95-21319. Radio Broadcast Services; Television Program Practices  

  • [Federal Register Volume 60, Number 167 (Tuesday, August 29, 1995)]
    [Rules and Regulations]
    [Pages 44773-44780]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 95-21319]
    
    
    
    =======================================================================
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
    
    47 CFR Part 73
    
    [MM Docket No. 94-123; FCC 95-314]
    
    
    Radio Broadcast Services; Television Program Practices
    
    AGENCY: Federal Communications Commission.
    
    ACTION: Final rule.
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    SUMMARY: This Report and Order repeals the Commission's Rules regarding 
    the Prime Time Access Rule. The Commission had invited comments in a 
    rulemaking proceeding to assess the legal and policy justifications, in 
    light of current economic and technological conditions, for the Prime 
    Time Access Rule and to consider the continued need for the rule in its 
    current form. Based on the comments received from interested parties, 
    including economic and empirical analyses of the effects of repealing 
    or retaining the rule, the Commission concludes that the public 
    interest warrants the repeal of PTAR. In repealing the rule, the 
    Commission believes a one-year transition period is appropriate to 
    provide parties time to adjust their programming strategies and 
    business arrangements.
    
    EFFECTIVE DATE: August 30, 1996.
    
    FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Charles W. Logan or Alan E. Aronowitz, 
    Mass Media Bureau, Policy and Rules Division, Legal Branch, (202) 776-
    1663, or Alan Baughcum, Mass Media Bureau, Policy and Rules Division, 
    Policy Analysis Branch, (202) 739-0770.
    
    SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a synopsis of the Commission's 
    Report and Order in MM Docket No. 94-123, adopted July 28, 1995, and 
    released July 31, 1995. The complete text of this document is available 
    for inspection and copying during normal business hours in the FCC 
    Reference Center (Room 239), 1919 M Street NW., Washington, D.C. 20554, 
    and may be purchased from the Commission's copy contractor, 
    International Transcription Service, (202) 857-3800, 2100 M Street NW., 
    Washington, D.C. 20037.
    
    Synopsis of the Report and Order
    
        1. The Commission's Prime Time Access Rule (``PTAR'') generally 
    prohibits network-affiliated television stations in the top 50 prime-
    time television markets (``Top 50 Market Affiliates'') from 
    broadcasting more than three hours of network programs (the ``network 
    restriction'') or former network programs (the ``off-network 
    restriction'') during the four prime time viewing hours (i.e., 7 to 11 
    p.m. Eastern and Pacific times; 6 to 10 p.m. Central and Mountain 
    times). The rule exempts certain types of programming (e.g., runovers 
    of live sports events, special news, documentary and children's 
    programming, and certain sports and network programming of a special 
    nature) which are not counted toward the three hours of network 
    programming.\1\ PTAR was promulgated in 1970 in response to a concern 
    that the three major television networks--ABC, CBS and NBC--dominated 
    the program production market, controlled much of the video fare 
    presented to the public, and inhibited the development of competing 
    program sources. The Commission believed that PTAR would increase the 
    level of competition in program production, reduce the networks' 
    control over their affiliates' programming decisions, and thereby 
    increase the diversity of programs available to the public. PTAR also 
    came to be viewed as a means of promoting the growth of independent 
    stations in that they did not have to compete with Top 50 Market 
    Affiliates in acquiring off-network programs to air during the access 
    period.
    
        \1\47 CFR 73.658(k)(1)-(6).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        2. On October 20, 1994, the Commission adopted a Notice of Proposed 
    Rule Making (``Notice''), 59 FR 55402 (November 7, 1994), in this 
    docket to conduct an overall review of the continuing need for PTAR 
    given the profound changes that have occurred in the television 
    industry since 1970. In response to the Notice, we received a 
    substantial number of comments from interested parties, including 
    economic and empirical analyses of the effects of repealing or 
    retaining the rule.
        3. Based on this record, the Commission concludes that PTAR should 
    be extinguished. The three major networks do not dominate the markets 
    relevant to PTAR. There are large numbers of sellers and buyers of 
    video programming. Entry, even by small business, is relatively easy. 
    There are a substantially greater number of broadcast programming 
    outlets today than when PTAR was adopted in 1970 due to the growth in 
    numbers of independent stations. In addition, nonbroadcast media have 
    proliferated. We also find, given these market conditions, and the 
    record before us, 
    
    [[Page 44774]]
    that the rule is not warranted as a means of promoting the growth of 
    independent stations and new networks, or of safeguards affiliate 
    autonomy. Indeed, the rule generates costs and inefficiencies that are 
    not now offset by substantial, if any, benefits.
        4. The Commission thus finds that the public interest warrants the 
    repeal of PTAR. In scheduling repeal of the rule, a one-year transition 
    period is appropriate to provide parties time to adjust their 
    programming strategies and business arrangements prior to the 
    elimination of a regulatory regime that has been in place for 25 years. 
    Consequently PTAR will be repealed effective August 30, 1996.
        5. This conclusion is consistent with the Commission's 1993 
    decision to schedule the repeal of the financial interest and 
    syndication rules ((``fin/syn''), which was upheld on appeal by the 
    U.S. Court of Appeals for the Seventh Circuit. See Capital Cities/ABC, 
    Inc. V. FCC, 29 F.3d 309 (7th Cir. 1994). We determined that repeal of 
    the fin/syn rules was warranted given the increased competition facing 
    the networks and the conditions in the television programming 
    marketplace. Based upon these findings we eliminated a number of the 
    fin/syn rules immediately and set a timetable for repeal of the 
    remainder.
        6. The Commission reaches its conclusion to PTAR by analyzing the 
    following factors: First, it evaluates whether the networks dominate 
    the markets relevant to the rule, or would be likely to dominate them 
    in the absence of PTAR. Second, it assesses the costs imposed by the 
    rule. Third, taking into account its findings regarding whether the 
    networks dominate and the costs of the rule, it analyzes whether the 
    rule is necessary as a means of pursuing the benefits of fostering 
    independent programming, promoting the growth of independent stations 
    and new networks, and safeguarding affiliate autonomy.
    I. The Networks and Their Affiliates Do Not Dominate Markets 
    Relevant to PTAR
    
