96-21589. Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996; Interconnection between Local Exchange Carriers and Commercial Mobile Radio Service Providers; Implementation of Sections 3(n) and 332 of the ...  

  • [Federal Register Volume 61, Number 169 (Thursday, August 29, 1996)]
    [Rules and Regulations]
    [Pages 45476-45637]
    From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
    [FR Doc No: 96-21589]
    
    
    
    [[Page 45475]]
    
    
    _______________________________________________________________________
    
    Part II
    
    
    
    
    
    Federal Communications Commission
    
    
    
    
    
    _______________________________________________________________________
    
    
    
    47 CFR Parts 1, 20, 51, and 90
    
    
    
    Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the 
    Telecommunications Act of 1996; Interconnection Between Local Exchange 
    Carriers and Commercial Mobile Radio Service Providers; Implementation 
    of Sections 3(n) and 332 of the Communications Act; Final Rule
    
    Federal Register / Vol. 61, No. 169, Thursday, August 29, 1996 / 
    Rules and Regulations
    
    [[Page 45476]]
    
    
    
    FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
    
    47 CFR Parts 1, 20, 51 and 90
    
    [CC Docket No. 96-98, CC Docket No. 95-185, GN Docket No. 93-252; FCC 
    96-325]
    
    
    Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the 
    Telecommunications Act of 1996; Interconnection between Local Exchange 
    Carriers and Commercial Mobile Radio Service Providers; Implementation 
    of Sections 3(n) and 332 of the Communications Act
    
    AGENCY: Federal Communications Commission.
    
    ACTION: Final rule.
    
    -----------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    SUMMARY: The Report and Order released August 8, 1996 promulgates 
    national rules and regulations implementing the statutory requirements 
    of the Telecommunications Act of 1996 (the 1996 Act) intended to 
    encourage the development of competition in local exchange and exchange 
    access markets. The Report and Order adopts certain national rules that 
    are consistent with the terms and goals of the 1996 Act and adopts 
    minimum requirements which states may augment with their own 
    requirements that are consistent with the 1996 Act and the Commission's 
    rules thereunder. The Report and Order also incorporates and resolves 
    issues regarding interconnection between CMRS providers and LECs, which 
    initially were raised in a separate docket. The Report and Order 
    enables the states and the Commission to begin implementing the local 
    competition provisions of the 1996 Act.
    
    EFFECTIVE DATE: September 30, 1996.
    
    FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Lisa Gelb, Attorney, Common Carrier 
    Bureau, Policy and Program Planning Division, (202) 418-1580, or David 
    Sieradzki, Attorney, Common Carrier Bureau, Competitive Pricing 
    Division, (202) 418-1520. For additional information concerning the 
    information collections contained in this Report and Order contact 
    Dorothy Conway at 202-418-0217, or via the Internet at dconway@fcc.gov.
    
    SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a summary of the Commission's Report 
    and Order adopted August 1, 1996, and released August 8, 1996. The full 
    text of this Report and Order is available for inspection and copying 
    during normal business hours in the FCC Reference Center (Room 239), 
    1919 M St., NW., Washington, DC. The complete text also may be obtained 
    through the World Wide Web, at http://www.fcc.gov/Bureaus/Common 
    Carrier/Orders/fcc96325.wp, or may be purchased from the Commission's 
    copy contractor, International Transcription Service, Inc., (202) 857-
    3800, 2100 M St., NW., Suite 140, Washington, DC 20037. Pursuant to the 
    Telecommunications Act of 1996, the Commission released a Notice of 
    Proposed Rulemaking, Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions 
    of the Telecommunications Act of 1996, CC Docket No. 96-98 (61 FR 18311 
    (April 25, 1996)) to seek comment on rules to implement sections 251, 
    252 and 253 of the 1996 Act.
    
    General
    
        Section 251 of the 1996 Act imposes specific obligations on 
    telecommunications carriers designed to promote competition in local 
    exchange markets across the country. Section 251(a) imposes general 
    obligations on all telecommunications carriers. Section 251(b) imposes 
    on all LECs certain requirements, including the obligation to provide 
    resale, access to rights-of-way, and to establish reciprocal 
    compensation arrangements for transport and termination of traffic. 
    Section 251(c) requires incumbent LECs to make available to new 
    entrants interconnection and access to unbundled network elements, and 
    to offer LEC retail services for resale to telecommunications carriers 
    at wholesale rates. Access to unbundled elements and resale 
    opportunities are methods by which telecommunications carriers can 
    enter the local exchange market.
    
    Interconnection
    
        Section 251(c)(2) of the 1996 Act requires incumbent LECs to 
    provide interconnection to any requesting telecommunications carrier at 
    any technically feasible point. The interconnection must be at least 
    equal in quality to that provided by the incumbent LEC to itself or its 
    affiliates, and must be provided on rates, terms, and conditions that 
    are just, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory. The term 
    ``interconnection'' under section 251(c)(2) refers only to the physical 
    linking of two networks for the mutual exchange of traffic. The 
    Commission identifies a minimum set of ``technically feasible'' points 
    of interconnection: (1) the line-side of a local switch; (2) the trunk-
    side of a local switch; (3) the trunk interconnection points for a 
    tandem-switch; (4) central office cross-connect points; and (5) out-of-
    band signaling transfer points. In addition, the points of access to 
    unbundled elements are also technically feasible points of 
    interconnection. The Commission states that telecommunications carriers 
    may request interconnection under section 251(c)(2) to provide 
    telephone exchange service or exchange access service, or both. If the 
    request is for such purposes, the incumbent LEC must provide 
    interconnection in accordance with section 251(c)(2) and the 
    Commission's rules thereunder to any telecommunications carrier, 
    including interexchange carriers and commercial mobile radio service 
    (CMRS) providers.
    
    Access to Unbundled Elements
    
        Section 251(c)(3) requires incumbent LECs to provide requesting 
    telecommunications carriers nondiscriminatory access to network 
    elements on an unbundled basis at any technically feasible point on 
    rates, terms, and conditions that are just, reasonable, and 
    nondiscriminatory. The Commission identifies a minimum set of network 
    elements that incumbent LECs must provide under this section. States 
    may require incumbent LECs to provide additional network elements on an 
    unbundled basis. The Commission identified the seven following network 
    elements: network interface devices, local loops, local and tandem 
    switches (including all software features provided by such switches), 
    interoffice transmission facilities, signalling and call-related 
    database facilities, operations support systems and information and 
    operator and directory assistance facilities. Incumbent LECs must 
    provide requesting carriers nondiscriminatory access to operations 
    support systems and information. The Order requires incumbent LECs to 
    provide access to network elements in a manner that allows requesting 
    carriers to combine such elements as they choose. Incumbent LECs may 
    not impose restrictions upon the use of network elements.
    
    Methods of Obtaining Interconnection and Access to Unbundled 
    Elements
    
        Section 251(c)(6) requires incumbent LECs to provide physical 
    collocation of equipment necessary for interconnection or access to 
    unbundled network elements at the incumbent LEC's premises, except that 
    the incumbent LEC may provide virtual collocation if it demonstrates to 
    the state commission that physical collocation is not practical for 
    technical reasons or because of space limitations. Incumbent LECs are 
    required to provide any technically feasible method of interconnection 
    or access requested by a telecommunications carrier, including
    
    [[Page 45477]]
    
    physical collocation, virtual collocation, and interconnection at meet 
    points. The Commission adopts, with certain modifications, the physical 
    and virtual collocation requirements it adopted earlier in the Expanded 
    Interconnection proceeding. The Commission also establishes rules 
    interpreting the requirements of section 251(c)(6).
    
    Pricing Methodologies
    
        The 1996 Act requires the states to set prices for interconnection 
    and unbundled elements that are cost-based, nondiscriminatory, and may 
    include a reasonable profit. To help the states accomplish this, the 
    Commission has concluded that the state commissions should set 
    arbitrated rates for interconnection and access to unbundled elements 
    pursuant a forward-looking economic cost pricing methodology. The 
    Commission has concluded that the prices that new entrants pay for 
    interconnection and unbundled elements should be based on the local 
    telephone companies Total Element Long-Run Incremental Cost (TELRIC) of 
    providing a particular network element, plus a reasonable share of 
    forward-looking joint and common costs. States will determine, among 
    other things, the appropriate risk-adjusted cost of capital and 
    depreciation rates. If states are unable to conduct a cost study and 
    apply an economic costing methodology within the statutory time frame 
    for arbitrating interconnection disputes, the Commission has 
    established default ceilings and ranges for the states to apply, on an 
    interim basis, to interconnection arrangements. The Commission 
    establishes a default range of 0.2-0.4 cents per minute for switching, 
    plus access charges as discussed below. For tandem switching, the 
    Commission establishes a default ceiling of 0.15 cents per minute. The 
    Order also will establish default ceilings for the other unbundled 
    network elements. These default provisions might provide an 
    administratively simpler approach for state establishment of prices, 
    for a limited interim period, and states, in the exercise of their 
    discretion, select the specific price within that range, or subject to 
    that ceiling.
    
    Access Charges for Unbundled Switching
    
        Nothing in the Commission's Order alters the collection of access 
    charges paid by an interexchange carrier under Part 69 of the 
    Commission's rules, when the incumbent LEC provides exchange access 
    service to an interexchange carrier, either directly or through service 
    resale. Because access charges are not included in the cost-based 
    prices for unbundled network elements, and because certain portions of 
    access charges currently support the provision of universal service, 
    until the access charge reform and universal service proceedings have 
    been completed, the Commission is continuing to provide for access 
    charge recovery with respect to use of an incumbent LEC's unbundled 
    switching element, for a defined period of time. This will minimize the 
    possibility that the incumbent LEC will be able to ``double recover,'' 
    through access charges, the facility costs that new entrants have 
    already paid to purchase unbundled elements, while preserving the 
    status quo with respect to subsidy payments. Under this Order, 
    incumbent LECs will recover from interconnecting carriers the carrier 
    common line charge and a charge equal to 75% of the transport 
    interconnection charge for all interstate minutes traversing the 
    incumbent LECs local switches for which the interconnecting carriers 
    pay unbundled network element charges. This aspect of the Order expires 
    at the earliest of: 1) June 30, 1997; 2) issuance of final decisions by 
    the Commission in the universal service and access reform proceedings; 
    or 3) if the incumbent LEC is a Bell Operating Company (BOC), the date 
    on which that BOC is authorized under section 271 of the Act to provide 
    in-region interLATA service, for any given state.
    
    Resale
    
        The 1996 Act requires all incumbent LECs to offer for resale any 
    telecommunications service that the carrier provides at retail to 
    subscribers who are not telecommunications carriers. Resale will be an 
    important entry strategy both in the short term for many new entrants 
    as they build out their own facilities and for small businesses that 
    cannot afford to compete in the local exchange market by purchasing 
    unbundled elements or by building their own networks. The 1996 Act's 
    pricing standard for wholesale rates requires state commissions to 
    identify what marketing, billing, collection, and other costs will be 
    avoided or that are avoidable by incumbent LECs when they provide 
    services wholesale, and calculate the portion of the retail rates for 
    those services that is attributable to the avoided and avoidable costs. 
    To define clearly a wholesale service, the Commission has identified 
    certain avoided costs. The application of this definition is left to 
    the states. If a state elects not to implement the methodology, it may 
    elect, on an interim basis, a discount rate from within a default range 
    of discount rates established by the Commission. The Commission 
    establishes a default discount range of 17-25% off retail prices, 
    leaving the states to set the specific rate within that range, in the 
    exercise of their discretion.
    
    Transport and Termination
    
        The 1996 Act requires that charges for transport and termination of 
    traffic be cost-based. The Commission concludes that state commissions, 
    during arbitrations, should set symmetrical prices based on the local 
    telephone company's forward-looking costs. The state commissions would 
    also use the TELRIC methodology when establishing rates for transport 
    and termination. The Commission establishes a default range of 0.2-0.4 
    cents per minute for end office termination for states which have not 
    conducted a TELRIC cost study. The Commission finds significant 
    evidence in the record in support of the lower end of the ranges. In 
    addition, the Commission finds that additional reciprocal charges could 
    apply to termination through a tandem switch. The default ceiling for 
    tandem switching is 0.15 cents per minute, plus applicable charges for 
    transport from the tandem switch to the end office. Each state opting 
    for the default approach for a limited period of time, may select a 
    rate within that range.
    
    Commercial Mobile Radio Service
    
        In the Order, the Commission concludes that CMRS providers are 
    telecommunications carriers, and therefore are entitled to reciprocal 
    compensation arrangements under section 251(b)(5). The Commission also 
    concludes that under section 251(b)(5) a LEC may not charge a CMRS 
    provider, including a paging company, or any other carrier for 
    terminating LEC-originated traffic. The Commission also states that 
    CMRS providers (specifically cellular, broadband PCS, and covered 
    specialized mobile radio (SMR) providers) offer telephone exchange 
    services, and such providers therefore may request interconnection 
    under section 251(c)(2). The Commission determines that CMRS providers 
    should not be classified as LECs at this time. In this decision, the 
    Commission applied sections 251 and 252 to LEC-CMRS interconnection. 
    The Commission acknowledges that section 332 is also a basis for 
    jurisdiction over LEC-CMRS interconnection, but declined to define the 
    precise extent of that jurisdiction at this time.
    
    [[Page 45478]]
    
    Access to Rights of Way
    
        The Commission also amends its rules to implement the pole 
    attachment provisions of the 1996 Act. Specifically, the Commission 
    establishes procedures for nondiscriminatory access by cable television 
    systems and telecommunications carriers to poles, ducts, conduits, and 
    rights-of-way owned by utilities or LECs. The Order includes several 
    specific rules as well as a number of more general guidelines designed 
    to facilitate the negotiation and mutual performance of fair, pro-
    competitive access agreements without the need for regulatory 
    intervention. Additionally, an expedited dispute resolution is provided 
    when good faith negotiations fail, as are requirements concerning 
    modifications to poles, ducts, conduits, and rights-of-way and the 
    allocation of the costs of such modifications.
    
    Exemptions, Suspensions, and Modifications of Section 251 Requirements 
    for Rural and Small Telephone Companies
    
        Section 251(f)(1) of the 1996 Act provides for exemption of the 
    requirements in section 251(c) for rural telephone companies (as 
    defined by the 1996 Act) under certain circumstances. Section 251(f)(2) 
    permits LECs with fewer than 2 percent of the nation's subscriber lines 
    to petition for suspension or modification of the requirements in 
    sections 251(b) or (c).
        States are primarily responsible for interpreting the provisions of 
    section 251(f) through rulemaking and adjudicative proceedings, and are 
    responsible for determining whether a LEC in a particular instance is 
    entitled to exemption, suspension, or modification of section 251 
    requirements.
        The Commission establishes a very limited set of rules interpreting 
    the requirements of section 251(f):
    
    --LECs bear the burden of proving to the state commission that a 
    suspension or modification of the requirements of section 251(b) or (c) 
    is justified.
    --Rural LECs bear the burden of proving that continued exemption of the 
    requirements of section 251(c) is justified, once a bona fide request 
    has been made by a carrier under to section 251.
    --Only LECs that, at the holding company level, have fewer than 2 
    percent of the nation's subscriber lines are entitled to petition for 
    suspension or modification of requirements under section 251(f)(2).
    
    Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
    
        As required by the Regulatory Flexibility Act, the Report and Order 
    contains a Final Regulatory Flexibility Analysis which is set forth in 
    Appendix C to the Report and Order. A brief description of the analysis 
    follows.
        Pursuant to Section 604 of the Regulatory Flexibility Act, the 
    Commission performed a comprehensive analysis of the Report and Order 
    with regard to small entities and small incumbent LECs. This analysis 
    includes: (1) a succinct statement of the need for, and objectives of, 
    the Commission's decisions in the Report and Order; (2) a summary of 
    the significant issues raised by the public comments in response to the 
    initial regulatory flexibility analysis, a summary of the Commission's 
    assessment of these issues, and a statement of any changes made in the 
    Report and Order as a result of the comments; (3) a description of and 
    an estimate of the number of small entities and small incumbent LECs to 
    which the Report and Order will apply; (4) a description of the 
    projected reporting, recordkeeping and other compliance requirements of 
    the Report and Order, including an estimate of the classes of small 
    entities and small incumbent LECs which will be subject to the 
    requirement and the type of professional skills necessary for 
    compliance with the requirement; (5) a description of the steps the 
    Commission has taken to minimize the significant economic impact on 
    small entities and small incumbent LECs consistent with the stated 
    objectives of applicable statutes, including a statement of the 
    factual, policy, and legal reasons for selecting the alternative 
    adopted in the Report and Order and why each one of the other 
    significant alternatives to each of the Commission's decisions which 
    affect the impact on small entities and small incumbent LECs was 
    rejected.
        The rules adopted in this Report and Order are necessary to 
    implement the provisions of the Telecommunications Act of 1996.
    
    Paperwork Reduction Act
    
        Public reporting burden for the collection of information is 
    estimated as follows:
        OMB Approval Number: 3060-0710.
        Title: Policy and rules concernng the implementation of the local 
    competition provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996.
        Form No.: N/A.
        Type of Review: New collection.
    
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                                    Annual hour     Total   
                                          No. of     burden per     annual  
          Information collection       respondents    response      burden  
                                         (approx.)    (hours)      (hours)  
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    Submission of information                                               
     necessary to reach agreement....           51          500       25,500
    Submission of agreements to the                                         
     state commission................  ...........  ...........          835
        New and modified.............           51            5             
        Class A carrier..............           16            5             
        Other preexisting............          500            1             
        Burden of proof regarding                                           
         interconnection and access                                         
         to unbundled network                                               
         elements....................          100          250       25,000
    Collocation......................          100          250       25,000
    Notification that state                                                 
     commission has failed to act....           30            1           30
    Rural and small carriers.........          500           10        5,000
    Pole attachment modifications:                                          
     private electric utilities and                                         
     telephone utilities.............        1,400          375      525,000
    Maintenance practices                                                   
     modifications: cable operators,                                        
     utilities and others............       12,250           .5        6,125
    Pole attachment access requests..        2,500            1        2,500
    Pole attachment denials of access          250            3          750
    Dispute resolution process for                                          
     denials of access: using in-                                           
     house assistance................          250           25        6,250
    Dispute resolution process for                                          
     denials of access: using outside                                       
     legal counsel...................          250            4        1,000
    Preparation of forward-looking                                          
     economic cost studies to                                               
     determine rates for                                                    
     interconnection and unbundled                                          
     network elements during                                                
     arbitration proceedings.........          100        1,216      121,600
    Preparation of a cost study on                                          
     avoidable costs to determine                                           
     resale discounts................          200          480       96,000
    Preparation of forward-looking                                          
     economic cost studies to                                               
     determine reciprocal rates for                                         
     transport and termination of                                           
     telecommunications traffic......          100        1,216      121,600
    
    [[Page 45479]]
    
                                                                            
    Measurement of traffic for                                              
     purposes of determining whether                                        
     transport and termination                                              
     traffic flows are symmetrical...          550          700      385,000
    Filing required for arbitration..          200            2          400
    Determination of rates for                                              
     interconnection, unbundled                                             
     network elements, and transport                                        
     and termination of                                                     
     telecommunications traffic--                                           
     state commission review of                                             
     forward-looking economic cost                                          
     studies.........................           50        2,160      108,000
    Determination of resale discount                                        
     percentage--state commission                                           
     review of avoided cost studies..           50          640       32,000
    Petition for incumbent LEC status           30            1           30
    Use of proxies by state                                                 
     commissions--articulating                                              
     written reasons for choice......           50          120        6,000
    Preparation of forward-looking                                          
     economic cost studies to                                               
     establish rates for transport                                          
     and termination for paging and                                         
     radiotelephone service,                                                
     narrowband personal                                                    
     communications services, and                                           
     paging operation in the private                                        
     land mobile radio services......           50          720       36,000
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        Total Annual Burden: 1,529,620 hours.
        Respondents: Business or other for-profit.
        Estimated costs per respondent: $0.
        Needs and Uses: The Report and Order implements parts of section 
    251 of the Telecommunications Act requiring that: incumbent local 
    exchange carriers (LECs) offer interconnection, unbundled network 
    elements, transport and termination, and wholesale rates for retail 
    services to new entrants; incumbent LECs price such services at rates 
    that are cost-based and just and reasonable; and incumbent LECs provide 
    access to rights-of-way, as well as establish reciprocal compensation 
    arrangements for the transport and termination of telecommunications 
    traffic.
    
    Synopsis of First Report and Order
    
    I. Introduction, Overview, and Executive Summary
    
    A. The Telecommunications Act of 1996--A New Direction
    
        1. The Telecommunications Act of 1996, (Telecommunications Act of 
    1996, Public Law No. 104-104, 110 Stat. 56, to be codified at 47 U.S.C. 
    Secs. 151 et seq. Hereinafter, all citations to the 1996 Act will be to 
    the 1996 Act as codified in the United States Code), fundamentally 
    changes telecommunications regulation. In the old regulatory regime 
    government encouraged monopolies. In the new regulatory regime, we and 
    the states remove the outdated barriers that protect monopolies from 
    competition and affirmatively promote efficient competition using tools 
    forged by Congress. Historically, regulation of this industry has been 
    premised on the belief that service could be provided at the lowest 
    cost to the maximum number of consumers through a regulated monopoly 
    network. State and federal regulators devoted their efforts over many 
    decades to regulating the prices and practices of these monopolies and 
    protecting them against competitive entry. The 1996 Act adopts 
    precisely the opposite approach. Rather than shielding telephone 
    companies from competition, the 1996 Act requires telephone companies 
    to open their networks to competition.
        2. The 1996 Act also recasts the relationship between the FCC and 
    state commissions responsible for regulating telecommunications 
    services. Until now, we and our state counterparts generally have 
    regulated the jurisdictional segments of this industry assigned to each 
    of us by the Communications Act of 1934. The 1996 Act forges a new 
    partnership between state and federal regulators. This arrangement is 
    far better suited to the coming world of competition in which 
    historical regulatory distinctions are supplanted by competitive 
    forces. As this Order demonstrates, we have benefitted enormously from 
    the expertise and experience that the state commissioners and their 
    staffs have contributed to these discussions. We look forward to the 
    continuation of that cooperative working relationship in the coming 
    months as each of us carries out the role assigned by the 1996 Act.
        3. Three principal goals established by the telephony provisions of 
    the 1996 Act are: (1) opening the local exchange and exchange access 
    markets to competitive entry; (2) promoting increased competition in 
    telecommunications markets that are already open to competition, 
    including the long distance services market; and (3) reforming our 
    system of universal service so that universal service is preserved and 
    advanced as the local exchange and exchange access markets move from 
    monopoly to competition. In this rulemaking and related proceedings, we 
    are taking the steps that will achieve the pro-competitive, 
    deregulatory goals of the 1996 Act. The Act directs us and our state 
    colleagues to remove not only statutory and regulatory impediments to 
    competition, but economic and operational impediments as well. We are 
    directed to remove these impediments to competition in all 
    telecommunications markets, while also preserving and advancing 
    universal service in a manner fully consistent with competition.
        4. These three goals are integrally related. Indeed, the 
    relationship between fostering competition in local telecommunications 
    markets and promoting greater competition in the long distance market 
    is fundamental to the 1996 Act. Competition in local exchange and 
    exchange access markets is desirable, not only because of the social 
    and economic benefits competition will bring to consumers of local 
    services, but also because competition eventually will eliminate the 
    ability of an incumbent local exchange carrier to use its control of 
    bottleneck local facilities to impede free market competition. Under 
    section 251, incumbent local exchange carriers (LECs), including the 
    Bell Operating Companies (BOCs), are mandated to take several steps to 
    open their networks to competition, including providing 
    interconnection, offering access to unbundled elements of their 
    networks, and making their retail services available at wholesale rates 
    so that they can be resold. Under section 271, once the BOCs have taken 
    the necessary steps, they are allowed to offer long distance service in 
    areas where they provide local telephone service, if we find that entry 
    meets the specific statutory requirements and is consistent with the 
    public interest. Thus, under the 1996 Act, the opening of one of the 
    last monopoly bottleneck strongholds in telecommunications--the local 
    exchange and exchange access markets--to competition is intended to 
    pave the way for enhanced competition in all telecommunications 
    markets, by allowing all providers to enter all
    
    [[Page 45480]]
    
    markets. The opening of all telecommunications markets to all providers 
    will blur traditional industry distinctions and bring new packages of 
    services, lower prices and increased innovation to American consumers. 
    The world envisioned by the 1996 Act is one in which all providers will 
    have new competitive opportunities as well as new competitive 
    challenges.
        5. The Act also recognizes, however, that universal service cannot 
    be maintained without reform of the current subsidy system. The current 
    universal service system is a patchwork quilt of implicit and explicit 
    subsidies. These subsidies are intended to promote telephone 
    subscribership, yet they do so at the expense of deterring or 
    distorting competition. Some policies that traditionally have been 
    justified on universal service considerations place competitors at a 
    disadvantage. Other universal service policies place the incumbent LECs 
    at a competitive disadvantage. For example, LECs are required to charge 
    interexchange carriers a Carrier Common Line charge for every minute of 
    interstate traffic that any of their customers send or receive. This 
    exposes LECs to competition from competitive access providers, which 
    are not subject to this cost burden. Hence, section 254 of the Act 
    requires the Commission, working with the states and consumer advocates 
    through a Federal/State Joint Board, to revamp the methods by which 
    universal service payments are collected and disbursed. Federal-State 
    Joint Board on Universal Service, CC Docket No. 96-45, Notice of 
    Proposed Rulemaking and Order Establishing Joint Board, FCC 96-93, 61 
    FR 10499 (March 14, 1996) (Universal Service NPRM). The present 
    universal service system is incompatible with the statutory mandate to 
    introduce efficient competition into local markets, because the current 
    system distorts competition in those markets. For example, without 
    universal service reform, facilities-based entrants would be forced to 
    compete against monopoly providers that enjoy not only the technical, 
    economic, and marketing advantages of incumbency, but also subsidies 
    that are provided only to the incumbents.
    
    B. The Competition Trilogy: Section 251, Universal Service Reform and 
    Access Charge Reform
    
        6. The rules that we adopt to implement the local competition 
    provisions of the 1996 Act represent only one part of a trilogy. In 
    this Report and Order, we adopt initial rules designed to accomplish 
    the first of the goals outlined above--opening the local exchange and 
    exchange access markets to competition. The steps we take today are the 
    initial measures that will enable the states and the Commission to 
    begin to implement sections 251 and 252. Given the dynamic nature of 
    telecommunications technology and markets, it will be necessary over 
    time to review proactively and adjust these rules to ensure both that 
    the statute's mandate of competition is effectuated and enforced, and 
    that regulatory burdens are lifted as soon as competition eliminates 
    the need for them. Efforts to review and revise these rules will be 
    guided by the experience of states in their initial implementation 
    efforts.
        7. The second part of the trilogy is universal service reform. In 
    early November, the Federal/State Universal Service Joint Board, 
    including three members of this Commission, will make its 
    recommendations to the Commission. These recommendations will serve as 
    the cornerstone of universal service reform. The Commission will act on 
    the Joint Board's recommendations and adopt universal service rules not 
    later than May 8, 1997, and, we hope, even earlier. Our universal 
    service reform order, consistent with section 254, will rework the 
    subsidy system to guarantee affordable service to all Americans in an 
    era in which competition will be the driving force in 
    telecommunications. By reforming the collection and distribution of 
    universal service funds, the states and the Commission will also ensure 
    that the goals of affordable service and access to advanced services 
    are met by means that enhance, rather than distort, competition. 
    Universal service reform is vitally connected to the local competition 
    rules we adopt today.
        8. The third part of the trilogy is access charge reform. It is 
    widely recognized that, because a competitive market drives prices to 
    cost, a system of charges which includes non-cost based components is 
    inherently unstable and unsustainable. It also well-recognized that 
    access charge reform is intensely interrelated with the local 
    competition rules of section 251 and the reform of universal service. 
    We will complete access reform before or concurrently with a final 
    order on universal service.
        9. Only when all parts of the trilogy are complete will the task of 
    adjusting the regulatory framework to fully competitive markets be 
    finished. Only when our counterparts at the state level complete 
    implementing and supplementing these rules will the complete blueprint 
    for competition be in place. Completion of the trilogy, coupled with 
    the reduction in burdensome and inefficient regulation we have 
    undertaken pursuant to other provisions of the 1996 Act, will unleash 
    marketplace forces that will fuel economic growth. Until then, 
    incumbents and new entrants must undergo a transition process toward 
    fully competitive markets. We will, however, act quickly to complete 
    the three essential rulemakings. We intend to issue a notice of 
    proposed rulemaking in 1996 and to complete the access charge reform 
    proceeding concurrently with the statutory deadline established for the 
    section 254 rulemaking. This timetable will ensure that actions taken 
    by the Joint Board in November and this Commission by not later than 
    May 1997 in the universal service reform proceeding will be coordinated 
    with the access reform docket.
    
    C. Economic Barriers
    
        10. As we pointed out in our Notice of Proposed Rulemaking in this 
    docket, Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions of the 
    Telecommunications Act of 1996, CC Docket No. 96-98, Notice of Proposed 
    Rulemaking, FCC 96-182 (April 19, 1996), 61 FR 18311 (April 25, 1996) 
    (NPRM), the removal of statutory and regulatory barriers to entry into 
    the local exchange and exchange access markets, while a necessary 
    precondition to competition, is not sufficient to ensure that 
    competition will supplant monopolies. An incumbent LEC's existing 
    infrastructure enables it to serve new customers at a much lower 
    incremental cost than a facilities-based entrant that must install its 
    own switches, trunking and loops to serve its customers. Furthermore, 
    absent interconnection between the incumbent LEC and the entrant, the 
    customer of the entrant would be unable to complete calls to 
    subscribers served by the incumbent LEC's network. Because an incumbent 
    LEC currently serves virtually all subscribers in its local serving 
    area, an incumbent LEC has little economic incentive to assist new 
    entrants in their efforts to secure a greater share of that market. An 
    incumbent LEC also has the ability to act on its incentive to 
    discourage entry and robust competition by not interconnecting its 
    network with the new entrant's network or by insisting on 
    supracompetitive prices or other unreasonable conditions for 
    terminating calls from the entrant's customers to the incumbent LEC's 
    subscribers.
        11. Congress addressed these problems in the 1996 Act by mandating 
    that the most significant economic impediments to efficient entry into 
    the monopolized local market must be
    
    [[Page 45481]]
    
    removed. The incumbent LECs have economies of density, connectivity, 
    and scale; traditionally, these have been viewed as creating a natural 
    monopoly. As we pointed out in our NPRM, the local competition 
    provisions of the Act require that these economies be shared with 
    entrants. We believe they should be shared in a way that permits the 
    incumbent LECs to maintain operating efficiency to further fair 
    competition, and to enable the entrants to share the economic benefits 
    of that efficiency in the form of cost-based prices. Congress also 
    recognized that the transition to competition presents special 
    considerations in markets served by smaller telephone companies, 
    especially in rural areas. We are mindful of these considerations, and 
    know that they will be taken into account by state commissions as well.
        12. The Act contemplates three paths of entry into the local 
    market--the construction of new networks, the use of unbundled elements 
    of the incumbent's network, and resale. The 1996 Act requires us to 
    implement rules that eliminate statutory and regulatory barriers and 
    remove economic impediments to each. We anticipate that some new 
    entrants will follow multiple paths of entry as market conditions and 
    access to capital permit. Some may enter by relying at first entirely 
    on resale of the incumbent's services and then gradually deploying 
    their own facilities. This strategy was employed successfully by MCI 
    and Sprint in the interexchange market during the 1970's and 1980's. 
    Others may use a combination of entry strategies simultaneously--
    whether in the same geographic market or in different ones. Some 
    competitors may use unbundled network elements in combination with 
    their own facilities to serve densely populated sections of an 
    incumbent LEC's service territory, while using resold services to reach 
    customers in less densely populated areas. Still other new entrants may 
    pursue a single entry strategy that does not vary by geographic region 
    or over time. Section 251 neither explicitly nor implicitly expresses a 
    preference for one particular entry strategy. Moreover, given the 
    likelihood that entrants will combine or alter entry strategies over 
    time, an attempt to indicate such a preference in our section 251 rules 
    may have unintended and undesirable results. Rather, our obligation in 
    this proceeding is to establish rules that will ensure that all pro-
    competitive entry strategies may be explored. As to success or failure, 
    we look to the market, not to regulation, for the answer.
        13. We note that an entrant, such as a cable company, that 
    constructs its own network will not necessarily need the services or 
    facilities of an incumbent LEC to enable its own subscribers to 
    communicate with each other. A firm adopting this entry strategy, 
    however, still will need an agreement with the incumbent LEC to enable 
    the entrant's customers to place calls to and receive calls from the 
    incumbent LEC's subscribers. Sections 251 (b)(5) and (c)(2) require 
    incumbent LECs to enter into such agreements on just, reasonable, and 
    nondiscriminatory terms and to transport and terminate traffic 
    originating on another carrier's network under reciprocal compensation 
    arrangements. In this item, we adopt rules for states to apply in 
    implementing these mandates of section 251 in their arbitration of 
    interconnection disputes, as well as their review of such arbitrated 
    arrangements, or a BOC's statement of generally available terms. We 
    believe that our rules will assist the states in carrying out their 
    responsibilities under the 1996 Act, thereby furthering the Act's goals 
    of fostering prompt, efficient, competitive entry.
        14. We also note that many new entrants will not have fully 
    constructed their local networks when they begin to offer service. 
    Joint Managers' Statement, S. Conf. Rep. No. 104-230, 104th Cong., 2d 
    Sess. 113 (1996) (``Joint Explanatory Statement'') at 121. Although 
    they may provide some of their own facilities, these new entrants will 
    be unable to reach all of their customers without depending on the 
    incumbent's facilities. Hence, in addition to an arrangement for 
    terminating traffic on the incumbent LEC's network, entrants will 
    likely need agreements that enable them to obtain wholesale prices for 
    services they wish to sell at retail and to use at least some portions 
    of the incumbents' facilities, such as local loops and end office 
    switching facilities.
        15. Congress recognized that, because of the incumbent LEC's 
    incentives and superior bargaining power, its negotiations with new 
    entrants over the terms of such agreements would be quite different 
    from typical commercial negotiations. As distinct from bilateral 
    commercial negotiation, the new entrant comes to the table with little 
    or nothing the incumbent LEC needs or wants. The statute addresses this 
    problem by creating an arbitration proceeding in which the new entrant 
    may assert certain rights, including that the incumbent's prices for 
    unbundled network elements must be ``just, reasonable and 
    nondiscriminatory.'' We adopt rules herein to implement these 
    requirements of section 251(c)(3).
    
    D. Operational Barriers
    
        16. The statute also directs us to remove the existing operational 
    barriers to entering the local market. Vigorous competition would be 
    impeded by technical disadvantages and other handicaps that prevent a 
    new entrant from offering services that consumers perceive to be equal 
    in quality to the offerings of incumbent LECs. Our recently-issued 
    number portability Report and Order addressed one of the most 
    significant operational barriers to competition by permitting customers 
    to retain their phone numbers when they change local carriers. 
    Telephone Number Portability, CC Docket No. 95-116, First Report and 
    Order and Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, FCC 96-286 (July 2, 
    1996) (61 FR 38605 (July 25, 1996)) (Number Portability Order). 
    Consistent with the 1996 Act, 47 U.S.C. Sec. 251(b)(2), we required 
    LECs to implement interim and long-term measures to ensure that 
    customers can change their local service providers without having to 
    change their phone number. Number portability promotes competition by 
    making it less expensive and less disruptive for a customer to switch 
    providers, thus freeing the customer to choose the local provider that 
    offers the best value.
        17. Closely related to number portability is dialing parity, which 
    we address in a companion order. Dialing parity enables a customer of a 
    new entrant to dial others with the convenience an incumbent provides, 
    regardless of which carrier the customer has chosen as the local 
    service provider. The history of competition in the interexchange 
    market illustrates the critical importance of dialing parity to the 
    successful introduction of competition in telecommunications markets. 
    Equal access enabled customers of non-AT&T providers to enjoy the same 
    convenience of dialing ``1'' plus the called party's number that AT&T 
    customers had. Prior to equal access, subscribers to interexchange 
    carriers (IXCs) other than AT&T often were required to dial more than 
    20 digits to place an interstate long-distance call. Industry data show 
    that, after equal access was deployed throughout the country, the 
    number of customers using MCI and other long-distance carriers 
    increased significantly. Federal Communications Commission, Statistics 
    of Communications Common Carriers 1994-95, at 344, Table 8.8; Federal 
    Communications Commission, Report on Long Distance Market Share, Second 
    Quarter 1995, at 14, table 6 (Oct. 1995). Thus, we believe that equal 
    access had a substantial pro-competitive
    
    [[Page 45482]]
    
    impact. Dialing parity should have the same effect.
        18. This Order addresses other operational barriers to competition, 
    such as access to rights of way, collocation, and the expeditious 
    provisioning of resale and unbundled elements to new entrants. The 
    elimination of these obstacles is essential if there is to be a fair 
    opportunity to compete in the local exchange and exchange access 
    markets. As an example, customers can voluntarily switch from one 
    interexchange carrier to another extremely rapidly, through automated 
    systems. This has been a boon to competition in the interexchange 
    market. We expect that moving customers from one local carrier to 
    another rapidly will be essential to fair local competition.
        19. As competition in the local exchange market emerges, 
    operational issues may be among the most difficult for the parties to 
    resolve. Thus, we recognize that, along with the state commissions and 
    the courts, we will be called upon to enforce provisions of arbitrated 
    agreements and our rules relating to these operational barriers to 
    entry. Because of the critical importance of eliminating these barriers 
    to the accomplishment of the Act's pro-competitive objectives, we 
    intend to enforce our rules in a manner that is swift, sure, and 
    effective. To this end we will review, with the states, our enforcement 
    techniques during the fourth quarter of 1996.
        20. We recognize that during the transition from monopoly to 
    competition it is vital that we and the states vigilantly and 
    vigorously enforce the rules that we adopt today and that will be 
    adopted in the future to open local markets to competition. If we fail 
    to meet that responsibility, the actions that we take today to 
    accomplish the 1996 Act's pro-competitive, deregulatory objectives may 
    prove to be ineffective.
    
    E. Transition
    
        21. We consider it vitally important to establish a ``pro-
    competitive, deregulatory national policy framework'' for local 
    telephony competition, but we are acutely mindful of existing common 
    carrier arrangements, relationships, and expectations, particularly 
    those that affect incumbent LECs. In light of the timing issues 
    described above, we think it wise to provide some appropriate 
    transitions.
        22. In this regard, this Order sets minimum, uniform, national 
    rules, but also relies heavily on states to apply these rules and to 
    exercise their own discretion in implementing a pro-competitive regime 
    in their local telephone markets. On those issues where the need to 
    create a factual record distinct to a state or to balance unique local 
    considerations is material, we ask the states to develop their own 
    rules that are consistent with general guidance contained herein. The 
    states will do so in rulemakings and in arbitrating interconnection 
    arrangements. On other issues, particularly those related to pricing, 
    we facilitate the ability of states to adopt immediate, temporary 
    decisions by permitting the states to set proxy prices within a defined 
    range or subject to a ceiling. We believe that some states will find 
    these alternatives useful in light of the strict deadlines of the law. 
    For example, section 252(b)(4)(C) requires a state commission to 
    complete the arbitration of issues that have been referred to it, 
    pursuant to section 252(b)(1), within nine months after the incumbent 
    local exchange carrier received the request for negotiation. Selection 
    of the actual prices within the range or subject to the ceiling will be 
    for the state commission to determine. Some states may use proxies 
    temporarily because they lack the resources necessary to review cost 
    studies in rulemakings or arbitrations. Other states may lack adequate 
    resources to complete such tasks before the expiration of the 
    arbitration deadline. However, we encourage all states to complete the 
    necessary work within the statutory deadline. Our expectation is that 
    the bulk of interconnection arrangements will be concluded through 
    arbitration or agreement, by the beginning of 1997. Not until then will 
    we be able to determine more precisely the impact of this Order on 
    promoting competition. Between now and then, we are eager to continue 
    our work with the states. In this period, as set forth earlier, we 
    should be able to take major steps toward implementing a new universal 
    service system and far-reaching reform of interstate access. These 
    reforms will reflect intensive dialogue between us and the states.
        23. Similarly, as states implement the rules that we adopt in this 
    order as well as their own decisions, they may find it useful to 
    consult with us, either formally or informally, regarding particular 
    aspects of these rules. We encourage and invite such inquiries because 
    we believe that such consultations are likely to provide greater 
    certainty to the states as they apply our rules to specific arbitration 
    issues and possibly to reduce the burden of expensive judicial 
    proceedings on states. A variety of formal and informal procedures 
    exist under our rules for such consultations, and we may find it 
    helpful to fashion others as we gain additional experience under the 
    1996 Act.
    
    F. Executive Summary
    
    1. Scope of Authority of the FCC and State Commissions
        24. The Commission concludes that sections 251 and 252 address both 
    interstate and intrastate aspects of interconnection, resale services, 
    and access to unbundled elements. The 1996 Act moves beyond the 
    distinction between interstate and intrastate matters that was 
    established in the 1934 Act, and instead expands the applicability of 
    national rules to historically intrastate issues, and state rules to 
    historically interstate issues. In the Report and Order, the Commission 
    concludes that the states and the FCC can craft a partnership that is 
    built on mutual commitment to local telephone competition throughout 
    the country, and that under this partnership, the FCC establishes 
    uniform national rules for some issues, the states, and in some 
    instances the FCC, administer these rules, and the states adopt 
    additional rules that are critical to promoting local telephone 
    competition. The rules that the FCC establishes in this Report and 
    Order are minimum requirements upon which the states may build. The 
    Commission also intends to review and amend the rules it adopts in this 
    Report and Order to take into account competitive developments, states' 
    experiences, and technological changes.
    2. Duty to Negotiate in Good Faith
        25. In the Report and Order, the Commission establishes some 
    national rules regarding the duty to negotiate in good faith, but 
    concludes that it would be futile to try to determine in advance every 
    possible action that might be inconsistent with the duty to negotiate 
    in good faith. The Commission also concludes that, in many instances, 
    whether a party has negotiated in good faith will need to be decided on 
    a case-by-case basis, in light of the particular circumstances. The 
    Commission notes that the arbitration process set forth in section 252 
    provides one remedy for failing to negotiate in good faith. The 
    Commission also concludes that agreements that were negotiated before 
    the 1996 Act was enacted, including agreements between neighboring 
    LECs, must be filed for review by the state commission pursuant to 
    section 252(a).
    
    [[Page 45483]]
    
    If the state commission approves such agreements, the terms of those 
    agreements must be made available to requesting telecommunications 
    carriers in accordance with section 252(i).
    3. Interconnection
        26. Section 251(c)(2) requires incumbent LECs to provide 
    interconnection to any requesting telecommunications carrier at any 
    technically feasible point. The interconnection must be at least equal 
    in quality to that provided by the incumbent LEC to itself or its 
    affiliates, and must be provided on rates, terms, and conditions that 
    are just, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory. The Commission concludes 
    that the term ``interconnection'' under section 251(c)(2) refers only 
    to the physical linking of two networks for the mutual exchange of 
    traffic. The Commission identifies a minimum set of five ``technically 
    feasible'' points at which incumbent LECs must provide interconnection: 
    (1) the line side of a local switch (for example, at the main 
    distribution frame); (2) the trunk side of a local switch; (3) the 
    trunk interconnection points for a tandem switch; (4) central office 
    cross-connect points; and (5) out-of-band signalling facilities, such 
    as signalling transfer points, necessary to exchange traffic and access 
    call-related databases. In addition, the points of access to unbundled 
    elements (discussed below) are also technically feasible points of 
    interconnection. The Commission finds that telecommunications carriers 
    may request interconnection under section 251(c)(2) to provide 
    telephone exchange or exchange access service, or both. If the request 
    is for such purpose, the incumbent LEC must provide interconnection in 
    accordance with section 251(c)(2) and the Commission's rules thereunder 
    to any telecommunications carrier, including interexchange carriers and 
    commercial mobile radio service (CMRS) providers.
    4. Access to Unbundled Elements
        27. Section 251(c)(3) requires incumbent LECs to provide requesting 
    telecommunications carriers nondiscriminatory access to network 
    elements on an unbundled basis at any technically feasible point on 
    rates, terms, and conditions that are just, reasonable, and 
    nondiscriminatory. In the Report and Order, the Commission identifies a 
    minimum set of network elements that incumbent LECs must provide under 
    this section. States may require incumbent LECs to provide additional 
    network elements on an unbundled basis. The minimum set of network 
    elements the Commission identifies are: local loops, local and tandem 
    switches (including all vertical switching features provided by such 
    switches), interoffice transmission facilities, network interface 
    devices, signalling and call-related database facilities, operations 
    support systems and information, and operator and directory assistance 
    facilities. The Commission concludes that incumbent LECs must provide 
    nondiscriminatory access to operations support systems and information 
    by January 1, 1997. The Commission concludes that access to such 
    operations support systems is critical to affording new entrants a 
    meaningful opportunity to compete with incumbent LECs. The Commission 
    also concludes that incumbent LECs are required to provide access to 
    network elements in a manner that allows requesting carriers to combine 
    such elements as they choose, and that incumbent LECs may not impose 
    restrictions upon the uses to which requesting carriers put such 
    network elements.
    5. Methods of Obtaining Interconnection and Access to Unbundled 
    Elements
        28. Section 251(c)(6) requires incumbent LECs to provide physical 
    collocation of equipment necessary for interconnection or access to 
    unbundled network elements at the incumbent LEC's premises, except that 
    the incumbent LEC may provide virtual collocation if it demonstrates to 
    the state commission that physical collocation is not practical for 
    technical reasons or because of space limitations. The Commission 
    concludes that incumbent LECs are required to provide for any 
    technically feasible method of interconnection or access requested by a 
    telecommunications carrier, including physical collocation, virtual 
    collocation, and interconnection at meet points. The Commission adopts, 
    with certain modifications, some of the physical and virtual 
    collocation requirements it adopted earlier in the Expanded 
    Interconnection proceeding. The Commission also establishes rules 
    interpreting the requirements of section 251(c)(6).
    6. Pricing Methodologies
        29. The 1996 Act requires the states to set prices for 
    interconnection and unbundled elements that are cost-based, 
    nondiscriminatory, and may include a reasonable profit. To help the 
    states accomplish this, the Commission concludes that the state 
    commissions should set arbitrated rates for interconnection and access 
    to unbundled elements pursuant a forward-looking economic cost pricing 
    methodology. The Commission concludes that the prices that new entrants 
    pay for interconnection and unbundled elements should be based on the 
    local telephone companies Total Element Long-Run Incremental Cost 
    (TELRIC) of providing a particular network element, plus a reasonable 
    share of forward-looking joint and common costs. States will determine, 
    among other things, the appropriate risk-adjusted cost of capital and 
    depreciation rates. For states that are unable to conduct a cost study 
    and apply an economic costing methodology within the statutory time 
    frame for arbitrating interconnection disputes, the Commission 
    establishes default ceilings and ranges for the states to apply, on an 
    interim basis, to interconnection arrangements. The Commission 
    establishes a default range of 0.2-0.4 cents per minute for switching, 
    plus access charges as discussed below. For tandem switching, the 
    Commission establishes a default ceiling of 0.15 cents per minute. The 
    Order also establishes default ceilings for the other unbundled network 
    elements.
    7. Access Charges for Unbundled Switching
        30. Nothing in this Report and Order alters the collection of 
    access charges paid by an interexchange carrier under Part 69 of the 
    Commission's rules, when the incumbent LEC provides exchange access 
    service to an interexchange carrier, either directly or through service 
    resale. Because access charges are not included in the cost-based 
    prices for unbundled network elements, and because certain portions of 
    access charges currently support the provision of universal service, 
    until the access charge reform and universal service proceedings have 
    been completed, the Commission continues to provide for access charge 
    recovery with respect to use of an incumbent LEC's unbundled switching 
    element, for a defined period of time. This will minimize the 
    possibility that the incumbent LEC will be able to ``double recover,'' 
    through access charges, the facility costs that new entrants have 
    already paid to purchase unbundled elements, while preserving the 
    status quo with respect to subsidy payments. Incumbent LECs will 
    recover from interconnecting carriers the carrier common line charge 
    and a charge equal to 75% of the transport interconnection charge for 
    all interstate minutes traversing the incumbent LECs local switches for 
    which the interconnecting carriers pay unbundled network element 
    charges. This aspect of the Order expires at the earliest of: (1)
    
    [[Page 45484]]
    
    June 30, 1997; (2) issuance of final decisions by the Commission in the 
    universal service and access reform proceedings; or (3) if the 
    incumbent LEC is a Bell Operating Company (BOC), the date on which that 
    BOC is authorized under section 271 of the Act to provide in-region 
    interLATA service, for any given state.
    8. Resale
        31. The 1996 Act requires all incumbent LECs to offer for resale 
    any telecommunications service that the carrier provides at retail to 
    subscribers who are not telecommunications carriers. Resale will be an 
    important entry strategy both in the short term for many new entrants 
    as they build out their own facilities and for small businesses that 
    cannot afford to compete in the local exchange market by purchasing 
    unbundled elements or by building their own networks. State commissions 
    must identify marketing, billing, collection, and other costs that will 
    be avoided or that are avoidable by incumbent LECs when they provide 
    services wholesale, and calculate the portion of the retail rates for 
    those services that is attributable to the avoided and avoidable costs. 
    The Commission identifies certain avoided costs, and the application of 
    this definition is left to the states. If a state elects not to 
    implement the methodology, it may elect, on an interim basis, a 
    discount rate from within a default range of discount rates established 
    by the Commission. The Commission establishes a default discount range 
    of 17-25% off retail prices, leaving the states to set the specific 
    rate within that range, in the exercise of their discretion.
    9. Requesting Telecommunications Carriers
        32. The Commission concludes that, to the extent that a carrier is 
    engaged in providing for a fee local, interexchange, or international 
    basic services directly to the public or to such classes of users as to 
    be effectively available directly to the public, the carrier is a 
    ``telecommunications carrier,'' and is thus subject to the requirements 
    of section 251(a) and the benefits of section 251(c). The Commission 
    concludes that CMRS providers are telecommunications carriers, and that 
    private mobile radio service (PMRS) providers generally are not 
    telecommunications carriers, except to the extent that a PMRS provider 
    uses excess capacity to provide local, interexchange, or international 
    services for a fee directly to the public. The Commission also 
    concludes that, if a company provides both telecommunications services 
    and information services, it must be classified as a telecommunications 
    carrier.
    10. Commercial Mobile Radio Service
        33. The Commission concludes that LECs are obligated, pursuant to 
    section 251(b)(5) and the corresponding pricing standards of section 
    252(d)(2) to enter into reciprocal compensation arrangements with CMRS 
    providers, including paging providers, for the transport and 
    termination of traffic on each other's networks. The Commission 
    concludes that many CMRS providers (specifically cellular, broadband 
    PCS and covered specialized mobile radio (SMR) providers) offer 
    telephone exchange service and exchange access, and that incumbent LECs 
    therefore must make interconnection available to these CMRS providers 
    in conformity with sections 251(c) and 252. The Commission concludes 
    that CMRS providers should not be classified as LECs at this time. The 
    Commission also concludes that it may apply section 251 and 252 to LEC-
    CMRS interconnection. By opting to proceed under sections 251 and 252, 
    the Commission is not finding that section 332 jurisdiction over 
    interconnection has been repealed by implication, and the Commission 
    acknowledges that section 332, in tandem with section 201, is a basis 
    for jurisdiction over LEC-CMRS interconnection.
    11. Transport and Termination
        34. The 1996 Act requires that charges for transport and 
    termination of traffic be cost-based. The Commission concludes that 
    state commissions, during arbitrations, should set symmetrical prices 
    based on the local telephone company's forward-looking costs. The state 
    commissions would also use the TELRIC methodology when establishing 
    rates for transport and termination. The Commission establishes a 
    default range of 0.2-0.4 cents per minute for end office termination 
    for states which have not conducted a TELRIC cost study. The Commission 
    finds significant evidence in the record in support of the lower end of 
    the ranges. In addition, the Commission finds that additional 
    reciprocal charges could apply to termination through a tandem switch. 
    The default ceiling for tandem switching is 0.15 cents per minute, plus 
    applicable charges for transport from the tandem switch to the end 
    office. Each state opting for the default approach for a limited period 
    of time, may select a rate within that range.
    12. Access to Rights of Way
        35. The Commission amends its rules to implement the pole 
    attachment provisions of the 1996 Act. Specifically, the Commission 
    establishes procedures for nondiscriminatory access by cable television 
    systems and telecommunications carriers to poles, ducts, conduits, and 
    rights-of-way owned by utilities or LECs. The Order includes several 
    specific rules as well as a number of more general guidelines designed 
    to facilitate the negotiation and mutual performance of fair, pro-
    competitive access agreements without the need for regulatory 
    intervention. Additionally, an expedited dispute resolution is provided 
    when good faith negotiations fail, as are requirements concerning 
    modifications to poles, ducts, conduits, and rights-of-way and the 
    allocation of the costs of such modifications.
    13. Obligations Imposed on non-incumbent LECs
        36. The Commission concludes that states generally may not impose 
    on non-incumbent LECs the obligations set forth in section 251(c) 
    entitled, ``Additional Obligations on Incumbent Local Exchange 
    Carriers.'' Section 251(h)(2) sets forth a process by which the 
    Commission may decide to treat LECs as incumbent LECs, and state 
    commissions or other interested parties may ask the Commission to issue 
    a rule, in accordance with section 251(h)(2), providing for the 
    treatment of a LEC as an incumbent LEC. In addition to this Report and 
    Order, the Commission addresses in separate proceedings some of the 
    obligations, such as dialing parity and number portability, that 
    section 251(b) imposes on all LECs.
    14. Exemptions, Suspensions, and Modifications of Section 251 
    Requirements
        37. Section 251(f)(1) provides for exemption from the requirements 
    in section 251(c) for rural telephone companies (as defined by the 1996 
    Act) under certain circumstances. Section 251(f)(2) permits LECs with 
    fewer than 2 percent of the nation's subscriber lines to petition for 
    suspension or modification of the requirements in sections 251(b) or 
    (c). In the Report and Order, the Commission establishes a very limited 
    set of rules interpreting the requirements of section 251(f). For 
    example, the Commission finds that LECs bear the burden of proving to 
    the state commission that a suspension or modification of the 
    requirements of section 251(b) or (c) is justified. Rural LECs bear the 
    burden of proving that
    
    [[Page 45485]]
    
    continued exemption of the requirements of section 251(c) is justified, 
    once a bona fide request has been made by a carrier under section 251. 
    The Commission also concludes that only LECs that, at the holding 
    company level, have fewer than 2 percent of the nation's subscriber 
    lines are entitled to petition for suspension or modification of 
    requirements under section 251(f)(2). For the most part, however, the 
    states will interpret the provisions of section 251(f) through 
    rulemaking and adjudicative proceedings, and will be responsible for 
    determining whether a LEC in a particular instance is entitled to 
    exemption, suspension, or modification of section 251 requirements.
    15. Commission Responsibilities Under Section 252
        38. Section 252(e)(5) requires the Commission to assume the state's 
    responsibilities under section 252 if the state ``fails to act to carry 
    out its responsibility'' under that section. In the Report and Order, 
    the Commission adopts a minimum set of rules that will provide notice 
    of the standards and procedures that the Commission will use if it has 
    to assume the responsibility of a state commission under section 
    252(e)(5). The Commission concludes that, if it arbitrates agreements, 
    it will use a ``final offer'' arbitration method, under which each 
    party to the arbitration proposes its best and final offer, and the 
    arbitrator chooses among the proposals. The arbitrator could choose a 
    proposal in its entirety, or could choose different parties' proposals 
    on an issue-by-issue basis. In addition, the parties could continue to 
    negotiate an agreement after they submit their proposals and before the 
    arbitrator makes a decision.
        39. Section 252(i) of the 1996 Act requires that incumbent LECs 
    make available to any requesting telecommunications carrier any 
    individual interconnection, service, or network element on the same 
    terms and conditions as contained in any agreement approved under 
    Section 252 to which they are a party. The Commission concludes that 
    section 252(i) entitles all carriers with interconnection agreements to 
    ``most favored nation'' status regardless of whether such a clause is 
    in their agreement. Carriers may obtain any individual interconnection, 
    service, or network element under the same terms and conditions as 
    contained in any publicly filed interconnection agreement without 
    having to agree to the entire agreement. Additionally, carriers seeking 
    interconnection, network elements, or services pursuant to section 
    252(i) need not make such requests pursuant to the procedures for 
    initial section 251 requests, but instead may obtain access to 
    agreement provisions on an expedited basis.
    
    II. Scope of the Commission's Rules
    
        40. In implementing section 251, we conclude that some national 
    rules are necessary to promote Congress's goals for a national policy 
    framework and serve the public interest, and that states should have 
    the major responsibility for prescribing the specific terms and 
    conditions that will lead to competition in local exchange markets. Our 
    approach in this Report and Order has been a pragmatic one, consistent 
    with the Act, with respect to this allocation of responsibilities. We 
    believe that the steps necessary to implement section 251 are not 
    appropriately characterized as a choice between specific national rules 
    on the one hand and substantial state discretion on the other. We adopt 
    national rules where they facilitate administration of sections 251 and 
    252, expedite negotiations and arbitrations by narrowing the potential 
    range of dispute where appropriate to do so, offer uniform 
    interpretations of the law that might not otherwise emerge until after 
    years of litigation, remedy significant imbalances in bargaining power, 
    and establish the minimum requirements necessary to implement the 
    nationwide competition that Congress sought to establish. This is 
    consistent with our obligation to ``complete all actions necessary to 
    establish regulations to implement the requirements'' of section 251. 
    Some of these rules will be relatively self-executing. In many 
    instances, however, the rules we establish call on the states to 
    exercise significant discretion and to make critical decisions through 
    arbitrations and development of state-specific rules. Over time, we 
    will continue to review the allocation of responsibilities, and we will 
    reallocate them if it appears that we have inappropriately or 
    inefficiently designated the decisionmaking roles.
        41. The decisions in this Report and Order, and in this Section in 
    particular, benefit from valuable insights provided by states based on 
    their experiences in establishing rules and taking other actions 
    intended to foster local competition. Through formal comments, ex parte 
    meetings, and open forums, state commissioners and their staffs 
    provided extensive, detailed information to us regarding difficult or 
    complex issues that they have encountered, and the various approaches 
    they have adopted to address those issues. Information from the states 
    highlighted both differences among communities within states, as well 
    as similarities among states. Recent state rules and orders that take 
    into account the local competition provisions of the 1996 Act have been 
    particularly helpful to our deliberations about the types of national 
    rules that will best further the statute's goal of encouraging local 
    telephone competition. See, e.g, Petition of AT&T for the Commission to 
    Establish Resale Rules, Rates, Terms and Condition and the Initial 
    Unbundling of Services, Docket No. 6352-U (Georgia Commission May 29, 
    1996); AT&T Communications of Illinois, Inc. et al., Petition for a 
    Total Local Exchange Wholesale Service Tariff from Illinois Bell 
    Telephone Company, Nos. 95-0458 and 95-0531 (consol.) (Illinois 
    Commission June 26, 1996); Hawaii Administrative Rules, Ch. 6-80, 
    ``Competition in Telecommunications Services,'' (Hawaii Commission May 
    17, 1996); Public Utilities Commission of Ohio Case No. 95-845-TP-COI 
    (Local Competition) (Ohio Commission June 12, 1996) and Implementation 
    of the Mediation and Arbitration Provisions of the Federal 
    Telecommunications Act of 1996, Case No. 96-463-TP-UNC (Ohio Commission 
    May 30, 1996); Proposed Rules regarding Implementation of Secs. 40-15-
    101 et seq. Requirements relating to Interconnection and Unbundling, 
    Docket No. 95R-556T (Colorado Commission April 25, 1996) (one of a 
    series of Orders adopted by the Colorado Commission in response to the 
    local competition provisions of the 1996 Act); Washington Utilities and 
    Transportation Commission, Fifteenth Supplemental Order, Decision and 
    Order Rejecting Tariff Revisions, Requiring Refiling, Docket No. UT-
    950200 (Washington Commission April 1996). These state decisions also 
    offered useful insights in determining the extent to which the 
    Commission should set forth uniform national rules, and the extent to 
    which we should ensure that states can impose varying requirements. Our 
    contact with state commissioners and their staffs, as well as recent 
    state actions, make clear that states and the FCC share a common 
    commitment to creating opportunities for efficient new entry into the 
    local telephone market. Our experience in working with state 
    commissions since passage of the 1996 Act confirms that we will achieve 
    that goal most effectively and quickly by working cooperatively with 
    one another now and in the future as the country's emerging competition 
    policy presents new difficulties and opportunities.
    
    [[Page 45486]]
    
        42. We also received helpful advice and assistance from other 
    government agencies, including the National Telecommunications and 
    Information Administration (NTIA), the Department of Justice, and the 
    Department of Defense about how national rules could further the public 
    interest. In addition, comments from industry members and consumer 
    advocacy groups helped us understand better the varying and competing 
    concerns of consumers and different representatives of the 
    telecommunications industry. We benefitted as well by discovering that 
    there are certain matters on which there is substantial agreement about 
    the role the Commission should play in establishing and enforcing 
    provisions of section 251.
    
    A. Advantages and Disadvantages of National Rules
    
    1. Background
        43. Section 251(d)(1) instructs the Commission, within six months 
    after the enactment of the 1996 Act (that is, by August 8, 1996), to 
    ``establish regulations to implement the requirements of [section 
    251].'' The Commission's implementing rules should be designed ``to 
    accelerate rapidly private sector deployment of advanced 
    telecommunications and information technologies and services to all 
    Americans by opening all telecommunications markets to competition.'' 
    Joint Explanatory Statement at 1. In addition, section 253 requires the 
    Commission to preempt the enforcement of any state or local statute, 
    regulation, or legal requirement that ``prohibit[s] or [has] the effect 
    of prohibiting the ability of any entity to provide any interstate or 
    intrastate telecommunications service.''
        44. In the NPRM, we stated our belief that we should implement 
    Congress's goal of a pro-competitive, de-regulatory, national policy 
    framework by adopting national rules that are designed to secure the 
    full benefits of competition for consumers, with due regard to work 
    already done by the states. We sought comment on the extent to which we 
    should adopt explicit national rules, and the extent to which 
    permitting variations among states would further Congress's pro-
    competitive goals. We anticipated that we would rely on actions some 
    states have already taken to address interconnection and other issues 
    related to opening local markets to competition. In the NPRM, we set 
    forth some of the benefits that would likely result from implementing 
    explicit national rules, and some of the benefits that would likely 
    result from allowing variations among states.
    2. Discussion
        45. Comments and ex parte discussions with state commission 
    representatives have convinced us that we share with states a common 
    goal of promoting competition in local exchange markets. We conclude 
    that states and the FCC can craft a working relationship that is built 
    on mutual commitment to local service competition throughout the 
    country, in which the FCC establishes uniform, national rules for some 
    issues, the states and the FCC administer these rules, and the states 
    adopt other critically important rules to promote competition. In 
    implementing the national rules we adopt in this Report and Order, 
    states will help to illuminate and develop innovative solutions 
    regarding many complex issues for which we have not attempted to 
    prescribe national rules at this time, and states will adopt specific 
    rules that take into account local concerns. In this Report and Order, 
    and in subsequent actions we intend to take, we have and will continue 
    to seek guidance from various states that have taken the lead in 
    establishing pro-competitive requirements. We also expect to rely 
    heavily on state input and experience in other FCC proceedings, such as 
    access reform and petitions concerning BOC entry into in-region 
    interLATA markets. Virtually every decision in this Report and Order 
    borrows from decisions reached at the state level, and we expect this 
    close association with and reliance on the states to continue in the 
    future. We therefore encourage states to continue to pursue their own 
    pro-competitive policies. Indeed, we hope and expect that this Report 
    and Order will foster an interactive process by which a number of 
    policies consistent with the 1996 Act are generated by states.
        46. We find that certain national rules are consistent with the 
    terms and the goals of the statute. Section 251 sets forth a number of 
    rights with respect to interconnection, resale services, and unbundled 
    network elements. We conclude that the Commission should define at 
    least certain minimum obligations that section 251 requires, 
    respectively, of all telecommunications carriers, LECs, or incumbent 
    LECs. For example, as discussed in more detail below, we conclude that 
    it is reasonable to identify a minimum number of network elements that 
    incumbent LECs must unbundle and make available to requesting carriers 
    pursuant to the standards set forth in sections 251 (c) and (d), while 
    also permitting states to go beyond that minimum list and impose 
    additional requirements that are consistent with the 1996 Act and the 
    FCC's implementing rules. We find no basis for permitting an incumbent 
    LEC in some states not to make available these minimum technically 
    feasible network elements that are provided by incumbent LECs in other 
    states. We point out, however, that a uniform rule does not necessarily 
    mean uniform results. For example, a national pricing methodology takes 
    into account local factors and inputs, and thus may lead to different 
    prices in different states, and different regions within states. In 
    addition, parties that voluntarily negotiate agreements need not comply 
    with the requirements we establish under sections 251 (b) and (c), 
    including any pricing rules we adopt. We intend to review on an ongoing 
    basis the rules we adopt herein in light of competitive developments, 
    states' experiences, and technological changes.
        47. We find that incumbent LECs have no economic incentive, 
    independent of the incentives set forth in sections 271 and 274 of the 
    1996 Act, to provide potential competitors with opportunities to 
    interconnect with and make use of the incumbent LEC's network and 
    services. Negotiations between incumbent LECs and new entrants are not 
    analogous to traditional commercial negotiations in which each party 
    owns or controls something the other party desires. Under section 251, 
    monopoly providers are required to make available their facilities and 
    services to requesting carriers that intend to compete directly with 
    the incumbent LEC for its customers and its control of the local 
    market. Therefore, although the 1996 Act requires incumbent LECs, for 
    example, to provide interconnection and access to unbundled elements on 
    rates, terms, and conditions that are just, reasonable, and 
    nondiscriminatory, incumbent LECs have strong incentives to resist such 
    obligations. The inequality of bargaining power between incumbents and 
    new entrants militates in favor of rules that have the effect of 
    equalizing bargaining power in part because many new entrants seek to 
    enter national or regional markets. National (as opposed to state) 
    rules more directly address these competitive circumstances.
        48. We emphasize that, under the statute, parties may voluntarily 
    negotiate agreements ``without regard to'' the rules that we establish 
    under sections 251 (b) and (c). However, fair negotiations will be 
    expedited by the promulgation of national rules. Similarly, state 
    arbitration of interconnection agreements now and in
    
    [[Page 45487]]
    
    the future will be expedited and simplified by a clear statement of 
    terms that must be included in every arbitrated agreement, absent 
    mutual consent to different terms. Such efficiency and predictability 
    should facilitate entry decisions, and in turn enhance opportunities 
    for local exchange competition. In addition, for new entrants seeking 
    to provide service on a national or regional basis, minimum national 
    requirements may reduce the need for designing costly multiple network 
    configurations and marketing strategies, and allow more efficient 
    competition. More efficient competition will, in turn, benefit 
    consumers. Further, national rules will reduce the need for competitors 
    to revisit the same issue in 51 different jurisdictions, thereby 
    reducing administrative burdens and litigation for new entrants and 
    incumbents.
        49. We also believe that some explicit national standards will be 
    helpful in enabling the Commission and the states to carry out other 
    responsibilities under the 1996 Act. For example, national standards 
    will enable the Commission to address issues swiftly if the Commission 
    is obligated to assume section 252 responsibilities because a state 
    commission has failed to act. In addition, BOCs that seek to offer long 
    distance service in their service areas must satisfy, inter alia, a 
    ``competitive checklist'' set forth in section 271(c)(2)(B). Many of 
    the competitive checklist provisions require compliance with specific 
    provisions of section 251. For example, the checklist requires BOCs to 
    provide ``nondiscriminatory access to network elements in accordance 
    with the requirements of sections 251(c)(3) and 252(d)(1).'' Some 
    national rules also will help the states, the DOJ, and the FCC carry 
    out their responsibilities under section 271, and assist BOCs in 
    determining what steps must be taken to meet the requirements of 
    section 271(c)(2)(B), the competitive checklist. In addition, national 
    rules that establish the minimum requirements of section 251 will 
    provide states with a consistent standard against which to conduct the 
    fact-intensive process of verifying checklist compliance, the DOJ will 
    have standards against which to evaluate the applications, and we will 
    have standards to apply in adjudicating section 271 petitions in an 
    extremely compressed time frame. Moreover, we believe that establishing 
    minimum requirements that arbitrated agreements must satisfy will 
    assist states in arbitrating and reviewing agreements under section 
    252, particularly in light of the relatively short time frames for such 
    state action. While some states reject the idea that national rules 
    will help the state commissions to satisfy their obligations under 
    section 252 to mediate, arbitrate, and review agreements, other states 
    have welcomed national rules, at least with respect to certain matters.
        50. A broad range of parties urge the Commission to adopt minimum 
    requirements that would permit states to impose additional, pro-
    competitive requirements that are consistent with the 1996 Act to 
    address local or state-specific circumstances. We agree generally that 
    many of the rules we adopt should establish non-exhaustive 
    requirements, and that states may impose additional pro-competitive 
    requirements that are consistent with the purposes and terms of the 
    1996 Act, including our regulations established pursuant to section 
    251. In contrast, we conclude that the 1996 Act limits the obligations 
    states may impose on non-incumbent carriers. See infra, Section XI.C. 
    We also anticipate that the rules we adopt regarding interconnection, 
    services, and access to unbundled elements will evolve to accommodate 
    developments in technology and competitive circumstances, and that we 
    will continue to draw on state experience in applying our rules and in 
    addressing new or additional issues. We recognize that it is vital that 
    we reexamine our rules over time in order to reflect developments in 
    the dynamic telecommunications industry. We cannot anticipate all of 
    the changes that will occur as a result of technological advancements, 
    competitive developments, and practical experience, particularly at the 
    state level. Therefore, ongoing review of our rules is inevitable. 
    Moreover, we conclude that arbitrated agreements must permit parties to 
    incorporate changes to our national rules, or to applicable state rules 
    as such changes may be effective, without abrogating the entire 
    contract. This will ensure that parties, regardless of when they enter 
    into arbitrated agreements, will be able to take advantage of all 
    applicable Commission and state rules as they evolve.
        51. Some parties contend that even minimum requirements may impede 
    the ability of state commissions to take varying approaches to address 
    particular circumstances or conditions. We agree with the contention 
    that, although there are different market conditions from one area to 
    another, such distinct areas do not necessarily replicate state 
    boundaries. For example, virtually all states include both more 
    densely-populated areas and sparsely populated rural areas, and all 
    include both business and residential areas. Although each state is 
    unique in many respects, demographic and other differences among states 
    do not suggest that national rules are inappropriate. Moreover, even 
    though it may not be appropriate to impose identical requirements on 
    carriers with different network technologies, our rules are intended to 
    accommodate such differences. See infra, Section IV.E. (concluding that 
    successful interconnection or access to an unbundled element at a 
    particular point in the network creates a rebuttable presumption that 
    such interconnection or access is technically feasible at networks that 
    employ substantially similar facilities). We agree with parties, such 
    as the Ohio Consumers' Counsel, that physical networks are not designed 
    on a state-by-state basis. Ohio Consumers' Counsel comments at 4. Some 
    parties have argued that explicit national standards will delay the 
    emergence of local telephone competition, but none has offered 
    persuasive evidence to substantiate that claim, and new entrants 
    overwhelmingly favor strong national rules. We conclude, for the 
    reasons set forth above, that some national rules will enhance 
    opportunities for local competition, and we have chosen to adopt 
    national rules where necessary to establish the minimum requirements 
    for a nationwide pro-competitive policy framework.
        52. We disagree with those parties that claim we are trying to 
    impose a uniformity that Congress did not intend. Variations among 
    interconnection agreements will exist, because parties may negotiate 
    their own terms, states may impose additional requirements that differ 
    from state to state, and some terms are beyond the scope of this Report 
    and Order. We conclude, however, that establishing certain rights that 
    are available, through arbitration, to all requesting carriers, will 
    help advise parties of their minimum rights and obligations, and will 
    help speed the negotiation process. In effect, the Commission's rules 
    will provide a national baseline for terms and conditions for all 
    arbitrated agreements. Our rules also may tend to serve as a useful 
    guide for negotiations by setting forth minimum requirements that will 
    apply to parties if they are unable to reach agreement. This is 
    consistent with the broad delegation of authority that Congress gave 
    the Commission to implement the requirements set forth in section 251.
        53. We also believe that national rules will assist smaller 
    carriers that seek to
    
    [[Page 45488]]
    
    provide competitive local service. As noted above, national rules will 
    greatly reduce the need for small carriers to expend their limited 
    resources securing their right to interconnection, services, and 
    network elements to which they are entitled under the 1996 Act. This is 
    particularly true with respect to discrete geographic markets that 
    include areas in more than one state. We agree with the Small Business 
    Administration that national rules will reduce delay and lower 
    transaction costs, which impose particular hardships for small entities 
    that are likely to have less of a financial cushion than larger 
    entities. In addition, even a small provider may wish to enter more 
    than one market, and national rules will create economies of scale for 
    entry into multiple markets. We reject the position advocated by some 
    parties that we should not adopt national rules because such rules will 
    be particularly burdensome for small or rural incumbent LECs. We note, 
    however, that section 251(f) provides relief from some of our rules.
        54. We recognize the concern of many state commissions that the 
    Commission not undermine or reverse existing state efforts to foster 
    local competition. We believe that Congress did not intend for us 
    needlessly to disrupt the pro-competitive actions some states already 
    have taken that are both consistent with the 1996 Act and our rules 
    implementing section 251. We believe our rules will in many cases be 
    consistent with pro-competitive actions already taken by states, and in 
    fact, many of the rules we adopt are based directly on existing state 
    commission actions. We also intend to continue to reflect states' 
    experiences as we revise our rules. We also recognize, however, that in 
    at least some instances existing state requirements will not be 
    consistent with the statute and our implementing rules. It will be 
    necessary in those instances for the subject states to amend their 
    rules and alter their decisions to conform to our rules. In our 
    judgment, national rules are highly desirable to achieve Congress's 
    goal of a pro-competitive national policy framework for the 
    telecommunications industry.
    
    B. Suggested Approaches for FCC Rules
    
    1. Discussion
        55. We intend to adopt minimum requirements in this proceeding; 
    states may impose additional pro-competitive requirements that are 
    consistent with the Act and our rules. We decline to adopt a 
    ``preferred outcomes'' approach, because such an approach would fail to 
    establish explicit national standards for arbitration, and would fail 
    to provide sufficient guidance to the parties' options in negotiations. 
    To the extent that parties advocate ``preferred outcomes'' from which 
    the parties could deviate in arbitrated agreements, we reject such a 
    proposal, because we conclude that it would not provide the benefits 
    conferred by establishing ``default'' requirements. To the extent that 
    commenters advocate a regulatory approach that would require parties to 
    justify a negotiated result different from the preferred outcomes, we 
    believe that such an approach would impose greater constraints on 
    voluntarily negotiated agreements than the 1996 Act permits. Under the 
    1996 Act, parties may freely negotiate any terms without justifying 
    deviation from ``preferred outcomes.'' The only restriction on such 
    negotiated agreements is that they must be deemed by the state 
    commission to be nondiscriminatory and consistent with the public 
    interest, under the standards set forth in section 252(e)(2)(A). In 
    response to the Illinois Commission's suggestion that we adopt a 
    process by which states may seek waivers of our rules, we note that 
    Commission rules already provide for waiver of our rules under certain 
    circumstances. We decline to adopt a special waiver process in this 
    proceeding.
        56. We intend our rules to give guidance to the parties regarding 
    their rights and obligations under section 251. The specificity of our 
    rules varies with respect to different issues; in some cases, we 
    identify broad principles and leave to the states the determination of 
    what specific requirements are necessary to satisfy those principles. 
    In other cases, we find that local telephone competition will be better 
    served by establishing specific requirements. In each of the sections 
    below, we discuss the basis for adopting particular national principles 
    or rules.
        57. We also believe that we should periodically review and amend 
    our rules to take into account experiences of carriers and states, 
    technological changes, and market developments. The actions we take 
    here are fully responsive to Congress's mandate that we complete all 
    actions necessary to establish regulations to implement the 
    requirements of section 251 by August 8, 1996. We nevertheless retain 
    authority to refine or augment our rules, or to follow a different 
    course, after developing some practical experience with the rules 
    adopted herein. It is beyond doubt that the Commission has ongoing 
    rulemaking authority. For example, section 4(i) provides that the 
    Commission ``may perform any and all acts, make such rules and 
    regulations, and issue such orders, not inconsistent with the Act, as 
    may be necessary in the execution of its functions.'' Section 4(j) 
    provides that the Commission ``may conduct its proceedings in such 
    manner as will best conduce to the proper dispatch and to the ends of 
    justice.'' We agree with Sprint, the Illinois Commission, and other 
    parties that we should address in this rulemaking the most important 
    issues, and continue to refine our rules on an ongoing basis to address 
    additional or unanticipated issues, and especially to learn from the 
    decisions and experiences of the states. We also reject the argument of 
    Margaretville Telephone Company that the 1996 Act constitutes an 
    unconstitutional taking because it seeks to deprive incumbent LECs of 
    their ``reasonable, investment-backed expectation to hold competitive 
    advantages over new market entrants.''
    
    C. Legal Authority of the Commission to Establish Rules Applicable to 
    Intrastate Aspects of Interconnection, Services, and Unbundled Network 
    Elements
    
    1. Background
        58. In the NPRM, we tentatively concluded that Congress intended 
    sections 251 and 252 to apply, and that our rules should apply, to both 
    interstate and intrastate aspects of interconnection, services, and 
    access to network elements. We stated in the NPRM that it would seem to 
    make little sense, in terms of economics or technology, to distinguish 
    between interstate and intrastate components for purposes of sections 
    251 and 252. We also believed that such a distinction would appear to 
    be inconsistent with Congress's desire to establish a national policy 
    framework for interconnection and other issues critical to achieving 
    local competition. We sought comment on these tentative conclusions.
        59. We further tentatively concluded in the NPRM that section 2(b) 
    of the 1934 Act does not require a contrary conclusion. Section 2(b) 
    states that, except as provided in certain enumerated sections not 
    including sections 251 and 252, ``nothing in [the 1934] Act shall be 
    construed to apply or to give to the Commission jurisdiction with 
    respect to * * * charges, classifications, practices, services, 
    facilities, or regulations for or in connection with intrastate 
    communication service by wire or radio of any carrier * * *.'' We noted 
    in the NPRM that sections 251 and 252 do not alter the jurisdictional 
    division of authority with respect to matters falling outside the scope 
    of these provisions. For example, rates charged to end users for local 
    exchange service have
    
    [[Page 45489]]
    
    traditionally been subject to state authority, and will continue to be.
    2. Discussion
        60. We conclude that, in enacting sections 251, 252, and 253, 
    Congress created a regulatory system that differs significantly from 
    the dual regulatory system it established in the 1934 Act. According to 
    Senator Pressler, ``Progress is being stymied by a morass of regulatory 
    barriers which balkanize the telecommunications industry into 
    protective enclaves. We need to design a national policy framework--a 
    new regulatory paradigm for telecommunications--which accommodates and 
    accelerates technological change and innovation.'' 141 Cong. Rec. 
    S7881-2, S7886 (June 7, 1995) (emphasis added). According to 
    Representative Fields, ``[Congress] is decompartmentalizing segments of 
    the telecommunications industry, opening the floodgates of competition 
    through deregulation, and most importantly, giving consumers choice * * 
    * '', 142 Cong. Rec. H1149 (Feb. 1, 1996). That Act generally gave 
    jurisdiction over interstate matters to the FCC and over intrastate 
    matters to the states. The 1996 Act alters this framework, and expands 
    the applicability of both national rules to historically intrastate 
    issues, and state rules to historically interstate issues. For example, 
    section 253(a) suggests that states may establish regulations regarding 
    interstate as well as intrastate matters. Indeed, many provisions of 
    the 1996 Act are designed to open telecommunications markets to all 
    potential service providers, without distinction between interstate and 
    intrastate services.
        61. For the reasons set forth below, we hold that section 251 
    authorizes the FCC to establish regulations regarding both interstate 
    and intrastate aspects of interconnection, services, and access to 
    unbundled elements. We also hold that the regulations the Commission 
    establishes pursuant to section 251 are binding upon states and 
    carriers and section 2(b) does not limit the Commission's authority to 
    establish regulations governing intrastate matters pursuant to section 
    251. Similarly, we find that the states' authority pursuant to section 
    252 also extends to both interstate and intrastate matters. Although we 
    recognize that these sections do not contain an explicit grant of 
    intrastate authority to the Commission or of interstate authority to 
    the states, we nonetheless find that this interpretation is the only 
    reasonable way to reconcile the various provisions of sections 251 and 
    252, and the statute as a whole. As we indicated in the NPRM, it would 
    make little sense in terms of economics or technology to distinguish 
    between interstate and intrastate components for purposes of sections 
    251 and 252. We believe that this interpretation is the most reasonable 
    one in light of our expectation that marketing and product offerings by 
    telecommunications carriers will diminish or eliminate the significance 
    of interstate-intrastate distinctions.
        62. We view sections 251 and 252 as creating parallel jurisdiction 
    for the FCC and the states. These sections require the FCC to establish 
    implementing rules to govern interconnection, resale of services, 
    access to unbundled network elements, and other matters, and direct the 
    states to follow the Act and those rules in arbitrating and approving 
    arbitrated agreements under sections 251 and 252. Among other things, 
    the fact that the Commission is required to assume the state 
    commission's responsibilities if the state commission fails to carry 
    out its section 252 responsibilities gives rise to the inevitable 
    inference that both the states and the FCC are to address the same 
    matters through their parallel jurisdiction over both interstate and 
    intrastate matters under sections 251 and 252.
        63. The only other possible interpretations would be that: (1) 
    sections 251 and 252 address only interstate aspects of 
    interconnection, services, and access to unbundled elements; (2) the 
    provisions address only the intrastate aspects of those issues; or (3) 
    the FCC's role is to establish rules for interstate aspects, and the 
    states' role is to arbitrate and approve agreements on intrastate 
    aspects. As explained below, none of these interpretations withstands 
    examination. Accordingly, we conclude that sections 251 and 252 address 
    both interstate and intrastate aspects of interconnection services and 
    access to unbundled elements.
        64. Some parties have argued that our authority under section 251 
    is limited by section 2(b). Ordinarily, in light of section 2(b), we 
    would interpret a provision of the Communications Act as addressing 
    only the interstate jurisdiction unless the provision (as well as 
    section 2(b) itself) provided otherwise. That interpretation is 
    contradicted in this case, however, by strong evidence in the statute 
    that the local competition provisions of the 1996 Act are directed to 
    both intrastate and interstate matters. For example, section 251(c)(2), 
    the interconnection requirement, requires LECs to provide 
    interconnection ``for the transmission and routing of telephone 
    exchange service and exchange access.'' Because telephone exchange 
    service is a local, intrastate service, section 251(c)(2) plainly 
    addresses intrastate service, but it also addresses interstate exchange 
    access. In addition, we note that in section 253, the statute 
    explicitly authorizes the Commission to preempt intrastate and 
    interstate barriers to entry.
        65. More generally, if these sections are read to address only 
    interstate services, the grant of substantial responsibilities to the 
    states under section 252 is incongruous. A statute designed to develop 
    a national policy framework to promote local competition cannot 
    reasonably be read to reduce significantly the FCC's traditional 
    jurisdiction over interstate matters by delegating enforcement 
    responsibilities to the states, unless Congress intended also to 
    implement its national policies by enhancing our authority to encompass 
    rulemaking authority over intrastate interconnection matters. The 
    legislative history is replete with statements indicating that Congress 
    meant to address intrastate local exchange competition. For instance, 
    Senator Lott stated that ``[i]n addressing local and long distance 
    issues, creating an open access and sound interconnection policy was 
    the key objective * * * '' 141 Cong. Rec. S7906 (June 7, 1995) 
    (emphasis added). Representative Markey noted that ``we take down the 
    barriers of local and long distance and cable company, satellite, 
    computer software entry into any business they want to get in.'' 142 
    Cong. Rec. H1151 (Feb. 1, 1996) (emphasis added).
        66. Some parties argue that section 251 addresses solely intrastate 
    matters. We do not find this argument persuasive. Under this narrow 
    view, section 251(c)(6) requiring incumbent LECs to offer physical 
    collocation would apply only to equipment used for intrastate services, 
    while new entrants would be limited to the use of virtual collocation 
    for equipment used in the provision of interstate services, pursuant to 
    the decision in Bell Atlantic. Bell Atlantic Telephone Companies v. 
    FCC, 24 F.3d 1441 (D.C. Cir. 1994) (Bell Atlantic) (holding that the 
    Commission did not have authority to require physical collocation for 
    the provision of interstate services). Such an interpretation would 
    force new entrants to use different methods of collocation based on the 
    jurisdictional nature of the traffic involved, and would thereby 
    greatly increase new entrants' costs. Moreover, such an interpretation 
    would fail to give effect to Congress's intent in
    
    [[Page 45490]]
    
    enacting section 251(c)(6) to reverse the result reached in Bell 
    Atlantic. The language in the House bill which closely matches the 
    language that appears in section 251(c)(6), noted that a provision 
    requiring physical collocation was necessary ``because a recent court 
    decision indicates that the Commission lacks authority under the 
    Communications Act to order physical collocation.'' H.R. Rep. No. 204, 
    pt. I, 104th Cong., 1st Sess., at 73 (1995).
        67. Another factor that makes clear that sections 251 and 252 did 
    not address exclusively intrastate matters is the provision in section 
    251(g), ``Continued Enforcement of Exchange Access and Interconnection 
    Requirements.'' That section provides that BOCs must follow the 
    Commission's ``equal access and nondiscriminatory interconnection 
    restrictions (including receipt of compensation)'' until they are 
    explicitly superseded by Commission regulations after the date of 
    enactment of the 1996 Act. This provision refers to existing Commission 
    rules governing interstate matters, and therefore it contradicts the 
    argument that section 251 addresses intrastate matters exclusively.
        68. Nor does the savings clause of section 251(i) require us to 
    conclude that sections 251 and 252 address only intrastate issues. 
    Section 251(i) provides that ``[n]othing in this section shall be 
    construed to limit or otherwise affect the Commission's authority under 
    section 201.'' This subsection merely affirms that the Commission's 
    preexisting authority under section 201 continues to apply for purely 
    interstate activities. It does not act as a limitation on the agency's 
    authority under section 251.
        69. As to the third possible interpretation, the FCC's role is to 
    establish rules for only the interstate aspects of interconnection, and 
    the states' role is to arbitrate and approve only the intrastate 
    aspects of interconnection agreements. No commenters support this 
    position, and we find that it would be inconsistent with the 1996 Act 
    to read into sections 251 and 252 such a distinction. The statute 
    explicitly contemplates that the states are to comply with the 
    Commission's rules, and the Commission is required to assume the state 
    commission's responsibilities if the state commission fails to act to 
    carry out its section 252 responsibilities. Thus, we believe the only 
    logical conclusion is that the Commission and the states have parallel 
    jurisdiction. We conclude, therefore, that these sections can only 
    logically be read to address both interstate and intrastate aspects of 
    interconnection, services, and access to unbundled network elements, 
    and thus to grant the Commission authority to establish regulations 
    under 251, binding on both carriers and states, for both interstate and 
    intrastate aspects.
        70. Section 2(b) of the Act does not require a different 
    conclusion. Section 2(b) provides that, except as provided in certain 
    enumerated sections not including sections 251 and 252, ``nothing in 
    [the 1934] Act shall be construed to apply or to give to the Commission 
    jurisdiction with respect to * * * charges, classifications, practices, 
    services, facilities, or regulations for or in connection with 
    intrastate communication service by wire or radio of any carrier * * 
    *''. As stated above, however, we have found that sections 251 and 252 
    do apply to ``charges, classifications, practices, services, 
    facilities, or regulations for or in connection with intrastate 
    communication service.'' In enacting sections 251 and 252 after section 
    2(b), and squarely addressing therein the issue of interstate and 
    intrastate jurisdiction, we find that Congress intended for sections 
    251 and 252 to take precedence over any contrary implications based on 
    section 2(b). We note also, that in enacting the 1996 Act, there are 
    other instances where Congress indisputably gave the Commission 
    intrastate jurisdiction without amending section 2(b). For instance, 
    section 251(e)(1) provides that ``[t]he Commission shall have exclusive 
    jurisdiction over those portions of the North American Numbering Plan 
    that pertain to the United States.'' Section 253 directs the FCC to 
    preempt state regulations that prohibit the ability to provide 
    intrastate services. Section 276(b) directs the Commission to 
    ``establish a per call compensation plan to ensure that payphone 
    service providers are fairly compensated for each and every completed 
    intrastate and interstate call.'' Section 276(d) provides that ``[t]o 
    the extent that any State requirements are inconsistent with the 
    Commission's regulations, the Commission's regulations on such matters 
    shall preempt such State requirements.'' None of these provisions is 
    specifically excepted from section 2(b), yet all of them explicitly 
    give the FCC jurisdiction over intrastate matters. Thus, we believe 
    that the lack of an explicit exception in section 2(b) should not be 
    read to require an interpretation that the Commission's jurisdiction 
    under sections 251 and 252 is limited to interstate services. A 
    contrary holding would nullify several explicit grants of authority to 
    the FCC, noted above, and would render parts of the statute 
    meaningless.
        71. Some parties find significance in the fact that earlier drafts 
    of the legislation would have amended section 2(b) to make an exception 
    for Part II of Title II, including section 251, but the enacted version 
    did not include that exception. These parties argue that this change in 
    drafting demonstrates an intention by Congress that the limitations of 
    section 2(b) remain fully in force with regard to sections 251 and 252. 
    We find this argument unpersuasive.
        72. Parties that attach significance to the omission of the 
    proposed amendment of section 2(b) rely on a rule of statutory 
    construction providing that, when a provision in a prior draft is 
    altered in the final legislation, Congress intended a change from the 
    prior version. This rule of statutory construction has been rejected, 
    however, when changes from one draft to another are not explained. In 
    this instance, the only statement from Congress regarding the meaning 
    of the omission of the section 2(b) amendment appears in the Joint 
    Explanatory Statement of the Conference Report. According to the Joint 
    Explanatory Statement, all differences between the Senate Bill, the 
    House Amendment, and the substitute reached in conference are noted 
    therein ``except for clerical corrections, conforming changes made 
    necessary by agreements reached by the conferees, and minor drafting 
    and clerical changes.'' Because the Joint Explanatory Statement did not 
    address the removal of the section 2(b) amendment from the final bill, 
    the logical inference is that Congress regarded the change as an 
    inconsequential modification rather than a significant alteration. 
    Moreover, it seems implausible that, by selecting the final version, 
    Congress intended a radical alteration of the Commission's authority 
    under section 251, given the total lack of legislative history to that 
    effect. We conclude that elimination of the proposed amendment of 
    section 2(b) was a nonsubstantive change because, as AT&T contends, 
    such amendment was unnecessary in light of the grants of authority 
    under sections 251 and 252, and would have had no practical effect.
        73. Some parties have argued that, to the extent that sections 251 
    and 252 address intrastate matters, the Commission's rulemaking 
    authority under those sections is limited to those instances where 
    Commission action regarding intrastate matters is specifically 
    mandated, such as number administration. We disagree. There is no 
    language limiting the Commission's
    
    [[Page 45491]]
    
    authority to establish rules under section 251. To the contrary, 
    section 251(d)(1) affirmatively requires Commission rules, stating that 
    ``the Commission shall complete all actions necessary to implement the 
    requirements of this section.'' Pursuant to sections 4(i), 201(b), and 
    303(r) of the Act, the Commission generally has rulemaking authority to 
    implement all provisions of the Communications Act. Courts have held 
    that the Commission, pursuant to its general rulemaking authority, has 
    ``expansive'' rather than limited powers. Further, where Congress has 
    expressly delegated to the Commission rulemaking responsibility with 
    respect to a particular matter, such delegation constitutes ``something 
    more than the normal grant of authority permitting an agency to make 
    ordinary rules and regulations * * *''. Indeed, to read these 
    provisions otherwise would negate the requirement that states ensure 
    that arbitrated agreements are consistent with the Commission's rules. 
    Thus, the explicit rulemaking requirements pointed out by some of the 
    parties is best read as giving the Commission more jurisdiction than 
    usual, not less. We believe that the delegation of authority set forth 
    in section 251(d)(1) is ``expansive'' and not limited. We therefore 
    reject assertions that the Commission has authority to establish 
    regulations regarding intrastate matters only with respect to certain 
    provisions of section 251, such as number administration.
        74. Moreover, the Court in Louisiana PSC does not suggest a 
    different result. The reasoning in Louisiana PSC applies to the dual 
    regulatory system of the 1934 Act. As set forth above, however, in 
    sections 251-253, Congress amended the dual regulatory system that the 
    Court addressed in Louisiana PSC. As a result, preemption in this case 
    is governed by the usual rule, also recognized in Louisiana PSC, that 
    an agency, acting within the scope of its delegated authority, may 
    preempt inconsistent state regulation. As discussed above, Congress 
    here has expressed an intent that our rules apply to intrastate 
    interconnection, services, and access to network elements. Therefore, 
    Louisiana PSC does not foreclose our adoption of regulations under 
    section 251 to govern intrastate matters.
        75. Parties have raised other arguments suggesting that the 
    Commission lacks authority over intrastate matters. We are not 
    persuaded by the argument that sections 256(c) and 261, as well as 
    section 601(c) of the 1996 Act, evince an intent by Congress to 
    preserve states' exclusive authority over intrastate matters. In fact, 
    section 261 supports the finding that the Commission may establish 
    regulations regarding intrastate aspects of interconnection, services 
    and access to unbundled elements that the states may not supersede. 
    Section 261(b) generally permits states to enforce regulations 
    prescribed prior to the date of enactment of the 1996 Act, and to 
    prescribe regulations after such date, if such regulations are not 
    inconsistent with the provisions of Part II of Title II. Section 261(c) 
    specifically provides that nothing in Part II of Title II ``precludes a 
    State from imposing requirements on a telecommunications carrier for 
    intrastate services that are necessary to further competition in the 
    provision of telephone exchange service or exchange access, as long as 
    the State's requirements are not inconsistent with this part or the 
    Commission's regulations to implement this part.'' We conclude that 
    state access and interconnection obligations referenced in section 
    251(d)(3) fall within the scope of section 261(c). Section 261(c), as 
    the more specific provision, controls over section 261(b) for matters 
    that fall within its scope. We note, too, that section 261(c) 
    encompasses all state requirements. It is not limited to requirements 
    that were prescribed prior to the enactment of the 1996 Act. By 
    providing that state requirements for intrastate services must be 
    consistent with the Commission's regulations, section 261(c) buttresses 
    our conclusion that the Commission may establish regulations regarding 
    intrastate aspects of interconnection, services, and access to 
    unbundled elements.
        76. Section 601 of the 1996 Act and section 256 also are consistent 
    with our conclusion. Section 601(c) of the 1996 Act provides that the 
    Act and its amendments ``shall not be construed to modify, impair, or 
    supersede Federal, State, or local law unless expressly so provided in 
    such Act or amendments.'' We conclude that section 251(d)(1), which 
    requires the Commission to ``establish regulations to implement the 
    requirements of this section,'' and section 261(c), were expressly 
    intended to modify federal and state law and jurisdictional authority.
        77. Section 256, entitled ``Coordination for Interconnectivity,'' 
    has no direct bearing on the issue of the Commission's authority under 
    section 251, because it provides only that ``[n]othing in this section 
    shall be construed as expanding or limiting any authority that the 
    Commission may have under law in effect before the date of enactment of 
    the Telecommunications Act of 1996.'' That provision is relevant, 
    however, as a contrast to section 251, which does not contain a similar 
    statement that the scope of the Commission's authority is unchanged by 
    section 251. Russello v. United States, 464 U.S. 16, 23 (1983); Cramer 
    v. Internal Revenue Service, 64 F.3d 1406, 1412 (9th Cir. 1995) (where 
    Congress includes a provision in one section of statute but omits it in 
    another section of the same Act, it should not be implied where it is 
    excluded).
        78. We further conclude that the Commission's regulations under 
    section 251 are binding on the states, even with respect to intrastate 
    issues. Section 252 provides that the agreements state commissions 
    arbitrate must comply with the Commission's regulations established 
    pursuant to section 251. In addition, section 253 requires the 
    Commission to preempt state or local regulations or requirements that 
    ``prohibit or have the effect of prohibiting the ability of any entity 
    to provide any interstate or intrastate telecommunications service.'' 
    As discussed above, section 261(c) provides further support for the 
    conclusion that states are bound by the regulations the Commission 
    establishes under section 251.
        79. We disagree with claims that section 251(d)(3) ``grandfathers'' 
    existing state regulations that are consistent with the 1996 Act, and 
    that such state regulations need not comply with the Commission's 
    implementing regulations. Section 251(d)(3) only specifies that the 
    Commission may not preclude enforcement of state access and 
    interconnection requirements that are consistent with section 251, and 
    that do not substantially prevent implementation of the requirements of 
    section 251 or the purposes of Part II of Title II. In this Report and 
    Order, we set forth only such rules that we believe are necessary to 
    implement fully section 251 and the purposes of Part II of Title II. 
    Thus, state regulations that are inconsistent with our rules may 
    ``substantially prevent implementation of the requirements of this 
    section and the purposes of [Part II of Title II].''
        80. We are not persuaded by arguments that, because other 
    provisions of the 1996 Act specifically require states to comply with 
    the Commission's regulations, the absence of such requirement in 
    section 251(d)(3) indicates that Congress did not intend such 
    compliance. Section 251(d)(3) permits states to prescribe and to 
    enforce access and interconnection requirements only to the extent that 
    such requirements ``are consistent with the requirements'' of section 
    251 and do not ``substantially prevent
    
    [[Page 45492]]
    
    implementation'' of the requirements of section 251 and the purposes of 
    Part II of Title II. The Commission is required to establish 
    regulations to ``implement the requirements of the section.'' 
    Therefore, in order to be consistent with the requirements of section 
    251 and not ``substantially prevent'' implementation of section 251 or 
    Part II of Title II, state requirements must be consistent with the 
    FCC's implementing regulations.
    
    D. Commission's Legal Authority and the Adoption of National Pricing 
    Rules
    
    1. Background
        81. In the NPRM, we sought comment on our tentative conclusion that 
    sections 251 (c)(2), (c)(3), and (c)(6) establish the Commission's 
    legal authority under section 251(d) to adopt pricing rules to ensure 
    that the rates, terms, and conditions for interconnection, access to 
    unbundled network elements, and collocation are just, reasonable, and 
    nondiscriminatory. We also sought comment on our tentative conclusion 
    that sections 251(b)(5) and 251(c)(4) establish our authority to define 
    ``wholesale rates'' for purposes of resale, and ``reciprocal 
    compensation arrangements'' for purposes of transport and termination 
    of telecommunications services. In addition, we asked parties to 
    comment on our tentative conclusion that the Commission's statutory 
    duty to implement the pricing requirements of section 251, as 
    elaborated in section 252, requires that we establish pricing rules 
    interpreting and further explaining the provisions of section 252(d). 
    The states would then apply these rules in establishing rates pursuant 
    to arbitrations and in reviewing BOC statements of generally available 
    terms and conditions.
        82. We further sought comment on our tentative conclusion that 
    national pricing rules would likely reduce or eliminate inconsistent 
    state regulatory requirements, increase the predictability of rates, 
    and facilitate negotiation, arbitration, and review of agreements 
    between incumbent LECs and competitive providers. We also sought 
    comment on the potential consequences of the Commission not 
    establishing specific pricing rules.
    2. Discussion
        83. In adopting sections 251 and 252, we conclude that Congress 
    envisioned complementary and significant roles for the Commission and 
    the states with respect to the rates for section 251 services, 
    interconnection, and access to unbundled elements. We interpret the 
    Commission's role under section 251 as ensuring that rates are just, 
    reasonable, and nondiscriminatory: in doing so, we believe it to be 
    within our discretion to adopt national pricing rules in order to 
    ensure that rates will be just, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory. The 
    Commission is also responsible for ensuring that interconnection, 
    collocation, access to unbundled elements, resale services, and 
    transport and termination of telecommunications are reasonably 
    available to new entrants. The states' role under section 252(c) is to 
    establish specific rates when the parties cannot agree, consistent with 
    the regulations prescribed by the Commission under sections 251(d)(1) 
    and 252(d).
        84. While we recognize that sections 201 and 202 create a very 
    different regulatory regime from that envisioned by sections 251 and 
    252, we observe that Congress used terms in section 251, such as the 
    requirement that rates, terms, and conditions be ``just, reasonable, 
    and nondiscriminatory,'' that are very similar to language in sections 
    201 and 202. This lends additional support for the proposition that 
    Congress intended to give us authority to adopt rules regarding the 
    justness and reasonableness of rates pursuant to section 251, 
    comparable in some respects to the authority Congress gave us pursuant 
    to sections 201 and 202.
        85. We believe that national pricing rules are a critical component 
    of the interconnection regime set out in sections 251 and 252. Congress 
    intended these sections to promote opportunities for local competition, 
    and directed us to establish regulations to ensure that rates under 
    this regime would be economically efficient. This, in turn, should 
    reduce potential entrants' capital costs, and should facilitate entry 
    by all types of service providers, including small entities. Further, 
    we believe that national rules will help states review and arbitrate 
    contested agreements in a timely fashion. From August to November and 
    beyond, states will be carrying the tremendous burden of setting 
    specific rates for interconnection and network elements, for resale, 
    and for transport and termination when parties bring these issues 
    before them for arbitration. As discussed in more detail below, we are 
    setting forth default proxies for states to use if they are unable to 
    set these rates using the necessary cost studies within the statutory 
    time frame. After that, both we and the states will need to review the 
    level of competition, revise our rules as necessary, and reconcile 
    arbitrated interconnection arrangements to those revisions on a going-
    forward basis.
        86. We believe that national rules should reduce the parties' 
    uncertainty about the outcome that may be reached by different states 
    in their respective regulatory proceedings, which will reduce 
    regulatory burdens for all parties including small incumbent LECs and 
    small entities. A national regime should also help to ensure consistent 
    federal court decisions on review of specific state orders under 
    sections 251 and 252. In addition, under the national pricing rules 
    that we adopt for interconnection and unbundled network elements, 
    states will retain the flexibility to consider local technological, 
    environmental, regulatory, and economic conditions. Failure to adopt 
    national pricing rules, on the other hand, could lead to widely 
    disparate state policies that could delay the consummation of 
    interconnection arrangements and otherwise hinder the development of 
    local competition. Lack of national rules could also provide 
    opportunities for incumbent LECs to inhibit or delay the 
    interconnection efforts of new competitors, and create great 
    uncertainty for the industry, capital markets, regulators, and courts 
    as to what pricing policies would be pursued by each of the individual 
    states, frustrating the potential entrants' ability to raise capital. 
    In sum, we believe that the pricing of interconnection, unbundled 
    elements, resale, and transport and termination of telecommunications 
    is important to ensure that opportunities to compete are available to 
    new entrants.
        87. As we observed in the NPRM, section 251 explicitly sets forth 
    certain requirements regarding rates for interconnection, access to 
    unbundled elements, and related offerings. Sections 251 (c)(2) and 
    (c)(3) require that incumbent LECs' ``rates, terms, and conditions'' 
    for interconnection and unbundled network elements be ``just, 
    reasonable, and nondiscriminatory in accordance with * * * the 
    requirements of sections 251 and 252.'' Section 251(c)(4) requires that 
    incumbent LECs offer ``for resale at wholesale rates any 
    telecommunications service that the carrier provides at retail to 
    subscribers who are not telecommunications carriers,'' without 
    unreasonable conditions or limitations. Section 251(c)(6) provides that 
    all LECs must provide physical collocation of equipment, ``on rates, 
    terms, and conditions that are just, reasonable, and 
    nondiscriminatory.'' Section 251(b)(5) requires that all LECs 
    ``establish reciprocal compensation arrangements for the transport and 
    termination of telecommunications.'' Section 251(d)(1) further 
    expressly directs the
    
    [[Page 45493]]
    
    Commission, without limitation, to ``complete all actions necessary to 
    implement the requirements of [section 251].''
        88. Section 252 generally sets forth the procedures that state 
    commissions, incumbent LECs, and new entrants must follow to implement 
    the requirements of section 251 and establish specific interconnection 
    arrangements. Section 252(c)(1) provides that ``in resolving by 
    arbitration * * * any open issues and imposing conditions upon the 
    parties to the agreement, a State commission shall * * * ensure that 
    such resolution and conditions meet the requirements of section 251, 
    including the regulations prescribed by the Commission pursuant to 
    section 251.''
        89. We conclude that, under section 251(d)(1), Congress granted us 
    broad authority to complete all actions necessary to implement the 
    requirements of section 251, including actions necessary to ensure that 
    rates for interconnection, access to unbundled elements, and 
    collocation are ``just, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory.'' We also 
    determine that the statute grants us the authority to define reasonable 
    ``wholesale rates'' for purposes of services to be resold, and 
    ``reciprocal compensation'' for purposes of transport and termination 
    of telecommunications. The argument advanced by the New York 
    Commission, NARUC, and others that the Commission's implementing 
    authority under section 251(d)(1) is limited to those provisions in 
    section 251 that mandate specific Commission rules, such as prescribing 
    regulations for number portability, unbundling, and resale, reads into 
    section 251(d)(1) limiting language that the section does not contain. 
    Congress did not confine the Commission's rulemaking authority to only 
    those matters identified in sections 251(b)(2), 251(c)(4)(B), and 
    251(d)(2), and there is no basis for inferring such an implicit 
    limitation. A narrow reading of section 251(d)(1), as proposed by the 
    New York Commission, NARUC, and others, would require the Commission to 
    neglect its statutory duty to implement the provisions of section 251 
    and to promote rapid competitive entry into local telephone markets.
        90. We also reject the arguments raised by several state 
    commissions that the language in section 252(c) indicates Congress' 
    intent for the Commission to have little or no authority with respect 
    to pricing of interconnection, access to unbundled elements, and 
    collocation. We do not believe that the statutory directive that state 
    commissions establish rates according to section 252(d) restricts our 
    authority under section 251(d)(1). States must comply with both the 
    statutory standards under section 252(d) and the regulations prescribed 
    by the Commission pursuant to section 251 when arbitrating rate 
    disputes or when reviewing BOC statements of generally available terms. 
    Section 252(c) enumerates three requirements that states must follow in 
    arbitrating issues. These requirements are not set forth in the 
    alternative; rather, states must comply with all three.
        91. We further reject the argument that section 251(d)(3) restricts 
    the Commission's authority to establish national pricing regulations. 
    Section 251(d)(3) provides that the Commission shall not preclude the 
    enforcement of any regulation, order, or policy of a state commission 
    that, inter alia, is consistent with the requirements of section 251 
    and does not substantially prevent implementation of the requirements 
    of section 251. This subsection, as discussed in section II.C., supra, 
    is intended to allow states to adopt regulations that are not 
    inconsistent with the Commission's rules; it does not address state 
    policies that are inconsistent with the pricing rules established by 
    the Commission.
        92. We also address the impact of our rules on small incumbent 
    LECs. For example, Rural Tel. Coalition argues that rigid rules, based 
    on the properties of large urban LECs, cannot blindly be applied to 
    small and rural LECs. As discussed above, however, we believe that 
    states will retain sufficient flexibility under our rules to consider 
    local technological, environmental, regulatory, and economic 
    conditions. We also note that section 251(f) may provide relief to 
    certain small carriers.
    
