98-21938. Draft Report to Congress on the Costs and Benefits of Federal Regulations  

  • [Federal Register Volume 63, Number 158 (Monday, August 17, 1998)]
    [Notices]
    [Pages 44034-44099]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 98-21938]
    
    
    
    [[Page 44033]]
    
    _______________________________________________________________________
    
    Part III
    
    
    
    
    
    Office of Management and Budget
    
    
    
    
    
    _______________________________________________________________________
    
    
    
    Draft Report to Congress on the Costs and Benefits of Federal 
    Regulations; Notice
    
    Federal Register / Vol. 63, No. 158 / Monday, August 17, 1998 / 
    Notices
    
    [[Page 44034]]
    
    
    
    OFFICE OF MANAGEMENT AND BUDGET
    
    
    Draft Report to Congress on the Costs and Benefits of Federal 
    Regulations
    
    AGENCY: Office of Management and Budget, Executive Office of the 
    President.
    
    ACTION: Notice and request for comments.
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    SUMMARY: The Office of Management and Budget (OMB) requests comments on 
    the attached draft report to Congress on the costs and benefits of 
    Federal regulations. The draft report is divided into an introduction 
    and four chapters. The introduction sets the context and provides the 
    background for the next four chapters. Chapter I presents OMB's best 
    estimate of the total costs and benefits of Federal regulatory programs 
    and discusses several retrospective studies of specific regulatory 
    programs to gain insight on how actual costs and benefits of 
    regulations may differ from the effects predicted prior to regulation. 
    Chapter II provides data on the costs and benefits of each of the 
    economically significant regulations reviewed by OMB under Executive 
    Order 12866 in the last year. Chapter III provides additional data on 
    the costs and benefits of the economically significant regulations 
    reviewed by OMB from April 1, 1995 through March 31, 1998. Chapter IV 
    discusses how OMB implemented last year's recommendations and presents 
    the Administration's proposal to restructure and deregulate the 
    electricity sector.
    
    DATES: To ensure consideration of comments as OMB prepares this draft 
    report for submission to Congress on or before September 30, 1998, 
    comments must be in writing and received by OMB no later than September 
    16, 1998.
    
    ADDRESSES: Comments on this draft report should be addressed to John F. 
    Morrall III, Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs, Office of 
    Management and Budget, NEOB, Room 10235, 725 17th Street, NW., 
    Washington, DC 20503.
        Comments may also be submitted by facsimile to (202) 395-6974, or 
    by electronic mail to [email protected] (Please note that the 
    ``l'' in ``A1'' is the number one and not the letter ``l''.) Be sure to 
    include your name and complete postal mailing address in the comments 
    sent by electronic mail. If you submit comments by facsimile or 
    electronic mail, please do not submit them by regular mail also.
        Electronic availability and addresses: This Federal Register notice 
    is available electronically from the OMB homepage on the World Wide 
    Web: http://www.whitehouse.gov/WH/EOP/OMB/html/fedreg.html.
    
    FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: John F. Morrall III, Office of 
    Information and Regulatory Affairs, Office of Management and Budget, 
    NEOB, Room 10235, 725 17th Street, NW., Washington, DC 20503. 
    Telephone: (202) 395-7316.
    
    SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: Congress directed OMB to prepare a report to 
    Congress on the costs and benefits of Federal regulations. 
    Specifically, under section 625 of the Treasury and Government 
    Appropriations Act, 1998 (Pub. L. 105-61), the Director of OMB is to 
    submit to Congress, no later than September 30, 1998, a report that, in 
    summary, provides (1) estimates of the total annual costs and benefits 
    of Federal regulatory programs, (2) estimates of the costs and benefits 
    of each rule that is likely to have a gross annual effect on the 
    economy of $100,000,000 or more in increased costs, (3) an assessment 
    of the direct and indirect impacts of Federal rules, and (4) 
    recommendations from OMB and a description of significant public 
    comments to reform or eliminate any Federal regulatory program that is 
    inefficient, ineffective, or is not a sound use of the Nation's 
    resources.
        The attached document is a draft of this report to Congress. OMB is 
    to provide public notice and an opportunity to comment on the report 
    before it is submitted to Congress no later than September 30, 1998.
    
    Issues for Comment
    
        Accordingly, OMB seeks comment on all aspects of the attached draft 
    report, particularly comments and suggestions pertaining to the 
    following:
         The validity and reliability of our new estimates of the 
    costs and benefits of regulations in the aggregate, as well as by 
    regulatory program or program element;
         Our discussion of the methodological problems of 
    estimating the costs and benefits of existing rules, e.g., the baseline 
    and comparability problems and complications introduced by using 
    prospective studies to evaluate existing programs; and difficulties 
    reconciling quantitative and qualitative estimates of costs and 
    benefits;
         Our review of several case studies of the costs and 
    benefits of existing regulations and the lessons we draw from them;
         Any additional studies that might provide reliable 
    estimates or assessments of the annual costs and benefits, or direct 
    and indirect effects on the private sector, State and local government, 
    and the Federal Government, of regulation in the aggregate or of the 
    individual regulations that we discuss;
         Our approach to estimating the costs and benefits of the 
    individual regulations issued between April 1, 1995, and March 31, 
    1998, that we discuss, and;
         Programs or program elements on which there is objective 
    and verifiable information that would lead to a conclusion that such 
    programs are inefficient or ineffective and should be eliminated or 
    reformed.
    Bruce McConnell,
    Acting Administrator, Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs.
    
    Draft Report to Congress on the Costs and Benefits of Federal 
    Regulations
    
    Introduction
    
        The Office of Management and Budget issued its first report to 
    Congress on the costs and benefits of Federal regulations on September 
    30, 1997. Section 625 of the Treasury and Government Appropriations 
    Act, 1998 (P.L. 105-61) directs OMB to issue a second regulatory 
    accounting report. The requirements of the report are the same as those 
    of last year. Section 625(a) directs the Director of the Office of 
    Management and Budget to submit to Congress, no later than September 
    30, 1998, a report that provides:
    
        ``(1) Estimates of the total annual costs and benefits of 
    Federal regulatory programs, including quantitative and non-
    quantitative measures of regulatory costs and benefits;
        ``(2) Estimates of the costs and benefits (including 
    quantitative and non-quantitative measures) of each rule that is 
    likely to have a gross annual effect on the economy of $100,000,000 
    or more in increased costs;
        ``(3) An assessment of the direct and indirect impacts of 
    Federal rules on the private sector, State and local government, and 
    the Federal Government; and
        ``(4) Recommendations from the Director and a description of 
    significant public comments to reform or eliminate any Federal 
    regulatory program or program element that is inefficient, 
    ineffective, or is not a sound use of the Nation's resources.''
    
        In last year's report we indicated that a complete accounting of 
    total costs and benefits of Federal regulation was a difficult 
    undertaking. The 1997 report was our effort to begin an incremental 
    process which we believe will lead to improved information on the 
    effects of regulations, and will help solve the many methodological 
    problems associated with this exercise. This year's report builds on 
    last year's work. In particular, we have additional data to
    
    [[Page 44035]]
    
    supplement our discussion of the aggregate costs and benefits of 
    regulation and expand our database of costs and benefits of individual, 
    major rules from one year (1997) to three years (1996 to 1998). In 
    addition, we have more experience in dealing with the methodological 
    problems.
        One fact has not changed since the first report. There are still 
    enormous data gaps in the information available on regulatory benefits 
    and costs. Although accurate data is still sparse and agreed-upon 
    methods for estimating many effects are still lacking, we have made 
    significant progress in improving these estimates, especially for the 
    major rules of the last three years. As we stated last year, explicitly 
    quantifying and monetizing benefits and costs significantly enhances 
    our ability to compare alternative approaches to achieving regulatory 
    goals, ultimately producing more benefits with fewer costs. President 
    Clinton's Executive Order 12866, ``Regulatory Planning and Review,'' 
    recognizes and incorporates this principle, requiring agencies to 
    quantify both costs and benefits to the best of their ability and to 
    the extent permitted by law. We continue to recognize that significant 
    regulatory costs and benefits may not be quantifiable, but may have to 
    be described in qualitative terms. All information, both qualitative 
    and quantitative, contributes to our understanding of the effects of 
    regulation.
        This year's report presents new information on both the total costs 
    and benefits of regulation and the costs and benefits of major 
    individual regulations. We hope to continue this important dialogue to 
    improve our knowledge about the effects of regulation on the public, 
    the economy, and American society.
        This document is a draft of our report. Section 625(b) requires the 
    Director of OMB to provide public notice and an opportunity to comment 
    on the report before it is submitted to Congress at the end of 
    September 1998. Furthermore, the final report is to contain a 
    description of significant public comments. Accordingly, we seek 
    comments on all aspects of this document, but in particular are 
    interested in comments and suggestions pertaining to the following:
         The validity and reliability of our new estimates of the 
    costs and benefits of regulations in the aggregate, as well as by 
    regulatory program or program element;
         Our discussion of the methodological problems of 
    estimating the costs and benefits of existing rules, e.g., the baseline 
    and comparability problems and complications introduced by using 
    prospective studies to evaluate existing programs;
         Our review of several case studies of the costs and 
    benefits of existing regulations and the lessons we draw from them;
         Any additional studies that might provide reliable 
    estimates or assessments of the annual costs and benefits, or direct 
    and indirect effects on the private sector, State and local government, 
    and the Federal Government, of regulation in the aggregate or of the 
    individual regulations that we discuss;
         Our approach to estimating the costs and benefits of the 
    individual regulations issued between April 1, 1995, and March 31, 
    1998, that we discuss; and
         Programs or program elements on which there is objective 
    and verifiable information that would lead to a conclusion that such 
    programs are inefficient or ineffective and should be eliminated or 
    reformed.
    
    All comments received will be carefully considered in preparing the 
    final report that will be submitted to Congress.
        The draft report is divided into four chapters. In accordance with 
    section 625(a)(1), chapter I presents our best estimate of the total 
    costs and benefits of Federal regulation. It builds on chapter II of 
    last year's report presenting updated and more detailed estimates of 
    the total annual costs and benefits of major Federal regulatory 
    programs.1 In particular, this year we present more 
    categories of regulatory costs and benefits than last year and use our 
    own estimates based on agency data of costs and benefits of individual 
    rules issued over the last three years (April 1, 1995 to March 31, 
    1998) to update the aggregate estimates. We also chose this year to 
    provide ranges of costs and benefits rather than point estimates to 
    emphasize the uncertainty embodied in the estimates.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \1\ Chapter I of last year's report discussed the role of 
    economic analysis in regulatory reform. We discussed the growth and 
    nature of regulation, the development of the U.S. regulatory 
    analysis and review program and the basic principles that should be 
    used in assessing regulatory costs and benefits. We did not repeat 
    that discussion this year but it is still useful for understanding 
    the context of this year's report. (See OMB 1997 or http://
    www.whitehouse.gov/WH/EOP/OMB/html/rcongress.htm).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As we did last year, we use the study by Hahn and Hird (1991) for 
    the costs and benefits of regulations as of 1988, supplemented by an 
    Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) Cost of a Clean Environment 
    report to Congress (1990). We also use a new (1997) retrospective EPA 
    report to Congress (The Benefits and Costs of the Clean Air Act, 1970 
    to 1990). Because there are no studies comparable to the Hahn and Hird 
    or the EPA retrospective studies for the regulations issued after 
    1988,2 we use information about costs and benefits from 
    agency prospective regulatory impact analyses (RIAs) to account for the 
    major regulations that have been issued since 1988. In almost all 
    cases, the RIAs have been subject to notice and comment and have been 
    reviewed by OMB. This year we have systematically started to improve 
    the consistency of the agency estimates and to show monetized estimates 
    of benefits where appropriate and feasible. We have completed this 
    analysis for the last three years and plan to complete additional years 
    in the future.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \2\ EPA's Clean Air Act report covers effects through 1990. 
    However, for the annual estimates that appear in table 1 and in the 
    text, we have, in consultation with EPA staff, adjusted EPA's 
    estimates to reflect only effects as of 1988.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The new estimates range from $170 billion to $224 billion in annual 
    costs and $258 billion to about $3.55 trillion in annual benefits for 
    social, i.e., health, safety, and environmental regulation. Using the 
    ranges to reflect the substantial uncertainty in the estimates, 
    quantified (and monetized) net benefits could be as low as $34 billion, 
    or as high as $3.38 trillion. The main reason why these estimates are 
    different from last year, especially on the upper end of the range of 
    benefits, is that we have incorporated retrospective estimates from a 
    recent EPA report on the benefits and costs of the Clean Air Act. This 
    report, discussed in detail in chapter I, estimates the benefits of the 
    Clean Air Act at up to $3.2 trillion. Three new regulations also 
    included in the estimates (EPA's revised particulate matter and ozone 
    primary National Ambient Air Quality Standards and OSHA's respirator 
    rule) are estimated (using midpoints) to provide approximately $35 
    billion in benefits per year. While this information is useful, we 
    still believe that the limitations of these estimates for use in making 
    recommendations about reforming or eliminating regulatory programs are 
    severe. Aggregate estimates of the costs and benefits of regulation 
    offer little guidance on how to improve the efficiency, effectiveness, 
    or soundness of the existing body of regulations.
        Chapter I also discusses the impacts of other types of regulation 
    and regulatory-like activities and reviews several estimates of the 
    aggregate costs of regulation as well as several retrospective case 
    studies. Estimates of
    
    [[Page 44036]]
    
    the impacts of economic efficiency losses, disclosure regulation, 
    economic transfers, tax compliance costs, Federal on-budget regulatory 
    expenditures, and the possible indirect effects of regulation on the 
    economy as directed by section 625(a)(3) are also presented and 
    discussed.
        In fulfillment of section 625(a)(2), chapter II provides data from 
    the agencies on the costs and benefits of each of the economically 
    significant regulations reviewed by OMB under Executive Order 12866 
    over the period from April 1, 1997, to March 31, 1998. The data were 
    developed by the agencies as required by the Executive order. For the 
    most part, these data were subject to notice and public comment and 
    reviewed by OMB. We also examined the reports on major rules that GAO 
    provides to Congress for the independent agencies not subject to 
    Executive Order 12866; however, these generally were not of sufficient 
    detail or quality to provide much useful information for the purposes 
    of this report. Finally, this chapter also highlights examples where 
    agencies have done a particularly exemplary job of following the 
    guidance in the Best Practices 3 document, which is on our 
    web site at http://www.whitehouse.gov/WH/EOP/OMB/html/miscdoc/
    riaguide.html.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \3\ OMB published in 1996 a document that describes ``Best 
    Practices'' for preparing the economic analysis called for by 
    Executive Order 12866 for significant regulatory actions. This 
    document represents the culmination of a two-year effort by an 
    interagency group to review the state of the art for economic 
    analyses required by the Executive order.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Chapter III provides estimates of the costs and benefits for the 
    economically significant/major rules issued between April 1, 1995 and 
    March 31, 1998, for which we were able to estimate costs and benefits. 
    The estimates that we present in chapter III for regulations issued 
    during these three years are either straightforward agency estimates, 
    or estimates that we calculated using a consistent methodology and 
    value estimates used by the agencies for other regulations or in some 
    cases found in the academic literature. We estimate annual costs of 
    major rules for these three years to be about $28 billion while annual 
    benefits range from $30 to $97 billion.
        Chapter IV discusses how we implemented last year's recommendations 
    aimed at further developing the information, methodologies, and 
    analyses necessary for improving the efficiency, effectiveness, and 
    soundness of regulatory programs and program elements as required by 
    section 625(a)(4). We discuss how the agencies and OMB worked together 
    to improve the quality of the data and analysis found in the economic 
    impact studies submitted to OMB under Executive Order 12866, and in 
    particular how we promoted the use of the Best Practices guidance 
    document. Finally, also in fulfillment of section 625(a) (4), we 
    present a discussion of the Administration's proposal to restructure 
    and deregulate the electricity sector.
    
    Chapter I: Estimating the Total Annual Costs and Benefits of 
    Federal Regulatory Programs
    
    A. Overview
    
        By using new data from agency regulatory impact analyses that 
    accompany regulations, this chapter builds on chapter II of last year's 
    report (OMB 1997) to present updated and more detailed estimates of the 
    total annual costs and benefits of Federal regulatory programs. We also 
    discuss and present quantitative estimates where available of indirect 
    impacts and other effects of regulation and related Government 
    policies. Finally, several retrospective studies of specific regulatory 
    programs are reviewed to gain insight on how the actual costs and 
    benefits of regulations may differ from the effects predicted prior to 
    regulation.
        We respond to the comments we received on last year's report in 
    several ways. First, we present more details by regulatory program and 
    build on agency analyses to monetize benefits estimates. Second, we 
    review the analyses from independent agencies and present more 
    systematic data on the costs and benefits of economic regulation, tax 
    compliance costs, transfers, Federal regulatory expenditures, and 
    indirect impacts. Finally, our review of several important 
    retrospective studies responds to important methodological issues 
    raised regarding the use of prospective studies to estimate the costs 
    and benefits of existing regulations.
    1. Estimation Problems
        Before proceeding with our new estimates, we reiterate and 
    reemphasize the methodological concerns and caveats that were discussed 
    in last year's report. These concerns remain of critical importance. It 
    remains extremely difficult, if not impossible, to estimate the actual 
    total costs and benefits of all existing Federal regulations with any 
    degree of precision. There is a variety of estimation problems for both 
    individual estimates and aggregate estimates.
        In order to estimate the impact of regulations on society and the 
    economy, one has to determine how things would have been if the 
    regulation had not been issued. In other words, what is the baseline 
    against which costs and benefits should be measured? With respect to 
    estimating total costs and benefits of all Federal regulations, the 
    baseline problem has several dimensions. First, what would have 
    happened in the absence of regulation can only be an educated guess 
    since it never happened. Furthermore, the greater the regulatory 
    change, the more problematic the exercise. For example, the assumptions 
    of welfare economics, upon which benefit-cost analysis is based, hold 
    only for marginal changes in economic activities. The larger the 
    changes, the less sure we are of the predictions. In other words, we 
    can be more confident in our estimates of the costs and benefits of a 
    small change in the level of automobile emissions permitted than in the 
    costs and benefits of all Clean Air Act regulations and still more 
    confident than in estimates of the costs and benefits of all 
    regulations issued by the Federal Government since the early 1900s. If 
    we use as a baseline a world with no regulation, one can reasonably 
    argue that the benefits of regulation must clearly swamp any likely 
    cost.
        Even disregarding the problem of modeling large changes, there are 
    significant difficulties in determining the counterfactual or baseline 
    for individual regulations that one could begin to aggregate. One can 
    survey firms and other regulated entities on their expected compliance 
    costs either prospectively, before the regulation is implemented, or 
    retrospectively, after the regulation has gone into effect. For both 
    types of studies, the problem of potential estimation bias must be kept 
    in mind since regulators and regulatees may have different interests in 
    the outcomes. The problem of bias is potentially greater for 
    prospective studies because both the baseline and the regulatory 
    effects must be predicted while for retrospective studies only the 
    baseline or counterfactual must be predicted. In the ordinary course, 
    therefore, the best estimates of the costs and benefits of regulation 
    are likely to be retrospective studies done by individuals who do not 
    have vested interests, but do have reputations as objective analysts to 
    uphold.
        To make matters even more complicated, a third type of study is 
    actually needed before recommendations can be made to eliminate or 
    modify regulatory programs. That is a hybrid study
    
