96-33222. Service Contract Act; Labor Standards for Federal Service Contracts  

  • [Federal Register Volume 61, Number 251 (Monday, December 30, 1996)]
    [Rules and Regulations]
    [Pages 68647-68664]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 96-33222]
    
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    
    DEPARTMENT OF LABOR
    29 CFR Part 4
    
    RIN 1215-AA78
    
    
    Service Contract Act; Labor Standards for Federal Service 
    Contracts
    
    AGENCY: Wage and Hour Division, Employment Standards Administration, 
    Labor.
    
    ACTION: Final rule.
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    SUMMARY: This document adopts as a final rule a new methodology for 
    establishing minimum health and
    
    [[Page 68648]]
    
    welfare benefits requirements under the McNamara-O'Hara Service 
    Contract Act (SCA). In this document, the Department of Labor (DOL or 
    the Department) also issues a variance, pursuant to Section 4(b) of the 
    Act, to reflect the Department's practice of issuing prevailing fringe 
    benefit determinations on a nationwide basis, rather than separately 
    for classes of employees and localities. This document also contains 
    other minor, clarifying modifications that conform the regulations to a 
    1985 court decision, a 1983 treaty, a 1996 intergovernmental compact, 
    and more recent amendments to the Fair Labor Standards Act (FLSA) 
    minimum wage provisions.
    
    EFFECTIVE DATE: June 1, 1997.
    
    FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: William Gross, Director, Division of 
    Wage Determinations, Wage and Hour Division, Employment Standards 
    Administration, U.S. Department of Labor, Room S-3506, 200 Constitution 
    Avenue, NW, Washington, DC 20210; telephone (202) 219-8353. This is not 
    a toll-free number.
    
    SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
    
    I. Paperwork Reduction Act
    
        This rule does not contain any new or added reporting or 
    recordkeeping requirements subject to the Paperwork Reduction Act of 
    1980 (Pub. L. 96-511). The existing information collection requirements 
    contained in Regulations, 29 CFR Part 4, were previously approved by 
    the Office of Management and Budget under OMB control number 1215-0150. 
    The general Fair Labor Standards Act (FLSA) recordkeeping requirements 
    which are restated in Part 4 were approved by the Office of Management 
    and Budget under OMB control number 1215-0017.
    
    II. Background
    
        The McNamara-O'Hara Service Contract Act of 1965 (SCA) requires 
    that the Department determine locally-prevailing wages and fringe 
    benefits for the various classes of service employees performing 
    contract work subject to the SCA. Federal service contracts over $2,500 
    (if the predecessor contract was not subject to a collective bargaining 
    agreement) are required to contain wage determinations issued by DOL 
    that specify the minimum monetary wages and fringe benefits that must 
    be paid to the various classes of workers who perform work on the 
    service contract, based upon rates determined by DOL to be prevailing 
    in the locality where the work is to be performed. However, because 
    fringe benefit data are not generally available on an occupation-
    specific or on a locality basis, DOL has issued fringe benefit 
    determinations for health and welfare based on nationwide data ever 
    since SCA was enacted.1
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \1\ For a complete description of the history and content of the 
    current methodology, see the Background section of the Notice of 
    proposed rulemaking published at 61 FR 19770 (May 2, 1996).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Service Employees International Union (SEIU) sued DOL in March 
    1991 in the United States District Court for the District of Columbia 
    over the longstanding administrative practice, since 1976, of issuing 
    two nationwide rates for health and welfare fringe benefits, and for 
    failure to periodically update SCA health and welfare fringe benefit 
    levels which, at that time, had not been updated since 1986 (SEIU v. 
    Martin, CA No. 91-0605 (JFP) (D.D.C. April 1, 1992)). Following a 
    remand to the Department for exhaustion of administrative remedies, the 
    DOL's Board of Service Contract Appeals remanded the matter to the Wage 
    and Hour Division to consider alternative methodologies for 
    implementing the statutory objectives. Accordingly, the Administrator 
    of the Wage and Hour Division, by Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (NPRM) 
    published in the Federal Register on May 2, 1996 (61 FR 19770), 
    proposed for public comment various alternative methodologies based on 
    data from the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Employment Cost Index 
    (ECI). Due to the time constraints, it was not feasible to publish the 
    required regulatory impact analysis for comment with the proposed rule.
        The Department thereafter developed information on the occupational 
    mix of service employees engaged in the performance of SCA-covered 
    contracts. Based on data collected by the Federal Procurement Data 
    System for Fiscal Year 1994, the Department conducted a survey which 
    provided specific information on service contract employment by 
    occupation within SIC industry classifications. By Notice published in 
    the Federal Register on October 25, 1996 (61 FR 55239), the Department 
    published its preliminary regulatory impact analysis containing 
    estimates of the economic impact of the various proposed alternatives.
        In an action filed by the SEIU in the U.S. District Court for the 
    District of Columbia, the court set a deadline for publication of this 
    final rule of December 24, 1996. SEIU v. Reich, CA No. 91--0605 (August 
    27, 1996).
        In response to the proposed rulemaking, the Department received 80 
    comments. This included comments from seven Federal agencies: 
    Department of the Army, Department of the Navy, Department of the Air 
    Force, Defense Commissary Agency, U.S. Postal Service, Environmental 
    Protection Agency (EPA), and National Aeronautics and Space 
    Administration (NASA). Comments were received from six union 
    organizations: Service Employees International Union (SEIU), the 
    American Federation of Labor-Congress of Industrial Organizations (AFL-
    CIO), the International Union of Operating Engineers, the Laborers' 
    International Union of North America (LIUNA), District No. 5--ITPE, 
    NMU/MEBA (AFL-CIO), and the International Association of Bridge, 
    Structural and Ornamental Iron Workers. The Contract Services 
    Association of America (CSA), which according to its comment represents 
    more than 240 companies that provide technical and support services to 
    37 Federal agencies, provided detailed comments, and thirty-three of 
    its member contractors separately submitted comments concurring with 
    CSA's position. Several major government service contractors, including 
    Johnson Controls, Lockheed Martin, Raytheon Aerospace, Aspen Systems 
    Corporation, and Kay and Associates, Inc., also provided comments. In 
    addition, the law firm of Hogg, Allen, Norton & Blue, which stated that 
    it represents a large number of service contractors throughout the 
    country, commented on the Department's proposal.
        Thirteen firms which employ or provide employment services to 
    disabled workers under the NISH program and the Javitz-Wagner-O'Day Act 
    (JWOD) submitted comments. The National Star Route Mail Contractor's 
    Association and six mail hauling firms also filed comments. Fringe 
    Insurance Benefits, Inc., which markets and provides services to the 
    Contractors and Employees Retirement Trust Fund and several health 
    plans designed specifically for prevailing wage employees, provided its 
    comments. ACIL, which represents firms performing scientific testing 
    and engineering services, also commented on the Department's proposal.
    
    III. Comments and Analysis of Alternatives
    
    Summary of Comments
    
        A majority of the commenters favored Alternative I, which would 
    provide for a single fringe benefit rate based on ECI all-industry 
    data. The CSA supported the Alternative I methodology, and thirty-three 
    of its member contractors concurred separately with CSA's position. 
    Both the Department of the Army and the Department of the Navy
    
    [[Page 68649]]
    
    preferred Alternative I. Alternative I was also supported by Lockheed 
    Martin and Kay and Associates, Inc. (KAI).
        Little support was offered by the commenters for Alternatives II, 
    III or IV, including the variations of these alternatives. The Defense 
    Commissary Agency and four firms which employ disabled workers 
    supported Alternative II-A, which would provide separate benefit levels 
    for six major occupational groupings, primarily because it would be the 
    least costly in their particular circumstances. None of the commenters 
    favored Alternative II-B, which would provide a single fringe benefit 
    rate based on the occupational mix of service employees engaged in the 
    performance of SCA-covered contracts, or Alternative II-C, which would 
    provide for two benefit levels based on combining occupational 
    groupings into two categories. Alternative III, under which separate 
    rates would apply to each of four geographic regions, was supported by 
    only three commenters. Alternative IV, which would provide for a fringe 
    benefit rate based on a percentage of wages paid was endorsed by Aspen 
    Systems Corporation, which desired a high benefit package for its 
    employees, and three firms which wanted a low benefit package.
        The Air Force strongly supported Alternative V-A, which would 
    continue the current methodology of applying two benefit levels based 
    on ECI size-of-establishment data. NASA, EPA, and the U.S. Postal 
    Service, and 3 other organizations also supported this alternative. 
    Three commenters supported Alternative V-B, a variation of the current 
    methodology in that it would be applied by the size, rather than 
    nature, of the contract and the lower benefit level would be based on 
    ``total benefit'' rather than ``insurance only'' ECI data.
        The unions commenting favored none of the proposed alternatives, 
    choosing instead to propose another alternative, which would preserve 
    the two-tier benefit system, but would use a different methodology for 
    calculating the lower ``insurance'' benefit rate. The unions proposed 
    that this lower rate be based on all-industry insurance only data, 
    rather than ``size-of-establishment'' insurance data, and that those 
    firms not providing health insurance be eliminated from the data (i.e., 
    eliminating the ``zeros''). The unions also proposed including data on 
    fringe benefits paid to public employees in the low level fringe 
    benefit calculation.
        Another alternative was also proposed by Fringe Insurance Benefits, 
    Inc., under which the Department would issue a single level for health 
    insurance which would be the same for all employees, and an additional 
    amount for pension which would vary based upon wages or job 
    classification.
        More detailed discussion of the comments on each of the 
    alternatives proposed follows:
        Alternative I: Issue a single benefit level based upon ECI data for 
    workers in private industry. The commenters who supported the 
    Alternative I methodology did so generally for three basic reasons. 
    First, they preferred its simplicity in establishing a uniform benefit 
    rate for all employees and the consequent ease with which contractors 
    could administer this rate and the government could verify SCA 
    compliance. Commenters also believed that this methodology would 
    eliminate the possibility of contractors manipulating employee 
    classifications in order to obtain a competitive advantage, which might 
    happen under some of the other proposed methodologies, thus ensuring a 
    ``level playing field for bidders.''
        Secondly, many commenters preferred Alternative I because it does 
    not discriminate between classes of employees based on the kind of job 
    they have or the location of their employment, and because it is easy 
    for employees to understand and would result in fewer morale problems. 
    KAI complained that because on some military installations the $2.56 
    ``total benefit'' package applies to some contracts while the $.90 
    ``insurance'' applies to others, it has lost highly qualified employees 
    to a different company working at the same base location which paid the 
    same wage but with the higher $2.56 benefit rate. According to KAI, its 
    employees ``never understand or accept why someone else on the same 
    base receives $2.56 per hour in benefits in comparison to the $.90 they 
    receive.'' Vinnell Corporation echoed this concern, stating as follows:
    
        We have long believed that the two tier fringe benefit rate 
    methodology used for service contracts is discriminatory and creates 
    a disparate impact on those individuals working on projects where 
    the lower rate is applicable. One of Vinnell's current service 
    contracts is at a location where the higher fringe rate is 
    applicable because the project was derived from an A-76 procurement 
    action approximately 15 years ago. At that same location we have a 
    second project where the lower fringe rate is applicable. We find it 
    inconceivable that two carpenters, both working for Vinnell on 
    different service contracts but at the same military installation 
    and receiving the same wage rate should not also receive the same 
    fringe benefit rate.
    
        KAI was also concerned that a two-tiered system ``results in added 
    administrative costs and negates the cost savings associated with 
    economies of scale.''
        Finally, many commenters preferred the Alternative I methodology 
    because, as CSA stated in its comments, it produces a benefit rate 
    which is ``sufficient to allow all service contractors to purchase a 
    good benefit package for employees that would cover a range of health 
    and welfare benefits for all contract workers.'' Many commenters 
    expressed their belief that due to the continually rising cost of 
    benefit packages, the current ``insurance only'' benefit rate of $.90 
    per hour is simply insufficient to purchase any meaningful benefit 
    package, especially one that would include adequate health insurance. 
    KAI offered the following concrete example:
    
        In 1993, $.89 per hour of benefits allowed the contractor to 
    provide a benefit package with 3 personal days, $10,000.00 of life 
    insurance, profit sharing contribution, dental insurance, and 
    medical insurance with a $250.00 deductible and supplemental 
    accident insurance. The $.90 per hour of benefits in 1996 allows the 
    contractor to provide a benefit package with 4 personal days, zero 
    life insurance, profit sharing contribution, zero dental insurance, 
    and a medical plan with a $350.00 deductible and no supplemental 
    accident insurance.
    
