99-22131. Telephone Number Portability  

  • [Federal Register Volume 64, Number 165 (Thursday, August 26, 1999)]
    [Rules and Regulations]
    [Pages 46571-46584]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 99-22131]
    
    
    =======================================================================
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
    
    47 CRF Part 52
    
    [CC Docket No. 95-116; FCC 99-151]
    
    
    Telephone Number Portability
    
    AGENCY: Federal Communications Commission.
    
    ACTION: Policy statement.
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    SUMMARY: This document addresses issues raised on reconsideration of 
    the First Report and Order relating to interim number portability. 
    First, the Commission affirms its earlier conclusion that it has the 
    authority to establish cost recovery guidelines for interim number 
    portability. Second, the Commission rejects claims that the cost 
    recovery guidelines for interim number portability set forth in the 
    First Report and Order are arbitrary and capricious, or constitute an 
    unconstitutional taking. The Commission denies the request that these 
    cost recovery guidelines be applied retroactively. The Commission also 
    affirms its earlier decision to adopt general cost recovery guidelines 
    for interim number portability while allowing states flexibility to 
    continue using a variety of cost recovery approaches that are 
    consistent with its guidelines. The Commission also clarifies issues 
    relating to terminating access charges, billing system modifications, 
    and certain cost recovery allocators, as each of these issues relates 
    to interim number portability.
    
    DATES: Effective September 27, 1999.
    
    FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Rhonda Lien or Janet Sievert at (202) 
    418-1520, Competitive Pricing Division, Common Carrier Bureau.
    
    SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This summarizes the Commission's Fourth 
    Memorandum Opinion and Order on Reconsideration in CC Docket No. 95-
    116, In re Telephone Number Portability, FCC 99-151, adopted June 23, 
    1999 and released July 16, 1999. The file in its entirety is available 
    for inspection and copying during the weekday hours of 9:00 a.m. to 
    4:30 p.m. in the Commission's Reference Center, 445 12th St. SW., Room 
    CY-A257, Washington DC, or copies may be purchased from the 
    Commission's duplicating contractor, ITS Inc., 1231 20th St. NW., 
    Washington DC 20036; (202) 857-3088.
    
    Analysis of Proceeding
    
    I. Introduction
    
        The Commission adopted the First Report and Order and Further 
    Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 61 FR 38605 (July 25, 1996) in this 
    docket, which implemented the provisions of section 251 of the 
    Communications Act of 1934, as amended, that relate to telephone number 
    portability. In re Telephone Number Portability, CC Docket No. 95-116, 
    First Report and Order and Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 11 
    FCC Rcd 8352 (1996) (First Report and Order). Specifically, section 
    251(b)(2) requires that all local exchange carriers (LECs) provide, 
    ``to the extent technically feasible, number portability in accordance 
    with requirements prescribed by the Commission.'' 47 U.S.C. 251(b)(2). 
    Section 251(e)(2) provides that ``the costs of establishing * * * 
    number portability shall be borne by all telecommunications carriers on 
    a competitively neutral basis as determined by the Commission.'' 47 
    U.S.C. 251(e)(2). The Communications Act of 1934, as amended (``the 
    Act'' or ``the 1996 Act'') defines ``number portability'' as ``the 
    ability of users of telecommunications services to retain, at the same 
    location, existing telecommunications numbers without impairment of 
    quality, reliability, or convenience when switching from one 
    telecommunications carrier to another.'' 47 U.S.C. 153(30). In the 
    First Report and Order, the Commission determined, among other things, 
    that it has authority under section 251 to promulgate rules regarding 
    long-term and currently available (or ``interim'') number portability, 
    as well as to establish cost recovery methods for each.
        Twenty-two parties filed petitions for reconsideration or 
    clarification of the First Report and Order. Nineteen parties filed 
    oppositions to or comments on the petitions, and 16 parties filed reply 
    comments. On March 6, 1997, the Commission adopted a First Memorandum 
    Opinion and Order on Reconsideration, 62 FR 18280 (April 15, 1997) in 
    this proceeding, addressing a number of these issues. In re Telephone 
    Number Portability, CC Docket 95-116, First Memorandum Opinion and 
    Order on Reconsideration, 12 FCC Rcd 7236 (1997). A Second Memorandum 
    Opinion and Order on Reconsideration, 63 FR 68197 (Dec. 10, 1998) 
    clarified that all LECs must discontinue using interim number 
    portability in areas where a long-term number portability method has 
    been implemented. In re
    
    [[Page 46572]]
    
    Telephone Number Portability, CC Docket 95-116, Second Memorandum 
    Opinion and Order on Reconsideration, 13 FCC Rcd 21,204 (1998). The 
    item also clarified that Remote Call Forwarding (RCF) and Flexible 
    Direct Inward Dialing (DID) are not the exclusive methods of providing 
    interim number portability that LECs are obligated to provide on a 
    transitional basis. Instead, LECs may implement any technically 
    feasible method of interim number portability comparable to RCF and 
    DID. The Commission also held that a LEC is required to implement the 
    specific method of interim number portability requested by a competing 
    carrier, provided that provision of the requested method is not unduly 
    burdensome. A Third Memorandum Opinion and Order on Reconsideration. CC 
    Docket No. 95-116, 13 FCC Rcd 16,090 (1998) denied a petition for 
    reconsideration that sought modification to the long-term number 
    portability deployment schedule. In its Third Report and Order on 
    number portability, 63 FR 35150 (June 29, 1998), CC Docket No. 95-116, 
    13 FCC Rcd 11,701 (1998), the Commission adopted rules governing 
    recovery of the costs of long-term number portability. In this Fourth 
    Memorandum Opinion and Order on Reconsideration, the Commission 
    addresses issues raised by petitioners relating to cost recovery for 
    interim number portability.
    
    II. Background
    
        3. In the First Report and Order, the Commission exercised its 
    authority to prescribe requirements governing the LECs' duty to provide 
    number portability. After determining that section 251(b)(2) requires 
    LECs to provide number portability in the short term, the Commission 
    prescribed that such number portability be provided through Remote Call 
    Forwarding (RCF), Flexible Direct Inward Dialing (DID), or other 
    comparable methods. The Commission based this finding on its conclusion 
    that section 251(b)(2), by referring to the provision of number 
    portability ``to the extent technically feasible,'' creates a dynamic 
    requirement that allows for changes in the methods by which a LEC 
    provides the required number portability. Accordingly, the Commission 
    concluded that because RCF, DID, and other comparable measures 
    currently are technically feasible number portability methods, section 
    251(b)(2) requires LECs to provide number portability through such 
    methods. The Commission stated that, upon receipt of a specific request 
    from another telecommunications carrier, a LEC must provide number 
    portability through such measures as soon as reasonably possible, until 
    such time as the LEC implements a long-term database method for number 
    portability in that area.
        4. In light of its finding that the Communications Act requires 
    LECs to provide interim number portability, the Commission also 
    determined that it must adopt cost recovery principles for interim 
    number portability measures pursuant to section 251(e)(2). The 
    Commission concluded that section 251(e)(2) ``gives us specific 
    authority to prescribe pricing principles that ensure that the costs of 
    establishing number portability are allocated on a `competitively 
    neutral' basis.'' Applying section 251(e)(2) to interim number 
    portability, the Commission concluded that it should adopt guidelines 
    that the states must follow in mandating cost recovery mechanisms for 
    interim number portability measures.
        5. Section 251(e)(2) requires that ``the costs of establishing 
    number administration and number portability be borne by all 
    telecommunications carriers on a competitively neutral basis.'' 47 
    U.S.C. 251(e)(2). In the First Report and Order, the Commission 
    determined that the costs of currently available (referred to here as 
    interim) number portability are those ``incremental costs incurred by a 
    LEC to transfer numbers initially and subsequently forward calls to new 
    service providers.'' The Commission also determined that for purposes 
    of interim number portability, the phrase ``all telecommunications 
    carriers'' was to be read literally, and included ``any provider of 
    telecommunications services,'' including incumbent LECs, new LECs, 
    commercial mobile radio service (CMRS) providers, and interexchange 
    carriers (IXCs).
        6. The Commission also set forth two criteria with which any cost 
    recovery method must comply in order to be considered competitively 
    neutral. First, ``a `competitively neutral' cost recovery mechanism 
    should not give one service provider an appreciable, incremental cost 
    advantage over another service provider, when competing for a specific 
    subscriber.'' Second, the cost recovery mechanism ``should not have a 
    disparate effect on the ability of competing service providers to earn 
    normal returns on their investments.'' In the First Report and Order, 
    the Commission provided some examples of methods currently in use that 
    would comply with these criteria. Such methods include, but are not 
    limited to: allocating incremental costs based on (a) the number of 
    ported numbers, (b) the number of active telephone numbers, (c) the 
    number of active telephone lines, (d) gross telecommunications revenues 
    net of charges paid to other carriers; and (e) each carrier bearing its 
    own costs. The Commission further stated that requiring new entrants to 
    bear all of the costs of interim number portability, measured on the 
    basis of incremental costs, would not comply with the statutory 
    requirements of section 251(e)(2). In setting forth these criteria, 
    however, the Commission left to the states the determination of the 
    specific cost recovery mechanism to be utilized. On May 5, 1998, the 
    Commission adopted a Third Report and Order that resolved numerous 
    issues regarding the means by which carriers will bear the costs of 
    providing long-term number portability. The Commission found that 
    section 251(e)(2) expressly and unconditionally grants the Commission 
    authority, and requires the Commission, to ensure that all 
    telecommunications carriers bear the costs of providing number 
    portability for interstate and intrastate calls on a competitively 
    neutral basis. The Commission concluded that section 251(e)(2) 
    addresses both interstate and intrastate matters and overrides the 
    reservation of authority of section 2(b) to the states over intrastate 
    matters. Thus, the Commission determined that section 251(e)(2) 
    authorizes it to provide the distribution and cost recovery mechanism 
    for all the costs of providing long-term number portability. The 
    Commission determined that an exclusively federal recovery mechanism 
    for long-term number portability ``will enable the Commission to 
    satisfy most directly its competitive neutrality mandate.''
    
    II. Reconsideration Issues
    
    A. Commission Authority To Require Interim Number Portability
    
    1. Background
        7. In the First Report and Order, the Commission required LECs to 
    provide interim number portability, based on the 1996 Act's requirement 
    that LECs provide number portability ``to the extent technically 
    feasible.'' The Commission based this conclusion on the language of 
    section 251(b)(2), which states that LECs have ``[t]he duty to provide, 
    to the extent technically feasible, number portability in accordance 
    with requirements prescribed by the Commission.'' Several carriers 
    challenge the Commission's finding that the 1996 Act provides authority 
    for the Commission to order LECs to provide interim number portability.
    
