 
    respectively. The respondent shall not be penalized for failure to 
    respond to these information collections unless the collection of 
    information displays a valid OMB control number.
        Respondents: Business or other for profit, including small 
    businesses.
        Frequency of Responses: On occasion.
        Necessity of Information: The proposed rule seeks to establish 
    reporting requirements that will provide information needed for the 
    market to operate more efficiently and for shippers and the Commission 
    to effectively monitor transactions for undue discrimination and the 
    exercise of market power.
        Internal Review: The Commission has assured itself, by means of its 
    internal review, that there is specific, objective support for the 
    burden estimates associated with the information collection 
    requirements. The Commission's Office of Pipeline Regulation will use 
    the data to monitor the market place to correct problems and minimize 
    the exercise of market power. Additionally, the industry itself will 
    use the information to make more informed choices from among 
    alternative capacity sources and to monitor the marketplace. The 
    Commission's determination of burden involves among other things, an 
    examination of adequacy of design, cost, reliability, and redundancy of 
    the information to be required. These requirements conform to the 
    Commission's plan for efficient information collection, communication, 
    and management within the natural gas pipeline industry.
        Interested persons may obtain information on the reporting 
    requirements by contacting the following: Federal Energy Regulatory 
    Commission, 888 First Street, NE, Washington, DC 20426, [Attention: 
    Michael Miller, Office of the Chief Information Officer, Phone: 
    (202)208-1415, fax: (202)273-0873, e-mail: michael.miller@ferc.fed.us]
        For submitting comments concerning the collections of 
    information(s) and the associated burden estimate(s), please send your 
    comments to the contact listed above and to the Office of Management 
    and Budget, Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs, Washington, 
    DC, 20503. [Attention: Desk Officer for the Federal Energy Regulatory 
    Commission, phone: (202)395-3087, fax: (202)395-7285.
    
    IX. Environmental Analysis
    
        The Commission is required to prepare an Environmental Assessment 
    or an Environmental Impact Statement for any action that may have a 
    significant adverse effect on the human environment.134 The 
    Commission has categorically excluded certain actions from these 
    requirements as not having a significant effect on the human 
    environment.135 The actions proposed to be taken here fall 
    within categorical exclusions in the Commission's regulations for rules 
    that are clarifying, corrective, or procedural, for information 
    gathering, analysis, and dissemination, and for sales, exchange, and 
    transportation of natural gas that requires no construction of 
    facilities.136 Therefore, an environmental assessment is 
    unnecessary and has not been prepared in this rulemaking.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \134\ Order No. 486, Regulations Implementing the National 
    Environmental Policy Act, 52 FR 47897 (Dec. 17, 1987), FERC Stats, & 
    Regs. Preambles 1986-1990 para.30,783 (1987).
        \135\ 18 CFR 380.4.
        \136\  See 18 CFR 380.4(a)(2)(ii), 380.4(a)(5), 380.4(a)(27).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    X. Regulatory Flexibility Act Certification
    
        The Regulatory Flexibility Act of 1980 (RFA) 137 
    generally requires a description and analysis of final rules that will 
    have significant economic impact on a substantial number of small 
    entities. The proposed regulations would impose requirements on 
    interstate pipelines, which generally are not small businesses. 
    Accordingly, pursuant to section 605(b) of the RFA, the Commission 
    proposes to certify that the regulations proposed herein will not have 
    a significant adverse impact on a substantial number of small entities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \137\ 5 U.S.C. 601-612.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    XI. Comment Procedures
    
        The Commission invites interested persons to submit written 
    comments on the matters and issues proposed in this notice to be 
    adopted, including any related matters or alternative proposals that 
    commenters may wish to discuss. An original and 14 copies of comments 
    must be filed with the Commission no later than November 9, 1998. 
    Comments should be submitted to the Office of the Secretary, Federal 
    Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street, NE, Washington, DC 
    20426, and should refer to Docket No. RM98-10-000. All written comments 
    will be placed in the Commission's public files and will be available 
    for inspection in the Commission's Public Reference Room at 888 First 
    Street, NE, Washington, DC 20426, during regular business hours.
        Additionally, comments should be submitted electronically. 
    Commenters are encouraged to file comments using Internet E-Mail. 
    Comments should be submitted through the Internet by E-Mail to 
    comment.rm@ferc.fed.us in the
    
