96-24599. Time Warner Inc., et al.; Proposed Consent Agreement With Analysis To Aid Public Comment  

  • [Federal Register Volume 61, Number 187 (Wednesday, September 25, 1996)]
    [Notices]
    [Pages 50301-50322]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 96-24599]
    
    
    =======================================================================
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION
    
    [File No. 961-0004]
    
    
    Time Warner Inc., et al.; Proposed Consent Agreement With 
    Analysis To Aid Public Comment
    
    AGENCY: Federal Trade Commission.
    
    ACTION: Proposed consent agreement.
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    SUMMARY: In settlement of alleged violations of federal law prohibiting 
    unfair or deceptive acts or practices and unfair methods of 
    competition, this consent agreement, accepted subject to final 
    Commission approval, would require, among other things, a restructuring 
    of the acquisition by Time Warner Inc. of Turner Broadcasting System, 
    Inc., which are two of the country's largest cable programmers. Time 
    Warner, Turner, TCI and its subsidiary Liberty Media Corp. have agreed 
    to make a number of structural changes and to abide by certain 
    restrictions designed to break down the entry barriers created by the 
    proposed transaction.
    
    DATES: Comments must be received on or before November 25, 1996.
    
    ADDRESSES: Comments should be directed to: FTC/Office of the Secretary, 
    Room 159, 6th St. and Pa. Ave., N.W., Washington, D.C. 20580.
    
    FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: William Baer or George Cary, FTC/H-
    374, Washington, D.C. 20580. (202) 326-2932 or 326-3741.
    
    SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: Pursuant to Section 6(f) of the Federal 
    Trade Commission Act, 38 Stat. 721, 15 U.S.C. 46 and Section 2.34 of 
    the Commission's Rules of Practice (16 CFR 2.34), notice is hereby 
    given that the following consent agreement containing a consent order 
    to cease and desist, having been filed with and accepted, subject to 
    final approval, by the Commission, has been placed on the public record 
    for a period of sixty (60) days. Public comment is invited. Such 
    comments or views will be considered by the Commission and will be 
    available for inspection and copying at its principal office in 
    accordance with Sec. 4.9(b)(6)(ii) of the Commission's Rules of 
    Practice (16 CFR 4.9(b)(6)(ii)).
    
    Agreement Containing Consent Order
    
        The Federal Trade Commission (``Commission''), having initiated an 
    investigation of the proposed acquisition of Turner Broadcasting 
    System, Inc. (``Turner'') by Time Warner Inc. (``Time Warner''), and 
    Tele-Communications, Inc.'s (``TCI'') and Liberty Media Corporation's 
    (``LMC'') proposed acquisitions of interests in Time Warner, and it now 
    appearing that Time Warner, Turner, TCI, and LMC, hereinafter sometimes 
    referred to as ``proposed respondents,'' are willing to enter into an 
    agreement containing an order to divest certain assets, and providing 
    for other relief:
        It is hereby agreed by and between proposed respondents, by their 
    duly authorized officers and attorneys, and counsel for the Commission 
    that:
        1. Proposed respondent Time Warner is a corporation organized, 
    existing and doing business under and by virtue of the laws of the 
    State of Delaware with its office and principal place of business 
    located at 75 Rockefeller Plaza, New York, New York 10019.
        2. Proposed respondent Turner is a corporation organized, existing 
    and doing business under and by virtue of the laws of the State of 
    Georgia, with its office and principal place of business located at One 
    CNN Center, Atlanta, Georgia 30303.
        3. Proposed respondent TCI is a corporation organized, existing and 
    doing business under and by virtue of the law of the State of Delaware, 
    with its office and principal place of business located at 5619 DTC 
    Parkway, Englewood, Colorado 80111.
        4. Proposed respondent LMC is a corporation organized, existing and 
    doing business under and by virtue of the law of the State of Delaware, 
    with its office and principal place of business located at 8101 East 
    Prentice Avenue, Englewood, Colorado 80111.
        5. Proposed respondents admit all the jurisdictional facts set 
    forth in the draft of complaint for purposes of this agreement and 
    order only.
        6. Proposed respondents waive:
        (1) any further procedural steps;
        (2) the requirement that the Commission's decision contain a 
    statement of findings of fact and conclusions of law;
        (3) all rights to seek judicial review or otherwise to challenge or 
    contest the validity of the order entered pursuant to this agreement; 
    and
        (4) any claim under the Equal Access to Justice Act.
        7. Proposed respondents shall submit (either jointly or 
    individually), within sixty (60) days of the date this
    
    [[Page 50302]]
    
    agreement is signed by proposed respondents, an initial report or 
    reports, pursuant to Sec. 2.33 of the Commission's Rules, signed by the 
    proposed respondents and setting forth in detail the manner in which 
    the proposed respondents will comply with Paragraphs VI, VII and VIII 
    of the order, when and if entered. Such report will not become part of 
    the public record unless and until this agreement and order are 
    accepted by the Commission for public comment.
        8. This agreement shall not become part of the public record of the 
    proceeding unless and until it is accepted by the Commission. If this 
    agreement is accepted by the Commission it, together with a draft of 
    the complaint contemplated hereby, will be placed on the public record 
    for a period of sixty (60) days and information in respect thereto 
    publicly released. The Commission thereafter may either withdraw its 
    acceptance of this agreement and so notify the proposed respondents, in 
    which event it will take such action as it may consider appropriate, or 
    issue and serve its complaint (in such form as the circumstances may 
    require) and decision, in disposition of the proceeding.
        9. This agreement is for settlement purposes only and does not 
    constitute an admission by proposed respondents that the law has been 
    violated as alleged in the draft of complaint, or that the facts as 
    alleged in the draft complaint, other than jurisdictional facts, are 
    true.
        10. This agreement contemplates that, if it is accepted by the 
    Commission, and if such acceptance is not subsequently withdrawn by the 
    Commission pursuant to the provisions of Sec. 2.34 of the Commission's 
    Rules, the Commission may, without further notice to the proposed 
    respondents, (1) issue its complaint corresponding in form and 
    substance with the draft of complaint here attached and its decision 
    containing the following order in disposition of the proceeding, and 
    (2) make information public with respect thereto. When so entered, the 
    order shall have the same force and effect and may be altered, modified 
    or set aside in the same manner and within the same time provided by 
    statute for other orders. The order shall become final upon service. 
    Delivery by the U.S. Postal Service of the complaint and decision 
    containing the agreed-to order to proposed respondents' addresses as 
    stated in this agreement shall constitute service. Proposed respondents 
    waive any right they may have to any other manner of service. The 
    complaint may be used in construing the terms of the order, and no 
    agreement, understanding, representation, or interpretation not 
    contained in the order or the agreement may be used to vary or 
    contradict the terms of the order.
        11. Proposed respondents have read the proposed complaint and order 
    contemplated hereby. Proposed respondents understand that once the 
    order has been issued, they will be required to file one or more 
    compliance reports showing that they have fully complied with the 
    order. Proposed respondents further understand that they may be liable 
    for civil penalties in the amount provided by law for each violation of 
    the order after it becomes final.
        12. Proposed respondents agree to be bound by all of the terms of 
    the Interim Agreement attached to this agreement and made a part hereof 
    as Appendix I, upon acceptance by the Commission of this agreement for 
    public comment. Proposed respondents agree to notify the Commission's 
    Bureau of Competition in writing, within 30 days of the date the 
    Commission accepts this agreement for public comment, of any and all 
    actions taken by the proposed respondents to comply with the Interim 
    Agreement and of any ruling or decision by the Internal Revenue Service 
    (``IRS'') concerning the Distribution of The Separate Company stock to 
    the holders of the Liberty Tracking Stock within two (2) business days 
    after service of the IRS Ruling.
        13. The order's obligations upon proposed respondents are 
    contingent upon consummation of the Acquisition.
    
    Order
    
    I
    
        As used in this Order, the following definitions shall apply:
        (A) ``Acquisition'' means Time Warner's acquisition of Turner and 
    TCI's and LMC's acquisition of interest in Time Warner.
        (B) ``Affiliated'' means having an Attributable Interest in a 
    Person.
        (C) ``Agent'' or ``Representative'' means a Person that is acting 
    in a fiduciary capacity on behalf of a principal with respect to the 
    specific conduct or action under review or consideration.
        (D) ``Attributable Interest'' means an interest as defined in 47 
    C.F.R. 76.501 (and accompanying notes), as that rule read on July 1, 
    1996.
        (E) ``Basic Service Tier'' means the Tier of video programming as 
    defined in 47 C.F.R. 76.901(a), as that rule read on July 1, 1996.
        (F) ``Buying Group'' or ``Purchasing Agent'' means any Person 
    representing the interests of more than one Person distributing 
    multichannel video programming that: (1) Agrees to be financially 
    liable for any fees due pursuant to a Programming Service Agreement 
    which it signs as a contracting party as a representative of its 
    members, or each of whose members, as contracting parties, agrees to be 
    liable for its portion of the fees due pursuant to the programming 
    service agreement; (2) agrees to uniform billing and standardized 
    contract provisions for individual members; and (3) agrees either 
    collectively or individually on reasonable technical quality standards 
    for the individual members of the group.
        (G) ``Carriage Terms'' means all terms and conditions for sale, 
    licensing or delivery to an MVPD for a Video Programming Service and 
    includes, but is not limited to, all discounts (such as for volume, 
    channel position and Penetration Rate), local advertising 
    availabilities, marketing, and promotional support, and other terms and 
    conditions.
        (H) ``CATV'' means a cable system, or multiple cable systems 
    Controlled by the same Person, located in the United States.
        (I) ``Closing Date'' means the date of the closing of the 
    Acquisition.
        (J) ``CNN'' means the Video Programming Service Cable News Network.
        (K) ``Commission'' means the Federal Trade Commission.
        (L) ``Competing MVPD'' means an Unaffiliated MVPD whose proposed or 
    actual service area overlaps with the actual service area of a Time 
    Warner CATV.
        (M) ``Control,'' ``Controlled'' or ``Controlled by'' has the 
    meaning set forth in 16 CFR 801.1 as that regulation read on July 1, 
    1996, except that Time Warner's 50% interest in Comedy Central (as of 
    the Closing Date) and TCI's 50% interests in Bresnan Communications, 
    Intermedia Partnerships and Lenfest Communications (all as of the 
    Closing Date) shall not be deemed sufficient standing alone to confer 
    Control over that Person.
        (N) ``Converted WTBS'' means WTBS once converted to a Video 
    Programming Service.
        (O) ``Fully Diluted Equity of Time Warner'' means all Time Warner 
    common stock actually issued and outstanding plus the aggregate number 
    of shares of Time Warner common stock that would be issued and 
    outstanding assuming the exercise of all outstanding options, warrants 
    and rights (excluding shares that would be issued in the event a poison 
    pill is triggered) and the
    
    [[Page 50303]]
    
    conversion of all outstanding securities that are convertible into Time 
    Warner common stock.
        (P) ``HBO'' means the Video Programming Service Home Box Office, 
    including multiplexed versions.
        (Q) ``Independent Advertising-Supported News and Information Video 
    Programming Service'' means a National Video Programming Service (1) 
    that is not owned, Controlled by, or Affiliated with Time Warner; (2) 
    that is a 24-hour per day service consisting of current national, 
    international, sports, financial and weather news and/or information, 
    and other similar programming; and (3) that has national significance 
    so that, as of February 1, 1997, it has contractual commitments to 
    supply its service to 10 million subscribers on Unaffiliated MVPDs, or, 
    together with the contractual commitments it will obtain from Time 
    Warner, it has total contractual commitments to supply its service to 
    15 million subscribers. If no such Service has such contractual 
    commitments, then Time Warner may choose from among the two Services 
    with contractual commitments with Unaffiliated MVPDs for the largest 
    number of subscribers.
        (R) ``Independent Third Party'' means (1) a Person that does not 
    own, Control, and is not Affiliated with or has a share of voting 
    power, or an Ownership Interest in, greater than 1% of any of the 
    following: TCI, LMC, or the Kearns-Tribune Corporation; or (2) a Person 
    which none of TCI, LMC, or the TCI Control Shareholders owns, Controls, 
    is Affiliated with, or in which any of them have a share of voting 
    power, or an Ownership Interest in, greater than 1%. Provided, however, 
    that an Independent Third Party shall not lose such status if, as a 
    result of a transaction between an Independent Third Party and The 
    Separate Company, such Independent Third Party becomes a successor to 
    The Separate Company and the TCI Control Shareholders collectively hold 
    an Ownership Interest of 5% or less and collectively hold a share of 
    voting power of 1% or less in that successor company.
        (S) ``LMC'' means Liberty Media Corporation, all of its directors, 
    officers, employees, Agents, and Representatives, and also includes (1) 
    all of its predecessors, successors, assigns, subsidiaries, and 
    divisions, all of their respective directors, officers, employees, 
    Agents, and Representatives, and the respective successors and assigns 
    of any of the foregoing; and (2) partnerships, joint ventures, and 
    affiliates that Liberty Media Corporation Controls, directly or 
    indirectly.
        (T) ``The Liberty Tracking Stock'' means Tele-Communications, Inc. 
    Series A Liberty Media Group Common Stock and Tele-Communications, Inc. 
    Series B Liberty Media Group Common Stock.
        (U) ``Multichannel Video Programming Distributor'' or ``MVPD'' 
    means a Person providing multiple channels of video programming to 
    subscribers in the United States for which a fee is charged, by any of 
    various methods including, but not limited to, cable, satellite master 
    antenna television, multichannel multipoint distribution, direct-to-
    home satellite (C-band, Ku-band, direct broadcast satellite), ultra 
    high-frequency microwave systems (sometimes called LMDS), open video 
    systems, or the facilities of common carrier telephone companies or 
    their affiliates, as well as Buying Groups or Purchasing Agents of all 
    such Persons.
        (V) ``National Video Programming Service'' means a Video 
    Programming Service that is intended for distribution in all or 
    substantially all of the United States.
        (W) ``Ownership Interest'' means any right(s), present or 
    contingent, to hold voting or nonvoting interest(s), equity 
    interest(s), and/or beneficial ownership(s) in the capital stock of a 
    Person.
        (X) ``Penetration Rate'' means the percentage of Total Subscribers 
    on an MVPD who receives a particular Video Programming Service.
        (Y) ``Person'' includes any natural person, corporate entity, 
    partnership, association, joint venture, government entity or trust.
        (Z) ``Programming Service Agreement'' means any agreement between a 
    Video Programming Vendor and an MVPD by which a Video Programming 
    Vendor agrees to permit carriage of a Video Programming Service on that 
    MVPD.
        (AA) ``The Separate Company'' means a separately incorporated 
    Person, either existing or to be created, to take the actions provided 
    by Paragraph II and includes without limitation all of The Separate 
    Company's subsidiaries, divisions, and affiliates Controlled, directly 
    or indirectly, all of their respective directors, officers, employees, 
    Agents, and Representatives, and the respective successors and assigns 
    of any of the foregoing, other than any Independent Third Party.
        (BB) ``Service Area Overlap'' means the geographic area in which a 
    Competing MVPD's proposed or actual service area overlaps with the 
    actual service area of a Time Warner CATV.
        (CC) ``Similarly Situated MVPDs'' means MVPDs with the same or 
    similar number of Total Subscribers as the Competing MVPD has 
    nationally and the same or similar Penetration Rate(s) as the Competing 
    MVPD makes available nationally.
        (DD) ``TCI'' means Tele-Communications, Inc., all of its directors, 
    officers, employees, Agents, and Representatives, and also includes (1) 
    all of its predecessors, successors, assigns, subsidiaries, and 
    divisions, all of their respective directors, officers, employees, 
    Agents, and Representatives, and the respective successors and assigns 
    of any of the foregoing; and (2) partnerships, joint ventures, and 
    affiliates that Tele-Communications, Inc. Controls, directly or 
    indirectly. TCI acknowledges that the obligations of subparagraphs 
    (C)(6), (8)-(9), (D)(1)-(2) of Paragraph II and of Paragraph III of 
    this order extend to actions by Bob Magness and John C. Malone, taken 
    in an individual capacity as well as in a capacity as an officer or 
    director, and agrees to be liable for such actions.
        (EE) ``TCI Control Shareholders'' means the following Persons, 
    individually as well as collectively: Bob Magness, John C. Malone, and 
    the Kearns-Tribune Corporation, its Agents and Representatives, and the 
    respective successors and assigns of any of the foregoing.
        (FF) ``TCI's and LMC's Interest in Time Warner'' means all the 
    Ownership Interest in Time Warner to be acquired by TCI and LMC, 
    including the right of first refusal with respect to Time Warner stock 
    to be held by R. E. Turner, III, pursuant to the Shareholders Agreement 
    dated September 22, 1995 with LMC or any successor agreement.
        (GG) ``TCI's and LMC's Turner-Related Businesses'' means the 
    businesses conducted by Southern Satellite Systems, Inc., a subsidiary 
    of TCI which is principally in the business of distributing WTBS to 
    MVPDs.
        (HH) ``Tier'' means a grouping of Video Programming Services 
    offered by an MVPD to subscribers for one package price.
        (II) ``Time Warner'' means Time Warner Inc., all of its directors, 
    officers, employees, Agents, and Representatives, and also includes (1) 
    all of its predecessors, successors, assigns, subsidiaries, and 
    divisions, including, but not limited to, Turner after the Closing 
    Date, all of their respective directors, officers, employees, Agents, 
    and Representatives, and the respective successors and assigns of any 
    of the foregoing; and (2) partnerships, joint ventures, and affiliates 
    that Time Warner Inc. Controls, directly or
    