    E. Authority To Take Enforcement Action
    
    1. Background
        93. The Commission's implementation of section 251 must be given 
    full effect in arbitrated agreements and incorporated into all such 
    agreements. There is judicial review of such arbitrated agreements, and 
    one issue surely will be the adherence of these agreements to our 
    rules. The Commission will have the opportunity to participate, upon 
    request by a party or a state or by submitting an amicus filing, in the 
    arbitration or the judicial review thereof. To clarify our potential 
    role, we consider the extent of the Commission's authority to review 
    and enforce agreements entered into pursuant to section 252. Section 
    252(e)(6) provides that, in ``any case in which a State commission 
    makes a determination under this section, any party aggrieved by such 
    determination may bring an action in an appropriate Federal district 
    court to determine whether the agreement or statement meets the 
    requirements of section 251 and this section.''
        94. In the NPRM, we sought comment on the relationship between 
    sections 251 and 252 and the Commission's existing authority under 
    section 208(a), which allows any person to file a complaint with the 
    Commission regarding ``anything done or omitted to be done by any 
    common carrier subject to this Act, in contravention of the provisions 
    thereof * * *'' We asked whether section 208 gives the Commission 
    authority over complaints alleging violations of requirements set forth 
    in sections 251 or 252. We also sought comment on the relationship 
    between sections 251 and 252 and any other applicable Commission 
    enforcement authority. We further sought comment on how we might 
    increase the effectiveness of the Commission's enforcement mechanisms. 
    Specifically, we asked for comment on how private rights of action 
    might be used under the Act, and the Commission's role in speeding 
    dispute resolution in forums used by private parties.
    2. Discussion
        95. Consistent with our decision in Telephone Number Portability 
    and the views of most commenters, we conclude that parties have several 
    options for seeking relief if they believe that a carrier has violated 
    the standards under section 251 or 252. Pursuant to section 252(e)(6), 
    a party aggrieved by a state commission arbitration determination under 
    section 252 has the right to bring an action in federal district court. 
    Commenters also suggest that the statute's provision for federal 
    district court review of state public utility commission decisions is 
    inconsistent with the 11th Amendment. That issue is not properly before 
    the Commission since it is the federal courts that will have to 
    determine the scope of their jurisdiction and in any case ``regulatory 
    agencies are not free to declare an act of Congress unconstitutional.'' 
    See Meredith Corp. versus FCC, 809 F.2d 863, 873 (D.C. Cir. 1987). 
    Federal district courts may choose to stay or dismiss proceedings 
    brought pursuant to section 252(e)(6), and refer issues of compliance 
    with the substantive requirements of sections 251 and 252 to the 
    Commission under the primary jurisdiction doctrine. We find, however, 
    that federal court review is not the exclusive remedy regarding state 
    determinations under section 252. The
    
    [[Page 45494]]
    
    1996 Act is clear when it intends for a remedy to be exclusive. For 
    example, section 252(e)(6) provides that, if a state commission fails 
    to act, as described in section 252(e)(5), ``the proceeding by the 
    Commission under [section 252(e)(5)] and any judicial review of the 
    Commission's actions shall be the exclusive remedies for a State 
    commission's failure to act.'' In contrast, the succeeding sentence in 
    section 252(e)(6) provides that any party aggrieved by a state 
    commission determination under section 252 ``may bring an action in an 
    appropriate Federal district court * * *''
        96. The Commission also stands ready to provide guidance to states 
    and other parties regarding the statute and our rules. In addition to 
    the informal consultations that we hope to continue with state 
    commissions, they or other parties may at any time seek a declaratory 
    ruling where necessary to remove uncertainty or eliminate a 
    controversy. See 47 CFR Sec. 1.2 (the Commission, in accordance with 
    section 5(d) of the Administrative Procedures Act, 5 U.S.C. 
    Sec. 554(e), may issue a declaratory ruling terminating a controversy 
    or removing uncertainty). Because section 251 is critical to the 
    development of competitive local markets, we intend to act 
    expeditiously on such requests for declaratory rulings.
        97. We further conclude that section 252(e)(6) does not divest the 
    Commission of jurisdiction, in whole or in part, over complaints that a 
    common carrier violated section 251 or 252 of the Act. Section 
    601(c)(1) of the 1996 Act provides that the 1996 Act ``shall not be 
    construed to modify, impair or supersede'' existing federal law--which 
    includes the section 208 complaint process--``unless expressly so 
    provided.'' Sections 251 and 252 do not divest the Commission of its 
    section 208 complaint authority.
        98. An aggrieved party could file a section 208 complaint with the 
    Commission, alleging that the incumbent LEC or requesting carrier has 
    failed to comply with the requirements of sections 251 and 252, 
    including Commission rules thereunder, even if the carrier is in 
    compliance with an agreement approved by the state commission. 
    Alternatively, a party could file a section 208 complaint alleging that 
    a common carrier is violating the terms of a negotiated or arbitrated 
    agreement. We plan to initiate a proceeding to adopt expedited 
    procedures for resolving complaints filed pursuant to section 208.
        99. We note that, in acting on a section 208 complaint, we would 
    not be directly reviewing the state commission's decision, but rather, 
    our review would be strictly limited to determining whether the common 
    carrier's actions or omissions were in contravention of the 
    Communications Act. While we would have authority to review such 
    complaints, we note that we might decline, at least in some instances, 
    to impose financial penalties upon a common carrier that is acting 
    pursuant to state requirements or authorization, even if we sustain the 
    allegations in the complaint. Thus, consistent with our past decisions 
    in analogous contexts (See Number Portability Order, supra; Freemon 
    versus AT&T, 59 FR 43125 (August 22, 1994) (provision permitting 
    persons aggrieved by violation of prohibition against unauthorized 
    publication of certain communications to ``bring a civil action in 
    United States district court or any other court of competent 
    jurisdiction'' did not bar a complaint under section 208 of the 
    Communications Act); see also Policies Governing the Provision of 
    Shared Telecommunications Service, 54 FR 478 (January 6, 1989) (the 
    section 208 complaint process is available to resolve any specific 
    problems that might arise regarding shared telecommunications service 
    regulation by a state that impinges upon a federal interest)), we 
    conclude that a person aggrieved by a state determination under 
    sections 251 and 252 of the Act may elect to either bring an action for 
    federal district court review or a section 208 complaint to the 
    Commission against a common carrier. Such a person could, as a further 
    alternative, pursuant to section 207, file a complaint against a common 
    carrier with the Commission or in federal district court for the 
    recovery of damages. We are unlikely, in adjudicating a complaint, to 
    examine the consistency of a state decision with sections 251 and 252 
    if a judicial determination has already been made on the issues before 
    us.
        100. Finally, we clarify, as one commenter requested, that nothing 
    in sections 251 and 252 of our implementing regulations is intended to 
    limit the ability of persons to seek relief under the antitrust laws, 
    other statutes, or common law. In addition, in appropriate 
    circumstances, the Commission could institute an inquiry on its own 
    motion, 47 U.S.C. Sec. 403, initiate a forfeiture proceeding, 47 U.S.C. 
    Sec. 503(b), initiate a cease-and-desist proceeding, 47 U.S.C. 
    Sec. 312(b), or in extreme cases, consider initiating a revocation 
    proceeding for violators with radio licenses, 47 U.S.C. Sec. 312(a), or 
    referring violations to the Department of Justice for possible criminal 
    prosecution under 47 U.S.C. Sec. 501, 502 & 503(a).
    
    F. Regulations of BOC Statements of Generally Available Terms
    
        101. We noted in the NPRM that section 251 and our implementing 
    regulations govern the states' review of BOC statements of generally 
    available terms and conditions, as well as arrangements reached through 
    compulsory arbitration pursuant to section 252(b). We tentatively 
    concluded that we should adopt a single set of standards with which 
    both arbitrated agreements and BOC statements of generally available 
    terms must comply.
        102. Only a few commenters addressed this issue, and most concurred 
    with the tentative conclusion that we should apply the same 
    requirements to both arbitrated agreements and BOC statements of 
    generally available terms. The Illinois Commission, for example, 
    asserts that, ``[s]ince the generally available terms could be viewed 
    as a baseline against which to craft arbitrated arrangements, it is 
    reasonable to hold both arbitrated agreements and the BOC statements of 
    generally available terms to the same standards.'' CompTel asserts 
    that, particularly if states require incumbent LECs to tariff the terms 
    and conditions in agreements that are subject to arbitration, there 
    will be few if any distinctions between arbitrated agreements and 
    generally available terms and conditions.
        103. We hereby find that our tentative conclusion that we should 
    apply a single set of standards to both arbitrated agreements and BOC 
    statements of generally available terms is consistent with both the 
    text and purpose of the 1996 Act. BOC statements of generally available 
    terms are relevant where a BOC seeks to provide in-region interLATA 
    service, and the BOC has not negotiated or arbitrated an agreement. 
    Therefore, such statements are to some extent a substitute for an 
    agreement for interconnection, services, or access to unbundled 
    elements. We also find no basis in the statute for establishing 
    different requirements for arbitrated agreements and BOC statements of 
    generally available terms. Moreover, a single set of requirements will 
    substantially ease the burdens of state commissions and the FCC in 
    reviewing agreements and statements of generally available terms 
    pursuant to sections 252 and 271.
    
    [[Page 45495]]
    
    G. States' Role in Fostering Local Competition Under Sections 251 and 
    252
    
        104. As already referenced, states will play a critical role in 
    promoting local competition, including by taking a key role in the 
    negotiation and arbitration process. We believe the negotiation/
    arbitration process pursuant to section 252 is likely to proceed as 
    follows. Initially, the requesting carrier and incumbent LEC will seek 
    to negotiate mutually agreeable rates, terms, and conditions governing 
    the competing carrier's interconnection to the incumbent's network, 
    access to the incumbent's unbundled network elements, or the provision 
    of services at wholesale rates for resale by the requesting carrier. 
    Either party may ask the relevant state commission to mediate specific 
    issues to facilitate an agreement during the negotiation process.
        105. Because the new entrant's objective is to obtain the services 
    and access to facilities from the incumbent that the entrant needs to 
    compete in the incumbent's market, the negotiation process contemplated 
    by the 1996 Act bears little resemblance to a typical commercial 
    negotiation. Indeed, the entrant has nothing that the incumbent needs 
    to compete with the entrant, and has little to offer the incumbent in a 
    negotiation. Consequently, the 1996 Act provides that, if the parties 
    fail to reach agreement on all issues, either party may seek 
    arbitration before a state commission. The state commission will 
    arbitrate individual issues specified by the parties, or conceivably 
    may be asked to arbitrate the entire agreement. In the event that a 
    state commission must act as arbitrator, it will need to ensure that 
    the arbitrated agreement is consistent with the Commission's rules. In 
    reviewing arbitrated and negotiated agreements, the state commission 
    may ensure that such agreements are consistent with applicable state 
    requirements.
        106. Under the statutory scheme in sections 251 and 252, state 
    commissions may be asked by parties to define specific terms and 
    conditions governing access to unbundled elements, interconnection, and 
    resale of services beyond the rules the Commission establishes in this 
    Report and Order. Moreover, the state commissions are responsible for 
    setting specific rates in arbitrated proceedings. For example, state 
    commissions in an arbitration would likely designate the terms and 
    conditions by which the competing carrier receives access to the 
    incumbent's loops. The state commission might arbitrate a description 
    or definition of the loop, the term for which the carrier commits to 
    the purchase of rights to exclusive use of a specific network element, 
    and the provisions under which the competing carrier will order loops 
    from the incumbent and the incumbent will provision an order. The state 
    commission may establish procedures that govern should the incumbent 
    refurbish or replace the element during the agreement period, and the 
    procedures that apply should an end user customer decide to switch from 
    the competing carrier back to the incumbent or a different provider. In 
    addition, the state commission will establish the rates an incumbent 
    charges for loops, perhaps with volume and term discounts specified, as 
    well as rates that carriers may charge to end users.
        107. State commissions will have similar responsibilities with 
    respect to other unbundled network elements such as the switch, 
    interoffice transport, signalling and databases. State commissions may 
    identify network elements to be unbundled, in addition to those 
    elements identified by the Commission, and may identify additional 
    points at which incumbent LECs must provide interconnection, where 
    technically feasible. State commissions are responsible for determining 
    when virtual collocation may be provided instead of physical 
    collocation, pursuant to section 251(c)(6). States also will determine, 
    in accordance with section 251(f)(1), whether and to what extent a 
    rural incumbent LEC is entitled to continued exemption from the 
    requirements of section 251(c) after a telecommunications carrier has 
    made a bona fide request under section 251. Under section 251(f)(2), 
    states will determine whether to grant petitions that may be filed by 
    certain LECs for suspension or modification of the requirements in 
    sections 251 (b) or (c).
        108. The foregoing is a representative sampling of the role that 
    states will have in steering the course of local competition. State 
    commissions will make critical decisions concerning a host of issues 
    involving rates, terms, and conditions of interconnection and 
    unbundling arrangements, and exemption, suspension, or modification of 
    the requirements in section 251. The actions taken by a state will 
    significantly affect the development of local competition in that 
    state. Moreover, actions in one state are likely to influence other 
    states, and to have a substantial impact on steps the FCC takes in 
    developing a pro-competitive national policy framework.
    
    III. Duty to Negotiate in Good Faith
    
    A. Background
    
        109. Section 251(c)(1) of the statute imposes on incumbent LECs the 
    ``duty to negotiate in good faith in accordance with section 252 the 
    particular terms and conditions of agreements to fulfill the duties 
    described'' in sections 251(b) and (c), and further provides that 
    ``(t)he requesting telecommunications carrier also has the duty to 
    negotiate in good faith the terms and conditions of such agreements.'' 
    In the NPRM, we asked parties to comment on the extent to which the 
    Commission should establish national rules defining the requirements of 
    the good faith negotiation obligation.
    
    B. Advantages and Disadvantages of National Rules
    
    1. Discussion
        110. We conclude that establishing some national standards 
    regarding the duty to negotiate in good faith could help to reduce 
    areas of dispute and expedite fair and successful negotiations, and 
    thereby realize Congress' goal of enabling swift market entry by new 
    competitors. In order to address the balance of the incentives between 
    the bargaining parties, however, we believe that we should set forth 
    some minimum requirements of good faith negotiation that will guide 
    parties and state commissions. As discussed above, the requirements in 
    section 251 obligate incumbent LECs to provide interconnection to 
    competitors that seek to reduce the incumbent's subscribership and 
    weaken the incumbent's dominant position in the market. Generally, the 
    new entrant has little to offer the incumbent. Thus, an incumbent LEC 
    is likely to have scant, if any, economic incentive to reach agreement. 
    In addition, incumbent LECs argue that requesting carriers may have 
    incentives to make unreasonable demands or otherwise fail to act in 
    good faith. The fact that an incumbent LEC has superior bargaining 
    power does not itself demonstrate a lack of good faith, or ensure that 
    a new entrant will act in good faith.
        111. We agree with commenters that it would be futile to try to 
    determine in advance every possible action that might be inconsistent 
    with the duty to negotiate in good faith. As discussed more fully 
    below, determining whether or not a party's conduct is consistent with 
    its statutory duty will depend largely on the specific facts of 
    individual negotiations. Therefore, we believe that it is appropriate 
    to identify factors or practices that may be evidence of failure to 
    negotiate in good faith, but
    
    [[Page 45496]]
    
    that will need to be considered in light of all relevant circumstances.
        112. Consistent with our discussion in Section II, above, we 
    believe that the Commission has authority to review complaints alleging 
    violations of good faith negotiation pursuant to section 208. We 
    previously have held that parties may raise allegations regarding good 
    faith negotiation pursuant to section 208. Cellular Interconnection 
    Proceeding, 4 FCC Rcd 2369 (1989). The Commission also held in that 
    case that ``the conduct of good faith negotiations is not 
    jurisdictionally severable.'' Id. at 2371. Penalties may be imposed 
    under sections 501, 502 and 503 for failure to negotiate in good faith. 
    In addition, we believe that state commissions have authority, under 
    section 252(b)(5), to consider allegations that a party has failed to 
    negotiate in good faith. We also reserve the right to amend these rules 
    in the future as we obtain more information regarding negotiations 
    under section 252.
    
    C. Specific Practices That May Constitute a Failure to Negotiate in 
    Good Faith
    
    1. Discussion
        113. The Uniform Commercial Code defines ``good faith'' as 
    ``honesty in fact in the conduct of the transaction concerned.'' U.C.C. 
    Sec. 1-201(19) (1981); see also Black's Law Dictionary at 353 (Abridged 
    ed. 1983) (``Good faith is an intangible and abstract quality with no 
    technical meaning or statutory definition, and it encompasses, among 
    other things, an honest belief, the absence of malice, and the absence 
    of design to defraud or to seek an unconscionable advantage * * *''). 
    When looking at good faith, the question ``is a narrow one focused on 
    the subjective intent with which the person in question has acted.'' 
    U.C.C. Sec. 1-201 (84). Even where there is no specific duty to 
    negotiate in good faith, certain principles or standards of conduct 
    have been held to apply. Steven J. Burton and Eric G. Anderson, 
    Contractual Good Faith, Sec. 8.2.2 at 332 (1995). For example, parties 
    may not use duress or misrepresentation in negotiations. Thus, the duty 
    to negotiate in good faith, at a minimum, prevents parties from 
    intentionally misleading or coercing parties into reaching an agreement 
    they would not otherwise have made. We conclude that intentionally 
    obstructing negotiations also would constitute a failure to negotiate 
    in good faith, because it reflects a party's unwillingness to reach 
    agreement.
        114. Because section 252 permits parties to seek mediation ``at any 
    point in the negotiation,'' and also allows parties to seek arbitration 
    as early as 135 days after an incumbent LEC receives a request for 
    negotiation under section 252, we conclude that Congress specifically 
    contemplated that one or more of the parties may fail to negotiate in 
    good faith, and created at least one remedy in the arbitration process. 
    Section 252(b)(4)(C) requires state commissions to ``conclude the 
    resolution of any unresolved issues not later than 9 months after the 
    date on which the local exchange carrier received the request under 
    this section.'' 47 U.S.C. Sec. 252(b)(4)(C). The possibility of 
    arbitration itself will facilitate good faith negotiation. For example, 
    parties seeking to avoid a legitimate accusation of breach of the duty 
    of good faith in negotiation will work to provide their negotiating 
    adversary all relevant information--given that section 252(b)(4)(B) 
    authorizes the state commission to require the parties ``to provide 
    such information as may be necessary for the State commission to reach 
    a decision on the unresolved issues.'' That provision also states that, 
    if either party ``fails unreasonably to respond on a timely basis to 
    any reasonable request from the State commission, then the State 
    commission may proceed on the basis of the best information available 
    to it from whatever source derived.'' The likelihood that an arbitrator 
    will review the positions taken by the parties during negotiations also 
    should discourage parties from refusing unreasonably to provide 
    relevant information to each other or to delay negotiations.
        115. We believe that determining whether a party has acted in good 
    faith often will need to be decided on a case-by-case basis by state 
    commissions or, in some instances the FCC, in light of all the facts 
    and circumstances underlying the negotiations. This is consistent with 
    earlier Commission decisions. See Amendment to the Commission's Rules 
    Regarding a Plan for Sharing the Costs of Microwave Relocation, WT 
    Docket 95-157, First Report and Order, FCC 96-196, at para. 20, 61 FR 
    24470 (May 15, 1996). In light of these considerations, we set forth 
    some minimum standards that will offer parties guidance in determining 
    whether they are acting in good faith, but leave specific 
    determinations of whether a party has acted in good faith to be decided 
    by a state commission, court, or the FCC on a case-by-case basis.
        116. We find that there may be pro-competitive reasons for parties 
    to enter into nondisclosure agreements. A broad range of commenters, 
    including IXCs, state commissions, and incumbent LECs, support this 
    view. We conclude that there can be nondisclosure agreements that would 
    not constitute a violation of the good faith negotiation duty, but we 
    caution that overly broad, restrictive, or coercive nondisclosure 
    requirements may well have anticompetitive effects. We therefore will 
    not prejudge whether a party has demonstrated a failure to negotiate in 
    good faith by requesting another party to sign a nondisclosure 
    agreement, or by failing to sign a nondisclosure agreement; such 
    demands by incumbents, however, are of concern and any complaint 
    alleging such tactics should be evaluated carefully. Agreements may 
    not, however, preclude a party from providing information requested by 
    the FCC, a state commission, or in support of a request for arbitration 
    under section 252(b)(2)(B).
        117. We reject the general contention that a request by a party 
    that another party limit its legal remedies as part of a negotiated 
    agreement will in all cases constitute a violation of the duty to 
    negotiate in good faith. A party may voluntarily agree to limit its 
    legal rights or remedies in order to obtain a valuable concession from 
    another party. In some circumstances, however, a party may violate this 
    statutory provision by demanding that another waive its legal rights. 
    For example, we agree with ALTS' contention that an incumbent LEC may 
    not demand that the requesting carrier attest that the agreement 
    complies with all provisions of the 1996 Act, federal regulations, and 
    state law, because such a demand would be at odds with the provisions 
    of sections 251 and 252 that are intended to foster opportunities for 
    competition on a level playing field. In addition, we find that it is a 
    per se failure to negotiate in good faith for a party to refuse to 
    include in an agreement a provision that permits the agreement to be 
    amended in the future to take into account changes in Commission or 
    state rules. Refusing to permit a party to include such a provision 
    would be tantamount to forcing a party to waive its legal rights in the 
    future.
        118. We decline to find that other practices identified by parties 
    constitute per se violations of the duty to negotiate in good faith. 
    Time Warner contends that we should find that a party is not 
    negotiating in good faith under section 252 if it seeks to tie 
    resolution of issues in that negotiation to the resolution of other, 
    unrelated disputes between the parties in another proceeding. On its 
    face, the hypothetical practice raises concerns. Time Warner, however, 
    did
    
    [[Page 45497]]
    
    not present specific examples of how linking two independent 
    negotiation proceedings would undermine good faith negotiations. We 
    believe that requesting carriers have certain rights under sections 251 
    and 252, and those rights may not be derogated by an incumbent LEC 
    demanding quid pro quo concessions in another proceeding. Parties, 
    however, could mutually agree to link section 252 negotiations to 
    negotiations on a separate matter. In fact, to the extent that 
    concurrent resolution of issues could offer more potential solutions or 
    may equalize the bargaining power between the parties, such action may 
    be pro-competitive. For example, an incumbent LEC that offers video 
    programming may be negotiating for the right to use video programming 
    owned by a cable company while the cable company is negotiating terms 
    for interconnecting with the incumbent LEC. Addressing some or all of 
    the issues in the two negotiations collectively could expand the 
    options for reaching agreement, and would equalize the parties' 
    bargaining power, because each has something that the other party 
    desires.
        119. We agree with parties contending that actions that are 
    intended to delay negotiations or resolution of disputes are 
    inconsistent with the statutory duty to negotiate in good faith. The 
    Commission will not condone any actions that are deliberately intended 
    to delay competitive entry, in contravention of the statute's goals. We 
    agree with SCBA that small entities seeking to enter the market may be 
    particularly disadvantaged by delay. However, whether a party has 
    failed to negotiate in good faith by employing unreasonable delaying 
    tactics must be determined on a specific, case-by-case basis. For 
    example, a party may not refuse to negotiate with a requesting 
    telecommunications carrier, and a party may not condition negotiation 
    on a carrier first obtaining state certification. A determination based 
    upon the intent of a party, however, is not susceptible to a 
    standardized rule. If a party refuses throughout the negotiation 
    process to designate a representative with authority to make binding 
    representations on behalf of the party, and thereby significantly 
    delays resolution of issues, such action would constitute failure to 
    negotiate in good faith. The Commission has reached a consistent 
    conclusion in other instances. See, e.g., Application of Gross 
    Telecasting, Inc., 57 FR 18857 (May 1, 1992); Public Notice, FCC Asks 
    for Comments Regarding the Establishment of an Advisory Committee to 
    Negotiate Proposed Regulations, 57 FR 18857 (May 1, 1992). In 
    particular, we believe that designating a representative authorized to 
    make binding representations on behalf of a party will assist small 
    entities and small incumbent LECs by centralizing communications and 
    thereby facilitating the negotiation process. On the other hand, it is 
    unreasonable to expect an agent to have authority to bind the principal 
    on every issue--i.e., a person may reasonably be an agent of limited 
    authority.
        120. We agree with incumbent LECs and new entrants that contend 
    that the parties should be required to provide information necessary to 
    reach agreement. See National Labor Relations Board v. Truitt Mfg Co., 
    351 U.S. 149, 153 (1956) (the trier of fact can reasonably conclude 
    that a party lacks good faith if it raises assertions about inability 
    to pay without making the slightest effort to substantiate that claim); 
    see also Microwave Facilities Operating in 1850-1990 MHz (2GHz) Band, 
    61 FR 29679, 29689 (June 12, 1996). Parties should provide information 
    that will speed the provisioning process, and incumbent LECs must prove 
    to the state commission, or in some instances the Commission or a 
    court, that delay is not a motive in their conduct. Review of such 
    requests, however, must be made on a case-by-case basis to determine 
    whether the information requested is reasonable and necessary to 
    resolving the issues at stake. It would be reasonable, for example, for 
    a requesting carrier to seek and obtain cost data relevant to the 
    negotiation, or information about the incumbent's network that is 
    necessary to make a determination about which network elements to 
    request to serve a particular customer. It would not appear to be 
    reasonable, however, for a carrier to demand proprietary information 
    about the incumbent's network that is not necessary for such 
    interconnection. This is consistent with previous FCC determinations. 
    See, e.g., Amendment of Rules and Policies Governing the Attachment of 
    Cable Television Hardware to Utility Poles, 4 FCC Rcd 468 (1989) (good 
    faith negotiations necessitate that, at a minimum, one party must 
    approach the other with a specific request). We conclude that an 
    incumbent LEC may not deny a requesting carrier's reasonable request 
    for cost data during the negotiation process, because we conclude that 
    such information is necessary for the requesting carrier to determine 
    whether the rates offered by the incumbent LEC are reasonable. We find 
    that this is consistent with Congress' intention for parties to use the 
    voluntary negotiation process, if possible, to reach agreements. On the 
    other hand, the refusal of a new entrant to provide data about its own 
    costs does not appear on its face to be unreasonable, because the 
    negotiations are not about unbundling or leasing the new entrants' 
    networks.
        121. We also find that incumbent LECs may not require requesting 
    carriers to satisfy a ``bona fide request'' process as part of their 
    duty to negotiate in good faith. Some of the information that incumbent 
    LECs propose to include in a bona fide request requirement may be 
    legitimately demanded from the requesting carrier; some of the proposed 
    requirements, on the other hand, exceed the scope of what is necessary 
    for the parties to reach agreement, and imposing such requirements may 
    discourage new entry. For example, parties advocate that a ``bona fide 
    request'' requirement should require requesting carriers to commit to 
    purchase services or facilities for a specified period of time. We 
    believe that forcing carriers to make such a commitment before critical 
    terms, such as price, have been resolved is likely to impede new entry. 
    Moreover, we note that section 251(c) does not impose any bona fide 
    request requirement. In contrast, section 251(f)(1) provides that a 
    rural telephone company is exempt from the requirements of 251(c) 
    until, among other things, it receives a ``bona fide request'' for 
    interconnection, services, or network elements. This suggests that, if 
    Congress had intended to impose a ``bona fide request'' requirement on 
    requesting carriers as part of their duty to negotiate in good faith, 
    Congress would have made that requirement explicit.
    
    D. Applicability of Section 252 to Preexisting Agreements
    
    1. Background
        122. Section 252(a)(1) provides that, ``[u]pon receiving a request 
    for interconnection, services, or network elements pursuant to section 
    251, an incumbent local exchange carrier may negotiate and enter into a 
    binding agreement with the requesting telecommunications carrier or 
    carriers without regard to the standards set forth in subsections (b) 
    and (c) of section 251. * * * The agreement, including any 
    interconnection agreement negotiated before the date of enactment of 
    the Telecommunications Act of 1996, shall be submitted to the State 
    commission under subsection (e) of this section.''
    
    [[Page 45498]]
    
        123. In the NPRM, we sought comment on whether sections 252(a)(1) 
    and 252(e) require parties that have negotiated agreements for 
    interconnection, services or network elements prior to the passage of 
    the 1996 Act to submit such agreements to state commissions for 
    approval. We also asked whether one party to such an existing agreement 
    could compel renegotiation and arbitration in accordance with the 
    procedures set forth in section 252.
    2. Discussion
        124. We conclude that the 1996 Act requires all interconnection 
    agreements, ``including any interconnection agreement negotiated before 
    the date of enactment of the Telecommunications Act of 1996,'' to be 
    submitted to the state commission for approval pursuant to section 
    252(e). The 1996 Act does not exempt certain categories of agreements 
    from this requirement. When Congress sought to exclude preexisting 
    contracts from provisions of the new law, it did so expressly. For 
    example, section 276(b)(3) provides that ``nothing in this section 
    shall affect any existing contracts between location providers and 
    payphone service providers or interLATA or intraLATA carriers that are 
    in force and effect as of the date of enactment of the 
    Telecommunications Act of 1996.'' Nothing in the legislative history 
    leads us to a contrary conclusion. Congress intended, in enacting 
    sections 251 and 252, to create opportunities for local telephone 
    competition. We believe that this pro-competitive goal is best effected 
    by subjecting all agreements to state commission review.
        125. The first sentence in section 252(a)(1) refers to requests for 
    interconnection ``pursuant to section 251.'' The final sentence in 
    section 252(a)(1) requires submission to the state commission of all 
    negotiated agreements, including those negotiated before the enactment 
    of the 1996 Act. Some parties have asserted that there is a tension 
    between those two sentences. We conclude that the final sentence of 
    section 252(a)(1), which requires that any interconnection agreement 
    must be submitted to the state commission, can and should be read to be 
    independent of the prior sentences in section 252(a)(1). The 
    interpretation suggested by some commenters that preexisting contracts 
    need only be filed if they are amended subsequent to the 1996 Act, or 
    incorporated by reference into agreements negotiated pursuant to the 
    1996 Act, would force us to impose conditions that were not intended by 
    Congress.
        126. As a matter of policy, moreover, we believe that requiring 
    filing of all interconnection agreements best promotes Congress' stated 
    goals of opening up local markets to competition, and permitting 
    interconnection on just, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory terms. State 
    commissions should have the opportunity to review all agreements, 
    including those that were negotiated before the new law was enacted, to 
    ensure that such agreements do not discriminate against third parties, 
    and are not contrary to the public interest. In particular, preexisting 
    agreements may include provisions that violate or are inconsistent with 
    the pro-competitive goals of the 1996 Act, and states may elect to 
    reject such agreements under section 252(e)(2)(A). Requiring all 
    contracts to be filed also limits an incumbent LEC's ability to 
    discriminate among carriers, for at least two reasons. First, requiring 
    public filing of agreements enables carriers to have information about 
    rates, terms, and conditions that an incumbent LEC makes available to 
    others. Second, any interconnection, service or network element 
    provided under an agreement approved by the state commission under 
    section 252 must be made available to any other requesting 
    telecommunications carrier upon the same terms and conditions, in 
    accordance with section 252(i). In addition, we believe that having the 
    opportunity to review existing agreements may provide state commissions 
    and potential competitors with a starting point for determining what is 
    ``technically feasible'' for interconnection.
        127. Conversely, excluding certain agreements from public 
    disclosure could have anticompetitive consequences. For example, such 
    contracts could include agreements not to compete. In addition, if we 
    exempt agreements between neighboring non-competing LECs, those parties 
    might have a disincentive to compete with each other in the future, in 
    order to preserve the terms of their preexisting agreements. Such a 
    result runs counter to the goal of the 1996 Act to encourage local 
    service competition. Moreover, preserving such ``non-competing'' 
    agreements could effectively insulate those parties from competition by 
    new entrants. For example, if a new entrant seeking to provide 
    competitive local service in a rural community is unable to obtain from 
    a neighboring BOC interconnection or transport and termination on terms 
    that are as favorable as those the BOC offers to the incumbent LEC in 
    the rural area, the new entrant cannot effectively compete. This 
    analysis does not address the separate question of whether an incumbent 
    LEC in a rural area must offer interconnection, resale services, or 
    unbundled network elements. As discussed infra, Section XII, Congress 
    provided rural carriers with an exemption from section 251(c) 
    requirements until the state commission removes such exemption. 47 
    U.S.C. Sec. 251(f)(1). This is because the new entrant will have to 
    charge its subscribers higher rates than the incumbent LEC charges to 
    place calls to subscribers of the neighboring BOC.
        128. We find that section 259 does not compel us to reach a 
    different conclusion regarding the application of section 252 to 
    agreements between neighboring LECs. Section 259 requires the 
    Commission to prescribe, within one year after the date of enactment of 
    the 1996 Act, regulations that require incumbent LECs ``to make 
    available to any qualifying carrier such public switched network 
    infrastructure, technology, information, and telecommunications 
    facilities and functions as may be requested by such qualifying carrier 
    to provide telecommunications services, or to provide access to 
    information services * * *'' 47 U.S.C. Sec. 259(a). A ``qualifying 
    carrier'' is a telecommunications carrier that ``lacks economies of 
    scale or scope,'' and that offers telephone exchange service, exchange 
    access, and any other service included in universal service to all 
    consumers in the service area without preference. 47 U.S.C. 
    Sec. 259(d). Section 259 is limited to agreements for infrastructure 
    sharing between incumbent LECs and telecommunications carriers that 
    lack ``economies of scale or scope,'' as determined in accordance with 
    regulations prescribed by the Commission. We conclude that the purpose 
    and scope of section 259 differ significantly from the purpose and 
    scope of section 251. The Commission plans to initiate a proceeding to 
    establish regulations pursuant to section 259. Section 259 is a limited 
    and discrete provision designed to bring the benefits of advanced 
    infrastructure to additional subscribers, in the context of the pro-
    competitive goals and provisions of the 1996 Act. Moreover, section 
    259(b)(7) requires LECs to file with the Commission or the state ``any 
    tariffs, contracts or other arrangements showing the rates, terms, and 
    conditions under which such carrier is making available public switched 
    network infrastructure and functions under this
    
    [[Page 45499]]
    
    section.'' We believe that this language further supports our 
    conclusion that Congress intended agreements between neighboring LECs 
    to be filed and available for public inspection. Commenters also have 
    failed to persuade us that universal service is jeopardized by our 
    finding that agreements between neighboring LECs are subject to section 
    252 filing and review provisions. Concerns regarding universal service 
    should be addressed by the Federal-State Joint Board, empaneled 
    pursuant to section 254 of the 1996 Act. The Joint Board has initiated 
    a comprehensive review of universal service issues and is considering, 
    among other matters, access to telecommunications and information 
    services in rural and high cost areas. In addition, as discussed in 
    Section XII, infra, the 1996 Act provides for exemptions, suspension, 
    or modification of some of the requirements in section 251 for rural or 
    smaller carriers.
        129. Some parties have suggested that we provide parties an 
    opportunity to renegotiate preexisting contracts. Parties, of course, 
    may mutually agree to renegotiate agreements, but we decline to mandate 
    that parties renegotiate existing contracts. In addition, as discussed 
    below, commercial mobile radio service (CMRS) providers that are party 
    to preexisting agreements with incumbent LECs that provide for non-
    mutual compensation have the option of renegotiating such agreements 
    with no termination liabilities or contract penalties. We believe that 
    generally requiring renegotiation of preexisting contracts is 
    unnecessary, however, because state commissions will review preexisting 
    agreements, and may reject any negotiated agreement that 
    ``discriminates against a telecommunications carrier not a party to the 
    agreement,'' or that ``is not consistent with the public interest, 
    convenience, and necessity.'' We recognize that preexisting agreements 
    were negotiated under very different circumstances, and may not provide 
    a reasonable basis for interconnection agreements under the 1996 Act. 
    For example, non-competing neighboring LECs may have negotiated terms 
    that simply are not viable in a competitive market. It would not foster 
    efficient long-term competition to force parties to make available to 
    all requesting carriers interconnection on terms not sustainable in a 
    competitive environment. In such circumstances, a state commission 
    would have authority to reject a preexisting agreement as inconsistent 
    with the public interest. If a state commission approves a preexisting 
    agreement, that agreement will be available to other parties in 
    accordance with section 252(i). Contrary to NYNEX's assertion, once a 
    state approves an agreement under section 252(e), that agreement is 
    ``approved under'' section 252.
        130. We decline to require immediate filing of preexisting 
    agreements. States should establish procedures and reasonable time 
    frames for requiring filing of preexisting agreements in a timely 
    manner. We leave these procedures largely in the hands of the states in 
    order to ensure that we do not impair some states' ability to carry out 
    their other duties under the 1996 Act, especially if a large number of 
    such agreements must be filed and approved by the state commission. We 
    believe, nevertheless, that we should set an outer time period to file 
    with the appropriate state commission agreements that Class A carriers 
    have with other Class A carriers that predate the 1996 Act. Class A 
    companies are defined as companies ``having annual revenues from 
    regulated telecommunications operations of $100,000,000 or more.'' 47 
    CFR Sec. 32.11(a)(1). We conclude that setting such a time limit will 
    ensure that third parties are not prevented indefinitely from reviewing 
    and taking advantage of the terms of preexisting agreements. We are 
    concerned, however, about the burden that a national filing deadline 
    might impose on small telephone companies that have preexisting 
    agreements with Class A carriers or with other small carriers. We 
    therefore limit the filing deadline requirement to preexisting 
    agreements between Class A carriers. We encourage all carriers to file 
    preexisting contracts with the appropriate state commission no later 
    than June 30, 1997, but impose this as a requirement only with respect 
    to agreements between Class A carriers. We find that requiring 
    preexisting agreements between Class A carriers to be filed no later 
    than June 30, 1997 is unlikely to burden state commissions unduly, and 
    will give parties a reasonable opportunity to renegotiate agreements if 
    they so choose, while at the same time, establishing this outer time 
    limit ensures that third parties will have access to the terms of such 
    agreements, under section 252(i), within a reasonable period. We expect 
    to have completed proceedings on universal service and access charges 
    by this filing deadline. States may impose a shorter time period for 
    filing preexisting agreements.
    
    IV. Interconnection
    
        131. This section of the Report and Order, and the three sections 
    that follow it, address the interconnection and unbundling obligations 
    that the Act imposes on incumbent LECs. Beyond the resale of incumbent 
    LEC services, it is these obligations that pave the way for the 
    introduction of facilities-based competition with incumbent LECs. The 
    interconnection obligation of section 251(c)(2), discussed in this 
    section, allows competing carriers to choose the most efficient points 
    at which to exchange traffic with incumbent LECs, thereby lowering the 
    competing carriers' costs of, among other things, transport and 
    termination of traffic. The unbundling obligation of section 251(c)(3) 
    further permits new entrants, where economically efficient, to 
    substitute incumbent LEC facilities for some or all of the facilities 
    the new entrant would have had to obtain in order to compete. Finally, 
    both the interconnection and unbundling sections of the Act, in 
    combination with the collocation obligation imposed on incumbents by 
    section 251(c)(6), allow competing carriers to choose technically 
    feasible methods of achieving interconnection or access to unbundled 
    elements.
        132. Section 251(c)(2) imposes upon incumbent LECs ``the duty to 
    provide, for the facilities and equipment of any requesting 
    telecommunications carrier, interconnection with the local exchange 
    carrier's network * * * for the transmission and routing of telephone 
    exchange service and exchange access.'' Such interconnection must be: 
    (1) provided by the incumbent LEC at ``any technically feasible point 
    within [its] network;'' (2) ``at least equal in quality to that 
    provided by the local exchange carrier to itself or * * * [to] any 
    other party to which the carrier provides interconnection;'' and (3) 
    provided on rates, terms, and conditions that are ``just, reasonable, 
    and nondiscriminatory, in accordance with the terms and conditions of 
    the agreement and the requirements of this section and section 252.''
    
    A. Relationship Between Interconnection and Transport and Termination
    
    1. Background
        133. In the NPRM, we sought comment on the relationship between the 
    obligation of incumbent LECs to provide ``interconnection'' under 
    section 251(c)(2) and the obligation of all LECs to establish 
    reciprocal compensation arrangements for the ``transport and 
    termination'' of
    
    [[Page 45500]]
    
    telecommunications pursuant to section 251(b)(5). We stated that the 
    term ``interconnection'' might refer only to the physical linking of 
    two networks or to both the linking of facilities and the transport and 
    termination of traffic. We noted in the NPRM that section 252(d) sets 
    forth different pricing standards for interconnection and transport and 
    termination.
    2. Discussion
        134. We conclude that the term ``interconnection'' under section 
    251(c)(2) refers only to the physical linking of two networks for the 
    mutual exchange of traffic. Including the transport and termination of 
    traffic within the meaning of section 251(c)(2) would result in reading 
    out of the statute the duty of all LECs to establish ``reciprocal 
    compensation arrangements for the transport and termination of 
    telecommunications,'' under section 251(b)(5). In addition, in setting 
    the pricing standard for section 251(c)(2) interconnection, section 
    252(d)(1) states it applies when state commissions make determinations 
    ``of the just and reasonable rate for interconnection of facilities and 
    equipment for purposes of subsection (c)(2) of section 251.'' Because 
    section 251(d)(1) states that it only applies to the interconnection of 
    ``facilities and equipment,'' if we were to interpret section 251(c)(2) 
    to refer to transport and termination of traffic as well as the 
    physical linking of equipment and facilities, it would still be 
    necessary to find a pricing standard for the transport and termination 
    of traffic apart from section 252(d)(1). We also reject CompTel's 
    argument that reading section 251(c)(2) to refer only to the physical 
    linking of networks implies that incumbent LECs would not have a duty 
    to route and terminate traffic. That duty applies to all LECs and is 
    clearly expressed in section 251(b)(5). We note that because 
    interconnection refers to the physical linking of two networks, and not 
    the transport and termination of traffic, access charges are not 
    affected by our rules implementing section 251(c)(2).
    
    B. National Interconnection Rules
    
    1. Background
        135. In the NPRM, we tentatively concluded that national 
    interconnection rules would facilitate swift entry by competitors in 
    multiple states by eliminating the need to comply with a multiplicity 
    of state variations in technical and procedural requirements. NPRM at 
    para. 40, 61 FR 18311 (April 25, 1996). We sought comment on this 
    tentative conclusion.
    2. Discussion
        136. As discussed more fully above, we conclude that national rules 
    regarding interconnection pursuant to section 251(c)(2) are necessary 
    to further Congress's goal of creating conditions that will facilitate 
    the development of competition in the telephone exchange market. 
    Uniform rules will permit all carriers, including small entities and 
    small incumbent LECs, to plan regional or national networks using the 
    same interconnection points in similar networks nationwide. Uniform 
    rules will also guarantee consistent, minimum nondiscrimination 
    safeguards and ``equal in quality'' standards in every state. Such 
    rules will also avoid relitigating, in multiple states, the issue of 
    whether interconnection at a particular point is technically feasible.
        137. We believe, however, that inflexible or overly detailed 
    national rules implementing section 251(c)(2) may inhibit the ability 
    of the states or the parties to reach arrangements that reflect 
    technological and market advances and regional differences. We also 
    believe that, on several issues, the record is not adequate at this 
    time to justify the establishment of national rules. Therefore, as 
    required by section 251(d)(3) and as discussed in section II.C. above, 
    our rules will permit states to go beyond the national rules discussed 
    below, and impose additional procompetitive interconnection 
    requirements, as long as such requirements are otherwise consistent 
    with the 1996 Act and the Commission's regulations. We believe that we 
    can benefit from state experience in our ongoing review of these 
    issues.
    
    C. Interconnection for the Transmission and Routing of Telephone 
    Exchange Service and Exchange Access
    
    1. Background
        138. Section 251(c)(2) imposes a duty upon incumbent LECs to 
    provide ``interconnection with the [LEC's] network * * * for the 
    transmission and routing of telephone exchange service and exchange 
    access.'' In the NPRM, we sought comment on whether a carrier could 
    request interconnection pursuant to subsection (c)(2) for purposes of 
    transmitting and routing telephone exchange service, exchange access, 
    or both, or whether this provision requires that such a request be 
    solely for purposes of providing both telephone exchange service and 
    exchange access.
    2. Discussion
        139. We conclude that the phrase ``telephone exchange service and 
    exchange access'' imposes at least three obligations on incumbent LECs: 
    an incumbent must provide interconnection for purposes of transmitting 
    and routing telephone exchange traffic or exchange access traffic or 
    both. We believe that this interpretation is consistent with both the 
    language of the statute and Congress's intent to foster entry by 
    competitive providers into the local exchange market. As the U.S. Court 
    of Appeals for the Fifth Circuit stated in Peacock v. Lubbock Compress 
    Company, ``the word `and' is not a word with a single meaning, for 
    chameleonlike, it takes its color from its surroundings.'' The court 
    held that ``[i]n the construction of statutes, it is the duty of the 
    Court to ascertain the clear intention of the legislature. In order to 
    do this, Courts are often compelled to construe `or' as meaning `and,' 
    and again `and' as meaning `or'.'' Peacock v. Lubbock Compress Company, 
    252 F.2d 892, 893 (5th Cir. 1958) (citing United States v. Fisk, 70 
    U.S. 445, 448). Moreover, the term ``local exchange carrier'' is 
    defined in the Act as ``any person that is engaged in the provision of 
    telephone exchange service or exchange access.'' Thus, we believe that 
    Congress intended to facilitate entry by carriers offering either 
    service. In imposing an interconnection requirement under section 
    251(c)(2) to facilitate such entry, however, we believe that Congress 
    did not want to deter entry by entities that seek to offer either 
    service, or both, and, as a result, section 251(c)(2) requires 
    incumbent LECs to interconnect with carriers providing ``telephone 
    exchange service and exchange access.'' Congress made clear that 
    incumbent LECs must provide interconnection to carriers that seek to 
    offer telephone exchange service and to carriers that seek to offer 
    exchange access. This interpretation is consistent with section 
    251(c)(2), which imposes an obligation on incumbent LECs, but not 
    requesting carriers. Thus, for example, an analogous requirement might 
    be that incumbent LECs must provide interconnection for the 
    transmission and routing of ``electrical and optical signals.'' Such a 
    hypothetical requirement could not rationally be read to obligate 
    requesting carriers to provide both electrical and optical signals.
        140. We also conclude that requiring new entrants to make available 
    both local exchange service and exchange access as a prerequisite to 
    obtaining interconnection to the incumbent LEC's network under 
    subsection (c)(2) would unduly restrict potential competitors. For 
    example, CAPs often enter the
    
    [[Page 45501]]
    
    telecommunications market as exchange access providers prior to 
    offering telephone exchange services. Further, applying separate 
    regulatory regimes (i.e., section 251 related-rules for providers of 
    telephone exchange and exchange access services and section 201 
    related-rules for providers of only exchange access services) with 
    divergent requirements to parties using essentially the same equipment 
    to transmit and route traffic, is undesirable in light of the new 
    procompetitive paradigm created by section 251. We see no convincing 
    justification for treating providers of exchange access services that 
    offer telephone exchange services differently from access providers who 
    do not offer telephone exchange services. We therefore conclude that 
    parties offering only exchange access are permitted to seek 
    interconnection pursuant to section 251(c)(2).
    
    D. Interexchange Service is Not Telephone Exchange Service or Exchange 
    Access
    
    1. Background
        141. Sections 251(c)(2) and 251(c)(3) impose duties upon incumbent 
    LECs to provide interconnection and nondiscriminatory access to 
    unbundled network elements to ``any requesting telecommunications 
    carrier.'' In the NPRM, we tentatively concluded that carriers 
    providing interexchange services are ``telecommunications carriers'' 
    and thus may seek interconnection and unbundled elements under 
    subsections (c)(2) and (c)(3). We also tentatively concluded, however, 
    that with respect to section 251(c)(2), the statute imposes limits on 
    the purposes for which any telecommunications carrier, including IXCs, 
    may request interconnection pursuant to that section. Section 251(c)(2) 
    imposes an obligation upon incumbent LECs to provide requesting 
    carriers with interconnection if the purpose of the interconnection is 
    for the ``transmission and routing of telephone exchange service and 
    exchange access.'' We tentatively concluded in the NPRM that 
    interexchange service does not appear to constitute either ``telephone 
    exchange service'' or ``exchange access.'' ``Exchange access'' is 
    defined in section 3(16) as ``the offering of access to telephone 
    exchange services or facilities for the purpose of the origination or 
    termination of telephone toll services.'' We stated that an IXC that 
    requests interconnection to originate or terminate an interexchange 
    toll call is not ``offering'' access services, but rather is 
    ``receiving'' access services.
    2. Discussion
        142. We conclude that IXCs are telecommunications carriers under 
    the 1996 Act, because they provide telecommunications services (i.e., 
    ``offer telecommunications for a fee directly to the public'') by 
    originating or terminating interexchange traffic. IXCs are permitted 
    under the statute to obtain interconnection pursuant to section 
    251(c)(2) for the ``transmission and routing of telephone exchange 
    service and exchange access.'' Moreover, traditional IXCs are a 
    significant potential new local competitor and we conclude that denying 
    them the right to obtain section 251(c)(2) interconnection lacks any 
    legal or policy justification. Thus, all carriers (including those 
    traditionally classified as IXCs) may obtain interconnection pursuant 
    to section 251(c)(2) for the purpose of terminating calls originating 
    from their customers residing in the same telephone exchange (i.e., 
    non-interexchange calls).
        143. We conclude, however, that an IXC that requests 
    interconnection solely for the purpose of originating or terminating 
    its interexchange traffic, not for the provision of telephone exchange 
    service and exchange access to others, on an incumbent LEC's network is 
    not entitled to receive interconnection pursuant to section 251(c)(2). 
    Section 251(c)(2) states that incumbent LECs have a duty to 
    interconnect with telecommunications providers ``for the transmission 
    and routing of telephone exchange service and exchange access.'' A 
    telecommunications carrier seeking interconnection only for 
    interexchange services is not within the scope of this statutory 
    language because it is not seeking interconnection for the purpose of 
    providing telephone exchange service. Nor does a carrier seeking 
    interconnection of interstate traffic only--for the purpose of 
    providing interstate services only--fall within the scope of the phrase 
    ``exchange access.'' Such a would-be interconnector is not ``offering'' 
    access to telephone exchange services. As we stated in the NPRM, an IXC 
    that seeks to interconnect solely for the purpose of originating or 
    terminating its own interexchange traffic is not offering access, but 
    rather is only obtaining access for its own traffic. Thus, we disagree 
    with CompTel's position that IXCs are offering exchange access when 
    they offer and provide exchange access as a part of long distance 
    service. We conclude that a carrier may not obtain interconnection 
    pursuant to section 251(c)(2) for the purpose of terminating 
    interexchange traffic, even if that traffic was originated by a local 
    exchange customer in a different telephone exchange of the same carrier 
    providing the interexchange service, if it does not offer exchange 
    access services to others. As we stated above, however, providers of 
    competitive access services are eligible to receive interconnection 
    pursuant to section 251(c)(2). Thus, traditional IXCs that offer access 
    services in competition with an incumbent LEC (i.e., IXCs that offer 
    access services to other carriers as well as to themselves) are also 
    eligible to obtain interconnection pursuant to section 251(c)(2). For 
    example, when an IXC interconnects at a local switch, bypassing the 
    incumbent LECs' transport network, that IXC may offer access to the 
    local switch in competition with the incumbent. In such a situation, 
    the interconnection point may be considered a section 251(c)(2) 
    interconnection point.
    
    E. Definition of ``Technically Feasible''
    
    1. Background
        144. In addition to specifying the purposes for which carriers may 
    request interconnection, section 251(c)(2) obligates incumbent LECs to 
    provide interconnection within their networks at any ``technically 
    feasible point.'' Similarly, section 251(c)(3) obligates incumbent LECs 
    to provide access to unbundled elements at any ``technically feasible 
    point.'' Thus our interpretation of the term ``technically feasible'' 
    applies to both sections.
        145. In the NPRM, we sought comment on a ``dynamic'' definition of 
    ``technically feasible'' that would provide flexibility for negotiating 
    parties and the states in determining interconnection and unbundling 
    points as network technology evolves. We requested comment on the 
    extent to which network reliability concerns should be included in a 
    technical feasibility analysis, and tentatively concluded that, if such 
    concerns were involved, the incumbent LEC had the burden to support 
    such a claim with detailed information. We also sought comment on the 
    role of other considerations, such as economic burden, in determining 
    technical feasibility under sections 251(c)(2) and 251(c)(3).
        146. We also tentatively concluded that interconnection or access 
    at a particular point in one LEC network evidences the technical 
    feasibility of providing the same or similar interconnection or access 
    in another, similarly structured LEC network. Finally, we tentatively 
    concluded that incumbent LECs have the burden of
    
    [[Page 45502]]
    
    proving the technical infeasibility of providing interconnection or 
    access at a particular point.
    2. Discussion
        147. We conclude that the term ``technically feasible'' refers 
    solely to technical or operational concerns, rather than economic, 
    space, or site considerations. We further conclude that the obligations 
    imposed by sections 251(c)(2) and 251(c)(3) include modifications to 
    incumbent LEC facilities to the extent necessary to accommodate 
    interconnection or access to network elements. Specific, significant, 
    and demonstrable network reliability concerns associated with providing 
    interconnection or access at a particular point, however, will be 
    regarded as relevant evidence that interconnection or access at that 
    point is technically infeasible. We also conclude that preexisting 
    interconnection or access at a particular point evidences the technical 
    feasibility of interconnection or access at substantially similar 
    points. Finally, we conclude that incumbent LECs must prove to the 
    appropriate state commission that a particular interconnection or 
    access point is not technically feasible.
        148. We find that the 1996 Act bars consideration of costs in 
    determining ``technically feasible'' points of interconnection or 
    access. In the 1996 Act, Congress distinguished ``technical'' 
    considerations from economic concerns. Section 251(f), for example, 
    exempts certain rural LECs from ``unduly economically burdensome'' 
    obligations imposed by section 251(c) even where satisfaction of such 
    obligations is ``technically feasible.'' Similarly, section 
    254(h)(2)(A) treats ``technically feasible'' and ``economically 
    reasonable'' as separate requirements. Finally, we note that the House 
    committee that considered H.R. 1555 (which was combined with Senate 
    Bill S.652 to form the 1996 Act) dropped the term ``economically 
    reasonable'' from its unbundling provision. The House committee 
    explicitly addressed this substantive change, reporting that ``this 
    requirement could result in certain unbundled * * * elements * * * not 
    being made available.'' H. Rep. 104-204, 71 (1995). Thus, the 
    deliberate and explained substantive omission of explicit economic 
    requirements in sections 251(c)(2) and 251(c)(3) cannot be undone 
    through an interpretation that such considerations are implicit in the 
    term ``technically feasible.'' Of course, a requesting carrier that 
    wishes a ``technically feasible'' but expensive interconnection would, 
    pursuant to section 252(d)(1), be required to bear the cost of that 
    interconnection, including a reasonable profit.
        149. USTA and SBC cite the Commission's 900 Service order (Policies 
    and Rules Concerning Interstate 900 Telecommunications Services, Report 
    and Order, 56 FR 56160 (November 1, 1991)) as support for the 
    contention that costs must be considered in a technical feasibility 
    analysis. In that order, the Commission concluded that ``[i]n defining 
    `technically feasible,' we balance both technical and economic 
    considerations with a view toward providing [900] blocking capability 
    to consumers without imposing undue economic burdens on LECs.'' Our 900 
    Service order, however, has little bearing on our interpretation of the 
    term ``technically feasible'' in the 1996 Act. As stated above, the 
    1996 Act distinguishes technical considerations from the ``undue 
    economic burdens'' considered in the 900 Service order. Indeed, 
    Congress used virtually the same language--``unduly economically 
    burdensome''--in drawing the distinction. If, as SBC contends, we are 
    to presume that Congress was aware of the Commission's analysis of the 
    technical feasibility of 900 call blocking, the 1996 Act appears 
    squarely to reject that view of technical feasibility. Moreover, unlike 
    the costs of providing 900 call blocking, which we imposed largely on 
    LECs in the 900 Service order, as noted above, to the extent incumbent 
    LECs incur costs to provide interconnection or access under sections 
    251(c)(2) or 251(c)(3), incumbent LECs may recover such costs from 
    requesting carriers.
        150. In addition to economic considerations, section 251(c)(6) 
    distinguishes considerations of ``space limitations'' from those of 
    ``technical reasons,'' and thus, in general, we believe existing space 
    or site restrictions should not be included within a technical 
    feasibility analysis. Of course, under section 251(c)(6) ``space'' 
    restrictions are expressly considered along with ``technical'' 
    considerations in determining whether an incumbent LEC must provide for 
    physical collocation. Where physical collocation is not practical 
    because of ``space limitations,'' however, incumbent LECs must provide 
    for virtual collocation. Section 251 is silent as to whether an 
    incumbent LEC's duty to provide for virtual collocation or other 
    methods of interconnection or access to unbundled elements is dependent 
    on space constraints. We conclude, as a practical matter, that space 
    limitations at a particular network site, without any possibility of 
    expansion, may render interconnection or access at that point 
    infeasible, technically or otherwise. Where such expansion is possible, 
    however, we conclude that, in light of the distinction drawn in section 
    251(c)(6), site restrictions do not represent a ``technical'' obstacle. 
    Again, however, the requesting party would bear the cost of any 
    necessary expansion. Nor do we believe the term ``technical,'' when 
    interpreted in accordance with its ordinary meaning as referring to 
    engineering and operational concerns in the context of sections 
    251(c)(2) and 251(c)(3), includes consideration of accounting or 
    billing restrictions.
        151. Several parties also attempt to draw a distinction between 
    what is ``feasible'' under the terms of the statute, and what is 
    ``possible.'' The words ``feasible'' and ``possible,'' however, are 
    used synonymously. Feasible is defined as ``capable of being 
    accomplished or brought about; possible.'' The statute itself provides 
    a more meaningful distinction. Unlike the ``technically feasible'' 
    terminology included in sections 251(c)(2) and 251(c)(3), section 
    251(c)(6) uses the term ``practical for technical reasons'' in 
    determining the scope of an incumbent LEC's obligation to provide for 
    physical collocation. ``Practical'' is defined as ``manifested in 
    practice or action * * * not theoretical or ideal'' or ``adapted or 
    designed for actual use; useful,'' and connotes similarity to ordinary 
    usage. Thus, it is reasonable to interpret Congress' use of the term 
    ``feasible'' in sections 251(c)(2) and 251(c)(3) as encompassing more 
    than what is merely ``practical'' or similar to what is ordinarily 
    done. That is, use of the term ``feasible'' implies that 
    interconnecting or providing access to a LEC network element may be 
    feasible at a particular point even if such interconnection or access 
    requires a novel use of, or some modification to, incumbent LEC 
    equipment. This interpretation is consistent with the fact that 
    incumbent LEC networks were not designed to accommodate third-party 
    interconnection or use of network elements at all or even most points 
    within the network. If incumbent LECs were not required, at least to 
    some extent, to adapt their facilities to interconnection or use by 
    other carriers, the purposes of sections 251(c)(2) and 251(c)(3) would 
    often be frustrated. For example, Congress intended to obligate the 
    incumbent to accommodate the new entrant's network architecture by 
    requiring the incumbent to provide interconnection ``for the facilities 
    and equipment'' of the new entrant.
    
    [[Page 45503]]
    
    Consistent with that intent, the incumbent must accept the novel use 
    of, and modification to, its network facilities to accommodate the 
    interconnector or to provide access to unbundled elements.
        152. We also conclude, however, that legitimate threats to network 
    reliability and security must be considered in evaluating the technical 
    feasibility of interconnection or access to incumbent LEC networks. 
    Negative network reliability effects are necessarily contrary to a 
    finding of technical feasibility. Each carrier must be able to retain 
    responsibility for the management, control, and performance of its own 
    network. Thus, with regard to network reliability and security, to 
    justify a refusal to provide interconnection or access at a point 
    requested by another carrier, incumbent LECs must prove to the state 
    commission, with clear and convincing evidence, that specific and 
    significant adverse impacts would result from the requested 
    interconnection or access. The reports of the Commission's Network 
    Reliability Council discuss network reliability considerations, and 
    establish templates that list activities that need to occur when 
    service providers connect their networks pursuant to defined 
    interconnection specifications or when they are attempting to define a 
    new network interface specification.
        153. We further conclude that successful interconnection or access 
    to an unbundled element at a particular point in a network, using 
    particular facilities, is substantial evidence that interconnection or 
    access is technically feasible at that point, or at substantially 
    similar points in networks employing substantially similar facilities. 
    In comparing networks for this purpose, the substantial similarity of 
    network facilities may be evidenced, for example, by their adherence to 
    the same interface or protocol standards. We also conclude that 
    previous successful interconnection at a particular point in a network 
    at a particular level of quality constitutes substantial evidence that 
    interconnection is technically feasible at that point, or at 
    substantially similar points, at that level of quality. Although most 
    parties agree with this conclusion, some LECs contend that such 
    comparisons are all but impossible because of alleged variability in 
    network technologies, even where the ultimate services offered by 
    separate networks are the same. We believe that, if the facilities are 
    substantially similar, the LECs' contention is adequately addressed.
        154. Finally, because sections 251(c)(2) and 251(c)(3) impose 
    duties upon incumbent LECs, we conclude that incumbent LECs must prove 
    to the appropriate state commission that interconnection or access at a 
    point is not technically feasible. Incumbent LECs possess the 
    information necessary to assess the technical feasibility of 
    interconnecting to particular LEC facilities. Further, incumbent LECs 
    have a duty to make available to requesting carriers general 
    information indicating the location and technical characteristics of 
    incumbent LEC network facilities. Without access to such information, 
    competing carriers would be unable to make rational network deployment 
    decisions and could be forced to make inefficient use of their own and 
    incumbent LEC facilities, with anticompetitive effects.
        155. We have considered the economic impact of our rules in this 
    section on small incumbent LECs. For example, the Rural Telephone 
    Coalition argues that the Commission should set interconnection points 
    in a flexible manner to recognize the differences between carriers and 
    regions. We do not adopt the Rural Telephone Coalition's position 
    because we believe that, in general, the Act does not permit incumbent 
    LECs to deny interconnection or access to unbundled elements for any 
    reason other than a showing that it is not technically feasible. We 
    believe that this interpretation will advance the procompetitive goals 
    of the statute. We also note, however, that section 251(f) of the 1996 
    Act provides relief to certain small LECs from our regulations 
    implementing section 251.
    
    F. Technically Feasible Points of Interconnection
    
    1. Background
        156. In the NPRM, we requested comment on which points within an 
    incumbent LEC's network constitute ``technically feasible'' points for 
    purposes of section 251(c)(2). Having defined the phrase ``technically 
    feasible'' above, we now determine a minimum set of technically 
    feasible points of interconnection.
    2. Discussion
        157. We conclude that we should identify a minimum list of 
    technically feasible points of interconnection that are critical to 
    facilitating entry by competing local service providers. Section 
    251(c)(2) gives competing carriers the right to deliver traffic 
    terminating on an incumbent LEC's network at any technically feasible 
    point on that network, rather than obligating such carriers to 
    transport traffic to less convenient or efficient interconnection 
    points. Section 251(c)(2) lowers barriers to competitive entry for 
    carriers that have not deployed ubiquitous networks by permitting them 
    to select the points in an incumbent LEC's network at which they wish 
    to deliver traffic. Moreover, because competing carriers must usually 
    compensate incumbent LECs for the additional costs incurred by 
    providing interconnection, competitors have an incentive to make 
    economically efficient decisions about where to interconnect.
        158. We conclude that, at a minimum, incumbent LECs must provide 
    interconnection at the line-side of a local switch (at, for example, 
    the main distribution frame), the trunk-side of a local switch; the 
    trunk interconnection points for a tandem switch; and central office 
    cross-connect points in general. This requirement includes 
    interconnection at those out-of-band signaling transfer points 
    necessary to exchange traffic and access call related databases. All of 
    these points of interconnection are used today by competing carriers, 
    noncompeting carriers, or LECs themselves for the exchange of traffic, 
    and thus we conclude that interconnection at such points is technically 
    feasible.
        159. A varied group of commenters, including Bell Atlantic and 
    AT&T, agree that interconnection at the line-side of the switch is 
    technically feasible. Interconnection at this point is currently 
    provided to some commercial mobile radio service (CMRS) carriers and 
    may be necessary for other competitors that have their own distribution 
    plant, but seek to interconnect to the incumbent's switch. We also 
    agree with numerous commenters that claim that interconnection at the 
    trunk-side of a switch is technically feasible and should be available 
    upon request. Interconnection at this point is currently used by 
    competing carriers to exchange traffic with incumbent LECs. 
    Interconnection to tandem switching facilities is also currently used 
    by IXCs and competing access providers, and is thus technically 
    feasible. Finally, central office cross-connect points, which are 
    designed to facilitate interconnection, are natural points of 
    technically feasible interconnection to, for example, interoffice 
    transmission facilities. There may be rare circumstances where there 
    are true technical barriers to interconnection at the line- or trunk-
    side of the switch or at central office cross-connect points, however, 
    the parties have not presented us with any such circumstances. Thus,
    
    [[Page 45504]]
    
    incumbent LECs must prove to the state commissions that such points are 
    not technically feasible interconnection points.
        160. We also note that the points of access to unbundled elements 
    discussed below may also serve as points of interconnection (i.e., 
    points in the network that may serve as places where potential 
    competitors may wish to exchange traffic with the incumbent LEC other 
    than for purposes of gaining access to unbundled elements), and thus we 
    incorporate those points by reference here. Finally, as noted above, we 
    have identified a minimum list of technically feasible interconnection 
    points: (1) The line-side of a local switch; (2) the trunk-side of a 
    local switch; (3) the trunk interconnection points for a tandem switch; 
    (4) central office cross-connect points; (5) out-of-band signaling 
    transfer points; and (6) the points of access to unbundled elements. In 
    addition, we anticipate and encourage parties and the states, through 
    negotiation and arbitration, to identify additional points of 
    technically feasible interconnection. We believe that the experience of 
    the parties and the states will benefit our ongoing review of 
    interconnection.
    
    G. Just, Reasonable, and Nondiscriminatory Rates, Terms, and Conditions 
    of Interconnection
    
    1. Background
        161. Section 251(c)(2)(D) requires that incumbent LECs provide 
    interconnection ``on rates, terms, and conditions that are just, 
    reasonable, and nondiscriminatory.'' In the NPRM, we sought comment on 
    whether we should adopt national requirements governing the terms and 
    conditions of providing interconnection. We also sought comment on how 
    we should determine whether the terms and conditions for 
    interconnection arrangements are just, reasonable, and 
    nondiscriminatory, and how we should enforce such rules. In particular, 
    we sought comment on whether we should adopt national guidelines 
    governing installation, service, maintenance, and repair of the 
    incumbent LEC's portion of interconnection facilities.
    2. Discussion
        162. We conclude that minimum national standards for just, 
    reasonable, and nondiscriminatory terms and conditions of 
    interconnection will be in the public interest and will provide 
    guidance to the parties and the states in the arbitration process and 
    thereafter. We believe that national standards will tend to offset the 
    imbalance in bargaining power between incumbent LECs and competitors 
    and encourage fair agreements in the marketplace between parties by 
    setting minimum requirements that new entrants are guaranteed in 
    arbitrations. Negotiations between an incumbent and a new entrant 
    differ from commercial negotiations in a competitive market because new 
    entrants are dependent solely on the incumbent for interconnection.
        163. Section 202(a) of the Act states that ``[i]t shall be unlawful 
    for any common carrier to make any unjust or unreasonable 
    discrimination in charges, practices, * * * facilities, or services for 
    or in connection with like communication service * * * by any means or 
    device, or to make or give any undue or unreasonable preference or 
    advantage to any particular person.'' By comparison, section 251(c)(2) 
    creates a duty for incumbent LECs ``to provide * * * any requesting 
    telecommunications carrier, interconnection with a LEC's network on 
    rates, terms, and conditions that are just, reasonable, and 
    nondiscriminatory.'' The nondiscrimination requirement in section 
    251(c)(2) is not qualified by the ``unjust or unreasonable'' language 
    of section 202(a). We therefore conclude that Congress did not intend 
    that the term ``nondiscriminatory'' in the 1996 Act be synonymous with 
    ``unjust and unreasonable discrimination'' used in the 1934 Act, but 
    rather, intended a more stringent standard.
        164. Given that the incumbent LEC will be providing interconnection 
    to its competitors pursuant to the purpose of the 1996 Act, the LEC has 
    the incentive to discriminate against its competitors by providing them 
    less favorable terms and conditions of interconnection than it provides 
    itself. Permitting such circumstances is inconsistent with the 
    procompetitive purpose of the Act. Therefore, we reject for purposes of 
    section 251, our historical interpretation of ``nondiscriminatory,'' 
    which we interpreted to mean a comparison between what the incumbent 
    LEC provided other parties in a regulated monopoly environment. We 
    believe that the term ``nondiscriminatory,'' as used throughout section 
    251, applies to the terms and conditions an incumbent LEC imposes on 
    third parties as well as on itself. In any event, by providing 
    interconnection to a competitor in a manner less efficient than an 
    incumbent LEC provides itself, the incumbent LEC violates the duty to 
    be ``just'' and ``reasonable'' under section 251(c)(2)(D). Also, 
    incumbent LECs may not discriminate against parties based upon the 
    identity of the carrier (i.e., whether the carrier is a CMRS provider, 
    a CAP, or a competitive LEC). As long as a carrier meets the statutory 
    requirements, as discussed in this section, it has a right to obtain 
    interconnection with the incumbent LEC pursuant to section 251(c)(2).
        165. We identify below specific terms and conditions for 
    interconnection in discussing physical or virtual collocation (i.e., 
    two methods of interconnection). We conclude here, however, that where 
    a carrier requesting interconnection pursuant to section 251(c)(2) does 
    not carry a sufficient amount of traffic to justify separate one-way 
    trunks, an incumbent LEC must accommodate two-way trunking upon request 
    where technically feasible. Refusing to provide two-way trunking would 
    raise costs for new entrants and create a barrier to entry. Thus, we 
    conclude that if two-way trunking is technically feasible, it would not 
    be just, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory for the incumbent LEC to 
    refuse to provide it.
        166. Finally, as discussed below, we reject Bell Atlantic's 
    suggestion that we impose reciprocal terms and conditions on incumbent 
    LECs and requesting carriers pursuant to section 251(c)(2). Section 
    251(c)(2) does not impose on non-incumbent LECs the duty to provide 
    interconnection. The obligations of LECs that are not incumbent LECs 
    are generally governed by sections 251 (a) and (b), not section 251(c). 
    Also, the statute itself imposes different obligations on incumbent 
    LECs and other LECs (i.e., section 251(b) imposes obligations on all 
    LECs while section 251(c) obligations are imposed only on incumbent 
    LECs). We do note, however, that 251(c)(1) imposes upon a requesting 
    telecommunications carrier a duty to negotiate the terms and conditions 
    of interconnection agreements in good faith. We also conclude that 
    MCI's POI proposal, permitting interconnecting carriers, both 
    competitors and incumbent LECs, to designate points of interconnection 
    on each other's networks, is at this time best addressed in 
    negotiations and arbitrations between parties. We believe that the 
    record on this issue is not sufficiently persuasive to justify 
    Commission action at this time. As market conditions evolve, we will 
    continue to review and revise our rules as necessary.
    
    H. Interconnection that is Equal in Quality
    
    1. Background
        167. Section 251(c)(2)(C) requires that the interconnection 
    provided by an
    
    [[Page 45505]]
    
    incumbent LEC be ``at least equal in quality to that provided by the 
    [incumbent LEC] to itself or to any subsidiary, affiliate, or any other 
    party to which the carrier provides interconnection.'' In the NPRM, we 
    sought comment on how to determine whether interconnection is ``equal 
    in quality.''
    2. Discussion
        168. We conclude that the equal in quality standard of section 
    251(c)(2)(C) requires an incumbent LEC to provide interconnection 
    between its network and that of a requesting carrier at a level of 
    quality that is at least indistinguishable from that which the 
    incumbent provides itself, a subsidiary, an affiliate, or any other 
    party. We agree with MFS that this duty requires incumbent LECs to 
    design interconnection facilities to meet the same technical criteria 
    and service standards, such as probability of blocking in peak hours 
    and transmission standards, that are used within their own networks. 
    Contrary to the view of some commenters, we further conclude that the 
    equal in quality obligation imposed by section 251(c)(2) is not limited 
    to the quality perceived by end users. The statutory language contains 
    no such limitation, and creating such a limitation may allow incumbent 
    LECs to discriminate against competitors in a manner imperceptible to 
    end users, but which still provides incumbent LECs with advantages in 
    the marketplace (e.g., the imposition of disparate conditions between 
    carriers on the pricing and ordering of services).
        169. We also note that section 251(c)(2) requires interconnection 
    that is ``at least'' equal in quality to that enjoyed by the incumbent 
    LEC itself. This is a minimum requirement. Moreover, to the extent a 
    carrier requests interconnection of superior or lesser quality than an 
    incumbent LEC currently provides, the incumbent LEC is obligated to 
    provide the requested interconnection arrangement if technically 
    feasible. Requiring incumbent LECs to provide upon request higher 
    quality interconnection than they provide themselves, subsidiaries, or 
    affiliates will permit new entrants to compete with incumbent LECs by 
    offering novel services that require superior interconnection quality. 
    We also conclude that, as long as new entrants compensate incumbent 
    LECs for the economic cost of the higher quality interconnection, 
    competition will be promoted.
    
    V. Access to Unbundled Network Elements
    
    A. Commission Authority to Identify Unbundled Network Elements
    
    1. Background
        170. Section 251(c)(3) imposes a duty on incumbent LECs to 
    ``provide, to any requesting telecommunications carrier for the 
    provision of a telecommunications service, nondiscriminatory access to 
    network elements on an unbundled basis at any technically feasible 
    point on rates, terms, and conditions that are just, reasonable, and 
    nondiscriminatory in accordance with the terms and conditions of the 
    agreement and the requirements of this section and section 252.'' This 
    section also requires incumbent LECs to provide these elements ``in a 
    manner that allows requesting carriers to combine such elements in 
    order to provide such telecommunications service.''
        171. Section 251(d)(1) provides that ``the Commission shall 
    complete all actions necessary to establish regulations to implement 
    the requirements of'' section 251 by August 8, 1996. Section 251(d)(2) 
    further provides that, ``[i]n determining what network elements should 
    be made available for purposes of subsection (c)(3), the Commission 
    shall consider, at a minimum, whether (A) Access to such network 
    elements as are proprietary in nature is necessary; and (B) the failure 
    to provide access to such network elements would impair the ability of 
    the telecommunications carrier seeking access to provide the services 
    that it seeks to offer.''
        172. In the NPRM, we sought comment on our tentative conclusion 
    that the 1996 Act requires the Commission to identify network elements 
    that incumbent LECs are required to make available to requesting 
    carriers on an unbundled basis under section 251(c)(3).
    2. Discussion
        173. We affirm our tentative conclusion in the NPRM that the 1996 
    Act requires the Commission to identify network elements that incumbent 
    LECs must offer requesting carriers on an unbundled basis under section 
    251(c)(3). Section 251(d)(1) directs the Commission to establish rules 
    implementing the requirements of section 251(c)(3). Further, section 
    251(d)(2) contemplates that, pursuant to this direction, the Commission 
    will identify unbundled network elements. We conclude that neither the 
    language in section 251(d), nor any other part of the 1996 Act, is 
    reasonably susceptible to the interpretation advanced by BellSouth that 
    our obligation to identify unbundled network elements arises only when 
    we act under section 252(e)(5).
    
    B. National Requirements for Unbundled Network Elements
    
    1. Background
        174. In the NPRM, we noted Congress' view that, when new entrants 
    begin providing services in local telephone markets, it is unlikely 
    they will own network facilities that completely duplicate those of 
    incumbent LECs because of the significant investment and time required 
    to build such facilities. The statutory requirement imposed on 
    incumbent LECs to provide access to unbundled network elements will 
    permit new entrants to offer competing local services by purchasing 
    from incumbents, at cost-based prices, access to elements which they do 
    not already possess, unbundled from those elements that they do not 
    need.
        175. It is possible that there will be sufficient demand in some 
    local telephone markets to support the construction of competing local 
    exchange facilities that duplicate most or even all of the elements of 
    an incumbent LEC's network. In these markets new entrants will be able 
    to use unbundled elements from the incumbent LEC to provide services 
    until such time as they complete the construction of their own 
    networks, and thus, no longer need to rely on the facilities of an 
    incumbent to provide local exchange and exchange access services. It is 
    also possible, however, that other local markets, now and even into the 
    future, may not efficiently support duplication of all, or even some, 
    of an incumbent LEC's facilities. Access to unbundled elements in these 
    markets will promote efficient competition for local exchange services 
    because, under the scheme set out in the 1996 Act, such access will 
    allow new entrants to enter local markets by obtaining use of the 
    incumbent LECs' facilities at prices that reflect the incumbents' 
    economies of scale and scope.
        176. In the NPRM, we tentatively concluded that the Commission 
    should identify a minimum number of elements that incumbent LECs must 
    make available to requesting carriers on an unbundled basis. We further 
    tentatively concluded that section 252(e)(3) preserves a state's 
    authority, during arbitration, to impose additional unbundling 
    requirements beyond those we specify, as long as such requirements are 
    consistent with the 1996 Act and our
    
    [[Page 45506]]
    
    regulations. Section 252(e) discusses a state commission's obligations 
    regarding the approval or rejection of agreements between incumbent 
    LECs and requesting telecommunications carriers for interconnection, 
    services or network elements. Subparagraph (3) of this section 
    specifically provides that a state commission is not prohibited ``from 
    establishing or enforcing other requirements of State law in its review 
    of an agreement,'' as long as such requirements do not violate the 
    terms of the statute. 47 U.S.C. Sec. 252(e)(3). We further note that 
    under section 252(f)(2) states may impose additional unbundling 
    requirements during review of BOC statements of generally available 
    terms and conditions. Section 252(f)(2) states that ``(e)xcept as 
    provided in section 253, nothing in this section shall prohibit a State 
    commission from establishing or enforcing other requirements of State 
    law in its review of such statement * * *'' 47 U.S.C. Sec. 252(f)(2). 
    Finally, we tentatively concluded that we have authority to identify 
    additional or different unbundling requirements in the future, as we 
    learn about changes in technology, the innovation of new services, and 
    the necessities of competition.
    2. Discussion
        177. We adopt our tentative conclusion and identify a minimum list 
    of unbundled network elements that incumbent LECs must make available 
    to new entrants upon request. We believe the procompetitive goals of 
    section 251(c)(3) will best be achieved through the adoption of such a 
    list. As discussed above, we believe that negotiations and arbitrations 
    will best promote efficient, rapid, and widespread new entry if we 
    establish certain minimum national unbundling requirements. As the 
    Department of Justice argues, there is ``no basis in economic theory or 
    in experience to expect incumbent monopolists to quickly negotiate 
    arrangements to facilitate disciplining entry by would-be competitors, 
    absent clear legal requirements to do so.'' Ad Hoc Telecommunications 
    Users Committee notes that ``[h]istorically, the [incumbent LECs] have 
    had strong incentives to resist, and have actively resisted, efforts to 
    open their networks to users, competitors, or new technology-driven 
    applications of network technology.''
        178. National requirements for unbundled elements will allow new 
    entrants, including small entities, seeking to enter local markets on a 
    national or regional scale to take advantage of economies of scale in 
    network design. If fifty states were to establish different unbundling 
    requirements, new entrants, including small entities, could be denied 
    the benefits of scale economies in obtaining access to unbundled 
    elements. National requirements will also: reduce the number of issues 
    states must consider in arbitrations, thereby facilitating the states' 
    ability to conduct such proceedings; reduce the likelihood of 
    litigation regarding the requirements of section 251(c)(3) and the 
    costs associated with such litigation; and provide financial markets 
    with greater certainty in assessing new entrants' business plans, thus 
    enhancing the ability of new entrants, including small entities, to 
    raise capital. In addition, to the extent the Commission assumes a 
    state's arbitration authority under section 252(e)(5), national 
    requirements for unbundled elements will help the Commission to 
    conclude such proceedings expeditiously.
        179. We reject the alternative option of developing an exhaustive 
    list of required unbundled elements, to which states could not add 
    additional elements, on the grounds that such a list would not 
    necessarily accommodate changes in technology, and it would not provide 
    states the flexibility they need to deal with local conditions.
        180. We also reject the proposal advanced by several parties that 
    we should adopt non-binding national guidelines for unbundled elements 
    that states would not be required to enforce. The parties asserting 
    that differences between incumbent LEC networks militate against the 
    adoption of national standards provide few, if any, specific examples 
    of what those differences are. In addition, they fail to articulate 
    persuasively why those differences are significant enough to weigh 
    against the adoption of national requirements. Accordingly, and as 
    previously discussed, we conclude that any differences that may exist 
    among states are not sufficiently great to overcome the procompetitive 
    benefits that would result from establishing a minimum set of binding 
    national rules. Moreover, we believe the authority granted the states 
    in section 252(e)(3), as well as our existing rules which set forth a 
    process by which incumbent LECs can request a waiver of the 
    requirements we adopt here, will provide the necessary flexibility in 
    our rules to permit states and parties to accommodate any truly unique 
    state conditions that might exist. We further observed in the NPRM that 
    under the voluntary negotiation paradigm set out in section 252, 
    parties to such negotiations can agree to provide unbundled network 
    elements that differ from those identified by the Commission. See NPRM 
    at para. 78 (citing 47 U.S.C. Sec. 252(a)). Accordingly, we adopt our 
    tentative conclusion that states may impose additional unbundling 
    requirements pursuant to section 252(e)(3), as long as such 
    requirements are consistent with the 1996 Act and our regulations. This 
    conclusion is consistent with the statement in section 252(e)(3) that 
    ``nothing in this section shall prohibit a State commission from 
    establishing or enforcing other requirements of State law in its review 
    of an agreement.''
        181. We find the arguments presented by parties opposing national 
    rules for unbundled elements unpersuasive especially in light of the 
    1996 Act's strong procompetitive goals. For example, in light of the 
    incumbent LECs' disincentives to negotiate with potential competitors, 
    we believe national rules will promote competition by making the 
    bargaining strength of potential competitors, including small entities, 
    more equal. We are not persuaded that national rules will discourage 
    incumbent LECs from developing new technologies and services; to the 
    contrary, based on our experience in other telecommunications markets, 
    we believe that competition will stimulate innovation by incumbent 
    LECs. We also believe that any failure of incumbent LECs to develop new 
    technologies or services would have a less significant adverse effect 
    on competition in local exchange markets than a failure to adopt 
    national rules. Nor is it likely that new entrants will seek 
    unnecessary elements merely to raise incumbents' costs because such new 
    entrants must pay the costs associated with unbundling. In addition, 
    the pricing standard of section 252(d)(1)(B), which allows incumbent 
    LECs to receive not only their costs but also a reasonable profit on 
    the provision of unbundled elements, should further alleviate concerns 
    regarding sham requests.
        182. We adopt our tentative conclusion that, in addition to 
    identifying unbundled network elements that incumbent LECs must make 
    available now, we have authority to identify additional, or perhaps 
    different, unbundling requirements that would apply to incumbent LECs 
    in the future. The rapid pace and ever changing nature of technological 
    advancement in the telecommunications industry makes it essential that 
    we retain the ability to revise our rules as circumstances change. 
    Otherwise, our rules might impede technological change and frustrate 
    the 1996 Act's overriding goal of bringing the benefits
    
    [[Page 45507]]
    
    of competition to consumers of local phone services. For the same 
    reasons that we believe we should adopt national unbundling 
    requirements, as discussed above, we reject the proposal that future 
    unbundling requirements should be determined solely by the parties to 
    voluntary negotiations.
        183. Finally, we have considered the economic impact of our rules 
    in this section on small incumbent LECs. For example, we have 
    considered the argument advanced by the Rural Telephone Coalition that 
    national unbundling requirements would be unworkable because of 
    technological, demographic and geographic variations between states. We 
    do not adopt the Rural Telephone Coalition's position, however, because 
    we believe that the minimum list we adopt can be applied to a broad 
    range of networks across geographic regions and any differences between 
    incumbent LEC networks in different states are not sufficiently great 
    to overcome the procompetitive benefits of a minimum list of required 
    unbundled network elements. We have also considered the argument 
    advanced by GVNW that unbundling requirements imposed on small 
    incumbent LECs should differ from those imposed on large, urban 
    incumbent LECs because of differences in networks and operational 
    procedures. We reject GVNW's proposal for two reasons. First, some 
    small incumbent LECs may not experience any problems complying with our 
    unbundling rules. Second, we note that section 251(f) of the 1996 Act 
    provides relief to certain small LECs from our regulations implementing 
    section 251.
        184. Although we have concluded in this proceeding that we can best 
    achieve the procompetitive aims of the 1996 Act by adopting minimum 
    national unbundling requirements for arbitrated agreements, the 1996 
    Act envisions that the states will administer those requirements 
    through approval of negotiated agreements and arbitrations. Through 
    arbitrations and review of negotiated agreements the states will add to 
    their significant expertise on issues relating to the provision of 
    access to unbundled network elements. We encourage state commissions to 
    take an active role in evaluating the success or difficulties in 
    implementing any of our requirements. The Commission intends to draw on 
    the expertise developed by the states when we review and revise our 
    rules as necessary.
    
    C. Network Elements
    
    1. Background
        185. Section 3(29) of the Communications Act defines the term 
    ``network element'' to mean both ``a facility or equipment used in the 
    provision of a telecommunications service'' and ``features, functions, 
    and capabilities that are provided by means of such facility or 
    equipment.'' Such features, functions, and capabilities include 
    ``subscriber numbers, databases, signaling systems, and information 
    sufficient for billing and collection or used in the transmission, 
    routing, or other provision of a telecommunications service.'' The 
    Joint Explanatory Statement explains that ``[t]he term `network 
    element' was included to describe the facilities, such as local loops, 
    equipment, such as switching, and the features, functions, and 
    capabilities that a local exchange carrier must provide for certain 
    purposes under other sections of the conference agreement.''
        186. In the NPRM, we noted that we could identify ``network 
    elements'' in two ways. First, we could identify a single ``network 
    element,'' and then further subdivide it into additional ``elements.'' 
    Alternatively, we could provide that, once we identify a particular 
    ``network element,'' it cannot be further subdivided. In the NPRM, we 
    asked for comment on these two approaches.
        187. We observed in the NPRM that the statutory definition of a 
    ``network element'' draws a distinction between a ``facility or 
    equipment used in the provision of a telecommunications service,'' and 
    the ``service'' itself. We asked for comment on the meaning of this 
    distinction in general, with respect to requirements for unbundling, 
    and in connection with specific unbundled elements. We noted that the 
    definition of a network element, i.e., a facility, function, or 
    capability, is not dependent on the particular types of services that 
    are provided by means of the element (e.g., interstate access, 
    intrastate local exchange), and asked whether a carrier purchasing 
    access to an element is obligated, pursuant to the definition, to 
    provide all services typically carried or provided by that element.
    2. Discussion
        188. We adopt the concept of unbundled elements as physical 
    facilities of the network, together with the features, functions, and 
    capabilities associated with those facilities. Carriers requesting use 
    of unbundled elements within the incumbent LEC's network seek in effect 
    to purchase the right to obtain exclusive access to an entire facility, 
    or use of some feature, function or capability of that element. For 
    some elements, especially the loop, the requesting carrier will 
    purchase exclusive access to the element for a specific period, such as 
    on a monthly basis. Carriers seeking other elements, especially shared 
    facilities such as common transport, are essentially purchasing access 
    to a functionality of the incumbent's facilities on a minute-by-minute 
    basis. This concept of network elements, as discussed infra at section 
    V.G., does not alter the incumbent LEC's physical control or ability or 
    duty to repair and maintain network elements.
        189. We conclude that we should identify a particular facility or 
    capability, for example, as a single network element, but allow 
    ourselves and the states (where appropriate) the discretion to further 
    identify, within that single facility or capability, additional 
    required network elements. Thus, for example, in this proceeding, we 
    identify the local loop as a single network element. We also ask the 
    states to evaluate, on a case-by-case basis, whether to require access 
    to subloop elements, which can be facilities or capabilities within the 
    local loop. We agree with those commenters that argue that identifying 
    a particular facility or capability as single network element, but 
    allowing such elements to be further subdivided into additional 
    elements, will allow our rules (as well as the states) to accommodate 
    changes in technology, and thus better serve the interests of new 
    entrants and incumbent LECs, and the procompetitive purposes of the 
    1996 Act. We are not persuaded by PacTel's argument that it is 
    unnecessary for our rules to permit the identification of additional 
    elements, beyond those specifically referenced in parts of the 1996 
    Act, because our rules must conform to the definition of a network 
    element, and they must accommodate changes in technology. Nor are we 
    persuaded by BellSouth that identification of network elements should 
    be left solely to the parties. We reject this approach for the same 
    reasons that led us to adopt national unbundling requirements. Finally, 
    we agree with NYNEX and others that we should not identify elements in 
    rigid terms, but rather by function.
        190. We agree with MCI and MFS that the definition of the term 
    network element includes physical facilities, such as a loop, switch, 
    or other node, as well as logical features, functions, and capabilities 
    that are provided by, for example, software located in a physical 
    facility such as a switch. We further agree with MCI that the embedded 
    features and functions within a network element are part of the 
    characteristics of that element and may not be removed from it. 
    Accordingly, incumbent LECs
    
    [[Page 45508]]
    
    must provide network elements along with all of their features and 
    functions, so that new entrants may offer services that compete with 
    those offered by incumbents as well as new services.
        191. The only limitation that the statute imposes on the definition 
    of a network element is that it must be ``used in the provision of a 
    telecommunications service.'' Incumbent LECs provide telecommunications 
    services not only through network facilities that serve as the basis 
    for a particular service, or that accomplish physical delivery, but 
    also through information (such as billing information) that enables 
    incumbents to offer services on a commercial basis to consumers. Our 
    interpretation of the term ``provision'' finds support in the 
    definition of the term ``network element.'' That definition provides 
    that the type of information that may constitute a feature or function 
    includes information ``used in the transmission, routing or other 
    provision of a telecommunications service.'' Since ``transmission'' and 
    ``routing'' refer to physical delivery, the phrase ``or other provision 
    of a telecommunications service'' goes beyond mere physical delivery.
        192. We conclude that the definition of the term ``network 
    element'' broadly includes all ``facilit[ies] or equipment used in the 
    provision of a telecommunications service,'' and all ``features, 
    functions, and capabilities that are provided by means of such facility 
    or equipment, including subscriber numbers, databases, signaling 
    systems, and information sufficient for billing and collection or used 
    in the transmission, routing, or other provision of a 
    telecommunications service.'' This definition thus includes, but is not 
    limited to, transport trunks, call-related databases, software used in 
    such databases, and all other unbundled elements that we identify in 
    this proceeding. The definition also includes information that 
    incumbent LECs use to provide telecommunications functions 
    commercially, such as information required for pre-ordering, ordering, 
    provisioning, billing, and maintenance and repair services. (The term 
    ``provisioning'' includes installation.) This interpretation of the 
    definition of the term ``network element'' will serve to guide both the 
    Commission and the states in evaluating further unbundling requirements 
    beyond those we identify in this proceeding.
        193. We disagree with those incumbent LECs which argue that 
    features that are sold directly to end users as retail services, such 
    as vertical features, cannot be considered elements within incumbent 
    LEC networks. If we were to conclude that any functionality sold 
    directly to end users as a service, such as call forwarding or caller 
    ID, cannot be defined as a network element, then incumbent LECs could 
    provide local service to end users by selling them unbundled loops and 
    switch elements, and thereby entirely evade the unbundling requirement 
    in section 251(c)(3). We are confident that Congress did not intend 
    such a result. We further reject Ameritech's argument that we should 
    not permit carriers to use unbundled elements to provide services that 
    are priced above cost at retail. We agree with those parties that argue 
    that competition will not develop if we find that supracompetitive 
    pricing is protected by the 1996 Act.
        194. Moreover, we agree with those commenters that argue that 
    network elements are defined by facilities or their functionalities or 
    capabilities, and thus, cannot be defined as specific services. A 
    single network element could be used to provide many different 
    services. For example, a local loop can be used to provision inter- and 
    intrastate exchange access services, as well as local exchange 
    services. We conclude, consistent with the findings of the Ohio and 
    Oregon Commissions, that the plain language of section 251(c)(3) does 
    not obligate carriers purchasing access to network elements to provide 
    all services that an unbundled element is capable of providing or that 
    are typically offered over that element. Section 251(c)(3) does not 
    impose any service-related restrictions or requirements on requesting 
    carriers in connection with the use of unbundled elements.
    
    D. Access to Network Elements
    
    1. Background
        195. In the NPRM, we observed that section 251(c)(3) requires 
    incumbent LECs to provide ``access'' to network elements ``on an 
    unbundled basis.'' We interpreted these terms to mean that incumbent 
    LECs must provide carriers with the functionality of a particular 
    element, separate from the functionality of other elements, and must 
    charge a separate fee for each element. We sought comment on this 
    interpretation and any alternative interpretations.
    2. Discussion
        196. We conclude that we should adopt our proposed interpretation 
    that the terms ``access'' to network elements ``on an unbundled basis'' 
    mean that incumbent LECs must provide the facility or functionality of 
    a particular element to requesting carriers, separate from the facility 
    or functionality of other elements, for a separate fee. We further 
    conclude that a telecommunications carrier purchasing access to an 
    unbundled network facility is entitled to exclusive use of that 
    facility for a period of time, or when purchasing access to a feature, 
    function, or capability of a facility, a telecommunications carrier is 
    entitled to use of that feature, function, or capability for a period 
    of time. The specified period may vary depending on the terms of the 
    agreement between the incumbent LEC and the requesting carrier. The 
    ability of other carriers to obtain access to a network element for 
    some period of time does not relieve the incumbent LEC of the duty to 
    maintain, repair, or replace the unbundled network element. We clarify 
    that title to unbundled network elements will not shift to requesting 
    carriers. We reject PacTel's interpretation of the terms quoted above 
    because it is inconsistent with our definition of the term network 
    element (i.e., an element includes all features and functions embedded 
    in it). Moreover, to the extent that PacTel's argument suggests that 
    the 1996 Act does not require unbundled elements to be provisioned in a 
    way that would make them useful, we find that its statutory 
    interpretation is inconsistent with the statute's goal of providing new 
    entrants with realistic means of competing against incumbents.
        197. We further conclude that ``access'' to an unbundled element 
    refers to the means by which requesting carriers obtain an element's 
    functionality in order to provide a telecommunications service. Just as 
    section 251(c)(2) requires ``interconnection * * * at any technically 
    feasible point,'' section 251(c)(3) requires ``access * * * at any 
    technically feasible point.'' We conclude, based on the terms of 
    sections 251 (c)(2), 251(c)(3), and 251(c)(6), that an incumbent LEC's 
    duty to provide ``access'' constitutes a duty to provide a connection 
    to a network element independent of any duty imposed by subsection 
    (c)(2). Thus, such ``access'' must be provided under the rates, terms, 
    and conditions that apply to unbundled elements.
        198. Specifically, section 251(c)(6) provides that incumbent LECs 
    must provide ``physical collocation of equipment necessary for 
    interconnection or access to unbundled network elements.'' The use of 
    the term ``or'' in this phrase means that interconnection is different 
    from ``access'' to unbundled elements. The text of sections 251(c)(2) 
    and (c)(3) leads to the same conclusion. Section 251(c)(2) requires 
    that interconnection be provided for ``the transmission and
    
    [[Page 45509]]
    
    routing of telephone exchange service and exchange access.'' Section 
    251(c)(3), in contrast, requires the provision of access to unbundled 
    elements to allow requesting carriers to provide ``a telecommunications 
    service.'' The term ``telecommunications service'' by definition 
    includes a broader range of services than the terms ``telephone 
    exchange service and exchange access.'' Subsection (c)(3), therefore, 
    allows unbundled elements to be used for a broader range of services 
    than subsection (c)(2) allows for interconnection. If we were to 
    conclude that ``access'' to unbundled elements under subsection (c)(3) 
    could only be achieved by means of interconnection under subsection 
    (c)(2), we would be limiting, in effect, the uses to which unbundled 
    elements may be put, contrary to the plain language of section 
    251(c)(3) and standard canons of statutory construction.
    
    E. Standards Necessary To Identify Unbundled Network Elements
    
    1. Background
        199. In the NPRM, we raised a number of issues concerning the 
    meaning of technical feasibility in connection with unbundled elements. 
    We also sought comment on the extent to which the Commission should 
    consider the standards set forth in section 251(d)(2) in identifying 
    required unbundled elements, and on how we ought to interpret these 
    standards. Subsection (d)(2) provides that ``(i)n determining what 
    network elements should be made available for purposes of subsection 
    (c)(3), the Commission shall consider, at a minimum'' the following two 
    standards, ``whether (A) access to such network elements as are 
    proprietary in nature is necessary; and (B) the failure to provide 
    access to such network elements would impair the ability of the 
    telecommunications carrier seeking access to provide the services that 
    it seeks to offer.'' We further asked about the relationship between 
    the latter standard and the requirement in section 251(c)(3) that 
    carriers be able to use unbundled elements to provide a 
    telecommunications service.
    2. Discussion
        200. Sections 251(c)(3) and 251(d)(2) set forth standards the 
    Commission must consider in identifying unbundled network elements that 
    incumbent LECs must make available in connection with arbitrations 
    before state commissions and BOC statements of generally available 
    terms and conditions. These standards guide the unbundling requirements 
    we issue today as well as any different or additional unbundling 
    requirements we may issue in the future. Similarly, the States must 
    follow our interpretation of these standards to the extent they impose 
    additional unbundling requirements during arbitrations or subsequent 
    rulemaking proceedings.
        201. Section 251(c)(3) requires incumbent LECs to provide 
    requesting carriers with ``nondiscriminatory access to network elements 
    on an unbundled basis at any technically feasible point.'' We find that 
    this clause imposes on an incumbent LEC the duty to provide all network 
    elements for which it is technically feasible to provide access on an 
    unbundled basis. Because section 251(d)(1) requires us to ``establish 
    regulations to implement the requirements of'' section 251(c)(3), we 
    conclude that we have authority to establish regulations that are 
    coextensive with the duty section 251(c)(3) imposes on incumbent LECs.
        202. Section 251(d)(2), however, sets forth standards that do not 
    depend on technical feasibility. More specifically, section 251(d)(2) 
    provides that, in identifying unbundled elements, the Commission shall 
    ``consider, at a minimum,'' whether access to proprietary elements is 
    necessary (the ``proprietary standard''), and whether requesting 
    carriers' ability to provide services would be impaired if the desired 
    elements were not provided by an incumbent LEC (the ``impairment 
    standard.'') Thus, section 251(d)(2) gives us the authority to decline 
    to require incumbent LECs to provide access to unbundled network 
    elements at technically feasible points if, for example, we were to 
    conclude that access to a particular proprietary element is not 
    necessary. To give effect to both sections 251(c)(3) and 251(d)(2), we 
    conclude that the proprietary and impairment standards in section 
    251(d)(2) grant us the authority to refrain from requiring incumbent 
    LECs to provide all network elements for which it is technically 
    feasible to provide access on an unbundled basis. The authority we 
    derive from section 251(d)(2) is limited, however, by our 
    interpretation of these standards, and this section, as set forth 
    below.
        203. We agree with BellSouth, SBC, and others that the plain import 
    of the ``at minimum'' language in section 251(d)(2) requires us, in 
    identifying unbundled network elements, to ``consider'' the standards 
    enumerated there, as well as other standards we believe are consistent 
    with the objectives of the 1996 Act. We conclude that the word 
    ``consider'' means we must weigh the standards enumerated in section 
    251(d)(2) in evaluating whether to require the unbundling of a 
    particular element.
        204. We further conclude that, in evaluating whether to impose 
    additional unbundling requirements during the arbitration process, 
    States must apply our definition of technical feasibility, discussed 
    above in section IV.D. A determination of technical feasibility would 
    then create a presumption in favor of requiring an incumbent LEC to 
    provide the element. If providing access to an unbundled element is 
    technically feasible, a State must then consider the standards set 
    forth in section 251(d)(2), as we interpret them below. Similarly, the 
    Commission will apply this analysis where we must arbitrate specific 
    unbundling issues, under section 252(e)(5), and in future rulemaking 
    proceedings that may consider additional or possibly different 
    unbundling requirements.
        205. Section 251(d)(2)(A) requires the Commission and the States to 
    consider whether access to proprietary elements is ``necessary.'' 
    ``Necessary'' means, in this context, that an element is a prerequisite 
    for competition. We believe that, in some instances, it will be 
    ``necessary'' for new entrants to obtain access to proprietary elements 
    (e.g., elements with proprietary protocols or elements containing 
    proprietary information), because without such elements, their ability 
    to compete would be significantly impaired or thwarted. As noted supra, 
    a number of commenters argue that section 251(d)(2)(A) requires us to 
    protect proprietary information, such as CPNI information, contained in 
    network elements. We intend to treat issues regarding CPNI in our 
    rulemaking proceeding on CPNI information. Telecommunications Carriers' 
    Use of Customer Proprietary Network Information and Other Customer 
    Information, CC Docket No. 96-115, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, FCC 
    96-221, 61 FR 26483 (May 28, 1996). Thus, as an initial matter, we 
    decline to adopt a general rule, as suggested by some incumbents, that 
    would prohibit access to such elements, or make access available only 
    upon a carrier demonstrating a heavy burden of need. We acknowledge 
    that prohibiting incumbents from refusing access to proprietary 
    elements could reduce their incentives to offer innovative services. We 
    are not persuaded, however, that this is a sufficient reason to 
    prohibit generally the unbundling of proprietary elements, because the 
    threat to competition from any such prohibition would far exceed any 
    costs to
    
    [[Page 45510]]
    
    consumers resulting from reduced innovation by the incumbent LEC. In 
    this proceeding, for example, we are requiring incumbent LECs to 
    provide the local switching element which includes vertical features 
    that some carriers contend are proprietary. See infra, Section V.J. 
    Moreover, the procompetitive effects of our conclusion generally will 
    stimulate innovation in the market, offsetting any hypothetical 
    reduction in innovation by the incumbent LECs.
        206. We further conclude that, to the extent new entrants seek 
    additional elements beyond those we identify herein, section 
    251(d)(2)(A) allows the Commission and the states to require the 
    unbundling of such elements unless the incumbent can prove to a state 
    commission that: (1) The element is proprietary, or contains 
    proprietary information that will be revealed if the element is 
    provided on an unbundled basis; and (2) a new entrant could offer the 
    same proposed telecommunications service through the use of other, 
    nonproprietary unbundled elements within the incumbent's network. We 
    believe this interpretation of section 251(d)(2)(A) will best advance 
    the procompetitive purposes of the 1996 Act. It allows new entrants to 
    obtain proprietary elements from incumbent LECs where they are 
    necessary to offer a telecommunications service, and, at the same time, 
    it gives incumbents the opportunity to argue, before the states or the 
    Commission, against unbundling proprietary elements where a new entrant 
    could offer the same service using other unbundled elements in the 
    incumbent's network. We decline to adopt the interpretation of section 
    251(d)(2)(A) advanced by some incumbents that incumbent LECs need not 
    provide proprietary elements if requesting carriers can obtain the 
    requested proprietary element from a source other than the incumbent. 
    Requiring new entrants to duplicate unnecessarily even a part of the 
    incumbent's network could generate delay and higher costs for new 
    entrants, and thereby impede entry by competing local providers and 
    delay competition, contrary to the goals of the 1996 Act.
        207. We further conclude that, to the extent new entrants do not 
    need access to all the proprietary information contained within an 
    element in order to provide a telecommunications service, the 
    Commission and the states may take action to protect the proprietary 
    information. For example, to provide a telecommunications service, a 
    new entrant might need access to information about a particular 
    customer that is in an incumbent LEC database. The database to which 
    the new entrant requires access, however, may contain proprietary 
    information about all of the incumbent LECs' customers. In this 
    circumstance, the new entrant should not have access to proprietary 
    information about the incumbent LEC's other customers where it is not 
    necessary to provide service to the new entrant's particular customer. 
    Accordingly, we believe the Commission and the states have the 
    authority to protect the confidentiality of proprietary information in 
    an unbundled network element, such as a database, where that 
    information is not necessary to enable a new entrant to offer a 
    telecommunications service to its particular customer.
        208. Section 251(d)(2)(B) requires us to consider whether the 
    failure to provide access to an element would ``impair'' the ability of 
    a new entrant to provide a service it seeks to offer. The term 
    ``impair'' means ``to make or cause to become worse; diminish in 
    value.'' We believe, generally, that an entrant's ability to offer a 
    telecommunications service is ``diminished in value'' if the quality of 
    the service the entrant can offer, absent access to the requested 
    element, declines and/or the cost of providing the service rises. We 
    believe we must consider this standard by evaluating whether a carrier 
    could offer a service using other unbundled elements within an 
    incumbent LEC's network. Accordingly, we interpret the ``impairment'' 
    standard as requiring the Commission and the states, when evaluating 
    unbundling requirements beyond those identified in our minimum list, to 
    consider whether the failure of an incumbent to provide access to a 
    network element would decrease the quality, or increase the financial 
    or administrative cost of the service a requesting carrier seeks to 
    offer, compared with providing that service over other unbundled 
    elements in the incumbent LEC's network.
        209. We decline to adopt the interpretation of the ``impairment'' 
    standard advanced by most BOCs and GTE. Under their interpretation, 
    incumbent LECs must provide unbundled elements only when the failure to 
    do so would prevent a carrier from offering a service. We also reject 
    the related interpretations that carriers are not impaired in their 
    ability to provide a service if they can obtain elements from another 
    source, or if they can provide the proposed service by purchasing the 
    service at wholesale rates from a LEC. In general, and as discussed 
    above, section 251(c)(3) imposes on incumbent LECs the obligation to 
    offer on an unbundled basis all network elements for which it is 
    technically feasible to provide access. We believe the plain language 
    of section 251(d)(2), and the standards articulated there, give us the 
    discretion to limit the general obligation imposed by subsection 
    251(c)(3), but they do not require us to do so. The standards set forth 
    in section 251(d)(2) are minimum considerations that the Commission 
    shall take into account in evaluating unbundling requirements. 
    Accordingly, we conclude that the statute does not require us to 
    interpret the ``impairment'' standard in a way that would significantly 
    diminish the obligation imposed by section 251(c)(3).
        210. The interpretation advanced by most of the BOCs and GTE, 
    described above, means that, if a requesting carrier could obtain an 
    element from a source other than the incumbent, then the incumbent need 
    not provide the element. We agree with the reasoning advanced by some 
    of the commenters that this interpretation would nullify section 
    251(c)(3) because, in theory, any new entrant could provide all of the 
    elements in the incumbents' networks. Congress made it possible for 
    competitors to enter local markets through the purchase of unbundled 
    elements because it recognized that duplication of an incumbent's 
    network could delay entry, and could be inefficient and unnecessary. 
    The interpretation proffered by the BOCs and GTE would inhibit new 
    entry and thus restrict the potential for meaningful competition, which 
    would undermine the procompetitive goals of the 1996 Act. As a 
    practical matter, if it is more efficient and less costly for new 
    entrants to obtain network elements from a source other than an 
    incumbent LEC, new entrants will likely pursue the more efficient and 
    less costly approach. Additionally, as discussed above at section IV.C, 
    we believe that allowing incumbent LECs to deny access to unbundled 
    elements on the grounds that an element is equivalent to a service 
    available at resale would lead to impractical results, because 
    incumbents could completely avoid section 251(c)(3)'s unbundling 
    obligations by offering unbundled elements to end users as retail 
    services.
        211. Finally, we decline at this time to adopt any of the 
    additional criteria proposed by commenters. We conclude that none of 
    the additional factors suggested by commenters enhances our ability to 
    identify unbundled network elements consistent with the procompetitive 
    goals of the 1996 Act. These additional considerations would limit 
    unbundling requirements or make it administratively more difficult for
    
    [[Page 45511]]
    
    new entrants to obtain additional unbundled elements beyond those 
    identified in our minimum list of required elements. For example, we 
    believe that the proposal that new entrants must provide detailed 
    estimates regarding projected market demand is not necessary for 
    incumbent LECs to efficiently plan for network growth.
    