    [[Page 44037]]
    
    somewhere between pure prospective and pure retrospective. The ideal 
    hybrid study would be a retrospective study of the existing regulation 
    with prospectively estimated costs and benefits of eliminating or 
    modifying it. A hybrid study is needed because ``sunk costs,'' such as 
    specialized capital costs and the cost of changing procedures already 
    in place, make the cost savings from eliminating regulation less than 
    the cost of complying with those regulations. Furthermore, on the 
    benefit side there appears to exist an asymmetry between giving someone 
    a benefit and taking it away. Studies have shown that people are 
    willing to pay less for a benefit than what they are willing to accept 
    in return for its loss. In other words, once people have attained safer 
    jobs or cars, or cleaner air or water, they appear willing to pay more 
    for keeping such benefits than they were willing to pay to attain them. 
    Very few studies of health, safety, and environmental regulation have 
    attempted to estimate the actual cost savings and benefit losses that 
    would result from reducing or eliminating an existing 
    regulation.4
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \4\ Note that the problem of bias may be the greatest in this 
    case because often both the regulators and the regulatees will 
    prefer the status quo, i.e., regulation. This appears to be the 
    lesson from the Occupational Health and Safety Administration's 
    (OSHA) reconsideration of the cotton dust standard during the Reagan 
    Administration. After opposing the regulation at the proposal stage 
    during the Carter Administration, the industry did not support the 
    Reagan Administration's proposal to withdraw it. (See Viscusi 1992).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Further, virtually all of the studies of the costs of regulation 
    produced to date measure the expenditures of firms required by 
    regulation, whereas the cost to society of regulation should be 
    measured by the change in consumer and producer ``surplus'' associated 
    with the regulation and with any price and/or income changes that may 
    result (Cropper and Oates 1992). At one extreme, ignoring the consumer 
    surplus loss produced by a ban on the sale of a product understates 
    costs to society because although no compliance expenditures are 
    required, consumers can no longer buy the product. At the other 
    extreme, calculating compliance expenditures based on pre-regulation 
    output overstates costs because if the firm raises prices to cover 
    compliance costs, consumers will shift to other products and thereby 
    reduce their welfare losses (Cropper and Oats 1992, p. 722).
        Another problem is the fact that many studies that we rely on for 
    cost and benefit estimates are dated. Over time the dynamic nature of 
    the economy may affect the estimation of both benefits and costs. 
    Technological improvements are often cited as the reason that predicted 
    costs of compliance often turn out to be less than actual costs (Office 
    of Technology Assessment 1995). Less well noted, however, is that 
    technological progress also takes place on the benefit side. For 
    example, medical progress can reduce the future benefits estimated for 
    health, safety and environmental regulations, just as productivity 
    improvements in manufacturing reduce the costs of compliance of some 
    regulations. New drugs or medical procedures can reduce the benefits of 
    regulations aimed at reducing exposure to certain harmful agents such 
    as an infectious disease. Regulations aimed at increasing the energy 
    efficiency of consumer products or buildings may see their expected 
    benefits reduced by new technology that reduces the cost of producing 
    energy. Furthermore, productivity improvements lead directly to higher 
    incomes, which lead people to demand better health and more safety. 
    Business responds to these demands by providing safer products and 
    workplaces, even in the absence of regulation. Individuals with rising 
    incomes may also purchase or donate land to nature conservancies to 
    provide ecological benefits. Yet, as on the cost side, the baseline 
    that is used is almost always the status quo, rather than what is 
    likely to be true in the future.
        It is often difficult to attribute changes in behavior to specific 
    Federal regulations apart from the many other motivating factors. In 
    addition to overlapping Federal regulations, often from different 
    agencies, e.g., environmental issues may be regulated by the 
    Environmental Protection Agency (EPA), the Department of Agriculture 
    (USDA), the Department of Energy (DOE), the Department of the Interior 
    (DOI), the Department of Commerce (DOC) and the Department of 
    Transportation (DOT), state and local regulations also require 
    compliance. The tort system, voluntary standards organizations, and 
    public pressure also cause firms to provide a certain degree of public 
    protection in the absence of Federal regulation. As the General 
    Accounting Office (GAO) points out, determining how much of the costs 
    and benefits of these activities to attribute solely to Federal 
    regulation is a difficult undertaking (GAO 1996).
        Adding to the complexity, the degree to which these other factors 
    cause firms and other regulated entities to provide safe and healthful 
    products and workplaces and engage in environmentally sound practices 
    changes over time, generally increasing with increasing per capita 
    incomes and knowledge about cause and effect. Thus, although the 
    National Highway Traffic Safety Administration (NHTSA) has 
    significantly increased the safety of automobiles, it is not likely 
    that if the agency's regulations were eliminated the automobile 
    companies would discontinue all the safety features that have been 
    mandated. Consumers are demanding safer cars and automobile companies 
    are concerned about product liability. This same phenomenon is taking 
    place in the environmental area. Environmentally responsible behavior 
    is good for the bottom line. Over time, this ``rising baseline'' 
    phenomenon, if correct, should reduce the true costs and benefits of 
    health, safety, and environmental regulations. Estimates of the 
    aggregate costs and benefits of regulation that include unadjusted 
    estimates from aging studies are thus likely to overestimate the 
    current costs and benefits of those regulations.
        Yet another problem may be termed the ``apples and oranges 
    problem.'' The attempts to aggregate the total costs and benefits of 
    Federal regulations have simply added together a diverse set of 
    individual studies. Unfortunately, these individual studies vary in 
    quality, methodology, and type of regulatory costs included. In 
    addition to using different assumptions about baselines and time 
    periods problems discussed above, the studies use different discount 
    rates, different valuations for the same attribute, and different 
    concepts of costs and approaches to dealing with uncertainty, to 
    mention a few. Furthermore, the possibility of interaction effects 
    between the tens of thousands of regulations is not addressed.
        A final reason that any regulatory accounting effort has limits is 
    the lack of information on the effects of regulations on distribution 
    or equity. None of the analyses addressed in this report provides 
    quantitative information on the distribution of benefits or costs by 
    income category, geographic region, or any other equity-related factor. 
    As a result, there is no basis for quantifying distributional or equity 
    impacts.
    2. Types of Regulation
        Because there are so many different types of Federal regulations, 
    it is useful to break this heterogeneous body up into categories. As we 
    did last year we describe five commonly used categories.
        Environmental. The true social cost of regulations aimed at 
    improving the quality of the environment is represented by the total 
    value that society places on the goods and services foregone as a 
    result of resources being diverted to environmental protection.
    
    [[Page 44038]]
    
    (EPA's Cost of a Clean Environment, pp. 1-2, 1-3.) These social costs 
    include the direct compliance costs of the capital equipment and labor 
    needed to meet the standard, as well as the more indirect consumer and 
    producer surplus losses from lost or delayed consumption and production 
    opportunities due to the higher prices and reduced output needed to pay 
    for the direct compliance costs. In the case of a product ban or 
    prohibitive compliance costs, almost all of the costs represent 
    consumer and producer surplus losses. Most of the cost estimates used 
    in this report do not include consumer and producer surplus losses 
    because it is difficult and often impractical to estimate the demand 
    and supply curves needed to do this type of analysis.
        Further indirect effects on productivity and efficiency result from 
    price and output changes that spread through other sectors of the 
    economy. Estimates of compliance costs likely understate substantially 
    the true long-term costs of pollution control.5 The 
    estimates used in this report do not include these indirect and general 
    equilibrium effects.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \5\ See Jaffe, Peterson, Portney, and Stavins' survey (1995), p. 
    153.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The benefits of environmental protection are represented by the 
    value that society places on improved health, recreational 
    opportunities, quality of life, visibility, preservation of ecosystems, 
    biodiversity, and other attributes of protecting or enhancing our 
    environment. This value is best measured by society's willingness-to-
    pay (WTP) for these attributes. Because most types of improvement in 
    environmental quality are not traded in markets, benefits must be 
    estimated by indirect means using sophisticated statistical techniques 
    or ``contingent valuation'' survey methods that generally make benefit 
    estimation more problematic than cost estimation.
        Other Social. This category of regulation includes rules designed 
    to advance the health and safety of consumers and workers, as well as 
    regulations aimed at promoting social goals such as equal opportunity, 
    equal access to facilities, and protection from fraud and deception. 
    They are often lumped together with environmental regulation in the 
    category of ``Social Regulation.'' Social regulation is mainly 
    concerned with controlling or reducing the harmful or unintended 
    consequences of market transactions, such as air pollution, 
    occupationally induced illness, or automobile accidents. These 
    consequences are commonly called ``negative externalities'' and 
    regulation designed to deal with them attempts to ``internalize'' the 
    externalities. This can be done by regulating the amount of the 
    externality, e.g., banning a pollutant or limiting it to a ``safe'' 
    level, or regulating how a product is produced or used. Social 
    regulation may also require the disclosure of information about a 
    product, service, or manufacturing process where access to inadequate 
    or asymmetric information may place consumers, citizens, or workers at 
    a disadvantage. The techniques and methodological concerns involved in 
    the estimation of the social costs and benefits generated by these 
    rules are similar to those involved in the estimation of costs and 
    benefits of environmental regulation discussed above. In the results 
    that we report below, we further break ``Other Social'' into three 
    categories: transportation, labor and other regulations. The third 
    category includes food and drug safety, energy efficiency, and quality 
    of medical care regulations.
        Economic. Economic regulation restricts firms' primary economic 
    activities, e.g., their pricing and output decisions. It may also limit 
    the entry or exit of firms into or out of certain specific types of 
    businesses. Such regulations are usually applied on an industry wide 
    basis, e.g., agriculture, trucking, or communications. In the United 
    States, this type of regulation at the Federal level has often been 
    administered by ``independent'' commissions, e.g., the Federal 
    Communications Commission (FCC), the Securities and Exchange Commission 
    (SEC), or the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC), whose 
    members are appointed but not removable without good cause by the 
    President. The economic losses caused by this type of regulation result 
    from the higher prices and inefficient operations that often occur when 
    competition is prevented from developing.
        The costs of such regulation are usually measured by modeling or 
    comparing specific regulated sectors with less regulated sectors, 
    estimating the consumer and producer surplus losses that result from 
    higher prices and lack of service, and estimating the excess costs that 
    may result from the lack of competition. In contrast to social 
    regulatory cost estimates, these are estimates of mainly indirect 
    costs.
        Economic regulation may produce social benefits when natural 
    monopolies are regulated to simulate competition. Although Hahn and 
    Hird (1991) argue that the dollar amount of such efficiency benefits 
    are small in a dynamic and technologically vibrant economy, their 
    judgment is an educated guess based on a reading of recent history, 
    rather than the result of an empirical study. It appears to be based 
    largely on the widely accepted view that the U.S. economy has become 
    more competitive over time, with fewer long-lasting natural monopolies, 
    and on the observation that much of the motivation for economic 
    regulation is to enhance one group at the expense of another. But even 
    though monopoly power may not be long lasting in a dynamic U.S. 
    economy, it does exist at a given point in time.6
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \6\ We are not including antitrust activities such as preventing 
    the formation of monopolies through mergers or anticompetitive 
    behavior in our definition of economic regulation. Clearly this type 
    of Government policy creates important social benefits.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Moreover, while Hahn and Hird (1991) define economic regulation as 
    including only regulation of entry, output, and prices, in practice 
    they appear to lump all Federal regulation of banking and other 
    financial institutions, as well as consumer protection regulation 
    through mandated disclosure requirements, into the ``economic 
    regulation'' category of their cost estimates. In our view, chartering, 
    branching, interest rate, and activity regulation are the only major 
    categories of banking regulation that conform to the definition of 
    economic regulation used here. The other categories are ``safety-and-
    soundness'' regulation and ``consumer information and protection'' 
    regulation, both of which fit more logically into the ``other social 
    regulations'' category used in this study (White 1991, pp. 32-33). 
    Consideration of this definitional issue is important because the type 
    and magnitude of benefits associated with the different categories of 
    banking regulation differ greatly. In particular, while costs may 
    exceed benefits for some types of economic regulation (entry, output, 
    and prices), safety-and-soundness regulation is essential to a well 
    functioning financial system and thus fully justifies the cost (White 
    1991), and the consumer protection regulation applicable to banking is 
    similar to consumer protection information for other industries where 
    there is general agreement that the benefits exceed the costs.
        Transfer. As discussed in OMB's Best Practices document, transfers 
    are payments from one group in society to another and, therefore, are 
    not real net costs to society as a whole. Nonetheless, the consequences 
    for individuals can be very significant. One person's loss is another 
    person's gain. Examples of transfers include payments to Social
    
    [[Page 44039]]
    
    Security recipients from taxpayers and the higher profits that farmers 
    receive as a result of the higher prices consumers must pay for farm 
    products limited by production quotas. Our guidance document states 
    that transfers should not be added to the cost and benefit totals 
    included in regulatory assessments but should be discussed and noted 
    for policy makers.
        Process. Process costs are the administrative or paperwork costs of 
    filling out Government forms such as income tax, immigration, social 
    security, procurement, etc. The majority of process costs is due to 
    program administration, Government procurement, and tax compliance, 
    which do not fall into either the social or economic regulatory 
    categories. Some of these, such as procurement costs, are reflected in 
    the Federal budget as greater fiscal expenditures and care must be 
    taken not to count them twice. Process costs can be viewed as part of 
    the costs of providing Government services or collecting revenues that 
    should be minimized for a given level or quality of service or revenue. 
    We break these types of costs into further categories and discuss their 
    effects in more detail below.
    
    B. New Estimate of the Costs and Benefits of Existing Social 
    Regulations
    
        Several commentators on last year's report called for more detail 
    on the costs and benefits of regulatory programs. It is important to 
    note that, as was the case last year, this section includes only 
    estimates of costs and benefits that have been quantified and 
    monetized. As we discuss elsewhere in this report, the fact that an 
    effect has not been monetized or quantified does not necessarily mean 
    that it is small or unimportant.
        Last year we broke out costs and benefits of existing social 
    regulations into two categories: environmental and other social (OMB 
    1997, table 1). This year we have been able to further subdivide other 
    social into three categories: labor, transportation, and other social 
    regulation, mainly regulations from HHS, DOE, and USDA. We were able to 
    do this by further utilization of the results of the 1991 article by 
    Hahn and Hird and the 1996 book by Hahn as well as the Cost of a Clean 
    Environment report (EPA 1990), and by making new estimates of the costs 
    and benefits of regulations issued over the last three years (April 1, 
    1995 to March 31, 1998), which we derive in chapter III using data from 
    the Regulatory Impact Analyses submitted by the agencies to OMB under 
    E.O. 12866. We have also incorporated EPA's recently published report, 
    The Benefits and Costs of the Clean Air Act, 1970-1990 (EPA 1997), 
    hereafter referred to as the ``Section 812 Retrospective.'' In 
    addition, we examined data submitted to GAO by the independent agencies 
    over the last two years under the Congressional Review Act for major 
    rules. In order to estimate aggregate regulatory costs and benefits, we 
    combine three data sources covering three time periods--pre-1988, 1988 
    to 1994, and 1995 to 1998.
        Since Hahn and Hird provide cost and benefit estimates for more 
    than two categories of social regulations, we were able to expand our 
    estimate detail from two categories last year to four this year. We 
    were limited to four categories because the cost data we relied upon to 
    fill the gap between the 1988 Hahn and Hird data and our cost and 
    benefit estimates starting in 1995, (from the 1996 OMB report, More 
    Benefits, Fewer Burdens) contain only the four categories listed above. 
    We also use additional information on the distribution of benefits that 
    we did not use last year. Last year we used Hahn and Hird's conclusion 
    that ``the net benefits of social regulation are positive but small'' 
    (p. 253) to estimate that the costs and benefits of both environmental 
    and other social regulations were approximately equal. They came to 
    this conclusion by taking the midpoint of their ranges for costs and 
    benefits. However, as we pointed out last year, there is much 
    uncertainty associated with these estimates. Moreover, we were 
    criticized for presenting point estimates when ranges would have been 
    more appropriate (Hahn 1998). This year we have elected to present 
    ranges both for the base case and later for our estimates of the costs 
    and benefits of the regulations that have been issued since the base 
    period. Table 1 shows these cost and benefit estimates derived from 
    Hahn and Hird for the four regulatory program areas as of 
    1988.7 Table 1 also includes new estimates from the Section 
    812 Retrospective.8
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \7\ We do not repeat the discussion of the derivation and the 
    qualifications of these estimates that appeared in last year's 
    report. We refer the reader to that discussion (OMB 1997 pp. 27-33) 
    for this information. Suffice it to say here that we realize, as 
    several commenters have pointed out, that there are gaps and 
    weaknesses in underlying studies that Hahn and Hird rely on for 
    their estimates and that not all the costs and benefits of social 
    regulation are captured in these estimates. We hope in future years 
    to fill in the gaps and use more accurate, up-to-date studies for 
    our estimates when such studies become available.
        \8\ Table 1 (and all succeeding tables mentioned in the text) 
    can be found in sequential order at the end of this report.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The addition of the Section 812 Retrospective significantly changes 
    the upper bound benefit estimate for environmental regulation, i.e., 
    more than 15 times the upper bound of the Hahn and Hird study. As we 
    outlined at the beginning of this chapter, there are a number of 
    critical estimation problems that must be confronted in developing 
    benefit and cost estimates. The available studies, such as the Hahn and 
    Hird study and the Section 812 Retrospective, also have had to confront 
    these problems and each study has had to make difficult choices. As a 
    result, there are advantages and disadvantages that attend each of 
    these studies. The EPA estimates of $378 million to $3.2 trillion per 
    year are substantially larger than the estimates presented by Hahn and 
    Hird. The Hahn and Hird estimates were based on a 1982 study by Freeman 
    that provided a synthesis of the available benefits literature. These 
    estimates do not reflect the benefits associated with Clean Air Act 
    initiatives in the 1980s, e.g., EPA's lead phasedown program. They also 
    do not reflect the recent literature suggesting an association between 
    exposure to fine particulate matter and premature mortality. In 
    addition, the 1982 Freeman estimates were based on actual air quality 
    improvements over the 1970s, i.e., they did not attempt to account for 
    the benefits associated with preventing degradation in air quality.
        The Section 812 Retrospective estimates were developed through an 
    EPA Science Advisory Board peer review process. It presents a more 
    comprehensive set of the benefits and costs under the Clean Air Act 
    over the period from 1970 to 1990; for example, it includes regulatory 
    actions taken during the 1980s. In addition, these estimates also 
    include the benefits and costs of preventing any deterioration in air 
    quality and reflect the benefits and costs of all air pollution control 
    efforts, not just the Federal Clean Air Act. Our detailed discussion in 
    section D below presents a more complete description of the Section 812 
    Retrospective and identifies some key uncertainties and assumptions 
    underlying the benefit estimates that may have an important effect on 
    the magnitude of these estimates.
        To get the costs of existing regulations as of 1997, last year's 
    report added to the 1988 base the costs of the major regulations 
    reviewed by OMB between 1987 and 1996 as estimated from the RIAs 
    agencies provided OMB under Executive Order 12866 and its predecessor 
    Executive Order 12291 (OMB 1996). To estimate benefits, last year we 
    used benefit/cost ratios for environmental and other social regulation 
    calculated from Hahn (1996), who estimated benefits and costs of
    
    [[Page 44040]]
    
    agency rules from 1990 to mid-1995, for a subset of our rules, to 
    estimate benefits that correspond to our rules. We then added that 
    total to the benefit estimate as of 1988 from Hahn and Hird. This year 
    we improve on that exercise by using benefit/cost ratios from Hahn 
    (1996) for environmental, transportation, labor, and other social 
    regulation to estimate benefits for rules issued between 1987 and 
    1995.9 For the rules issued from 1995 through the first 
    quarter of 1998, we used information from agency-supplied RIAs modified 
    for consistency with Best Practices as appropriate and extended to 
    provide more monetized estimates of benefits and costs using consensus 
    value estimates used by the agencies or found in the literature. These 
    calculations are shown and explained in chapter III. Our latest 
    estimates are shown in table 2.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \9\ Admittedly this is a crude estimation procedure because 
    Hahn's inventory of rules begins in 1990 and ours extends back to 
    1987. Consequently, we are assuming that the relationship between 
    costs and benefits that Hahn found for the later period extends back 
    three years. Still, we know of no other approach to fill this gap in 
    the data until RIAs for these years are re-examined.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Table 3 combines the results from tables 1 and 2 to present our new 
    estimates for the existing costs of social regulation as of the first 
    quarter in 1998. It shows that health, safety and environmental 
    regulation produces between $34 and $3.38 trillion of net benefits per 
    year.
        We must underline the uncertainty of these estimates. They are 
    useful primarily for drawing general conclusions about categories of 
    regulations that should be corroborated by additional data and 
    analysis. As specific values, however, they are fraught with 
    uncertainties. As discussed above, the baseline, apples and oranges, 
    and other methodological problems significantly reduce the likelihood 
    that these findings are robust. In addition to these problems, we are 
    also concerned that as the aggregate categories are divided into 
    smaller parts, the accuracy of the estimates may weaken because it is 
    less likely that randomly distributed errors in the data and analysis 
    even out. Furthermore, one must be doubly careful about drawing 
    conclusions from these results because these estimates are average 
    benefits and costs for aggregates of existing regulations, not the 
    incremental costs and benefits that are required to be able to make 
    reliable recommendations to improve specific regulatory programs or 
    regulations. Also note that these estimates are a combination of the 
    1988 baseline estimates, which are mostly from retrospective studies, 
    and the 1988 to 1998 estimates that are from the prospective studies 
    for individual rules. How well the cost and benefit estimates of 
    prospective studies predict actual costs and benefits is a question 
    that has not been answered. In section D of this chapter, we review the 
    evidence from several case studies that might shed light on this 
    question. Where we can make direct comparisons between prospective and 
    retrospective analyses, we find that both costs and benefits were 
    sometimes overestimated by prospective studies. In other instances, 
    costs were underestimated.
        Finally regarding the utility of these estimates for making 
    recommendations for changes in regulatory programs, it bears repeating 
    that the actual costs and benefits of a regulation or regulatory 
    program are not the appropriate calculation. Rather, before a 
    recommendation is made to repeal or modify a regulation or regulatory 
    program, the necessary question is: ``What would be the incremental 
    costs and benefits of repealing the regulation or regulatory program.''
    