    [[Page 50304]]
    
    indirectly. Time Warner shall, except for the purposes of definitions 
    OO and PP, include Time Warner Entertainment Company, L.P., so long as 
    it falls within this definition.
        (JJ) ``Time Warner CATV'' means a CATV which is owned or Controlled 
    by Time Warner. ``Non-Time Warner CATV'' means a CATV which is not 
    owned or Controlled by Time Warner. Obligations in this order 
    applicable to Time Warner CATVs shall not survive the disposition of 
    Time Warner's Control over them.
        (KK) ``Time Warner National Video Programming Vendor'' means a 
    Video Programming Vendor providing a National Video Programming Service 
    which is owned or Controlled by Time Warner. Likewise, ``Non-Time 
    Warner National Video Programming Vendor'' means a Video Programming 
    Vendor providing a National Video Programming Service which is not 
    owned or Controlled by Time Warner.
        (LL) ``TNT'' means the Video Programming Service Turner Network 
    Television.
        (MM) ``Total Subscribers'' means the total number of subscribers to 
    an MVPD other than subscribers only to the Basic Service Tier.
        (NN) ``Turner'' means Turner Broadcasting System, Inc., all of its 
    directors, officers, employees, Agents, and Representatives, and also 
    includes (1) all of its predecessors, successors (except Time Warner), 
    assigns (except Time Warner), subsidiaries, and divisions; and (2) 
    partnerships, joint ventures, and affiliates that Turner Broadcasting 
    System, Inc., Controls, directly or indirectly.
        (OO) ``Turner Video Programming Services'' means each Video 
    Programming Service owned or Controlled by Turner on the Closing Date, 
    and includes (1) WTBS, (2) any such Video Programming Service and WTBS 
    that is transferred after the Closing Date to another part of Time 
    Warner (including TWE), and (3) any Video Programming Service created 
    after the Closing Date that Time Warner owns or Controls that is not 
    owned or Controlled by TWE, for so long as the Video Programming 
    Service remains owned or Controlled by Time Warner.
        (PP) ``Turner-Affiliated Video Programming Services'' means each 
    Video Programming Service, whether or not satellite-delivered, that is 
    owned, Controlled by, or Affiliated with Turner on the Closing Date, 
    and includes (1) WTBS, (2) any such Video Programming Service and WTBS 
    that is transferred after the Closing Date to another part of Time 
    Warner (including TWE), and (3) any Video Programming Service created 
    after the Closing Date that Time Warner owns, Controls or is Affiliated 
    with that is not owned, Controlled by, or Affiliated with TWE, for so 
    long as the Video Programming Service remains owned, Controlled by, or 
    affiliated with Time Warner.
        (QQ) ``TWE'' means Time Warner Entertainment Company, L.P., all of 
    its officers, employees, Agents, Representatives, and also includes (1) 
    all of its predecessors, successors, assigns, subsidiaries, divisions, 
    including, but not limited to, Time Warner Cable, and the respective 
    successors and assigns of any of the foregoing, but excluding Turner; 
    and (2) partnerships, joint ventures, and affiliates that Time Warner 
    Entertainment Company, L.P., Controls, directly or indirectly.
        (RR) ``TWE's Management Committee'' means the Management Committee 
    established in Section 8 of the Admission Agreement dated May 16, 1993, 
    between TWE and U S West, Inc., and any successor thereof, and includes 
    any management committee in any successor agreement that provides for 
    membership on the management committee for non-Time Warner individuals.
        (SS) ``TWE Video Programming Services'' means each Video 
    Programming Service owned or Controlled by TWE on the Closing Date, and 
    includes (1) any such Video Programming Service transferred after the 
    Closing Date to another part of Time Warner and (2) any Video 
    Programming Service created after the Closing Date that TWE owns or 
    Controls, for so long as the Video Programming Service remains owned or 
    Controlled by TWE.
        (TT) ``TWE-Affiliated Video Programming Services'' means each Video 
    Programming Service, whether or not satellite-delivered, that is owned, 
    Controlled by, or Affiliated with TWE, and includes (1) any such Video 
    Programming Service transferred after the Closing Date to another part 
    of Time Warner and (2) any Video Programming Service created after the 
    Closing Date that TWE owns or Controls, or is Affiliated with, for so 
    long as the Video Programming Service remains owned, Controlled by, or 
    Affiliated with TWE.
        (VV) ``Unaffiliated MVPD'' means an MVPD which is not owned, 
    Controlled by, or Affiliated with Time Warner.
        (WW) ``United States'' means the fifty states, the District of 
    Columbia, and all territories, dependencies, or possessions of the 
    United States of America.
        (XX) ``Video Programming Service'' means a satellite-delivered 
    video programming service that is offered, alone or with other 
    services, to MVPDs in the United States. It does not include pay-per-
    view programming service(s), interactive programming service(s), over-
    the-air television broadcasting, or satellite broadcast programming as 
    defined in 47 C.F.R. 76.1000(f) as that rule read on July 1, 1996.
        (YY) ``Video Programming Vendor'' means a Person engaged in the 
    production, creation, or wholesale distribution to MVPDs of Video 
    Programming Services for sale in the United States.
        (ZZ) ``WTBS'' means the television broadcast station popularly 
    known as TBS Superstation, and includes any Video Programming Service 
    that may be a successor to WTBS, including Converted WTBS.
    
    II
    
        It is ordered that:
        (A) TCI and LMC shall divest TCI's and LMC's Interest in Time 
    Warner and TCI's and LMC's Turner-Related Businesses to The Separate 
    Company by:
        (1) combining TCI's and LMC's Interest in Time Warner Inc. and 
    TCI's and LMC's Turner-Related Businesses in The Separate Company;
        (2) distributing The Separate Company stock to the holders of 
    Liberty Tracking Stock (``Distribution''); and
        (3) using their best efforts to ensure that The Separate Company's 
    stock is registered or listed for trading on the Nasdaq Stock Market or 
    the New York Stock Exchange or the American Stock Exchange.
        (B) TCI and LMC shall make all regulatory filings, including, but 
    not limited to, filings with the Federal Communications Commission and 
    the Securities and Exchange Commission that are necessary to accomplish 
    the requirements of Paragraph II(A).
        (C) TCI, LMC, and The Separate Company shall ensure that:
        (1) The Separate Company's by-laws obligate The Separate Company to 
    be bound by this order and contain provisions ensuring compliance with 
    this order;
        (2) The Separate Company's board of directors at the time of the 
    Distribution are subject to the prior approval of the Commission;
        (3) The Separate Company shall, within six (6) months of the 
    Distribution, call a shareholder's meeting for the purpose of electing 
    directors;
        (4) No member of the board of directors of The Separate Company, 
    both at the time of the Distribution and pursuant to any election now 
    or at any time in the future, shall, at the time of his or her election 
    or while serving as
    
    [[Page 50305]]
    
    a director of The Separate Company, be an officer, director, or 
    employee of TCI or LMC or shall hold, or have under his or her 
    direction or Control, greater than one-tenth of one percent (0.1%) of 
    the voting power of TCI and one-tenth of one percent (0.1%) of the 
    Ownership Interest in TCI or greater than one-tenth of one percent 
    (0.1%) of the voting power of LMC and one-tenth of one percent (0.1%) 
    of the Ownership Interest in LMC;
        (5) No officer, director or employee of TCI or LMC shall 
    concurrently serve as an officer or employee of The Separate Company. 
    Provided further, that TCI or LMC employees who are not TCI Control 
    Shareholders or directors or officers of either Tele-Communications, 
    Inc. or Liberty Media Corporation may provide to The Separate Company 
    services contemplated by the attached Transition Services Agreement;
        (6) The TCI Control Shareholders shall promptly exchange the shares 
    of stock received by them in the Distribution for shares of one or more 
    classes or series of convertible preferred stock of The Separate 
    Company that shall be entitled to vote only on the following issues on 
    which a vote of the shareholders of The Separate Company is required: a 
    proposed merger; consolidation or stock exchange involving The Separate 
    Company; the sale, lease, exchange or other disposition of all or 
    substantially all of The Separate Company's assets; the dissolution or 
    winding up of The Separate Company; proposed amendments to the 
    corporate charter or bylaws of The Separate Company; proposed changes 
    in the terms of such classes or series; or any other matters on which 
    their vote is required as a matter of law (except that, for such other 
    matters, The Separate Company and the TCI Control Shareholders shall 
    ensure that the TCI Control Shareholders' votes are apportioned in the 
    exact ratio as the votes of the rest of the shareholders);
        (7) No vote on any of the proposals listed in subparagraph (6) 
    shall be successful unless a majority of shareholders other than the 
    TCI Control Shareholders vote in favor of such proposal;
        (8) After the Distribution, the TCI Control Shareholders shall not 
    seek to influence, or attempt to control by proxy or otherwise, any 
    other Person's vote of The Separate Company stock;
        (9) After the Distribution, no officer, director or employee of TCI 
    or LMC, or any of the TCI Control Shareholders shall communicate, 
    directly or indirectly, with any officer, director, or employee of The 
    Separate Company. Provided, however, that the TCI Control Shareholders 
    may communicate with an officer, director or employee of The Separate 
    Company when the subject is one of the issues listed in subparagraph 6 
    on which TCI Control Shareholders are permitted to vote, except that, 
    when a TCI Control Shareholder seeks to initiate action on a subject 
    listed in subparagraph 6 on which the TCI Control Shareholders are 
    permitted to vote, the initial proposal for such action shall be made 
    in writing. Provided further, that this provision does not apply to 
    communications by TCI or LMC employees who are not TCI Control 
    Shareholders or directors or officers of either Tele-Communications, 
    Inc. or Liberty Media Corporation in the context of providing to The 
    Separate Company services contemplated by the attached Transition 
    Services Agreement or to communications relating to the possible 
    purchase of services from TCI's and LMC's Turner-Related Businesses;
        (10) The Separate Company shall not acquire or hold greater than 
    14.99% of the Fully Diluted Equity of Time Warner. Provided, however, 
    that, if the TCI Control Shareholders reduce their collective holdings 
    in The Separate Company to no more than one-tenth of one percent (0.1%) 
    of the voting power of The Separate Company and one-tenth of one 
    percent (0.1%) of the Ownership Interest in The Separate Company or 
    reduce their collective holdings in TCI and LMC to no more than one-
    tenth of one percent (0.1%) of the voting power of TCI and one-tenth of 
    one percent (0.1%) of the Ownership Interest in TCI and one-tenth of 
    one percent (0.1%) of the voting power of LMC and one-tenth of one 
    percent (0.1%) of the Ownership Interest in LMC, then The Separate 
    Company shall not be prohibited by this order from increasing its 
    holding of Time Warner stock beyond that figure; and
        (11) The Separate Company shall not acquire or hold, directly or 
    indirectly, any Ownership Interest in Time Warner that is entitled to 
    exercise voting power except (a) a vote of one-one hundredth (\1/100\) 
    of a vote per share owned, voting with the outstanding common stock, 
    with respect to the election of directors and (b) with respect to 
    proposed changes in the charter of Time Warner Inc. or of the 
    instrument creating such securities that would (i) adversely change any 
    of the terms of such securities or (ii) adversely affect the rights, 
    power, or preferences of such securities. Provided, however, that any 
    portion of The Separate Company's stock in Time Warner that is sold to 
    an Independent Third Party may be converted into voting stock of Time 
    Warner. Provided, further, that, if the TCI Control Shareholders reduce 
    their collective holdings in The Separate Company to no more than one-
    tenth of one percent (0.1%) of the voting power of The Separate Company 
    and one-tenth of one percent (0.1%) of the Ownership Interest in The 
    Separate Company or reduce their collective holdings in both TCI and 
    LMC to no more than one-tenth of one percent (0.1%) of the voting power 
    of TCI and one-tenth of one percent (0.1%) of the Ownership Interest in 
    TCI and one-tenth of one percent (0.1%) of the voting power of LMC and 
    one-tenth of one percent (0.1%) of the Ownership Interest in LMC, The 
    Separate Company's Time Warner stock may be converted into voting stock 
    of Time Warner.
        (D) TCI and LMC shall use their best efforts to obtain a private 
    letter ruling from the Internal Revenue Service to the effect that the 
    Distribution will be generally tax-free to both the Liberty Tracking 
    Stock holders and to TCI under Section 355 of the Internal Revenue Code 
    of 1986, as amended (``IRS Ruling''). Upon receipt of the IRS Ruling, 
    TCI and LMC shall have thirty (30) days (excluding time needed to 
    comply with the requirements of any federal securities and 
    communications laws and regulations, provided that TCI and LMC shall 
    use their best efforts to comply with all such laws and regulations) to 
    carry out the requirements of Paragraph II (A) and (B). Pending the IRS 
    Ruling, or in the event that TCI and LMC are unable to obtain the IRS 
    Ruling,
        (1) TCI, LMC, Bob Magness and John C. Malone, collectively or 
    individually, shall not acquire or hold, directly or indirectly, an 
    Ownership Interest that is more than the lesser of 9.2% of the Fully 
    Diluted Equity of Time Warner or 12.4% of the actual issued and 
    outstanding common stock of Time Warner, as determined by generally 
    accepted accounting principles. Provided, however, that day-to-day 
    market price changes that cause any such holding to exceed the latter 
    threshold shall not be deemed to cause the parties to be in violation 
    of this subparagraph; and
        (2) TCI, LMC and the TCI Control Shareholders shall not acquire or 
    hold any Ownership Interest in Time Warner that is entitled to exercise 
    voting power except (a) a vote of one-one hundredth (\1/100\) of a vote 
    per share owned, voting with the outstanding common stock, with respect 
    to the election of directors and (b) with respect to proposed changes 
    in the charter of Time Warner Inc. or of the instrument creating such 
    securities that would (i) adversely change any of the terms of such
    
    [[Page 50306]]
    
    securities or (ii) adversely affect the rights, power, or preferences 
    of such securities. Provided, however, that any portion of TCI's and 
    LMC's Interest in Time Warner that is sold to an Independent Third 
    Party may be converted into voting stock of Time Warner.
        In the event that TCI and LMC are unable to obtain the IRS Ruling, 
    TCI and LMC shall be relieved of the obligations set forth in 
    subparagraphs (A), (B) and (C).
    
    III
    
        It is further ordered that
        After the Distribution, TCI, LMC, Bob Magness and John C. Malone, 
    collectively or individually, shall not acquire or hold, directly or 
    indirectly, any voting power of, or other Ownership Interest in, Time 
    Warner that is more than the lesser of 1% of the Fully Diluted Equity 
    of Time Warner or 1.35% of the actual issued and outstanding common 
    stock of Time Warner, as determined by generally accepted accounting 
    principles (provided, however, that such interest shall not vote except 
    as provided in Paragraph II(D)(2)), without the prior approval of the 
    Commission. Provided, further, that day-to-day market price changes 
    that cause any such holding to exceed the latter threshold shall not be 
    deemed to cause the parties to be in violation of this Paragraph.
    
    IV
    
        It is further ordered that
        (A) For six months after the Closing Date, TCI and Time Warner 
    shall not enter into any new Programming Service Agreement that 
    requires carriage of any Turner Video Programming Service on any analog 
    Tier of TCI's CATVs.
        (B) Any Programming Service Agreement entered into thereafter that 
    requires carriage of any Turner Video Programming Service on TCI's 
    CATVs on an analog Tier shall be limited in effective duration to five 
    (5) years, except that such agreements may give TCI the unilateral 
    right(s) to renew such agreements for one or more five-year periods.
        (C) Notwithstanding the foregoing, Time Warner, Turner and TCI may 
    enter into, prior to the Closing Date, agreements that require carriage 
    on an analog Tier by TCI for no more than five years for each of WTBS 
    (with the five year period to commence at the time of WTBS' conversion 
    to Converted WTBS) and Headline News, and such agreements may give TCI 
    the unilateral right(s) to renew such agreements for one or more five-
    year periods.
    
    V
    
        It is further ordered that
        Time Warner shall not, expressly or impliedly:
        (A) refuse to make available or condition the availability of HBO 
    to any MVPD on whether that MVPD or any other MVPD agrees to carry any 
    Turner-Affiliated Video Programming Service;
        (B) condition any Carriage Terms for HBO to any MVPD on whether 
    that MVPD or any other MVPD agrees to carry any Turner-Affiliated Video 
    Programming Service;
        (C) refuse to make available or condition the availability of each 
    of CNN, WTBS, or TNT to any MVPD on whether that MVPD or any other MVPD 
    agrees to carry any TWE-Affiliated Video Programming Service; or
        (D) condition any Carriage Terms for each of CNN, WTBS, or TNT to 
    any MVPD on whether that MVPD or any other MVPD agrees to carry any 
    TWE-Affiliated Video Programming Service.
    
    VI
    
        It is further ordered that
        (A) For subscribers that a Competing MVPD services in the Service 
    Area Overlap, Time Warner shall provide, upon request, any Turner Video 
    Programming Service to that Competing MVPD at Carriage Terms no less 
    favorable, relative to the Carriage Terms then offered by Time Warner 
    for that Service to the three MVPDs with the greatest number of 
    subscribers, than the Carriage Terms offered by Turner to Similarly 
    Situated MVPDs relative to the Carriage Terms offered by Turner to the 
    three MVPDs with the greatest number of subscribers for that Service on 
    July 30, 1996. For Turner Video Programming Services not in existence 
    on July 30, 1996, the pre-Closing Date comparison will be to relative 
    Carriage Terms offered with respect to any Turner Video Programming 
    Service existing as of July 30, 1996.
        (B) Time Warner shall be in violation of this Paragraph if the 
    Carriage Terms it offers to the Competing MVPD for those subscribers 
    outside the Service Area Overlap are set at a higher level compared to 
    Similarly Situated MVPDs so as to avoid the restrictions set forth in 
    subparagraph (A).
    
    VII
    
        It is further ordered that
        (A) Time Warner shall not require a financial interest in any 
    National Video Programming Service as a condition for carriage on one 
    or more Time Warner CATVs.
        (B) Time Warner shall not coerce any National Video Programming 
    Vendor to provide, or retaliate against such a Vendor for failing to 
    provide exclusive rights against any other MVPD as a condition for 
    carriage on one or more Time Warner CATVs.
        (C) Time Warner shall not engage in conduct the effect of which is 
    to unreasonably restrain the ability of a Non-Time Warner National 
    Video Programming Vendor to compete fairly by discriminating in video 
    programming distribution on the basis of affiliation or nonaffiliation 
    of Vendors in the selection, terms, or conditions for carriage of video 
    programming provided by such Vendors.
    
    VIII
    
        It is further ordered that
        (A) Time Warner shall collect the following information, on a 
    quarterly basis:
        (1) for any and all offers made to Time Warner's corporate office 
    by a Non-Time Warner National Video Programming Vendor to enter into or 
    to modify any Programming Service Agreement for carriage on an Time 
    Warner CATV, in that quarter:
        (a) the identity of the National Video Programming Vendor;
        (b) a description of the type of programming;
        (c) any and all Carriage Terms as finally agreed to or, when there 
    is no final agreement but the Vendor's initial offer is more than three 
    months old, the last offer of each side;
        (d) any and all commitment(s) to a roll-out schedule, if 
    applicable, as finally agreed to or, when there is no final agreement 
    but the Vendor's initial offer is more than three months old, the last 
    offer of each side;
        (e) a copy of any and all Programming Service Agreement(s) as 
    finally agreed to or, when there is no final agreement but the Vendor's 
    initial offer is more than three months old, the last offer of each 
    side; and
        (2) on an annual basis for each National Video Programming Service 
    on Time Warner CATVs, the actual carriage rates on Time Warner CATVs 
    and
        (a) the average carriage rates on all Non-Time Warner CATVs for 
    each National Video Programming Service that has publicly-available 
    information from which Penetration Rates can be derived; and
        (b) the carriage rates on each of the fifty (50) largest (in total 
    number of subscribers) Non-Time Warner CATVs for each National Video 
    Programming Service that has publicly-available information from which 
    Penetration Rates can be derived.
        (B) The information collected pursuant to subparagraph (A) shall be
    
    [[Page 50307]]
    
    provided to each member of TWE's Management Committee on the last day 
    of March, June, September and December of each year. Provided, however, 
    that, in the event TWE's Management Committee ceases to exist, the 
    disclosures required in this Paragraph shall be made to any and all 
    partners in TWE; or, if there are no partners in TWE, then the 
    disclosures required in this Paragraph shall be made to the Audit 
    Committee of Time Warner.
        (C) The General Counsel within TWE who is responsible for CATV 
    shall annually certify to the Commission that it believes that Time 
    Warner is in compliance with Paragraph VII of this order.
        (D) Time Warner shall retain all of the information collected as 
    required by subparagraph (A), including information on when and to whom 
    such information was communicated as required herein in subparagraph 
    (B), for a period of five (5) years.
    