        7. The Commission's adoption of PTAR in 1970 was premised on a view 
    that the three networks dominated television programming. The 
    Commission's analysis of the record leads it to conclude that neither 
    the networks nor their affiliates dominate video programming 
    distribution or the video programming production market. The Commission 
    reaches this conclusion by employing a two-step market power analysis 
    which involves defining the relevant market and examining evidence of 
    undue market power.
    
    A. Video Programming Distribution
    
        8. PTAR applies to ABC, CBS, and NBC affiliates in the Top 50 PTAR 
    Markets. These networks and their affiliates display or ``distribute'' 
    television programming to viewers and sell air time to customers 
    seeking to advertise. In program distribution, networks and their 
    affiliates compete with programs broadcast by independent stations. The 
    list of economic substitutes for network broadcasts may also include 
    cable programs, programs over satellite television systems, 
    videocassette rentals, and other alternatives. For purposes of its 
    review of PTAR, the Commission will focus on program distribution 
    comprising only broadcast television station operators and their 
    networks. This is a conservative, perhaps overly narrow, approach given 
    that a good case can be made that, from the viewers' perspectives, 
    cable system operators inter alia are economically relevant alternative 
    distributors of video programming. Since PTAR constrains the market 
    activities of affiliates of the three major networks in the Top 50 PTAR 
    Markets, the Commission's primary focus in this section is whether 
    these network affiliates would be able to exercise undue market power 
    in the delivery of video programming in their respective local markets.
        9. Based on the record, it is clear that, in the Top 50 PTAR 
    Markets, the three original networks and their affiliates face more 
    competition for viewers than they did in 1970 or even in 1980. There 
    are substantially greater numbers of television stations than there 
    were in 1970. For example, the number of independent stations has grown 
    by 450 percent during this time. The effects of this competition are 
    readily apparent in examining the networks' audience shares over the 
    years. Looking at prime time alone, the time period when the networks' 
    viewing shares are the highest, each network's average share of the 
    prime time audience declined from a 31.1 viewing share during the 1971/
    72 season to a 20.2 share during the 1993/94 season, a loss of almost 
    one-third of each network's audience. ABC, CBS, NBC, and Fox had 
    individual 1993/94 prime-time audience shares of 20.1 , 22.7, 17.8 and 
    11.4 percent, respectively. The Commission's calculation of affiliate 
    audience shares in each of the Top 50 PTAR Markets is consistent with 
    network audience shares nationally. No single network or network 
    affiliate would seem to have the ability to dominate video programming 
    distribution in any of these local markets.
        10. Nor is it likely that affiliates in a local Top 50 PTAR Market 
    would dominate as a group since video programming distribution is only 
    moderately concentrated. In its 1993 decision setting a timetable for 
    repeal of the fin/syn rules, the Commission stated that ``inter-network 
    competition for programming is `intense.''' Nothing in the record 
    before us calls this conclusion into doubt, as the networks continue to 
    wage a ratings war that has only been heightened with the emergence of 
    the Fox network.
        11. The Commission thus concludes that, even focusing narrowly on 
    local broadcast video programming distribution, the three networks and 
    their affiliates cannot singly or jointly dominate video program 
    distribution in the Top 50 PTAR Markets. This is a strong conclusion 
    because the inclusion of additional television alternatives such as 
    cable, satellite systems, video dialtone, etc., would serve to make 
    domination by the networks and their affiliates even less likely.
    
    B. The Video Programming Production Market
    
        12. Defining the relevant video programming production market 
    begins by focusing on the products produced by beneficiaries of PTAR. 
    Entertainment series, news magazine shows, and game shows are examples 
    of the programs sold by independent producers and syndicators of prime-
    time programs to network affiliates and independents. The list can be 
    extended to include movies (whether for television, theatrical 
    presentation, or cassette rental), sports programs, talk shows, news 
    programming (local and national), musical variety, dramas, arts 
    presentations, etc. Suppliers of these programs include not only those 
    suppliers that actually are employed in a given year to produce 
    programming for network prime time but also those producers willing and 
    able to produce such programming in the event that market price 
    increased above the competitive level. The list of suppliers will 
    include television networks, independent syndicators, Hollywood movie 
    studios, and international video producers. Buyers of such programming 
    are not limited to television broadcasters but will include other 
    purchasers of video programming such as cable networks and operators, 
    direct broadcast satellite operators, videocassette distributers and, 
    most recently, video programming affiliates of local telephone 
    companies, which propose to offer video dialtone service. This market 
    is clearly national and perhaps international in scope, because 
    