    C. Other Regulatory Impacts
    
        Despite the weaknesses in the estimates of the costs and benefits 
    of social regulation, the estimates of the costs and especially the 
    benefits of the other types of regulation are even more problematic. In 
    last year's report, we made the assumption that the costs and benefits 
    of fundamentally different types of regulations and government policies 
    could be aggregated and displayed in one table, with caveats. In doing 
    this, however, we were adding regulatory programs together that had 
    quantified costs and unquantified benefits with regulatory programs 
    that had quantified costs and quantified benefits. We also added 
    together the direct compliance costs of social regulation with the 
    indirect, mostly consumer surplus, losses of economic regulation. 
    However, direct compliance costs may have significantly different long 
    run effects than indirect consumer surplus losses. We have concluded 
    this year that such totals are more misleading than helpful, even with 
    extensive explanation of the absent benefit estimates and the apples 
    and oranges and other problems. To prevent confusion, this year we are 
    presenting the estimates separately in table 4.
        Table 4 presents a list of the other types of regulation or 
    regulatory-like activities. In some cases we do not agree that these 
    activities are true regulations or should be considered in the same 
    category with what we have classified as social regulation. However, 
    this wide range of activities was noted by several commenters who urged 
    us to include them in this year's report. Table 4 also lists costs and 
    benefits, and is followed by a discussion of each.
    1. Efficiency Losses From Economic Regulation
        In last year's report, we presented an estimate that the efficiency 
    costs of economic, i.e., price and entry, regulation amounted to about 
    $71 billion. This is based on an estimate by Hopkins (1992) of $81 
    billion, which we adjusted downward by $10 billion to account for the 
    deregulation and increase in competition that has occurred in the 
    financial and telecommunications sectors since Hopkins' estimates were 
    made in 1992. Our estimate has recently been corroborated by analysis 
    in a recent, comprehensive two volume Organization for Economic 
    Cooperation and Development (OECD) report, OECD Report on Regulatory 
    Reform (OECD 1997), which attempts to estimate the benefits of further 
    economic deregulation of five sectors of the economy (electricity, 
    airlines, trucking, telecommunications, and retail and wholesale 
    distribution) for five countries (the U.S., Japan, Germany, France, and 
    the U.K.). Adding up any remaining benefits from deregulating these 
    sectors and using a macroeconomic model to simulate the economy-wide 
    effects on GDP, the OECD estimated that U.S. GDP would increase by 0.9 
    percent from these actions. This estimate implies that the current 
    costs of regulation in these sectors is $68 billion (0.9 percent of 
    1996's GDP of $7.6 trillion). Although the two estimates are not 
    strictly comparable, because our estimate of $71 billion includes 
    import restrictions and the OECD estimate does not and our estimate is 
    only for Federal regulation and the OECD estimate includes State and 
    local as well as National, the two estimates are close enough to be 
    mutually supportive.
        There appear to be no reliable quantified estimates of the total 
    benefits of economic regulation. We pointed out last year that price 
    regulation of natural monopolies does have the potential to provide 
    consumer surplus benefits. However, most economists believe that few 
    natural monopolies, except perhaps in local distribution markets, have 
    long staying power because of the globalization of markets and rapidly 
    changing technology. Over time both the benefits and costs of 
    regulation (assuming regulation does not change) are eroded by changes 
    in technology and adaptive behavior, i.e., the rising baseline 
    phenomenon discussed above.
    
    [[Page 44041]]
    
    The static welfare benefits of economic regulation are not likely to be 
    long lasting in a dynamic world. The OECD report also implies that few 
    benefits are produced by sectoral entry restrictions. The report points 
    out that the loss of universal service may be a concern, but states 
    that methods besides regulation, e.g., targeted subsidies, can be 
    adopted to provide services to worthy entities less able to pay full 
    costs. In table 4 we enter under the benefits of economic regulation 
    the term ``expected to be small.''
        Last year, we received comments from several independent economic 
    regulatory agencies suggesting that we had not emphasized the potential 
    benefits of economic regulation enough. The comments made good points. 
    Economic regulatory agencies are producing significant benefits. 
    However, these benefits do not flow from their imposing new 
    restrictions on entry. Rather, the benefits stem from their efforts to 
    open up markets and promote competition, which often means preempting 
    State competition or correcting past mistakes. In other words, some 
    agencies view the reduced costs created by deregulating as a benefit of 
    regulation. The correct view is determined by the baseline. Is the 
    baseline the existing patchwork of State and Federal regulation, which 
    has produced artificially constructed telecommunications and financial 
    services firms, or the more competitive environment that most likely 
    would have existed if we had not had these restrictions? There is no 
    inconsistency in saying that economic regulation has produced few 
    significant benefits, as Hahn and Hird (1992) state in summarizing the 
    consensus view of economists on this subject, and saying that economic 
    regulatory agencies are currently providing important benefits to 
    society by promoting competition.
        The OECD study points out the important role that regulators have 
    in smoothing the transition toward a more competitive environment. 
    Regulators must carefully consider the issues of stranded capital 
    costs, unemployment, and universal service as competition is 
    introduced. However, the long run benefits of reform appear to have 
    been worth the transitional costs. The OECD study points out that the 
    US's regulatory reform efforts have already produced major benefits, 
    especially compared to the other major industrial countries. The study 
    estimates that the average GDP gain for the other seven countries from 
    deregulation of the five sectors would be 4.7 percent, ranging from 3.5 
    percent for the U.K. to 5.6 percent for Japan. The 4.7 percent of GDP 
    estimate would be equivalent to $360 billion if applied to U.S. GDP. 
    The study also points out that a significant portion of the 0.9 percent 
    remaining benefits for the U.S. is likely to be achieved by regulatory 
    reform efforts already underway because of the Telecommunications Act 
    of 1996 and the early State efforts at electricity restructuring. 
    Clearly economic deregulation does not imply that the economic 
    regulatory agencies' jobs are done.
    2. Disclosure Regulation
        A second type of regulation often mixed in with economic regulation 
    is information disclosure. There is a strong consensus among economists 
    that regulations requiring the disclosure of information about the 
    price and quality of products and services can produce significant 
    benefits for consumers and improve the functioning of markets when this 
    information would not otherwise be available. Our estimate, based on 
    burden-hour calculations for the independent regulatory agencies, e.g., 
    SEC, FCC, FTC, reported in OMB's Information Collection Budget for FY 
    1998 (272 million hours) and Hopkins' opportunity costs of time 
    estimate ($26.50 per hour), is that disclosure costs are about $7 
    billion. Although benefits have not been quantified, we expect that 
    they are significantly greater than $7 billion.
    3. Transfers From Economic Regulation
        Economic regulation often produces income transfers from one group 
    to another. These transfers are not social costs or benefits; they 
    neither create new net benefits for society nor reduce society's scarce 
    resources. Consequently benefit-cost analysis is not appropriate or 
    meaningful for evaluating transfer programs. As the Best Practices 
    document makes clear, distributional analysis, which should be part of 
    the economic assessment, is the proper method of analyzing transfers. 
    Table 4 includes an estimate for transfers based on the Hopkins 
    approach that assumes that the transfers created by economic regulation 
    are about twice the economic efficiency loss. The estimate is $140 
    billion (two times $70 billion), which we enter in both the costs and 
    benefits columns.
        Although as one commenter pointed out (Hopkins 1997), transfers may 
    be associated with real lobbying costs, this fact of life does not 
    justify equating transfer costs with social costs. Lobbying goes on for 
    all sorts of Government policies including expenditure, tax, and 
    regulatory policies whether they exist or not, which are impossible to 
    measure separately. For example, lobbying goes on in an attempt to 
    impose regulations that do not now exist and therefore have no 
    efficiency costs. In this case, the multiple of two times the 
    efficiency loss would estimate social costs of zero. The best approach 
    to including these types of costs is by directly estimating the costs 
    of lobbying rather than using a multiple of economic efficiency losses. 
    Once that is done it is not clear how to evaluate the social benefits 
    of lobbying, which clearly produces benefits because at least some 
    amount of lobbying, i.e., citizen participation, is a necessary part of 
    a democratic government.
    4. Tax Compliance
        Last year we stopped short of including tax compliance costs and 
    transfer costs in the totals. Although we were criticized for that 
    (Hopkins 1997 and Dudley and Antonelli 1997), other commenters (Hahn 
    1998) agreed with us that such data should be reported, but not 
    included in the totals. As we pointed out in last year's report, a 
    major reason for not including tax compliance costs in our totals, 
    despite their real nature and obvious concern to the public, is that it 
    would be misleading to add these types of costs to the totals without 
    accounting for the fact that taxes are necessary for the basic 
    functions of government. Cost-effectiveness analysis, not benefit-cost 
    analysis, is the appropriate way to evaluate the efficiency of tax 
    policy. In Table 4, we present an estimate of the paperwork costs of 
    the tax code by multiplying the number of hours of tax preparation time 
    required to file tax forms (5.3 billion in FY 1997) according to OMB's 
    Information Collection Budget (OMB 1998) by an estimate of the 
    opportunity costs of the average hour spent on the forms ($26.50) based 
    on Hopkins (1991). That cost estimate is $140 billion. While we do not 
    have quantitative estimates of the aggregate benefits of tax 
    compliance, they are undoubtedly very large. Tax compliance is 
    necessary for the whole range of services the government provides.
    5. Federal Budgetary Expenditures
        Several comments also suggested that we report the Federal 
    budgetary costs of regulation. These Federal expenditures include the 
    costs of developing and issuing regulations and enforcing them once 
    they are on the books. For many years, the Center for the Study of 
    American Business at Washington University has compiled Federal 
    Expenditures for the Regulatory Agencies of the U.S. Government. 
    Douglas, Orlando, and Warren (1997) have produced the latest estimates.
    
    [[Page 44042]]
    
    Table 4 presents these estimates for both social and economic 
    regulation.10 For benefits, we reproduce the quantified 
    estimate of the net benefits for social regulation as shown above in 
    table 3 and summarize the earlier discussion of qualitative benefits of 
    economic regulation.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \10\ Note that they do not consider the Internal Revenue Service 
    to be a regulatory agency and therefore do not include it in their 
    estimates. Their approach is consistent with ours and inconsistent 
    with Hopkins (1997).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    6. Welfare Effects
        A final category of regulatory effects, which several commenters 
    suggested we include in our estimates, is the indirect or full welfare 
    impacts of regulation. The estimates presented above for social 
    regulation are mostly estimates of direct compliance costs. However, as 
    our Best Practices document points out, the proper concept of the cost 
    of regulation is the best estimate of the value of the opportunity 
    foregone as a result of the imposition of the regulation. The 
    opportunity costs are likely to be greater than direct compliance 
    costs. In addition to the consumer surplus losses that result when 
    compliance costs drive up prices and reduce consumption of the goods 
    and services produced by the regulated entity, there may be secondary 
    effects on other markets, which reduce consumer welfare. The effects 
    result because regulation increases the overall costs of consumption 
    relative to output and reduces investment and productivity. These 
    effects can only be estimated with a computable general equilibrium 
    model that traces the myriad interrelationships that make up the modern 
    economy. Unfortunately the results of these models are highly dependent 
    on model specifications, which are not transparent to outside reviewers 
    making it difficult to determine the reasonableness of model 
    estimates.11
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \11\ See Hahn and Hird, pp. 244-246, for a discussion of these 
    problems and several others.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The two most well known models that have been used to estimate the 
    general equilibrium effects apply to environmental regulation. These 
    models find that by 1990 the social welfare effects were about twice 
    the direct compliance cost effects (Hazilla and Kopp 1990 and Jorgenson 
    and Wilcoxen 1990). In table 4 we present this estimate for 
    environmental regulation but not for workplace and product regulation. 
    The reasons are that the estimates were made for environmental 
    regulation and there is no theoretical reason why the effect should be 
    the same for the two types of regulation. This is because the benefits 
    of environmental regulation generally flow to third parties not 
    involved in the production of the regulated product, while the benefits 
    of workplace health and safety regulation and product safety and 
    energy-efficiency regulations mostly flow to parties that are part of 
    the transaction (workers and consumers of the product). This factor 
    causes the costs to the regulated firms to be less than the direct 
    compliance costs because firms will likely eventually reap at least a 
    portion of the benefits of the regulation through lower employee costs 
    for workplace regulation and higher product quality for product safety 
    and energy-efficiency regulation. If the actual costs of compliance to 
    firms are less than the estimated direct compliance costs, the general 
    equilibrium effects will also likely be smaller.
        The general equilibrium or secondary effects of the regulation on 
    the benefit side are less well understood than they are for the cost 
    side. But as discussed in last year's report, the health and safety 
    benefits of regulation, in particular, should result in indirect 
    welfare benefits for the economy. Because a healthier and longer-living 
    population is likely to have a longer time horizon and more optimistic 
    outlook, it is also likely to work more years more productively and 
    save and invest more. These effects could very well expand economic 
    activity and increase the standard of living significantly, especially 
    in the long run.
    
    D. Lessons Learned from Studies of Federal Regulation
    
        A review of several studies of the costs and benefits of regulation 
    offers insights into both the actual effects of regulations and into 
    the problems that attend any estimation of their benefits and costs. 
    Below we discuss the two key studies underlying our estimate of the 
    aggregate benefits and costs of environmental regulation and a new 
    study by Robert Hahn of 106 regulations using prospective estimates of 
    costs and benefits published by the agencies at the time the final 
    rules were issued (Hahn forthcoming). We also review two additional 
    retrospective studies that compare the actual and predicted costs and 
    benefits of regulation.
        First, as noted earlier, EPA recently published its Section 812 
    Retrospective study of the costs and benefits of the Clean Air Act, as 
    required by section 812 of the Clean Air Act of 1990. It estimated that 
    the present value of benefits of the Clean Air Act regulations issued 
    between 1970 and 1990 is $22.2 trillion (central estimate, 1990$). 
    Publication of the Section 812 Retrospective provides an opportunity to 
    compare it with the Hahn and Hird study, which served as the basis for 
    our estimates in last year's report.
        Hahn's study expands on his earlier one, which we used in section 2 
    in our aggregate estimate to cover the years 1987 to 1994 (Hahn 1996). 
    The 106 final regulations with both costs and benefits in the new study 
    were issued between 1982 and mid-1996 by EPA, OSHA, NHTSA, HHS, HUD, 
    and USDA. Hahn uses consensus estimates to value reduced units of 
    pollution and increased life-years to calculate benefits of health, 
    safety and environmental regulation. He takes as given the quantity 
    estimates of benefits and the monetized estimates of costs found in the 
    agency-produced regulatory impact analyses. He also converted to 
    constant 1995 dollars and used a 5 percent discount rate to put costs 
    and benefits in a consistent present value framework. Hahn estimated 
    that the net present value of benefits of the 106 regulations is about 
    $1.6 trillion. However, he also found that not all agency rules 
    provided net benefits. In fact, less than half of all final rules 
    provided benefits greater than costs. The main reason for his large 
    estimate of net benefits and relatively poor performance for many 
    individual regulations was that a few rules provided most of the net 
    benefits. NHTSA's automatic restraints in cars and EPA's lead phasedown 
    in gasoline provided just over 70 percent of total net benefits (Hahn 
    forthcoming, p. 15).
    1. EPA's Retrospective Report to Congress on the Benefits and Costs of 
    the Clean Air Act
        EPA's Section 812 Retrospective represents the culmination of a 
    six-year effort by EPA. The Section 812 Retrospective also reflects, as 
    required by section 812, peer review by an independent, external panel 
    of economists, health scientists, and environmental scientists known as 
    the Science Advisory Board Council on Clean Air Act Compliance Analysis 
    (Council). The Council provided detailed review and guidance throughout 
    each step of study design, implementation, and report drafting. The 
    quality and reliability of the Section 812 Retrospective was addressed 
    by the Council in its review closure letter by stating that the Council 
    ``finds that the Retrospective Study Report to Congress by the Agency 
    is a serious, careful study and employs sound methods along with the 
    best data available.'' 12 The Council further concluded that 
    the Section 812
    
    [[Page 44043]]
    
    Retrospective's findings are ``consistent with the weight of available 
    evidence.'' 13
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \12\ SAB Council, letter to EPA Administrator Browner, July 8, 
    1997, p. 1.
        \13\ Ibid.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Section 812 Retrospective presents estimates of monetized 
    benefits ranging from $6 to $50 trillion (present value in 1990$) over 
    the period from 1970 through 1990, with a central estimate of $22 
    trillion. Over this same period, the Section 812 Retrospective 
    estimated direct compliance expenditures of roughly $0.5 trillion. The 
    estimated net monetized benefits for the 1970 to 1990 period range from 
    $5.1 to $48.9 trillion dollars, with a central estimate of $21.7 
    trillion. The Section 812 Retrospective also notes that the monetized 
    benefits estimate may understate benefits because a number of benefit 
    categories were not quantified and/or monetized, e.g., air toxics 
    effects and ecosystem effects. Table 5 presents the non-monetized 
    benefits listed by the Section 812 Retrospective.
        While the findings of the Section 812 Retrospective suggest that 
    the aggregate historical benefits of the clean air regulatory programs 
    substantially exceed the aggregate costs, the Section 812 Retrospective 
    itself provides the following cautionary note on page ES-10:
    
        Finally, the results of the retrospective study provide useful 
    lessons with respect to the value and limitations of cost-benefit 
    analysis as a tool for evaluating environmental programs. Cost-
    benefit analysis can provide a valuable framework for organizing and 
    evaluating information on the effects of environmental programs. 
    When used properly, cost-benefit analysis can help illuminate 
    important effects of changes in policy and can help set priorities 
    for closing information gaps and reducing uncertainty. Such proper 
    use, however, requires that sufficient levels of time and resources 
    be provided to permit careful, thorough, and technically and 
    scientifically sound data-gathering and analysis. When cost-benefit 
    analyses are presented without effective characterization of the 
    uncertainties associated with the results, cost-benefit studies can 
    be used in highly misleading and damaging ways. Given the 
    substantial uncertainties which permeate cost-benefit assessment of 
    environmental programs, as demonstrated by the broad range of 
    estimated benefits presented in this study, cost-benefit analysis is 
    best used to inform, but not dictate, decisions related to 
    environmental protection policies, programs, and research.
    