    F. Provision of a Telecommunications Service Using Unbundled Network 
    Elements
    
    1. Background
        212. Section 251(c)(3) provides that an incumbent LEC must provide 
    access to ``unbundled network elements in a manner that allows 
    requesting carriers to combine such elements in order to provide'' a 
    telecommunications service. In the NPRM, we sought comment on the 
    meaning of this requirement.
    2. Discussion
        213. Under section 251(c)(3), incumbent LECs must provide access to 
    ``unbundled network elements in a manner that allows requesting 
    carriers to combine such elements in order to provide'' a 
    telecommunications service. We agree with the Illinois Commission, the 
    Texas Public Utility Counsel, and others that this language bars 
    incumbent LECs from imposing limitations, restrictions, or requirements 
    on requests for, or the sale or use of, unbundled elements that would 
    impair the ability of requesting carriers to offer telecommunications 
    services in the manner they intend. For example, incumbent LECs may not 
    restrict the types of telecommunications services requesting carriers 
    may offer through unbundled elements, nor may they restrict requesting 
    carriers from combining elements with any technically compatible 
    equipment the requesting carriers own. We also conclude that section 
    251(c)(3) requires incumbent LECs to provide requesting carriers with 
    all of the functionalities of a particular element, so that requesting 
    carriers can provide any telecommunications services that can be 
    offered by means of the element. We believe this interpretation 
    provides new entrants with the requisite ability to use unbundled 
    elements flexibly to respond to market forces, and thus is consistent 
    with the procompetitive goals of the 1996 Act.
        214. We agree with AT&T and Comptel that the quoted text in section 
    251(c)(3) bars incumbent LECs from separating elements that are ordered 
    in combination, unless a requesting carrier specifically asks that such 
    elements be separated. We also conclude that the quoted text requires 
    incumbent LECs, if necessary, to perform the functions necessary to 
    combine requested elements in any technically feasible manner either 
    with other elements from the incumbent's network, or with elements 
    possessed by new entrants, subject to the technical feasibility 
    restrictions discussed below. We adopt these conclusions for two 
    reasons. First, in practice it would be impossible for new entrants 
    that lack facilities and information about the incumbent's network to 
    combine unbundled elements from the incumbents' network without the 
    assistance of the incumbent. If we adopted NYNEX's proposal, we believe 
    requesting carriers would be seriously and unfairly inhibited in their 
    ability to use unbundled elements to enter local markets. We therefore 
    reject NYNEX's contention that the statute requires requesting 
    carriers, rather than incumbents, to combine elements. We do not 
    believe it is possible that Congress, having created the opportunity to 
    enter local telephone markets through the use of unbundled elements, 
    intended to undermine that opportunity by imposing technical 
    obligations on requesting carriers that they might not be able to 
    readily meet.
        215. Second, given the practical difficulties of requiring 
    requesting carriers to combine elements that are part of the incumbent 
    LEC's network, we conclude that section 251(c)(3) should be read to 
    require incumbent LECs to combine elements requested by carriers. More 
    specifically, section 251(c)(3) provides that incumbent LECs must 
    provide unbundled elements ``in a manner that allows requesting 
    carriers to combine them'' to provide a telecommunications service. We 
    believe this phrase means that incumbents must provide unbundled 
    elements in a way that enables requesting carriers to combine them to 
    provide a service. The phrase ``allows requesting carriers to combine 
    them,'' does not impose the obligation of physically combining elements 
    exclusively on requesting carriers. Rather, it permits a requesting 
    carrier to combine the elements if the carrier is reasonably able to do 
    so. If the carrier is unable to combine the elements, the incumbent 
    must do so. In this context, we conclude that the term ``combine'' 
    means connecting two or more unbundled network elements in a manner 
    that would allow a requesting carrier to offer the telecommunications 
    service it seeks to offer.
        216. Our conclusion that incumbent LECs must combine unbundled 
    elements when so requested is consistent with the method we have 
    adopted to identify unbundled network elements. Under our method, 
    incumbents must provide, as a single, combined element, facilities that 
    could comprise more than one element. This means, for example, that, if 
    the states require incumbent LECs to provision subloop elements, 
    incumbent LECs must still provision a local loop as a single, combined 
    element when so requested, because we identify local loops as a single 
    element in this proceeding.
        217. We decline to adopt the view proffered by some parties that 
    incumbents must combine network elements in any technically feasible 
    manner requested. This proposal necessarily means that carriers could 
    request incumbent LECs to combine elements that are not ordinarily 
    combined in the incumbent's network. We are concerned that, in some 
    instances, this could potentially affect the reliability and security 
    of the incumbent's network, and the ability of other carriers to obtain 
    interconnection, or request and use unbundled elements. Accordingly, 
    incumbent LECs are required to perform the functions necessary to 
    combine those elements that are ordinarily combined within their 
    network, in the manner in which they are typically combined. Incumbent 
    LECs are also required to perform the functions necessary to combine 
    elements, even if they are not ordinarily combined in that manner, or 
    they are not ordinarily combined in the incumbent's network, provided 
    that such combination is technically feasible, and such combination 
    would not undermine the ability of other carriers to access unbundled 
    elements or interconnect with the incumbent LEC's network. As discussed 
    in Section IV, effects on network reliability and security are factors 
    to be considered in determining technical feasibility. Incumbent LECs 
    must prove to state commissions that a request to combine particular 
    elements in a particular manner is not technically feasible, or that 
    the request would undermine the ability of other carriers to access 
    unbundled elements and interconnect because they have the information 
    to support such a claim.
        218. We agree with Sprint and the Florida Commission, respectively, 
    that in some cases incumbent LECs may be required to provision a 
    particular element in different ways, depending on the service a 
    requesting carrier seeks to offer; and, in other instances, where a new 
    entrant needs a particular variant of an element to offer a service, 
    that element should be treated as distinct from other variants of the 
    element. This means, for example, that we will treat
    
    [[Page 45512]]
    
    local loops with a particular type of conditioning as distinct elements 
    that are different from loops with other types of conditioning. As 
    discussed below, we agree with CompTel that incumbent LECs must provide 
    the operational and support systems necessary for requesting carriers 
    to purchase and combine network elements. Incumbent LECs use these 
    systems to provide services to their own end users, and new entrants 
    similarly must have access to them to provide telecommunications 
    services using unbundled elements. Finally, we agree with BellSouth 
    that requesting carriers must specify to incumbent LECs the network 
    elements they seek before they can obtain such elements on an unbundled 
    basis. We do not believe, however, that it will always be possible for 
    new entrants to do this either before negotiations (or arbitrations) 
    begin, or before they end, because new entrants will likely lack 
    knowledge about the facilities and capabilities of a particular 
    incumbent LEC's network. We further believe that incumbent LECs must 
    work with new entrants to identify the elements the new entrants will 
    need to offer a particular service in the manner the new entrants 
    intend.
    
    G. Nondiscriminatory Access to Unbundled Network Elements and Just, 
    Reasonable and Nondiscriminatory Terms and Conditions for the Provision 
    of Unbundled Network Elements
    
    1. Background
        219. Section 251(c)(3) requires incumbent LECs to provide 
    requesting carriers ``nondiscriminatory access to network elements on 
    an unbundled basis * * * on rates, terms, and conditions that are just, 
    reasonable, and nondiscriminatory.'' In the NPRM, we sought comment on 
    whether we should adopt minimum national requirements governing the 
    terms and conditions for the provision of unbundled network elements. 
    We further asked what rules could ensure that the terms and conditions 
    for access to unbundled network elements are just, reasonable and 
    nondiscriminatory, and how we should enforce such rules. In particular, 
    we sought comment on whether we should adopt uniform national rules 
    governing provisioning, service, maintenance, technical standards and 
    nondiscrimination safeguards in connection with the provision of 
    unbundled network elements. We also asked whether we should consider 
    any of the terms and conditions applicable to the provision of access 
    to unbundled elements in evaluating BOC applications to provide in-
    region interLATA services under section 271(b).
    2. Discussion
        220. We agree with those commenters, including the Florida, 
    Illinois and Washington Commissions, that to achieve the procompetitive 
    goals of the 1996 Act, it is necessary to establish rules that define 
    the obligations of incumbent LECs to provide nondiscriminatory access 
    to unbundled network elements, and to provide such elements on terms 
    and conditions that are just, reasonable and nondiscriminatory. As 
    discussed above at sections II.A, II.B and V.B, we believe that 
    incumbent LECs have little incentive to facilitate the ability of new 
    entrants, including small entities, to compete against them and, thus, 
    have little incentive to provision unbundled elements in a manner that 
    would provide efficient competitors with a meaningful opportunity to 
    compete. We are also cognizant of the fact that incumbent LECs have the 
    incentive and the ability to engage in many kinds of discrimination. 
    For example, incumbent LECs could potentially delay providing access to 
    unbundled network elements, or they could provide them to new entrants 
    at a degraded level of quality.
        221. Consistent with arguments advanced by the Florida and 
    Washington Commissions, incumbent LECs, and potential competitors, and 
    as more fully discussed in the specific sections below, we adopt 
    general, national rules defining ``nondiscriminatory access'' to 
    unbundled network elements, and ``just, reasonable, and 
    nondiscriminatory'' terms and conditions for the provision of such 
    elements. We have chosen this approach, rather than allowing states 
    exclusively to consider these issues, because we believe that some 
    national rules regarding nondiscriminatory access will reduce the costs 
    of entry and speed the development of competition.
        222. We conclude, for example, that national rules defining the 
    1996 Act's requirements regarding nondiscriminatory access to, and 
    provision of, unbundled elements will reduce costs associated with 
    potential litigation over these issues, and will enable states to 
    conduct arbitrations more quickly by reducing the number of issues they 
    must consider. Such rules will also facilitate the ability of the 
    Commission to conduct arbitrations, should we assume a state's 
    responsibilities under section 252(e)(5). We conclude further that such 
    rules will create some uniformity across states in connection with the 
    terms under which new entrants may obtain access to network elements, 
    thus facilitating the ability of potential competitors, including small 
    entities, to enter local markets on a regional or national scale. 
    Accordingly, for all of these reasons, we reject the arguments of 
    PacTel and USTA that we should not adopt national rules relating to 
    incumbent LEC obligations to provide access to, and provision, 
    unbundled elements in a nondiscriminatory manner.
        223. The record compiled in this proceeding supports the adoption 
    of uniform general rules that rely on states to develop more specific 
    requirements in arbitrations and other state proceedings. More 
    significantly, however, we agree with the California and Florida 
    Commissions that the states are best situated to issue specific rules 
    because of their existing knowledge regarding incumbent LEC networks, 
    capabilities, and performance standards in their separate jurisdictions 
    and because of the role they will play in conducting mediations, 
    arbitrations, and approving agreements. We expect that the states will 
    implement the general nondiscrimination rules set forth herein by 
    adopting, inter alia, specific rules determining the timing in which 
    incumbent LECs must provision certain elements, and any other specific 
    conditions they deem necessary to provide new entrants, including small 
    competitors, with a meaningful opportunity to compete in local exchange 
    markets. The states will continue to gain expertise in connection with 
    issues relating to just, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory access and 
    provision of unbundled network elements. We expect to turn to the 
    states, and rely on the expertise they develop in this area, when we 
    review and revise our rules as necessary.
        224. We agree with those commenters that argue that incumbent LECs 
    should be required to fulfill some type of reporting requirement to 
    ensure that they provision unbundled elements in a nondiscriminatory 
    manner. We believe the record is insufficient at this time to adopt 
    such requirements, and we may reexamine this issue in the future. We 
    encourage the states, however, to adopt reporting requirements. We 
    decline to address whether the Commission should consider any of the 
    terms and conditions adopted here in evaluating BOC applications to 
    provide in-region long distance services. We will consider this issue, 
    as it arises, when we evaluate individual BOC applications.
    a. Nondiscriminatory Access to Unbundled Network Elements
        225. We conclude that the obligation to provide ``nondiscriminatory 
    access to
    
    [[Page 45513]]
    
    network elements on an unbundled basis'' refers to both the physical or 
    logical connection to the element and the element itself. In 
    considering how to implement this obligation in a manner that would 
    achieve the 1996 Act's goal of promoting local exchange competition, we 
    recognize that new entrants, including small entities, would be denied 
    a meaningful opportunity to compete if the quality of the access to 
    unbundled elements provided by incumbent LECs, as well as the quality 
    of the elements themselves, were lower than what the incumbent LECs 
    provide to themselves. Thus, we conclude it would be insufficient to 
    define the obligation of incumbent LECs to provide ``nondiscriminatory 
    access'' to mean that the quality of the access and unbundled elements 
    incumbent LECs provide to all requesting carriers is the same. As 
    discussed above with respect to interconnection, an incumbent LEC could 
    potentially act in a nondiscriminatory manner in providing access or 
    elements to all requesting carriers, while providing preferential 
    access or elements to itself. Accordingly, we conclude that the phrase 
    ``nondiscriminatory access'' in section 251(c)(3) means at least two 
    things: first, the quality of an unbundled network element that an 
    incumbent LEC provides, as well as the access provided to that element, 
    must be equal between all carriers requesting access to that element; 
    second, where technically feasible, the access and unbundled network 
    element provided by an incumbent LEC must be at least equal-in-quality 
    to that which the incumbent LEC provides to itself. We note that 
    providing access or elements of lesser quality than that enjoyed by the 
    incumbent LEC would also constitute an ``unjust'' or ``unreasonable'' 
    term or condition.
        226. We believe that Congress set forth a ``nondiscriminatory 
    access'' requirement in section 251(c)(3), rather then an absolute 
    equal-in-quality requirement, such as that set forth in section 
    251(c)(2)(C), because, in rare circumstances, it may be technically 
    infeasible for incumbent LECs to provide requesting carriers with 
    unbundled elements, and access to such elements, that are equal-in-
    quality to what the incumbent LECs provide themselves. According to 
    some commenters, this problem arises in connection with one variant of 
    one of the unbundled network elements we identify in this order. These 
    commenters argue that a carrier purchasing access to a 1AESS local 
    switch may not be able to receive, for example, the full measure of 
    customized routing features that such a switch may afford the 
    incumbent. In the rare circumstances where it is technically infeasible 
    for an incumbent LEC to provision access or elements that are equal-in-
    quality, we believe disparate access would not be inconsistent with the 
    nondiscrimination requirement. Accordingly, we require incumbent LECs 
    to provide access and unbundled elements that are at least equal-in-
    quality to what the incumbent LECs provide themselves, and allow for an 
    exception to this requirement only where it is technically infeasible 
    to meet. The exception described here does not excuse incumbent LECs 
    from the obligation to modify elements within their networks to allow 
    requesting carriers to obtain access to such elements where this is 
    technically feasible. See supra, Section IV.D. We expect incumbent LECs 
    to fulfill this requirement in nearly all instances where they 
    provision unbundled elements because we believe the technical 
    infeasibility problem will arise rarely. We further conclude, however, 
    that the incumbent LEC must prove to a state commission that it is 
    technically infeasible to provide access to unbundled elements, or the 
    unbundled elements themselves, at the same level of quality that the 
    incumbent LEC provides to itself.
        227. Our conclusion that an incumbent LEC must provide unbundled 
    elements, as well as access to them, that is ``at least'' equal in 
    quality to that which the incumbent provides itself, does not excuse 
    incumbent LECs from providing, when requested and where technically 
    feasible, access or unbundled elements of higher quality. An incumbent 
    LEC, in accommodating a carrier's request for a particular unbundled 
    element, may ultimately provision an element that is higher in quality 
    than what the incumbent provides to itself. See infra, Section V.J.1. 
    As we discuss below, we do not believe that this obligation is unduly 
    burdensome to incumbent LECs because the 1996 Act requires a requesting 
    carrier to pay the costs of unbundling, and thus incumbent LECs will be 
    fully compensated for any efforts they make to increase the quality of 
    access or elements within their own network. (See infra, Section V.J. 
    We require, for example, that incumbent LECs provide local loops 
    conditioned to enable the provision of digital services (where 
    technically feasible) even if the incumbent does not itself provide 
    such digital services.) Moreover, to the extent this obligation allows 
    new entrants, including small entities, to offer services that are 
    different from those offered by the incumbent, we believe it is 
    consistent with Congress's goal to promote local exchange competition. 
    We note that, to the extent an incumbent LEC provides an element with a 
    superior level of quality to a particular carrier, the incumbent LEC 
    must provide all other requesting carriers with the same opportunity to 
    obtain that element with the equivalent higher level of quality. We 
    further note that where a requesting carrier specifically requests 
    access or unbundled elements that are lower in quality to what the 
    incumbent LECs provide themselves, incumbent LECs may offer such 
    inferior quality if it is technically feasible. Finally, we conclude 
    that the incumbent LEC must prove to a state commission that it is 
    technically infeasible to provide access to unbundled elements, or the 
    unbundled elements themselves, at a level of quality that is superior 
    to or lower than what the incumbent LEC provides to itself.
    b. Just, Reasonable and Nondiscriminatory Terms and Conditions for the 
    Provision of Unbundled Network Elements
        228. The duty to provide unbundled network elements on ``terms, and 
    conditions that are just, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory'' means, at 
    a minimum, that whatever those terms and conditions are, they must be 
    offered equally to all requesting carriers, and where applicable, they 
    must be equal to the terms and conditions under which the incumbent LEC 
    provisions such elements to itself. We also conclude that, because 
    section 251(c)(3) includes the terms ``just'' and ``reasonable,'' this 
    duty encompasses more than the obligation to treat carriers equally. 
    Interpreting these terms in light of the 1996 Act's goal of promoting 
    local exchange competition, and the benefits inherent in such 
    competition, we conclude that these terms require incumbent LECs to 
    provide unbundled elements under terms and conditions that would 
    provide an efficient competitor with a meaningful opportunity to 
    compete. Such terms and conditions should serve to promote fair and 
    efficient competition. This means, for example, that incumbent LECs may 
    not provision unbundled elements that are inferior in quality to what 
    the incumbent provides itself because this would likely deny an 
    efficient competitor a meaningful opportunity to compete. We reach this 
    conclusion because providing new entrants, including small entities, 
    with a
    
    [[Page 45514]]
    
    meaningful opportunity to compete is a necessary precondition to 
    obtaining the benefits that the opening of local exchange markets to 
    competition is designed to achieve.
        229. As is more fully discussed below, to enable new entrants, 
    including small entities, to share the economies of scale, scope, and 
    density within the incumbent LECs' networks, we conclude that incumbent 
    LECs must provide carriers purchasing access to unbundled network 
    elements with the pre-ordering, ordering, provisioning, maintenance and 
    repair, and billing functions of the incumbent LECs operations support 
    systems. (The term ``provisioning'' includes installation.) Moreover, 
    the incumbent must provide access to these functions under the same 
    terms and conditions that they provide these services to themselves or 
    their customers. We discuss specific terms and conditions applicable to 
    the unbundled elements identified in this order below, in Section V.J.
    
    H. The Relationship Between Sections 251(c)(3) and 251(c)(4)
    
    1. Background
        230. Section 251(c)(4) provides that incumbent LECs must offer 
    ``for resale at wholesale rates any telecommunications service that the 
    carrier provides at retail to subscribers that are not 
    telecommunications carriers.'' In the NPRM, we asked for comment on the 
    relationship between this provision and section 251(c)(3). 
    Specifically, we asked whether carriers can order and combine network 
    elements to offer the same services that incumbent LECs offer for 
    resale under section 251(c)(4). We observed that different pricing 
    standards under section 252(d) apply to unbundled elements under 
    section 251(c)(3) and resold services under section 251(c)(4), and that 
    section 251(c)(3) contemplates the purchase of unseparated facilities 
    (i.e., facilities that can be used for either inter- or intrastate 
    services) while subsection (c)(4) does not necessarily contemplate 
    this. We asked for comment on the implications or significance of these 
    differences.
    2. Discussion
        231. The language of section 251(c)(3) is cast exclusively in terms 
    of obligations imposed on incumbent LECs, and it does not discuss, 
    reference, or suggest a limitation or requirement in connection with 
    the right of new entrants to obtain access to unbundled elements. We 
    conclude, therefore, that Congress did not intend section 251(c)(3) to 
    be read to contain any requirement that carriers must own or control 
    some of their own local exchange facilities before they can purchase 
    and use unbundled elements to provide a telecommunications service. We 
    note that the Illinois Commission has reached the same conclusion.
        232. We reject the arguments advanced by Bell Atlantic and NYNEX 
    that the language of section 251(c)(3) requires carriers seeking access 
    to unbundled elements to own some local exchange facilities, and that 
    this serves to distinguish section 251(c)(3) from section 251(c)(4). 
    The ``at any technically feasible point'' language in section 251(c)(3) 
    refers to points in an incumbent LEC's network where new entrants may 
    obtain access to elements. It does not, however, require that new 
    entrants interconnect local exchange facilities which they own or 
    control at that technically feasible access point. If we were to 
    conclude otherwise, then new entrants would be prohibited from 
    requesting two network elements that are connected to each other 
    because the new entrant would be required to connect a single network 
    element to a facility of its own. The 1996 Act, however, does not 
    impose any limitations on carriers' ability to obtain access to 
    unbundled network elements. Moreover, we conclude that Congress did not 
    intend to limit access to unbundled elements in this manner because 
    such a limit would seriously inhibit the ability of potential 
    competitors to enter local markets through the use of unbundled 
    elements, and thus would retard the development of local exchange 
    competition. We also reject NYNEX's argument that the phrase ``such 
    telecommunications service'' excludes services provided by the 
    incumbent. This interpretation is inconsistent with the 1996 Act's 
    definition of a telecommunications service, which includes all 
    telecommunications services provided by an incumbent.
        233. We also reject the argument that language in the Joint 
    Explanatory Statement requires us to conclude that carriers must own 
    facilities to obtain access to unbundled elements. Congress may have 
    recognized that carriers that own some of their own facilities will 
    more likely benefit by entering local markets through unbundled 
    elements rather than resale, but this consideration does not imply that 
    carriers must own their own facilities to obtain access to unbundled 
    elements.
        234. We are not persuaded that, in order to give meaning and effect 
    to section 251(c)(4), we must require new entrants to own some local 
    exchange facilities in order to obtain access to unbundled elements. We 
    disagree with the premise that no carrier would consider entering local 
    markets under the terms of section 251(c)(4) if it could use recombined 
    network elements solely to offer the same or similar services that 
    incumbents offer for resale. We believe that sections 251(c)(3) and 
    251(c)(4) present different opportunities, risks, and costs in 
    connection with entry into local telephone markets, and that these 
    differences will influence the entry strategies of potential 
    competitors. We therefore find that it is unnecessary to impose a 
    limitation on the ability of carriers to enter local markets under the 
    terms of section 251(c)(3) in order to ensure that section 251(c)(4) 
    retains functional validity as a means to enter local phone markets.
        235. The principal distinction between sections 251(c)(3) and 
    251(c)(4), in terms of the opportunities each section presents to new 
    entrants, is that carriers using solely unbundled elements, compared 
    with carriers purchasing services for resale, will have greater 
    opportunities to offer services that are different from those offered 
    by incumbents. More specifically, carriers reselling incumbent LEC 
    services are limited to offering the same service an incumbent offers 
    at retail. This means that resellers cannot offer services or products 
    that incumbents do not offer. The only means by which a reseller can 
    distinguish the services it offers from those of an incumbent is 
    through price, billing services, marketing efforts, and to some extent, 
    customer service. The ability of a reseller to differentiate its 
    products based on price is limited, however, by the margin between the 
    retail and wholesale price of the product.
        236. In contrast, a carrier offering services solely by recombining 
    unbundled elements can offer services that differ from those offered by 
    an incumbent. For example, some incumbent LECs have capabilities within 
    their networks, such as the ability to offer Centrex, which they do not 
    use to offer services to consumers. Carriers purchasing access to 
    unbundled elements can offer such services. Additionally, carriers 
    using unbundled elements can bundle services that incumbent LECs sell 
    as distinct tariff offerings, as well as services that incumbent LECs 
    have the capability to offer, but do not, and can market them as a 
    bundle with a single price. The ability to package and market services 
    in ways that differ from the incumbent's existing service offerings 
    increases the requesting carrier's ability to compete against the 
    incumbent and is likely to
    
    [[Page 45515]]
    
    benefit consumers. Additionally, carriers solely using unbundled 
    network elements can offer exchange access services. These services, 
    however, are not available for resale under section 251(c)(4) of the 
    1996 Act.
        237. If a carrier taking unbundled elements may have greater 
    competitive opportunities than carriers offering services available for 
    resale, they also face greater risks. A carrier purchasing unbundled 
    elements must pay for the cost of that facility, pursuant to the terms 
    and conditions agreed to in negotiations or ordered by states in 
    arbitrations. It thus faces the risk that end-user customers will not 
    demand a sufficient number of services using that facility for the 
    carrier to recoup its cost. (Many network elements can be used to 
    provide a number of different services.) A carrier that resells an 
    incumbent LEC's services does not face the same risk. This distinction 
    in the risk borne by carriers entering local markets through resale as 
    opposed to unbundled elements is likely to influence the entry 
    strategies of various potential competitors. Some new entrants will be 
    unable or unwilling to bear the financial risks of entry by means of 
    unbundled elements and will choose to enter local markets under the 
    terms of section 251(c)(4) irrespective of the fact that they can 
    obtain access to unbundled elements without owning any of their own 
    facilities. Moreover, some markets may never support new entry through 
    the use of unbundled elements because new entrants seeking to offer 
    services in such markets will be unable to stimulate sufficient demand 
    to recoup their investment in unbundled elements. Accordingly, in these 
    markets carriers will enter through the resale of incumbent LEC 
    services, irrespective of the fact that they could enter exclusively 
    through the use of unbundled elements.
        238. We are not persuaded by the argument set forth by Ameritech, 
    NYNEX, and MFS that allowing carriers to use solely recombined network 
    elements would eviscerate the joint marketing restriction in section 
    271(e)(1). It is true that the terms of section 271(e) do not restrict 
    joint marketing through the use of unbundled elements pursuant to 
    section 251(c)(3). As discussed above, differences in opportunities and 
    risk will cause some new entrants to consider entering local telephone 
    markets through resale of incumbent LEC services, even if they could 
    enter solely through the use of unbundled elements. Thus, we conclude 
    that section 271(e)(1) will impose a meaningful limitation on joint 
    marketing.
        239. We note, moreover, that the 1996 Act does not prohibit all 
    forms of joint marketing. For example, it does not prohibit carriers 
    who own local exchange facilities from jointly marketing local and 
    interexchange service. Nor does it prohibit joint marketing by carriers 
    who provide local exchange service through a combination of local 
    facilities which they own or possess, and unbundled elements. Because 
    the 1996 Act does not prohibit all forms of joint marketing, we see no 
    principled basis for reading into section 271(e)(1) a further 
    limitation on the ability of carriers to jointly market local and long 
    distance services without concluding that this section prohibits all 
    forms of joint marketing. In other words, we see no basis upon which we 
    could conclude that section 271(e)(1) restricts joint marketing of long 
    distance services, and local services provided solely through the use 
    of unbundled network elements, without also concluding that the section 
    restricts the ability of carriers to jointly market long distance 
    services and local services that are provided through a combination of 
    a carriers' own facilities and unbundled network elements. Moreover, we 
    do not believe that we have the discretion to read into the 1996 Act a 
    restriction on competition which is not required by the plain language 
    of any of its sections.
        240. We also reject the argument advanced by BellSouth and 
    Ameritech that allowing carriers to use solely unbundled elements to 
    provide services available through resale would allow carriers to evade 
    a possible prohibition, which is reserved to the discretion of the 
    states, on the sale of certain services to certain categories of 
    consumers. Under section 251(c)(4)(B) states are permitted to restrict 
    resellers from offering certain services to certain consumers, in the 
    same manner that states restrict incumbent LECs. For example, states 
    that prohibit incumbent LECs from selling to business consumers 
    residential services priced below cost have the ability to restrict 
    resellers from selling such services to business consumers.
        241. We do not believe, however, that carriers using solely 
    unbundled elements to provide local exchange services will be able to 
    evade any potential restrictions states may impose under section 
    251(c)(4)(B). In this section Congress granted the states the 
    discretion to impose certain limited restrictions on the sale of 
    services available for resale. It did not, however, grant states, in 
    section 251(c)(3), the same discretion to impose similar restrictions 
    on the use of unbundled elements. Accordingly, we are not persuaded 
    that allowing carriers to use solely unbundled elements to provide 
    services that incumbent LECs offer for resale would allow competing 
    carriers to evade a possible marketing restriction that Congress 
    intended to reserve to the discretion of the states.
        242. We agree with those commenters who argue that it would be 
    administratively impossible to impose a requirement that carriers must 
    own some of their own local exchange facilities in order to obtain 
    access to unbundled elements, and they must use these facilities, in 
    combination with unbundled elements, for the purpose of providing local 
    services. We conclude that it would not be possible to identify the 
    elements carriers must own without creating incentives to build 
    inefficient network architectures that respond not to marketplace 
    factors, but to regulation. We further conclude that such a requirement 
    could delay possible innovation. These effects would diminish 
    competition for local telephone services, and thus any local exchange 
    facilities requirement would be inconsistent with the 1996 Act's goals 
    of promoting competition. Moreover, if we imposed a facilities 
    ownership requirement that attempted to avoid these competitive 
    pitfalls, it would likely be so easy to meet it would ultimately be 
    meaningless.
        243. We reject the argument that requiring carriers to own some 
    local exchange facilities would promote competition for local exchange 
    services, or that we should impose such a requirement for other policy 
    reasons. To the contrary, we conclude that allowing carriers to use 
    unbundled elements as they wish, subject only to the maintenance of the 
    key elements of the access charge regime, described below at section 
    VII, will lead to more efficient competition in local phone markets. If 
    we were to limit access to unbundled network elements to those markets 
    where carriers already own, or could efficiently build, some local 
    exchange facilities, we would limit the ability of carriers to enter 
    local markets under the pricing standard for unbundled elements to 
    those markets that could efficiently support duplication of some or all 
    of the incumbent LECs' networks. We believe that such a result could 
    diminish competition, and that allowing new entrants to take full 
    advantage of incumbent LECs' scale and scope economies will promote 
    more rapid and efficient entry and will result in more robust 
    competition.
        244. Finally, we conclude that a new entrant may offer services to 
    one group of consumers using unbundled network elements, and it may 
    offer services to a
    
    [[Page 45516]]
    
    separate group of consumers by reselling an incumbent LEC's services. 
    With the exception noted in Section VII, infra, we do not address the 
    issue of whether the 1996 Act permits a new entrant to offer services 
    to the same set of consumers through a combination of unbundled 
    elements and services available for resale.
    
    I. Provision of Interexchange Services Through The Use of Unbundled 
    Network Elements
    
    1. Background
        245. In the NPRM, we tentatively concluded that interexchange 
    carriers are telecommunications carriers, and thus such carriers are 
    entitled to access to unbundled elements under the terms of section 
    251(c)(3). We also tentatively concluded that carriers may request 
    unbundled elements for purposes of originating and terminating toll 
    services, in addition to any other services they seek to provide, 
    because section 251(c)(3) provides that carriers may request unbundled 
    elements to provide a ``telecommunications service,'' and interexchange 
    services are a telecommunications service.
        246. In the NPRM, we sought comment on whether the 1996 Act permits 
    carriers to use unbundled elements to provide exchange access services 
    only, or whether carriers seeking to provide exchange access services 
    using unbundled elements must provide local exchange service as well. 
    We premised the latter view on the definition of the term ``network 
    element,'' as a facility and not a service, and on the pricing standard 
    under section 252(d)(1) that requires network elements to be priced 
    based on economic costs (rather than jurisdictionally separated costs.) 
    We also sought comment on whether allowing carriers to purchase 
    unbundled elements to provide exchange access services exclusively 
    would be inconsistent with the terms of sections 251(i) and 251(g) and, 
    further, whether this would result in a fundamental jurisdictional 
    shift of the administration of interstate access charges to state 
    jurisdictions.
        247. Finally, in the NPRM, we tentatively concluded that, if 
    carriers purchase unbundled elements to provide exchange access 
    services to themselves, irrespective of whether they provide such 
    services alone or in connection with local exchange services, incumbent 
    LECs cannot assess Part 69 access charges in addition to charges for 
    the cost of the unbundled elements. We based this tentative conclusion 
    on the view that the imposition of access charges in addition to cost-
    based charges for unbundled elements would depart from the statutory 
    mandate of cost-based pricing of elements.
    2. Discussion
        248. We confirm our tentative conclusion in the NPRM that section 
    251(c)(3) permits interexchange carriers and all other requesting 
    telecommunications carriers, to purchase unbundled elements for the 
    purpose of offering exchange access services, or for the purpose of 
    providing exchange access services to themselves in order to provide 
    interexchange services to consumers. Although we conclude below that we 
    have discretion under the 1934 Act, as amended by the 1996 Act, to 
    adopt a limited, transitional plan to address public policy concerns 
    raised by the bypass of access charges via unbundled elements, we 
    believe that our interpretation of section 251(c)(3) in the NPRM is 
    compelled by the plain language of the 1996 Act. As we observed in the 
    NPRM, section 251(c)(3) provides that requesting telecommunications 
    carriers may seek access to unbundled elements to provide a 
    ``telecommunications service,'' and exchange access and interexchange 
    services are telecommunications services. Moreover, section 251(c)(3) 
    does not impose restrictions on the ability of requesting carriers ``to 
    combine such elements in order to provide such telecommunications 
    service[s].'' Thus, we find that there is no statutory basis upon which 
    we could reach a different conclusion for the long term.
        249. We also confirm our conclusion in the NPRM that, for the 
    reasons discussed below in section V.J, carriers purchase rights to 
    exclusive use of unbundled loop elements, and thus, as the Department 
    of Justice and Sprint observe, such carriers, as a practical matter, 
    will have to provide whatever services are requested by the customers 
    to whom those loops are dedicated. This means, for example, that, if 
    there is a single loop dedicated to the premises of a particular 
    customer and that customer requests both local and long distance 
    service, then any interexchange carrier purchasing access to that 
    customer's loop will have to offer both local and long distance 
    services. That is, interexchange carriers purchasing unbundled loops 
    will most often not be able to provide solely interexchange services 
    over those loops.
        250. We reject the argument advanced by a number of incumbent LECs 
    that section 251(i) demonstrates that requesting carriers using 
    unbundled elements must continue to pay access charges. Section 251(i) 
    provides that nothing in section 251 ``shall be construed to limit or 
    otherwise affect the Commission's authority under section 201.'' We 
    conclude, however, that our authority to set rates for these services 
    is not limited or affected by the ability of carriers to obtain 
    unbundled elements for the purpose of providing interexchange services. 
    Our authority to regulate interstate access charges remains unchanged 
    by the 1996 Act. What has potentially changed is the volume of access 
    services, in contrast to the number of unbundled elements, 
    interexchange carriers are likely to demand and incumbent LECs are 
    likely to provide. When interexchange carriers purchase unbundled 
    elements from incumbents, they are not purchasing exchange access 
    ``services.'' They are purchasing a different product, and that product 
    is the right to exclusive access or use of an entire element. Along 
    this same line of reasoning, we reject the argument that our conclusion 
    would place the administration of interstate access charges under the 
    authority of the states. When states set prices for unbundled elements, 
    they will be setting prices for a different product than ``interstate 
    exchange access services.'' Our exchange access rules remain in effect 
    and will still apply where incumbent LECs retain local customers and 
    continue to offer exchange access services to interexchange carriers 
    who do not purchase unbundled elements, and also where new entrants 
    resell local service. The application of our exchange access rules in 
    the circumstances described will continue beyond the transition period 
    described at infra, Section VII.
        251. We also reject the incumbent LECs' arguments that language 
    contained in bills that were not enacted, or legislative history 
    connected to such bills, demonstrates that carriers cannot purchase 
    access to unbundled elements to provide exchange access services to 
    themselves, for the purpose of providing long distance services to 
    consumers. The incumbent LECs are arguing in effect, that we should 
    read into the current statute a limitation on the ability of carriers 
    to use unbundled network elements, despite the fact that no such 
    limitation survived the Conference Committee's amendments to the 1996 
    Act. We conclude, however, that the language of section 251(c)(3), 
    which provides that telecommunications carriers may purchase unbundled 
    elements in order to provide a telecommunications service is not 
    ambiguous. Accordingly, we must
    
    [[Page 45517]]
    
    interpret it pursuant to its plain meaning and not by referencing 
    earlier versions of the statute that were ultimately not adopted by 
    Congress.
        252. Moreover, we do not believe that the Joint Explanatory 
    Statement, which describes the House and Senate versions of the 
    statute, and the 1996 Act as enacted, compels a different conclusion. 
    The Joint Explanatory Statement states that the statute incorporates 
    provisions from the Senate Bill and the House Amendment in connection 
    with the interconnection model adopted in section 251. It notes that 
    the provision in the Senate Bill relating to interconnection did not 
    apply to interconnection arrangements between local and long distance 
    carriers for the purpose of providing long distance services. The text 
    of section 251 of the Senate Bill is consistent with this comment 
    because it states that a local exchange carrier must offer 
    interconnection to other carriers to allow such carriers to provide 
    telephone exchange or exchange access services. The Joint Explanatory 
    Statement, however, does not describe any restriction in the House 
    Amendment regarding the ability of carriers to use unbundled elements 
    to provide long distance service. Indeed, the House Amendment 
    specifically states that carriers may obtain access to unbundled 
    elements to offer ``a telecommunications service,'' which is not 
    limited to telephone exchange and exchange access services. We observe 
    that the Conference Committee incorporated language from the House 
    Amendment and not the Senate Bill in describing in section 251(c)(3) 
    the services carriers may offer using unbundled elements. Accordingly, 
    we do not believe that the Joint Explanatory Statement's description of 
    the provision in the Senate Bill controls our interpretation of section 
    251(c)(3) as enacted.
        253. We also reject the argument that allowing carriers to use 
    unbundled elements to provide originating and terminating toll services 
    is inconsistent with the purposes of the 1996 Act. Congress intended 
    the 1996 Act to promote competition for not only telephone exchange 
    services and exchange access services, but also for toll services. 
    Section 251(b)(3), for example, imposes a duty on LECs to provide 
    dialing parity for telephone toll service.
        254. We disagree with the incumbent LECs which argue that section 
    251(g) requires requesting carriers using unbundled elements to 
    continue to pay federal and state access charges indefinitely. Section 
    251(g) provides that the federal and state equal access rules 
    applicable before enactment, including the ``receipt of compensation,'' 
    will continue to apply after enactment, ``until such restrictions and 
    obligations are explicitly superseded by regulations prescribed by the 
    Commission after such date of enactment.'' We believe this provision 
    does not apply to the exchange access ``services'' requesting carriers 
    may provide themselves or others after purchasing unbundled elements. 
    Rather, the primary purpose of section 251(g) is to preserve the right 
    of interexchange carriers to order and receive exchange access services 
    if such carriers elect not to obtain exchange access through their own 
    facilities or by means of unbundled elements purchased from an 
    incumbent.
        255. We affirm our tentative conclusion in the NPRM that, 
    telecommunications carriers purchasing unbundled network elements to 
    provide interexchange services or exchange access services are not 
    required to pay federal or state exchange access charges except as 
    described in section VII, infra, for a temporary period. As we 
    explained in the NPRM, if we were to require indefinitely carriers 
    purchasing unbundled elements to also pay access charges, then 
    incumbent LECs would receive compensation in excess of their underlying 
    network costs. This result would be inconsistent with the pricing 
    standard for unbundled elements set forth in section 252(d)(1). In 
    addition, we believe this conclusion is consistent with Congress's 
    overriding goal of promoting efficient competition for local telephony 
    services, because it will allow, in the long term, new entrants using 
    unbundled elements to compete on the basis of the economic costs 
    underlying the incumbent LECs' networks. The facilities used to provide 
    exchange access services are the same as those used to provide local 
    exchange services. We note, however, as discussed below, (see infra, 
    Section VII, discussing an interim mechanism addressing near-term 
    access charge bypass) that certain additional charges are necessary for 
    a specific, limited duration to smooth the transition to a competitive 
    marketplace. We also note that where new entrants purchase access to 
    unbundled network elements to provide exchange access services, whether 
    or not they are also offering toll services through such elements, the 
    new entrants may assess exchange access charges to IXCs originating or 
    terminating toll calls on those elements. In these circumstances, 
    incumbent LECs may not assess exchange access charges to such IXCs 
    because the new entrants, rather than the incumbents, will be providing 
    exchange access services, and to allow otherwise would permit incumbent 
    LECs to receive compensation in excess of network costs in violation of 
    the pricing standard in section 252(d). See 47 U.S.C. Sec. 252. We 
    further note, however, that in these same circumstances the new entrant 
    purchasing access to an unbundled switch element must pay to the 
    incumbent LEC the charges included in the transitional mechanism, 
    described infra, at Section VII, for a temporary period.
        256. We further conclude that when a carrier purchases a local loop 
    for the purpose of providing interexchange services or exchange access 
    services, incumbent LECs may not recover the subscriber line charge 
    (SLC) now paid by end users. (As discussed at infra, Section VIII, a 
    different result will occur when interconnecting carriers purchase LEC 
    retail services at wholesale rates under section 251(c)(4).) The SLC 
    recovers the portion of loop costs allocated to the interstate 
    jurisdiction, but as discussed in Section II.C, supra, we conclude that 
    the 1996 Act creates a new jurisdictional regime outside of the current 
    separations process. The unbundled loop charges paid by new entrants 
    under section 251(c)(3) will therefore recover the unseparated cost of 
    the loop, including the interstate component now recovered through the 
    SLC. If end users or carriers purchasing access to local loops were 
    required to pay the SLC in this situation, LECs would enjoy double 
    recovery, and the effective price of unbundled loops would exceed the 
    cost-based levels required under section 251(d)(1).
        257. Finally, we have considered the economic impact on small 
    incumbent LECs of our conclusion that carriers purchasing access to 
    unbundled network elements to provide interexchange or exchange access 
    services are not required to pay federal or state access charges, 
    except as described in Section VII, infra, for a temporary period. For 
    example, the Rural Telephone Coalition argues that rural ratepayers 
    could be subject to higher local service rates if interexchange 
    carriers are allowed to bypass access charges through the purchase of 
    unbundled elements before proceedings regarding access reform and 
    universal service are completed. We reject the Rural Telephone 
    Coalition's argument, however, because our rules, as discussed in 
    Section VII, infra, provide for a limited, transitional plan to address 
    public policy concerns raised by the bypass of access charges through 
    unbundled network elements.
    
    [[Page 45518]]
    
    J. Specific Unbundling Requirements
    
        258. Having interpreted the standards set forth in the 1996 Act for 
    the unbundling of network elements, we now apply those standards to 
    incumbent LECs' networks. Based on the information developed in this 
    proceeding, we require incumbent LECs to provide unbundled access to 
    local loops, network interface devices, end office and tandem 
    switching, and various interoffice facilities, as described below. 
    These network elements represent a minimum set of elements that must be 
    unbundled by incumbent LECs. State commissions, as previously noted, 
    are free to prescribe additional elements, and parties may agree on 
    different or additional network elements in the voluntary negotiation 
    process.
    1. Local Loops
    (a) Background
        259. In the NPRM, we tentatively concluded that incumbent LECs 
    should be required to unbundle local loops. We sought comment on 
    appropriate requirements for loop unbundling that would promote entry 
    and build upon existing state initiatives, and whether we should adopt 
    specific provisioning requirements for loop unbundling. We also sought 
    comment on our tentative conclusion that incumbent LECs should make 
    available as individual network elements various subloop elements such 
    as the feeder, distribution, and concentration equipment.
    (b) Discussion
        260. We conclude that incumbent LECs must provide local loops on an 
    unbundled basis to requesting carriers. We note that the Joint 
    Explanatory Statement lists local loops as an example of an unbundled 
    network element. As discussed below, the record demonstrates that it is 
    technically feasible for incumbent LECs to provide access to unbundled 
    local loops, and that such access is critical to encouraging market 
    entry. Further, the competitive checklist contained in section 271 
    requires BOCs to offer unbundled loops separate from switching as a 
    precondition to entry into the in-region, interLATA services market.
        261. Requiring incumbent LECs to make available unbundled local 
    loops will facilitate market entry and improve consumer welfare. 
    Without access to unbundled local loops, new entrants would need to 
    invest immediately in duplicative facilities in order to compete for 
    customers. Such investment and building would likely delay market entry 
    and postpone the benefits of local telephone competition for consumers. 
    Moreover, without access to unbundled loops, new entrants would be 
    required to make a large initial sunk investment in loop facilities 
    before they had a customer base large enough to justify such an 
    expenditure. As of year end 1995, Class A carriers reported $268 
    billion of total plant in service, of which $229 billion was classified 
    as network plant. Local loop plant comprises approximately $109 billion 
    of total plant in service, which represents 41 percent of total plant 
    in service and 48 percent of network plant. See 1995 ARMIS Report 43-
    04. This would increase the risk of entry and raise the new entrant's 
    cost of capital. By contrast, the ability of a new entrant to purchase 
    unbundled loops from the incumbent LEC allows the new entrant to build 
    facilities gradually, and to deploy loops for its customers where it is 
    efficient to do so. Moreover, in some areas, the most efficient means 
    of providing competing service may be through the use of unbundled 
    loops. In such cases, preventing access to unbundled loops would either 
    discourage a potential competitor from entering the market in that 
    area, thereby denying those consumers the benefits of competition, or 
    cause the competitor to construct unnecessarily duplicative facilities, 
    thereby misallocating societal resources.
        262. Section 251(c)(3) requires incumbent LECs to provide access to 
    unbundled elements ``at any technically feasible point.'' The vast 
    majority of commenters, including incumbent LECs, agree with our 
    tentative conclusion that it is technically feasible to provide access 
    to unbundled local loops, and a number of commenters identify the main 
    distribution frame in a LEC central office as an appropriate access 
    point. Moreover, access to unbundled loops is currently provided by 
    several LECs pursuant to state unbundling requirements. Thus, we 
    conclude that it is technically feasible for incumbent LECs to provide 
    access to unbundled local loops at, for example, a central office 
    distribution frame.
        263. We further conclude that the local loop element should be 
    defined as a transmission facility between a distribution frame, or its 
    equivalent, in an incumbent LEC central office, and the network 
    interface device at the customer premises. This definition includes, 
    for example, two-wire and four-wire analog voice-grade loops, and two-
    wire and four-wire loops that are conditioned to transmit the digital 
    signals needed to provide services such as ISDN, ADSL, HDSL, and DS1-
    level signals. ISDN (Integrated Services Digital Network) at the Basic 
    Rate Interface level permits the transmission of digital signals over 
    the loop at the rate of 144 kbps, which provides two standard 64 kbps 
    voice or data channels and a 16 kbps data channel. ISDN at the Primary 
    Rate Interface permits 23 standard 64 kbps channels plus one 16 kbps 
    data channel. ADSL (Asynchronous Digital Subscriber Line) is a 
    transmission path that facilitates 6 Mbps digital signal downstream and 
    640 kbps digital signal upstream, while simultaneously carrying an 
    analog voice signal. Two-wire HDSL (High-bit-rate Digital Subscriber 
    Line) permits the transmission of a 768 kbps digital signal over a 
    copper loop, while four-wire HDSL allows the transmission of 1.544 Mbps 
    over two two-wire pairs. We note that a number of parties proposed 
    definitions of the local loop that encompassed some or all of these 
    loop types. In addition, we agree with ITIC that the ability to offer 
    various digital loop functions in competition with incumbent LECs may 
    be particularly beneficial to small entities by allowing them to serve 
    niche markets.
        264. Incumbent LECs are required to provide access to these 
    transmission facilities only to the extent technically feasible. That 
    is, if it is not technically feasible to condition a loop facility to 
    support a particular functionality, the incumbent LEC need not provide 
    unbundled access to that loop so conditioned. For example, a local loop 
    that exceeds the maximum length allowable for the provision of a high-
    bit rate digital service could not feasibly be conditioned for such 
    service. Such loop conditioning may involve removing load coils or 
    bridged taps that interfere with the transmission of digital signals. 
    Such a situation may necessitate a request for subloop elements. 
    Nevertheless, section 251(c)(3) does not limit the types of 
    telecommunications services that competitors may provide over unbundled 
    elements to those offered by the incumbent LEC.
        265. Our definition of loops will in some instances require the 
    incumbent LEC to take affirmative steps to condition existing loop 
    facilities to enable requesting carriers to provide services not 
    currently provided over such facilities. For example, if a competitor 
    seeks to provide a digital loop functionality, such as ADSL, and the 
    loop is not currently conditioned to carry digital signals, but it is 
    technically feasible to condition the facility, the incumbent LEC must 
    condition the loop to permit the transmission of digital signals. Thus, 
    we reject BellSouth's position that requesting carriers ``take the LEC 
    networks as they find them''
    
    [[Page 45519]]
    
    with respect to unbundled network elements. As discussed above, some 
    modification of incumbent LEC facilities, such as loop conditioning, is 
    encompassed within the duty imposed by section 251(c)(3). The 
    requesting carrier would, however, bear the cost of compensating the 
    incumbent LEC for such conditioning.
        266. We further conclude that incumbent LECs must provide 
    competitors with access to unbundled loops regardless of whether the 
    incumbent LEC uses integrated digital loop carrier technology, or 
    similar remote concentration devices, for the particular loop sought by 
    the competitor. IDLC technology allows a carrier to aggregate and 
    multiplex loop traffic at a remote concentration point and to deliver 
    that multiplexed traffic directly into the switch without first 
    demultiplexing the individual loops. If we did not require incumbent 
    LECs to unbundle IDLC-delivered loops, end users served by such 
    technologies would not have the same choice of competing providers as 
    end users served by other loop types. Further, such an exception would 
    encourage incumbent LECs to ``hide'' loops from competitors through the 
    use of IDLC technology.
        267. We find that it is technically feasible to unbundle IDLC-
    delivered loops. One way to unbundle an individual loop from an IDLC is 
    to use a demultiplexer to separate the unbundled loop(s) prior to 
    connecting the remaining loops to the switch. Commenters identify a 
    number of other methods for separating out individual loops from IDLC 
    facilities, including methods that do not require demultiplexing. 
    Again, the costs associated with these mechanisms will be recovered 
    from requesting carriers.
        268. We decline to define a loop element in functional terms, 
    rather than in terms of the facility itself. Some parties advocate 
    defining a loop element as merely a functional piece of a shared 
    facility, similar to capacity purchased on a shared transport trunk. 
    According to these parties, this definition would enable an IXC to 
    purchase a loop element solely for purposes of providing interexchange 
    service. While such a definition, based on the types of traffic 
    provided over a facility, may allow for the separation of costs for a 
    facility dedicated to one end user, we conclude that such treatment is 
    inappropriate. Giving competing providers exclusive control over 
    network facilities dedicated to particular end users provides such 
    carriers the maximum flexibility to offer new services to such end 
    users. In contrast, a definition of a loop element that allows 
    simultaneous access to the loop facility would preclude the provision 
    of certain services in favor of others. For example, carriers wishing 
    to provide solely voice-grade service over a loop would preclude 
    another carrier's provision of a digital service, such as ISDN or ADSL, 
    over that same loop. Digital services such as ISDN and ADSL occupy the 
    same frequency spectrum on a loop as ordinary voice-grade services. We 
    note that these two types of services could be provided by different 
    carriers over, for example, separate two-wire loop elements to the same 
    end user.
        269. Incumbent LECs must provide cross-connect facilities, for 
    example, between an unbundled loop and a requesting carrier's 
    collocated equipment, in order to provide access to that loop. As we 
    conclude in section IV.D, above, an incumbent LEC must take the steps 
    necessary to allow a competitor to combine its own facilities with the 
    incumbent LEC's unbundled network elements. We highlight this 
    requirement for unbundled loops because of allegations by competitive 
    providers that incumbent LECs have imposed unreasonable rates, terms, 
    and conditions for such cross-connect facilities in the past. Incumbent 
    LECs may recover the cost of providing such facilities in accordance 
    with our rules on the costs of interconnection and unbundling. Charges 
    for all such facilities must meet the cost-based standard provided in 
    section 252(d)(1), and the terms and conditions of providing these 
    facilities must be reasonable and nondiscriminatory under section 
    251(c)(3).
        270. At this time, we decline to adopt additional terms and 
    conditions, such as the five-minute loop cutover requirement proposed 
    by MFS, for loop provisioning. We agree with commenters who contend 
    that the provisioning of unbundled local loops must be subject to close 
    scrutiny to ensure that incumbent LECs do not delay loop cutover or 
    otherwise complicate the acquisition of loops by a competitor. We 
    conclude, however, that the rules we adopt in the Access to Unbundled 
    Network Elements section that require nondiscriminatory terms and 
    conditions for provisioning, billing, testing, and repair of unbundled 
    elements, and the availability of electronic ordering systems, 
    adequately address these concerns. We will continue to review and 
    revise our rules in this area as necessary.
        271. Section 251(d)(2)(A) requires the Commission to consider 
    whether ``access to such network elements as are proprietary in nature 
    is necessary.'' Most parties did not identify any proprietary concerns 
    associated with providing unbundled access to local loops. Ericsson 
    notes that some ``active'' loop equipment, such as channel banks and 
    remote terminal equipment, is often proprietary in nature, and that 
    manufacturers would require time to modify such equipment to create 
    end-to-end network compatibility on a national basis. Ericsson does not 
    contend, however, that any proprietary information would be revealed if 
    loops using such equipment were unbundled, or that use of such 
    equipment should prevent loop unbundling in general. Thus, we conclude 
    that loop elements are, in general, not proprietary in nature under our 
    interpretation of section 251(d)(2)(A). Even if loop elements were 
    proprietary in nature, however, Ericsson does not meet the second 
    consideration in our section 251(d)(2)(A) standard, which requires a 
    showing that a new entrant can offer the proposed telecommunications 
    service through the use of other, nonproprietary elements in the 
    incumbent LEC's network. Ericsson merely contends that manufacturers 
    may need time to establish compatibility between its proprietary 
    equipment and equipment of other manufacturers. Therefore, we find that 
    Ericsson's concerns do not justify withholding unbundled loops from 
    requesting carriers pursuant to section 251(d)(2)(A).
        272. Section 251(d)(2)(B) directs the Commission to consider 
    whether ``the failure to provide access to such network elements would 
    impair the ability of the telecommunications carrier seeking access to 
    provide the services that it seeks to offer.'' We have interpreted the 
    term ``impair'' to mean either increased cost or decreased service 
    quality that would result from using network elements of the incumbent 
    LEC other than the one sought. Commenters do not identify alternative 
    facilities that would fulfill requesting carriers' need for 
    transmission between the central office and the customer premises at 
    the same cost and same quality of service. Accordingly, we conclude 
    that competitors' ability to provide telephone exchange, exchange 
    access, or other telecommunications services would be significantly 
    impaired if they did not have the opportunity to purchase unbundled 
    loops from incumbent LECs.
        273. As a general matter, we believe that subloop unbundling could 
    give competitors flexibility in deploying some portions of loop 
    facilities, while relying on the incumbent LEC's facilities where 
    convenient. For example, a competitor may seek to minimize its reliance 
    on the LEC's
    
    [[Page 45520]]
    
    facilities by combining its own feeder plant with the incumbent LEC's 
    distribution plant. In addition, some high bandwidth services, such as 
    ADSL, cannot be provided over long loop lengths. ITIC, Compaq, and 
    Intel assert that subloop unbundling would lead to innovative new data 
    services. In these situations, carriers would need access at points 
    along the loop closer to the customer premises. The record presents 
    evidence primarily of logistical, rather than technical, impediments to 
    subloop unbundling. Several LECs and USTA, for example, assert that 
    incumbent LECs would need to create databases for identifying, 
    provisioning, and billing for subloop elements. Further, incumbent LECs 
    argue that there is insufficient space at certain possible subloop 
    interconnection points. We note that these concerns do not represent 
    ``technical'' considerations under our interpretation of the term 
    ``technically feasible.''
        274. Nonetheless, we decline at this time to identify the feeder, 
    feeder/distribution interface (FDI), and distribution components of the 
    loop as individual network elements. We find that proponents of subloop 
    unbundling do not address certain technical issues raised by incumbent 
    LECs concerning subloop unbundling. Incumbent LECs contend that access 
    by a competitor's personnel to loop equipment necessary to provide 
    subloop elements, such as the FDI, raise network reliability concerns 
    for customers served through that FDI. SBC, for example, asserts that 
    access to its loop concentration points by competitors would increase 
    the risk of error by a competitor's technicians that may disrupt 
    service to customers of one or both carriers. U S West contends that 
    the potential for poor technical implementation of subloop 
    interconnection and the lack of overall responsibility for loop 
    performance is very likely to degrade overall service quality. 
    Proponents of subloop unbundling do not adequately respond to these 
    arguments by incumbent LECs. As discussed above, we have determined 
    that we must take into account specific, demonstrable claims regarding 
    network reliability in determining whether to identify any particular 
    component as an element that must be unbundled. Therefore, we believe 
    that, at this stage, based on the current record evidence, the 
    technical feasibility of subloop unbundling is best addressed at the 
    state level on a case-by-case basis at this time. We encourage states 
    to pursue subloop unbundling in response to requests for subloop 
    elements by competing providers. Information developed by the parties 
    in the context of a specific request for subloop unbundling will 
    provide a useful framework for addressing the loop maintenance and 
    network reliability matters that we have identified. Based on actions 
    taken by the states or other future developments, and on the importance 
    of subloop unbundling in light of technological advancements, we intend 
    to revisit the specific issue of subloop unbundling sometime in 1997.
        275. We require incumbent LECs to offer unbundled access to the 
    network interface device (NID), as a network element, as described 
    below. The NID is a cross-connect device used to connect loop 
    facilities to inside wiring. When a competitor deploys its own loops, 
    the competitor must be able to connect its loops to customers' inside 
    wiring in order to provide competing service, especially in multi-
    tenant buildings. In many cases, inside wiring is connected to the 
    incumbent LEC's loop plant at the NID. In order to provide service, a 
    competitor must have access to this facility. Therefore, we conclude 
    that a requesting carrier is entitled to connect its loops, via its own 
    NID, to the incumbent LEC's NID.
        276. Pursuant to section 251(c)(3), we find that this arrangement 
    clearly is technically feasible. Ameritech notes that it currently 
    maintains such connections with competitors that have deployed their 
    own loop facilities. This is persuasive evidence that unbundled access 
    at the NID, in this manner, does not raise network reliability 
    concerns. Under section 251(d)(2)(A), the record contains no evidence 
    of proprietary concerns with unbundled access to the NID. In addition, 
    under our interpretation of the ``impair'' test of section 
    251(d)(2)(B), commenters do not contend that new entrants could obtain 
    the same functionality at the same cost and service quality through 
    other network elements of the incumbent LEC. Moreover, the record 
    indicates that certain network architectures used by new entrants, such 
    as fiber rings, can most efficiently connect end users to the new 
    entrant's switching office without use of the incumbent LEC's 
    facilities. Thus, we conclude that the unavailability of access to 
    incumbent LECs' NIDs would impair the ability of carriers deploying 
    their own loops to provide service. Further, we believe that unbundled 
    access to the NID will facilitate entry strategies premised on the 
    deployment of loops. As discussed in section VII, above, the new 
    entrant bears the costs connecting its NID to the incumbent LEC's NID.
        277. We do not require an incumbent LEC to permit a new entrant to 
    connect its loops directly to the incumbent LEC's NID. MCI contends 
    that directly connecting its loops to incumbent LEC's NIDs is ``[t]he 
    only practical solution'' for gaining access to inside wiring. 
    According to MCI, there is no extra wiring to connect the incumbent 
    LEC's NID to the new entrant's NID. Ameritech demonstrates, however, 
    that it currently provides access to inside wiring through the type of 
    arrangement that MCI asserts is not practical--that is, by connecting a 
    new entrant's loops to inside wiring via the new entrant's NID and 
    Ameritech's NID. MCI does not demonstrate that its ability to provide 
    competing service is unreasonably limited by the arrangements explained 
    by Ameritech.
        278. The record contains conflicting evidence on the technical 
    feasibility of requiring incumbent LECs to permit competitors to 
    connect their loops directly to incumbent LECs' NIDs. Ameritech asserts 
    that such a direct connection would leave Ameritech's unused loops 
    without overvoltage protection. MCI argues that overvoltage protection 
    is provided through the incumbent LEC's ``protector module'' that is 
    separate from the NID. Ameritech responds that its NIDs are integrated 
    units providing both overvoltage protection and a demarcation point, 
    and that these two functions of the NID are ``inseverable.'' AT&T 
    contends direct access to incumbent LECs NIDs is technically feasible. 
    According to AT&T, if a competitor connects its loops directly to the 
    incumbent LEC's NID, the incumbent LEC's loops remain connected to the 
    grounding equipment that protects against overvoltage. According to 
    AT&T, when the competitor does not use spare terminals on the NID, the 
    competitor would be required to ground the incumbent LEC's unused loops 
    to protect against overvoltage.
        279. We find that the record in this proceeding does not permit a 
    determination on the technical feasibility of the direct connection of 
    a competitor's loops to the incumbent LEC's NID. Our requirement of a 
    NID-to-NID connection addresses the most critical need of competitors 
    that deploy their own loops--obtaining access to the inside wiring of 
    the building. We recognize, however, that competitors may benefit by 
    directly connecting their loops to the incumbent LEC's NID, for 
    example, by avoiding the cost of deploying NIDs. States should 
    determine whether direct connection to the NID can be achieved in a 
    technically feasible manner in the context of
    
    [[Page 45521]]
    
    specific requests by competitors for direct access to incumbent LECs' 
    NIDs.
    2. Switching
    (a) Background
        280. In the NPRM, we tentatively concluded that incumbent LECs 
    should be required to make available local switching capability as an 
    unbundled network element. We sought comment on how a local switching 
    element should be defined, and we identified two possible models: the 
    switch ``platform'' approach, which would entitle and require a 
    requesting carrier to purchase all of the features and functions of the 
    switch on a per-line basis and the port approach used by the New York 
    Commission, which offers local switching capability through the 
    purchase of a port at a retail rate. We also sought comment on other 
    definitions of a local switching element. In addition, we requested 
    that commenters address whether vertical switching functions, such as 
    those enabling the provision of custom local area signaling service 
    (CLASS) features and call waiting, should be considered individual 
    network elements separate from the basic switching functionality.
    (b) Discussion
    (i) Local Switching
        281. We conclude that incumbent LECs must provide local switching 
    as an unbundled network element. The record supports a finding that it 
    is technically feasible for incumbent LECs to provide access to an 
    unbundled local switching element, and that denying access to a local 
    switching element would substantially impair the ability of many 
    competing carriers to provide switched telecommunications services. We 
    also note that section 271 requires BOCs to offer or provide ``[l]ocal 
    switching unbundled from transport, local loop transmission, or other 
    services'' as a precondition to providing in-region interLATA services. 
    As discussed below, we identify a local switching element that includes 
    the basic function of connecting lines and trunks as well as vertical 
    switching features, such as custom calling and CLASS features. We agree 
    with the Illinois Commission that defining the switching element in 
    this way will permit competitors to compete more effectively by 
    designing new packages and pricing plans.
        282. In the United States, there are over 23,000 central office 
    switches, the vast majority of which are operated by incumbent LECs. It 
    is unlikely that consumers would receive the benefits of competition 
    quickly if new entrants were required to replicate even a small 
    percentage of incumbent LECs' existing switches prior to entering the 
    market. The Illinois Commission staff presented evidence in a recent 
    proceeding indicating that it takes between nine months and two years 
    for a carrier to purchase and install a switch. We find this to be 
    persuasive evidence of the entry barrier that would be created if new 
    entrants were unable to obtain unbundled local switching from the 
    incumbent LEC. The ability to purchase unbundled switching will also 
    promote competition in an area until the new entrant has built up a 
    sufficient customer base to justify investing in its own switch. We 
    expect that the availability of unbundled local switching is likely to 
    increase the number of carriers that will successfully enter the 
    market, and thus should accelerate the development of local 
    competition.
        283. We define the local switching element to encompass line-side 
    and trunk-side facilities plus the features, functions, and 
    capabilities of the switch. The NPRM used the terms ``switch platform'' 
    and ``port,'' as they had been developed by the Illinois and New York 
    Commissions, respectively, to describe two possible approaches to 
    establishing an unbundled local switching element. Parties commenting 
    on the unbundled switching element attributed a variety of 
    functionalities to each of these terms. To avoid confusion, we will not 
    use these terms in discussing the unbundled local switching element. 
    Instead, we will address commenters' proposals according to the 
    functionality that they recommend be included in the definition of an 
    unbundled local switching element. The line-side facilities include the 
    connection between a loop termination at, for example, a main 
    distribution frame (MDF), and a switch line card. Trunk-side facilities 
    include the connection between, for example, trunk termination at a 
    trunk-side cross-connect panel and a trunk card. The ``features, 
    functions, and capabilities'' of the local switch include the basic 
    switching function of connecting lines to lines, lines to trunks, 
    trunks to lines, trunks to trunks. It also includes the same basic 
    capabilities that are available to the incumbent LEC's customers, such 
    as a telephone number, directory listing, dial tone, signaling, and 
    access to 911, operator services, and directory assistance. Purchasing 
    the local switching element does not entitle a requesting carrier to 
    connect its own AIN call processing database to the incumbent LEC's 
    switch, either directly or via the incumbent LEC's signal transfer 
    point or database. Section V.I.4, which discusses the unbundling of 
    incumbent LECs' signaling systems and databases. We also note that E911 
    and operator services are further unbundled from local switching. In 
    addition, the local switching element includes all vertical features 
    that the switch is capable of providing, including custom calling, 
    CLASS features, and Centrex, as well as any technically feasible 
    customized routing functions. Thus, when a requesting carrier purchases 
    the unbundled local switching element, it obtains all switching 
    features in a single element on a per-line basis. A requesting carrier 
    will deploy individual vertical features on its customers' lines by 
    designating, via an electronic ordering interface, which features the 
    incumbent LEC is to activate for particular customer lines.
        284. We disagree with commenters who argue that vertical switching 
    features should be classified exclusively as retail services, available 
    to competing providers only through the resale provision of section 
    251(c)(4). The 1996 Act defines network element as ``a facility or 
    equipment used in the provision of a telecommunications service'' and 
    ``the features, functions, and capabilities that are provided by means 
    of such facility or equipment.'' Vertical switching features, such as 
    call waiting, are provided through operation of hardware and software 
    comprising the ``facility'' that is the switch, and thus are 
    ``features'' and ``functions'' of the switch. In some cases vertical 
    features may be provided using hardware and software external to the 
    actual switch. In those instances, the functionality of such external 
    hardware and software is a separate element under section 251(c)(3), 
    and is available to competing providers. We note that the Illinois 
    Commission recently defined an unbundled local switching element to 
    include vertical switching features. Although we find that vertical 
    switching features should be available to competitors through the 
    resale provision of section 251(c)(4), we reject the view that Congress 
    intended for section 251(c)(4) implicitly to remove vertical switching 
    features from the definition of ``network element.'' Therefore, we find 
    that vertical switching features are part of the unbundled local 
    switching element.
        285. At this time we decline to require further unbundling of the 
    local switch into a basic switching element and independent vertical 
    feature elements. Such unbundling does not appear to be necessary to 
    promote local competition. Indeed, most potential local competitors do 
    not recommend that vertical switching features be available as
    
    [[Page 45522]]
    
    separate network elements. MCI, AT&T and LDDS believe that such 
    features should be available to new entrants as part of the local 
    switch element. We also note that additional unbundling of the local 
    switching would not result in a practical difference in the way the 
    local switching element is provisioned. As discussed below, when a 
    competing provider orders the unbundled basic switching element for a 
    particular customer line, it will designate which vertical features 
    should be activated by the incumbent LEC for that line. In addition, 
    the record indicates that the incremental costs associated with 
    vertical switching features on a per-line basis may be quite small, and 
    may not justify the administrative difficulty for the incumbent LEC or 
    the arbitrator to determine a price for each vertical element. Thus, 
    states can investigate, in arbitration or other proceedings, whether 
    vertical switching features should be made available as separate 
    network elements. We will continue to review and revise our rules in 
    this area as necessary.
        286. We conclude that providing access to an unbundled local 
    switching element at a LEC central office is technically feasible. We 
    are not persuaded by the argument that shared use of an unbundled 
    switching element would jeopardize network security and reliability by 
    permitting competitors independently to activate and deactivate various 
    switching features. A competing provider will purchase and obtain the 
    local switching element the same way it obtains an unbundled local 
    loop, that is, by ordering, via electronic interfaces, the local 
    switching element and particular vertical switching features. The 
    incumbent LEC will receive the order and activate (or deactivate) the 
    particular features on the customer line designated by the competing 
    provider. Consequently, the incumbent LEC is not required to relinquish 
    control over operations of the switch.
        287. We also reject the argument that a definition of local 
    switching that incorporates shared use of a local switch would involve 
    physical partitioning of the switch. The requirements we establish for 
    local switch unbundling do not entail physical division of the switch, 
    and consequently do not impose the inefficiency or technical 
    difficulties identified by some commenters.
        288. Nor are we persuaded by the arguments of some incumbent LECs 
    that an unbundled switching element based on shared use of the local 
    switch is technically infeasible because incumbent LECs lack 
    significant excess capacity at any given time. Initially, many requests 
    for local switching elements from competitors will likely result from 
    the loss of customers by the incumbent LEC. Thus, at least initially, 
    an increase in the use of the local switch element by the requesting 
    carrier is not likely to lead to an enormous, immediate increase in 
    switch use overall. If incumbent LECs and competing providers believe 
    that they would benefit by quantifying their anticipated demand for 
    switch resources, they are free to do so in the negotiation and 
    arbitration processes. Such planning may be necessary when a competitor 
    anticipates that usage of the local switching element by its customers 
    will place demands on the incumbent LEC's switch that exceed the usage 
    levels anticipated by the incumbent LEC.
        289. We conclude that customized routing, which permits requesting 
    carriers to designate the particular outgoing trunks that will carry 
    certain classes of traffic originating from the competing provider's 
    customers, is technically feasible in many LEC switches. Customized 
    routing will enable a competitor to direct particular classes of calls 
    to particular outgoing trunks, which will permit a new entrant to self-
    provide, or select among other providers of, interoffice facilities, 
    operator services, and directory assistance. In addition, we note that 
    the Illinois Commission recently directed Ameritech and Centel to 
    permit a carrier purchasing wholesale local exchange service to 
    designate a provider of operator services and directory assistance 
    other than that of the incumbent LEC. Such access is accomplished 
    through the routing of such calls from the incumbent LEC's switch to 
    the competing provider of the operator service or directory assistance. 
    Bell Atlantic notes that customized routing is generally technically 
    feasible for local calling, although it notes that the technology and 
    capacity constraints vary from switch to switch. SBC contends that 
    customized routing is technically infeasible for older switches, such 
    as the 1AESS switch. AT&T acknowledges that, although the ability to 
    establish customized routing in 1AESS switches may be affected by the 
    ``call load'' in each office, only 9.8% of the switches used by the 
    seven RBOCs, GTE and SNET are 1AESS switches. We recognize that the 
    ability of an incumbent LEC to provide customized routing to a 
    requesting carrier will depend on the capability of the particular 
    switch in question. Thus, our requirement that incumbent LECs provide 
    customized routing as part of the ``functionality'' of the local 
    switching element applies, by definition, only to those switches that 
    are capable of performing customized routing. An incumbent LEC must 
    prove to the state commission that customized routing in a particular 
    switch is not technically feasible.
        290. Section 251(d)(2)(A) requires the Commission, in determining 
    which network elements should be made available to competing providers, 
    to consider ``whether access to such network elements as are 
    proprietary in nature is necessary.'' To withhold a proposed network 
    element from a competing provider, an incumbent LEC must demonstrate 
    that the element is proprietary and that gaining access to that element 
    is not necessary because the competing provider can use other, 
    nonproprietary elements in the incumbent LEC's network to provide 
    service. U S West asserts that switch unbundling could raise concerns 
    involving, among other things, ``licensing of intellectual property.'' 
    It cites a request by one interconnector to be the exclusive provider 
    of particular features in U S West's generic switching software. Bell 
    Atlantic states that it is not at liberty to sub-license the software 
    that operates vertical switching features. We note, however, that these 
    incumbent LECs do not object to providing vertical switching 
    functionalities to requesting carriers under the resale provision of 
    section 251(c)(4). In addition, the vast majority of parties that 
    discuss unbundled local switching do not raise proprietary concerns 
    with the unbundling of either basic local switching or vertical 
    switching features. Even if we accept the claim of U S West and Bell 
    Atlantic that vertical features are proprietary in nature, these 
    carriers do not meet the second consideration in our section 
    251(d)(2)(A) standard, which requires an incumbent LEC to show that a 
    new entrant could offer the proposed telecommunications service through 
    the use of other, nonproprietary elements in the incumbent LEC's 
    network. Accordingly, we find that access to unbundled local switching 
    is clearly ``necessary'' under our interpretation of section 
    251(d)(2)(A).
        291. Section 251(d)(2)(B) directs the Commission to consider 
    whether the failure to provide access to an unbundled element ``would 
    impair the ability of the telecommunications carrier seeking access to 
    provide the services that it seeks to offer.'' We have interpreted the 
    term ``impair'' to mean either increased cost or decreased service 
    quality that would result from using network elements of the incumbent 
    LEC other than the one sought. SBC and MFS contend that
    
    [[Page 45523]]
    
    access to unbundled local switching may not be essential for new 
    entrants because competitors are likely to deploy their own switches. 
    These parties present no evidence that competitors could provide 
    service using another element in the LEC's network at the same cost and 
    at the same level of quality. In addition, most commenters that address 
    this issue generally argue that local switching is essential for the 
    provision of competing local service, and we agree. We thus conclude 
    that a requesting carrier's ability to offer local exchange services 
    would be impaired, if not thwarted, without access to an unbundled 
    local switching element.
        292. Section 251(c)(3) requires that incumbent LECs provide access 
    to unbundled network elements on terms and conditions that are ``just, 
    reasonable, and nondiscriminatory.'' We agree with CompTel and LDDS 
    that new entrants will be disadvantaged if customer switchover is not 
    rapid and transparent. We also note that the Michigan Commission has 
    recognized the significance of customer switchover intervals and has 
    directed Ameritech and GTE to file proposals on how they will ``ensure 
    the equal availability of expeditious processing of local, interLATA, 
    and intraLATA carrier changes.'' Therefore, we require incumbent LECs 
    to switch over customers for local service in the same interval as LECs 
    currently switch end users between interexchange carriers. This 
    requirement applies to switchovers that only require the incumbent LEC 
    to make changes to software. Switchovers that require the incumbent LEC 
    to make physical modifications to its network, such as connecting a 
    competitor's loop to its switch, are not subject to this requirement, 
    and instead are governed by our terms and conditions for all unbundled 
    elements. Today, incumbent LECs routinely change customers' 
    presubscribed interexchange carriers quickly and transparently, thereby 
    contributing to the competitiveness of the interexchange market. We 
    expect that a similar requirement for local exchange switchovers that 
    require only a software change will similarly contribute to local 
    exchange competition.
        293. We reject the proposal by some incumbent LECs to define 
    unbundled local switching as the facilities that provide a point of 
    access to the switch, but that would not actually include switching 
    functionality. Under this definition, the purchaser of the local 
    switching element would not actually obtain local switching, only the 
    right to purchase local switching functionality and other switching 
    features at wholesale rates. We believe that the unbundled local 
    switching element must include the functionality of connecting lines 
    and trunks. The definition proposed by these incumbent LECs would 
    contravene the requirement in section 251(c)(3) that incumbent LECs 
    provide network elements ``in a manner that allows requesting carriers 
    to combine such elements in order to provide such telecommunications 
    service.'' If a competing provider combined its own loops and transport 
    with the local switching element (``point of access''), it would be 
    unable to provide telecommunications service without separately 
    purchasing, at wholesale rates, switching functionality from the 
    incumbent LEC.
        294. We also disagree with the proposal to define local switching 
    as a point of access plus basic switching functionality, but that would 
    exclude vertical switching features. As a legal matter, this definition 
    is inconsistent with the 1996 Act's definition of ``network element,'' 
    which includes all the ``features, functionalities, and capabilities 
    provided by means of such facility or equipment.'' In addition, this 
    definition would not fulfill the pro-competitive objectives of the 1996 
    Act as effectively as the per-line definition we adopt. A competitor 
    that obtains basic and vertical switching features at cost-based rates 
    will have maximum flexibility to distinguish its offerings from those 
    of the incumbent LEC by developing a variety of service packages and 
    pricing plans. Moreover, an upfront purchase of all local switching 
    features may speed entry by simplifying practical issues such as the 
    pricing of individual switching features.
        295. We also address the impact on small incumbent LECs. For 
    example, the Illinois Independent Telephone Association and the Rural 
    Telephone Coalition favor rules that recognize the differences between 
    larger and smaller LECs. We have considered the economic impact of our 
    rules in this section on small incumbent LECs. In this section, for 
    example, we expressly provide for the fact that certain LECs may 
    possess switches that are incapable of performing customized routing 
    for competitors that purchase unbundled local switching. As noted by 
    Rural Telephone Coalition and the Illinois Independent Telephone 
    Coalition, this approach is necessary to accommodate the different 
    technical capabilities of large and small carriers. We also note that 
    section 251(f) of the 1996 Act provides relief for certain small LECs 
    from our regulations under section 251.
    (ii) Tandem Switching
        296. We also affirm our tentative conclusion in the NPRM that it is 
    technically feasible for incumbent LECs to provide access to their 
    tandem switches unbundled from interoffice transmission facilities. We 
    note that some states already have required incumbent LECs to unbundle 
    tandem switching. Parties do not contend, pursuant to section 
    251(d)(2)(A), that tandem switches are proprietary in nature. With 
    regard to section 251(d)(2)(B), we find that competitors' ability to 
    provide telecommunications service would be impaired without unbundled 
    access to tandem switching. Therefore, we find that the availability of 
    unbundled tandem switching will ensure that competitors can deploy 
    their own interoffice facilities and connect them to incumbent LECs' 
    tandem switches where it is efficient to do so.
        297. We define the tandem switch element as including the 
    facilities connecting the trunk distribution frames to the switch, and 
    all the functions of the switch itself, including those facilities that 
    establish a temporary transmission path between two other switches. The 
    definition of the tandem switching element also includes the functions 
    that are centralized in tandems rather than in separate end office 
    switches, such as call recording, the routing of calls to operator 
    services, and signaling conversion functions.
    (iii) Packet Switching
        298. At this time, we decline to find, as requested by AT&T and 
    MCI, that incumbent LECs' packet switches should be identified as 
    network elements. Because so few parties commented on the packet 
    switches in connection with section 251(c)(3), the record is 
    insufficient for us to decide whether packet switches should be defined 
    as a separate network element. We will continue to review and revise 
    our rules, but at present, we do not adopt a national rule for the 
    unbundling of packet switches.
    3. Interoffice Transmission Facilities
    (a) Background
        299. In the NPRM, we proposed to require incumbent LECs to make 
    available unbundled transport facilities in a manner that corresponds 
    to the rate structure for interstate transport charges. We specifically 
    proposed to require unbundled access to links between the end office 
    and the serving wire center (SWC), the SWC and the IXC point of 
    presence (POP), the end office and the tandem switch, and the tandem 
    switch and the SWC. We also tentatively
    
    [[Page 45524]]
    
    concluded that incumbent LECs should be required to unbundle channel 
    termination facilities for special access from the interoffice 
    facilities. In addition, we requested comment on whether and how other 
    interoffice facilities used by incumbent LECs should be unbundled.
    (b) Discussion
        300. We conclude that incumbent LECs must provide interoffice 
    transmission facilities on an unbundled basis to requesting carriers. 
    The record supports our conclusion that such access is technically 
    feasible and would promote competition in the local exchange market. We 
    note that the 1996 Act requires BOCs to unbundle transport facilities 
    prior to entering the in-region, interLATA market.
        301. We require incumbent LECs to provide unbundled access to 
    shared transmission facilities between end offices and the tandem 
    switch. Further, incumbent LECs must provide unbundled access to 
    dedicated transmission facilities between LEC central offices or 
    between such offices and those of competing carriers. This includes, at 
    a minimum, interoffice facilities between end offices and serving wire 
    centers (SWCs), SWCs and IXC POPs, tandem switches and SWCs, end 
    offices or tandems of the incumbent LEC, and the wire centers of 
    incumbent LECs and requesting carriers. The incumbent LEC must also 
    provide, to the extent discussed below, all technically feasible 
    transmission capabilities, such as DS1, DS3, and Optical Carrier levels 
    (e.g. OC-3/12/48/96) that the competing provider could use to provide 
    telecommunications services. We conclude that an incumbent LEC may not 
    limit the facilities to which such interoffice facilities are 
    connected, provided such interconnection is technically feasible, or 
    the use of such facilities. In general, this means that incumbent LECs 
    must provide interoffice facilities between wire centers owned by 
    incumbent LECs or requesting carriers, or between switches owned by 
    incumbent LECs or requesting carriers. For example, an interoffice 
    facility could be used by a competitor to connect to the incumbent 
    LEC's switch or to the competitor's collocated equipment. We agree with 
    the Texas Commission that a competitor should have the ability to use 
    interoffice transmission facilities to connect loops directly to its 
    switch. We anticipate that these requirements will reduce entry 
    barriers into the local exchange market by enabling new entrants to 
    establish efficient local networks by combining their own interoffice 
    facilities with those of the incumbent LEC.
        302. The ability of new entrants to purchase the interoffice 
    facilities we have identified will increase the speed with which 
    competitors enter the market. By unbundling various dedicated and 
    shared interoffice facilities, a new entrant can purchase all 
    interoffice facilities on an unbundled basis as part of a competing 
    local network, or it can combine its own interoffice facilities with 
    those of the incumbent LEC. The opportunity to purchase unbundled 
    interoffice facilities will decrease the cost of entry compared to the 
    much higher cost that would be incurred by an entrant that had to 
    construct all of its own facilities. An efficient new entrant might not 
    be able to compete if it were required to build interoffice facilities 
    where it would be more efficient to use the incumbent LEC's facilities. 
    We recognize that there are alternative suppliers of interoffice 
    facilities in certain areas. We are convinced, however, that entry will 
    be facilitated if competitors have greater, not fewer, options for 
    procuring interoffice facilities as part of their local networks, and 
    that Congress intended for competitors to have these options available 
    from competitors. Thus, the rules we establish for the unbundled 
    interoffice facilities should maximize a competitor's flexibility to 
    use new technologies in combination with existing LEC facilities.
        303. We find that it is technically feasible for incumbent LECs to 
    unbundle the foregoing interoffice facilities as individual network 
    elements. The interconnection and unbundling arrangements among the 
    larger LECs, IXCs, and CAPs that resulted from our Expanded 
    Interconnection rules confirm the technical feasibility of unbundling 
    interoffice facilities used by incumbent LECs to provide special access 
    and switched transport. As AT&T and Telecommunications Resellers 
    Association point out, IXCs currently interconnect with incumbent LECs' 
    transport facilities pursuant to standard specifications. We also note 
    that commenters do not identify technical feasibility problems with 
    unbundling interoffice facilities.
        304. We also find that it is technically feasible for incumbent 
    LECs to unbundle certain interoffice facilities not addressed in our 
    Expanded Interconnection proceeding. First, we conclude that an 
    incumbent LEC must provide unbundled access to interoffice facilities 
    between its end offices, and between any of its switching offices and a 
    new entrant's switching office, where such interoffice facilities 
    exist. This allows a new entrant to purchase unbundled facilities 
    between two end offices of the incumbent LEC, or between the new 
    entrant's switching office and the incumbent LEC's switching office. 
    Although our Expanded Interconnection rules did not specifically 
    require incumbent LECs to unbundle these facilities, commenters do not 
    identify any potential technical problem with such unbundling. 
    Moreover, some LECs already offer unbundled dedicated interoffice 
    facilities, for example, between their end offices and SWCs for 
    exchange access.
        305. In addition, as a condition of offering unbundled interoffice 
    facilities, we require incumbent LECs to provide requesting carriers 
    with access to digital cross-connect system (DCS) functionality. A DCS 
    aggregates and disaggregates high-speed traffic carried between IXCs' 
    POPs and incumbent LECs' switching offices, thereby facilitating the 
    use of cost-efficient, high-speed interoffice facilities. AT&T notes 
    that the BOCs, GTE, and other large LECs currently make DCS 
    capabilities available for the termination of interexchange traffic. We 
    find that the use of DCS functionality could facilitate competitors' 
    deployment of high-speed interoffice facilities between their own 
    networks and LECs' switching offices. Therefore, we require incumbent 
    LECs to offer DCS capabilities in the same manner that they offer such 
    capabilities to IXCs that purchase transport services.
        306. We disagree with PacTel's assertion that it is not technically 
    feasible for incumbent LECs to provide DCS functionality to competitors 
    that purchase unbundled interoffice facilities. First, contrary to 
    PacTel's assertion, we do not require incumbent LECs to develop new 
    arrangements for the offering of DCS capabilities to competitors. We 
    only require that DCS capabilities be made available to competitors to 
    the extent incumbent LECs offer such capabilities to IXCs. Second, 
    PacTel suggests the provision of DCS capabilities requires physical 
    partitioning of the DCS equipment in order to prevent carriers from 
    gaining control of each other's traffic. We do not require such 
    partitioning for the provision of DCS capabilities. As noted above, we 
    only require incumbent LECs to permit competitors to use DCS 
    functionality in the same manner that incumbent LECs now permit IXCs to 
    use such functionality.
        307. Section 251(d)(2)(A) requires the Commission to consider 
    whether ``access to such network elements as are
    
    [[Page 45525]]
    
    proprietary in nature is necessary.'' Commenters do not identify any 
    proprietary concerns relating to the provision of interoffice 
    facilities that LECs are required to unbundle. We also note that many 
    of these facilities are also currently offered on an unbundled basis to 
    competing carriers. Therefore, the record provides no basis for 
    withholding these facilities from competitors based on proprietary 
    considerations.
        308. Section 251(d)(2)(B) requires the Commission to consider 
    whether the failure to provide access to an unbundled element ``would 
    impair the ability of the telecommunications carrier seeking access to 
    provide the services that it seeks to offer.'' We have interpreted the 
    term ``impair'' to mean either increased cost or decreased service 
    quality that would result from using network elements other than the 
    one sought. Certain commenters contend that unbundled access to these 
    facilities would improve their ability to provide competitive local 
    exchange and exchange access service. MCI, for example, argues that its 
    inability to obtain unbundled access to trunks between an incumbent 
    LEC's end offices raises its cost of providing local service. 
    Accordingly, we conclude that the section 251(d)(2)(B) requires 
    incumbent LECs to provide access to shared interoffice facilities and 
    dedicated interoffice facilities between the above-identified points in 
    incumbent LECs' networks, including facilities between incumbent LECs' 
    end offices, new entrant's switching offices and LEC switching offices, 
    and DCSs. We believe that access to these interoffice facilities will 
    improve competitors' ability to design efficient network architecture, 
    and in particular, to combine their own switching functionality with 
    the incumbent LEC's unbundled loops.
        309. We reject Cincinnati Bell's argument that existing tariffs for 
    transport and special access services filed pursuant to our Expanded 
    Interconnection rules fulfill our obligation to implement the 
    requirements of section 251(c). First, the Expanded Interconnection 
    rules require the unbundling of interstate transport services only by 
    Class A carriers whereas section 251(c) requires network unbundling by 
    all incumbent LECs, except for carriers that are exempt under section 
    251(f) from our interconnection rules. Consequently, some non-Class A 
    carriers that were not subject to our Expanded Interconnection 
    requirements will be required to comply with the requirements of this 
    Order. Second, we find that the Class A carriers' existing tariffs for 
    unbundled transport elements do not satisfy the unbundling requirement 
    of section 251(c), as suggested by Cincinnati Bell, because such 
    tariffs are only for interstate access services, not for unbundled 
    interoffice facilities. As such, existing federal tariffs for transport 
    and special access exclude intrastate transport, and therefore are not 
    equivalent to unbundled interoffice facilities, which we have 
    determined to be nonjurisdicational in nature.
        310. We also disagree with MECA, GTE, and Ameritech that we should 
    consider ``pricing distortions'' in adopting rules for unbundled 
    interoffice facilities. Section, below, addresses the pricing of 
    unbundled network elements identified pursuant to section 251(c)(3) as 
    it relates to our current access charge rules. Nor are we are persuaded 
    by MECA's argument that incumbent LECs not subject to the MFJ should 
    not be required to unbundle transport facilities because, according to 
    MECA, such facilities are unnecessary for local competition. As 
    discussed above, the ability of a new entrant to obtain unbundled 
    access to incumbent LECs' interoffice facilities, including those 
    facilities that carry interLATA traffic, is essential to that 
    competitor's ability to provide competing telephone service.
        311. We do not impose specific terms and conditions for the 
    provision of unbundled interoffice facilities. We believe that the 
    rules we establish in this Order for all unbundled network elements 
    adequately address ALTS's concern regarding the provisioning, billing, 
    and maintenance of unbundled transport facilities. We also decline at 
    this time to address the unbundling of incumbent LECs' ``dark fiber.'' 
    Parties that address this issue do not provide us with information on 
    whether dark fiber qualifies as a network element under sections 
    251(c)(3) and 251(d)(2). Therefore, we lack a sufficient record on 
    which to decide this issue. We will continue to review and revise our 
    rules in this area as necessary.
        312. Rural Telephone Coalition contends that incumbent LECs should 
    not be required to construct new facilities to accommodate new 
    entrants. We have considered the economic impact of our rules in this 
    section on small incumbent LECs. In this section, for example, we 
    expressly limit the provision of unbundled interoffice facilities to 
    existing incumbent LEC facilities. We also note that section 251(f) of 
    the 1996 Act provides relief for certain small LECs from our 
    regulations under section 251.
    4. Databases and Signaling Systems
    a. Background
    (1) NPRM
        313. In the NPRM, we tentatively concluded that incumbent LECs 
    should be required to unbundle access to their signaling systems and 
    databases as network elements. We asked commenters to identify points 
    at which carriers interconnect with SS7 networks today, as well as the 
    technical feasibility of establishing other points of access and 
    interconnection. We also asked commenters to identify those signaling 
    and database functions currently provided by incumbent LECs on an 
    unbundled basis, and other functions not currently offered by incumbent 
    LECs, that the parties believe should be offered on an unbundled basis.
        314. In the NPRM, we noted the possibility that competitors that 
    provide local exchange service using resold incumbent LEC services or 
    unbundled elements might want to connect an alternative call processing 
    database to the incumbent LEC's SS7 network in order to offer services 
    and features not available through the incumbent LEC's own SS7 network 
    databases.
        315. We also sought comment on unbundling access to the Advanced 
    Intelligent Network (AIN), and referenced our separate Intelligent 
    Networks proceeding which deals with related issues. We sought comment 
    on whether to unbundle access to AIN facilities and functionalities.
    (2) SS7 Signaling Network Technology
        316. Signaling systems facilitate the routing of telephone calls 
    between switches. Most LECs employ signaling networks that are 
    physically separate from their voice networks, and these ``out-of-
    band'' signaling networks simultaneously carry signaling messages for 
    multiple calls. In general, most LECs' signaling networks adhere to a 
    Bellcore standard Signaling System 7 (SS7) protocol.
        317. SS7 networks use signaling links to transmit routing messages 
    between switches, and between switches and call-related databases. A 
    typical SS7 network includes a signaling link, which transmits 
    signaling information in packets, from a local switch to a signaling 
    transfer point (STP), which is a high-capacity packet switch. The STP 
    switches packets onto other links according to the address information 
    contained in the packet. These additional links extend to other 
    switches, databases, and STPs in the LEC's network. A switch routing a 
    call to another switch will initiate a series of signaling messages via 
    signaling links
    
    [[Page 45526]]
    
    through an STP to establish a call path on the voice network between 
    the switches.
        318. As mentioned above, the SS7 network also employs signaling 
    links (via STPs) between switches and call-related databases, such as 
    the Line Information Database (LIDB), Toll Free Calling (i.e., 800, 888 
    number) database, and AIN databases. These links enable a switch to 
    send queries via the SS7 network to call-related databases, which 
    return customer information or instructions for call routing to the 
    switch.
        319. From the perspective of a switch in a LEC network, the 
    databases discussed above merely supply information or instructions. 
    Updating or populating the information in such databases, however, 
    takes place through a separate process involving different equipment. 
    Carriers input information directly into a service management system 
    (SMS), which in turn downloads such information into the individual 
    databases.
        320. The Advanced Intelligent Network (AIN) is a network 
    architecture that uses distributed intelligence in centralized 
    databases to control call processing and manage network information, 
    rather than performing those functions at every switch. An AIN-capable 
    switch halts call progress when a resident software ``trigger'' is 
    activated, and uses the SS7 network to access intelligent databases, 
    known as Service Control Points (SCPs), that contain service software 
    and subscriber information, for instruction on how to route, monitor, 
    or terminate the call. AIN is being used in the deployment of number 
    portability, wireless roaming, and such advanced services as same 
    number service (i.e., 500 number service) and voice recognition 
    dialing. AIN services are designed and tested in an off-line computer 
    known as a Service Creation Environment (SCE). Once a service is 
    successfully tested, the software is transferred to an SMS that 
    administers and supports SCP databases in the network. The SMS then 
    regularly downloads software and information to an SCP where 
    interaction with the voice network takes place via the signaling links 
    and STPs discussed above.
    b. Discussion
        321. In the interconnection section above, we conclude that the 
    exchange of signaling information between LECs necessary to exchange 
    traffic and access call related databases was included within the 
    interconnection obligation of section 251(c)(2). We emphasize below, 
    such exchange of signaling information does not include the exchange of 
    AIN signaling information between networks for the purpose of providing 
    AIN messages to the incumbent LEC's switch from a competitor's SCP 
    database. Thus, notwithstanding any obligations under section 
    251(c)(3), incumbent LECs are required to accept and provide signaling 
    in accordance with the exchange of traffic between interconnecting 
    networks. We conclude that this exchange of signaling information may 
    occur through an STP-to-STP interconnection.
    (1) Signaling Links and STP
        322. We conclude that incumbent LECs, upon request, must provide 
    nondiscriminatory access to their signaling links and STPs on an 
    unbundled basis. We believe it is technically feasible for incumbent 
    LECs to provide such access, and that such access is critical to entry 
    in the local exchange market. Further, the 1996 Act requires BOCs to 
    provide ``nondiscriminatory access to databases and associated 
    signaling necessary for call routing and completion'' as a precondition 
    for entry into in-region interLATA services. Thus, it appears that 
    Congress contemplated the unbundling of signaling systems as network 
    elements.
        323. We conclude that access to unbundled signaling links and STPs 
    is technically feasible. The majority of commenters, including 
    incumbent LECs, agree that it is technically feasible to provide 
    unbundled access to signaling links and STPs. Parties note that 
    incumbent LECs and signaling aggregators already provide such access. 
    In addition, several state commissions already require incumbent LECs 
    to provide unbundled elements of SS7 networks. Because of the screening 
    role played by the STP and associated network reliability concerns that 
    were raised in the record, however, we do not require that incumbent 
    LECs permit requesting carriers to link their own STPs directly to the 
    incumbent's switch or call-related databases. We take a deliberately 
    conservative approach here because of significant evidence in the 
    record and we note that mere conclusory objections to technical 
    feasibility would not alone be sufficient evidence.
        324. Under section 251(d)(2)(A), the Commission must consider 
    whether access to proprietary network elements is necessary. Commenters 
    did not identify proprietary concerns with signaling protocols for the 
    SS7 network. Moreover, in general, SS7 signaling networks adhere to 
    Bellcore standards, rather then LEC-specific protocols and provide 
    seamless interconnectivity between networks. Thus, we conclude that the 
    unbundling of signaling links and STPs does not present proprietary 
    concerns with respect to the incumbent LEC.
        325. Under section 251(d)(2)(B), the Commission must consider 
    whether ``the failure to provide access to such network elements would 
    impair the ability of the telecommunications carrier seeking access to 
    provide the services that it seeks to offer.'' Access to signaling 
    systems continues to be a critical element to providing competing local 
    exchange and exchange access service. The vast majority of calls made 
    over incumbent LEC networks are set-up and controlled by separate 
    signaling networks. Incumbent LECs argue that access to signaling 
    systems and associated databases is already available from other 
    providers and therefore, they should not have to unbundle them for 
    access by competitors. As discussed above, section 251(d)(2)(B) only 
    relieves an incumbent LEC of its unbundling obligation if other 
    unbundled elements in its network could provide the same service 
    without diminution of quality. Because alternative signaling methods, 
    such as in-band signaling, would provide a lower quality of service, we 
    conclude that a competitor's ability to provide service would be 
    significantly impaired if it did not have access to incumbent LECs' 
    unbundled signaling links and STPs.
        326. The purchase of unbundled elements of the SS7 network gives 
    the competitive provider the right to use those elements for signaling 
    between its switches (including unbundled switching elements), between 
    its switches and the incumbent LEC's switches, and between its switches 
    and those third party networks with which the incumbent LEC's SS7 
    network is interconnected. When a competitive provider purchases 
    unbundled switching from the incumbent LEC, the incumbent LEC must 
    provide nondiscriminatory access to its SS7 network from that switch in 
    the same manner in which it obtains such access itself. Carriers that 
    provide their own switching facilities should be able to access the 
    incumbent LEC's SS7 network for each of their switches via a signaling 
    link between their switch and an incumbent LEC's STP. Competitive 
    carriers should be able to make this connection in the same manner as 
    an incumbent LEC connects one of its own switches to the STP. This 
    could be accomplished by the incumbent providing an unbundled signaling 
    link from its STP to the competitor's switch or by a competitor 
    bringing a signaling
    