        Contractors favoring Alternative I also believe that the resulting 
    increase in the benefit level for many of their employees would aid 
    them in attracting and retaining qualified employees to work on service 
    contracts with the Federal government.
        Both the Department of the Army and the Department of the Navy 
    supported the establishment of a single health and welfare benefit rate 
    to be issued on all SCA wage determinations. The Army stated that it 
    supports one flat rate ``in the interests of simplicity and acquisition 
    streamlining.'' The Army preferred a ``single rate'' methodology 
    because it believes that the standards currently used by DOL to apply 
    the high benefit rate have no rational basis. The Army cited as an 
    example the Department's policy of applying the high rate to ``OMB 
    Circular A-76'' contracts.2 The Army stated that if DOL is to 
    continue with a two-rate methodology, it must ``publish clear 
    understandable and fair guidance to explain when each rate is 
    applied.''
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \2\ OMB Circular A-76 actions are solicitations with potential 
    for displacement of Federal civilian workers. The rationale behind 
    applying the high benefit level to such contracts is that Federal 
    workers whose jobs are being converted to the private sector should 
    not suffer an abrupt decrease in their benefits.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Army appears to regard the $1.89 rate as acceptable since it 
    ``splits the
    
    [[Page 68650]]
    
    difference between the `low' and the `high' fringe rate.'' However, the 
    Army believes that ``it is important that the contracting agencies have 
    the ability to challenge that one rate by industry. If rates are 
    significantly lower for a particular industry, then DOL should deviate 
    from the one rate and set a lower rate for that industry.''
        The Navy similarly concludes that ``[t]he single rate is far more 
    justifiable in terms of both contracting for services and compliance 
    within established employer wage and benefit programs.'' The Navy also 
    expressed belief that DOL has applied the current ``high'' health and 
    welfare benefit level in an artificial manner. Like the Army, the Navy 
    specifically mentioned the OMB Circular A-76 contracts involving 
    displacement of Federal employees as an example of improper application 
    of the high benefit rate. The Navy stated that once the high rate is 
    applied to such a contract, it continues to apply indefinitely to 
    follow-on contracts, and consequently, ``many service contracts contain 
    the artificially high benefit level while the prevailing rates for 
    those contracts are considerably lower.''
        The Navy also stated that ``information available within the 
    Federal Employees Health Benefits Program'' would provide a sound basis 
    for establishing a single benefit rate. The Navy is concerned that 
    implementation of the $1.89 rate would create a significant cost 
    increase that might result in ``the federal contracting agencies' 
    inability to continue funding certain services, or existing service 
    levels, or [cause agencies] to reconsider decisions to contract out 
    such services to the private sector,'' thus causing a reduction in the 
    service contract workforces. The CSA also was concerned that 
    ``[i]ncreased cost to government agencies could result in downsizing of 
    contracts and layoffs of employees.''
        On the other hand, the Department of the Air Force opposed the 
    Alternative I methodology on the bases that the $1.89 ECI-based rate is 
    too costly and not appropriate for any contractor, being ``too low for 
    employees of large companies or with high-skilled workers and too high 
    for employees of small companies or low-skilled employees.'' The Air 
    Force, however, agreed with the Army and the Navy that ``[t]he current 
    problems with the two rate system stem from the inconsistent 
    application of the two fringe benefit levels resulting in confusion and 
    frustration by Federal contracting agencies, contractors, and service 
    contractors.'' The Air Force further stated that ``[t]he inflexibility, 
    for example, in applying the `high' fringe benefit rate to A-76 
    [Federal employee displacement] solicitations and then maintaining the 
    high benefit level regardless of the type of continued circumstances of 
    the contract has created the climate for complaints and attacks on the 
    two level system.''
        The Defense Commissary Agency believed that Alternative I would be 
    cost-prohibitive for its contracting purposes since that agency 
    normally uses ``service occupations'' that would be paid the ``low'' 
    health and welfare benefit rate under the current methodology.
        Another disadvantage to the Alternative I methodology, specifically 
    mentioned by CSA, is that the all-industry ECI data upon which the 
    Alternative I benefit rate would be based includes ``zeros''--that is 
    data from companies that do not provide the benefit surveyed, thus 
    resulting in a lower rate that does not accurately reflect the actual 
    cost of such benefits. This concern was also reflected in the unions' 
    alternative proposal for determining health and welfare benefit rates, 
    which is separately discussed below.
        Many commenters expressed concern that lowering the current high 
    ``total benefit'' rate to the Alternative I single benefit rate would 
    result in serious employee morale problems and disruption in benefits. 
    Accordingly, as will be more fully discussed below, many commenters 
    favored some type of ``grandfathering'' or ``phase-in'' mechanism to 
    ameliorate the disruptive effects resulting from a change in the health 
    and welfare benefit rate methodology.
        The unions unanimously opposed the single rate methodology provided 
    in Alternative I primarily because it would reduce existing benefits 
    currently received by those service contract workers to which the 
    higher level ``total benefits'' rate applies. They believed that 
    Alternative I met their primary criterion of establishing a rate high 
    enough to purchase health insurance coverage, but nonetheless found 
    this alternative unacceptable because it would eliminate the existing 
    ``total benefits'' rate. SEIU also opposed Alternative I for the 
    specific reasons that it excludes public employee data and fails to 
    give ``due consideration'' to Federal employee rates.
        Alternative II-A: Issue a single benefit level for each of six 
    major occupational groupings based on ECI data for all workers in each 
    of these groupings in private industry. This alternative was favored by 
    the Defense Commissary Agency and four firms which employ workers with 
    disabilities pursuant to programs sponsored under the Javitz-Wagner-
    O'Day Act (JWOD), based primarily on their view that this alternative 
    would be the least costly in their individual circumstances. The 
    Defense Commissary Agency recommended use of Alternative II-A because 
    the ``service occupations'' it normally uses ``really would justify 
    only a rate of $.62 per hour.'' Eastern Carolina Vocational Center 
    (ECVC), which operates a work center for disabled individuals, 
    explained that Alternative II would be the best alternative for its 
    operations based on cost reasons. While ECVC acknowledged that 
    Alternative II-A may be the most expensive to the government as a 
    whole, it would be the least costly where ECVC was concerned since its 
    workers fall within the second lowest paid occupational group 
    (handlers, equipment cleaners, helpers and laborers, which would 
    receive fringe benefits of $1.24 per hour [based on 1995 ECI data] 
    under this alternative).
        Most of the commenters who opposed adoption of Alternative II-A 
    believed that it would be too difficult to administer and enforce, and 
    would result in ``additional costs to the contractor, and ultimately to 
    the contracting agency, for personnel and systems to administer the 
    program.'' The Air Force was concerned that the increase in the 
    complexity of accounting resulting from this alternative would pose 
    ``additional compliance difficulties for contractors and [Wage-Hour] 
    investigators.''
        Commenters also expressed concern that too much subjectivity would 
    be inherent in the administration of this alternative. Both CSA and 
    Aspen Systems Corporation specifically stated that utilization of this 
    alternative could lead to gamesmanship involving manipulation of 
    classifications by contractors during the competitive bidding process.
        Many commenters expressed their belief that minimum fringe benefit 
    rates differentiating among various groups of employees under 
    Alternative II-A would not reflect the prevailing practice in the 
    service contracting industry and would be unfair to employees in lower-
    paid occupations. CSA stated that a ``vast majority'' of its member 
    companies ``provide the same level of benefits to all workers, except 
    those workers who are covered under a Collective Bargaining Agreement 
    or a prevailing wage law.'' The AFL-CIO also stated that employers 
    generally provide the same rate of fringe benefits, particularly health 
    insurance, to all employees working on the same
    
    [[Page 68651]]
    
    contract. The AFL-CIO further stated that ``a system based on 
    occupational groupings that would provide different employees working 
    for the same employer under the same contract with widely different 
    fringe benefits simply could not be considered to be prevailing since 
    such a system is rarely found among employers.''
        Several contractors stated that, especially on those contracts with 
    a mix of labor categories, there could be a high potential for 
    discrimination problems arising under the Internal Revenue Code in view 
    of the large disparity between the various benefit rates. Several 
    commenters were also concerned that having the various benefit levels 
    under Alternative II-A would create serious labor and morale problems. 
    In addressing this point, the AFL-CIO stated as follows:
    
        [Q]uality health insurance is needed by all service workers 
    regardless of their occupational groupings. The cost of insurance is 
    the same for the custodian as for the computer technician. 
    Establishing different minimum fringe benefit levels based on 
    occupational titles or groupings probably would lead to different 
    levels of health care among service workers, creating basic problems 
    in the workplace.
    
        Finally, several commenters, including Fringe Insurance Benefits, 
    Inc., opposed this alternative because the $.62 rate for ``service 
    occupation'' employees would not be sufficient for such employees to 
    obtain any meaningful health insurance.
        Alternative II-B: Issue a single benefit rate adjusted to reflect 
    the difference between the BLS ECI occupational universe and the actual 
    mix of comparable occupations on SCA contracts. No commenters favored 
    this alternative; Lockheed Martin was the only commenter to provide any 
    favorable comments concerning this alternative. 3 Lockheed Martin 
    believes that the benefit rate produced under this methodology would be 
    less than the $1.89 rate produced under Alternative I and that it 
    ``would be more reflective of prevailing benefit levels of SCA type 
    contracts.'' Lockheed Martin also believed this alternative to be easy 
    to administer.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \3\ Lockheed Martin supported Alternative I.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Most commenters opposed Alternative II-B simply because they 
    believed it to be too complicated. CSA believed that ``the data 
    required to effectively accomplish this may be too difficult to obtain 
    and may have too much error to be effective.'' Aspen Systems expressed 
    concern that this alternative would be difficult for the government to 
    implement, thus creating delay, and that it was unclear as to which 
    agency would have the authority to set the single benefit rate. Several 
    commenters, including the AFL-CIO and the Air Force, questioned the 
    accuracy of the Department's calculation of the occupational mix of 
    service employees contained in the regulatory impact analysis, which 
    formed the basis of the cost estimate for this alternative. The Air 
    Force also believes this alternative to be the most inflationary of all 
    those proposed.
        Alternative II-C: Issue two benefit levels based on combining the 
    occupational groupings. This alternative likewise garnered no support 
    from any commenters. Many commenters had the same objections to this 
    alternative that they had to Alternative II-A. The commenters generally 
    complained that this alternative would be too complex administratively, 
    and would be discriminatory against workers in certain types of 
    occupations leading to employee morale problems. Aspen Systems believed 
    that there would be too much subjectivity in determining under which of 
    the two broad occupational groupings certain classifications would 
    fall.
        Alternative III: Issue a single rate for each of four geographic 
    regions based on ECI data for all workers in private industry. This 
    alternative was endorsed by Goodwill Industries, Inc. of Eastern 
    Nebraska and Southwest Iowa, which stated that this alternative ``would 
    provide the least financial burden to the Federal Government and 
    provide a significant increase in benefits to [its] employees,'' and by 
    the EPA, which believed this alternative to be ``among the most prudent 
    cost effective alternatives.'' 4
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \4\ EPA equally supported Alternative V-A.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Commenters which opposed this alternative stated that regional data 
    is not an adequate substitute for locality data, especially since this 
    methodology would not take into consideration fringe benefit 
    differences within a particular region. One commenter noted that the 
    District of Columbia and Mississippi would be located in the same 
    region, yet the labor costs in these two regions are significantly 
    different. Similarly, the AFL-CIO points out that prevailing rates in 
    San Francisco, which is located in the Western region, are much more 
    likely to be similar to the prevailing rates in Boston than to the 
    prevailing rates in Boise, Idaho, which is also in the Western region. 
    Commenters therefore questioned the usefulness of the geographic 
    breakdown embodied in Alternative III.
        Several commenters also pointed out that fringe benefits are 
    provided to employees within a company on a similar basis without 
    reference to geographic location and that benefit plans to which 
    employers subscribe are not structured to take into account 
    geographical differences. CSA and its member companies disliked 
    Alternative III, finding it too difficult to administer because it 
    would possibly require four separate benefit plans. They were also 
    concerned that implementation of this alternative would necessitate 
    major payroll, accounting and administrative changes, and would be 
    especially problematic with regard to employees who work in more than 
    one region. CSA was also concerned as to how contract bids would be 
    evaluated in situations where place of performance of the service 
    contract would be determined by the location of the successful bidder. 
    Finally, CSA believed that this alternative ``could cause non-
    compliance with IRS discrimination rules on pension plans.'' Hogg, 
    Allen, Norton & Blue was concerned that the establishment of a higher 
    benefit for one geographic region than another might give rise to 
    ``control group issues under ERISA.''
        Alternative IV: Issue a single fringe benefit rate (as a percent of 
    wages) based on the relationship between the ECI all-private industry 
    ``total benefit'' rate and the ECI all-private industry average wage 
    rate. This alternative was endorsed by Aspen Systems Corporation and 
    three firms which employ workers with disabilities pursuant to programs 
    sponsored under the JWOD. Aspen Systems believed that this alternative 
    would provide positive incentive to employees ``in the sense that the 
    higher an employee's hourly wage, the higher the employee's fringe 
    benefit rates.'' Aspen Systems also stated that implementation of this 
    methodology would aid firms in attracting and retaining employees in 
    high level classifications, such as specialty and technical personnel. 
    Aspen Systems did not view this alternative as being too burdensome 
    from an administrative standpoint and recommended that the methodology 
    be applied as a percentage of each individual employee's wages rather 
    than of an average based on all wages paid under a contract. The JWOD 
    firms which favored this alternative appeared to do so because the 
    percentage methodology when applied to the wage rates typically paid to 
    their low-wage employees would serve to decrease their labor costs and 
    enhance their competitiveness.
        Many commenters believed that this alternative would not be
    