        In terms of our charge under section 625(a), we must also consider 
    these new benefit and cost estimates in developing an overall estimate 
    of the benefits and costs of Federal regulation. The magnitude of EPA's 
    benefit estimate, $22 trillion over the 1970 to 1990 period, is very 
    large. The expected value of the estimated monetized benefit for 1990 
    is $1.25 trillion per year. This represents approximately 20 percent of 
    total 1990 Gross Domestic Product and is comparable in magnitude to 
    total 1990 U.S. expenditures on nondurable goods. There are several 
    important elements of the analysis in the Section 812 Retrospective 
    which deserve further discussion in order to understand the basis for 
    the benefit estimates over the 1970 to 1990 period.14
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \14\ ``A final, brief interagency review, pursuant to Circular 
    A-19, was organized in August 1997 by the Office of Management and 
    Budget and conducted following the completion of the extensive 
    expert panel peer review by the SAB Council. During the course of 
    the final interagency discussions, it became clear that several 
    agencies held different views pertaining to several key assumptions 
    in this study as well as to the best techniques to apply in the 
    context of environmental program benefit-cost analyses, including 
    the present study. These concerns include: (1) The extent to which 
    air quality would have deteriorated from 1970 to 1990 in the absence 
    of the Clean Air Act, (2) the methods used to estimate the number of 
    premature deaths and illnesses avoided due to the CAA, (3) the 
    methods used to estimate the value individuals place on avoiding 
    those risks, and (4) the methods used to value non-health related 
    benefits. However, due to the court deadline the resulting concerns 
    were not resolved during this final, brief interagency review. 
    Therefore, this report reflects the findings of EPA and not 
    necessarily other agencies in the Administration.'' See Section 812 
    Retrospective, p. ES-2.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        (a) Establishing a baseline. The Section 812 Retrospective uses as 
    a counter-factual ``baseline'' the modeled air quality in the United 
    States over the 1970 to 1990 period for a scenario in which control 
    technology and requirements are frozen at the levels mandated in 1970. 
    It assumed that no additional air pollution controls would have been 
    imposed by any other level of government or voluntarily initiated by 
    private entities after 1970. The Section 812 Retrospective acknowledges 
    that this is an obvious oversimplification and that, in fact, State and 
    local governments as well as private initiatives were responsible for 
    an important fraction of the estimated benefits and costs over the 
    period from 1970 to 1990.15 At the same time, it notes that 
    the Federal CAA played an essential role in achieving these results and 
    leaves to others the question of parsing out the precise fraction of 
    costs and benefits attributable to the Federal CAA.16
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \15\ Section 812 Retrospective, pp. 2-3.
        \16\ Ibid, p. 3.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Because the modeled baseline includes significant growth in 
    population, car and truck travel, and economic activity, there is a 
    marked deterioration in baseline air quality over the period from 1970 
    to 1990. While there is no direct sensitivity analysis of alternative 
    baselines, the available documentation for the ``no control'' scenario 
    suggests that a substantial fraction of the estimated benefits are 
    attributable to the degradation in modeled air quality from 1970 
    levels, rather than the result of an improvement in air quality from 
    the levels that existed in the United States in 1970.17
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \17\ Of course, any change in the baseline scenario would also 
    require revision of the cost estimates. The Section 812 
    Retrospective specifically notes that the ``no control'' scenario 
    avoids the difficulties of sorting out the fraction of costs 
    required to maintain an alternative baseline, such as maintaining 
    air quality at 1970 levels. See Section 812 Retrospective, pp. 2-3.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In any event, considerable uncertainty necessarily surrounds ``what 
    would have happened'' over this 20-year period, rendering all attempts 
    to construct aggregate benefit and cost estimates somewhat speculative.
        (b) Key benefit categories. The Section 812 Retrospective developed 
    monetized benefit estimates for ten benefit categories, including 
    mortality, hospital admissions, chronic bronchitis, soiling damage, and 
    visibility. (See table 6.) As indicated by table 6, the monetized 
    benefit estimates associated with reducing exposure to fine particulate 
    matter (PM) account for 90 percent of the total estimated benefits. The 
    discussion below discusses three key elements in developing benefit 
    estimates associated with reductions in PM levels.
        (i) Uncertainties in magnitude and causation. The Section 812 
    Retrospective describes some elements of the uncertainty in the 
    estimates of health risks, focusing on those elements of uncertainty 
    that are most readily quantifiable. For example, it addresses specific, 
    quantifiable elements of the uncertainty in the benefits estimates 
    through the use of a ``Monte Carlo'' analysis. It also presents a 
    thoughtful, qualitative discussion of some of the uncertainties 
    associated with the estimated mortality risk--for example, the effect 
    of an historical trend in particulate matter levels and the effect of 
    intercity movement of population on the concentration-response 
    relationship.
        The Section 812 Retrospective offers little discussion, however, of 
    the uncertainty associated with the critical question of the causal 
    relationship between fine particulate matter levels and mortality. It 
    observes that the Clean Air Scientific Advisory Committee has pointed 
    out that a causal mechanism has not been clearly established. It 
    concludes that ``the well-established correlation between exposure to 
    elevated PM and premature mortality is sufficiently compelling to 
    warrant an
    
    [[Page 44044]]
    
    assumption of a causal relationship and derivation of quantitative 
    estimates of a PM-related mortality.'' 18
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \18\ Ibid., p. 34.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The preamble to EPA's 1996 proposal to revise the National Ambient 
    Air Quality Standard for Particulate Matter (PM NAAQS) discusses at 
    greater length the difficulties associated with the interpretation of 
    specific concentration-response relationships, pointing out that it is 
    the most problematic issue in conducting risk assessments for PM-
    associated health effects. These include: 19
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \19\ 61 FR 65650. The preamble to the final rule reaffirms these 
    concerns by citing the proposal and a more complete discussion in 
    the criteria document (chapters 10-13) and the staff paper (chapter 
    IV). See 62 FR 38655 and 38656.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        (1) The absence of clear evidence regarding mechanisms of action 
    for the various health effects of interest;
        (2) Uncertainties about the shape of the concentration-response 
    relationships; and
        (3) Concern about whether the use of ambient PM2.5 and 
    ambient PM10 fixed-site monitoring data adequately reflects 
    the relevant population exposures to PM that are responsible for the 
    reported health effects.
        (ii) Timing of effects. The Section 812 Retrospective assumed that 
    reductions in ambient PM concentrations yield contemporaneous 
    reductions in the mortality and chronic health risks associated with 
    long-term exposure. Given that the concentration-response relationships 
    in the underlying study are presumptively thought to be the result of 
    long-term exposure, the assumption of a contemporaneous response--that 
    is, a zero lag in the response--represents only one end in a range of 
    possibilities. It is quite possible, however, that there is a lag in 
    the changes in the risk of chronic health effects and mortality with 
    changes in exposure to particulate matter. Other researchers (World 
    Health Organization, 1996) have assumed the effect of particulate 
    matter exposure does not begin until 15 years of exposure.20 
    The incorporation of a latency period can have an important effect on 
    the benefits estimate. The adoption of an alternative latency 
    assumption of 15 years, for example, would reduce the estimated present 
    value of the mortality benefits by a factor of two, given the discount 
    rate of five percent used in the Section 812 Retrospective.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \20\ Section 812 retrospective, p. D-17.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        (iii) Valuation of changes in health risk (``benefits transfer''). 
    The Section 812 Retrospective also highlights the difficulties of 
    transferring estimates from other settings to value the projected 
    benefits of a regulatory initiative, e.g., changes in mortality risk. 
    In valuing changes in mortality risk, EPA reviewed 26 studies to 
    develop an estimate of the ``value of a statistical life'' based on the 
    willingness-to-pay (WTP) of individuals to avoid small increases in 
    mortality risk. Using a Weibull distribution to fit the estimates from 
    these 26 studies, the Section 812 Retrospective estimated a mean value 
    of $4.8 million per statistical life (with a standard deviation of $3.2 
    million in 1990).21 This estimate reflects a WTP of $5 for a 
    reduction in mortality risk of one in a million.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \21\ Section 812 Retrospective, p.44.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        This estimate is derived from studies involving very small changes 
    in mortality risk. However, the changes in mortality risk associated 
    with changes in particulate matter exposure estimated in the Section 
    812 Retrospective are roughly 10 to 100 times greater than the changes 
    associated with these valuation studies. When the marginal valuation of 
    $5 for a one in a million change in mortality risk is applied to the 
    ``no control'' scenario where modeled baseline mortality risk is on the 
    order of 1 in a 1000, the resulting WTP estimates for changes in 
    mortality risk represent a large share of each household's annual 
    budget, i.e., household ability to pay. Since the total outlay for risk 
    reduction represents a large share of the household budget, this 
    situation is very different from that examined by the 26 valuation 
    studies where the WTP estimates were a small fraction of household 
    budgets.
        (c) Hahn and Hird's estimate for environmental benefits. For its 
    environmental benefit estimate, the Hahn and Hird assessment relied on 
    an analysis by Freeman conducted in the late 1970s (Freeman, 
    1982).22 The Freeman analysis largely represented a 
    synthesis of the best existing work of the 1970s. The analysis 
    estimates air pollution control benefits for the year 1978, and water 
    pollution control benefits for the year 1985. Hahn and Hird adjust the 
    Freeman estimates to account for inflation; but these adjustments do 
    not reflect other changes--for example, additional regulations--in the 
    air pollution control program between 1978 and 1988 and in the water 
    pollution program control between 1985 and 1988. For water pollution 
    control benefits, the Freeman analysis may still represent the most 
    comprehensive estimate available. There are, however, several elements 
    of the Freeman analysis that deserve further discussion in order to 
    understand the strengths and limitations of the benefit estimates used 
    by Hahn and Hird.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \22\ See Hahn and Hird (1991 pages 253, 273; Portney (1990) 
    pages 54-60; Freeman (1990 in Portney (1990) page 123.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        (i) Establishing a baseline. As noted elsewhere in this report, 
    choice of an analytic baseline can be difficult, since many options are 
    available, and the preferred baseline may be unworkable due to the 
    inadequacy of available data. In the Freeman analysis, different 
    baselines were chosen for the air and water benefits analyses.
        The Freeman analysis evaluated the improvement in ambient air 
    quality between 1972 and 1978, and did not consider the deterioration 
    in air quality that might have occurred in the absence of air pollution 
    regulations.23 In effect, the counterfactual baseline was 
    assumed to be the level of air quality in 1972. As a result, the air 
    quality improvements that were analyzed were much smaller than those 
    incorporated in the CAA Section 812 Retrospective (EPA, 1997). 
    Furthermore, the baseline used for the air benefits analysis was not 
    consistent with that used for Freeman's cost analysis, which estimated 
    all air pollution control costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \23\ Implicitly, the Analysis assumed increased state, local, 
    and private initiatives great enough to offset air quality 
    deterioration due to increased economic activity, population growth, 
    and vehicle-miles-traveled (VMT) by automobiles and trucks during 
    the 1972 to 1978 period.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The baseline used for the water analysis, on the other hand, 
    assumed changing population and recreational participation rates 
    between 1972 and 1985. The baseline used for the water benefits 
    analysis was consistent with that used for Freeman's water pollution 
    control cost analysis.
        (ii) Key benefit categories. Freeman's air pollution benefits 
    analysis developed monetized benefit estimates for six categories: 
    human health (mortality), human health (morbidity), soiling and 
    cleaning, vegetation, materials, and property values. Approximately two 
    thirds of the monetized benefits were for human health improvements, 
    primarily reduced mortality incidence, due to reductions in ambient air 
    concentrations of particulate matter and sulfur oxides. His analysis 
    does not include any estimate of the benefits arising from reductions 
    in airborne lead (Pb) concentrations, which were a significant source 
    of air pollution control benefits found by later studies. The 
    discussion below addresses 3 key factors to bear in mind when 
    interpreting the primary benefit category, i.e., reduced mortality, 
    found in the air benefits estimates of his analysis.
    
    [[Page 44045]]
    
        1. Uncertainties in Magnitudes of Physical Effects: The Freeman 
    analysis surveys seven studies from the 1970s which developed a dose-
    response relationship between particulate matter and human 
    mortality.24 Based on these studies, Freeman provides a 
    range of possible results, with a ``best-guess'' estimate assumed to be 
    at the midpoint of the range. Since 1978, a number of additional 
    epidemiological studies have been completed on the relationship between 
    particulate matter and human mortality rates. It does not reflect the 
    advances in knowledge achieved in the 1980s and 1990s.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \24\ Freeman (1982), pages 63-66. Five of the seven studies 
    relied on the statistical work by Lave and Seskin from 1970, 1973, 
    and 1977.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        2. Timing of Effects: The Freeman analysis assumed that reductions 
    in ambient PM concentrations yield contemporaneous reductions in the 
    mortality risks associated with exposure to PM. If one were to assume, 
    for example, a significant lag, e.g., many years, between changes in 
    exposure and changes in risk, then the mortality benefit estimates 
    would be reduced.
        3. Valuation of Changes in Health Risk: The Freeman analysis 
    assumed a value per statistical life (VSL) of $2.4 
    million.25 Since 1978, there have been significant 
    additional contributions to the economic literature on the value of 
    mortality risk. After considering these more recent studies, the 
    Section 812 Retrospective adopted a midpoint of $4.8 million ($1990) as 
    a better estimate on the population's willingness-to-pay for reductions 
    in mortality risk. Use of an alternative valuation for mortality risk 
    would have a significant effect on the aggregate benefit estimate in 
    the Freeman analysis.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \25\ Freeman (1982), page 68. The estimate of $1 million in 1978 
    is converted to 1996 using the CPI.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Freeman's water pollution benefits analysis developed monetized 
    benefits estimates for four categories: recreation, nonuse, commercial 
    fisheries, and diversionary uses. Approximately half of the monetized 
    benefits are attributable to recreation. This analysis is based on a 
    number of studies carried out in the 1960s and 1970s, with benefits 
    projected forward to reflect projected population and recreational 
    participation rates in 1985. However, these estimates do not include 
    benefits associated with the reduction in toxic loadings in waste water 
    discharges, even though Freeman's cost estimates include ``substantial 
    costs for the control of discharges of these substances'' (Freeman, 
    1982). Benefits of non-point source pollution control also were not 
    included. Benefits to new and existing recreational users for hiking, 
    picnicking and nature observation that might result from improvements 
    in water quality were also omitted because of the absence of data for 
    these activities.
        (d) Summary assessment of Section 812 Retrospective. The discussion 
    above illustrates the difficulty, which we emphasize throughout this 
    report, of developing aggregate estimates of the benefits and costs of 
    major Federal regulatory programs. The results obtained in both the 
    Section 812 Retrospective and the Freeman analysis used by Hahn and 
    Hird appear to be sensitive to choices made concerning the baseline for 
    the analysis and the translation of the reduction of air pollution into 
    human health benefits.
    2. Two Other Retrospective Studies
        In general, retrospective studies are likely to provide more 
    accurate results than prospective studies because there are fewer 
    unknowns to deal with. Prospective studies must estimate what will 
    happen as a result of a proposed regulation and compare it with what 
    would happen without the regulation (the counterfactual). Retrospective 
    studies only need to measure the actual and estimate the 
    counterfactual. Below we discuss several case studies from the 
    literature that compare retrospective studies with their respective 
    prospective studies. NHTSA recently completed the third in a series of 
    studies of its 1983 center high-mounted stop lamp regulation. In brief 
    the studies found that although benefits exceeded costs, costs had been 
    underestimated by a factor of two and that the effectiveness of the 
    rule had been over estimated by a factor of seven in the prospective 
    study. The second case study examines eight regulations issued by OSHA 
    between 1974 and 1989 by drawing on an Office of Technology Assessment 
    (1995) report and a book by Viscusi (1992) that examined the cost 
    estimates and actual impacts of various OSHA regulations. The case 
    studies reveal that in some cases the agency overestimated expected 
    costs compared to the actual and in other cases it underestimated them. 
    The OTA study itself concluded that the agency had a tendency to 
    overestimate costs because of unanticipated improvements in compliance 
    technology after the regulations were issued. However, as in the NHTSA 
    example, the agency also appears to have overestimated the 
    effectiveness of its rule, if not the benefits.
        (a) The Center High-Mounted Stop Lamp Case. A comparison of NHTSA's 
    prospective with its retrospective analyses of its Center High-Mounted 
    Stop Lamp (CHMSL) 26 regulation illustrates how the benefits 
    and costs of a rule can be substantially different in practice than 
    what one would have expected based solely on the prospective 
    work.27 It further illustrates that early post-rule 
    estimates may differ substantially from long-term estimates. In the 
    case of the CHMSL rule, the Final Regulatory Impact Analysis (FRIA) in 
    support of the rule made what appeared to be an overwhelming case that 
    the rule would generate very large net benefits. The FRIA was based on 
    substantial amounts of experimental data and for many years served as a 
    model of an RIA that consistently employed sound benefit-cost analysis 
    principles. Nevertheless, when compared with NHTSA's long-term 
    evaluation, the FRIA overestimated the actual effectiveness (though not 
    the consequent benefits) of CHMSLs by a factor of more than seven and 
    underestimated the cost by a factor of more than two. Despite these 
    revelations, however, the analyses continue to confirm that the rule 
    generates positive net benefits, though not nearly as large as what one 
    might have expected at the time the rule was proposed or even based on 
    the early post-rule analyses.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \26\ CHMSLs are the ``third tail light'' found on all new cars 
    beginning with the 1986 model year. The purpose of CHMSLs is to 
    reduce the time it takes for following drivers to react when drivers 
    in front of them put on their brakes, allowing them to stop sooner 
    and thereby avoid crashes (or reduce the speed at which impact 
    occurs).
        \27\ Over the years, NHTSA has conducted a total of five 
    distinct analyses of its rule. These include two prospective 
    analyses (preliminary and final regulatory impact analyses) and 
    three retrospective analyses.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        (i) 1980 and 1983 Regulatory Impact Analyses. In early 1981 NHTSA 
    proposed to require CHMSLs. At that time the agency estimated in its 
    Preliminary Regulatory Impact Analysis (PRIA) that the rule would 
    reduce rear-end collisions by 35 percent (see table 7). NHTSA estimated 
    this would lead to 1,511,000 fewer crashes per year once the entire 
    passenger-car fleet was so equipped. NHTSA also estimated that an 
    additional 1,339,000 crashes per year would be less severe than they 
    otherwise would have been. The combined value of the savings in 
    property damage would range from $1.3 to $2.3 billion per year. In 
    addition, the PRIA estimated the rule would prevent 66,000 injuries and 
    533 fatalities per year. NHTSA estimated the cost of the proposal at 
    $49 million per year. Thus the analysis of the proposal held out the
    
    [[Page 44046]]
    
    promise of very large net benefits in property damage reductions 
    alone.28
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \28\ Since the costs occur when the vehicles are manufactured 
    and the benefits occur over the lifetime of the vehicle, it is 
    inappropriate simply to subtract annual costs from benefits. Even 
    after discounting, however, the PRIA estimates would yield net 
    benefits of between $600 million and $1.3 billion annually in 
    property damage alone.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        NHTSA completed its FRIA and published the final rule in 1983. In 
    response to comments it received on the proposal and in light of some 
    new evidence of the effectiveness of CHMSLs, NHTSA revised several 
    components of its benefit estimates downward. The FRIA also included a 
    somewhat refined cost estimate. The FRIA estimated the effectiveness of 
    CHMSL at 33 percent. In order to provide a more ``conservative'' 
    estimate of the benefits, NHTSA applied this effectiveness rate to a 
    smaller proportion of rear-end crashes than in the PRIA.29 
    In the FRIA, NHTSA also assumed a lower value of damage per crash 
    avoided ($510 vs. $1,116 in the PRIA). The result of these and other 
    related adjustments was estimates of 902,500 fewer crashes, $434 
    million in reduced property damage, 40,000 fewer injuries and no 
    estimate of reduced fatalities.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \29\ For example, the estimate excluded rural accidents, which 
    account for nearly one quarter of all accidents, because the test 
    fleets were driven in urban areas only thus leaving NHTSA with no 
    evidence that CHMSLs would be effective in rural settings. As NHTSA 
    later discovered, the actual effectiveness was about the same 
    between urban and rural settings.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The effectiveness estimates were based on three separate 
    experimental studies for which CHMSLs had been installed on fleets of 
    taxis and telephone company passenger cars. The three studies covered 
    over 3,000 vehicles and over 150 million vehicle miles. Nevertheless, 
    as early as 1980, NHTSA recognized the possibility that the 
    effectiveness estimate based on experimental studies may overstate the 
    true effectiveness of CHMSLs if there is a ``novelty'' effect which 
    caused following drivers to react more quickly than they would once 
    CHMSLs became commonplace. The effectiveness estimate was critical to 
    the decision to go forward with the rule because it underlies all 
    components of the benefit estimates. To its credit, NHTSA committed at 
    the time it proposed the rule to reassess the effectiveness after the 
    fact, if NHTSA adopted a CHMSL requirement in a final rule.
        (ii) 1987, 1989, and 1998 retrospective studies. Since the rule 
    became effective with the 1986 model year, NHTSA has conducted three 
    analyses with the benefit of hindsight. The most important results of 
    these studies are that: (1) The effectiveness of CHMSLs is considerably 
    lower than NHTSA estimated in the PRIA and FRIA; (2) the effectiveness 
    has fallen over time, though it now appears to have stabilized; (3) 
    actual costs are about double those estimated in the RIAs; and, most 
    importantly, (4) despite these findings, the rule still generates net 
    benefits.
        In 1987, NHTSA conducted a preliminary evaluation of the 
    effectiveness of production CHMSLs.30 It found an 
    effectiveness of about 15 percent. Thus, even though the CHMSLs were 
    installed in a small percentage of cars nationwide, i.e., when any 
    ``novelty effect'' would most likely occur, effectiveness was less than 
    half of the estimates in the RIAs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \30\ This study did not attempt to evaluate the benefits in a 
    broader sense or the costs.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In 1989, NHTSA conducted the second of its retrospective studies. 
    This study was based on 1987 data, by which time about one-fourth of 
    the passenger car fleet was equipped with CHMSLs. By this time, the 
    estimate of effectiveness had fallen again, to about 11 percent. 
    Despite the drop in estimated effectiveness and a corresponding 
    reduction in the number of accidents prevented compared with the FRIA, 
    the estimated benefits of CHMSLs increased. The number of injuries 
    prevented rose to between 79,000 and 101,000 and the estimate of 
    property damage prevented increased to $774 million per year. At that 
    time, NHTSA also concluded that CHMSLs were unlikely to prevent any 
    fatalities. The reasons for the increase in the benefits estimate 
    despite the reduction in effectiveness is due to three factors: (1) The 
    retrospective estimate includes all accidents (not just urban ones); 
    (2) the injury reduction estimate was based on actual crashes whereas 
    the estimates in the RIAs were modeled based on estimates of the 
    reduced speeds at which crashes that weren't avoided would occur; and 
    (3) the actual value of property damage given an accident was much 
    higher than NHTSA assumed in the FRIA. In other words, had NHTSA used 
    the same methodology and data for the FRIA and the retrospective, each 
    of the benefit categories would contain a value of about one-third of 
    what the FRIA reported, as the difference in effectiveness rates would 
    suggest.
        Earlier this year, NHTSA completed its long-term study of the 
    benefits and costs of CHMSLs.31 This most recent estimate of 
    the effectiveness of CHMSLs is 4.3 percent. NHTSA does not expect it to 
    fall further since it has remained steady throughout the last seven 
    years of data NHTSA has analyzed (1989 to 1995). Part of the decline in 
    effectiveness between the 1989 study and this one is attributable to a 
    further refinement in NHTSA's methodology which more accurately 
    controls for vehicle age, which is a factor in rear-end crashes. (Had 
    NHTSA used the same methodology in the 1989 study, the effectiveness 
    would have been about 8.5 percent, rather than 11.3 percent, and the 
    corresponding benefits would have been proportionately lower.) Thus, 
    the long-term effectiveness of CHMSLs is about one-eighth of NHTSA's 
    original estimate, while the costs are more than double. Even so, these 
    estimates imply that the rule continues to produce net benefits, though 
    not nearly as large as what NHTSA estimated prospectively.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \31\ In the early 1990s, NHTSA extended the CHMSL requirement to 
    include ``light trucks,'' i.e., minivans, sport-utility vehicles, 
    and pickup trucks, which comprise about 40 percent of the fleet. The 
    estimates in the long-term study include the effects on these 
    vehicles as well. However, in order to facilitate comparisons with 
    NHTSA's previous estimates which pertained to cars only, all 
    aggregate estimates in this study have been reduced by 40 percent to 
    reflect the effects on cars only.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The FRIA included an aggregate cost estimate of $70 million ($7 per 
    vehicle) in each of the first two years and $40 million ($4 per 
    vehicle) each year thereafter. The retrospective analyses estimated the 
    cost at $89 million (about $9 per vehicle) per year, or more than twice 
    the long-term cost estimate in the FRIA.
        (iii) Lessons learned from CHMSLs. These analyses confirm what many 
    believe: that benefits and costs are difficult to estimate 
    prospectively. In this instance, the RIAs overstated the effectiveness 
    of CHMSLs despite the advantage of substantial data from field 
    experiments. The estimates of benefits in the FRIA were not nearly as 
    large as those estimates presented in the PRIA. Nevertheless, the FRIA 
    estimates overstated the effectiveness of the rule by a factor of more 
    than seven. The changes in effectiveness estimates over time suggest 
    that it is important to re-evaluate the effects of regulations, 
    particularly where behavioral responses to the regulation may evolve 
    over time.
        With respect to cost, even though the only cost component was a 
    fairly simple piece of hardware, the FRIA estimate was less than half 
    the actual cost. It is interesting that, in their comments on the 
    proposed rule, the three domestic manufacturers estimated costs in the 
    $8 to $15 range. The low end of this range was lower than NHTSA's 
    actual (long-term retrospective) estimate and the high end was only 
    slightly further from actual costs than the FRIA estimate.
    