    [[Page 43020]]
    
    following format: on the subject line, specify Docket No. RM98-10-000; 
    in the body of the E-Mail message, specify the name of the filing 
    entity and the name, telephone number and E-Mail address of a contact 
    person; and attach the comment in WordPerfect 6.1 or lower 
    format or in ASCII format as an attachment to the E-Mail message. The 
    Commission will send a reply to the E-Mail to acknowledge receipt. 
    Questions or comments on electronic filing using Internet E-Mail should 
    be directed to Marvin Rosenberg at 202-208-1283, E-Mail address 
    marvin.rosenberg@ferc.fed.us.
        Commenters also can submit comments on computer diskette in 
    WordPerfect 6.1 or lower format or in ASCII format, with the 
    name of the filer and Docket No. RM98-10-000 on the outside of the 
    diskette.
    
    List of Subjects
    
    18 CFR Part 161
    
        Natural gas, Reporting and recordkeeping requirements.
    
    18 CFR Part 250
    
        Natural gas, Reporting and recordkeeping requirements.
    
    CFR Part 284
    
        Continental shelf, Incorporation by reference, Natural gas, 
    Reporting and recordkeeping requirements.
    
        By direction of the Commission.
    David P. Boergers,
    Acting Secretary.
    
        In consideration of the foregoing, the Commission proposes to amend 
    part 161, part 250, and part 284, chapter I, title 18, Code of Federal 
    Regulations, as set forth below.
    
    PART 161--STANDARDS OF CONDUCT FOR INTERSTATE PIPELINES WITH 
    MARKETING AFFILIATES
    
        1. The authority citation for Part 161 continues to read as 
    follows:
    
        Authority: 15 U.S.C. 717-717w, 3301-3432; 42 U.S.C. 7101-7352.
    
        2. In Sec. 161.3, paragraphs (i) through (k) are renumbered (j) 
    through (l) and paragraph (i) is added to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 161.3  Standards of conduct
    
    * * * * *
        (i) A pipeline must post the following information concerning its 
    affiliates on its Internet web site complying with Sec. 284.13 of this 
    chapter and update the information within three business days of any 
    change, posting the date on which the information was updated.
        (1) A complete list of operating personnel and facilities shared by 
    the pipeline and its marketing affiliates.
        (2) Comprehensive organizational charts and job descriptions for 
    its employees and the employees of its marketing affiliates identifying 
    which employees are engaged in transportation and which are engaged in 
    sales or marketing, and clearly showing the chain of command. The job 
    descriptions need not include employees whose jobs are purely clerical 
    or those without responsibility or access to information concerning the 
    processing or administration of requests for transportation service. 
    Each job description must include: the employee's title, duties and 
    status as an operating or non-operating employee; and in the case of a 
    senior employee (i.e., any employee who supervises non-clerical 
    employees), the employee's name.
    * * * * *
        3. In Sec. 161.3(h)(2), revise all references to ``284.10(a)'' to 
    read ``284.13'' and remove the words ``Electronic Bulletin Board, 
    operated pursuant to'' and add, in their place, the words ``Internet 
    Web site complying with''.
    
    PART 250--FORMS
    
        4. The authority citation for part 250 continues to read as 
    follows:
    
        Authority: 15 U.S.C. 717-717w, 3301-3432; 42 U.S.C. 7101-7352.
    
        5. In Sec. 250.16, paragraph (b)(1) is removed, paragraph (b)(2) is 
    redesignated as (b)(1), and paragraph (b)(2) is reserved.
    
    
    Sec. 250.16  [Amended]
    
        6. In Sec. 250.16(c)(2), revise all references to ``284.10(a)'' to 
    read ``284.13'' and remove the words ``Electronic Bulletin Board, 
    operated pursuant to'' and add, in their place, the words'' Internet 
    Web site complying with''.
    
    PART 284--CERTAIN SALES AND TRANSPORTATION OF NATURAL GAS UNDER THE 
    NATURAL GAS POLICY ACT OF 1978 AND RELATED AUTHORITIES
    
        7. The authority citation for part 284 continues to read as 
    follows:
    
        Authority: 15 U.S.C. 717-717w, 3301-3432; 42 U.S.C 7101-7532; 43 
    U.S.C 1331-1356.
    
    
    Sec. 284.12  [Removed]
    
        8(a) Part 284 is amended by removing Sec. 284.12.
        8(b) Part 284 is amended by redesignating the sections as set forth 
    in the following redesignation table:
    
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                                                      New   
                             Old section                            section 
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    284.7.......................................................      284.10
    284.8.......................................................       284.7
    284.10......................................................      284.13
    284.11......................................................      284.12
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        9. In newly redesignated Sec. 284.7, paragraph (b)(3) is removed 
    and paragraph (b)(4) is redesignated as paragraph (b)(3).
        10. Part 284 is amended by adding Sec. 284.8 to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 284.8  Release of firm transportation service.
    