    [[Page 46573]]
    
    2. Discussion
        8. The Commission reaffirms its earlier conclusion that it has 
    authority to require that number portability be implemented ``to the 
    extent technically feasible'' and that its authority under section 
    251(b)(2) encompasses all forms of number portability. Section 3(30) of 
    the Act defines number portability as ``the ability of users of 
    telecommunications services to retain, at the same location, existing 
    telecommunications numbers without impairment of quality, reliability, 
    or convenience when switching from one telecommunications carrier to 
    another.'' This definition is not limited to any one technical method 
    of number portability. Nor is the duty of LECs pursuant to section 
    251(b)(2), to provide number portability ``to the extent technically 
    feasible . . . in accordance with requirements prescribed by the 
    Commission,'' limited to long-term number portability. The Commission 
    acknowledges that some ambiguity exists regarding the statutory mandate 
    to require the provision of interim number portability, because, while 
    sections 251(b) and 3(30) refer to the provision of ``number 
    portability,'' section 271(c)(2)(B) refers to both ``regulations 
    pursuant to section 251 to require number portability'' and ``interim 
    number portability'' to be provided by Bell Operating Companies (BOCs) 
    until the Commission issues such regulations.'' See 47 U.S.C. 
    251(b)(2), 271(c)(2)B)(ix), 153(30). The Commission finds, however, 
    that its earlier interpretation of section 251(b)(2), that is, 
    requiring all LECs to provide number portability to the extent 
    technically feasible, is consistent with, and necessary to effectuate, 
    Congress's goal to promote competition in the provision of local 
    telecommunications service. Indeed, prior Commission decisions reflect 
    its understanding of Congress's intent, stated in the First Report and 
    Order, that number portability is a dynamic concept that allows for 
    changes in the methods by which LECs provide it. Additionally, in 
    placing number portability obligations within section 251, which is 
    concerned overall with the development of competitive local markets, 
    Congress recognized the importance of number portability to the 
    development of local competition. Because the statutory language, like 
    the language in the House bill, requires LECs to provide number 
    portability ``to the extent technically feasible'' and according to 
    requirements prescribed by the Commission, rather than ``when 
    technically feasible,'' the Commission does not believe that this 
    legislative history suggests an intent by Congress to prevent the 
    Commission from requiring LECs to provide ``interim,'' ``currently 
    available,'' or ``transitional'' number portability until ``true'' 
    number portability becomes available.
        9. The Commission finds unpersuasive BellSouth's contention that, 
    because Congress considered including a specific reference to interim 
    number portability, but did not adopt it in section 251(b), the lack of 
    such language demonstrates that the Commission is without jurisdiction 
    in this area, in particular regarding language set forth in section 261 
    of Senate Bill 652. This language was not included in the final version 
    of the legislation. Because the legislative history provides no 
    explanation for the deletion of this language, it is subject to various 
    interpretations, and the Commission is not persuaded that BellSouth's 
    is the most reasonable among them. See Mead Corp. v. Tilley, 490 U.S. 
    714, 723 (1989); Rastelli v. Warnder, 782 F.2d 17, 23 (2d Cir. 1986). 
    The Joint Explanatory Statement of the Conference Report states that 
    all differences between the Senate Bill, the House Amendment, and the 
    substitute reached in conference are noted therein ``except for 
    clerical corrections, conforming changes made necessary by agreements 
    reached by the conferees, and minor drafting and clerical changes.'' 
    Because the Joint Explanatory Statement does not address the omission 
    of section 261 of the Senate Bill from the final legislation, the more 
    logical inference from the quoted statement is that Congress regarded 
    the change as an inconsequential modification rather than a significant 
    alteration. This view is supported by two additional facts noted above: 
    first, the statement in the Joint Explanatory Statement that section 
    251 ``incorporates provisions from both the Senate Bill and the House 
    Amendment;'' and second, the statements from the House Report 
    suggesting that the Commission's authority to prescribe requirements 
    for number portability extends both to interim number portability, 
    which is being provided now, and to long-term number portability, which 
    will ``be deployed when it is technically feasible.''
        10. This reading of the term ``number portability'' to include all 
    forms of number portability, whether interim or long-term, also is more 
    consistent than BellSouth's reading with Congress' goal of fostering 
    competition in the local exchange marketplace. Congress recognized that 
    number portability is essential to meaningful competition in the 
    provision of local exchange services, and the record in this proceeding 
    demonstrates that customers are reluctant to switch carriers if doing 
    so requires that they give up their current telephone numbers. Nor is 
    this view inconsistent with the distinction between ``interim number 
    portability'' and ``section 251 number portability'' referenced in 
    section 271(c)(2)(B)(ix). The legislative history of the 1996 Act does 
    not explain why Congress decided to refer specifically to interim 
    number portability only in section 271(c)(2)(B)(ix). In the absence of 
    such an explanation, and given the broad definition of number 
    portability in section 3(30) and the legislative history described 
    above, it seems unlikely that Congress's reference to interim number 
    portability in section 271(c)(2)(B)(ix) was intended to narrow the 
    concept of number portability as used elsewhere in the statute.
        11. Contrary to BellSouth's assertion, in the First Report and 
    Order, the Commission did not rely on section 271(c)(2)(B)(xi) as the 
    basis for requiring all LECs to provide interim number portability. 
    Rather, the Commission merely referred to section 271(c)(2)(B)(xi) as 
    offering further support for its interpretation of section 251(b)(2). 
    In addition, the Commission explained that its interpretation of 
    section 251(b)(2) would prevent a BOC seeking interLATA authorization, 
    pursuant to section 271 of the Act, from being able to avoid providing 
    number portability during the time between the adoption of the 
    Commission's number portability rules and the implementation of long-
    term number portability measures. See 47 U.S.C. 271. Under BellSouth's 
    interpretation, a BOC could refuse to offer interim number portability 
    from the time of the adoption of the First Report and Order until the 
    actual implementation of long-term number portability, yet still be in 
    compliance with the number portability checklist requirement set forth 
    in section 271. The Commission believes that a more logical 
    interpretation of these sections is that, in providing for both types 
    of number portability, Congress did not intend for there to be such a 
    time lag but instead required the provision of interim number 
    portability until long-term number portability is in place.
    
    [[Page 46574]]
    
    B. Commission Authority To Establish Cost Recovery Guidelines for 
    Interim Number Portability
    
    1. Background
        12. In the First Report and Order, the Commission asserted 
    jurisdiction over interim number portability and established cost 
    recovery guidelines for interim number portability measures for the 
    states to implement. Several commenters assert that the Commission 
    lacks authority to promulgate cost recovery guidelines for interim 
    number portability.
    2. Discussion
        13. The Commission upholds its earlier decision and affirms its 
    authority to establish cost recovery guidelines for interim number 
    portability measures. Its interpretation of the statute finds support 
    in the language of the 1996 Act, is consistent with the Act's 
    underlying goals, and is consistent with the conclusions reached in the 
    Third Report and Order.
        14. The Commission finds that sections 251(b)(2) and 251(e)(2) 
    grant it explicit authority over, respectively, the provision of and 
    the recovery of costs associated with number portability. 47 U.S.C. 
    251(b)(2), (e)(2). The Commission finds that its authority under 
    section 251(e)(2), as with section 251(b)(2), is not limited to long-
    term number portability, since the statutory definition of number 
    portability draws no distinction between interim and long-term number 
    portability. Section 3(30) of the Act defines number portability as 
    ``the ability of users of telecommunications services to retain, at the 
    same location, existing telecommunications numbers without impairment 
    of quality, reliability, or convenience when switching from one 
    telecommunications carrier to another. 47 U.S.C. 153(30). This 
    definition is not limited to one technical method of providing number 
    portability. Similarly, sections 251(b)(2) and 251(e)(2) refer only to 
    the provision and cost recovery of ``number portability,'' but do not 
    limit the term ``number portability'' to long-term measures. As 
    discussed above, given the broad definition of number portability in 
    section 3(30), it seems unlikely that Congress's reference to interim 
    number portability in section 271(c)(2)(B)(ix) was intended to narrow 
    the concept of number portability as used elsewhere in the statute, 
    such as in sections 251(b)(2) and 251(e)(2). In addition, the 
    Commission finds that its interpretation of section 251(b)(2), 
    requiring all LECs to provide interim number portability, is consistent 
    with, and necessary to effectuate Congress's goal to promote 
    competition in the provision of local telecommunications service.
        15. The Commission also notes that its conclusion that it has 
    statutory authority over interim number portability, regardless of 
    whether it is characterized as an intrastate or interstate service, and 
    the establishment of cost recovery rules for interim number 
    portability, is consistent with its holdings in the Third Report and 
    Order. There, the Commission concluded that the express and 
    unconditional grant of authority of section 251(e)(2) to the Commission 
    grants us the authority to ensure that carriers bear the costs of 
    providing number portability on a competitively neutral basis for both 
    interstate and intrastate calls. Section 251(e)(2) states that carriers 
    shall bear the costs of number portability ``as determined by the 
    Commission,'' and does not distinguish between costs incurred in 
    connection with intrastate calls and costs incurred in connection with 
    interstate calls. Thus, the Commission concludes for interim number 
    portability, as it did in the Third Report and Order for long-term 
    number portability, that section 251(e)(2) addresses both interstate 
    and intrastate matters and overrides the reservation of authority to 
    the states over intrastate matters contained in section 2(b). 47 U.S.C. 
    152(b). See Iowa Utils. Bd. v. FCC, 120 F.3d at 792, 794 and n.10, 795 
    and n.12, 802 and n.23, 806. See also In re Implementation of the Local 
    Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, CC Docket 
    No. 96-98, First Report and Order, 61 FR 45476 (August 29, 1996), 11 
    FCC Rcd 15,499 at 15,548 and n.155 (1996), vacated in part, aff'd in 
    part, Iowa Utils. Bd. v. FCC, 120 F.3d 753 (8th Cir. 1997), rev'd in 
    part, aff'd in part and remanded sub nom. AT&T Corp. v. Iowa Utils. 
    Bd., 119 S.Ct. at 730.
        16. The Commission is not persuaded that it lacks jurisdiction over 
    cost recovery for interim number portability measures because the 
    states have historically regulated the retail provision of RCF and DID. 
    The states' regulation of rates for these services when provided on a 
    retail basis does not preclude an express Congressional grant of 
    authority to this Commission under section 251(e)(2) to regulate the 
    cost recovery for interim number portability. Section 251(e)(2) states 
    that carriers shall bear the costs of number portability ``as 
    determined by the Commission,'' and does not distinguish between costs 
    incurred in connection with intrastate calls and costs incurred in 
    connection with interstate calls.
        17. The Commission disagrees with Bell Atlantic's claim that, 
    because section 251(e)(2) refers to the costs of ``establishing'' 
    number portability and there is nothing to ``establish'' with respect 
    to interim number portability, the Commission is without authority to 
    adopt cost recovery guidelines for the provision of interim number 
    portability. In arguing that there is nothing to ``establish'' 
    regarding interim number portability, Bell Atlantic defines the term 
    ``establish'' narrowly, i.e, limiting the meaning of ``establish'' to 
    physically upgrading the public switched telephone network or creating 
    databases necessary for customers to retain their telephone numbers 
    when switching carriers. To give full effect to the pro-competitive 
    objectives of the 1996 Act, the Commission concludes that the term 
    ``establish'' should be read more broadly. Although the functionalities 
    necessary to provide interim number portability already exist in most 
    public switched telephone networks, additional actions are necessary to 
    implement interim number portability in a manner useful to new 
    entrants. The actions required to establish interim number portability 
    and the associated costs vary according to where the call originates in 
    a carrier's network. The provision of interim number portability 
    results in switching and transport costs, and may include some small 
    non-recurring costs, such as administrative costs. Because additional 
    actions are required by LECs in the provision of interim number 
    portability, the Commission finds that the process of transferring 
    numbers and subsequently forwarding calls is what ``establishes'' 
    (i.e., ``creates'' or ``brings into existence'') interim number 
    portability for use by new entrants.
        18. In addition to disagreeing with Bell Atlantic's narrow 
    interpretation of the term ``establish'' in section 251(e)(2), the 
    Commission also finds that it would be contrary to Congressional intent 
    to conclude that the Commission's authority to impose a competitively 
    neutral cost recovery mechanism is limited to long-term number 
    portability. Congress imposed a number portability requirement on all 
    LECs, and directed the Commission to adopt a competitively neutral cost 
    recovery mechanism, in order to give new entrants a realistic 
    opportunity to compete against incumbent LECs for local exchange 
    customers. 47 U.S.C. 251(e). Mandating a number portability requirement 
    without ensuring a competitively neutral cost recovery mechanism could 
    significantly handicap the ability of new entrants to
    