    [[Page 44047]]
    
        (b) Eight OSHA cases. The Office of Technology Assessment was asked 
    by Congress in 1992 to examine how well OSHA had estimated the impacts 
    of the regulations it had issued. OTA attempted to answer this question 
    by comparing OSHA's prospective analysis of impacts with actual 
    outcomes for a selective set of regulations. Although OTA did not 
    directly attempt to estimate actual benefits, in some cases they can be 
    inferred from the discussion and in other cases other information 
    sources, e.g., Viscusi 1992, can be used. Because of funding 
    constraints, three of the eight cases--vinyl chloride, cotton dust, and 
    ethylene oxide--were chosen because existing studies had already been 
    done. For the other five, new retrospective studies were commissioned.
        The eight cases examined exhibited a variety of outcomes. Table 8, 
    based on our analysis of the report's findings as well as other 
    information, shows that costs and benefits were both over-and 
    underestimated and that benefits were sometimes overestimated by OSHA 
    in its prospective analyses of the impacts of the rules. The 1974 
    regulation of vinyl chloride is often cited as an example of an agency 
    overestimating costs, although to be fair to OSHA the cost estimate was 
    supplied by industry and OSHA at that time did not conduct its own 
    economic analyses of prospective regulations. When cotton dust was 
    issued four years later, the agency was conducting economic analyses 
    for major rules. Cotton dust is also often cited as an example of the 
    agency overestimating compliance costs. OSHA, itself, contracted for a 
    retrospective study of the regulation five years after the rule was 
    issued but before the final controls took effect. The study found that 
    OSHA had earlier overestimated actual capital costs by a factor of five 
    (Viscusi 1992). The later study also found that benefits had also been 
    overestimated by at least two fold because of mistakes in methodology 
    and overcounting of the number of exposed individuals.
        In the secondary lead smelters case, also issued in 1978, OSHA 
    underestimated costs and overestimated benefits. The OTA report (p. 62) 
    points out that as of 1995 secondary lead smelters were not able to 
    comply with the engineering controls requirement to reduce air-lead 
    levels to the permissible exposure limit because compliance was 
    economically infeasible, i.e., costs had been underestimated. However, 
    smelters had found less expensive and more direct ways than engineering 
    controls to reduce blood-lead levels, the key health indicator and 
    performance goal. In other words, reducing air-lead levels through 
    engineering controls was not needed to attain the sought-after health 
    benefits. The benefits of engineering controls had been overestimated.
        In the 1984 ethylene oxide regulation of hospitals, OTA found that 
    OSHA had underestimated the costs of ventilation equipment but that 
    hospitals had little trouble complying with the standard by other 
    means. OTA found that overall hospitals spent more than expected, but 
    that was because they brought exposure levels down significantly below 
    the regulated level. On average, the agency had estimated costs about 
    right.
        The agency appears to have overestimated costs by about a factor of 
    two for metal foundries in its 1987 regulation of formaldehyde because 
    firms used low-formaldehyde resins rather than the predicted 
    ventilation controls to attain compliance.
        The next three case studies were for safety standards and the 
    findings are difficult to summarize. The OTA study did not directly 
    estimate costs or benefits for grain handling but found that the 
    standard was economically feasible. The PSDI power presses and powered 
    platforms rules were actually attempts at deregulation. In both cases 
    the cost savings that were predicted failed to materialize because 
    firms did not take advantage of the newly offered flexibility, 
    presumably because the agency had underestimated the costs and/or 
    overestimated the benefits of the flexibility. (See OTA 1995 p. 62.)
        Looking at this evidence, OTA concluded that OSHA tended to 
    overestimate costs because new technology was often developed between 
    the time the analysis was done, which in several cases was several 
    years before the final rule was issued, and the compliance date. The 
    report recommended that the agency consider the dynamic nature of 
    technology including the possibility of ``regulation-induced 
    innovation'' in order to set lower compliance levels (p. 11). However, 
    there is an opportunity cost to forcing innovation that is being 
    neglected. The resources that are directed at reducing compliance costs 
    by developing new technologies have to be pulled from other projects, 
    which presumably the company thought had a larger potential for payoff. 
    Since adding another constraint to the economic system is not likely to 
    increase the overall rate of technological progress for the economy, 
    ``regulation-induced innovation'' is not likely to be the ``win-win'' 
    situation that the report suggests (p. 53).
        Taken as a whole, these retrospective studies show that OSHA has 
    both underestimated and overestimated costs, sometimes by large 
    amounts. At the same time, in instances where there are clear data, 
    OSHA appears generally to have overestimated benefits. Although there 
    are important cases of overestimating costs because technological 
    progress and learning-by-doing over time reduced expected costs, it is 
    not clear that agencies should compensate for this tendency by reducing 
    costs estimates. These same factors may also lead to a tendency to 
    overestimate benefits.
    
    Chapter II: Estimates of Benefits and Costs of This Year's 
    ``Economically Significant'' Rules
    
    A. Scope
    
        In this chapter, we examine the benefits and costs of ``each rule 
    that is likely to have a gross annual effect on the economy of 
    $100,000,000 or more in increased costs,'' as required by section 
    645(a)(2). We have included in our review those final regulations on 
    which OIRA concluded review during the 12-month period April 1, 1997, 
    through March 31, 1998. This ``regulatory year'' is the same time 
    period we chose for last year's report. We chose this time period to 
    ensure that we covered a full year's regulatory actions as close as 
    practicable to the date our report is due, given the need to compile 
    and analyze data and publish the report for public comment. In 
    addition, we thought it would be useful to adopt a time period close to 
    that used for the annual OMB report required by the Unfunded Mandates 
    Reform Act of 1995.
        The statutory language categorizing the rules we are to consider 
    for this report is somewhat different from the definition of 
    ``economically significant'' in Executive Order 12866 (section 
    3(f)(1)). It also differs from similar statutory definitions in the 
    Unfunded Mandates Reform Act and subtitle E of the Small Business 
    Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act of 1996--Congressional Review of 
    Agency Rulemaking. Given these varying definitions, we interpreted 
    section 645(a)(2) broadly to include all final rules promulgated by an 
    Executive branch agency that meet any one of the following three 
    measures:
         Rules designated as ``economically significant'' under 
    section 3(f)(1) of Executive Order 12866
         Rules designated as ``major'' under 5 U.S.C. 804(2) 
    (Congressional Review Act)
         Rules designated as meeting the threshold under title II 
    of the Unfunded Mandates Reform Act (2 U.S.C. 1531-1538)
    
    
    [[Page 44048]]
    
    
    This year we also include a discussion of major rules issued by 
    independent regulatory agencies, although we do not review these rules 
    under Executive Order 12866. This discussion is based on data provided 
    by these agencies to the General Accounting Office (GAO) under the 
    Congressional Review Act.
        During the regulatory year selected, OIRA reviewed 33 final rules 
    that met the criteria noted above. Of these final rules HHS submitted 
    10; EPA nine; USDA five; DOI and DOE two each; DOL, DOT, DOJ, and VA 
    one each. In addition three agencies, DOL, HHS, and Treasury, worked 
    together to issue one common rule. These 33 rules represent about 14 
    percent of the 230 final rules reviewed by OIRA between April 1, 1997, 
    and March 31, 1998, and less than one percent of the 4,720 final rule 
    documents published in the Federal Register during this period. 
    Nevertheless, because of their greater scale and scope, we believe that 
    they represent the vast majority of the costs and benefits of new 
    Federal regulations during this period.
    1. Overview
        As noted in chapter I of last year's report, Executive Order 12866 
    ``reaffirms the primacy of Federal agencies in the regulatory decision-
    making process'' because agencies are given the legal authority and 
    responsibility for rulemaking under both their organic statutes and 
    certain process-oriented statutes, such as the Administrative Procedure 
    Act, the Unfunded Mandates Reform Act, and the Small Business 
    Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act. The Executive order also reaffirms 
    the legitimacy of centralized review generally and in particular review 
    of the agencies' benefit-cost analyses that are to accompany their 
    proposals. The Executive order recognizes that in some instances the 
    consideration of benefits or costs is precluded by law. For example, 
    the primary National Ambient Air Quality Standards under the Clean Air 
    Act are to be health-based standards set by EPA solely on the basis of 
    the scientific evidence. A variation is the Occupational Safety and 
    Health Act, where health standards must be based on reducing 
    significant risks to the extent doing so is economically and 
    technologically feasible. However, the Executive order requires 
    agencies to prepare and submit benefit-cost analyses even if those 
    considerations are not a factor in the decision-making process. Again, 
    it is the agencies that have the responsibility to prepare these 
    analyses, and it is expected that OIRA will review (but not redo) this 
    work. The costs and benefits identified may be attributable solely to 
    the regulation in question, where the agency has substantial 
    discretion, or they may in fact be attributable just as much to the act 
    of Congress that they are implementing.
        Reviewing for this report the benefit-cost analyses accompanying 
    the 33 final rules listed in table 9, we found, as we did last year, a 
    wide variety in the type, form, and format of the data generated and 
    used by the agencies. For example, agencies developed estimates of 
    benefits, costs, and transfers that were sometimes monetized, sometimes 
    quantified but not monetized, sometimes qualitative, and, most often, 
    some combination of the three. Generally, the boundaries between these 
    types of estimates are relatively well defined.
    2. Benefits and Costs of Economically Significant/Major Final Rules 
    (April 1997 to March 1998)
        (a) Social Regulation. Of the 33 rules reviewed by OIRA, 22 are 
    regulations requiring substantial additional private expenditures and/
    or providing new social benefits.32 (See table 9). EPA 
    issued nine of these rules; USDA three; HHS three; DOI and DOE two 
    each; DOT and DOL one each; and HHS/DOL/Treasury jointly issued one 
    rule. Agency estimates and discussion are presented in a variety of 
    ways, ranging from a purely qualitative discussion, e.g., the benefits 
    of EPA's toxics release inventory rule, to a more complete benefit-cost 
    analysis, e.g., DOE's energy conservation standards for refrigerators 
    and freezers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \32\ The other 11 are ``transfer'' rules.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        (i) Benefits analysis. Agencies monetized at least some benefit 
    estimates in a number of cases including: (1) USDA's $2.41 billion over 
    15 years from the effects of its environmental quality incentives 
    program on net farm income, pollution damage reductions, and wildlife 
    enhancements; (2) EPA's $12 to $57 million per year in terms of better 
    water quality from its pulp and paper effluent guidelines rule; and (3) 
    DOE's $7.62 billion over 30 years in energy savings from its energy 
    efficiency rule for refrigerators and freezers.
        Of the 22 (non-transfer) rules listed in table 9, agencies 
    monetized all the benefit estimates that they were able to quantify in 
    eight cases. In five cases, agencies provided some of the benefit 
    estimates in monetized and quantified form, but did not monetize other, 
    important components of benefits. DOE's two energy efficiency rules 
    monetized the value of energy savings and quantified, but did not 
    monetize, the power plant emission reductions associated with the 
    reduced energy consumption. DOL's respiratory protection rule monetized 
    the out-of-pocket savings associated with its estimate of injury and 
    illness reductions, but monetized neither the other aspects of those 
    injuries and illnesses (such as pain and suffering) nor the fatalities 
    avoided.
        In three cases, agencies provided quantified but not monetized 
    benefit estimates. These included: (1) HHS's 297 to 1306 life-years 
    extended as a result of its organ transplant rule; (2) EPA's 593,000 
    tons of nitrogen oxide emission reductions per year from its highway 
    heavy-duty engines rule; and (3) EPA's annualized emission reductions 
    of 385,000 tons of nitrogen oxides, 6,000 tons of hydrocarbons and 
    4,000 tons of particulate matter from its locomotives rule.
        Finally, in six cases, agencies reported neither monetized nor 
    quantified benefit estimates. In many, though not all, of these cases, 
    the agency provided a qualitative description of benefits. For example, 
    HHS' animal feed rule discusses the potential benefits of avoiding an 
    outbreak of ``mad cow'' disease, but does not estimate the probability 
    of such an episode. EPA's analysis of its expansion of its toxic 
    release inventory reporting rule includes a qualitative discussion of 
    making these data available to the public.
        (ii) Cost analysis. In 19 of the 22 cases, agencies provided 
    monetized cost estimates. These include such items as: USDA's estimate 
    of $1.65 billion over 15 years for its environmental quality incentives 
    program; DOL's estimate of $111 million per year for its respiratory 
    protection rule; and EPA's estimate of $37 billion per year to achieve 
    full attainment of its revised primary National Ambient Air Quality 
    Standard for particulate matter. For three deregulatory rules--USDA's 
    Sonoran pork and Argentinian beef rules and EPA's PCB disposal rule--
    agencies' monetized cost estimates were small or zero.
        For the remaining three rules, the agencies did not estimate costs. 
    These included DOI's two migratory bird hunting rules and NHTSA's light 
    truck fuel economy rule.
        (iii) Net monetized benefits. Thirteen of these 22 rules provided 
    at least some monetized estimates of both benefits and costs. Of those, 
    six have positive net monetized benefits, that is, estimated monetized 
    benefits that unambiguously exceed the estimated monetized costs of
    
    [[Page 44049]]
    
    the rules. For example, DOE's energy conservation standards for 
    refrigerators and freezers will generate an estimated net benefit of 
    $4.18 billion (present value) through 2030. EPA's PCB disposal rule 
    will result in an estimated net benefit of about $161 million per year. 
    Four rules resulted in negative net monetized benefits. These included 
    DOL's respiratory protection rule and EPA's medical waste incinerator 
    rule. Two rules resulted in monetized benefit estimates that were 
    sufficiently uncertain as to include both possibilities (net benefits 
    and net costs). For example, EPA's pulp and paper hazardous air 
    pollutant rule was estimated to generate between $925 million in net 
    benefits and $1.165 billion in net costs. Finally, one rule (USDA's 
    Sonoran pork rule) was estimated to have $0 benefits and $0 costs.
        (iv) Rules with quantified effects of less than $100 million per 
    year. Seven of the rules in table 9 are classified as economically 
    significant even though they have no quantified effects that exceed 
    $100 million in any one year. These deserve comment:
        USDA (2 Rules)--Importation of Pork from Sonora, Mexico, and Beef 
    from Argentina: In 1997, USDA began implementing a new general policy 
    allowing, under certain conditions, the importation of animal products 
    from certain regions of countries shown to be free of pests. This 
    policy was promulgated by rule on October 28, 1997 (62 FR 56000, 
    56027), but was not designated as major because the Department 
    concluded that analysis of the benefits and costs of the general policy 
    was infeasible. Instead, the Department undertook to perform such 
    analyses on each significant action implementing the general policy:
    
        Because this framework will not be fully implemented until we 
    receive a new request to allow the importation of animals or animal 
    products into the United States, and because we do not know the 
    number or sources of requests we will receive in the future, we 
    cannot estimate the economic impact of this rule as stipulated in 
    E.O. 12866. We are therefore committed to performing a risk 
    assessment and cost-benefit analysis on a case-by-case basis for 
    each request we receive in the near future. [62 FR 56010]
    
    The individual rulemakings concerning the importation of pork from 
    Sonora, Mexico, and beef from Argentina represent the first two 
    applications of this general regionalization policy and were analyzed 
    as if they were ``major'' pursuant to this departmental commitment.
        HHS--Substances Prohibited in Animal Feed: FDA estimated that this 
    rule will cost $53 million per year. It did not attempt to estimate the 
    benefits to be expected from the rule because it was unable to estimate 
    the probability of an outbreak of Bovine Spongiform Encephalopathy 
    (``mad cow disease''). However, FDA did estimate that the consequences 
    of an outbreak, should one occur, would be substantial. It estimated 
    the losses from the destruction of exposed livestock would be about 
    $3.8 billion.
        DOI--Migratory Bird Hunting (2 Rules): These are unusual rules in 
    that they are permissive rather than restrictive; that is, migratory 
    bird hunting is prohibited absent these annual regulations which allow 
    hunting, setting bag limits and other controls on both early and late 
    season hunts. Thus the rules permit such spending rather than requiring 
    the expenditure of private resources. DOI reports that the National 
    Survey of Fishing, Hunting, and Wildlife Associated Recreation 
    indicated that expenditures by migratory bird hunters (exclusive of 
    licenses, tags, permits, etc.) totaled $686 million in 1991. Based on 
    this estimate, DOI estimated expenditures for duck hunters would be 
    over $400 million per year in 1995. However, this figure is not in the 
    commonly used sense a social benefit.
        DOE--Room Air Conditioners: This rule was proposed as part of a 
    substantially larger rulemaking that included seven other types of 
    household appliances, such as water heaters, fluorescent lamp ballasts, 
    and mobile home furnaces. Energy efficiency standards for all eight 
    combined clearly would have been economically significant. Even though 
    the monetized effects of this rule are less than $100 million in any 
    year, the annualized energy savings benefits (about $60 million per 
    year) are substantial. This fact, combined with the rule's history led 
    to the decision to maintain the ``economically significant'' 
    designation.
        DOT--Light Truck CAFE: Each year, DOT must establish a corporate 
    average fuel economy (CAFE) standard for light trucks, including sport-
    utility vehicles and minivans. (DOT also sets a separate standard for 
    passenger cars but is not required to revisit the standard each year.) 
    For the past three years, however, appropriations language has 
    prohibited NHTSA from spending any funds to change the standards. In 
    effect, it has frozen the light truck standard at its existing level of 
    20.7 miles per gallon (mpg) and has prohibited NHTSA from analyzing 
    effects at either 20.7 mpg or alternative levels. Although benefits and 
    costs are not estimated, DOT's experience in previous years indicates 
    that they may be substantial. Over 5 million new light trucks are 
    subject to these standards each year, and the standard, at 20.7 mpg, is 
    binding on several manufacturers. Some are just above the standard and 
    at least one is currently below 20.7 mpg. Because of these likely, 
    substantial effects, we designated the rule as economically significant 
    even though analysis of the effects was prohibited by law.
        (b) Transfer Regulations. Of the 33 rules listed in table 9, 11 
    were rules necessary to implement Federal budgetary programs. The 
    budget outlays associated with these rules are ``transfers'' to program 
    beneficiaries. Of the 11, two are USDA rules that implement Federal 
    appropriations language regarding home day care meal programs and 
    agricultural policies; seven are HHS rules that implement Medicare and 
    Medicaid policy; one is a DOJ rule regarding immigration policy; and 
    one is a VA rule regarding compensation of veterans who have 
    cardiovascular disabilities.
        (c) Major rules for independent agencies. Several commenters 
    suggested that last year we omitted a major category of costs and 
    benefits: the costs and benefits of major rules from the independent 
    agencies. The General Accounting Office (GAO) is required to submit 
    reports on major rules to the Committees of Jurisdiction in both houses 
    of Congress under the congressional review provisions of the Small 
    Business Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act (SBREFA), including rules 
    issued by agencies not subject to Executive Order 12866 (the so-called 
    independent agencies). We reviewed the information on the costs and 
    benefits of major rules contained in the GAO reports for the period 
    April 1, 1996 to March 31, 1998. According to the GAO reports, five 
    independent agencies issued 41 major rules during this period. The 
    agencies are listed in table 10 along with a summary of the kinds of 
    information provided by the agencies as summarized by GAO.
        Table 10 clearly reveals that the independent agencies provide 
    relatively little quantitative information on the costs and benefits of 
    regulations for major rules, especially compared to the agencies 
    subject to E.O. 12866. Indeed, according to a recent GAO report, 
    Regulatory Reform: Major Rules Submitted for Congressional Review 
    During the First 2 Years, (April 24, 1998), the independent agencies 
    themselves reported doing benefit/cost analyses for only eight, or 18 
    percent, of the 44 major rules they submitted to GAO during this 
    period. That compares to 72 out of 78 rules, or 92 percent, that
    