    [[Page 68652]]
    
    administratively feasible. For example, Johnson Controls stated that 
    many of its contracts are not staffed with administrative personnel who 
    could adequately perform the requirements associated with this 
    alternative. The Air Force was also specifically concerned that 
    applying multiple fringe benefit rates on a contract would impose an 
    excessive administrative burden on contractors, particularly small 
    contractors such as those operating under the Small Business 
    Administration's ``8a'' program and the ``NISH'' programs. The Air 
    Force also believes that the complexity of accounting inherent in this 
    alternative would pose added compliance difficulties for contractors 
    and Wage-Hour investigators alike. Fringe Insurance Benefits, Inc. was 
    concerned that use of this alternative would provide incentives for 
    employers to intentionally misclassify employees.
        Several commenters stated that a methodology providing for multiple 
    fringe benefit rates would naturally lead to problems of inequity and 
    morale in the workforce. CSA and the AFL-CIO both expressed concern 
    that lower paid workers might not be able to obtain adequate health 
    insurance under this alternative. Finally, Fringe Insurance Benefits, 
    Inc., while pointing out that ``the cost of health has no relationship 
    to wages,'' stated that this methodology is ``inconsistent with the 
    traditional approach of providing all non-exempt employees with the 
    same health benefit level.''
        Alternative V-A: Issue two fringe benefit levels based on BLS ECI 
    size-of-establishment data for all workers in private industry (Current 
    methodology--applied based on nature of contract). The Air Force, NASA, 
    EPA and the United States Postal Service specifically recommended this 
    alternative. Moreover, several commenters, including Johnson Controls 
    and Hogg, Allen, Norton & Blue, even though they did not choose this 
    alternative, believe this to be the least disruptive alternative since 
    it most closely approximates the present two-level methodology.
        The Air Force believes this to be the least costly of all the 
    alternatives proposed and that experience over the past twenty years 
    shows that a methodology providing a two-tier system would best ``meet 
    the needs of large or high-skill contractors and provide a 
    representative rate for the small and low-skill contractors.'' The Air 
    Force further believes that ``[t]he current problems with the two rate 
    system stem from the inconsistent application of the two fringe benefit 
    levels resulting in confusion and frustration by Federal contracting 
    agencies, contractors, and service employees.'' The Air Force favored 
    establishment of regulations that would ``place a high fringe benefit 
    level only on large dollar contracts and contracts that require the use 
    of a highly skilled workforce.''
        The United States Postal Service preferred this alternative so that 
    ``the current methods of calculating wages and benefits for highway 
    transportation contract employees would be continued.'' The Postal 
    Service's preference stems from its desire to preserve the status quo 
    with respect to the Department's current policy of special treatment of 
    the mail transportation industry.
        The primary objections to this alternative are that the two levels 
    are inconsistently and subjectively applied to contracts and that the 
    insurance level is too low to provide adequate benefits and/or attract 
    and retain qualified employees. SEIU points out that ``size-of-
    establishment'' data has no direct correlation to the population of 
    establishments performing SCA contracts and the types of contracts to 
    which the two benefit levels apply, i.e., the size of the business has 
    no relationship to the nature of the service contract or to the level 
    of benefit applied under the current methodology. SEIU and the AFL-CIO 
    both stated that the ``size-of-establishment'' approach for the lower 
    ``insurance'' rate has been rejected by the Department's Board of 
    Service Contract Appeals.
        Alternative V-B: Issue two fringe benefit levels based on BLS ECI 
    size-of-establishment data for all workers in private industry 
    (variation of current methodology--applied by size/number of employees 
    on contract; lower fringe benefit rate based on ``total benefit'' 
    level). This alternative was favored only by CCAR Services, Inc., an 
    employer of persons with disabilities, whose primary concern was that 
    an increase in the cost of benefit packages would result in a reduction 
    in the number of employees on government service contracts.
        The Air Force opposed this alternative because of the problems 
    attendant to its application. The Air Force notes that ECI fringe 
    benefit data is based on the number of employees in the firm, whereas 
    the suggested application would be based on the number of employees on 
    the contract. The Air Force believes this illogical given that many 
    large firms that would normally pay high fringe benefit rates have 
    contracts that utilize only a small number of employees. CSA states 
    that employees would be penalized for working on smaller contracts and 
    that it would be difficult to attract and retain highly skilled workers 
    on small contracts. Finally, Job Options, Inc. states this alternative 
    would lead to a perception by employees of arbitrariness and unfairness 
    since ``there is really no difference from the workers point of view 
    whether or not he or she works for a large or small employer, the 
    workers' needs are the same. Therefore, to either penalize or reward 
    them based on the size of the employer seems unfair to employees.''
    
    Other Alternatives
    
    Unions' Proposal
    
        The union commenters suggested an alternative methodology that 
    would maintain the existing ``two-tier'' system, including the ``total 
    benefits'' rate (currently at $2.56) utilizing the current methodology, 
    but would provide a different methodology for determining only the 
    lower ``insurance'' rate.5 SEIU and the AFL-CIO both stated that 
    the Department should continue to set the lower fringe benefit rate 
    based on the cost that employers pay for insurance because BLS data 
    shows that insurance is the only benefit which a majority of service 
    workers receive. However, rather than using the ECI size-of-
    establishment data currently used to determine the ``insurance'' rate, 
    the unions recommended using ECI all-industry data, but only after 
    those establishments that reported no health insurance costs are 
    factored out of the survey data, i.e., after eliminating the ``zeros.'' 
    The unions argued that inclusion of ``zeros'' as amounts paid for 
    health insurance distorts the cost of health insurance paid by 
    employers which actually provide health insurance, and therefore 
    artificially deflates the prevailing fringe benefit rate. The AFL-CIO 
    believes that its proposal would bring the ``insurance level'' cost 
    within the range of $2.00.6 As discussed below, the unions'' 
    proposal also would include State, local and Federal data in the 
    computation. They argue that inclusion of State and local data is 
    appropriate because nothing in the Act suggests that prevailing rates 
    are based only on private industry. They further suggest
    
    [[Page 68653]]
    
    that inclusion of Federal rates is appropriate because of the statutory 
    provision for the Department to give ``due consideration'' to the rates 
    paid Federal employees.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \5\ SEIU recommends that the ``Total Benefits'' rate should be 
    ``frozen at $2.56 until such time as the ECI data for all benefits 
    for establishments of 100 or more employees rises above the $2.56'' 
    because the ECI data for 1995 and 1996 fell below this rate.
        \6\ Fringe benefit data with ``zeros'' excluded is not currently 
    available from BLS. SEIU claims in its comments that BLS has 
    informed them that ``establishments with zero health care benefits 
    can be eliminated from the ECI data by some programming changes * * 
    *''
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        As an alternative, SEIU suggested that the ``insurance'' rate could 
    be based on data derived from the Federal Employee Health Benefits 
    Program (FEHBP). According to SEIU, the family coverage contribution 
    rate under the FEHBP program was $1.65 in 1996, whereas a blend of 
    single and family coverage rates as reflected in the actual cost per 
    employee to the Federal government would amount to approximately $1.30 
    per hour. Apparently, SEIU would support either of these two rates as 
    the basis for the ``insurance'' rate.
        The Army believes that the unions' proposal to change the ``low'' 
    rate methodology, but retain the methodology for computing the ``high'' 
    rate as it now stands is a ``protectionist stance * * * that cannot be 
    defended.'' The Army states that if DOL decides to continue with a two-
    rate methodology, the rationale for each rate must be the same. In 
    other words, it would be illogical and inconsistent to determine the 
    lower ``insurance'' rate based on all-industry data, while continuing 
    to determine the higher ``total benefits'' rate based only on ``size-
    of-establishment'' data.
    
    Insurance Plus Variable Rate
    
        Fringe Insurance Benefits, Inc. (FIBI) recommended implementation 
    of ``a prevailing rate for health insurance that is level and 
    consistent for all employees on the contract and a pension rate that is 
    based on either wages or job classification.'' Under this method, 
    health care costs for each class of employee would be consistent, but 
    other fringe benefits such as pension amount would vary by occupation 
    or wage rate. FIBI suggested that this method would better conform to 
    actual market place practices. Furthermore, FIBI suggested that the 
    Department closely review the National Association of Insurance 
    Commissioners' Small Employer Health Insurance Availability Model Act.
    
    ``Due Consideration'' and Inclusion of State and Local Data
    
        Five organizations commented concerning the appropriate procedure 
    for the Department to give due consideration to the wage and fringe 
    benefits paid Federal employees, as required by the Act. Three unions 
    and one contractor stated that due consideration should be given to the 
    wage and fringe benefit rates being paid Federal employees in making 
    SCA wage determinations. SEIU stated that due consideration was 
    intended to narrow the disparity between the compensation received by 
    Federal employees and service contract workers. SEIU's view is that 
    Wage and Hour has made no attempt to determine the cost of Federal 
    employees' fringe benefit in order to close the gap. The AFL-CIO 
    contends that the Department cannot rationally maintain that it gives 
    ``due consideration'' to Federal wage and fringe benefit rates, as 
    required by the statute, when Federal workers are excluded from the 
    data on which the SCA fringe benefit rates are based. LIUNA and 
    Lockheed Martin concurred that in computing the insurance level, ECI 
    insurance benefit costs from all civilian sectors, including government 
    employees, should be used.
        The unions strongly supported the inclusion of fringe benefits paid 
    to all public employees, including State and local as well as Federal 
    employees, in SCA fringe benefit rate determinations. According to 
    SEIU, data on fringe benefits paid State and local government employees 
    is readily available in that the ECI now publishes data on fringe 
    benefits paid to ``civilian workers'' including both private and State 
    and local workers combined. SEIU and the AFL-CIO also maintain that 
    data on fringe benefits paid to Federal workers, which SEIU states is 
    ``readily available'' from the Office of Personnel Management, should 
    also be factored into the fringe benefit rates. SEIU states that fringe 
    benefits received by State, local, and Federal workers ``tend to be 
    higher than the fringe benefits paid in private industry'' and their 
    exclusion artificially suppresses the rates currently published by the 
    Department. The unions pointed out that neither the Act nor the 
    regulations make a distinction between private and public service 
    employees, and therefore, there is no basis for excluding public sector 
    fringe benefit data.
        In contrast, the Air Force states that if ECI fringe benefit data 
    is to be used, State and local government fringe benefit data should be 
    excluded. The Air Force states that not only are fringe benefits paid 
    by these entities ordinarily above the levels provided by local private 
    industry, but that a disproportionate number of these employees are 
    represented by unions. These factors would tend to skew the data and 
    results, just as would the inclusion of Federal government data. 
    Furthermore, the CSA states that the benefit rate should be based on 
    private industry data and does not believe that the Department should 
    explore the cost and feasibility of expanding ECI to include fringe 
    benefits of State and local workers.
    
    ``Grandfathering'' or ``Phase-In''
    
        Nine organizations provided comments concerning the possibility of 
    ``grandfathering'' and/or ``phasing-in'' any of the proposed 
    alternative health and welfare benefit rate(s). CSA and its member 
    contractors specifically recommend that the current ``total benefit'' 
    level of $2.56 be ``grandfathered'' throughout the life of all existing 
    contracts, including all options and extensions, and that all new 
    contracts and recompetitions convert to the new health and welfare rate 
    at the time of award. The Navy concurs that ``the revised benefit rate 
    should be implemented only at the resolicitation of a contract, or the 
    new solicitation of contract services.'' The Navy also states that 
    ``[a]ny existing contract would continue with the same present benefit 
    level through the end of that contract, regardless of options or 
    extensions.'' The Navy did not specifically indicate whether its 
    ``grandfathering'' scheme would apply only to the ``total benefit'' 
    level or would also apply to the current ``insurance'' level of $.90 as 
    well. The Army also agrees that ``implementation should occur when a 
    contract is being resolicited or a new requirement is being awarded.'' 
    The Army anticipates that this would allow implementation ``to occur 
    over a period of one to four years, given the fact that most contracts 
    are for a five year term.''
        KIA, on the other hand, suggested that contracts subject to the 
    $2.56 level be ``grandfathered to protect the current level until such 
    time as the lower single level of $1.89 can catch up to it.'' Hogg, 
    Allen, Norton & Blue also offered this suggestion. These commenters 
    generally believe that this approach would protect incumbent employees 
    against a reduction in their fringe benefits upon recompetition and 
    would protect incumbent contractors against predatory pricing practices 
    by non-incumbents at the time of recompetition. They believe that 
    grandfathering the high benefit level until the new rate catches up, 
    provided it is not cost-prohibitive for the agencies involved, would 
    cause the least disruption for contractors and employees alike.
        SEIU states that equity dictates that no employee's benefits should 
    be cut back. In addition, LIUNA believes it appropriate for the 
    Secretary of Labor to issue an exemption or variance for purposes of 
    preserving the current high benefit rate. Another organization 
    concurred, stating that because of the inevitable employee 
    dissatisfaction resulting from a reduction in benefits,
    
    [[Page 68654]]
    
    contracts should be grandfathered to protect the current level ``until 
    any lower level H & W rate can catch up because failure to do so would 
    negatively impact employee morale and retention.''
        The AFL-CIO proposes a two-year phase-in approach for 
    implementation of its recommended new ``insurance'' rate. The AFL-CIO 
    recommended that implementation of the new ``insurance'' rate start 
    with all contract anniversary dates after September 30, 1997, and that 
    only one-half of the difference between the current rate and the new 
    rates which would otherwise apply for fiscal year 1998 be implemented 
    at that time. On the next anniversary date of the contract, the second 
    half of the increase would be implemented.
        The Air Force strongly opposes grandfathering the high fringe 
    benefit level should a final rule be adopted to change to a methodology 
    other than Alternative V-A. The Air Force objects to the Department 
    artificially retaining higher fringe benefit rates, which they do not 
    believe to be supported by the surveys. The Air Force recommends a 
    ``phase-in'' period whereby the rate[s] would ``take effect only upon 
    recompetition of each contract.'' The Air Force believes that, while a 
    phase-in period would not reduce the eventual cost of the benefit 
    increase, it would at least serve to ``reduce the immediate negative 
    impact on employees facing layoffs.''
        The Defense Commissary Agency recommends against a permanent 
    grandfathering at the current rate because that agency believes that 
    the current rates are already too high for the type of work for which 
    it contracts. Instead, the Defense Commissary Agency recommends a 
    phase-in period of two years, with half the reduction occurring the 
    first year, and movement to the then-current rate the second year.
    