        (a) An interstate pipeline that offers transportation service on a 
    firm basis under subparts B or G of this part must include in its 
    tariff a mechanism for firm shippers to release firm capacity to the 
    pipeline for resale by the pipeline on a firm basis.
        (b) To the extent necessary, a firm shipper on an interstate 
    pipeline that offers transportation service on a firm basis under 
    subpart B or G of this part is granted a limited-jurisdiction blanket 
    certificate of public convenience and necessity pursuant to section 7 
    of the Natural Gas Act solely for the purpose of releasing firm 
    capacity pursuant to this section.
        (c) The pipeline must enter into a contract with the replacement 
    shipper purchasing the capacity. Unless otherwise agreed by the 
    pipeline, the contract of the shipper releasing capacity will remain in 
    full force and effect, with the net proceeds from any resale to a 
    replacement shipper credited to the releasing shipper's reservation 
    charge.
        (d) Releases of capacity for a period of less than one year must 
    conform to the requirements of the auction established under 
    Sec. 284.10(c)(5) of this part.
        (e) Releases of capacity of one year or more must comply with the 
    following requirements.
        (1) A shipper may arrange for a replacement shipper to obtain its 
    released capacity from the pipeline. The releasing and replacement 
    shippers or an authorized agent must notify the pipeline of the terms 
    and conditions of the release.
        (2) A shipper may post any capacity it has available on the 
    pipeline's Internet site and may authorize the pipeline to accept bids 
    for such capacity. A releasing shipper posting capacity for bid must 
    notify the pipeline of the terms and conditions under which it will 
    release its capacity.
    
    [[Page 43021]]
    
        (3) For releases of capacity of one year or more, the rate may not 
    exceed the maximum rate in the pipeline's tariff.
    
    
    Sec. 284.9  [Amended]
    
        11. In Sec. 284.9, paragraph (b)(3) is removed and paragraph (b)(4) 
    is redesignated paragraph as (b)(3).
        12. In newly redesignated Sec. 284.10, paragraphs (c)(5) and (c)(6) 
    are revised, and paragraph (c)(7) is added to read as follows.
    
    
    Sec. 284.10  Rates.
    
    * * * * *
        (c) * * *
        (5) Rates for short-term transportation services. For 
    transportation contracts of less than one year for pipeline firm and 
    interruptible service and for capacity released pursuant to Sec. 284.8 
    of this part, the rates will be determined in the following manner.
        (i) Minimum rate. The minimum rate charged for such service may not 
    be lower than the minimum rate in the pipeline's tariff.
        (ii) Capacity auction. The rate charged for any transaction at or 
    above the minimum rate will be determined by an auction that conforms 
    to the following requirements:
        (A) All available short-term capacity must be sold through an 
    auction;
        (B) Daily capacity from the pipeline must be sold through an 
    auction without the establishment of a reserve or minimum bid price;
        (C) All eligible shippers must be permitted to bid with no 
    favoritism shown to pipeline affiliates or other shippers;
        (D) The procedures and rules for each auction, including the 
    auction schedule, must be disclosed in the pipeline's tariff in advance 
    of the auction and must be applied to each auction;
        (E) Capacity must be allocated based on established criteria and 
    parameters known in advance to all bidders and the same criteria and 
    parameters must apply to pipeline and released capacity;
        (F) Shippers must be able to validate that the auction was run 
    properly either through the posting of information sufficient to permit 
    them to validate that the winners were selected appropriately or 
    through the use of other mechanisms, such as an independent third-
    party, which will validate the results.
        (6) Rates for long-term transportation services. (i) Except as 
    provided in section (ii) of this paragraph and Sec. 284.11 of this 
    part, for transportation contracts of one year or longer for pipeline 
    firm and interruptible service, the pipeline may charge an individual 
    customer a rate that is neither greater than the maximum rate nor less 
    than the minimum rate on file for that service.
        (ii) The pipeline may not file a revised or new rate designed to 
    recover costs not recovered under rates previously in effect.
        (7) Rates involving marketing affiliates. If a pipeline does not 
    hold a blanket certificate under subpart G of this part, it may not 
    charge, in a transaction involving its marketing affiliate, a rate that 
    is lower than the highest rate it charges in any transaction not 
    involving its marketing affiliate.
        13. Part 284 is amended by adding Sec. 284.11 to read as follows.
    