    [[Page 46575]]
    
    win customers, whether the method of porting numbers is long-term or 
    interim. In the First Report and Order, the Commission concluded that, 
    because interim number portability costs will be small and incurred for 
    a relatively short period, requiring carriers to bear their own costs 
    would meet its competitive neutrality guidelines. The Commission 
    specifically prohibited incumbent LECs from shifting all of their costs 
    onto new entrants, however. Because both carriers would be competing 
    for the same customer, the new provider may be forced to charge higher 
    prices due to its need to recover the incumbent LEC's incremental costs 
    of number portability, while the customer would face no additional 
    charges if it stayed with the incumbent LEC. Thus, the Commission 
    concludes that Bell Atlantic's interpretation--that the Commission has 
    authority under section 251(e)(2) to impose a competitively neutral 
    cost recovery mechanism for long-term number portability, but lacks 
    such authority over interim number portability--will not promote 
    competition.
        19. The Commission similarly is not persuaded by Bell Atlantic's 
    claim that cost recovery for interim number portability must be subject 
    to negotiation between carriers, and that the Commission therefore 
    lacks authority to establish cost recovery guidelines. Bell Atlantic's 
    argument is based on language in the Senate Report discussing section 
    261 of Senate Bill 652, which states that interconnection agreements 
    reached under section 251 must, if requested, provide for interim 
    number portability, including the method by which it will be provided, 
    and the amount of compensation. As discussed above, section 261, as it 
    appeared in Senate Bill 652, distinguished between interim and final 
    number portability, but was ultimately dropped from the final version 
    of the 1996 Act. The Commission finds unpersuasive Bell Atlantic's 
    interpretation of the legislative history. See Helvering v. Hallock, 
    309 U.S. 106, 119-20 (1940); Brennan v. Midwestern United Life 
    Insurance, 259 F. Supp. 673 (1966); Women Involved in Farm Economics v. 
    USDA, 682 F. Supp. 599 (1988).
        20. The Commission rejects BellSouth's assertion that the 
    Commission lacks authority to depart from cost-causative pricing 
    principles. As the Commission explained in the Third Report and Order, 
    Congress imposed a number portability requirement on all LECs, and 
    directed the Commission to adopt a competitively neutral cost recovery 
    mechanism, in order to give new entrants a realistic opportunity to 
    compete against incumbent LECs for local exchange customers. A cost 
    causative basis for pricing number portability could defeat the purpose 
    for which number portability was mandated. Mandating a number 
    portability requirement without ensuring a competitively neutral cost 
    recovery mechanism could significantly handicap the ability of new 
    entrants to win customers, whether the method of porting numbers is 
    long-term or interim, because they could be forced to bear all 
    incremental costs of number portability and pass those costs onto 
    customers in the form of higher prices.
        21. Finally, the Commission rejects BellSouth's contention that the 
    Commission based its jurisdiction to order interim number portability 
    on pre-1996 Act provisions and is therefore precluded from relying on 
    section 251(e)(2) for jurisdiction to determine cost recovery for such 
    interim measures. To the contrary, in the First Report and Order the 
    Commission concluded only that sections 1 and 202 of the Communications 
    Act provide a pre-existing and independent basis for its jurisdiction 
    to require the provision of interim number portability methods. The 
    Commission did not rely solely on sections 1 and 202 as a basis for 
    jurisdiction, and hereby clarifies that, although it finds that 
    sections 1 and 202 provide an additional statutory basis on which it 
    may require interim number portability, it has independent authority to 
    do so by virtue of sections 251(b)(2) and 251(e)(2) of the Act.
        22. The Commission reiterates its earlier finding, as discussed 
    above, that section 251(e)(2) addresses both interstate and intrastate 
    matters, and overrides section 2(b)'s reservation of authority to the 
    states over intrastate matters. Although the Commission asserts federal 
    jurisdiction over interim number portability and affirms its authority 
    to establish cost recovery guidelines for interim number portability 
    measures, it denies requests that it generally preempt state number 
    portability cost recovery policies. Instead, the Commission affirms its 
    earlier conclusion that states may continue to utilize various cost 
    recovery mechanisms as long as they meet the Commission's competitive 
    neutrality guidelines. This cost recovery approach is different than 
    the one adopted in the Third Report and Order for long-term number 
    portability cost recovery, in which the Commission adopted an 
    exclusively federal cost recovery mechanism. The Commission notes that 
    in the Third Report and Order, it found that section 251(e)(2) 
    authorizes the Commission to provide the distribution and recovery 
    mechanism for all the costs of providing long-term number portability, 
    but did not interpret the statute to require the adoption of an 
    exclusively federal recovery mechanism for all forms of number 
    portability. Instead, an exclusively federal cost recovery mechanism 
    for long-term number portability was adopted for several policy reasons 
    that are inapplicable to interim number portability. The Commission 
    determined in the Third Report and Order that an exclusively federal 
    cost recovery mechanism for long-term number portability will enable it 
    ``to satisfy most directly its competitive neutrality mandate and will 
    minimize the administrative and enforcement difficulties that might 
    arise where jurisdiction over long-term number portability divided.'' 
    Additionally, an exclusively federal cost recovery mechanism for long-
    term number portability obviates the need for state allocation of the 
    shared costs of the regional database, a task that would likely be 
    complicated by the database's multistate nature.
        23. Although the Commission has determined that the Commission's 
    authority to provide the distribution and recovery mechanism for all 
    number portability costs extends to long-term and interim number 
    portability, it does not find it necessary to establish an exclusively 
    federal recovery mechanism for interim number portability. Instead, it 
    will continue to permit states to provide for cost recovery in accord 
    with the competitive neutrality standards adopted in the First Report 
    and Order, and elaborated here, for the following reasons. First, the 
    Commission believes that adopting an exclusively federal cost recovery 
    mechanism would be very disruptive to existing interim number 
    portability cost recovery. States have been providing for interim 
    number portability cost recovery since 1996. Also, cost recovery for 
    interim number portability has been determined through existing 
    interconnection agreements, as incumbent LECs are required by section 
    251(c) to provide for interim number portability in their 
    interconnection agreements. 47 U.S.C. 251(c). The Commission notes that 
    federal courts have upheld the interim number portability cost recovery 
    guidelines established in the First Report and Order. See, e.g., 
    Southwestern Bell Telephone v. AT&T, 1998 WL 657717*4 (D.Tex. 1998); 
    see also US WEST Communications v. MFS Intelnet, 35 F. Supp. 2d 1221, 
    1236 (D.Or. 1998).
    
    [[Page 46576]]
    
    Second, the Commission believes that disruption of existing cost 
    recovery mechanisms is not warranted because interim number portability 
    will remain in place for a very limited period of time. Interim number 
    portability was replaced by long-term number portability in the 100 
    largest MSAs by the end of 1998, and is subsequently being replaced in 
    other switches in which a bona fide request for number portability has 
    been received. Third, the Commission believes that a cost allocation 
    method that requires LECs to bear their own costs of interim number 
    portability is competitively neutral, as individual carrier's costs 
    will be small and no shared costs or database costs must be allocated. 
    As previously indicated, to the extent that RCF, DID and other 
    comparable methods are used to provide currently available number 
    portability, and the capability for currently available number 
    portability already exists in the incumbent LEC network, only the 
    short-run incremental costs are properly attributed to interim number 
    portability. Having already provisioned their switches with enough 
    capacity to carry all of their respective customers' incoming and 
    outgoing calls, the Commission does not expect incumbent LECs to incur 
    additional costs with respect to switch capacity when a customer 
    chooses to port its number to a new service provider and the incumbent 
    LEC must forward calls using interim number portability methods. As a 
    result, the Commission expects little or no change in the level of 
    incumbent LECs switching and transport costs per ported number.
        24. As stated in the First Report and Order, if a carrier believes 
    that a LEC's pricing provisions for number portability violate the 
    Commission's competitive neutrality guidelines or violate a state-
    mandated cost recovery mechanism, it may be able to seek relief from 
    its state commission. If the carrier is not able to obtain relief in 
    this way, or if a state has not yet adopted a cost recovery mechanism 
    for cost recovery of interim number portability measures, it may be 
    able to bring action against the LEC in federal district court pursuant 
    to section 207 for damages or file a section 208 complaint with this 
    Commission against another carrier alleging a violation of the Act or 
    the Commission's rules. Alternatively, if a carrier believes that a 
    state has not properly applied the statute or Commission rules, or if a 
    state's cost recovery mechanism is not competitively neutral because it 
    improperly burdens new entrants with interim number portability costs, 
    it may file a request for declaratory ruling with the Commission or 
    otherwise seek court review of the state cost recovery mechanism.
    