    [[Page 44775]]
    television broadcasters obtain a large portion of their programs from 
    national providers.
        13. There is no evidence in the record that the networks exercise 
    monopsony or oligopsony power in the video programming production 
    market, i.e., that one (monopsony) or several firms (oligopsony) 
    artificially restrict the consumption of programming and depress the 
    market price paid for programming. Aside from the growth in the 
    broadcast industry described above, there are nearly 150 national and 
    regional cable networks, most of which transmit original, non-network 
    programming. Also, other nonbroadcast video program distributors--such 
    as cable, wireless cable, and satellite services--have grown. Finally, 
    first-run syndicators are quite active as buyers (and sellers). 
    According to the record, in 1994 the video entertainment programming 
    purchased by each of the three networks accounted for approximately 9.4 
    percent of aggregate expenditures on video programming in the United 
    States, after taking into account distribution fees associated with 
    syndicated programming and home videos. These market shares indicate 
    that demand for video programming is not concentrated, and that the 
    networks clearly cannot be said to exercise undue market power in the 
    video programming production market, either individually or together. 
    The record also shows that the supply side of the video programming 
    production market is no more concentrated than the demand side.
        14. The Commission therefore concludes that no buyers or sellers, 
    acting alone or together, are likely to be able to exercise undue 
    market power in the video programming production market. In addition, 
    entry barriers are low. In particular, it is unlikely that the three 
    networks will be able to exercise market power in the video programming 
    production market, either on the demand or supply side, if PTAR is 
    repealed.
    
    C. The National Television Advertising Market
    
        15. Several proponents of PTAR argue that the three networks 
    dominate the television advertising market. But these parties do not 
    present sufficient evidence to support this argument. Moreover, PTAR 
    was not adopted to address the structure or performance of the 
    advertising industry. This is why the Notice did not explicitly seek 
    information on television advertising markets. The Commission adopted 
    PTAR due to concerns that the three networks dominated the production 
    and delivery of television programming. Examination of video 
    programming distribution and the video programming production market is 
    thus directly relevant to whether PTAR is necessary under today's 
    market conditions. The Commission cannot say the same for the 
    television advertising market, nor are we persuaded that PTAR is the 
    appropriate mechanism for addressing the networks' role in these 
    markets.
    II. The Costs of PTAR
    
        16. In assessing the continuing need for PTAR, the Commission must 
    take into account the costs the rule imposes on the networks, their 
    affiliates, producers of network programming, television viewers, and 
    the efficient functioning of the market. One obvious cost of the rule 
    is that it restricts the programming choices of Top 50 Market 
    Affiliates. They cannot air either network or off-network programming 
    during the access period. One set of comments describes how the off-
    network restriction interferes with the smooth functioning of the 
    network-affiliate relationship by raising the overall costs of network 
    broadcasting. With PTAR in place, the affiliate must either make 
    investments to produce programs itself, or it must purchase first-run 
    programs from syndicators. In the latter case, the affiliate bears the 
    transaction costs of establishing relationships with syndicators and 
    independent programmers. In either case, the affiliate bears the added 
    risk of how first-run programming will perform relative to known-to-be 
    popular network reruns. As a result of these higher costs, the total of 
    net revenues to be shared among networks and affiliates is made smaller 
    by PTAR.
        17. PTAR harms not only networks and affiliates, but the producers 
    of network programming. The off-network restrictions has had the 
    unintended effect of discouraging investment in prime-time programming. 
    Producers rely to a great extent on their ability to sell reruns of 
    their programs--i.e., off-network programs--to recoup their costs and 
    to earn a profit. The license fee the networks pay for the right to air 
    prime-time entertainment programs often does not cover the costs of 
    producing these programs. The off-network restriction, however, 
    diminishes producers' ability to recoup unrecovered costs by 
    artificially restraining the prices of off-network programming. It does 
    so by eliminating the Top 50 Market Affiliates from the range of 
    potential purchasers of this programming. By reducing demand, the 
    prices for off-network shows are reduced. The Commission believes that 
    PTAR produces costs and inefficiencies to viewers that are larger than 
    the benefits, if any, of PTAR to viewers.
        18. In addition, PTAR as a whole prevents the networks and their 
    affiliates from taking advantage of network efficiencies during the 
    access hour. Networks can deliver large audiences to advertisers, which 
    in turn allows the networks and their affiliates to provide higher cost 
    programming that is quite popular among audiences during prime time. 
    While the parties dispute the size of the economic cost due to the loss 
    of network efficiencies, the Commission concludes that this cost far 
    exceeds PTAR's economic benefits.
    
    III. Analyzing the Public Interest Need for PTAR
    
    A. Increasing Opportunities for Independent Programmers
    
        19. PTAR's principal purpose was to promote source diversity by 
    strengthening existing independent television program producers and 
    encouraging entry of new producers. In adopting PTAR, the Commission 
    predicted that the rule would increase the net amount of diverse 
    programming available to the viewing public and induce the entry of new 
    program suppliers into the market.
        20. A number of parties argue that PTAR has failed to promote these 
    goals. They point out that four companies--Paramount, Warner Brothers, 
    Fox, and King World--distribute over 95 percent of the first-run 
    syndicated programming aired during the PTAR access period. Putting 
    aside the question of who distributes access period programming, 
    opponents of the rule also argue that PTAR has failed to increase 
    diversity in terms of who produces such programming. Moreover, the rule 
    has been criticized for actually lowering program quality and 
    diversity. Without judging the quality of particular programs, the 
    Commission agrees that PTAR, by eliminating network programming during 
    the access hour, may have resulted in the loss of efficiencies that the 
    networks and their affiliates may have enjoyed in the absence of the 
    rule. The Commission notes, however that there are many variables that 
    affect the number of program producers and program types in the market, 
    with or without PTAR. Nevertheless, we recognize the limits of 
    regulatory efforts to promote program diversity, and realize that PTAR 
    prevents the use of network efficiencies during the access hour.
        21. Mindful of these issues, the Commission turns to the critical 
    question of whether PTAR is necessary today as a means of promoting the 
    