    Analysis
    
        Based on a careful review of the comments and further analysis of 
    the various alternatives, the Department has concluded that Alternative 
    I best accords with the Department's dual responsibilities to determine 
    fringe benefits which prevail, and to select a methodology which is 
    administrable and not unduly disruptive for employees, contractors, 
    contracting agencies, and the Department. Currently there are no 
    occupation-specific or locality-based fringe benefit data available. 
    Furthermore, virtually all commenters opposed any alternative which 
    would result in their having to pay different fringe benefits to 
    different classes of workers or in different parts of the country. 
    While recognizing that no methodology will satisfy all parties 
    interested in the service contracting process, the Department believes 
    that Alternative I represents a reasonable application of the statutory 
    requirement to establish prevailing fringe benefit rates and best meets 
    the concerns expressed by the commenters to the Department's proposal. 
    (See also the discussion below concerning the Department's issuance of 
    a variance under Section 4(b) of the Act.)
        Pursuant to the Alternative I methodology, the applicable fringe 
    benefit level would be based on employer costs per hour worked for all 
    benefits--excluding holidays and vacations, which are separately 
    determined, and excluding benefits otherwise required by law, such as 
    social security, unemployment insurance, and workers' compensation 
    payments--as reported annually by the BLS Employment Cost Index (ECI) 
    study of employer costs for employee compensation in the private sector 
    (i.e., all workers, all industries, all establishment sizes, and all 
    occupations). Under this ``total benefits'' approach, the Department 
    will issue a single nationwide health and welfare fringe benefit level 
    applicable to all employees engaged in the performance of SCA-covered 
    contracts, based on the average cost 7 for the following 
    compensation components:
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \7\ The cost of the benefit components in the BLS ECI study is 
    an average based on data from all employers in the survey, including 
    those employers that do not provide the particular benefit. 
    Averaging in these ``zeros'' gives consideration to the degree to 
    which a benefit in fact is paid by employers.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        (1) sick and other leave (excluding vacation and holiday leave);
        (2) insurance, consisting of life, health, and sickness and 
    accident insurance plans;
        (3) retirement and savings, consisting of pension and savings and 
    thrift plans; and
        (4) other benefits not otherwise required by law.
        The Department chooses Alternative I because, as noted by many 
    commenters, this determination method is simple to understand and to 
    comply with, and relatively simple to administer and enforce. The 
    Department also chooses Alternative I because it is consistent with the 
    Department's general practice of using cross-industry data which is not 
    differentiated by size-of-firm in determining prevailing wage rates. 
    The Department has concluded that use of size-of-firm data should not 
    be continued because the Department's application of the two benefit 
    levels did not in fact correspond to the size of the employer, and 
    because review of the survey conducted in preparation of the 
    Department's impact analysis (61 FR 55239, October 25, 1996) led the 
    Department to conclude that the low ``insurance'' level which was 
    applied to most contracts was particularly inappropriate for the large 
    numbers of white collar and skilled blue collar workers employed on 
    Federal service contracts.
        Furthermore, the Department prefers Alternative I over the current 
    methodology (Alternative V-A) because it addresses concerns expressed 
    by commenters that the current two-tier system has been inconsistently 
    and subjectively applied. This approach is also preferable because it 
    applies the same minimum hourly benefit level for all service employees 
    and does not require any subjective judgments as to which benefit level 
    to apply based on the type of contract or employee. Accordingly, 
    adoption of Alternative I will largely avoid the potential for employee 
    morale problems and perceptions of unfairness and inequity that are 
    inherent in the current system and in those alternatives that would 
    establish different rates for different occupations (Alternatives II-A, 
    II-C, and IV).
        The Department also notes that Alternative I provides a benefit 
    level that is sufficient for service contract employees to obtain 
    meaningful health insurance coverage and will allow service contractors 
    to obtain and retain qualified employees. This is consistent with the 
    Department's goals of encouraging employers to provide a high quality 
    and high performance work place. In contrast, the current low insurance 
    fringe benefit level, because it is based on only ``small'' employers 
    and averages in those employers which provide no fringe benefits, has 
    resulted in a fringe benefit level significantly lower than the level 
    actually paid by employers in private industry.
        Alternative I also is consistent with the desire of almost all 
    commenters that health and welfare fringe benefit rates be based upon 
    nationwide data. The Department agrees with those commenters which 
    opposed the alternative (III) which would base rates on the four 
    regional breakdowns because it does not take into account the 
    potentially wider prevailing rate disparities within regions and 
    because employers commented that they generally provide similar 
    benefits to their employees regardless of location.
        The Department has decided not to mix State and local government 
    fringe benefit data with ECI private industry data in determining the 
    fringe benefit
    
    [[Page 68655]]
    
    level applicable under this methodology. The Department has concluded 
    that the determination of the prevailing fringe benefit level should be 
    based only on private industry data since this is the sector that 
    competes for government contracts. Public employee benefit rates are 
    not representative of the benefit levels paid by the universe of 
    private firms that comprises SCA contractors. Rather, fringe benefit 
    levels paid by State and local governments are substantially different 
    than private industry, and consequently, inclusion of such data would 
    inappropriately skew the fringe benefit determination.
        The Department has also concluded that inclusion of Federal fringe 
    benefit data is not feasible.8 The Department has not been able to 
    obtain usable cost data for Federal benefits other than health and life 
    insurance. The pension system provides a defined benefit package for 
    one group of employees 9 and a defined contribution system for 
    others, with contributions which vary according to the level of 
    contributions by employees. Pension and sick leave both vary with the 
    pay of employees. Thus, it is apparent that data on fringe benefits 
    paid to Federal employees would not readily mix with ECI private 
    industry data. However, the Department has taken ``due consideration'' 
    of the Federal benefit system in its selection of Alternative I, which 
    utilizes ``total benefits'' data and will bring SCA fringe benefit 
    levels more into line with Federal benefits.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \8\ Inclusion of Federal benefits would likely have little 
    impact in any event. For example, Federal health insurance would 
    affect the insurance level by no more than a few cents per hour.
        \9\ The level of the defined benefit plan presumably is also 
    affected by the fact that participating employees do not receive 
    credit towards Social Security benefits for their period of 
    Government service.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        The Department shares the view of many commenters that any change 
    in the methodology should avoid the serious adverse effect of a 
    substantial reduction in fringe benefits for those service employees 
    currently employed on contracts subject to the ``total benefit'' level. 
    We anticipate that employers paying the higher benefits in accordance 
    with past determinations of the Department will face the Hobson's 
    choice of cutting fringe benefits for their workers (possibly losing 
    them to employers who are not Federal service contractors which pay 
    higher fringe benefit packages) or becoming uncompetitive. Similarly, 
    Federal agencies may lose the continuity of services provided by major 
    contractors which may become uncompetitive, or by valuable employees 
    who leave because of the reduction in their fringe benefits.
        Accordingly, the Department has concluded that the current ``total 
    benefit'' level should be grandfathered at the present rate ($2.56 per 
    hour) until the single benefit provided by Alternative I (all-industry, 
    all-occupation average) reaches or exceeds $2.56. This grandfathered 
    rate will apply to all contracts which currently contain the high, 
    ``total benefit'' level, and future solicitations for those contracts. 
    The grandfathered rate will not apply to contracts for new services.
        The Department also believes it is necessary to allow contracting 
    agencies (which may have budgeted based upon existing fringe benefit 
    levels) and contractors (which will likely need to develop new fringe 
    benefit plans) a period of time in which to prepare for the change in 
    minimum fringe benefit levels. Accordingly, the new methodology 
    established by this final rule will apply only to wage determinations 
    issued on or after June 1, 1997. This date was selected so that the new 
    rate will apply to contracts solicited and options exercised for the 
    fiscal year beginning October 1, 1997. For the same budgetary and 
    planning reasons, the Department has also concluded that a four-year 
    phase-in of the rate set by the new methodology would be appropriate. 
    The Department believes that this approach is preferable to the 
    alternative suggestion of applying the new rate only to new 
    solicitations, and not to extensions and options on existing contracts, 
    because it is more equitable. Furthermore, the Department is concerned 
    about potentially serious problems in applying the proper fringe 
    benefit determination because of difficulties in ascertaining whether 
    the wage determination is needed for a new contract or exercise of an 
    option.
        As discussed above, most of the alternative methodologies proposed 
    did not garner significant support from commenters, though they were 
    fully considered by the Department in light of the rulemaking record.
        The Department did not select Alternative II-A, which would set 
    different rates for each of six occupational groups, because it would 
    be much more difficult for contractors to administer and for Wage-Hour 
    to enforce. The Department considered it significant that commenters 
    stated that providing different levels of benefits according to 
    occupation is contrary to the common practice of employers providing 
    the same benefit program to most employees, and that it would be 
    difficult for insurance carriers to accommodate. Commenters also agreed 
    generally that having different benefit levels based upon occupation 
    would create serious labor-management and morale problems. The 
    Department also shares the concern expressed by several commenters 
    about subjectivity inherent in this alternative and the possibility 
    that some contractors might attempt to manipulate the classifications 
    in order to obtain a competitive advantage.
        Alternative II-B is similar to Alternative I in that it would 
    provide a single benefit level for all employees and all contracts. 
    However, no commenters responded favorably to this new concept for 
    computing health and welfare fringe benefits, which would set the 
    fringe benefit level based upon available information regarding the mix 
    of occupations used on Federal service contracts. Under this 
    alternative, fringe benefit rates would be determined based upon the 
    survey the Department conducted last year which formed the basis for 
    its impact analysis. Commenters generally expressed little confidence 
    in the Department's efforts to determine the occupational mix on SCA-
    covered contracts.
        The Department did not select Alternative II-C for many of the same 
    reasons it declined to adopt Alternative II-A. Reducing the 
    occupational groupings from six to two would decrease the frequency of 
    having different levels paid to groups of employees on the same 
    contract. However, where that situation arose, there still would be a 
    distinct possibility of perceptions of discrimination and consequent 
    employee morale problems. Moreover, determining the appropriate mixing 
    and weighting of the various occupational group rates would be 
    difficult.
        The Department rejected Alternative III because the Department 
    agrees with the many commenters expressing the belief that establishing 
    benefit rates on a regional basis offers no significant advantage over 
    using a nationwide rate. To the contrary, regional data does not 
    reflect variations in labor costs and fringe benefit rates within a 
    region, which, as the commenters pointed out, are often more 
    substantial than variations among regions. Moreover, this option would 
    be inconsistent with the reportedly common practice among employers, 
    including service contractors, of providing similar fringe benefits to 
    most employees nationwide, without regard to either occupation or 
    geographic location. This alternative would be particularly problematic 
    to those government service contractors which perform contracts for 
    similar services at various facilities and installations throughout the 
    country. It
    
    [[Page 68656]]
    
    could also create serious administrative problems for service 
    contractors whose contracts require performance in multiple locations 
    that fall within different regions.
        Alternative IV (benefits based on a fixed percentage of each 
    employee's wages) was not chosen by the Department primarily because of 
    the extreme difficulty that would be posed by its administrative 
    requirements. Several commenters expressed serious concern that the 
    additional administrative and recordkeeping requirements that would be 
    associated with this alternative would simply be too burdensome, 
    especially for smaller contractors. Although the Department is of the 
    view that there is a correlation between wage levels and fringe 
    benefits paid when viewed across the entire workforce, the Department 
    recognizes that individual employers reportedly provide the same or 
    similar benefit packages to most employees (especially insurance 
    benefits), without regard to wage levels. Moreover, the Department 
    agrees with the commenters that this alternative has the greatest 
    potential for creating problems of inequity and morale in the workf 
    orce. The Department also notes that under this alternative many lower 
    paid workers simply would not receive adequate health insurance.
        As discussed above, the Department decided against continuing the 
    methodology proposed under Alternative V-A or the variation proposed 
    under Alternative V-B primarily because of the lack of evidence 
    justifying continued use of ECI ``size-of-establishment'' data, which 
    has been difficult to defend before the Board of Service Contract 
    Appeals, and commenter concerns regarding the manner in which the two 
    rates have been applied and the resulting effects on the morale of the 
    work force.
        The Department also seriously considered the union proposal. The 
    Department was concerned about the lack of opportunity for comment on 
    this specific alternative. Furthermore, the Department believes that 
    the union proposal, which would maintain the existing ``two-tier'' 
    system, including the current method for determining the high ``total 
    benefits'' rate, while providing a revised methodology for determining 
    the lower ``insurance'' rate, would be difficult to support given that 
    the two rates would be based on inconsistent methodologies. Under the 
    union proposal, the high ``total benefit'' rate would continue to be 
    set based on ECI ``size-of-establishment'' data for large firms 
    (establishments with 100 or more employees). However, the Department's 
    use of ``size-of-establishment'' data was successfully challenged in 
    proceedings before the BSCA. Though the specific challenge was to the 
    use of ECI ``size-of-establishment'' data as a basis for the low 
    ``insurance'' rate, the Department believes that any legal shortcomings 
    identified in that action would likely apply as well to the use of such 
    data in establishing the ``total benefit'' level. Neither the comments 
    nor the Department's own survey provided evidence to refute the 
    Department's statement in its Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (61 FR 
    19773) that the major problem with the continued use of ``size-of-
    establishment'' data is that there is little evidence to show that the 
    average benefit level for small firms corresponds best to benefits paid 
    by private employers on contracts similar to most SCA contracts, or 
    that the benefit level paid by large firms corresponds to the rates 
    paid by employers on contracts to which the ``total benefit'' package 
    has been applied under SCA. Thus, just as there is questionable 
    justification for relying upon ``size-of-establishment'' data as the 
    basis for the ``insurance'' rate, there is equally questionable basis 
    for relying upon such data in setting the ``total benefit'' rate. 
    Finally, the union proposal would continue to raise concerns about the 
    potential for inconsistent and subjective application of the two 
    levels.
        The Department also rejected the alternative suggested by the FIBI. 
    Like the union alternative, this alternative had not been offered for 
    public comment. It has the distinct advantage of being consistent with 
    many employers' reported practice of providing one insurance benefit 
    package to their employees, while providing pension or other benefits 
    at a level varying with wages. However, the Department is concerned 
    that this proposal would be difficult and burdensome to administer, 
    requiring detailed recordkeeping.
    