    C. Cost Recovery Guidelines
    
    1. Background
        25. In the First Report and Order, the Commission established two 
    criteria with which any cost recovery method must comply in order to be 
    considered competitively neutral. First, ``a `competitively neutral' 
    cost recovery mechanism should not give one service provider an 
    appreciable, incremental cost advantage over another service provider, 
    when competing for a specific subscriber.'' Second, the cost recovery 
    mechanism ``should not have a disparate effect on the ability of 
    competing service providers to earn normal returns on their 
    investments.'' In setting forth these criteria, however, the Commission 
    left to the states the determination of the exact cost recovery 
    mechanism to be utilized. Several carriers have challenged the 
    Commission's cost recovery guidelines.
    2. Discussion
        26. The Commission rejects the claims of those carriers that assert 
    that its cost recovery guidelines are arbitrary, capricious, or plain 
    error. Number portability promotes competition by allowing customers to 
    switch carriers easily without having to change their telephone 
    numbers. In the First Report and Order, the Commission explained that 
    the Commission departed from cost causation principles with respect to 
    interim number portability because, ``[d]epending on the technology 
    used, to price number portability on a cost causative basis could 
    defeat the purpose for which it was mandated.'' As the Commission 
    stated in the Third Report and Order, pricing number portability on a 
    cost-causative basis could defeat Congress's purpose of removing 
    barriers to local competition because the nature of the costs involved 
    with some number portability solutions might make it economically 
    infeasible for some carriers to compete for a customer serviced by 
    another carrier. If it is assumed that the customer who ports his or 
    her number is the cost causer, and all of the costs associated with 
    forwarding a call are placed on the customer who switches carriers, 
    customers who want to retain their telephone numbers could be deterred 
    from switching carriers due to increased costs. This result is wholly 
    contrary to the pro-competitive intent of sections 251(b)(2) and 
    252(e)(2) regarding the provision of number portability.
        27. Additional economic and policy considerations also support the 
    Commission's decision not to follow strict principles of cost causation 
    in this specific context by imposing all interim number portability 
    costs on new entrants. First, all customers benefit from number 
    portability because number portability promotes competition, lower 
    prices, increased choices, and greater innovation. In addition, other 
    customers will benefit to the extent that they need not search for a 
    customer's new number when that customer switches carriers. Since 
    number portability generates an externality from which all customers 
    benefit, the porting customers should not pay the full economic costs. 
    Moreover, as discussed in the First Report and Order and Third Report 
    and Order, if the costs are placed entirely on one carrier or group of 
    carriers, ``the new entrant's share of the cost [could be] so large, 
    relative to its expected profits, that the entrant would decide not to 
    enter.'' Preventing new, efficient entrants from offering service 
    because of costs associated with number portability would directly 
    contravene one of the 1996 Act's primary purposes, namely to encourage 
    local exchange competition.
        28. Furthermore, the Commission agrees with MCI that the costs of 
    number portability should not be viewed narrowly as simply costs of 
    entry, but more broadly as costs of creating a competitive environment 
    that will benefit all consumers. In the Third Report and Order, the 
    Commission concluded that applying principles of competitive neutrality 
    to long-term number portability cost recovery would ensure that the 
    cost of number portability does not undermine the goal of the 1996 Act 
    to ``promote a competitive environment'' for the provision of local 
    communications services. Similarly, the Commission concludes that 
    requiring incumbent LECs to share in the costs of providing both 
    interim and long-term number portability is in the public interest and 
    will contribute to the development of competition in the local exchange 
    market.
        29. BellSouth asserts that the cost recovery guidelines for interim 
    number portability are ``vague and ambiguous,'' and that the Commission 
    failed to define the phrases ``appreciable cost advantage'' and 
    ``normal return.'' As applied to its cost recovery guidelines, the 
    Commission clarifies that, when the Commission used the phrase 
    ``appreciable cost advantage'' the Commission meant a difference in 
    costs that, if reflected in retail prices, would cause a not-
    insignificant number of
    
    [[Page 46577]]
    
    customers to change, or decline to change, carriers. The Commission 
    also finds that a ``normal return'' in economic terms is the return 
    sufficient to assure confidence in the financial integrity of the 
    company so as to maintain its credit and attract capital. Normal return 
    in this context does not guarantee that all firms will be profitable 
    and, hence, remain in the industry. Rather, this concept means that 
    number portability costs imposed on a particular carrier should not be 
    so significant, by themselves, as to drive existing carriers out of the 
    market or make continued operations unprofitable, or deter the entry of 
    carriers that, but for the number portability costs, would have entered 
    the market.
        30. The Commission finds no merit to BellSouth's suggestion that 
    the Commission's definition of, and criteria for, competitive 
    neutrality, are novel or unprecedented. The ``competitively neutral'' 
    principles established in the First Report and Order were drawn from 
    well-accepted principles of economic theory. To be competitive, a firm 
    must be able to offer a particular customer a service/price package 
    which that customer finds comparable to that offered by other carriers, 
    and it must be able to do so while earning a normal rate of return. In 
    making business decisions, firms are concerned with both the short-run 
    and the long-run. In the short-run, firms are concerned with their 
    ability to compete, while in the long-run firms are concerned with 
    remaining in the market. The first criterion of the competitive 
    neutrality test addresses the short-run concern, in that carriers 
    cannot compete effectively if one carrier has an appreciable, 
    incremental cost advantage over other carriers. The second criterion 
    addresses the concern that the cost recovery mechanism should not have 
    a disparate effect on the ability of competing service providers to 
    earn normal returns on their investments.
        31. The Commission also rejects arguments that the methods 
    currently suggested in the First Report and Order fail to meet the 
    second criterion of competitive neutrality, which states that ``[the 
    allocation mechanism] should not have a disparate effect on the ability 
    of competing service providers to earn normal returns on their 
    investments.'' As applied to interim number portability, the methods 
    for allocating the costs of interim number portability suggested in the 
    First Report and Order, including allocation according to a carrier's 
    number of active lines or number of active telephone numbers, meet the 
    criteria established for competitive neutrality. Given the relatively 
    small incremental costs of interim number portability, the Commission 
    concludes that using either number of telephone lines or number of 
    active telephone numbers as the basis for allocation also meets the 
    second criterion. Although that carrier's costs for number portability 
    go up relative to other carriers, it also receives the corresponding 
    revenues generated by the new customer. One characteristic of these 
    rules is that the costs allocated to particular carriers increase with 
    the size of the carrier so that smaller carriers will not be driven 
    from the market. In creating the competitive neutrality criteria, the 
    Commission also was guided by the 1996 Act's objectives. Number 
    portability and competitively neutral cost recovery are necessary to 
    fulfill the 1996 Act.
        32. The Commission also rejects BellSouth's argument that it is 
    arbitrary and capricious to use transitional measures as an incentive 
    to adopt long-term number portability as quickly as possible. As 
    discussed above, the Commission finds that it has jurisdiction over 
    number portability, and that number portability is a dynamic, not 
    static, concept. Section 271 of the Act explicitly states that BOCs 
    must provide ``interim telecommunications number portability'' until 
    ``the date by which the Commission issues regulations pursuant to 
    section 251 to require number portability.'' While the costs of long-
    term number portability will be greater than those of interim number 
    portability, carriers will be able to recover their costs through two 
    separate federally-tariffed charges, and end-user and query service 
    charge.
        33. The Commission disagrees that it is interfering with existing 
    state-mandated interim number portability cost recovery mechanisms. As 
    the Commission stated in the First Report and Order, the Commission 
    provides flexibility for the states to determine their own cost 
    allocation mechanisms, subject to the guidelines set forth in the First 
    Report and Order. If a state previously determined its cost allocation 
    scheme without taking section 251(e)(2) into account, that state must 
    now ensure that its method comports with the 1996 Act and the 
    Commission's implementing regulations.
        34. The Commission disagrees with AirTouch's assertion that 
    carriers that do not serve customers with ported numbers, such as 
    wireless carriers, should not be required to share in the cost of 
    number portability because such carriers do not benefit from number 
    portability. The Commission looks to section 251(e)(2) of the Act, 
    which plainly requires that the costs of establishing number 
    portability be borne by ``all telecommunications carriers on a 
    competitively neutral basis as determined by the Commission.'' 47 
    U.S.C. 251(e)(2). This interpretation is consistent with the Third 
    Report and Order, wherein the Commission concluded that the provisions 
    of section 3 of the Act, when read together, define ``all 
    telecommunications carriers'' as all persons or entities other than 
    aggregators that charge to transmit information for the public without 
    changing the form or content of the information, regardless of the 
    facilities they use. Applying the statutory definition to section 
    251(e)(2), the Commission concluded that the way all telecommunications 
    carriers bear the costs of providing number portability--including 
    incumbent LECs, competitive LECs, CMRS providers, IXCs, and resellers--
    must be competitively neutral as determined by the Commission. The 
    Commission has exercised its statutory mandate by articulating criteria 
    for states to use in adopting cost recovery mechanisms. As the states 
    develop cost recovery mechanisms pursuant to the statutory mandate, 
    carriers will bear their own costs or states may allocate costs in a 
    competitively neutral fashion on all telecommunications carriers that 
    does not unduly burden any particular carrier or group of carriers.
        35. The Commission finds no merit in SCLP and SCI's claim that 
    requiring CMRS providers to contribute to number portability would have 
    a ``disparate effect'' on their ability to earn a normal rate of 
    return. These carriers have failed to present any evidence to support 
    their claim that contributing to the costs of interim number 
    portability would have such an effect. As noted in the First Report and 
    Order, a disparate effect may be said to exist when a ``new entrant's 
    share of the [interim number portability] costs may be so large, 
    relative to its expected profits, that the entrant would decide not to 
    enter the market.'' With respect to existing carriers, the Commission 
    clarifies that a disparate effect under its definition would exist if 
    that carrier or class of carriers would be driven from the market, 
    while other carriers would not, as a result of number portability 
    costs. These carriers' unsupported allegations that contributing to the 
    costs of interim number portability would have a disparate effect are 
    insufficient to support their request for a blanket exemption for all 
    CMRS carriers.
        36. The Commission also disagrees with SCLP and SCI's assertion 
    that its
    
    [[Page 46578]]
    