    [[Page 45527]]
    
    link from its switch to the incumbent LEC's STP.
    (2) Call-Related Databases
        327. We conclude that incumbent LECs, upon request, must provide 
    nondiscriminatory access on an unbundled basis to their call-related 
    databases for the purpose of switch query and database response through 
    the SS7 network. Query and response access to a call-related database 
    is intended to require the incumbent LEC only to provide access to its 
    call-related databases as is necessary to permit a competing provider's 
    switch (including the use of unbundled switching) to access the call-
    related database functions supported by that database. The incumbent 
    LEC may mediate or restrict access to that necessary for the competing 
    provider to provide such services as are supported by the database. 
    Thus, for example, we find that it is technically feasible for 
    incumbent LECs to provide access to the Line Information Database 
    (LIDB), the Toll Free Calling Database and Number Portability 
    downstream databases. The vast majority of parties, including incumbent 
    LECs, agree that it is technically feasible to provide access to the 
    LIDB and the Toll Free Calling databases at an STP linked to the 
    database. Several state commissions also report that they have ordered 
    incumbent LECs' to provide such access to the LIDB and the Toll Free 
    Calling databases. We require incumbent LECs to provide this access to 
    their call-related databases by means of physical access at the STP 
    linked to the unbundled database. We find that such access is critical 
    to entry in the local exchange market.
        328. We conclude that it is not technically feasible to unbundle 
    the SCP from its associated STP. We note that the overwhelming majority 
    of commenters contend that it is not technically feasible to access 
    call-related databases in a manner other than by connection at the STP 
    directly linked to the call-related database. Parties argue that the 
    STP is designed to provide mediation and screening functions for the 
    SS7 network that are not performed at the switch or database. We, 
    therefore, emphasize that access to call-related databases must be 
    provided through interconnection at the STP and that we do not require 
    direct access to call-related databases.
        329. Several commenters also identified access to call-related 
    databases used in the incumbent's AIN to be critical to fair 
    competition in the local market, and some state commissions have 
    ordered incumbent LECs to provide access to AIN databases. We conclude 
    that such access is technically feasible via an STP for those call-
    related databases used in the incumbent LEC's AIN. First, of course, 
    when a new entrant purchases an incumbent's local switching element it 
    is technically feasible for the new entrant to use the incumbent's SCP 
    element in the same manner, and via the same signaling links, as the 
    incumbent itself. Thus, we find no technical impediments in the record 
    with regard to such access when a requesting carrier is also purchasing 
    a local switching element associated with the AIN call-related 
    database.
        330. Further, we conclude that when a new entrant deploys its own 
    switch, and links it to the incumbent LEC's signaling system, it is 
    technically feasible for the incumbent to provide access to the 
    incumbent's SCP to provide AIN-supported services to customers served 
    by the new entrant's switch. Some SS7 network services resellers 
    currently provide such access. Other potential local competitors 
    present additional evidence supporting the technical feasibility of 
    such access. Unlike the situation where a competitor's SCP would 
    control the incumbent's switch (which is discussed below in section 
    V.I.4.c.(4)), in this scenario, the incumbent's SCP will respond to and 
    control the competitor's switch, and potential competitors that have 
    commented in the record do not express network reliability concerns 
    with regard to such control. Further, like the software resident in a 
    switch, the incumbent LEC's applications resident in an SCP are merely 
    part of the overall software and hardware making up the SCP facility. 
    Thus, carriers purchasing access under either scenario above may use 
    the incumbent's service applications in addition to their own.
        311. Although we conclude that access to incumbent AIN SCPs is 
    technically feasible, we agree with BellSouth that such access may 
    present the need for mediation mechanisms to, among other things, 
    protect data in incumbent AIN SCPs and ensure against excessive traffic 
    volumes. In addition, there may be mediation issues a competing carrier 
    will need to address before requesting such access. Mediation may be 
    necessary for requesting carriers to ensure that inadvertent feature 
    interactions, network management control and customer privacy concerns 
    do not arise from such access. Accordingly, if parties are unable to 
    agree to appropriate mediation mechanisms through negotiations, we 
    conclude that during arbitration of such issues the states (or the 
    Commission acting pursuant to section 252(e)(5)) must consider whether 
    such mediation mechanisms will be available and will adequately protect 
    against intentional or unintentional misuse of the incumbent's AIN 
    facilities. We encourage incumbent LECs and competitive carriers to 
    participate in industry fora and industry testing to resolve 
    outstanding mediation concerns. Incumbent LECs may establish reasonable 
    certification and testing programs for carriers proposing to access AIN 
    call related databases in a manner similar to those used for SS7 
    certification.
        332. We recognize that providing unbundled access to AIN call-
    related databases at cost, and in particular providing access to the 
    incumbent LEC's software applications that reside in the AIN databases, 
    may reduce the incumbent's incentive to develop new and advanced 
    services using AIN. In the near term, however, requiring entrants to 
    bear the cost of deploying a fully redundant network architecture, 
    including AIN databases and their application software, would 
    constitute a significant barrier to market entry for competitive 
    carriers. As local service markets develop, however, competition may 
    reduce the incumbent LEC's control over bottleneck facilities and 
    increase the importance of innovation. In those circumstances it is 
    important that incumbent LECs have the incentive to develop unique and 
    innovative services supported by AIN. Therefore at a later date, we 
    will revisit the proper balance between providing unbundled access and 
    maintaining the incentives of incumbent LECs to innovate.
        333. Parties generally do not identify proprietary concerns when 
    access to call-related databases is provided via STPs. In general, 
    signaling protocols used to access call-related databases adhere to 
    open Bellcore standards. Parties also do not raise proprietary concerns 
    with specific call-related databases themselves. Today, many separate 
    carriers access incumbent LEC Toll Free Calling and LIDB databases for 
    the proper routing and billing of calls. Thus, we conclude that, in 
    general, unbundled access to call-related databases does not present 
    proprietary concerns with respect to section 251(d)(2)(A). Incumbent 
    LECs may, however, present such proprietary concerns in the arbitration 
    process with regard to specific databases, and states (or the 
    Commission acting pursuant to section 252(e)(5)) may take action to 
    limit unnecessary access to proprietary information.
        334. We also conclude that denying access to call-related databases 
    would
    
    [[Page 45528]]
    
    impair the ability of a competing provider to offer services such as 
    Alternative Billing Services and AIN-based services. AIN-based services 
    represent the cutting edge of telephone exchange services, and 
    competitors would be at a significant disadvantage if they were forced 
    to develop their own AIN capability immediately. In addition, the 
    record indicates that deployment of call-related databases in the near 
    term would represent a substantial cost to new entrants. As mentioned 
    above, incumbent LECs argue that access to certain call-related 
    databases is already competitively available and therefore they should 
    not have to unbundle access to them. As discussed above, however, 
    section 251(d)(2)(B) would only relieve an incumbent LEC of its 
    unbundling obligation if other unbundled elements in its network could 
    provide the same service without diminution of quality. Because of the 
    absence of such elements, we conclude that a competitor's ability to 
    provide service would be significantly impaired if it did not have 
    unbundled access to incumbent LECs' call-related databases, including 
    the LIDB, Toll Free Calling, AIN, and number portibility downstream 
    databases for the purpose of switch query and database response through 
    the SS7 network.
        335. We also conclude that access to call-related databases as 
    discussed above, and access to the service management system discussed 
    below, must be provided to, and obtained by, requesting carriers in a 
    manner that complies with section 222 of the Act. Section 222, which 
    was effective upon adoption, sets out requirements for privacy of 
    customer information. Section 222(a) provides that all 
    telecommunications carriers have a duty to protect the confidentiality 
    of proprietary information of other carriers, including resellers, 
    equipment manufacturers, and customers. Section 222(b) requires that 
    telecommunications carriers that use proprietary information obtained 
    from another telecommunications carrier in providing any 
    telecommunications service ``shall use that information only for such 
    purpose, and shall not use such information for its own marketing 
    purposes.'' Sections 222 (c) and (d) provide protection for, and 
    limitations on the use of, and access to, customer proprietary network 
    information (CPNI). We note that we have initiated a proceeding to 
    clarify the obligations of carriers with regard to sections 222 (c) and 
    (d).
    (3) Service Management Systems
        336. Finally, we conclude that incumbent LECs should provide 
    access, on an unbundled basis, to the service management systems (SMS), 
    which allow competitors to create, modify, or update information in 
    call-related databases. We believe it is technically feasible for 
    incumbent LECs to provide access to the SMS in the same manner and 
    method that they provide for their own access. We find that such access 
    is necessary for competitors to effectively use call-related databases, 
    which we have already found to be critical to entry in the local 
    exchange market.
        337. Commenters argue that they need equal access to incumbent 
    LECs' SMSs to write or populate their own information in call-related 
    databases. As discussed above, information bound for many call-related 
    databases is entered first at an off-line SMS, which then downloads the 
    information to the call-related database for real time use on the 
    network. We find that competing provider access to the SMS is 
    technically feasible if it is provided in the same or equivalent manner 
    that the incumbent LEC currently uses to provide such access to itself. 
    For example, if the incumbent LEC inputs information into the SMS using 
    magnetic tapes, the competitive carrier must be able to create and 
    submit magnetic tapes for the incumbent to input into the SMS in the 
    same way the incumbent inputs its own magnetic tapes. If the incumbent 
    accesses the SMS through an electronic interface, the competitive 
    carrier should be able to access the SMS through an equivalent 
    electronic interface. We further conclude that, whatever method is 
    used, the incumbent LEC must provide the competing carrier with the 
    information necessary to correctly enter or format for entry the 
    information relevant for input into the particular incumbent LEC SMS.
        338. Specifically with respect to AIN, we find that the record in 
    the Intelligent Networks proceeding supports access to the SMS. A 
    competing carrier seeking access to the SMS that is part of the 
    incumbent LEC's AIN would do so through the incumbent LEC's service 
    creation environment (SCE), an interface used to design, create, and 
    test AIN supported services. Software successfully tested in the SCE is 
    transferred to the SMS, where it is then downloaded into an SCP 
    database for active deployment on the network. We are persuaded that 
    the risk of harm to the public switched network from such access to the 
    SMS is minimized by the technical safeguards inherent in the SCE and 
    SMS. As described in comments filed in the Intelligent Networks docket, 
    competitors accessing the SCE and SMS would not communicate directly 
    with the LEC's database or switch. We therefore conclude that such 
    access is technically feasible, and that incumbent LECs should provide 
    requesting carriers with the same access to design, create, test, and 
    deploy AIN-based services at the SMS that the incumbent LEC provides 
    for itself. While many incumbent LECs express concerns with the 
    technical feasibility of access to AIN, we conclude that those concerns 
    deal primarily with the interconnection of third party AIN SCP 
    databases to the incumbent LEC's AIN and not access to the SCE and SMS.
        339. We recognize that, although technically feasible, providing 
    nondiscriminatory access to the SMS and SCE for the creation and 
    deployment of AIN services may require some modifications, including 
    appropriate mediation, to accommodate such access by requesting 
    carriers. We note that BellSouth is currently prepared to tariff and 
    offer such access to third parties, and other incumbent LECs, including 
    Bell Atlantic and Ameritech, indicate that they have made significant 
    progress towards implementing such access. Therefore, if parties are 
    unable to agree to appropriate mediation mechanisms through 
    negotiations, we conclude that during arbitration of such issues the 
    states (or the Commission acting pursuant to section 252(e)(5)) must 
    consider whether such mediation mechanisms will be available and will 
    adequately protect against intentional or unintentional misuses of the 
    incumbent's AIN facilities. We again encourage incumbent LECs and 
    competitive carriers to participate in industry fora and industry 
    testing to resolve outstanding mediation concerns.
        340. Parties did identify some proprietary concerns regarding 
    access to the SCE and SMS used in the incumbent LEC's AIN. Some 
    incumbent LECs contend that the interface used at the SCE is 
    proprietary in nature. GVNW argues that specific AIN-based services 
    designed by carriers should be proprietary in nature. Competitors 
    correctly argue that AIN can be used, not only for telecommunication 
    services traditionally supported by the switch, but as a means to 
    deploy advanced services not otherwise possible. We find that competing 
    providers without access to AIN would be at a significant disadvantage 
    to incumbent LECs, because they could not necessarily offer the same 
    services to the customer. This access will help competing providers 
    without imposing costs on incumbent
    
    [[Page 45529]]
    
    LECs because the entrants will pay the cost. We therefore conclude, 
    under section 251(d)(2)(A), that access to AIN, including those 
    elements that may be proprietary, is necessary for successful entry 
    into the local service market.
        341. Most parties generally did not identify proprietary concerns 
    with access to those SMSs used other than for AIN. Some parties, 
    however, argue that there are proprietary interfaces used to enter 
    information into various databases. Competing carriers counter that 
    competitive providers would not need to have direct access to the 
    proprietary methods of data entry used by incumbent LECs, and as a 
    result we conclude that the unbundled access to SMSs used for other 
    than AIN does not present proprietary concerns with respect to section 
    251(d)(2)(A).
        342. We also conclude that unbundled access to all SMSs is 
    necessary for a competing provider to effectively use unbundled call-
    related databases. We find that the inability of competing carriers to 
    use the SMS in the same manner that an incumbent LEC uses to input data 
    itself would impair the ability of a competing carrier to effectively 
    offer services to its customers using unbundled call-related databases. 
    Commenters in the record point out that access to call-related 
    databases alone would not allow the competing carrier to provide such 
    services to its customers without access to an SMS. We also conclude 
    that AIN-based services are important to a new entrant's ability to 
    compete effectively for customers with the incumbent LEC, and in 
    developing new business by introducing new AIN based services. Thus we 
    conclude that a competitor's ability to provide service would be 
    significantly impaired if it did not have unbundled access to an 
    incumbent LEC's SMS, including access to the SMS(s) used to input data 
    to the LIDB, Toll Free Calling, Number Portability and AIN call-related 
    databases.
        343. We reject the contention by several incumbent LECs that 
    signaling and database access was meant by the 1996 Act to apply only 
    to such access as is necessary for call routing and completion. 
    Although the competitive checklist for BOC entry into in-region 
    interLATA services under section 271 requires ``nondiscriminatory 
    access to databases and associated signaling necessary for call routing 
    and completion'' the definition of a network element is more 
    comprehensive in scope. A network element as defined by the 1996 Act 
    includes ``databases'' and in particular ``databases sufficient for 
    billing and collection or used in the transmission, routing, or other 
    provision of a telecommunications service.'' We find that the inclusion 
    of ``other provision of a telecommunications service'' meant Congress 
    intended the unbundling of databases to be read broadly and could 
    include databases beyond those directly used in the transmission or 
    routing of a telecommunications service.
    (4) Third Party Call-Related Databases
        344. We find that there is not enough evidence in the record to 
    make a determination as to the technical feasibility of interconnection 
    of third party call-related databases to the incumbent LEC's signaling 
    system. Some parties argue that such interconnection, including the 
    interconnection of third party AIN SCP databases, would allow them to 
    provide more efficient or advanced call processing and services to 
    customers, thereby increasing their ability to compete with the 
    incumbent LEC. AT&T and MCI specifically argue that it would be 
    technically feasible for them to interconnect their AIN SCP database to 
    an incumbent LEC's AIN for the purpose of providing call processing 
    instructions to the incumbent LEC's switch. Incumbent LECs contend that 
    such interconnection would leave their switch vulnerable to a multitude 
    of potential harms because sufficient mediation for such 
    interconnection does not currently exist at the STP or SCP and has not 
    yet been developed. AT&T counters that there is no need for additional 
    mediation and that sufficient certification and testing of AIN based 
    services before deployment in such a fashion is technically feasible.
        345. At this time, in view of this record and the record compiled 
    in the Intelligent Networks docket, we cannot make a determination of 
    the technical feasibility of such interconnection. We do, however, 
    believe that state commissions could find such an arrangement to be 
    technically feasible and we do not intend to preempt such an order 
    through these rules. The Illinois Commission recently ordered access to 
    incumbent LECs' AIN that does allow for this type of interconnection. 
    We intend to address this issue early in 1997, either in the IN docket 
    or in a subsequent phase of this proceeding, taking into account, inter 
    alia, any relevant decisions of state commissions.
        346. We also address the impact on small incumbent LECs. For 
    example, GVNW asserts that any national rule requiring this form of 
    interconnection would require many small incumbent LECs to make 
    uneconomic upgrades of their switches in order to accommodate it. We 
    have considered the economic impact of our rules in this section on 
    small incumbent LECs. Accordingly, we have not adopted any national 
    standards concerning AIN at this time. We also note that section 251(f) 
    provides relief for certain small LECs from our regulations 
    implementing section 251.
    5. Operation Support Systems
    a. Background
        347. We sought comment, in the NPRM, on whether national 
    requirements for electronic ordering interfaces would reduce the time 
    and resources required for new entrants to enter and compete in 
    regional markets. We also sought comment on the unbundling of databases 
    generally in our discussion on unbundling database and signaling 
    systems.
    b. Discussion
        348. We conclude that operations support systems and the 
    information they contain fall squarely within the definition of 
    ``network element'' and must be unbundled upon request under section 
    251(c)(3), as discussed below. Congress included in the definition of 
    ``network element'' the terms ``databases'' and ``information 
    sufficient for billing and collection or used in the transmission, 
    routing, or other provision of a telecommunications service.'' We 
    believe that the inclusion of these terms in the definition of 
    ``network element'' is a recognition that the massive operations 
    support systems employed by incumbent LECs, and the information such 
    systems maintain and update to administer telecommunications networks 
    and services, represent a significant potential barrier to entry. It is 
    these systems that determine, in large part, the speed and efficiency 
    with which incumbent LECs can market, order, provision, and maintain 
    telecommunications services and facilities. Thus, we agree with 
    Ameritech that ``[o]perational interfaces are essential to promote 
    viable competitive entry.''
        349. Nondiscriminatory access to operations support systems 
    functions can be viewed in at least three ways. First, operations 
    support systems themselves can be characterized as ``databases'' or 
    ``facilit[ies] * * * used in the provision of a telecommunications 
    service,'' and the functions performed by such systems can be 
    characterized as ``features, functions, and capabilities that are 
    provided by means of such facilit[ies].'' Second, the information 
    contained in, and processed by operations support systems can be 
    classified as
    
    [[Page 45530]]
    
    ``information sufficient for billing and collection or used in the 
    transmission, routing, or other provision of a telecommunications 
    service.'' Third, nondiscriminatory access to the functions of 
    operations support systems, which would include access to the 
    information they contain, could be viewed as a ``term or condition'' of 
    unbundling other network elements under section 251(c)(3), or resale 
    under section 251(c)(4). Thus, we conclude that, under any of these 
    interpretations, operations support systems functions are subject to 
    the nondiscriminatory access duty imposed by section 251(c)(3), and the 
    duty imposed by section 251(c)(4) to provide resale services under 
    just, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory terms and conditions.
        350. Much of the information maintained by these systems is 
    critical to the ability of other carriers to compete with incumbent 
    LECs using unbundled network elements or resold services. Without 
    access to review, inter alia, available telephone numbers, service 
    interval information, and maintenance histories, competing carriers 
    would operate at a significant disadvantage with respect to the 
    incumbent. Other information, such as the facilities and services 
    assigned to a particular customer, is necessary to a competing 
    carrier's ability to provision and offer competing services to 
    incumbent LEC customers. Finally, if competing carriers are unable to 
    perform the functions of pre-ordering, ordering, provisioning, 
    maintenance and repair, and billing for network elements and resale 
    services in substantially the same time and manner that an incumbent 
    can for itself, competing carriers will be severely disadvantaged, if 
    not precluded altogether, from fairly competing. Thus providing 
    nondiscriminatory access to these support systems functions, which 
    would include access to the information such systems contain, is vital 
    to creating opportunities for meaningful competition.
        351. As noted in the comments above, several state commissions have 
    ordered real-time access or have ongoing proceedings working to develop 
    and implement it within their jurisdictions. The New York Commission, 
    building on its pioneering experience with the Rochester Telephone 
    ``Open Market Plan,'' has facilitated a working group on electronic 
    interfaces comprised of both incumbent LECs and potential competitors. 
    The New York Commission focused on these issues in response to the 
    frustrations and concerns of resellers in the Rochester market. In 
    particular, AT&T alleged that it was ``severely disadvantaged due to 
    the fact that [Rochester Telephone] has failed to provide procedures 
    for resellers to access [their] databases for on-line queries needed to 
    perform basic service functions [such] as scheduling customer 
    appointments.'' The New York Commission has concluded that wherever 
    possible NYNEX will provide new entrants with real-time electronic 
    access to its systems. As another example, the Georgia Commission 
    recently ordered BellSouth to provide electronic interfaces such that 
    resellers have the same access to operations support systems and 
    informational databases as BellSouth does, including interfaces for 
    pre-ordering, ordering and provisioning, service trouble reporting, and 
    customer daily usage. In testimony before the Georgia Commission, a 
    BellSouth witness acknowledged that ``[n]o one is happy, believe me, 
    with a system that is not fully electronic.'' As noted above, Georgia 
    ordered BellSouth to establish these interfaces within two months of 
    its order (by July 15, 1996), but recently extended the deadline an 
    additional month (to August 15th). Both the Illinois and Indiana 
    Commissions ordered incumbent LECs immediately to provide to 
    competitors access to operational interfaces at parity with those 
    provided to their own retail customers, or submit plans with specific 
    timetables for achieving such access. Several other states have passed 
    laws or adopted rules ordering incumbent LECs to provide interfaces for 
    access equal to that the incumbent provides itself. We recognize the 
    lead taken by these states and others, and we generally rely upon their 
    conclusions in this Order.
        352. We conclude that providing nondiscriminatory access to 
    operations support systems functions is technically feasible. Incumbent 
    LECs today provide IXCs with different types of electronic ordering or 
    trouble interfaces that demonstrate the feasibility of such access, and 
    perhaps also provide a basis for adapting such interfaces for use 
    between local service providers. Further, as discussed above, several 
    incumbent LECs, including NYNEX and Bell Atlantic, are already testing 
    and operating interfaces that support limited functions, and are 
    developing the interfaces to support access to the remaining functions 
    identified by most potential competitors. Some incumbent LECs 
    acknowledge that nondiscriminatory access to operations support systems 
    functions is technically feasible. Finally, several industry groups are 
    actively establishing standards for inter-telecommunications company 
    transactions.
        353. Section 251(d)(2)(A) requires the Commission to consider 
    whether ``access to such network elements as are proprietary in nature 
    is necessary.'' Incumbent LECs argue that there are proprietary 
    interfaces used to access these databases and information. Parties 
    seeking to compete with incumbent LECs counter that access to such 
    databases and information is vitally important to the ability to 
    broadly compete with the incumbent. As discussed above, competitors 
    also argue that such access is necessary to order, provision, and 
    maintain unbundled network elements and resold services, and to market 
    competing services effectively to an incumbent LEC's customers. We find 
    that it is absolutely necessary for competitive carriers to have access 
    to operations support systems functions in order to successfully enter 
    the local service market.
        354. Section 251(d)(2)(B) requires the Commission to consider 
    whether ``the failure to provide access to such network elements would 
    impair the ability of the telecommunications carrier seeking access to 
    provide the services that it seeks to offer.'' As mentioned above, 
    parties identified access to operations support systems functions as 
    critical to the provision of local service. We find that such 
    operations support systems functions are essential to the ability of 
    competitors to provide services in a fully competitive local service 
    market. Therefore, we conclude that competitors' ability to provide 
    service successfully would be significantly impaired if they did not 
    have access to incumbent LECs' operations support systems functions.
        355. We thus conclude that an incumbent LEC must provide 
    nondiscriminatory access to their operations support systems functions 
    for pre-ordering, ordering, provisioning, maintenance and repair, and 
    billing available to the LEC itself. We adopt the definition of these 
    terms as set forth in the AT&T-Bell Atlantic Joint Ex Parte as the 
    minimum necessary for our requirements. We note, however, that 
    individual incumbent LEC's operations support systems may not clearly 
    mirror these definitions. Nevertheless, incumbent LECs must provide 
    nondiscriminatory access to the full range of functions within pre-
    ordering, ordering, provisioning, maintenance and repair and billing 
    enjoyed by the incumbent LEC. Such nondiscriminatory access necessarily 
    includes access to the functionality of
    
    [[Page 45531]]
    
    any internal gateway systems the incumbent employs in performing the 
    above functions for its own customers. For example, to the extent that 
    customer service representatives of the incumbent have access to 
    available telephone numbers or service interval information during 
    customer contacts, the incumbent must provide the same access to 
    competing providers. Obviously, an incumbent that provisions network 
    resources electronically does not discharge its obligation under 
    section 251(c)(3) by offering competing providers access that involves 
    human intervention, such as facsimile-based ordering.
        356. We recognize that, although technically feasible, providing 
    nondiscriminatory access to operations support systems functions may 
    require some modifications to existing systems necessary to accommodate 
    such access by competing providers. Although, as discussed above, many 
    incumbent LECs are actively developing these systems, even the largest 
    and most advanced incumbent LECs have not completed interfaces that 
    provide such access to all of their support systems functions. State 
    commissions such as Georgia, Illinois, and Indiana, however, have 
    ordered that such access be made available to requesting carriers in 
    the near term. As a practical matter, the interfaces developed by 
    incumbents to accommodate nondiscriminatory access will likely provide 
    such access for services and elements beyond a particular state's 
    boundaries, and thus we believe that requirements for such access by a 
    small number of states representing a cross-section of the country will 
    quickly lead to incumbents providing access in all regions.
        357. In all cases, however, we conclude that in order to comply 
    fully with section 251(c)(3) an incumbent LEC must provide, upon 
    request, nondiscriminatory access to operations support systems 
    functions for pre-ordering, ordering, provisioning, maintenance and 
    repair, and billing of unbundled network elements under section 
    251(c)(3) and resold services under section 251(c)(4). Incumbent LECs 
    that currently do not comply with this requirement of section 251(c)(3) 
    must do so as expeditiously as possible, but in any event no later than 
    January 1, 1997. We believe that the record demonstrates that incumbent 
    LECs and several national standards-setting organizations have made 
    significant progress in developing such access. This progress is also 
    reflected in a number of states requiring competitor access to these 
    transactional functions in the near term. Thus, we believe that it is 
    reasonable to expect that by January 1, 1997, new entrants will be able 
    to compete for end user customers by obtaining nondiscriminatory access 
    to operations support systems functions.
        358. We have considered the economic impact of our rules in this 
    section on small incumbent LECs. For example, RTC urges us to recognize 
    the differences between carriers in regards to computerized network 
    administration and operational interfaces. Our requirement of 
    nondiscriminatory access to operations support systems recognizes that 
    different incumbent LECs possess different existing systems. We also 
    note, however, that section 251(f) of the 1996 Act provides relief for 
    certain small LECs from our regulations implementing section 251.
        359. Ideally, each incumbent LEC would provide access to support 
    systems through a nationally standardized gateway. Such national 
    standards would eliminate the need for new entrants to develop multiple 
    interface systems, one for each incumbent. We believe that the progress 
    made by standards-setting organizations to date evidences a strong 
    national movement toward such a uniform standard. For example, both 
    AT&T and Bell Atlantic agree that, given appropriate guidance from the 
    Commission, the industry can achieve consensus on national standards 
    such that within 12 months 95% of all inter-telecommunications company 
    transactions may be processed via nationally standardized electronic 
    gateways.
        360. In order to ensure continued progress in establishing national 
    standards, we propose to monitor closely the progress of industry 
    organizations as they implement the rules adopted in this proceeding. 
    Depending upon the progress made, we will make a determination in the 
    near future as to whether our obligations under the 1996 Act require us 
    to issue a separate notice of proposed rulemaking or take other action 
    to guide industry efforts at arriving at appropriate national standards 
    for access to operations support systems.
    6. Other Network Elements
    a. Background
        361. In the NPRM, we requested comment on other network elements 
    the Commission should require incumbent LECs to unbundle. We 
    tentatively concluded that ``subscriber numbers'' and ``operator call 
    completion services'' should be unbundled. We also, under our 
    discussion of section 251(b)(3), sought comment on nondiscriminatory 
    access to telephone numbers, operator services, and directory 
    assistance.
    b. Discussion
    (1) Operator Services and Directory Assistance
        362. We conclude that incumbent LECs are under the same duty to 
    permit competing carriers nondiscriminatory access to operator services 
    and directory assistance as all LECs are under section 251(b)(3). We 
    further conclude that, if a carrier requests an incumbent LEC to 
    unbundle the facilities and functionalities providing operator services 
    and directory assistance as separate network elements, the incumbent 
    LEC must provide the competing provider with nondiscriminatory access 
    to such facilities and functionalities at any technically feasible 
    point. We believe that these facilities and functionalities are 
    important to facilitate competition in the local exchange market. 
    Further, the 1996 Act imposes upon BOCs, as a condition of entry into 
    in-region interLATA services the duty to provide nondiscriminatory 
    access to directory assistance services and operator call completion 
    services. We therefore conclude that unbundling facilities and 
    functionalities providing operator services and directory assistance is 
    consistent with the intent of Congress.
        363. As discussed in our section on nondiscriminatory access under 
    section 251(b)(3), the provision of nondiscriminatory access to 
    operator services and directory assistance must conform to the 
    requirements of section 222, which restricts carrier's use of CPNI. In 
    particular, access to directory assistance and underlying directory 
    information does not require incumbent LECs to provide access to 
    unlisted or unpublished telephone numbers, or other information that 
    the incumbent LEC's customer has requested the LEC not to make 
    available. In conforming to section 222, we anticipate that incumbent 
    LECs will provide such access in a manner that will protect against the 
    inadvertent release of unlisted customer names and numbers.
        364. We note that several competitors advocate unbundling the 
    facilities and functionalities providing operator services and 
    directory assistance from particular resold services or the unbundled 
    local switching element, so that a competing provider can provide these 
    services to its customers supported by its own systems rather than 
    those of the incumbent LEC. Some incumbent LECs argue that such 
    unbundling, however, is not technically feasible because of their 
    inability to
    
    [[Page 45532]]
    
    route individual end user calls to multiple systems. We find that 
    unbundling both the facilities and functionalities providing operator 
    services and directory assistance as separate network elements will be 
    beneficial to competition and will aid the ability of competing 
    providers to differentiate their service from the incumbent LECs. We 
    also note that the Illinois Commission has recently ordered such 
    access. We therefore find that incumbent LECs must unbundle the 
    facilities and functionalities providing operator services and 
    directory assistance from resold services and other unbundled network 
    elements to the extent technically feasible. As discussed above in our 
    section on unbundled switching, we require incumbent LECs, to the 
    extent technically feasible, to provide customized routing, which would 
    include such routing to a competitor's operator services or directory 
    assistance platform.
        365. We also note that some competitors seek access to operator 
    services and directory assistance in order to serve their own 
    customers. Some of these parties argue that nondiscriminatory access to 
    such network elements requires incumbent LECs to provide rebranded 
    operator call completion services and directory assistance to the 
    competing carrier's customers. Incumbent LECs argue that the provision 
    of these services on an unbranded or rebranded basis is not technically 
    feasible because of their inability at the operator services or 
    directory assistance platforms to identify the carrier serving the end 
    user. As we concluded in our discussion on section 251(b)(3), we find 
    that incumbent LECs must permit nondiscriminatory access to both 
    operator services and directory assistance in the same manner required 
    of all LECs. We make no finding on the technical feasibility of 
    providing branded or unbranded service to competitors based on the 
    record before us. We note, however, that the Illinois Commission has 
    ordered incumbent LECs to provide rebranded operator call completion 
    services and directory assistance to requesting competitive carriers.
        366. As discussed above, incumbent LECs must provide access to 
    databases as unbundled network elements. We find that the databases 
    used in the provision of both operator call completion services and 
    directory assistance must be unbundled by incumbent LECs upon a request 
    for access by a competing provider. In particular, the directory 
    assistance database must be unbundled for access by requesting 
    carriers. Such access must include both entry of the requesting 
    carrier's customer information into the database, and the ability to 
    read such a database, so as to enable requesting carriers to provide 
    operator services and directory assistance concerning incumbent LEC 
    customer information. We clarify, however, that the entry of a 
    competitor's customer information into an incumbent LEC's directory 
    assistance database can be mediated by the incumbent LEC to prevent 
    unauthorized use of the database. We find that the arrangement ordered 
    by the California Commission concerning the shared use of such a 
    database by Pacific Bell and GTE is one possible method of providing 
    such access.
        367. Section 251(d)(2)(A) requires the Commission to consider 
    whether ``access to such network elements as are proprietary in nature 
    is necessary.'' Parties generally did not identify proprietary concerns 
    with unbundling access to operator call completion services or 
    directory assistance. Incumbent LECs generally did not claim a 
    proprietary interest in their directory assistance databases. Many 
    parties contend that proprietary interests leading to restrictions on 
    use or sharing of such database information would injure their ability 
    to compete effectively for local service. For the reasons described 
    below, we find that access to the systems supporting both operator call 
    completion services and directory assistance is necessary for new 
    entrants to provide competing local exchange service.
        368. Section 251(d)(2)(B) requires the Commission to consider 
    whether ``the failure to provide access to such network elements would 
    impair the ability of the telecommunications carrier seeking access to 
    provide the services that it seeks to offer.'' Parties identified 
    access to operator call completion services and directory assistance as 
    critical to the provision of local service. Therefore we conclude that 
    competitors' ability to provide service would be significantly impaired 
    if they did not have access to incumbent LEC's operator call completion 
    services and directory assistance.
    (2) Subscriber Numbers
        369. Some commenters argue that the Commission should require 
    incumbent LECs to unbundle access to subscriber numbers. We conclude 
    that no Commission action under section 251(b)(3) is required at this 
    time to ensure nondiscriminatory access to subscriber numbers. Issues 
    regarding access to subscriber numbers will be addressed by our 
    implementation of section 251(e).
    
    VI. Methods of Obtaining Interconnection and Access to Unbundled 
    Elements
    
        370. In this section, we address the means of achieving 
    interconnection and access to unbundled network elements that incumbent 
    LECs are required to make available to requesting carriers.
    
    A. Overview
    
    1. Background
        371. Section 251(c)(2) requires incumbent LECs to provide 
    interconnection with the LEC's network ``for the facilities and 
    equipment of any requesting telecommunications carrier.'' Section 
    251(c)(6) imposes upon incumbent LECs ``the duty to provide * * * for 
    physical collocation of equipment necessary for interconnection or 
    access to unbundled network elements at the premises of the [LEC], 
    except that the carrier may provide for virtual collocation if the 
    [LEC] demonstrates to the State commission that physical collocation is 
    not practical for technical reasons or because of space limitations.'' 
    In the NPRM, we noted that section 251(c)(6) does not expressly limit 
    the Commission's authority under section 251(c)(2) to establish rules 
    requiring incumbent LECs to make available a variety of methods of 
    interconnection, except in situations where the incumbent can 
    demonstrate to the State commission that physical collocation is not 
    practical for technical reasons or space limitations. We tentatively 
    concluded that the Commission has the authority to require any 
    reasonable method of interconnection, including physical collocation, 
    virtual collocation, and meet point interconnection arrangements. Under 
    the Commission's Expanded Interconnection rules, LECs are not required 
    to offer a collocating carrier a choice between physical and virtual 
    collocation. Special Access Order, 57 FR 54323 (November 18, 1992); 
    Switched Transport Order, 58 FR 48756 (September 17, 1993); see also 
    Physical Collocation Designation Order, 8 FCC Rcd 4589 (under our 
    Expanded Interconnection rules, LECs must provide virtual collocation 
    where: virtual collocation is available on an intrastate basis; a LEC 
    has negotiated an interstate virtual collocation arrangement; LECs are 
    exempted from providing physical collocation because of space 
    constraints; or a state commission has granted a waiver). Also, see 
    Section VI.B.1.b. regarding the
    
    [[Page 45533]]
    
    definitions of physical and virtual collocation.
    2. Discussion
        372. We conclude that, under sections 251(c)(2) and 251(c)(3), any 
    requesting carrier may choose any method of technically feasible 
    interconnection or access to unbundled elements at a particular point. 
    Section 251(c)(2) imposes an interconnection duty at any technically 
    feasible point; it does not limit that duty to a specific method of 
    interconnection or access to unbundled elements.
        373. Physical and virtual collocation are the only methods of 
    interconnection or access specifically addressed in section 251. Under 
    section 251(c)(6), incumbent LECs are under a duty to provide physical 
    collocation of equipment necessary for interconnection unless the LEC 
    can demonstrate that physical collocation is not practical for 
    technical reasons or because of space limitations. In that event, the 
    incumbent LEC is still obligated to provide virtual collocation of 
    interconnection equipment. Under section 251, the only limitation on an 
    incumbent LEC's duty to provide interconnection or access to unbundled 
    elements at any technically feasible point is addressed in section 
    251(c)(6) regarding physical collocation. Unless a LEC can establish 
    that the specific technical or space limitations in subsection (c)(6) 
    are met with respect to physical collocation, we conclude that 
    incumbent LECs must provide for any technically feasible method of 
    interconnection or access requested by a competing carrier, including 
    physical collocation. If, for example, we interpreted section 251(c)(6) 
    to limit the means of interconnection available to requesting carriers 
    to physical and virtual collocation, the requirement in section 
    251(c)(2) that interconnection be made available ``at any technically 
    feasible point'' would be narrowed dramatically to mean that 
    interconnection was required only at points where it was technically 
    feasible to collocate equipment. We are not pursuaded that Congress 
    intended to limit interconnection points to locations only where 
    collocation is possible.
        374. Section 251(c)(6) provides the Commission with explicit 
    authority to mandate physical collocation as a method of providing 
    interconnection or access to unbundled elements. Such authority was 
    previously found lacking by the U.S. Court of Appeals for the D.C. 
    Circuit in Bell Atlantic v. FCC, (Bell Atlantic Telephone Companies v. 
    FCC, 24 F.3d 1441 (D.C. Cir. 1994) (Bell Atlantic v. FCC)), which was 
    decided prior to enactment of the 1996 Act. While section 251(c)(6) 
    limits an incumbent LEC's duty to provide physical collocation in 
    certain circumstances, we find that it does not limit our authority to 
    require, under sections 251 (c)(2) and (c)(3), the provision of virtual 
    collocation. We note that under our Expanded Interconnection rules, 
    that were amended subsequent to the Bell Atlantic decision, competitive 
    entrants using physical collocation were required by many incumbent 
    LECs to convert to virtual collocation. If the Commission concluded 
    that subsection (c)(6) places a limitation on our authority to require 
    virtual collocation, competitive providers would be required to 
    undertake costly and burdensome actions to convert back to physical 
    collocation even if they were satisfied with existing virtual 
    collocation arrangements. We conclude that Congress did not intend to 
    impose such a burden on requesting carriers that wish to continue to 
    use virtual collocation for purposes of section 251(c). Further, the 
    record indicates that this requirement would be costly and would delay 
    competition. In short, we conclude that, in enacting section 251(c)(6), 
    Congress intended to expand the interconnection choices available to 
    requesting carriers, not to restrict them.
        375. We also conclude that requiring incumbent LECs to provide 
    virtual collocation and other technically feasible methods of 
    interconnection or access to unbundled elements is consistent with 
    Congress' desire to facilitate entry into the local telephone market by 
    competitive carriers. In certain circumstances, competitive carriers 
    may find, for example, that virtual collocation is less costly or more 
    efficient than physical collocation. We believe that this may be 
    particularly true for small carriers which lack the financial resources 
    to physically collocate equipment in a large number of incumbent LEC 
    premises. Moreover, since requesting carriers will bear the costs of 
    other methods of interconnection or access, this approach will not 
    impose an undue burden on the incumbent LECs.
        376. Consistent with this view, other methods of technically 
    feasible interconnection or access to incumbent LEC networks, such as 
    meet point arrangements, in addition to virtual and physical 
    collocation, must be available to new entrants upon request. See 
    Teleport comments at 26-30; see also Washington Utilities and 
    Transportation Commission, Fourth Supplemental Order Rejecting Tariff 
    Filings and Ordering Refiling; Granting Complaints, in Part, 
    (Washington Commission Oct. 31, 1995), Docket No. UT-941464, at 45; 
    Application of Electric Lightwave, Inc., MFS Intelnet of Oregon, Inc., 
    and MCI Metro Access Transmission Services, Inc., Public Utility 
    Commission of Oregon Order, Order No. 96-021, (Oregon Commission Jan. 
    12, 1996), at 68-69; Rules for Telecommunications Interconnection and 
    Unbundling, Arizona Corporation Commission Order, Decision No. 59483, 
    (Arizona Commission Jan. 11, 1996), Proposed Rule R14-2-1303 
    (Attachment E hereto). Meet point arrangements (or mid-span meets), for 
    example, are commonly used between neighboring LECs for the mutual 
    exchange of traffic, and thus, in general, we believe such arrangements 
    are technically feasible. The Michigan Commission recently required 
    Ameritech to provide meet point interconnection. Michigan Public 
    Service Commission, Case No. U-10860 (Michigan June 5, 1996) at 18 n.4. 
    Further, although the creation of meet point arrangements may require 
    some build out of facilities by the incumbent LEC, we believe that such 
    arrangements are within the scope of the obligations imposed by 
    sections 251(c)(2) and 251(c)(3). In a meet point arrangement, the 
    ``point'' of interconnection for purposes of sections 251(c)(2) and 
    251(c)(3) remains on ``the local exchange carrier's network'' (e.g., 
    main distribution frame, trunk-side of the switch), and the limited 
    build-out of facilities from that point may then constitute an 
    accommodation of interconnection. In a meet point arrangement each 
    party pays its portion of the costs to build out the facilities to the 
    meet point. We believe that, although the Commission has authority to 
    require incumbent LECs to provide meet point arrangements upon request, 
    such an arrangement only makes sense for interconnection pursuant to 
    section 251(c)(2) but not for unbundled access under section 251(c)(3). 
    New entrants will request interconnection pursuant to section 251(c)(2) 
    for the purpose of exchanging traffic with incumbent LECs. In this 
    situation, the incumbent and the new entrant are co-carriers and each 
    gains value from the interconnection arrangement. Under these 
    circumstances, it is reasonable to require each party to bear a 
    reasonable portion of the economic costs of the arrangement. In an 
    access arrangement pursuant to section 251(c)(3), however, the 
    interconnection point will be a part of the new entrant's network and 
    will be used to carry traffic from one element in the new entrant's 
    network to another. We conclude that in a section 251(c)(3)
    
    [[Page 45534]]
    
    access situation, the new entrant should pay all of the economic costs 
    of a meet point arrangement. Regarding the distance from an incumbent 
    LEC's premises that an incumbent should be required to build out 
    facilities for meet point arrangements, we believe that the parties and 
    state commissions are in a better position than the Commission to 
    determine the appropriate distance that would constitute the required 
    reasonable accommodation of interconnection.
        377. Finally, in accordance with our interpretation of the term 
    ``technically feasible,'' we conclude that, if a particular method of 
    interconnection is currently employed between two networks, or has been 
    used successfully in the past, a rebuttable presumption is created that 
    such a method is technically feasible for substantially similar network 
    architectures. Moreover, because the obligation of incumbent LECs to 
    provide interconnection or access to unbundled elements by any 
    technically feasible means arises from sections 251(c)(2) and 
    251(c)(3), we conclude that incumbent LECs bear the burden of 
    demonstrating the technical infeasibility of a particular method of 
    interconnection or access at any individual point.
    
    B. Collocation
    
    1. Collocation Standards
    a. Adoption of National Standards
    (1) Background
        378. In the NPRM we tentatively concluded that we should adopt 
    national rules for virtual and physical collocation. This tentative 
    conclusion was based on the belief that national standards would help 
    to speed the development of competition. We also sought comment on 
    specific national standards that we might adopt, and on whether any 
    specific state approaches would serve as an appropriate model.
    (2) Discussion
        379. We conclude that we should adopt explicit national rules to 
    implement the collocation requirements of the 1996 Act. We find that 
    specific rules defining minimum requirements for nondiscriminatory 
    collocation arrangements will remove barriers to entry by potential 
    competitors and speed the development of competition. Our experience in 
    the Expanded Interconnection proceeding indicates that incumbent LECs 
    have an economic incentive to interpret regulatory ambiguities to delay 
    entry by new competitors. Our review of the LECs' initial physical and 
    virtual collocation tariffs raised significant concerns regarding the 
    implementation of our Expanded Interconnection requirements and 
    resulted in the designation of numerous issues for investigation. The 
    Commission has not yet reached decisions on most of these issues, 
    though it has found that certain rates for virtual collocation were 
    unlawful. We and the states should therefore adopt, to the extent 
    possible, specific and detailed collocation rules. We find, however, 
    that states should have flexibility to apply additional collocation 
    requirements that are otherwise consistent with the 1996 Act and our 
    implementing regulations.
    b. Adoption of Expanded Interconnection Terms and Conditions for 
    Physical and Virtual Collocation Under Section 251
    (1) Background
        380. In our Expanded Interconnection proceeding, we required LECs 
    to offer expanded interconnection to all interested parties, which 
    allowed competitors and end users to terminate their own special access 
    and switched transport access transmission facilities at LEC central 
    offices. Expanded Interconnection with Local Telephone Company 
    Facilities, First Report and Order, 57 FR 54323 (November 18, 1992) 
    (Special Access Order), vacated in part and remanded, Bell Atlantic, 24 
    F.3d 1441 (1994); First Reconsideration, 57 FR 62481 (December 31, 
    1992); vacated in part and remanded, Bell Atlantic, 24 F.3d 1441; 
    Second Reconsideration, 58 FR 48752 (September 17, 1993); Second Report 
    and Order, 58 FR 48756 (September 17, 1993) (Switched Transport Order), 
    vacated in part and remanded, Bell Atlantic Telephone Cos., v. FCC, 24 
    F.3d 1441; Remand Order, 9 FCC Rcd 5154 (1994) (Virtual Collocation 
    Order), remanded for consideration of 1996 Act, Pacific Bell, et al. v. 
    FCC, 81 F.3d 1147 (1996) (collectively referred to as Expanded 
    Interconnection). Interstate access is a service traditionally provided 
    by local telephone companies and enables IXCs and other customers to 
    originate and terminate interstate telephone traffic. Special access is 
    a form of interstate access that uses dedicated transmission lines 
    between two points, without switching the traffic on those lines. 
    Switched transport is another form of interstate access comprising the 
    transmission of traffic between interexchange carriers' (or other 
    customers') points of presence and local telephone companies' end 
    offices, where the traffic is switched and routed to end users. We 
    required Tier 1 LECs to offer physical collocation, with the 
    interconnecting party paying the LEC for central office floor space. 
    (Tier 1 LECs are local exchange carriers having $100 million or more in 
    ``total company annual regulated revenues.'' Commission Requirements 
    for Cost Support Material to be Filed with 1990 Annual Access Tariffs, 
    5 FCC Rcd 1364, 1364 (Com. Car. Bur. 1990)). We required that LECs 
    provide space to interested parties on a first-come first-served basis, 
    and that they provide virtual collocation when space for physical 
    collocation is exhausted. Under virtual collocation, interconnectors 
    are allowed to designate central office transmission equipment 
    dedicated to their use, as well as to monitor and control their 
    circuits terminating in the LEC central office. Interconnectors, 
    however, do not pay for the incumbent's floor space under virtual 
    collocation arrangements and have no right to enter the LEC central 
    office. Under our virtual collocation requirements, LECs must install, 
    maintain, and repair interconnector-designated equipment under the same 
    intervals and with the same or better failure rates for the performance 
    of similar functions for comparable LEC equipment.
        381. In the Expanded Interconnection proceeding, we required the 
    LECs to file tariffs to implement our virtual and physical collocation 
    requirements. Our initial review of the LECs' tariffs raised 
    significant concerns regarding the LECs' provision of physical and 
    virtual collocation. Consequently, the Bureau partially suspended the 
    rates proposed by many of the LECs and allowed these rates to take 
    effect subject to investigation and an accounting order.
        382. In 1994, the U.S. Court of Appeals for the District of 
    Columbia Circuit found that the FCC lacked the authority under section 
    201 of the 1934 Communications Act to require physical collocation and 
    remanded all other issues to the Commission. Bell Atlantic v. FCC, 24 
    F.3d 1441. On remand, we adopted rules for both special access and 
    switched transport that required LECs to provide either virtual or 
    physical collocation, at the LECs' option. Those rules currently are in 
    place, although the court of appeals remanded the Remand Order to us to 
    consider the impact of the 1996 Act on those rules. Pacific Bell et al. 
    v. FCC, 81 F.3d 1147 (D.C. Cir. 1996). As discussed below, we find that 
    the 1996 Act does not supplant or otherwise alter our Expanded 
    Interconnection rules for interstate interconnection services provided 
    pursuant to section 201 of the Communications Act. In the 1996 Act, 
    Congress specifically directed
    
    [[Page 45535]]
    
    incumbent LECs to provide physical collocation for interconnection and 
    access to unbundled network elements, absent technical or space 
    constraints, pursuant to section 251(c)(6) of the Communications Act.
        383. We sought comment in the NPRM on whether, for purposes of 
    implementing physical and virtual collocation under section 251, we 
    should readopt the standards set out in our Expanded Interconnection 
    proceeding and, if so, how to adapt those standards to reflect the new 
    statutory requirements and other policy considerations of the 1996 Act.
    (2) Discussion
        384. We conclude that we should adopt the existing Expanded 
    Interconnection requirements, with some modifications, as the rules 
    applicable for collocation under section 251. Those rules were 
    established on the basis of an extensive record in the Expanded 
    Interconnection proceeding, and are largely consistent with the 
    requirements of section 251(c)(6). Adoption of those requirements for 
    purposes of collocation under section 251, moreover, has substantial 
    support in the record of this proceeding. Thus, the standards 
    established for physical and virtual collocation in our Expanded 
    Interconnection proceeding will generally apply to collocation under 
    section 251. The most significant requirements of Expanded 
    Interconnection are specifically set out in rules we adopt here. We 
    address pricing and rate structure issues separately, in section VII 
    below.
        385. We find, however, that certain modifications to our Expanded 
    Interconnection requirements are necessary to account for specific 
    provisions of section 251(c)(6) and service arrangements that differ 
    from those contemplated in our Expanded Interconnection orders. For 
    example, the Expanded Interconnection requirements apply to Tier 1 LECs 
    that are not NECA pool members, and section 251 applies to ``incumbent 
    LECs,'' though there is an exemption for certain rural carriers. 
    Expanded Interconnection also allows end-users to interconnect their 
    equipment, while section 251 requires that interconnection and access 
    to unbundled network elements be provided to ``any requesting 
    telecommunications carrier.'' Accordingly, we set forth below several 
    modifications to the terms and conditions for collocation as they are 
    described in our Expanded Interconnection orders for application in 
    implementing section 251. We believe that, in light of the expedited 
    statutory time frame for this rulemaking and limited record addressing 
    the specific terms and conditions for collocation under section 251 in 
    this proceeding, it would be impractical and imprudent to develop a 
    large number of new substantive collocation requirements in this order. 
    We may consider the need for additional or different requirements in a 
    subsequent proceeding, if we determine that such action is warranted.
        386. The most significant difference between the Expanded 
    Interconnection rules and the collocation rules we adopt to implement 
    the 1996 Act concerns the collocation tariffing requirement. As 
    discussed below, the 1996 Act does not require that collocation be 
    federally tariffed. We thus do not adopt, under section 251, the 
    Expanded Interconnection tariffing requirements originally adopted 
    under section 201 for physical and virtual collocation. The existing 
    tariffing requirements of Expanded Interconnection for interstate 
    special access and switched transport will continue to apply for use by 
    customers that wish to subscribe to those interstate services.
        387. We reject SBC's contention that we may not adopt any terms and 
    conditions in this proceeding that differ from those in the Expanded 
    Interconnection proceeding. SBC argues that Congress intended, in 
    section 251(c)(6), to use the term ``physical collocation'' as a term 
    of art, and thereby to adopt wholesale the terms and conditions for 
    physical collocation that the Commission adopted in the Expanded 
    Interconnection proceeding. A variety of terms and conditions for 
    physical collocation are possible and section 251(c)(6) makes no 
    reference to the Commission's decisions on these issues in the Expanded 
    Interconnection proceeding. If Congress had intended to readopt those 
    rules wholesale without permitting the Commission any flexibility in 
    the matter, we believe that Congress would have been more explicit 
    rather than merely using the phrase ``physical collocation.'' Thus, we 
    believe that we can and should modify our preexisting standards, as set 
    forth below, for purposes of implementing the provisions of section 
    251(c)(6). In the following sections (c.-i.) we address comments filed 
    by interested parties concerning application of our existing Expanded 
    Interconnection requirements for purposes of collocation under section 
    251. (In a number of instances, we decline to adopt proposals for 
    modifications to our Expanded Interconnection requirements.)
        388. Finally, our experience reviewing the tariffs that incumbent 
    LECs filed to implement our requirements for physical and virtual 
    collocation suggests that rates, terms, and conditions under which 
    incumbent LECs propose to provide these arrangements pursuant to 
    section 251(c)(6) bear close scrutiny. We strongly urge state 
    commissions to be vigilant in their review of such arrangements. Some 
    areas our investigations have found problematic in the past include 
    channel assignment, letters of agency, charges for repeaters, and 
    placement of point-of-termination bays. We will review this issue and 
    revise our requirements as necessary.
    c. The Meaning of the Term ``Premises''
    (1) Background
        389. In the Expanded Interconnection proceeding, we required 
    collocation at end offices, serving wire centers, and tandem switches, 
    as well as at remote distribution nodes and any other points that the 
    LEC treats as a ``rating point.'' A rating point is a point used in 
    calculating the length of interoffice special access links. Section 
    251(c)(6) requires physical collocation ``at the premises of the local 
    exchange carrier.'' In the NPRM, we tentatively concluded that the term 
    ``premises'' includes, in addition to LEC central offices and tandem 
    offices, all buildings or similar structures owned or leased by the 
    incumbent LEC that house LEC network facilities. We sought comment on 
    whether structures that house LEC network facilities on public rights-
    of-way, such as vaults containing loop concentrators or similar 
    structures, should be deemed to be LEC ``premises.''
    (2) Discussion
        390. The 1996 Act does not address the definition of premises, nor 
    is the term discussed in the legislative history. Therefore, we look to 
    the purposes of the 1996 Act and general uses of the term ``premises'' 
    in other contexts in order to define this term for purposes of section 
    251(c)(6). The term ``premises'' is defined in varying ways, according 
    to the context in which it is used. In light of the 1996 Act's 
    procompetitive purposes, we find that a broad definition of the term 
    ``premises'' is appropriate in order to permit new entrants to 
    collocate at a broad range of points under the incumbent LEC's control. 
    A broad definition will allow collocation at points other than those 
    specified for collocation under the existing Expanded Interconnection 
    requirements. We find that this result is
    
    [[Page 45536]]
    
    appropriate because the purposes of physical and virtual collocation 
    under section 251 are broader than those established in the Expanded 
    Interconnection proceeding. We therefore interpret the term 
    ``premises'' broadly to include LEC central offices, serving wire 
    centers and tandem offices, as well as all buildings or similar 
    structures owned or leased by the incumbent LEC that house LEC network 
    facilities. We also treat as incumbent LEC premises any structures that 
    house LEC network facilities on public rights-of-way, such as vaults 
    containing loop concentrators or similar structures.
        391. As discussed below, we conclude that section 251(c)(6) 
    requires collocation only where technically feasible. In light of this 
    conclusion, we find that adoption of a definition of ``premises'' that 
    depends on whether interconnection or access to unbundled network 
    elements at a particular point is ``technically feasible,'' as 
    suggested by Ameritech and Pacific Telesis, would be superfluous. We 
    also conclude that it is not appropriate to adopt a definition of 
    ``premises,'' as suggested by several parties, that is dependent on 
    whether it is ``practical'' to collocate equipment at a particular 
    point. We note however, that neither physical nor virtual collocation 
    is required at points where not technically feasible. We therefore 
    decline to adopt specific requirements regarding collocation at 
    particular points in the LEC network, as suggested by GVNW and others. 
    Because collocation is only required where technically feasible, the 
    approach we here adopt will enable competitors to take advantage of 
    opportunities to collocate equipment without imposing undue burdens on 
    incumbent LECs, whether large or small.
        392. We also address the impact on small incumbent LECs. For 
    example, the Rural Tel. Coalition asks that interconnection and 
    collocation points be established in a flexible manner. We have 
    considered the economic impact of our rules in this section on small 
    incumbent LECs. For example, we do not adopt rigid requirements for 
    locations where collocation must be provided. Incumbent LECs are not 
    required to physically collocate equipment in locations where not 
    practical for technical reasons or because of space limitations, and 
    virtual collocation is required only where technically feasible. We 
    also note, however, that section 251(f) of the 1996 Act provides relief 
    to certain small LECs from our regulations implementing section 251.
    d. Collocation Equipment
    (1) Background
        393. In the Expanded Interconnection proceeding, we allowed 
    collocation for central office equipment needed to terminate basic 
    transmission facilities between LEC central offices and third-party 
    premises. Acceptable equipment included optical terminating equipment 
    and multiplexers. We did not require the LECs to permit collocation of 
    enhanced services equipment or customer premises equipment because such 
    equipment was not necessary to foster competition in the provision of 
    basic transmission services. We also did not require LECs to allow the 
    collocation of switches. Section 251(c)(6) requires incumbent LECs to 
    allow collocation of ``equipment necessary for interconnection or 
    access to unbundled elements. * * *'' We sought comment in the NPRM on 
    what types of equipment competitors should be permitted to collocate on 
    LEC premises.
    (2) Discussion
        394. We believe that section 251(c)(6) generally requires that 
    incumbent LECs permit the collocation of equipment used for 
    interconnection or access to unbundled network elements. Although the 
    term ``necessary,'' read most strictly, could be interpreted to mean 
    ``indispensable,'' we conclude that for the purposes of section 
    251(c)(6) ``necessary'' does not mean ``indispensable'' but rather 
    ``used'' or ``useful.'' This interpretation is most likely to promote 
    fair competition consistent with the purposes of the Act. (We note that 
    this view is consistent with the findings of the Colorado Commission.) 
    Colorado Public Utilities Commission, Proposed Rules Regarding 
    Implementation of Secs. 40-15-101 et seq., Requirements Relating to 
    Interconnection and Unbundling, Docket No. 95R-556T, (Colorado 
    Commission, March 29, 1996) at 19-20. Thus, we read section 251(c)(6) 
    to refer to equipment used for the purpose of interconnection or access 
    to unbundled network elements. Cf. National Railroad Passenger 
    Corporation v. Boston and Maine Corp., 503 U.S. 407, 417 (1992) 
    (upholding the ICC's interpretation of the word ``required'' as 
    ``useful or appropriate,'' rather than ``indispensable''); McCulloch v. 
    Maryland, 4 Wheat. 316, 413 (1819) (Chief Justice Marshall read the 
    word ``necessary'' to mean ``convenient, or useful,'' rejecting a 
    stricter reading of the term). Even if the collocator could use other 
    equipment to perform a similar function, the specified equipment may 
    still be ``necessary'' for interconnection or access to unbundled 
    network elements under section 251(c)(6). We can easily imagine 
    circumstances, for instance, in which alternative equipment would 
    perform the same function, but with less efficiency or at greater cost. 
    A strict reading of the term ``necessary'' in these circumstances could 
    allow LECs to avoid collocating the equipment of the interconnectors' 
    choosing, thus undermining the procompetitive purposes of the 1996 Act.
        395. Consistent with this interpretation, we conclude that 
    transmission equipment, such as optical terminating equipment and 
    multiplexers, may be collocated on LEC premises. We also conclude that 
    LECs should continue to permit collocation of any type of equipment 
    currently being collocated to terminate basic transmission facilities 
    under the Expanded Interconnection requirements. In addition, whenever 
    a telecommunications carrier seeks to collocate equipment for purposes 
    within the scope of section 251(c)(6), the incumbent LEC shall prove to 
    the State commission that such equipment is not ``necessary,'' as we 
    have defined that term, for interconnection or access to unbundled 
    network elements. State commissions may designate specific additional 
    types of equipment that may be collocated pursuant to section 
    251(c)(6).
        396. We do not find, however, that section 251(c)(6) requires 
    collocation of equipment used to provide enhanced services, contrary to 
    the arguments of the Association of Telemessaging Services 
    International. We also decline to require incumbent LECs to allow 
    collocation of any equipment without restriction. Section 251(c)(6) 
    requires collocation only of equipment ``necessary for interconnection 
    or access to unbundled elements.'' Section 251(c)(2) requires incumbent 
    LECs to provide ``interconnection'' for the ``transmission and routing 
    of telephone exchange service and exchange access,'' and section 
    251(c)(3) requires incumbent LECs to provide access to unbundled 
    network elements ``for the provision of a telecommunications service.'' 
    Section 251(c)(6) therefore requires incumbent LECs to provide physical 
    or virtual collocation only for equipment ``necessary'' or used for 
    those purposes. We find that section 251(c)(6) does not require 
    collocation of equipment necessary to provide enhanced services. We 
    declined to require collocation of enhanced services equipment in our 
    Computer III and ONA proceedings. See Third Computer
    
    [[Page 45537]]
    
    Inquiry, Report and Order, 51 FR 24350 (July 3, 1986); Computer III 
    Remand, 57 FR 4373 (February 5, 1992). Enhanced services are defined as 
    services that ``employ computer processing applications which act on 
    the format, content, code, protocol or similar aspects of the 
    subscriber's transmitted information; provide the subscriber 
    additional, different, or restructured information; or involve 
    subscriber interaction with stored information.'' 47 CFR Sec. 64.702. 
    This definition appears not to include the provision of 
    ``telecommunications services.'' See 47 U.S.C. Sec. 153(43), (46). At 
    this time, we do not impose a general requirement that switching 
    equipment be collocated since it does not appear that it is used for 
    the actual interconnection or access to unbundled network elements. We 
    recognize, however, that modern technology has tended to blur the line 
    between switching equipment and multiplexing equipment, which we permit 
    to be collocated. We expect, in situations where the functionality of a 
    particular piece of equipment is in dispute, that state commissions 
    will determine whether the equipment at issue is actually used for 
    interconnection or access to unbundled elements. We also reserve the 
    right to reexamine this issue at a later date if it appears that such 
    action would further achievement of the 1996 Act's procompetitive 
    goals. Finally, because we lack an adequate record on the issue, we 
    decline to adopt AT&T's proposal that we require that incumbent LECs 
    allow collocated equipment to be used for ``hubbing.'' AT&T advocates 
    requiring LECs to allow new entrants to ``connect additional equipment 
    of their own to their collocated equipment in the collocated space.''
        397. In response to WinStar's suggestion that we require 
    collocation of microwave transmission facilities, we note that 
    collocation of microwave transmission equipment was required where 
    reasonably feasible by the Special Access Order. We also require the 
    collocation of microwave equipment under section 251, although we 
    modify the Expanded Interconnection standard we adopt under section 251 
    for when such collocation is required slightly to conform to the 
    standard for the provision of physical collocation in section 
    251(c)(6). We therefore require that incumbent LECs allow competitors 
    to use physical collocation for microwave transmission facilities 
    except where this is not practical for technical reasons or because of 
    space limitations, in which case virtual collocation is required where 
    technically feasible.
    e. Allocation of Space
    (1) Background
        398. In the Expanded Interconnection proceeding, we required LECs 
    to allocate space for physical collocation on a first-come, first-
    served basis. We also required LECs to take into account interconnector 
    demand for collocation space when reconfiguring space or building new 
    central offices, and we found that imposing reasonable restrictions on 
    warehousing of space by collocating carriers was appropriate. The NPRM 
    sought comment on whether national guidelines would deter 
    anticompetitive behavior through the manipulation or unreasonable 
    allocation of space by either incumbent LECs or new entrants.
    (2) Discussion
        399. We believe that incumbent LECs have the incentive and 
    capability to impede competitive entry by minimizing the amount of 
    space that is available for collocation by competitors. Accordingly, we 
    adopt our Expanded Interconnection space allocation rules for purposes 
    of section 251, except as indicated herein. LECs will thus be required 
    to make space available to requesting carriers on a first-come, first-
    served basis. We also conclude that collocators seeking to expand their 
    collocated space should be allowed to use contiguous space where 
    available. We further conclude that LECs should not be required to 
    lease or construct additional space to provide physical collocation to 
    interconnectors when existing space has been exhausted. We find such a 
    requirement unnecessary because section 251(c)(6) allows incumbent LECs 
    to provide virtual collocation where physical collocation is not 
    practical for technical reasons or because of space limitations. 
    Consistent with the requirements and findings of the Expanded 
    Interconnection proceeding, we conclude that incumbent LECs should be 
    required to take collocator demand into account when renovating 
    existing facilities and constructing or leasing new facilities, just as 
    they consider demand for other services when undertaking such projects. 
    We find that this requirement is necessary in order to ensure that 
    sufficient collocation space will be available in the future. We 
    decline, however, to adopt a general rule requiring LECs to file 
    reports on the status and planned increase and use of space. State 
    commissions will determine whether sufficient space is available for 
    physical collocation, and we conclude that they have authority under 
    the 1996 Act to require incumbent LECs to file such reports. We expect 
    individual state commissions to determine whether the filing of such 
    reports is warranted.
        400. We also agree with Pacific Telesis that restrictions on 
    warehousing of space by interconnectors are appropriate. Because 
    collocation space on incumbent LEC premises may be limited, inefficient 
    use of space by one competitive entrant could deprive another entrant 
    of the opportunity to collocate facilities or expand existing space. In 
    the Expanded Interconnection proceeding, we allowed ``reasonable 
    restrictions on warehousing of space,'' and will adopt this provision 
    for purposes of section 251. As discussed below, we also adopt measures 
    to ensure that incumbent LECs themselves do not unreasonably 
    ``warehouse'' space, although we do permit them to reserve a limited 
    amount of space for specific future uses. Incumbent LECs, however, are 
    not permitted to set maximum space limitations without demonstrating 
    that space constraints make such restrictions necessary, as such 
    maximum limits could constrain a collocator's ability to provide 
    service efficiently.
        401. We also address the impact on small incumbent LECs. For 
    example, GVNW argues that we should require collocation in rural areas 
    only where there is space available. We have considered the impact of 
    our rules in this section on small incumbent LECs and do not require 
    physical collocation at any point where there is insufficient space 
    available. We decline, however, to adopt rules regarding space 
    availability that apply differently to small, rural carriers because 
    the rules we here adopt are sufficiently flexible. We also note, 
    however, that section 251(f) of the 1996 Act provides relief to certain 
    small LECs from our regulations implementing section 251.
    f. Leasing Transport Facilities
    (1) Background
        402. Our Expanded Interconnection rules require LECs to provide 
    collocation for the purpose of allowing collocators to terminate their 
    own transmission facilities for special access or switched transport 
    service. We did not require that collocation be made available for 
    other purposes, for example, when the interconnecting party wished only 
    to connect incumbent LEC transmission facilities to collocated 
    equipment. We sought comment in the NPRM on whether we should modify
    
    [[Page 45538]]
    
    the standards of the Expanded Interconnection proceeding in light of 
    the new statutory requirements and disputes that have arisen in the 
    investigations regarding the incumbent LECs' physical and virtual 
    collocation tariffs.
    (2) Discussion
        403. Although in Expanded Interconnection the Commission required 
    that interested parties interconnect collocated equipment with their 
    own transmission facilities, we conclude that it would be inconsistent 
    with the provisions of the 1996 Act to adopt that requirement under 
    section 251. Rather, we conclude that a competitive entrant should not 
    be required to bring transmission facilities to LEC premises in which 
    it seeks to collocate facilities. Entrants should instead be permitted 
    to collocate and connect equipment to unbundled network transmission 
    elements obtained from the incumbent LEC. The purpose of the Expanded 
    Interconnection requirement was to foster competition in the market for 
    interstate switched and special access transmission facilities. The 
    purposes of section 251 are broader. Section 251(c)(3) requires that 
    competitive entrants be given access to unbundled elements and that 
    they be permitted to combine such elements. Prohibiting competitors 
    from connecting unbundled network elements to their collocated 
    equipment would appear contrary to the provisions of section 251(c)(3).
        404. Finally, we find that Bell Atlantic's opposition to this 
    requirement is without merit. Bell Atlantic argues that collocators 
    should be required to provide their own transmission facilities because 
    otherwise new entrants could compete without providing any of their own 
    facilities. Section 251(c)(3) specifically states that unbundled 
    elements are to be provided in a manner that allows requesting carriers 
    to combine elements in order to provide telecommunications service. As 
    stated above, requiring collocators to supply their own transmission 
    facilities would amount to a prohibition on connecting unbundled 
    transmission facilities to other unbundled elements connected to 
    equipment in the collocation space. Although such interconnection 
    arrangements were not required by our Expanded Interconnection 
    requirements, we conclude that they are required by section 251 when 
    collocated equipment is used to achieve interconnection or access to 
    unbundled network elements.
    g. Co-Carrier Cross-Connect
    (1) Background
        405. In the most common collocation configuration under existing 
    requirements, the designated physical collocation space of several 
    competitive entrants is located close together within the LEC premises. 
    Since carriers connect to the collocation space via high-capacity 
    lines, different competitive entrants seeking to interconnect with each 
    other may find connecting between their respective collocation spaces 
    on the LEC premises the most efficient means of interconnecting with 
    each other. We sought comment in the NPRM on whether we should adopt 
    any requirements in addition to those adopted in the Expanded 
    Interconnection proceeding in order to fulfill the mandate of the 1996 
    Act.
    (2) Discussion
        406. We believe that it serves the public interest and is 
    consistent with the policy goals of section 251 to require that 
    incumbents permit two or more collocators to interconnect their 
    networks at the incumbent's premises. Parties opposed to this proposal 
    have offered no legitimate objection to such interconnection. Allowing 
    incumbent LECs to prohibit collocating carriers from interconnecting 
    their collocated equipment would require them to interconnect 
    collocated facilities by routing transmission facilities outside of the 
    LECs' premises. We find that such a policy would needlessly burden 
    collocating carriers. To the extent equipment is collocated for the 
    purposes expressly permitted under section 251(c)(6), the statute does 
    not bar us from requiring that incumbent LECs allow connection of such 
    equipment to other collocating carriers located nearby. We find that 
    requiring LECs to allow such interconnection of collocated equipment 
    will foster competition by promoting efficient operation. It is also 
    unlikely to have a significant effect on space availability. We find 
    authority for such a requirement in section 251(c)(6), which requires 
    that collocation be provided on ``terms and conditions that are just, 
    reasonable, and nondiscriminatory'' and in section 4(i), which permits 
    the Commission to ``perform any and all acts, make such rules and 
    regulations, and issue such orders, not inconsistent with this Act, as 
    may be necessary in the execution of its functions.'' We therefore will 
    require that incumbent LECs allow collocating telecommunications 
    carriers to connect collocated equipment to such equipment of other 
    carriers within the same LEC premises so long as the collocated 
    equipment is used for interconnection with the incumbent LEC or access 
    to the LEC's unbundled network elements.
        407. We clarify that we here require incumbent LECs to provide the 
    connection between the equipment in the collocated spaces of two or 
    more collocating telecommunications carriers unless they permit the 
    collocating parties to provide this connection for themselves. We do 
    not require incumbent LECs to allow placement of connecting 
    transmission facilities owned by competitors within the incumbent LEC 
    premises anywhere outside of the actual physical collocation space.
    h. Security Arrangements
    (1) Background
        408. Under our Expanded Interconnection requirements, incumbent 
    LECs typically require that physically collocated equipment be placed 
    inside a collocation cage within the incumbent LEC facility. Such cages 
    are intended to separate physically the competitors' facilities from 
    those of the incumbent and to prevent access by unauthorized personnel 
    to any parties' equipment. Such cages frequently add considerably to 
    the cost of establishing physical collocation at a particular LEC 
    premises and could constitute a barrier to entry in certain 
    circumstances.
    (2) Discussion
        409. Based on the comments in this proceeding and our previous 
    experience with physical collocation in the Expanded Interconnection 
    docket, we will continue to permit LECs to require reasonable security 
    arrangements to separate an entrant's collocation space from the 
    incumbent LEC's facilities. The physical security arrangements around 
    the collocation space protect both the LEC's and competitor's equipment 
    from interference by unauthorized parties. We reject the suggestion of 
    ALTS and MCI that security measures be provided only at the request of 
    the entrant since LECs have legitimate security concerns about having 
    competitors' personnel on their premises as well. We conclude that the 
    physical separation provided by the collocation cage adequately 
    addresses these concerns. At the same time, we recognize that the 
    construction costs of physical security arrangements could serve as a 
    significant barrier to entry, particularly for smaller competitors. We 
    also conclude that LECs have both an incentive and the capability to 
    impose higher construction costs than the new
    
    [[Page 45539]]
    
    entrant might need to incur. We therefore conclude that collocating 
    parties should have the right to subcontract the construction of the 
    physical collocation arrangements with contractors approved by the 
    incumbent LEC. Incumbent LECs shall not unreasonably withhold such 
    approval of contractors. Approval by incumbent LECs of such contractors 
    should be based on the same criteria as such LECs use for approving 
    contractors for their own purposes. We decline, however, to require 
    that competitive entrants' personnel be subject to minimum training and 
    proficiency requirements as suggested by GVNW. We find that such 
    concerns are better resolved through negotiation and arbitration.
    i. Allowing Virtual Collocation in Lieu of Physical
    (1) Background
        410. Section 251(c)(6) requires that incumbent LECs provide 
    physical collocation unless the carrier ``demonstrates to the state 
    commission that physical collocation is not practical for technical 
    reasons or because of space limitations * * *.'' In the NPRM, we sought 
    comment on whether the Commission should establish guidelines for 
    states to apply when determining whether physical collocation is not 
    practical for ``technical reasons or because of space limitations.''
    (2) Discussion
        411. Section 251(c)(6) clearly contemplates the provision of 
    virtual collocation when physical collocation is not practical for 
    technical reasons or because of space limitations. Section 251(c)(6) 
    requires the incumbent LEC to demonstrate to the state commission's 
    satisfaction that there are space limitations on the LEC premises or 
    that technical considerations make collocation impractical. Because the 
    space limitations and technical practicality issues will vary 
    considerably depending on the location at which competitor equipment is 
    to be collocated, we find that these issues are best handled on a case-
    by-case basis, as they were under our Expanded Interconnection 
    requirements. In light of our experience in the Expanded 
    Interconnection proceeding, we require that incumbent LECs provide the 
    state commission with detailed floor plans or diagrams of any premises 
    where the incumbent alleges that there are space constraints. 
    Submission of floor plans will enable state commissions to evaluate 
    whether a refusal to allow physical collocation on the grounds of space 
    constraints is justified. We also find that the approach detailed by 
    AT&T in its July 12 Ex Parte submission to be useful and believe that 
    state commissions may find it a valuable guide. AT&T describes a 
    detailed proposed showing that would be required of an incumbent LEC 
    that claims physical collocation is not practical because of space 
    exhaustion. The proposed showing would require the specific 
    identification of the space on incumbent LEC premises that is used for 
    various purposes, as well as specific plans for rearrangement/expansion 
    and identification of steps taken to avoid exhaustion.
        412. Although section 251(c)(6) provides that incumbent LECs are 
    not required to provide physical collocation where impractical for 
    technical reasons or because of space limitations, our experience in 
    the Expanded Interconnection proceeding has not demonstrated that 
    technical reasons, apart from those related to space availability, are 
    a significant impediment to physical collocation. We therefore decline 
    to adopt any rules for determining when physical collocation should be 
    deemed impractical for technical reasons.
        413. Incumbent LECs are allowed to retain a limited amount of floor 
    space for defined future uses. Allowing competitive entrants to claim 
    space that incumbent LECs had specifically planned to use could prevent 
    incumbent LECs from serving their customers effectively. Incumbent LECs 
    may not, however, reserve space for future use on terms more favorable 
    than those that apply to other telecommunications carriers seeking to 
    hold collocation space for their own future use.
        414. We decline to adopt AT&T's suggestion that incumbent LECs 
    should be required to lease additional space or provide trunking at no 
    cost where they have insufficient space for physical collocation. In 
    light of the availability of substitute virtual collocation 
    arrangements, we find that requiring the type of ``substitute'' for 
    physical collocation as advocated by AT&T is unnecessary. We similarly 
    reject Time Warner's suggestion that incumbent LECs supply a 
    ``substitute'' for physical collocation at cost, except to the extent 
    we require virtual collocation. On the other hand, we will require 
    incumbent LECs with limited space availability to take into account the 
    demands of interconnectors when planning renovations and leasing or 
    constructing new premises, as we have in the Expanded Interconnection 
    proceeding.
        415. Incumbent LECs are not required to provide collocation at 
    locations where it is not technically feasible to provide virtual 
    collocation. Although space constraints are a concern normally 
    associated with physical collocation, given our broad reading of the 
    term ``premises,'' we find that space constraints could preclude 
    virtual collocation at certain LEC premises as well. State commissions 
    will decide whether virtual collocation is technically feasible at a 
    given point. We do, however, require that incumbent LECs relinquish any 
    space held for future use before denying virtual collocation due to a 
    lack of space unless the incumbent can prove to a state commission that 
    virtual collocation at that point is not technically feasible. 
    Moreover, when virtual collocation is not feasible, we require that 
    incumbent LECs provide other forms of interconnection and access to 
    unbundled network elements to the extent technically feasible.
        416. Finally, we decline to require that incumbent LECs provide 
    virtual collocation that is equal in all functional aspects to physical 
    collocation. Our Expanded Interconnection rules required a variety of 
    standards for the virtual collocation and have been largely successful. 
    In addition, Congress was aware of the differences between virtual and 
    physical collocation when it adopted section 251(c)(6), and this 
    section does not specify any requirements for virtual collocation. As 
    discussed above, we adopt the Expanded Interconnection requirements for 
    virtual collocation under section 251. We find, however, that a 
    standard simply requiring equality in all functional aspects could be 
    difficult to administrate and could lead to substantial disputes. We 
    also decline to adopt the suggestion that we require LECs to offer 
    virtual collocation under the ``$1 sale and repurchase option.'' This 
    configuration is described as involving ``the acquisition by the 
    interconnectors of the equipment to be dedicated for interconnectors' 
    use on the LEC premises and the sale of that equipment to the LECs for 
    a nominal $1 sum while maintaining a repurchase option.'' We do not 
    find evidence that such a specific requirement is necessary at this 
    time. We reserve the right to revisit these issues in the future, 
    however, if we perceive that smaller entities would be disadvantaged by 
    our existing standards.
    2. Legal Issues
    a. Relationship Between Expanded Interconnection Tariffs and Section 
    251
    (1) Background
        417. The enactment of sections 251 and 252 raises the question of 
    whether,
    
    [[Page 45540]]
    
    and to what extent, the interconnection, access to unbundled network 
    element, and collocation requirements set forth in those sections, and 
    the delegation of specific rate-setting authority to the states under 
    section 252(d)(1), as a matter of law supplant our section 201 Expanded 
    Interconnection requirements. We tentatively concluded in the NPRM that 
    our existing Expanded Interconnection policies for interstate special 
    access and switched transport should continue to apply.
    (2) Discussion
        418. Our Expanded Interconnection rules require the largest 
    incumbent LECs to file tariffs with the Commission to offer collocation 
    to parties that wish to terminate interstate special access and 
    switched transport transmission facilities. Section 252 of the 1996 
    Act, on the other hand, provides for interconnection arrangements 
    rather than tariffs, for review and approval of such agreements by 
    state commissions rather than the FCC, and for public filing of such 
    agreements. Section 252 procedures, however, apply only to ``request[s] 
    for interconnection, services, or network elements pursuant to section 
    251.'' Such procedures do not, by their terms, apply to requests for 
    service under section 201. Moreover, section 251(i) expressly provides 
    that ``[n]othing in this section shall be construed to limit or 
    otherwise affect the Commission's authority under section 201,'' which 
    provided the statutory basis for our Expanded Interconnection rules. 
    Thus, we find that the 1996 Act, as a matter of law, does not displace 
    our Expanded Interconnection requirements, and, in fact, grants 
    discretion to the FCC to preserve our existing rules and tariffing 
    requirements to the extent they are consistent with the Communications 
    Act.
        419. We further conclude that it would make little sense to find 
    that sections 251 and 252 supersede our Expanded Interconnection rules, 
    because the two sets of requirements are not coextensive. For example, 
    our Expanded Interconnection rules encompass collocation for interstate 
    purposes for all parties, including non-carrier end users, that seek to 
    terminate transmission facilities at LEC central offices. In 
    comparison, section 251 requires collocation only for ``any requesting 
    telecommunications carrier.'' Certain competing carriers--and non-
    carrier customers not covered by section 251--may prefer to take 
    interstate expanded interconnection service under general interstate 
    tariff schedules. We find that it would be unnecessarily disruptive to 
    eliminate that possibility at this time. We also conclude that 
    permitting requesting carriers to seek interconnection pursuant to our 
    Expanded Interconnection rules as well as section 251 is consistent 
    with the goals of the 1996 Act to permit competitive entry through a 
    variety of entry strategies. Thus, a requesting carrier would have the 
    choice of negotiating an interconnection agreement pursuant to sections 
    251 and 252 or of taking tariffed interstate service under our Expanded 
    Interconnection rules.
        420. Finally, we expect that, over time, sections 251 and 252 and 
    our implementing rules may replace our Expanded Interconnection rules 
    as the primary regulations governing interconnection for carriers. We 
    note that section 251 is broader than our Expanded Interconnection 
    requirements in certain respects. For example, section 251 requires 
    incumbent LECs to offer collocation for purposes of accessing unbundled 
    network elements, whereas our Expanded Interconnection rules require 
    collocation only for the provision of interstate special access and 
    switched transport. In addition, section 251(c)(6) requires incumbents 
    to offer physical collocation subject to certain exceptions, whereas 
    our existing Expanded Interconnection rules only require carriers to 
    offer virtual collocation, although they may choose to offer physical 
    collocation under Title II regulation in lieu of virtual collocation. 
    In the future, we may review the need for a separate set of Expanded 
    Interconnection requirements and revise our requirements if necessary. 
    We believe that this approach is consistent with Congress' 
    determination that the need for federal regulations will likely 
    decrease as the provisions of the 1996 Act take effect and competition 
    develops in the local exchange and exchange access markets.
    b. Takings Issues
    (1) Background
        421. In Bell Atlantic v. FCC, the U.S. Court of Appeals for the DC 
    Circuit found that the Commission lacked authority under the 
    Communications Act to impose physical collocation on the LECs. The 
    court found that this requirement implicated the Fifth Amendment 
    takings clause. See Bell Atlantic v. FCC, 24 F.3d 1441 (DC Cir. 1994). 
    On remand, the Commission required LECs to provide virtual collocation. 
    In Pacific Bell v. FCC, 81 F.3d 1147 (DC Cir. 1996), several LECs 
    challenged the Commission's virtual collocation rules on essentially 
    identical grounds, claiming that the virtual collocation rules also 
    constituted an unauthorized taking. The court did not reach the merits 
    of these claims. Instead, addressing the scope of section 251 
    immediately following enactment and before the FCC had yet exercised 
    its interpretive authority with respect to the provision, the court 
    stated that regulations enacted to implement the 1996 Act would render 
    moot questions regarding the future effect of the virtual collocation 
    order under review. The court did not vacate the order, but remanded to 
    the Commission the issues presented in that case.
    (2) Discussion
        422. We conclude that the ruling in Bell Atlantic does not preclude 
    the rules we are adopting in this proceeding. The court in Bell 
    Atlantic did not hold that an agency may never ``take'' property; the 
    court acknowledged that, as a constitutional matter, takings are 
    unlawful only if they are not accompanied by ``just compensation.'' 
    Instead, the court simply said that the Communications Act of 1934 
    should not be construed to permit the FCC to take LEC property without 
    express authorization. Because the court concluded that mandatory 
    physical collocation would likely constitute a taking, and that section 
    201 of the Act did not expressly authorize physical collocation, the 
    court held that the Commission was without authority under section 201 
    to impose physical collocation requirements on LECs. The Commission 
    maintains the position, however, that mandatory physical collocation 
    should not properly be seen to create a takings issue. See Remand 
    Order, 9 FCC Rcd at 5169.
        423. The question of statutory authority to impose (physical or 
    virtual) collocation obligations on incumbent LECs largely evaporates 
    in the context of the 1996 Act. New section 251(c)(6) expressly 
    requires incumbent LECs to provide physical collocation, absent space 
    or technical limitations. Where such limitations exist, the statute 
    expressly requires virtual collocation. Thus, under the court's 
    analysis in Bell Atlantic, there is no warrant for a narrowing 
    construction of section 251 that would deny us the authority to require 
    either form of collocation. Moreover, for the reasons stated in the 
    Virtual Collocation Order, we continue to believe that virtual 
    collocation, as we have defined it, is not a taking, and that our 
    authority to order such collocation (under either section 251 or 
    section 201) is not subject to the strict construction canon announced 
    in Bell Atlantic.
        424. Given that we now have express statutory authority to order 
    physical and
    
    [[Page 45541]]
    
    virtual collocation pursuant to section 251, any remaining takings-
    related issue necessarily is limited to the question of just 
    compensation. As discussed in Section VII.B.2.a.(3).(c), below, we find 
    that the ratemaking methodology we are adopting to implement the 
    collocation obligations under section 251(c) is consistent with 
    congressional intent and fully satisfies the just compensation 
    standard. There is, therefore, no merit to the LECs' Fifth Amendment-
    based claims.
    
    VII. Pricing of Interconnection and Unbundled Elements
    
    A. Overview
    
        425. The prices of interconnection and unbundled elements, along 
    with prices of resale and transport and termination, are critical terms 
    and conditions of any interconnection agreement. If carriers can agree 
    on such prices voluntarily without government intervention, these 
    agreements will be submitted directly to the states for approval under 
    section 252. To the extent that the carriers, in voluntary 
    negotiations, cannot determine the prices, state commissions will have 
    to set those prices. The price levels set by state commissions will 
    determine whether the 1996 Act is implemented in a manner that is pro-
    competitor and favors one party (whether favoring incumbents or 
    entrants) or, as we believe Congress intended, pro-competition. As 
    discussed more fully in Section II.D. above, it is therefore critical 
    to implementing Congress' pro-competitive, de-regulatory national 
    policy framework to establish among the states a common, pro-
    competition understanding of the pricing standards for interconnection 
    and unbundled elements, resale, and transport and termination. While 
    such a common interpretation might eventually emerge through judicial 
    review of state arbitration decisions, we believe that such a process 
    could delay competition for years and require carriers to incur 
    substantial legal costs. We therefore conclude that, to expedite the 
    development of fair and efficient competition, we must set forth rules 
    now establishing this common, pro-competition understanding of the 1996 
    Act's pricing standards. Accordingly, the rules we adopt today set 
    forth the methodological principles for states to use in setting 
    prices. This section addresses interconnection and unbundled elements, 
    and subsequent sections address resale and transport and termination, 
    respectively.
        426. While every state should, to the maximum extent feasible, 
    immediately apply the pricing methodology for interconnection and 
    unbundled elements that we set forth below, we recognize that not every 
    state will have the resources to implement this pricing methodology 
    immediately in the arbitrations that will need to be decided this fall. 
    Therefore, so that competition is not impaired in the interim, we 
    establish default proxies that a state commission shall use to resolve 
    arbitrations in the period before it applies the pricing methodology. 
    In most cases, these default proxies for unbundled elements and 
    interconnection are ceilings, and states may select lower prices. In 
    one instance, the default proxy we establish is a price range. Once a 
    state sets prices according to an economic cost study conducted 
    pursuant to the cost-based pricing methodology we outline, the defaults 
    cease to apply. In setting a rate pursuant to the cost-based pricing 
    methodology, and especially when setting a rate above a default proxy 
    ceiling or outside the default proxy range, the state must give full 
    and fair effect to the economic costing methodology we set forth in 
    this Order and must create a factual record, including the cost study, 
    sufficient for purposes of review after notice and opportunity for the 
    affected parties to participate.
        427. In the following sections, we first set forth generally, based 
    on the current record, a cost-based pricing methodology based on 
    forward-looking economic costs, which we conclude is the approach for 
    setting prices that best furthers the goals of the 1996 Act. In dynamic 
    competitive markets, firms take action based not on embedded costs, but 
    on the relationship between market-determined prices and forward-
    looking economic costs. If market prices exceed forward-looking 
    economic costs, new competitors will enter the market. If their 
    forward-looking economic costs exceed market prices, new competitors 
    will not enter the market and existing competitors may decide to leave. 
    Prices for unbundled elements under section 251 must be based on cost 
    under the law, and that should be read as requiring that prices be 
    based on forward-looking economic costs. New entrants should make their 
    decisions whether to purchase unbundled elements or to build their own 
    facilities based on the relative economic costs of these options. By 
    contrast, because the cost of building an element is based on forward-
    looking economic costs, new entrants' investment decisions would be 
    distorted if the price of unbundled elements were based on embedded 
    costs. In arbitrations of interconnection arrangements, or in 
    rulemakings the results of which will be applied in arbitrations, 
    states must set prices for interconnection and unbundled network 
    elements based on the forward-looking, long-run, incremental cost 
    methodology we describe below. Using this methodology, states may not 
    set prices lower than the forward-looking incremental costs directly 
    attributable to provision of a given element. They may set prices to 
    permit recovery of a reasonable share of forward-looking joint and 
    common costs of network elements. In the aftermath of the arbitrations 
    and relying on the state experience, we will continue to review this 
    costing methodology, and issue additional guidance as necessary.
        428. We reject various arguments raised by parties regarding the 
    recovery of costs other than forward-looking economic costs in section 
    251 (c)(2) and (c)(3) prices, including the possible recovery of: (1) 
    embedded or accounting costs in excess of economic costs; (2) incumbent 
    LECs' opportunity costs; (3) universal service subsidies; and (4) 
    access charges. As discussed in Section VII.B.2.a. below, certain 
    portions of access charges may continue to be collected for an interim 
    period in addition to section 251(c)(3) prices.
        429. With respect to prices developed under the forward-looking, 
    cost-based pricing methodology, we conclude that incumbent LECs' rates 
    for interconnection and unbundled elements must recover costs in a 
    manner that reflects the way they are incurred. We adopt certain rules 
    that states must follow in setting rates in arbitrations. These rules 
    are designed to ensure the efficient cost-based rates required by the 
    1996 Act.
        430. In the next section of the Order, we establish default proxies 
    that states may elect to use prior to utilizing an economic study and 
    developing prices using the cost-based pricing methodology. We 
    recognize that certain states may find it difficult to apply an 
    economic costing methodology within the statutory time frame for 
    arbitrating interconnection disputes. We therefore set forth default 
    proxies that will be relatively easy to apply on an interim basis to 
    interconnection arrangements. We discuss with respect to particular 
    unbundled elements the reasonable rate structure for those elements and 
    the particular default proxies we are establishing for use pending our 
    adoption of a generic forward-looking cost model. Finally, we discuss 
    the following additional matters: generic forward-looking costing 
    models that we intend to examine further by the first quarter of 1997 
    in order to determine
    
    [[Page 45542]]
    
    whether any of those models, with modifications, could serve as better 
    default proxies; the future adjustment of rates; the relationship of 
    unbundled element prices to retail prices; and the meaning of the 
    statutory prohibition against discrimination in sections 251 and 252.
        431. Those states that have already established methodologies for 
    setting interconnection and unbundled rates must review those 
    methodologies against the rules we are adopting in this Order. To the 
    extent a state's methodology is consistent with the approach we set 
    forth herein, the state may apply that methodology in any section 252 
    arbitration. However, if a state's methodology is not consistent with 
    the rules we adopt today, the state must modify its approach. We invite 
    any state uncertain about whether its approach complies with this Order 
    to seek a declaratory ruling from the Commission.
    
    B. Cost-Based Pricing Methodology
    
        432. As discussed more fully in Section II.D. above, although the 
    states have the crucial role of setting specific rates in arbitrations, 
    the Commission must establish a set of national pricing principles in 
    order to implement Congress's national policy framework. For the 
    reasons set forth in the preceding section and as more fully explained 
    below, we are adopting a cost-based methodology for states to follow in 
    setting interconnection and unbundled element rates. In setting forth 
    the cost-based pricing methodology for interconnection and access to 
    unbundled elements, there are three basic sets of questions that must 
    be addressed. First, does the 1996 Act require that the same standard 
    apply to the pricing of interconnection provided pursuant to section 
    251(c)(2), and unbundled elements provided pursuant to section 
    251(c)(3)? Second, what is the appropriate methodology for establishing 
    the price levels for interconnection and for each unbundled element, 
    how should costs be defined, and is the price based on economic costs, 
    embedded costs, or other costs? Third, what are the appropriate rate 
    structures to be used to set prices designed to recover costs, 
    including a reasonable profit? We address each of these questions in 
    the following sections.
    1. Application of the Statutory Pricing Standard
     a. Background
        433. In the NPRM, we proposed that any pricing principles we adopt 
    should be the same for interconnection and unbundled network elements 
    because sections 251(c)(2) and (c)(3) and 252(d)(1) use the same 
    pricing standard. We invited parties to comment on this issue and to 
    justify any proposed distinction in the priority for interconnection 
    and unbundled network elements. We also stated our belief that the same 
    pricing rules that apply to interconnection and unbundled network 
    elements should also apply to collocation under section 251(c)(6) of 
    the 1996 Act.
    b. Discussion
        434. Sections 251(c)(2) and (c)(3) impose an identical duty on 
    incumbent LECs to provide interconnection and access to network 
    elements ``on rates, terms, and conditions that are just, reasonable, 
    and nondiscriminatory.'' In addition, both interconnection and 
    unbundled network elements are made subject to the same pricing 
    standard in section 252(d)(1). Based on the plain language of sections 
    251(c)(2), (c)(3), and section 252(d)(1), we conclude that Congress 
    intended to apply the same pricing rules to interconnection and 
    unbundled network elements. The pricing rules we adopt shall, 
    therefore, apply to both.
        435. We further conclude that, because section 251(c)(6) requires 
    that incumbent LECs provide physical collocation on ``rates, terms, and 
    conditions that are just, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory,'' which is 
    identical to the standard for interconnection and unbundled elements in 
    sections 251(c)(2) and (c)(3), collocation should be subject to the 
    same pricing rules. We also note that, because collocation is a method 
    of obtaining interconnection and access to unbundled network elements, 
    collocation is properly treated under the same pricing rules. This 
    legal conclusion that there should be a single set of pricing rules for 
    interconnection, unbundled network elements, and collocation provides 
    greater consistency and guidance to the industry, regulators, and the 
    courts. Moreover, it reduces the regulatory burdens on state 
    commissions of developing and applying different pricing rules for 
    collocation, interconnection, and unbundled network elements. We note 
    that our adoption of this single set of pricing rules should minimize 
    regulatory burdens, conflicts, and uncertainties associated with 
    multiple, and possibly inconsistent rules, thus facilitating 
    competition on a reasonable and efficient basis minimizing the economic 
    impact of our rules for all parties, including small entities and small 
    incumbent LECs.
    2. Rate Levels
    a. Pricing Based on Economic Cost
    (1) Background
        436. We observed in the NPRM that economists generally agree that 
    prices based on forward-looking long-run incremental costs (LRIC) give 
    appropriate signals to producers and consumers and ensure efficient 
    entry and utilization of the telecommunications infrastructure. We 
    noted, however, that there was a lack of general agreement on the 
    specifics of methodology for deriving prices based on LRIC or total 
    service long-run incremental cost (TSLRIC). We invited parties to 
    comment on whether we should require the states to employ a LRIC-based 
    pricing methodology and to explain with specificity the costing 
    methodology they support. We recognized, however, that prices based on 
    LRIC might not permit recovery of forward-looking costs if there were 
    significant forward-looking joint and common costs among network 
    elements. We sought comment on how, if rates are set above incremental 
    cost, to deal with the problems inherent in allocating common costs and 
    any other overheads. We observed that, by defining the unbundled 
    elements at a sufficiently aggregated level, it may be possible to 
    reduce the costs to be allocated as joint and common by identifying a 
    substantial portion of costs as incremental to a particular element. To 
    the extent that joint and common costs cannot be entirely eliminated, 
    we sought comment on various methodologies for assigning them, 
    including the use of a fixed allocator or on the basis of inverse 
    demand elasticity. We also sought comment on whether, regardless of the 
    method of allocating common costs, we should limit rates to levels that 
    do not exceed stand-alone costs. Finally, we invited parties to comment 
    on whether a LRIC-based methodology would establish a price for 
    interconnection and unbundled network elements that includes a 
    reasonable profit and thus complies with section 252(d)(1).
        437. A number of states already employ, or have plans to utilize, 
    some form of LRIC or TSLRIC methodology in their approach to setting 
    prices for unbundled network elements, with several states choosing 
    LRIC or TSLRIC as a price floor. For instance, the Connecticut 
    Commission adopted a TSLRIC methodology to measure the cost of service 
    of SNET, its principal incumbent LEC. Arizona also requires incumbent 
    LECs to conduct TSLRIC cost studies to establish the underlying cost
    
    [[Page 45543]]
    
    of unbundled services and facilities. The Ohio Commission has adopted 
    Long Run Service Incremental Cost (``LRSIC''), which is closely related 
    to TSLRIC. The Missouri and Wyoming Commissions are among a number of 
    state commissions that have not yet adopted a pricing methodology, but 
    are considering LRIC or TSLRIC. Oklahoma law provides for submission of 
    LRIC cost studies and studies identifying a contribution to common 
    costs for interconnection of facilities and access to network elements 
    to the Oklahoma Commission during an arbitration. A number of states 
    have yet to choose a pricing methodology. For instance, the New York 
    Commission sets prices on a case-by-case basis. Unbundled element 
    prices also exist in several states pursuant to negotiated 
    interconnection agreements that have either already been approved by 
    state commissions or are under consideration.
        438. Section 252(d)(1) requires, inter alia, that rates for 
    interconnection and unbundled network elements be based on ``cost 
    (determined without reference to a rate-of-return or other rate-based 
    proceeding).'' We tentatively concluded in the NPRM that this language 
    precludes states from setting rates by use of traditional cost-of 
    service regulation, with its detailed examination of historical carrier 
    investment and expenses. Instead, we indicated our belief that the 
    statute contemplates the use of other forms of cost-based price 
    regulation, such as the setting of prices based on forward-looking 
    economic cost methodologies (such as LRIC) that do not involve the use 
    of an embedded rate base. We sought comment on whether section 
    252(d)(1) forecloses consideration of historical or embedded costs or 
    merely prohibits state commissions from conducting a traditional rate-
    of-return proceeding to establish prices for interconnection and 
    unbundled network elements. Embedded costs are the costs that the 
    incumbent LECs carry on their accounting books that reflect historical 
    purchase prices, regulatory depreciation rates, system configurations, 
    and operating procedures. We invited parties to comment on whether 
    incumbent LECs should be permitted to recover some portion of their 
    historical or embedded costs over TSLRIC.
        439. In the NPRM, we noted that certain incumbent LECs had 
    advocated that interconnection and access to unbundled element prices 
    be based on the ``efficient component pricing rule'' (ECPR). Under this 
    approach, an incumbent LEC that sells an essential input element, such 
    as interconnection, to a competing network would set the price of that 
    input element equal to ``the input's direct per-unit incremental costs 
    plus the opportunity cost to the input supplier of the sale of a unit 
    of input.'' We tentatively concluded in the NPRM that ECPR or 
    equivalent methodologies are inconsistent with the section 252(d)(1) 
    requirement that rates be based on ``cost,'' and we proposed to 
    preclude the states from using this methodology.
        440. Section 254 requires the Commission and the Joint Board 
    established thereunder to ensure that ``[a]ll providers of 
    telecommunications service * * * make an equitable and 
    nondiscriminatory contribution to the preservation and advancement of 
    universal service. * * *'' That section further provides that ``[t]here 
    should be specific, predictable, and sufficient Federal and State 
    mechanisms to preserve and advance universal service.'' The Conference 
    Committee also explained that these provisions require any such 
    universal service support payment to be, to the extent possible, 
    ``explicit, rather than implicit as many support mechanisms are 
    today.'' In the NPRM, we sought comment on whether ``it would be 
    consistent with sections 251(d)(1) and 254 for states to include any 
    universal service costs or subsidies in the rates they set for 
    interconnection, collocation, and unbundled network elements.'' In 
    particular, we discussed the ``play or pay'' system adopted by the 
    State of New York in which interconnectors that agree to serve all 
    customers in their self-defined service areas (``players'') potentially 
    pay a substantially lower interconnection rate than those that serve 
    only selected customers (``payers'') and are, therefore, liable to pay 
    additional contribution charges. We noted that the statutory schedule 
    for the completion of the universal service reform proceeding (15 
    months from the enactment of the 1996 Act) is different from that for 
    this proceeding (6 months from the date of enactment of the 1996 Act). 
    We asked whether the ability of states to take universal service 
    support into account differs pending completion of the section 254 
    Joint Board proceeding or state universal service proceedings, pursuant 
    to section 254(f), during any transition period that may be established 
    in the section 254 proceeding or thereafter.
    (2) Discussion
        441. Overview. Having concluded in Section II.D., above, that we 
    have the requisite legal authority and that we should establish 
    national pricing rules, we conclude here that prices for 
    interconnection and unbundled elements pursuant to sections 251(c)(2), 
    251(c)(3), and 252(d)(1), should be set at forward-looking long-run 
    economic cost. In practice, this will mean that prices are based on the 
    TSLRIC of the network element, which we will call Total Element Long 
    Run Incremental Cost (TELRIC), and will include a reasonable allocation 
    of forward-looking joint and common costs. The 1996 Act encourages 
    competition by removing barriers to entry and providing an opportunity 
    for potential new entrants to purchase unbundled incumbent LEC network 
    elements to compete efficiently to provide local exchange services. We 
    believe that the prices that potential entrants pay for these elements 
    should reflect forward-looking economic costs in order to encourage 
    efficient levels of investment and entry.
        442. In this section, we describe this forward-looking, cost-based 
    pricing standard in detail. First, we define the terms we are using, 
    explain how the methodology we are adopting differs from other costing 
    approaches, and describe how it should be implemented. In particular, 
    we explain that the price of a network element should include the 
    forward-looking costs that can be attributed directly to the provision 
    of services using that element, which includes a reasonable return on 
    investment (i.e., ``profit''), plus a reasonable share of the forward-
    looking joint and common costs. Second, we address potential cost 
    measures that must not be included in a TELRIC analysis, such as 
    embedded (or historical) costs, opportunity costs, or universal service 
    subsidies. Finally, we refute arguments that this methodology would 
    violate the incumbent LECs' rights under the Fifth Amendment.
    (a) Total Element Long-Run Incremental Cost
        443. Definitions of Terms. In light of the various possible 
    definitions of a number of the critical economic terms used in this 
    context, we begin by defining terms as we use them in this Order. 
    Specifically, we provide definitions for the following terms: 
    ``incremental cost;'' ``economic cost;'' ``embedded or accounting 
    cost;'' ``joint cost;'' ``common cost;'' ``long-run incremental cost;'' 
    ``total service long-run incremental cost;'' ``total element long-run 
    incremental cost.'' In addition to defining these terms, we explain the 
    economic rationale behind the concepts.
        444. Incremental costs are the additional costs (usually expressed 
    as a cost per unit) that a firm will incur as a result of expanding the 
    output of a good or service by producing an additional quantity of the 
    good or
    
    [[Page 45544]]
    
    service. Incremental costs are forward-looking in the sense that these 
    costs are incurred as the output level changes by a given increment. 
    The costs that are considered incremental will vary greatly depending 
    on the size of the increment. For example, the incremental cost of 
    carrying an additional call from a residence that is already connected 
    to the network to its end office is virtually zero. The incremental 
    cost of connecting a new residence to its end office, however, is the 
    cost of the loop. Forward-looking incremental costs, plus a portion of 
    the forward-looking joint and common costs, are sometimes referred to 
    as ``economic costs.'' Embedded or accounting costs are costs that 
    firms incurred in the past for providing a good or service and are 
    recorded as past operating expenses and depreciation. Due to changes in 
    input prices and technologies, incremental costs may differ from 
    embedded costs of that same increment. In competitive markets, the 
    price of a good or service will tend towards its long-run incremental 
    cost.
        445. Certain types of costs arise from the production of multiple 
    products or services. We use the term ``joint costs'' to refer to costs 
    incurred when two or more outputs are produced in fixed proportion by 
    the same production process (i.e., when one product is produced, a 
    second product is generated by the same production process at no 
    additional cost). The term ``common costs'' refers to costs that are 
    incurred in connection with the production of multiple products or 
    services, and remains unchanged as the relative proportion of those 
    products or services varies (e.g., the salaries of corporate managers). 
    Such costs may be common to all services provided by the firm or common 
    to only a subset of those services or elements. If a cost is common 
    with respect to a subset of services or elements, for example, a firm 
    avoids that cost only by not providing each and every service or 
    element in the subset. For the purpose of our discussion, we refer to 
    joint and common costs as simply common costs unless the distinction is 
    relevant in a particular context.
        446. The term ``long-run,'' in the context of ``long run 
    incremental cost,'' refers to a period long enough so that all of a 
    firm's costs become variable or avoidable. The term ``total service,'' 
    in the context of TSLRIC, indicates that the relevant increment is the 
    entire quantity of the service that a firm produces, rather than just a 
    marginal increment over and above a given level of production. 
    Depending on what services are the subject of a study, TSLRIC may be 
    for a single service or a class of similar services. TSLRIC includes 
    the incremental costs of dedicated facilities and operations that are 
    used by only the service in question. TSLRIC also includes the 
    incremental costs of shared facilities and operations that are used by 
    that service as well as other services.
        447. While we are adopting a version of the methodology commonly 
    referred to as TSLRIC as the basis for pricing interconnection and 
    unbundled elements, we are coining the term ``total element long-run 
    incremental cost'' (TELRIC) to describe our version of this 
    methodology. The incumbent LEC offerings to be priced using this 
    methodology generally will be ``network elements,'' rather than 
    ``telecommunications services,'' as defined by the 1996 Act. More 
    fundamentally, we believe that TELRIC-based pricing of discrete network 
    elements or facilities, such as local loops and switching, is likely to 
    be much more economically rational than TSLRIC-based pricing of 
    conventional services, such as interstate access service and local 
    residential or business exchange service. As discussed in greater 
    detail below, separate telecommunications services are typically 
    provided over shared network facilities, the costs of which may be 
    joint or common with respect to some services. The costs of local loops 
    and their associated line cards in local switches, for example, are 
    common with respect to interstate access service and local exchange 
    service, because once these facilities are installed to provide one 
    service they are able to provide the other at no additional cost. By 
    contrast, the network elements, as we have defined them, largely 
    correspond to distinct network facilities. Therefore, the amount of 
    joint and common costs that must be allocated among separate offerings 
    is likely to be much smaller using a TELRIC methodology rather than a 
    TSLRIC approach that measures the costs of conventional services. 
    Because it is difficult for regulators to determine an economically 
    optimal allocation of any such joint and common costs, we believe that 
    pricing elements, defined as facilities with associated features and 
    functions, is more reliable from the standpoint of economic efficiency 
    than pricing services that use shared network facilities.
        448. Description of TELRIC-Based Pricing Methodology. Adopting a 
    pricing methodology based on forward-looking economic costs best 
    replicates, to the extent possible, the conditions of a competitive 
    market. In addition, a forward-looking cost methodology reduces the 
    ability of an incumbent LEC to engage in anti-competitive behavior. 
    Congress recognized in the 1996 Act that access to the incumbent LECs' 
    bottleneck facilities is critical to making meaningful competition 
    possible. As a result of the availability to competitors of the 
    incumbent LEC's unbundled elements at their economic cost, consumers 
    will be able to reap the benefits of the incumbent LECs' economies of 
    scale and scope, as well as the benefits of competition. Because a 
    pricing methodology based on forward-looking costs simulates the 
    conditions in a competitive marketplace, it allows the requesting 
    carrier to produce efficiently and to compete effectively, which should 
    drive retail prices to their competitive levels. We believe that our 
    adoption of a forward-looking cost-based pricing methodology should 
    facilitate competition on a reasonable and efficient basis by all firms 
    in the industry by establishing prices for interconnection and 
    unbundled elements based on costs similar to those incurred by the 
    incumbents, which may be expected to reduce the regulatory burdens and 
    economic impact of our decision for many parties, including both small 
    entities seeking to enter the local exchange markets and small 
    incumbent LECs.
        449. We note that incumbent LECs have greater access to the cost 
    information necessary to calculate the incremental cost of the 
    unbundled elements of the network. Given this asymmetric access to cost 
    data, we find that incumbent LECs must prove to the state commission 
    the nature and magnitude of any forward-looking cost that it seeks to 
    recover in the prices of interconnection and unbundled network 
    elements.
        450. Some parties express concern that the information required to 
    compute prices based on forward-looking costs is inherently so 
    hypothetical as to be of little or no practical value. Based on the 
    record before us, we disagree. A number of states, which ultimately 
    will have to review forward-looking cost studies in carrying out their 
    duties under section 252, either have already implemented forward-
    looking, incremental costing methodologies to set prices for 
    interconnection and unbundled network elements or support the use of 
    such an approach. While these states have applied somewhat different 
    definitions of, and approaches to setting prices developed on, an 
    incremental cost methodology, the record demonstrates that such 
    approaches are practical and implementable.
    