    IV. Comments and Analysis of Other Fringe Benefit Issues
    
    Variance Under Section 4(b) of the Act
    
        Approximately ten organizations commented regarding the 
    Department's proposal to issue a variance under Section 4(b) of the Act 
    from the statutory requirement that the Secretary determine prevailing 
    fringe benefits for the various classes of service employees in the 
    locality.
        Johnson Controls stated that using a single nationwide rate ``does 
    not reflect the economic factors of the local geographic areas for the 
    prevailing benefits from a competitive and comparability standpoint. 
    Nationwide average data is skewed and does not reflect a valid 
    depiction of benefits when compared with local geographic prevailing 
    benefit data.'' However, Johnson Controls did not identify any source 
    of locality-based fringe benefit data nor did it support the use of 
    regional data as proposed in Alternative III. Rather, Johnson Controls 
    opposed use of such regional data because it would not take into 
    consideration ``the economic fringe benefit differences within the 
    region.''
        SEIU stated that the absence of available data that could be used 
    to set the fringe benefit rates on a locality basis is universally 
    recognized. SEIU therefore supported the Department's proposal that ``a 
    variance be permitted to establish national fringe benefit rates on the 
    grounds that there is no reliable locality data available which would 
    permit the department to establish fringe benefit rates on a locality 
    basis.'' The AFL-CIO believed that ``only a national `insurance level' 
    rate is practical and consistent with the SCA.'' The AFL-CIO favored 
    nationwide rates not only because of the absence of reliable locality-
    based data, but also because many insurance plans operate on a national 
    basis and Federal service contractors often operate in multiple 
    locations.
        District No. 5--ITPE, NMU/MEBA (AFL-CIO) stated that they strongly 
    support the position of the AFL-CIO that the fringe benefit rates 
    should be uniform throughout the nation. In addition, the CSA 
    recommended that the Department continue to issue health and welfare 
    benefits on a national level stating that employers typically provide 
    similar benefits regardless of location. Most of CSA's member companies 
    felt that the utilization of locality-based fringe benefit data for 
    selected metropolitan areas is not a desirable practice. Further, they 
    felt that the benefits derived from collecting the data on a locality 
    basis would not be worth the considerable survey costs.
        The Air Force also did not favor using locality-based fringe 
    benefit data for certain metropolitan areas. In their opinion, the 
    resulting disparity in fringe benefit rates for large metropolitan 
    areas versus the remainder of the nation would be inequitable and 
    discriminatory to those workers outside the metropolitan areas.
        Pony Express stated that any plan should take into account the 
    differences in pay and fringes by region or locality.
        After review of the comments, the Department has concluded that it 
    is
    
    [[Page 68657]]
    
    appropriate to issue a variance from the statutory requirement in 
    Section 2(a)(2) of the Act that the Secretary determine the fringe 
    benefits to be prevailing for the ``various classes of service 
    employees'' ``in the locality.'' Fringe benefit data simply are not 
    available for specific classes of employees or localities. Furthermore, 
    it is evident from the comments that there would be significant 
    administrative burdens to employers in providing fringe benefit plans 
    which vary by locality or by class of employee. Such a system would be 
    contrary to the reportedly common practice by employers, as evidenced 
    by the comments, of providing one fringe benefit package to most 
    employees. Any other system would likely also result in significant 
    morale problems among employees.
        Therefore, the Department has determined that a variance is 
    necessary and proper in the public interest. Furthermore, the 
    Department has determined that in light of the reportedly common 
    practice of employers providing the same fringe benefit plan to most 
    employees, a variance to provide a uniform nationwide level of benefits 
    would be in accord with the remedial purposes of the Act to protect 
    prevailing labor standards.
    
    Different Benefit Levels for Certain Industries
    
        The National Star Route Mail Contractors' Association and their 
    member organizations support the current method used by the Department 
    for setting wage and fringe benefit rates for the mail hauling 
    industry. The Department sets wage and fringe benefit rates for the 
    mail hauling industry for four geographic regions based on a special 
    survey by the U.S. Postal Service. Wage determinations applicable to 
    this industry contain monetary amounts due for health and welfare and 
    pension benefits.
        In addition, both the Department of the Army and the Department of 
    the Navy supported having variation in fringe benefit rates under 
    certain circumstances. Specifically, the Army stated that if a national 
    rate were the standard, it would be important that the contracting 
    agencies have the ability to challenge that one rate by industry. 
    Moreover, if rates are found to be significantly lower for a particular 
    industry, then the DOL should deviate from that one rate and set a 
    lower rate for that industry. The Department of the Navy supported 
    having a single health and welfare benefit rate for all SCA wage 
    determinations. At the same time, however, it suggested use of the 
    Section 4(b) variance procedure to prevent impairment of the 
    Government's business where the agency can show that the fringe benefit 
    rate determined under these regulations ``would prevent adequate 
    contract competition.''
        After review of the comments, and in consideration of the limited 
    circumstances where special wage rates and fringe benefit rates are 
    currently issued for certain industries, the Department has determined 
    that it is appropriate to allow variances to permit industry-specific 
    fringe benefits in certain limited circumstances upon application of 
    the contracting agency. Such variations from the single nationwide rate 
    will be allowed only on a showing that the variation is necessary and 
    proper in the public interest or to avoid the serious impairment of 
    government business. This might be satisfied, for example, where an 
    agency is unable to obtain contractors willing to bid on the services 
    because the service will be performed at the contractor's facility by 
    employees performing work for the Government and other customers, and 
    as a result, paying the required SCA fringe benefits would cause undue 
    disruption to the contractor's own work force and pay practices. In all 
    cases, in order to obtain a variance, it will also be necessary for the 
    contracting agency to provide comprehensive data from a valid survey 
    demonstrating the prevailing fringe benefits for the specific industry 
    (not broad ECI data), in order to demonstrate that the variance is in 
    accordance with the remedial purpose of the Act to protect prevailing 
    labor standards.
        This variance procedure does not constitute an opportunity to 
    request a separate fringe benefit package for every class of employee 
    or industry, but rather will require a showing of special 
    circumstances. As discussed, it is evident from the ECI that practices 
    do in fact vary widely among industries and occupations. Such an 
    industry-by-industry or occupation-by-occupation approach has already 
    been rejected through the consideration of the various alternatives and 
    the decision to issue fringe benefit determinations without regard to 
    occupation and based on cross-industry data.
        If the criteria for granting a variance are met, and industry-
    specific data are found to be adequate for establishing an alternative 
    prevailing fringe benefit determination, the party presenting such data 
    will be responsible for updating the data on a regular basis. If the 
    data are not regularly updated, then future procurements will be 
    subject to the standard cross-industry determination.
        Significant support was received for continuing the special fringe 
    benefit determination for the mail transportation industry. The 
    regulation acknowledges the appropriateness of industry determinations 
    under certain conditions; the specific merits of such an approach for 
    the mail industry is not appropriately an issue for this rulemaking 
    proceeding, but will receive the Department's prompt attention.
    
    Average Cost
    
        Approximately 15 organizations commented regarding the average cost 
    issue. Under the Department's regulations at Sec. 4.175, fringe benefit 
    contributions (or cash payments in lieu thereof) must ordinarily be 
    made with respect to each service employee in the amount specified on 
    the wage determination for all hours worked on the contract up to 40 
    hours per week. However, the regulations at Sec. 4.175(b) prescribe a 
    different compliance rule where the wage determination specifically 
    identifies the benefit as an ``average cost.'' Under the ``average 
    cost'' fringe benefit determination, a contractor's contributions to a 
    ``bona fide'' fringe benefit plan may vary among employees so long as 
    total contributions for all hours worked (not just hours up to 40 in a 
    workweek) by service employees on a particular contract average at 
    least the specified amount per hour per service employee. In practice 
    this average cost methodology is used only for the high ``total 
    benefits'' fringe benefit rate.
        CSA (and its 35 or so member organizations which filed comments in 
    general support of CSA's comments) supported the average cost concept 
    because of the flexibility it permits employers in the establishment of 
    fringe benefit plans. Specifically, the CSA (and CSA member 
    organizations which concurred with CSA's comments) stated that average 
    cost is the preferred method because it allows companies to offer 
    benefits in a comprehensive package that provides a variety of options. 
    It allows for flexible benefit design for employees and helps service 
    contractors to remain competitive. CSA stated that the average cost 
    concept is the basis for the development of group insurance premiums, 
    and that it allows for more efficiency in auditing. CSA believed that 
    eliminating average cost would cause such an administrative burden on 
    larger employers with self-insured medical plans that such an option 
    would no longer be feasible. CSA also believed that the average cost 
    concept allows small companies to obtain relief from administrative 
    burdens by ``outsourcing benefits administration and/or
    
    [[Page 68658]]
    
    purchasing `packaged service contract benefit plans.' ''
        National Star Route Mail Contractors' Association and seven member 
    organizations strongly oppose the use of an average cost concept. While 
    acknowledging that some type of average cost concept ``may be 
    advisable,'' National Star Route believes that any advantages would be 
    outweighed by the significant administrative and bookkeeping 
    difficulties inherent in such a system, especially in circumstances 
    where ``an employee works on several contracts covered by different 
    wage determinations.'' National Star Route was also concerned that use 
    of average cost would result in substantial decreases in benefits for 
    large numbers of service employees, would not guarantee equal benefits 
    to all employees, and would create the possibility that some employees 
    would not be provided with any benefits (e.g., employees not working 
    enough hours to become eligible for medical coverage). In short, 
    National Star Route believes that ``[i]nstead of averaging, employees 
    should be benefitted on their individual basis.''
        National Star Route also believes that an averaging system would 
    necessitate delay in some fringe benefit payments, since that averaging 
    process would have to await the closing of the pay period. Finally, 
    National Star Route expressed strong opposition to any methodology that 
    would require its members to make fringe benefit payment for hours 
    worked over 40. It stated that this would create such an increase in 
    their overall labor costs that they might be rendered non-competitive 
    against railroads, airlines and ``various transportation groups within 
    the U.S. Postal Service itself,'' thus causing the trucking industry to 
    lose its market share of mail transportation.
        Other commenters opposed to the average cost concept stated that 
    the unequal division of benefits would unfairly disadvantage single 
    versus married employees and short-term versus long-term employees. 
    Some commenters foresaw the possibility that ``a handful of very 
    compensated employees could tilt the average high enough to meet the 
    minimum average benefit with little or no contributions to the 
    `average' employee.''
        The Air Force also opposed the average cost concept in conjunction 
    with any of the proposed fringe benefit methodologies. The Air Force 
    believes that average cost allows some workers to receive preferential 
    compensation based on personal circumstances, and that some companies 
    use average cost to ``exclude specific workers or to cause portions of 
    their work force to suffer at the expense of more favored groups.'' The 
    Air Force is of the opinion that it is more appropriate ``for workers 
    with higher risks or with more costly health care plans to pay these 
    costs individually and not cause other workers to pay disproportionate 
    shares of earnings or benefits to subsidize others.'' The Air Force 
    also recommends that regulations be adopted to limit the hourly fringe 
    benefit contributions to the standard 40 hour work week since ``this is 
    routinely done for both the private sector and government sector 
    benefit plans.''
        The Department has concerns as to whether it is appropriate to 
    expand the average cost concept to the basic fringe benefit level to be 
    established under Alterative I. The Department is concerned that this 
    concept, which would involve a radical change for most contractors, did 
    not receive sufficient attention in the comments to warrant further 
    action at this time. The Department is also concerned about the 
    inequities of averaging, which allows contractors to make arbitrary 
    determinations to deny fringe benefits altogether to some workers or 
    classes of workers. Currently this system, which may be difficult to 
    understand and administer for small contractors, is utilized primarily 
    by sophisticated major contractors. Furthermore, the average cost 
    concept requires payments or contributions at the prescribed fringe 
    benefit level with respect to all hours worked, including hours over 
    40. Therefore this method could increase the costs of some contracts 
    where the employees work a significant amount of overtime.
        On the other hand, the Department recognizes the advantages of 
    allowing averaging across a workforce where a contractor has an 
    elaborate fringe benefit system with variable costs based on factors 
    such as choice of health benefit plans, and pension and sick leave 
    contributions, and payments which vary based on wages. The Department 
    is considering further rulemaking on this issue and would welcome 
    additional comments, including comments on any revisions to the current 
    averaging method which may be appropriate. If there is significant 
    support, the Department will consider further rulemaking. In the 
    meantime, the Department is making no change in the regulation at 
    Sec. 4.175(b).
    