    First Report and Order demonstrates an intent that the costs of interim 
    number portability be placed on non-cost causers only where necessary 
    to preserve competitive neutrality. In making this claim, SCLP and SCI 
    rely on the word ``relevant'' in the Commission's statement that 
    ``states may apportion the incremental costs of interim measures among 
    relevant carriers by using competitively neutral allocators.'' In using 
    the term ``relevant carriers,'' the Commission intended to reflect that 
    differing cost recovery mechanisms, all of which could satisfy its 
    competitively neutral mandate, might encompass all, or a subset of all, 
    telecommunications carriers, depending on the specifics of the cost 
    recovery mechanism.
        37. In the First Report and Order, the Commission concluded that, 
    in choosing the phrase ``all telecommunications carriers,'' Congress 
    intended to include all types of carriers in the cost recovery 
    mechanism because, unlike the requirement to provide number portability 
    which applies solely to local exchange carriers, the requirements 
    relating to number portability cost recovery apply to ``all 
    telecommunications carriers on a competitively neutral basis.'' The 
    term ``telecommunications carrier'' is defined in the Act as ``any 
    provider of telecommunications services. * * *'' 47 U.S.C. 153(44). The 
    Commission adopted a literal reading of the statutory requirement and 
    of the statutory definition of ``telecommunications carriers.'' While 
    the Commission's interpretation prevents an incumbent LEC from 
    recovering its costs entirely from the new entrant, such an incumbent 
    LEC may be able to recover its incremental interim number portability 
    costs via the state-adopted allocation mechanism from ``all 
    telecommunications carriers'' if a state implements such a cost 
    recovery mechanism. Since the carrier providing the call forwarding 
    itself falls within the category of ``all telecommunications 
    carriers,'' the carrier providing the forwarding is prevented by 
    statute from recovering all of its costs from other carriers. States 
    could also permit incumbent LECs to recover any remaining costs in some 
    other manner, e.g., from end-users.
        38. The Commission affirms its finding that a ``mechanism that 
    requires each carrier to pay for its own costs of interim number 
    portability measures'' is competitively neutral and would constitute an 
    acceptable cost recovery scheme that states could adopt. First, no 
    significant capital costs are incurred by the carrier winning the 
    customer or by the carrier losing the customer. Thus, the cost recovery 
    mechanism does not give one service provider an appreciable, 
    incremental advantage over another service provider when competing for 
    the same customer. Second incumbent LECs should still be able to earn a 
    normal return, as the anticipated costs of interim number portability 
    measures are relatively small.
        39. The Commission disagrees with BellSouth's argument that 
    ``having determined that the costs of [interim number portability] will 
    be incurred solely by the incumbent LECs,'' it was arbitrary and 
    capricious for the Commission to determine that requiring each carrier 
    to bear its own costs does not operate to the competitive disadvantage 
    of the incumbent LECs. The Commission also disagrees with Bell 
    Atlantic's argument that the First Report and Order was not 
    competitively neutral because the Commission denied Bell Atlantic the 
    ability to recover incremental costs of interim number portability. As 
    a threshold matter, these carriers are incorrect when they assert that 
    the Commission determined that the costs of providing interim number 
    portability will be incurred solely by incumbent LECs. Although finding 
    that ``initially, the costs of providing interim number portability 
    will be incurred primarily by the incumbent LEC, because the incumbent 
    LECs currently hold the vast majority of numbers in use,'' the First 
    Report and Order imposed interim number portability requirements on all 
    local exchange carriers. The Commission finds that it would be 
    competitively neutral for carriers to pay their own incremental interim 
    number portability costs, that is, to absorb the costs themselves or 
    pass the costs onto their own retail customers. Additionally, the 
    Commission has not foreclosed incumbent LECs from recovering all of 
    their incremental costs of interim number portability, but has 
    permitted each state to adopt a cost recovery mechanism, consistent 
    with its competitive neutrality guidelines. The First Report and Order 
    does not deny any carrier the right to recover costs, but, rather 
    adopts guidelines that states must follow in implementing a cost 
    recovery mechanism.
        40. The Commission also concludes that the assertion by Bell 
    Atlantic and Cincinnati Bell that new entrants should be required to 
    bear all the costs of interim number portability is not consistent with 
    the pro-competitive intent of sections 251(b)(2), 252(e)(2), and the 
    1996 Act as a whole. As the Commission stated in the Third Report and 
    Order, the Commission has interpreted the Congressional mandate of 
    competitive neutrality to require the Commission to depart from cost-
    causation principles when necessary to ensure that the cost of number 
    portability borne by each carrier does not significantly affect any 
    carrier's ability to compete with other carriers. The Commission 
    specifically prohibited incumbent LECs from shifting all of their costs 
    onto new entrants, however. Despite the fact that such incremental 
    costs are small, shifting all of an incumbent LEC's costs of interim 
    number portability to a new entrant could result in a cost so large, 
    ``relative to expected profits,'' that the new entrant would decide not 
    to enter the market. As the Commission stated in the First Report and 
    Order, imposing the full incremental cost of interim number portability 
    solely on new entrants would place them at an ``appreciable, 
    incremental cost disadvantage relative to another service provider when 
    competing for the same customer'' and would, therefore, violate the 
    first criteria of the competitive neutrality mandate.
        41. The Commission is not persuaded by BellSouth's contention that 
    the cost allocation mechanisms discussed in the First Report and Order 
    guarantee the profitability of the new entrants. Number portability 
    facilitates the development of competition among local providers. 
    Through its competitive neutrality criteria and state-determined cost 
    allocation mechanisms, the First Report and Order removes a potential 
    barrier to entry that could result from high rates or charges that 
    incumbent LECs potentially could impose for interim number portability 
    on new entrants that possess their own switches. It does not guarantee 
    that a new entrant will be profitable or be able to compete 
    successfully in the market.
        42. GTE suggests a third criterion, that ``a cost recovery 
    mechanism must not influence a customer's selection of his or her 
    service provider.'' While the Commission agrees with GTE that a cost 
    recovery mechanism should not influence a customer's selection of his 
    or her service provider, this criterion is effectively embodied in the 
    first prong of its competitive neutrality test and, thus, the 
    Commission sees no need to revise that test.
    
    D. Alternative Allocators for Cost Recovery of Interim Number 
    Portability
    
    1. Background
        43. In the First Report and Order, the Commission provided a list 
    of examples of allocators for interim number portability cost recovery 
    that would
    
    [[Page 46579]]
    
    meet the Commission's criteria for competitive neutrality. The 
    Commission stated, for example, that a cost allocator based on a 
    carrier's number of active telephone numbers, or a carrier's relative 
    number of presubscribed customers, would meet its competitive 
    neutrality guidelines. Several parties ask the Commission to approve 
    additional allocators, or take exception to cost allocators deemed to 
    be competitively neutral by the Commission in the First Report and 
    Order.
    
    2. Discussion
    
        44. In the First Report and Order, the Commission provided a non-
    exhaustive list of examples of allocators for interim number 
    portability cost recovery that would meet the Commission's criteria for 
    competitive neutrality. The Commission disagrees with GTE's argument 
    that a federally-mandated cost pooling mechanism needs to be 
    implemented. For the reasons discussed in the First Report and Order, 
    the Commission believes that states should be able to adopt various 
    cost recovery mechanisms based on its competitive neutrality 
    guidelines. The Commission is not, however, precluding states from 
    selecting cost pooling as a cost recovery mechanism, nor is the 
    Commission determining that cost pooling is not competitively neutral 
    for the recovery of interim number portability costs. Although in the 
    Third Report and Order the Commission rejected pooling of carriers' 
    long-term number portability costs as a mechanism for recovery of these 
    costs because pooling mechanisms, in general, reduce carrier incentives 
    to provide service efficiently, states may find that these 
    disadvantages are not as significant when pooling is used as a 
    mechanism for the recovery of interim number portability costs. Because 
    the costs of interim number portability are relatively small, given 
    that incumbent LECs have already provisioned their switches with the 
    capacity to provide the services needed for interim number portability, 
    creating incentives for carriers to provide service efficiently may be 
    less of a concern. The Commission allows states to utilize various cost 
    recovery mechanisms, and states will make the decision as to whether 
    they will choose pooling as a recovery mechanism and impose cost 
    accounting and distribution mechanisms on carriers.
        45. In clarifying that the list of potential allocators referenced 
    in the First Report and Order is not exhaustive, the Commission also 
    affirms that a cost recovery mechanism based on a carriers' gross 
    revenues is an acceptable means of allocating costs among carriers. 
    Financial measures, including gross revenues, are developed for 
    different uses, such as for tax filings, annual reports, and SEC 
    filings, and are readily available for this use. Additionally, such an 
    allocator does not disparately affect the incremental costs of winning 
    a specific customer or group of customers. A LEC with a small share of 
    the market's revenues would pay a percentage of the incremental costs 
    of interim number portability that is small enough that it will have no 
    appreciable affect on its ability to compete for that customer. 
    Accordingly, utilizing a gross revenues allocator does not violate the 
    Commission's competitive neutrality guidelines.
        46. It appears that carriers' concerns with some of the allocators 
    approved by the Commission are focused on its second criterion, on 
    whether losing a customer affects a firm's ``normal return.'' Losing a 
    customer will necessarily affect a firm's revenues and subsequent 
    return on investment. The First Report and Order did not intend to 
    change that. Rather, as stated in the Third Report and Order, the 
    second prong of the competitive neutrality test does not guarantee any 
    particular rate of return, but merely states that an allocator should 
    not disparately affect a carrier's ability to earn a normal return. The 
    Commission also stated that allocating costs on an active telephone 
    number basis would meet the second criteria, because it should not give 
    any carrier a cost advantage, relative to its competitors.
        47. In a written ex parte presentation to the Commission, AT&T 
    summarized a number of existing state cost recovery mechanisms in 
    effect at that time. In one method, cost elements required for interim 
    number portability are attributed to the requesting carrier, which is 
    deemed the cost causer, and must be borne by that entity. This method 
    allocates all incremental costs of interim number portability to the 
    new entrant. The Commission reiterates its earlier conclusion in the 
    First Report and Order that a cost recovery mechanism that imposes the 
    entire incremental costs of interim number portability on a facilities-
    based new entrant violates its competitive neutrality criteria. New 
    entrants subjected to such a cost recovery mechanism may pursue one of 
    the enforcement options discussed above.
        48. NYNEX suggests that allocating costs on the basis of total 
    telecommunications retail revenues is competitively neutral and should 
    be permitted as an allocator. The Commission agrees with NYNEX that 
    such an allocation may meet its competitive neutrality guidelines 
    because, as with allocators based on gross telecommunications revenues, 
    it would not give one service provider an appreciable, incremental cost 
    advantage over another service provider. Under this allocation method, 
    a LEC with a small share of the market's revenues would pay a 
    percentage of the incremental cost of number portability that will be 
    small enough to have no appreciable affect on its ability to compete 
    for a customer.
        49. In sum, the Commission reaffirms its determination to allow 
    each state to determine the appropriate cost recovery mechanism for its 
    jurisdiction as long as it meets its competitive neutrality criteria. 
    The Commission recognizes that, in the First Report and Order, the 
    Commission tentatively concluded that a cost recovery mechanism for 
    interim number portability that assesses charges based on a carrier's 
    gross revenues less charges carriers paid to other carriers would meet 
    its competitive neutrality guidelines, while in the Third Report and 
    Order, the Commission declined to utilize this allocator for long-term 
    number portability cost recovery. The Commission notes, however, that 
    interim number portability and long-term number portability, as 
    implemented pursuant to industry-wide discussions, have very different 
    cost characteristics. A cost recovery method that is appropriate for 
    one may not be suitable for the other. Although the Commission has 
    established one particular cost recovery mechanism for long-term number 
    portability, the Commission declines to issue an exclusive list of 
    acceptable cost recovery methods for interim number portability from 
    which the states may choose to adopt. States are free to adopt an 
    appropriate cost recovery method pursuant to the competitive neutrality 
    criteria.
    