    
    [[Page 44776]]
    growth of independent programmers and source diversity. In answering 
    this question, it is important to remember that in adopting PTAR, the 
    Commission cautioned that it was not its intention to carve out a 
    competition free haven for syndicators or to smooth the path for 
    existing syndicators. Rather, the central objective of the rule was to 
    provide opportunity for the competitive development of alternate 
    sources of television programs. The Commission no longer believes PTAR 
    is necessary to provide this opportunity under today's market 
    conditions. The Commission reached a similar conclusion in eliminating 
    the fin/syn rules' restriction on network acquisition of financial 
    interest and syndication rights in network prime time entertainment 
    programming. In reaching this conclusion, the Commission dealt with the 
    same source diversity concerns and stated that if profits are 
    competitive, then the only reason to employ regulatory devices to 
    protect producer profits is if we determined that, for some reason, the 
    public required a greater array of producers than the market would 
    normally bear. As in the fin/syn proceeding, no party has provided any 
    reasoned justification for such a result here.
        22. Repeal of PTAR will subject suppliers of first-run syndicated 
    programming to greater competition during the access period. This 
    competition in today's marketplace can provide incentives to provide 
    more innovative, higher quality programming, all of which benefits the 
    consumer. Repeal of PTAR will also eliminate the costs generated by the 
    rule. Most importantly, prices for off-network programming will no 
    longer be artificially constrained, which we expect will encourage 
    investment in the production of network programming.
        23. Proponents of the rule have not provided any evidence to 
    support their claims that this competition will destroy the market for 
    first-run non-network syndicated programming. The record indicates that 
    first-run programming is often quite popular among audiences, and may 
    very well be carried by network affiliates during the access hour in 
    the Top 50 PTAR markets even after repeal of the rule. To the extent 
    off-network or network programming would displace first-run syndicated 
    programs from the Top 50 Market Affiliates, first-run programs should 
    be able to find a place on independent stations, not to mention other 
    outlets such as cable.
    
    B. Fostering the Growth of Independent Stations and New Networks
    
        24. PTAR provides independent stations greater access to off-
    network programming and prevents them from having to compete against 
    network programming during the access hour. Proponents of PTAR argue 
    that the rule is necessary to promote the Commission's outlet diversity 
    goals by fostering the growth of independent stations and new networks. 
    But the record does not conclusively show that repeal of either the 
    off-network provision or the network restriction of PTAR will undo the 
    growth of independent stations since the rule was adopted. Nor will 
    repeal of the rule likely undermine the development of new broadcast 
    networks, or otherwise harm the Commission's outlet diversity goals.
        25. The number of independent television stations has grown by 
    almost 450 percent since PTAR was adopted, from 82 stations in 1970 to 
    over 450 today. The record indicates that advances in television 
    design, the growth of cable penetration, and the growth in demand for 
    television advertising all have strengthened independent television. 
    Independents also have a robust supply of programming to turn to under 
    today's market conditions. The repeal of PTAR is unlikely to threaten 
    these advancements. Nor is there sufficient basis in the record to 
    conclude that repeal will so undermine the ratings and profits of 
    independent stations that our outlet diversity goals will be 
    implicated. It is likely that repeal of the rule will subject these 
    stations to greater competition in acquiring off-network programming 
    and in attracting audiences during the access hour and prime time. But 
    there is not sufficient evidence in the record to support the claims 
    that this competition will result in dramatic ratings declines and 
    revenue losses to an extent that threatens the overall viability of 
    independent stations and their ability to satisfy their public interest 
    obligations. Relatedly, there is no reliable evidence to indicate that 
    repeal of PTAR will jeopardize the station base of the new networks or 
    threaten their further development.
        26. The Commission consequently concludes that PTAR is not 
    warranted as a means of ensuring the growth of independent television 
    stations or new networks. This is especially the case given the costs 
    of the rule. The off-network provision discourages investment in 
    network programming. Moreover, it is becoming increasingly inequitable 
    to provide a competitive advantage to independent stations over network 
    affiliates in today's marketplace. The networks and their affiliates, 
    like independents, face growing competition from non-broadcast media.
        27. The Commission reaches this conclusion by addressing three 
    questions raised by the commenters: First, does the record show that 
    the ``UHF handicap'' warrants affording independent stations a 
    competitive advantage in the form of PTAR? Second, does the record 
    demonstrate that PTAR is needed to support independent television 
    stations' ratings and profitability and that repeal of PTAR would 
    significantly harm outlet diversity? Third, does the record support the 
    argument that the repeal of PTAR will frustrate the development of new 
    networks?
    1. The UHF Handicap
        28. Proponents of the rule seek to justify PTAR by pointing to the 
    signal reach disadvantage of UHF stations relative to VHF stations. 
    They maintain that this ``UHF handicap'' places independent stations at 
    a structural disadvantage since most of them are in the UHF band. 
    Affiliates of the three major networks are predominantly VHF stations.
        29. The Commission's review of the record, however, as well as 
    Commission findings in other proceedings, leads it to conclude that the 
    UHF handicap has been reduced to some extent. First, Congress and the 
    Commission have taken a number of steps over the years to ameliorate 
    this handicap by requiring television equipment improvements. Second, 
    the growth of cable has resulted in a reduction in the UHF handicap 
    with respect to those viewers that subscribe to cable. However, 
    although cable has reduced the UHF handicap, the Commission understands 
    that it may still affect some portion of viewers who are not cable 
    subscribers.
        30. While the UHF disparity continues for some viewers, we do not 
    think the public interest is served by tying PTAR to its complete 
    elimination. The rule does not and cannot address the technical 
    disparities that still exist between some stations. Moreover, the rule 
    has never been tailored to the UHF/VHF distinction. Rather, PTAR 
    provides a competitive advantage to independent stations by limiting 
    the programming options available to Top 50 Market Affiliates, even in 
    cases where the affected network affiliates are themselves UHF 
    stations. The Commission does not believe this is appropriate given 
    today's market 
    