    [[Page 45545]]
    
        451. We conclude that, under a TELRIC methodology, incumbent LECs' 
    prices for interconnection and unbundled network elements shall recover 
    the forward-looking costs directly attributable to the specified 
    element, as well as a reasonable allocation of forward-looking common 
    costs. Per-unit costs shall be derived from total costs using 
    reasonably accurate ``fill factors'' (estimates of the proportion of a 
    facility that will be ``filled'' with network usage); that is, the per-
    unit costs associated with a particular element must be derived by 
    dividing the total cost associated with the element by a reasonable 
    projection of the actual total usage of the element. Directly 
    attributable forward-looking costs include the incremental costs of 
    facilities and operations that are dedicated to the element. Such costs 
    typically include the investment costs and expenses related to primary 
    plant used to provide that element. Directly attributable forward-
    looking costs also include the incremental costs of shared facilities 
    and operations. Those costs shall be attributed to specific elements to 
    the greatest extent possible. Telephone Company-Cable Television Cross-
    Ownership Rules, Memorandum Opinion and Order on Reconsideration and 
    Third Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 59 FR 63909 (December 12, 
    1994). For example, the costs of conduits shared by both transport and 
    local loops, and the costs of central office facilities shared by both 
    local switching and tandem switching, shall be attributed to specific 
    elements in reasonable proportions. More broadly, certain shared costs 
    that have conventionally been treated as common costs (or overheads) 
    shall be attributed directly to the individual elements to the greatest 
    extent possible. The forward-looking costs directly attributable to 
    local loops, for example, shall include not only the cost of the 
    installed copper wire and telephone poles but also the cost of payroll 
    and other back office operations relating to the line technicians, in 
    addition to other attributable costs.
        452. Forward-looking cost methodologies, like TELRIC, are intended 
    to consider the costs that a carrier would incur in the future. Thus, a 
    question arises whether costs should be computed based on the least-
    cost, most efficient network configuration and technology currently 
    available, or whether forward-looking cost should be computed based on 
    incumbent LECs' existing network infrastructures, taking into account 
    changes in depreciation and inflation. The record indicates three 
    general approaches to this issue. Under the first approach, the 
    forward-looking economic cost for interconnection and unbundled 
    elements would be based on the most efficient network architecture, 
    sizing, technology, and operating decisions that are operationally 
    feasible and currently available to the industry. Prices based on the 
    least-cost, most efficient network design and technology replicate 
    conditions in a highly competitive marketplace by not basing prices on 
    existing network design and investments unless they represent the 
    least-cost systems available for purchase. This approach, however, may 
    discourage facilities-based competition by new entrants because new 
    entrants can use the incumbent LEC's existing network based on the cost 
    of a hypothetical least-cost, most efficient network.
        453. Under the second approach, the cost of interconnection and 
    unbundled network elements would be based on existing network design 
    and technology that are currently in operation. Because this approach 
    is not based on a hypothetical network in the short run, incumbent LECs 
    could recover costs based on their existing operations, and prices for 
    interconnection and unbundled elements that reflect inefficient or 
    obsolete network design and technology. This is essentially an embedded 
    cost methodology.
        454. Under the third approach, prices for interconnection and 
    access to unbundled elements would be developed from a forward-looking 
    economic cost methodology based on the most efficient technology 
    deployed in the incumbent LEC's current wire center locations. This 
    approach mitigates incumbent LECs' concerns that a forward-looking 
    pricing methodology ignores existing network design, while basing 
    prices on efficient, new technology that is compatible with the 
    existing infrastructure. This benchmark of forward-looking cost and 
    existing network design most closely represents the incremental costs 
    that incumbents actually expect to incur in making network elements 
    available to new entrants. Moreover, this approach encourages 
    facilities-based competition to the extent that new entrants, by 
    designing more efficient network configurations, are able to provide 
    the service at a lower cost than the incumbent LEC. We, therefore, 
    conclude that the forward-looking pricing methodology for 
    interconnection and unbundled network elements should be based on costs 
    that assume that wire centers will be placed at the incumbent LEC's 
    current wire center locations, but that the reconstructed local network 
    will employ the most efficient technology for reasonably foreseeable 
    capacity requirements.
        455. We agree with USTA, Bell Atlantic, and BellSouth that, as a 
    theoretical matter, the combination of significant sunk investment, 
    declining technology costs, and competitive entry may increase the 
    depreciation costs and cost of capital of incumbent LECs. We do not 
    agree, however, that TSLRIC does not or cannot account for risks that 
    an incumbent LEC incurs because it has sunk investments in facilities. 
    On the contrary, properly designed depreciation schedules should 
    account for expected declines in the value of capital goods. Both AT&T 
    and MCI appear to agree with this proposition. For example, AT&T 
    states, ``[i]n order to estimate TSLRIC, one must perform a discounted 
    cash flow analysis of the future costs associated with the decision to 
    invest. * * * One-time costs associated with the acquisition of capital 
    goods are amortized over the economic life of the assets using the user 
    cost of capital * * *, which requires accounting for both expected 
    capital good price changes and economic depreciation.'' Moreover, we 
    are confident that parties to an arbitration with TELRIC studies can 
    propose specific depreciation rate adjustments that reflect expected 
    asset values over time.
        456. As noted, we also agree that, as a matter of theory, an 
    increase in risk due to entry into the market for local exchange 
    service can increase a LEC's cost of capital. We believe that this 
    increased risk can be partially mitigated, however, by offering term 
    discounts, since long-term contracts can minimize the risk of stranded 
    investment. In addition, growth in overall market demand can increase 
    the potential of the incumbent LEC to use some of its displaced 
    facilities for other purposes. Overall, we think that these factors can 
    and should be captured in any LRIC model and therefore we do not agree 
    that this requires a departure from the general principle of forward-
    looking cost-based pricing for network elements.
        457. We are not persuaded by USTA's argument that forward looking 
    methodologies fail to adjust the cost of capital to reflect the risks 
    associated with irreversible investments and that they are ``biased 
    downward by a factor of three.'' First, USTA's argument unrealistically 
    assumes that competitive entry would be instantaneous. The more 
    reasonable assumption of entry occurring over time will reduce the 
    costs associated with sunk investment. Second, we find it unlikely that 
    investment in communications
    
    [[Page 45546]]
    
    equipment is entirely irreversible or that such equipment would become 
    valueless once facilities-based competition begins. In a growing 
    market, there most likely would be demand for at least some embedded 
    telecommunications equipment, which would therefore retain its value. 
    Third, contractual arrangements between the new entrant and the 
    incumbent that specifically address USTA's concerns and protect 
    incumbent's investments during transition can be established.
        458. Finally we are not persuaded that the use by firms of hurdle 
    rates that exceed the market cost of capital is convincing evidence 
    that sunk investments significantly increase a firm's cost of capital. 
    An alternative explanation for this phenomenon is that the process that 
    firms use to choose among investment projects results in overestimates 
    of their returns. Firms therefore use hurdle rates in excess of the 
    market cost of capital to account for these overestimates.
        459. Summary of TELRIC Methodology. The following summarizes our 
    conclusions regarding setting prices of interconnection and access to 
    unbundled network elements based on the TELRIC methodology for such 
    elements. The increment that forms the basis for a TELRIC study shall 
    be the entire quantity of the network element provided. As we have 
    previously stated, all costs associated with providing the element 
    shall be included in the incremental cost. Only forward-looking, 
    incremental costs shall be included in a TELRIC study. Costs must be 
    based on the incumbent LEC's existing wire center locations and most 
    efficient technology available.
        460. Any function necessary to produce a network element must have 
    an associated cost. The study must explain with specificity why and how 
    specific functions are necessary to provide network elements and how 
    the associated costs were developed. Only those costs that are incurred 
    in the provision of the network elements in the long run shall be 
    directly attributable to those elements. Costs must be attributed on a 
    cost-causative basis. Costs are causally-related to the network element 
    being provided if the costs are incurred as a direct result of 
    providing the network elements, or can be avoided, in the long run, 
    when the company ceases to provide them. Thus, for example, the 
    forward-looking costs of capital (debt and equity) needed to support 
    investments required to produce a given element shall be included in 
    the forward-looking direct cost of that element. Directly attributable 
    costs shall include costs such as certain administrative expenses, 
    which have traditionally been viewed as common costs, if these costs 
    vary with the provision of network elements. Retailing costs, such as 
    marketing or consumer billing costs associated with retail services, 
    are not attributable to the production of network elements that are 
    offered to interconnecting carriers and must not be included in the 
    forward-looking direct cost of an element.
        461. In a TELRIC methodology, the ``long run'' used shall be a 
    period long enough that all costs are treated as variable and 
    avoidable. This ``long run'' approach ensures that rates recover not 
    only the operating costs that vary in the short run, but also fixed 
    investment costs that, while not variable in the short term, are 
    necessary inputs directly attributable to providing the element.
        462. States may review a TELRIC economic cost study in the context 
    of a particular arbitration proceeding, or they may conduct such 
    studies in a rulemaking and apply the results in various arbitrations 
    involving incumbent LECs. In the latter case, states must replace any 
    interim rates set in arbitration proceedings with the permanent rate 
    resulting from the separate rulemaking. This permanent rate will take 
    effect at or about the time of the conclusion of the separate 
    rulemaking and will apply from that time forward.
        463. Forward-Looking Common Costs. Certain common costs are 
    incurred in the provision of network elements. As discussed above, some 
    of these costs are common to only a subset of the elements or services 
    provided by incumbent LECs. Such costs shall be allocated to that 
    subset, and should then be allocated among the individual elements or 
    services in that subset, to the greatest possible extent. For example, 
    shared maintenance facilities and vehicles should be allocated only to 
    the elements that benefit from those facilities and vehicles. Common 
    costs also include costs incurred by the firm's operations as a whole, 
    that are common to all services and elements (e.g., salaries of 
    executives involved in overseeing all activities of the business), 
    although for the purpose of pricing interconnection and access to 
    unbundled elements, which are intermediate products offered to 
    competing carriers, the relevant common costs do not include billing, 
    marketing, and other costs attributable to the provision of retail 
    service. Given these common costs, setting the price of each discrete 
    network element based solely on the forward-looking incremental costs 
    directly attributable to the production of individual elements will not 
    recover the total forward-looking costs of operating the wholesale 
    network. Because forward-looking common costs are consistent with our 
    forward-looking, economic cost paradigm, a reasonable measure of such 
    costs shall be included in the prices for interconnection and access to 
    network elements.
        464. The incumbent LECs generally argue that common costs are quite 
    significant, while several other parties maintain that these amounts 
    are minimal. Because the unbundled network elements correspond, to a 
    great extent, to discrete network facilities, and have different 
    operating characteristics, we expect that common costs should be 
    smaller than the common costs associated with the long-run incremental 
    cost of a service. We expect that many facility costs that may be 
    common with respect to the individual services provided by the 
    facilities can be directly attributed to the facilities when offered as 
    unbundled network elements. Moreover, defining the network elements at 
    a relatively high level of aggregation, as we have done, should also 
    reduce the magnitude of the common costs. A properly conducted TELRIC 
    methodology will attribute costs to specific elements to the greatest 
    possible extent, which will reduce the common costs. Nevertheless, 
    there will remain some common costs that must be allocated among 
    network elements and interconnection services. For example, at the sub-
    element level of study (e.g., identifying the respective costs of 2-
    wire loops, 4-wire loops, ISDN loops, and so on), common costs may be a 
    significant proportion of all the costs that must be recovered from 
    sub-elements. Given the likely asymmetry of information regarding 
    network costs, we conclude that, in the arbitration process, incumbent 
    LECs shall have the burden to prove the specific nature and magnitude 
    of these forward-looking common costs.
        465. We conclude that forward-looking common costs shall be 
    allocated among elements and services in a reasonable manner, 
    consistent with the pro-competitive goals of the 1996 Act. One 
    reasonable allocation method would be to allocate common costs using a 
    fixed allocator, such as a percentage markup over the directly 
    attributable forward-looking costs. We conclude that a second 
    reasonable allocation method would allocate only a relatively small 
    share of common costs to certain critical network elements, such as the 
    local loop and collocation, that are most difficult for entrants to 
    replicate promptly (i.e., bottleneck facilities). Allocation of common 
    costs
    
    [[Page 45547]]
    
    on this basis ensures that the prices of network elements that are 
    least likely to be subject to competition are not artificially inflated 
    by a large allocation of common costs. On the other hand, certain other 
    allocation methods would not be reasonable. For example, we conclude 
    that an allocation methodology that relies exclusively on allocating 
    common costs in inverse proportion to the sensitivity of demand for 
    various network elements and services may not be used. We conclude that 
    such an allocation could unreasonably limit the extent of entry into 
    local exchange markets by allocating more costs to, and thus raising 
    the prices of, the most critical bottleneck inputs, the demand for 
    which tends to be relatively inelastic. Such an allocation of these 
    costs would undermine the pro-competitive objectives of the 1996 Act.
        466. We believe that our treatment of forward-looking common costs 
    will minimize regulatory burdens and economic impact for all parties 
    involved in arbitration of agreements for interconnection and access to 
    unbundled elements, and will advance the 1996 Act's pro-competitive 
    objectives for local exchange and exchange access markets. In our 
    decisionmaking, we have considered the economic impact of our rules in 
    this section on small incumbent LECs. For example, although opposed to 
    the use of a forward-looking, economic cost methodology, small 
    incumbent LECs favor the recovery of joint and common costs in the 
    event the Commission adopts forward-looking cost methodology. We are 
    adopting such an approach. Moreover, the cost-based pricing methodology 
    that we are adopting is designed to permit incumbent LECs to recover 
    their economic costs of providing interconnection and unbundled 
    elements, which may minimize the economic impact of our decisions on 
    incumbent LECs, including small incumbent LECs. We also note that 
    certain small incumbent LECs are not subject to our rules under section 
    251(f)(1) of the 1996 Act, unless otherwise determined by a state 
    commission, and certain other small incumbent LECs may seek relief from 
    their state commissions from our rules under section 251(f)(2) of the 
    1996 Act.
        467. We further conclude that, for the aggregate of all unbundled 
    network elements, incumbent LECs must be given a reasonable opportunity 
    to recover their forward-looking common costs attributable to operating 
    the wholesale network. In no instance should prices exceed the stand-
    alone cost for a specific element, and in most cases they should be 
    below stand-alone costs. Stand-alone costs are defined as the forward-
    looking cost that an efficient entrant would incur in providing a given 
    element or any combination of elements. No price higher than stand-
    alone cost could be sustained in a market from which entry barriers 
    were completely absent. Where there are few common costs, there is 
    likely to be only a minimal difference between the forward-looking 
    costs that are directly attributable to the particular element, which 
    excludes these costs, and stand-alone cost, which includes all of them. 
    Network elements should not, however, be priced at levels that would 
    enable the incumbent LEC to recover the same common costs multiple 
    times from different elements. Any multiple recovery would be 
    unreasonable and thus in violation of the statutory standard. Further, 
    we note that the sum of the direct costs and the forward-looking common 
    costs of all elements will likely differ from the incumbent LEC's 
    historical, fully distributed costs.
        468. Reasonable Return on Investment and ``Profit.'' Section 
    252(d)(1) states that rates for interconnection and access to unbundled 
    elements ``may include a reasonable profit.'' We find that the TELRIC 
    pricing methodology we are adopting provides for such a reasonable 
    profit and thus no additional profit is justified under the statutory 
    language. We note there are two types of profit. First, in plain 
    English, profit is defined as ``the excess of returns over expenditure 
    in a transaction or a series of transactions.'' This is also known as a 
    ``normal'' profit, which is the total revenue required to cover all of 
    the costs of a firm, including its opportunity costs. Second, there is 
    ``economic'' profit, which is any return in excess of normal profit. 
    Thus, for example, if the normal return in an industry is 10 percent 
    and a firm earns a return of 14 percent, the economic profit for that 
    firm is 4 percent. Economic is also referred to as ``supranormal'' 
    profit. We conclude that the definition of ``normal'' profit is 
    embodied in ``reasonable profit'' under Section 252(d)(1).
        469. The concept of normal profit is embodied in forward-looking 
    costs because the forward-looking cost of capital, i.e., the cost of 
    obtaining debt and equity financing, is one of the forward-looking 
    costs of providing the network elements. This forward-looking cost of 
    capital is equal to a normal profit. We conclude that allowing greater 
    than normal profits would not be ``reasonable'' under sections 251(c) 
    and 252(d)(1). Bluefield Water Works & Improvement Co. v. Public 
    Service Comm'n of West Virginia, 262 U.S. 679 (1923); Federal Power 
    Comm'n v. Hope Natural Gas Co., 320 U.S. 591 (1944). Thus, contrary to 
    the arguments put forth by several incumbent LECs, we find that adding 
    an additional measure of profit to the risk-adjusted cost of capital in 
    setting the prices for interconnection and access to unbundled elements 
    would violate the requirements of sections 251(c) and 252(d)(1) of the 
    1996 Act.
        470. Possible accounting losses from the sale of interconnection 
    and unbundled network elements using a reasonable forward-looking cost-
    based methodology do not necessarily indicate that incumbent LECs are 
    being denied a ``reasonable profit'' under the statute. The use of a 
    forward-looking, economic, cost-based pricing methodology, including a 
    reasonable allocation of legitimate joint and common costs, will permit 
    incumbent LECs the opportunity to earn a reasonable return on their 
    investment in network elements. Finally, contrary to PacTel's argument, 
    and as discussed below in detail, we conclude that our forward-looking 
    cost-based pricing methodology is consistent with the Fifth Amendment 
    and is not confiscatory.
        471. Based on the current record, we conclude that the currently 
    authorized rate of return at the federal or state level is a reasonable 
    starting point for TELRIC calculations, and incumbent LECs bear the 
    burden of demonstrating with specificity that the business risks that 
    they face in providing unbundled network elements and interconnection 
    services would justify a different risk-adjusted cost of capital or 
    depreciation rate. These elements generally are bottleneck, monopoly 
    services that do not now face significant competition. We recognize 
    that incumbent LECs are likely to face increased risks given the 
    overall increases in competition in this industry, which generally 
    might warrant an increased cost of capital, but note that, earlier this 
    year, we instituted a preliminary inquiry as to whether the currently 
    authorized federal 11.25 percent rate of return is too high given the 
    current marketplace cost of equity and debt. On the basis of the 
    current record, we decline to engage in a time-consuming examination to 
    determine a new rate of return, which may well require a detailed 
    proceeding. States may adjust the cost of capital if a party 
    demonstrates to a state commission that either a higher or lower level 
    of cost of capital is warranted, without that commission conducting a 
    ``rate-of-return or other rate based proceeding.'' We note that the 
    risk-adjusted cost of capital need not be uniform for all
    
    [[Page 45548]]
    
    elements. We intend to re-examine the issue of the appropriate risk-
    adjusted cost of capital on an ongoing basis, particularly in light of 
    the state commissions' experiences in addressing this issue in specific 
    situations.
        472. We disagree with the conclusion that, when there are mostly 
    sunk costs, forward-looking economic costs should not be the basis for 
    pricing interconnection elements. The TELRIC of an element has three 
    components, the operating expenses, the depreciation cost, and the 
    appropriate risk-adjusted cost of capital. We conclude that an 
    appropriate calculation of TELRIC will include a depreciation rate that 
    reflects the true changes in economic value of an asset and a cost of 
    capital that appropriately reflects the risks incurred by an investor. 
    Thus, even in the presence of sunk costs, TELRIC-based prices are an 
    appropriate pricing methodology.
    (b) Cost Measures Not Included in Forward-Looking Cost Methodology
        473. Embedded Costs. We read section 252(d)(1)(A)(i) to prohibit 
    states from conducting traditional rate-of-return or other rate-based 
    proceedings to determine rates for interconnection and access to 
    unbundled network elements. We find that the parenthetical, 
    ``(determined without reference to a rate-of-return or other rate-based 
    proceeding),'' does not further define the type of costs that may be 
    considered, but rather specifies a type of proceeding that may not be 
    employed to determine the cost of interconnection and unbundled network 
    elements. The legislative history demonstrates that Congress was eager 
    to set in motion expeditiously the development of local competition and 
    intended to avoid imposing the costs and administrative burdens 
    associated with a traditional rate case. Prior to the joint conference, 
    the Senate version of the 1996 Act contained the parenthetical 
    language. In addition, the Senate version of the 1996 Act eliminated 
    rate-of-return regulation, as did the House version. Conferees removed 
    the provisions eliminating rate-of-return regulation, but retained the 
    parenthetical.
        474. Section 252(d)(1)(A)(i) does not specify whether historical or 
    embedded costs should be considered or whether only forward-looking 
    costs should be considered in setting arbitrated rates. We are not 
    persuaded by incumbent LEC arguments that prices for interconnection 
    and unbundled network elements must or should include any difference 
    between the embedded costs they have incurred to provide those elements 
    and their current economic costs. Neither a methodology that 
    establishes the prices for interconnection and access to network 
    elements directly on the costs reflected in the regulated books of 
    account, nor a price based on forward looking costs plus an additional 
    amount reflecting embedded costs, would be consistent with the approach 
    we are adopting. The substantial weight of economic commentary in the 
    record suggests that an ``embedded cost''-based pricing methodology 
    would be pro-competitor--in this case the incumbent LEC--rather than 
    pro-competition. We therefore decline to adopt embedded costs as the 
    appropriate basis of setting prices for interconnection and access to 
    unbundled elements. Rather, we reiterate that the prices for the 
    interconnection and network elements critical to the development of a 
    competitive local exchange should be based on the pro-competition, 
    forward-looking, economic costs of those elements, which may be higher 
    or lower than historical embedded costs. Such pricing policies will 
    best ensure the efficient investment decisions and competitive entry 
    contemplated by the 1996 Act, which should minimize the regulatory 
    burdens and economic impact of our decisions on small entities.
        475. Incumbent LECs contend generally that, in order to ensure they 
    will recover their total investment costs and earn a profit, they must 
    recover embedded costs. These costs, they argue, were incurred under 
    federal and regulatory oversight and therefore should be recoverable. 
    We are not convinced by the incumbent LECs' principal arguments for 
    recognizing embedded cost in setting section 251 pricing rules. Even if 
    the incumbent LECs' contention is correct, increasing the rates for 
    interconnection and unbundled elements offered to competitors would 
    interfere with the development of efficient competition, and is not the 
    proper remedy for any past under-depreciation. Moreover, contrary to 
    assertions by some incumbent LECs, regulation does not and should not 
    guarantee full recovery of their embedded costs. Such a guarantee would 
    exceed the assurances that we or the states have provided in the past. 
    We have considered the economic impact of precluding recovery of small 
    incumbent LECs' embedded costs. We do not believe that basing the 
    prices of interconnection and unbundled elements on an incumbent LEC's 
    embedded costs would advance the pro-competitive goals of the statute. 
    We also note that certain small incumbent LECs are not subject to our 
    rules under section 251(f)(1) of the 1996 Act, unless otherwise 
    determined by a state commission, and certain other small incumbent 
    LECs may seek relief from their state commissions from our rules under 
    section 251(f)(2) of the 1996 Act.
        476. We acknowledge that some incumbent LECs may have incurred 
    certain embedded costs reasonably before the passage of the 1996 Act, 
    based on different regulatory regimes. Some incumbent LECs may assert 
    that they have made certain historical investments required by 
    regulators that they have been denied a reasonable opportunity to 
    recover in the past and that the incumbent LECs may no longer have a 
    reasonable opportunity to recover in the new environment of the 1996 
    Act. The record before us, however, does not support the conclusion 
    that significant residual embedded costs will necessarily result from 
    the availability of network elements at economic costs. To the extent 
    that any such residual consists of costs of meeting universal service 
    obligations, the recovery of such costs can and should be considered in 
    our ongoing universal service proceeding. Universal Service NPRM. To 
    the extent a significant residual exists within the interstate 
    jurisdiction that does not fall within the ambit of section 254, we 
    intend that to address that issue in our upcoming proceeding on access 
    reform.
        477. Opportunity Cost--Efficient Component Pricing Rule. A number 
    of incumbent LECs advocate using the ``efficient component pricing 
    rule'' (ECPR) to set the prices that incumbent LECs charge new entrants 
    for inputs required to produce the same retail services the incumbent 
    produces. Under the ECPR, the price of an input should be equal to the 
    incremental cost of the input plus the opportunity cost that the 
    incumbent carrier incurs when the new entrant provides the services 
    instead of the incumbent. The opportunity cost, which is computed as 
    revenues less all incremental costs, represents both profit and 
    contribution to common costs of the incumbent, given the existing 
    retail prices of the services being sold.
        478. We conclude that ECPR is an improper method for setting prices 
    of interconnection and unbundled network elements because the existing 
    retail prices that would be used to compute incremental opportunity 
    costs under ECPR are not cost-based. Moreover, the ECPR does not 
    provide any mechanism for moving prices towards competitive levels; it 
    simply takes prices as given. The record indicates that both incumbents 
    and new entrants agree that
    
    [[Page 45549]]
    
    retail prices are not based on costs. Incumbents generally argue that 
    local residential retail prices are below costs while new entrants 
    contend that they exceed competitive levels. In either case, 
    application of ECPR would result in input prices that would be either 
    higher or lower than those which would be generated in a competitive 
    market and would not lead to efficient retail pricing.
        479. In markets where retail prices exceed competitive levels, 
    entry would take place if network element prices were set at efficient 
    competitive levels. The ECPR, however, will serve to discourage 
    competition in these very markets because it relies on the prevailing 
    retail price in setting the price which new entrants pay the incumbent 
    for inputs. While ECPR establishes conditions for efficient entry given 
    existing retail prices, as its advocates contend, the ECPR provides no 
    mechanism that will force retail prices to their competitive levels. We 
    do not believe that Congress envisioned a pricing methodology for 
    interconnection and network elements that would insulate incumbent 
    LECs' retail prices from competition. Instead, Congress specifically 
    determined that input prices should be based on costs because this 
    would foster competition in the retail market. Therefore, we reject the 
    use of ECPR for establishing prices for interconnection and unbundled 
    elements.
        480. As discussed above, the record in this docket shows that end 
    user prices are not cost-based. In Open Video Systems, in contrast, we 
    did not find that there would be a problem with the determination of 
    end user prices. Implementation of Section 302 of the 
    Telecommunications Act of 1996--Open Video Systems, Second Report and 
    Order, 61 FR 28698 (June 5, 1996). We concluded that ``[u]se of [an 
    ECPR] approach is appropriate in circumstances where the pricing is 
    applicable [sic] to a new market entrant (the open video system 
    operator) that will face competition from an existing incumbent 
    provider (the incumbent cable operator), as opposed to circumstances 
    where the pricing is used to establish a rate for an essential input 
    service that is charged to a competing new entrant by an incumbent 
    provider.'' In addition, in Open Video Systems, we concluded that the 
    ECPR is appropriate because it encourages entry for open video system 
    operators and also enhances the availability of carriage for 
    unaffiliated programmers. The ECPR generally protects the provider's 
    profits and provides opportunities for third parties to use the 
    provider's inputs. The ECPR does not provide a mechanism to drive 
    retail prices to competitive levels, however. In Open Video Systems, we 
    wanted to encourage entry by open video system providers and to 
    encourage them to have incentives to open their systems to unaffiliated 
    programmers. Here, our goal is to ensure that competition between 
    providers, including third party providers using interconnection and 
    unbundled elements, will drive prices toward competitive levels and 
    thus use of the ECPR is inappropriate.
        481. Universal Service Subsidies. We conclude that funding for any 
    universal service mechanisms adopted in the universal service 
    proceeding may not be included in the rates for interconnection, 
    network elements, and access to network elements that are arbitrated by 
    the states under sections 251 and 252. Sections 254(d) and 254(e) of 
    the 1996 Act mandate that universal service support be recovered in an 
    equitable and nondiscriminatory manner from all providers of 
    telecommunications services. We conclude that permitting states to 
    include such costs in rates arbitrated under sections 251 and 252 would 
    violate that requirement by requiring carriers to pay specified 
    portions of such costs solely because they are purchasing services and 
    elements under section 251. Section 252(d)(1) requires that rates for 
    interconnection, network elements, and access to network elements 
    reflect the costs of providing those network elements, not the costs of 
    supporting universal service.
        482. Section 254(f) provides that a state may adopt equitable, 
    nondiscriminatory, specific, and predictable mechanisms to advance 
    universal service within that state. If a state collects universal 
    service funding in rates for elements and services pursuant to sections 
    251 and 252, it will be imposing non-cost based charges in those rates. 
    Including non-cost based charges in the rates for interconnection and 
    unbundled elements is inconsistent with our rules implementing sections 
    251 and 252 which require that these rates be cost-based. It is also 
    inconsistent with the requirement of section 254(f) that 
    telecommunications carriers contribute to state universal service on a 
    nondiscriminatory basis, because telecommunications carriers requesting 
    interconnection or access to unbundled network elements will be 
    required to make contributions to universal service support through 
    such surcharges. States may not, therefore, include universal service 
    support funding in the rates for elements and services pursuant to 
    sections 251 and 252, nor may they implement mechanisms that have the 
    same effect. For example, states may not fund universal service support 
    by imposing higher rates for interconnection, unbundled elements, or 
    transport and termination on carriers that offer service to different 
    types of customers or different geographic areas. To the extent that 
    New York's ``pay or play'' system funds universal service in this 
    manner, it violates sections 251, 252, and 254 of the 1996 Act. Nothing 
    in the 1996 Act or in this Order, however, precludes a state from 
    adopting a universal service funding mechanism, whether interim or 
    otherwise, if such funds are collected in accordance with section 
    254(f) on an ``equitable and nondiscriminatory basis'' through 
    ``specific, predictable, and sufficient mechanisms that do not rely on 
    or burden Federal universal service support mechanisms.''
        483. Our decision here does not exempt carriers purchasing elements 
    or services under section 251 from contributing to (or possibly 
    receiving) universal service support. Rather, the recovery of universal 
    service support costs from telecommunications carriers, including 
    carriers requesting unbundled network elements, will be governed by 
    section 254 of the 1996 Act. Federal universal service support 
    mechanisms will be determined by our decisions reached in CC Docket 96-
    45, based on the recommendations of the Federal/State Universal Service 
    Joint Board, and states may adopt additional universal service support 
    mechanisms consistent with section 254(f).
        484. We are mindful that the requirements of the 1996 Act may be 
    disruptive to existing state universal service support mechanisms 
    during the period commencing with this order and continuing until we 
    complete our universal service proceeding to implement section 254. As 
    discussed in the subsection immediately below, we permit incumbent LECs 
    to continue to recover certain non-cost-based interstate access charge 
    revenues for a limited period of time, largely because of concerns 
    about possible deleterious impacts on universal service. We also 
    authorize incumbent LECs, for a similar limited period of time, to 
    continue to recover explicit intrastate universal service subsidy 
    revenues based on intrastate access charges. This mechanism minimizes 
    any possibility that implementation of sections 251 and 252 will unduly 
    harm universal service during the interim period prior to completion of 
    our universal service and access reform proceedings. Because we 
    conclude this action should adequately provide for the continuation of 
    a portion
    
    [[Page 45550]]
    
    of existing subsidy flows during a transition period until completion 
    of our proceeding implementing section 254, we decline to permit any 
    additional funding of universal service support through rates for 
    interconnection, unbundled elements, and transport and termination 
    during the interim period.
        485. Interim Application of Access Charges to Purchasers of 
    Unbundled Local Switching Element. In the introduction of this Order, 
    we emphasize that implementation of section 251 of the 1996 Act is 
    integrally related to both universal service reform as required under 
    section 254, and to reform of the interstate access charge system. In 
    order to achieve pro-competitive, deregulatory markets for all 
    telecommunications services, we must create a new system of funding 
    universal service that is specific, explicit, predictable, sufficient, 
    and competitively neutral. We also must move access charges to more 
    cost-based and economically efficient levels. We intend to fulfill both 
    of these goals in the coming months, by completing our pending 
    universal service proceeding to implement section 254 by our statutory 
    deadline of May 1997, and by addressing access charge issues in an 
    upcoming access reform proceeding. The 1996 Act, however, requires us 
    to adopt rules implementing section 251 by August 1996. We are 
    concerned that implementation of the requirements of section 251 now, 
    without taking into account the effects of the new rules on our 
    existing access charge and universal service regimes, may have 
    significant, immediate, adverse effects that were neither intended nor 
    foreseen by Congress.
        486. Specifically, as we conclude above, the 1996 Act permits 
    telecommunications carriers that purchase access to unbundled network 
    elements from incumbent LECs to use those elements to provide 
    telecommunications services, including the origination and termination 
    of interstate calls. Without further action on our part, section 251 
    would allow entrants to use those unbundled network facilities to 
    provide access services to customers they win from incumbent LECs, 
    without having to pay access charges to the incumbent LECs. This result 
    would be consistent with the long term outcome in a competitive market. 
    In the short term, however, while other aspects of our regulatory 
    regime are in the process of being reformed, such a change may have 
    detrimental consequences.
        487. The access charge system includes non-cost-based components 
    and elements that at least in part may represent subsidies, such as the 
    carrier common line charge (CCLC) and the transport interconnection 
    charge (TIC). The CCLC recovers part of the allocated interstate costs 
    for incumbent LECs to provide local loops to end users. In the 
    universal service NPRM, we observed that the CCLC may result in higher-
    volume toll users paying rates that exceed cost, and some customers 
    paying rates that are below cost. We sought comment on whether that 
    subsidy should be continued, and on whether and how it should be 
    restructured. Universal Service NPRM. The nature of most of the 
    revenues recovered through the TIC is unclear and subject to dispute, 
    although a portion of the TIC is associated with certain costs related 
    to particular transport facilities. Although the TIC was not created to 
    subsidize local rates, some parties have argued in the Transport 
    proceeding and elsewhere that some portion of the revenues now 
    recovered through the TIC may be misallocated local loop or intrastate 
    costs that operate to support universal service. First Transport Order. 
    57 FR 54717 (November 20, 1992). In the forthcoming access reform 
    proceeding, we intend to consider the appropriate disposition of the 
    TIC, including the development of cost-based transport rates as 
    directed by the United States Court of Appeals for the District of 
    Columbia Circuit in Competitive Telecommunications Association v. FCC, 
    87 F.3d 522 (1996) (CompTel v. FCC).
        488. Without a temporary mechanism such as the one we adopt below, 
    the implementation of section 251 would permit competitive local 
    service providers that also provide interstate long-distance service to 
    avoid totally the CCLC and the TIC, which in part represent 
    contributions toward universal service, by serving their local 
    customers solely through the use of unbundled network elements rather 
    than through resale. We believe that allowing such a result before we 
    have reformed our universal service and access charge regimes would be 
    undesirable as a matter of both economics and policy, because carrier 
    decisions about how to interconnect with incumbent LECs would be driven 
    by regulatory distortions in our access charge rules and our universal 
    service scheme, rather than the unfettered operation of a competitive 
    market. Because of our desire to err on the side of caution where 
    universal service may be implicated, we conclude that some action is 
    needed during the interim period before we complete our access reform 
    and universal service proceedings.
        489. We conclude that we should establish a temporary transitional 
    mechanism to help complete all of the steps toward the pro-competitive 
    goal of the 1996 Act, including the implementation of a new, 
    competitively-neutral system to fund universal service and a 
    comprehensive review of our system of interstate access charges. 
    Therefore, for a limited period of time, incumbent LECs may recover 
    from interconnecting carriers the CCLC and a charge equal to 75 percent 
    of the TIC for all interstate minutes traversing the incumbent LECs' 
    local switches for which the interconnecting carriers pay unbundled 
    local switching element charges. Incumbent LECs may recover these 
    charges only until the earliest of: (1) June 30, 1997; (2) the 
    effective date of final decisions by the Commission in both the 
    universal service and access reform proceedings; or (3) if the 
    incumbent LEC is a BOC, the date on which that BOC is authorized under 
    section 271 of the 1996 Act to offer in-region interLATA service. The 
    end date for BOCs that are authorized to offer interLATA service shall 
    apply only to the recovery of access charges in those states in which 
    the BOC is authorized to offer such service.
        490. We tentatively concluded in the NPRM that purchasers of 
    unbundled network elements should not be required to pay access 
    charges. We reaffirm our conclusion above in our discussion of 
    unbundled network elements that nothing on the face of sections 
    251(c)(3) and 252(d)(1) compels telecommunications carriers that use 
    unbundled elements to pay these charges, nor limits these carriers' 
    ability to use unbundled elements to originate or terminate interstate 
    calls, and that payment of rates based on TELRIC plus a reasonable 
    allocation of common costs, pursuant to section 251(d)(1), represents 
    full compensation to the incumbent LEC for use of the network elements 
    that telecommunications carriers purchase. Because of the unique 
    situation described in the preceding paragraphs, however, we conclude, 
    contrary to our proposal in the NPRM, that during a time-limited 
    period, interconnecting carriers should not be able to use unbundled 
    elements to avoid access charges in all cases. As detailed below, this 
    temporary mechanism will apply only to carriers that purchase the local 
    switch as an unbundled network element, and use that element to 
    originate or terminate interstate traffic. We are applying these 
    transitional charges to the unbundled local switching element, rather 
    than to any
    
    [[Page 45551]]
    
    other network elements, because such an approach is most closely 
    analogous to the manner in which the CCLC and TIC are recovered in the 
    interstate access regime. Currently, the CCLC and TIC apply to 
    interstate switched access minutes that traverse incumbent LECs' local 
    switches. Applying the CCLC and 75 percent of the TIC to the unbundled 
    local switching element is consistent with our goal of minimizing 
    disruptions while we reform our universal service system and consider 
    changes to our access charge mechanisms. Moreover, the CCLC and the TIC 
    are recovered on a per-minute basis, and the local switch is the 
    primary point at which incumbent LECs are capable of recording 
    interstate minutes for traffic associated with end user customers of 
    requesting carriers.
        491. We have crafted this short-term continuation of certain access 
    charge revenue flows to minimize the possibility that incumbent LECs 
    will be able to ``double recover'' through access charges the facility 
    costs that new entrants have already paid to purchase unbundled 
    elements. For that reason, we do not permit incumbent LECs to assess on 
    purchasers of the unbundled local switching element any interstate 
    access charges other than the CCLC and 75 percent of the TIC. The other 
    access charges are all designed to recover the cost of particular 
    facilities involved in the provision of interstate access services, 
    such as local switching, dedicated interoffice transport circuits, and 
    tandem switching. Imposition of these facility-based access charges in 
    addition to the cost-based charges for comparable network elements 
    established under Section 252 could result in double recovery. The 
    mechanism we establish will ensure that incentives created by non-cost-
    based elements of access charges do not result in harmful consequences 
    prior to completion of access reform and our universal service 
    proceeding. Imposition of additional access charges is therefore not 
    necessary. We note that this mechanism serves to minimize the 
    potentially disruptive effects of our decisions on incumbent LECs, 
    including small incumbent LECs.
        492. For the same reason, we permit incumbent LECs to recover only 
    75 percent of the TIC. Some portion of the TIC recovers revenues 
    associated with specific transport facilities. To the extent that these 
    costs can be identified clearly, they should not be imposed on new 
    entrants through the TIC. Incumbent LECs will be fully compensated for 
    any transport facilities that new entrants purchase from them through 
    the unbundled element rates states establish under 252(d)(1), which, as 
    we have stated, must be based on economic cost rather than access 
    charges. In our interim transport rate restructuring, we explicitly set 
    the initial tandem switching rate at 20 percent of the interstate 
    revenue requirement, with the remainder included in the TIC. Transport 
    Rate Structure and Pricing, Report and Order and Further Notice of 
    Proposed Rulemaking, 57 FR 54717 (November 20, 1992). In addition, 
    certain costs of upgrading incumbent LEC networks to support SS7 
    signaling were allocated to transport through then-existing separations 
    procedures. In our interim transport rate restructuring, we did not 
    create any facility-based charges to recover these costs, so the 
    associated revenues presumably were incorporated into the TIC. There 
    may also be other revenues associated with transport facilities that 
    are recovered today through the TIC. While we are uncertain of the 
    precise magnitude of these revenues, in our best judgment, based on the 
    record in the Transport proceeding and other information before us, we 
    find that it is likely that these revenues approach, but probably do 
    not exceed 25 percent of the TIC for most incumbent LECs. Thus, we 
    believe that 25 percent is a conservative amount to exclude from the 
    TIC to ensure that incumbent LECs do not double recover revenues 
    associated with transport facilities from new entrants. Moreover, the 
    Court in CompTel v. FCC remanded our Transport decision, in part, 
    because of the inclusion of tandem switching revenues in the TIC rather 
    than in the rate element for tandem switching. We find that excluding 
    25 percent of the TIC represents a reasonable exercise of our 
    discretion to prevent revenues associated with the tandem switching 
    revenue requirement from being recovered from purchasers or unbundled 
    local switching.
        493. We strongly emphasize that these charges will apply to 
    purchasers of the unbundled switching element only for a very limited 
    period, to avoid the possible harms that might arise if we were to 
    ignore the effects on access charges and universal service of 
    implementation of section 251. BOCs shall not be permitted to recover 
    these revenues once they are authorized to offer in-region interLATA 
    service, because at that time the potential loss of access charge 
    revenues faced by a BOC most likely will be able to be offset by new 
    revenues from interLATA services. Moreover, although we do not prejudge 
    the conditions necessary to grant BOC petitions under section 271 to 
    offer in-region interLATA service, we do decide that BOCs should not be 
    able to charge the CCLC and the TIC, which are not based on forward-
    looking economic costs, to competitors that use unbundled elements 
    under section 251 once they are authorized to provide in-region 
    interLATA service. Only BOCs are subject to special restrictions in the 
    1996 Act to ensure that their entry into the in-region interLATA market 
    does not have an adverse impact on competition. We conclude that this 
    additional trigger date after which BOCs may not continue to receive 
    access charges from purchasers of unbundled local switching is 
    consistent with this Congressional design.
        494. We have selected June 30, 1997 as an ultimate end date for 
    this transitional mechanism to coincide with the effective date for LEC 
    annual access tariffs, and because we believe it is imperative that 
    this transitional requirement be limited in duration. We can conceive 
    of no circumstances under which the requirement that certain entrants 
    pay the CCLC or a portion of the TIC on calls carried over unbundled 
    network elements would be extended further. The fact that access or 
    universal service reform have not been completed by that date would not 
    be a sufficient justification, nor would any actual or asserted harm to 
    the financial status of the incumbent LECs. By June 30, 1997, the 
    industry will have had sufficient time to plan for and adjust to 
    potential revenue shifts that may result from competitive entry. Thus, 
    the economic impact of our decision on competitive local service 
    providers, including those that are small entities, should be 
    minimized.
        495. We believe that we have ample legal authority to implement 
    this temporary transitional measure, and we find that this approach is 
    consistent with the letter and spirit of the 1996 Act. We recognize 
    that the CCLC and TIC have not been developed in accordance with the 
    pricing standards of section 252(d)(1), and that to comply with the 
    1996 Act, the rates that states establish for interconnection and 
    unbundled network elements may not include non-cost-based amounts or 
    subsidies. The 1934 and 1996 Acts do, however, give us legal authority 
    to determine, for policy reasons, that users of LEC facilities should 
    pay certain access charges for a period of time. New England Tel. and 
    Tel . Co. v. FCC, 826 F.2d 1101 (DC. Cir 1987); North American 
    Telecommunications Association v. FCC, 772 F.2d (7th Cir. 1085); 
    Lincoln Tel. and Tel. Co. v. FCC, 659 F.2d (DC. Cir. 1989). Section 
    4(i) of the 1934 Act authorizes the Commission to ``perform any and all 
    acts * * * not
    
    [[Page 45552]]
    
    inconsistent with this Act, as may be necessary in the execution of its 
    functions.'' Given the extraordinary upheaval in the industry's 
    structure set in motion by the 1996 Act, and the specific concerns 
    described above, we believe that a temporary mechanism is necessary in 
    order to ensure that the policy goals underlying the access charge 
    system and the Communications Act itself are not undermined. Further, 
    we believe section 251(g) of the 1996 Act lends support to our 
    decision. As discussed above, section 251(g) does not require that 
    incumbent LECs continue to receive access charge revenues when 
    telecommunications carriers use unbundled incumbent LEC network 
    elements to originate and terminate interstate traffic. That section 
    does, however, provide evidence of Congressional recognition of the 
    potential tension between existing interconnection obligations, such as 
    access charges, and the new methods of interconnection mandated by 
    section 251, and therefore supports our decision to create a limited-
    duration mechanism to address this tension.
        496. The decision of the court in CompTel v. FCC to remand our 
    decision to adopt the TIC is not inconsistent with this approach. The 
    Court's concern stemmed, in part, from the inclusion of a portion of 
    the interstate tandem switching revenue requirement in the TIC. We have 
    excluded from the charges that purchasers of unbundled local switching 
    must pay a percentage of the TIC that, at a minimum, includes these 
    allocated tandem switching revenues from the transitional charges that 
    incumbent LECs may assess on IXCs. Furthermore, the Court directed the 
    Commission to develop a cost-based transport rate structure, or to 
    explain why it chose not to do so. Competitive Telecommunications 
    Association v. FCC, 87 F.3d 522 (DC. Cir 1996). We intend to fulfill 
    this obligation in the forthcoming access reform proceeding. The charge 
    equal to 75 percent of the TIC will be applied only as an interim 
    measure for a brief, clearly-identified period, until that 
    restructuring of access charges is completed. The court expressly 
    acknowledged that the 1996 Act would have implications for the access 
    charge system. For the reasons described above, we conclude that these 
    effects necessitate temporary application of a portion of the TIC to 
    entrants that win end user customers from LECs, and that purchase the 
    local switch as an unbundled element to originate and terminate 
    interstate and intrastate toll traffic for such end users. In the 
    access reform proceeding, we intend to determine the appropriate 
    disposition for these revenues. Until we have had the opportunity to do 
    so, however, we permit incumbent LECs to recover a transitional charge 
    equal to 75 percent of the TIC under the limited circumstances 
    described herein.
        497. The interim mechanism we establish here differs from the 
    waiver relief we have previously granted to NYNEX and Ameritech to 
    permit them to recover certain interstate access charge revenues 
    through ``bulk billing'' of revenues to all interstate switched access 
    customers. Those orders responded to waiver requests filed prior to the 
    passage of the 1996 Act. Our responsibility in those proceedings was to 
    determine whether special circumstances existed, and whether the 
    specific relief requested better served the public interest than 
    continued application of our general rules. By constrast, the action we 
    take today addresses industry-wide issues that arise from the new 
    regime put into place by section 251 of the 1996 Act, which allows 
    states to establish unbundled network element rates that recover the 
    full unseparated cost of elements. Our response to the Ameritech and 
    NYNEX waiver petitions does not, simply because those petitions also 
    concerned access charge recovery, constrain our decision in this 
    proceeding.
        498. It would be unreasonable to provide such a transitional 
    mechanism on the federal level, but to deny similar authority to the 
    states. Therefore, states may continue existing explicit universal 
    service support mechanisms based on intrastate access charges for an 
    interim period of a similar brief, clearly-defined length. During that 
    period, unless decided otherwise by the state, incumbent LECs may 
    continue to recover such revenues from purchasers of unbundled local 
    switching elements that use those elements to originate or terminate 
    intrastate toll calls for end user customers they win from incumbent 
    LECs. States may terminate these mechanisms at any time. We define 
    mechanisms based on intrastate access charges as those mechanisms that 
    require purchasers of intrastate access services from incumbent LECs to 
    pay non-cost-based charges for those access services on the basis of 
    their intrastate access minutes of use.
        499. We do not intend, however, that such a transitional mechanism 
    eviscerate the requirements of sections 252 and 254, which, as we have 
    stated, prohibit funding of universal service subsidies through rates 
    for interconnection and unbundled network elements. Mechanisms such as 
    New York's ``pay or play'' system, which would impose intrastate access 
    charges on non-access services rather than allowing incumbent LECs to 
    recover non-cost-based revenues from purchasers of access services, may 
    not be included in this interim system. Such a result is justified 
    because state ``pay or play'' mechanisms do not at present constitute a 
    significant revenue stream to incumbent LECs, and therefore elimination 
    of this mechanism is unlikely, in the short term, to have significant 
    detrimental effects on universal service support.
        500. These state mechanisms must end on the earlier of: (1) June 
    30, 1997; or (2) if the incumbent LEC that receives the transitional 
    access charge revenues is a BOC, the date on which that BOC is 
    authorized under section 271 of the 1996 Act to offer in-region 
    interLATA service. With one exception, the analysis provided above as 
    to the rationale for the end dates for the transitional interstate 
    access charge mechanism applies here as well. Because our access reform 
    proceeding focuses on federal charges, and because the full extent of 
    the section 254 universal service mechanism remains to be determined in 
    that proceeding, intrastate access charge-based universal service 
    support mechanisms should not now be required to terminate upon the 
    completion of those proceedings.
        501. As with our decision to permit incumbent LECs to continue to 
    receive certain interstate access charge revenues from some purchasers 
    of unbundled local switching for a limited period of time, we believe 
    our decision to allow states to preserve certain intrastate universal 
    service support mechanisms based on access charges is within our 
    authority under section 251(d)(1) of the 1996 Act, and section 4(i) of 
    the 1934 Act. Moreover, although section 251(g) does not directly refer 
    to intrastate access charge mechanisms, it would be incongruous to 
    conclude that Congress was concerned about the effects of potential 
    disruption to the interstate access charge system, but had no such 
    concerns about the effects on analogous intrastate mechanisms.
    (c) Fifth Amendment Issues
        502. We conclude that our decision that prices for incumbent LECs' 
    unbundled elements and interconnection offerings be based on forward-
    looking economic cost does not violate the incumbent LECs' rights under 
    the Fifth Amendment of the Constitution. The Supreme Court has 
    recognized that public utilities owned and operated by private 
    investors, even though their assets are employed in the public interest 
    to provide consumers
    
    [[Page 45553]]
    
    with service, may assert their rights under the Takings Clause of the 
    Fifth Amendment. Duquesne Light Co. v. Barasch, 488 U.S. 299, 307 
    (1989). In applying the Takings Clause to rate setting for public 
    utilities, the Court has stated that ``[t]he guiding principle has been 
    that the Constitution protects utilities from being limited to a charge 
    for their property serving the public which is so `unjust' as to be 
    confiscatory.''
        503. The Supreme Court has held that the determination of whether a 
    rate is confiscatory depends on whether that rate is just and 
    reasonable, and not on what methodology is used. In re Permian Basin 
    Area Rate Cases, 390 U.S. 747 (1968); Federal Power Commission v. 
    Memphis Light, Gas & Water Division, 411 U.S. 458 (1973); Jersey 
    Central Power & Light v. FERC, 810 F.2d 1168 (D.C. Cir. 1987). In 
    Federal Power Comm'n v. Hope Natural Gas Co., 320 U.S. 591 (1944), the 
    Court upheld the Federal Power Commission's order that required the 
    company to make a large reduction in wholesale gas rates. The 
    commission based its determination of a reasonable rate of return on a 
    plant valuation determined by using a historical cost methodology that 
    was only half as large as the company's own valuation based on forward-
    looking reproduction costs. In its decision, the Court set forth the 
    governing legal standard for determining whether a rate is 
    constitutional:
    
        Under the statutory standard of ``just and reasonable'' it is 
    the result reached not the method employed that is controlling. It 
    is not the theory but the impact of the rate order which counts. If 
    the total effect of the rate order cannot be said to be unjust and 
    unreasonable, judicial inquiry under the Act is at an end. The fact 
    that the method employed to reach that result may contain 
    infirmities is not then important.
    
        504. The Court went on to explain that, in determining whether a 
    rate is reasonable, the regulatory body must balance the interests of 
    both the investor and consumer. ``From the investor or company point of 
    view, it is important that there be enough revenue not only for 
    operating expenses but also for the capital costs of the business * * 
    *. [T]he return on the equity owner should be commensurate with returns 
    on investments in other enterprises having corresponding risks.''
        505. Under sections 251(c) (2) and (3) of the 1996 Act, incumbent 
    LECs must establish rates for interconnection and unbundled elements 
    that are just and reasonable. In adopting the rules that govern those 
    rates, under Hope Natural Gas we must consider whether the end result 
    of incumbent LEC rates is just and reasonable. Incumbent LECs argue 
    that establishing a rate structure that does not permit recovery of 
    historical or embedded costs is confiscatory. We disagree. As stated 
    above, the Court has consistently held since Hope Natural Gas that it 
    is the end result, not the method used to achieve that result, that is 
    the issue to be addressed. Indeed, the Court has found that the 
    ``fixing of prices, like other applications of the police power, may 
    reduce the value of the property which is being regulated. But the fact 
    that the value is reduced does not mean that the regulation is 
    invalid.'' Moreover, the Court has upheld as reasonable changes in 
    ratemaking methodology when the change resulted in the exclusion of 
    historical costs prudently incurred. Thus, the mere fact that an 
    incumbent LEC may not be able to set rates that will allow it to 
    recover a particular cost incurred in establishing its regulated 
    network does not, in and of itself, result in confiscation.
        506. Moreover, Hope Natural Gas requires only that the end result 
    of our overall regulatory framework provides LECs a reasonable 
    opportunity to recover a return on their investment. In other words, 
    incumbent LECs' overall rates must be considered, including the 
    revenues for other services under our jurisdiction.
        507. In this proceeding, we are establishing pricing rules that 
    should produce rates for monopoly elements and services that 
    approximate what the incumbent LECs would be able to charge if there 
    were a competitive market for such offerings. We believe that a 
    forward-looking economic cost methodology enables incumbent LECs to 
    recover a fair return on their investment, i.e., just and reasonable 
    rates. The record does not compel a contrary conclusion. No incumbent 
    LEC has provided persuasive evidence that prices based on a forward-
    looking economic cost methodology would have a significant impact on 
    its ``financial integrity.'' We further note that at least one federal 
    appellate court has held incremental cost-based pricing constitutional. 
    Metropolitan Transp. Auth. v. Interstate Commerce Commission, 792 F.2d 
    287, 297 (2d Cir.), cert. denied, 479 U.S. 1017 (1986).
        508. Incumbent LECs may seek relief from the Commission's pricing 
    methodology if they provide specific information to show that the 
    pricing methodology, as applied to them, will result in confiscatory 
    rates. We also do not completely foreclose the possibility that 
    incumbent LECs will be afforded an opportunity to recover, to some 
    extent, their embedded costs through a mechanism separate from rates 
    for interconnection and unbundled network elements. As stated above, we 
    intend to explore this issue in detail in our upcoming access reform 
    proceeding.
        509. GTE argues that the proper standard to review our ratemaking 
    methodology is the just compensation standard generally reserved for 
    takings of property. This is in effect a contention that the 1996 Act's 
    physical collocation and unbundled network facility requirements 
    constitute physical occupation of their property that should be deemed 
    a taking and that must be subject to ``just compensation.'' Assuming 
    for the sake of argument that the physical collocation and unbundled 
    facilities requirements do result in a taking, we nevertheless find 
    that the ratemaking methodology we have adopted satisfies the just 
    compensation standard. Just compensation is normally measured by the 
    fair market value of the property subject to the taking. Just 
    compensation is not, however, intended to permit recovery of monopoly 
    rents. The just and reasonable rate standard of TELRIC plus a 
    reasonable allocation of the joint and common costs of providing 
    network elements that we are adopting attempts to replicate, with 
    respect to bottleneck monopoly elements, the rates that would be 
    charged in a competitive market, Policy and Rules Concerning Rates for 
    Dominant Carriers, Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 53 FR 22356 
    (June 15, 1988), and, we believe, is entirely consistent with the just 
    compensation standard. Indeed, a similar rate methodology based on 
    incremental costs has been found to satisfy the just compensation 
    requirement. For these reasons, we conclude that, even if the 1996 
    Act's physical collocation and unbundled network facility requirements 
    constitute a taking, a forward-looking economic cost methodology 
    satisfies the Constitution's just compensation standard.
    3. Rate Structure Rules
    a. General Rate Structure Rules
    (1) Background
        510. In addition to applying our economic pricing methodology to 
    determine the rate level of a specific element or interconnection, the 
    state must also determine the appropriate rate structure. We discuss in 
    this section general principles for analyzing rate structure questions, 
    such as in what circumstances charges should be flat-rated or usage 
    sensitive and in what circumstances they should be recurring or non-
    recurring. These rate structure
    
    [[Page 45554]]
    
    rules will apply as well if a state sets rates based on default proxies 
    discussed in Section VII.C.2 below, where we also discuss the 
    appropriate rate structure for specific network elements. Network 
    providers incur costs in providing two broad categories of facilities, 
    dedicated and shared. Dedicated facilities are those that are used by a 
    single party--either an end user or an interconnecting network. Shared 
    facilities are those used by multiple parties. In the NPRM, we proposed 
    that costs should be recovered in a manner that reflects the way they 
    are incurred. We also sought comment on whether we should require 
    states to provide for recovery of dedicated facility costs on a flat-
    rated basis, or at a minimum, require LECs to offer a flat-rate option.
    (2) Discussion
        511. We conclude, as a general rule, that incumbent LECs' rates for 
    interconnection and unbundled elements must recover costs in a manner 
    that reflects the way they are incurred. This will conform to the 1996 
    Act's requirement that rates be cost-based, ensure requesting carriers 
    have the right incentives to construct and use public network 
    facilities efficiently, and prevent incumbent LECs from inefficiently 
    raising costs in order to deter entry. We note that this conclusion 
    should facilitate competition on a reasonable and efficient basis by 
    all firms in the industry by establishing prices for interconnection 
    and unbundled elements based on costs similar to those incurred by the 
    incumbents, which may be expected to reduce the regulatory burdens and 
    economic impact of our decision for many parties, including both small 
    entities seeking to enter the local exchange markets and small 
    incumbent LECs. We also adopt some more specific rules that follow from 
    this general rule.
        512. First, we require that the charges for dedicated facilities be 
    flat-rated, including, but not limited to, charges for unbundled loops, 
    dedicated transport, interconnection, and collocation. These charges 
    should be assessed for fixed periods, such as a month. We are requiring 
    flat-rated charges for dedicated facilities. Usage-based charges for 
    dedicated facilities would give purchasers of access to network 
    elements an uneconomic incentive to reduce their traffic volumes. 
    Moreover, purchasers of access to network elements with low volumes of 
    traffic would pay below-cost prices, and therefore have an incentive to 
    add lines that they would not add if they had to pay the full cost. As 
    stated in the NPRM, a flat-rated charge is most efficient for dedicated 
    facilities, because it ensures that a customer will pay the full cost 
    of the facility, and no more. It ensures that an entrant will, for 
    example, purchase the exclusive right to use additional loops only if 
    the entrant believes that the benefits of the additional loops will 
    exceed its costs. It also ensures that the entrant will not face an 
    additional (and non-cost-based) usage charge.
        513. Second, if we apply our general rule that costs should be 
    recovered in a manner that reflects the way they are incurred, then 
    recurring costs must be recovered through recurring charges, rather 
    than through a nonrecurring charge. A recurring cost is one incurred 
    periodically over time. A LEC may not recover recurring costs such as 
    income taxes, maintenance expenses, and administrative expenses through 
    a nonrecurring charge because these are costs that are incurred in 
    connection with the asset over time. For example, we determine that 
    maintenance expenses relating to the local loop must be recovered 
    through the recurring loop charge, rather than through a nonrecurring 
    charge imposed upon the entrant.
        514. We find that recovering a recurring cost through a 
    nonrecurring charge would be unjust and unreasonable because it is 
    unlikely that incumbent LECs will be able to calculate properly the 
    present value of recurring costs. To calculate properly the present 
    value of recurring costs, an incumbent LEC would have to project 
    accurately the duration, level, and frequency of the recurring costs 
    and estimate properly its overall cost of capital. We find that, in 
    practice, the present value of the recurring costs cannot be calculated 
    with sufficient accuracy to warrant up-front recovery of these costs 
    because incumbent LECs lack sufficient experience with the provision of 
    interconnection and unbundled rate elements. Without sufficient 
    experience, incumbent LECs are unable to project the length of time 
    that an average entrant would interconnect with, or take an unbundled 
    element from, the incumbent LEC, or how expenses associated with 
    interconnection and unbundled rate elements would change over time. In 
    contrast, a recurring charge for a recurring cost would ensure that a 
    customer is only charged for the costs the entrant incurs while that 
    entrant is taking interconnection service or unbundled rate elements 
    from the incumbent LEC. Moreover, when costs associated with the 
    interconnection and particular unbundled rate elements change, the 
    incumbent LEC can make appropriate adjustments to the charges at the 
    time such cost changes occur.
        515. Accordingly, we find that imposing nonrecurring charges for 
    recurring costs could pose a barrier to entry because these charges may 
    be excessive, reflecting costs that may (1) not actually occur; (2) be 
    incurred later than predicted; (3) not be incurred for as long as 
    predicted; (4) be incurred at a level that is lower than predicted; (5) 
    be incurred less frequently than predicted; and (6) be discounted to 
    the present using a cost of capital that is too low.
        516. Notwithstanding the foregoing, where recurring costs are de 
    minimis, we will permit incumbent LECs to recover such costs through 
    nonrecurring charges. We find that recurring costs are de minimis where 
    the costs of administering the recurring charge would be excessive in 
    relation to the amount of the recurring costs.
        517. Third, states may, but need not, require incumbent LECs in an 
    arbitrated agreement to recover nonrecurring costs, costs that are 
    incurred only once, through recurring charges over a reasonable period 
    of time. The recovery of such nonrecurring costs through recurring 
    charges is a common practice for telecommunications services. 
    Construction of an interconnector's physical collocation cage is an 
    example of a nonrecurring cost. We find that states may, where 
    reasonable, require an incumbent LEC to recover construction costs for 
    an interconnector's physical collocation cage as a recurring charge 
    over a reasonable period of time in lieu of a nonrecurring charge. This 
    arrangement would decrease the size of the entrant's initial capital 
    outlay, thereby reducing financial barriers to entry. At the same time, 
    any such reasonable arrangement would ensure that incumbent LECs are 
    fully compensated for their nonrecurring costs.
        518. We require, however, that state commissions take steps to 
    ensure that incumbent LECs do not recover nonrecurring costs twice and 
    that nonrecurring charges are imposed equitably among entrants. A state 
    commission may, for example, decide to permit incumbent LECs to charge 
    the initial entrants the full amount of costs incurred for shared 
    facilities for physical collocation service, even if future entrants 
    may benefit. A state commission may, however, require subsequent 
    entrants, who take physical collocation service in the same central 
    office and receive benefits as a result of costs for shared facilities, 
    to pay the incumbent LEC for their proportionate share of those costs, 
    less depreciation (if
    
    [[Page 45555]]
    
    an asset is involved). Under this approach, the state commission could 
    require the incumbent LEC to provide the initial entrants pro rata 
    refunds, reflecting the full amount of the charges collected from the 
    subsequent entrants. Alternatively, a state commission may decide to 
    permit incumbent LECs to charge initial entrants a proportionate 
    fraction of the costs incurred, based on a reasonable estimate of the 
    total demand by entrants for the particular interconnection service or 
    unbundled rate elements.
        519. In addition, state commissions must ensure that nonrecurring 
    charges imposed by incumbent LECs are equitably allocated among 
    entrants where such charges are imposed on one entrant for the use of 
    an asset and another entrant uses the asset after the first entrant 
    abandons the asset. For example, when an entrant pays a nonrecurring 
    charge for construction of a physical collocation cage and the entrant 
    discontinues occupying the cage before the end of the economic life of 
    the cage, a state commission could require that the initial entrant 
    receive a pro rata refund from the incumbent LEC for the undepreciated 
    value of the cage in the event that a subsequent entrant takes physical 
    collocation service and uses the asset. Under this approach, the state 
    commission could require that the subsequent entrant pay the incumbent 
    LEC a nonrecurring charge equal to the remaining unamortized value of 
    the cage and the initial entrant will receive a credit from the 
    incumbent LEC equal to the unamortized value of the cage at the time 
    the subsequent entrant takes service and utilizes the cage.
        520. BellSouth's concern that rate structure rules could preclude 
    mutually agreeable alternative structures is misplaced. The rate 
    structure rules we adopt here apply only to rates imposed by the states 
    in arbitration among the parties and to state review of BOC statements 
    of generally available terms. Our rules do not restrict parties from 
    agreeing to alternative rate structures. On the contrary, our intent, 
    following the clear pro-negotiation spirit of the 1996 Act, is for 
    parties to use the backdrop of state arbitrations conducted under our 
    rules, to negotiate more efficient, mutually agreeable arrangements, 
    subject, of course, to the antitrust laws and to the 1996 Act's 
    requirements that voluntarily negotiated agreements not unreasonably 
    discriminate against third parties.
    b. Additional Rate Structure Rules for Shared Facilities
    (1) Background
        521. In the NPRM, we stated our belief that the costs of shared 
    facilities should be recovered in a manner that efficiently apportions 
    costs among users that share the facility. The NPRM noted that, for 
    shared facilities, it may be efficient to set prices using any of the 
    following: a usage-sensitive charge; a usage-sensitive charge for peak-
    time usage and a lower charge for off-peak usage; or a flat charge for 
    the peak capacity that an interconnector wishes to pay for and use as 
    though that portion of the facility were dedicated to the 
    interconnector.
    (2) Discussion
        522. The costs of shared facilities including, but not limited to, 
    much of local switching, tandem switching, transmission facilities 
    between the end office and the tandem switch, and signaling, should be 
    recovered in a manner that efficiently apportions costs among users. 
    Because the cost of capacity is determined by the volume of traffic 
    that the facilities are able to handle during peak load periods, we 
    believe, as a matter of economic theory, that if usage-sensitive rates 
    are used, then somewhat higher rates should apply to peak period 
    traffic, with lower rates for non-peak usage. The peak load price would 
    be designed to recover at least the cost of the incremental network 
    capacity added to carry peak period traffic. Pricing traffic during 
    peak periods based on the cost of the incremental capacity needed to 
    handle additional traffic would be economically efficient because 
    additional traffic would be placed on the network if and only if the 
    user or interconnecting network is willing to pay the cost of the 
    incremental network capacity required to handle this additional 
    traffic. Such pricing would ensure that a call made during the peak 
    period generates enough revenue to cover the cost of the facilities 
    expansion it requires, and would thus give carriers an incentive to 
    expand and develop the network efficiently. In contrast, off-peak 
    traffic imposes relatively little additional cost because it does not 
    require any incremental capacity to be added to base plant, and 
    consequently, the price for carrying off-peak traffic should be lower.
        523. We recognize, however, that there are practical problems 
    associated with a peak-sensitive pricing system. For example, different 
    parts of a given provider's network may experience peak traffic volumes 
    at different times (e.g., business districts may experience their peak 
    period between 10:00 and 11:00 a.m., while suburban areas may have 
    their peak periods between 7:00 and 8:00 p.m.) Moreover, peak periods 
    may change over time. For instance, growth in Internet usage may create 
    new peak periods in the late evening. Further, charging different 
    prices for calls made during different parts of the day may cause some 
    customers to shift their calling to the less expensive time periods, 
    which could shift the peak or create new peaks. Thus, to design an 
    efficient peak-sensitive pricing system requires detailed knowledge of 
    both the structure of costs as well as demand.
        524. We conclude that the practical problems associated with peak-
    sensitive pricing make it inappropriate for us to require states to 
    impose such a rate structure for unbundled local switching or other 
    shared facilities whose costs vary with capacity. Because we believe 
    that such a structure may be the most economically efficient, however, 
    we do not prohibit states from imposing peak-sensitive pricing. We also 
    expect that parties may be able to negotiate agreements with peak/off-
    peak differences if the benefits of such distinctions are sufficiently 
    high. We conclude that states may use either usage-sensitive rates or 
    flat capacity-based rates for shared facilities, if a state finds that 
    such rates reasonably reflect the costs imposed by the various users. 
    States may consider for guidance rate structures developed in 
    competitive markets for shared facilities. We note that our decisions 
    in this section may benefit small entity entrants in local exchange and 
    exchange access markets by minimizing the extent to which purchasers of 
    interconnection and unbundled access pay rates that diverge from the 
    costs of those facilities and services.
    c. Geographic/Class-of-Service Averaging
    (1) Background
        525. In the NPRM, we asked about the appropriate level of 
    aggregation for rates for interconnection and access to unbundled 
    elements. We noted that geographic averaging is simple to administer 
    and prevents unreasonable or unlawful rate differences but, where 
    averaging covers high and low cost areas, it could distort competitors' 
    decisions whether to lease unbundled elements or build their own 
    facilities. We sought comment on the geographic deaveraging of 
    interconnection and unbundled element rates by zone, LATA, or other 
    area.
    
    [[Page 45556]]
    
        526. We also inquired about disaggregation by class of service. We 
    questioned whether business and residential loops, or loops deployed 
    using different technologies should be charged different rates, and how 
    large a differential should be allowed.
    (2) Discussion
        527. Geographic Deaveraging. The 1996 Act mandates that rates for 
    interconnection and unbundled elements be ``based on the cost * * * of 
    providing the interconnection of network elements.'' We agree with most 
    parties that deaveraged rates more closely reflect the actual costs of 
    providing interconnection and unbundled elements. Thus, we conclude 
    that rates for interconnection and unbundled elements must be 
    geographically deaveraged.
        528. The record reflects that at least two states have implemented 
    geographically-deaveraged rate zones. These rate zone pricing systems 
    have generally included a minimum of three zones. In the Expanded 
    Interconnection proceeding, the Commission also permitted LECs to 
    implement a three zone structure. Expanded Interconnection Order. 57 FR 
    54323 (November 18, 1992); Expanded Interconnection Second Report and 
    Order and Third Notice of Proposed Rulemaking. 58 FR 48756 (September 
    17, 1993). We conclude that three zones are presumptively sufficient to 
    reflect geographic cost differences in setting rates for 
    interconnection and unbundled elements, and that states may, but need 
    not, use these existing density-related rate zones. Where such systems 
    are not in existence, states shall create a minimum of three cost-
    related rate zones to implement deaveraged rates for interconnection 
    and unbundled elements. A state may establish more than three zones 
    where cost differences in geographic regions are such that it finds 
    that additional zones are needed to adequately reflect the costs of 
    interconnection and access to unbundled elements.
        529. Class-of-Service Deaveraging. The record leads us to the 
    opposite conclusion for class-of-service deaveraging. Under the 1996 
    Act, wholesale rates for resold services will be based on retail rates 
    less avoided costs. Rates for interconnection and access to unbundled 
    elements, however, are to be based on costs. We conclude that the 
    pricing standard for interconnection and unbundled elements prohibits 
    deaveraging that is not cost based. Interconnection and unbundled 
    elements are intermediate services provided by incumbent LECs to other 
    telecommunications carriers, and there is no evidence that the cost of 
    providing these intermediate services varies with the class of service 
    the telecommunications carrier is providing to its end-user customers. 
    We conclude that states may not impose class-of-service deaveraging on 
    rates for interconnection and unbundled elements. We disagree with the 
    Ohio Consumers' Counsel's position that the 1996 Act's explicit 
    permission of class-of-service deaveraging of resold services implies 
    that class-of-service deaveraging should be permitted for 
    interconnection and unbundled elements. Finally, we note that these 
    decisions concerning averaging may be expected to lead to increased 
    competition and a more efficient allocation of resources, which should 
    benefit the entire industry, including small entities and small 
    incumbent LECs.
    
    C. Default Proxy Ceilings and Ranges
    
        530. As previously discussed, we strongly encourage state 
    commissions, as a general rule, to set arbitrated rates for 
    interconnection and access to unbundled network elements pursuant to 
    the forward-looking, economic cost pricing methodology we adopt in this 
    Order. Such rates would approximate levels charged in a competitive 
    market, would be economically efficient, and would be based on the 
    forward-looking, economic cost of providing interconnection and 
    unbundled elements. We recognize, however, that, in some cases, it may 
    not be possible for carriers to prepare, or the state commission to 
    review, economic cost studies within the statutory time frame for 
    arbitration and thus here first address situations in which a state has 
    not approved a cost study. States that do not complete their review of 
    a forward-looking economic cost study within the statutory time periods 
    but must render pricing decisions, will be able to establish interim 
    arbitrated rates based on the proxies we provide in this Order. A proxy 
    approach might provide a faster, administratively simpler, and less 
    costly approach to establishing prices on an interim basis than a 
    detailed forward-looking cost study.
        531. The default proxies we establish will, in most cases, serve as 
    presumptive ceilings. States may set prices below those ceilings if the 
    record before them supports a lower price. States should provide a 
    reasoned basis for selecting a particular default price. In one case, 
    for local switching, the default proxy is a range within which a state 
    may set prices.
        532. States that set prices based upon the default proxies must 
    also require the parties to update the prices in the interconnection 
    agreement on a going-forward basis, either after the state conducts or 
    approves an economic study according to the cost-based pricing 
    methodology or pursuant to any revision of the default proxy. We 
    believe generic economic cost models, in principle, best comport with 
    the preferred economic cost approach described previously, and we 
    intend to examine further such models by the first quarter of 1997 to 
    determine whether any of those models, with any appropriate 
    modifications, could serve as better default proxies. Any updated price 
    would take effect beginning at the time of the completed and approved 
    study or the application of the revised default proxy.
        533. Second, if a state has approved or conducted an economic cost 
    study, prior to this Order, that complies with the methodology we adopt 
    in this Order, the state may continue to apply the resulting rate even 
    when not consistent with our default proxies. There must, however, be a 
    factual record, including the cost study, sufficient for purposes of 
    review after notice and opportunity for the affected parties to 
    participate.
        534. Finally, while we provide for the use by states of default 
    proxies, we recognize that certain states that are unable to utilize an 
    economic cost study may wish to obtain the benefits of setting rates 
    pursuant to such a study for its residents. The Commission will 
    therefore entertain requests by states to review an economic cost 
    study, to assist the state in conducting or reviewing such a study, or 
    to conduct such a study.
    1. Use of Proxies Generally
    a. Background
        535. In the NPRM, we discussed the possibility of setting certain 
    outside limits for interconnection and unbundled element rates, in 
    particular, by the use of proxies. We invited parties to comment on 
    whether the use of certain proxies to set outer boundaries on the 
    prices for interconnection and unbundled elements would be consistent 
    with the pricing principles of the 1996 Act. Specifically, in the NPRM, 
    we asked parties to comment on the benefits of various types of 
    proxies: (1) generic cost studies, such as the Benchmark Cost Model and 
    the Hatfield models; (2) some measure of nationally-averaged cost data; 
    (3) rates in existing interconnection and unbundling arrangements 
    between incumbent LECs and other providers of local service, such as 
    neighboring incumbent LECs, CMRS providers, or other entrants in the
    
    [[Page 45557]]
    
    same service area; (4) a subset of the incumbent LECs' existing 
    interstate access rates, charged for interconnection with IXCs and 
    other access customers, or an intrastate equivalent; (5) use of the 
    interstate prices established in the ONA proceeding for unbundled 
    features and functions of the local switch as ceilings for the same 
    unbundled elements under section 251; and (6) any other 
    administratively simple methods for establishing a ceiling for 
    interconnection and unbundled network element rates. As a counterpart 
    to ceilings, we also sought comment on whether it would be necessary or 
    appropriate for us to establish floors for interconnection and 
    unbundled element prices.
    b. Discussion
        536. We adopt, in the section below, default proxies for particular 
    network elements. We believe that these default proxies generally will 
    result in reasonable price ceilings or price ranges and, for 
    administrative and practical reasons, will be beneficial to the states 
    in conducting initial rate arbitrations, especially in the time period 
    prior to completion of a cost study. The proxies we adopt are designed 
    to approximate prices that will enable competitors to enter the local 
    exchange market swiftly and efficiently and will constrain the 
    incumbent LECs' ability to preclude efficient entry by manipulating the 
    allocation of common costs among services and elements. States that 
    utilize the default proxies we establish to set prices in an 
    arbitration should revise those prices on a going-forward basis when 
    they are able to utilize the preferred economic costing methodology we 
    describe in Section VII.B.2.a. above, or if we subsequently adopt new 
    proxies.
        537. We have considered the economic impact of the adoption of 
    default proxy ceilings and ranges on small entities, including new 
    entrants and small incumbent LECs. The adoption of proxies for interim 
    arbitrated rates should minimize regulatory burdens on the parties to 
    arbitration, including small entities seeking to enter the local 
    exchange markets and small incumbent LECs, by permitting states to 
    implement the 1996 Act more quickly and facilitating competition on a 
    reasonable and efficient basis by all firms in the industry. We 
    therefore believe that the adoption of default proxy ranges and 
    ceilings advances the pro-competitive goals of the 1996 Act. We also 
    note that certain small incumbent LECs are not subject to our rules 
    under section 251(f)(1) of the 1996 Act, unless otherwise determined by 
    a state commission, and certain other small incumbent LECs may seek 
    relief from their state commissions from our rules under section 
    251(f)(2) of the 1996 Act.
        538. The proxies that we establish represent the price ceiling or 
    price ranges for the particular element on an averaged basis. In 
    Section VII.B.3.c. above, we required that rates be set on a 
    geographically-deaveraged basis. Consequently, states utilizing the 
    proxies shall set rates such that the average rate for the particular 
    element in a study area does not exceed the applicable proxy ceiling or 
    lie outside the proxy range.
        539. We reject the use of rates in interconnection agreements that 
    predate the 1996 Act as a proxy-based ceiling for interconnection and 
    unbundled element rates. These existing interconnection agreements were 
    not reached in a competitive market environment. Further, such 
    agreements may reflect the divergent bargaining power of the parties to 
    the agreement, various public policy initiatives to advance rural 
    telephone service, or non-monetary quid pro quos often found in 
    voluntarily negotiated business arrangements that may be difficult to 
    quantify. There is little basis for us to conclude that rates in these 
    interconnection agreements reflect the forward-looking, incremental 
    cost of interconnection and unbundled network elements. Prices in 
    agreements reached since the 1996 Act are more likely than prior 
    agreements to provide useful information about forward-looking costs, 
    which together with other information may be useful in establishing 
    proxies.
        540. In the NPRM, we also raised the issue of using some measure of 
    nationally-averaged cost data as a proxy. No such study has been 
    submitted into the record in this proceeding.
    2. Proxies for Specific Elements
    a. Overview
        541. Although we encourage states to use an economic cost 
    methodology to set rates for interconnection, unbundled network 
    elements, and collocation, we will permit states unable to analyze an 
    economic costing study within the statutory time constraints to use 
    default proxies in setting and reviewing rates. We set forth below the 
    default proxies for specific network elements. These proxies are 
    interim only. They will apply only until a state sets rates in 
    arbitrations on the basis of an economic cost study, or until we 
    promulgate new proxies based on economic cost models. We also set forth 
    below the rate structure rules that apply to each of network elements. 
    These rate structure requirements are applicable regardless of whether 
    a state uses an economic cost study or the proxy approach to set rate 
    levels.
    b. Discussion
    (1) Loops
    (a) Discussion
        542. Most loop costs are associated with a single customer. MTS and 
    WATS Market Structure, Third Report and Order. 48 FR 10319 (March 11, 
    1983). Outside plant between a customer's premises and ports on 
    incumbent LEC switches is typically either physically separate for each 
    individual customer, or has costs that can easily be apportioned among 
    users. We therefore conclude that costs associated with unbundled loops 
    should be recovered on a flat-rated basis. Usage-based rates for an 
    unbundled loop would most likely translate into usage-based rates for 
    new entrants' retail local customers. A retail usage-based rate would 
    distort incentives for efficient use. Customers that had to pay a usage 
    charge would have an incentive not to use the network in situations 
    where the benefit of using the network exceeds the true cost of using 
    the network. Usage-based loop prices would put an entrant at an 
    artificial cost disadvantage when competing for high-volume customers. 
    We note that MFS has filed a separate petition asking the Commission to 
    preempt certain provisions of the Texas statute, which it contends 
    requires incumbent LECs to sell unbundled local loops on a usage-
    sensitive basis. We will rule specifically on the Texas statute when we 
    consider the MFS Texas Petition.
        543. In general, we believe that states should use a TELRIC 
    methodology to establish geographically deaveraged, flat-rate charges 
    for access to unbundled loops. As discussed above, however, we 
    recognize that, in some cases, it may not be possible for carriers to 
    prepare, or for state commissions to review, economic cost studies 
    within the statutory time frame for arbitration proceedings. Because 
    reviewing and approving such cost studies takes time and because many 
    states have not yet begun, or have only recently begun, to develop and 
    examine such studies, it is critical for the near-term development of 
    local competition to have proxies that provide an approximation of 
    forward-looking economic costs and can be used by states almost 
    immediately. These proxies would be used by a state commission until it 
    is able either to complete a cost study or to evaluate and adopt the 
    results of a study or studies
    
    [[Page 45558]]
    
    submitted in the record. In an NPRM to be issued shortly, we will 
    investigate more fully various long-run incremental cost models in the 
    record with an eye to developing a model that can be used to generate 
    proxies for the forward looking economic costs of network elements. 
    Until such time as we can develop such a model, we have developed the 
    following default proxy ceilings that state commissions that have not 
    completed forward looking economic cost studies may use in the interim 
    as an approximation to the forward looking cost of the local loop.
        544. State commissions may use this proxy to derive a maximum (or 
    ceiling) loop rate for each incumbent LEC operating within their state, 
    and may establish actual unbundled loop rates at any level less than or 
    equal to this maximum rate in specific arbitrations or other 
    proceedings. Of course, we are encouraging states to have economic 
    studies completed wherever feasible. Moreover, states will have to 
    replace this proxy ceiling with the results of their own forward 
    looking economic cost study or the results produced by a generic 
    economic cost model that the Commission has approved.
        545. We are adopting a proxy ceiling based on two cost models and 
    rates for unbundled loops allowed by six states that had available to 
    them the results of forward-looking economic cost studies at the time 
    they considered either interim or permanent rates for the unbundled 
    loop element. These states are Colorado, Connecticut, Florida, 
    Illinois, Michigan, and Oregon. Each of these states has used a 
    standard that appears to be reasonably close to the forward-looking 
    economic cost methodology that we require to be used, although possibly 
    not consistent in every detail with our TELRIC methodology. Generally, 
    these states appear to have included an allocation of forward-looking 
    common costs in their unbundled loop prices. The individual state 
    studies resulted in the following average rates for unbundled local 
    loops: Colorado, $18; Connecticut, $12.95; Florida, $17.28; Illinois, 
    $10.93; Michigan, $10.03; and Oregon, $12.45, computed as set forth 
    below.
        546. The Colorado Commission set an interim rate of $18 per month 
    for unbundled loops terminated at the main distribution frame of the 
    LEC switch. The Connecticut Commission ruled that SNET must provide the 
    following interim unbundled loop prices varying by four zones: metro 
    $10.18; urban $11.33; suburban $15.33; and rural $14.97. In the absence 
    of further information about customer density or average loop length by 
    zone, we used a simple average equal to $12.95. The Florida Commission 
    set an interim rate for 2-wire loops at $17.00 per month for BellSouth, 
    $15.00 for United/Centel, and $20.00 for GTE. Using weights equal to 
    the number of loops served by each company in 1994 as reported in the 
    Monitoring Report, we computed a weighted average price equal to 
    $17.28. Pursuant to its Customers First Order, the Illinois Commerce 
    Commission approved tariffs establishing business rates equal to $7.08, 
    $10.92, and $14.45, and residential rates equal to $4.59, $8.67, and 
    $12.14 in three density zones. Based on data from Table 2.5, page 20 of 
    the Common Carrier Statistics, 1995 Preliminary, we found a 36 percent-
    64 percent business residential split. Using Illinois Commission data 
    for number of households in each density zone (996,750 in zone A; 
    2,788,759 in zone B; 4,594,567 in zone C), we computed an average loop 
    cost of $10.93. The Michigan Commission approved transitional rates of 
    $8.00 per loop for business and $11 per loop for residence. Based on 
    Common Carrier Statistics, 1995 Preliminary data, we computed a 32 
    percent-68 percent business-residential split in Michigan, which leads 
    to an average rate of $10.03. The Oregon Commission set the rate for a 
    ``basic 2-wire loop set'' at $11.95 plus $0.50 for a network access 
    channel connection, for a total price of $12.45.
        547. In order to set a proxy ceiling for unbundled loop elements we 
    make use of the two cost models for which nationwide data are available 
    and upon which parties have had the opportunity to comment in this 
    proceeding. These models are the Benchmark Cost Model (BCM) and the 
    Hatfield 2.2. Based on our current information, we believe that both 
    these models are based on detailed engineering and demographic 
    assumptions that vary among states, and that the outputs of these 
    models represent sufficiently reasonable predictions of relative cost 
    differences among states to be used as set forth below to set a proxy 
    ceiling on unbundled loop prices for each state. We do not believe, 
    however, that these model outputs by themselves necessarily represent 
    accurate estimates of the absolute magnitude of loop costs. As we 
    discuss below, further analysis is necessary in order to evaluate fully 
    the procedures and input assumptions that the models use in order to 
    derive cost estimates. Furthermore, in the case of BCM, model outputs 
    include costs in addition to the cost of the local loop. In order to 
    correct for these considerations, we have developed a hybrid cost proxy 
    in the following manner. First, we have applied a scaling factor to the 
    cost estimates of each model. This scaling is based on the actual rates 
    computed for unbundled loop elements in the six states referred to 
    above. Specifically we have multiplied the cost estimate produced by 
    each model in each state by a factor equal to the unweighted average of 
    rates adopted by state commissions in the six states, divided by the 
    unweighted average of the model cost estimates for the same six states. 
    Our hybrid cost proxy is computed as the simple average of the scaled 
    cost estimates for the two models in each of the 48 contiguous states 
    and the District of Columbia. Neither BCM nor Hatfield 2.2 provide cost 
    estimates for Alaska and only the BCM provides an estimate for Hawaii. 
    Our default loop cost proxies for Hawaii and Puerto Rico are based on 
    the default loop cost proxies of the states that most closely 
    approximate them in population density per square mile. We are not 
    setting default loop cost proxies in this Order for Alaska or for any 
    of the remaining non-contiguous areas subject to the 1996 Act 
    requirement that incumbent LECs offer unbundled loop elements. We are 
    not establishing default loop cost proxies for these areas because we 
    are unsure that comparisons of the population densities of the 
    continental states and of Alaska and other non-contiguous areas subject 
    to the 1996 Act fully capture differences in loop costs. Regulatory 
    authorities in those areas may seek assistance from this Commission 
    should default loop cost proxies be needed before they have completed 
    their investigations of the forward-looking costs of providing 
    unbundled loop elements. Since our intention is to establish a ceiling 
    for unbundled loop rates, we believe that it is necessary to take 
    account of the variation in the data that we have used for scaling. 
    While the six states that we considered appear to have based their 
    rates on forward-looking economic cost pricing principles, the actual 
    rates that they approved appear to reflect other factors as well. 
    Furthermore, because only a small number of states have conducted such 
    studies, some upward adjustment is warranted as a safety margin to 
    ensure that the ceiling captures the variation in forward-looking 
    economic costing prices on a state-by-state basis. We have therefore 
    chosen to adjust the hybrid cost estimates upward by five percent for 
    each state. A table listing the proxy ceilings on a statewide average 
    basis is contained in Appendix D.
    
    [[Page 45559]]
    
        548. A number of parties have opposed the use of either the 
    Hatfield model or BCM. Some critics, for example, have argued that the 
    models may lead to inaccurate cost estimates since these estimates 
    assume that a network is built ``from scratch.'' Others have criticized 
    specific procedures that have been used in the models to estimate both 
    operating expenses and capital costs. As discussed below in Section 
    VII.C.3., we believe that these criticisms may have merit. In a future 
    rulemaking proceeding, we intend to examine in greater detail various 
    forward looking economic cost models. For the purposes of setting an 
    interim proxy, however, we note that the criticisms have been directed 
    largely toward the absolute level of cost estimates produced by the 
    models, rather than the relative cost estimates across states. Since 
    our hybrid proxy ceiling explicitly scales the model cost estimates 
    based on existing state decisions and uses the model results simply to 
    compute relative prices, we believe that these criticisms do not apply 
    in the present context.
        549. We also note that a third model, the BCM 2, could have been 
    used in the construction of our interim cost proxy by simply taking the 
    scaled cost estimates from three cost models instead of two. We have 
    chosen not to follow this approach since parties have not had an 
    opportunity to comment on the possible deficiencies of the BCM 2. For 
    comparison purposes, however, we have computed the corresponding 
    ceiling cost estimates, and have found that the scaled costs using the 
    three model proxy are very similar to the estimated costs that were 
    derived using the two models.
        550. As discussed above, we believe that cost-based rates should be 
    implemented on a geographically deaveraged basis. We allow states to 
    determine the number of density zones within the state, provided that 
    they designate at least three zones, but require that in all cases the 
    weighted average of unbundled loop prices, with weights equal to the 
    number of loops in each zone, should be less than the proxy ceiling set 
    for the statewide average loop cost set forth in Appendix D.
        551. As noted above, we have not yet had sufficient time to 
    evaluate fully any of the cost models that have been submitted in the 
    record, and our hybrid proxy is therefore intended to be used only on 
    an interim basis. We believe that the methodology is consistent with 
    forward-looking cost studies, but we also recognize that there may be 
    situations in which forward looking loop costs will differ from 
    computed costs, and accordingly, we have increased the state average 
    loop costs by five percent and established the proxy as a ceiling. We 
    emphasize that use of the hybrid proxy model can be superseded at any 
    time by a full forward looking economic cost study that follows the 
    guidelines set forth in this order. In addition, we are currently in 
    the process of evaluating the more detailed cost models that have been 
    submitted in the record, and will issue a further notice on the use of 
    these models in the near future.
    (2) Local Switching
    (a) Discussion
        552. We conclude that a combination of a flat-rated charge for line 
    ports, which are dedicated to a single new entrant, and either a flat-
    rate or per-minute usage charge for the switching matrix and for trunk 
    ports, which constitute shared facilities, best reflects the way costs 
    for unbundled local switching are incurred and is therefore reasonable. 
    We find that there is an insufficient basis in the record to conclude 
    that we should require two flat rates for unbundled local switching 
    charges as proposed by Sprint.
        553. Based on the record in this proceeding and in the LEC-CMRS 
    Interconnection proceeding, we conclude that a range between 0.2 cents 
    ($0.002) per minute of use and 0.4 cents ($0.004) per minute of use for 
    unbundled local switching is a reasonable default proxy. In setting 
    this default price range, we consider the range of evidence in the 
    record, and believe that the most credible studies fall at the lower 
    end of this range. However, so as to minimize disruption for any state 
    that has set a rate only marginally outside this range, we will 
    grandfather any state that has set a rate at 0.5 cents ($0.005) per 
    minute of use or less pending completion of an economic study pursuant 
    to the methodology set forth in this Order.
        554. The forward-looking cost studies contained in the record 
    estimate that the average cost of end-office switching ranges from 0.18 
    cents ($0.0018) per minute of use to 0.35 cents ($0.0035) per minute of 
    use. Maryland and Florida have adopted rates based on forward-looking 
    economic cost studies that fall within the default price range we are 
    adopting. NYNEX's estimate of 0.129 cents ($0.00129) per minute of use, 
    in the Massachusetts proceeding, is an estimate of the marginal cost of 
    end-office switching. As discussed above, we generally expect studies 
    estimating marginal costs to generate estimates that are less than 
    estimates derived from TELRIC-based studies. We, therefore, conclude 
    that 0.2 cents ($0.002) per minute of use is a reasonable lower end of 
    the price range for end-office switching.
        555. USTA's estimate of 1.3 cents ($0.013) appears to be an outlier 
    that is significantly higher than the other estimates. We find that 
    USTA's estimate does not represent an appropriate cost model for 
    termination of traffic. USTA's estimate is based on the high end of a 
    set of econometric estimates of LEC-reported cost data rather than an 
    independent cost estimate, and USTA gives no explanation of why we 
    should regard this as the best estimate. In addition, USTA's figure is 
    derived, at least in part, from studies that attempt to measure the 
    incremental cost of end-to-end use of the network for local calls, not 
    the cost of local switching. Pacific Bell's study of the average LRIC 
    of a call terminating under ``Feature Group B'' apparently includes 
    terminations at tandem switches in addition to end-office terminations.
        556. Michigan and Illinois have adopted rates for transport and 
    termination of traffic that are higher than the default price range we 
    adopt for end-office switching. Michigan, which established mutual 
    compensation rates of 1.5 cents ($0.015) per minute of use, did not 
    review a forward-looking cost study. Illinois's 0.5 cents ($0.005) per 
    minute rate for termination through the end office is just outside the 
    range we are establishing. First, as previously stated, we are 
    grandfathering rates of 0.5 cents ($0.005) per minute or lower. 
    Further, we do not believe Illinois's rate overrides the weight of 
    evidence in the record, which supports the range we are establishing.
        557. States that do not calculate the rate for the unbundled local 
    switching element pursuant to a forward-looking economic cost study 
    may, in the interim, set the rate so that the sum of the flat-rated 
    charge for line ports and the product of the projected minutes of use 
    per port and the usage-sensitive charges for switching and trunk ports, 
    all divided by the projected minutes of use, does not exceed 0.4 cents 
    ($0.004) per minute of use and is not lower than 0.2 cents ($0.002) per 
    minute of use. A state may impose a rate for unbundled local switching 
    that is outside this range if it finds that a forward-looking economic 
    cost study shows a higher or lower rate is justified. States that use 
    our proxy and impose flat-rated charges for unbundled local switching 
    should set rates so that the price falls within the range of 0.2 cents 
    ($0.002) per minute of use and 0.4 cents ($0.004) per minute of use if 
    converted through use of a geographically disaggregated average
    
    [[Page 45560]]
    
    usage factor. A default price range of 0.2 cents ($0.002) per minute of 
    use and 0.4 cents ($0.004) per minute of use should allow carriers the 
    opportunity to recover fully their additional cost of terminating a 
    call including, according to Maryland's study, a reasonable allocation 
    of common costs. We observe that the most credible studies in the 
    record before us fall at the lower end of this range and we encourage 
    states to consider such evidence in their analysis.
        558. With respect to the argument that vertical features should be 
    priced pursuant to the resale price standards, we concluded earlier 
    that vertical features are part of the unbundled local switching 
    element, because they are provided through the operation of hardware 
    and software comprising the ``facility'' that is the switch. 
    Accordingly, the pricing standard in 252(d)(1) applies to vertical 
    features as part of the functionality of the switch. As previously 
    discussed, allowing new entrants to purchase switching and vertical 
    features as part of the local switching network element is an integral 
    part of a separate option Congress has provided for new entrants to 
    compete against incumbent LECs.
        559. The 1996 Act establishes different pricing standards for these 
    two options available to new entrants--resale of services pursuant to 
    section 251(c)(4) and unbundled elements pursuant to section 251(c)(3). 
    Where the new entrant purchases vertical features as part of its 
    purchase of an unbundled local switching element, the price of that 
    element, including associated vertical features, should be determined 
    according to section 252(d)(1). The availability of vertical services 
    as part of a wholesale service offering is distinct from their 
    availability as part of the local switching network element. In these 
    circumstances, allowing the new entrant to combine unbundled elements 
    with wholesale services is an option that is not necessary to permit 
    the new entrant to enter the local market.
        560. As to Bell Atlantic's takings argument, we concluded above 
    that the pricing of unbundled elements according to the just and 
    reasonable standard in section 251 (c)(2) and (c)(3), and applied in 
    section 252(d)(1), is not an unconstitutional taking. That analysis, 
    which looks at the overall rates established by our regulations, 
    applies with equal force to the pricing of unbundled local switching, 
    inclusive of associated vertical features. A forward-looking economic 
    cost methodology enables incumbent LECs to recover a fair return on 
    their investments and Bell Atlantic has provided no specific evidence 
    to the contrary. We conclude that our pricing methodology for unbundled 
    local switching, inclusive of associated vertical features, provides 
    just compensation to incumbent LECs.
    (3) Other Elements
    (a) Discussion
        561. The primary categories of network elements identified in this 
    Order, other than loops and switching, are transport, signaling, and 
    collocation. Our rule that dedicated facilities shall be priced on a 
    flat-rated basis applies to dedicated transmission links because these 
    facilities are dedicated to the use of a specific customer.
        562. For dedicated transmission links, states must use existing 
    rates for interstate dedicated switched transport as a default proxy 
    ceiling. We believe these rates are currently at or close to economic 
    cost levels. Such rates were set based on interstate special access 
    rates, which we found based on the record in the Transport proceeding 
    were relatively close to costs. First Transport Order. 57 FR 54717 
    (November 20, 1992); Transport Rate Structure and Pricing, Third 
    Memorandum Opinion and Order on Reconsideration and Supplemental Notice 
    of Proposed Rulemaking. 60 FR 2068 (January 6, 1995). These interstate 
    access rates originally were based on incumbent LEC accounting costs, 
    rather than a forward-looking economic cost model. Since 1991, however, 
    incumbent LEC interstate access rates have been subject to price cap 
    regulation, and have therefore been disengaged from embedded costs. 
    Interstate access rates for dedicated transport vary by region, type of 
    circuit, mileage, and other factors. For example, BellSouth's entrance 
    facility charge, for transport from an IXC's point of presence to a 
    BellSouth serving wire center, is $134 monthly per DS1 circuit ($5.58 
    per derived voice grade circuit) and $2,100 monthly per DS3 circuit 
    ($3.13 per derived voice grade circuit). Dedicated transport for 10 
    miles of interoffice transmission between a serving wire center and an 
    end office is $325 monthly per DS1 circuit ($13.54 per derived voice 
    grade circuit) and $2,950 monthly per DS3 circuit ($4.39 per derived 
    voice grade circuit). Installation, multiplexing, and other transport-
    related charges may also apply.
        563. Typically, transmission facilities between tandem switches and 
    end offices are shared facilities. Pursuant to our rate structure 
    guidelines, states may establish usage-sensitive or flat-rate charges 
    to recover those costs. For shared transmission facilities between 
    tandem switches and end offices, states may use as a default proxy 
    ceiling the rate derived from the incumbent LEC's interstate direct 
    trunked transport rates in the same manner that we derive presumptive 
    price caps for tandem switched transport under our interstate price cap 
    rules, using the same weighting and loading factors. Specifically, when 
    the transport rate restructure was implemented, the initial levels of 
    tandem-switched transmission rates were presumed reasonable if they 
    were based on a weighted per-minute equivalent of direct-trunked 
    transport DS1 and DS3 rates that reflects the relative number of DS1 
    and DS3 circuits used in the tandem to end office links, calculated 
    using a loading factor of 9000 minutes per month per voice-grade 
    circuit. 47 CFR Sec. 69.111. We conclude above that interstate direct-
    trunked transport rates provide a reasonable default proxy ceiling for 
    unbundled dedicated transport rates. First Transport Order. Interstate 
    access rates for tandem-switched transport vary by region and mileage. 
    The average charge by RBOCs in Density Zone 1 for transport termination 
    and one mile of switched common transport facility between a tandem 
    switching office and end office equals 0.033 cents ($0.000331) per 
    minute. For a five-mile facility, the average charge is 0.048 cents 
    ($0.000479) per minute; for a ten-mile facility, 0.066 cents 
    ($0.000664) per minute. When we restructured the incumbent LECs' 
    interstate transport rates to be more closely aligned with cost, we 
    derived presumptive tandem-switched transmission rate levels from 
    direct-trunked transport rates. This proxy ceiling for shared 
    transmission facilities between tandem switches and end offices, 
    therefore, should be similarly derived.
        564. The United States Court of Appeals for the District of 
    Columbia Circuit recently remanded our interim transport rules. The 
    court concluded that the Commission had not provided sufficient 
    justification for its method of establishing the rate level of the 
    interstate switched access rate element for tandem switching. We do not 
    believe, however, that the CompTel v. FCC decision is inconsistent with 
    the rules we establish here because the decision did not address or 
    criticize the Commission's determination of the rates for dedicated 
    transport or tandem-switched transport links. Because our proxies do 
    not involve the interstate access rate for tandem switching, they are 
    not inconsistent with the court's analysis.
        565. Tandem switching also employs shared facilities. States may, 
    therefore,
    
    [[Page 45561]]
    
    establish usage-sensitive charges to recover tandem-switching costs. 
    For those states that cannot complete a forward-looking economic cost 
    study within the arbitration period or cannot devote the necessary 
    resources to such a review, we establish a default rate ceiling of 0.15 
    cents ($0.0015) per minute of use. The additional cost of termination 
    at a tandem in comparison to termination at an end office consists of 
    the cost of tandem switching and the cost of tandem-switched transport 
    transmission. Illinois and Maryland have adopted rates for the 
    transport and termination of traffic from the tandem switch that are, 
    respectively, 0.25 cents ($0.0025) per minute of use and 0.2 cents 
    ($0.002) per minute of use, higher than rates for termination at end 
    office switches. In both instances, our default rate ceiling for tandem 
    switching constitutes at least 60 percent of the implicit tandem 
    switching and transport to the end office switch. We, therefore, find 
    the default rate ceiling we adopt for tandem switching to be consistent 
    with both Illinois's and Maryland's adopted rates for transport and 
    switching of traffic from the tandem office. States that use our proxy 
    and impose flat-rated charges for tandem switching should set rates so 
    that the price does not exceed 0.15 cents ($0.0015) per minute of use 
    if converted through use of a geographically disaggregated usage 
    factor.
        566. Rates for signaling and database services should be usage-
    sensitive, based either on the number of queries or the number of 
    messages, with the exception of the dedicated circuits known as 
    signaling links, which should be charged on a flat-rated basis. Usage 
    charges of this type appear to reflect most accurately the underlying 
    costs of these services. Interstate access rates for most of these 
    elements have been justified using the price caps new services test, 
    which roughly approximates the results of a forward-looking economic 
    cost study. Amendments of Part 69 of the Commission's Rules Relating to 
    the Creation of Access Charge Supplements for Open Network 
    Architecture, CC Docket Nos. 89-79 and 87-313, Report and Order, Order 
    on Reconsideration, and Supplemental Notice of Proposed Rulemaking. 56 
    FR 33879 (July 24, 1991), modified on recon. 57 FR 37720 (August 20, 
    1992). In addition, the costs of these services were forward-looking, 
    in that the services were completely new and hence, by definition, used 
    the best-available technology. Thus, we establish as a default proxy 
    ceiling for these elements corresponding interstate access charges for 
    these elements. Interstate database services consist of Line 
    Information Database (LIDB) and 800 Database. Deployment of SS7 (out-
    of-band signaling) has enabled LECs to offer these services. The 
    average charge for RBOCs for LIDB in Density Zone 1 equals 3.34 cents 
    ($0.034) per database query. For elements that have not been subject to 
    the new services test, states may establish proxy ceilings by 
    identifying the direct costs of providing the element and adding a 
    reasonable allocation of joint and common costs. Because we expect that 
    the joint and common costs associated with the forward-looking cost of 
    network elements are substantially less than those associated with 
    traditional service-based costs, allowing a reasonable allocation is 
    sufficient to protect against possible anticompetitive pricing. Absent 
    any proxy, this approach will provide the most reasonable approximation 
    of forward-looking economic cost.
        567. We have established rate structure rules for collocation 
    elements in connection with our Expanded Interconnection proceeding. 
    Expanded Interconnection with Local Telephone Company Facilities. 59 FR 
    38922 (August 1, 1994). Many collocation elements established under 
    section 251(c)(6) are likely to represent the same facilities, and 
    should have the same cost characteristics, as existing interstate 
    expanded interconnection services, and therefore we require states to 
    use the same rate structure rules for those collocation elements that 
    we established in the Expanded Interconnection proceeding. As a proxy 
    ceiling, states may use the rates the LEC has in effect in its federal 
    expanded interconnection tariff for the equivalent services. Expanded 
    interconnection services are subject to the new services test, which, 
    as discussed above, uses a forward-looking methodology. Although LECs 
    have filed expanded interconnection tariffs, we have not yet completed 
    our investigation into those tariffs. Any price for unbundled 
    collocation elements set based on LEC expanded interconnection tariffs 
    would therefore be subject to any modification of those tariffs that 
    results from our pending investigation, and any state-imposed prices 
    based on those tariffs will need to be adjusted accordingly.
        568. We find it unnecessary to specify rate structures for other 
    unbundled elements. The states shall make those determinations by 
    applying our general rate structure principles described above. In the 
    absence of an acceptable forward-looking cost study, states may 
    establish default proxy ceilings for other unbundled elements by 
    identifying the direct costs of providing the element and adding a 
    reasonable allocation of joint and common costs.
    3. Forward-Looking Cost Model Proxies
    a. Background
        569. In the NPRM, we sought comment on the use of certain generic 
    cost studies. Commenters discussed several such models. These models 
    include: (1) the Hatfield 2; (2) the Hatfield 2.2; (3) the BCM; (4) the 
    BCM 2; and (5) the CPM.
    b. Discussion
        570. We believe that the generic forward-looking costing models, in 
    principle, appear best to comport with the preferred economic cost 
    approach discussed previously. Several such models were placed in the 
    record, including Hatfield 2, Hatfield 2.2, BCM, BCM 2, and the CPM. 
    The BCM is designed to produce ``benchmark'' costs for the provision of 
    basic telephone service within specific geographic regions defined by 
    the Bureau of the Census as Census Block Groups. The Hatfield 2 model 
    combines output from the BCM with independently-developed investment 
    data to produce annual cost estimates for eleven basic network 
    functions. The CPM is similar in structure to the BCM and Hatfield 2 
    models, although it uses different algorithms.
        571. These models appear to offer a method of estimating the cost 
    of network elements on a forward-looking basis that is practical to 
    implement and that allows state commissions the ability to examine the 
    assumptions and parameters that go into the cost estimates. Although 
    these models were submitted too late in this proceeding for the 
    Commission and parties to evaluate them fully, our initial examination 
    leads us to believe that the remaining practical and empirical issues 
    can be resolved in the near future. In light of the advantages of such 
    a generic approach, we will further examine these generic economic cost 
    models by the first quarter of 1997 to determine whether we should use 
    one of them to replace the default proxies we adopt in this proceeding. 
    In that event, states would have the option of setting rates in 
    arbitrations on the basis of an economic cost study or by using a 
    generic forward-looking cost model approved at that time.
        572. Finally, we note that Commission staff developed a model of 
    the telecommunications industry that they designed to simulate industry 
    demand and supply characteristics. In
    
    [[Page 45562]]
    
    order to encourage an open-ended discussion of the utility of the staff 
    model, the Common Carrier Bureau sought comment on a working draft of 
    the model that was released. Almost all parties commenting on the staff 
    model urged the Commission not to rely upon the staff model as record 
    evidence in this proceeding. We are not relying on the staff model to 
    develop the requirements imposed by this Order.
    