    V. Comments and Analysis of Other Issues
    
    Time-Frame for Section 4(c) Substantial Variance Hearings
    
        The SCA and the regulations provide a procedure to request a 
    determination that collectively bargained wages and fringe benefit 
    rates required to be paid pursuant to Section 4(c) of the Act are 
    ``substantially at variance'' from prevailing local wages or fringe 
    benefits. The Department requested comments on a proposal suggested by 
    the National Performance Review (NPR) that the regulations be tightened 
    to provide a 60-day time-frame for completion of substantial variance 
    hearings.
        Seven organizations commented concerning the Section 4(c) variance 
    issue. SEIU, AFL-CIO, CSA, District No. 5--ITPE, NMU/MEBA (AFL-CIO), 
    and the LIUNA strongly opposed the proposal to reduce the 60-day time 
    limit to conduct the entire Section 4(c) hearing process. They believed 
    that the proposed restricted time frame for the completion of 
    substantial variance hearings is totally impractical and should, 
    therefore, be rejected. In fact, they believe the current time-frame of 
    60 days from the issuance of an Order of Reference until the opening of 
    the hearing to be too short; they recommended that if any changes in 
    the time-frames were to be made, the deadline should be extended.
        The unions stated that this ``fast track'' approach, suggested by 
    the National Performance Review without input from workers and unions, 
    ignores the practical difficulties of litigation. They point out that 
    in most instances where the contracting agency requests a substantial 
    variance hearing, ``the agency has enjoyed the benefit of months spent 
    assembling the data that it will use to challenge the wage rates 
    negotiated between the service contractor and the unions. The new time 
    frame suggested essentially forces the service contractor or union to 
    proceed to the substantial variance hearing without the time necessary 
    to assemble the supportive evidence.''
        The Army suggested that the time frame be expanded to within 90 to 
    120 days. They stated that the current system can take years and 
    affords no relief to the agencies.
        In contrast, the Air Force strongly supported any effort to reduce 
    the amount of time in the substantial variance process. The Air Force 
    stated that reducing the time-frames will force the parties to address 
    the issues in a prompt manner, while simplifying the process, and 
    stated that an unbiased third party should be able to look at the
    
    [[Page 68659]]
    
    facts and determine if the data supports the existence of a substantial 
    variance. They assert that the fact that the contractor must continue 
    to pay the rates being challenged in the hearing makes it imperative 
    that a timely and final decision be made. Finally, the Air Force 
    recommended that regulations be implemented to stay the payment of 
    rates that are being challenged until the final decision is made. In 
    this regard, the Air Force stated as follows:
    
        The current structure forces the contracting agency into paying 
    the cost of the increased rate or rates until a decision is made. 
    This leaves the contracting agency no way to recover funds paid on 
    rates that are ultimately determined to be substantially at 
    variance. If rates are deemed to be at variance, this results in 
    legal victory without proper cost recovery. If the rates were 
    temporarily frozen this would not result in a loss if the final 
    determination was made that rates did not substantially vary. It 
    would simply delay the payment long enough for that decision to be 
    made and applied.
    
        The regulations currently provide a period of only 85 days from the 
    date of the Order of Reference to the Chief Administrative Law Judge to 
    appoint an administrative law judge (ALJ) to conduct a hearing, to the 
    date of the ALJ decision. It is believed that this time-frame, if 
    followed, provides a sufficiently fast track for proceedings. In 
    addition, the Department has initiated a procedure to alert affected 
    parties (union, contractor and agency, as appropriate) when a request 
    for a substantial variance proceeding is received, in order to allow 
    additional preparation time.
    
    Other Proposals
    
        The Department also proposed certain minor, technical modifications 
    necessitated by amendments to the FLSA, a 1985 court decision, a 1983 
    treaty, and a 1986 intergovernmental compact. The Department received 
    no comments on these minor proposals and has decided to proceed with 
    these proposed minor changes.
        In order to conform to more recent amendments to the FLSA 
    establishing a new minimum wage, Sec. 4.2 is revised to delete the 
    reference to now out-of-date minimum wage rates; likewise, the tip 
    credit example in Section 4.6(q) is modified to delete the language in 
    the proviso that is based on the minimum wage rates provided by the 
    1978 amendments to the FLSA.
        The text of Sec. 4.112, which was invalidated by the 1985 court 
    decision in AFL-CIO v. Donovan, 757 F.2d 330 (D.C. Cir. 1985), is 
    modified to reinstate the language of the previous regulations as they 
    appeared in the July 1, 1983, edition of the CFR. Final regulations 
    published on October 27, 1983 (48 FR 49736), among other things, 
    established a new provision in 29 CFR 4.112 that would have excluded 
    from the Act's coverage contracts under which only a minor or 
    incidental portion of the services would be performed within the 
    geographical limits of the United States as defined in the Act. The 
    D.C. Circuit held that this new provision had been adopted in violation 
    of the notice-and-comment requirements of the Administrative Procedure 
    Act. Under the restored language, which conforms to the Department's 
    practice in the administration of this provision since the 1985 
    decision, if a service contract is performed in part within and in part 
    outside the United States, any portion performed in the United States 
    is covered.
        In addition, the restored regulatory language includes changes that 
    were necessary to conform to more recent enactments pertaining to the 
    geographic scope of the SCA. As indicated in Sec. 4.112, the SCA covers 
    contract services furnished ``in the United States,'' as that phrase is 
    defined in Section 8(d) of the Act. The geographical area included 
    within this definition was changed in the invalidated 1983 regulation 
    to conform to the Treaty of Friendship Between the United States and 
    the Republic of Kiribati, T.I.A.S. No. 10777, ratified June 21, 1983, 
    by excluding Canton Island. The regulations are further amended to take 
    into consideration changes necessitated by the 1986 Compact of Free 
    Association between the United States and the Governments of Marshall 
    Islands and the Federated States of Micronesia, set forth at 48 U.S.C. 
    1901 note, to exclude the Eniwetok Atoll, and the Kwajalein Atoll. In 
    addition, pursuant to the Covenant to Establish a Commonwealth of the 
    Northern Mariana Islands in Political Union with the United States of 
    America, set forth at 48 U.S.C. 1801 note, all laws not explicitly 
    dealt with elsewhere in the Covenant which are applicable to Guam and 
    are of general application to the States, are applicable to the 
    Commonwealth of the Northern Mariana Islands (CNMI). Because the SCA is 
    applicable to Guam, the regulation is amended to add the CNMI.
    
    VI. Conclusion
    
        For the foregoing reasons and after consideration of all of the 
    comments submitted in response to the proposed rule published on May 2, 
    1996, in the Federal Register (61 FR 19770) and the preliminary 
    regulatory impact analysis published in the Federal Register on October 
    25, 1996 (61 FR 55239), the Department is making the following changes 
    in the regulations:
        The Department has decided to issue a new Sec. 4.52 \10\ to set 
    forth the methodology for determining future prevailing fringe benefit 
    determinations. The Department is adopting the methodology provided in 
    Alternative I as the appropriate methodology for establishing minimum 
    health and welfare benefit rates under the SCA. Pursuant to this 
    methodology, the fringe benefit rate will be based on nationwide ECI 
    data for all employees in private industry, and will include all 
    benefits (excluding holidays and vacation, ``benefits otherwise 
    required by law'', and supplemental pay such as shift differentials, 
    considered to be wages under SCA).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \10\ Existing 4.52 and subsequent sections are renumbered 
    accordingly.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        This methodology replaces the current methodology of issuing two 
    benefit rates, ``insurance'' and ``total benefit,'' based on ECI size-
    of-establishment data, which have applied to SCA contracts on the basis 
    of the nature of the contract. However, the Department has decided to 
    ``grandfather'' the current ``total benefit'' rate at its present level 
    ($2.56) until the rate determined in accordance with Alternative I 
    equals or exceeds $2.56. This grandfathered rate will apply to those 
    contracts which currently are subject to the ``total benefit'' level, 
    and to future solicitations for such contracts; the grandfathered rate 
    will not apply to solicitations for new services.
        The regulations will also allow for a four-year ``phase-in'' period 
    under which only one-quarter of the difference between the current 
    ``insurance'' rate and the new all-industry rate will be implemented 
    for wage determinations issued on or after June 1, 1997. One-third of 
    the remainder of the increase would be implemented the following year, 
    and one-half of the remainder the following year. Beginning June 1, 
    2000, the new methodology will be fully implemented.
        The Department has also decided that it is necessary and proper in 
    the public interest and in accordance with the remedial purposes of the 
    Act to protect prevailing labor standards to issue a variance pursuant 
    to Section 4(b) of the Act and Sec. 4.123 of the regulations from the 
    Act's provisions that require fringe benefit determinations be made for 
    various classes of workers in the locality. Pursuant to this variance, 
    the Department will issue a nationwide level of benefits applicable to 
    all classes of employees. The Department has also
    
    [[Page 68660]]
    
    provided a procedure to permit contracting agencies to request a 
    variance to allow industry-specific fringe benefits in certain limited 
    circumstances. Finally, the regulation will continue to recognize as 
    prevailing those situations (ordinarily where the provisions of a 
    collective bargaining agreement are found to prevail) where a single 
    fringe benefit rate is paid with respect to a majority of the workers 
    in an occupation in a locality.
    
    VII. Executive Order 12866/Small Business Regulatory Enforcement 
    Fairness Act
    
        On the assumption that the change in methodology for determining 
    prevailing fringe benefits would have an annual impact on the economy 
    of $100 million or more, the Department prepared and sought comments on 
    its preliminary regulatory impact analysis (61 FR 55239 (October 25, 
    1996)). As discussed below, the Department has now completed its final 
    regulatory impact analysis and has concluded that this rule, after full 
    implementation, will have an annual effect on the economy of $100 
    million or more. Therefore the Department has concluded that the rule 
    is economically significant within the meaning of Executive Order 
    12866, and that the rule is a major rule within the meaning of Section 
    804(2) of the Small Business Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act. 
    However, the rule does not require an economic impact analysis under 
    Section 202 of the Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995 because it will 
    not require State, local, or tribal government, or private sector 
    expenditures, in excess of $100 million in any one year; rather, the 
    costs of the increases in fringe benefits will be borne by the Federal 
    government.
    
    Discussion of Comments
    
        Five commenters provided specific comments regarding the Wage and 
    Hour Division's SCA Occupational Employment Survey and Impact Analysis: 
    the AFL-CIO, the Contract Services Association, the Navy, the Air 
    Force, and the Army. Their comments concerned six areas:
        Survey Purpose: The Army and Navy were critical of the survey for 
    being directed exclusively toward Federal contractors whose wages and 
    benefits are already established by DOL's own wage determinations, not 
    by the labor market of the locality where the services are performed. 
    At the same time, the Navy contended that ``prevailing benefits are 
    unattainable by any reasonable or affordable survey effort.'' The Air 
    Force criticized the survey because it did not survey ``prevailing 
    rates'' in the locality labor market.
        These comments reflect a misunderstanding of the purpose of the 
    survey. The survey only sought information on occupational employment 
    under the SCA, along with the relevant wage determination issued for 
    each contract. As stated in several communications with each Federal 
    agency asked to participate in the survey, its purpose was to 
    ``estimate the distribution of employment by occupation on contracts 
    covered by the McNamara-O'Hara Service Contract Act.'' As noted in the 
    preliminary impact analysis, wage data utilized in the analysis were 
    from the Bureau of Labor Statistics, Employment Cost Index, not from 
    the fringe benefits paid by these contractors or from the wage 
    determinations used for these contracts.
        Survey Procedures: The Army, Navy and Air Force were critical of 
    the survey procedures. Specifically, the Navy contended that receipt of 
    the survey material was the first notification contracting agencies 
    received from DOL that such a survey was being conducted. The Navy also 
    contended that the survey methodology had not been discussed or 
    coordinated ahead of time with the contracting agencies. The Air Force 
    claimed that the survey was developed without agency Labor Advisor 
    input. The Army stated that there was not meaningful coordination and 
    communication between DOL and the Army.
        As summarized in the preliminary impact analysis, the then U.S. 
    Army Labor Advisor fully participated in the work group that helped 
    design the survey procedures and materials. Staff of the Office of 
    Federal Procurement Policy also participated in this process, which was 
    initiated in April 1995. In June 1995, the U.S. Air Force and General 
    Services Administration Labor Advisors participated in pilot testing 
    the survey process and materials, and were specifically requested to 
    provide ideas for improvement. The initial survey mailing was to each 
    Federal Procurement Agency's Federal Procurement Executive, in 
    September 1995. In that transmittal from the Wage and Hour 
    Administrator, top agency procurement officers were asked to 
    ``designate a data collection coordinator to assume overall 
    responsibility for your agency's role in this special study.'' Several 
    of these designees were the agency Labor Advisor, or comparable agency 
    staff. These coordinators were asked to ``contact each of the offices 
    responsible for contracts selected for this survey * * * and ensure 
    that data collection instructions are properly followed).'' Throughout 
    the course of the survey, written and telephone contacts were 
    maintained between the Wage and Hour Division and participating survey 
    coordinators.
        Survey Universe: The Contract Services Association, Navy, and Air 
    Force had concerns regarding the reliability of the survey universe. 
    The Contract Services Association and the Air Force stated that the 
    universe under represents the actual population of covered FTEs, 
    especially contracts under $25,000. At the same time, the Navy claimed 
    that the universe overstated the number of contracts, by including 
    procurements that actually were not covered by SCA.
        The preliminary impact analysis acknowledges that the FPDS excludes 
    certain segments of the contract universe. ``For example, it does not 
    contain data from the U.S. Postal Service, Air Force/Army Exchange 
    Service, and most contracts under $25,000. Therefore, since the impact 
    analysis is based upon a sample drawn from the FPDS population, 
    estimates made only represent the covered contracts included in the 
    FPDS, and should not be considered as representing the universe of all 
    covered contracts. For this reason, the focus of the Impact Analysis 
    was on the relative differences among costs likely to be generated by 
    each alternative listed.'' (61 FR 55246) As with many large surveys, it 
    should be expected that some sampled units may be wrongly included 
    because they should not have been included in the population. 
    Therefore, the questionnaires returned with notation by the contracting 
    offices indicating that the contract was not covered by SCA were 
    excluded from the survey and were used to correct the population of 
    SCA-covered contract obligations by SIC. These corrections were based 
    upon an assumption by the Wage and Hour Division that those closest to 
    contract administration are best informed regarding SCA coverage.
        Survey Findings: Both the Air Force and the Navy contended that the 
    survey overestimates the number of contracts assigned the current high 
    ($2.56) health and welfare benefit level and underestimates the number 
    assigned the low ($0.90) level. The Navy stated: ``If one were to 
    accept the contention made in DOL's survey impact report, that the 
    ``high'' health and welfare benefit level is paid on a large percentage 
    of all service contracts, that conclusion would be due in part to DOL's 
    own historical practice of applying that benefit level artificially.'' 
    The Navy further stated that the majority of contract workers are paid 
    at or near the low health and
    