    [[Page 44777]]
    conditions and the costs imposed by the rule. The handicap has been 
    reduced. Affiliates, like independents, are facing increased 
    competition in the television marketplace from non-broadcast sources. 
    The Commission thus concludes that the UHF handicap that remains does 
    not warrant continuation of PTAR.
    2. PTAR and the Ratings, Growth, and Profitability of Independent 
    Television Stations
        31. The Impact of PTAR on Ratings and Station Growth. Proponents of 
    the rule rely on a regression analysis set forth in the comments 
    submitted by the Law and Economics Consulting Group (``the LECG 
    Study'') to support their claims regarding the importance of PTAR to 
    independent stations. The LECG analysis attempts to demonstrate that 
    the adoption of each of the two components of PTAR (the three-hour 
    network restriction and the off-network restriction) increased the 
    ratings of independent stations. The same analysis also seeks to show 
    that repealing PTAR will result in a 58 percent drop in access period 
    ratings and in a carry-over 67 percent drop in the ratings for the 
    first (following) prime-time hour for independent television stations.
        32. After an extensive review of the LECG Study, the Commission 
    concludes that the LECG Study, and the arguments advanced by parties 
    based on this study, do not provide sufficient evidence to demonstrate 
    that repeal of PTAR will result in significant ratings declines for 
    independent stations. For the same reasons, the study does not provide 
    reliable evidence that PTAR has as a historical matter increased 
    independent station ratings. There are numerous flaws in LECG's 
    analysis that lead the Commission to this conclusion, including the 
    following: (1) LECG does not link its econometric model to an 
    underlying conceptual model of behavior in the television industry; (2) 
    LECG ignores to problem of hysteresis (i.e., even if PTAR caused 
    certain changes in the past, there is no guarantee that its elimination 
    will reverse those changes); (3) LECG's statistical methodology links 
    changes in independent station's ratings PTAR solely to PTAR, and does 
    not take into account other regulations that have benefited these 
    stations; (4) There are errors and gaps in LECG's data sets; (5) There 
    seem to be problems with LECG's specifications of its equations and 
    their estimation; and (6) LECG's analysis reports point estimates for 
    regression coefficients without confidence intervals, making it 
    impossible to confirm that LECG's predicted ratings decline for 
    independent stations are statistically distinguishable from zero.
        33. The Commission further observes that while independent stations 
    will be forced to pay competitive prices for off-network programming in 
    the absence of PTAR, they will not necessarily be outbid for such 
    programming. In market 51-100, 76 percent of syndicated programs aired 
    by network affiliates is first-run rather than off-network. Moreover, 
    in 1993, two of the top five off-network programs broadcast in markets 
    51-100 were aired more often on independent stations than on 
    affiliates. It is also unlikely that all network affiliates in a market 
    will flock to off-network shows, given the incentive to counter-program 
    with different program formats. In addition, in the event the networks 
    and their affiliates opt to run network programming during the access 
    hour, off-network fare will continue to be available to independents. 
    Finally, in the event an off-network program is displaced from an 
    independent station, the station can turn to first-run syndicated 
    programming. First-run programming can generate higher ratings than 
    off-network shows, with associated carryover ratings benefits.
        34. The Commission also notes that the argument advanced in favor 
    of giving a competitive advantage to independent stations, taken to its 
    logical conclusion, would suggest that PTAR coverage be redefined so 
    that it applies to smaller, and less financially secure, markets. Yet 
    no party has proposed such a result. To the contrary, PTAR's benefits 
    appear to flow mainly to the stronger independent stations in the 
    country. In fact, these stations generally have affiliated with one of 
    the new networks or are part of a jointly owned station group. 
    According to comments submitted by NBC, there is not a single 
    independent station in the top 50 markets showing a top-five rated off-
    network program that is (1) a UHF station that is (2) not affiliated 
    with Fox, UPN, or WB, and/or (3) not owned by a company owning three or 
    more stations. Thus, the impact of repeal of the rule may primarily be 
    felt by the stronger independent stations. In addition, these stations 
    participate in joint purchasing or production arrangements that may 
    ameliorate some of the effects of PTAR's repeal on program prices.
        35. Growth in Numbers of Independents. One of the reasons that the 
    LECG Study and INTV claim as support for the proposition that repeal of 
    PTAR will substantially hurt UHF independent stations is that the 
    adoption of PTAR allegedly was responsible for significant growth in 
    the number of independent stations, albeit not until 5-15 years later. 
    However, a study submitted by Economics, Inc. (``EI''), shows that 
    LECG's model can be used to demonstrate that PTAR is not responsible 
    for the increase in the number of independent stations. Thus, the 
    Commission cannot conclude that PTAR's adoption caused a significant 
    increase in the number of independent stations. Nor can the Commission 
    therefore conclude that PTAR's repeal will cause the large reduction in 
    the number of independent stations claimed by the rule's proponents.
        36. The impact of PTAR on Profits and Programming. Even if the 
    Commission assumes that PTAR proponents are correct in their prediction 
    of a ratings decline for independent stations in the event PTAR is 
    repealed, they have not demonstrated how that would affect independent 
    stations and the future development of new networks. In particular, 
    LECG has not provided any convincing estimate of how a decline in 
    audience share during 1 or 2 hours of prime time, would lead to a large 
    decline in station revenues and a resulting decline in station profits. 
    Proponents of the rule have thus not provided any reliable basis to 
    find that the profits of independent stations would decline 
    significantly. More importantly, there is no reliable evidence in the 
    record to support these parties' claims that repeal of the rule will so 
    affect the financial health of independent stations as to force 
    stations off the air or undermine their ability to provide public 
    interest programming, including news and other public affairs 
    programming.
        37. What the record does show is a generally healthy financial 
    picture for independent stations. Profit data published by the National 
    Associate of Broadcasters (``NAB'') indicate that the average 
    independent station has generally been profitable, at least since the 
    mid-1980s. The average UHF station has been profitable since 1992 after 
    a number of unprofitable years through the 1980s. This strong financial 
    picture extends to the independent stations not affiliated with the 
    largest of the new networks, Fox. These stations reported, on average, 
    1993 profits of four million dollars per station. UHF non-Fox 
    affiliated independents reported average annual profits of $1.5 million 
    per station in 1993. Also, these average profits understate 
    profitability in the largest markets, those to which PTAR applies.
        38. Conclusions. The Commission thus concludes that PTAR, which has 
    become overly broad and inequitable, is not necessary to provide 
    independent 
    