    D. Other Issues
    
    1. Future Adjustments to Interconnection and Unbundled Element Rate 
    Levels
    a. Background
        573. In the NPRM, we sought comment on whether some cost index or 
    price cap system would be appropriate to ensure that rates reflect 
    expected changes in costs over time.
    b. Discussion
        574. As noted earlier, we will continue to review our pricing 
    methodology, and will make revisions as appropriate. Accordingly, there 
    is no present need to establish a Commission price cap or cost index 
    system to adjust interconnection and unbundled element rate levels.
    2. Imputation
    a. Background
        575. We sought comment in the NPRM on whether we should require an 
    ``imputation rule'' in establishing rates for unbundled network 
    elements. An imputation rule would require that the sum of prices 
    charged for a basket of unbundled network elements not exceed the 
    retail price for a service offered using the same basket of elements. 
    We further solicited comment on any other rules that could be adopted 
    regarding pricing of unbundled network elements that would help to 
    promote the pro-competitive goals of the 1996 Act.
    b. Discussion
        576. Although we recognize, as several commenters observe, that an 
    imputation rule could help detect and prevent price squeezes, we 
    decline to impose an imputation requirement. Adoption of an imputation 
    rule could force states to engage in a major rate rebalancing effort at 
    this time, because it would impose substantial additional burdens on 
    states at a time when they will need to devote significant resources to 
    implementing the 1996 Act.
        577. In addition to our practical concerns regarding implementation 
    of an imputation rule, we find that an imputation rule may not be 
    necessary to achieve the pro-competitive goals of the 1996 Act. As some 
    commenters, including several state commissions, suggest, competing 
    providers may be able to provide basic service, at less than the cost 
    of facilities and associated management, just as incumbent LECs do 
    currently, by selling customers higher profit vertical or intrastate 
    toll services, or through receipt of access revenues and subsidies. 
    Further, the Ohio Consumers' Counsel suggest that below-cost rates may 
    not be sufficiently prevalent to justify a national imputation rule. 
    The Joint Consumer Advocates and the Ohio Consumers' Counsel question 
    whether local service is, in fact, underpriced.
        578. We give special weight to the comments of several state 
    commissions that currently employ imputation rules. These state 
    commissions endorse imputation as a tool to prevent price squeezes, but 
    urge us only to provide states with the flexibility to adopt imputation 
    rules. We agree with those state commission commenters that argue that 
    nothing in the 1996 Act prohibits individual states from adopting 
    imputation rules. While an imputation rule may be pro-competitive, we 
    will leave the implementation of such rules to individual states for 
    the time being.
    3. Discrimination
    a. Background
        579. In the NPRM, we noted the different usages of the term 
    ``discrimination'' in the 1996 Act and the 1934 Act. Sections 251 and 
    252 require that interconnection and unbundled element rates be 
    ``nondiscriminatory.'' Similarly, section 251(c)(4) requires that, in 
    making resale available, carriers not impose ``discriminatory 
    conditions or limitations on resale.'' Finally, section 252(e) provides 
    that states may reject a negotiated agreement or a portion of the 
    agreement if it ``discriminates'' against a carrier not a party to the 
    agreement and section 252(i) requires incumbent LECs to ``make 
    available any interconnection, service, or network element provided 
    under an agreement * * * to which it is a party to any requesting 
    telecommunications carrier upon the same terms and conditions.'' In 
    contrast, section 202(a) of the 1934 Act provides that ``(i)t shall be 
    unlawful for any common carrier to make any unjust or unreasonable 
    discrimination in charges * * * for * * * like communication service.''
        580. We sought comment on ``the meaning of the term 
    `nondiscriminatory' in the 1996 Act compared with the phrase 
    `unreasonable discrimination' in the 1934 Act.'' We asked specifically 
    whether Congress intended to prohibit all price discrimination, 
    including measures such as density zone pricing or volume and term 
    discounts, by choosing the word ``nondiscriminatory.'' We further asked 
    whether sections 251 and 252 could be interpreted to prohibit only 
    unjust or unreasonable discrimination. Finally, we sought comment on 
    whether the 1996 Act prohibited carriers from charging different rates 
    to parties that are not similarly situated.
    b. Discussion
        581. We conclude that the term ``nondiscriminatory'' in the 1996 
    Act is not synonymous with ``unjust and unreasonable discrimination'' 
    in section 202(a), but rather is a more stringent standard. Finding 
    otherwise would fail to give meaning to Congress's decision to use 
    different language. We agree, however, with those parties that argue 
    that cost-based differences in rates are permissible under sections 251 
    and 252.
        582. Section 252(d)(1), for example, requires carriers to base 
    interconnection and network element charges on costs. Where costs 
    differ, rate differences that accurately reflect those differences are 
    not discriminatory. This is consistent with the economic definition of 
    price discrimination, which is ``the practice of selling the same 
    product at two or more prices where the price differences do not 
    reflect cost differences * * * An important feature of the economic 
    definition of price discrimination is that it occurs not only when 
    prices are different in the presence of similar costs but also when the 
    prices are the same and the costs of supplying customers are 
    different.'' As one economist has recognized, differential pricing is 
    ``one of the most prevalent forms of marketing practices'' of 
    competitive enterprises. Strict application of the term 
    ``nondiscriminatory'' as urged by those commenters who argue that 
    prices must be uniform would itself be discriminatory according to the 
    economic definition of price discrimination. If the 1996 Act is read to 
    allow no price distinctions between companies that impose very 
    different interconnection costs on LECs, competition for all 
    competitors, including small companies, could be impaired. Thus, we 
    find that price differences, such as volume and term discounts, when 
    based upon legitimate variations in costs are permissible under the 
    1996 Act, if justified.
        583. On the other hand, price differences based not on cost 
    differences but on such considerations as competitive relationships, 
    the
    
    [[Page 45563]]
    
    technology used by the requesting carrier, the nature of the service 
    the requesting carrier provides, or other factors not reflecting costs, 
    the requirements of the Act, or applicable rules, would be 
    discriminatory and not permissible under the new standard. Such 
    examples include the imposition of different rates, terms and 
    conditions based on the fact that the competing provider does or does 
    not compete with the incumbent LEC, or offers service via wireless 
    rather than wireline facilities. We find that it would be unlawfully 
    discriminatory, in violation of sections 251 and 252, if an incumbent 
    LEC were to charge one class of interconnecting carriers, such as CMRS 
    providers, higher rates for interconnection than it charges other 
    carriers, unless the different rates could be justified by differences 
    in the costs incurred by the incumbent LEC.
        584. State regulations permitting non-cost based discriminatory 
    treatment are prohibited by the 1996 Act. This conclusion is consistent 
    with both the letter and the spirit of the 1996 Act and our 
    determination that the pricing for interconnection, unbundled elements, 
    and transport and termination of traffic should not vary based on the 
    identity or classification of the interconnector.
    
    VIII. Resale
    
        585. Section 251(c)(4) imposes a duty on incumbent LECs to offer 
    certain services for resale at wholesale rates. Specifically, section 
    251(c)(4) requires an incumbent LEC:
        (A) to offer for resale at wholesale rates any telecommunications 
    service that the carrier provides at retail to subscribers who are not 
    telecommunications carriers; and
        (B) not to prohibit, and not to impose unreasonable or 
    discriminatory conditions or limitations on, the resale of such 
    telecommunications service, except that a State commission may, 
    consistent with regulations prescribed by the Commission under this 
    section, prohibit a reseller that obtains at wholesale rates a 
    telecommunications service that is available at retail only to a 
    category of subscribers from offering such service to a different 
    category of subscribers.
        586. The requirement that incumbent LECs offer services at 
    wholesale rates is described in section 252(d)(3), which sets forth the 
    pricing standard that states must use in arbitrating agreements and 
    reviewing rates under BOC statements of generally available terms and 
    conditions:
        [A] State commission shall determine wholesale rates on the basis 
    of retail rates charged to subscribers for the telecommunications 
    service requested, excluding the portion thereof attributable to any 
    marketing, billing, collection, and other costs that will be avoided by 
    the local exchange carrier.
        Section VIII.A. of this Order discusses the scope of section 
    251(c)(4). Section VIII.B. addresses the determination of ``wholesale 
    rates.'' Section VIII.C. considers the issue of conditions or 
    limitations on resale under this section, Section VIII.D. discusses the 
    resale obligations under section 251(b)(1), and Section VIII.E. 
    considers the application of access charges in the resale environment.
    
    A. Scope of Section 251(c)(4)
    
    1. Background
        587. In the NPRM, we sought comment generally on the scope of 
    section 251(c)(4).
    2. Discussion
        588. Section 251(c)(4)(A) imposes on all incumbent LECs the duty to 
    offer for resale ``any telecommunications service that the carrier 
    provides at retail to subscribers who are not telecommunications 
    carriers.'' We conclude that an incumbent LEC must establish a 
    wholesale rate for each retail service that: (1) meets the statutory 
    definition of a ``telecommunications service;'' and (2) is provided at 
    retail to subscribers who are not ``telecommunications carriers.'' We 
    thus find no statutory basis for limiting the resale duty to basic 
    telephone services, as some suggest.
        589. We need not prescribe a minimum list of services that are 
    subject to the resale requirement. State commissions, incumbent LECs, 
    and resellers can determine the services that an incumbent LEC must 
    provide at wholesale rates by examining that LEC's retail tariffs. The 
    1996 Act does not require an incumbent LEC to make a wholesale offering 
    of any service that the incumbent LEC does not offer to retail 
    customers. State commissions, however, may have the power to require 
    incumbent LECs to offer specific intrastate services.
        590. Exchange access services are not subject to the resale 
    requirements of section 251(c)(4). The vast majority of purchasers of 
    interstate access services are telecommunications carriers, not end 
    users. It is true that incumbent LEC interstate access tariffs do not 
    contain any limitation that prevents end users from buying these 
    services, and that end users do occasionally purchase some access 
    services, including special access, Feature Group A, and certain 
    Feature Group D elements for large private networks. Despite this fact, 
    we conclude that the language and intent of section 251 clearly 
    demonstrates that exchange access services should not be considered 
    services an incumbent LEC ``provides at retail to subscribers who are 
    not telecommunications carriers'' under section 251(c)(4). We note that 
    virtually all commenters in this proceeding agree, or assume without 
    stating, that exchange access services are not subject to the resale 
    requirements of section 251(c)(4).
        591. We find several compelling reasons to conclude that exchange 
    access services should not be subject to resale requirements. First, 
    these services are predominantly offered to, and taken by, IXCs, not 
    end users. Part 69 of our rules defines these charges as ``carrier's 
    carrier charges,'' and the specific part 69 rules that describe each 
    interstate switched access element refer to charges assessed on 
    ``interexchange carriers'' rather than end users. The mere fact that 
    fundamentally non-retail services are offered pursuant to tariffs that 
    do not restrict their availability, and that a small number of end 
    users do purchase some of these services, does not alter the essential 
    nature of the services. Moreover, because access services are designed 
    for, and sold to, IXCs as an input component to the IXC's own retail 
    services, LECs would not avoid any ``retail'' costs when offering these 
    services at ``wholesale'' to those same IXCs. Congress clearly intended 
    section 251(c)(4) to apply to services targeted to end user 
    subscribers, because only those services would involve an appreciable 
    level of avoided costs that could be used to generate a wholesale rate. 
    Furthermore, as explained in the following paragraph, section 251(c)(4) 
    does not entitle subscribers to obtain services at wholesale rates for 
    their own use. Permitting IXCs to purchase access services at wholesale 
    rates for their own use would be inconsistent with this requirement.
        592. We conclude that section 251(c)(4) does not require incumbent 
    LECs to make services available for resale at wholesale rates to 
    parties who are not ``telecommunications carriers'' or who are 
    purchasing service for their own use. The wholesale pricing requirement 
    is intended to facilitate competition on a resale basis. Further, the 
    negotiation process established by Congress for the implementation of 
    section 251 requires incumbent LECs to negotiate agreements, including 
    resale agreements, with ``requesting telecommunications carrier or 
    carriers,'' not with end users or other entities. We further discuss 
    the definition of
    
    [[Page 45564]]
    
    ``telecommunications carrier'' in Section IX. of the Order.
        593. With regard to independent public payphone providers, however, 
    we agree with the American Public Communication Council's argument that 
    such carriers are not ``telecommunications carriers'' under section 
    3(44). We therefore also agree with the American Public Communications 
    Council's contention that the services independent public payphone 
    providers obtain from incumbent LECs are telecommunications services 
    that incumbent LECs provide ``at retail to subscribers who are not 
    telecommunications carriers'' and that such services should be 
    available at wholesale rates to telecommunications carriers. Because we 
    conclude that independent public payphone providers are not 
    ``telecommunications carriers,'' however, we conclude that incumbent 
    LECs need not make available service to independent public payphone 
    providers at wholesale rates. This is consistent with our finding that 
    wholesale offerings must be purchased for the purpose of resale by 
    ``telecommunications carriers.''
        594. We conclude that the plain language of the 1996 Act requires 
    that the incumbent LEC make available at wholesale rates retail 
    services that are actually composed of other retail services, i.e., 
    bundled service offerings. Section 251(c)(4) states that the incumbent 
    LEC must offer for resale ``any telecommunications service'' provided 
    at retail to subscribers who are not telecommunications carriers. The 
    resale provision of the 1996 Act does not contain any language 
    exempting services if those services can be duplicated or approximated 
    by combining other services. On the other hand, section 251(c)(4) does 
    not impose on incumbent LECs the obligation to disaggregate a retail 
    service into more discrete retail services. The 1996 Act merely 
    requires that any retail services offered to customers be made 
    available for resale.
    
    B. Wholesale Pricing
    
    1. Background
        595. As discussed above, section 251(c)(4) requires incumbent LECs 
    to offer at ``wholesale rates'' any telecommunications services that 
    the carrier provides at retail to subscribers who are not 
    telecommunications carriers. Section 252(d)(3) establishes the standard 
    that states must use in determining wholesale rates in arbitrations or 
    in reviewing wholesale rates under BOC statements of generally 
    available terms and conditions. Specifically, section 252(d)(3) 
    provides that wholesale rates shall be set ``on the basis of retail 
    rates charged to subscribers for the telecommunications service 
    requested, excluding the portion thereof attributable to any marketing, 
    billing, collection, and other costs that will be avoided by the local 
    exchange carrier.''
        596. In the NPRM, we generally sought comment on the meaning of the 
    term ``wholesale rates'' in section 251(c)(4). We asked if we could and 
    should establish principles for the states to apply in order to 
    determine wholesale prices in an expeditious and consistent manner. We 
    also sought comment on whether we should issue rules for states to 
    apply in determining avoided costs. We stated that we could, for 
    example, determine that states are permitted under the 1996 Act to 
    direct incumbent LECs to quantify their costs for any marketing, 
    billing, collection, and similar activities that are associated with 
    offering retail, but not wholesale, services. We also sought comment on 
    whether avoided costs should include a share of common costs and 
    general overhead or ``markup'' assigned to such costs. LECs would then 
    reduce retail rates by this amount, offset by any portion of expenses 
    that they incur in the provision of wholesale rates. We noted that this 
    approach appeared to be consistent with the 1996 Act, but would create 
    certain administrative difficulties because all of the information 
    regarding costs is under the control of the incumbent LECs. We also 
    asked for comment on several alternative approaches. For example, we 
    asked whether we could establish a uniform set of presumptions 
    regarding avoided costs that states could adopt and that would apply in 
    the absence of a quantification of such costs by incumbent LECs. 
    Additionally, we asked whether we should identify specific accounts or 
    portions of accounts in the Commission's Uniform System of Accounts 
    (``USOA'') that the states should include as avoided costs. We also 
    requested comment on whether we should establish rules that allocate 
    avoided costs across services. We asked whether incumbent LECs should 
    be allowed, or required, to vary the percentage wholesale discounts 
    across different services based on the degree the avoided costs relate 
    to those services. Finally, we asked whether we should adopt a uniform 
    percentage discount off of the retail rate of each service.
    2. Discussion
        597. Resale will be an important entry strategy for many new 
    entrants, especially in the short term when they are building their own 
    facilities. Further, in some areas and for some new entrants, we expect 
    that the resale option will remain an important entry strategy over the 
    longer term. Resale will also be an important entry strategy for small 
    businesses that may lack capital to compete in the local exchange 
    market by purchasing unbundled elements or by building their own 
    networks. In light of the strategic importance of resale to the 
    development of competition, we conclude that it is especially important 
    to promulgate national rules for use by state commissions in setting 
    wholesale rates. For the same reasons discussed in Section II.D of the 
    Order, we believe that we have legal authority under the 1996 Act to 
    articulate principles that will apply to the arbitration or review of 
    wholesale rates. We also believe that articulating such principles will 
    promote expeditious and efficient entry into the local exchange market. 
    Clear resale rules will create incentives for parties to reach 
    agreement on resale arrangements in voluntary negotiations. Clear rules 
    will also aid states in conducting arbitrations that will be 
    administratively workable and will produce results that satisfy the 
    intent of the 1996 Act. The rules we adopt and the determinations we 
    make in this area are crafted to achieve these purposes. We also note 
    that clear resale rules should minimize regulatory burdens and 
    uncertainty for all parties, including small entities and small 
    incumbent LECs.
        598. The statutory pricing standard for wholesale rates requires 
    state commissions to (1) identify what marketing, billing, collection, 
    and other costs will be avoided by incumbent LECs when they provide 
    services at wholesale; and (2) calculate the portion of the retail 
    prices for those services that is attributable to the avoided costs. 
    Our rules provide two methods for making these determinations. The 
    first, and preferred, method requires state commissions to identify and 
    calculate avoided costs based on avoided cost studies. The second 
    method allows states to select, on an interim basis, a discount rate 
    from within a default range of discount rates adopted by this 
    Commission. They may then calculate the portion of a retail price that 
    is attributable to avoided costs by multiplying the retail price by the 
    discount rate.
    
    [[Page 45565]]
    
        599. We adopt a minimum set of criteria for avoided cost studies 
    used to determine wholesale discount rates. The record before us 
    demonstrates that avoided cost studies can produce widely varying 
    results, depending in large part upon how the proponent of the study 
    interprets the language of section 252(d)(3). The criteria we adopt are 
    designed to ensure that states apply consistent interpretations of the 
    1996 Act in setting wholesale rates based on avoided cost studies which 
    should facilitate swift entry by national and regional resellers, which 
    may include small entities. At the same time, our criteria are intended 
    to leave the state commissions broad latitude in selecting costing 
    methodologies that comport with their own ratemaking practices for 
    retail services. Thus, for example, our rules for identifying avoided 
    costs by USOA expense account are cast as rebuttable presumptions, and 
    we do not adopt as presumptively correct any avoided cost model.
        600. Based on the comments filed in this proceeding and on our 
    analysis of state decisions setting wholesale discounts, we adopt a 
    default range of rates that will permit a state commission to select a 
    reasonable default wholesale rate between 17 and 25 percent below 
    retail rate levels. A default wholesale discount rate shall be used if: 
    (1) an avoided cost study that satisfies the criteria we set forth 
    below does not exist; (2) a state commission has not completed its 
    review of such an avoided cost study; or (3) a rate established by a 
    state commission before release of this Order is based on a study that 
    does not comply with the criteria described in the following section. A 
    state commission must establish wholesale rates based on avoided cost 
    studies within a reasonable time from when the default rate was 
    selected. This approach will enable state commissions to complete 
    arbitration proceedings within the statutory time frames even if it is 
    infeasible to conduct full-scale avoided cost studies that comply with 
    the criteria described below for each incumbent LEC.
    a. Criteria for Cost Studies
        601. There has been considerable debate on the record in this 
    proceeding and before the state commissions on whether section 
    252(d)(3) embodies an ``avoided'' cost standard or an ``avoidable'' 
    cost standard. We find that ``the portion [of the retail rate] * * * 
    attributable to costs that will be avoided'' includes all of the costs 
    that the LEC incurs in maintaining a retail, as opposed to a wholesale, 
    business. In other words, the avoided costs are those that an incumbent 
    LEC would no longer incur if it were to cease retail operations and 
    instead provide all of its services through resellers. Thus, we reject 
    the arguments of incumbent LECs and others who maintain that the LEC 
    must actually experience a reduction in its operating expenses for a 
    cost to be considered ``avoided'' for purposes of section 252(d)(3). We 
    do not believe that Congress intended to allow incumbent LECs to 
    sustain artificially high wholesale prices by declining to reduce their 
    expenditures to the degree that certain costs are readily avoidable. We 
    therefore interpret the 1996 Act as requiring states to make an 
    objective assessment of what costs are reasonably avoidable when a LEC 
    sells its services wholesale. We note that Colorado, Georgia, Illinois, 
    New York, and Ohio commissions have all interpreted the 1996 Act in 
    this manner.
        602. We find that, under this ``reasonably avoidable'' standard 
    discussed above, an avoided cost study must include indirect, or 
    shared, costs as well as direct costs. We agree with MCI, AT&T, and the 
    California, Illinois, Ohio, Colorado, and Georgia commissions that some 
    indirect or shared costs are avoidable and likely to be avoided when a 
    LEC provides retail services to a reseller instead of to the end user. 
    This is because indirect or shared costs, such as general overheads, 
    support all of the LEC's functions, including marketing, sales, billing 
    and collection, and other avoided retail functions. Therefore, a 
    portion of indirect costs must be considered ``attributable to costs 
    that will be avoided'' pursuant to section 252(d)(3). It is true that 
    expenses recorded in indirect or shared expense accounts will continue 
    to be incurred for wholesale operations. It is also true, however, that 
    the overall level of indirect expenses can reasonably be expected to 
    decrease as a result of a lower level of overall operations resulting 
    from a reduction in retail activity.
        603. A portion of contribution, profits, or mark-up may also be 
    considered ``attributable to costs that will be avoided'' when services 
    are sold wholesale. MCI's model makes this attribution by means of a 
    calculation that applies the same mark-up to wholesale services as to 
    retail services. The Illinois Commission achieved a similar effect by 
    removing a pro rata portion of contribution from the retail rate for 
    each service. In AT&T's model, the portion of return on investment 
    (profits) that was attributable to assets used in avoided retail 
    activities was treated as an avoided cost. We find that these 
    approaches are consistent with the 1996 Act.
        604. An avoided cost study may not calculate avoided costs based on 
    non-cost factors or policy arguments, nor may it make disallowances for 
    reasons not provided for in section 252(d)(3). The language of section 
    252(d)(3) makes no provision for selecting a wholesale discount rate on 
    policy grounds. We therefore reject NCTA's argument that discount rates 
    should be ten percent or less in order to avoid discouraging 
    facilities-based competition, as well as AT&T's suggestion that 
    wholesale discount rates should be set at levels that ensure the 
    viability of the reseller's business. We also reject, for example, 
    MCI's assertion that no external relations or research and development 
    costs should be allowed in wholesale rates because the activities 
    represented by those costs are contrary to the interests of the LEC 
    competitors that purchase wholesale services. Our analysis also 
    precludes a state commission from adopting AT&T's suggestion that an 
    increment should be added to the base discount rate to compensate 
    resellers for alleged deficiencies in the provisioning of services.
        605. The 1996 Act requires that wholesale rates be based on 
    existing retail rates, and thus clearly precludes use of a ``bottom 
    up'' TSLRIC study to establish wholesale rates that are not related to 
    the rates for the underlying retail services. We thus reject the 
    suggestions of those parties that ask us to require use of TSLRIC to 
    set wholesale rates. The 1996 Act does not, however, preclude use of 
    TSLRIC cost studies to identify the portion of a retail rate that is 
    attributable to avoided retail costs. TSLRIC studies would be entirely 
    appropriate in states where the retail rates were established using a 
    TSLRIC method. For example, the Illinois Commission calculated its 
    wholesale rate using an avoided cost formula and long run incremental 
    cost studies. Embedded cost studies, such as the studies used by the 
    Georgia Commission, may also be used to identify avoided costs. 
    Ideally, a state would use a study methodology that is consistent with 
    the manner in which it sets retail rates.
        606. We neither prohibit nor require use of a single, uniform 
    discount rate for all of an incumbent LEC's services. We recognize that 
    a uniform rate is simple to apply, and avoids the need to allocate 
    avoided costs among services. Therefore, our default wholesale discount 
    is to be applied uniformly. On the other hand, we also agree with 
    parties who observe that avoided costs
    
    [[Page 45566]]
    
    may, in fact, vary among services. Accordingly, we allow a state to 
    approve nonuniform wholesale discount rates, as long as those rates are 
    set on the basis of an avoided cost study that includes a demonstration 
    of the percentage of avoided costs that is attributable to each service 
    or group of services.
        607. All costs recorded in accounts 6611 (product management), 6612 
    (sales), 6613 (product advertising) and 6623 (customer services) are 
    presumed to be avoidable. The costs in these accounts are the direct 
    costs of serving customers. All costs recorded in accounts 6621 (call 
    completion services) and 6622 (number services) are also presumed 
    avoidable, because resellers have stated they will either provide these 
    services themselves or contract for them separately from the LEC or 
    from third parties. These presumptions regarding accounts 6611-6613 and 
    6621-6623 may be rebutted if an incumbent LEC proves to the state 
    commission that specific costs in these accounts will be incurred with 
    respect to services sold at wholesale, or that costs in these accounts 
    are not included in the retail prices of the resold services.
        608. General support expenses (accounts 6121-6124), corporate 
    operations expenses (accounts 6711, 6712, 6721-6728), and 
    telecommunications uncollectibles (account 5301) are presumed to be 
    avoided in proportion to the avoided direct expenses identified in the 
    previous paragraph. Expenses recorded in these accounts are tied to the 
    overall level of operations in which an incumbent LEC engages. Because 
    the advent of wholesale operations will reduce the overall level of 
    operations--for example, staffing should decrease because customer 
    inquiries and billing and collection activity will decrease--overhead 
    and support expenses are in part avoided. We select the revenue offset 
    account of 5301 rather than accounts 5300 or 6790 because account 5301 
    most directly represents overheads attributable to the services being 
    resold.
        609. Plant-specific and plant non-specific expenses (other than 
    general support expenses) are presumptively not avoidable.
        610. In the case of carriers designated as Class B under section 
    32.11 of our rules that use certain summary accounts in lieu of 
    accounts designated in this subsection of the Order, our avoided cost 
    study criteria shall apply to the relevant summary account in its 
    entirety.
    b. Default Range of Wholesale Discount Rates
        611. Parties to this proceeding present evidence or arguments 
    supporting wholesale discount rates ranging from 4.76 percent to 55 
    percent:
    
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                                          Percent           
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    Sprint/United Telephone study:                                          
      Simple Access service..................  4.76                         
      Other services.........................  7.19                         
    NCTA.....................................  10.0                         
    Comcast..................................  10.0                         
    Massachusetts Attorney General...........  25.0                         
    ACTA.....................................  25.0                         
    MCI Model................................  25.6-33.2                    
    Telecommunications Resellers Ass'n.......  30.0-50.0                    
    AT&T Model...............................  23.05-55.52                  
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        612. States applying wholesale pricing standards similar to the 
    standards in section 252(d)(3) have set the following wholesale 
    discounts:
    
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                                                    Percent 
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    California:                                                             
      PacTel:                                                               
        Business................................................       17.0 
        Residential.............................................       10.0 
      GTE:                                                                  
        Business................................................       12.0 
        Residential.............................................        7.0 
    Colorado:                                                               
      Residential...............................................        9.0 
      Business..................................................       16.0 
      Toll Services.............................................       30.0 
      Central Office-Based Features.............................       50.0 
      All other services........................................       18.0 
    Georgia:                                                                
      Residential...............................................       20.3 
      Business..................................................       17.3 
    Illinois....................................................       20.07
    New York:                                                               
      NYNEX:                                                                
        Business................................................       17.0 
        Residential.............................................       11.0 
      Rochester Telephone.......................................       13.5 
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        613. We find unpersuasive various arguments presented by parties at 
    the lower and higher ends of the range of possible discounts. The 
    Sprint/United Telephone study produces unreasonably low measures of 
    avoided costs because the study considers only avoided direct expenses 
    in five accounts. As explained above, we interpret the statutory 
    language providing for a wholesale price that excludes the ``portion 
    [of a retail rate] attributable to any marketing, billing, collection, 
    and other costs that will be avoided'' to include indirect as well as 
    direct costs. The proposals of NCTA and Comcast for a maximum discount 
    of 10 percent are premised on the view that any greater discount would 
    unduly discourage facilities-based competition. Section 252(d)(3), 
    however, requires wholesale prices to be set based on avoided costs, 
    not on any policy preference for facilities-based competition. For the 
    same statutory reason, we reject as inconsistent with section 252(d)(3) 
    the policy arguments of the Telecommunications Resellers Association 
    and AT&T that we should establish national wholesale discounts at 
    levels that will ensure that resale of local exchange services is a 
    viable business.
        614. We find AT&T's model unsuitable for purposes of establishing 
    in this proceeding a range for default wholesale discount rates. The 
    AT&T model does in many respects satisfy the general criteria we 
    establish above for avoided cost studies. The model, however, 
    incorporates numerous assumptions, cost allocation factors, and 
    studies, and because AT&T submitted its model with its reply comments, 
    and other parties have not analyzed the model in detail. We find that 
    we would need to develop a more complete record on the AT&T model 
    before deciding whether to endorse it. We do not, however, preclude a 
    state commission from considering in a wholesale rate proceeding 
    evidence developed using this model.
        615. We find that we can use MCI's model, with some modifications, 
    along with the results of certain state proceedings, to establish a 
    range of rates that would produce an acceptable default wholesale 
    discount rate that reasonably approximates the amount of avoided costs 
    that should be subtracted from the retail rate. A default rate is to be 
    used only in three instances: (1) in a state arbitration proceeding if 
    an avoided cost study that satisfies the criteria we set forth above 
    does not exist; (2) where a state has not completed its review of such 
    an avoided cost study; (3) where a rate established by a state before 
    the release date of this Order is based on a study that does not comply 
    with the criteria described in the previous section. We emphasize that 
    the default rate is to be used as an interim measure only, and should 
    be replaced with an avoided cost study within a reasonable time. The 
    MCI model is a reasonable attempt at estimating avoided cost in 
    accordance with section 252(d)(3) using only publicly-available data. 
    We find, however, that we should modify certain features of the model.
        616. First, MCI treats account 6722 (external relations) and 
    account 6727 (research and development) as avoidable costs. MCI argues 
    that purchasers of wholesale services are competing with LECs and, 
    therefore, should not be forced to fund regulatory
    
    [[Page 45567]]
    
    activities reflected in account 6722. MCI claims that research and 
    development are not of practical use for the services that resellers 
    will purchase. As explained above, this type of disallowance is not 
    contemplated by the avoided cost standard of section 252(d)(3). We 
    therefore adjust the model to treat these costs in the same manner as 
    other overhead expense accounts.
        617. Second, MCI treats a number of accounts as ``other avoided 
    costs'' on the grounds that the expenses in those accounts are not 
    relevant to the provision of telecommunications services that an 
    incumbent LEC currently provides. Based on this rationale, MCI excludes 
    account 6113 (aircraft expense), account 6341 (large PBX expense), 
    account 6511 (property held for future telecommunications use expense), 
    account 6351 (public telephone terminal equipment expense), account 
    6512 (provisioning expense), account 6562 (depreciation expense for 
    property held for future telecommunications use), and account 6564 
    (amortization expense, intangible). Public telephone terminal equipment 
    expense and large PBX expense are not ``avoided'' precisely because 
    they are unrelated to the retail services being discounted. We would 
    not expect these expenses to be included in retail service rates for 
    resold services; but if these expenses were included in retail rates, 
    they would not be avoided when the services are purchased by resellers. 
    The rest of MCI's ``other'' accounts contain costs that support all of 
    the telecommunications services offered by the company. MCI has not 
    shown that any of these costs are either reduced or eliminated when 
    services are sold at wholesale. We, therefore, adjust the MCI model so 
    as not to treat these accounts as avoidable costs.
        618. Third, MCI treats accounts 6611 (product management), 6612 
    (sales), 6613 (product advertising), and 6623 (customer services) as 
    costs that are entirely avoided with respect to services purchased at 
    wholesale. We agree that a large portion of the expenses in these 
    accounts is avoided when service is sold at wholesale. We also agree, 
    however, with parties that argue that some expenses in these accounts 
    will continue to be incurred with respect to wholesale products and 
    customers, and that some new expenses may be incurred in addressing the 
    needs of resellers as customers. No party in this proceeding has 
    suggested a specific adjustment to the MCI model that would account for 
    these costs of the wholesale operation. We note that, in their own 
    proceedings, several states have made varying estimates concerning the 
    level of wholesale-related expenses in these accounts. Colorado, for 
    example, estimated that none of the costs in accounts 6611-6613 would 
    relate to wholesale services, and that only five percent of the costs 
    in account 6623 would be incurred in a wholesale operation. The Georgia 
    Commission, on the other hand, decided that 25 percent of sales and 
    product advertising expenses would continue to be incurred in the 
    wholesale operation. Given the lack of evidence, and the wide range of 
    estimates that have been made by these states, we find it reasonable to 
    assume, for purposes of determining a default range of wholesale 
    discount rates, that ten percent of costs in accounts 6611, 6612, 6613, 
    and 6623 are not avoided by selling services at wholesale.
        619. Fourth, MCI uses a complex formula to calculate the portions 
    of overhead and general support expense that are attributable to 
    avoided costs. We find that this formula is constructed in a way that 
    tends to inflate the results of the calculation. We have, therefore, 
    substituted a more straightforward approach in which we apply to each 
    indirect expense category the ratio of avoided direct expense to total 
    expenses. We also identify a slightly different list of accounts 
    representing indirect costs than that proposed by MCI.
        620. With the modifications described above, and using actual 1995 
    data, MCI's model produces the following results for the RBOCs and GTE:
    
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                                                    Percent 
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    U S West.....................................................      18.80
    GTE..........................................................      18.81
    BellSouth....................................................      19.20
    Bell Atlantic................................................      19.99
    SBC..........................................................      20.11
    NYNEX........................................................      21.31
    Pacific......................................................      23.87
    Ameritech....................................................      25.98
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        621. We also take into account the experience of those state 
    commissions, Illinois and Georgia, that have undertaken or approved 
    detailed avoided cost studies under the pricing standard of section 
    252(d)(3) of the 1996 Act. Applying the statutory standard to the 
    examination of significant cost studies, those commissions derived 
    average wholesale discounts of 18.74 percent and 20.07 percent. We find 
    that these decisions present evidence of an appropriate wholesale 
    discount that should be given more weight than state commission 
    decisions that have set their discounts under other pricing standards 
    or only on an interim basis.
        622. Accordingly, based on the record before us, we establish a 
    range of default discounts of 17-25 percent that is to be used in the 
    absence of an avoided cost study that meets the criteria set forth 
    above. A state commission that has not set wholesale prices based on 
    avoided cost studies that meet the criteria set forth above as of the 
    release date of this Order shall use a default wholesale discount rate 
    between 17 and 25 percent. A state should articulate the basis for 
    selecting a particular discount rate. If this default discount rate is 
    used, the state commission must establish wholesale rates based on 
    avoided cost studies within a reasonable time. The avoided cost study 
    must comply with the criteria for avoided cost studies described above. 
    A state commission may submit an avoided cost study to this Commission 
    for a determination of whether it complies with these criteria. If a 
    party (either a reseller or an incumbent LEC) believes that a state 
    commission has failed to act within a reasonable period of time, that 
    party may file a petition for declaratory ruling with this Commission, 
    asking us to determine whether the state has failed to comply with this 
    rule. We will, in making such determinations, consider the particular 
    circumstances in the state involved. If a state commission has adopted 
    as of the release date of this Order an interim wholesale pricing 
    decision that relies on an avoided cost study that meets the criteria 
    set forth above, the state commission may continue to require an 
    incumbent LEC to offer services for resale under such interim wholesale 
    prices in lieu of the default discount range, so long as the state 
    commission's interim pricing rules are fully enforceable by resellers 
    and followed by a final decision within a reasonable period of time 
    that adopts an avoided cost study that meets the criteria set forth 
    above.
        623. We select the 17 to 25 percent range of default discounts 
    based on our evaluation of the record. The adjusted results of the MCI 
    model taken together with the results of those state proceedings 
    discussed above that indicated they applied the statutory standard 
    produces, a range between 18.74 and 25.98 percent. A majority of these 
    wholesale discount rates fall between 18.74 and 21.11 percent. Other 
    state commissions, such as California and New York, that have employed 
    avoided cost studies have produced wholesale discount rates somewhat 
    below the low end of this range. Furthermore, it has been argued that 
    smaller incumbent LECs' avoided costs are likely to be less than those 
    of the larger incumbent LECs, whose data was used by MCI. Therefore, to 
    allow for
    
    [[Page 45568]]
    
    these considerations, we select 17 percent as the lower end of the 
    range. We select 25 percent as the top of the range because it 
    approximates the top of the range of results produced by the modified 
    MCI model. This range gives state commissions flexibility in addressing 
    circumstances of incumbent LECs serving their states and permits resale 
    to proceed until such time as the state commission can review a fully-
    compliant avoided cost study.
        624. We have considered the economic impact of our rules in this 
    section on small incumbent LECs. For example, Bay Springs, et al., 
    argues that national wholesale pricing rules will insufficiently 
    consider operational differences between small and large incumbent 
    LECs. We take this into consideration in setting the default discount 
    rate and in requiring state commissions to perform carrier-specific 
    avoided cost studies within a reasonable period of time that will 
    reflect carrier-to-carrier differences. We believe, however, that the 
    procompetitive goals of the 1996 Act require us to establish a default 
    discount rate for state commissions to use in the absence of avoided 
    cost studies that comply with the criteria we set forth above. The 
    presumptions we establish in conducting avoided cost studies regarding 
    the avoidability of certain expenses may be rebutted by evidence that 
    certain costs are not avoided, which should minimize any economic 
    impact of our decisions on small incumbent LECs. We also note that 
    certain small incumbent LECs are not subject to our rules under section 
    251(f)(1) of the 1996 Act, unless otherwise determined by a state 
    commission, and certain other small incumbent LECs may seek relief from 
    their state commissions from our rules under section 251(f)(2) of the 
    1996 Act.
    
    C. Conditions and Limitations
    
        625. Section 251(c)(4) requires incumbent LECs to make their 
    services available for resale without unreasonable or discriminatory 
    conditions or limitations. This portion of this Order addresses various 
    issues relating to conditions or limitations on resale. It first 
    discusses restrictions, generally, in Section VIII.C.1. Next, it turns 
    to promotional and discounted offerings and the conditions that may 
    attach to such offerings in Section VIII.C.2., and then to refusals to 
    resell residential and below-cost services in Section VIII.C.3. 
    Limitations on the categories of customers to whom a reseller may sell 
    incumbent LEC services are discussed in VIII.C.4. Resale restrictions 
    in the form of withdrawal of service are discussed in VIII.C.5. 
    Finally, Section VIII.C.6. discusses resale restrictions relating to 
    provisioning.
    1. Restrictions, Generally, and Burden of Proof
     a. Background
        626. In the NPRM, we asked whether incumbent LECs should have the 
    burden of proving that restrictions on resale are reasonable and 
    nondiscriminatory. We stated our belief that, given the pro-competitive 
    goals of the 1996 Act and the view that restrictions and conditions 
    were likely to be evidence of an exercise of market power, the range of 
    permissible restrictions should be quite narrow.
     b. Discussion
        627. We conclude that resale restrictions are presumptively 
    unreasonable. Incumbent LECs can rebut this presumption, but only if 
    the restrictions are narrowly tailored. Such resale restrictions are 
    not limited to those found in the resale agreement. They include 
    conditions and limitations contained in the incumbent LEC's underlying 
    tariff. As we explained in the NPRM, the ability of incumbent LECs to 
    impose resale restrictions and conditions is likely to be evidence of 
    market power and may reflect an attempt by incumbent LECs to preserve 
    their market position. In a competitive market, an individual seller 
    (an incumbent LEC) would not be able to impose significant restrictions 
    and conditions on buyers because such buyers turn to other sellers. 
    Recognizing that incumbent LECs possess market power, Congress 
    prohibited unreasonable restrictions and conditions on resale. We, as 
    well as state commissions, are unable to predict every potential 
    restriction or limitation an incumbent LEC may seek to impose on a 
    reseller. Given the probability that restrictions and conditions may 
    have anticompetitive results, we conclude that it is consistent with 
    the procompetitive goals of the 1996 Act to presume resale restrictions 
    and conditions to be unreasonable and therefore in violation of section 
    251(c)(4). This presumption should reduce unnecessary burdens on 
    resellers seeking to enter local exchange markets, which may include 
    small entities, by reducing the time and expense of proving 
    affirmatively that such restrictions are unreasonable. We discuss 
    several specific restrictions below including certain restrictions for 
    which we conclude the presumption of unreasonableness shall not apply. 
    We also discuss certain restrictions that we will presume are 
    reasonable.
    2. Promotions and Discounts
     a. Background
        628. In the NPRM, we asked whether an incumbent LEC's obligation to 
    make their services available for resale at wholesale rates applies to 
    discounted and promotional offerings and, if so, how. We also asked, if 
    the wholesale pricing obligation applies to promotions and discounts, 
    whether the reseller entrant's customer must take service pursuant to 
    the same restrictions that apply to the incumbent LEC's retail 
    customers.
     b. Discussion
        629. Section 251(c)(4) provides that incumbent LECs must offer for 
    resale at wholesale rates ``any telecommunications service'' that the 
    carrier provides at retail to noncarrier subscribers. This language 
    makes no exception for promotional or discounted offerings, including 
    contract and other customer-specific offerings. We therefore conclude 
    that no basis exists for creating a general exemption from the 
    wholesale requirement for all promotional or discount service offerings 
    made by incumbent LECs. A contrary result would permit incumbent LECs 
    to avoid the statutory resale obligation by shifting their customers to 
    nonstandard offerings, thereby eviscerating the resale provisions of 
    the 1996 Act. In discussing promotions here, we are only referring to 
    price discounts from standard offerings that will remain available for 
    resale at wholesale rates, i.e., temporary price discounts. Limited 
    time offerings of service are still subject to resale pursuant to 
    Section VIII.A.
        630. There remains, however, the question of whether all short-term 
    promotional prices are ``retail rates'' for purposes of calculating 
    wholesale rates pursuant to section 252(d)(3). The 1996 Act does not 
    define ``retail rate;'' nor is there any indication that Congress 
    considered the issue. In view of this ambiguity, we conclude that 
    ``retail rate'' should be interpreted in light of the pro-competitive 
    policies underlying the 1996 Act. We recognize that promotions that are 
    limited in length may serve procompetitive ends through enhancing 
    marketing and sales-based competition and we do not wish to 
    unnecessarily restrict such offerings. We believe that, if promotions 
    are of limited duration, their procompetitive effects will outweigh any 
    potential anticompetitive effects. We therefore conclude that short-
    term promotional
    
    [[Page 45569]]
    
    prices do not constitute retail rates for the underlying services and 
    are thus not subject to the wholesale rate obligation.
        631. We must also determine when a promotional price ceases to be 
    ``short term'' and must therefore be treated as a retail rate for an 
    underlying service. Incumbent LEC commenters support 120 days as the 
    maximum period for such promotions. This has been criticized as being 
    too long. We are concerned that excluding promotions that are offered 
    for as long as four months may unreasonably hamper the efforts of new 
    competitors that seek to enter local markets through resale. We believe 
    that promotions of up to 90 days, when subjected to the conditions 
    outlined below, will have significantly lower anticompetitive 
    potential, especially as compared to the potential procompetitive 
    marketing uses of such promotions. We therefore establish a presumption 
    that promotional prices offered for a period of 90 days or less need 
    not be offered at a discount to resellers. Promotional offerings 
    greater than 90 days in duration must be offered for resale at 
    wholesale rates pursuant to section 251(c)(4)(A). To preclude the 
    potential for abuse of promotional discounts, any benefit of the 
    promotion must be realized within the time period of the promotion, 
    e.g., no benefit can be realized more than ninety days after the 
    promotional offering is taken by the customer if the promotional 
    offering was for ninety days. In addition, an incumbent LEC may not use 
    promotional offerings to evade the wholesale obligation, for example by 
    consecutively offering a series of 90-day promotions.
        632. We find unconvincing the arguments that the offerings under 
    section 251(c)(4) should not apply to volume-based discounts. The 1996 
    Act on its face does not exclude such offerings from the wholesale 
    obligation. If a service is sold to end users, it is a retail service, 
    even if it is priced as a volume-based discount off the price of 
    another retail service. The avoidable costs for a service with volume-
    based discounts, however, may be different than without volume 
    contracts.
        633. We are concerned that conditions that attach to promotions and 
    discounts could be used to avoid the resale obligation to the detriment 
    of competition. Allowing certain incumbent LEC end user restrictions to 
    be made automatically binding on reseller end users could further 
    exacerbate the potential anticompetitive effects. We recognize, 
    however, that there may be reasonable restrictions on promotions and 
    discounts. We conclude that the substance and specificity of rules 
    concerning which discount and promotion restrictions may be applied to 
    resellers in marketing their services to end users is a decision best 
    left to state commissions, which are more familiar with the particular 
    business practices of their incumbent LECs and local market conditions. 
    These rules are to be developed, as necessary, for use in the 
    arbitration process under section 252.
        634. With respect to volume discount offerings, however, we 
    conclude that it is presumptively unreasonable for incumbent LECs to 
    require individual reseller end users to comply with incumbent LEC 
    high-volume discount minimum usage requirements, so long as the 
    reseller, in aggregate, under the relevant tariff, meets the minimal 
    level of demand. The Commission traditionally has not permitted such 
    restrictions on the resale of volume discount offers. Regulatory 
    Policies Concerning Resale and Shared Use of Common Carrier Services 
    and Facilities, 41 FR 30657 (July 26, 1976). We believe restrictions on 
    resale of volume discounts will frequently produce anticompetitive 
    results without sufficient justification. We, therefore, conclude that 
    such restrictions should be considered presumptively unreasonable. We 
    note, however, that in calculating the proper wholesale rate, incumbent 
    LECs may prove that their avoided costs differ when selling in large 
    volumes.
    3. Below-Cost and Residential Service
    a. Background
        635. Responding to our general questions regarding the scope of 
    limitations that may be placed on competitors' resale of incumbent LEC 
    services, parties addressed in their comments whether below-cost and 
    residential services are subject to section 251(c)(4).
    b. Discussion
        636. Subject to the cross-class restrictions discussed below, we 
    believe that below-cost services are subject to the wholesale rate 
    obligation under section 251(c)(4). First, the 1996 Act applies to 
    ``any telecommunications service'' and thus, by its terms, does not 
    exclude these types of services. Given the goal of the 1996 Act to 
    encourage competition, we decline to limit the resale obligation with 
    respect to certain services where the 1996 Act does not specifically do 
    so. Second, simply because a service may be priced at below-cost levels 
    does not justify denying customers of such a service the benefits of 
    resale competition. We note that, unlike the pricing standard for 
    unbundled elements, the resale pricing standard is not based on cost 
    plus a reasonable profit. The resale pricing standard gives the end 
    user the benefit of an implicit subsidy in the case of below-cost 
    service, whether the end user is served by the incumbent or by a 
    reseller, just as it continues to take the contribution if the service 
    is priced above cost. So long as resale of the service is generally 
    restricted to those customers eligible to receive such service from the 
    incumbent LEC, as discussed below, demand is unlikely to be 
    significantly increased by resale competition. Thus, differences in 
    incumbent LEC revenue resulting from the resale of below-cost services 
    should be accompanied by proportionate decreases in expenditures that 
    are avoided because the service is being offered at wholesale.
        637. We have considered the economic impact of our rules in this 
    section on small incumbent LECs. For example, MECA argues that services 
    incumbent LECs offer at below-cost rates should not be subject to 
    resale under section 251(c)(4). We do not adopt MECA's proposal. As 
    explained above, we conclude that the 1996 Act provides that below-cost 
    services are subject to the section 251(c)(4) resale obligation and 
    that differences in incumbent LEC revenue resulting from the resale of 
    below-cost services should be accompanied by decreases in expenditures 
    that are avoided because the service is being offered at wholesale. 
    Therefore, resale of below-cost services at wholesale rates should not 
    adversely impact small incumbent LECs. We also note that certain small 
    incumbent LECs are not subject to our rules under section 251(f)(1) of 
    the 1996 Act, unless otherwise determined by a state commission, and 
    certain other small incumbent LECs may seek relief from their state 
    commissions from our rules under section 251(f)(2) of the 1996 Act.
    4. Cross-Class Selling
    a. Background
        638. In the NPRM, we sought comment on the meaning of section 
    251(c)(4)(B) which provides that ``[a] State commission may, consistent 
    with regulations prescribed by the Commission under this section, 
    prohibit a reseller that obtains at wholesale rates a 
    telecommunications service that is available at retail only to a 
    category of subscribers from offering such service to a different 
    category of subscribers.'' We suggested that competing 
    telecommunications carriers should not be allowed to purchase a 
    subsidized service that is offered to a specific
    
    [[Page 45570]]
    
    category of subscribers and then resell such service to other 
    customers. We tentatively concluded, for example, that it might be 
    reasonable for a state to restrict the resale of a residential exchange 
    service that is limited to low-income consumers, such as the existing 
    Lifeline program. We noted that we have generally not allowed carriers 
    to prevent other carriers from purchasing high-volume, low-price 
    offerings to resell to a broad pool of lower volume customers. 
    Similarly, we inquired into the propriety of practices such as limiting 
    the resale of flat-rated service.
    b. Discussion
        639. There is general agreement that residential services should 
    not be resold to nonresidential end users, and we conclude that 
    restrictions prohibiting such cross-class reselling of residential 
    services are reasonable. We conclude that section 251(c)(4)(B) permits 
    states to prohibit resellers from selling residential services to 
    customers ineligible to subscribe to such services from the incumbent 
    LEC. For example, this would prevent resellers from reselling 
    wholesale-priced residential service to business customers. We also 
    conclude that section 251(c)(4)(B) allows states to make similar 
    prohibitions on the resale of Lifeline or any other means-tested 
    service offering to end users not eligible to subscribe to such service 
    offerings. State commissions have established rate structures that take 
    into account certain desired balances between residential and business 
    rates and the goal of maximizing access by low-income consumers to 
    telecommunications services. We do not wish to disturb these efforts by 
    prohibiting or overly narrowing state commissions' ability to impose 
    such restrictions on resale.
        640. Shared tenant services are made possible through the resale 
    and trunking of flat-rated services to multiple customers. We do not 
    believe that these or other efficient uses of technology should be 
    discouraged through restrictions on the resale of flat-rated offerings 
    to multiple end users, even if incumbent LECs have not always priced 
    such offerings assuming these usage patterns. We therefore conclude 
    that such restrictions are presumptively unreasonable.
        641. We also conclude that all other cross-class selling 
    restrictions should be presumed unreasonable. Without clear statutory 
    direction concerning potentially allowable cross-class restrictions, we 
    are not inclined to allow the imposition of restrictions that could 
    fetter the emergence of competition. As with volume discount and flat-
    rated offerings, we will allow incumbent LECs to rebut this presumption 
    by proving to the state commission that the class restriction is 
    reasonable and nondiscriminatory.
    5. Incumbent LEC Withdrawal of Services
    a. Background
        642. In the NPRM, we sought comment on whether an incumbent LEC can 
    avoid making a service available at wholesale rates by ceasing to offer 
    the retail service on a retail basis, or whether the incumbent should 
    first be required to make a showing that withdrawing the offering is in 
    the public interest or that competitors will continue to have an 
    alternative way of providing service. We also asked if access to 
    unbundled elements addresses the concern that incumbent LECs could 
    withdraw retail services.
    b. Discussion
        643. We are concerned that the incumbent LECs' ability to withdraw 
    services may have anticompetitive effects where resellers are 
    purchasing such services for resale in competition with the incumbent. 
    We decline to issue general rules on this subject because we conclude 
    that this is a matter best left to state commissions. Many state 
    commissions have rules regarding the withdrawal of retail services and 
    have experience regulating such matters. States can assess, for 
    example, the universal service implications of an incumbent LEC's 
    proposal to withdraw a retail service. Therefore, we conclude that our 
    general presumption that incumbent LEC restrictions on resale are 
    unreasonable does not apply to incumbent LEC withdrawal of service. 
    States must ensure that procedural mechanisms exist for processing 
    complaints regarding incumbent LEC withdrawals of services. We find it 
    important, however, to ensure that grandfathered customers--subscribers 
    to the service being withdrawn who are allowed by an incumbent LEC to 
    continue purchasing services--not be denied the benefits of 
    competition. We conclude that, when an incumbent LEC grandfathers its 
    own customers of a withdrawn service, such grandfathering should also 
    extend to reseller end users. For the duration of any grandfathering 
    period, all grandfathered customers should have the right to purchase 
    such grandfathered services either directly from the incumbent LEC or 
    indirectly through a reseller. The incumbent LEC shall offer wholesale 
    rates for such grandfathered services to resellers for the purpose of 
    serving grandfathered customers.
    6. Provisioning
        644. We conclude that service made available for resale be at least 
    equal in quality to that provided by the incumbent LEC to itself or to 
    any subsidiary, affiliate, or any other party to which the carrier 
    directly provides the service, such as end users. Practices to the 
    contrary violate the 1996 Act's prohibition of discriminatory 
    restrictions, limitations, or prohibitions on resale. This requirement 
    includes differences imperceptible to end users because such 
    differences may still provide incumbent LECs with advantages in the 
    marketplace. Additionally, we conclude that incumbent LEC services are 
    to be provisioned for resale with the same timeliness as they are 
    provisioned to that incumbent LEC's subsidiaries, affiliates, or other 
    parties to whom the carrier directly provides the service, such as end 
    users. This equivalent timeliness requirement also applies to incumbent 
    LEC claims of capacity limitations and incumbent LEC requirements 
    relating to such limitations, such as potential down payments. We note 
    that common carrier obligations, established by federal and state law 
    and our rules, continue to apply to incumbent LECs in their relations 
    with resellers. With regard to customer changeover charges, we conclude 
    that states should determine reasonable and nondiscriminatory rates for 
    such charges.
        645. Brand identification is likely to play a major role in markets 
    where resellers compete with incumbent LECs for the provision of local 
    and toll service. This brand identification is critical to reseller 
    attempts to compete with incumbent LECs and will minimize consumer 
    confusion. Incumbent LECs are advantaged when reseller end users are 
    advised that the service is being provided by the reseller's primary 
    competitor. We therefore conclude that where operator, call completion, 
    or directory assistance service is part of the service or service 
    package an incumbent LEC offers for resale, failure by an incumbent LEC 
    to comply with reseller branding requests presumptively constitutes an 
    unreasonable restriction on resale. This presumption may be rebutted by 
    an incumbent LEC proving to the state commission that it lacks the 
    capability to comply with unbranding or rebranding requests. We 
    recognize that an incumbent LEC may incur costs in complying with a 
    request for unbranding or rebranding. Because we
    
    [[Page 45571]]
    
    do not have a record on which to determine the level of fees or 
    wholesale pricing offsets that may reasonably be assessed to recover 
    these costs, we leave such determinations to the state commissions.
    
    D. Resale Obligations of LECs Under Section 251(b)(1)
    
        646. Section 251(b)(1) imposes a duty on all LECs to offer certain 
    services for resale. Specifically, section 251(b)(1) requires LECs 
    ``not to prohibit, and not to impose unreasonable or discriminatory 
    conditions or limitations on, the resale of its telecommunications 
    services.''
    1. Background
        647. In the NPRM, we sought comment generally on the relationship 
    of section 251(b)(1) to section 251(c)(4). We sought comment on whether 
    all LECs are prohibited from imposing unreasonable restrictions on 
    resale of their services, but only incumbent LECs that provide retail 
    services to subscribers that are not telecommunications carriers are 
    required to make such services available at wholesale rates to 
    requesting telecommunications carriers. We also sought comment on what 
    types of resale restrictions should be permitted under section 
    251(b)(1) and stated our belief that few, if any, conditions or 
    limitations should be permitted for the same reasons that resale 
    restrictions are sharply limited under section 251(c)(4). We also asked 
    what standards should be adopted for determining whether resale 
    restrictions should be permitted, and whether presumptions should be 
    established.
    2. Discussion
        648. There are two differences between the resale obligations in 
    section 251(b)(1) and in section 251(c)(4): the scope of services that 
    must be resold and the pricing of such resale offerings. Section 
    251(b)(1) requires resale of all telecommunications services offered by 
    the carrier while section 251(c)(4) only applies to telecommunications 
    services that the carrier provides at retail to subscribers who are not 
    telecommunications carriers. Thus, the scope of services to which 
    section 251(b)(1) applies is larger and necessarily includes all 
    services subject to resale under section 251(c)(4). We need not 
    prescribe a minimum list of services that are subject to the 251(b)(1) 
    resale requirement for the same reasons that we specified for not 
    prescribing such a list in Section VIII.A. of this Order. We note that 
    section 251(b)(1) clearly omits a wholesale pricing requirement. We 
    therefore conclude that the 1996 Act does not impose wholesale pricing 
    requirements on nonincumbent LECs. Nonincumbent LECs definitionally 
    lack the market power possessed by incumbent LECs and were therefore 
    not made subject to the wholesale pricing obligation in the 1996 Act. 
    Their wholesale rates will face competition by incumbent LECs, making a 
    wholesale pricing requirement for nonincumbent LECs unnecessary.
        649. Sections 251(b)(1) and 251(c)(4) contain the same statutory 
    standards regarding resale restrictions. Therefore, we conclude that 
    our rules concerning resale restrictions under section 251(b)(1), such 
    as the general presumption that all resale restrictions are 
    unreasonable, should be the same as under section 251(c)(4). We 
    conclude that any restriction of a type that has been found reasonable 
    for incumbent LECs should be deemed reasonable for all other LECs as 
    well.
    
    E. Application of Access Charges
    
    1. Background
        650. In the NPRM, we suggested that an entrant that merely resold a 
    bundled retail service purchased at wholesale rates would not receive 
    access revenues. In other words, IXCs must still pay access charges to 
    incumbent LECs for originating and terminating interstate traffic of an 
    end user served by a telecommunications carrier that resells incumbent 
    LEC services under section 251(c)(4).
    2. Discussion
        651. We conclude that the 1996 Act requires that incumbent LECs 
    continue to receive access charge revenues when local services are 
    resold under section 251(c)(4). IXCs must still pay access charges to 
    incumbent LECs for originating or terminating interstate traffic, even 
    when their end user is served by a telecommunications carrier that 
    resells incumbent LEC retail services. Resale, as defined in section 
    251(b)(1) and 251(c)(4), involves services, in contrast to section 
    251(c)(3), which governs sale of network elements. New entrants that 
    purchase retail local exchange services from an incumbent LEC at 
    wholesale rates are entitled to resell only those retail services, and 
    not any other services--such as exchange access--the LEC may offer 
    using the same facilities. IXCs must therefore still purchase access 
    services from incumbent LECs outside of the resale framework of 
    251(c)(4), through existing interstate access tariffs.
        652. Most existing interstate access charges are recovered from 
    IXCs, and therefore can easily be recovered by incumbent LECs whether 
    or not the incumbent LEC retains its billing relationship with the end 
    user subscriber. To allow incumbent LECs to continue recovering the 
    subscriber line charge (SLC), however, the mechanism for assessment of 
    the SLC must be modified. The SLC is currently assessed directly on end 
    users as a monthly charge. When an end user customer receives local 
    exchange service from a reseller, however, the incumbent LEC will have 
    no direct commercial relationship with that end user. Because the end 
    user would not be a customer of the incumbent LEC, the incumbent LEC 
    could not bill SLC directly to the end user as specified under our 
    existing rules.
        653. In March 1995, in the Rochester Waiver Order, we granted 
    Rochester Telephone waivers to permit Rochester Telephone to recover 
    the SLC from carriers that purchase local exchange service for resale, 
    rather than recovering the SLC directly from end users. In that order, 
    we stated that by offering the local exchange service for resale and by 
    unbundling subscriber lines from other network functions, Rochester 
    Telephone created a situation where it would no longer have a direct 
    relationship with end users, IXCs, or both, and that such a situation 
    was not contemplated when the Commission created the rules governing 
    the recovery of access charges. We also permitted Rochester Telephone 
    to bill to resellers the PIC change charge, which is assessed by 
    incumbent local exchange carriers on end users that wish to change 
    their primary interexchange carrier (PIC).
        654. The resale requirements of the 1996 Act create a situation for 
    the entire industry that is analogous to the situation Rochester 
    Telephone faced in 1995. We therefore conclude that similar relief is 
    warranted here with respect to the SLC, so that incumbent LECs can 
    recover the SLC from resellers, as we conclude the 1996 Act mandates. 
    Although the PIC change charge is not a part of access charges, and is 
    assessed only when an end user changes his or her primary interexchange 
    carrier, this charge has similar characteristics to the SLC and 
    therefore should also be subject to the rule we adopt. Incumbent LECs 
    may assess the SLC and the PIC change charge on telecommunications 
    carriers that resell incumbent LEC services under section 251(c)(4).
        655. Although incumbent LECs may continue to recover the SLC when 
    other carriers resell their local exchange services, the SLC is not 
    subject to the wholesale pricing standard of section 252(d)(3). As 
    described above, resellers
    
    [[Page 45572]]
    
    of local exchange service are not reselling access services; they are 
    purchasing these services from incumbent LECs in the same manner they 
    do today. The SLC is a component of interstate access charges, not of 
    intrastate local service rates. Consistent with the principles of cost-
    causation and economic efficiency, we have required the portion of 
    interstate allocated loop costs represented by the SLC to be recovered 
    from end users, rather than from carriers as with other access charges. 
    Although the SLC is listed on end user monthly local service bills, 
    this charge does not represent a ``telecommunications service [an 
    incumbent LEC] provides at retail to subscribers.'' Rather, the SLC, 
    like other interstate access charges, relates solely to incumbent LEC 
    interstate access services, which are provided to other carriers rather 
    than retail subscribers and which we have concluded are not subject to 
    the resale requirements of section 251(c)(4). Therefore, the reseller 
    shall pay the SLC to the incumbent LEC for each subscriber taking 
    resold service. The specific SLC that applies depends upon the identity 
    of the end user served by the reselling telecommunications carrier.
    
    IX. Duties Imposed on ``Telecommunications Carriers'' by Section 251(a)
    
    A. Background
    
        656. Section 251(a) imposes two fundamental duties on all 
    telecommunications carriers: (1) ``to interconnect directly or 
    indirectly with the facilities and equipment of other 
    telecommunications carriers;'' and (2) ``not to install network 
    features, functions, or capabilities that do not comply with the 
    guidelines and standards established pursuant to sections 255 or 256.'' 
    47 U.S.C. 251(a). Section 255 addresses access by persons with 
    disabilities and ensures that manufacturers and providers of 
    telecommunications will design equipment and provide service that is 
    accessible to, and usable by, individuals with disabilities. Section 
    256 provides for coordination for interconnectivity ``to promote 
    nondiscriminatory accessibility by the broadest number of users and 
    vendors of communications products and services.'' 47 U.S.C. Secs. 255, 
    256. In this proceeding we determine which carriers are 
    ``telecommunications carriers'' as defined in section 3(44) of the Act. 
    The term telecommunications carrier means ``any provider of 
    telecommunications services, except that such term does not include 
    aggregators of telecommunications services (as defined in section 226). 
    A telecommunications carrier shall be treated as a common carrier under 
    this Act only to the extent that it is engaged in providing 
    telecommunications services, except that the Commission shall determine 
    whether the provision of fixed and mobile satellite service shall be 
    treated as common carriage.'' 47 U.S.C. 153(44). In the NPRM, we 
    tentatively concluded that, pursuant to the statute's definition of 
    ``telecommunications carrier'' and ``telecommunications service,'' to 
    the extent a carrier is engaged in providing for a fee local, 
    interexchange, or international services, directly to the public or to 
    such classes of users as to be effectively available directly to the 
    public, that carrier falls within the definition of 
    ``telecommunications carrier.'' We sought comment on which carriers are 
    included under this definition, and on whether a provider may qualify 
    as a telecommunications carrier for some purposes but not others.
        657. We also tentatively concluded that we should determine whether 
    the provision of mobile satellite services is Commercial Mobile Radio 
    Services (CMRS) or Private Mobile Radio Service (PMRS) based on the 
    factors set forth in the CMRS Second Report and Order. NPRM at para 
    247. The Commission makes this determination by looking at an array of 
    public interest considerations (e.g., the types of services being 
    offered and the number of licensees being authorized). See, e.g., 
    Amendment of Parts 2, 22 and 25 of the Commission's Rules to Allocate 
    Spectrum for, and To Establish Other Rules and Policies Pertaining to 
    the Use of Radio Frequencies in a Land Mobile Satellite Service for the 
    Provision of Various Common Carrier Services, GEN Docket No. 84-1234, 
    Second Report and Order, 52 FR 4017 (February 9, 1987); Amendment to 
    the Commission's Rules to Allocate Spectrum for, and to Establish Other 
    Rules and Policies Pertaining to a Radiodetermination Satellite 
    Service, GEN Docket No. 84-689, Second Report and Order, 51 FR 18444 
    (May 20, 1986). We sought comment on the meaning of offering service 
    ``directly or indirectly'' to the public in the context of section 
    251(a)(1) and on whether section 251(a) allows non-incumbent LECs 
    discretion to interconnect directly or indirectly with a requesting 
    carrier. We also sought comment on what other actions we should take to 
    ensure that carriers do not install network features, functions, or 
    capabilities that are inconsistent with guidelines and standards 
    established pursuant to sections 255 and 256.
    
    B. Discussion
    
        658. A ``telecommunications carrier'' is defined as ``any provider 
    of telecommunications services, except that such term does not include 
    aggregators of telecommunications services (as defined in section 
    226).'' 47 U.S.C. 153(44). The term ``aggregator'' is defined as ``any 
    person that, in the ordinary course of its operations, makes telephones 
    available to the public or to transient users of its premises, for 
    interstate telephone calls using a provider of operator services.'' 47 
    U.S.C. 226(a)(2). A telecommunications carrier shall be treated as a 
    common carrier under the Act ``only to the extent that it is engaged in 
    providing telecommunications services, except that the Commission shall 
    determine whether the provision of fixed and mobile satellite service 
    shall be treated as common carriage.'' A ``telecommunications service'' 
    is defined as the ``offering of telecommunications for a fee directly 
    to the public, or to such classes of users as to be effectively 
    available directly to the public, regardless of the facilities used.'' 
    We conclude that to the extent a carrier is engaged in providing for a 
    fee domestic or international telecommunications, directly to the 
    public or to such classes of users as to be effectively available 
    directly to the public, the carrier falls within the definition of 
    ``telecommunications carrier.'' We find that this definition is 
    consistent with the 1996 Act, and there is nothing in the record in 
    this proceeding that suggests that this definition should not be 
    adopted. Also, enhanced service providers, to the extent that they are 
    providing telecommunications services, are entitled to the rights under 
    section 251(a).
        659. We believe, as a general policy matter, that all 
    telecommunications carriers that compete with each other should be 
    treated alike regardless of the technology used unless there is a 
    compelling reason to do otherwise. We agree with those parties that 
    argue that all CMRS providers are telecommunications carriers and are 
    thus obligated to comply with section 251(a). The term ``CMRS'' is 
    defined as ``any mobile service * * * that is provided for profit and 
    makes interconnected service available (A) to the public or (B) to such 
    classes of eligible users as to be effectively available to a 
    substantial portion of the public.'' 47 U.S.C. Sec. 332(d)(1). CMRS 
    includes, among others, some private paging, personal communications 
    services, business radio services, and
    
    [[Page 45573]]
    
    mobile service that is the functional equivalent of a commercial mobile 
    radio service. 47 CFR Sec. 20.9. These carriers meet the definition of 
    ``telecommunications carrier'' because they are providers of 
    telecommunications services as defined in the 1996 Act and are thus 
    entitled to the benefits of section 251(c), which include the right to 
    request interconnection and obtain access to unbundled elements at any 
    technically feasible point in an incumbent LEC's network. PMRS is 
    defined as any mobile service that is not a commercial service or the 
    functional equivalent of a commercial mobile service. We conclude that 
    to the extent a PMRS provider uses capacity to provide domestic or 
    international telecommunications for a fee directly to the public, it 
    will fall within the definition of ``telecommunications carrier'' under 
    the Act and will be subject to the duties listed in section 251(a). The 
    Commission held in the CMRS Second Report and Order that any PMRS 
    provider that ``employs spectrum for not-for-profit services, such as 
    an internal operation, but also uses its excess capacity to make 
    available a service that is intended to receive compensation, will be 
    deemed to be a `for profit' service to the extent of such excess 
    capacity activities.'' Implementation of Section 3(n) and 332 of the 
    Communications Act, Second Report and Order, GN Docket No. 93-252, 59 
    FR 18493 (April 19, 1994) (CMRS Second Report and Order).
        660. We conclude that cost-sharing for the construction and 
    operation of private telecommunications networks is not within the 
    definition of ``telecommunications services'' and thus such operators 
    of private networks are not subject to the requirements of section 
    251(a). We believe that such methods of cost-sharing do not equate to a 
    ``fee directly to the public'' under the definition of 
    ``telecommunications service.'' Conversely, to the extent an operator 
    of a private telecommunications network is offering 
    ``telecommunications'' (the term ``telecommunications'' means ``the 
    transmission, between or among points specified by the user, of 
    information of the user's choosing, without change in form or content 
    of the information as sent and received'' 47 U.S.C. Sec. 153(43)) for a 
    fee directly to the public, or to such classes of users as to be 
    effectively available directly to the public (i.e., providing a 
    telecommunications service), the operator is a telecommunications 
    carrier and is subject to the duties in section 251(a). Providing to 
    the public telecommunications (e.g., selling excess capacity on private 
    fiber or wireless networks), constitutes provision of a 
    telecommunications service and thus subjects the operator of such a 
    network to the duties of section 251(a) to that extent.
        661. We conclude that, if a company provides both 
    telecommunications and information services, it must be classified as a 
    telecommunications carrier for purposes of section 251, and is subject 
    to the obligations under section 251(a), to the extent that it is 
    acting as a telecommunications carrier. We also conclude that 
    telecommunications carriers that have interconnected or gained access 
    under sections 251(a)(1), 251(c)(2), or 251(c)(3), may offer 
    information services through the same arrangement, so long as they are 
    offering telecommunications services through the same arrangement as 
    well. Under a contrary conclusion, a competitor would be precluded from 
    offering information services in competition with the incumbent LEC 
    under the same arrangement, thus increasing the transaction cost for 
    the competitor. We find this to be contrary to the pro-competitive 
    spirit of the 1996 Act. By rejecting this outcome we provide 
    competitors the opportunity to compete effectively with the incumbent 
    by offering a full range of services to end users without having to 
    provide some services inefficiently through distinct facilities or 
    agreements. In addition, we conclude that enhanced service providers 
    that do not also provide domestic or international telecommunications, 
    and are thus not telecommunications carriers within the meaning of the 
    Act, may not interconnect under section 251.
        662. Consistent with our tentative conclusion in the NPRM, we will 
    determine whether the provision of mobile satellite service (MSS) is 
    CMRS (and therefore common carriage) or PMRS based on the factors set 
    forth in theCMRS Second Report and Order. Commenters have not raised 
    objections to the Commission's tentative conclusion on this issue.
        663. Regarding the issue of interconnecting ``directly or 
    indirectly'' with the facilities of other telecommunications carriers, 
    we conclude that telecommunications carriers should be permitted to 
    provide interconnection pursuant to section 251(a) either directly or 
    indirectly, based upon their most efficient technical and economic 
    choices. The interconnection obligations under section 251(a) differ 
    from the obligations under section 251(c). Unlike section 251(c), which 
    applies to incumbent LECs, section 251(a) interconnection applies to 
    all telecommunications carriers including those with no market power. 
    Given the lack of market power by telecommunication carriers required 
    to provide interconnection via section 251(a), and the clear language 
    of the statute, we find that indirect connection (e.g., two non-
    incumbent LECs interconnecting with an incumbent LEC's network) 
    satisfies a telecommunications carrier's duty to interconnect pursuant 
    to section 251(a). We decline to adopt, at this time, Metricom's 
    suggestion to forbear under section 10 of the 1996 Act from imposing 
    any interconnection requirements upon non-dominant carriers. We believe 
    that, even for telecommunications carriers with no market power, the 
    duty to interconnect directly or indirectly is central to the 1996 Act 
    and achieves important policy objectives. Nothing in the record 
    convinces us that we should forbear from imposing the provisions of 
    section 251(a) on non-dominant carriers. In fact, section 251 
    distinguishes between dominant and non-dominant carriers, and imposes a 
    number of additional obligations exclusively on incumbent LECs. 
    Similarly, we also do not agree with the Texas Commission's argument 
    that the obligations of section 251(a) should apply equally to all 
    telecommunications carriers. Section 251 is clear in imposing different 
    obligations on carriers depending upon their classification (i.e., 
    incumbent LEC, LEC, or telecommunications carrier). For example, 
    section 251(c) specifically imposes obligations upon incumbent LECs to 
    interconnect, upon request, at all technically feasible points. This 
    direct interconnection, however, is not required under section 251(a) 
    of all telecommunications carriers.
        664. Section 251(a)(2) prohibits telecommunications carriers from 
    installing network features, functions, and capabilities that do not 
    comply with standards or guidelines established under sections 255 and 
    256. Because the Commission and the Architectural and Transportation 
    Barriers Compliance Board have not developed standards or guidelines 
    under section 255, we find that it would be premature at this point to 
    attempt to delineate specific requirements or definitions of terms to 
    implement Section 251(a)(2). The Illinois Commission lists several 
    features which could provide access to individuals with disabilities, 
    such as access to interrupt messages, directory assistance and operator 
    services by users of text telephones (TTYs). Illinois
    
    [[Page 45574]]
    
    Commission comments at 82-83. Specific accessibility requirements such 
    as those proposed by the Illinois Commission will need to be developed 
    in proceedings to implement section 255, and therefore, we will not set 
    forth any required ``features, functions, or capabilities'' in this 
    proceeding. Similarly, the Commission has asked its federal advisory 
    committee, the Network Reliability and Interoperability Council, for 
    recommendations on how the Commission should implement Section 256. We 
    intend to issue a further notice of proposed rulemaking seeking comment 
    on what accessibility and compatibility requirements apply to 
    telecommunications carriers who install network features, functions and 
    capabilities.
    
    X. Commercial Mobile Radio Service Interconnection
    
        665. In the NPRM, we sought comment on whether interconnection 
    arrangements between incumbent LECs and CMRS providers fall within the 
    scope of sections 251 and 252. Application of sections 251 and 252 to 
    LEC-CMRS interconnection arrangements involves two distinct issues. One 
    is whether the terms and conditions of the physical interconnection 
    between incumbent LECs and CMRS providers are governed under section 
    251(c)(2), and the corresponding pricing standards set forth in section 
    252(d)(1). The second, and perhaps more critical issue from the CMRS 
    providers' perspective, is whether CMRS providers are entitled to 
    reciprocal compensation for transport and termination under section 
    251(b)(5), and the corresponding pricing standards set forth in section 
    252(d)(2).
        666. We tentatively concluded in the NPRM that CMRS providers are 
    not obliged to provide to requesting telecommunications carriers either 
    reciprocal compensation for transport and termination of 
    telecommunications under section 251(b)(5), or interconnection under 
    the provisions of section 251(c)(2), but that CMRS providers may be 
    entitled to request interconnection under section 251(c)(2) for the 
    purposes of providing ``telephone exchange service and exchange 
    access.'' We sought comment on this tentative conclusion. We also asked 
    for comment on the separate but related question of whether LEC-CMRS 
    transport and termination arrangements fall within the scope of section 
    251(b)(5). In addition, we sought comment on the relationship between 
    section 251 and section 332(c). 47 U.S.C. 332(c). This section sets 
    forth the regulatory treatment for mobile services, including the 
    common carrier treatment of CMRS providers (except for such provisions 
    of Title II as the Commission may specify), the right of CMRS providers 
    to request (and the Commission to order) physical interconnection with 
    other common carriers and the preemption of state regulation of the 
    entry of or the rates charged by any CMRS providers. We acknowledged 
    that issues relating to LEC-CMRS interconnection pursuant to section 
    332(c) were part of an ongoing proceeding initiated before the passage 
    of the 1996 Act, (Interconnection Between Local Exchange Carriers and 
    Commercial Mobile Radio Service Providers, Notice of Proposed 
    Rulemaking, CC Docket No. 95-185, 61 FR 3644 (February 1, 1996) (LEC-
    CMRS Interconnection NPRM)), and retained the prerogative of 
    incorporating by reference the comments filed in that docket to the 
    extent necessary. We hereby do so.
    
    A. CMRS Providers and Obligations of Local Exchange Carriers Under 
    Section 251(b) and Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers Under Section 
    251(c)
    
    1. Background
        667. Section 251(b) imposes duties only on LECs, and section 251(c) 
    imposes duties only on incumbent LECs. Section 3(26) of the Act defines 
    ``local exchange carrier'' to mean ``any person that is engaged in the 
    provision of telephone exchange service or exchange access,'' but 
    ``does not include a person insofar as such person is engaged in the 
    provision of a commercial mobile service under section 332(c), except 
    to the extent that the Commission finds that such service should be 
    included in the definition of such term.'' In the NPRM, we sought 
    comment on whether, and to what extent, CMRS providers should be 
    classified as ``local exchange carriers'' and therefore subject to the 
    duties and obligations imposed by section 251(b).
    2. Discussion
        668. We are not persuaded by those arguing that CMRS providers 
    should be treated as LECs, and decline at this time to treat CMRS 
    providers as LECs. Section 3(26) of the Act, quoted above, makes clear 
    that CMRS providers should not be classified as LECs until the 
    Commission makes a finding that such treatment is warranted. We 
    disagree with COMAV and National Wireless Resellers Association that 
    CMRS providers are de facto LECs (and even incumbent LECs if they are 
    affiliated with a LEC) simply because they provide telephone exchange 
    and exchange access services. Congress recognized that some CMRS 
    providers offer telephone exchange and exchange access services, and 
    concluded that their provision of such services, by itself, did not 
    require CMRS providers to be classified as LECs. We further note that, 
    because the determination as to whether CMRS providers should be 
    defined as LECs is within the Commission's sole discretion, states are 
    preempted from requiring CMRS providers to classify themselves as 
    ``local exchange carriers'' or be subject to rate and entry regulation 
    as a precondition to participation in interconnection negotiations and 
    arbitrations under sections 251 and 252.
        669. NARUC argues that CMRS providers should be classified as LECs 
    if they provide fixed service. We are currently seeking comment in our 
    CMRS Flexibility Proceeding, (Amendment of the Commission's Rules to 
    Permit Flexible Service Offerings in the Commercial Mobile Radio 
    Services, WT Docket No. 96-6, First Report and Order and Further Notice 
    of Proposed Rulemaking, FCC 96-283 (released August 1, 1996)), on the 
    regulatory treatment to be afforded CMRS providers when they provide 
    fixed services. Thus, we believe that it would be premature to answer 
    that question here, based only on the record in this proceeding. We 
    also decline to adopt the Illinois Commission's suggestion that we find 
    that a CMRS provider is a LEC if the CMRS provider seeks to compete 
    directly with a wireline LEC. Even if we were to accept the Illinois 
    Commission's underlying assumption, the record in this proceeding 
    contains no evidence that wireless local loops have begun to replace 
    wireline loops for the provision of local exchange service. Thus, until 
    such time that we decide otherwise, CMRS providers will not be 
    classified as LECs, and are not subject to the obligations of section 
    251(b). We further note that, even if we were to classify some CMRS 
    providers as LECs, other types of CMRS providers, such as paging 
    providers, might not be so classified because they do not offer local 
    exchange service or exchange access.
        670. We further note that, because CMRS providers do not fall 
    within the definition of a LEC under section 251(h)(1), they are not 
    subject to the duties and obligations imposed on incumbent LECs under 
    section 251(c). An incumbent LEC is defined in section 251(h)(1), and 
    includes only those LECs that were, on the date of enactment of the 
    1996 Act, deemed to be members of NECA pursuant to 47 CFR 
    Sec. 69.601(b), or the successor or assign of a NECA member. Similarly, 
    we do not find that
    
    [[Page 45575]]
    
    CMRS providers satisfy the criteria set forth in section 251(h)(2), 
    which grants the Commission the discretion to, by rule, provide for the 
    treatment of a LEC as an incumbent LEC if certain conditions are met.
    
    B. Reciprocal Compensation Arrangements Under Section 251(b)(5)
    
        671. Some parties contend that LEC-CMRS transport and termination 
    arrangements do not fall within the scope of 251(b)(5), which requires 
    LECs to establish reciprocal compensation arrangements for transport 
    and termination. Other commenters argue that because CMRS providers 
    fall within the definition of ``telecommunications carriers,'' they 
    fall within the scope of section 251(b)(5).
        672. Under section 251(b)(5), LECs have a duty to establish 
    reciprocal compensation arrangements for the transport and termination 
    of ``telecommunications.'' Under section 3(43), ``[t]he term 
    `telecommunications' means the transmission, between or among points 
    specified by the user, of information of the user's choosing, without 
    change in the form or content of the information as sent and 
    received.'' All CMRS providers offer telecommunications. Accordingly, 
    LECs are obligated, pursuant to section 251(b)(5) (and the 
    corresponding pricing standards of section 252(d)(2)), to enter into 
    reciprocal compensation arrangements with all CMRS providers, including 
    paging providers, for the transport and termination of traffic on each 
    other's networks, pursuant to the rules governing reciprocal 
    compensation set forth in Section XI.B, below.
    
    C. Interconnection Under Section 251(c)(2)
    
    1. Background
        673. Section 251(c)(2)(A) provides that an incumbent LEC must 
    provide interconnection with its local exchange network to ``any 
    requesting telecommunications carrier * * * for the transmission and 
    routing of telephone exchange service and exchange access.'' In the 
    NPRM, we tentatively concluded that CMRS providers may be entitled to 
    request interconnection under section 251(c)(2) for the purposes of 
    providing telephone exchange service and exchange access. We sought 
    comment on this tentative conclusion.
    2. Discussion
        674. As discussed in the preceding section, CMRS providers meet the 
    statutory definition of ``telecommunications carriers.'' We also agree 
    with several commenters that many CMRS providers (specifically 
    cellular, broadband PCS and covered SMR) also provide telephone 
    exchange service and exchange access as defined by the 1996 Act. 
    Incumbent LECs must accordingly make interconnection available to these 
    CMRS providers in conformity with the terms of sections 251(c) and 252, 
    including offering rates, terms, and conditions that are just, 
    reasonable and nondiscriminatory.
        675. The 1996 Act defines ``telephone exchange service'' as 
    ``service within a telephone exchange, or within a connected system of 
    telephone exchanges within the same exchange area * * * and which is 
    covered by the exchange service charge, or (B) comparable service 
    provided through a system of switches, transmission equipment, or other 
    facilities (or combination thereof) by which a subscriber can originate 
    and terminate a telecommunications service.'' 47 U.S.C. 153(47) 
    (emphasis added). This is a broader definition of ``telephone exchange 
    service'' than had previously existed; Congress changed the definition 
    in the 1996 Act to include services ``comparable'' to telephone 
    exchange. At a minimum, we find that cellular, broadband PCS, and 
    covered SMR providers fall within the second part of the definition 
    because they provide ``comparable service'' to telephone exchange 
    service. The services offered by cellular, broadband PCS, and covered 
    SMR providers are comparable because, as a general matter, and as some 
    commenters note, these CMRS carriers provide local, two-way switched 
    voice service as a principal part of their business. Indeed, the 
    Commission has described cellular service as exchange telephone 
    service, (See Need to Promote Competition and Efficient Use of Spectrum 
    for Radio Common Carriers, Memorandum Opinion and Order, 59 Rad. Reg. 
    2d 1275, 1278 (1986)), and cellular carriers as ``generally engaged in 
    the provision of local exchange telecommunications in conjunction with 
    local telephone companies * * *.'' In the Matter of the Need to Promote 
    Competition and Efficient Use of Spectrum For Radio Common Carrier 
    Services, Memorandum Opinion and Order, 59 Rad. Reg. 2d 1275, 1278 
    (1986) (Competition Opinion); see also id. at 1284 (cellular carriers 
    are primarily engaged in the provision of local, intrastate exchange 
    telephone service); Equal Access and Interconnection Obligations 
    Pertaining to Commercial Radio Services, CC Docket No. 94-54, Notice of 
    Proposed Rulemaking and Notice of Inquiry, 59 FR 35664 (July 13, 1994). 
    In addition, although CMRS providers are not currently classified as 
    LECs, the fact that most CMRS providers are capable, both technically 
    and pursuant to the terms of their licenses, of providing fixed 
    services, as LECs do, buttresses our conclusion that these CMRS 
    providers offer services that are ``comparable'' to telephone exchange 
    service and supports the notion that these services may become a true 
    economic substitute for wireline local exchange service in the future. 
    See Amendment of the Commission's Rules to Permit Flexible Service 
    Offerings in the Commercial Mobile Radio Services, WT Docket No. 96-6, 
    First Report and Order and Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, FCC 
    96-283 (released August 1, 1996) (amending rules to allow providers of 
    narrowband and broadband PCS, cellular, CMRS SMR, CMRS paging, CMRS 220 
    MHz service, and for-profit interconnected business radio services to 
    offer fixed wireless services on their assigned spectrum on a co-
    primary basis with mobile services).
        676. We also believe that other definitions in the Act support the 
    conclusion that cellular, broadband PCS, and covered SMR licensees 
    provide telephone exchange service. The fact that the 1996 Act's 
    definition of a LEC excludes CMRS until the Commission finds that such 
    service should be included in the definition,'' suggests that Congress 
    found that some CMRS providers were providing telephone exchange 
    service or exchange access, but sought to afford the Commission the 
    discretion to decide whether CMRS providers should be treated as LECs 
    under the new Act. Similarly, section 253(f) permits the states to 
    impose certain obligations on ``telecommunications carrier[s] that 
    seek[ ] to provide telephone exchange service'' in rural areas. The 
    provision further provides that ``[t]his subsection shall not apply * * 
    * to a provider of commercial mobile services.'' It would have been 
    unnecessary for the statute to include this exception if some CMRS were 
    not telephone exchange service. Similarly, section 271(c)(1)(A), which 
    sets forth conditions for determining the presence of a facilities-
    based competitor for purposes of BOC applications to provide in-region, 
    interLATA services, provides that Part 22 [cellular] services ``shall 
    not be considered to be telephone exchange services,'' for purposes of 
    that section. Again, if Congress did not believe that cellular 
    providers were engaged in the provision of telephone exchange service, 
    it would not have
    
    [[Page 45576]]
    
    been necessary to exclude cellular providers from this provision.
        677. The arguments that CMRS traffic flows may differ from wireline 
    traffic, that CMRS providers' termination costs may differ from LECs, 
    that CMRS service areas do not coincide with wireline local exchange 
    areas, or that CMRS providers are not LECs, do not alter our conclusion 
    that cellular, broadband PCS, and covered SMR licensees provide 
    telephone exchange service. These considerations are not relevant to 
    the statutory definition of telephone exchange service in section 
    3(47). Incumbent LECs are required to provide interconnection to CMRS 
    providers who request it for the transmission and routing of telephone 
    exchange service or exchange access, under the plain language of 
    section 251(c)(2).
    
    D. Jurisdictional Authority for Regulation of LEC-CMRS Interconnection 
    Rates
    
    1. Background
        678. In the NPRM, we sought comment on the relationship between 
    section 251 and section 332(c). As noted above, we hereby incorporate 
    by reference the comments filed in CC Docket No. 95-185 to the extent 
    relevant to our analysis. In the NPRM, we noted that we had previously 
    sought comment on the relationship of these two statutory provisions in 
    the LEC-CMRS Interconnection proceeding. In the LEC-CMRS proceeding, we 
    tentatively concluded that the Commission has sufficient authority to 
    promulgate specific federal requirements for interstate and intrastate 
    LEC-CMRS interconnection arrangements, including the adoption of a 
    specific interim bill and keep arrangement. However, we reached that 
    tentative conclusion before the enactment of the 1996 Act.
    2. Discussion
        679. Several parties in this proceeding argue that sections 251 and 
    252 provide the exclusive jurisdictional basis for regulation of LEC-
    CMRS interconnection rates. Other parties assert that sections 332 and 
    201 provide the exclusive jurisdictional basis for regulation of LEC-
    CMRS interconnection rates. Some parties have argued that jurisdiction 
    resides concurrently under sections 251 and 252, on the one hand, and 
    under sections 332 and 201 on the other.
        680. Sections 251, 252, 332 and 201 are designed to achieve the 
    common goal of establishing interconnection and ensuring 
    interconnection on terms and conditions that are just, reasonable, and 
    fair. It is consistent with the broad authority of these provisions to 
    hold that we may apply sections 251 and 252 to LEC-CMRS 
    interconnection. By opting to proceed under sections 251 and 252, we 
    are not finding that section 332 jurisdiction over interconnection has 
    been repealed by implication, or rejecting it as an alternative basis 
    for jurisdiction. We acknowledge that section 332 in tandem with 
    section 201 is a basis for jurisdiction over LEC-CMRS interconnection; 
    we simply decline to define the precise extent of that jurisdiction at 
    this time.
        681. As a practical matter, sections 251 and 252 create a time-
    limited negotiation and arbitration process to ensure that 
    interconnection agreements will be reached between incumbent LECs and 
    telecommunications carriers, including CMRS providers. We expect that 
    our establishment of pricing methodologies and default proxies which 
    may be used as interim rates will help expedite the parties' 
    negotiations and drive voluntary CMRS-LEC interconnection agreements. 
    We also believe that sections 251 and 252 will foster regulatory parity 
    in that these provisions establish a uniform regulatory scheme 
    governing interconnection between incumbent LECs and all requesting 
    carriers, including CMRS providers. Thus, we believe that sections 251 
    and 252 will facilitate consistent resolution of interconnection issues 
    for CMRS providers and other carriers requesting interconnection.
        682. Although we are applying sections 251 and 252 to LEC-CMRS 
    interconnection at this time, we preserve the option to revisit this 
    determination in the future. We note that Section 332 generally 
    precludes states from rate and entry regulation of CMRS providers, and 
    thus, differentiates CMRS providers from other carriers. In passing 
    section 332 in 1993, Congress stated that it intended to ``foster the 
    growth and development of mobile services that, by their nature, 
    operate without regard to state lines as an integral part of the 
    national telecommunications infrastructure.'' H.R. Report No. 103-11, 
    103d. Cong., 1st Sess. 260 (1993). We also recognize that, based on the 
    combined record in CC Docket No. 95-185 and CC Docket No. 96-68, there 
    have been instances in which state commissions have treated CMRS 
    providers in a discriminatory manner with respect to the terms and 
    conditions of interconnection. Should the Commission determine that the 
    regulatory scheme established by sections 251 and 252 does not 
    sufficiently address the problems encountered by CMRS providers in 
    obtaining interconnection on terms and conditions that are just, 
    reasonable and nondiscriminatory, the Commission may revisit its 
    determination not to invoke jurisdiction under section 332 to regulate 
    LEC-CMRS interconnection rates.
        683. Our decision to proceed under section 251 as a basis for 
    regulating LEC-CMRS interconnection rates should not be interpreted as 
    undercutting our intent to enforce Section 332(c)(3), for example, 
    where state regulation of interconnection rates might constitute 
    regulation of CMRS entry. In such situations, state action might be 
    precluded by either section 332 or section 253. Such circumstances 
    would require a case-by-case evaluation. We note, however, that we are 
    aware of numerous specific state requirements that may constitute CMRS 
    entry or rate regulation preempted by section 332. For example, many 
    states, such as California, require all telecommunications providers to 
    certify that the public convenience and necessity will be served as a 
    precondition to construction and operation of telecommunications 
    services within the state. CAL. PUBLIC UTILITIES CODE Sections 
    1001,1005 (West 1995); ALASKA STAT. Section 42.05221 (1995); CONN. GEN. 
    STAT. Section 16-247g (1995); HAW. REV. STAT. Section 269-7.5 (1995); 
    NEB. REV. STAT. Section 86-805 (1995); N.M. STAT. ANN. Section 63-9B-4 
    (Michie 1996). Some states, such as Alaska and Connecticut, also 
    require CMRS providers to certify as service providers other than CMRS 
    in order to obtain the same treatment afforded other telecommunications 
    providers under state law. See In the Matter of Motion for a 
    Declaratory Ruling Concerning Preemption of Alaska Call Routing and 
    Interexchange Certification Regulation as Applies to Cellular Carriers, 
    File No. WTB/POL 95-2, Motion for a Declaratory Ruling, Alaska-3 
    Cellular d/b/a CellularOne, p.5, para. 11 (filed Sept. 22, 1995); 
    Decision, Investigation Into Wireless Mutual Compensation Plans, State 
    of Connecticut, Department of Public Utility control, at 15 
    (Connecticut Commission Sept. 22, 1995). Hawaii and Louisiana, in 
    addition to imposing a certification requirement, require CMRS 
    providers and other telecommunications carriers to file tariffs with 
    the state commission. HAW. REV. STAT. Section 6-80-29 (1996); see In re 
    Regulations for Competition in the Local Telecommunications Market, 
    General
    
    [[Page 45577]]
    
    Order, Louisiana Public Service Commission, Secs. 301, 401 (Louisiana 
    Commission March 15, 1996). We will not permit entry regulation through 
    the exercise of states' sections 251/252 authority or otherwise. In 
    this regard, we note that states may not impose on CMRS carriers rate 
    and entry regulation as a pre-condition to participation in 
    interconnection agreements that may be negotiated and arbitrated 
    pursuant to sections 251 and 252. We further note that the Commission 
    is reviewing filings made pursuant to section 253 alleging that 
    particular states or local governments have requirements that 
    constitute entry barriers, in violation of section 253. We will 
    continue to review any allegations on an ongoing basis, including any 
    claims that states or local governments are regulating entry or 
    imposing requirements on CMRS providers that constitute barriers to 
    market entry.
    