    IX
    
        It is further ordered that
        (A) By February 1, 1997, Time Warner shall execute a Programming 
    Service Agreement with at least one Independent Advertising-Supported 
    News and Information National Video Programming Service, unless the 
    Commission determines, upon a showing by Time Warner, that none of the 
    offers of Carriage Terms are commercially reasonable.
        (B) If all the requirements of either subparagraph (A) or (C) are 
    met, Time Warner shall carry an Independent Advertising-Supported News 
    and Information Video Programming Service on Time Warner CATVs at 
    Penetration Rates no less than the following:
        (1) If the Service is carried on Time Warner CATVs as of July 30, 
    1996, Time Warner must make the Service available:
        (a) By July 30, 1997, so that it is available to 30% of the Total 
    Subscribers of all Time Warner CATVs at that time; and
        (b) By July 30, 1999, so that it is available to 50% of the Total 
    Subscribers of all Time Warner CATVs at that time.
        (2) If the Service is not carried on Time Warner CATVs as of July 
    30, 1996, Time Warner must make the Service available:
        (a) By July 30, 1997, so that it is available to 10% of the Total 
    Subscribers of all Time Warner CATVs at that time;
        (b) By July 30, 1999, so that it is available to 30% of the Total 
    Subscribers of all Time Warner CATVs at that time; and
        (c) By July 30, 2001, so that it is available to 50% of the Total 
    Subscribers of all Time Warner CATVs at that time.
        (C) If, for any reason, the Independent Advertising-Supported News 
    and Information National Video Programming Service chosen by Time 
    Warner ceases operating or is in material breach of its Programming 
    Service Agreement with Time Warner at any time before July 30, 2001, 
    Time Warner shall, within six months of the date that such Service 
    ceased operation or the date of termination of the Agreement because of 
    the material breach, enter into a replacement Programming Service 
    Agreement with a replacement Independent Advertising-Supported News and 
    Information National Video Programming Service so that replacement 
    Service is available pursuant to subparagraph (B) within three months 
    of the execution of the replacement Programming Service Agreement, 
    unless the Commission determines, upon a showing by Time Warner, that 
    none of the Carriage Terms offered are commercially reasonable. Such 
    replacement Service shall have, six months after the date the first 
    Service ceased operation or the date of termination of the first 
    Agreement because of the material breach, contractual commitments to 
    supply its Service to at least 10 million subscribers on Unaffiliated 
    MVPDs, or, together with the contractual commitments it will obtain 
    from Time Warner, total contractual commitments to supply its Service 
    to 15 million subscribers; if no such Service has such contractual 
    commitments, then Time Warner may choose from among the two Services 
    with contractual commitments with Unaffiliated MVPDs for the largest 
    number of subscribers.
    
    X
    
        It is further ordered that:
        (A) Within sixty (60) days after the date this order becomes final 
    and every sixty (60) days thereafter until respondents have fully 
    complied with the provisions of Paragraphs IV(A) and IX(A) of this 
    order and, with respect to Paragraph II, until the Distribution, 
    respondents shall submit jointly or individually to the Commission a 
    verified written report or reports setting forth in detail the manner 
    and form in which they intend to comply, are complying, and have 
    complied with Paragraphs II, IV(A) and IX(A) of this order.
        (B) One year (1) from the date this order becomes final, annually 
    for the next nine (9) years on the anniversary of the date this order 
    becomes final, and at other times as the Commission may require, 
    respondents shall file jointly or individually a verified written 
    report or reports with the Commission setting forth in detail the 
    manner and form in which they have complied and are complying with each 
    Paragraph of this order.
    
    XI
    
        It is further ordered that respondents shall notify the Commission 
    at least thirty (30) days prior to any proposed change in respondents 
    (other than this Acquisition) such as dissolution, assignment, sale 
    resulting in the emergence of a successor corporation, or the creation 
    or dissolution of subsidiaries or any other change in the corporation 
    that may affect compliance obligations arising out of the order.
    
    XII
    
        It is further ordered that, for the purpose of determining or 
    securing compliance with this order, and subject to any legally 
    recognized privilege, upon written request, respondents shall permit 
    any duly authorized representative of the Commission:
        1. Access, during regular business hours upon reasonable notice and 
    in the presence of counsel for respondents, to inspect and copy all 
    books, ledgers, accounts, correspondence, memoranda and other records 
    and documents in the possession or under the control of respondents 
    relating to any matters contained in this order; and
        2. Upon five days' notice to respondents and without restraint or 
    interference from it, to interview officers, directors, or employees of 
    respondents, who may have counsel present, regarding such matters.
    
    XIII
    
        It is further ordered that this order shall terminate ten (10) 
    years from the date this order becomes final.
    
    Appendix I
    
    Interim Agreement
    
        This Interim Agreement is by and between Time Warner Inc. (``Time 
    Warner''), a corporation organized, existing, and doing business under 
    and by virtue of the law of the State of Delaware, with its office and 
    principal place of business at New York, New York; Turner Broadcasting 
    System, Inc. (``Turner''), a corporation organized, existing, and doing 
    business under and by virtue of the law of the State of Georgia with 
    its office and principal place of business at Atlanta, Georgia; Tele-
    Communications, Inc. (``TCI''), a corporation organized, existing, and 
    doing business under and by virtue of
    
    [[Page 50308]]
    
    the law of the State of Delaware, with its office and principal place 
    of business located at Englewood, Colorado; Liberty Media Corp. 
    (``LMC''), a corporation organized, existing and doing business under 
    and by virtue of the law of the State of Delaware, with its office and 
    principal place of business located at Englewood, Colorado; and the 
    Federal Trade Commission (``Commission''), an independent agency of the 
    United States Government, established under the Federal Trade 
    Commission Act of 1914, 15 U.S.C. 41 et seq.
        Whereas Time Warner entered into an agreement with Turner for Time 
    Warner to acquire the outstanding voting securities of Turner, and TCI 
    and LMC proposed to acquire stock in Time Warner (hereinafter ``the 
    Acquisition'');
        Whereas the Commission is investigating the Acquisition to 
    determine whether it would violate any statute enforced by the 
    Commission;
        Whereas TCI and LMC are willing to enter into an Agreement 
    Containing Consent Order (hereafter ``Consent Order'') requiring them, 
    inter alia, to divest TCI's and LMC's Interest in Time Warner and TCI's 
    and LMC's Turner-Related Businesses, by contributing those interests to 
    a separate corporation, The Separate Company, the stock of which will 
    be distributed to the holders of Liberty Tracking Stock (``the 
    Distribution''), but, in order to fulfill paragraph II(D) of that 
    Consent Order, TCI and LMC must apply now to receive an Internal 
    Revenue Service ruling as to whether the Distribution will be generally 
    tax-free to both the Liberty Tracking Stock holders and to TCI under 
    Section 355 of the Internal Revenue Code of 1986, as amended (``IRS 
    Ruling'');
        Whereas ``TCI's and LMC's Interest in Time Warner`` means all of 
    the economic interest in Time Warner to be acquired by TCI and LMC, 
    including the right of first refusal with respect to Time Warner stock 
    to be held by R. E. Turner, III, pursuant to the Shareholders Agreement 
    dated September 22, 1995 with LMC or any successor agreement;
        Whereas ``TCI's and LMC's Turner-Related Businesses'' means the 
    businesses conducted by Southern Satellite Systems, Inc., a subsidiary 
    of TCI which is principally in the business of distributing WTBS to 
    MVPDs;
        Whereas ``Liberty Tracking Stock'' means Tele-Communications, Inc. 
    Series A Liberty Media Group Common Stock and Tele-Communications, Inc. 
    Series B Liberty Media Group Common Stock;
        Whereas Time Warner, Turner, TCI, and LMC are willing to enter into 
    a Consent Order requiring them, inter alia, to forego entering into 
    certain new programming service agreements for a period of six months 
    from the date that the parties close this Acquisition (``Closing 
    Date''), but, in order to comply more fully with that requirement, they 
    must cancel now the two agreements that were negotiated as part of this 
    Acquisition: namely, (1) the September 15, 1995, program service 
    agreement between TCI's subsidiary, Satellite Services, Inc. (``SSI''), 
    and Turner and (2) the September 14, 1995, cable carriage agreement 
    between SSI and Time Warner for WTBS (hereafter ``Two Programming 
    Service Agreements'');
        Whereas if the Commission accepts the attached Consent Order, the 
    Commission is required to place the Consent Order on the public record 
    for a period of at least sixty (60) days and may subsequently withdraw 
    such acceptance pursuant to the provisions of Rule 2.34 of the 
    Commission's Rules of Practice and Procedure, 16 C.F.R. 2.34;
        Whereas the Commission is concerned that if the parties do not, 
    before this order is made final, apply to the IRS for the IRS Ruling 
    and cancel the Two Programming Service Agreements, compliance with the 
    operative provisions of the Consent Order might not be possible or 
    might produce a less than effective remedy;
        Whereas Time Warner, Turner, TCI, and LMC's entering into this 
    Agreement shall in no way be construed as an admission by them that the 
    Acquisition is illegal;
        Whereas Time Warner, Turner, TCI, and LMC understand that no act or 
    transaction contemplated by this Agreement shall be deemed immune or 
    exempt from the provisions of the antitrust laws or the Federal Trade 
    Commission Act by reason of anything contained in this Agreement;
        Now, therefore, upon understanding that the Commission has not yet 
    determined whether the Acquisition will be challenged, and in 
    consideration of the Commission's agreement that, unless the Commission 
    determines to reject the Consent Order, it will not seek further relief 
    from Time Warner, Turner, TCI, and LMC with respect to the Acquisition, 
    except that the Commission may exercise any and all rights to enforce 
    this Agreement and the Consent Order to which this Agreement is annexed 
    and made a part thereof, the parties agree as follows:
        1. Within thirty (30) days of the date the Commission accepts the 
    attached Consent Order for public comment, TCI and LMC shall apply to 
    the IRS for the IRS Ruling.
        2. On or before the Closing Date, Time Warner, Turner and TCI shall 
    cancel the Two Programming Service Agreements.
        3. This Agreement shall be binding when approved by the Commission.
    
    Analysis of Proposed Consent Order to Aid Public Comment
    
    I. Introduction
        The Federal Trade Commission has accepted for public comment from 
    Time Warner Inc. (``Time Warner''), Turner Broadcasting System, Inc. 
    (``Turner''), Tele-Communications, Inc. (``TCI''), and Liberty Media 
    Corporation (``LMC'') (collectively ``the proposed respondents'') an 
    Agreement Containing Consent Order (``the proposed consent order''). 
    The Commission has also entered into an Interim Agreement that requires 
    the proposed respondents to take specific action during the public 
    comment period.
        The proposed consent order is designed to remedy likely antitrust 
    effects arising from Time Warner's acquisition of Turner as well as 
    related transactions, including TCI's proposed ownership interest in 
    Time Warner and long-term cable television programming service 
    agreements between Time Warner and TCI for post-acquisition carriage by 
    TCI of Turner programming.
    II. Description of the Parties, the Acquisition and Related 
    Transactions
        Time Warner is a leading provider of cable networks and a leading 
    distributor of cable television. Time Warner Entertainment (``TWE''), a 
    partnership in which Time Warner holds the majority interest, owns HBO 
    and Cinemax, two premium cable networks. Time Warner and Time Warner 
    Cable, a subsidiary of TWE, are collectively the nation's second 
    largest distributor of cable television and serve approximately 11.5 
    million cable subscribers or approximately 17 percent of U.S. cable 
    television households.
        Turner is a leading provider of cable networks. Turner owns the 
    following ``marquee'' or ``crown jewel'' cable networks: Cable News 
    Network (``CNN''), Turner Network Television (``TNT''), and TBS 
    SuperStation (referred to as ``WTBS''). Turner also owns Headline News 
    (``HLN''), Cartoon Network, Turner Classic Movies, CNN International 
    USA and CNN Financial Network.
        TCI is the nation's largest operator of cable television systems, 
    serving approximately 27 percent of all U.S. cable television 
    households. LMC, a subsidiary of TCI, is a leading provider of cable 
    programming. TCI also owns interests in a large number of cable 
    networks.
    
    [[Page 50309]]
    
        In September 1995, Time Warner and Turner entered into an agreement 
    for Time Warner to acquire the approximately 80 percent of the 
    outstanding shares in Turner that it does not already own. TCI and LMC 
    have an approximately 24 percent existing interest in Turner. By 
    trading their interest in Turner for an interest in Time Warner, TCI 
    and LMC would acquire approximately a 7.5 percent interest in the fully 
    diluted equity of Time Warner as well as the right of first refusal on 
    the approximately 7.4 percent interest in Time Warner that R. E. 
    Turner, III, chairman of Turner, would receive as a result of this 
    acquisition. Although Time Warner has a `poison pill' that would 
    prevent TCI from acquiring more than a certain amount of stock without 
    triggering adverse consequences, that poison pill would still allow TCI 
    to acquire approximately 15 percent of the Fully Diluted Equity, and if 
    the poison pill were to be altered or waived, TCI could acquire more 
    than 15 percent of the fully diluted equity of Time Warner. Also in 
    September 1995, Time Warner entered into two long-term mandatory 
    carriage agreements referred to as the Programming Service Agreements 
    (PSAs). Under the terms of these PSAs, TCI would be required, on 
    virtually all of its cable television systems, to carry CNN, HLN, TNT 
    and WTBS for a twenty-year period.
    III. The Complaint
        The draft complaint accompanying the proposed consent order and the 
    Interim Agreement alleges that the acquisition, along with related 
    transactions, would allow Time Warner unilaterally to raise the prices 
    of cable television programming and would limit the ability of cable 
    television systems that buy such programming to take responsive action 
    to avoid such price increases. It would do so, according to the draft 
    complaint, both through horizontal combination in the market for cable 
    programming (in which Time Warner, after the acquisition, would control 
    about 40% of the market) and through higher entry barriers into that 
    market as a result of the vertical integration (by merger and contract) 
    between Turner's programming interests and Time Warner's and TCI's 
    cable distribution interests. The complaint alleges that TCI and Time 
    Warner, respectively, operate the first and second largest cable 
    television systems in the United States, reaching nearly half of all 
    cable households; that Time Warner would gain the power to raise prices 
    on its own and on Turner's programming unilaterally; that TCI's 
    ownership interest in Time Warner and concurrent long term contractual 
    obligations to carry Turner programming would undermine TCI's incentive 
    to sign up better or less expensive non-Time Warner programming, 
    preventing rivals to the combined Time Warner and Turner from achieving 
    sufficient distribution to realize economies of scale and thereby to 
    erode Time Warner's market power; that barriers to entry into 
    programming and into downstream retail distribution markets would be 
    raised; and that substantial increases in wholesale programming costs 
    for both cable systems and alternative service providers--including 
    direct broadcast satellite service and other forms of non-cable 
    distribution--would lead to higher service prices and fewer 
    entertainment and information sources for consumers.
        The Commission has reason to believe that the acquisition and 
    related transactions, if successful, may have anticompetitive effects 
    and be in violation of Section 7 of the Clayton Act and Section 5 of 
    the Federal Trade Commission Act.
    IV. Terms of the Proposed Consent Order
        The proposed consent order would resolve the alleged antitrust 
    concerns by breaking down the entry barriers that would otherwise be 
    erected by the transaction. It would do so by: (1) Requiring TCI to 
    divest all of its ownership interests in Time Warner or, in the 
    alternative, capping TCI's ownership of Time Warner stock and denying 
    TCI and its controlling shareholders the right to vote any such Time 
    Warner stock; (2) canceling the PSAs; (3) prohibiting Time Warner from 
    bundling Time Warner's HBO with any Turner networks and prohibiting the 
    bundling of Turner's CNN, TNT, and WTBS with any Time Warner networks; 
    (4) prohibiting Time Warner from discriminating against rival 
    Multichannel Video Programming Distributors (``MVPDs'') in the 
    provision of Turner programming; (5) prohibiting Time Warner from 
    foreclosing rival programmers from access to Time Warner's 
    distribution; and (6) requiring Time Warner to carry a 24-hour all news 
    channel that would compete with Turner's CNN. The following sections 
    discuss the primary provisions of the proposed consent order in more 
    detail.
        A. TCI Will Divest Its Interest in Time Warner or Accept a Capped 
    Nonvoting Interest. The divestiture provision of the proposed consent 
    order (Paragraph II) requires TCI and LMC to divest their collective 
    ownership of approximately 7.5 percent of the fully diluted shares in 
    Time Warner - the amount they will obtain from Time Warner in exchange 
    for their 24 percent ownership interest in Turner--to a different 
    company (``The Separate Company'') that will be spun off by TCI and 
    LMC. The stock of The Separate Company would be distributed to all of 
    the shareholders of TCI's LMC subsidiary. Because that stock would be 
    freely tradeable on an exchange, the ownership of The Separate Company 
    would diverge over time from the ownership of the Liberty Media 
    Tracking Stock (and would, at the outset, be different from the 
    ownership of TCI). TCI would therefore breach its fiduciary duty to its 
    shareholders if it forestalled programming entry that could benefit TCI 
    as a cable system operator in order to benefit Time Warner's interests 
    as a programmer.
        In addition to the divestiture provisions ensuring that TCI will 
    have no incentive to forgo its own best interests in order to favor 
    those of Time Warner, the proposed consent order contains provisions to 
    ensure that the transaction will not leave TCI or its management in a 
    position to influence Time Warner to alter its own conduct in order to 
    benefit TCI's interests. Absent restrictions in the consent order, the 
    TCI Control Shareholders (John C. Malone, Bob Magness, and Kearns-
    Tribune Corporation) would have a controlling share of the voting power 
    of The Separate Company. To prevent those shareholders from having 
    significant influence over Time Warner's conduct, the proposed consent 
    order contains the following provisions that will wall off the TCI 
    Control Shareholders from influencing the officers, directors, and 
    employees of The Separate Company and its day-to-day operations:
         The Commission must approve the initial board of directors 
    of The Separate Company;
         Within six months of the distribution of The Separate 
    Company's stock, the stockholders (excluding the TCI Control 
    Shareholders) of The Separate Company must elect new directors;
         Members of the board of directors of The Separate Company 
    are prohibited from serving as officers, directors, or employees of TCI 
    or LMC, or holding or controlling greater than one-tenth of one percent 
    (0.1%) of the ownership in or voting power of TCI or LMC;
         Officers, directors or employees of TCI or LMC are 
    prohibited from concurrently serving as officers, directors, or 
    employees of The Separate Company, with a narrow exception so that TCI 
    or LMC employees may provide limited operational services to The 
    Separate Company;
    