    
    Sec. 284.11  Negotiated rates and services.
    
        (a) Authority. An interstate pipeline that provides transportation 
    service under subparts B or G of this part may negotiate with shippers 
    the rates, or terms and conditions of service, in any contract, 
    provided the pipeline offers all shippers recourse to transportation 
    service under its generally applicable transportation tariff as an 
    alternative to negotiated service.
        (b) Limitations on negotiations. Pipelines cannot negotiate rates 
    and services that:
        (1) result in undue discrimination or preference;
        (2) degrade the quality of existing services;
        (3) hinder the release of capacity or otherwise significantly 
    reduce competition; or
        (4) require customers, as a condition of obtaining negotiated rates 
    or services, to purchase sales, storage, or gathering services provided 
    by the pipeline, its affiliates, or upstream or downstream entities 
    that are unnecessary to the provision of the negotiated service.
        (c) Review of recourse service. Pipelines must file (every 3 or 5 
    years) the following information regarding negotiated rates and terms 
    of service and recourse service.
        (1) For each negotiated transaction, the pipeline must file, for 
    each calendar year, by category of negotiated transaction (transactions 
    taking effect on shortened notice and transactions subject to 30 days 
    notice) the following: the name of the shipper, the shipper's 
    designation (e.g., marketer, producer, LDC, end-user), the contract 
    number, the docket number under which the contract was filed with the 
    Commission, the type of service (e.g., firm or interruptible 
    transportation or storage), the contract demand, the rate, and the 
    volume. For transactions taking effect under shortened notice, the 
    pipeline must include an indication of the tariff categories under 
    which the contract was negotiated. For transactions subject to thirty 
    days notice, the pipeline must include a short description of the terms 
    and conditions negotiated.
        (2) For each year, for each category of negotiated service and for 
    recourse services, by rate schedule, the pipeline must file data 
    showing aggregate contract demand, aggregate volumes, and aggregate 
    revenue.
        14. In newly redesignated Sec. 284.13, paragraphs (c)(1)(ii) and 
    (c)(2)(iii) through (v) are added and paragraph (b)(1)(v) is revised to 
    read as follows.
    
    
    Sec. 284.13  Standards for pipeline business operations and 
    communications.
    
    * * * * *
        (b) * * *
        (1) * * *
        (v) Capacity Release Related Standards (Version 1.2,
        July 31, 1997), with the exception of Standard 5.3.2.
        (c) * * *
        (1) * * *
        (ii) Capacity release nominations. Pipelines must permit shippers 
    acquiring released capacity to submit a nomination at the earliest 
    available nomination opportunity after the acquisition of capacity. If 
    the pipeline requires the replacement shipper to enter into a contract, 
    the contract must be issued within one hour of submission of the 
    transaction, but the requirement for contracting must not inhibit the 
    ability to submit a nomination at the time the transaction is complete.
        (2) * * *
        (iii) Imbalance management. A pipeline must provide, to the extent 
    operationally practicable, parking and lending or other services that 
    facilitate the ability of its shippers to manage transportation 
    imbalances. A pipeline must provide such services without undue 
    discrimination or preference of any kind against third parties that 
    seek to provide similar services to the shippers of the pipeline.
        (iv) Penalties. A pipeline may include in its tariff transportation 
    penalties only to the extent necessary for system operations. A 
    pipeline must provide, on a timely basis, as much information as 
    possible about the imbalance and overrun status of each shipper and the 
    imbalance of the pipeline's system.
        (v) Operational flow orders. A pipeline must take all reasonable 
    actions to minimize the issuance and adverse impacts of operational 
    flow orders (OFOs) or other measures taken to respond to adverse 
    operational events on its system. A pipeline must set forth in its 
    tariff clear standards for when such measures will begin and end and 
    must provide timely information that
    
    [[Page 43022]]
    
    will enable shippers to minimize the adverse impacts of these measures.
    * * * * *
        15. Part 284 is amended by adding Sec. 284.14 to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 284.14  Reporting requirements for interstate pipelines.
    