    [[Page 44050]]
    
    GAO examined for the agencies subject to Executive Order 12866. Table 
    10 also shows that 12 of the 41 rules, or 29 percent, from independent 
    agencies in our sample, which were all in the GAO sample, included some 
    discussion of benefits and costs even though in some cases the agencies 
    reported that they did not do a benefit cost analysis. However, table 
    10 also reveals that only four of the 41 regulations had any monetized 
    cost information and only one had any monetized benefit information.
        The one rule in table 10 that estimated both benefits and costs was 
    an SEC rule amending the Investment Advisors Act of 1940 to exempt 
    certain types of investment advisors from the prohibition of SEC 
    registration as investment advisors. The SEC estimated benefits of $7 
    million and costs of $930,000.The three other rules for which costs 
    were estimated are the SEC's rule allowing electronic storage for 
    brokers or dealer reporting, which the industry estimated would reduce 
    costs by $160 million per year; a Federal Reserve Board (FRB) bank 
    holding regulation that would reduce paperwork burden by $1.3 million 
    per year; and an FCC regulation that requires that phones in most 
    public facilities be hearing aid compatible with volume controls, which 
    was estimated to increase the costs of a phone by from 50 cents to a 
    dollar.
        The only estimate of costs or benefits of approximately $100 
    million was the industry-supplied estimate of $160 million savings for 
    the SEC's broker/dealer reporting rule. Since we have used a criterion 
    of using only agency or academic peer reviewed estimates, we conclude 
    that the 41 GAO reports contain no information useful for estimating 
    the aggregate costs and benefits of regulations.
    3. Best Practices and RIAs
        Based on a review of the 21 agency cost-benefit analyses for the 
    period from April 1, 1996 to March 31, 1997, last year's report 
    concluded that we need better information in order to determine whether 
    proposed regulations produce the greatest net benefits. Based on a 
    review of 22 additional agency analyses for the year from April 1, 1997 
    to March 31, 1998, that conclusion still stands. Nevertheless, agencies 
    are making significant efforts to apply the Best Practices principles 
    in their RIAs. Below we discuss several examples of agencies' 
    application of these principles to their analytical work.
        Serious deviations from Best Practices on any one criterion can 
    dramatically diminish the usefulness of the analysis, or worse, lead to 
    analytical results that distort the facts and ultimately result in 
    regulatory decisions that are far from optimal. Because of the 
    importance of ``getting it right,'' we thought it would be instructive 
    to select several criteria from the Best Practices document and discuss 
    some examples of how agencies properly applied them in their regulatory 
    analyses:
         Quantification and monetization of estimates and treatment 
    of qualitative estimates
         Determination of a consistent and reasonable baseline
         Evaluation of regulatory options
         Treatment of bias and uncertainty
         Treatment of future streams of benefits and costs
        (i) Quantification, monetization and treatment of qualitative 
    estimates. All monetized estimates are, by definition, given in dollars 
    and (unless there are overlapping effects of rules that are not 
    accounted for) permit ready comparison and aggregation. Monetized 
    estimates of effects are what is most generally considered the basis of 
    benefit-cost analysis. Even when such figures are available, however, 
    care must be taken when interpreting them because they depend for 
    comparability on a number of distinct elements. Specifically, monetized 
    estimates consist of: (1) The dollar value itself; (2) the base year of 
    the dollar used; (3) the initial year in which the effects occur; (4) 
    the final year after which the effects disappear; and (5) the discount 
    rate used to convert future into current values (or vice versa).
        Quantified estimates may take the form of a variety of different 
    units, but they share in common a numeric measure. Generally, 
    quantified estimates of benefits, costs, and transfers must be 
    interpreted with the same elements noted above in mind. The most 
    important difference, of course, is that quantified estimates are 
    expressed in units other than dollars. Such estimates may be aggregated 
    only if they are presented in the same or similar units. Also, a 
    quantified estimate should identify the applicable time period, e.g., 
    tons of pollution controlled per year, number of endangered species 
    protected from extinction per decade. Quantified estimates that lack 
    reference to the time periods to which they apply may be highly 
    misleading, and should be converted to similar time periods to be 
    comparable. Indeed, even when estimates of a similar type include 
    explicit reference to their underlying time periods, care must be taken 
    when aggregating or comparing them because of the risk of summing 
    estimates based on different time periods or inconsistent base years.
        In contrast, qualitative estimates may not have any units at all, 
    or they may be expressed in units that do not lend themselves to simple 
    comparisons. As has often been observed, it is more frequently the case 
    that costs are monetized and that benefits are more often quantified or 
    presented in qualitative form. Qualitative effects should be evaluated 
    in terms of their uniqueness, reversibility, timing, and geographic 
    scope and severity. These effects are the most difficult to interpret, 
    and this may lead some to give them short shrift. The fact that an 
    effect has not been monetized or quantified does not, however, 
    necessarily mean that it is small or unimportant.
        Qualitative effects must be used with care for other reasons as 
    well. Because they tend to be general and descriptive, they may be 
    broader than the incremental effects of the particular regulation being 
    analyzed. For example, in developing a rule designed to address a 
    particular safety problem, an agency may describe the extent of the 
    problem--that is, so many persons injured per year from this particular 
    cause. While important in estimating the benefits of the rule, this 
    figure itself is not a benefit estimate unless and until it is linked 
    to the likely effectiveness of the proposed rule. Finally, qualitative 
    estimates cannot be aggregated at all because they do not contain units 
    that permit arithmetic operations. In addition, not infrequently they 
    fail to contain relevant information about the period of time during 
    which they apply.
        (ii) Baseline. One of the criticisms often cited in evaluating RIAs 
    is the failure to use a consistent baseline against which to estimate 
    both benefits and costs, or the failure to adopt a baseline that 
    reflects current and future conditions (including current regulatory 
    requirements). Using inconsistent or incorrect baselines will lead to 
    biased estimates of benefits and/or costs. When this happens, the 
    analysis may incorrectly make one or more of the various regulatory 
    options appear reasonable or vice versa.
        The Best Practices document states that the baseline should be the 
    best assessment of the way the world would look absent the proposed 
    regulation. In addition, when more than one baseline appears reasonable 
    or the baseline is very uncertain, the agency may choose to measure 
    benefits and costs against multiple alternative baselines as a form of 
    sensitivity analysis.
        In its analysis of the cost impacts for the final PCB disposal 
    rule, for example, EPA considered three alternative baselines 
    reflecting different interpretations of existing regulatory
    
    [[Page 44051]]
    
    requirements. EPA's preferred baseline scenario reflects EPA policy as 
    it has evolved over the period since 1979 when EPA published an earlier 
    final rule with regard to PCBs generally (although it does not reflect 
    the special circumstances associated with the disposal of PCB-
    contaminated ship hulls). A second baseline reflects a literal 
    interpretation of the 1979 rule; a third alternative, the ``special 
    circumstances'' baseline, reflects current EPA policy because the Navy 
    is already disposing of ship hulls in a manner consistent with the new 
    rule. Using these alternative baselines, EPA estimates that the final 
    PCB rule would yield net cost savings ranging from $150 million for the 
    special circumstances baseline to $740 million for a literal 
    interpretation of the 1979 rule. The use of multiple baselines is 
    informative because it illustrates that changes in EPA policy in 
    implementing regulations can have a substantial effect on the cost of a 
    regulatory program. In this case, in the years after EPA adopted a 
    final disposal rule in 1979, changes in EPA policy--especially allowing 
    the disposal of automobile ``shredder fluff'' in municipal landfills--
    have operated to reduce the cost of the program by more than $500 
    million per year.
        (iii) Regulatory options. The analysis should consider the most 
    important alternative regulatory options in addressing the problem. 
    Failure to do so may give the selected option the appearance of being 
    the best alternative when in fact there are one or more others that 
    result in higher benefits and/or lower costs and thus greater net 
    benefits. It is critical that the alternatives analyzed be reasonable. 
    Analyzing bogus or ``straw man'' options only exacerbates the problem.
        The analysis might consider, for example, the use of performance-
    based standards, different levels of stringency, differential standards 
    for different parts of the regulated population, and differential 
    approaches for assuring compliance. If the proposed regulation is 
    composed of a number of distinct provisions, it is important to 
    evaluate the benefits and costs of the different provisions separately. 
    Particularly in the case of alternative levels of stringency, the 
    analysis should estimate the incremental benefits and costs of each 
    option as compared with the next-less-stringent option.
        DOE's final rule setting new energy efficiency standards for 
    refrigerators and freezers, for example, includes analysis of a 
    comprehensive set of options. For each of eight classes of 
    refrigerators, e.g., top-mounted freezer with automatic defrost, DOE 
    estimated the benefits and costs of at least 12 alternative levels of 
    performance standards. For one class, DOE analyzed 28 options. This 
    extensive analysis of alternatives provided DOE with a very rich array 
    of information on the relative effects of alternative standards. For 
    example, DOE's analysis of over 20 alternative performance standards 
    for one class of top-mounted refrigerators enabled it to select an 
    option that resulted in per-unit net benefits more than $200 greater 
    than for the least attractive option considered in the analysis.
        (iv) Bias and uncertainty. The analysis should address areas of 
    uncertainty and potential bias. The analysis should also provide a 
    clear discussion of the assumptions underlying the analysis and address 
    the uncertainties that attend these assumptions. Sensitivity analysis 
    helps to identify the truly critical assumptions, thereby enabling the 
    analysts to focus their efforts on further refinements to the analysis 
    in those areas.
        The Best Practices document states that where benefit or cost 
    estimates are heavily dependent on certain assumptions, it is essential 
    to identify these assumptions explicitly and to carry out sensitivity 
    analyses based on alternative plausible assumptions.
        EPA's analysis for the two rules revising primary National Ambient 
    Air Quality Standards (NAAQS) for ozone and particulate matter (PM) 
    presents a plausible range for the benefits estimates; the range 
    reflects alternative assumptions with respect to the estimates for 
    specific benefit categories (EPA, RIA for PM and ozone primary NAAQS, 
    pp. ES-9 and 10). For example, the analysis presents high and low ozone 
    benefit estimates which reflect differences in the treatment of the 
    possible effect of ozone on premature mortality. Similarly, the 
    analysis presents high and low PM benefit estimates to reflect 
    differences in the treatment of a possible threshold below which PM 
    would have little or no effect on premature mortality.
        (v) Future streams of benefits and costs. As discussed above, care 
    must be taken in comparing estimates of effects to assure that they are 
    presented in a comparable time frame. This requires consideration of 
    several factors: (1) The initial year in which the effects occur; (2) 
    the final year after which the effects disappear; (3) the discount rate 
    used to convert future into current values (or vice versa); and (4) the 
    format in which the value is presented.
        Format means the characterization of the monetized or quantified 
    effects over time. In the rules on which we are reporting, we found 
    that agencies used a variety of formats:
        (1) Annualized values;
        (2) Present values;
        (3) Constant annual values; and
        (4) Other or unknown formats.
        From the perspective of benefit-cost analysis, annualized and 
    present value formats are always preferred because they permit 
    aggregation and comparisons within and across regulatory actions. 
    Constant annual values are slightly less desirable insofar as they 
    require the additional step of discounting to permit such aggregation 
    and comparison. Constant annual values are typically found in monetized 
    cost estimates involving Federal budget outlays, and in quantified 
    benefit estimates where agencies have chosen not to discount. 
    Aggregation and comparison within and across regulations generally 
    cannot be performed without a common discounting methodology. Where an 
    agency's estimation methodology follows an unknown format, further 
    research needs to be performed to ascertain how to convert or 
    reconstruct annualized or present value estimates.
        The analysis should present a schedule of the stream of benefits 
    and costs where there is a variation in benefits and costs over time or 
    where they occur in different years, e.g., where there is a delay in 
    the timing of benefits relative to the costs. These streams of benefits 
    and costs should either be discounted to yield ``present value'' 
    estimates or ``annualized'' to provide an estimate of annual benefits 
    and costs in a typical year so that they can be considered in a 
    comparable time frame. Failure to do so will bias the analysis in favor 
    of alternatives that deliver benefits later or impose costs sooner.
        The Best Practices document refers to OMB Circular A-94 as the 
    basic guidance on discount rates for regulatory analyses. As noted in 
    the A-94 guidance, agencies may also present sensitivity analyses using 
    other discount rates (with a justification for using these alternative 
    rates).
        For example, EPA's analysis of its final rule setting both effluent 
    limits for wastewater discharges and air toxic emission limits for pulp 
    and paper mills developed present value estimates using discount rates 
    of three and seven percent for benefit and cost streams over a 30 year 
    period (EPA, Economic Analysis * * *, October 1997, pp.10-3 and 10-4). 
    EPA phased in the recreational benefits over a two-year period (full 
    value in year three and thereafter) and the health benefits over a five 
    year period (full value in year six and thereafter). On the cost side, 
    EPA
    
    [[Page 44052]]
    
    assumed the capital costs would be incurred in years one and twenty-one 
    with operations and maintenance costs incurred in the second through 
    thirtieth years. The analysis adopted the 7 percent discount rate in 
    accordance with OMB guidance and used 3 percent, reflecting the social 
    rate of time preference, to reflect the sensitivity of these estimates 
    to alternative discount rates. The benefit estimates (including the 
    lower absolute value of the bound negative benefit estimate) are 
    roughly 50 percent larger and the costs are roughly 40 percent larger 
    using a 3 percent discount rate vis-a-vis a 7 percent discount rate.
    4. GAO Report
        A review completed by GAO looked at how well the regulatory impact 
    analyses for 20 economically significant health, safety, and 
    environmental regulations issued between July 1996 and March 1997 
    followed our Best Practices guidelines (GAO 1998). For example, 
    according to GAO, five of the 20 rules examined did not discuss 
    alternatives, six did not assign dollar values to benefits, and one did 
    not assign dollar values to costs--all practices recommended by our 
    guidance (GAO, 1998). In addition, GAO found that the analyses differed 
    in their treatment of assumptions and uncertainty. For example, 
    agencies used various discount rates that ranged from 2.1 percent to 10 
    percent, and for the six analyses that used an estimate for the value 
    of a statistical life, the estimates ranged from $1.6 million to $5.5 
    million. GAO does point out, however, that the Best Practices guidance 
    does allow agencies flexibility to vary the assumptions to fit the 
    circumstances of the specific rules, although GAO also points out that 
    in many cases the agencies do not explain why they varied from Best 
    Practice recommendations.
        On a more positive note, GAO also reported that according to agency 
    officials, 12 of the 20 analyses were used to help identify the most 
    cost-effective of several alternatives or to cost-effectively implement 
    health-based regulations and that seven of the remaining analyses were 
    used to define the scope and timing of implementation, document and 
    defend regulatory decisions, and reduce health risks at feasible costs. 
    Only one of the analyses played almost no part in regulatory decisions, 
    and that was because the statute was too prescriptive to leave any 
    discretion in implementing the regulation.
        As we stated last year:
    
        Although considerable progress has been made in providing micro 
    data in advance of regulatory proposals and in developing the Best 
    Practices guidance, further progress is needed to continue improving 
    regulatory decisions. Specifically, we need to ensure that the 
    quality of data and analysis used by the agencies improves, that 
    standardized assumptions and methodologies are applied more 
    uniformly across regulatory programs and agencies, and that data and 
    methodologies designed to determine whether existing regulations 
    need to be reformed are developed and used appropriately.
    
    Chapter III: Estimates of Benefits and Costs of ``Economically 
    Significant'' Rules, April 1995-March 1998
    
        In last year's report, we recommended that OIRA continue to develop 
    a data base on benefits and costs of major rules. This chapter seeks to 
    respond to that recommendation by presenting the available benefit and 
    cost estimates for individual rules from April 1, 1995 through March 
    31, 1998. The summary of agency estimates for final rules from the 
    current year (April 1, 1997 to March 31, 1998) is presented in chapter 
    II, table 9. The summary of agency estimates for final rules from the 
    preceding two years (April 1, 1995 to March 31, 1997) is presented in 
    tables 17 and 18.
        In assembling agency estimates of benefits and costs, we have:
        (1) Applied a uniform format for the presentation of benefit and 
    cost estimates in order to make agency estimates more closely 
    comparable with each other, e.g., provided the benefit and cost streams 
    over time, annualized benefit and cost estimates, etc., and
        (2) Monetized quantitative estimates where the agency has not done 
    so, e.g., converted tons of pollutant per year to dollars.
        The adoption of a format that allows the presentation of agency 
    estimates so that they are more closely comparable also allows, at 
    least for purposes of illustration, the aggregation of benefit and cost 
    estimates across rules. At the same time we caution the reader that 
    agencies have used different methodologies and valuations in 
    quantifying and monetizing effects and we have attempted to be faithful 
    to the respective agency approaches. In this chapter, we also aggregate 
    benefit and cost estimates for those Federal rules with significant 
    quantified benefit and cost estimates.
        As noted in chapters I and II, the substantial limitations of the 
    available data on the benefits and costs for this set of rules raise 
    significant obstacles to the development of a meaningful aggregate 
    estimate of benefits and costs for even a single year's regulations. 
    For example, in many cases agencies identified important benefits of 
    their rules that were not quantifiable. In such cases, we necessarily 
    omitted them from the monetized estimates we develop in this chapter. 
    To the extent that these benefits are substantial, the monetized 
    estimates will understate the total value of the benefits. The 
    discussion below addresses other limitations in the data and outlines 
    the steps we have taken in an effort to overcome some of them.
    