    [[Page 50310]]
    
         The TCI Control Shareholders are prohibited from voting 
    (other than a de minimis voting share necessary for tax purposes) any 
    stock of The Separate Company to elect the board of directors or on 
    other matters. There are limited exceptions for voting on major issues 
    such as a proposed merger or sale of The Separate Company, the 
    disposition of all or substantially all of The Separate Company's 
    assets, the dissolution of The Separate Company, or proposed changes in 
    the corporate charter or bylaw of The Separate Company. However, no 
    vote on any of these excepted issues would be successful unless a 
    majority of shareholders other than the TCI Control Shareholders vote 
    in favor of such proposal;
         The TCI Control Shareholders are prohibited from seeking 
    to influence, or attempting to control by proxy or otherwise, any other 
    person's vote of The Separate Company's stock;
         Officers, directors, and employees of TCI or LMC, or any 
    of the TCI Control Shareholders are prohibited from communicating with 
    any officer, director, or employee of The Separate Company except on 
    the limited matters on which they are permitted to vote. Further 
    restrictions require that, in order for a TCI Control Shareholder to 
    seek to initiate action on an issue on which they are entitled to vote, 
    they must do so in writing;
         The Separate Company is prohibited from acquiring more 
    than 14.99% of the fully diluted equity shares of Time Warner, with 
    exceptions in the event that the TCI Control Shareholders sell their 
    stock in The Separate Company or in TCI and LMC; and
         The Separate Company is prohibited from voting its shares 
    (other than a de minimis voting share necessary for tax purposes) in 
    Time Warner, except that such shares can become voting if The Separate 
    Company sells them to an Independent Third Party or in the event that 
    the TCI Control Shareholders sell their stock in The Separate Company 
    or in TCI and LMC.
        The Commission has reason to believe that the divestiture of TCI's 
    and LMC's interest in Time Warner to The Separate Company is in the 
    public interest. The required divestiture of the Time Warner stock by 
    TCI and LMC and the ancillary restrictions outlined above are 
    beneficial to consumers because (1) they would restore TCI's otherwise 
    diminished incentives to carry cable programming that would compete 
    with Time Warner's cable programming; and (2) they would eliminate 
    TCI's and LMC's ability to influence the operations of Time Warner.
        The proposed consent order also requires TCI and LMC to apply to 
    the Internal Revenue Service (``IRS'') for a ruling that the 
    divestiture of TCI's and LMC's interest in Time Warner to The Separate 
    Company would be generally tax-free. Upon receipt of the IRS Ruling, 
    TCI and LMC has thirty days to transfer its Time Warner stock to The 
    Separate Company. After TCI and LMC divest this interest in Time Warner 
    to The Separate Company, TCI, LMC, Magness and Malone are prohibited 
    from acquiring any stock in Time Warner, above a collective de minimis 
    nonvoting amount, without the prior approval of the Commission.
        Pending the ruling by the IRS, or in the event that the TCI and LMC 
    are unable to obtain such an IRS ruling, (1) TCI, LMC, John C. Malone 
    and Bob Magness, collectively and individually, are capped at level no 
    more than the lesser of 9.2 percent of the fully diluted equity of Time 
    Warner or 12.4% of the actual issued and outstanding common stock of 
    Time Warner, as determined by generally accepted accounting principles; 
    and (2) TCI, LMC and the TCI Control Shareholders' interest in Time 
    Warner must be nonvoting (other than a de minimis voting share 
    necessary for tax purposes), unless the interest is sold to an 
    Independent Third Party. This nonvoting cap is designed to restore 
    TCI's otherwise diminished incentives to carry cable programming that 
    would compete with Time Warner's cable programming as well as to 
    prevent TCI from seeking to influence Time Warner's competitive 
    behavior.
        B. TCI's Long-Term Carriage Agreement With Turner Is Canceled. As 
    part of the transaction, Time Warner and TCI entered into PSAs that 
    required TCI to carry Turner programming for the next twenty years, at 
    a price set at the lesser of 85% of the industry average price or the 
    lowest price given to any distributor. According to the complaint, the 
    PSAs would tend to prevent Time Warner's rivals from achieving 
    sufficient distribution to threaten Time Warner's market power by 
    locking up scarce TCI channel space for an extended period of time. By 
    negotiating this arrangement as part of the Turner acquisition, and not 
    at arms length, Time Warner was able to compensate TCI for helping to 
    achieve this result. Under the Interim Agreement, TCI and Time Warner 
    are obligated to cancel the PSAs. Following cancellation of the PSAs, 
    there would be a six month ``cooling off'' period during which Time 
    Warner and TCI could not enter into new mandatory carriage requirements 
    on an analog tier for Turner programming.1 This cooling off period 
    will ensure that such agreements are negotiated at arm's length. 
    Thereafter, the parties cannot enter into any agreement that would 
    secure Time Warner guaranteed mandatory carriage rights on TCI analog 
    channel capacity for more than five-year periods. This restriction 
    would not prevent TCI from having renewal options to extend for 
    additional five-year periods, but would prohibit Time Warner from 
    obligating TCI to carry a Time Warner channel for more than five years. 
    The only exceptions to the cooling off period for Time Warner/TCI 
    carriage agreements would relate to WTBS and HLN on which there are no 
    existing contracts. Any such carriage agreements for those services 
    would also be limited to five years.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \1\Analog technology is currently used for cable programming 
    distribution and places significant limitations on the addition of 
    new channels. Digital technology, which is still in its infancy and 
    not currently a competitive factor in video distribution, has the 
    potential to expand capacity sixfold, thereby substantially 
    alleviating capacity constraints on the digital tier.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In requiring the cancellation of the PSAs and prescribing shorter 
    renewal option periods, the Commission has not concluded that any such 
    long-term programming agreements are anticompetitive in and of 
    themselves or would violate the antitrust laws standing alone. Rather, 
    the Commission has concluded that the PSAs are anticompetitive in the 
    context of the entire transaction arising from the merger and ownership 
    of Time Warner stock by TCI and in light of those two companies' 
    significant market shares in both programming and cable service. The 
    divestiture and rescission requirements would therefore sever 
    complementary ownership and long-term contractual links between TCI and 
    Time Warner. This would restore incentives for TCI, a cable operator 
    serving nearly a third of the nation's cable households, to place non-
    Time Warner programming on its cable systems, in effect disciplining 
    any market power resulting from a combination of Time Warner and Turner 
    programming.
        C. Time Warner is Barred From Bundling HBO with any Turner 
    Programming and CNN, TNT and WTBS with Time Warner Programming. 
    Paragraph V bars Time Warner from bundling HBO with Turner channels--
    that is, making HBO available, or available on more favorable terms, 
    only if the purchaser agrees to take the Turner channels. Time Warner 
    is also barred from bundling CNN, TNT, or
    
    [[Page 50311]]
    
    WTBS with Time Warner channels. This provision applies to new 
    programming as well as existing programming. This provision is designed 
    to address concerns that the easiest way the combined firm could exert 
    substantially greater negotiating leverage over cable operators is by 
    combining all or some of such ``marquee'' services and offering them as 
    a package or offering them along with unwanted programming. Because the 
    focus of the provision is on seeking to prevent the additional market 
    power arising from this combination of programming, this provision does 
    not prevent bundling engaged in pre-merger--that is, Turner channels 
    with Turner channels and pre- merger Time Warner channels with Time 
    Warner channels. Rather, it is narrowly targeted at Time Warner's use 
    of its newly-acquired stable of ``marquee'' channels to raise prices by 
    bundling.
        The Commission emphasizes that, in general, bundling often benefits 
    customers by giving firms an incentive to increase output and serve 
    buyers who would otherwise not obtain the product or service. The 
    Commission, however, believes that, in the context of this transaction, 
    the limited bar on bundling is a prudent measure that will prevent 
    actions by Time Warner that are likely to harm competition.
        D. Time Warner is Barred from Price Discrimination Against Rival 
    MVPDs. Paragraph VI is designed to prevent Time Warner from using its 
    larger stable of programming interests to disadvantage new entrants 
    into the distribution of cable programs such as Direct Broadcast 
    Services, wireless systems, and systems created by telephone companies. 
    The complaint alleges that, as a programmer that does not own its own 
    distribution, Turner pre- merger had no incentive to and did not 
    generally charge significantly higher prices to new MVPD entrants 
    compared to the prices offered to established MVPDs. Under the terms of 
    Paragraph VI, the preacquisition range of pricing offered by Turner is 
    used as a benchmark to prevent Time Warner from discriminating against 
    the rival distributors of programming in its service areas, and Time 
    Warner may not increase the range of pricing on Turner programming 
    services between established MVPDs and new entrants any more than 
    Turner had pre-merger. Because Time Warner's incentive to discriminate 
    against MVPDs stems from an incentive to protect its own cable company 
    from those in or entering its downstream distribution areas, this 
    provision only covers competitors in Time Warner's distribution areas. 
    Because the price charged by Time Warner as a programmer to Time 
    Warner's cable systems is, to some extent, an internal transfer price, 
    the proposed consent order uses as a benchmark the price charged to the 
    three largest cable system operators nationwide rather than the price 
    charged to Time Warner. This provision, therefore, compares the price 
    charged to Time Warner's competitors in the overlap areas with the 
    price charged to the three largest cable system operators, and asks 
    whether the spread between the two is any greater than the pre-merger 
    spread between a similarly situated MVPD and the three largest cable 
    system operators. It thus focuses on the greater possibility for price 
    discrimination against new MVPD entrants arising directly as a result 
    of this merger. It both ensures that Time Warner's additional market 
    power as a result of this merger does not result in higher prices to 
    new MVPD entrants, while it narrowly protects only those new entrants 
    that Time Warner may have an incentive to harm.
        E. Conduct and Reporting Requirements Designed to Ensure that Time 
    Warner Cable Does Not Discriminatorily Deny Carriage to Unaffiliated 
    Programmers. The order has two main provisions designed to address 
    concerns that this combination increases Time Warner's incentives to 
    disadvantage unaffiliated programmers in making carriage decisions for 
    its own cable company. Paragraph VII, drawn from statutory provisions 
    in the 1992 Cable Act, is designed to prevent Time Warner from 
    discriminating in its carriage decisions so as to exclude or 
    substantially impair the ability of an unaffiliated national video 
    programmer to enter into or to compete in the video programming market. 
    The Commission views these provisions as working in tandem with the 
    collection and reporting requirements contained in Paragraph VIII. 
    Under that paragraph, Time Warner is required to collect and maintain 
    information about programming offers received and the disposition of 
    those offers as well as information comparing Time Warner cable 
    systems' carriage rates to carriage rates on other MVPDs for national 
    video programming services. Such information would be reported on a 
    quarterly basis to the management committee of TWE. TWE's management 
    committee includes representatives of U S West since U S West is a 
    minority partner in TWE. TWE owns or operates all of Time Warner's 
    cable systems. Because U S West's incentives would be to maximize 
    return to TWE's cable systems rather than to Time Warner's wholly owned 
    programming interests, it would have strong incentives to alert the 
    Commission to actions by Time Warner that favored Time Warner's wholly 
    owned programming interests at the expense of Time Warner cable 
    systems' profitability. Such information would also be available for 
    inspection independently by the Commission. Furthermore, Time Warner's 
    General Counsel responsible for cable systems is required to certify 
    annually to the Commission its compliance with the substantive 
    prohibitions in Paragraph VII.
        F. Time Warner Cable Agrees to Carry CNN Rival. Of the types of 
    programming in which the post-merger Time Warner will have a leading 
    position, the one with the fewest existing close substitutes is the 
    all-news segment, in which CNN is by far the most significant player. 
    There are actual or potential entrants that could in the future erode 
    CNN's market power, but their ability to do so is partly dependent on 
    their ability to secure widespread distribution. Without access to Time 
    Warner's extensive cable holdings, such new entry may not be 
    successful. Time Warner's acquisition of CNN gives it both the ability 
    and incentive to make entry of competing news services more difficult, 
    by denying them access to its extensive distribution system. To remedy 
    this potential anticompetitive effect, Time Warner would be required to 
    place a news channel on certain of its cable systems under Paragraph IX 
    of the proposed agreement. The rate of roll-out and the final 
    penetration rate is set at levels so as not to interfere with Time 
    Warner's carriage of other programming. It is set at such a level that 
    Time Warner may continue carrying any channel that it is now carrying, 
    may add any channel that it is contractually committed to carry in the 
    future, and may continue any plans it has to carry unaffiliated 
    programming in the future. It limits only Time Warner's ability to give 
    effect to its incentive to deny access even to a news channel that does 
    not interfere with such commitments or plans. Time Warner has committed 
    to achieve penetration of 50% of total basic subscribers by July 30, 
    1999, if it seeks to fulfill this provision by increasing carriage for 
    an existing channel, or to achieve penetration of 50% of total basic 
    subscribers by July 30, 2001, if it seeks to fulfill this provision by 
    carrying a channel not currently carried by Time Warner. This shorter 
    period is possible in the former case because, to the extent that Time 
    Warner is already committed to carry the channel on a portion of Time 
    Warner's systems, less additional
    
    [[Page 50312]]
    
    capacity would need to be found in order to achieve the required 
    penetration. On the other hand, the longer period if a new news service 
    is selected assures that an existing news service or other service need 
    not be displaced to make room for the new service.
        This provision was crafted so as to give Time Warner flexibility in 
    choosing a new news channel, without undermining the Commission's 
    competitive concern that the chosen service have the opportunity to 
    become a strong competitor to CNN. To ensure that the competing news 
    channel is competitively significant, the order obligates Time Warner 
    to choose a news service that will have contractual commitments with 
    unaffiliated cable operators to reach 10 million subscribers by 
    February 1, 1997. Together with Time Warner's commitments required by 
    the proposed order, such a service would have commitments for a total 
    of approximately 15 million subscribers. In the alternative, Time 
    Warner could take a service with a smaller unaffiliated subscriber 
    base, if it places the service on more of its own systems in order to 
    assure that the service's total subscribers would reach 15 million. In 
    order to attract advertisers and become a competitive force, a news 
    service must have a critical mass of subscribers. The thresholds 
    contained in this order give Time Warner flexibility while ensuring 
    that the service selected has enough subscribers to have a credible 
    opportunity to become an effective competitor. The February 1, 1997, 
    date was selected so as to give competitive news services an 
    opportunity to achieve the required number of subscribers.
        Accordingly, this provision should not interfere with Time Warner's 
    plans to carry programming of its choosing or unduly involve the 
    Commission in Time Warner's choice of a new service. It is analogous to 
    divestiture of one channel on some cable systems and is thus far less 
    burdensome to Time Warner than the typical antitrust remedy which would 
    require that Time Warner divest some or all of cable systems in their 
    entirety. The Commission, however, recognizes that this provision is 
    unusual and invites public comment on the appropriateness of such a 
    requirement.
    V. Opportunity for Public Comment
        The proposed consent order has been placed on the public record for 
    60 days for reception of comments from interested persons. Comments 
    received during this period will become part of the public record. 
    After 60 days, the Commission will again review the agreement and 
    comments received, and will decide whether it should withdraw from the 
    agreement or make final the order contained in the agreement.
        By accepting the consent order subject to final approval, the 
    Commission anticipates that the competitive problems alleged in the 
    complaint will be resolved. The purpose of this analysis is to invite 
    and facilitate public comment concerning the consent order. It is not 
    intended to constitute an official interpretation of the agreement and 
    proposed order or in any way to modify their terms.
    Benjamin I. Berman,
    Acting Secretary.
    