    [[Page 68661]]
    
    welfare benefit level, while an Air Force internal study concluded that 
    64 percent of FTEs are at the low level and 19 percent at the high.
        In fact, the survey did not find a large number of contracts at the 
    high health and welfare benefit level. Table 4 of the preliminary 
    impact analysis clearly shows 80.7 percent of contracts at the low 
    level, 14.3 percent at the high level, and 5.0 percent set by 
    collective bargaining agreement pursuant to Section 4(c) of the Act. 
    The survey did find 42.5 percent of FTEs at the high level, 34.1 
    percent at the low, and 23.4 percent under Section 4(c). Of course, 
    there is no reason to believe that such ratios are necessarily the same 
    for all agencies.
        Survey Reliability: Four of the five commenting parties questioned 
    survey reliability. The Contract Services Association, Air Force, and 
    AFL-CIO expressed concern over the survey's ``7 percent'' response 
    rate. In addition, the Contract Services Association and the Air Force 
    questioned the size and representativeness of the sample. The AFL-CIO 
    claimed that nonresponse to the survey was a source of systematic bias 
    and error, resulting in population estimates not reflective of the SCA 
    population.
        As explained in the preliminary impact analysis, the survey usable 
    response rate was 20.2 percent of the sample (not 7 percent). The 
    sample, which was selected by contract value within industry group, 
    represented 35 percent of the number of contracts in the population, 
    and 63 percent of population contract value. Usable responses to the 
    survey represented 7.2 percent of population contracts and 19 percent 
    of contract value. At the same time, the apparent similarity to the 
    FPDS data in the universe by industry appears to limit the potential 
    for bias of the estimates obtained from the sample data. The process 
    whereby FTE/contract value ratios (by occupational group within 
    industry group), once established, were applied to the population (not 
    the sample) to estimate FTE totals would also tend to limit the 
    potential for bias caused by the low response rate.
        Impact Analysis: The Air Force claimed that the survey 
    underestimates the number of FTEs at the low health and welfare benefit 
    level, and therefore that the impact analysis underestimates cost 
    increases associated with the various alternatives. Based on its survey 
    of Air Force contracts, the agency developed its own estimate of the 
    cost of the current size-of-firm methodology ($612,202,240) and of the 
    cost of Alternative I, based on increasing the low benefit to $1.89 
    ($970,503,040). The Air Force then compared its estimate of the cost of 
    Alternative I to its calculation of the DOL estimates 11 
    ($720,462,080 and $961,800,320, respectively, according to the Air 
    Force). Therefore, the Air Force concludes that a total annual cost 
    increase of $358,300,800 would be incurred by accepting ``DOL's 
    proposed single fringe benefit alternative of $1.89 per hour,'' and not 
    the ``DOL estimate'' of $241,338,240.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \11\ The Department's proposed impact analysis as published in 
    the Federal Register did not set forth a total cost for the various 
    methodologies, but rather advised the public of the cost per FTE. 
    Therefore the Air Force did its own calculations of the Department's 
    estimated cost.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Even assuming that the results of Air Force's survey of the number 
    of contracts/employees subject to the two current fringe benefit rates 
    could be generalized to other agencies, the Air Force analysis appears 
    to be incorrect in four respects: (1) In doing its calculations of the 
    DOL estimate, the Air Force seems to have mistakenly multiplied the low 
    benefit health and welfare amount ($0.90) times the high benefit FTE 
    total (117,200), and the high benefit amount ($2.56) times the low 
    benefit FTE total (94,100). Therefore the Air Force underestimated the 
    DOL current cost estimate by $79,741,585. (2) By underestimating 
    current costs by almost $80 million, alternative cost increases were 
    overestimated by a like amount. (3) The Air Force cost computations for 
    Alternative I assumed the Department would continue to issue the high 
    rate for contracts currently receiving that rate. Although comments 
    were solicited on the issue of grandfathering the high rate, the 
    Department's estimate was not based on this assumption. (4) The Air 
    Force computations for combining the $2.56 with a $1.89 level appear to 
    have understated costs by over $5 million.
    
    Final Regulatory Impact Analysis
    
        After review of the comments, the Department has concluded that 
    there is no reason to change its estimates of the relative costs of the 
    various alternatives projected, as set forth in the preliminary 
    regulatory impact analysis.
        The Department has now obtained 1996 ECI data, which shows that the 
    all-private-industry, all-employee rate under Alternative I would 
    increase from $1.89 (1995 data) to $1.91 (1996 data) per hour. The 
    Department therefore has computed the cost of the alternative selected 
    utilizing 1996 data, and based on the survey projection that 44.5 
    percent of covered employees (94,048 FTE) are employed on contracts 
    currently subject to the low ($.90) benefit, and 55.5 percent (117,215 
    FTE) are employed on contracts currently subject to the high ($2.56) 
    benefit:
        1. The cost of prevailing fringe benefits determined in accordance 
    with the current methodology:
        Cost for employees receiving benefits of $.90 per hour: $.90  x  
    94,048 FTE  x  2080 hrs. = $176,057,856
        Cost for employees receiving benefits of $2.56 per hour: $2.56  x  
    117,215 FTE  x  2080 hrs. = $624,146,432
        Cost of current methodology: $176,057,856 + $624,146,432 = 
    $800,204,288 ($3788 per FTE)
        2. The first-year increase in the cost of the new methodology, 
    i.e., the cost of increasing the fringe benefits for employees 
    currently receiving $.90 per hour by $.25 per hour (one-fourth of the 
    increase to $1.91): $.25  x  94,048 FTE  x  2080 hrs. = $48,904,960 
    ($231 per FTE)
        Thus the first-year increase in costs caused by the new methodology 
    would be less than $50 million per year. In succeeding years it can be 
    anticipated that the increase in fringe benefits costs for employees 
    receiving the low rate may be somewhat higher than $.25 per hour as the 
    cost of fringe benefits varies from year to year. However, it is 
    anticipated that this increase will be more than offset by savings 
    where contracts currently requiring fringe benefits of $2.56 are not 
    succeeded by new contracts for substantially the same services; 
    contracts for new services which would have received the $2.56 rate 
    under the former procedures will receive the new ``all-industry, all-
    employee'' rate at the rate it is being phased in.
        By the fourth year, if the $1.91 rate were to hold, the increased 
    annual cost would be approximately: $1.01  x  94,048 FTE  x  2080 hrs. 
    = $197,576,038 ($935 per FTE)
        The administrative burden, if any, of the various alternatives 
    proposed is discussed in some detail in the preamble above. From the 
    comments, it is evident that the alternative chosen is among the least 
    burdensome of the various alternatives, since it does not involve 
    paying different benefits to different workers on the same contract or 
    in different regions of the country. However, during the period where 
    both rates are issued, those contractors which have contracts subject 
    to both rates (as is sometimes currently the case) will continue to 
    have the burden of administering two benefit programs. In addition, the 
    change in the fringe benefit rate will involve the administrative 
    burden of contractors making changes in their fringe benefit plans to 
    accommodate changed fringe
    
    [[Page 68662]]
    
    benefit rates, both during the transition period and as prevailing 
    benefits change over time.
        The Department has not been able to obtain data which would allow 
    it to quantify the benefits to the affected workers and to society of 
    providing workers prevailing fringe benefits, or to quantify any 
    indirect effects on jobs, productivity, or the Federal deficit, and no 
    such data was provided by commenters. A significant issue raised in the 
    comments, as discussed above, is the concern that the current low 
    ``insurance'' rate is not high enough to provide meaningful health 
    insurance to employees. The Department believes, as stated by many 
    commenters, that the rate established through the selected methodology 
    will allow employers to provide meaningful health benefits, with the 
    concomitant direct benefit to the employees and indirect benefit to 
    society from a healthier work force, including reduced pressure on 
    public health resources.
    
    IX. Regulatory Flexibility Act
    
        Under the Regulatory Flexibility Act, Public Law 96-354 (94 Stat. 
    1164; 5 U.S.C. 601 et seq.), Federal agencies are required to prepare a 
    final regulatory flexibility analysis that describes the anticipated 
    impact of a rule on small entities. After review of the comments 
    received and consideration of the various alternatives, the Department 
    has prepared the following regulatory flexibility analysis regarding 
    this rule:
        (1) The need for and objectives of the rule.
        SCA requires that the Department of Labor (DOL) determine locally-
    prevailing wages and fringe benefits for the various classes of service 
    employees performing contract work subject to the SCA. Contracts over 
    $2,500 (if the predecessor contract was not subject to a collective 
    bargaining agreement) are required to contain wage determinations 
    issued by DOL that specify the minimum monetary wages and fringe 
    benefits that must be paid to the various classes of workers who 
    perform work on the service contract, based upon rates determined by 
    DOL to be prevailing in the locality where the work is to be performed. 
    As discussed previously, fringe benefit data are not generally 
    available on an occupation-specific or on a locality basis, which 
    prompted DOL to issue fringe benefit determinations for health and 
    welfare based on nationwide data ever since SCA was enacted.
        The Service Employees International Union (SEIU) sued DOL in March 
    1991 in the United States District Court for the District of Columbia 
    over the longstanding administrative practice, since 1976, of issuing 
    two nationwide rates for health and welfare fringe benefits, and for 
    failure to periodically update SCA health and welfare fringe benefit 
    levels which, at that time, had not been updated since 1986 (SEIU v. 
    Martin, CA No. 91-0605 (JFP) (D.D.C. April 1, 1992)). In this court 
    challenge, the district court remanded the case to DOL for exhaustion 
    of administrative remedies and final agency action, which led to the 
    decisions of DOL's Board of Service Contract Appeals that remanded the 
    matter to the Wage and Hour Division to consider alternative 
    methodologies for implementing the statutory objectives (BSCA Case No. 
    92-01 (August 28, 1992) and Case No. 93-08 (September 23, 1993)). Based 
    on the Board's decisions, the Department decided that the best process 
    for developing a methodology to establish prevailing SCA fringe 
    benefits consistent with statutory requirements would be to propose 
    various alternatives through rulemaking. In the meantime, SEIU moved 
    the district court to reopen its case against the Department. The 
    district court dismissed the case without prejudice to SEIU's right to 
    reopen for reconsideration upon a showing that DOL has not adopted a 
    final rule in this matter by July 31, 1996 (SEIU v. Reich, CA No. 91-
    0605 (CRR) (D.D.C. January 19, 1996)).
        On May 2, 1996, the Administrator of the Wage and Hour Division 
    published a Notice in the Federal Register (61 FR 19770) proposing for 
    public comment various alternative fringe benefit determination 
    methodologies. As explained in the proposed rule, however, it was not 
    feasible to publish a regulatory impact analysis for comment with the 
    proposed rule. At the time the Department was completing the 
    development of data on the occupational mix of service contract 
    employees in order to provide a basis for the impact analysis. That 
    analysis was completed and published for comment on October 25, 1996 
    (61 FR 55239). In the meantime, the Court set a deadline for 
    publication of the final rule of December 24, 1996. SEIU v. Reich, CA 
    No. 91-0605 (August 27, 1996).
        (2) Summary of significant issues raised by the public comments in 
    response to the initial regulatory flexibility analysis.
        The Department received a number of comments regarding the economic 
    impact analysis and the survey that was conducted to determine the 
    occupational mix on Federal service contracts. Those comments are 
    specifically addressed in the economic impact analysis section above. 
    No comments were received on the initial regulatory flexibility 
    analysis.
        (3) Number of small entities covered under the rule.
        The definition of ``small business'' varies considerably depending 
    upon the policy issues and circumstances under review, the industry 
    being studied, and the measures used. The Small Business 
    Administration's Office of Advocacy generally uses employment data as a 
    basis for size comparisons, with firms having fewer than 100 employees 
    or fewer than 500 employees defined as small.12
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \12\ The State of Small Business: A Report of the President 
    Transmitted to the Congress (1991), together with The Annual Report 
    on Small Business and Competition of the U.S. Small Business 
    Administration (United States Government Printing Office, 
    Washington, D.C., 1991), p. 19. A more detailed breakdown also used 
    is: under 20 employees, very small; 20-99, small; 100-499, medium-
    sized; and over 500, large. In general, a business bidding on a 
    government contract is regarded as small if it has fewer than 500 
    employees (see p. 221).
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Statistics published by the Internal Revenue Service indicate that 
    in 1990, an estimated 20.4 million business tax returns were filed for 
    4.4 million corporations, 1.8 million partnerships, and 14.2 million 
    sole proprietorships, most of which are ``small''--fewer than 7,000 
    would qualify as large businesses if an employment measure of 500 
    employees or less is used to define small and medium-sized 
    businesses.13
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \13\ U.S. Department of the Treasury, Internal Revenue Service, 
    SO Bulletin (Spring 1990) Table 19; reprinted by SBA in The State of 
    Small Business (1991), Id., p. 21.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Federal procurement data are compiled and reported by the Federal 
    Procurement Data Center (FPDC) in the Federal Procurement Data System 
    Federal Procurement Report (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing 
    Office). The value of Federal contracts and volume of contract 
    ``actions'' are currently reported individually to the FPDC for 
    contract actions exceeding $25,000; actions of less than $25,000 are 
    reported only in the aggregate. A contract ``action'' differs from an 
    initial contract ``award'' because a single contract may involve more 
    than one action--for example, a modification to an initial contract 
    award is reported to the FPDC as a separate action and may involve the 
    obligation or de-obligation of funds.
        Small businesses were awarded $58.8 billion of the $184.2 billion 
    spent by the Federal government on goods and services in Fiscal Year 
    (FY) 1989, including $31.6 billion awarded directly to small firms and 
    $27.2 billion awarded to small subcontractors by Federal
    