        An interstate pipeline that provides transportation service under 
    subparts B or G of this part must comply with the following reporting 
    requirements.
        (a) Cross references. The pipeline must comply with the 
    requirements in part 161, part 250, and part 260, where applicable.
        (b) Index of customers. (1) On the first business day of each 
    calendar quarter, subsequent to the initial implementation of this 
    provision, an interstate pipeline must provide for electronic 
    dissemination of an index of all its firm transportation and storage 
    customers under contract as of the first day of the calendar quarter. 
    Electronic dissemination will be by placing a file, adhering to the 
    requirements set forth by the Commission, on the pipeline's Internet 
    web site, pursuant to section 284.13 of this part, in a format which 
    can be downloaded. The pipeline must also submit the electronic file to 
    the Commission.
        (2) Until an interstate pipeline is in compliance with the 
    reporting requirements of this paragraph, the pipeline must comply with 
    the index of customer requirements applicable to transportation and 
    sales under part 157, set forth under Sec. 154.111(b) and (c) of this 
    chapter.
        (3) For each customer receiving firm transportation or storage 
    service, the index must include the information listed below:
        (i) The full legal name of the customer;
        (ii) The rate schedule number of the service being provided;
        (iii) The contract number;
        (iv) The contract effective date;
        (v) The contract expiration date;
        (vi) For transportation service, maximum daily contract quantity 
    (specify unit of measurement);
        (vii) For storage service, maximum storage quantity (specify unit 
    of measurement);
        (viii) The receipt and delivery points and the zones or segments in 
    which the capacity is held;
        (ix) An indication as to whether the contract includes negotiated 
    rates or terms and conditions;
        (x) Any affiliate relationship between the pipeline and the 
    customer or any affiliate relationships between contract holders;
        (xi) The name of any agent or asset manager managing 20% or more of 
    the transportation service in a pipeline rate zone and the agent's and 
    asset manager's rights with respect to managing the transportation 
    service.
        (4) The information included in the quarterly index must be 
    available on the pipeline's web site until the next quarterly index is 
    established.
        (5) The requirements of this section do not apply to contracts 
    which relate solely to the release of capacity under Sec. 284.8, unless 
    the release is permanent.
        (6) The requirements for the electronic index can be obtained at 
    the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, Division of Information 
    Services, Public Reference and Files Maintenance Branch, Washington, DC 
    20426.
        (c) Reports on firm and interruptible services. An interstate 
    pipeline must post the following information on its Internet web site, 
    and provide the information in downloadable file formats, in conformity 
    with section 284.13 of this part.
        (1) For pipeline firm service, whether provided by the pipeline or 
    from release transactions under section 284.8 of this part, the 
    pipeline must post, contemporaneously with the execution of a contract 
    for service:
        (i) The full legal name of the shipper receiving service under the 
    contract and the full legal name of the releasing shipper if a capacity 
    release is involved or an indication that the pipeline is the seller of 
    transportation capacity;
        (ii) The contract number for the shipper receiving service under 
    the contract, and, in addition, for released transactions, the contract 
    number of the releasing shipper's contract;
        (iii) The rate charged under each contract;
        (iv) The duration of the contract;
        (v) The receipt and delivery points and mainline segments covered 
    by the contract;
        (vi) The contract quantity or the volumetric quantity under a 
    volumetric release;
        (vii) Any special terms and conditions applicable to the contract; 
    and
        (viii) Whether there is an affiliate relationship between the 
    pipeline and the shipper or between the releasing and replacement 
    shipper.
        (2) For pipeline interruptible service, the pipeline must post on a 
    daily basis:
        (i) The full legal name of the shipper;
        (ii) The rate charged;
        (iii) The receipt and delivery points and mainline segments over 
    which the shipper is entitled to nominate gas;
        (iv) The quantity of gas the shipper is entitled to nominate;
        (v) Whether the shipper is affiliated with the pipeline.
        (d) Available capacity. (1) An interstate pipeline must provide on 
    its Internet web site and in downloadable file formats, in conformity 
    with section 284.13 of this part, equal and timely access to 
    information relevant to the availability of all transportation 
    services, including, but not limited to, the availability of capacity 
    at receipt points, on the mainline, at delivery points, and in storage 
    fields, whether the capacity is available directly from the pipeline or 
    through capacity release, the total design capacity of each point or 
    segment on the system, the amount scheduled at each point or segment on 
    a daily basis, and all planned and actual service outages or reductions 
    in service capacity.
        (2) An interstate pipeline must make an annual filing by March 1 of 
    each year showing the estimated peak day capacity of the pipeline's 
    system, and the estimated storage capacity and maximum daily delivery 
    capability of storage facilities under reasonably representative 
    operating assumptions and the respective assignments of that capacity 
    to the various firm services provided by the pipeline.
        (e) Semi-annual storage report. Within 30 days of the end of each 
    complete storage injection and withdrawal season, the interstate 
    pipeline must file with the Commission a report of storage activity. 
    The report must be signed under oath by a senior official, consist of 
    an original and five conformed copies, and contain a summary of storage 
    injection and withdrawal activities to include the following:
        (1) The identity of each customer injecting gas into storage and/or 
    withdrawing gas from storage, identifying any affiliation with the 
    interstate pipeline;
        (2) The rate schedule under which the storage injection or 
    withdrawal service was performed;
        (3) The maximum storage quantity and maximum daily withdrawal 
    quantity applicable to each storage customer;
        (4) For each storage customer, the volume of gas (in dekatherms) 
    injected into and/or withdrawn from storage during the period;
        (5) The unit charge and total revenues received during the 
    injection/withdrawal period from each storage customer, noting the 
    extent of any discounts permitted during the period; and
        (6) The related docket numbers in which the interstate pipeline 
    reported storage related injection/withdrawal transportation services.
        16. In Sec. 284.106, paragraph (c) is removed and paragraph (b) is 
    revised to read as follows:
    