    Separate Statement of Chairman Pitofsky, and Commissioners Steiger and 
    Varney In the Matter of Time Warner Inc., File No. 961-0004
    
        The proposed merger and related transactions among Time Warner, 
    Turner, and TCI involve three of the largest firms in cable programming 
    and delivery--firms that are actual or potential competitors in many 
    aspects of their businesses. The transaction would have merged the 
    first and third largest cable programmers (Time Warner and Turner). At 
    the same time it would have further aligned the interests of TCI and 
    Time Warner, the two largest cable distributors. Finally, the 
    transaction as proposed would have greatly increased the level of 
    vertical integration in an industry in which the threat of foreclosure 
    is both real and substantial.1 While the transaction posed 
    complicated and close questions of antitrust enforcement, the 
    conclusion of the dissenters that there was no competitive problem at 
    all is difficult to understand.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \1\ Both Congress and the regulators have identified problems 
    with the effects of vertical foreclosure in this industry. See 
    generally James W. Olson and Lawrence J. Spiwak, Can Short-term 
    Limits on Strategic Vertical Restraints Improve Long-term Cable 
    industry Market Performance?, 13 Cardozo Arts & Entertainment Law 
    Journal 283 (1995). Enforcement action in this case is wholly 
    consistent with the goals of Congress in enacting the 1992 Cable 
    Act: providing greater access to programming and promoting 
    competition in local cable markets.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Many of the concerns raised in the dissenting Commissioners 
    statements are carefully addressed in the analysis to aid public 
    comment. We write to clarify our views on certain specific issues 
    raised in the dissents.
        Product market. The dissenting Commissioners suggest that the 
    product market alleged, ``the sale of Cable Television Programming 
    Services to MVPDs (Multichannel Video Programming Distributors),'' 
    cannot be sustained. The facts suggest otherwise. Substantial evidence, 
    confirmed in the parties' documents and testimony, as well as documents 
    and sworn statements from third-parties, indicated the existence of an 
    all cable television market. Indeed, there was significant evidence of 
    competitive interaction in terms of carriage, promotions and marketing 
    support, subscriber fees, and channel position between different 
    segments of cable programming, including basic and premium channel 
    programming. Cable operators look to all types of cable programming to 
    determine the proper mix of diverse content and format to attract a 
    wide range of subscribers.
        Although a market that includes both CNN and HBO may appear 
    somewhat unusual on its face, the Commission was presented here with 
    substantial evidence that MVPDs require access to certain ``marquee'' 
    channels, such as HBO and CNN, to retain existing subscribers or expand 
    their subscriber base. Moreover, we can not concur that evidence in the 
    record supports Commissioner Azcuenaga's proposed market definition, 
    which would segregate offerings into basic and premium cable 
    programming markets.
        Entry. Although we agree that entry is an important factor, we 
    cannot concur with Commissioner Azcuenaga's overly generous view of 
    entry conditions in this market. While new program channels have 
    entered in the past few years, these channels have not become 
    competitively significant. None of the channels that has entered since 
    1991 has acquired more than a 1% market share.
        Moreover, the anticompetitive effects of this acquisition would 
    have resulted from one firm's control of several marquee channels. In 
    that aspect of the market, entry has proven slow and costly. The 
    potential for new entry in basic services cannot guarantee against 
    competitive harm. To state the matter simply, the launch of a new 
    ``Billiards Channel,'' ``Ballet Channel,'' or the like will barely make 
    a ripple on the shores of the marquee channels through which Time 
    Warner can exercise market power.
        Technology. Commissioner Azcuenaga also seems to suggest that the 
    Commission has failed to recognize the impact of significant 
    technological changes in the market, such as the emergence of new 
    delivery systems such as direct broadcast satellite networks 
    (``DBS'').2 We agree that these alternative technologies may 
    someday become a significant competitive force
    
    [[Page 50313]]
    
    in the market. Indeed, that prospect is one of the reasons the 
    Commission has acted to prevent Time Warner from being able to 
    disadvantage these competitors by discriminating in access to 
    programming.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \2\ DBS providers are included as participants in the relevant 
    product market.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        But to suggest that these technologies one day may become more 
    widespread does not mean they currently are, or in the near future will 
    be, important enough to defeat anticompetitive conduct. Alternative 
    technologies such as DBS have only a small foothold in the market, 
    perhaps a 3% share of total subscribers. Moreover, DBS is more costly 
    and lacks the carriage of local stations. It seems rather unlikely that 
    the emerging DBS technology is sufficient to prevent the competitive 
    harm that would have arisen from this transaction.
        Horizontal competitive effects. Although Commissioner Starek 
    presents a lengthy argument on why we need not worry about the 
    horizontal effects of the acquisition, the record developed in this 
    investigation strongly suggests anticompetitive effects would have 
    resulted without remedial action. This merger would combine the first 
    and third largest providers of cable programming, resulting in a merged 
    firm controlling over 40% of the market, and several of the key marquee 
    channels including HBO and CNN. The horizontal concerns are 
    strengthened by the fact that Time Warner and TCI are the two largest 
    MVPDs in the country. The Commission staff received an unprecedented 
    level of concern from participants in all segments of the market about 
    the potential anticompetitive effects of this merger.
        One of the most frequent concerns expressed was that the merger 
    heightens the already formidable entry barriers into programming by 
    further aligning the incentives of both Time Warner and TCI to deprive 
    entrants of sufficient distribution outlets to achieve the necessary 
    economies of scale. The proposed order addresses the impact on entry 
    barriers as follows. First, the prohibition on bundling would deter 
    Time Warner from using the practice to compel MVPDs to accept unwanted 
    channels which would further limit available channel capacity to non-
    Time Warner programmers. Second, the conduct and reporting requirements 
    in paragraphs VII and VIII provide a mechanism for the Commission to 
    become aware of situations where Time Warner discriminates in handling 
    carriage requests from programming rivals.
        Third, the proposed order reduces entry barriers by eliminating the 
    programming service agreements (PSAs), which would have required TCI to 
    carry certain Turner networks until 2015, at a price set at the lower 
    of 85% of the industry average price or the lowest price given to any 
    other MVPD. The PSAs would have reduced the ability and incentives of 
    TCI to handle programming from Time Warner's rivals. Channel space on 
    cable systems is scarce. If the PSAs effectively locked up significant 
    channel space on TCI, the ability of rival programmers to enter would 
    have been harmed. This effect would have been exacerbated by the 
    unusually long duration of the agreement and the fact that TCI would 
    have received a 15% discount over the most favorable price given to any 
    other MVPD. Eliminating the twenty-year PSAs and restricting the 
    duration of future contracts between TCI and Time Warner would restore 
    TCI's opportunities and incentives to evaluate and carry non-Time 
    Warner programming.
        We believe that this remedy carefully restricts potential 
    anticompetitive practices, arising from this acquisition, that would 
    have heightened entry barriers.
        Vertical foreclosure. The complaint alleges that post-acquisition 
    Time Warner and TCI would have the power to: (1) Foreclose unaffiliated 
    programming from their cable systems to protect their programming 
    assets; and (2) disadvantage competing MVPDs, by engaging in price 
    discrimination. Commissioner Azcuenaga contends that Time Warner and 
    TCI lack the incentives and the ability to engage in either type of 
    foreclosure. We disagree.
        First, it is important to recognize the degree of vertical 
    integration involved. Post-merger Time Warner alone would control more 
    than 40% of the programming assets (as measured by subscriber revenue 
    obtained by MVPDs). Time Warner and TCI, the nation's two largest 
    MVPDs, control access to about 44% of all cable subscribers. The case 
    law have found that these levels of concentration can be 
    problematic.3
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \3\ See Ash Grove Cement Co. v. FTC, 577 F2d 1368 (9th Cir. 
    1978); Mississippi River Corp. v. FTC, 454 F.2d 1083 (8th Cri. 
    1972); United States Steel Corp. v. FTC, 426 F.2d 592 (6th Cir. 
    1970); see generally Herbert Hovenkamp, Federal Antitrust Policy 
    Sec. 9.4 (1994).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Second, the Commission received evidence that these foreclosure 
    threats were real and substantial. There was clearly reason to believe 
    that this acquisition would increase the incentives to engage in this 
    foreclosure without remedial action. For example, the launch of a new 
    channel that could achieve marquee status would be almost impossible 
    without distribution on either the Time Warner or TCI cable systems. 
    Because of the economies of scale involved, the successful launch of 
    any significant new channel usually requires distribution on MVPDs that 
    cover 40-60% of subscribers.
        Commissioner Starek suggests that we need not worry about 
    foreclosure because there are sufficient number of unaffiliated 
    programmers and MVPDs so that each can survive by entering into 
    contracts. With all due respect, this view ignores the competitive 
    realities of the marketplace. TCI and Time Warner are the two largest 
    MVPDs in the U.S. with market shares of 27% and 17% respectively.4 
    Carriage on one or both systems is critical for new programming to 
    achieve competitive viability. Attempting to replicate the coverage of 
    these systems by lacing together agreements with the large number of 
    much smaller MVPDs is costly and time consuming.5 The Commission 
    was presented with evidence that denial of coverage on the Time Warner 
    and TCI systems could further delay entry of potential marquee channels 
    for several years.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \4\ They are substantially larger than the next largest MVPD, 
    Continental, which has an approximately 6% market share.
        \5\ See U.S. Department of Justice Horizontal Merger Guidelines, 
    para. 13,103 Trade Cas. (CCH) at 20,565-66, Secs. 4.2 4,21(June 14, 
    1984), incorporation in U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade 
    Commission Horizontal Merger Guidelines, para. 13,104 Trade Cas. 
    (CCH) (Apirl 7, 1992).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        TCI ownership of Time Warner. Commissioner Azcuenaga suggests that 
    TCI's potential acquisition of a 15% interest in Time Warner, with the 
    prospect of acquiring up to 25% without further antitrust review, does 
    not pose any competitive problem. We disagree. Such a substantial 
    ownership interest, especially in a highly concentrated market with 
    substantial vertically interdependent relationships and high entry 
    barriers, poses significant competitive concerns.6 In particular, 
    the interest would give TCI greater incentives to disadvantage 
    programmer competitors of Time Warner; similarly it would increase Time 
    Warner's incentives to disadvantage MVPDs that compete with TCI. The 
    Commission's remedy would eliminate these incentives to act 
    anticompetitively by making TCI's interest truly passive.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \6\ See United States v. dupont de Nemours & Co., 353 U.S. 586 
    (1957); F&M Schaefer Corp v. C. Schmidt & Sons, Inc., 597 F.2d 814, 
    818-19 (2d Cir. 1979); Gulf & Western Indus. v. Great Atlantic & 
    Pacific Tea Co., 476 F.2d 687 (2d Cir. 1973).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Efficiencies. Finally, Commissioner Azcuenaga seems to suggest that 
    the acquisition may result in certain efficiencies in terms of ``more 
    and better programming options'' and ``reduced
    
    [[Page 50314]]
    
    transactions costs.'' There was little or no evidence presented to the 
    Commission to suggest that these efficiencies were likely to occur.
    
    Dissenting Statement of Commissioner Mary L. Azcuenaga in Time Warner 
    Inc., File No. 961-0004
    
        The Commission today accepts for public comment a proposed consent 
    agreement to settle allegations that the proposed acquisition by Time 
    Warner Inc. (Time Warner) of Turner Broadcasting System, Inc. (Turner), 
    and related agreements with Tele-Communications, Inc. (TCI),1 
    would be unlawful. Alleging that this transaction violates the law is 
    possible only by abandoning the rigor of the Commission's usual 
    analysis under Section 7 of the Clayton Act. To reach this result, the 
    majority adopts a highly questionable market definition, ignores any 
    consideration of efficiencies and blindly assumes difficulty of entry 
    in the antitrust sense in the face of overwhelming evidence to the 
    contrary. The decision of the majority also departs from more general 
    principles of antitrust law by favoring competitors over competition 
    and contrived theory over facts.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \1\ Liberty Media Corporation, a wholly-owned subsidiary of TCI, 
    also is named in the complaint and order. For simplicity, references 
    in this statement to TCI include Liberty.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The usual analysis of competitive effects under the law, unlike the 
    apparent analysis of the majority, would take full account of the 
    swirling forces of innovation and technological advances in this 
    dynamic industry. Unfortunately, the complaint and the underlying 
    theories on which the proposed order is based do not begin to satisfy 
    the rigorous standard for merger analysis that this agency has applied 
    for years. Instead, the majority employs a looser standard for 
    liability and a regulatory order that threatens the likely efficiencies 
    from the transaction. Having found no reason to relax our standards of 
    analysis for this case, I cannot agree that the order is warranted.
    Product Market
        We focus in merger analysis on the likelihood that the transaction 
    will create or enhance the ability to exercise market power, i.e., 
    raise prices. The first step usually is to examine whether the merging 
    firms sell products that are substitutes for one another to see if 
    there is a horizontal competitive overlap. This is important in a case 
    based on a theory of unilateral anticompetitive effects, as this one 
    is, because according to the merger guidelines, the theory depends on 
    the factual assumption that the products of the merging firms are the 
    first and second choices for consumers.2
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \2\ 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines para. 2.2. The theory is 
    that when the post-merger firm raises the price on product A or on 
    products A and B, sales lost due to the price increase on the first-
    choice product (A) will be diverted to the second-choice product 
    (B). The price increase is unlikely to be profitable unless a 
    significant share of consumers regard the products of the merged 
    firm as their first and second choices.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In this case, it could be argued that from the perspective of cable 
    system operators and other multichannel video program distributors 
    (MVPDs), who are purchasers of programming services, all network 
    services are substitutes. This is the horizontal competitive overlap 
    that is alleged in the complaint.3
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \3\ Complaint para. 24.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        One problem with the alleged all-programming market is that basic 
    services (such as Turner's CNN) and premium services (such as Time 
    Warner's HBO) are not substitutes along the usual dimensions of 
    competition. Most significantly, they do not compete on price. CNN is 
    sold to MVPDs for a fee per subscriber that is on average less than 
    one-tenth of the average price for HBO, and it is resold as part of a 
    package of basic services for an inclusive fee. HBO is sold at 
    wholesale for more than ten times as much; it is resold to consumers on 
    an a la carte basis or in a package with other premium services, and a 
    subscription to basic service usually is a prerequisite. It is highly 
    unlikely that a cable operator, to avoid a price increase, would drop a 
    basic channel and replace it with a significantly more expensive 
    premium channel. Furthermore, cable system operators tell us that when 
    the price for basic cable services increases, consumers drop pay 
    services, suggesting that at least at the retail level these goods are 
    complementary, rather than substitutes for one another.
        Another possible argument is that CNN and HBO should be in the same 
    product market because, from the cable operator's perspective, each is 
    ``necessary to attract and retain a significant percentage of their 
    subscribers.'' 4 If CNN and HBO were substitutes in this sense, we 
    would expect to see cable system operators playing them against one 
    another to win price concessions in negotiations with programming 
    sellers, but there is no evidence that they have been used this way, 
    and cable system operators have told us that basic and premium channels 
    do not compete on price.5 There are closer substitutes, in terms 
    of price and content, for CNN (in the basic tier) and for HBO (in the 
    premium tier).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \4\ Complaint Paras. II.4 & III.9. To the extent that each 
    network (CNN and HBO) is viewed as ``necessary'' to attract 
    subscribers, as alleged in the complaint, each would appear to have 
    market power quite independent of the proposed transaction and of 
    each other.
        \5\ If the market includes premium cable channels, it probably 
    ought also to include video cassette rentals, which constrain the 
    pricing of premium channels. Federal Communications Commission, 
    Second Annual Report on the Status of Competition in the Market for 
    the Delivery of Video Programming para. 121 (Dec. 7, 1995) 
    (hereafter ``FCC Report''). If the theory is that HBO and CNN 
    compete for channel space, the market probably should include over-
    the-air broadcast networks, at least to the extent that they can 
    obtain cable channel space as the price for retransmission rights.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        I am not persuaded that the product market alleged in the complaint 
    could be sustained. The products of Time Warner and Turner are not the 
    first and second choices for consumers (or cable system operators or 
    other MVPDs), and there are no other horizontal overlaps warranting 
    enforcement action in any other cable programming market.6 Under 
    these circumstances, it would seem appropriate to withdraw the proposed 
    complaint.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \6\ In the two product markets most likely to be sustained under 
    the law, basic cable services and premium cable services, the 
    transaction falls within safe harbors described in the 1992 Merger 
    Guidelines.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Entry
        The proposed complaint alleges that entry is difficult and 
    unlikely.7 This is an astonishing allegation, given the amount of 
    entry in the cable programming market. The number of cable programming 
    services increased from 106 to 129 in 1995, according to the FCC.8 
    One source reported thirty national 24-hour channels expected to launch 
    this year,9 and another recently identified seventy-three networks 
    ``on the launch pad'' for 1996.10 That adds up to between fifty-
    three and ninety-six new and announced networks in two years. Another 
    source listed 141 national 24-hour cable networks launched or announced 
    between January 1993 and March 1996.11
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \7\ Complaint Paras. 33-35.
        \8\ FCC Report para. 10.
        \9\ National Cable Television Association, Cable Television 
    Developments 103-17 (Fall 1995).
        \10\ ``On the Launch Pad,'' Cable World, April 29, 1996, at 143; 
    see also Cablevision, Jan. 22, 1996, at 54 (98 announced services 
    with expected launches in 1996).
        \11\ ``A Who's Who of New Nets,'' Cablevision, April 15, 1996 
    (Special Supp.) at 27A-44A (as of March 28, 1996, 163 new networks 
    when regional, pay-per-view and interactive services are included).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        This does not mean that entry is easy or inexpensive. Not all the 
    channels that have announced will launch a service, and not all those 
    that launch will succeed.12 But some of them will. Some
    
    [[Page 50315]]
    