    E. Takings
    
    1. Background
        50. Several petitioners claim that its cost recovery guidelines for 
    interim number portability do not ensure adequate compensation and 
    therefore constitute an unlawful taking under the Fifth and Fourteenth 
    Amendments to the Constitution.
    
    2. Discussion
    
        51. The Commission rejects the claim that the cost recovery 
    guidelines for interim number portability established in the First 
    Report and Order violate the Fifth Amendment's mandate that no private 
    property shall be ``taken for public use without just compensation.''
    
    [[Page 46580]]
    
    See U.S. Const. amend. V. As discussed below, the Commission concludes 
    that the petitioners' takings claim is premature. More importantly, in 
    examining its cost recovery guidelines in light of criteria articulated 
    by the Supreme Court, the Commission finds that the petitioners' 
    takings claim fails on the merits.
        52. In the First Report and Order, the Commission clearly stated 
    that, although its guidelines govern state allocation of costs of 
    interim number portability, it is the responsibility of the states to 
    adopt specific cost recovery mechanisms. Although petitioners have 
    broadly stated that they believe that incumbent LECs will not receive 
    adequate compensation as a result of the guidelines established in the 
    First Report and Order, they have not shown the actual impact of the 
    guidelines based on state orders. The Commission concludes, therefore, 
    that, absent an actual rate order under which the impact of the cost 
    recovery guidelines can be evaluated, the petitioners' takings argument 
    is premature. This conclusion is consistent with FPC v. Texaco Inc., in 
    which the Supreme Court held that ``[a]ny broadside assertion that 
    indirect regulation will be confiscatory is premature. The consequences 
    of indirect regulation can only be viewed in the entirety of the rate 
    of return allowed on investment, and this effect will be unknown until 
    the Commission has applied its scheme in individual cases over a period 
    of time.'' FPC v. Texaco Inc. 417 U.S. 380, 391-92 (1974).
        53. Assuming arguendo that the petitioners' takings claim is not 
    premature, the Commission finds it without merit. The Supreme Court has 
    made clear that ``government may execute laws or programs that 
    adversely affect recognized economic values,'' Penn Central v. City of 
    New York, 438 U.S. 104, 124 (1978), and that ``given the propriety of 
    governmental power to regulate, it cannot be said that the Takings 
    Clause is violated whenever legislation requires one person to use his 
    or her assets for the benefit of another.'' Connolly v. Pension Benefit 
    Guaranty Corp., 475 U.S. 211, 222 (1986). In fact, ``government hardly 
    could go on if to some extent values incident to property could not be 
    diminished without paying for every such change in the general law.'' 
    Pennsylvania Coal Co. v. Mahon, 260 U.S. 393, 413 (1922). Despite the 
    conclusory assertion of Cincinnati Bell to the contrary, its guidelines 
    will not result in a significant economic impact on incumbent LECs. As 
    noted in the First Report and Order, ``the capability to provide number 
    portability through interim methods, such as RCF and DID, already 
    exists in most of today's networks, and no additional network upgrades 
    are necessary.'' The incremental costs associated with the utilization 
    of pre-existing network functionality for purposes of interim number 
    portability are relatively small.
        54. In Duquesne Light Co. v. Barasch, the Supreme Court rejected a 
    takings claim on the grounds that it was permissible to preclude 
    certain costs from inclusion in an electric utility's rate base because 
    the overall rate was within constitutional requirements. Duquesne Light 
    Co. v. Barasch, 488 U.S. 299 (1989). A rate is too low for 
    constitutional purposes, according to the Court, if it is ``so unjust 
    as to destroy the value of [the] property for all the purposes for 
    which it was acquired.'' The Court held that `` `[i]t is not the 
    theory, but the impact of the rate order which counts.' . . . The 
    Constitution protects the utility from the net effect of the rate order 
    on its property. Inconsistencies in one aspect of the methodology have 
    no constitutional effect on the utility's property if they are 
    compensated by countervailing factors in some other aspect.''
        55. In determining that the overall impact of the rate order was 
    not constitutionally objectionable and that the takings clause was not 
    violated, the Court in Duquesne Light Company took note of the fact 
    that ``[n]o argument has been made that these slightly reduced rates 
    jeopardize the financial integrity of the companies, either by leaving 
    them insufficient operating capital or by impeding their ability to 
    raise future capital. Nor has it been demonstrated that these rates are 
    inadequate to compensate current equity holders for the risk associated 
    with their investments. . . .'' Similarly, no showing has been made 
    that the cost recovery guidelines at issue here will ``jeopardize the 
    financial integrity'' of incumbent LECs, nor has a showing been made 
    that the cost recovery guidelines will result in state rate orders that 
    are inadequate to compensate LECs ``for the risk associated with their 
    investments.''
        56. Having already provisioned their switches with enough capacity 
    to carry all of their customers' incoming and outgoing calls, incumbent 
    LECs should incur no additional costs with respect to switch capacity 
    when losing customers and using RCF to provide number portability. 
    Although RCF will require additional switch capacity--and an increase 
    in transport costs--to process incoming calls, this effect is offset by 
    the fact that the incumbent LEC will no longer handle the outgoing 
    calls originated by the ported customer. As a result, little or no 
    change in the level of incumbent LEC switching and transport costs per 
    ported number should occur. The Commission concludes, therefore, that 
    the additional incremental costs of interim number portability to 
    incumbent LECs will be extremely small. Additionally, incumbent LECs 
    may be able to recover some portion of their costs from other carriers 
    through state-mandated cost recovery mechanisms. Additionally, as 
    discussed above, if a carrier believes that a LEC's pricing provisions 
    for number portability violate the Commission's competitive neutrality 
    guidelines or violate a state-mandated cost recovery mechanism, a 
    carrier has a variety of ways it may seek relief.
        57. Moreover, as the Supreme Court has stated, ``[t]hose who do 
    business in the regulated field cannot object if the legislative scheme 
    is buttressed by subsequent amendments to achieve the legislative 
    end.'' Based on the extensive public debate that preceded enactment of 
    the 1996 Act, it cannot be said that investors lacked adequate notice 
    of possible changes to the Communications Act, including the number 
    portability requirement at issue here. Indeed, while courts have 
    readily found that a taking has occurred when interference with 
    property rights can be characterized as a physical invasion or 
    permanent appropriation, such a finding has not been reached when the 
    challenged interference arises from a public program adjusting the 
    benefits and burdens of economic life to promote the common good. The 
    Commission's number portability cost recovery guidelines, which are 
    designed to facilitate local telephone competition and thereby benefit 
    all consumers of telecommunications services, falls squarely into the 
    latter category. In short, the petitioners have failed to demonstrate 
    that the Commission's cost recovery guidelines violate the Fifth and 
    Fourteenth Amendments.
    
    F. Retroactive Application of Cost Recovery Guidelines for Interim 
    Number Portability
    
    1. Background
        58. ACSI asks the Commission to allow new entrants to recover 
    retroactively number portability costs paid to incumbent LECs in excess 
    of that required pursuant to the guidelines set forth in the First 
    Report and Order. Specifically, ACSI requests that the Commission 
    provide for a true-up of rates paid in excess of those required 
    pursuant to the First Report and Order
    
    [[Page 46581]]
    
    as far back as February 8, 1996, the date the 1996 Act became 
    effective, or the date number portability was first provided to the new 
    entrant, whichever is later.
    2. Discussion
        59. The Commission denies ACSI's request that its cost recovery 
    rules for interim number portability be applied to number portability 
    provided prior to the adoption and effective date of those rules. In 
    section 251(e)(2) of the Act, Congress required that ``the cost of 
    establishing. . . number portability shall be borne by all 
    telecommunications carriers on a competitively neutral basis as 
    determined by the Commission.'' The plain language of this section 
    demonstrates that, while establishing the parameters on how number 
    portability costs are to be allocated and who should pay such costs, 
    Congress intended that specific cost recovery rules were to be 
    established by the Commission at some point in time following the 
    enactment of the 1996 Act. The Commission rejects ACSI's argument that, 
    because the number portability provision became effective on February 
    8, 1996, ACSI is merely seeking to have the Commission give effect to 
    this pre-existing requirement. Section 251(e)(2) is not self-executing, 
    but is dependent on Commission action. The Commission sees no basis in 
    the record for applying the rules adopted pursuant to section 251(e) 
    retroactively.
        60. The Commission's cost recovery guidelines for interim number 
    portability became effective August 26, 1996, however, and the 
    Commission agrees that it may be appropriate for states to provide a 
    true-up of interim number portability costs from that date through the 
    effective date of a state-approved cost recovery program. To provide 
    the states with the flexibility during the interim period to continue 
    using a variety of cost recovery approaches, the Commission did not 
    adopt a fixed cost recovery mechanism. Instead, it adopted guidelines 
    for the states to follow in mandating cost recovery for interim number 
    portability. The Commission recognizes, however, that a significant 
    period of time may have elapsed before each state adopted a cost 
    recovery mechanism for interim number portability. Thus, absent a true-
    up from the effective date of the First Report and Order, the benefits 
    of a competitively neutral cost recovery mechanism for interim number 
    portability may be lost for many new entrants if they have been paying 
    cost recovery amounts in excess of what would be allowed under the 
    competitive guidelines of the First Report and Order. The Commission 
    notes that several state arbitration decisions have adopted a true-up 
    approach pending the adoption of a state-approved cost recovery 
    mechanism. The Commission strongly encourages states to review their 
    cost recovery mechanisms. Consistent with its competitive neutrality 
    principles, the Commission encourages states to adopt a true-up of 
    amounts paid for interim number portability between August 26, 1996 and 
    the date the state-approved cost recovery program takes effect, to the 
    extent such amounts exceed what would have been paid under the state-
    approved plan, had it been in effect.
    