    [[Page 44778]]
    stations a competitive advantage relative to the Top 50 Market 
    Affiliates. Independent stations may face greater competition in 
    programming the access hour without PTAR. But there is no reliable 
    evidence that this will so jeopardize the financial health of 
    independent stations as to implicate public interest concerns, 
    particularly those relating to outlet diversity.
    3. Repeal of PTAR and New Broadcast Networks
        39. According to proponents of PTAR, one of the major reasons why 
    PTAR has been and continues to be important is that by promoting the 
    health of independent stations, it has helped create an important and 
    necessary condition for the development of the new networks--Fox, UPN 
    and WB. Proponents of the rule argue that repeal will severely harm 
    independent stations and, in turn, harm the growth of UPN and WB. These 
    parties, however, have not demonstrated the link between the asserted 
    harm to independent stations as a result of the repeal of PTAR and the 
    decreased likelihood of the development of new networks. In their 
    analysis concerning PTAR and the improving position of those stations 
    and new networks, PTAR proponents seem to suggest that the 
    profitability of independent stations has been responsible for the 
    growth of newly emerging networks, especially the Fox network. However, 
    it is equally plausible that many affiliates of the Fox network owe 
    their improved profit position to their affiliation with Fox. 
    Regardless of the possible importance of both parts of this 
    interaction, parties favoring continuation of PTAR have not 
    demonstrated in any convincing way that PTAR itself is ultimately 
    responsible for the development of newly emerging networks.
        40. The Commission does not believe that repeal of PTAR will create 
    the grounds for failure of newly-launched television networks nor for 
    significant slowing in their development. Some independent stations may 
    find their profits reduced as the industry adjusts to this change and 
    other regulatory and technological changes. However, the Commission 
    concludes that the prospects for independent stations and new networks 
    overall are good. First, the Commission believes that the UHF signal 
    disparity has been reduced, albeit not entirely. This permits 
    competition for programming on more even terms between similarly 
    situated UHF and VHF stations, most of which are now network 
    affiliates. Second, the video programming production market appears to 
    be open to entry by large and small firms with many producers actively 
    seeking outlets for their programs. Third, the numbers of independent 
    stations remain large enough to make it possible for new networks to 
    add affiliates and expand audience reach. Finally, at the present time, 
    virtually all categories of television broadcast stations are, on 
    average, profitable. The repeal of PTAR will reduce costs imposed by 
    the rule's restrictions on affiliates, network program producers, and 
    viewers who prefer high-cost programming, and will not create 
    significant problems for independent stations and new networks.
    