    recent entrants include CNNfn (December 1995), Nick at Nite (April 
    1996), MS/NBC (July 1996) and the History Channel (January 
    1995).13 The Fox network plans to launch a third 24-hour news 
    channel, and Westinghouse and CBS Entertainment recently announced that 
    they will launch a new entertainment and information cable channel, Eye 
    on People, in March 1997.14 The fact of so much ongoing entry 
    indicates that entry should be regarded as virtually immediate.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \12\ ``The stamina and pocket-depth of backers of new players 
    [networks] still remain key factors for survival. However, 
    distribution is still the name of the game.'' Cablevision, April 15, 
    1996 (Special Supp.), at 3A.
        \13\ Carter, ``For History on Cable, the Time Has Arrived,'' 
    N.Y. Times, May 20, 1996, at D1. The article reported that the 
    History Channel began in January 1995 with one million subscribers, 
    reached 8 million subscribers by the end of the year and by May 1996 
    was seen in 18 million homes.
        \14\ Carmody, ``The TV channel,'' The Washington Post, Aug. 21, 
    1996, at D12.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        New networks need not be successful or even launched before they 
    can exert significant competitive pressure. Announced launches can 
    affect pricing immediately. The launch of MS/NBC and the announcement 
    of Fox's cable news channel already may have affected the incumbent 
    all-news channel, CNN, because cable system operators can credibly 
    threaten to switch to one of the new news networks in negotiations to 
    renew CNN.15
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \15\ This is the kind of competition we would expect to see 
    between cable networks that are substitutes for one another and the 
    kind of competition that is non-existent between CNN and HBO.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Any constraint on cable channel capacity does not appear to be 
    deterring entry of new networks. Indeed, the amount of entry that is 
    occurring apparently reflects confidence that channel capacity will 
    expand, for example, by digital technology. In addition, alternative 
    MVPDs, such as Direct Broadcast Satellite (DBS), may provide a 
    launching pad for new networks.16 For example, CNNfn was launched 
    in 1995 with 4 to 5 million households, divided between DBS and cable.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \16\ The entry of alternative MVPD technologies may put 
    competitive pressure on cable system operators to expand capacity 
    more quickly. See ``The Birth of Networks,'' Cablevision (Special 
    Supp. April 15, 1996), at 8A (cable system operators ``don't want 
    DBS and the telcos to pick up the services of tomorrow while they 
    are being overly arrogant about their capacity'').
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Nor should we ignore significant technological changes in video 
    distribution that are affecting cable programming. One such change is 
    the development and commercialization of new distribution methods that 
    can provide alternatives for both cable programmers and subscribers. 
    DBS is one example. With digital capability, DBS can provide hundreds 
    of channels to subscribers. By September 1995, DBS was available in all 
    forty-eight contiguous states and Alaska.17 In April 1996, DBS had 
    2.4 million customers; in August 1996, DBS had 3.34 million subscribers 
    18 (compared to 62 million cable customers in the U.S.). AT&T 
    recently invested $137.5 million in DirecTV, a DBS provider, began to 
    sell satellite dishes and programming to its long distance customers in 
    four markets, and reportedly plans to expand to the rest of the country 
    in September 1996.19 EchoStar and AlphaStar both have launched new 
    DBS services, and MCI Communication and News Corp. have announced a 
    partnership to enter DBS.20 Some industry analysts predict that 
    DBS will serve 15 million subscribers by 2000.21
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \17\ FCC Report para. 49.
        \18\ DBS Digest, Aug. 22, 1996 (http://www.dbsdish.com/
    dbsdata,html (Sept. 5, 1996)).
        \19\ See Breznick, ``Crowded Skies,'' Cable World (April 29, 
    1996) (http://www.mediacentral.com/magazines/Cable Worls/News96/
    1996042913.htm/539128 (Setp. 3, 1996); see also N.Y. Times, JUly 14, 
    1996, at 23 (AT&T full page ad for digital satellite system DirecTV 
    and USSB); USA Today, Aug. 20, 1996, at 5D (DISH Network full page 
    ad for digital satellite system and channels).
        \20\ Breznick, ``Crowded Skies,'' Cable World, April 29, 1996 
    (http://www.mediacentral.com/magazines/Cable World/news96/
    1996042913.htm/539128 (Sept. 3, 1996)).
        \21\ See id.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Digital technology, which would expand cable capacity to as many as 
    500 channels, is another important development. DBS already uses 
    digital technology, and some cable operators plan to begin providing 
    digital service later this year. Discovery Communications (The 
    Discovery Channel) has announced that it will launch four new 
    programming services designed for digital boxes in time for TCI's 
    ``digital box rollout'' this fall.22 (Even without digital 
    service, cable systems have continued to upgrade their capacity; in 
    1994, about 64% of cable systems offered thirty to fifty-three 
    channels, and more than 14% offered fifty-four or more 
    channels.23) Local telephone companies have entered as 
    distributors via video dialtone, MMDS 24 and cable systems, and 
    the telcos are exploring additional ways to enter video distribution 
    markets. Digital compression and advanced television technologies could 
    make it possible for multiple programs to be broadcast over a single 
    over-the-air broadcast channel.25 When these developments will be 
    fully realized is open to debate, but it is clear that they are on the 
    way and affecting competition. According to one trade association 
    official, cable operators are responding to competition by ``upgrading 
    their infrastructures with fiber optics and digital compression 
    technologies to boost channel capacity. * * * What's more, cable 
    operators are busily trying to polish their images with a public that 
    has long registered gripes over pricing, customer service and 
    programming choice.'' 26
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \22\ Katz, ``Discovery Goes Digital,'' Multichannel News Digest, 
    Sept. 3, 1996 (``The new networks * * * will launch Oct. 22 in order 
    to be included in Tele-Communications Inc.'s digital box rollout in 
    Hartford, Conn.'') (http://www.multichannel.com/digest.htm (Sept. 5, 
    1996)).
        \23\ FCC Report at B-2 (Table 3).
        \24\ MMDS stands for multichannel multipoint distribution 
    service, a type of wireless cable See FCC Report at Paras. 68.85. 
    Industry observers project that MMDS will serve more than 2 million 
    subscribers in 1997 and grow more than 280% between 1995 and 1998. 
    FCC Report para. 71.
        \25\ FCC Report para. 116.
        \26\ Pendleton, ``Keeping Up With Cable Competition,'' Cable 
    World, April 29, 1996, at 158.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Ongoing entry in programming suggests that no program seller could 
    maintain an anticompetitive price increase and, therefore, there is no 
    basis for liability under Section 7 of the Clayton Act. Changes in the 
    video distribution market will put additional pressure on both cable 
    systems and programming providers to be competitive by providing 
    quality programming at reasonable prices. The quality and quantity of 
    entry in the industry warrants dismissal of the complaint.
    Horizontal Theory of Liability
        The proposed complaint alleges that Time Warner will be able to 
    exploit its ownership of HBO and the Turner basic channels by 
    ``bundling'' Turner networks with HBO, that is, by selling them as a 
    package.27 As a basis for liability in a merger case, this appears 
    to be without precedent.28 Bundling is not always anticompetitive, 
    and one problem with the theory is that we cannot predict when it will 
    be anticompetitive.29 Bundling can be used to transfer market 
    power from the ``tying'' product to the ``tied'' product, but it also 
    is used in many industries as a means of discounting. Popular cable 
    networks, for example, have been sold in a package at a discount from 
    the single product price. This can be a way for a programmer to 
    encourage cable system operators to carry multiple
    
    [[Page 50316]]
    
    networks and achieve cross-promotion among the networks in the package. 
    Even if it seemed more likely than not that Time Warner would bundle 
    HBO with Turner networks after the merger, we could not a priori 
    identify this as an anticompetitive effect.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \27\ Complaint para. 38a.
        \28\ Cf. Heublein, Inc., 96 F.T.C. 385, 596-99 (1980) (rejecting 
    a claim of violation based on leveraging).
        \29\ See Whinston, ``Tying, Foreclosure, and Exclusion,'' 80 Am. 
    Econ. Rev. 837, 855-56 (1990) (tying can be exclusionary, but ``even 
    in the simple models considered [in the article], which ignore a 
    number of other possible motivations for the practice, the impact of 
    this exclusion on welfare is uncertain. This fact, combined with the 
    difficulty of sorting out the leverage-based instances of tying from 
    other cases, makes the specification of a practical legal standard 
    extremely difficult.'').
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The alleged violation rests on a theory that the acquisition raises 
    the potential for unlawful tying. To the best of my knowledge, Section 
    7 of the Clayton Act has never been extended to such a situation. There 
    are two reasons not to adopt the theory here. First, challenging the 
    mere potential to engage in such conduct appears to fall short of the 
    ``reasonable probability'' standard under Section 7 of the Clayton Act. 
    We do not seek to enjoin mergers on the mere possibility that firms in 
    the industry may later choose to engage in unlawful conduct. It is 
    difficult to imagine a merger that could not be enjoined if ``mere 
    possibility'' of unlawful conduct were the standard. Here, the 
    likelihood of anticompetitive effects is even more removed, because 
    tying, the conduct that might possibly occur, in turn might or might 
    not prove to be unlawful. Second, anticompetitive tying is unlawful, 
    and Time Warner would face private law suits and agency enforcement 
    action for such conduct.
        The proposed remedy for the alleged bundling is to prohibit 
    it,30 with no attempt to distinguish efficient bundling from 
    anticompetitive bundling.31 Assuming liability on the basis of an 
    anticompetitive horizontal overlap, the obvious remedy would be to 
    enjoin the transaction or require the divestiture of HBO. Divestiture 
    is a simple, easily reviewable and complete remedy for an 
    anticompetitive horizontal overlap. The weakness of the Commission's 
    case seems to be the only impediment to imposing that remedy here.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \30\ Order para. V.
        \31\ Although the proposed order would permit any bundling that 
    Time Warner or Turner could have implemented independently before 
    the merger, the reason for this distinction appears unrelated to 
    distinguishing between pro- and anti-competitive bundling.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Vertical Theories
        The complaint also alleges two vertical theories of competitive 
    harm. The first is foreclosure of unaffiliated programming from Time 
    Warner and TCI cable systems.32 The second is anticompetitive 
    price discrimination against competing MVPDs in the sale of cable 
    programming.33 Neither of these alleged outcomes appears 
    particularly likely.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \32\ Complaint para. 38b.
        \33\ Complaint para. 38c.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Foreclosure
        Time Warner cannot foreclose the programming market by refusing 
    carriage on its cable system, because Time Warner has less than 20% of 
    cable subscribers in the United States. Even if TCI were willing to 
    join in an attempt to barricade programming produced by others from 
    distribution, TCI and Time Warner together control less than 50% of the 
    cable subscribers in the country. In that case, entry of programming 
    via cable might be more expensive (because of the costs of obtaining 
    carriage on a number of smaller systems), but it need not be 
    foreclosed. And even if Time Warner and TCI together controlled a 
    greater share of cable systems, the availability of alternative 
    distributors of video programming and the technological advances that 
    are expanding cable channel capacity make foreclosure as a result of 
    this transaction improbable.
        The foreclosure theory also is inconsistent with the incentives of 
    the market. Cable system operators want more and better programming, to 
    woo and win subscribers. To support their cable systems, Time Warner 
    and TCI must satisfy their subscribers by providing programming that 
    subscribers want at reasonable prices. Given competing distributors and 
    expanding channel capacity, neither of them likely would find it 
    profitable to attempt to exclude new programming.
        TCI as a shareholder of Time Warner, as the transaction has been 
    proposed to us (with a minority share of less than 10%), would have no 
    greater incentive than it had as a 23% shareholder of Turner to protect 
    Turner programming from competitive entry. Indeed, TCI's incentive to 
    protect Turner programming would appear to be diminished.34 If 
    TCI's interest in Time Warner increased, it stands to reason that TCI's 
    interest in the well-being of the Turner networks also would increase. 
    But it is important to remember that TCI's principal source of income 
    is its cable operations, and its share of Time Warner profits from 
    Turner programming would be insufficient incentive for TCI to 
    jeopardize its cable business.35 It may be that TCI could acquire 
    an interest in Time Warner that could have anticompetitive 
    consequences, but the Commission should analyze that transaction when 
    and if TCI increases its holdings. The divestiture requirement imposed 
    by the order 36 is not warranted at this time.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \34\ Turner programming would account for only part of TCI's 
    interest in Time Warner.
        \35\ Even if its share of Time Warner were increased to 18%, 
    TCI's interest in the combined Time Warner/Turner cash flow would be 
    only slightly greater than TCI's pre-transaction interest in Turner 
    cash flow, and it would still amount to only an insignificant 
    fraction of the cash flow generated by TCI's cable operations.
        \36\ Order Paras. II & III.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Another aspect of the foreclosure theory alleged in the complaint 
    is a carriage agreement (programming service agreement or PSA) between 
    TCI and Turner. Under the PSA, TCI would carry certain Turner networks 
    for twenty years, at a discount from the average price at which Time 
    Warner sells the Turner networks to other cable operators. The 
    complaint alleges that TCI's obligations under the PSA would diminish 
    its incentives and ability to carry programming that competes with 
    Turner programming,37 which in turn would raise barriers to entry 
    for unaffiliated programming. The increased difficulty of entry, so the 
    theory goes, would in turn enable Time Warner to raise the price of 
    Turner programming sold to cable operators and other MVPDs. It is hard 
    to see that the PSA would have anticompetitive effects. TCI already has 
    contracts with Turner that provide for mandatory carriage of CNN and 
    TNT, and TCI is likely to continue to carry these programming networks 
    for the foreseeable future.38 The current agreements do not raise 
    antitrust issues, and the PSA raises no new ones. Any theoretical 
    bottleneck on existing systems would be even further removed by the 
    time the carriage requirements under the PSA would have become 
    effective (when existing carriage commitments expire), because 
    technological changes will have expanded cable channel capacity and 
    alternative MVPDs will have expanded their subscribership. The PSA 
    could even give TCI incentives to encourage the entry of new 
    programming to compete with Time Warner's programming and keep TCI's 
    costs down.39 The PSA would have afforded Time Warner long term 
    carriage for the Turner networks, given TCI long term programming 
    commitments with some price protection, and eliminated the costs of 
    renegotiating a number of existing Turner/TCI carriage agreements as 
    they expire. These are efficiencies. No compelling reason has been
    
    [[Page 50317]]
    
    advanced for requiring that the carriage agreement be cancelled.40
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \37\ Complaint para. 38b(2).
        \38\ Cable system operators like to keep their subscribers 
    happy, and subscribers do not like to have popular programming 
    cancelled.
        \39\ Under the ``industry average price'' provision of the PSA, 
    Time Warner could raise price to TCI by increasing the price it 
    charges other MVPDs. TCI could encourage entry to defeat any attempt 
    by Time Warner to increase price.
        \40\ See Order para. IV. There would appear to be even less 
    justification for cancelling the PSA after ECI has been required 
    either to divest or to cap its shareholdings in Time Warner.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In addition to divestiture by TCI of its Time Warner shares and 
    cancellation of the TCI/Turner carriage agreement, the proposed 
    remedies for the alleged foreclosure include: (1) Antidiscrimination 
    provisions by which Time Warner must abide in dealing with program 
    providers; 41 (2) recordkeeping requirements to police compliance 
    with the antidiscrimination provision; 42 and (3) a requirement 
    that Time Warner carry ``at least one Independent Advertising-Supported 
    News and Information National Video Programming Service.'' 43 
    These remedial provisions are unnecessary, and they may be harmful.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \41\ Order para. VII.
        \42\ Order para. VIII.
        \43\ Order para. IX.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Paragraph VII of the proposed order, the antidiscrimination 
    provision, seeks to protect unaffiliated programming vendors from 
    exploitation and discrimination by Time Warner. The order provision is 
    taken almost verbatim from a regulation of the Federal Communications 
    Commission.44 It is highly unusual, to say the least, for an order 
    of the FTC to require compliance with a law enforced by another federal 
    agency, and it is unclear what expertise we might bring to the process 
    of assuring such compliance. Although a requirement to obey existing 
    law and FCC regulations may not appear to burden Time Warner unduly, 
    the additional burden of complying with the FTC order may be costly for 
    both Time Warner and the FTC. In addition to imposing extensive 
    recordkeeping requirements,45 the order apparently would create 
    another forum for unhappy programmers, who could seek to instigate an 
    FTC investigation of Time Warner's compliance with the order, instead 
    of or in addition to citing the same conduct in a complaint filed with 
    and adjudicated by the FCC.46 The burden of attempting to enforce 
    compliance with FCC regulations is one that this agency need not and 
    should not assume.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \44\ See 47 CFR 76.1301(a)-(c).
        \45\ The recordkeeping requirement may simply replicate an FCC 
    requirement and perhaps impose no additional costs on Time Warner.
        \46\ See 47 CFR 76.1302. The FCC may mandate carriage and impose 
    prices, terms and other conditions of carriage.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Paragraph IX of the proposed order requires Time Warner to carry an 
    independent all-news channel (presumably MS/NBC or the anticipated Fox 
    all-news channel). This requirement is entirely unwarranted. A duty to 
    deal might be appropriate on a sufficient showing if Time Warner were a 
    monopolist. But with less than 20% of cable subscribers in the United 
    States, Time Warner is neither a monopolist nor an ``essential 
    facility'' in cable distribution.47 CNN, the apparent target of 
    the FTC-sponsored entry, also is not a monopolist but is one of many 
    cable programming services in the all-programming market alleged in the 
    complaint. Clearly, CNN also is one of many sources of news and 
    information readily available to the public, although this is not a 
    market alleged in the complaint. Antitrust law, properly applied, 
    provides no justification whatsoever for the government to help 
    establish a competitor for CNN. Nor is there any apparent reason, other 
    than the circular reason that it would be helpful to them, why 
    Microsoft, NBC, or Rupert Murdoch's Fox needs a helping hand from the 
    FTC in their new programming endeavors. CNN and other program networks 
    did not obtain carriage mandated by the FTC when they launched; why 
    should the Commission now tilt the playing field in favor of other 
    entrants?
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \47\ Even in New York City, undoubtedly an important media 
    market, available data indicate that Time Warner apparently serves 
    only about one-quarter of cable households. See Cablevision, May 13, 
    1996, at 57; April 29, 1996, at 131 (Time Warner has about 1.1 
    million subscribers in New York, which has about 4.5 million cable 
    households). We do not have data about alternative MVPD subscribers 
    in the New York area.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Price Discrimination
        The complaint alleges that Time Warner could discriminatory raise 
    the prices of programming services to its MVPD rivals,48 
    presumably to protect its cable operations from competition. This 
    theory assumes that Time Warner has market power in the all-cable 
    programming market. As discussed above, however, there are reasons to 
    think that the alleged all-cable programming market would not be 
    sustained, and entry into cable programming is widespread and, because 
    of the volume of entry, immediate. Under those circumstances, it 
    appears not only not likely but virtually inconceivable that Time 
    Warner could sustain any attempt to exercise market power in the all-
    cable programming market.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \48\ Complaint para. 38c.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Whatever the merits of the theory in this case, however, 
    discrimination against competing MVPDs in price or other terms of sale 
    of programming is prohibited by federal statute 49 and by FCC 
    regulations,50 and the FCC provides a forum to adjudicate 
    complaints of this nature. Unfortunately, the majority is not content 
    to leave policing of telecommunications to the FCC.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \49\ 47 U.S.C.A. 548.
        \50\ CFR 76.1000-76.1002.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Paragraph VI of the proposed order addresses the alleged violation 
    in the following way: (1) It requires Time Warner to provide Turner 
    programming to competing MVPDs on request; and (2) it establishes a 
    formula for determining the prices that Time Warner can charge MVPDs 
    for Turner programming in areas in which Time Warner cable systems and 
    the MVPDs compete. The provision is inconsistent with two antitrust 
    principles: Antitrust traditionally does not impose a duty to deal 
    absent monopoly, which does not exist here, and antitrust traditionally 
    has not viewed price regulation as an appropriate remedy for market 
    power. Indeed, price regulation usually is seen as antithetical to 
    antitrust.
        Although Paragraph VI ostensibly has the same nondiscrimination 
    goal as federal telecommunications law and FCC regulations, the bright 
    line standard in the proposed order for determining a nondiscriminatory 
    price fails to take account of the circumstances Congress has 
    identified in which price differences could be justified, such as, for 
    example, cost differences, economies of scale or ``other direct and 
    legitimate economic benefits reasonably attributable to the number of 
    subscribers serviced by the distributor.'' 51 These are 
    significant omissions, particularly for an agency that has taken pride 
    in its mission to prevent unfair methods of competition. There is no 
    apparent reason or authority for creating this exception to a 
    congressional mandate. To the extent that the proposed order creates a 
    regulatory scheme different from that afforded by the FCC, disgruntled 
    MVPDs may find it to their advantage to seek sanctions against Time 
    Warner at the FTC.52 This is likely to be costly for the FTC and 
    for Time Warner, and the differential scheme of regulation also could 
    impose other, unforeseen costs on the industry.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \51\ U.S.C.A. 548(c)(B)(i)-(iii)
        \52\ Most people outside the FTC and the FCC already confuse the 
    two agencies. Surely we do not want to contribute to this confusion.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    Efficiencies
        As far as I can tell, the proposed consent order entirely ignores 
    the likely efficiencies of the proposed transaction. The potential 
    vertical efficiencies include more and better programming options for 
    consumers and reduced transaction costs for the merging firms.
    