    G. Terminating Access Charges
    
    1. Background
        61. In the First Report and Order, the Commission stated that 
    terminating access charges for calls forwarded from an incumbent LEC to 
    a competing provider through the use of a interim number portability 
    method should be shared between the incumbent LEC, which is the donor 
    switch and the terminating switch carrier. A ``donor'' switch is the 
    end office switch to which the called telephone number was originally 
    assigned. The Commission stated that the ``overarching principle'' in 
    such billing arrangements was that carriers were to share in the access 
    revenues for a ported call, because neither the incumbent LEC 
    forwarding carrier nor the terminating carrier provides all the 
    facilities used to terminate a ported call. The Commission also held 
    that incumbent LECs and new entrants should assess their terminating 
    access charges on IXCs through meet-point billing arrangements. MCI 
    asserts that, regardless of what type of billing arrangement is 
    adopted, IXCs should not be charged increased access charges as a 
    result of the additional call routing and associated costs necessary to 
    terminate a call to a ported number under interim number portability 
    measures.
    2. Discussion
        62. IXCs currently pay LECs access charges for terminating calls on 
    LEC switches. In a competitive local exchange market, an IXC 
    terminating a call to a long distance customer that has ported his or 
    her number to a new entrant will terminate the call to the incumbent 
    LEC's switch, which then will forward it to the new entrant's switch 
    utilizing interim number portability measures. Under this scenario, 
    incumbent LECs and new entrants both provide facilities used to 
    terminate calls to ported numbers using interim number portability. In 
    the First Report and Order, the Commission required both forwarding and 
    terminating carriers to assess charges on IXCs for terminating access 
    through meet-point billing arrangements. In requiring that these 
    revenues be shared, the Commission left to the carriers whether ``each 
    issues a bill for access on a ported call, or whether one of them 
    issues a bill to the IXCs covering all of the transferred calls and 
    shares the correct portion of the revenues with the other carriers 
    involved.'' The Commission further provided that, if carriers determine 
    it more efficient to issue individual bills, the forwarding carrier 
    must ``provide the terminating carrier with the necessary information 
    to permit the terminating carrier to issue a bill.''
        63. The Commission finds that the additional costs that local 
    exchange carriers may incur should not be included in the access 
    charges paid by IXCs for terminating long-distance calls because any 
    additional routing and transport costs that are a result of interim 
    number portability are incremental costs of providing number 
    portability. Such costs may be recovered through a local number 
    portability cost recovery mechanism, or borne by the local exchange 
    carrier that forwards the call, as determined by the state, on a 
    competitively neutral basis. Because they are telecommunications 
    carriers, IXCs may be required to contribute to the costs of interim 
    number portability through the cost recovery mechanism adopted by state 
    commissions. The Commission clarifies that, to prevent double recovery 
    on the part of the terminating switch carrier, new entrants receiving a 
    portion of access charges from IXCs for terminating calls may not also 
    impose terminating charges on the incumbent LEC.
        64. As discussed in the First Report and Order, carriers may incur 
    incremental costs for forwarding calls when utilizing interim number 
    portability. MCI requests that the Commission clarify what is included 
    in these incremental costs and, thus, what should be shared by all 
    carriers on a competitively neutral basis. The incremental costs of 
    providing number portability via RCF, DID, or other comparable 
    technically feasible measures are the costs that the forwarding carrier 
    incurs in forwarding the call that it would not incur if it did not 
    forward the call. As mentioned in the First Report and Order, such 
    costs may differ depending on where the call originates within the 
    network, and on the type of technology utilized to forward the call. 
    Thus, the Commission
    
    [[Page 46582]]
    
    declines to list each potential additional cost that may be incurred 
    and who should be allowed to bill for those incremental costs.
        65. Finally, the Commission notes that it has ``not foreclose[d] 
    arrangements in which one exchange carrier bills the entire amount [of 
    access charges] and remits the other exchange carrier its share.'' The 
    First Report and Order does not require that the carrier that owns the 
    donor switch and the carrier that owns the terminating switch each 
    issue a separate bill to the IXC. The First Report and Order states 
    that ``it is up to the carriers whether they each issue a bill for 
    access on a ported call, or whether one of them issues a bill to the 
    IXCs covering all of the transferred calls and shares the correct 
    portion of the revenues with the other carriers involved.'' Thus, 
    either the carrier that owns the donor switch or the carrier that owns 
    the terminating switch may bill the entire amount of access charges and 
    remit to the other local exchange carrier its share of the invoiced 
    charges. In short, the First Report and Order does not prohibit 
    carriers who mutually agree from sending one bill to the IXC and then 
    splitting the access charges appropriately between themselves.
    
    H. Modification of Billing Systems to Accommodate the Sharing of Access 
    Charges in Meet-Point Billing Type Arrangements
    
    1. Background
        66. In the First Report and Order, the Commission concluded that 
    meet-point billing between neighboring incumbent LECs provides the 
    appropriate model for the proper access billing arrangement for interim 
    number portability. In complying with the Commission's directive that 
    forwarding and terminating carriers share access revenues received from 
    IXCs for ported calls through meet-point billing arrangements, GTE 
    argues that LECs should not be required to modify their billing 
    systems.
    2. Discussion
        67. The First Report and Order did not specify whether carriers 
    must modify their billing systems in order to accommodate the 
    requirement that access charges be shared in meet-point billing type 
    arrangements. It requires that the forwarding carrier provide ``the 
    necessary information to permit the terminating carrier to issue a 
    bill,'' but does not specify whether carriers have to make 
    modifications in their billing systems in order to do so. The 
    Commission agrees with GTE and Time Warner that it would not be cost 
    effective to require carriers to modify their billing systems to 
    accommodate interim number portability. It does not require carriers to 
    modify their billing systems to track and record the details of every 
    call. It does require, however, that carriers adopt some method of 
    implementing its requirement to share terminating access revenues, by, 
    for example, providing information about PIU (percent interstate 
    usage), traffic samples, or total access charges per line.
        68. If carriers cannot agree on appropriate meet-point billing 
    arrangements, the Commission agrees that this issue may be included in 
    mediation or arbitration before a state commission, or be subject to 
    other dispute resolution processes chosen by the carriers involved. The 
    Commission rejects GTE's suggestion, however, that parties seek 
    informal assistance from the Commission as a means of resolving meet-
    point billing arrangement disputes. Also, if a meet-point billing 
    arrangement dispute arises in the context of an interconnection request 
    made pursuant to section 251, the 1996 Act clearly places the 
    responsibility for arbitration and/or mediation of unresolved issues on 
    the state commissions.
    
    IV. Supplemental Regulatory Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
    
        69. As required by the Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA), see 5 
    U.S.C. 601 et seq. (the RFA, see 5 U.S.C. 601 et seq., has been amended 
    by the Contract with America Advancement Act of 1996, Pub. L. No. 104-
    121, 110 Stat. 847 (1996) (CWAAA); Title II of the CWAAA is the Small 
    Business Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act of 1996 (SBREFA)), an 
    Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis (IRFA) was incorporated in the 
    First Report and Order. In addition, the Commission sought comments on 
    the proposals included in the Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis 
    (IRFA) in the First Report and Order. The Commission incorporated a 
    Final Regulatory Flexibility Analysis in the Third Report and Order. 
    The additional Regulatory Flexibility Analysis in this Fourth 
    Memorandum Opinion and Order is as follows:
        70. Need for and Objectives of Action: The Commission, in 
    compliance with sections 251(b)(2), 251(d)(1), and 251(e)(2) of the 
    Communications Act of 1934, as amended by the Telecommunications Act of 
    1996, adopted rules and procedures in the Third Report and Order that 
    are intended to ensure the implementation of telephone number 
    portability with the minimum regulatory and administrative burden on 
    telecommunications carriers. Congress has recognized that number 
    portability will lower barriers to entry and promote competition in the 
    local exchange marketplace. To prevent the cost of number portability 
    from itself becoming a barrier to local competition, section 251(e)(2) 
    requires that ``[t]he cost of establishing telecommunications numbering 
    administration arrangements and number portability shall be borne by 
    all telecommunications carriers on a competitively neutral basis as 
    determined by the Commission.'' The Commission issued this Fourth 
    Memorandum Opinion and Order to address issues relating to cost 
    recovery for interim number portability. Interim number portability 
    utilizes an interim method to allow consumers to change carriers while 
    retaining their telephone numbers before long-term number portability 
    becomes available.
        71. Summary of Significant Issues Raised by the Public Response to 
    the FRFA: There were no comments submitted specifically in response to 
    the Regulatory Flexibility Analysis. In the Third Report and Order, the 
    Commission adopted rules and regulations to ensure that the way all 
    telecommunications carriers, including small entities, bear the costs 
    of number portability does not significantly affect any carrier's 
    ability to compete with other carriers for customers in the 
    marketplace. This Fourth Memorandum Opinion and Order addresses issues 
    relating to cost recovery for interim number portability. It affirms 
    the Commission's conclusion that it has the authority to establish cost 
    recovery guidelines for interim number portability. Second, the 
    Commission rejects claims that the cost recovery guidelines for interim 
    number portability set forth in the First Report and Order are 
    arbitrary and capricious, or constitute an unconstitutional taking. The 
    item denies the request that these cost recovery guidelines be applied 
    retroactively. The item affirms the Commission's earlier decision to 
    adopt general cost recovery guidelines for interim number portability 
    while allowing states flexibility to continue using a variety of cost 
    recovery approaches that are consistent with its guidelines. Finally, 
    the item clarifies issues relating to terminating access charges, 
    modification of billing systems, and the competitive neutrality of 
    certain cost recovery allocators, as each of these issues relates to 
    interim number portability.
        72. Description and Estimate of Number of Small Businesses to Which 
    Actions Will Apply: The Regulatory
    
    [[Page 46583]]
    