    A. Monetized Benefit and Cost Estimates for Individual Rules
    
        First, we have only included in this chapter those major rules with 
    quantified estimates of benefits and costs. These include six rules 
    from the 1995/96 period, 15 rules from the 1996/97 period, and 13 rules 
    from 1997/98 period. We have excluded 13 rules without quantified 
    estimates of either benefits or costs. (See table 11.) Six additional 
    rules listed in table 12 have also been excluded from further 
    discussion because only quantified cost estimates were available and/or 
    there were only relatively small benefit and cost estimates.
        Second, for some of the remaining rules, agencies quantified 
    estimates of significant effects, but did not assign a monetized value 
    to these effects. Some of the quantified effects--for example, small 
    changes in the risk of premature death or serious injury--are 
    frequently identified as outcomes for a variety of rules. In a number 
    of instances, though, agencies did assign monetized estimates to these 
    outcomes.
        Differences in valuation across rules are often critical, 
    particularly in comparisons between and among individual rules or 
    programs. Furthermore, the different approaches in the quantification 
    and monetization of these effects across agencies result in an ``apples 
    and oranges'' problem in aggregating estimates; in particular, where 
    effects have been quantified, but not monetized, the different 
    quantitative effects cannot be summed because they are not expressed in 
    common units. In order to address this problem, this section takes the 
    additional step of assigning a monetized value in order to provide a 
    more consistent set of estimates in those cases where agencies only 
    quantified significant effects. We have not, however, attempted to 
    quantify or monetize any qualitative effects identified by agencies 
    where the agency did not at least quantify them.
        Agencies have, over the years, taken, and continue to take, several 
    different approaches toward rules that affect small risks of premature 
    death. In some cases, such as FDA's tobacco rule, agencies have 
    quantified and monetized
    
    [[Page 44053]]
    
    these effects in terms of ``quality-adjusted statistical life years.'' 
    In other cases, such as FRA's roadway worker protection rule, agencies 
    have quantified and monetized these effects in terms of statistical 
    lives. In still other cases, such as HHS's organ procurement rule and 
    NHTSA's air bag depowering rule, agencies have quantified risks of 
    death in terms of life-years or lives, but have not monetized them. 
    Finally, in some cases, such as FDA's animal feed rule, the agency did 
    not develop a quantified estimate of the rule's mortality effects.
        Estimates for the value of a statistical life varied across 
    agencies. For the tobacco rule, FDA estimated benefits based on a value 
    of $2.5 million per statistical life. For the roadway worker rule, FRA 
    used $2.7 million per statistical life. For the upper-bound estimates 
    of EPA's ozone and PM NAAQS rules, the agency used $4.8 million per 
    statistical life; and for its mammography rule, FDA also used $5 
    million per statistical life.33 Similarly, agency estimates 
    for the value of a statistical life-year have also varied. FDA used 
    $116,500 per life-year for its tobacco rule; EPA used $120,000 per 
    life-year to produce its lower-bound estimates of benefits in its ozone 
    and PM NAAQS rules; FDA used $368,000 per life-year in its mammography 
    rule. As a general matter, we have deferred to the individual agency's 
    judgment in this area. In cases where the agency both quantified and 
    monetized fatality risks, we have made no adjustments to the agency's 
    estimate.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \33\ There is a relatively rich body of academic literature on 
    this subject. The methodologies used and the resulting estimates 
    vary substantially across the academic studies. Based on this 
    literature, agencies have developed estimates they believe are 
    appropriate for their particular regulatory circumstances.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In cases where the agency provided only a quantified estimate of 
    fatality risk, but did not monetize it, we have monetized these 
    estimates in order to convert these effects into a common unit. For 
    example, in the case of HHS's organ donor rule, the agency estimated, 
    but did not monetize, statistical life-years saved, although it 
    discussed HHS's use of $116,500 per life-year in other contexts. We 
    valued those life-years at $116,500 each. For NHTSA's air bag 
    depowering rule, we used a value of $2.7 million per statistical life. 
    In cases where agencies have not adopted estimates of the value of 
    reducing these risks, we used estimates supported by the relevant 
    academic literature. For DOL's respirator rule, for example, we used $5 
    million per statistical life. As a practical matter, the aggregate 
    benefit and cost estimates are relatively insensitive to the values we 
    have assigned for these rules because the aggregate estimates are 
    dominated by the FDA tobacco rule and EPA's rules revising the ozone 
    and PM primary NAAQS. Finally, we did not attempt to quantify or 
    monetize fatality risk reductions in cases where the agency did not at 
    least quantify them.
    
    B. Valuation Estimates for Other Regulatory Effects
    
        The following is a brief discussion of our valuation estimates for 
    other types of effects which agencies identified and quantified, but 
    did not monetize.
         Injury. For the air bag depowering rule, we adopted the 
    Department of Transportation approach of converting injuries to 
    ``equivalent fatalities.'' These ratios are based on DOT's estimates of 
    the value individuals place on reducing the risk of injury of varying 
    severity relative to that of reducing risk of death. For the two OSHA 
    rules we used a ratio of 20 injuries per equivalent fatality.
         Change in Gasoline Fuel Consumption. We valued reduced 
    gasoline consumption at $.80 per gallon pre-tax.
         Reduction in Barrels of Crude Oil Spilled. We valued each 
    barrel prevented from being spilled at $2,000. This reflects double the 
    sum of the most likely estimates of environmental damages plus cleanup 
    costs contained in a recent published journal article (Brown and 
    Savage, 1996).
         Change in Emissions of Air Pollutants. We used estimates 
    of the benefits per ton for reductions in hydrocarbon, nitrogen oxide 
    (NOX), sulfur dioxide (SO2), and fine particulate 
    matter (PM) presented in EPA's Pulp and Paper cluster rule (October, 
    1997). These estimates were obtained from the RIA prepared for EPA's 
    July, 1997 rules revising the primary NAAQS for ozone and fine PM. We 
    note that in this area, as in others, the academic literature offers a 
    number of methodologies and underlying studies to quantify the 
    benefits. There remain considerable uncertainties with each of these 
    approaches. For each of these pollutants, we used the following values 
    (all in 1996$) for changes in emissions: 34
    
        \34\ Where applicable, the lower (higher) end of the value 
    ranges in all of the tables throughout this report reflect the lower 
    (higher) values in these ranges.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Hydrocarbons: $519 to $2,360/ton;
    Nitrogen Oxides: $519 to $2,360/ton;
    Particulate Matter: $11,539/ton; and
    Sulfur Dioxide: $3,768 to $11,539/ton.
    
        Third, in order to make agency estimates more consistent, we 
    developed benefit and cost time streams for each of the rules. Where 
    agency analyses provide annual or annualized estimates of benefits and 
    costs, we used these estimates in developing streams of benefits and 
    costs over time. Where the agency estimate only provided annual 
    benefits and costs for specific years, we used a linear interpolation 
    to represent benefits and costs in the in-between years. In the case of 
    EPA's Federal test procedure rule, for example, the analysis reported 
    emission reductions for only four years, i.e., 2005, 2010, 2015, and 
    2020. We used linear interpolation to provide benefit and cost streams 
    over the intervening years.
        In addition, agency estimates of benefits and costs cover widely 
    varying time periods. For example, EPA's analysis for the pulp and 
    paper effluent guidelines rules developed annualized benefit estimates 
    for a stream of benefits over 30 years. Annualized cost estimates for 
    this rule were based on installation of control equipment in the first 
    year with full replacement of the control equipment in year 21 at the 
    end of the 20-year useful life for the control equipment and operating 
    and maintenance costs after the first year. USDA's analysis of the 
    conservation reserve program provided annual benefit and cost estimates 
    for the five-year period from 1997 to 2002. On the other hand, DOE's 
    analysis of energy conservation standards for refrigerators and 
    freezers evaluated a much longer time frame from 2000 to 2030, and 
    EPA's analysis of its rule setting emission standards for new 
    locomotives used a time frame of forty years (2000 to 2040).
        These differences in the time frames evaluated reflect specific 
    characteristics of individual rules. The short time frame of USDA's 
    conservation reserve program rule reflects, for example, the five-year 
    legislative cycle of the farm bills. On the other hand, the longer time 
    frames of DOE's refrigerators and freezers rule and EPA's new 
    locomotives rule reflect the relatively long period required for 
    turnover of the existing stock of equipment and replacement with 
    equipment meeting the new standards. Because there are substantial 
    differences in the time frame of analysis for these rules, we have 
    decided--with the one exception of DOT's air bag depowering rule--to 
    treat the benefit and cost streams as though all of these rules are in 
    place through the year 2050. We made the one exception to this approach 
    for DOT's air bag depowering rule because the rule automatically 
    terminates at the end of five years. We believe that this is a 
    reasonable treatment of the benefit and
    
    [[Page 44054]]
    
    cost streams because a number of these rules will not achieve their 
    full effect for many years into the future. In addition, major 
    regulatory programs tend to be long-lived and, thus, the adoption of a 
    longer time horizon appears to be appropriate. This approach holds the 
    baseline constant and does not consider, of course, the potential 
    effect of a ``rising baseline'' as a result of technological change, 
    cultural changes, etc. (See discussion in chapter I.)
        Finally, we have not made any changes to agency monetized 
    estimates. To the extent that agencies have adopted different monetized 
    values for effects, e.g., different values for a statistical life, or 
    different discounting methods, these differences remain embedded in 
    tables 13 through 15. Any comparison or aggregation across rules should 
    also consider a number of factors which the presentation in tables 13 
    through 15 does not address. First, for example, these rules may use 
    different baselines in terms of the regulations and controls already in 
    place. In addition, these rules may well treat uncertainty in different 
    ways. In some cases, agencies may have developed alternative estimates 
    reflecting upper- and lower-bound estimates. In other cases, the 
    agencies may offer a midpoint estimate of benefits and costs, and in 
    some cases the agency estimates may reflect only upper-bound estimates 
    of the likely benefits and costs. Also, in order for comparisons or 
    aggregation to be meaningful, benefit and cost estimates should 
    correctly account for all substantial effects of regulatory actions, 
    including potentially offsetting effects, which may or may not be 
    reflected in the available data.
    
    C. Aggregation of Benefit and Cost Estimates Across Rules
    
        In table 16, we aggregated the estimates for individual rules from 
    tables 13 through 15 by year. This approach yields ex ante estimates of 
    the benefits and costs that Federal agencies expected from major rules 
    issued in each of the last three years.
        We have several important observations to offer on these aggregate 
    estimates. First, the 1996 HHS rule placing restrictions on the sale of 
    tobacco and EPA's 1997 rules revising the NAAQS for ozone and 
    particulate matter dominate the annualized and present value aggregates 
    presented in table 16. Changes in estimation methodology for these 
    rules, as reflected by the ``plausible range'' adopted by the analysis 
    for the EPA NAAQS rules for ozone and particulate matter, will have a 
    marked effect on the aggregated benefit and cost estimates for the 
    rules published over the period from April 1, 1995 to March 31, 1998. 
    By the same token, the aggregate estimates are not very sensitive to 
    different approaches for the remaining rules.
        The presentation of these aggregates as annualized benefit and cost 
    streams or as net present value estimates may obscure the actual timing 
    of benefits and costs. In the case of the tobacco rule, for example, 
    the annualized benefit estimates were estimated to be $9 to $10 billion 
    per year. However, the health benefits associated with successfully 
    reducing the number of young tobacco users will not begin to be 
    realized until after 2015 because of the lag in the adverse effects 
    associated with tobacco use.
        In addition, the benefits and costs of the revised ozone and 
    particulate matter NAAQS will only be realized in the years after 2005. 
    These estimates of ``out-year'' benefits and costs are also uncertain. 
    EPA will complete its next periodic review of the particulate matter 
    NAAQS, scheduled for 2002, before it begins implementation of the 
    revised particulate matter NAAQS. If this review yields a ``mid-
    course'' change in the standard, the estimates of benefits and costs 
    could change. EPA has also expressed a continuing concern with the 
    uncertainty of the full attainment cost estimates because EPA believes 
    technological change over the next decade will yield lower-cost 
    approaches that will achieve the revised NAAQS.
        Second, as noted above, there are significant methodological issues 
    that need to be confronted when aggregating estimates from a set of 
    individual rules (as presented in tables 13 through 15) in an effort to 
    obtain an estimate of the total benefits and costs of Federal 
    regulation. These issues include:
        (1) Adoption of a reasonable, consistent baseline (it is difficult 
    to patch together a sensible baseline from the differing baseline 
    scenarios adopted across rules).
        (2) The use of ex ante estimates (versus ex post estimates) of the 
    benefits and costs of regulation, e.g., the reliance on ex ante 
    estimates may well fail to reflect important changes in taste, 
    innovation by the private sector, or changes in Federal/State/local 
    regulation.
        (3) The ``apples and oranges'' problem associated with combining 
    estimates from different studies, i.e., different measures of benefits 
    and costs, double-counting of benefits and costs across related rules, 
    differing approaches to uncertainty such as the use of upper-and lower-
    bound estimates versus the use of an upper-bound only estimate, 
    different discount rates, etc.
        Because of these concerns with aggregating the prospective benefit 
    and cost estimates taken from the regulatory analysis for individual 
    rules, we are interested in comments on:
        (1) The merits of aggregating prospective estimates from individual 
    rules to obtain an aggregate estimate of the benefits and costs of 
    Federal regulation.
        (2) The best approach to address the concerns with baseline, ex 
    ante estimates, and the various ``apples and oranges'' problems 
    identified above.
        A final reason that any regulatory accounting effort has limits is 
    the lack of information on the effects of regulations on distribution 
    or equity. None of the analyses addressed in this report provides 
    quantitative information on the distribution of benefits or costs by 
    income category, geographic region, or any other equity-related factor. 
    As a result, there is no basis for quantifying distributional or equity 
    impacts.
    
    Chapter IV: Recommendations
    
        As with last year's report, this year's is to include 
    ``recommendations from the Director of OMB and a description of 
    significant public comments to reform or eliminate any Federal 
    regulatory program or program element that is inefficient, ineffective, 
    or is not a sound use of the Nation's resources' (section 625 (a)(4)). 
    We are soliciting comments on a wide range of issues related to our 
    discussion of the methodology used in evaluating total annual benefits 
    and costs of Federal regulatory programs and on estimates of the 
    benefits and costs of ``economically significant'' or ``major'' rules. 
    In particular, we are soliciting comments on our approach to estimating 
    the total costs and benefits of regulation by combining existing 
    retrospective or ex post studies with agency-produced prospective or ex 
    ante estimates; the best ways to deal with the baseline and apple and 
    oranges problems discussed above; and whether we have missed important 
    data sources that would fill in the gaps in our estimates. We are also 
    seeking comment on regulatory programs or program elements that are 
    ``inefficient, ineffective, or * * * not a sound use of the Nation's 
    resources.''
        In chapter I we presented aggregate estimates of the costs and 
    benefits of several categories of regulation to further the discussion 
    and generate comments that we hope will lead to better estimates. 
    However, these aggregate estimates are at best only general indicators 
    of the importance of regulation undertaken thus far and not guides to 
    future specific regulatory changes. We discussed at some length
    
    [[Page 44055]]
    
    the various shortcomings of these estimates, including the problem 
    that, most of them are based either on dated studies of existing 
    regulations or on estimates for proposed regulations.
        In chapter II, we presented the prospective cost and benefit data 
    that the agencies had estimated for the major rules that they issued 
    over the period April 1, 1997 to March 31, 1998. These data for 
    individual regulations show that in many, but not all cases, agencies 
    have done a good job following the recommendations of the Best 
    Practices document. The overall picture remains one of slow but steady 
    progress toward the Best Practices standards. In any case, even if Best 
    Practices are fully adhered to in developing regulations, these 
    prospective analyses alone would not be suitable for determining 
    whether existing regulatory programs or program elements should be 
    reformed or eliminated.
        In spite of these methodological difficulties, we believe that 
    prospective studies such as those discussed in chapter II do provide 
    useful general information about existing regulatory programs. In this 
    spirit, we developed in chapter III cost and benefit estimates for a 
    set of major regulations issued by the agencies over the last three 
    years by using standardized assumptions and common values on benefits 
    derived from agency practice and the academic literature. These values 
    and assumptions are not necessarily appropriate for all individual 
    regulations but when applied to a set of analyses offer additional 
    general information about agencies' regulatory systems. We are still in 
    the early stages of this process and seek comments on whether this line 
    of analysis should be pursued. In summary, at this stage we do not 
    believe it is appropriate to make recommendations on specific 
    regulatory programs based on the incomplete and uneven data that we 
    discuss at length above. We note, however, that agencies are continuing 
    to reform and improve their regulatory programs. These specific efforts 
    are described at length in the Regulatory Plan, published each fall 
    with the Unified Agenda of Federal Regulatory and Derergulatory 
    Actions.
        We have discerned some general themes during our review of the 
    academic literature and analysis of data on the economic impacts of 
    regulation. In particular, we note the general success of large scale 
    regulatory reforms that have embraced industrial or business sectors. 
    For example, the Federal government undertook reforms of the statutory 
    and regulatory regimes that governed practices in the airline, 
    trucking, and natural gas and oil markets in the 1970s and 1980s. The 
    Clinton Administration has continued this work with regulatory reforms 
    in banking, intrastate trucking, securities and financial services, 
    pensions, and telecommunications. In many of these areas, the older 
    regulatory schemes attempted to proscribe entry by firms into lines of 
    business or to limit production for reasons other than health, safety, 
    or environmental protection.
        Although there exist theoretical arguments that in the case of 
    natural monopolies entry of new firms could increase costs to 
    consumers, these arguments are based primarily on static models not 
    appropriate for our current dynamic, technological world. The 
    consistency of the movement toward regulatory reform over the past 25 
    years is a tribute to the benefits that flow from opened markets. It 
    appears that opening up markets to all qualified entities and 
    individuals has been and continues to be a mainstay of regulatory 
    reform. It is worth noting, however, that such regulatory reform does 
    not mean the end of regulation. While outmoded regulatory programs are 
    changed, new regulations are generally needed, particularly during 
    transitions between the old and new systems, to open up markets and 
    ensure that fair competition is maintained. For example, the 
    Telecommunications Act of 1996 directs the FCC to establish the 
    regulation that is needed to allow new entrants access to the local 
    network in order to establish competition in local telecommunications 
    markets. Without access to the local network, there would be little 
    competition.
    
    A. Electricity Restructuring
    
        A new regulatory area in which the Administration is recommending 
    reform is the decades old system of electricity generation. The 
    Administration has transmitted to Congress a bill that would 
    restructure this industry and bring substantial savings to consumers. 
    Economic forces are forging a new era in electricity prices, where 
    electricity prices will be determined primarily by the market rather 
    than by regulation. Under this new system, often called ``retail 
    choice,'' consumers are allowed to choose their electricity supplier, 
    much as they have chosen long distance telephone service for over a 
    decade. Electricity policy is moving in this direction because 
    subjecting utilities to competition will lead to increased efficiency 
    in the industry and thus benefit the economy and the environment.
        In the past, electricity customers did not have the ability to 
    choose their supplier. Instead, under State law, utilities generally 
    were monopolies with both a right and responsibility to serve all 
    consumers in a particular area. The State permitted the utility to 
    charge customers a regulated rate for electric power based on the cost 
    of producing such power plus a ``rate of return'' on investment. In 
    general, the electric monopoly system has provided reliable power to 
    electric consumers in the United States. However, a monopoly system has 
    a fundamental weakness: it does not provide incentives to be cost-
    efficient because a monopoly supplier does not have to compete and 
    essentially has a guarantee that its costs will be recovered.
        Under electricity restructuring, competition will replace 
    regulation as the primary mechanism for setting electricity generation 
    prices. Utilities would be required to open up their distribution and 
    transmission wires to all qualified sellers. The transmission and 
    distribution of electricity would continue to be regulated because they 
    will remain monopolies for the foreseeable future. The system would be 
    restructured, not completely deregulated.
    1. The Need for Federal Action
        The Administration's proposal respects the actions of those States 
    which are in the process of implementing retail competition and seeks 
    to build on, rather than disrupt, those efforts. Nevertheless, 
    effective retail competition is unlikely to happen without Federal 
    legislation. First, electrons do not respect State borders. 
    Accordingly, as States remove the constraints of monopoly franchise 
    territories, electricity markets will naturally become more 
    regionalized.
        Only federal legislation can adequately address the needs of these 
    regional markets. For example, to allow for effective and efficient 
    competitive markets, FERC must have regulatory jurisdiction over all 
    owners of transmission facilities. Currently, FERC has no regulatory 
    authority to order open access to transmission facilities by municipal 
    utilities, cooperatives, or federal power entities. Moreover, effective 
    competitive markets require that FERC be given additional regulatory 
    authority to require the formation of Independent System Operators and 
    to address market power issues.
        The electric industry is also hampered by statutes which inhibit 
    the development of competitive markets. The entire Federal electricity 
    law framework dates from the New Deal and is premised upon State-
    regulated monopolies rather than regional
    
    [[Page 44056]]
    
    competitive markets. Federal law should be updated so that it 
    stimulates, rather than stifles, competition. For example, the Public 
    Utility Holding Company Act, which regulates utility holding companies, 
    and the ``must buy'' provision of section 210 of the Public Utility 
    Regulatory Policies Act, which requires that utilities buy power from 
    qualified cogenerators and small power producers, should be repealed.
        Finally, the States alone cannot obtain the full economic and 
    environmental benefits of competition for American consumers. Without 
    comprehensive Federal electricity restructuring legislation, neither 
    State nor Federal regulators will have the necessary tools to ensure 
    that regional electricity markets are truly competitive and operate as 
    efficiently as possible. Moreover, absent a Federal role, there will be 
    no assurances that support for renewable technologies and other 
    important public purpose programs will continue absent a Federal 
    program. Without such tools, electricity prices will likely be higher 
    and the environmental gains which we expect under the Administration's 
    plan will not be fully realized.
    2. Benefits of Electricity Restructuring
        The Comprehensive Electricity Competition Plan embodies the overall 
    agenda of the Clinton Administration to expand the economy and improve 
    the environment. A more competitive electricity industry will provide 
    large benefits to individual American consumers as well as being an 
    overall boon to our economy. It will result in lower prices, a cleaner 
    environment, greater innovation and new services, and a more reliable 
    power supply grid. It will also save the government money.
        The Department of Energy estimates that retail competition will 
    save consumers at least $20 billion a year on their electricity bills. 
    This translates into direct savings to the typical family of four of 
    $104 per year. Indirect savings, which would arise from the lower costs 
    of other goods and services in a competitive market, are $128 per year 
    for a typical family of four. Thus, total projected savings for such a 
    family are $232 a year.
        Competition will also spark innovation in the American economy, 
    creating new industries, jobs, products and services just as 
    telecommunications reform spawned cellular phones and other new 
    technologies. This will further strengthen our nation's position as the 
    most vibrant and dynamic economy in the world.
        Major benefits will accrue to the Federal, State and local 
    governments through lower electricity prices. Total government spending 
    on electricity was $19.5 billion in 1995. With competition, these costs 
    are likely to decline by at least 10 percent, a savings of close to $2 
    billion year. This restructuring dividend will help governments 
    maintain balanced budgets into the future while meeting critical public 
    needs.
        Restructuring will also produce significant environmental benefits 
    through both market mechanisms and policies that promote investment in 
    energy efficiency and renewable energy. Competitive forces will create 
    an efficient, leaner, and cleaner industry. For, example, DOE estimates 
    that the Administration's plan will reduce greenhouse gas emissions by 
    roughly 25 to 40 million metric tons in 2010. A generator that wrings 
    as much energy as it can from every unit of fuel will be rewarded by 
    the market. Today, a monopoly supplier recovers its costs regardless of 
    whether it uses its power resources efficiently. Competition also 
    provides opportunities for consumers to vote with their wallets for 
    green power and facilitates the marketing of energy efficiency services 
    along with electricity.
        Restructuring also makes possible the introduction of new policy 
    mechanisms such as the renewable portfolio standard and enhanced public 
    benefit funding, which will guarantee substantial environmental 
    benefits notwithstanding market outcomes. The environmental benefits 
    from the Administration's restructuring plan, which includes the 
    renewable portfolio standard and the public benefit fund, will outweigh 
    any negative effects associated with the demand increasing effects of 
    lower prices or other factors.
        The Administration's proposal for electricity competition 
    legislation reflect the need for the simultaneous calibration of many 
    elements in an interconnected statutory framework in order to achieve 
    the desired bottom line: achieving the economic benefits of competition 
    in a manner that is fair and improves the environmental performance of 
    the electricity industry.
        Our restructuring proposal is best understood in terms of five main 
    objectives: (1) Encouraging States to implement retail competition; (2) 
    protecting consumers by facilitating competitive markets; (3) assuring 
    access to and reliability of the transmission system; (4) promoting and 
    preserving public benefits; and (5) amending existing Federal statutes 
    to clarify Federal and State authority.
    