    C. Reducing Network Ability to Dictate Affiliate Programming Choices
    
        41. PTAR prohibits the Top 50 Market Affiliates from obtaining 
    network-provided programs or off-network programs during the access 
    period. In 1970, when it adopted PTAR, the Commission concluded that 
    this was a reasonable method of protecting affiliates against the power 
    of the networks. Under this reasoning, the affiliates did not have 
    sufficient bargaining power to refuse to run network programs, even 
    when doing so was not in their economic self-interest. Thus, although 
    the rule limited the programming options available to affiliates during 
    one hour and consequently limited to the same extent the viewing 
    options available to viewers, nonetheless the affiliates may have 
    believed they were better off with the rule than without the rule, 
    given the dominant position of the three networks. The view was that 
    while a network would dictate one program shown nationally for the 
    access period, the rule would permit the affiliate to choose instead 
    from a range of choices (i.e., in-house or independently produced 
    programs).
        42. While advocating repeal of the off-network provision of PTAR, 
    proponents of the network restriction argue that there are some 
    indications that the networks continue to have significant bargaining 
    leverage over their affiliates. Prime time clearance levels are very 
    high. The record also shows that affiliates rarely preempt prime time 
    network programming, and that affiliate agreements are often structured 
    to discourage preemption. In addition, the increase in the number of 
    independent stations may have increased the demand and competition for 
    the most lucrative network affiliations. This may therefore reduce, at 
    least to some degree, the increased leverage the network affiliates 
    appear to have gained as a result of the emergence of the Fox network. 
    Moreover, the WB and UPN networks, only recently launched and presently 
    offering a minimal program schedule, may not yet provide a competitive 
    alternative to affiliation with one of the other four networks.
        43. On balance, however, the Commission does not believe PTAR's 
    network restriction is the appropriate mechanism under current market 
    conditions to address the issue of the relative bargaining power 
    between networks and affiliates. As an initial matter, high clearance 
    rates do not necessarily indicate undue network leverage; they may 
    simply reflect the popularity and efficiencies of network programming. 
    There is also evidence in the record indicating greater affiliate 
    bargaining power today. The emergence of the Fox network certainly can 
    be said to have improved affiliate bargaining power by creating a 
    viable affiliation alternative to ABC, CBS, and NBC. The networks also 
    point to the fact that the total amount of network programming during 
    non-prime time dayparts has declined over the years as evidence of the 
    inability of networks to dictate to affiliates. Finally, there are 
    today many more options for obtaining programming even without having a 
    network affiliation.
        44. The Commission notes that it is not concerned with the relative 
    bargaining position of networks and their affiliates to the extent it 
    merely affects the distribution of profits between the parties. Rather, 
    the public interest is implicated where network leverage prevents an 
    affiliate from fulfilling its public interest obligations, such as 
    broadcasting programming responsive to local interests, or distorts the 
    normal market incentive to air programming according to viewer 
    preferences.
        45. The Commission thinks these issues are best addressed in the 
    context of our rules governing a station's right to reject network 
    programming, the filing of affiliation agreements, and its other rules 
    regarding the network-affiliate relationship. The Commission has 
    initiated a comprehensive review of these rules. In doing so, it will 
    address the issues the parties have raised here, including whether 
    networks have the capability and the incentive to exercise undue market 
    or bargaining power in the absence of these rules and the public 
    interest concerns any such capability and incentive would raise. These 
    rules, and their corollary rulemaking proceedings, are better tailored 
    to weigh these public interest issues and strike the appropriate 
    balance regarding regulation of the network-affiliate relationship. 
    PTAR, in contrast, is an 
    
    [[Page 44779]]
    imprecise, indiscriminate response to these concerns.
    