    [[Page 68663]]
    
    prime contractors.14 Small firms accounted for more than one-half 
    (51.3 percent) of the value of contracts under $25,000, but only 14.1 
    percent of those over $25,000 in FY 1989.15 Since FY 1979 when the 
    FPDC first began reporting procurement data regularly, the share of 
    Federal procurement dollars awarded to small firms has fluctuated 
    between 14 and 16 percent over the entire period--for FY 1989 it was 
    14.1 percent overall.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \14\ The State of Small Business, supra at 220.
        \15\ Ibid.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Of the major product/service categories under which contract 
    actions are reported to the FPDC, the ``other services'' category 
    (which includes a variety of non-construction activities ranging from 
    technical, sociological, administrative, and other professional 
    services, to installation, maintenance, and repair of equipment) 
    amounted to 28.9 percent of the total Federal prime contract actions 
    reported individually in FY 1989. Small businesses were awarded $6.8 
    billion or 14.7 percent of the contract dollars awarded for services in 
    FY 1989.16
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \16\ Id., pp. 223, 226 & 235-237.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        This FPDS data on small business awards does not correlate 
    precisely with the number of contract actions or contract dollars 
    awarded that are subject to the SCA. However, the ``services'' category 
    can be considered a reliable proxy for analyzing the universe of SCA-
    covered contracts reported to the FPDC that may be awarded to small 
    businesses. Of a total 502,138 contract actions valued at $177.8 
    billion that were individually reported to the FPDC in FY 1992 (i.e., 
    actions over $25,000 each), 82,957 contract actions, valued at $18.1 
    billion, were classified as subject to the SCA.17 Of these awards, 
    we estimate that $2.66 billion (14.7 percent) went to small businesses. 
    These figures, however, do not include any portion of the contract 
    actions not individually reported but reported in summary to the FPDC, 
    which totaled 19.6 million contract actions valued at $22.02 
    billion.18 Based upon the percentage of contract actions and 
    contract dollars in the services category that were reported 
    individually to FPDC as being subject to SCA, we estimate that an 
    additional 2,905,696 actions, valued at $2.2 billion, of the actions 
    reported in summary to the FPDC were subject to SCA. Of these awards, 
    we estimate that $1.1 billion (50 percent) went to small businesses.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \17\ Federal Procurement Data System Standard Report, Fiscal 
    Year 1992, Fourth Quarter, pp. 74-75.
        \18\ Id., p. 74.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        No current employment data are available by size of business that 
    would relate to Federal contracts awarded subject to SCA. (The SBA 
    measures employment change on a current basis for each small- or large-
    business-dominated industry using Bureau of Labor Statistics payroll 
    data.19)
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        \19\ Id., p. 34.
    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        (4) Reporting, Recordkeeping and Other Compliance Requirements of 
    the Rule.
        All SCA-covered contractors (including small businesses) are 
    required to maintain records specified under 29 CFR Part 4 that 
    demonstrate compliance with the statutory requirements to furnish 
    equivalent fringe benefits or cash equivalents at not less than 
    prevailing rates.
        This final rule, which relates to the procedures to be followed by 
    DOL for determining prevailing health and welfare fringe benefits to be 
    paid to service employees working on Federal service contracts covered 
    by SCA, contains no new reporting, recordkeeping, or other compliance 
    requirements applicable to small businesses. Although some of the 
    proposed alternatives likely would have involved additional 
    recordkeeping obligations, the alternative selected does not require 
    any additional recordkeeping. In fact, contractor comments regarding 
    the ease of administration and compliance under this alternative were 
    an important factor in selecting the alternative.
        (5) Description of the steps taken to minimize the significant 
    economic impact on small entities consistent with the objectives of the 
    Service Contract Act.
        As noted in the discussion of the various alternatives, the 
    methodology selected (Alternative I) was clearly the alternative 
    favored by most employers, many of which were small businesses. The 
    factual, policy and legal reasons for selecting Alternative I and the 
    reasons for rejecting the other alternatives are fully addressed in the 
    discussion of the various alternatives. A key factor underlying the 
    support of Alternative I by many employers, including many small 
    entities, was the ease of administration and compliance under this 
    alternative. In addition, this alternative was favored because it 
    produces a benefit rate that is sufficient to allow all service 
    contractors to purchase a reasonable benefit package for all contract 
    workers. Under the current two-tier benefit structure, the low level 
    benefit has been generally considered to be too low for employers to 
    purchase even a minimal health and welfare package for their workers.
        Proposed Alternatives II--IV were generally viewed by most 
    commenters as being administratively difficult, especially for small 
    employers. Notwithstanding the greater administrative burden, these 
    alternatives were favored by some because they yielded a lower fringe 
    benefit rate for many workers. For service contractors in general, 
    however, these alternatives would have imposed significant 
    administration and compliance difficulties.
    
    List of Subjects in 29 CFR Part 4
    
        Administrative practice and procedures, Employee benefit plans, 
    Government contracts, Investigations, Labor, Law enforcement, Minimum 
    wages, Penalties, Recordkeeping requirements, Reporting requirements, 
    Wages.
        Accordingly, for the reasons set out in the preamble, 29 CFR Part 4 
    is amended as set forth below:
    
    PART 4--LABOR STANDARDS FOR FEDERAL SERVICE CONTRACTS
    
        1. The authority citation for Part 4 continues to read as follows:
    
        Authority: 41 U.S.C. 351, et seq., 79 Stat. 1034, as amended in 
    86 Stat. 789, 90 Stat. 2358; 41 U.S.C. 38 and 39; 5 U.S.C. 301; and 
    108 Stat. 4101(c).
    
        2. Section 4.2 of Subpart A is revised to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 4.2  Payment of minimum wage specified in section 6(a)(1) of the 
    Fair Labor Standards Act of 1938 under all service contracts.
    
        Section 2(b)(1) of the Service Contract Act of 1965 provides in 
    effect that, regardless of contract amount, no contractor or 
    subcontractor performing work under any Federal contract the principal 
    purpose of which is to furnish services through the use of service 
    employees shall pay any employees engaged in such work less than the 
    minimum wage specified in section 6(a)(1) of the Fair Labor Standards 
    Act of 1938, as amended.
        3. The introductory text of Sec. 4.6(q) of Subpart A is revised to 
    read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 4.6  Labor standard clauses for Federal service contracts 
    exceeding $2,500.
    
    * * * * *
        (q) Where an employee engaged in an occupation in which he or she 
    customarily and regularly receives more than $30 a month in tips, the 
    amount of tips received by the employee may be credited by the employer 
    against the minimum wage required by Section 2(a)(1) or 2(b)(1) of the 
    Act to the extent permitted by section 3(m) of the Fair
    
    [[Page 68664]]
    
    Labor Standards Act and Regulations, 29 CFR Part 531. To utilize this 
    proviso:
    * * * * *
    
    
    Secs. 4.52 through 4.55  [Redesignated as Secs. 4.53 through 4.56]
    
        4. Sections 4.52 through 4.55 of Subpart B are redesignated as 
    Secs. 4.53 through 4.56 respectively.
        5. A new Sec. 4.52 is added to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 4.52  Fringe benefit determinations.
    
        (a) Wage determinations issued pursuant to the Service Contract Act 
    ordinarily contain provisions for vacation and holiday benefits 
    prevailing in the locality. In addition, wage determinations contain a 
    prescribed minimum rate for all other benefits, such as insurance, 
    pension, etc., which are not required as a matter of law (i.e., 
    excluding Social Security, unemployment insurance, and workers' 
    compensation payments and similar statutory benefits), based upon the 
    sum of the benefits contained in the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, 
    Employment Cost Index (ECI), for all employees in private industry, 
    nationwide (and excluding ECI components for supplemental pay, such as 
    shift differential, which are considered wages rather than fringe 
    benefits under SCA). Pursuant to Section 4(b) of the Act and 
    Sec. 4.123, the Secretary has determined that it is necessary and 
    proper in the public interest, and in accord with remedial purposes of 
    the Act to protect prevailing labor standards, to issue a variation 
    from the Act's requirement that fringe benefits be determined for 
    various classes of service employees in the locality.
        (b) The minimum rate for all benefits (other than holidays and 
    vacation) which are not legally required, as prescribed in paragraph 
    (a) of this section, shall be phased in over a four-year period 
    beginning June 1, 1997. The first year the rate will be $.90 per hour 
    plus one-fourth of the difference between $.90 per hour and the rate 
    prescribed in paragraph (a) of this section; the second year the rate 
    will be increased by one-third of the difference between the rate set 
    the first year and the rate prescribed; the third year the rate will be 
    increased by one-half of the difference between the rate set in the 
    second year and the rate prescribed; and the fourth year and thereafter 
    the rate will be the rate prescribed in paragraph (a) of this section.
        (c) Where it is determined pursuant to Sec. 4.51(b) that a single 
    fringe benefit rate is paid with respect to a majority of the workers 
    in a class of service employees engaged in similar work in a locality, 
    that rate will be determined to prevail notwithstanding the rate which 
    would otherwise be prescribed pursuant to this section. Ordinarily, it 
    will be found that a majority of workers receive fringe benefits at a 
    single level where those workers are subject to a collective bargaining 
    agreement whose provisions have been found to prevail in the locality.
        (d) A significant number of contracts contain a prevailing fringe 
    benefit rate of $2.56 per hour. Generally, these contracts are large 
    base support contracts, contracts requiring competition from large 
    corporations, contracts requiring highly technical services, and 
    contracts solicited pursuant to A-76 procedures (displacement of 
    Federal employees), as well as successor contracts thereto. The $2.56 
    benefit rate shall continue to be issued for all contracts containing 
    the $2.56 benefit rate, as well as resolicitations and other successor 
    contracts for substantially the same services, until the fringe benefit 
    rate determined in accordance with paragraphs (a) and (b) of this 
    section equals or exceeds $2.56 per hour.
        (e) Variance procedure. (1) The Department will consider variations 
    requested by contracting agencies pursuant to Section 4(b) of the Act 
    and Sec. 4.123, from the methodology described in paragraph (a) of this 
    section for determining prevailing fringe benefit rates. This variation 
    procedure will not be utilized to routinely permit separate fringe 
    benefit packages for classes of employees and industries, but rather 
    will be limited to the narrow circumstances set forth herein where 
    special needs of contracting agencies require this procedure. Such 
    variations will be considered where the agency demonstrates that 
    because of the special circumstances of the particular industry, the 
    variation is necessary and proper in the public interest or to avoid 
    the serious impairment of government business. Such a demonstration 
    might be made, for example, where an agency is unable to obtain 
    contractors willing to bid on a contract because the service will be 
    performed at the contractor's facility by employees performing work for 
    the Government and other customers, and as a result, paying the 
    required SCA fringe benefits would cause undue disruption to the 
    contractor's own work force and pay practices.
        (2) It will also be necessary for the agency to demonstrate that a 
    variance is in accordance with the remedial purpose of the Act to 
    protect prevailing labor standards, by providing comprehensive data 
    from a valid survey demonstrating the prevailing fringe benefits for 
    the specific industry. If the agency does not continue to provide 
    current data in subsequent years, the variance will be withdrawn and 
    the rate prescribed in paragraph (a) of this section will be issued for 
    the contract.
        6. Section 4.112 of Subpart C is revised to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 4.112  Contracts to furnish services ``in the United States.''
    
        (a) The Act and the provisions of this part apply to contract 
    services furnished ``in the United States,'' including any State of the 
    United States, the District of Columbia, Puerto Rico, the Virgin 
    Islands, Outer Continental Shelf lands as defined in the Outer 
    Continental Shelf Lands Act, American Samoa, Guam, the Commonwealth of 
    the Northern Mariana Islands, Wake Island, and Johnston Island. The 
    definition expressly excludes any other territory under the 
    jurisdiction of the United States and any United States base or 
    possession within a foreign country. Services to be performed 
    exclusively on a vessel operating in international waters outside the 
    geographic areas named in this paragraph would not be services 
    furnished ``in the United States'' within the meaning of the Act.
        (b) A service contract to be performed in its entirety outside the 
    geographical limits of the United States as thus defined is not covered 
    and is not subject to the labor standards of the Act. However, if a 
    service contract is to be performed in part within and in part outside 
    these geographic limits, the stipulations required by Sec. 4.6 or 
    Sec. 4.7, as appropriate, must be included in the invitation for bids 
    or negotiation documents and in the contract, and the labor standards 
    must be observed with respect to that part of the contract services 
    that is performed within these geographic limits. In such a case the 
    requirements of the Act and of the contract clauses will not be 
    applicable to the services furnished outside the United States.
    
        Signed at Washington, D.C., on this 24th day of December, 1996.
    Gene Karp,
    Deputy Assistant Secretary for Employment Standards.
    [FR Doc. 96-33222 Filed 12-26-96; 10:05 am]
    BILLING CODE 4510-27-P
    
    
    

Document Information

Effective Date:
6/1/1997
Published:
12/30/1996
Department:
Labor Department
Entry Type:
Rule
Action:
Final rule.
Document Number:
96-33222
Dates:
June 1, 1997.
Pages:
68647-68664 (18 pages)
RINs:
1215-AA78: Labor Standards for Federal Service Contracts
RIN Links:
https://www.federalregister.gov/regulations/1215-AA78/labor-standards-for-federal-service-contracts
PDF File:
96-33222.pdf
CFR: (7)
29 CFR 4.175(b)
29 CFR 4.2
29 CFR 4.6
29 CFR 4.7
29 CFR 4.52
More ...