    [[Page 43023]]
    
    Sec. 284.106  Reporting requirements
    
    * * * * *
        (b) An interstate pipeline providing transportation service under 
    this subpart must comply with the reporting requirements of Sec. 284.14 
    of this part.
    
    
    Sec. 284.223  [Amended]
    
        17. In Sec. 284.223, paragraph (b) is removed and reserved.
        18. Subpart H is revised to read as follows:
    
    Subpart H--Assignment of Capacity on Upstream Interstate Pipelines
    
    
    Sec. 284.241.  Upstream interstate pipelines.
    
        An interstate pipeline that offers transportation service on a firm 
    basis under subpart B or G of this part must offer without undue 
    discrimination to assign to its firm shippers its firm transportation 
    capacity, including contract storage, on all upstream pipelines, 
    whether the firm capacity is authorized under part 284 or part 157. An 
    upstream pipeline is authorized and required to permit a downstream 
    pipeline to assign its firm capacity to the downstream pipeline's firm 
    shippers.
    
    
    Secs. 284.10, 284.123, 284.221, 284.261, 284.263, 284.266, and 
    284.286  [Amended]
    
        19. Secs. 284.10, 284.123, 284.221, 284.261, 284.263, 284.266, and 
    284.286 [Amended]
        In addition to the amendments set forth above, in 18 CFR part 284, 
    the following nomenclature changes are made:
        A. Revise all references to ``Sec. 284.7'' to read ``Sec. 284.10'' 
    in the following places:
        1. Section 284.221(d)(2)(ii);
        2. Section 284.261;
        3. Section 284.263; and
        4. Sections 284.266(a)(1) and (a)(2).
        B. Revise all references to ``Secs. 284.8-284.13'' to read 
    ``Secs. 284.7-284.9 and Secs. 284.11-284.14'' in the following places:
        1. Section 284.261; and
        2. Section 284.263.
        C. Revise all references to ``Sec. 284.8(d)'' to read 
    ``Sec. 284.7(d)'' in newly redesignated Secs. 284.10(c)(1) and (c)(2).
        D. Revise all references to ``Secs. 284.8'' to read ``Secs. 284.7'' 
    in Sec. 284.123 (b)(1).
        E. Revise all references to ``Secs. 284.8(b)(2)'' to read 
    ``Secs. 284.7(b)(2)'' in Sec. 284.286(b).
        F. Remove the words ``Secs. 161.3(c), (e), (f), (g), and (h)'' and 
    add, in its place, the words ``Secs. 161.3(c), (e), (f), (g), (h), and 
    (i)'' in section 284.286(c).
    
    [FR Doc. 98-20998 Filed 8-10-98; 8:45 am]
    BILLING CODE 6717-01-P
    
    
    

Document Information

Published:
08/11/1998
Department:
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
Entry Type:
Proposed Rule
Action:
Notice of proposed rulemaking.
Document Number:
98-20998
Dates:
Comments are due November 9, 1998.
Pages:
42982-43023 (42 pages)
Docket Numbers:
Docket No. RM98-10-000
PDF File:
98-20998.pdf
CFR: (14)
18 CFR 284.10(c)(5)
18 CFR 284.106(c)(3)
18 CFR 161.3
18 CFR 250.16
18 CFR 284.8
More ...