    Flexibility Act generally defines the term ``small business'' as having 
    the same meaning as the term ``small business concern'' under the Small 
    Business Act. See 15 U.S.C. 632. A small business concern is one which: 
    (1) Is independently owned and operated; (2) is not dominant in its 
    field of operation; and (3) satisfies any additional criteria 
    established by the Small Business Administration (SBA). Id. According 
    to SBA's regulations, entities engaged in the provision of telephone 
    service may have a maximum of 1,500 employees in order to qualify as a 
    small business concern. See 13 CFR 121.201. This standard also applies 
    in determining whether an entity is a small business for purposes of 
    the RFA.
        73. As described in the previous Regulatory Flexibility Analysis 
    contained in the Third Report and Order, the Commission's rules 
    governing number portability cost recovery apply to all 
    telecommunications carriers, including incumbent LECs, new LEC 
    entrants, and IXCs, as well as cellular, broadband PCS, and covered SMR 
    providers. Small incumbent LECs subject to these rules are either 
    dominant in their filed of operations or are independently owned and 
    operated, and, consistent with the Commission's prior practice, are 
    excluded from the definition of ``small entities'' and ``small business 
    concerns.'' See In re Implementation of the Local Competition 
    Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, First Report and 
    Order, 11 FCC Rcd 15499, 16144-45, 16149-50 (1996), vacated in part, 
    aff'd in part, Iowa Utils. Bd. v. FCC, 120 F.3d 753 (8th Cir. 1997), 
    rev'd in part, aff'd in part and remanded sub nom. AT&T Corp. v. Iowa 
    Utils. Bd., 119 S.Ct. (1998). Accordingly, the Commission's use of the 
    terms ``small entities'' and ``small businesses'' does not encompass 
    small incumbent LECs. Local Competition Order, 11 FCC Rcd at 16,150. 
    Out of an abundance of caution, however, for regulatory flexibility 
    analysis purposes, see 13 CFR 121.902(b)(4), the Commission will 
    consider small incumbent LECs within this analysis and use the term 
    ``small incumbent LECs'' to refer to any incumbent LECs that arguably 
    might be defined by the SBA as ``small business concerns.''
        74. Insofar as the Commission's rules apply to all 
    telecommunications carriers, they may have an economic impact on a 
    substantial number of small businesses, as well as on small incumbent 
    LECs. The rules may have an impact upon new entrant LECs and small 
    incumbent LECs, as well as cellular, broadband PCS, and covered SMR 
    providers. Based upon data contained in the most recent census and a 
    report by the Commission's Common Carrier Bureau, the Commission 
    estimates that 2,100 small entities could be affected. The Commission 
    has derived this estimate based on the following analysis.
        75. According to the 1992 Census of Transportation, Communications, 
    and Utilities, there were approximately 3,469 firms with under 1,000 
    employees operating under the Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) 
    category 481--Telephone. See U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Bureau of the 
    Census, 1992 Census of Transportation, Communications, and Utilities 
    (issued May 1995). Many of these firms are the incumbent LECs and, as 
    noted above, would not satisfy the SBA definition of a small business 
    because of their market dominance. There were approximately 1,350 LECs 
    in 1995. Industry Analysis Division, FCC, Carrier Locator: Interstate 
    Service Providers at Table 1 (Number of Carriers Reporting by Type of 
    Carrier and Type of Revenue) (December 1995). Subtracting this number 
    from the total number of firms leaves approximately 2,119 entities 
    which potentially are small businesses which may be affected. This 
    number contains various categories of carriers, including small 
    incumbent LECs, competitive access providers, cellular carriers, 
    interexchange carriers, mobile service carriers, operator service 
    providers, pay telephone operators, PCS providers, covered SMR 
    providers, and resellers. Some of these carriers, although not 
    dominant, may not meet the other requirement of the definition of a 
    small business because they are not ``independently owned and 
    operated.'' See 15 U.S.C. 632(a)(1). For example, a PCS provider that 
    is affiliated with a long distance company with more than 1,500 
    employees would not meet the definition of a small business. Another 
    example would be if a cellular provider is affiliated with a dominant 
    LEC. Thus, a reasonable estimate of the number of ``small businesses'' 
    affected by this item would be approximately 2,100.
        76. Description of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping and Other 
    Compliance Requirements of the Rules: The Fourth Memorandum Opinion and 
    Order provides guidance regarding issues relating to cost recovery for 
    interim number portability. This Fourth Memorandum Opinion and Order 
    affirms the Commission's conclusion that it has the authority to 
    establish cost recovery guidelines for interim number portability. 
    Second, the Commission rejects claims that the cost recovery guidelines 
    for interim number portability set forth in the First Report and Order 
    are arbitrary and capricious, or constitute an unconstitutional taking. 
    This item denies the request that these cost recovery guidelines be 
    applied retroactively. This item affirms the Commission's earlier 
    decision to adopt general cost recovery guidelines for interim number 
    portability while allowing states flexibility to continue using a 
    variety of cost recovery approaches that are consistent with its 
    guidelines.
        77. The Fourth Memorandum Opinion and Order also confirms an 
    earlier Commission decision that a cost recovery mechanism based on a 
    carrier's gross revenues is an acceptable means of allocating costs 
    among carriers. It states that no additional recordkeeping will be 
    required for this option of recordkeeping, because such gross revenue 
    reporting is readily available through such things as tax filings, 
    annual reports and SEC filings, which are developed for other purposes. 
    The item does not require carriers to adopt any one billing arrangement 
    for sharing costs when they forward calls while utilizing interim 
    number portability. The item allows carriers to determine the best 
    method of splitting these costs between them, but requires them to 
    adopt some method of sharing terminating access revenues. Additionally, 
    it affirms the Commission's earlier determination that meet-point 
    billing between neighboring incumbent LECs provides the appropriate 
    model for the proper access billing arrangement for interim number 
    portability, but states that carriers are not required to modify their 
    billing systems to track and record the details of every call.
        78. Steps Taken to Minimize Impact on Small Entities Consistent 
    With Stated Objectives: The record in this proceeding indicates that 
    the need for customers to change their telephone numbers when changing 
    local service providers is a barrier to local competition. Requiring 
    number portability, and ensuring that all telecommunications carriers 
    bear the costs of number portability on a competitively neutral basis, 
    will make it easier for competitive providers, many of which may be 
    small entities, to enter the market. The Bureau has attempted to keep 
    regulatory burdens on all local exchange carriers to a minimum to 
    ensure that the public receives the benefits of the expeditious 
    provision of service provider number portability in accordance with the 
    statutory requirements. For example, the Fourth Memorandum Opinion and 
    Order affirms the Commission's earlier determination that meet-point 
    billing
    
    [[Page 46584]]
    
    between neighboring incumbent LECs provides the appropriate model for 
    the proper access billing arrangement for interim number portability, 
    but states that carriers are not required to modify their billing 
    systems to track and record the details of every call. Such 
    determination recognizes that number portability will cause some 
    carriers, including small entities, to incur costs that they would not 
    ordinarily have incurred in providing telecommunications services, but 
    attempts to keep such costs to a minimum.
        79. Report to Congress: The Commission will send a copy of this 
    Fourth Memorandum Opinion and Order, including this supplemental RFA, 
    in a report to Congress pursuant to the Small Business Regulatory 
    Enforcement Fairness Act of 1996. See 5 U.S.C. 801(a)(1)(A). A copy of 
    the Third Report and Order and this supplemental FRFA (or summaries 
    thereof) will be sent to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the Small 
    Business Administration. See 5 U.S.C. 604(b).
        80. Paperwork Reduction Act: This Fourth Memorandum Opinion and 
    Order provides guidance regarding issues relating to cost recovery for 
    interim number portability. The Third Report and Order concluded that 
    carriers may recover the portion of their number portability joint 
    costs that is demonstrably an incremental cost incurred in the 
    provision of number portability. Third Report and Order, 13 FCC Rcd at 
    11,740, para. 73. The Third Report and Order also requires incumbent 
    LECs that choose to recover their carrier-specific costs directly 
    related to providing number portability to use federally-tariffed end-
    user charges. Id. at 11,776. The Commission also concluded that 
    carriers may identify only those incremental overheads that they can 
    demonstrate were incurred specifically in the provision of number 
    portability. Id. at 11,740. In this Fourth Memorandum Opinion and 
    Order, the Commission affirms its earlier decision that it has the 
    authority to establish cost recovery guidelines for interim number 
    portability. Second, the Commission rejects claims that the cost 
    recovery guidelines for interim number portability set forth in the 
    First Report and Order are arbitrary and capricious, or constitute an 
    unconstitutional taking. This item denies the request that these cost 
    recovery guidelines be applied retroactively. The item affirms the 
    Commission's earlier decision to adopt general cost recovery guidelines 
    for interim number portability while allowing states flexibility to 
    continue using a variety of cost recovery approaches that are 
    consistent with its guidelines. The item also confirms an earlier 
    Commission decision that a cost recovery mechanism based on a carrier's 
    gross revenues is an acceptable means of allocation costs among 
    carriers. The item states that no additional recordkeeping will be 
    required for this option of recordkeeping, because such gross revenue 
    reporting is readily available through such things as tax filings, 
    annual reports and SEC filings, which are developed for other purposes. 
    The item does not require carriers to adopt any one billing arrangement 
    for sharing costs when they forward calls while utilizing interim 
    number portability. The item allows carriers to determine the best 
    method of splitting these costs between them, but requires them to 
    adopt some method of sharing terminating access revenues. Additionally, 
    the item affirms the Commission's earlier determination that meet-point 
    billing between neighboring incumbent LECs provides the appropriate 
    model for the proper access billing arrangement for interim number 
    portability, but states that carriers are not required to modify their 
    billing systems to track and record the details of every call. These 
    information collection requirements are contingent upon approval of the 
    Office of Management and Budget (OMB).
    
    V. Ordering Clauses
    
        81. Accordingly, it is ordered that pursuant to authority contained 
    in sections 1, 2, 4(i), 201-205, 215, 251(b)(2), 251(e)(2), and 332 of 
    the Communications Act of 1934, as amended, 47 U.S.C. 151, 152, 154(i), 
    201-205, 215, 251(b)(2), 251(e)(2), and 332, and Parts 1, 20 and 52 of 
    the Commission's rules, 47 CFR 1.106, 20, and 52, the Petitions for 
    Reconsideration and/or Clarification are granted to the extent 
    indicated herein and otherwise are denied.
        82. It is further ordered that the Motion to Accept Late-filed 
    Comments of Telecommunications Resellers Association and the Motion to 
    Accept Late-Filed Reply Comments of US WEST are granted.
        83. It is further ordered that the Commission's Office of Public 
    Affairs Reference Operations Division shall send a copy of this 
    Memorandum Opinion and Order including the supplemental Regulatory 
    Flexibility Analysis to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the Small 
    Business Administration.
    
    List of Subjects in 47 CFR Part 52
    
        Communications, Common Carriers, Telecommunications, Telephone.
    
    Federal Communications Commission.
    Magalie Roman Salas,
    Secretary.
    [FR Doc. 99-22131 Filed 8-25-99; 8:45 am]
    BILLING CODE 6712-01-P
    
    
    

Document Information

Effective Date:
9/27/1999
Published:
08/26/1999
Department:
Federal Communications Commission
Entry Type:
Rule
Action:
Policy statement.
Document Number:
99-22131
Dates:
Effective September 27, 1999.
Pages:
46571-46584 (14 pages)
Docket Numbers:
CC Docket No. 95-116, FCC 99-151
PDF File:
99-22131.pdf