    XI. Obligations Imposed on LECs by Section 251(b)
    
    A. Reciprocal Compensation for Transport and Termination of 
    Telecommunications
    
    1. Statutory Language
        684. Section 251(b)(5) provides that all LECs, including incumbent 
    LECs, have the duty to ``establish reciprocal compensation arrangements 
    for the transport and termination of telecommunications.'' Section 
    252(d)(2) states that, for the purpose of compliance by an incumbent 
    LEC with section 251(b)(5), a state commission shall not consider the 
    terms and conditions for reciprocal compensation to be just and 
    reasonable unless such terms and conditions both: (1) provide for the 
    ``mutual and reciprocal recovery by each carrier of costs associated 
    with the transport and termination on each carrier's network facilities 
    of calls that originate on the network facilities of the other 
    carrier,'' and (2) ``determine such costs on the basis of a reasonable 
    approximation of the additional costs of terminating such calls.'' That 
    subsection further provides that the foregoing language shall not be 
    construed ``to preclude arrangements that afford the mutual recovery of 
    costs through the offsetting of reciprocal obligations, including 
    arrangements that waive mutual recovery (such as bill and keep 
    arrangements),'' or to authorize the Commission or any state to 
    ``engage in any rate regulation proceeding to establish with 
    particularity the additional costs of transporting or terminating 
    calls, or require carriers to maintain records with respect to the 
    additional costs of such calls.'' The legislative history indicates 
    that ``mutual and reciprocal recovery of costs * * * may include a 
    range of compensation schemes, such as in-kind exchange of traffic 
    without cash payment (known as bill-and-keep arrangements).''
    2. Definition of Transport and Termination of Telecommunications
    a. Background
        685. In the NPRM, we sought comment on whether ``transport and 
    termination of telecommunications'' under section 251(b)(5) is limited 
    to certain types of traffic. We noted that the statutory provision 
    appears to encompass telecommunications traffic that originates on the 
    network of one LEC and terminates on the network of a competing 
    provider in the same local service area as well as traffic passing 
    between LECs and CMRS providers. We sought comment on whether section 
    251(b)(5) also encompasses telecommunications traffic passing between 
    neighboring LECs that do not compete with one another. We also observed 
    in the NPRM that section 252(d)(2) is entitled ``Charges for Transport 
    and Termination of Traffic,'' and it could be interpreted to permit 
    separate charges for these two components of reciprocal compensation. 
    We sought comment on this issue.
    b. Discussion
    (1) Distinction Between ``Transport and Termination'' and Access
        686. We recognize that transport and termination of traffic, 
    whether it originates locally or from a distant exchange, involves the 
    same network functions. Ultimately, we believe that the rates that 
    local carriers impose for the transport and termination of local 
    traffic and for the transport and termination of long distance traffic 
    should converge. We conclude, however, as a legal matter, that 
    transport and termination of local traffic are different services than 
    access service for long distance telecommunications. Transport and 
    termination of local traffic for purposes of reciprocal compensation 
    are governed by sections 251(b)(5) and 252(d)(2), while access charges 
    for interstate long-distance traffic are governed by sections 201 and 
    202 of the Act. The Act preserves the legal distinctions between 
    charges for transport and termination of local traffic and interstate 
    and intrastate charges for terminating long-distance traffic.
        687. We conclude that section 251(b)(5) reciprocal compensation 
    obligations should apply only to traffic that originates and terminates 
    within a local area, as defined in the following paragraph. We disagree 
    with Frontier's contention that section 251(b)(5) entitles an IXC to 
    receive reciprocal compensation from a LEC when a long-distance call is 
    passed from the LEC serving the caller to the IXC. Access charges were 
    developed to address a situation in which three carriers--typically, 
    the originating LEC, the IXC, and the terminating LEC--collaborate to 
    complete a long-distance call. As a general matter, in the access 
    charge regime, the long-distance caller pays long-distance charges to 
    the IXC, and the IXC must pay both LECs for originating and terminating 
    access service. In addition, both the caller and the party receiving 
    the call pay a flat-rated interstate access charge--the end-user common 
    line charge--to the respective incumbent LEC to whose network each of 
    these parties is connected. By contrast, reciprocal compensation for 
    transport and termination of calls is intended for a situation in which 
    two carriers collaborate to complete a local call. In this case, the 
    local caller pays charges to the originating carrier, and the 
    originating carrier must compensate the terminating carrier for 
    completing the call. This reading of the statute is confirmed by 
    section 252(d)(2)(A)(i), which establishes the pricing standards for 
    section 251(b)(5). Section 251(d)(2)(A)(i) provides for ``recovery by 
    each carrier of costs associated with the transport and termination on 
    each carrier's network facilities of calls that originate on the 
    network facilities of the other carrier.'' We note that our conclusion 
    that long distance traffic is not subject to the transport and 
    termination provisions of section 251 does not in any way disrupt the 
    ability of IXCs to terminate their interstate long-distance traffic on 
    LEC networks. Pursuant to section 251(g), LECs must continue to offer 
    tariffed interstate access services just as they did prior to enactment 
    of the 1996 Act. We find that the reciprocal compensation provisions of 
    section 251(b)(5) for transport and termination of traffic do not apply 
    to the transport or termination of interstate or intrastate 
    interexchange traffic.
        688. With the exception of traffic to or from a CMRS network, state 
    commissions have the authority to determine what geographic areas 
    should be considered ``local areas'' for the purpose of applying 
    reciprocal compensation obligations under section 251(b)(5), consistent 
    with the state commissions' historical practice of defining local 
    service areas for wireline LECs. Traffic originating or terminating
    
    [[Page 45578]]
    
    outside of the applicable local area would be subject to interstate and 
    intrastate access charges. We expect the states to determine whether 
    intrastate transport and termination of traffic between competing LECs, 
    where a portion of their local service areas are not the same, should 
    be governed by section 251(b)(5)'s reciprocal compensation obligations 
    or whether intrastate access charges should apply to the portions of 
    their local service areas that are different. This approach is 
    consistent with a recently negotiated interconnection agreement between 
    Ameritech and ICG that restricted reciprocal compensation arrangements 
    to the local traffic area as defined by the state commission. 
    Continental Cablevision, in an ex parte letter, states that many 
    incumbent LECs offer optional expanded local area calling plans, in 
    which customers may pay an additional flat rate charge for calls within 
    a wider area than that deemed as local, but that terminating intrastate 
    access charges typically apply to calls that originate from competing 
    carriers in the same wider area. Continental Cablevision argues that 
    local transport and termination rates should apply to these calls. We 
    lack sufficient record information to address the issue of expanded 
    local area calling plans; we expect that this issue will be considered, 
    in the first instance, by state commissions. In addition, we expect the 
    states to decide whether section 251(b)(5) reciprocal compensation 
    provisions apply to the exchange of traffic between incumbent LECs that 
    serve adjacent service areas.
        689. On the other hand, in light of this Commission's exclusive 
    authority to define the authorized license areas of wireless carriers, 
    we will define the local service area for calls to or from a CMRS 
    network for the purposes of applying reciprocal compensation 
    obligations under section 251(b)(5). Different types of wireless 
    carriers have different FCC-authorized licensed territories, the 
    largest of which is the ``Major Trading Area'' (MTA). See Rand McNally, 
    Inc., 1992 Commercial Atlas & Marketing Guide 38-39 (1992). Because 
    wireless licensed territories are federally authorized, and vary in 
    size, we conclude that the largest FCC-authorized wireless license 
    territory (i.e., MTA) serves as the most appropriate definition for 
    local service area for CMRS traffic for purposes of reciprocal 
    compensation under section 251(b)(5) as it avoids creating artificial 
    distinctions between CMRS providers. Accordingly, traffic to or from a 
    CMRS network that originates and terminates within the same MTA is 
    subject to transport and termination rates under section 251(b)(5), 
    rather than interstate and intrastate access charges.
        690. We conclude that section 251(b)(5) obligations apply to all 
    LECs in the same state-defined local exchange service areas, including 
    neighboring incumbent LECs that fit within this description. Contrary 
    to the arguments of NYNEX and Pacific Telesis, neither the plain 
    language of the Act nor its legislative history limits this subsection 
    to the transport and termination of telecommunications traffic between 
    new entrants and incumbent LECs. In addition, applying section 
    251(b)(5) obligations to neighboring incumbent LECs in the same local 
    exchange area is consistent with our decision that all interconnection 
    agreements, including agreements between neighboring LECs, must be 
    submitted to state commissions for approval pursuant to section 252(e).
        691. Under section 252, neighboring states may establish different 
    rate levels for transport and termination of traffic. In cases in which 
    territory in multiple states is included in a single local service 
    area, and a local call from one carrier to another crosses state lines, 
    we conclude that the applicable rate for any particular call should be 
    that established by the state in which the call terminates. This 
    provides an administratively convenient rule, and termination of the 
    call typically occurs in the same state where the terminating carrier's 
    end office switch is located and where the cost of terminating the call 
    is incurred.
     (2) Distinction Between ``Transport'' and ``Termination''
        692. We conclude that transport and termination should be treated 
    as two distinct functions. We define ``transport,'' for purposes of 
    section 251(b)(5), as the transmission of terminating traffic that is 
    subject to section 251(b)(5) from the interconnection point between the 
    two carriers to the terminating carrier's end office switch that 
    directly serves the called party (or equivalent facility provided by a 
    non-incumbent carrier). Many alternative arrangements exist for the 
    provision of transport between the two networks. These arrangements 
    include: dedicated circuits provided either by the incumbent LEC, the 
    other local service provider, separately by each, or jointly by both; 
    facilities provided by alternative carriers; unbundled network elements 
    provided by incumbent LECs; or similar network functions currently 
    offered by incumbent LECs on a tariffed basis. Charges for transport 
    subject to section 251(b)(5) should reflect the forward-looking cost of 
    the particular provisioning method.
        693. We define ``termination,'' for purposes of section 251(b)(5), 
    as the switching of traffic that is subject to section 251(b)(5) at the 
    terminating carrier's end office switch (or equivalent facility) and 
    delivery of that traffic from that switch to the called party's 
    premises. In contrast to transport, for which some alternatives exist, 
    alternatives for termination are not likely to exist in the near term. 
    A carrier or provider typically has no other mechanism for delivering 
    traffic to a called party served by another carrier except by having 
    that called party's carrier terminate the call. In addition, forward-
    looking costs are calculated differently for the transport of traffic 
    and the termination of traffic, as discussed above in the unbundled 
    elements section. As such, we conclude that we need to treat transport 
    and termination as separate functions--each with its own cost. With 
    respect to GST's contention that separate charges for transport and 
    termination of traffic will allow incumbent LECs to ``game'' the system 
    through network design decisions, we conclude in the interconnection 
    section above that interconnecting carriers may interconnect at any 
    technically feasible point. We find that this sufficiently limits LECs' 
    ability to disadvantage interconnecting parties through their network 
    design decisions.
    (3) CMRS-Related Issues
        694. Section 251(b)(5) obligates LECs to establish reciprocal 
    compensation arrangements for the transport and termination of 
    telecommunications traffic. Although section 252(b)(5) does not 
    explicitly state to whom the LEC's obligation runs, we find that LECs 
    have a duty to establish reciprocal compensation arrangements with 
    respect to local traffic originated by or terminating to any 
    telecommunications carriers. CMRS providers are telecommunications 
    carriers and, thus, LECs' reciprocal compensation obligations under 
    section 251(b)(5) apply to all local traffic transmitted between LECs 
    and CMRS providers.
        695. We conclude that, pursuant to section 251(b)(5), a LEC may not 
    charge a CMRS provider or other carrier for terminating LEC-originated 
    traffic. Section 251(b)(5) specifies that LECs and interconnecting 
    carriers shall compensate one another for termination of traffic on a 
    reciprocal basis. This section does not address charges payable to a 
    carrier that originates traffic. We therefore conclude that
    
    [[Page 45579]]
    
    section 251(b)(5) prohibits charges such as those some incumbent LECs 
    currently impose on CMRS providers for LEC-originated traffic. As of 
    the effective date of this order, a LEC must cease charging a CMRS 
    provider or other carrier for terminating LEC-originated traffic and 
    must provide that traffic to the CMRS provider or other carrier without 
    charge.
        696. As noted above, CMRS providers' license areas are established 
    under federal rules, and in many cases are larger than the local 
    exchange service areas that state commissions have established for 
    incumbent LECs' local service areas. We reiterate that traffic between 
    an incumbent LEC and a CMRS network that originates and terminates 
    within the same MTA (defined based on the parties' locations at the 
    beginning of the call) is subject to transport and termination rates 
    under section 251(b)(5), rather than interstate or intrastate access 
    charges. Under our existing practice, most traffic between LECs and 
    CMRS providers is not subject to interstate access charges unless it is 
    carried by an IXC, with the exception of certain interstate 
    interexchange service provided by CMRS carriers, such as some 
    ``roaming'' traffic that transits incumbent LECs' switching facilities, 
    which is subject to interstate access charges. ``[S]ome cellular 
    carriers provide their customers with a service whereby a call to a 
    subscriber's local cellular number will be routed to them over 
    interstate facilities when the customer is ``roaming'' in a cellular 
    system in another state. In this case, the cellular carrier is 
    providing not local exchange service but interstate, interexchange 
    service. In this and other situations where a cellular company is 
    offering interstate, interexchange service, the local telephone company 
    providing interconnection is providing exchange access to an 
    interexchange carrier and may expect to be paid the appropriate access 
    charge. * * * Therefore, to the extent that a cellular operator does 
    provide interexchange service through switching facilities provided by 
    a telephone company, its obligation to pay carrier's carrier [i.e., 
    access] charges is defined by Sec. 69.5(b) of our rules.'' See 
    Regulatory Treatment of Mobile Services Second Report and Order, 59 FR 
    18493 (April 19, 1994). Based on our authority under section 251(g) to 
    preserve the current interstate access charge regime, we conclude that 
    the new transport and termination rules should be applied to LECs and 
    CMRS providers so that CMRS providers continue not to pay interstate 
    access charges for traffic that currently is not subject to such 
    charges, and are assessed such charges for traffic that is currently 
    subject to interstate access charges.
        697. CMRS customers may travel from location to location during the 
    course of a single call, which could make it difficult to determine the 
    applicable transport and termination rate or access charge. In the LEC-
    CMRS Interconnection NPRM, we observed that a significant amount of 
    LEC-CMRS traffic crosses state lines, because CMRS service areas often 
    cross state lines and CMRS customers are mobile. LEC-CMRS 
    Interconnection NPRM, 61 FR 3644 (February 1, 1996). We recognize that, 
    using current technology, it may be difficult for CMRS providers to 
    determine, in real time, which cell site a mobile customer is connected 
    to, let alone the customer's specific geographic location. Enhanced 911 
    Emergency Calling Systems Report and Order and Further NPRM, 61 FR 
    40374 (August 2, 1996). This could complicate the computation of 
    traffic flows and the applicability of transport and termination rates, 
    given that in certain cases, the geographic locations of the calling 
    party and the called party determine whether a particular call should 
    be compensated under transport and termination rates established by one 
    state or another, or under interstate or intrastate access charges. We 
    conclude, however, that it is not necessary for incumbent LECs and CMRS 
    providers to be able to ascertain geographic locations when determining 
    the rating for any particular call at the moment the call is connected. 
    We conclude that parties may calculate overall compensation amounts by 
    extrapolating from traffic studies and samples. For administrative 
    convenience, the location of the initial cell site when a call begins 
    shall be used as the determinant of the geographic location of the 
    mobile customer. As an alternative, LECs and CMRS providers can use the 
    point of interconnection between the two carriers at the beginning of 
    the call to determine the location of the mobile caller or called 
    party.
        698. As discussed above, pursuant to section 251(b)(5) of the Act, 
    all local exchange carriers, including small incumbent LECs and small 
    entities offering competitive local exchange services, have a duty to 
    establish reciprocal compensation arrangements for the transport and 
    termination of local exchange service. CMRS providers, including small 
    entities, and LECs, including small incumbent LECs and small entity 
    competitive LECs, will receive reciprocal compensation for terminating 
    certain traffic that originates on the networks of other carriers, and 
    will pay such compensation for certain traffic that they transmit and 
    terminate to other carriers. We believe that these arrangements should 
    benefit all carriers, including small incumbent LECs and small 
    entities, because it will facilitate competitive entry into new markets 
    while ensuring reasonable compensation for the additional costs 
    incurred in terminating traffic that originates on other carriers' 
    networks. We also recognize that, to implement transport and 
    termination pursuant to section 251(b)(5), carriers, including small 
    incumbent LECs and small entities, may be required to measure the 
    exchange of traffic, but we believe that the cost of such measurement 
    to these carriers is likely to be substantially outweighed by the 
    benefits of these arrangements.
    3. Pricing Methodology
    a. Background
        699. In the NPRM, we sought comment on how to interpret section 
    252(d)(2) of the Act. Specifically, we asked if we should establish a 
    generic pricing methodology or impose a ceiling to guide the states in 
    setting the charge for the transport and termination of traffic. We 
    also asked whether such a generic pricing methodology or ceiling should 
    be established using the same principles we adopt for interconnection 
    and unbundled elements. Additionally, we sought comment on the use of 
    an interim and transitional pricing mechanism that would address 
    concerns about unequal bargaining power in negotiations.
    b. Discussion
    (1) Statutory Standard
        700. We conclude that the pricing standards established by section 
    252(d)(1) for interconnection and unbundled elements, and by section 
    252(d)(2) for transport and termination of traffic, are sufficiently 
    similar to permit the use of the same general methodologies for 
    establishing rates under both statutory provisions. Section 252(d)(2) 
    states that reciprocal compensation rates for transport and termination 
    shall be based on ``a reasonable approximation of the additional costs 
    of terminating such calls.'' Moreover, there is some substitutability 
    between the new entrant's use of unbundled network elements for 
    transporting traffic and its use of transport under section 252(d)(2). 
    Depending on the interconnection arrangements, carriers may transport 
    traffic to the competing carriers' end offices or hand traffic off to 
    competing carriers at meet points for termination
    
    [[Page 45580]]
    
    on the competing carriers' networks. Transport of traffic for 
    termination on a competing carrier's network is, therefore, largely 
    indistinguishable from transport for termination of calls on a 
    carrier's own network. Thus, we conclude that transport of traffic 
    should be priced based on the same cost-based standard, whether it is 
    transport using unbundled elements or transport of traffic that 
    originated on a competing carrier's network. We, therefore, find that 
    the ``additional cost'' standard permits the use of the forward-
    looking, economic cost-based pricing standard that we are establishing 
    for interconnection and unbundled elements.
    (2) Pricing Rule
        701. States have three options for establishing transport and 
    termination rate levels. A state commission may conduct a thorough 
    review of economic studies prepared using the TELRIC-based methodology 
    outlined above in the section on the pricing of interconnection and 
    unbundled elements. Alternatively, the state may adopt a default price 
    pursuant to the default proxies outlined below. If the state adopts a 
    default price, it must either commence review of a TELRIC-based 
    economic cost study, request that this Commission review such a study, 
    or subsequently modify the default price in accordance with any revised 
    proxies we may adopt. As previously noted, we intend to commence a 
    future rulemaking on developing proxies using a generic cost model, and 
    to complete such proceeding in the first quarter of 1997. As a third 
    alternative, in some circumstances states may order a ``bill and keep'' 
    arrangement, as discussed below.
    (3) Cost-Based Pricing Methodology
        702. Consistent with our conclusions about the pricing of 
    interconnection and unbundled network elements, we conclude that states 
    that elect to set rates through a cost study must use the forward-
    looking economic cost-based methodology, which is described in greater 
    detail above, in establishing rates for reciprocal transport and 
    termination when arbitrating interconnection arrangements. We find that 
    section 252(d)(2)(B)(ii), which indicates that section 252(d)(2) shall 
    not be construed to ``authorize the Commission or any State to engage 
    in any rate regulation proceeding to establish with particularity the 
    additional costs of transporting or terminating calls,'' does not 
    preclude states or this Commission from reviewing forward-looking 
    economic cost studies. First, we believe that Congress intended the 
    term ``rate regulation proceeding'' in section 252(d)(2)(B)(ii) to mean 
    the same thing as ``a rate-of-return or other rate-based proceeding'' 
    in section 252(d)(1)(A)(i). In the section on the pricing of 
    interconnection and unbundled elements above, we conclude that the 
    statutory prohibition of the use of such proceedings is intended to 
    foreclose the use of traditional rate case proceedings using rate-of-
    return regulation. Moreover, forward-looking economic cost studies 
    typically involve ``a reasonable approximation of the additional 
    cost,'' rather than determining such costs ``with particularity,'' such 
    as by measuring labor costs with detailed time and motion studies.
        703. We find that, once a call has been delivered to the incumbent 
    LEC end office serving the called party, the ``additional cost'' to the 
    LEC of terminating a call that originates on a competing carrier's 
    network primarily consists of the traffic-sensitive component of local 
    switching. The network elements involved with the termination of 
    traffic include the end-office switch and local loop. The costs of 
    local loops and line ports associated with local switches do not vary 
    in proportion to the number of calls terminated over these facilities. 
    The duty to terminate calls that originate on the network of a 
    competitor does not directly affect the number of calls routed to a 
    particular end user and any costs that result from inadequate loop 
    capacity are, therefore, not considered ``additional costs.'' We 
    conclude that such non-traffic sensitive costs should not be considered 
    ``additional costs'' when a LEC terminates a call that originated on 
    the network of a competing carrier. For the purposes of setting rates 
    under section 252(d)(2), only that portion of the forward-looking, 
    economic cost of end-office switching that is recovered on a usage-
    sensitive basis constitutes an ``additional cost'' to be recovered 
    through termination charges.
        704. Rates for termination established pursuant to a TELRIC-based 
    methodology may recover a reasonable allocation of common costs. A rate 
    equal to incremental costs may not compensate carriers fully for 
    transporting and terminating traffic when common costs are present. We 
    therefore reject the argument by some commenters that ``additional 
    costs'' may not include a reasonable allocation of forward-looking 
    common costs. We recognize that, as noted by Time Warner, call 
    termination is an essential element in completing calls because 
    competitors are required to use the incumbent LECs' existing networks 
    to terminate calls to incumbent LEC customers. The 1996 Act envisions a 
    seamless interconnection of competing networks, rather than the 
    development of redundant, ubiquitous networks throughout the nation. In 
    order to terminate traffic ubiquitously to other companies' local 
    customers, all LECs are given the right to use termination services 
    from those companies rather than construct facilities to everyone. 
    While, on the originating end, carriers have different options to reach 
    their revenue-paying customers--including their own network facilities, 
    purchasing access to unbundled elements of the incumbent LEC, or 
    resale--they have no realistic alternatives for terminating traffic 
    destined for competing carriers' subscribers other than to use those 
    carriers' networks. Thus, all carriers--incumbent LECs as well as 
    competing carriers--have a greater incentive and opportunity to charge 
    prices in excess of economically efficient levels on the terminating 
    end. To ensure that rates for reciprocal compensation make possible 
    efficient competitive entry, we conclude that termination rates should 
    include an allocation of forward-looking common costs that is no 
    greater proportionally than that allocated to unbundled local loops, 
    which, as discussed above, should be relatively low. Additionally, we 
    conclude that rates for the transport and termination of traffic shall 
    not include an element that allows incumbent LECs to recover any lost 
    contribution to basic, local service rates represented by the 
    interconnecting carriers' service, because such an element would be 
    inconsistent with the statutory requirement that rates for transport 
    and termination be based on additional costs. In the section addressing 
    prices for unbundled elements we conclude that the ECPR, which would 
    allow incumbent LECs to recover such lost contributions, or collection 
    of universal service costs through interconnection rates, leads to 
    significant distortions in markets when existing retail prices are not 
    cost-based.
        705. We also address the impact on small incumbent LECs. For 
    example, the Western Alliance argues that it is especially important 
    for small LECs to recover lost contributions and common costs through 
    termination charges. We have considered the economic impact of our 
    rules in this section on small incumbent LECs. For example, we conclude 
    that termination rates for all LECs should include an allocation of 
    forward-looking common costs, but find that the inclusion of an element 
    for the
    
    [[Page 45581]]
    
    recovery of lost contribution may lead to significant distortions in 
    local exchange markets. We also note that certain small incumbent LECs 
    are not subject to our rules under section 251(f)(1) of the 1996 Act, 
    unless otherwise determined by a state commission, and certain other 
    small incumbent LECs may seek relief from their state commissions from 
    our rules under section 251(f)(2) of the 1996 Act.
    (4) Default Proxies
        706. As with unbundled network elements, we recognize that it may 
    not be feasible for some state commissions conducting or reviewing 
    economic studies to establish transport and termination rates using our 
    TELRIC-based pricing methodology within the time required for the 
    arbitration process, particularly given some states' resource 
    limitations. Thus, for the time being, we adopt a default price range 
    of 0.2 cents ($0.002) to 0.4 cents ($0.004) per minute of use for calls 
    handed off at the end-office switch. This default price range is based 
    on the same proxies that apply to local switching as an unbundled 
    network element. In establishing end-office termination rates, states 
    may adopt a default termination price that is within our default price 
    range or at either of the end points of the range. States should 
    articulate the basis for selecting a particular price within this 
    range. Thus, in arbitration proceedings, states must set the price for 
    end office termination of traffic by: (1) using a forward-looking, 
    economic cost study that complies with the forward-looking, economic-
    cost methodology set forth above; or (2) adopting a price less than or 
    equal to 0.4 cents ($0.004) per minute, and greater than or equal to 
    0.2 cents ($0.002) per minute, pending the completion of such a 
    forward-looking, economic cost study. We observe that the most credible 
    studies in the record before us fall at the lower end of this range, 
    and we encourage states to consider such evidence in their analysis. 
    The adoption of a range of rates to serve as a default price range for 
    interconnection agreements being arbitrated by the states provides 
    carriers with a clearer understanding of the terms and conditions that 
    will govern them if they fail to reach an agreement and helps to reduce 
    the transaction costs of arbitration and litigation. We also find that 
    states that have already adopted end-office termination rates based on 
    an approach other than a full forward-looking cost study, either 
    through arbitration or rulemaking proceedings, may keep such rates in 
    effect, pending their review of a forward-looking cost study, as long 
    as they do not exceed 0.5 cents ($0.005) per minute. As discussed 
    below, a state may also order a ``bill and keep'' arrangement subject 
    to certain limitations. Additionally, our adoption of a default price 
    range temporarily relieves small and mid-sized carriers from the burden 
    of conducting forward-looking economic cost studies.
        707. Similarly, in establishing transport rates under sections 
    251(b)(5) and 252(d)(2), state commissions should be guided by the 
    price proxies that we are establishing for unbundled transport elements 
    discussed above. States should explain the basis for selecting a 
    particular default price subject to the applicable ceiling. 
    Specifically, when interconnecting carriers hand off traffic at an 
    incumbent LEC's tandem switch (or equivalent facilities of a carrier 
    other than an incumbent LEC), the rates for the tandem switching and 
    transmission from the tandem switch to end offices--a portion of the 
    ``transport'' component of transport and termination rates-- should be 
    subject to the proxies that apply to the analogous unbundled network 
    elements. Thus, for the time being, when states set rates for tandem 
    switching under section 252(d)(2), they may set a default price at or 
    below the default price ceiling that applies to the tandem switching 
    unbundled element as an alternative to reviewing a forward-looking 
    economic cost study using our TELRIC methodology. Similarly, when 
    states set rates for transmission facilities between tandem switches 
    and end offices, they may establish rates equal to the default prices 
    we are adopting for such transmission, as discussed above in the 
    section on unbundled elements.
        708. Finally, in establishing the rates for transmission facilities 
    that are dedicated to the transmission of traffic between two networks, 
    state commissions should be guided by the default price level we are 
    adopting for the unbundled element of dedicated transport. For such 
    dedicated transport, we can envision several scenarios involving a 
    local carrier that provides transmission facilities (the ``providing 
    carrier'') and another local carrier with which it interconnects (the 
    ``interconnecting carrier''). The amount an interconnecting carrier 
    pays for dedicated transport is to be proportional to its relative use 
    of the dedicated facility. For example, if the providing carrier 
    provides one-way trunks that the interconnecting carrier uses 
    exclusively for sending terminating traffic to the providing carrier, 
    then the interconnecting carrier is to pay the providing carrier a rate 
    that recovers the full forward-looking economic cost of those trunks. 
    The interconnecting carrier, however, should not be required to pay the 
    providing carrier for one-way trunks in the opposite direction, which 
    the providing carrier owns and uses to send its own traffic to the 
    interconnecting carrier. Under an alternative scenario, if the 
    providing carrier provides two-way trunks between its network and the 
    interconnecting carrier's network, then the interconnecting carrier 
    should not have to pay the providing carrier a rate that recovers the 
    full cost of those trunks. These two-way trunks are used by the 
    providing carrier to send terminating traffic to the interconnecting 
    carrier, as well as by the interconnecting carrier to send terminating 
    traffic to the providing carrier. Rather, the interconnecting carrier 
    shall pay the providing carrier a rate that reflects only the 
    proportion of the trunk capacity that the interconnecting carrier uses 
    to send terminating traffic to the providing carrier. This proportion 
    may be measured either based on the total flow of traffic over the 
    trunks, or based on the flow of traffic during peak periods. Carriers 
    operating under arrangements which do not comport with the principles 
    we have set forth above, shall be entitled to convert such arrangements 
    so that each carrier is only paying for the transport of traffic it 
    originates, as of the effective date of this order.
    (5) Rate Structure
        709. Nearly all commenters agree that flat rates, rather than 
    usage-sensitive rates, should apply to the purchase of dedicated 
    facilities. As discussed in the NPRM, economic efficiency may generally 
    be maximized when non-traffic sensitive services, such as the use of 
    dedicated facilities for the transport of traffic, are priced on a 
    flat-rated basis. We, therefore, require all interconnecting parties to 
    be offered the option of purchasing dedicated facilities, for the 
    transport of traffic, on a flat-rated basis. As discussed by Lincoln 
    Telephone, the connection between an incumbent LEC's end or tandem 
    office and an interconnecting LEC's network is likely to be a dedicated 
    facility. We recognize that the facility itself can be provided in a 
    number of different ways--by use of two service providers, by the other 
    carrier, or jointly in a meet-point arrangement. We conclude first 
    that, no matter what the specific arrangements, these costs should be 
    recovered in a cost-causative manner and that usage-based charges 
    should be limited to situations where costs are usage sensitive. In 
    cases going to arbitration and in reviewing BOC statements of terms and 
    conditions, the
    
    [[Page 45582]]
    
    carrier actually providing the facility should presumptively be 
    entitled to a rate that is set based on the forward-looking economic 
    cost of providing the portion of the facility that is used for 
    terminating traffic that originates on the network of a competing 
    carrier. We recognize that negotiated agreements may incorporate flat-
    rated charges when it is efficient to do so and find that the presence 
    of the arbitration default rule is likely to lead parties to negotiate 
    efficient rate structures.
        710. We recognize that the costs of transporting and terminating 
    traffic during peak and off-peak hours may not be the same. As 
    suggested by the Massachusetts Attorney General, rates that are the 
    same during peak and off-peak hours may not reflect the cost of using 
    the network and could lead to inefficient use of the network. The 
    differences in the cost of transporting and terminating traffic during 
    peak and off-peak hours, however, are likely to vary depending on the 
    network, and the amount and type of traffic terminated at a particular 
    switch. For example, peak periods may vary within a local service area 
    depending upon whether the switch is located in a business or 
    residential area. As a result, there may be administrative difficulties 
    in establishing peak-load pricing schemes that may outweigh the 
    benefits of such schemes. The negotiating parties, however, are likely 
    to be in a position to more accurately determine how traffic patterns 
    will adjust to peak-load pricing schemes and we encourage parties to 
    address such pricing schemes in the negotiation process. For similar 
    reasons, we neither require nor forbid states from adopting rates that 
    reflect peak and off-peak costs. We hope some states will evaluate the 
    benefits and costs of pricing schemes that consist of different rates 
    for peak and off-peak traffic. We do require, however, that peak-load 
    pricing schemes, adopted through the arbitration process, comply with 
    our default price level if not based on a forward-looking cost study 
    (e.g., the average rate, weighted by the projected relative minutes of 
    use during peak and off-peak periods, should fall within our default 
    price range of 0.2 to 0.4 cents or the level determined by an 
    incremental cost study).
    (6) Interim Transport and Termination Rate Levels
        711. We are concerned that some new entrants that do not already 
    have interconnection arrangements with incumbent LECs may face delays 
    in initiating service solely because of the need to negotiate transport 
    and termination arrangements with the incumbent LEC. In particular, a 
    new entrant that has already constructed facilities may have a 
    relatively weak bargaining position because it may be forced to choose 
    either to accept transport and termination rates not in accord with 
    these rules or to delay its commencement of service until the 
    conclusion of the arbitration and state approval process. To promote 
    the Act's goal of rapid competition in the local exchange, we order 
    incumbent LECs upon request from new entrants to provide transport and 
    termination of traffic, on an interim basis, pending resolution of 
    negotiation and arbitration regarding transport and termination prices, 
    and approval by the state commission. A carrier may take advantage of 
    this interim arrangement only after it has requested negotiation with 
    the incumbent LEC. The interim arrangement shall cease to be in effect 
    when one of the following occurs: (1) an agreement has been negotiated 
    and approved; (2) an agreement has been arbitrated and approved; or (3) 
    the period for requesting arbitration has passed with no such request. 
    We also conclude that interim prices for transport and termination 
    shall be symmetrical. Because the purpose of this interim termination 
    requirement is to permit parties without existing interconnection 
    agreements to enter the market expeditiously, this requirement shall 
    not apply with respect to requesting carriers that have existing 
    interconnection arrangements that provide for termination of local 
    traffic by the incumbent LEC. The ability to interconnect with an 
    incumbent LEC prior to the completion of a forward-looking, economic 
    cost study, based on an interim presumptive price ceiling, allows 
    carriers, including small entrants, to enter into local exchange 
    service expeditiously.
        712. In states that have already conducted or reviewed forward-
    looking economic cost studies and promulgated transport and termination 
    rates based on such studies, an incumbent LEC receiving a request for 
    interim transport and termination shall use these state-determined 
    rates as interim transport and termination rates. In states that have 
    not conducted or reviewed a forward-looking economic cost study, but 
    have set rates for transport and termination of traffic consistent with 
    the default price ranges and ceilings discussed above, an incumbent LEC 
    shall use these state-determined rates as interim rates. In states that 
    have neither set rates consistent with the default price ceilings and 
    ranges nor reviewed or conducted forward-looking economic cost studies, 
    we must establish an interim default price in order to facilitate rapid 
    competition in the local exchange market. In those states, an incumbent 
    LEC shall set interim rates at the default ceilings for end-office 
    switching (0.4 cents per minute of use), tandem switching (0.15 cents 
    per minute of use), and transport described above. Using the ceiling as 
    a default interim price, pending a state commission's completion of a 
    forward-looking economic cost analysis, should ensure that both the 
    incumbent LEC and the competing provider recovers no less than their 
    full transport and termination costs. We note, however, that the most 
    credible evidence in the record suggests that the actual forward-
    looking economic cost of end-office switching is closer to 0.2 cents 
    ($0.002) per minute of use than the ceiling of 0.4 cents ($0.004) per 
    minute of use. States must adopt ``true-up'' mechanisms to ensure that 
    no carrier is disadvantaged by an interim rate that differs from the 
    final rate established pursuant to arbitration.
        713. We conclude that section 251, in conjunction with our broad 
    rulemaking authority under section 4(i), provides us with authority to 
    create interim pricing rules to facilitate market entry. Because 
    section 251(d)(1) gives the FCC authority ``to establish regulations to 
    implement the requirements of this section,'' we find that section 
    251(d)(1) gives the Commission authority to establish interim 
    regulations that address the ``just and reasonable'' rates for the 
    ``reciprocal compensation'' requirement of section 251(b)(5), subject 
    to the preservation requirements of section 251(d)(3). Courts have 
    upheld our adoption of interim compensation arrangements pursuant to 
    our authority under section 4(i) of the 1934 Communications Act on 
    numerous occasions in the past. See New England Tel. and Tel. Co. v. 
    FCC, 826 F.2d 1101 (D.C. Cir. 1987); North American Telecommunications 
    Association v. FCC, 772 F.2d 1092 (7th Cir. 1085); Lincoln Tel. and 
    Tel. Co. v. FCC, 659 F.2d (D.C. Cir. 1989). In particular, we have 
    authority, under section 4(i), to set interim rates subject to a later 
    ``true-up'' when final rates are established. ``[T]he Commission's 
    establishment of an interim billing and collection arrangement was both 
    a helpful and necessary step for the Commission to take in implementing 
    its `immediate' interconnection order.'' Lincoln Telephone & Telegraph 
    Co. v. FCC, 659 F.2d 1092, 1107 (D.C. Cir. 1981) (upholding Commission 
    decision requiring an incumbent LEC to interconnect with MCI 
    immediately, in
    
    [[Page 45583]]
    
    order not to delay interconnection, at interim rates subject to later 
    adjustment); see also FTC Communications v. FCC, 750 F.2d 226 (2d Cir. 
    1984) (affirming Commission's authority under Section 4(i) to set 
    interim rates for interconnection between the domestic record carrier, 
    Western Union, and international record carriers, subject to an 
    accounting order, pending the conclusion of a rulemaking to set 
    permanent rates replacing expired, contract-based rates). We therefore 
    conclude that the default prices discussed above need not in all 
    instances await the conclusion of the negotiation, arbitration, and 
    state approval process set forth in section 252, but must nevertheless 
    be in accordance with the requirements of section 251(d)(3) preserving 
    state access regulations. We also observe that we proposed a similar 
    interim transport and termination arrangement, albeit with different 
    rate levels, in our NPRM in the LEC-CMRS Interconnection proceeding. 
    LEC-CMRS Interconnection NPRM, 61 FR 3644 (February 1, 1996).
        714. We have considered the economic impact of our rules in this 
    section on small incumbent LECs. For example, Cincinnati Bell asserts 
    that interim mechanisms are not required because large corporations are 
    not disadvantaged by unequal bargaining power in negotiations with 
    small and mid-size incumbent LECs. We do not adopt Cincinnati Bell's 
    position because some new entrants, regardless of their size, that do 
    not already have interconnection arrangements with incumbent LECs may 
    face delays in initiating service solely because of the need to 
    negotiate transport and termination arrangements with the incumbent 
    LEC. We believe that the adoption of interim rates, subject to a 
    ``true-up,'' advances the pro-competitive goals of the statute. We also 
    note that certain small incumbent LECs are not subject to our rules 
    under section 251(f)(1) of the 1996 Act, unless otherwise determined by 
    a state commission, and certain other small incumbent LECs may seek 
    relief from their state commissions from our rules under section 
    251(f)(2) of the 1996 Act.
    4. Symmetry
    a. Background
        715. Symmetrical compensation arrangements are those in which the 
    rate paid by an incumbent LEC to another telecommunications carrier for 
    transport and termination of traffic originated by the incumbent LEC is 
    the same as the rate the incumbent LEC charges to transport and 
    terminate traffic originated by the other telecommunications carrier. 
    Incumbent LECs are not likely to purchase interconnection or unbundled 
    elements from competitive LECs, except for termination of traffic, and 
    possibly transport. In the NPRM, we sought comment on whether rate 
    symmetry requirements are consistent with the statutory requirement 
    that rates set by states for transport and termination of traffic be 
    based on ``costs associated with the transport and termination on each 
    carrier's network facilities of calls that originate on the network 
    facilities of the other carrier,'' and ``a reasonable approximation of 
    the additional costs of terminating such calls.''
        716. In addition, we noted in the NPRM that the Illinois, Maryland, 
    and New York commissions have established different rates for 
    termination of traffic on an incumbent LEC's network, depending upon 
    whether the traffic is handed off at the incumbent LEC's end office or 
    tandem switch. We also observed that California and Michigan have 
    established one rate that applies to transport and termination of all 
    competing local exchange carrier traffic on incumbent LEC networks, 
    regardless of whether the traffic is handed off at the incumbent LEC's 
    end office or tandem switch, although this rate does not currently 
    apply to CMRS. We, therefore, address whether rates for transport and 
    termination should be symmetrical and consist of only a single rate 
    regardless of where the call is handed off, or if rates should be 
    priced on an element-by-element basis.
        717. In the LEC-CMRS Interconnection NPRM, we sought comment on 
    whether incumbent LECs were utilizing their greater bargaining power to 
    negotiate with wireless carriers interconnection agreements that did 
    not reflect principles of mutual compensation. We sought comment on 
    whether we should institute some procedure or mechanism in addition to 
    our section 208 enforcement process to ensure that incumbent LECs 
    comply with our existing rules requiring mutual compensation. LEC-CMRS 
    Interconnection NPRM, 61 FR 3644 (February 1, 1996).
    b. Discussion
    (1) Symmetry in General
        718. Regardless of whether the incumbent LEC's transport and 
    termination prices are set using a TELRIC-based economic cost study or 
    a default proxy, we conclude that it is reasonable to adopt the 
    incumbent LEC's transport and termination prices as a presumptive proxy 
    for other telecommunications carriers' additional costs of transport 
    and termination. Both the incumbent LEC and the interconnecting 
    carriers usually will be providing service in the same geographic area, 
    so the forward-looking economic costs should be similar in most cases. 
    We also conclude that using the incumbent LEC's forward-looking costs 
    for transport and termination of traffic as a proxy for the costs 
    incurred by interconnecting carriers satisfies the requirement of 
    section 252(d)(2) that costs be determined ``on the basis of a 
    reasonable approximation of the additional costs of terminating such 
    calls.'' Using the incumbent LEC's cost studies as proxies for 
    reciprocal compensation is consistent with section 252(d)(2)(B)(ii), 
    which prohibits ``establishing with particularity the additional costs 
    of transporting or terminating calls.'' If both parties are incumbent 
    LECs (e.g., an independent LEC and an adjacent BOC), we conclude that 
    the larger LEC's forward-looking costs should be used to establish the 
    symmetrical rate for transport and termination. We conclude that larger 
    LECs are generally in a better position to conduct a forward-looking 
    economic cost study than smaller carriers.
        719. We conclude that imposing symmetrical rates based on the 
    incumbent LEC's additional forward-looking costs will not substantially 
    reduce carriers' incentives to minimize those costs. A symmetric 
    compensation rule gives the competing carriers correct incentives to 
    minimize its own costs of termination because its termination revenues 
    do not vary directly with changes in its own costs. Moreover, 
    symmetrical rates based on the incumbent LEC's costs should not 
    seriously affect incumbent LECs' incentives to control costs. We expect 
    that incumbent LECs will transport and terminate much more traffic that 
    originates on their own networks than traffic that originates on 
    competing carriers' networks. Even if, under the additional cost 
    standard, incumbent LECs were required to reflect any improvements in 
    operating efficiency, and consequent cost reductions, in reduced 
    termination rates, the cost savings realized by the incumbent LEC are 
    likely to be much greater than its reduction in net termination 
    revenues, because the majority of traffic transported and terminated is 
    likely to be its own. Even if a pass-through of incumbent LEC's cost 
    reductions were instantaneous and complete, the number of minutes of 
    use on which an incumbent LEC's net termination revenues is assessed is 
    much smaller
    
    [[Page 45584]]
    
    than its overall number of minutes of switching and transport. 
    Moreover, if a portion of the reduction in costs is specific to 
    exchange traffic, under symmetrical rates, the LEC's revenues from 
    terminating traffic originating from another local carrier are based on 
    the net difference in traffic, which is likely to be much smaller than 
    the total traffic it terminates. Consider a situation approximating 
    traditional LEC-CMRS interconnection, in which traffic flows are 
    substantially unbalanced: let us suppose, of 1,000,000 minutes of use, 
    750,000 are CMRS-to-LEC and 250,000 LEC-to-CMRS. Thus, under symmetric 
    compensation at 0.3 cents per minute, the LEC receives 0.3 cents times 
    500,000, or $1,500.00. If it reduced its per-minute cost, for some 
    reason only on terminating CMRS-to-LEC traffic, to 0.2 cents per 
    minute, it would save 0.1 cent times 750,000, or $750.00, in reduced 
    costs, whereas its terminating revenues would fall by only 0.1 cent 
    times 500,000, or $500.00. Thus, it would still have substantial 
    incentive to make the cost reduction in question. In situations closer 
    to traffic balance, the incentive is even more favorable. And, of 
    course, the LEC probably also reduces its cost of switching on many 
    millions of other minutes that do not involve other networks at the 
    same time. For example, in the case where traffic is balanced, net 
    termination charges are zero, a figure that is unaffected by changes in 
    the incumbent LEC's costs, and the incumbent LEC is provided with 
    correct incentives to minimize termination costs.
        720. We also find that symmetrical rates may reduce an incumbent 
    LEC's ability to use its bargaining strength to negotiate excessively 
    high termination charges that competitors would pay the incumbent LEC 
    and excessively low termination rates that the incumbent LEC would pay 
    interconnecting carriers. As discussed by commenters in the LEC-CMRS 
    Interconnection proceeding, LECs have used their unequal bargaining 
    position to impose asymmetrical rates for CMRS providers and, in some 
    instances, have charged CMRS providers origination as well as 
    termination charges. On the other hand, symmetrical rates largely 
    eliminate such advantages because they require incumbent LECs, as well 
    as competing carriers, to pay the same rate for reciprocal 
    compensation.
        721. Symmetrical compensation rates are also administratively 
    easier to derive and manage than asymmetrical rates based on the costs 
    of each of the respective carriers. In addition, we believe that using 
    the incumbent LEC's cost studies to establish the presumptive 
    symmetrical rates will establish reasonable opportunities for local 
    competition, including opportunities for small telecommunications 
    companies entering the local exchange market. We have considered the 
    economic impact of our rules in this section on small incumbent LECs. 
    For example, RTC argues that symmetrical rates do not consider the 
    costs involved in the use of another carrier's network. We find, 
    however, that incumbent LECs' costs, including small incumbent LECs' 
    costs, serve as reasonable proxies for other carriers' costs of 
    transport and termination for the purpose of reciprocal compensation. 
    We also note that certain small incumbent LECs are not subject to our 
    rules under section 251(f)(1) of the 1996 Act, unless otherwise 
    determined by a state commission, and certain other small incumbent 
    LECs may seek relief from their state commissions from our rules under 
    section 251(f)(2) of the 1996 Act. In addition, symmetry will avoid the 
    need for small businesses to conduct forward-looking economic cost 
    studies in order for the states to arbitrate reciprocal compensation 
    disputes.
        722. Given the advantages of symmetrical rates, we direct states to 
    establish presumptive symmetrical rates based on the incumbent LEC's 
    costs for transport and termination of traffic when arbitrating 
    disputes under section 252(d)(2) and in reviewing BOC statements of 
    generally available terms and conditions. If a competing local service 
    provider believes that its cost will be greater than that of the 
    incumbent LEC for transport and termination, then it must submit a 
    forward-looking economic cost study to rebut this presumptive 
    symmetrical rate. In that case, we direct state commissions, when 
    arbitrating interconnection arrangements, to depart from symmetrical 
    rates only if they find that the costs of efficiently configured and 
    operated systems are not symmetrical and justify a different 
    compensation rate. In doing so, however, state commissions must give 
    full and fair effect to the economic costing methodology we set forth 
    in this order, and create a factual record, including the cost study, 
    sufficient for purposes of review after notice and opportunity for the 
    affected parties to participate. In the absence of such a cost study 
    justifying a departure from the presumption of symmetrical 
    compensation, reciprocal compensation for the transport and termination 
    of traffic shall be based on the incumbent local exchange carrier's 
    cost studies.
        723. We find that the ``additional costs'' incurred by a LEC when 
    transporting and terminating a call that originated on a competing 
    carrier's network are likely to vary depending on whether tandem 
    switching is involved. We, therefore, conclude that states may 
    establish transport and termination rates in the arbitration process 
    that vary according to whether the traffic is routed through a tandem 
    switch or directly to the end-office switch. In such event, states 
    shall also consider whether new technologies (e.g., fiber ring or 
    wireless networks) perform functions similar to those performed by an 
    incumbent LEC's tandem switch and thus, whether some or all calls 
    terminating on the new entrant's network should be priced the same as 
    the sum of transport and termination via the incumbent LEC's tandem 
    switch. Where the interconnecting carrier's switch serves a geographic 
    area comparable to that served by the incumbent LEC's tandem switch, 
    the appropriate proxy for the interconnecting carrier's additional 
    costs is the LEC tandem interconnection rate.
        724. We disagree with TCI's claim that higher charges for routing 
    calls through tandem switches rather than directly through incumbent 
    LECs' end offices will materially discourage carriers from routing 
    traffic through tandem switches, even when it is efficient to do so. 
    New entrants will only be encouraged to interconnect at end-office 
    switches, rather than tandem switches, when the decrease in incumbent 
    LEC transport charges justifies the extra costs incurred by the new 
    entrant to route traffic directly through the incumbent LEC's end-
    office switches. Carriers will interconnect in a way that minimizes 
    their costs of interconnection, including the use of cost-based LEC 
    network elements. In addition, the flexibility given to states may 
    allow carriers, including small entities, with different network 
    architectures to establish rates for terminating calls originating on 
    other carriers' networks that are asymmetrical, if they can show that 
    the costs of efficiently configured and operated systems are not 
    symmetrical and justify different compensation rates, instead of being 
    based on competitors' network architectures.
        725. We believe, with respect to interconnection between LECs and 
    paging providers, that there should be an exception to our rule that 
    states must establish presumptive symmetrical rates based on the 
    incumbent LEC's costs for transport and termination of traffic. While 
    paging providers, as telecommunications carriers, are entitled to 
    mutual compensation for the
    
    [[Page 45585]]
    
    transport and termination of local traffic, and should not be required 
    to pay charges for traffic that originates on other carriers' networks, 
    we believe that incumbent LECs' forward-looking costs may not be 
    reasonable proxies for the costs of paging providers. Paging is 
    typically a significantly different service than wireline or wireless 
    voice service and uses different types and amounts of equipment and 
    facilities. PageNet's own network, for example, is based on a regional 
    hub and spoke network that transmits paging calls from radio 
    transmitters to provide regional or national coverage. This 
    configuration is distinctly different from either LEC wireline 
    networks, with their hierarchy of switches and transmission facilities, 
    or cellular carriers, with their multiple cells and sophisticated 
    systems for handing off calls as a vehicle moves across cell 
    boundaries. In addition, most calls terminated by paging companies are 
    brief (averaging 15 seconds) in duration and contain no voice message, 
    but only an alpha-numeric message of a few characters. Using incumbent 
    LEC's costs for termination of traffic as a proxy for paging providers' 
    costs, when the LECs' costs are likely higher than paging providers' 
    cost, might create uneconomic incentives for paging providers to 
    generate traffic simply in order to receive termination compensation. 
    Thus, using LEC costs for termination of voice calls thus may not be a 
    reasonable proxy for paging costs as the types of switching and 
    transport that paging carriers perform are different from those of LECs 
    and other voice carriers.
        726. Given the lack of information in the record concerning paging 
    providers' costs to terminate local traffic, we have decided to 
    initiate a further proceeding to try to determine what an appropriate 
    proxy for paging costs would be and, if necessary, to set a specific 
    paging default proxy. In the interim, however, in the event that LECs 
    and paging companies cannot negotiate agreed-upon rates, we direct 
    states, when arbitrating disputes under section 252(d)(2), to establish 
    rates for the termination of traffic by paging providers based on the 
    forward-looking economic costs of such termination to the paging 
    provider. The paging provider seeking termination fees must prove to 
    the state commission the costs of terminating local calls. Given the 
    lack of information in the record concerning paging providers' costs, 
    we further conclude that the default price for termination of traffic 
    from the end office that we adopt in this proceeding in Section 
    XI.B.3., supra, does not apply to termination of traffic by paging 
    providers. This default price is based on estimates in the record of 
    the costs to LECs of termination from the end office or end-office 
    switching. There are no such estimates with respect to paging in the 
    record, and as discussed above, we find that estimates of LEC costs may 
    not reflect paging providers' costs.
    (2) Existing Non-Reciprocal Agreements Between Incumbent LECs and CMRS 
    Providers
        727. Section 20.11 of our rules, which predates enactment of the 
    1996 Act, requires that interconnection agreements between incumbent 
    LECs and CMRS providers comply with principles of mutual compensation, 
    and that each carrier pay reasonable compensation for transport and 
    termination of the other carrier's calls. Based on the extensive record 
    in the LEC-CMRS Interconnection proceeding, as well as that in this 
    proceeding, we conclude that, in many cases, incumbent LECs appear to 
    have imposed arrangements that provide little or no compensation for 
    calls terminated on wireless networks, and in some cases imposed 
    charges for traffic originated on CMRS providers' networks, both in 
    violation of section 20.11 of our rules. Accordingly, we conclude that 
    CMRS providers that are party to pre-existing agreements with incumbent 
    LECs that provide for non-mutual compensation have the option to 
    renegotiate these agreements with no termination liabilities or other 
    contract penalties. Pending the successful completion of negotiations 
    or arbitration, symmetrical reciprocal compensation provisions shall 
    apply, with the transport and termination rate that the incumbent LEC 
    charges the CMRS provider from the pre-existing agreement applying to 
    both carriers, as of the effective date of the rules we adopt pursuant 
    to this order.
        728. In addition, we conclude that this opportunity for CMRS 
    providers currently operating under arrangements with non-mutual 
    transport and termination rates to renegotiate such arrangements 
    advances the mutual compensation regime contemplated under section 
    251(b)(5) of the 1996 Act. We use the term ``reciprocal compensation'' 
    and ``mutual compensation'' synonymously to mean that compensation 
    flows in both directions between interconnecting networks. LEC-CMRS 
    Interconnection NPRM. We find that extending the opportunity to 
    establish symmetrical reciprocal compensation for the transport and 
    termination of traffic addresses inequalities in bargaining power that 
    incumbent LECs may use to disadvantage interconnecting wireless 
    carriers. At the same time, our rule will place wireless carriers with 
    non-mutual, existing agreements on the same footing as other new 
    entrants, who will be able to negotiate more equitable interconnection 
    agreements because of the rules we put in place with this Report and 
    Order. We find that we have ample authority under section 4(i) of the 
    1934 Act as well as section 251 of the 1996 Act, to order this remedy. 
    Courts have held that ``the Commission has the power to prescribe a 
    change in contract rates when it finds them to be unlawful * * * and to 
    modify other provisions of private contracts when necessary to serve 
    the public interest.'' Western Union Tel. Co. v. FCC, 815 F.2d 1495, 
    1501 (D.C. Cir. 1987). The Commission has adopted similar ``fresh 
    look'' requirements in the past. The opportunity that we are affording 
    to CMRS providers in this context is consistent with similar ``fresh 
    look'' requirements that we have adopted in the past. See, e.g., 
    Expanded Interconnection with Local Telephone Company Facilities Report 
    and Order and NPRM, 57 FR 54323 (November 18, 1992), recon., 58 FR 
    48752 (September 17, 1993) (fresh look to enable customers to take 
    advantage of new competitive opportunities under special access 
    expanded interconnection), vacated on other grounds and remanded for 
    further proceedings sub nom. Bell Atlantic Tel. Cos. v. FCC, 24 F.3d 
    1441 (1994); Competition in the Interstate Interexchange Marketplace 
    Memorandum Opinion and Order on Reconsideration, 57 FR 20206 (May 12, 
    1992) (``fresh look'' in context of 800 bundling with interexchange 
    offerings); Amendment of the Commission's Rules Relative to Allocation 
    of the 849-851/894-896 MHz Bands Memorandum Opinion and Order on 
    Reconsideration, 56 FR 37853 (August 9, 1991) (``fresh look'' 
    requirements imposed in context of air-ground radiotelephone service as 
    condition of grant of Title III license).
    5. Bill and Keep
    a. Background
        729. Local Competition NPRM. In the NPRM, we defined bill-and-keep 
    arrangements as those in which neither of two interconnecting networks 
    charges the other network for terminating traffic that originated on 
    the other network. Instead, each network recovers from its own end 
    users the cost of both originating traffic delivered to the other 
    network and terminating traffic received from the other network. A 
    bill-and-keep approach for termination of traffic does
    
    [[Page 45586]]
    
    not, however, preclude a positive flat-rated charge for transport of 
    traffic between carriers' networks.
        730. We sought comment on what guidance we should give state 
    commissions regarding the use of bill-and-keep arrangements in 
    arbitrated interconnection arrangements. We sought comment on whether 
    section 252(d)(2)(B)(ii) specifically authorizes states to impose bill-
    and-keep arrangements in the arbitration process, at least when certain 
    conditions are met. We also sought comment on whether we should 
    interpret the statute as placing any limits on the circumstances in 
    which states may adopt bill-and-keep arrangements. We also asked for 
    comment on the meaning of the statutory description of bill-and-keep 
    arrangements as ``arrangements that waive mutual recovery.'' In 
    addition, we sought comment on whether there are any circumstances in 
    which the statute requires states to establish bill-and-keep 
    arrangements.
        731. LEC-CMRS Interconnection NPRM. In the LEC-CMRS Interconnection 
    NPRM, we proposed bill and keep as an interim arrangement. LEC-CMRS 
    Interconnection NPRM, 61 FR 3644 (February 1, 1996). We noted there 
    that proponents have argued that bill-and-keep would be economically 
    efficient if either of two conditions are met: (1) traffic flows 
    between competing LECs are balanced; or (2) the per-unit cost of 
    interconnection is de minimis. We, therefore, address whether interim 
    bill-and-keep arrangements for LEC-CMRS traffic should be imposed.
    b. Discussion
        732. As an additional option for reciprocal compensation 
    arrangements for termination services, we conclude that state 
    commissions may impose bill-and-keep arrangements if neither carrier 
    has rebutted the presumption of symmetrical rates and if the volume of 
    terminating traffic that originates on one network and terminates on 
    another network is approximately equal to the volume of terminating 
    traffic flowing in the opposite direction, and is expected to remain 
    so, as defined below. We disagree with commenters who contend that the 
    Commission and states do not have the authority to mandate bill-and-
    keep arrangements under any circumstances. Section 252(d)(2)(B)(i) 
    provides that the definition of what may be considered ``just and 
    reasonable'' terms and conditions for reciprocal compensation ``shall 
    not be construed to preclude arrangements that afford mutual recovery 
    (such as bill-and-keep arrangements).'' We conclude that section 
    252(d)(2) would be superfluous if bill-and-keep arrangements were 
    limited to negotiated agreements, because none of the standards in 
    section 252(d) apply to voluntarily-negotiated agreements. Therefore, 
    it is clear that bill-and-keep arrangements may be imposed in the 
    context of the arbitration process for termination of traffic, at least 
    in some circumstances.
        733. Section 252(d)(2)(A)(i) provides that to be just and 
    reasonable, reciprocal compensation must ``provide for the mutual and 
    reciprocal recovery by each carrier of costs associated with transport 
    and termination.'' In general, we find that carriers incur costs in 
    terminating traffic that are not de minimis, and consequently, bill-
    and-keep arrangements that lack any provisions for compensation do not 
    provide for recovery of costs. In addition, as long as the cost of 
    terminating traffic is positive, bill-and-keep arrangements are not 
    economically efficient because they distort carriers' incentives, 
    encouraging them to overuse competing carriers' termination facilities 
    by seeking customers that primarily originate traffic. On the other 
    hand, when states impose symmetrical rates for the termination of 
    traffic, payments from one carrier to the other can be expected to be 
    offset by payments in the opposite direction when traffic from one 
    network to the other is approximately balanced with the traffic flowing 
    in the opposite direction. In such circumstances, bill-and-keep 
    arrangements may minimize administrative burdens and transaction costs. 
    We find that, in certain circumstances, the advantages of bill-and-keep 
    arrangements outweigh the disadvantages, but no party has convincingly 
    explained why, in such circumstances, parties themselves would not 
    agree to bill-and-keep arrangements. We are mindful, however, that 
    negotiations may fail for a variety of reasons. We conclude, therefore, 
    that states may impose bill-and-keep arrangements if traffic is roughly 
    balanced in the two directions and neither carrier has rebutted the 
    presumption of symmetrical rates.
        734. We further conclude that states may adopt specific thresholds 
    for determining when traffic is roughly balanced. If state commissions 
    impose bill-and-keep arrangements, those arrangements must either 
    include provisions that impose compensation obligations if traffic 
    becomes significantly out of balance or permit any party to request 
    that the state commission impose such compensation obligations based on 
    a showing that the traffic flows are inconsistent with the threshold 
    adopted by the state. For example, the Michigan Commission adopted a 
    five percent threshold for the difference between the traffic flows in 
    the two directions. States may, however, also apply a general 
    presumption that traffic between carriers is balanced and is likely to 
    remain so. In that case, a party asserting imbalanced traffic 
    arrangements must prove to the state commission that such imbalance 
    exists. Under such a presumption, bill-and-keep arrangements would be 
    justified unless a carrier seeking to rebut this presumption satisfies 
    its burden of proof. We also find that states that have adopted bill-
    and-keep arrangements prior to the date that this order becomes 
    effective, either in arbitration or rulemaking proceedings, may retain 
    such arrangements, unless a party proves to the state commission that 
    traffic is not roughly balanced. In that case, the state commission is 
    to determine the transport and termination rates based either on the 
    forward-looking economic cost-based methodology or consistent with the 
    default proxies in this order. Finally, we observe that carriers have 
    an incentive to agree to bill-and-keep arrangements if it is 
    economically efficient to do so, and that nothing in the Act prevents 
    parties from agreeing to bill-and-keep arrangements even if a state 
    declines to mandate such arrangements. For example, we note that Time 
    Warner/BellSouth interconnection agreement provides for a bill-and-keep 
    arrangement based on a ``roughly balanced traffic'' concept.
        735. In determining whether traffic is balanced, we find that 
    precise traffic measurement is not necessary. It is sufficient to use 
    approximations based on samples and studies comparable to reports on 
    percentages of interstate use often used for access charge billing. 
    Such an approach is likely to reduce implementation costs and 
    complexities. Alternatively, state commissions may require that traffic 
    flowing in the two directions be measured as accurately as possible 
    during some defined period of time, which may commence no later than 
    six months after an interconnection arrangement goes into effect. All 
    affected carriers are required to cooperate with the state commission 
    in implementing this measurement. A state commission that adopts a 
    traffic flow measurement approach may adopt a ``true-up'' mechanism to 
    ensure that no carrier is disadvantaged by an interim rate that differs 
    from the rate established once such a measurement is undertaken. 
    Finally, state commissions may require that local traffic and access 
    traffic be carried on separate trunk groups if they deem such measures 
    to be necessary to
    
    [[Page 45587]]
    
    ensure accurate measurement and billing.
        736. We have considered the economic impact of our rules in this 
    section on small incumbent LECs. For example, RTC argues that bill-and-
    keep arrangements fail to adequately deal with each carrier's costs. In 
    addition to basing reciprocal compensation on the incumbent LECs costs, 
    we believe that by allowing carriers to rebut a presumption of balanced 
    traffic volumes, the concern that bill-and-keep arrangements fail to 
    adequately deal with each carrier's costs are addressed. We also note 
    that certain small incumbent LECs are not subject to our rules under 
    section 251(f)(1) of the 1996 Act, unless otherwise determined by a 
    state commission, and certain other small incumbent LECs may seek 
    relief from their state commissions from our rules under section 
    251(f)(2) of the 1996 Act.
        737. We disagree with commenters that argue that mandating bill-
    and-keep arrangements in these circumstances violates the taking clause 
    of Fifth Amendment. We reject BellSouth's argument that mandating bill-
    and-keep mechanisms would constitute a physical intrusion of LEC 
    property. As NCTA observes, bill-and-keep arrangements are not a 
    ``physical occupation'' of incumbent LEC property and thus per se 
    takings cases are irrelevant. See Loretto v. Telepromter Manhattan CATV 
    Corp., 458 U.S. 419, 426 (1982); Lucas v. South Carolina Coastal 
    Council, 112 S.Ct. 2886, 2893 (1992). We also reject arguments that the 
    bill-and-keep arrangements we adopt here would not adequately 
    compensate incumbent LECs for transport and termination. As Congress 
    recognized, bill-and-keep arrangements allow each carrier compensation 
    ``in-kind'' in the form of access to the other carrier's network. 
    Therefore, the type of bill-and-keep arrangements that we have 
    permitted states to adopt are not unconstitutionally confiscatory.
        738. Commenters in the LEC-CMRS Interconnection NPRM assert that 
    the estimated per minute cost of LEC termination ranges from 0.2 to 1.3 
    cents, and most of the estimates are clustered near the lower end of 
    this range. These estimates are based primarily on interconnection at a 
    LEC end office, while most interconnections occur at tandem offices 
    where LECs' costs of call completion are higher than terminations 
    routed directly through the end office switch. Moreover, the record 
    contains no estimates of the cost of CMRS termination. That cost is 
    generally considered to be greater than the cost of LEC termination; 
    but only one oral, ex parte estimate of CMRS cost has been offered: 
    2.25 to 4.0 cents per minute. Further, there is no showing that the 
    transaction costs of measuring traffic flows and making net payments 
    would be so high that a bill-and-keep regime would be more efficient. 
    Moreover, no party has demonstrated that aggregate cost flows between 
    interconnecting LECs and CMRS providers are in balance.
        739. In light of the overall transport and termination policy we 
    are adopting, we do not adopt the interim bill and keep arrangement 
    tentatively proposed in the LEC-CMRS Interconnection NPRM. 
    Notwithstanding our conclusions about bill and keep above, under which 
    states may rule on bill and keep for particular pairs of firms based on 
    the circumstances prevailing between them, we conclude that we are 
    correct in not adopting bill and keep as a single, nationwide policy 
    that would govern all LEC-CMRS transport and termination of traffic. 
    Thus, we reject our tentative conclusion in the LEC-CMRS 
    Interconnection NPRM. We expect, however, that when it is economically 
    efficient to do so, parties will adopt bill and keep arrangements in 
    the negotiation process. Also, as described above, a state commission 
    may impose bill-and-keep arrangements with respect to CMRS-LEC traffic 
    when it finds that traffic is roughly balanced and is expected to 
    remain so.
    
    B. Access to Rights of Way
    
    1. Overview
        740. Section 251(b)(4) imposes upon each LEC the ``duty to afford 
    access to the poles, ducts, conduits, and rights-of-way of such carrier 
    to competing providers of telecommunications services on rates, terms, 
    and conditions that are consistent with section 224.'' The access 
    provisions of section 224, as amended by the 1996 Act, differ from the 
    requirements of section 251(b)(4) with respect to both the entities 
    required to grant access and the entities that may demand access. 
    Section 224(f)(1) imposes upon all utilities, including LECs, the duty 
    to ``provide a cable television system or any telecommunications 
    carrier with nondiscriminatory access to any pole, duct, conduit, or 
    right-of-way owned or controlled by it.'' For purposes of section 224, 
    the term ``telecommunications carrier'' excludes any incumbent LEC as 
    that term is defined in section 251(h).
        741. In the NPRM, we sought comment on various aspects of this 
    access requirement, as well as on section 224(f)(2) which creates the 
    following limited exception to the obligations of section 224(f)(1):
    
        Notwithstanding paragraph (1), a utility providing electric 
    service may deny a cable television system or any telecommunications 
    carrier access to its poles, ducts, conduits, or rights-of-way, on a 
    non-discriminatory basis where there is insufficient capacity and 
    for reasons of safety, reliability and generally applicable 
    engineering purposes.
    
        742. Additionally, we sought comment on section 224(h), which 
    provides:
    
        Whenever the owner of a pole, duct, conduit, or right-of-way 
    intends to modify or alter such pole, duct, conduit, or right-of-
    way, the owner shall provide written notification of such action to 
    any entity that has obtained an attachment to such conduit or right-
    of-way so that such entity may have a reasonable opportunity to add 
    to or modify its existing attachment. Any entity that adds to or 
    modifies its existing attachment after receiving such notification 
    shall bear a proportionate share of the costs incurred by the owner 
    in making such pole, duct, conduit, or right-of-way accessible.
    
        743. In this Order, we establish rules implementing these 
    provisions. Based on the comments received and the plain language of 
    the statute, and in furtherance of our original mandate to institute an 
    expeditious procedure for determining just and reasonable pole 
    attachment rates with a minimum of administrative costs and consistent 
    with fair and efficient regulation, we adopt herein a program for 
    nondiscriminatory access to poles, ducts, conduits and rights-of-way. 
    This Order includes several specific rules as well as a number of more 
    general guidelines that are designed to give parties flexibility to 
    reach agreements on access to utility-controlled poles, ducts, 
    conduits, and rights-of-way, without the need for regulatory 
    intervention. We provide for expedited dispute resolution when good 
    faith negotiations fail, and we establish requirements concerning 
    modifications to pole attachments and the allocation of the cost of 
    such modifications. We also explain the division of responsibility 
    between federal and state regulation envisioned by the 1996 Act.
    2. Section 224(f): Non-Discriminatory Access
    a. Background
        744. Pursuant to section 224(f)(1), a utility must grant 
    telecommunications carriers and cable operators nondiscriminatory 
    access to all poles, ducts, conduits, and rights-of-way owned or 
    controlled by the utility. This directive seeks to ensure that no party 
    can use its control of the enumerated facilities and property to 
    impede, inadvertently or otherwise, the
    
    [[Page 45588]]
    
    installation and maintenance of telecommunications and cable equipment 
    by those seeking to compete in those fields. Section 224(f)(1) appears 
    to mandate access every time a telecommunications carrier or cable 
    operator seeks access to the utility facilities or property identified 
    in that section, with a limited exception allowing electric utilities 
    to deny access ``where there is insufficient capacity and for reasons 
    of safety, reliability and generally applicable engineering purposes.'' 
    While Congress recognized the legitimate interests of utilities in 
    protecting and promoting the safety and reliability of their core 
    services, on balance we believe section 224(f) reflects Congress' 
    determination that utilities generally must accommodate requests for 
    access by telecommunications carriers and cable operators.
    b. Discussion
    (1) Generally
        745. We conclude that the reasonableness of particular conditions 
    of access imposed by a utility should be resolved on a case-specific 
    basis. We discuss below the forum for such resolutions. The record 
    makes clear that there are simply too many variables to permit any 
    other approach with respect to access to the millions of utility poles 
    and untold miles of conduit in the nation. The broader access mandated 
    by the Act, in conjunction with the reasonableness variables mentioned 
    here, will likely increase the number of disputes over access. In turn, 
    this may cause small incumbent LECs and small entities to incur the 
    need for additional resources to evaluate, process, and resolve such 
    disputes, as well as to make poles and conduits physically accessible. 
    We will not enumerate a comprehensive regime of specific rules, but 
    instead establish a few rules supplemented by certain guidelines and 
    presumptions that we believe will facilitate the negotiation and mutual 
    performance of fair, pro-competitive access agreements. We will monitor 
    the effect of this approach and propose more specific rules at a later 
    date if reasonably necessary to facilitate access and the development 
    of competition in telecommunications and cable services. We believe 
    that the rules, guidelines and presumptions established herein strike 
    the appropriate balance between the need for uniformity, on the one 
    hand, and the need for flexibility, on the other, which should minimize 
    the regulatory burdens and economic impact for both small entities and 
    small incumbent LECs.
        746. We also address the impact on small incumbent LECs. For 
    example, the Rural Telephone Coalition opposes adoption of sweeping 
    national rules because local circumstances will be relevant to disputes 
    over access to poles or rights-of-way. We have considered the economic 
    impact of our rules in this section on small incumbent LECs. For 
    example, we have adopted a flexible regulatory approach to pole 
    attachment disputes that ensures consideration of local conditions and 
    circumstances.
        747. Our determination not to prescribe numerous specific rules is 
    supported by acknowledgements in the relevant national industry codes 
    that no single set of rules can take into account all of the issues 
    that can arise in the context of a single installation or attachment. 
    The NESC, one of the national codes that virtually all commenters 
    regard as containing reasonable attachment requirements, contains 
    thousands of rules and dozens of tables and figures, all designed to 
    ensure ``the practical safeguarding of persons during the installation, 
    operation, or maintenance of electric supply and communication lines 
    and associated equipment.''
        748. For example, with respect to overhead wires, the NESC contains 
    64 pages of rules dictating minimum ``clearances,'' i.e., the minimum 
    separations between a particular wire, cable, or other piece of 
    equipment and other wires, cables, equipment, structures, and property. 
    A short list of only a few of the variables in that discussion 
    includes: the type of wire or equipment in question; the type of 
    current being transmitted; the nature of the structure supporting the 
    wires; the proximity and nature of other equipment and structures; the 
    temperature of the conducting element; and the use of the land below 
    the wires. These separation requirements dictate the required distances 
    between various wires and other transmission and distribution 
    equipment, as well as distances between such equipment and other 
    objects that are not a part of the transmission and distribution 
    network. Prescribed separations between wires will vary between the 
    point at which wires are attached to a pole and at mid-points between 
    poles, with the latter separations dictated by the predicted amount of 
    sag that the wires will experience. The amount of sag will itself 
    depend upon additional variables. Changing just one variable can 
    radically alter the separation requirements. Other rules dictate: 
    electrical loading requirements that vary depending upon wind and ice 
    conditions and the predicted sag of the lines being installed; 
    structural strength requirements that vary depending upon the amount 
    and type of installations and the nature of the supporting structure; 
    and line insulation requirements. A wholly separate and equally 
    extensive array of rules apply to underground lines.
        749. Despite this specificity, the introduction to the NESC states 
    that the code ``is not intended as a design specification or an 
    instruction manual.'' Indeed, utilities typically impose requirements 
    more stringent than those prescribed by NESC and other industry codes. 
    In some cases stricter requirements and restrictions are dictated by 
    federal, state, or local law. Potentially applicable federal 
    regulations include rules promulgated by the Federal Energy Regulatory 
    Commission (``FERC'') and by the Occupational Safety and Health 
    Administration (``OSHA''). Various restrictions can apply at the state 
    level as well. Some local requirements governing zoning, aesthetics, or 
    road clearances impose more stringent or more specific requirements 
    than those of the national industry codes or of federal or state law.
        750. In addition to operating under federal, state, and local 
    requirements, a utility normally will have its own operating standards 
    that dictate conditions of access. Utilities have developed their own 
    individual standards and incorporated them into pole attachment 
    agreements because industry-wide standards and applicable legal 
    requirements are too general to take into account all of the variables 
    that can arise. A utility's individual standards cover not simply its 
    policy with respect to attachments, but all aspects of its business. 
    Standards vary between companies and across different regions of the 
    country based on the experiences of each utility and on local 
    conditions. As Duquesne notes, the provision of electricity is the 
    result of varied engineering factors that continue to evolve. Because 
    there is no fixed manner in which to provide electricity, there is no 
    way to develop an exhaustive list of specific safety and reliability 
    standards. In addition, increasing competition in the provision of 
    electricity is forcing electric utilities to engineer their systems 
    more precisely, in a way that is tailored to meet the specific needs of 
    the electric company and its customers. As a result, each utility has 
    developed its own internal operating standards to suit its individual 
    needs and experiences.
        751. The record contains numerous factors that may vary from region 
    to region, necessitating different operating
    
    [[Page 45589]]
    
    procedures particularly with respect to attachments. Extreme 
    temperatures, ice and snow accumulation, wind, and other weather 
    conditions all affect a utility's safety and engineering practices. In 
    some instances, machinery used by local industries requires higher than 
    normal clearances. Particular utility work methods and equipment may 
    require specific separations between attachments and may restrict the 
    height of the poles that a utility will use. The installation and 
    maintenance of underground facilities raise distinct safety and 
    reliability concerns. It is important that such variables be taken into 
    account when drafting pole attachment agreements and considering an 
    individual attachment request. The number of variables makes it 
    impossible to identify and account for them all for purposes of 
    prescribing uniform standards and requirements. Universally accepted 
    codes such as the NESC do not attempt to prescribe specific 
    requirements applicable to each attachment request and neither shall 
    we.
        752. We are sensitive to concerns of cable operators and 
    telecommunications carriers regarding utility-imposed restrictions that 
    could be used unreasonably to prevent access. We note in particular 
    that a utility that itself is engaged in video programming or 
    telecommunications services has the ability and the incentive to use 
    its control over distribution facilities to its own competitive 
    advantage. A number of utilities have obtained, or are seeking, the 
    right and ability to provide telecommunications or video programming 
    services. We agree, however, with Duquesne that the best safeguard is 
    not the adoption of a comprehensive set of substantive engineering 
    standards, but the establishment of procedures that will require 
    utilities to justify any conditions they place on access. These 
    procedures are outlined in section E below. In the next two sections, 
    we set forth rules of general applicability and broader guidelines 
    relating to specific issues that are intended to govern access 
    negotiations between the parties.
    (2) Specific Rules
        753. We establish five rules of general applicability. First, in 
    evaluating a request for access, a utility may continue to rely on such 
    codes as the NESC to prescribe standards with respect to capacity, 
    safety, reliability, and general engineering principles. We have no 
    reason to question the reasonableness of the virtually unanimous 
    judgment of the commenters, many of whom have otherwise diverse and 
    conflicting interests, in this regard. Utilities may incorporate such 
    standards into their pole attachment agreements in accordance with 
    section 224(f)(2). Other industry codes also will be presumed 
    reasonable if shown to be widely-accepted objective guides for the 
    installation and maintenance of electrical and communications 
    facilities.
        754. Second, federal requirements, such as those imposed by FERC 
    and OSHA, will continue to apply to utilities to the extent such 
    requirements affect requests for attachments to utility facilities 
    under section 224(f)(1). We see no reason to supplant or modify 
    applicable federal regulations promulgated by FERC, OSHA, or other 
    federal agencies acting in accordance with their lawful authority.
        755. Third, we will consider state and local requirements affecting 
    pole attachments. We note that section 224(c)(1) provides:
    
        Nothing in this section shall be construed to apply to, or to 
    give the Commission jurisdiction with respect to rates, terms and 
    conditions, or access to poles, ducts, conduits, and rights-of-way 
    as provided in subsection (f), for pole attachments in any case 
    where such matters are regulated by the State.
    
        756. In a separate section we discuss the authority of a state to 
    preempt federal regulation of pole attachments. For present purposes, 
    we conclude that state and local requirements affecting attachments are 
    entitled to deference even if the state has not sought to preempt 
    federal regulations under section 224(c). The 1996 Act increased 
    significantly the Commission's role with respect to attachments by 
    creating federal access rights and obligations, which for decades had 
    been the subject of state and local regulation. Such regulations often 
    relate to matters of local concern that are within the knowledge of 
    local authorities and are not addressed by standard codes such as the 
    NESC. We do not believe that regulations of this sort necessarily 
    conflict with the scheme established in this Order. More specifically, 
    we see nothing in the statute or in the record that compels us to 
    preempt such local regulations as a matter of course. Regulated 
    entities and other interested parties are familiar with existing state 
    and local requirements and have adopted operating procedures and 
    practices in reliance on those requirements. We believe it would be 
    unduly disruptive to invalidate summarily all such local requirements. 
    We thus agree with commenters who suggest that such state and local 
    requirements should be presumed reasonable. Thus, even where a state 
    has not asserted preemptive authority in accordance with section 
    224(c), state and local requirements affecting pole attachments remain 
    applicable, unless a complainant can show a direct conflict with 
    federal policy. Where a local requirement directly conflicts with a 
    rule or guideline we adopt herein, our rules will prevail. We note that 
    a standard prescribed by the NESC is not a specific Commission rule, 
    and therefore a state requirement that is more restrictive than the 
    corresponding NESC standard may still apply.
        757. It is important to note that the discretion of state and local 
    authorities to regulate in the area of pole attachments is tempered by 
    section 253, which invalidates all state or local legal requirements 
    that ``prohibit or have the effect of prohibiting the ability of any 
    entity to provide any interstate or intrastate telecommunications 
    service.'' This restriction does not prohibit a state from imposing 
    ``on a competitively neutral basis and consistent with section 254, 
    requirements necessary to preserve and advance universal service, 
    protect the public safety and welfare, ensure the continued quality of 
    telecommunications services, and safeguard the rights of consumers.'' 
    In addition, section 253 specifically recognizes the authority of state 
    and local governments to manage public rights-of-way and to require 
    fair and reasonable compensation for the use of such rights-of-way.
        758. Fourth, where access is mandated, the rates, terms, and 
    conditions of access must be uniformly applied to all 
    telecommunications carriers and cable operators that have or seek 
    access. Except as specifically provided herein, the utility must charge 
    all parties an attachment rate that does not exceed the maximum amount 
    permitted by the formula we have devised for such use, and that we will 
    revise from time to time as necessary. Other terms and conditions also 
    must be applied on a nondiscriminatory basis.
        759. Fifth, except as specifically noted below, a utility may not 
    favor itself over other parties with respect to the provision of 
    telecommunications or video programming services. We interpret the 
    statutory requirement of nondiscriminatory access as compelling this 
    result, particularly when read in the context of other provisions of 
    the statute. This element of nondiscrimination is evident in section 
    224(g), which requires a utility to impute to itself or to its 
    affiliate the pole attachment rate such entity would be charged were it 
    a non-affiliated entity. Further, we believe it unlikely that Congress 
    intended to allow an
    
    [[Page 45590]]
    
    incumbent LEC to favor itself over its competitors with respect to 
    attachments to the incumbent LEC's facilities, given that section 
    224(a)(5) has just the opposite effect in that it operates to preclude 
    the incumbent LEC from obtaining access to the facilities of other 
    LECs. A utility will be able to discriminate in favor of itself with 
    respect to the provision of telecommunications or cable services only 
    as expressly provided herein.
        760. Aside from the conditions described above, we will not adopt 
    specific rules to determine when access may be denied because of 
    capacity, safety, reliability, or engineering concerns. In addition, we 
    reject the contention of some utilities that they are the primary 
    arbiters of such concerns, or that their determinations should be 
    presumed reasonable. We recognize that the public welfare depends upon 
    safe and reliable provision of utility services, yet we also note that 
    the 1996 Act reinforces the vital role of telecommunications and cable 
    services. As noted above, section 224(f)(1) in particular reflects 
    Congress' intention that utilities must be prepared to accommodate 
    requests for attachments by telecommunications carriers and cable 
    operators.
    (3) Guidelines Governing Certain Issues
        761. In addition to the rules articulated above, we will establish 
    guidelines concerning particular issues that have been raised in this 
    proceeding. These guidelines are intended to provide general ground 
    rules upon which we expect the parties to be able to implement pro-
    competitive attachment polices and procedures through arms-length 
    negotiations, rather than having to rely on multiple adjudications by 
    the Commission in response to complaints or by other forums. We do not 
    discuss herein every issue raised in the comments. Rather, we discuss 
    only major issues that we believe will arise often. Issues not 
    discussed herein may be important in a particular case, but are not 
    susceptible to any general observation or presumption.
        762. We note that a utility's obligation to permit access under 
    section 224(f) does not depend upon the execution of a formal written 
    attachment agreement with the party seeking access. We understand that 
    such agreements are the norm and encourage their continued use, subject 
    to the requirements of section 224. Complaint or arbitration procedures 
    will, of course, be available when parties are unable to negotiate 
    agreements.
    (a) Capacity Expansions
        763. When a utility cannot accommodate a request for access because 
    the facility in question has no available space, it often must modify 
    the facility to increase its capacity. In some cases, a request for 
    access can be accommodated by rearranging existing facilities to make 
    room for a new attachment. Another method of maximizing useable 
    capacity is to permit ``overlashing,'' by which a new cable is wrapped 
    around an existing wire, rather than being strung separately. A utility 
    pole filled to capacity often can be replaced with a taller pole. New 
    underground installations can be accommodated by the installation of 
    new duct, including subducts that divide a standard duct into four 
    separate, smaller ducts. Cable companies and others contend that there 
    is rarely a lack of capacity given the availability of taller poles and 
    additional conduits. These commenters suggest that utilities should 
    rarely be permitted to deny access on the basis of a lack of capacity, 
    particularly since under section 224(h) the party or parties seeking to 
    increase capacity will be responsible for all associated costs. 
    Utilities argue that neither the statute nor its legislative history 
    requires facility owners to expand or alter their facilities to 
    accommodate entities seeking to lease space. These commenters argue 
    that, if Congress intended such a result, the statute would have 
    imposed the requirement explicitly.
        764. A utility is able to take the steps necessary to expand 
    capacity if its own needs require such expansion. The principle of 
    nondiscrimination established by section 224(f)(1) requires that it do 
    likewise for telecommunications carriers and cable operators. In 
    addition, we note that section 224(f)(1) mandates access not only to 
    physical utility facilities (i.e., poles, ducts, and conduit), but also 
    to the rights-of-way held by the utility. The lack of capacity on a 
    particular facility does not necessarily mean there is no capacity in 
    the underlying right-of-way that the utility controls. For these 
    reasons, we agree with commenters who argue that a lack of capacity on 
    a particular facility does not automatically entitle a utility to deny 
    a request for access. Since the modification costs will be borne only 
    by the parties directly benefitting from the modification, neither the 
    utility nor its ratepayers will be harmed, despite the assertions of 
    utilities to the contrary.
        765. In some cases, however, increasing capacity involves more than 
    rearranging existing attachments or installing a new pole or duct. For 
    example, the record suggests that utility poles of 35 and 40 feet in 
    height are relatively standard, but that taller poles may not always be 
    readily available. The transportation, installation, and maintenance of 
    taller poles can entail different and more costly practices. Many 
    utilities have trucks and other service equipment designed to maintain 
    poles of up to 45 feet, but no higher. Installing a 50 foot pole may 
    require the utility to invest in new and costly service equipment. 
    Expansion of underground conduit space entails a very complicated 
    procedure, given the heightened safety and reliability concerns 
    associated with such facilities. Local regulators may seek to restrict 
    the frequency of underground excavations. We find it inadvisable to 
    attempt to craft a specific rule that prescribes the circumstances in 
    which, on the one hand, a utility must replace or expand an existing 
    facility in response to a request for access and, on the other hand, it 
    is reasonable for the utility to deny the request due to the 
    difficulties involved in honoring the request. We interpret sections 
    224 (f)(1) and (f)(2) to require utilities to take all reasonable steps 
    to accommodate requests for access in these situations. Before denying 
    access based on a lack of capacity, a utility must explore potential 
    accommodations in good faith with the party seeking access.
        766. We will not require telecommunications providers or cable 
    operators seeking access to exhaust any possibility of leasing capacity 
    from other providers, such as through a resale agreement, before 
    requesting a modification to expand capacity. As indicated elsewhere in 
    this Order, resale will play an important role in the development of 
    competition in telecommunications. However, as we also have noted, 
    there are benefits to facilities-based competition as well. We do not 
    wish to discourage unduly the latter form of competition solely because 
    the former might better suit the preferences of incumbent utilities 
    with respect to pole attachments.
    (b) Reservation of Space by Utility
        767. Utilities routinely reserve space on their facilities to meet 
    future needs. Local economic growth and property development may 
    require an electric utility to install additional lines or transformers 
    that use previously available space on the pole. A utility may install 
    an underground duct in which it can later install additional 
    distribution lines, if necessitated by a subsequent increase in demand 
    or by
    
    [[Page 45591]]
    
    damage to the original lines. Reserving space allows the utility to 
    respond quickly and efficiently to changed circumstances. This 
    practice, however, also can result in a utility denying access to a 
    telecommunications carrier or a cable operator even though there is 
    unused capacity on the pole or duct.
        768. This issue is of particular concern because section 224(h) 
    imposes the cost of modifying attachments on those parties that benefit 
    from the modification. If, for example, a cable operator seeks to make 
    an attachment on a facility that has no available capacity, the 
    operator would bear the full cost of modifying the facility to create 
    new capacity, such as by replacing an existing pole with a taller pole. 
    Other parties with attachments would not share in the cost, unless they 
    expanded their own use of the facilities at the same time. If the 
    electric utility decides to change a pole for its own benefit, and no 
    other parties derive a benefit from the modification, then the electric 
    company would bear the full cost of the new pole.
        769. Some commenters contend that utilities will reserve space on a 
    pole and then claim there is no capacity available, as a way of forcing 
    cable operators and telecommunications carriers to pay for new utility 
    facilities. These commenters contend that we should restrict or 
    eliminate the authority of utilities to reserve space. Utilities 
    respond that it is unfair to force a utility to accommodate full 
    occupation of its facility by third parties and then to saddle the 
    utility with the cost of modifying the facility when the utility's own 
    needs change and require a costly increase in capacity.
        770. The near-universal public demand for their core utility 
    services, while imposing certain obligations, arguably entitles 
    utilities to certain prerogatives vis-a-vis other parties, including 
    the right to reserve capacity to meet anticipated future demand for 
    those utility services. Recognition of such a right, however, could 
    conflict with the nondiscrimination requirement of section 224(f)(1) 
    which prohibits a utility from favoring itself or its affiliates with 
    respect to the provision of telecommunications and video services. In 
    addition, allowing space to go unused when a cable operator or 
    telecommunications carrier could make use of it is directly contrary to 
    the goals of Congress.
        771. Balancing these concerns leads us to the following 
    conclusions. We will permit an electric utility to reserve space if 
    such reservation is consistent with a bona fide development plan that 
    reasonably and specifically projects a need for that space in the 
    provision of its core utility service. The electric utility must permit 
    use of its reserved space by cable operators and telecommunication 
    carriers until such time as the utility has an actual need for that 
    space. At that time, the utility may recover the reserved space for its 
    own use. The utility shall give the displaced cable operator or 
    telecommunications carrier the opportunity to pay for the cost of any 
    modifications needed to expand capacity and to continue to maintain its 
    attachment. An electric utility may not reserve or recover reserved 
    space to provide telecommunications or video programming service and 
    then force a previous attaching party to incur the cost of modifying 
    the facility to increase capacity, even if the reservation of space 
    were pursuant to a reasonable development plan. The record does not 
    contain sufficient data for us to establish a presumptively reasonable 
    amount of pole or conduit space subject that an electric utility may 
    reserve. If parties cannot agree, disputes will be resolved on a case-
    by-case approach based on the reasonableness of the utility's forecast 
    of its future needs and any additional information that is relevant 
    under the circumstances.
        772. With respect to a utility providing telecommunications or 
    video services, we believe the statute requires a different result. 
    Section 224(f)(1) requires nondiscriminatory treatment of all providers 
    of such services and does not contain an exception for the benefit of 
    such a provider on account of its ownership or control of the facility 
    or right-of-way. Congress seemed to perceive such ownership and control 
    as a threat to the development of competition in these areas, thus 
    leading to the enactment of the provision in question. Allowing the 
    pole or conduit owner to favor itself or its affiliate with respect to 
    the provision of telecommunications or video services would nullify, to 
    a great extent, the nondiscrimination that Congress required. 
    Permitting an incumbent LEC, for example, to reserve space for local 
    exchange service, to the detriment of a would-be entrant into the local 
    exchange business, would favor the future needs of the incumbent LEC 
    over the current needs of the new LEC. Section 224(f)(1) prohibits such 
    discrimination among telecommunications carriers. As indicated above, 
    this prohibition does not apply when an electric utility asserts a 
    future need for capacity for electric service, to the detriment of a 
    telecommunications carrier's needs, since the statute does not require 
    nondiscriminatory treatment of all utilities; rather, it requires 
    nondiscriminatory treatment of all telecommunications and video 
    providers.
    (c) Definition of ``Utility''
        773. The access obligations of section 224(f) apply to any 
    ``utility,'' which is defined as:
    
    any person who is a local exchange carrier or an electric, gas, 
    water, steam, or other public utility, and who owns or controls 
    poles, ducts, conduits, or other rights-of-way used, in whole or in 
    part, for any wire communications. Such term does not include any 
    railroad, any person who is cooperatively organized, or any person 
    owned by the Federal Government or any State.
    
        774. Arguably a provider of utility service does not fall within 
    this definition if it has refused to permit any wired communications 
    use of its facilities and rights-of-way since, in that case, its 
    facilities and rights-of-way are not ``used, in whole or in part, for 
    wire communications.'' Under this construction, an electric utility 
    would have no obligation to grant access under section 224(f) until the 
    utility voluntarily has granted access to one communications provider 
    or has used its facilities for wire communications. Only after its 
    facilities were being used for wire communications would the utility 
    have to grant access to all telecommunications carriers and cable 
    operators on a nondiscriminatory basis.
        775. We conclude that this construction of the statute is mandated 
    by its plain language and is indeed nondiscriminatory, since denial of 
    access to all discriminates against none. We see no statutory basis, 
    however, for the argument made by some utilities that they should be 
    permitted to devote a portion of their poles, ducts, conduits, and 
    rights-of-way to wire communications without subjecting all such 
    property to the access obligations of section 224(f)(1). Those 
    obligations apply to any ``utility,'' which section 224(a)(1) defines 
    to include an entity that controls ``poles, ducts, conduits, or rights-
    of-way used, in whole or in part, for any wire communications.'' The 
    use of the phrase ``in whole or in part'' demonstrates that Congress 
    did not intend for a utility to be able to restrict access to the exact 
    path used by the utility for wire communications. We further conclude 
    that use of any utility pole, duct, conduit, or right-of-way for wire 
    communications triggers access to all poles, ducts, conduits, and 
    rights-of-way owned or controlled by the utility, including those not 
    currently used for wire communications.
    
    [[Page 45592]]
    
        776. We reject the contention that, because an electric utility's 
    internal communications do not pose a competitive threat to third party 
    cable operators or telecommunications carriers, such internal 
    communications are not ``wire communications'' and do not trigger 
    access obligations. Although internal communications are used solely to 
    promote the efficient distribution of electricity, the definition of 
    ``wire communication'' is broad and clearly encompasses an electric 
    utility's internal communications.
    (d) Application of Section 224(f)(2) to Non-Electric Utilities
        777. While all utilities are subject to the access obligations of 
    section 224(f)(1), the provisions of section 224(f)(2), permitting a 
    utility to deny access due to a lack of capacity or for reasons of 
    safety, reliability, and generally applicable engineering purposes, 
    apply only to ``a utility providing electric service * * *.'' Based on 
    this statutory language, some commenters suggest that LECs and other 
    utilities that do not provide electric service must grant requests for 
    access, regardless of any concerns relating to safety, reliability, and 
    general engineering principles. If there is a lack of capacity, a LEC 
    must create more capacity, according to these commenters.
        778. While the express language of sections 224 (f)(1) and (f)(2) 
    suggests that only utilities providing electric service can take into 
    consideration concerns relating to safety and reliability, we are 
    reluctant to ignore these concerns simply because the pole owner is not 
    an electric utility. Even parties seeking broad access rights under 
    section 224 recognize that, in some circumstances, a LEC will have 
    legitimate safety or engineering concerns that may need to be 
    accommodated. We believe that Congress could not have intended for a 
    telecommunications carrier to ignore safety concerns when making pole 
    attachment decisions. Rather than reach this dangerous result which 
    would require us to ignore the dictates of sections 1 and 4(o) of the 
    Communications Act, we conclude that any utility may take into account 
    issues of capacity, safety, reliability and engineering when 
    considering attachment requests, provided the assessment of such 
    factors is done in a nondiscriminatory manner.
        779. Nevertheless, we believe that section 224(f)(2) reflected 
    Congress' acknowledgment that issues involving capacity, safety, 
    reliability and engineering raise heightened concerns when electricity 
    is involved, because electricity is inherently more dangerous than 
    telecommunications services. Accordingly, although we determine that it 
    is proper for non-electric utilities to raise these matters, they will 
    be scrutinized very carefully, particularly when the parties concerned 
    have a competitive relationship.
    (e) Third-Party Property Owners
        780. Section 224(f)(1) mandates that the utility grant access to 
    any pole, duct, conduit, or right-of-way that is ``owned or controlled 
    by it.'' Some utilities and LECs argue that certain private easement 
    agreements, when interpreted under the applicable state property laws, 
    deprive the utilities of the ownership or control that triggers their 
    obligation to accommodate a request for access. Moreover, they contend, 
    access to public rights-of-way may be restricted by state law or local 
    ordinances. Opposing commenters contend that the addition of cable 
    television or telecommunications facilities is compatible with electric 
    service and therefore does not violate easements that have been granted 
    for the provision of electric service. These commenters also assert 
    that the statute does not draw specific distinctions between private 
    and public easements. Further, some cable operators contend that 
    utility easements are accessible to cable operators pursuant to section 
    621(a)(2) of the Communications Act as long as the easements are 
    physically compatible with such use, regardless of the terms of a 
    written easement agreement. Another commenter suggests utilities are 
    best positioned to determine when access requests would affect a 
    private easement, foreclosing the need to determine whether a private 
    owner would consent to the requested attachment. As for local 
    ordinances restricting access to public rights-of-way, one commenter 
    suggests that such restrictions would violate section 253(a) of the 
    Act, which blocks state or local rules that prohibit competition.
        781. The scope of a utility's ownership or control of an easement 
    or right-of-way is a matter of state law. We cannot structure general 
    access requirements where the resolution of conflicting claims as to a 
    utility's control or ownership depends upon variables that cannot now 
    be ascertained. We reiterate that the access obligations of section 
    224(f) apply when, as a matter of state law, the utility owns or 
    controls the right-of-way to the extent necessary to permit such 
    access.
        782. Section 621(a)(2) states that a cable franchise shall be 
    construed as authorizing the construction of cable facilities in public 
    rights-of-way and ``through easements * * * which have been dedicated 
    for compatible uses * * * .'' The scope of a cable operator's access to 
    easements under this provision has been the subject of a number of 
    court opinions. To the extent section 621(a)(2) has been construed to 
    permit access to easements, a cable operator must be permitted to 
    attach to utility poles, ducts, and conduits within such easements in 
    accordance with section 224(f).
        783. Finally, we disagree with those utilities that contend that 
    they should not be forced to exercise their powers of eminent domain to 
    establish new rights-of-way for the benefit of third parties. We 
    believe a utility should be expected to exercise its eminent domain 
    authority to expand an existing right-of-way over private property in 
    order to accommodate a request for access, just as it would be required 
    to modify its poles or conduits to permit attachments. Congress seems 
    to have contemplated an exercise of eminent domain authority in such 
    cases when it made provisions for an owner of a right-of-way that 
    ``intends to modify or alter such * * * right-of-way * * * .''
    (f) Other Matters
        784. Utilities stress the importance of ensuring that only 
    qualified workers be permitted in the proximity of utility facilities. 
    Some utilities seek to limit access to their facilities to the 
    utility's own specially trained employees or contractors, particularly 
    with respect to underground conduits. According to these commenters, 
    parties seeking to make attachments to utility facilities should be 
    required to pay for the use of the utility's workers if the utility 
    concludes that only its workers are fit for the job. While we agree 
    that utilities should be able to require that only properly trained 
    persons work in the proximity of the utilities' lines, we will not 
    require parties seeking to make attachments to use the individual 
    employees or contractors hired or pre-designated by the utility. A 
    utility may require that individuals who will work in the proximity of 
    electric lines have the same qualifications, in terms of training, as 
    the utility's own workers, but the party seeking access will be able to 
    use any individual workers who meet these criteria. Allowing a utility 
    to dictate that only specific employees or contractors be used would 
    impede the access that Congress sought to bestow on telecommunications 
    providers and cable operators and would inevitably lead to disputes 
    over rates to be paid to the workers.
    
    [[Page 45593]]
    
        785. Some electric utilities argue that high voltage transmission 
    facilities should not be accessible by telecommunications carriers or 
    cable operators under section 224(f)(1). These commenters contend that 
    transmission facilities, which are used for high voltage transmissions 
    over great distances, are far more delicate and dangerous than local 
    distribution facilities. Permitting attachments to transmission 
    facilities, they argue, poses a greater risk to the safety and 
    reliability of the electric distribution system than is the case with 
    distribution lines. They further state that transmission facilities 
    generally are not located where cable operators and telecommunications 
    carriers need to install facilities. ConEd suggests that transmission 
    towers do not even fall within the scope of the statute.
        786. Section 224(f)(1) mandates access to ``any pole, duct, 
    conduit, or right-of-way,'' owned or controlled by the utility. The 
    utilities do not suggest that transmission facilities do not use poles 
    or rights-of-way, for which the statute does mandate the right of 
    access. The utilities' arguments for excepting transmission facilities 
    from access requirements are based on safety and reliability concerns. 
    We believe that the breadth of the language contained in section 
    224(f)(1) precludes us from making a blanket determination that 
    Congress did not intend to include transmission facilities. As with any 
    facility to which access is sought, however, section 224(f)(2) permits 
    the electric utility to impose conditions on access to transmission 
    facilities, if necessary for reasons of safety and reliability. To the 
    extent safety and reliability concerns are greater at a transmission 
    facility, the statute permits a utility to impose stricter conditions 
    on any grant of access or, in appropriate circumstances, to deny access 
    if legitimate safety or reliability concerns cannot be reasonably 
    accommodated.
        787. We note that some commenters favor a broad interpretation of 
    ``pole, duct, conduit, or right-of-way'' because that approach would 
    minimize the risk that a ``pathway'' vital to competition could be shut 
    off to new competitors. Others argue for a narrow construction of this 
    statutory phrase, contending that Congress addressed access to other 
    LEC facilities elsewhere in the 1996 Act. We recognize that an overly 
    broad interpretation of this phrase could impact the owners and mangers 
    of small buildings, as well as small incumbent LECs, by requiring 
    additional resources to effectively control and monitor such rights-of-
    way located on their properties. We do not believe that section 
    224(f)(1) mandates that a utility make space available on the roof of 
    its corporate offices for the installation of a telecommunications 
    carrier's transmission tower, although access of this nature might be 
    mandated pursuant to a request for interconnection or for access to 
    unbundled elements under section 251(c)(6). The intent of Congress in 
    section 224(f) was to permit cable operators and telecommunications 
    carriers to ``piggyback'' along distribution networks owned or 
    controlled by utilities, as opposed to granting access to every piece 
    of equipment or real property owned or controlled by the utility.
        788. The statute does not describe the specific type of 
    telecommunications or cable equipment that may be attached when access 
    to utility facilities is mandated. We do not believe that establishing 
    an exhaustive list of such equipment is advisable or even possible. We 
    presume that the size, weight, and other characteristics of attaching 
    equipment have an impact on the utility's assessment of the factors 
    determined by the statute to be pertinent--capacity, safety, 
    reliability, and engineering principles. The question of access should 
    be decided based on those factors.
    3. Constitutional Takings
    a. Background
        789. The access provisions of section 224(f) restrict the right of 
    a utility to exclude third parties from its property and therefore may 
    raise Fifth Amendment issues. While we have no jurisdiction to 
    determine the constitutionality of a federal statute, constitutional 
    concerns are relevant for purposes of construing a statute.
    b. Discussion
        790. Section 224(f)(1) mandates that a utility grant access to a 
    requesting telecommunications provider or cable system operator, 
    subject to certain conditions that we discuss elsewhere in this Order. 
    That provision is not reasonably susceptible of a reading that gives 
    the pole owner the choice of whether to grant telecommunications 
    carriers or cable television systems access. Even if such mandatory 
    access results in a taking, we cannot agree that it necessarily raises 
    a constitutional issue. The Fifth Amendment permits takings as long the 
    property owner receives just compensation for the property taken.
        791. As for the amount of compensation provided under the statute, 
    GTE suggests that mandatory access will result in an unconstitutional 
    taking when considered in conjunction with the methodology for pole 
    attachment rates set forth in section 224(e)(2). We, of course, have no 
    power to declare any provision of the Communications Act 
    unconstitutional. In any event, we cannot agree. Congress has provided 
    for compensation to pole owners, in the event that they cannot resolve 
    a dispute with telecommunications carriers regarding the charges for 
    use of the owners' poles, that would allow them to recover the cost of 
    providing usable space to each entity and two-thirds of the cost of the 
    unusable space apportioned among such users. The Commission soon will 
    initiate a separate rulemaking proceeding that will give greater 
    content to this statutory standard. GTE and others may present their 
    just compensation arguments with respect to the ratemaking standards 
    the Commission adopts in that proceeding. GTE has not shown here, 
    however, how the statutory standard contained in section 224(e) 
    necessarily would deny pole owners just compensation.
    4. Modifications
    a. Background
        792. In the NPRM we sought comment on section 224(h) which 
    provides:
    
        Whenever the owner of a pole, duct, conduit, or right-of-way 
    intends to modify or alter such pole, duct, conduit, or right-of-
    way, the owner shall provide written notification of such action to 
    any entity that has obtained an attachment to such conduit or right-
    of-way so that such entity may have a reasonable opportunity to add 
    to or modify its existing attachment. Any entity that adds to or 
    modifies its existing attachment after receiving such notification 
    shall bear a proportionate share of the costs incurred by the owner 
    in making such pole, duct, conduit, or right-of-way accessible.
    
        793. The NPRM requested comments addressing the manner and timing 
    of the notice that must be provided to ensure a reasonable opportunity 
    to add to or modify its attachment. In addition, we sought comment 
    regarding the establishment of rules apportioning the cost of a 
    modification among the various users of the modified facility. Finally, 
    we requested comment on whether any payment of costs should be offset 
    by the potential increase in revenues to the owner. If, for example, an 
    owner modifies a pole to allow additional attachments that generate 
    additional fees for the owner, should such revenues offset the share of 
    modification costs borne by entities with preexisting access to the 
    pole?
    
    [[Page 45594]]
    
    b. Discussion
        794. We recognize that, when a modification is planned, parties 
    with preexisting attachments to a pole or conduit need time to evaluate 
    how the proposed modification affects their interest and whether 
    activity related to the modification presents an opportunity to adjust 
    the attachment in a desirable manner. At the same time, we also 
    recognize that not all adjustments to utility facilities are alike. 
    Some adjustments may be sufficiently routine or minor as to not create 
    the type of opportunity that triggers the notice requirement. Indeed, 
    it is possible that in some cases lengthy notice requirements could 
    delay unnecessarily the kinds of modifications that would expedite the 
    onset of meaningful competition in the provision of telecommunications 
    services. Although the period of advance notice has varied widely among 
    commenters, we note that 60 days has been advocated by several parties.
        795. Several commenters expressed a preference for negotiated 
    notification terms. They have explained that circumstances will vary 
    among owners of facilities. The time needed to commence a modification 
    could vary according to pole conditions, technological improvements and 
    demand growth. Attaching parties in rural markets may need more time to 
    study facilities than facility users in urban markets. To demonstrate 
    their ability to develop appropriate negotiated agreements, some 
    commenters have described notice requirements in existing agreements. 
    Such cases, they contend, illustrate that notification rules are 
    unnecessary.
        796. We conclude that, absent a private agreement establishing 
    notification procedures, written notification of a modification must be 
    provided to parties holding attachments on the facility to be modified 
    at least 60 days prior to the commencement of the physical modification 
    itself. Notice should be sufficiently specific to apprise the recipient 
    of the nature and scope of the planned modification. These notice 
    requirements should provide small entities with sufficient time to 
    evaluate the impact of or opportunities made possible by the proposed 
    modifications on their interests and plan accordingly. If the 
    contemplated modification involves an emergency situation for which 
    advanced written notice would prove impractical, the notice requirement 
    does not apply except that notice should be given as soon as reasonably 
    practicable, which in some cases may be after the modification is 
    completed. Further, we believe that the burden of requiring specific 
    written notice of routine maintenance activities would not produce a 
    commensurate benefit. Utilities and parties with attachments should 
    exchange maintenance handbooks or other written descriptions of their 
    standard maintenance practices. Changes to these practices should be 
    made only upon 60 days written notice. Recognizing that the parties 
    themselves are best able to determine the circumstances where notice 
    would be reasonable and sufficient, as well as the types of 
    modifications that should trigger notice obligations, we encourage the 
    owner of a facility and parties with attachments to negotiate 
    acceptable notification terms.
        797. Even with the adoption of a specific notice period, however, 
    we still encourage communication among owners and attaching parties. 
    Indeed, in cases where owners and users routinely share information 
    about upgrades and modifications, agreements regarding notice periods 
    and procedures are ancillary matters.
        798. With respect to the allocation of modification costs, we 
    conclude that, to the extent the cost of a modification is incurred for 
    the specific benefit of any particular party, the benefiting party will 
    be obligated to assume the cost of the modification, or to bear its 
    proportionate share of cost with all other attaching entities 
    participating in the modification. If a user's modification affects the 
    attachments of others who do not initiate or request the modification, 
    such as the movement of other attachments as part of a primary 
    modification, the modification cost will be covered by the initiating 
    or requesting party. Where multiple parties join in the modification, 
    each party's proportionate share of the total cost shall be based on 
    the ratio of the amount of new space occupied by that party to the 
    total amount of new space occupied by all of the parties joining in the 
    modification. For example, a CAP's access request might require the 
    installation of a new pole that is five feet taller than the old pole, 
    even though the CAP needs only two feet of space. At the same time, a 
    cable operator may claim one foot of the newly-created capacity. If 
    these were the only parties participating in the modification, the CAP 
    would pay two-thirds of the modification costs and the cable operator 
    one-third.
        799. As a general approach, requiring that modification costs be 
    paid only by entities for whose benefit the modification is made 
    simplifies the modification process. For these purposes, however, if an 
    entity uses a proposed modification as an opportunity to adjust its 
    preexisting attachment, the ``piggybacking'' entity should share in the 
    overall cost of the modification to reflect its contribution to the 
    resulting structural change. A utility or other party that uses a 
    modification as an opportunity to bring its facilities into compliance 
    with applicable safety or other requirements will be deemed to be 
    sharing in the modification and will be responsible for its share of 
    the modification cost. This will discourage parties from postponing 
    necessary repairs in an effort to avoid the associated costs.
        800. We recognize that limiting cost burdens to entities that 
    initiate a modification, or piggyback on another's modification, may 
    confer incidental benefits on other parties with preexisting 
    attachments on the newly modified facility. Nevertheless, if a 
    modification would not have occurred absent the action of the 
    initiating party, the cost should not be borne by those that did not 
    take advantage of the opportunity by modifying their own facilities. 
    Indeed, the Conference Report accompanying the passage of the 1996 Act 
    imposes cost sharing obligations on an entity ``that takes advantage of 
    such opportunity to modify its own attachments.'' This suggests that an 
    attaching party, incidentally benefiting from a modification, but not 
    initiating or affirmatively participating in one, should not be 
    responsible for the resulting cost. As for pole owners themselves, the 
    imposition of cost burdens for modifications they do not initiate could 
    be particularly cumbersome if excess space created by modifications 
    remained unused for extended periods.
        801. Apart from entities that initiate modifications and 
    preexisting attachers that use the opportunity to modify their own 
    attachments, some entities may seek to add new attachments to the 
    modified facility after the modification is completed to avoid any 
    obligation to share in the cost. If this occurs, the entity initiating 
    and paying for the modification might pay the entire cost of expanding 
    a facility's capacity only to see a new competitor take advantage of 
    the additional capacity without sharing in the cost. Moreover, entities 
    with preexisting attachments may, due to cost considerations, forgo the 
    opportunity to adjust their attachment only to see a new entrant attach 
    to a pole without sharing the modification cost. To protect the 
    initiators of modifications from absorbing costs that should be shared 
    by others, we will allow the modifying party or parties to
    
    [[Page 45595]]
    
    recover a proportionate share of the modification costs from parties 
    that later are able to obtain access as a result of the modification. 
    The proportionate share of the subsequent attacher should be reduced to 
    take account of depreciation to the pole or other facility that has 
    occurred since the modification. These provisions are intended to 
    ensure that new entrants, especially small entities with limited 
    resources, bear only their proportionate costs and are not forced to 
    subsidize their later-entering competitors. To the extent small 
    entities avail themselves of this cost-saving mechanism, however, they 
    will incur certain record keeping obligations.
        802. Parties requesting or joining in a modification also will be 
    responsible for resulting costs to maintain the facility on an ongoing 
    basis. We believe determining the method by which to allocate such 
    costs can best be resolved in the context of a proceeding addressing 
    the determination of appropriate rates for pole attachments or other 
    facility uses. We will postpone consideration of these issues until 
    such time.
        803. We recognize that in some cases a facility modification will 
    create excess capacity that eventually becomes a source of revenue for 
    the facility owner, even though the owner did not share in the costs of 
    the modification. We do not believe that this requires the owner to use 
    those revenues to compensate the parties that did pay for the 
    modification. Section 224(h) limits responsibility for modification 
    costs to any party that ``adds to or modifies its existing attachment 
    after receiving notice'' of a proposed modification. The statute does 
    not give that party any interest in the pole or conduit other than 
    access. Creating a right for that party to share in future revenues 
    from the modification would be tantamount to bestowing an interest that 
    the statute withholds. Requiring an owner to offset modification costs 
    by the amount of future revenues emanating from the modification 
    expands the category of responsible parties based on factors that 
    Congress did not identify as relevant. Since Congress did not provide 
    for an offset, we will not impose it ourselves. Indeed, a requirement 
    that utilities pass additional attachment fees back to parties with 
    preexisting attachments may be a disincentive to add new competitors to 
    modified facilities, in direct contravention of the general intent of 
    Congress.
    5. Dispute Resolution
    a. Background
        804. Implementation of the access requirements of sections 224 and 
    251(b)(4) require the adoption of enforcement procedures. In the NPRM, 
    we sought comment on, among other things, whether to impose upon a 
    utility the burden of justifying its denial of access to its poles, 
    ducts, conduits, and rights-of-way due to lack of capacity, safety, 
    reliability, and engineering issues.
    b. Discussion
    (1) General Complaint Procedures Under Section 224
        805. Section 224(f)(2) provides that an electric utility may deny 
    non-discriminatory access ``where there is insufficient capacity and 
    for reasons of safety, reliability and generally applicable engineering 
    purposes.'' We have determined that other utilities also may consider 
    these concerns when faced with an access request. A denial of access, 
    while proper in some cases, is an exception to the general mandate of 
    section 224(f). We note that utilities contend that they are in the 
    best position to determine when access should be denied, because they 
    possess the information and expertise to make such decisions and 
    because of the varied circumstances impacting these decisions. We think 
    it appropriate that the utility bear the burden of justifying why its 
    denial of access to a cable television or telecommunications carrier 
    fits within that exception. We therefore agree that utilities have the 
    ultimate burden of proof in denial-of-access cases. We believe this 
    will minimize uncertainty and reduce litigation and transaction costs, 
    because new entrants generally, and small entities in particular, are 
    unlikely to have access to the relevant information without cooperation 
    from the utilities.
        806. We also agree with Virginia Power that a telecommunications 
    carrier or cable television provider filing a complaint with the 
    Commission must establish a prima facie case. A petitioner's complaint, 
    in addition to showing that it is timely filed, must state the grounds 
    given for the denial of access, the reasons those grounds are unjust or 
    unreasonable, and the remedy sought. The complaint must be supported by 
    the written request for access, the utility's response, and information 
    supporting its position. The Commission will deny the petitioner's 
    claim if a prima facie case is not established. A complaint will not be 
    dismissed if a petitioner is unable to obtain a utility's written 
    response, or if a petitioner is denied any other relevant information 
    by the utility needed to establish a prima facie case. Thus, we expect 
    a utility that receives a legitimate inquiry regarding access to its 
    facilities or property to make its maps, plats, and other relevant data 
    available for inspection and copying by the requesting party, subject 
    to reasonable conditions to protect proprietary information. This 
    provision eliminates the need for costly discovery in pursuing a claim 
    of improper denial of access, allowing attaching parties, including 
    small entities with limited resources, to seek redress of such denials.
        807. We agree with the Joint Cable Commenters that ``time is of the 
    essence.'' The Joint Cable Commenters contend that the Commission 
    should implement an expedited review process for denial of access 
    cases. By implementing specific complaint procedures for denial of 
    access cases, we seek to establish swift and specific enforcement 
    procedures that will allow for competition where access can be 
    provided. In order to provide a complete record, written requests for 
    access must be provided to the utility. If access is not granted within 
    45 days of the request, the utility must confirm the denial in writing 
    by the 45th day. Although these written requirements involve some 
    recordkeeping obligations, which could impose a burden on small 
    incumbent LECs and small entities, we believe that burden is outweighed 
    by the benefits of certainty and expedient resolution of disputes which 
    this procedure encourages. The denial must be specific, and include all 
    relevant evidence or information supporting its denial. It must 
    enumerate how the evidence relates to one of the reasons that access 
    can be denied under section 224(f)(2), i.e., lack of capacity, safety, 
    reliability or engineering standards.
        808. For example, a utility may attempt to deny access because of 
    lack of capacity on a 40-foot pole. We would expect a utility to 
    provide the information demonstrating why there is no capacity. In 
    addition, the utility should show why it declined to replace the pole 
    with a 45-foot pole. Upon the receipt of a denial notice from the 
    utility, the requesting party shall have 60 days to file its complaint 
    with the Commission. We anticipate that by following this procedure the 
    Commission will, upon receipt of a complaint, have all relevant 
    information upon which to make its decision. The petition must be 
    served pursuant to section 1.1404(b) of the Commission's rules. Final 
    decisions relating to access will be resolved by the Commission
    
    [[Page 45596]]
    
    expeditiously. Because we are using the expedited process described 
    herein, we do not believe stays or other equitable relief will be 
    granted in the absence of a specific showing, beyond the prima facie 
    case, that such relief is warranted.
    (2) Procedures Under Section 251
        809. A telecommunications carrier seeking access to the facilities 
    or property of a LEC may invoke section 251(b)(4) in lieu of, or in 
    addition to, section 244(f)(1). Because section 251(b)(4) mandates 
    access ``on rates terms, and conditions that are consistent with 
    section 224,'' we believe that the section 224 complaint procedures 
    established above should be available regardless of whether a 
    telecommunications provider invokes section 224(f)(1) or section 
    251(b)(4), or both.
        810. If a telecommunications carrier seeks access to the facilities 
    or property of an incumbent LEC, however, it shall have the option of 
    invoking the procedures established by section 252 in lieu of filing a 
    complaint under section 224. Section 252 governs procedures for the 
    negotiation, arbitration, and approval of certain agreements between 
    incumbent LECs and telecommunications carriers. In pertinent part, 
    section 252(a)(1) provides:
    
        Upon receiving a request for interconnection, services, or 
    network elements pursuant to section 251, an incumbent local 
    exchange carrier may negotiate and enter into a binding agreement 
    with the requesting telecommunications carrier or carriers without 
    regard to the standards set sforth in subsections (b) or (c) of 
    section 251.
    