    B. Need for Further Methodological Progress: Steps Taken, Steps Needed
    
        Last year we made five recommendations to improve the quality of 
    data and analysis on individual regulations and on regulatory programs 
    and program elements as a first step toward developing the evidence 
    needed to propose major changes in regulatory programs:
         That OIRA lead an effort among the agencies to raise the 
    quality of analyses used in developing new regulations by promoting 
    greater use of the Best Practices guidelines and by offering technical 
    outreach programs and training sessions on the guidelines;
         That an interagency group subject a selected number of 
    agency regulatory analyses to ex post disinterested peer review in 
    order to identify areas that need improvement and stimulate the 
    development of better estimation techniques more useful for assessing 
    existing regulations;
         That OIRA continue to develop a data base on benefits and 
    costs of major rules by using consistent assumptions and better 
    estimation techniques to refine agency estimates of incremental costs 
    and benefits of regulatory programs and elements;
         That OIRA continue to work on developing methodologies 
    appropriate for evaluating whether existing regulatory programs or 
    their elements should be reformed or eliminated using its Best 
    Practices document as the starting point; and
         That OIRA work toward a system to track the net benefits 
    (benefits minus costs) provided by new regulations and reforms of 
    existing regulations for use in determining the specific regulatory 
    reforms or eliminations, if any, to recommend.
        To implement these recommendations, we took several specific steps, 
    which should be viewed as first steps in an ongoing effort:
         After the September 30, 1997 report was issued, we met 
    with interested parties to hear their suggestions for implementing its 
    recommendations and improving the next report. The interested parties 
    included Congressional staffs, agency officials, academic experts, and 
    the public at large at a well attended open meeting sponsored by the 
    Brookings Institution and the American Enterprise Institute. We also 
    put the report on the OMB home page at: http://www.whitehouse.gov/WH/
    EOP/OMB/html/rcongress.htm and distributed hundreds of hard copies to 
    the interested public. We also discussed the report with our regulatory 
    counterparts
    
    [[Page 44057]]
    
    from other countries and with officials at the OECD studying regulatory 
    reform. These discussions have been very helpful, and their influences 
    are reflected in this year's report.
         On December 12, 1997, the Administrator of OIRA sent a 
    memorandum to the Regulatory Working Group made up of the top 
    regulatory officials of the key agencies, requesting that they give 
    greater attention to the analysis of economically significant rules and 
    to focus specifically on the Best Practices guidance. The memorandum 
    also told the agencies of our intention to disaggregate further our 
    total benefit and cost estimates and to provide more information on 
    economically significant rules, including filling gaps by monetizing 
    benefit estimates where the agencies had quantified but not monetized. 
    We have followed up the memorandum with meetings of the Regulatory 
    Working Group and discussions with individual agency officials that 
    emphasized the importance of good analysis.
         We reviewed examples of ex post analyses, including those 
    of NHTSA, OSHA, and EPA regulations. This review helped contribute to 
    an investigation of the methodological problems associated with 
    regulatory analysis.
         We convened a meeting of an Interagency Technical Working 
    Group (ITWG) of staff from the major regulatory agencies co-chaired by 
    CEA to examine the methodological issues raised in the first report, 
    review existing regulatory analyses, and propose better estimation 
    techniques useful in evaluating new and existing 
    regulations.35 The group met several times a month 
    throughout the first half of 1998, and invited individuals with 
    recognized expertise to make presentations about estimation methods. 
    The group heard presentations on methods of estimating the value of 
    mortality risk reduction, the quantification of morbidity, the value of 
    wetlands, and the value of changes in travel time. Materials used in 
    these presentations are available in the OIRA public docket room. Based 
    on these presentations, and its own discussions, the group considered 
    the following recommendations to OMB in the context of OMB's report to 
    Congress:
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \35\ It included representatives of DOE, Commerce, USDA, 
    Treasury, HUD, Interior, Labor, NHTSA, Education, FDA, and EPA as 
    well as CEA and OMB.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        (1) That OMB complete agency estimates of reductions in mortality 
    risk by estimating the additional longevity, e.g., years of life 
    gained, to complement conventional estimates of statistical lives 
    saved, in instances where supportable methods exist.
        (2) That OMB complete agency estimates of small reductions in 
    mortality risk by estimating the value of these changes using 
    appropriate unit values from the literature on willingness-to-pay.
        (3) That OMB complete agency estimates of the value of reductions 
    in morbidity, taking into account lags, e.g., ``latency'' periods, if 
    any, in the realization of harm due to disease or injury, using a range 
    of appropriate discount rates.
        (4) That OMB complete agency estimates of reductions in morbidity 
    by estimating (1) the value of cases of disease or injury averted, 
    where there are independent estimates of willingness-to-pay to reduce 
    the risks of such disease or injury, and (2) where appropriate 
    willingness-to-pay estimates are not available, an index of loss in 
    function relative to death, such as a quality adjusted life-year 
    approach.
        (5) OMB not generally assign values to agency estimates of changes 
    in the quantity or quality of wetlands, without specific information 
    justifying the appropriateness of the unit values to the wetlands 
    affected, given the wide variety of wetlands.
        Recommendations (1) and (5) were adopted unanimously. Although the 
    other recommendations enjoyed support from a majority of agencies, they 
    were not supported unanimously. Another recommendation on the value of 
    increases or decreases in travel time was discussed, but no 
    recommendation has yet been made.
         As the report itself shows, we have begun to implement the 
    recommendations that the ITWG discussed and considered in order to 
    develop a data base on the costs and benefits of major rules using 
    consistent assumptions and better estimation techniques to refine 
    estimates of the incremental costs and benefits of regulatory programs 
    and individual regulations. We hope this will enable us to move closer 
    toward developing a system to track the net benefits provided by new 
    regulations and reforms of existing regulation and for identification 
    of specific regulatory reform proposals.
        Last year's report established a much needed baseline from which 
    progress toward better data and methods regarding the impacts of 
    Federal regulation can be measured. We indicated that this statutory 
    charge was an ambitious one, but believe a good start was made. This 
    year we report steady progress toward better data and improved 
    analysis. We have refined the aggregate estimates of benefits and 
    costs; made progress in establishing more consistent data for ongoing 
    benefit-cost analyses; widened our own data base from one to three 
    years; further analyzed and refined our understanding of methodological 
    difficulties; and recommended reform in the electricity generation 
    industry.
        We continue to view the task as a formidable one that must be 
    approached with the expectation of a long steady movement forward. We 
    believe this report represents a significant step down that path. We 
    intend to continue these efforts to improve the quality of data and 
    analysis needed to put us in a stronger position to continue to make 
    more recommendations for regulatory reforms.
    
    Bibliography
    
    Brown, R. Scott and Ian Savage, ``The Economics of Double-Hulled 
    Tankers'' Maritime Policy and Management, Vol. 23, No. 2 (1996).
    Crandall, Robert W., et al. An Agenda For Federal Regulatory Reform 
    (Washington D.C.: American Enterprise Institute and the Brookings 
    Institution, 1997).
    Crandall, Robert W., Howard Gruenspecht, Ted Keeler and Lester Lave. 
    Regulating the Automobile (Washington D.C.: Brookings Institution, 
    1986).
    Crandall, Robert W. ``What Ever Happened to Deregulation?'' in David 
    Boaz (ed.) Assessing the Reagan Years (Washington D.C.: Cato 
    Institution, 1988).
    Cropper, Maureen L. and Wallace E. Oates. ``Environmental Economics: 
    A Survey,'' Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 30, No. 2 (June 
    1992).
    Denison, Edward F. Accounting for Slower Economic Growth: The U.S. 
    in the 1970s (Washington D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1979).
    Dudley, Susan E. And Angela Antonelli, ``Congress and the Clinton 
    OMB: Unwilling Partners in Regulatory Oversight,'' Regulation (Fall 
    1997).
    Eads, George C. and Michael Fix. Relief or Reform? Reagan's 
    Regulatory Dilemma (Washington, D.C.: The Urban Institute Press, 
    1984).
    Elliehausen, Gregory. The Cost of Bank Regulation: A Review of the 
    Evidence (Washington D.C.: Federal Reserve Board Staff Study, 1997).
    Gardner, Bruce L. Protection of U.S. Agriculture: Why, How, and Who 
    Loses? (University of Maryland Dept. Agriculture and Resource 
    Economics Working Paper No. 87-15).
    Grant Thorton. Regulatory Burden: The Cost to Community Banks, A 
    study prepared by the Independent Bankers Association of America, 
    (1993).
    Gray, W. B. ``The Cost of Regulation: OSHA, EPA, and the 
    Productivity Slowdown,'' American Economic Review, (December 1987).
    
    [[Page 44058]]
    
    Hahn, Robert W. and John A. Hird. ``The Costs and Benefits of 
    Regulation: Review and Synthesis,'' Yale Journal on Regulation, 
    (Vol. 8, No. 1, Winter 1991).
    Hahn, Robert W. and Robert E. Litan. Improving Regulatory 
    Accountability (Washington D.C.: American Enterprise Institute and 
    the Brooks Institution, 1997).
    Hahn, Robert W. ``Regulatory Reform: Assessing the Government's 
    Numbers'' in Reviving Regulatory Reform: A Global Perspective, 
    (Cambridge University Press and A.I. Press, Forthcoming).
    Hahn, Robert W. ``Regulatory Reform: What do the Numbers Tell Us?'' 
    in Hahn, Robert W., ed., Risks, Costs, and Lives Saved: Getting 
    Better Results From Regulation, (New York: Oxford University Press 
    and A.I. Press, 1996).
    Hazilla, Michael and Raymond Kopp. ``Social Cost of Environmental 
    Quality Regulations: A General Equilibrium Analysis,'' Journal of 
    Political Economy, (Vol. 98, No. 4, 1990).
    Himmelstein, David U. and Steffie Woolhandler. ``Cost Without 
    Benefit: Administrative Waste in U.S. Health Care,'' The New England 
    Journal of Medicine, (Vol. 314, No. 7, February, 13, 1986).
    Hopkins, Thomas D. ``Cost of Regulation,'' Report Prepared for the 
    Regulatory Information Service Center, Washington, D.C., (August 
    1991).
    Hopkins, Thomas D. ``Cost of Regulation: Filling the Gaps,'' Report 
    Prepared for the Regulatory Information Service Center, Washington 
    D.C., (August 1992).
    Hopkins, Thomas D. ``Profiles of Regulatory Costs,'' Report to U.S. 
    Small Business Administration, (November 1995).
    Hopkins, Thomas D. ``OMB's Regulatory Accounting Report Falls Short 
    of the Mark,'' Center for the Study of American Business (October 
    1997).
    Hopkins, Thomas D. ``Regulatory Costs in Profile,'' Policy Study No. 
    132, Center for the Study of American Business, (August 1996).
    Hufbauer, Gary C., Diane T. Berliner and Kimberly Ann Elliot. Trade 
    Protection in the United States (Washington, D.C.: Institute for 
    International Economics, 1986).
    Jaffe, Adam B., Steven R. Peterson, Paul R. Portney and Robert 
    Stavins. ``Environmental Regulation and the Competitiveness of U.S. 
    Manufacturing,'' Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 33, No. 1 
    (March 1995).
    James Jr., Harvey S. Estimating OSHA Compliance Costs, Center for 
    the Study of American Business (October 1996).
    Jorgenson, Dale W. and Peter J. Wilcoxen. ``Environmental Regulation 
    and U.S. Economic Growth,'' Rand Journal of Economics (Vol. 21, No. 
    2, Summer 1990).
    Kahane, Charles J., The Effectiveness of Center High-Mounted Stop 
    Lamps: A Preliminary Evaluation. Technical Report No. DOT HS 807 
    076. Washington, DC: National Highway Traffic Safety Administration, 
    (1987).
    Kahane, Charles J., An Evaluation of Center High-Mounted Stop Lamps 
    Based on 1987 Data. Technical Report No. DOT HS 807 442. Washington, 
    DC: National Highway Traffic Safety Administration, (1989).
    Kahane, Charles J., and Ellen Hertz. Long-Term Effectiveness of 
    Center High-Mounted Stop Lamps in Passenger Cars and Light Trucks. 
    Technical Report No. DOT HS 808 696. Washington, DC: National 
    Highway Traffic Safety Administration, (1998).
    Litan, Robert E. and William D. Nordhaus. Reforming Federal 
    Regulation (New Haven, Ct.: Yale University Press, 1983).
    Morrison, Steven A. and Clifford Winston. The Economic Effects of 
    Airline Deregulation (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 
    1986).
    Morrison, Steven A. and Clifford Winston. ``Enhancing Performance of 
    the Deregulated Air Transportation System, ``Brookings Papers on 
    Economic Activity: Microeconomics, 1989.
    Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. The OECD 
    Report on Regulatory Reform Volume I: Sectoral Studies (Paris: 
    1997).
    U.S., Council of Economic Advisers. Economic Report of the President 
    (February 1997).
    U.S., Environmental Protection Agency. Environmental Investments: 
    The Cost of a Clean Environment (December 1990).
    U.S., Environmental Protection Agency. Technical and Economic 
    Capacity of States and Public Water Systems to Implement Drinking 
    Water Regulations--Report to Congress (1993).
    U.S., Environmental Protection Agency. 1972-1992 Retrospective 
    Analysis: Impacts of Municipal Treatment Improvement for Inland 
    Waterways (1995).
    U.S., Environmental Protection Agency. The Benefits and Costs of the 
    Clean Air Act, 1970-1990 (October 1997).
    U.S., General Accounting Office. Regulatory Burden: Measurement 
    Challenges Raised by Selected Companies (November 1996).
    U.S., General Accounting Office. Regulatory Reform: Agencies Could 
    Improve Development, Documentation, and Clarity of Regulatory 
    Analyses (May 1998).
    U.S., General Accounting Office. Regulatory Reform: Information on 
    Costs, Cost-Effectiveness, and Mandated Deadlines for Regulations 
    (March 1995).
    U.S., General Accounting Office. Regulatory Reform: Major Rules 
    Submitted for Congressional Review During the First 2 Years (April 
    1998).
    U.S., National Highway Traffic Safety Administration. [Preliminary] 
    Regulatory Impact Analysis, Federal Motor Vehicle Safety Standard 
    108, Center High-Mounted Stoplamps, Washington, DC (1980).
    U.S., National Highway Traffic Safety Administration. Final 
    Regulatory Impact Analysis, Federal Motor Vehicle Safety Standard 
    108, Center High-Mounted Stoplamps. Washington, DC (1983).
    U.S., Office of Management and Budget. More Benefits Fewer Burdens: 
    Creating a Regulatory System that Works for the American People 
    (December 1996).
    U.S., Office of Management and Budget, Report to Congress On the 
    Costs and Benefits of Federal Regulations (September 30, 1997).
    U.S., Office of Management and Budget, Reports to Congress Under the 
    Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995 (September 1997).
    U.S., Office of Management and Budget. Information Collection Budget 
    of The United States Government (Various Years).
    U.S., Office of Technology Assessment. Gauging Control Technology 
    and Regulatory Impacts in Occupational Safety and Health (September 
    1995).
    U.S. Small Business Administration. The Changing Burden of 
    Regulation, Paperwork, and Tax Compliance on Small Business: A 
    Report to Congress (October 1995).
    Viscusi, W. Kip. Fatal Tradeoffs: Public and Private 
    Responsibilities for Risk (New York: Oxford University Press, 1992).
    Viscusi, W. Kip. Risk by Choice: Regulating Health and Safety in the 
    Workplace (Cambridge Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1983).
    Weidenbaum, Murray L. and Robert DeFina. ``The Cost of Federal 
    Regulation of Economic Activity,'' (Washington D.C.: American 
    Enterprise Institute, 1978).
    Wenders, J. The Economics of Telecommunications: Theory and 
    Practice, 83 (1987).
    White, Lawrence J. The S&L Debacle: Public Policy Lessons for Bank 
    and Thrift Regulation (New York: Oxford University Press, 1991).
    BILLING CODE 3110-01-P
    
    Tables for Draft Report
    
    [[Page 44059]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.000
    
    
    
    [[Page 44060]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.001
    
    
    
    [[Page 44061]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.002
    
    
    
    [[Page 44062]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.003
    
    
    
    [[Page 44063]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.004
    
    
    
    [[Page 44064]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.005
    
    
    
    [[Page 44065]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.006
    
    
    
    [[Page 44066]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.007
    
    
    
    [[Page 44067]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.008
    
    
    
    [[Page 44068]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.009
    
    
    
    [[Page 44069]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.010
    
    
    
    [[Page 44070]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.011
    
    
    
    [[Page 44071]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.012
    
    
    
    [[Page 44072]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.013
    
    
    
    [[Page 44073]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.014
    
    
    
    [[Page 44074]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.015
    
    
    
    [[Page 44075]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.016
    
    
    
    [[Page 44076]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.017
    
    
    
    [[Page 44077]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.018
    
    
    
    [[Page 44078]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.019
    
    
    
    [[Page 44079]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.020
    
    
    
    [[Page 44080]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.021
    
    
    
    [[Page 44081]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.022
    
    
    
    [[Page 44082]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.023
    
    
    
    [[Page 44083]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.024
    
    
    
    [[Page 44084]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.025
    
    
    
    [[Page 44085]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.026
    
    
    
    [[Page 44086]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.027
    
    
    
    [[Page 44087]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.028
    
    
    
    [[Page 44088]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.029
    
    
    
    [[Page 44089]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.030
    
    
    
    [[Page 44090]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.031
    
    
    
    [[Page 44091]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.032
    
    
    
    [[Page 44092]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.033
    
    
    
    [[Page 44093]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.034
    
    
    
    [[Page 44094]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.035
    
    
    
    [[Page 44095]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.036
    
    
    
    [[Page 44096]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.037
    
    
    
    [[Page 44097]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.038
    
    
    
    [[Page 44098]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.039
    
    
    
    [[Page 44099]]
    
    [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17AU98.040
    
    
    
    [FR Doc. 98-21938 Filed 8-14-98; 8:45 am]
    BILLING CODE 3110-01-C
    
    
    

Document Information

Published:
08/17/1998
Department:
Management and Budget Office
Entry Type:
Notice
Action:
Notice and request for comments.
Document Number:
98-21938
Dates:
To ensure consideration of comments as OMB prepares this draft report for submission to Congress on or before September 30, 1998, comments must be in writing and received by OMB no later than September 16, 1998.
Pages:
44034-44099 (66 pages)
PDF File:
98-21938.pdf