    IV. Summary of Findings and Transition
    
        46. The record shows that the three networks now face greater 
    competition than they did in 1970. There has been dramatic growth in 
    the number of independent stations, and broadcasters now must compete 
    for audiences with the increasing numbers of non-broadcast outlets, 
    especially cable service. The networks can no longer be viewed as a 
    funnel through which all television programming must pass. PTAR is thus 
    not necessary to promote independent program sources, PTAR's primary 
    goal. The record shows that the large number of video programming 
    outlets today creates a healthy demand for non-network programs. The 
    record further shows that there is no public interest reason for 
    continuing PTAR as a means of providing independent stations or new 
    broadcast networks a competitive advantage relative to network 
    affiliates in programming the access hour. Finally, the Commission 
    finds that PTAR is not an appropriate mechanism for safeguarding 
    affiliate autonomy. The Commission thus finds that the public interest 
    does not warrant the continuation of PTAR, especially given the costs 
    the rule imposes.
        47. The Notice sought comment on whether, in the event the 
    Commission concluded that PTAR should be eliminated, it should repeal 
    the rule immediately or adopt a transition mechanism that would sunset 
    the rule after a certain period of time. As noted above, the record 
    provides strong support for repeal of the rule. A transition 
    consequently is not necessary to take a ``wait and see'' approach in 
    order to test, and possibly revisit, the Commission's conclusion to 
    repeal the rule. The Commission does, however, believe a short 
    transition period is appropriate to allow industry participants to 
    adjust to the changing economic conditions that might result from 
    repeal of PTAR. The PTAR regulatory scheme has been in place for over 
    two decades, during which time members of the industry have come to 
    rely on the structure imposed by that scheme. Eliminating that 
    structure precipitously may have disruptive effects as the marketplace 
    adjusts to the deregulated environment. A one-year transition will give 
    parties time to adjust their business plans and contractual 
    arrangements prior to repeal of the rule and moderate an unnecessarily 
    abrupt impact on affected stations.
        48. The Commission rejects transition proposals that would continue 
    PTAR for an indefinite or overly long period of time. Such proposals, 
    if adopted, would impose costs that outweigh any possible benefits of a 
    longer transition. The record in this proceeding demonstrates that 
    continuation of the rule in the public interest; prolonging PTAR simply 
    as a means of continuing to confer competitive benefits on independent 
    stations therefore cannot be justified.
        49. Nor does the Commission believe the scheduled repeal of the 
    remaining fin/syn rules calls for a longer transition period for PTAR. 
    A number of the fin/syn rules, including restrictions on network 
    acquisition of financial interests in prime time programming, were 
    eliminated over two years ago; the marketplace thus should have had 
    time to adjust to the elimination of these rules. No party has made a 
    convincing case that the upcoming planned repeal of the remainder of 
    these rules will lead to any anticompetitive activities by the networks 
    or undue disruption of the marketplace so as to warrant postponing PTAR 
    repeal beyond a year. The Commission also does not believe it is 
    necessary to take a staggered approach to repeal or schedule a final 
    review of the rule prior to its scheduled expiration, as it did in the 
    fin/syn proceeding. The record in this proceeding clearly supports 
    repeal of PTAR, and the three networks can be said to be facing even 
    more competition today than they were when the Commission established 
    its fin/syn transition in 1993. Phased deregulation is less useful when 
    the transition period is used as a means of minimizing disruption in 
    repealing a regulation as opposed to taking several cautionary steps in 
    order to confirm the planned elimination of an entire rule. The 
    transition plan the Commission has adopted is not motivated by any 
    uncertainty over its conclusion to repeal PTAR, but rather by a concern 
    that immediate repeal could be unnecessarily disruptive. The Commission 
    will thus schedule repeal of the rule in its entirety for August 30, 
    1996.
        50. Other Issues. Given the Commission's conclusion that PTAR no 
    longer serves the public interest and should be repealed, the 
    Commission need not address the argument advanced by a number of 
    parties that the rule is contrary to the First Amendment. The 
    Commission also does not believe it is appropriate to alter the 
    definition of ``network'' to include the new networks as urged by some 
    parties. The Commission is not persuaded that this definition is 
    inequitable or that it causes new networks to curtail their prime time 
    offerings in order to evade the application of PTAR. In any event, the 
    rule will expire in a year and would have little if any impact on an 
    entity that became a ``network'' during that time period given the 
    grandfathering provisions presently set forth in the rule. Finally, 
    given the Commission's decision to repeal the rule, we will not modify 
    the current exemptions to PTAR as proposed by a number of commenters. 
    The proposed revisions to the definition of a ``network'' and the 
    rule's exemptions are not appropriate for the one-year transition the 
    Commission has established. Indeed, modifying these provisions of the 
    rule could run directly counter to the purposes of the transition by 
    creating uncertainty and disruption during a period that is intended to 
    provide parties time to adjust for repeal of PTAR. The Commission will 
    consequently retain PTAR in its existing form during the one-year 
    transition period.
    
    V. Administrative Matters
    
        51. Reason for the Action: This action is taken to repeal the prime 
    time access rule, 47 C.F.R. Sec. 73.658(k), in response to changes in 
    the communications marketplace, and to better adjust to the needs of 
    the public.
        52. Objective of this Action: The Commission believes that this 
    action will remove barriers to competition in the markets for video 
    programming and enhance program diversity for television viewers. The 
    rule will be repealed on August 30, 1996, which will give affected 
    parties time to adjust their business plans and contractual 
    arrangements in order to avoid an unnecessarily abrupt impact 
    associated with repeal to viewer and industry structures that have 
    developed in the 25 years that the subject rule has been in place.
        53. Legal Basis: Authority for the actions taken in this Report and 
    Order may be found in Section 4(i) and 303(r) of the Communications Act 
    of 1934, as amended, 47 U.S.C. Section 154(i) and 303(r).
        54. Any Significant Alternatives Minimizing the Impact on Small 
    Entities and Consistent with the Stated Objectives: The Commission 
    determined that, based on the record developed in this proceeding and 
    existing marketplace conditions, the public interest will be served by 
    repeal of PTAR. Proponents of retaining the rule failed to establish 
    that it remains necessary to ensure the diversity of programming 
    sources and outlets contemplated by adoption of PTAR. Moreover, these 
    parties have not demonstrated convincingly that PTAR 
    
    [[Page 44780]]
    itself is ultimately responsible for the development of newly emerging 
    networks or that repeal of the rule will threaten the station base of 
    the new networks. Those favoring repeal of the rule established that 
    the rule unnecessarily limits the programming choices of network-
    affiliated stations in the Top 50 television markets and discourages 
    investment in network programming, without off-setting public interest 
    benefits.
    
    List of Subjects in 47 CFR Part 73
    
        Radio broadcasting, Television broadcasting.
    
    Rule Changes
    
        Part 73 of Title 47 of the Code of Federal Regulations is amended 
    as follows:
    
    PART 73--RADIO BROADCAST SERVICES
    
        1. The authority citation for Part 73 continues to read as follows:
    
        Authority: 47 U.S.C. Sections 154, 303, 334.
    
    
    Sec. 73.658  [Amended]
    
        2. Section 73.658 is amended by removing and reserving paragraph 
    (k).
    
    Federal Communications Commission.
    William F. Caton,
    Acting Secretary.
    [FR Doc. 95-21319 Filed 8-28-95; 8:45 am]
    BILLING CODE 6712-01-M
    
    

Document Information

Effective Date:
8/30/1996
Published:
08/29/1995
Department:
Federal Communications Commission
Entry Type:
Rule
Action:
Final rule.
Document Number:
95-21319
Dates:
August 30, 1996.
Pages:
44773-44780 (8 pages)
Docket Numbers:
MM Docket No. 94-123, FCC 95-314
PDF File:
95-21319.pdf
CFR: (1)
47 CFR 73.658