    [[Page 50318]]
    
    The potential horizontal efficiencies include savings from the 
    integration of overlapping operations and of film and animation 
    libraries. For many years, the Commission has devoted considerable time 
    and effort to identifying and evaluating efficiencies that may result 
    from proposed mergers and acquisitions. Although cognizable 
    efficiencies occur less frequently than one might expect, the 
    Commission has not stinted in its efforts to give every possible 
    consideration to efficiencies. That makes the apparent disinterest in 
    the potential efficiencies of this transaction decidedly odd.
    Industry Complaints
        We have heard many expressions of concern about the proposed 
    transaction. Cable system operators and alternative MVPDs have been 
    concerned about the price and availability of programming from Time 
    Warner after the acquisition. Program providers have been concerned 
    about access to Time Warner's cable system. These are understandable 
    concerns, and I am sympathetic to them. To the extent that these 
    industry members want assured supply or access and protected prices, 
    however, this is the wrong agency to help them. Because Time Warner 
    cannot foreclose either level of service and is neither a monopolist 
    nor an ``essential facility'' in the programming market or in cable 
    services, there would appear to be no basis in antitrust for the access 
    requirements imposed in the order.
        The Federal Communications Commission is the agency charged by 
    Congress with regulating the telecommunications industry, and the FCC 
    already has rules in place prohibiting discriminatory prices and 
    practices. While there may be little harm in requiring Time Warner to 
    comply with communications law, there also is little justification for 
    this agency to undertake the task. To the extent that the proposed 
    consent order offers a standard different from that promulgated by 
    Congress and the FCC, it arguably is inconsistent with the will of 
    Congress. To the extent that the proposed consent order would offer a 
    more attractive remedy for complaints from disfavored competitors and 
    customers of Time Warner, they are more likely to turn to us than to 
    the FCC. There is much to be said for having the FTC confine itself to 
    FTC matters, leaving FCC matters to the FCC.
        The proposed order should be rejected.
    
    Dissenting Statement of Commissioner Roscoe B. Starek, III, in the 
    Matter of Time Warner Inc., et al. File No. 961-0004
    
        I respectfully dissent from the Commission's decision to accept a 
    consent agreement with Time Warner Inc. (``TW''), Turner Broadcasting 
    System, Inc. (``TBS''), Tele-Communications, Inc. (``TCI''), and 
    Liberty Media Corporation. The proposed complaint against these 
    producers and distributors of cable television programming alleges 
    anticompetitive effects arising from (1) The horizontal integration of 
    the programming interests of TW and TBS and (2) the vertical 
    integration of the TBS's programming interests with TW's and TCI's 
    distribution interests. I am not persuaded that either the horizontal 
    or the vertical aspects of this transaction are likely ``substantially 
    to lessen competition'' in violation of Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 
    15 U.S.C. 18, or otherwise to constitute ``unfair methods of 
    competition'' in violation of Section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission 
    Act, 15 U.S.C. 45. Moreover, even if one were to assume the validity of 
    one or more theories of violation underlying this action, the proposed 
    order does not appear to prevent the alleged effects and may instead 
    create inefficiency.
    Horizontal Theories of Competitive Harm
        This transaction involves, inter alia, the combination of TW and 
    TBS, two major suppliers of programming to multichannel video program 
    distributors (``MVPDs''). Accordingly, there is a straightforward 
    theory of competitive harm that merits serious consideration by the 
    Commission. In its most general terms, the theory is that cable 
    operators regard TW programs as close substitutes for TBS programs. 
    Therefore, the theory says, TW and TBS act as premerger constraints on 
    each other's ability to raise program prices. Under this hypothesis, 
    the merger eliminates this constraint, allowing TW--either unilaterally 
    or in coordination with other program vendors--to raise prices on some 
    or all of its programs.
        Of course, this story is essentially an illustration of the 
    standard theory of competitive harm set forth in Section 2 of the 1992 
    Horizontal Merger Guidelines.1 Were an investigation pursuant to 
    this theory to yield convincing evidence that it applies to the current 
    transaction, under most circumstances the Commission would seek 
    injunctive relief to prevent the consolidation of the assets in 
    question. The Commission has eschewed that course of action, however, 
    choosing instead a very different sort of ``remedy'' that allows the 
    parties to proceed with the transaction but restricts them from 
    engaging in some (but not all) ``bundled'' sales of programming to 
    unaffiliated cable operators.2 Clearly, this choice of relief 
    implies an unusual theory of competitive harm from what ostensibly is a 
    straightforward horizontal transaction. The Commission's remedy does 
    nothing to prevent the most obvious manifestation of postmerger market 
    power--an across-the-board price increase for TW and TBS programs. Why 
    has the Commission forgone its customary relief directed against its 
    conventional theory of harm?
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \1\ U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission, 
    Horizontal Merger Guidelines, Sec. 2 (1992), 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) 
    para. 13,104 at 20,573-6 et seq.
        \2\ In the Analysis of Proposed consent Order to Aid Public 
    Comment (Sec. IV.C), the Commission asserts that ``the easiest way 
    the combined firm could exert substantially greater negotiating 
    leverage over cable operators is by combining all or some of such 
    `marquee' services and offering them as a package or offering them 
    along with unwanted programming.'' As I note below, it is far from 
    obvious why this bundling strategy represents the ``easiest'' way to 
    exercise market power against cable operators. The easiest way to 
    exercise any newly-created market power would be simply to announce 
    higher programming prices.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The plain answer is that there is little persuasive evidence that 
    TW's programs constrain those of TBS (or vice-versa) in the fashion 
    described above. In a typical FTC horizontal merger enforcement action, 
    the Commission relies heavily on documentary evidence establishing the 
    substitutability of the parties' products or services.3 For 
    example, it is
    
    [[Page 50319]]
    
    standard to study the parties' internal documents to determine which 
    producers they regard as their closest competitors. This assessment 
    also depends frequently on internal documents supplied by customers 
    that show them playing off one supplier against another--via credible 
    threats of supplier termination--in an effort to obtain lower prices.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \3\ The Merger Guidelines emphasize the importance of such 
    evidence. Section 1.11 specifically identifies the following two 
    types of evidence as particularly informative: ``(1) Evidence that 
    buyers have shifted or have considered shifting purchases between 
    products in response to relative changes in price or other 
    competitive variables [and] (2) evidence that sellers base business 
    decisions on the prospect of buyer substitution between products in 
    response to relative changes in price or other competitive 
    variables.''
        To illustrate, in Coca-Cola Bottling Co. of the Southwest, 
    Docket No. 9215, complaint counsel argued in favor of a narrow 
    product market consisting of ``all branded carbonated soft drinks'' 
    (``CSDs''), while respondent argued for a much broader market. In 
    determining that all branded CSDs constituted the relevant market, 
    the Commission place great weight on internal documents from local 
    bottlers of branded CSDs showing that those bottlers ``[took] into 
    account only the prices of other branded CSD products [and not the 
    prices of private label or warehouse-delivered soft drinks] in 
    deciding on pricing for their own branded CSD products.'' 5 Trade 
    Reg. Rep. (CCH) para.23,681 at 23,413 (Aug. 31, 1994), vacated and 
    remanded on other grounds, Coca-Cola Bottling Co. of the Southwest 
    v. FTC, No. 94-41224 (5th Cir., June 10, 1996). (The Commission 
    dismissed its complaint on September 6, 1996.)
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In this matter, however, documents of this sort are conspicuous by 
    their absence. Notwithstanding a voluminous submission of materials 
    from the respondents and third parties (and the considerable incentives 
    of the latter--especially other cable operators--to supply the 
    Commission with such documents), there are no documents that reveal 
    cable operators threatening to drop a TBS ``marquee'' network (e.g., 
    CNN) in favor of a TW ``marquee'' network (e.g., HBO). There also are 
    no documents from, for instance, TW suggesting that it sets the prices 
    of its ``marquee'' networks in reference to those of TBS, taking into 
    account the latter's likely competitive response to unilateral price 
    increases or decreases. Rather, the evidence supporting any prediction 
    of a postmerger price increase consists entirely of customers' 
    contentions that program prices would rise following the acquisition. 
    Although customers' opinions on the potential effects of a transaction 
    often are important, they seldom are dispositive. Typically the 
    Commission requires substantial corroboration of these opinions from 
    independent information sources.4
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \4\ For example, in R.R. Donnelley Sons & Co., et al., Docket 
    No. 9243, the Administrative Law Judge's decision favoring complaint 
    counsel rested in part on his finding that ``[a]s soon as the 
    Meredith/Burda acquisition was announced, customers expressed 
    concern to the FTC and the parties about the decrease in competition 
    that might result.'' (Initial Decision Finding 404.) In overturning 
    the ALJ's decision, the Commission cautioned: ``There is some danger 
    in relying on these customer complaints to draw any general 
    conclusions about the likely effects of the acquisition or about the 
    analytical premises for those conclusions. The complaints are 
    consistent with a variety of effects, and many--including those the 
    ALJ relied upon--directly contradict [c]omplaint [c]ounsel's 
    prediction of unilateral price elevation.'' 5 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) 
    para.23,876 at 23,660 n. 189 (July 21, 1995).
        Also, in several instances involving hospital mergers in 
    concentrated markets, legions of third parties came forth to attest 
    to the transaction's efficiency. The Commission has discounted this 
    testimony, however, when these third parties could not articulate or 
    document the source of the claimed efficiency, or when the testimony 
    lacked corroboration from independent information sources. I believe 
    that the Commission should apply the same evidentiary standards to 
    the third-party testimony in the current matter.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Independent validation of the anticompetitive hypothesis becomes 
    particularly important when key elements of the story lack credibility. 
    For a standard horizontal theory of harm to apply here, one key element 
    is that, prior to the acquisition, a MVPD could credibly threaten to 
    drop a marquee network (e.g., CNN), provided it had access to another 
    programmer's marquee network (e.g., HBO) that it could offer to 
    potential subscribers. This threat would place the MVPD in a position 
    to negotiate a better price for the marquee networks than if those 
    networks were jointly owned.
        Here, the empirical evidence gathered during the investigation 
    reveals that such threats would completely lack credibility. Indeed, 
    there appears to be little, if any, evidence that such threats ever 
    have been made, let alone carried out. CNN and HBO are not substitutes, 
    and both are carried on virtually all cable systems nationwide. If, as 
    a conventional horizontal theory of harm requires, these program 
    services are truly substitutes--if MVPDs regularly play one off against 
    the other, credibly threatening to drop one in favor of another--then 
    why are there virtually no instances in which an MVPD has carried out 
    this threat by dropping one of the marquee services? The absence of 
    this behavior by MVPDs undermines the empirical basis for the asserted 
    degree of substitutability between the two program services.5
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \5\ In virtually any case involving less pressure to come up 
    with something to show for the agency's strenuous investigative 
    efforts, the absence of such evidence would lead the Commission to 
    reject a hypothesized product market that included both marquee 
    services. Suppose that two producers of product A proposed to merge 
    and sought to persuade the Commission that the relevant market also 
    included product B, but they could not provide any examples of 
    actual substitution of B for A, or any evidence that threats of 
    substitution of B for A actually elicited price reductions from 
    sellers of A. In the usual run of cases, this lack of 
    substitutability would almost surely lead the Commission to reject 
    the expanded market definition. But not so here.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Faced with this pronounced lack of evidence to support a 
    conventional market power story and a conventional remedy, the 
    Commission has sought refuge in what appears to be a very different 
    theory of postmerger competitive behavior. This theory posits an 
    increased likelihood of program ``bundling'' as a consequence of the 
    transaction.6 But there are two major problems with this theory as 
    a basis for an enforcement action. First, there is no strong 
    theoretical or empirical basis for believing that an increase in 
    bundling of TW and TBS programming would occur postmerger. Second, even 
    if such bundling did occur, there is no particular reason to think that 
    it would be competitively harmful.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \6\ As I noted earlier, a remedy that does nothing more than 
    prevent ``bundling'' of different programs would fail completely to 
    prevent the manifestations of market power--such as across-the-board 
    price increases--most consistent with conventional horizontal 
    theories of competitive harm.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Given the lack of documentary evidence to show that TW intends to 
    bundle its programming with that of TBS, I do not understand why the 
    majority considers an increase in program bundling to be a likely 
    feature of the postmerger equilibrium, nor does economic theory supply 
    a compelling basis for this prediction. Indeed, the rationale for this 
    element of the case (as set forth in the Analysis to Aid Public 
    Comment) can be described charitably as ``incomplete.'' According to 
    the Analysis, unless the FTC prevents it, TW would undertake a bundling 
    strategy in part to foist ``unwanted programming'' upon cable 
    operators.7 Missing from the Analysis, however, is any sensible 
    explanation of why TW should wish to pursue this strategy, because the 
    incentives to do so are not obvious.8
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \7\ As I have noted, supra n. 2, the Analysis also claims that 
    TW could obtain ``substantially greater negotiating leverage over 
    cable operator * * * by combining all or some of [the merged firm's] 
    `marquee' services and offering them as a package * * *'' If the 
    Analysis uses the term ``negotiating leverage'' to mean ``market 
    power'' as the latter is conventionally defined, then it confronts 
    three difficulties: (1) The record fails to support the proposition 
    that the TW and TBS ``marquee'' channels are close substitutes for 
    each other; (2) even assuming that those channels are close 
    substitutes, there are more straightforward ways for TW to exercise 
    postmerger market power; and (3) the remedy does nothing to prevent 
    these more straightforward exercises of market power. See discussion 
    supra.
        \8\ In ``A Note on Block Booking'' in The Organization of 
    Industry (1968), George Stigler analyzed the practice of ``block 
    booking''--or, in current parlance, ``bundling''--``marquee'' motion 
    pictures with considerably less popular films. Some years earlier, 
    the United States Supreme Court had struck this practice down as an 
    anticompetitive ``leveraging'' of market power from desirable to 
    undesirable films. United States v. Loew's Inc., 371 U.S. 38 (1962). 
    As Stigler explained (at 165), it is not obvious why distributors 
    should wish to force exhibitors to take the inferior film:
        Consider the following simple example. One film, Justice 
    Goldberg cited Gone with the Wind, is worth $10,000 to the buyer, 
    while a second film, the Justice cited Getting Gertie's Garter, is 
    worthless to him. The seller could sell the one for $10,000, and 
    throw away the second, for no matter what its cost, bygones are 
    forever bygones. Instead the seller compels the buyer to take both. 
    But surely he can obtain no more than $10,000, since by hypothesis 
    this is the value of both films to the buyer. Why not, in short, use 
    his monopoly power directly on the desirable film? It seems no more 
    sensible, on this logic, to block book the two films than it would 
    be to compel the exhibitor to buy Gone with the Wind and seven Ouija 
    boards, again for $10,000.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        A possible anticompetitive rationale for ``bundling'' might run as 
    follows: by requiring cable operators to purchase a bundle of TW and 
    TBS programs that contains substantial amounts of ``unwanted'' 
    programming, TW can tie
    
    [[Page 50320]]
    
    up scarce channel capacity and make entry by new programmers more 
    difficult. But even if that strategy were assumed arguendo to be 
    profitable,9 the order would have only a trivial impact on TW's 
    ability to pursue it. The order prohibits only the bundling of TW 
    programming with TBS programming; TW remains free under the order to 
    create new ``bundles'' comprising exclusively TW, or exclusively TBS, 
    programs. Given that many TW and TBS programs are now sold on an 
    unbundled basis--a fact that calls into question the likelihood of 
    increased postmerger bundling 10--and given that, under the 
    majority's bundling theory, any TW or TBS programming can tie up a 
    cable channel and thereby displace a potential entrant's programming, 
    the order hardly would constrain TW's opportunities to carry out this 
    ``foreclosure'' strategy.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \9\ The argument here basically is a variant of the argument 
    often used to condemn exclusive dealing as a tool for monopolizing a 
    market. Under this argument, an upstream monopolist uses its market 
    power to obtain exclusive distribution rights from its distributors, 
    thereby foreclosing potential manufacturing entrants and obtaining 
    additional market power. But there is problem with this argument, as 
    Bork explains in The Antitrust Paradox (1978):
        [The monopolist can extract in the prices it charges retailers 
    all that the uniqueness of its line is worth. It cannot charge the 
    retailers that full worth in money and then charge it again in 
    exclusively the retailer does not wish to grant. To suppose that it 
    can is to commit the error of double counting. If [the firm] must 
    forgo the higher prices it could have demanded in order to get 
    exclusivity, then exclusivity is not an imposition, it is a 
    purchase. Id. at 306; see also id. at 140-43.
        Although modern economic theory has established the theoretical 
    possibility that a monopolist might, under very specific 
    circumstances, outbid an entrant for the resources that would allow 
    entry to occur (thus preserving the monopoly), modern theory also 
    has shown that this is not a generally applicable result. It breaks 
    down, for example, when (as is likely in MVPD markets) many units of 
    new capacity are likely to become available sequentially. See, e.g., 
    Krishna, ``Auctions with Endogenous Valuations: The Persistence of 
    Monopoly Revisited,'' 83 Am. Econ. Rev. 147 (1993); Malueg and 
    Schwartz, ``Preemptive investment, toehold entry, and the mimicking 
    principle,'' 22  RAND J. Econ. 1 (1991).
        \10\ If bundling is profitable for anticompetitive reasons, why 
    do we not observe TW and TBS now exploiting all available 
    opportunities to reap these profits?
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Finally, all of the above analysis implicitly assumes that the 
    bundling of TW and TBS programming, if undertaken, would more likely 
    than not be anticompetitive. The Analysis to Aid Public Comment, 
    however, emphasizes that bundling programming in many other instances 
    can be procompetitive. There seems to be no explanation of why the 
    particular bundles at issue here would be anticompetitive, and no 
    articulation of the principles that might be used to differentiate 
    welfare-enhancing from welfare-reducing bundling.11
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \11\ Perhaps this reflects the fact that the economics 
    literature does not provide clear guidance on this issue. See, e.g., 
    Adams and Yellen, ``Commodity Bundling and the Burden of Monopoly,'' 
    90 Q.J. Econ. 475 (1976). Adams and Yellen explain how a monopolist 
    might use bundling as a method of price discrimination. (This also 
    was Stigler's explanation, supra n. 8.) As Adams and Yellen note, 
    ``public policy must take account of the fact that prohibition of 
    commodity bundling without more may increase the burden of monopoly 
    * * * [M]onopoly itself must be eliminated to achieve high levels of 
    social welfare.'' 90 Q.J. Econ. at 498. Adams and Yellen's 
    conclusion is apposite here: if the combination of TW and TBS 
    creates (or enhances) market power, then the solution is to enjoin 
    the transaction rather than to proscribe certain types of bundling, 
    since the latter ``remedy'' may actually make things worse. And if 
    the acquisition does not create or enhance market power, the basis 
    for the bundling proscription is even harder to discern.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Thus, I am neither convinced that increased program bundling is a 
    likely consequence of this transaction nor persuaded that any such 
    bundling would be anticompetitive. Were I convinced that 
    anticompetitive bundling is a likely consequence of this transaction, I 
    would find the proposed remedy inadequate.
    Vertical Theories of Competitive Harm
        The proposed consent order also contains a number of provisions 
    designed to alleviate competitive harm purportedly arising from the 
    increased degree of vertical integration between program suppliers and 
    program distributors brought about by this transaction.12 I have 
    previously expressed my skepticism about enforcement actions predicated 
    on theories of harm from vertical relationships.13 The current 
    complaint and proposed order only serve to reinforce my doubts about 
    such enforcement actions and about remedies ostensibly designed to 
    address the alleged competitive harms.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \12\ Among other things, the order (1) constrains the ability of 
    TW and TCI to enter into long-term carriage agreements (para. IV); 
    (2) compels TW to sell Turner programming to downstream MVPD 
    entrants at regulated prices (para. VI); (3) prohibits TW from 
    unreasonably discriminating against non-TW programmers seeking 
    carriage on TW cable systems (para. VII(C)); and (4) compels TW to 
    carry a second 24-hour news service (i.e., in addition to CNN) 
    (para. IX).
        \13\ Dissenting Statement of Commissioner Roscoe B. Starek, III, 
    in Waterous Company, Inc./Hale Products, Inc., File No. 901 0061, 5 
    Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) para. 24,076 at 23,888-90; Dissenting 
    Statement of Commissioner Roscoe B. Starek, III, in Silicon 
    Graphics, Inc. (Alias Research, Inc., and Wavefront Technologies, 
    Inc.), Docket No. C-3626 (Nov. 14, 1995), 61 Fed. Reg. 16797 (Apr. 
    17, 1996); Remarks of Commissioner Roscoe B. Starek, III. 
    ``Reinventing Antitrust Enforcement? Antitrust at the FTC in 1995 
    and Beyond,'' remarks before a conference on ``A New Age of 
    Antitrust Enforcement: Antitrust in 1995'' (Marina Del Rey, 
    California, Feb. 24, 1995) [available on the Commission's World Wide 
    Web site at http://www.ftc.gov].
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The vertical theories of competitive harm posited in this matter, 
    and the associated remedies, are strikingly similar to those to which I 
    objected in Silicon Graphics, Inc. (``SGI''), and the same essential 
    criticisms apply. In SGI, the Commission's complaint alleged 
    anticompetitive effects arising from the vertical integration of SGI--
    the leading manufacturer of entertainment graphics workstations--with 
    Alias Research, Inc., and Wavefront Technologies, Inc.--two leading 
    suppliers of entertainment graphics software. Although the acquisition 
    seemingly raised straightforward horizontal competitive problems 
    arising from the combination of Alias and Wavefront, the Commission 
    inexplicably found that the horizontal consolidation was not 
    anticompetitive on net.14 Instead, the order addressed only the 
    alleged vertical problems arising from the transaction. The Commission 
    alleged, inter alia, that the acquisitions in SGI would reduce 
    competition through two types of foreclosure: (1) Nonintegrated 
    software vendors would be excluded from the SGI platform, thereby 
    inducing their exit (or deterring their entry); and (2) rival hardware 
    manufacturers would be denied access to Alias and Wavefront software, 
    without which they could not effectively compete against SGI. 
    Similarly, in this case the Commission alleges (1) that nonintegrated 
    program vendors will be excluded from TW and TCI cable systems and (2) 
    that potential MVPD entrants into TW's cable markets will be denied 
    access to (or face supracompetitive prices for) TW and TBS 
    programming--thus lessening their ability to effectively compete 
    against TW's cable operations. The complaint further charges that the 
    exclusion of nonintegrated program vendors from TW's and TCI's cable 
    systems will deprive those vendors of scale economies, render them 
    ineffective competitors vis-a-vis the TW/Turner programming services, 
    and thus confer market power on TW as a seller of programs to MVPDs in 
    non-TW/non-TCI markets.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \14\ I say ``inexplicably'' not because I necessarily believed 
    this horizontal combination should have been enjoined, but because 
    the horizontal aspect of the transaction would have exacerbated the 
    upstream market power that would have had to exist for the vertical 
    theories to have had any possible relevance.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        My dissenting statement in SGI identified the problems with this 
    kind of analysis. For one thing, these two types of foreclosure--
    foreclosure of independent program vendors from the TW and TCI cable 
    systems, and foreclosure of independent MVPD firms from TW and TBS 
    programming--tend
    
    [[Page 50321]]
    
    to be mutually exclusive. The very possibility of excluding independent 
    program vendors from TW and TCI cable systems suggests the means by 
    which MVPDs other than TW and TCI can avoid foreclosure. The 
    nonintegrated program vendors surely have incentives to supply the 
    ``foreclosed'' MVPDs, and each MVPD has incentives to induce 
    nonintegrated program suppliers to produce programming for it.15
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \15\ Moreover, as was also true in SGI, the proposed complaint 
    in the present case characterizes premerger entry conditions in a 
    way that appears to rule out significant anticompetitive foreclosure 
    of nonintegrated upstream producers as a consequence of the 
    transaction. Paragraphs 33, 34, and 36 of the complaint allege in 
    essence that there are few producters of ``marquee'' programming 
    before the merger (other than TW and TBS), in large part because 
    entry into ``marquee'' programming is so very difficult (stemming 
    form, e.g., the substantial irreversible investments that are 
    required). If that is true--i.e., if the posited programming market 
    already was effectively foreclosed before the merger--then, as in 
    SGI, TW's acquistion of TBS could not cause substantial postmerger 
    foreclosure of competitively significant alternatives to TW/TBS 
    programming.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        In response to this criticism, one might argue--and the complaint 
    alleges 16--that pervasive scale economies in programming, 
    combined with a failure to obtain carriage on the TW and TCI systems, 
    would doom potential programming entrants (and ``foreclosed'' incumbent 
    programmers) because, without TW and/or TCI carriage, they would be 
    deprived of the scale economies essential to their survival. In other 
    words, the argument goes, the competitive responses of ``foreclosed'' 
    programmers and ``foreclosed'' distributors identified in the preceding 
    paragraph never will materialize. There are, however, substantial 
    conceptual and empirical problems with this argument, and its 
    implications for competition policy have not been fully explored.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \16\ See Paragraph 38.b of the proposed complaint.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        First, if one believes that programming is characterized by such 
    substantial scale economies that the loss of one large customer results 
    in the affected programmer's severely diminished competitive 
    effectiveness (in the limit, that programmer's exit), then this 
    essentially is an argument that the number of program producers that 
    can survive in equilibrium (or, perhaps more accurately, the number of 
    program producers in a particular program ``niche'') will be small--
    with perhaps only one survivor. Under the theory of the current case, 
    this will result in a supracompetitive price for that program. Further, 
    this will occur irrespective of the degree of vertical integration 
    between programmers and distributors. Indeed, under these 
    circumstances, there is a straightforward reason why vertical 
    integration between a program distributor and a program producer would 
    be both profitable and procompetitive (i.e., likely to result in lower 
    prices to consumers): Instead of monopoly markups by both the program 
    producer and the MVPD, there would be only one markup by the vertically 
    integrated firm.17
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \17\ See, e.g., Tirole, The Theory of Industrial Organization 
    174-76 (1988). The program price reductions would be observed only 
    in those geographic markets where TW owned cable systems. Thus, the 
    greater the number of cable subscribers served by TW, the more 
    widespread would be the efficiencies. According to the proposed 
    complaint (para. 32), TW cable systems serve only 17 percent of 
    cable subscribers nationwide, so one might argue that the 
    efficiencies are accordingly limited. But this, of course, leaves 
    the Commission in the uncomfortable position of arguing that TW's 
    share of total cable subscribership is too small to yield 
    significant efficiencies, yet easily large enough to generate 
    substantial ``foreclosure'' effects.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Second, and perhaps more important, if the reasoning of the 
    complaint is carried to its logical conclusion, it constitutes a basis 
    for challenging any vertical integration by large cable operators or 
    large programmers--even if that vertical integration were to occur via 
    de novo entry by an operator into the programming market, or by de novo 
    entry by a programmer into distribution. Consider the following 
    hypothetical: A large MVPD announces both that it intends to enter a 
    particular program niche and that it plans to drop the incumbent 
    supplier of that type of programming. According to the theory 
    underlying the proposed complaint, the dropped program would suffer 
    substantially from lost scale economies, severely diminishing its 
    competitive effectiveness, which in turn would confer market power on 
    the vertically integrated entrant in its program sales to other MVPDs. 
    Were the Commission to apply its current theory of competitive harm 
    consistently, it evidently would have to find this de novo entry into 
    programming by this large MVPD competitively objectionable.
        I suspect, of course, that virtually no one would be comfortable 
    challenging such integration, since there is a general predisposition 
    to regard expansions of capacity as procompetitive.18 
    Consequently, one might attempt to reconcile the differential treatment 
    of the two forms of vertical integration by somehow distinguishing them 
    from each other.19 But in truth, the situations actually merit 
    similar treatment--albeit not the treatment prescribed by the proposed 
    order. In neither case should an enforcement action be brought, because 
    any welfare loss flowing from either scenario derives from the 
    structure of the upstream market, which in turn is determined primarily 
    by the size of the market and by technology, not by the degree of 
    vertical integration between different stages of production.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \18\ This would appear true especially when, as posited here, 
    there is substantial premerger market power upstream because, under 
    such circumstances, vertical integration is a means by which a 
    downstream firm can obtain lower input prices. As noted earlier 
    (supra n.17 and accompanying text), this integration can be 
    procompetitive whether it occurs via merger or internal expansion.
        \19\ One might attempt to differentiate my hypothetical from a 
    situation involving an MVPD's acquisition of a program supplier by 
    arguing that the former would yield two suppliers of the relevant 
    type of programming, but the latter only one. But this conclusion 
    would be incorrect. If we assume that the number of suppliers that 
    can survive in equilibrium is determined by the magnitude of scale 
    economies relative to the size of the market, and that the pre-entry 
    market structure represented an equilibrium, then the existence of 
    two program suppliers will be only a transitory phenomenon, and the 
    market will revert to the equilibrium structure dictated by these 
    technological considerations--that is, one supplier. Upstream 
    integration by the MVPD merely replaces one program monopolist with 
    another; but as noted above, under these circumstances vertical 
    integration can yield substantial efficiencies.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Third, it is far from clear that TCI's incentives to preclude entry 
    into programming are the same as TW's.20 As an MVPD, TCI is harmed 
    by the creation of entry barriers to new programming. Even if TW 
    supplies it with TW programming at a competitive price, TCI is still 
    harmed if program variety or innovation is diminished. On the other 
    hand, as a part owner of TW, TCI benefits if TW's programming earns 
    supracompetitive returns on sales to other MVPDs. TCI's net incentive 
    to sponsor new programming depends on which factor dominates--its 
    interest in program quality and innovation, or its interest in 
    supracompetitive returns on TW programming. All of the analyses of 
    which I am aware concerning this tradeoff show that TCI's ownership 
    interest in TW would have to increase substantially--far beyond what 
    the current transaction contemplates, or what would be possible without 
    a significant modification of TW's internal governance structure 
    21--for TCI to have an incentive to deter entry by independent 
    programmers. TCI's incentive to encourage programming
    
    [[Page 50322]]
    
    entry is intensified, moreover, by the fact that it has undertaken an 
    ambitious expansion program to digitize its system and increase 
    capacity to 200 channels. Because this appears to be a costly process, 
    and because not all cable customers can be expected to purchase digital 
    service, the cost per buyer--and thus the price--of digital services 
    will be fairly high. How can TCI expect to induce subscribers to buy 
    this expensive service if, through programming foreclosure, it has 
    restricted the quantity and quality of programming that would be 
    available on this service tier? 22
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \20\ Even TW has mixed incentives to preclude programming entry. 
    As a programmer allegedly in possession of market power, TW would 
    wish to deter programming entry to protect this market power. But as 
    a MVPD, TW--like any other MVPD--benefits from the creation of 
    valuable new programming servics that it can sell to its 
    subscribers. On net, however, it appears true that TW's incentives 
    balance in favor of wishing to prevent entry.
        \21\ TW has a ``poison pill'' provision that would make it 
    costly for TCI to increase its ownership of TW above 18 percent.
        \22\ Note too that there is an inverse relationship between 
    TCI's ability to prevent programming entry and its incentives to do 
    so. Much of the analysis in this case has emphasized that TCI's size 
    (27 percent of cable households) gives it considerably ability to 
    determine which programs succeed and which fail, and the logic of 
    the proposed complaint is that TCI will exercise this ability so as 
    to protect TW's market power in program sales to non-TCI MVPDs. But 
    although increases in TCI's size may increase its ability to 
    preclude entry into programming, at the same time such increases 
    reduce TCI's incentives to do so. The reasoning is simple: as the 
    size of the non-TW/non-TCI cable market shrinks, the 
    supracompetitive profits obtained from sales of programming to this 
    sector also shrink. Simultaneously, the harm from TCI (as a MVPD) 
    from precluding the entry of new programmers increases with TCI's 
    subscriber share. (In the limit--i.e., if TCI and TW controlled all 
    cable households--there would be non non-TW/non-TCI MVPDs, no sales 
    of programming to such MVPDs, and thus no profits to be obtained 
    from such sales.) Any future increases in TCI's subscriber share 
    would, other things held constant, reduce is incentives to 
    ``foreclose;'' entry by independent programmers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The foregoing illustrates why foreclosure theories fell into 
    intellectual disrepute: because of their inability to articulate how 
    vertical integration harms competition and not merely competitors. The 
    majority's analysis of the Program Service Agreement (``PSA'') 
    illustrates this perfectly. The PSA must be condemned, we are told, 
    because a TCI channel slot occupied by a TW program is a channel slot 
    that cannot be occupied by a rival programmer. As Bork noted, this is a 
    tautology, not a theory of competitive harm.23 It is a theory of 
    harm to competitors--competitors that cannot offer TCI inducements 
    (such as low prices) sufficient to cause TCI to patronize them rather 
    than TW.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \23\ /Bork, The Antitrust Paradox, supra n.9, at 304.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        All of the majority's vertical theories in this case ultimately can 
    be shown to be theories of harm to competitors, not to competition. 
    Thus, I have not been persuaded that the vertical aspects of this 
    transaction are likely to diminish competition substantially. Even were 
    I to conclude otherwise, however, I could not support the 
    extraordinarily regulatory remedy contained in the proposed order, two 
    of whose provisions merit special attention: (1) The requirement that 
    TW sell programming to MVPDs seeking to compete with TW cable systems 
    at a price determined by a formula contained in the order; and (2) the 
    requirement that TW carry at least one ``Independent Advertising-
    Supported News and Information National Video Programming Service.''
        Under Paragraph VI of the proposed order, TW must sell Turner 
    programming to potential entrants into TW cable markets at prices 
    determined by a ``most favored nation'' clause that gives the entrant 
    the same price--or, more precisely, the same ``carriage terms''--that 
    TW charges the three largest MVPDs currently carrying this programming. 
    As is well known, most favored nation clauses have the capacity to 
    cause all prices to rise rather than to fall.24 But even putting 
    this possibility aside, this provision of the order converts the 
    Commission into a de facto price regulator--a task, as I have noted on 
    several previous occasions, to which we are ill-suited.25 During 
    the investigation third parties repeatedly informed me of the 
    difficulty that the Federal Communications Commission has encountered 
    in attempting to enforce its nondiscrimination regulations. The FTC's 
    regulatory burden would be lighter only because, perversely, our 
    pricing formula would disallow any of the efficiency-based rationales 
    for differential pricing recognized by the Congress and the FCC.26
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \24\ See, e.g., RxCare of Tennessee, Inc., et al., Docket No. C-
    3664, 5 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) para. 23,957 (June 10, 1996); see also 
    Cooper and Fries, ``The most-favored-nation pricing policy and 
    negotiated prices,'' 9 int'l J. Ind. Org. 209 (1991). The logic is 
    straightforward: if by cutting price to another (noncompeting) MVPD 
    TW is compelled also to cut price to downstream competitors, the 
    incentives to make this price cut is diminished. Although this 
    effect might be small in the early years of the order (when the 
    gains to TW from cutting price to a large independent MVPD might 
    swamp the losses from cutting price to its downstream competitors) 
    its magnitude will grow over the order's 10-year duration, as TW 
    cable systems confront greater competition.
        \25\ See my dissenting statements in Silicon Graphics and 
    Waterous/Hale, supra n.13.
        \26\ Mirroring the applicable statute, the FCC rules governing 
    the sale of cable programming by vertically integrated programmers 
    to nonaffiliated MVPDs allow for price differentials reflecting, 
    inter alia, ``economies of scale, cost savings, or other direct and 
    legitimate economic benefits reasonably attributable to the number 
    of subscribers served by the distributor.'' 47 U.S.C. 
    Sec. 548(c)(2)(B)(iii); 47 C.F.R. 76.1002(b)(3).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Most objectionable is Paragraph IX of the order, the ``must carry'' 
    provision that compels TW to carry an additional 24-hour news service. 
    I am baffled how the Commission has divined that consumers would prefer 
    that a channel of supposedly scarce cable capacity be used for a second 
    news service, instead of for something else. More generally, although 
    remedies in horizontal merger cases sometimes involve the creation of a 
    new competitor to replace the competition eliminated by the 
    transaction, no competitor has been lost in the present case. Indeed, 
    there is substantial entry already occurring in this segment of the 
    programming market, notwithstanding the severe ``difficulty'' of 
    entering the markets alleged in the complaint.27 Obviously, the 
    incentives to buy programming from an independent vendor are diminished 
    (all else held constant) when a distributor integrates vertically into 
    programming. This is true whether the integration is procompetitive or 
    anticompetitive on net, and whether the integration occurs via merger 
    or via de novo entry.28 I could no more support a must-carry 
    provision for TW as a result of its acquisition of CNN than I could 
    endorse a similar requirement to remedy the ``anticompetitive 
    consequences'' of de novo integration by TW into the news business.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \27\ The Microsoft/NBC joint venture, MSNBC, already is in 
    service; the Fox entry apparently will also be operational shortly.
        \28\ The premise inherent in this provision of the order is that 
    TW can ``foreclose'' independent programming entry in independently 
    (i.e., without the cooperation of TCI, whose incentives to sponsor 
    independent programming are ostensibly preserved by the stock 
    ownership cap contained in Paragraphs II and III of the order). 
    Given that TW has only 17 percent of total cable subscribership, I 
    find this proposition fanciful.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [FR Doc. 96-24599 Filed 9-24-96; 8:45 am]
    BILLING CODE 6750-01-P
    
    
    

Document Information

Published:
09/25/1996
Department:
Federal Trade Commission
Entry Type:
Notice
Action:
Proposed consent agreement.
Document Number:
96-24599
Dates:
Comments must be received on or before November 25, 1996.
Pages:
50301-50322 (22 pages)
Docket Numbers:
File No. 961-0004
PDF File:
96-24599.pdf