        811. Where parties are unable to reach an agreement under this 
    section, any party may petition the relevant state commission to 
    arbitrate the open issues. In resolving the dispute, the state 
    commission must ensure, among other things, that the ultimate 
    resolution ``meet[s] the requirements of section 251, including the 
    regulations prescribed by the Commission pursuant to section 251 * * 
    *.'' The Commission may assume the state's authority under section 252 
    if the state ``fails to carry out its responsibility'' under that 
    section.
        812. Section 251(c)(1) creates an obligation on the part of an 
    incumbent LEC ``to negotiate in good faith in accordance with section 
    252 the particular terms and conditions of agreements * * *'' to 
    fulfill its section 251(b)(4) obligation. Therefore, a 
    telecommunications carrier may seek access to the facilities or 
    property of an incumbent LEC pursuant to section 251(b)(4) and trigger 
    the negotiation and arbitration procedures of section 252. If a 
    telecommunications carrier intends to invoke the section 252 
    procedures, it should affirmatively state such intent in its formal 
    request for access to the incumbent LEC. We impose this requirement 
    because the two procedures have separate deadlines by which the parties 
    may or must take certain steps, and therefore the incumbent LEC 
    receiving the request has a need to know which procedure has been 
    invoked. Section 224 shall be the default procedure that will apply if 
    the telecommunications carrier fails to make an affirmative election.
        813. We note that section 252 does not impose any obligations on 
    utilities other than incumbent LECs, and does not grant rights to 
    entities that are not telecommunications providers. Therefore, section 
    252 may be invoked in lieu of section 224 only by a telecommunications 
    carrier and only if it is seeking access to the facilities or property 
    of an incumbent LEC.
        814. In addition, incumbent LECs cannot use section 251(b)(4) as a 
    means of gaining access to the facilities or property of a LEC. A LEC's 
    obligation under section 251(b)(4) is to afford access ``on rates, 
    terms, and conditions that are consistent with section 224.'' Section 
    224 does not prescribe rates, terms, or conditions governing access by 
    an incumbent LEC to the facilities or rights-of-way of a competing LEC. 
    Indeed, section 224 does not provide access rights to incumbent LECs. 
    We cannot infer that section 251(b)(4) restores to an incumbent LEC 
    access rights expressly withheld by section 224. We give deference to 
    the specific denial of access under section 224 over the more general 
    access provisions of section 251(b)(4). Accordingly, no incumbent LEC 
    may seek access to the facilities or rights-of-way of a LEC or any 
    utility under either section 224 or section 251(b)(4).
    6. Reverse Preemption
    a. Background
        815. Even prior to enactment of the 1996 Act, section 224(b)(1) 
    gave the Commission jurisdiction to ``regulate the rates, terms, and 
    conditions for pole attachments * * *.'' Under former section 
    224(c)(1), that jurisdiction was preempted where a state regulated such 
    matters. Such reverse preemption was conditioned upon the state 
    following a certification procedure and meeting certain compliance 
    requirements set forth in sections 224(c) (2) and (3). The 1996 Act 
    expanded the Commission's jurisdiction to include not just rates, 
    terms, and conditions, but also the authority to regulate non-
    discriminatory access to poles, ducts, conduits and rights-of-way under 
    section 224(f). At the same time, the 1996 Act expanded the preemptive 
    authority of states to match the expanded scope of the Commission's 
    jurisdiction. Section 224(c)(1) now provides:
    
        Nothing in this section shall be construed to apply to, or to 
    give the Commission jurisdiction with respect to rates, terms and 
    conditions, or access to poles, ducts, conduits, and rights-of-way 
    as provided in subsection (f), for pole attachments in any case 
    where such matters are regulated by the State.
    b. Discussion
        816. To resolve this issue, we will begin with access requests that 
    can arise solely under section 224(f)(1). These circumstances include 
    when a cable system or telecommunications carrier seeks access to the 
    facilities or rights-of-way of a non-LEC utility. In such cases, the 
    expansion of the Commission's authority to require utilities to provide 
    nondiscriminatory access under section 224(f) is countered by a 
    corresponding expansion in the scope of a state's authority under 
    section 224(c)(1) to preempt federal requirements. The authority of a 
    state under section 224(c)(1) to preempt federal regulation in these 
    cases is clear.
        817. The issue becomes more complicated when a telecommunications 
    carrier seeks access to LEC facilities or property under section 
    251(b)(4). By its express terms, section 251(b)(4) imposes upon LECs, 
    ``[t]he duty to afford access to the poles, ducts, conduits, and 
    rights-of-way of such a carrier to competing providers of 
    telecommunications services on rates, terms and conditions that are 
    consistent with section 224.'' We believe the reference in section 
    251(b)(4) to section 224 incorporates all aspects of the latter 
    section, including the state preemption authority of section 224(c)(1). 
    This interpretation is consistent not only with the plain meaning of 
    the statute but with the overall application of sections 251 and 252.
        818. In the 1996 Act, Congress expanded section 224(c)(1) to reach 
    access issues. Congress' clear grant of authority to the states to 
    preempt federal regulation in these cases undercuts the suggestion that 
    Congress sought to establish federal access regulations of universal 
    applicability. Moreover, we do not find it significant that the access 
    provisions of sections 251 and 271 contain no specific reference to the 
    preemptive authority of states under section 224(c)(1), since both 
    provisions expressly refer to section 224 generally.
    
    [[Page 45597]]
    
        819. Thus, when a state has exercised its preemptive authority 
    under section 224(c)(1), a LEC satisfies its duty under section 
    251(b)(4) to afford access by complying with the state's regulations. 
    If a state has not exercised such preemptive authority, the LEC must 
    comply with the federal rules. Similarly, when a telecommunications 
    carrier seeks access rights from an incumbent LEC by choosing to avail 
    itself of the negotiation and arbitration procedures established in 
    section 252, a state that has exercised its preemption rights will 
    apply its own set of regulations in the arbitration process pursuant to 
    section 252 (c)(1). Finally, we note that state regulation in this area 
    is subject to the provisions of section 253.
        820. We note that Congress did not amend section 224(c)(2) to 
    prescribe a certification procedure with respect to access (as distinct 
    from the rates, terms, and conditions of access). Therefore, upon the 
    filing of an access complaint with the Commission, the defending party 
    or the state itself should come forward to apprise us whether the state 
    is regulating such matters. If so, we shall dismiss the complaint 
    without prejudice to it being brought in the appropriate state forum. A 
    party seeking to show that a state regulates access issues should cite 
    to state laws and regulations governing access and establishing a 
    procedure for resolving access complaints in a state forum. Especially 
    probative will be a requirement that the relevant state authority 
    resolve an access complaint within a set period of time following the 
    filing of the complaint.
    
    C. Imposing Additional Obligations on LECS
    
    1. Background
        821. Section 251(c) imposes obligations on incumbent LECs in 
    addition to the obligations set forth in sections 251 (a) and (b). It 
    establishes obligations of incumbent LECs regarding: (1) good faith 
    negotiation; (2) interconnection; (3) unbundling network elements; (4) 
    resale; (5) providing notice of network changes; and (6) collocation.
        822. Section 251(h)(1) defines an incumbent LEC as a LEC within a 
    particular service area that: (1) as of the enactment of the 1996 Act, 
    provided telephone exchange service in such area; and (2) as of the 
    enactment of the 1996 Act, was deemed to be a member of the exchange 
    carrier association pursuant to 47 CFR Sec. 69.601(b) or, on or after 
    the enactment of the 1996 Act, became a successor or assign of such 
    carrier. Section 252(h)(2) provides that, ``[t]he Commission may, by 
    rule, provide for the treatment of a local exchange carrier (or class 
    or category thereof) as an incumbent local exchange carrier for 
    purposes of this section if (A) such carrier occupies a position in the 
    market for telephone exchange service within an area that is comparable 
    to the position occupied by a carrier described in paragraph (1); (B) 
    such carrier has substantially replaced an incumbent local exchange 
    carrier described in paragraph (1); and (C) such treatment is 
    consistent with the public interest, convenience, and necessity and the 
    purposes of this section.''
        823. In the NPRM, we sought comment on whether we should establish 
    at this time standards and procedures by which interested parties could 
    prove that a particular LEC should be treated as an incumbent LEC. We 
    also sought comment on whether carriers that are not deemed to be 
    incumbent LECs under section 251(h) may be required to comply with any 
    or all of the obligations that apply to incumbent LECs, and whether 
    states may impose on non-incumbent LECs the obligations that are 
    imposed on incumbent LECs under section 251(c).
    2. Discussion
        824. We conclude that allowing states to impose on non-incumbent 
    LECs obligations that the 1996 Act designates as ``Additional 
    Obligations on Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers,'' distinct from 
    obligations on all LECs, would be inconsistent with the statute. We 
    understand that some states may be imposing on non-incumbent LECs 
    obligations set forth in section 251(c). See, e.g., Colorado Commission 
    comments at 11-12; Draft Decision, State of Connecticut Department of 
    Public Utility Control, Docket No. 94-10-04 at 60, 65 (Connecticut 
    Commission July 11, 1996); Illinois Commission comments at 19. We 
    believe that these actions may be inconsistent with the 1996 Act. Some 
    parties assert that certain provisions of the 1996 Act, such as 
    sections 252(e)(3) and 253(b), explicitly permit states to impose 
    additional obligations. Such additional obligations, however, must be 
    consistent with the language and purposes of the 1996 Act.
        825. Section 251(h)(2) sets forth a process by which the FCC may 
    decide to treat LECs as incumbent LECs. Thus, when the conditions set 
    forth in section 251(h)(2) are met, the 1996 Act contemplates that new 
    entrants will be subject to the same obligations imposed on incumbents. 
    While we find that states may not unilaterally impose on non-incumbent 
    LECs obligations the 1996 Act expressly imposes only on incumbent LECs, 
    we find that state commissions or other interested parties could ask 
    the FCC to classify a carrier as an incumbent LEC pursuant to section 
    251(h)(2). At this time, we decline to adopt specific procedures or 
    standards for determining whether a LEC should be treated as an 
    incumbent LEC. Instead, we will permit interested parties to ask the 
    FCC to issue an order declaring a particular LEC or a class or category 
    of LECs to be treated as incumbent LECs. We expect to give particular 
    consideration to filings from state commissions. We further anticipate 
    that we will not impose incumbent LEC obligations on non-incumbent LECs 
    absent a clear and convincing showing that the LEC occupies a position 
    in the telephone exchange market comparable to the position held by an 
    incumbent LEC, has substantially replaced an incumbent LEC, and that 
    such treatment would serve the public interest, convenience, and 
    necessity and the purposes of section 251.
    
    XI. Exemptions, Suspensions, and Modifications of Section 251 
    Requirements
    
    A. Background
    
        826. Section 251(f)(1) grants rural telephone companies an 
    exemption from section 251(c), until the rural telephone company has 
    received a bona fide request for interconnection, services, or network 
    elements, and the state commission determines that the exemption should 
    be terminated. A rural telephone company is defined as a local exchange 
    carrier operating entity to the extent that such entity ``(A) provides 
    common carrier service to any local exchange carrier study area that 
    does not include either-- (i) any incorporated place of 10,000 
    inhabitants or more, or any part thereof * * *; or (ii) any territory, 
    incorporated or unincorporated, included in an urbanized area * * *; 
    (B) provides telephone exchange service, including exchange access, to 
    fewer than 50,000 access lines; (C) provides telephone exchange service 
    to any local exchange carrier study area with fewer than 100,000 access 
    lines; or (D) has less than 15 percent of its access lines in 
    communities of more than 50,000 on the date of enactment of the 
    Telecommunications Act of 1996.'' 47 U.S.C. 153(37). Section 251(f)(2) 
    allows LECs with fewer than two percent of the nation's subscriber 
    lines to petition a state commission for a suspension or modification 
    of any requirements of sections 251 (b) and (c). Section 251(f)
    
    [[Page 45598]]
    
    imposes a duty on state commissions to make determinations under this 
    section, and establishes the criteria and procedures for the state 
    commissions to follow. In the NPRM, we tentatively concluded that state 
    commissions have the sole authority to make determinations under 
    section 251(f). In addition, we sought comment on whether we should 
    issue guidelines to assist state commissions when they make 
    determinations regarding exemptions, suspensions, or modifications 
    under section 251(f).
        827. Although subsections (f)(1) and (f)(2) both address the 
    circumstances under which an incumbent LEC could be relieved of duties 
    otherwise imposed by section 251, subsection 251(f)(2) also applies to 
    non-incumbent LECs. The standard for determining whether to exempt a 
    carrier under subsection 251(f)(1) is different from the standard for 
    determining whether to grant a suspension or modification under 
    subsection (f)(2). Subsection 251(f)(1)(B) requires state commissions 
    to determine that terminating a rural exemption is consistent with the 
    universal service provisions of the 1996 Act. Subsection 
    251(f)(2)(A)(i) requires state commissions to grant a suspension or 
    modification if it is necessary to ``avoid a significant adverse 
    economic impact on users of telecommunications services generally,'' 
    and subsection 251(f)(2)(B) requires a suspension or modification to be 
    ``consistent with the public interest, convenience, and necessity.'' 
    Although we address these two subsections together, we highlight 
    instances in which we believe that differences in statutory language 
    require different treatment by state commissions.
        828. We discuss below issues raised by the commenters, and 
    establish some rules regarding the requirements of section 251(f) that 
    we believe will assist state commissions as they carry out their duties 
    under section 251(f). For the most part, however, we expect that states 
    will interpret the requirements of section 251(f) through rulemaking 
    and adjudicative proceedings. We may in the future initiate a Notice of 
    Proposed Rulemaking on certain additional issues raised by section 
    251(f) if it appears that further action by the Commission is 
    warranted.
    
    B. Need for National Rules
    
    1. Discussion
        829. We agree with parties, including small incumbent LECs, who 
    argue that determining whether a telephone company is entitled, 
    pursuant to section 251(f), to exemption, suspension, or modification 
    of the requirements of section 251 generally should be left to state 
    commissions. Requests made pursuant to section 251(f) seek to carve out 
    exceptions to application of the section 251 rules that we are 
    establishing in this proceeding. We find that Congress intended the 
    section 251 requirements, and the Commission's implementing rules 
    thereunder, to apply to all carriers throughout the country, except in 
    the circumstances delineated in the statute. We find convincing 
    assertions that it would be an overwhelming task at this time for the 
    Commission to try to anticipate and establish national rules for 
    determining when our generally-applicable rules should not be imposed 
    upon carriers. Therefore, we establish in this Order a very limited set 
    of rules that will assist states in their application of the provisions 
    in section 251(f).
        830. Many parties have proposed varying interpretations of the 
    provisions in section 251(f), and have asked for Commission 
    determination or a statement of agreement. Because it appears that many 
    parties welcome some guidance from the Commission, we briefly set forth 
    our interpretation of certain provisions of section 251(f). Such 
    statements will assist parties and, in particular, state commissions 
    that must make determinations regarding requests for exemption, 
    suspension, and modification.
    
    C. Application of Section 251(f)
    
    1. Discussion
        831. Congress generally intended the requirements in section 251 to 
    apply to carriers across the country, but Congress recognized that in 
    some cases, it might be unfair or inappropriate to apply all of the 
    requirements to smaller or rural telephone companies. We believe that 
    Congress intended exemption, suspension, or modification of the section 
    251 requirements to be the exception rather than the rule, and to apply 
    only to the extent, and for the period of time, that policy 
    considerations justify such exemption, suspension, or modification. We 
    believe that Congress did not intend to insulate smaller or rural LECs 
    from competition, and thereby prevent subscribers in those communities 
    from obtaining the benefits of competitive local exchange service. 
    Thus, we believe that, in order to justify continued exemption once a 
    bona fide request has been made, or to justify suspension, or 
    modification of the Commission's section 251 requirements, a LEC must 
    offer evidence that application of those requirements would be likely 
    to cause undue economic burdens beyond the economic burdens typically 
    associated with efficient competitive entry. State commissions will 
    need to decide on a case-by-case basis whether such a showing has been 
    made.
        832. Given the pro-competitive focus of the 1996 Act, we find that 
    rural LECs must prove to the state commission that they should continue 
    to be exempt pursuant to section 251(f)(1) from requirements of section 
    251(c), once a bona-fide request has been made, and that smaller 
    companies must prove to the state commission, pursuant to section 
    251(f)(2), that a suspension or modification of requirements of 
    sections 251 (b) or (c) should be granted. We conclude that it is 
    appropriate to place the burden of proof on the party seeking relief 
    from otherwise applicable requirements. Moreover, the party seeking 
    exemption, suspension, or modification is in control of the relevant 
    information necessary for the state to make a determination regarding 
    the request. A rural company that falls within section 251(f)(1) is not 
    required to make any showing until it receives a bona fide request for 
    interconnection, services, or network elements. We decline at this time 
    to establish guidelines regarding what constitutes a bona fide request. 
    We also decline in this Report and Order to adopt national rules or 
    guidelines regarding other aspects of section 251(f). For example, we 
    will not rule in this proceeding on the universal service duties of 
    requesting carriers that seek to compete with rural LECs. We may offer 
    guidance on these matters at a later date, if we believe it is 
    necessary and appropriate.
        833. We find that Congress intended section 251(f)(2) only to apply 
    to companies that, at the holding company level, have fewer than two 
    percent of subscriber lines nationwide. This is consistent with the 
    fact that the standard is based on the percent of subscriber lines that 
    a carrier has ``in the aggregate nationwide.'' Moreover, any other 
    interpretation would permit almost any company, including Bell 
    Atlantic, Ameritech, and GTE affiliates, to take advantage of the 
    suspension and modification provisions in section 251(f)(2). Such a 
    conclusion would render the two percent limitation virtually 
    meaningless.
        834. We note that some parties recommend that, in adopting rules 
    pursuant to section 251, the Commission provide different treatment or 
    impose different obligations on smaller or rural carriers. We conclude 
    that section 251(f) adequately provides for varying treatment for 
    smaller or rural LECs where such variances are justified in particular 
    instances. We conclude
    
    [[Page 45599]]
    
    that there is no basis in the record for adopting other special rules, 
    or limiting the application of our rules to smaller or rural LECs.
    
    XIII. Advanced Telecommunications Capabilities
    
        835. Section 706(a) provides that the Commission ``shall encourage 
    the deployment on a reasonable and timely basis of advanced 
    telecommunications capability to all Americans (including, in 
    particular, elementary and secondary schools and classrooms) by 
    utilizing, in a manner consistent with the public interest, 
    convenience, and necessity, price cap regulation, regulatory 
    forbearance, measures that promote competition in the local 
    telecommunications market, or other regulating methods that remove 
    barriers to infrastructure investment.'' In the NPRM, we sought comment 
    on how we can advance Congress's section 706(a) goal within the context 
    of our implementation of sections 251 and 252.
        836. A number of parties suggest that rules allowing them to 
    compete effectively and earn a profit in the telecommunications 
    industry would assist the industry in providing telecommunications 
    services to all Americans. MFS suggests that ``all LECs should be 
    required, as a condition of eligibility for universal service 
    subsidies, to meet network modernization standards for rural telephone 
    companies.'' Several state commissions indicate that they have already 
    established programs to assist institutions eligible under section 706 
    in deploying advanced telecommunications services. The Alliance for 
    Public Technology asserts that section 706 should underlie all of the 
    FCC's proceedings. Ericsson states that the industry should work with 
    government agencies to promote leading edge technology to ensure that 
    it is introduced on a reasonably timely basis. For example, it contends 
    that ``Plug and Play Internet use'' will greatly help the public and 
    schools access information, and that advanced technology such as 
    asynchronous transfer mode (ATM), wireless data/video, and AIN will 
    enhance interconnection capabilities of public and private networks. 
    The Illinois Commission contends that, depending on the pricing 
    standard the Commission adopts for interconnection and access to 
    unbundled elements, and the Commission's interpretation of the 
    prohibition against discrimination, the Commission should adopt special 
    rules for carriers when they provide interconnection or access to 
    unbundled network elements to serve a school, library, or healthcare 
    provider.
        837. We decline to adopt rules regarding section 706 in this 
    proceeding. We intend to address issues related to section 706 in a 
    separate proceeding.
    
    XIV. Provisions of Section 252
    
    A. Section 252(e)(5)
    
    1. Background
        838. Section 252(e)(5) directs the Commission to assume 
    responsibility for any proceeding or matter in which the state 
    commission ``fails to act to carry out its responsibility'' under 
    section 252. In the NPRM, we asked whether the Commission should 
    establish rules and regulations necessary to carry out our obligation 
    under section 252(e)(5). In addition, we sought comment on whether in 
    this proceeding we should establish regulations necessary and 
    appropriate to carry out our obligations under section 252(e)(5). In 
    particular, we sought comment on what constitutes notice of failure to 
    act, what procedures, if any, we should establish for parties to notify 
    the Commission, and what are the circumstances under which a state 
    commission should be deemed to have ``fail[ed] to act'' under section 
    252(e)(5).
        839. Section 252(e)(4) provides that, if the state commission does 
    not approve or reject (1) a negotiated agreement within 90 days, or (2) 
    an arbitrated agreement within 30 days, from the time the agreement is 
    submitted by the parties, the agreement shall be ``deemed approved.'' 
    We sought comment on the relationship between this provision and our 
    obligation to assume responsibility under section 252(e)(5). We also 
    sought comment on whether the Commission, once it assumes the 
    responsibility of the state commission, is bound by all of the laws and 
    standards that would have applied to the state commission, and whether 
    the Commission is authorized to determine whether an agreement is 
    consistent with applicable state law as the state commission would have 
    been under section 252(e)(3). In addition, we sought comment on 
    whether, once the Commission assumes responsibility under section 
    252(e)(5), it retains jurisdiction, or whether that matter or 
    proceeding subsequently should be remanded to the state.
        840. Finally, we sought comment on whether we should adopt, in this 
    proceeding, some standards or methods for arbitrating disputes in the 
    event we must conduct an arbitration under section 252(e)(5). We noted 
    some of the benefits and drawbacks of both ``final offer'' arbitration 
    and open-ended arbitration, and asked for comment on both.
    2. Discussion
        841. After careful review of the record, we are convinced that 
    establishing regulations to carry out our obligations under section 
    252(e)(5) will provide for an efficient and fair transition from state 
    jurisdiction should we have to assume the responsibility of the state 
    commission under Section 252(e)(5). The rules we establish in this 
    section with respect to arbitration under section 252 apply only to 
    instances where the Commission assumes jurisdiction under section 
    252(e)(5); we do not purport to advise states on how to conduct 
    arbitration when the Commission has not assumed jurisdiction. The rules 
    we establish will give notice of the procedures and standards the 
    Commission would apply to mediation and arbitration, avoid delay if the 
    Commission had to arbitrate disputes in the near future, and may also 
    offer guidance the states may, at their discretion, wish to consider in 
    implementing their own mediation and arbitration procedures and 
    standards. We decline to adopt national rules governing state 
    arbitration procedures. We believe the states are in a better position 
    to develop mediation and arbitration rules that support the objectives 
    of the 1996 Act. States may develop specific measures that address the 
    concerns of small entities and small incumbent LECs participating in 
    mediation or arbitration.
        842. The rules we adopt herein are minimum, interim procedures. 
    Adopting minimum interim procedures now will allow the Commission to 
    learn from the initial experiences and gain a better understanding of 
    what types of situations may arise that require Commission action. We 
    note that the Commission is not required to adopt procedures and 
    standards for mediation and arbitration within the six-month statutory 
    deadline and that, by adopting minimum interim procedures, the 
    Commission can better direct its resources to more pressing matters 
    that fall within the six-month statutory deadline.
        843. Regarding what constitutes a state's ``failure to act to carry 
    out its responsibility under'' section 252, the Commission was 
    presented with numerous options. The Commission will not take an 
    expansive view of what constitutes a state's ``failure to act.'' 
    Instead, the Commission interprets ``failure to act'' to mean a state's 
    failure to complete its duties in a timely manner. This would limit 
    Commission action to instances where a state commission fails to 
    respond, within a reasonable time, to a request for
    
    [[Page 45600]]
    
    mediation or arbitration, or fails to complete arbitration within the 
    time limits of section 252(b)(4)(C). The Commission will place the 
    burden of proof on parties alleging that the state commission has 
    failed to respond to a request for mediation or arbitration within a 
    reasonable time frame. We note the work done by states to date in 
    putting in place procedures and regulations governing arbitration and 
    believe that states will meet their responsibilities and obligations 
    under the 1996 Act. See, e.g., In the Matter of the Implementation of 
    the Mediation and Arbitration Provisions of the Federal 
    Telecommunications Act of 1996, Case No. 96-463-TP-UNC, Ohio 
    Commission, (May 30, 1996); Illinois Commerce Commission On Its Own 
    Motion Adoption of 83 Ill. Adm. Code 761 to Implement the Arbitration 
    Provisions of Section 252 of the Telecommunications Act of 1996, Docket 
    No. 96-0297, Illinois Commission (June 14, 1996).
        844. We agree with the majority of commenters that argue that our 
    authority to assume the state commission's responsibilities is not 
    triggered when an agreement is ``deemed approved'' under section 
    252(e)(4) due to state commission inaction. Section 252(e)(4) provides 
    for automatic approval if a state fails to approve or reject a 
    negotiated or arbitrated agreement within 90 days or 30 days, 
    respectively. Rules of statutory construction require us to give 
    meaning to all provisions and to read provisions consistently, where it 
    is possible to do so. We thus conclude that the most reasonable 
    interpretation is that automatic approval under section 252(e)(4) does 
    not constitute a failure to act.
        845. We also believe that we should establish interim procedures 
    for interested parties to notify the Commission that a state commission 
    has failed to act under section 252. We believe that parties should be 
    required to file a detailed written petition, backed by affidavit, that 
    will, at the outset, give the Commission a better understanding of the 
    issues involved and the action, or lack of action, taken by the state 
    commission. Allowing less detailed notification increases the 
    likelihood that frivolous requests will be made. With less detailed 
    notification, the Commission's investigations would be broader and more 
    burdensome. A detailed written petition will facilitate a decision 
    about whether the Commission should assume jurisdiction based on 
    section 252(e)(5).
        846. The moving party should submit a petition to the Secretary of 
    the Commission stating with specificity the basis for the petition and 
    any information that supports the claim that the state has failed to 
    act, including, but not limited to the applicable provision(s) of the 
    Act and the factual circumstances which support a finding that a state 
    has failed to act. The moving party must ensure that the applicable 
    state commission and the parties to the proceeding or matter for which 
    preemption is sought are served with the petition on the same date the 
    party serves the petition on the Commission. The petition will serve as 
    notice to parties to the state proceeding and the state commission who 
    will have fifteen days from the date the petition is filed with the 
    Commission to comment. Under section 252(e)(5), the Commission must 
    ``issue an order preempting the state commission's jurisdiction of that 
    proceeding or matter'' no later than 90 days from the date the petition 
    is filed. If the Commission takes notice, as section 252(e)(5) permits, 
    that a state commission has failed to act, it will, on its own motion, 
    issue a public notice and provide fifteen days for interested parties 
    to submit comment on whether the Commission should assume 
    responsibility under section 252(e)(5).
        847. If the Commission assumes authority under section 252(e)(5), 
    the Commission must also decide whether it retains authority for that 
    proceeding or matter. We agree with those parties who argue that, once 
    the Commission assumes jurisdiction of a proceeding or matter, it 
    retains authority for that proceeding or matter. For example, if the 
    Commission obtains jurisdiction after a state commission fails to 
    respond to a request for arbitration, the Commission maintains 
    jurisdiction over the arbitration proceeding. Therefore, once the 
    proceeding is before the Commission, any and all further action 
    regarding that proceeding or matter will be before the Commission. We 
    note that there is no provision in the Act for returning jurisdiction 
    to the state commission; moreover, the Commission, with significant 
    knowledge of the issues at hand, would be in the best position 
    efficiently to conclude the matter. Thus, as both a legal and policy 
    matter, we believe that the Commission retains jurisdiction over any 
    matter and proceeding for which it assumes responsibility under Section 
    252(e)(5).
        848. We reject the suggestion by some parties that, once the 
    Commission has mediated or arbitrated an agreement, the agreement must 
    be submitted to the state commission for approval under state law. We 
    note that section 252(e)(5) provides for the Commission to ``assume the 
    responsibility of the State commission under this section with respect 
    to the proceeding or matter and act for the State commission.'' This 
    includes acting for the state commission under section 252(e)(1), which 
    calls for state commission approval of ``any interconnection agreement 
    adopted by negotiation or arbitration.'' We, therefore, do not read 
    section 252(e)(1) or any other provision as calling for state 
    commission approval or rejection of agreements mediated or arbitrated 
    by the Commission. In those instances where a state has failed to act, 
    the Commission acts on behalf of the state and no additional state 
    approval is required.
        849. Requirements set forth in section 252(c) for arbitrated 
    agreements would apply to arbitration conducted by the Commission. We 
    see no reason, and no party has suggested a policy or legal basis, for 
    not applying such standards when the Commission conducts arbitration. 
    Thus, arbitrated agreements must: (1) meet the requirements of section 
    251, including regulations prescribed by the Commission pursuant to 
    section 251; (2) establish any rates for interconnection, services, or 
    network elements according to section 252(d); and (3) provide a 
    schedule for implementation of the terms and conditions by the parties 
    to the agreement. We reject the suggestion made by some parties that, 
    if the Commission steps into the state commission role, it is bound by 
    state laws and standards that would have applied to the state 
    commission. While states are permitted to establish and enforce other 
    requirements, these are not binding standards for arbitrated agreements 
    under section 252(c). Moreover, the resources and time potentially 
    needed to review adequately and interpret the different laws and 
    standards of each state render this suggestion untenable. Finally, we 
    conclude that it would not make sense to apply to the Commission the 
    timing requirements that section 252(b)(4)(c) imposes on state 
    commissions. The Commission, in some instances, might not even assume 
    jurisdiction until nine months (or more) have lapsed since a section 
    251 request was initiated.
        850. Based on the comments of the parties, we conclude that a 
    ``final offer'' method of arbitration, similar to the approach 
    recommended by Vanguard, would best serve the public interest. Under 
    ``final offer'' arbitration, each party to the negotiation proposes its 
    best and final offer and the arbitrator determines which of the 
    proposals become binding. The arbitrator would
    
    [[Page 45601]]
    
    have the option of choosing one of the two proposals in its entirety, 
    or the arbitrator could decide on an issue-by-issue basis. Each final 
    offer must: (1) meet the requirements of section 251, including the 
    Commission's rules thereunder; (2) establish rates for interconnection, 
    services, or network elements according to section 252(d); and (3) 
    provide a schedule for implementation of the terms and conditions by 
    the parties to the agreement. If a final offer submitted by one or more 
    parties fails to comply with these requirements, the arbitrator would 
    have discretion to take steps designed to result in an arbitrated 
    agreement that satisfies the requirements of section 252(c), including 
    requiring parties to submit new final offers within a time frame 
    specified by the arbitrator, or adopting a result not submitted by any 
    party that is consistent with the requirements in section 252(c).
        851. The parties could continue to negotiate an agreement after 
    they submit their proposals and before the arbitrator makes a decision. 
    Under this approach, the Commission will encourage negotiations, with 
    or without the assistance of the arbitrator, to continue after 
    arbitration offers are exchanged. Parties are not precluded from 
    submitting subsequent final offers following such negotiations. We 
    believe that permitting post-offer negotiations will increase the 
    likelihood that the parties will reach consensus on unresolved issues. 
    In addition, permitting post-offer negotiations will increase 
    flexibility and will allow parties to tailor counter-proposals after 
    arbitration offers are exchanged. To provide an opportunity for final 
    post-offer negotiation, the arbitrator will not issue a decision for at 
    least 15 days after submission of the final offers by the parties. In 
    addition, the offers must be consistent with section 251, including the 
    regulations prescribed by the Commission. We reject SBC's suggestion 
    that an arbitrated agreement is not binding on the parties. Absent 
    mutual agreement to different terms, the decision reached through 
    arbitration is binding. We conclude that it would be inconsistent with 
    the 1996 Act to require incumbent LECs to provide interconnection, 
    services, and unbundled elements, impose a duty to negotiate in good 
    faith and a right to arbitration, and then permit incumbent LECs to not 
    be bound by an arbitrated determination. We also believe that, although 
    competing providers do not have an affirmative duty to enter into 
    agreements under section 252, a requesting carrier might face penalties 
    if, by refusing to enter into an arbitrated agreement, that carrier is 
    deemed to have failed to negotiate in good faith. Such penalties should 
    serve as a disincentive for requesting carriers to force an incumbent 
    LEC to expand resources in arbitration if the requesting carrier does 
    not intend to abide by the arbitrated decision.
        852. Adopting a ``final offer'' method of arbitration and 
    encouraging negotiations to continue allows us to maintain the benefits 
    of final offer arbitration, giving parties an incentive to submit 
    realistic ``final offers,'' while providing additional flexibility for 
    the parties to agree to a resolution that best serves their interests. 
    To the extent that these procedures encourage parties to negotiate 
    voluntarily rather than arbitrate, such negotiated agreements will be 
    subject to review pursuant to section 252(e)(2)(A), which would allow 
    the Commission to reject agreements if they are inconsistent with the 
    public interest. This approach also addresses the argument that under 
    ``final offer'' arbitration neither offer might best serve the public 
    interest, because it allows the parties to obtain feedback from the 
    arbitrator on public interest matters.
        853. We believe that the arbitration proceedings generally should 
    be limited to the requesting carrier and the incumbent local exchange 
    provider. This will allow for a more efficient process and minimize the 
    amount of time needed to resolve disputed issues. We believe that 
    opening the process to all third parties would be unwieldy and would 
    delay the process. We will, however, consider requests by third parties 
    to submit written pleadings. This may, in some instances, allow 
    interested parties to identify important public policy issues not 
    raised by parties to an arbitration.
    
    B. Requirements of Section 252(i)
    
     1. Background
        854. Section 251 requires that interconnection, unbundled element, 
    and collocation rates be ``nondiscriminatory'' and prohibits the 
    imposition of ``discriminatory conditions'' on the resale of 
    telecommunications services. Section 252(i) of the 1996 Act provides 
    that a ``local exchange carrier shall make available any 
    interconnection, service, or network element provided under an 
    agreement approved under [section 252] to which it is a party to any 
    other requesting telecommunications carrier upon the same terms and 
    conditions as those provided in the agreement.'' In the NPRM, we 
    expressed the view that section 252(i) appears to be a primary tool of 
    the 1996 Act for preventing discrimination under section 251, and we 
    sought comment on whether we should adopt national standards for 
    resolving disputes under section 252(i) in the event that we must 
    assume the state's responsibilities pursuant to section 252(e)(5). In 
    addition, because we may need to interpret section 252(i) if we assume 
    the state commission's responsibilities, we sought comment on the 
    meaning of section 252(i).
        855. We also sought comment in the NPRM on whether section 252(i) 
    requires that only similarly-situated carriers may enforce against 
    incumbent LECs provisions of agreements filed with state commissions, 
    and, if so, how ``similarly-situated carrier'' should be defined. In 
    particular, we asked whether section 252(i) requires that the same 
    rates for interconnection must be offered to all requesting carriers 
    regardless of the cost of serving that carrier, or whether it would be 
    consistent with the statute to permit different rates if the costs of 
    serving carriers are different. We also asked whether the section can 
    be interpreted to allow incumbent LECs to make available 
    interconnection, services, or network elements only to requesting 
    carriers serving a comparable class of subscribers or providing the 
    same service (i.e., local, access, or interexchange) as the original 
    parties to the agreement. In the NPRM, we tentatively concluded that 
    the language of the statute appears to preclude such differential 
    treatment among carriers.
        856. Additionally, we sought comment in the NPRM on whether section 
    252(i) permits requesting telecommunications carriers to choose among 
    individual provisions of publicly-filed interconnection agreements or 
    whether they must subscribe to an entire agreement. We also sought 
    comment regarding what time period an agreement must remain available 
    for use by other requesting telecommunications carriers.
    2. Discussion
        857. We conclude that it will assist the carriers in determining 
    their respective obligations, facilitate the development of a single, 
    uniform legal interpretation of the Act's requirements and promote a 
    procompetitive, national policy framework to adopt national standards 
    to implement section 252(i). Issues such as whether section 252(i) 
    allows requesting telecommunications carriers to choose among 
    provisions of prior interconnection agreements or requires them to 
    accept an entire agreement are issues of law that should not vary from 
    state to state and are also central to the statutory scheme and to
    
    [[Page 45602]]
    
    the emergence of competition. National standards will help state 
    commissions and parties to expedite the resolution of disputes under 
    section 252(i).
        858. We conclude that the text of section 252(i) supports 
    requesting carriers' ability to choose among individual provisions 
    contained in publicly filed interconnection agreements. As we note 
    above, section 252(i) provides that a ``local exchange carrier shall 
    make available any interconnection, service, or network element 
    provided under an agreement * * * to which it is a party to any other 
    requesting telecommunications carrier upon the same terms and 
    conditions as those provided in the agreement.'' Thus, Congress drew a 
    distinction between ``any interconnection, service, or network 
    element[s] provided under an agreement,'' which the statute lists 
    individually, and agreements in their totality. Requiring requesting 
    carriers to elect entire agreements, instead of the provisions relating 
    to specific elements, would render as mere surplusage the words ``any 
    interconnection, service, or network element.''
        859. We disagree with BellSouth regarding the significance of the 
    legislative history quoted in the NPRM. The Conference Committee 
    amended section 251(g), S. 652's predecessor to section 252(i), and 
    changed ``service, facility, or function'' to ``interconnection, 
    service, or element.'' The House of Representatives' bill did not 
    contain a version of section 252(i). Although H.R. 1555's section 
    244(d) contained similar ideas, its language and structure are 
    sufficiently different from that of section 252(i) that we do not 
    consider section 244(d) to be a prior version of section 252(i). We 
    find that section 252(i)'s language does not differ substantively from 
    the text of the Senate bill's section 251(g). The Senate Commerce 
    Committee stated its provision, section 251(g), was intended to ``make 
    interconnection more efficient by making available to other carriers 
    the individual elements of agreements that have been previously 
    negotiated.''
        860. We also find that practical concerns support our 
    interpretation. As observed by AT&T and others, failure to make 
    provisions available on an unbundled basis could encourage an incumbent 
    LEC to insert into its agreement onerous terms for a service or element 
    that the original carrier does not need, in order to discourage 
    subsequent carriers from making a request under that agreement. In 
    addition, we observe that different new entrants face differing 
    technical constraints and costs. Since few new entrants would be 
    willing to elect an entire agreement that would not reflect their costs 
    and the specific technical characteristics of their networks or would 
    not be consistent with their business plans, requiring requesting 
    carriers to elect an entire agreement would appear to eviscerate the 
    obligation Congress imposed in section 252(i).
        861. We also choose this interpretation despite concerns voiced by 
    some incumbent LECs that allowing carriers to choose among provisions 
    will harm the public interest by slowing down the process of reaching 
    interconnection agreements by making incumbent LECs less likely to 
    compromise. In reaching this conclusion, we observe that new entrants, 
    who stand to lose the most if negotiations are delayed, generally do 
    not argue that concern over slow negotiations would outweigh the 
    benefits they would derive from being able to choose among terms of 
    publicly filed agreements. Unbundled access to agreement provisions 
    will enable smaller carriers who lack bargaining power to obtain 
    favorable terms and conditions--including rates--negotiated by large 
    IXCs, and speed the emergence of robust competition.
        862. We conclude that incumbent LECs must permit third parties to 
    obtain access under section 252(i) to any individual interconnection, 
    service, or network element arrangement on the same terms and 
    conditions as those contained in any agreement approved under section 
    252. We find that this level of disaggregation is mandated by section 
    252(a)(1), which requires that agreements shall include ``charges for 
    interconnection and each service or network element included in the 
    agreement,'' and section 251(c)(3), which requires incumbent LECs to 
    provide ``non-discriminatory access to network elements on an unbundled 
    basis.'' In practical terms, this means that a carrier may obtain 
    access to individual elements such as unbundled loops at the same 
    rates, terms, and conditions as contained in any approved agreement. We 
    agree with ALTS that such a view comports with the statute, and lessens 
    the concerns of carriers that argue that unbundled availability will 
    delay negotiations.
        863. We reject GTE's argument that section 252(i)'s statement, that 
    requesting carriers must receive individual elements ``upon the same 
    terms and conditions'' as those contained in the agreement, precludes 
    unbundled availability of individual elements. GTE's argument fails to 
    give meaning to Congress's distinction between agreements and elements, 
    and ignores the 1996 Act's prime goals of nondiscriminatory treatment 
    of carriers and promotion of competition. Instead, we conclude that the 
    ``same terms and conditions'' that an incumbent LEC may insist upon 
    shall relate solely to the individual interconnection, service, or 
    element being requested under section 252(i). For instance, where an 
    incumbent LEC and a new entrant have agreed upon a rate contained in a 
    five-year agreement, section 252(i) does not necessarily entitle a 
    third party to receive the same rate for a three-year commitment. 
    Similarly, that one carrier has negotiated a volume discount on loops 
    does not automatically entitle a third party to obtain the same rate 
    for a smaller amount of loops. Given the primary purpose of section 
    252(i) of preventing discrimination, we require incumbent LECs seeking 
    to require a third party agree to certain terms and conditions to 
    exercise its rights under section 252(i) to prove to the state 
    commission that the terms and conditions were legitimately related to 
    the purchase of the individual element being sought. By contrast, 
    incumbent LECs may not require as a ``same'' term or condition the new 
    entrant's agreement to terms and conditions relating to other 
    interconnection, services, or elements in the approved agreement. 
    Moreover, incumbent LEC efforts to restrict availability of 
    interconnection, services, or elements under section 252(i) also must 
    comply with the 1996 Act's general nondiscrimination provisions. See 
    Section VII.d.3.
        864. We further conclude that section 252(i) entitles all parties 
    with interconnection agreements to ``most favored nation'' status 
    regardless of whether they include ``most favored nation'' clauses in 
    their agreements. Congress's command under section 252(i) was that 
    parties may utilize any individual interconnection, service, or element 
    in publicly filed interconnection agreements and incorporate it into 
    the terms of their interconnection agreement. This means that any 
    requesting carrier may avail itself of more advantageous terms and 
    conditions subsequently negotiated by any other carrier for the same 
    individual interconnection, service, or element once the subsequent 
    agreement is filed with, and approved by, the state commission. We 
    believe the approach we adopt will maximize competition by ensuring 
    that carriers' obtain access to terms and elements on a 
    nondiscriminatory basis.
        865. We find that section 252(i) permits differential treatment 
    based on the LEC's cost of serving a carrier. We
    
    [[Page 45603]]
    
    further observe that section 252(d)(1) requires that unbundled element 
    rates be cost-based, and sections 251(c)(2) and (c)(3) require 
    incumbent LECs to provide only technically-feasible forms of 
    interconnection and access to unbundled elements, while section 252(i) 
    mandates that the availability of publicly-filed agreements be limited 
    to carriers willing to accept the same terms and conditions as the 
    carrier who negotiated the original agreement with the incumbent LEC. 
    We conclude that these provisions, read together, require that 
    publicly-filed agreements be made available only to carriers who cause 
    the incumbent LEC to incur no greater costs than the carrier who 
    originally negotiated the agreement, so as to result in an 
    interconnection arrangement that is both cost-based and technically 
    feasible. However, as discussed in Section VII regarding 
    discrimination, where an incumbent LEC proposes to treat one carrier 
    differently than another, the incumbent LEC must prove to the state 
    commission that that differential treatment is justified based on the 
    cost to the LEC of providing that element to the carrier.
        866. We conclude, however, that section 252(i) does not permit LECs 
    to limit the availability of any individual interconnection, service, 
    or network element only to those requesting carriers serving a 
    comparable class of subscribers or providing the same service (i.e., 
    local, access, or interexchange) as the original party to the 
    agreement. In our view, the class of customers, or the type of service 
    provided by a carrier, does not necessarily bear a direct relationship 
    with the costs incurred by the LEC to interconnect with that carrier or 
    on whether interconnection is technically feasible. Accordingly, we 
    conclude that an interpretation of section 252(i) that attempts to 
    limit availability by class of customer served or type of service 
    provided would be at odds with the language and structure of the 
    statute, which contains no such limitation.
        867. We agree with those commenters who suggest that agreements 
    remain available for use by requesting carriers for a reasonable amount 
    of time. Such a rule addresses incumbent LEC concerns over technical 
    incompatibility, while at the same time providing requesting carriers 
    with a reasonable time during which they may benefit from previously 
    negotiated agreements. In addition, this approach makes economic sense, 
    since the pricing and network configuration choices are likely to 
    change over time, as several commenters have observed. Given this 
    reality, it would not make sense to permit a subsequent carrier to 
    impose an agreement or term upon an incumbent LEC if the technical 
    requirements of implementing that agreement or term have changed.
        868. We observe that section 252(h) expressly provides that state 
    commissions maintain for public inspection copies of interconnection 
    agreements approved under section 252(e). We therefore decline Jones 
    Intercable's suggestion that we require carriers to file agreements at 
    the FCC, in addition to section 252(h)'s filing requirement. However, 
    when the Commission performs the state's responsibilities under section 
    252(e)(5), parties must file their agreements with the Commission, as 
    well as with the state commission. We note section 22.903(d) of our 
    rules, which remains in effect, requires the BOCs to file with us their 
    interconnection agreements with their affiliated cellular providers. 47 
    CFR Sec. 22.903(d).
        869. We further conclude that a carrier seeking interconnection, 
    network elements, or services pursuant to section 252(i) need not make 
    such requests pursuant to the procedures for initial section 251 
    requests, but shall be permitted to obtain its statutory rights on an 
    expedited basis. We find that this interpretation furthers Congress's 
    stated goals of opening up local markets to competition and permitting 
    interconnection on just, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory terms, and 
    that we should adopt measures that ensure competition occurs as quickly 
    and efficiently as possible. We conclude that the nondiscriminatory, 
    pro-competition purpose of section 252(i) would be defeated were 
    requesting carriers required to undergo a lengthy negotiation and 
    approval process pursuant to section 251 before being able to utilize 
    the terms of a previously approved agreement. Since agreements shall 
    necessarily be filed with the states pursuant to section 252(h), we 
    leave to state commissions in the first instance the details of the 
    procedures for making agreements available to requesting carriers on an 
    expedited basis. Because of the importance of section 252(i) in 
    preventing discrimination, however, we conclude that carriers seeking 
    remedies for alleged violations of section 252(i) shall be permitted to 
    obtain expedited relief at the Commission, including the resolution of 
    complaints under section 208 of the Communications Act, in addition to 
    their state remedies.
        870. We conclude as well that agreements negotiated prior to 
    enactment of the 1996 Act must be available for use by subsequent, 
    requesting carriers. Section 252(i) must be read in conjunction with 
    section 252(a)(1), which clearly states that ``agreement'' for purposes 
    of section 252, ``includ[es] any interconnection agreement negotiated 
    before the date of enactment * * *.'' We conclude that this language 
    demonstrates that Congress intended 252(i) to apply to agreements 
    negotiated prior to enactment of the 1996 Act and approved by the state 
    commission pursuant to section 252(e), as well as those approved under 
    the section 251/252 negotiation process. Accordingly, we find that 
    agreements negotiated prior to enactment of the 1996 Act must be 
    disclosed publicly, and be made available to requesting 
    telecommunications carriers pursuant to section 252(i).
        871. We also find that section 252(i) applies to interconnection 
    agreements between adjacent, incumbent LECs. We note that section 
    252(i) requires a local exchange carrier to make available to 
    requesting telecommunications carriers ``any interconnection service, 
    or network element provided under an agreement approved under this 
    section * * *.'' The plain meaning of this section is that any 
    interconnection agreement approved by a state commission, including one 
    between adjacent LECs, must be made available to requesting carriers 
    pursuant to section 252(i). Requiring availability of such agreements 
    will provide new entrants with a realistic benchmark upon which to base 
    negotiations, and this will further the Congressional purpose of 
    increasing competition. As stated in Section III of this Order, 
    adjacent, incumbent LECs will be given an opportunity to renegotiate 
    such agreements before they become subject to section 252(i)'s 
    requirements. In Section III, we also consider, and reject, the Rural 
    Tel. Coalition's argument that making agreements between adjacent, non-
    competing LECs available under section 252 will have a detrimental 
    effect on small, rural carriers. See Section III, supra.
    
    XV. Final Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
    
        872. As required by Section 603 of the Regulatory Flexibility Act 
    (RFA), 5 U.S.C. Sec. 603, an Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis 
    (IRFA) was incorporated in the NPRM. The Commission sought written 
    public comment on the proposals in the NPRM. The Commission's Final 
    Regulatory Flexibility Analysis (FRFA) in this Order conforms to the 
    RFA, as amended by the Contract With America Advancement Act of 1996 
    (CWAAA),
    
    [[Page 45604]]
    
    Public Law No. 104-121, 110 Stat. 847 (1996).
    
    A. Need for and Objectives of This Report and Order and the Rules 
    Adopted Herein
    
        873. The Commission, in compliance with section 251(d)(1) of the 
    Communications Act of 1934, as amended by the Telecommunications Act of 
    1996 (the 1996 Act), promulgates the rules in this Order to ensure the 
    prompt implementation of sections 251 and 252 of the 1996 Act, which 
    are the local competition provisions. Congress sought to establish 
    through the 1996 Act ``a pro-competitive, de-regulatory national policy 
    framework'' for the United States telecommunications industry. Three 
    principal goals of the telephony provisions of the 1996 Act are: (1) 
    opening local exchange and exchange access markets to competition; (2) 
    promoting increased competition in telecommunications markets that are 
    already open to competition, particularly long distance services 
    markets; and, (3) reforming our system of universal service so that 
    universal service is preserved and advanced as local exchange and 
    exchange access markets move from monopoly to competition.
        874. The rules adopted in this Order implement the first of these 
    goals--opening local exchange and exchange access markets to 
    competition. The objective of the rules adopted in this Order is to 
    implement as quickly and effectively as possible the national 
    telecommunications policies embodied in the 1996 Act and to promote the 
    development of competitive, deregulated markets envisioned by Congress. 
    In doing so, we are mindful of the balance that Congress struck between 
    this goal of bringing the benefits of competition to all consumers and 
    its concern for the impact of the 1996 Act on small incumbent local 
    exchange carriers, particularly rural carriers, as evidenced in section 
    251(f) of the 1996 Act.
    
    B. Analysis of Significant Issues Raised in Response to the IRFA
    
        875. Summary of the Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis (IRFA). 
    In the NPRM, the Commission performed an IRFA. In the IRFA, the 
    Commission found that the rules it proposed to adopt in this proceeding 
    may have a significant impact on a substantial number of small business 
    as defined by section 601(3) of the RFA. The Commission stated that its 
    regulatory flexibility analysis was inapplicable to incumbent LECs 
    because such entities are dominant in their field of operation. The 
    Commission noted, however, that it would take appropriate steps to 
    ensure that the special circumstances of smaller incumbent LECs are 
    carefully considered in our rulemaking. The Commission also found that 
    the proposed rules may overlap or conflict with the Commission's Part 
    69 access charge and Expanded Interconnection rules. Finally, the IRFA 
    solicited comment on alternatives to our proposed rules that would 
    minimize the impact on small entities consistent with the objectives of 
    this proceeding.
    1. Treatment of Small LECs
        876. Discussion. In essence, SBA and Rural Tel. Coalition argue 
    that we exceeded our authority under the RFA by certifying all 
    incumbent LECs as dominant in their field of operation, and concluding 
    on that basis that they are not small businesses under the RFA. SBA and 
    Rural Tel. Coalition contend that the authority to make a size 
    determination rests solely with SBA and that, by excluding a group 
    (small incumbent LECs) from coverage under the RFA, the Commission made 
    an unauthorized size determination. Neither SBA nor Rural Tel. 
    Coalition cites any specific authority for this latter proposition.
        877. We have found incumbent LECs to be ``dominant in their field 
    of operation'' since the early 1980's, and we consistently have 
    certified under the RFA that incumbent LECs are not subject to 
    regulatory flexibility analyses because they are not small businesses. 
    We have made similar determinations in other areas. We recognize SBA's 
    special role and expertise with regard to the RFA, and intend to 
    continue to consult with SBA outside the context of this proceeding to 
    ensure that the Commission is fully implementing the RFA. Although we 
    are not fully persuaded on the basis of this record that our prior 
    practice has been incorrect, in light of the special concerns raised by 
    SBA and Rural Tel. Coalition in this proceeding, we will, nevertheless, 
    include small incumbent LECs in this FRFA to remove any possible issue 
    of RFA compliance. We, therefore, need not address Rural Tel. 
    Coalition's arguments that incumbent LECs are not dominant.
    2. Other Issues
        878. Discussion. We disagree with SBA's assessment of our IRFA. 
    Although the IRFA referred only generally to the reporting and 
    recordkeeping requirements imposed on incumbent LECs, our Federal 
    Register notice set forth in detail the general reporting and 
    recordkeeping requirements as part of our Paperwork Reduction Act 
    statement. The IRFA also sought comment on the many alternatives 
    discussed in the body of the NPRM, including the statutory exemption 
    for certain rural telephone companies. The numerous general public 
    comments concerning the impact of our proposal on small entities in 
    response to the NPRM, including comments filed directly in response to 
    the IRFA, enabled us to prepare this FRFA. Thus, we conclude that the 
    IRFA was sufficiently detailed to enable parties to comment 
    meaningfully on the proposed rules and, thus, for us to prepare this 
    FRFA. We have been working with, and will continue to work with SBA, to 
    ensure that both our IRFAs and FRFAs fully meet the requirements of the 
    RFA.
        879. SBA also objects to the NPRM's requirement that responses to 
    the IRFA be filed under a separate and distinct heading, and proposes 
    that we integrate RFA comments into the body of general comments on a 
    rule. Almost since the adoption of the RFA, we have requested that IRFA 
    comments be submitted under a separate and distinct heading. Neither 
    the RFA nor SBA's rules prescribe the manner in which comments may be 
    submitted in response to an IRFA and, in such circumstances, it is well 
    established that an administrative agency can structure its proceedings 
    in any manner that it concludes will enable it to fulfill its statutory 
    duties. Based on our past practice, we find that separation of comments 
    responsive to the IRFA facilitates our preparation of a compulsory 
    summary of such comments and our responses to them, as required by the 
    RFA. Comments on the impact of our proposed rules on small entities 
    have been integrated into our analysis and consideration of the final 
    rules. We, therefore, reject SBA's argument that we improperly required 
    commenters to include their comments on the IRFA in a separate section.
        880. We also reject SBA's assertion that none of the alternatives 
    in the NPRM is designed to minimize the impact of the proposed rules on 
    small businesses. For example, we proposed that incumbent LECs be 
    required to offer competitors access to unbundled local loop, 
    switching, and transport facilities. These proposals permit potential 
    competitors to enter the market by relying, in part or entirely, on the 
    incumbent LEC's facilities. Reduced economic entry barriers are 
    designed to provide reasonable opportunities for new entrants, 
    particularly small entities, to enter the market by minimizing the 
    initial investment needed to begin providing service. In addition, we
    
    [[Page 45605]]
    
    believe section 251(f) and our rules provide states with significant 
    flexibility to ``deal with the needs of individual companies in light 
    of public interest concerns,'' as requested by the Idaho Commission. 
    With regard to the potential burdens on small entities other than 
    incumbent LECs, we believe our rules permit states to structure 
    arbitration procedures, for example, in ways that minimize filing or 
    other burdens on new entrants that are small entities.
        881. We also disagree with SCBA's assertion that the IRFA was 
    deficient because it did not identify small cable operators as entities 
    that would be affected by the proposed rules. The IRFA in the NPRM 
    states: ``Insofar as the proposals in this Notice apply to 
    telecommunications carriers other than incumbent LECs (generally 
    interexchange carriers and new LEC entrants), they may have a 
    significant impact on a substantial number of small entities.'' The 
    phrase ``new LEC entrants'' clearly encompasses small cable operators 
    that become providers of local exchange service. The NPRM even 
    identifies cable operators as potential new entrants.
        882. We agree with SCBA's argument that the Commission should 
    identify certain minimum standards to provide guidance on the 
    requirement that parties negotiate in good faith. As discussed in 
    Section III.B, we conclude that we should establish minimum standards 
    that will offer parties guidance in determining whether they are acting 
    in good faith. We believe that these minimum standards address SCBA's 
    assertion that federal guidelines for good faith negotiations may be 
    particularly important for small entities because unreasonable delays 
    in negotiations could represent an entry barrier for small entities.
        883. We also agree with SCBA's recommendation that we should 
    establish guidelines for the application of section 251(f) regarding 
    exemptions, suspensions, and modifications of our rules governing 
    interconnection with rural carriers. As discussed in section XII.B, we 
    find that a rural incumbent LEC should not be able to obtain an 
    exemption, suspension, or modification of its obligations under section 
    251 unless it offers evidence that the application of those 
    requirements would be likely to cause injury beyond the financial harm 
    typically associated with efficient competitive entry. We are also 
    persuaded by the suggestion of SCBA and others that incumbent LECs 
    should bear the burden of showing that they should be exempt pursuant 
    to section 251(f)(1) from national interconnection requirements. We 
    believe that this finding is consistent with the pro-competitive goals 
    of the 1996 Act and our determination in Section XII that Congress did 
    not intend to withhold from consumers the benefits of local telephone 
    competition that could be provided by small entities, such as small 
    cable operators.
        884. We do not adopt SCBA's proposal to establish abbreviated 
    arbitration procedures. Most commenters oppose adoption of federal 
    rules to govern state mediation and arbitration proceedings. As set out 
    in Section XIV.A, we conclude that state commissions are better 
    positioned to develop rules for mediation and arbitration that support 
    the objectives of the 1996 Act. The rules we adopt in Section XIV.A 
    apply only where the Commission assumes a state commission's 
    responsibilities pursuant to section 252(e)(5). States may develop 
    specific measures that address the concerns of small entities 
    participating in mediation or arbitration, as suggested by SCBA. In 
    addition, although we do not specifically incorporate SCBA's request 
    that the Commission designate a ``small company contact person at 
    incumbent LECs and state commissions,'' we find that a refusal 
    throughout the negotiation process to designate a representative with 
    authority to make binding representations on behalf of the party, and 
    thereby significantly delay resolution of issues, would constitute 
    failure to negotiate in good faith. Therefore, we conclude that the 
    potential benefits of SCBA's proposal are achieved by our determination 
    that the failure of an incumbent LEC to designate a person authorized 
    to bind his or her company in negotiations is a violation of the good 
    faith obligation of section 251.
    
    C. Description and Estimates of the Number of Small Entities Affected 
    by this Report and Order
    
        885. For the purposes of this Order, the RFA defines a ``small 
    business'' to be the same as a ``small business concern'' under the 
    Small Business Act, 15 U.S.C. 632, unless the Commission has developed 
    one or more definitions that are appropriate to its activities. Under 
    the Small Business Act, a ``small business concern'' is one that: (1) 
    Is independently owned and operated; (2) is not dominant in its field 
    of operation; and (3) meets any additional criteria established by the 
    Small Business Administration (SBA). SBA has defined businesses for 
    Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) categories 4812 
    (Radiotelephone Communications) and 4813 (Telephone Communications, 
    Except Radiotelephone) to be small entities when they have fewer than 
    1,500 employees. We first discuss generally the total number of small 
    telephone companies falling within both of those SIC categories. Then, 
    we discuss the number of small businesses within the two subcategories, 
    and attempt to refine further those estimates to correspond with the 
    categories of telephone companies that are commonly used under our 
    rules.
        886. Consistent with our prior practice, we shall continue to 
    exclude small incumbent LECs from the definition of a small entity for 
    the purpose of this FRFA. Nevertheless, as mentioned above, we include 
    small incumbent LECs in our FRFA. Accordingly, our use of the terms 
    ``small entities'' and ``small businesses'' does not encompass ``small 
    incumbent LECs.'' We use the term ``small incumbent LECs'' to refer to 
    any incumbent LECs that arguably might be defined by SBA as ``small 
    business concerns.''
    1. Telephone Companies (SIC 481)
        887. Total Number of Telephone Companies Affected. Many of the 
    decisions and rules adopted herein may have a significant effect on a 
    substantial number of the small telephone companies identified by SBA. 
    The United States Bureau of the Census (``the Census Bureau'') reports 
    that, at the end of 1992, there were 3,497 firms engaged in providing 
    telephone services, as defined therein, for at least one year. This 
    number contains a variety of different categories of carriers, 
    including local exchange carriers, interexchange carriers, competitive 
    access providers, cellular carriers, mobile service carriers, operator 
    service providers, pay telephone operators, PCS providers, covered SMR 
    providers, and resellers. It seems certain that some of those 3,497 
    telephone service firms may not qualify as small entities or small 
    incumbent LECs because they are not ``independently owned and 
    operated.'' For example, a PCS provider that is affiliated with an 
    interexchange carrier having more than 1,500 employees would not meet 
    the definition of a small business. It seems reasonable to conclude, 
    therefore, that fewer than 3,497 telephone service firms are small 
    entity telephone service firms or small incumbent LECs that may be 
    affected by this Order.
        888. Wireline Carriers and Service Providers. SBA has developed a 
    definition of small entities for telephone communications companies 
    other than radiotelephone (wireless) companies.
    
    [[Page 45606]]
    
    The Census Bureau reports that, there were 2,321 such telephone 
    companies in operation for at least one year at the end of 1992. 
    According to SBA's definition, a small business telephone company other 
    than a radiotelephone company is one employing fewer than 1,500 
    persons. All but 26 of the 2,321 non-radiotelephone companies listed by 
    the Census Bureau were reported to have fewer than 1,000 employees. 
    Thus, even if all 26 of those companies had more than 1,500 employees, 
    there would still be 2,295 non-radiotelephone companies that might 
    qualify as small entities or small incumbent LECs. Although it seems 
    certain that some of these carriers are not independently owned and 
    operated, we are unable at this time to estimate with greater precision 
    the number of wireline carriers and service providers that would 
    qualify as small business concerns under SBA's definition. 
    Consequently, we estimate that there are fewer than 2,295 small entity 
    telephone communications companies other than radiotelephone companies 
    that may be affected by the decisions and rules adopted in this Order.
        889. Local Exchange Carriers. Neither the Commission nor SBA has 
    developed a definition of small providers of local exchange services 
    (LECs). The closest applicable definition under SBA rules is for 
    telephone communications companies other than radiotelephone (wireless) 
    companies. The most reliable source of information regarding the number 
    of LECs nationwide of which we are aware appears to be the data that we 
    collect annually in connection with the Telecommunications Relay 
    Service (TRS). According to our most recent data, 1,347 companies 
    reported that they were engaged in the provision of local exchange 
    services. Although it seems certain that some of these carriers are not 
    independently owned and operated, or have more than 1,500 employees, we 
    are unable at this time to estimate with greater precision the number 
    of LECs that would qualify as small business concerns under SBA's 
    definition. Consequently, we estimate that there are fewer than 1,347 
    small incumbent LECs that may be affected by the decisions and rules 
    adopted in this Order.
        890. Interexchange Carriers. Neither the Commission nor SBA has 
    developed a definition of small entities specifically applicable to 
    providers of interexchange services (IXCs). The closest applicable 
    definition under SBA rules is for telephone communications companies 
    other than radiotelephone (wireless) companies. The most reliable 
    source of information regarding the number of IXCs nationwide of which 
    we are aware appears to be the data that we collect annually in 
    connection with TRS. According to our most recent data, 97 companies 
    reported that they were engaged in the provision of interexchange 
    services. Although it seems certain that some of these carriers are not 
    independently owned and operated, or have more than 1,500 employees, we 
    are unable at this time to estimate with greater precision the number 
    of IXCs that would qualify as small business concerns under SBA's 
    definition. Consequently, we estimate that there are fewer than 97 
    small entity IXCs that may be affected by the decisions and rules 
    adopted in this Order.
        891. Competitive Access Providers. Neither the Commission nor SBA 
    has developed a definition of small entities specifically applicable to 
    providers of competitive access services (CAPs). The closest applicable 
    definition under SBA rules is for telephone communications companies 
    other than radiotelephone (wireless) companies. The most reliable 
    source of information regarding the number of CAPs nationwide of which 
    we are aware appears to be the data that we collect annually in 
    connection with the TRS. According to our most recent data, 30 
    companies reported that they were engaged in the provision of 
    competitive access services. Although it seems certain that some of 
    these carriers are not independently owned and operated, or have more 
    than 1,500 employees, we are unable at this time to estimate with 
    greater precision the number of CAPs that would qualify as small 
    business concerns under SBA's definition. Consequently, we estimate 
    that there are fewer than 30 small entity CAPs that may be affected by 
    the decisions and rules adopted in this Order.
        892. Operator Service Providers. Neither the Commission nor SBA has 
    developed a definition of small entities specifically applicable to 
    providers of operator services. The closest applicable definition under 
    SBA rules is for telephone communications companies other than 
    radiotelephone (wireless) companies. The most reliable source of 
    information regarding the number of operator service providers 
    nationwide of which we are aware appears to be the data that we collect 
    annually in connection with the TRS. According to our most recent data, 
    29 companies reported that they were engaged in the provision of 
    operator services. Although it seems certain that some of these 
    companies are not independently owned and operated, or have more than 
    1,500 employees, we are unable at this time to estimate with greater 
    precision the number of operator service providers that would qualify 
    as small business concerns under SBA's definition. Consequently, we 
    estimate that there are fewer than 29 small entity operator service 
    providers that may be affected by the decisions and rules adopted in 
    this Order.
        893. Pay Telephone Operators. Neither the Commission nor SBA has 
    developed a definition of small entities specifically applicable to pay 
    telephone operators. The closest applicable definition under SBA rules 
    is for telephone communications companies other than radiotelephone 
    (wireless) companies. The most reliable source of information regarding 
    the number of pay telephone operators nationwide of which we are aware 
    appears to be the data that we collect annually in connection with the 
    TRS. According to our most recent data, 197 companies reported that 
    they were engaged in the provision of pay telephone services. Although 
    it seems certain that some of these carriers are not independently 
    owned and operated, or have more than 1,500 employees, we are unable at 
    this time to estimate with greater precision the number of pay 
    telephone operators that would qualify as small business concerns under 
    SBA's definition. Consequently, we estimate that there are fewer than 
    197 small entity pay telephone operators that may be affected by the 
    decisions and rules adopted in this Order.
        894. Wireless (Radiotelephone) Carriers. SBA has developed a 
    definition of small entities for radiotelephone (wireless) companies. 
    The Census Bureau reports that there were 1,176 such companies in 
    operation for at least one year at the end of 1992. According to SBA's 
    definition, a small business radiotelephone company is one employing 
    fewer than 1,500 persons. The Census Bureau also reported that 1,164 of 
    those radiotelephone companies had fewer than 1,000 employees. Thus, 
    even if all of the remaining 12 companies had more than 1,500 
    employees, there would still be 1,164 radiotelephone companies that 
    might qualify as small entities if they are independently owned or 
    operated. Although it seems certain that some of these carriers are not 
    independently owned and operated, we are unable at this time to 
    estimate with greater precision the number of radiotelephone carriers 
    and service providers that would qualify as small business concerns 
    under SBA's definition. Consequently, we estimate that there are fewer 
    than 1,164 small entity radiotelephone companies that may be
    
    [[Page 45607]]
    
    affected by the decisions and rules adopted in this Order.
        895. Cellular Service Carriers. Neither the Commission nor SBA has 
    developed a definition of small entities specifically applicable to 
    providers of cellular services. The closest applicable definition under 
    SBA rules is for telephone communications companies other than 
    radiotelephone (wireless) companies. The most reliable source of 
    information regarding the number of cellular service carriers 
    nationwide of which we are aware appears to be the data that we collect 
    annually in connection with the TRS. According to our most recent data, 
    789 companies reported that they were engaged in the provision of 
    cellular services. Although it seems certain that some of these 
    carriers are not independently owned and operated, or have more than 
    1,500 employees, we are unable at this time to estimate with greater 
    precision the number of cellular service carriers that would qualify as 
    small business concerns under SBA's definition. Consequently, we 
    estimate that there are fewer than 789 small entity cellular service 
    carriers that may be affected by the decisions and rules adopted in 
    this Order.
        896. Mobile Service Carriers. Neither the Commission nor SBA has 
    developed a definition of small entities specifically applicable to 
    mobile service carriers, such as paging companies. The closest 
    applicable definition under SBA rules is for telephone communications 
    companies other than radiotelephone (wireless) companies. The most 
    reliable source of information regarding the number of mobile service 
    carriers nationwide of which we are aware appears to be the data that 
    we collect annually in connection with the TRS. According to our most 
    recent data, 117 companies reported that they were engaged in the 
    provision of mobile services. Although it seems certain that some of 
    these carriers are not independently owned and operated, or have more 
    than 1,500 employees, we are unable at this time to estimate with 
    greater precision the number of mobile service carriers that would 
    qualify under SBA's definition. Consequently, we estimate that there 
    are fewer than 117 small entity mobile service carriers that may be 
    affected by the decisions and rules adopted in this Order.
        897. Broadband PCS Licensees. The broadband PCS spectrum is divided 
    into six frequency blocks designated A through F. As set forth in 47 
    CFR Sec. 24.720(b), the Commission has defined ``small entity'' in the 
    auctions for Blocks C and F as a firm that had average gross revenues 
    of less than $40 million in the three previous calendar years. Our 
    definition of a ``small entity'' in the context of broadband PCS 
    auctions has been approved by SBA. The Commission has auctioned 
    broadband PCS licenses in Blocks A, B, and C. We do not have sufficient 
    data to determine how many small businesses bid successfully for 
    licenses in Blocks A and B. There were 90 winning bidders that 
    qualified as small entities in the Block C auction. Based on this 
    information, we conclude that the number of broadband PCS licensees 
    affected by the decisions in this Order includes, at a minimum, the 90 
    winning bidders that qualified as small entities in the Block C 
    broadband PCS auction.
        898. At present, no licenses have been awarded for Blocks D, E, and 
    F of broadband PCS spectrum. Therefore, there are no small businesses 
    currently providing these services. However, a total of 1,479 licenses 
    will be awarded in the D, E, and F Block broadband PCS auctions, which 
    are scheduled to begin on August 26, 1996. Eligibility for the 493 F 
    Block licenses is limited to entrepreneurs with average gross revenues 
    of less than $125 million. We cannot estimate, however, the number of 
    these licenses that will be won by small entities under our definition, 
    nor how many small entities will win D or E Block licenses. Given that 
    nearly all radiotelephone companies have fewer than 1,000 employees and 
    that no reliable estimate of the number of prospective D, E, and F 
    Block licensees can be made, we assume for purposes of this FRFA, that 
    all of the licenses in the D, E, and F Block Broadband PCS auctions may 
    be awarded to small entities under our rules, which may be affected by 
    the decisions and rules adopted in this Order.
        899. SMR Licensees. Pursuant to 47 CFR Sec. 90.814(b)(1), the 
    Commission has defined ``small entity'' in auctions for geographic area 
    800 MHz and 900 MHz SMR licenses as a firm that had average annual 
    gross revenues of less than $15 million in the three previous calendar 
    years. This definition of a ``small entity'' in the context of 800 MHz 
    and 900 MHz SMR has been approved by the SBA. The rules adopted in this 
    Order may apply to SMR providers in the 800 MHz and 900 MHz bands that 
    either hold geographic area licenses or have obtained extended 
    implementation authorizations. We do not know how many firms provide 
    800 MHz or 900 MHz geographic area SMR service pursuant to extended 
    implementation authorizations, nor how many of these providers have 
    annual revenues of less than $15 million. We assume, for purposes of 
    this FRFA, that all of the extended implementation authorizations may 
    be held by small entities, which may be affected by the decisions and 
    rules adopted in this Order.
        900. The Commission recently held auctions for geographic area 
    licenses in the 900 MHz SMR band. There were 60 winning bidders who 
    qualified as small entities in the 900 MHz auction. Based on this 
    information, we conclude that the number of geographic area SMR 
    licensees affected by the rule adopted in this Order includes these 60 
    small entities. No auctions have been held for 800 MHz geographic area 
    SMR licenses. Therefore, no small entities currently hold these 
    licenses. A total of 525 licenses will be awarded for the upper 200 
    channels in the 800 MHz geographic area SMR auction. However, the 
    Commission has not yet determined how many licenses will be awarded for 
    the lower 230 channels in the 800 MHz geographic area SMR auction. 
    There is no basis, moreover, on which to estimate how many small 
    entities will win these licenses. Given that nearly all radiotelephone 
    companies have fewer than 1,000 employees and that no reliable estimate 
    of the number of prospective 800 MHz licensees can be made, we assume, 
    for purposes of this FRFA, that all of the licenses may be awarded to 
    small entities who, thus, may be affected by the decisions in this 
    Order.
        901. Resellers. Neither the Commission nor SBA has developed a 
    definition of small entities specifically applicable to resellers. The 
    closest applicable definition under SBA rules is for all telephone 
    communications companies. The most reliable source of information 
    regarding the number of resellers nationwide of which we are aware 
    appears to be the data that we collect annually in connection with the 
    TRS. According to our most recent data, 206 companies reported that 
    they were engaged in the resale of telephone services. Although it 
    seems certain that some of these carriers are not independently owned 
    and operated, or have more than 1,500 employees, we are unable at this 
    time to estimate with greater precision the number of resellers that 
    would qualify as small business concerns under SBA's definition. 
    Consequently, we estimate that there are fewer than 206 small entity 
    resellers that may be affected by the decisions and rules adopted in 
    this Order.
    2. Cable System Operators (SIC 4841)
        902. SBA has developed a definition of small entities for cable and 
    other pay television services, which includes all such companies 
    generating less than
    
    [[Page 45608]]
    
    $10 million in revenue annually. This definition includes cable systems 
    operators, closed circuit television services, direct broadcast 
    satellite services, multipoint distribution systems, satellite master 
    antenna systems and subscription television services. According to the 
    Census Bureau, there were 1,323 such cable and other pay television 
    services generating less than $11 million in revenue that were in 
    operation for at least one year at the end of 1992.
        903. The Commission has developed its own definition of a small 
    cable system operator for the purposes of rate regulation. Under the 
    Commission's rules, a ``small cable company'' is one serving fewer than 
    400,000 subscribers nationwide. The Commission developed this 
    definition based on its determination that a small cable system 
    operator is one with annual revenues of $100 million or less. 
    Implementation of Sections of the 1992 Cable Act: Rate Regulation, 
    Sixth Report and Order and Eleventh Order on Reconsideration, 60 FR 
    544919 (September 15, 1995). Based on our most recent information, we 
    estimate that there were 1,439 cable operators that qualified as small 
    cable system operators at the end of 1995. Since then, some of those 
    companies may have grown to serve over 400,000 subscribers, and others 
    may have been involved in transactions that caused them to be combined 
    with other cable operators. Consequently, we estimate that there are 
    fewer than 1,468 small entity cable system operators that may be 
    affected by the decisions and rules adopted in this Order.
        904. The Communications Act also contains a definition of a small 
    cable system operator, which is ``a cable operator that, directly or 
    through an affiliate, serves in the aggregate fewer than 1 percent of 
    all subscribers in the United States and is not affiliated with any 
    entity or entities whose gross annual revenues in the aggregate exceed 
    $250,000,000.'' There were 63,196,310 basic cable subscribers at the 
    end of 1995, and 1,450 cable system operators serving fewer than one 
    percent (631,960) of subscribers. Although it seems certain that some 
    of these cable system operators are affiliated with entities whose 
    gross annual revenues exceed $250,000,000, we are unable at this time 
    to estimate with greater precision the number of cable system operators 
    that would qualify as small cable operators under the definition in the 
    Communications Act.
    
    D. Summary Analysis of the Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping, and 
    Other Compliance Requirements and Steps Taken to Minimize the 
    Significant Economic Impact of this Report and Order on Small Entities 
    and Small Incumbent LECs, Including the Significant Alternatives 
    Considered and Rejected
    
        905. Structure of the Analysis. In this section of the FRFA, we 
    analyze the projected reporting, recordkeeping, and other compliance 
    requirements that may apply to small entities and small incumbent LECs 
    as a result of this Order. As a part of this discussion, we mention 
    some of the types of skills that will be needed to meet the new 
    requirements. We also describe the steps taken to minimize the economic 
    impact of our decisions on small entities and small incumbent LECs, 
    including the significant alternatives considered and rejected. Due to 
    the size of this Order, we set forth our analysis separately for 
    individual sections of the item, using the same headings as were used 
    above in the corresponding sections of the Order.
        906. We provide this summary analysis to provide context for our 
    analysis in this FRFA. To the extent that any statement contained in 
    this FRFA is perceived as creating ambiguity with respect to our rules 
    or statements made in preceding sections of this Order, the rules and 
    statements set forth in those preceding sections shall be controlling.
    Summary Analysis of Section II--Scope of the Commission's Rules
        907. Summary of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping and Other 
    Compliance Requirements. As discussed in Section II.E, a common 
    carrier, which may be a small entity or a small incumbent LEC, may be 
    subject to an action for relief in several different fora if a party 
    believes that small entity or incumbent LEC violated the standards 
    under section 251 or 252. Should a small entity or a small incumbent 
    LEC be subjected to such an action for relief, it will require the use 
    of legal skills.
        908. Steps Taken to Minimize Significant Economic Impact on Small 
    Entities and Small Incumbent LECs, and Alternatives Considered. We 
    believe that our actions establishing minimum national rules will 
    facilitate the development of competition in the local exchange and 
    exchange access markets for the reasons discussed in Sections II.A and 
    II.B above. For example, national rules may: help equalize bargaining 
    power; minimize the need for duplicative marketing strategies and 
    multiple network configurations; lower administrative costs; lessen the 
    need to re-litigate the same issue in multiple jurisdictions; and 
    reduce delay and transaction costs, which can pose particular burdens 
    for small businesses. In addition, our rules are designed to 
    accommodate differences among regions and carriers, and the reduced 
    regulatory burdens and increased certainty produced by national rules 
    may be expected to minimize the economic impact of our decisions for 
    all parties, including any small entities and small incumbent LECs. As 
    set forth in Section II.A above, we reject suggestions to adopt more, 
    or fewer, national rules than we ultimately adopt in this Order. We 
    reject the arguments that we should establish ``preferred outcomes'' 
    from which parties could deviate upon an adequate showing, or that we 
    establish a process by which state commissions could seek a waiver from 
    the Commission's rules, for the reasons set forth in Section II.B 
    above.
        909. We believe that our determination that there are multiple 
    methods for bringing enforcement actions against parties regarding 
    their obligations under sections 251 and 252 will assist all parties, 
    including small entities and small incumbent LECs, by providing a 
    variety of methods and fora for seeking enforcement of such 
    obligations. (Section II.E--Authority to Take Enforcement Action.) 
    Similarly, our conclusion that Bell Operating Company (BOC) statements 
    of generally available terms and conditions are governed by the same 
    national rules that apply to agreements arbitrated under section 252 
    should ease administrative burdens for all parties in markets served by 
    BOCs, which may include small entities, because they will not need to 
    evaluate and comply with different sets of rules. (Section II.F--BOC 
    Statements of Generally Available Terms.) Finally, we decline to adopt 
    different requirements for agreements arbitrated under section 252 and 
    BOC statements of generally available terms and conditions for the 
    reasons set forth in section II.F above.
    Summary Analysis of Section III--Duty To Negotiate in Good Faith
        910. Summary of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping and Other 
    Compliance Requirements. Incumbent LECs, including small incumbent LECs 
    that receive requests for access to network elements and/or services 
    pursuant to sections 251 and 252 of the Act will be required to 
    negotiate in good faith over the terms of interconnection agreements. 
    As set forth in section III.C, above, this Order identifies several 
    practices as violations of the duty to
    
    [[Page 45609]]
    
    negotiate in good faith, including: (1) a party's seeking or entering 
    into an agreement prohibiting disclosure of information requested by 
    the FCC or a state commission, or supplied in support of a request for 
    arbitration pursuant to section 252(b)(2)(B); (2) seeking or entering 
    into an agreement precluding amendment of the agreement to account for 
    changes in federal or state rules; (3) an incumbent's denial of a 
    reasonable request for cost data during negotiations; and (4) an 
    entrant's failure to provide to the incumbent LEC information necessary 
    to reach agreement. Complying with the projected requirements of this 
    section may require the use of legal skills. In addition, incumbent 
    LECs and new entrants having interconnection agreements that predate 
    the 1996 Act must file such agreements with the state commission for 
    approval under section 252(e), as discussed above in section III.D.
        911. Steps Taken to Minimize Significant Economic Impact on Small 
    Entities and Small Incumbent LECs, and Alternatives Considered. As set 
    forth above, we believe our decision to establish national rules and a 
    review process concerning parties' duties to negotiate in good faith 
    are designed to facilitate good faith negotiations, which should 
    minimize regulatory burdens and the economic impact of our decisions 
    for all parties, including small entities and small incumbent LECs. 
    (Section III.B--Advantages and Disadvantages of National Rules.) We 
    also expect economic impacts to be minimized for small entities seeking 
    to enter into agreements with incumbent LECs as a result of the 
    decision that incumbent LECs may not impose a bona fide request 
    requirement on carriers seeking agreements pursuant to sections 251 and 
    252. (Section III.C--Specific Practices that may Constitute a Violation 
    of Good Faith Negotiation.) For the reasons set forth in Section III.C 
    above, we also find that certain additional practices are not always 
    violations of the duty to negotiate in good faith, including the 
    suggested alternative that all nondisclosure agreements violate the 
    good faith duty.
        912. We do not require immediate filing of preexisting 
    interconnection agreements, including those involving small incumbent 
    LECs and small entities. We set an outer time limit of June 30, 1997, 
    by which preexisting agreements between Class A carriers must be filed 
    with the relevant state commission. This decision will ensure that 
    third parties, including small entities, are not prevented indefinitely 
    from reviewing and taking advantage of the terms of preexisting 
    agreements. It also limits burdens that a national filing deadline 
    might impose on small carriers. In addition, the determination that 
    preexisting agreements must be filed with state commissions seems 
    likely to foster opportunities for small entities and small incumbent 
    LECs to gain access to such agreements without requiring investigation 
    or discovery proceedings or other administrative burdens that could 
    increase regulatory burdens. (Section III.C--Applicability of Section 
    252 to Preexisting Agreements). For the reasons set forth in Section 
    III.C above, we reject the alternative of not requiring certain 
    agreements to be filed with state commissions.
    Summary Analysis of Section IV--Interconnection
        913. Summary of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping and Other 
    Compliance Requirements. Incumbent LECs, including small incumbent 
    LECs, are required by section 251(c) to provide interconnection to all 
    requesting telecommunications carriers for the transmission and routing 
    of telephone exchange service and exchange access service. Such 
    interconnection must be: (1) provided at any technically feasible 
    point; (2) at least equal in quality to that provided to the incumbent 
    LEC itself and to any other parties with interconnection agreements; 
    and (3) provided on rates, terms, and conditions that are ``just, 
    reasonable, and nondiscriminatory * * *.'' We conclude that 
    interconnection refers solely to the physical linking of networks for 
    the mutual exchange of traffic, and identify a minimum set of 
    technically feasible points of interconnection. The minimum points at 
    which an incumbent LEC, which may be a small incumbent LEC, must 
    provide interconnection are: (1) the line side of a local switch; (2) 
    the trunk side of a local switch; (3) the trunk interconnection points 
    for a tandem switch; (4) central office cross-connect points; and (5) 
    out-of-band signaling facilities. In addition, the points of access to 
    unbundled elements (discussed below) are also technically feasible 
    points of interconnection. Compliance with these requests may require 
    the use of engineering, technical, operational, accounting, billing, 
    and legal skills.
        914. To obtain interconnection pursuant to section 251(c)(2), 
    telecommunications carriers must seek interconnection for the purpose 
    of transmitting and routing telephone exchange traffic, or exchange 
    access traffic, or both. (Section IV.D.--Definition of ``Technically 
    Feasible.'') This will require new entrants to provide either local 
    exchange service or exchange access service to obtain section 251(c)(2) 
    interconnection. A requesting carrier will be required to bear the 
    additional costs imposed on incumbent LECs as a result of 
    interconnection. (Section IV.E.--Technically Feasible Points of 
    Interconnection.) Carriers seeking interconnection, including small 
    entities, may be required to collect information to refute claims by 
    incumbent LECs that the requested interconnection poses a legitimate 
    threat to network reliability. (Id.)
        915. Steps Taken to Minimize Significant Economic Impact on Small 
    Entities and Small Incumbent LECs, and Alternatives Considered. The 
    decision to adopt clear national rules in this section of the Order is 
    also intended to help equalize bargaining power between incumbent LECs 
    and requesting carriers, expedite and simplify negotiations, and 
    facilitate comprehensive business and network planning. This could 
    decrease entry barriers and provide reasonable opportunities for all 
    carriers, including small entities and small incumbent LECs, to provide 
    service in markets for local exchange and exchange access services. 
    (Section IV.B.--National Interconnection Rules). National rules should 
    also facilitate the consistent development of standards and resolution 
    of issues, such as technical feasibility, without imposing additional 
    litigation costs on parties, including small entities and small 
    incumbent LECs. We determine that successful interconnection at a 
    particular point in a network creates a rebuttable presumption that 
    interconnection is technically feasible at other comparable points in 
    the network. (Section IV.E--Definition of ``Technically Feasible.'') We 
    also identify minimum points of interconnection where interconnection 
    is presumptively technically feasible: (1) the line side of a switch; 
    (2) the trunk side of a switch; (3) trunk interconnection points at a 
    tandem switch; (4) central office cross-connect points; and (5) out-of-
    band signaling facilities. (Section IV.F--Technically Feasible Points 
    of Interconnection.) These decisions may be expected to facilitate 
    negotiations by promoting certainty and reducing transaction costs, 
    which should minimize regulatory burdens and the economic impact of our 
    decisions for all parties, including small entities and small incumbent 
    LECs. We decline, however, to identify additional points where 
    interconnection is technically feasible for the reasons set forth in 
    section IV.F above.
    
    [[Page 45610]]
    
        916. The ability to enter local markets by offering only telephone 
    exchange service or only exchange access service may minimize 
    regulatory burdens and the economic impact of our decisions for some 
    entrants, including small entities. We decline, however, to interpret 
    section 251(c)(2) as requiring incumbent LECs to provide 
    interconnection to carriers seeking to offer only interexchange 
    services for the reasons set forth in section IV.C above. In addition, 
    we determine that an incumbent LEC may refuse to interconnect on the 
    grounds that specific, significant, and demonstrable network 
    reliability concerns may make interconnection at a particular point 
    sufficiently infeasible. We further determine that the incumbent LEC 
    must prove such infeasibility to the state commission. (Section IV.E. 
    Definition of ``Technically Feasible.'')
        917. Competitive carriers, many of whom may be small entities, will 
    be permitted to request interconnection at any technically feasible 
    point, and the determination of feasibility must be conducted without 
    consideration of the cost of providing interconnection at a particular 
    point. (Section IV.D.--Definition of ``Technically Feasible.'') 
    Consequently, our rules permit the party requesting interconnection, 
    which may be a small entity, and not the incumbent LEC to decide the 
    points that are necessary to compete effectively. (Section IV.E.--
    Definition of ``Technically Feasible.'') We decline, however, to impose 
    reciprocal terms and conditions for interconnection on carriers 
    requesting interconnection. Our decision that a party requesting 
    interconnection must pay the costs of interconnecting should minimize 
    regulatory burdens and the economic impact of our interconnection 
    decisions for small incumbent LECs. Similarly, regulatory burdens and 
    the economic impact of our decisions may be minimized through the 
    decision that, while a requesting party is permitted to obtain 
    interconnection that is of higher quality than that which the incumbent 
    LEC provides to itself, the requesting party must pay the additional 
    costs of receiving the higher quality interconnection. (Section IV.H.--
    Interconnection that is Equal in Quality.)
    Summary Analysis of Section V--Access to Unbundled Network Elements
        918. Summary of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping and Other 
    Compliance Requirements. Under section 251(c), incumbent LECs are 
    required to provide nondiscriminatory access to unbundled network 
    elements. We identify a minimum set of network elements: (1) local 
    loops; (2) local and tandem switches; (3) interoffice transmission 
    facilities; (4) network interface devices; (5) signaling and call-
    related database facilities; (6) operations support systems and 
    functions; and (7) operator and directory assistance facilities. 
    (Section V.J.--Specific Unbundling Requirements.) Incumbent LECs are 
    required to provide nondiscriminatory access to operations support 
    systems and information by January 1, 1997. States may require 
    incumbent LECs to provide additional network elements on an unbundled 
    basis. As discussed in Section V.F., above, LECs must perform the 
    functions necessary to combine unbundled elements in a manner that 
    allows requesting carriers to offer a telecommunications service, and 
    the incumbent LEC may not impose restrictions on the subsequent use of 
    network elements. Compliance with these requests may require the use of 
    engineering, technical, operational, accounting, billing, and legal 
    skills.
        919. If a requesting carrier, which may be a small entity, seeks 
    access to an incumbent LEC's unbundled elements, the requesting carrier 
    is required to compensate the incumbent LEC for any costs incurred to 
    provide such access. For example, in the case of operation support 
    systems functions, such work may include the development of interfaces 
    for competing carriers to access incumbent LEC functions for pre-
    ordering, ordering, provisioning, maintenance and repair, and billing. 
    Requesting carriers may also have to deploy their own operations 
    support systems interfaces, including electronic interfaces, in order 
    to access the incumbent LEC's operations support systems functions. The 
    development of interfaces may require new entrants, including small 
    entities, to perform engineering work. (Section V.J.5--Operations 
    Support Systems Unbundling.)
        920. Steps Taken to Minimize Significant Economic Impact on Small 
    Entities and Small Incumbent LECs, and Alternatives Considered. The 
    establishment of minimum national requirements for unbundled elements 
    should facilitate negotiations and reduce regulatory burdens and 
    uncertainty for all parties, including small entities and small 
    incumbent LECs. National requirements for unbundling may allow new 
    entrants, including small entities, to take advantage of economies of 
    scale in network design, which may minimize the economic impact of our 
    decision. As set forth in Section V.B, above, we reject several 
    alternatives in making this determination, including proposals 
    suggesting that the Commission should: (1) not identify any required 
    elements; (2) allow the states exclusively to identify required 
    elements; or (3) adopt an exhaustive list of elements.
        921. As set forth above, the 1996 Act defines a network element to 
    include ``all facilit(ies) or equipment used in the provision of a 
    telecommunications service,'' and all ``features, functions, and 
    capabilities that are provided by means of such facility or equipment, 
    including subscriber numbers, databases, signaling systems and 
    information sufficient for billing and collection or used in the 
    transmission, routing or other provision of a telecommunications 
    service.'' (Section V.C--Network Elements.) As a result, new entrants, 
    which may include small entities, should have access to the same 
    technologies and economies of scale and scope that are available to 
    incumbent LECs. In reaching our determination, we reject for the 
    reasons set forth in Section V.C above, the following alternatives: (1) 
    that we should not adopt a method for identifying elements beyond those 
    identified in the 1996 Act; and (2) that features sold directly to end 
    users as retail services are not network elements. Finally, we reject 
    the argument that requesting carriers, which may include small 
    entities, are required to provide all services typically furnished by 
    means of an element they purchase. (Id.) Our rejection of this last 
    alternative may reduce burdens for some small entities by permitting 
    them to offer some, but not all, of the services provided by the 
    incumbent LEC.
        922. We conclude that the requirement to provide ``access'' to 
    unbundled network elements is independent of the interconnection duty 
    imposed by section 251(c)(2), and that such ``access'' must be 
    provisioned under the rates, terms and conditions applicable to 
    unbundled network elements. We believe these conclusions may provide 
    small entities seeking to compete with incumbent LECs with the 
    flexibility to offer other telecommunications services in addition to 
    local exchange and exchange access services. (Section V.D.--Access to 
    Network Elements.) For the reasons set forth above in Section V.D, we 
    reject the argument that incumbent LECs are not required to provide 
    access to an element's functionality, and that ``access'' to unbundled 
    elements can only be achieved by interconnecting under the terms of 
    section 251(c)(2).
        923. As set forth above, we conclude that an incumbent LEC, which 
    may be a small incumbent LEC, may decline to provide a network element 
    beyond
    
    [[Page 45611]]
    
    those identified by the Commission where it can demonstrate that the 
    network element is proprietary, and that the competing provider could 
    offer the proposed telecommunications service using other 
    nonproprietary elements within the incumbent's network. (Section V.E--
    Standards Necessary to Identify Unbundled Network Elements.) This 
    should minimize regulatory burdens and the economic impact of our 
    decisions for incumbent LECs, including small incumbent LECs, by 
    permitting such entities to retain exclusive use of certain proprietary 
    network elements.
        924. We conclude that incumbent LECs: (1) cannot impose 
    restrictions, requirements or limitations on requests for, or the sale 
    or use of, unbundled network elements; (2) must provide requesting 
    carriers with all of the functionalities of a particular element so 
    that requesting carriers can provide any telecommunications services 
    that can be offered by means of that element; (3) must permit new 
    entrants to combine network elements which new entrants purchase access 
    to, if so requested; (4) must prove to a state commission that they 
    cannot combine elements that are not ordinarily combined within their 
    network, or that are not ordinarily combined in that manner, because 
    such combination is not technically feasible or it would impair the 
    ability of other carriers to access unbundled elements and interconnect 
    with the incumbent LEC; and (5) must provide the operational and 
    support systems necessary to purchase and combine network elements. As 
    a result of these conclusions, many small entities should face 
    significantly reduced barriers to entry in markets for local exchange 
    services. (Section V.F--Provision of a Telecommunications Service Using 
    Unbundled Elements.) For the reasons set forth in section V.F, we 
    reject the following alternatives: (1) that incumbent LECs, in all 
    instances, must combine elements that are not ordinarily combined in 
    their networks; and (2) that incumbent LECs are not obligated to 
    combine elements for requesting carriers.
        925. By establishing minimum national rules concerning 
    nondiscriminatory access to unbundled network elements, requesting 
    carriers, including small entities, may face reduced transaction and 
    regulatory costs in seeking to enter local telecommunications markets. 
    Among these minimum rules are: (1) access and elements which new 
    entrants receive are to be equal in quality between carriers; (2) 
    incumbent LECs must prove technical infeasibility; (3) the rates, terms 
    and conditions established for the provisioning of unbundled elements 
    must be equal between all carriers, and where applicable, between 
    requesting carriers and the incumbent LEC itself, and they must provide 
    efficient competitors with a meaningful opportunity to compete; and (4) 
    incumbent LECs must provide carriers purchasing unbundled elements with 
    access to electronic interfaces if incumbents use such functions 
    themselves in provisioning telecommunications services. (Section V.G--
    Nondiscriminatory Access to Unbundled Network Elements.)
        926. As set forth above, we conclude that section 251(c)(3) does 
    not require new entrants to own or control their own local exchange 
    facilities in order to purchase and use unbundled network elements and, 
    thus, new entrants can provide services solely by recombining unbundled 
    network elements. (Section V.H--The Relationship Between Sections 
    251(c)(3) and 251(c)(4).)
        927. As discussed in Section V.J above, we adopt a minimum list of 
    required unbundled network elements that incumbent LECs, including 
    small incumbent LECs, must make available to requesting carriers. In 
    adopting this list, we sought to minimize the regulatory burdens and 
    economic impact for small incumbent LECs. For example, we declined to 
    adopt a detailed list including many additional elements, as set forth 
    in Section V.B. We also provided for the fact that certain LECs may 
    possess switches that are incapable of performing customized routing 
    for competitors, as discussed in Section V.J.2.(c).(ii).
    Summary Analysis of Section VI--Methods of Obtaining Interconnection 
    and Access to Unbundled Network Elements
        928. Summary of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping, and Other 
    Compliance Requirements. We conclude that Section 251(c)(6) requires 
    incumbent LECs, including small incumbent LECs, to provide for any 
    technically feasible method of interconnection or access to unbundled 
    network elements, including physical collocation, virtual collocation, 
    and meet-point interconnection. With certain modifications, we adopt 
    some of the requirements concerning physical and virtual collocation 
    that we adopted in the Expanded Interconnection proceeding. Compliance 
    with these requests may require the use of engineering, technical, 
    operational, accounting, billing, and legal skills.
        929. In a meet-point arrangement the new entrant will build out 
    facilities to the agreed-upon point, which will likely entail the use 
    of engineering and installation personnel as well as the acquisition of 
    equipment. We allow incumbent LECs to impose reasonable restrictions on 
    the warehousing of space by collocators. Therefore, small entities 
    collocating equipment may be required to use the provided space for the 
    collocation of equipment necessary for interconnection or access to 
    unbundled network elements or risk losing the right to use that space. 
    (Section VI.B.1.e--Allocation of Space.) To take advantage of its right 
    to collocate equipment on an incumbent LEC's premises, competitive 
    entrants, which may include small entities, will be required to build 
    or lease transmission facilities between their own equipment, located 
    outside of the incumbent LECs' premises, and the collocated space. 
    (Section VI.B.1.f--Leasing Transport Facilities.) We allow incumbent 
    LECs to require reasonable security arrangements to separate an 
    entrant's collocation space from the incumbent LEC's facilities. Small 
    entities collocating equipment may therefore be required to pay for 
    such security arrangements. (Section VI.B.1.h--Security Arrangements.)
        930. Steps Taken to Minimize Significant Economic Impact on Small 
    Entities and Small Incumbent LECs, and Alternatives Considered. By 
    readopting our Expanded Interconnection terms and conditions, which 
    allow competitors to collocate equipment for interconnection with the 
    incumbent LEC, regulatory burdens have likely been reduced because the 
    terms and conditions for collocation have already been established. 
    (Section VI.B.1.b--Readoption of Expanded Interconnection Terms and 
    Conditions.) This seems likely to benefit all parties, including small 
    entities and small incumbent LECs, since it should reduce the time and 
    expense of negotiation, and reduce the costs of adapting to new terms 
    and conditions for collocation.
        931. Due to our conclusion that requesting carriers may choose any 
    method of technically feasible interconnection or access to unbundled 
    elements, new entrants, including small entities, should have the 
    flexibility to obtain interconnection or access in the manner that best 
    suits their needs. (Section VI.A.--Methods of Obtaining Interconnection 
    and Access to Unbundled Elements.) In particular, as discussed in 
    Section VI.A.3, we recognize that carriers, including small entities, 
    may find virtual collocation or meet-point arrangements more efficient 
    than physical collocation in certain circumstances, particularly if 
    they lack the resources to collocate physically in
    
    [[Page 45612]]
    
    a large number of incumbent LEC premises.
        932. We adopt a broad definition of the term ``premises,'' which 
    should allow carriers, including small entities, to collocate equipment 
    for interconnection and access to unbundled network elements at a range 
    of incumbent LEC locations. (Section VI.B.1.c--The Meaning of the Term 
    ``Premises.'') For the reasons set forth in Section VI.B above, we 
    interpret the term ``premises'' broadly to include incumbent LEC 
    central offices, serving wire centers and tandem offices, as well as 
    all buildings or similar structures owned or leased by the incumbent 
    LEC that house incumbent LEC facilities. However, as set forth above, 
    we reject the suggestion that security measures be provided only at the 
    request of the entrant, which should minimize regulatory burdens and 
    the economic impact of our decisions for small incumbent LECs. (Id.)
        933. We interpret the statute broadly to allow collocation of any 
    equipment used for interconnection or access to unbundled network 
    elements. (Section VI.B.1.d--Collocation Equipment.) This standard 
    should offer all competitors, including small entities, flexibility in 
    collocating equipment they need to interconnect their networks to those 
    of incumbent LECs. Incumbent LECs will also be required to make space 
    available to requesting carriers on a first-come, first-served basis, 
    and collocators seeking to expand their collocated space should be 
    allowed to use contiguous space where available. (Section VI.B.1.e--
    Allocation of Space.) These provisions should minimize regulatory 
    burdens and economic impacts for small entity entrants by reducing 
    opportunities for discriminatory treatment based on the size of the 
    requesting carrier. We decline, however, to require incumbent LECs to 
    file reports on the status, planned increase, and use of space for the 
    reasons set forth in Section VI.B.1. above, which will reduce the 
    regulatory burdens and economic impact of our decisions for small 
    incumbent LECs.
        934. We conclude that a competitive entrant should be permitted to 
    lease transmission facilities from the incumbent LEC. (Section 
    VI.B.1.f--Leasing Transport Facilities). This provision will allow 
    small entities to lease transmission facilities from incumbent LECs to 
    transmit traffic between the collocated space and their own networks, 
    which may be comparatively less burdensome for small entities than the 
    alternative of bringing their own facilities to the collocated 
    equipment on the incumbent LEC's premises. We also require incumbent 
    LECs to permit two or more carriers that are collocating at the 
    incumbent LEC's premises to interconnect their networks. (Section 
    VI.B.1.g--Co-Carrier Cross-Connect.) This requirement should make it 
    easier for new entrants to interconnect their networks with those of 
    competitors.
        935. We require incumbent LECs to provide the relevant state 
    commissions with detailed floor plans or diagrams of any premises where 
    the incumbent LEC alleges that there are space constraints. (Section 
    VI.B.1.i.--Allowing Virtual Collocation in Lieu of Physical). This 
    requirement may reduce burdens for all parties, including small 
    entities and small incumbent LECs, by aiding state commissions with 
    their evaluation of incumbent LEC refusals to allow physical 
    collocation on the grounds of space constraints. For the reasons set 
    forth in Section VI.B.1 above, however, we decline to require incumbent 
    LECs to lease additional space or provide trunking at no cost where 
    they have insufficient space for physical collocation, which should 
    minimize the regulatory burdens and economic impact of our decisions 
    for incumbent LECs, including small incumbent LECs.
    Summary Analysis of Section VII--Pricing of Interconnection and 
    Unbundled Network Elements
        936. Summary of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping, and Other 
    Compliance Requirements. Pursuant to sections 251(c) and 252(d) of the 
    1996 Act, incumbent LECs must provide interconnection and access to 
    unbundled network elements on rates, terms, and conditions that are 
    just, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory. In Section VII above, we adopt 
    a methodology for setting arbitrated prices for interconnection and 
    unbundled elements on the basis of forward-looking economic cost 
    studies prepared in conformance with a methodology prescribed by the 
    Commission. Until states utilize economic studies to develop cost-based 
    prices, they must use default proxies established by the Commission. 
    Small incumbent LECs may be required, therefore, to prepare economic 
    cost studies. In addition, small entities seeking arbitration for rates 
    for interconnection or unbundled elements may find it useful to prepare 
    economic cost studies or prepare critiques of cost studies prepared by 
    incumbent LECs and others. In both cases, this may entail the use of 
    economic experts, legal advice, and possibly accounting personnel.
        937. Steps Taken to Minimize Significant Economic Impact on Small 
    Entities and Small Incumbent LECs, and Alternatives Considered. Our 
    conclusion that prices for interconnection and unbundled elements 
    should be set at forward-looking long-run economic cost, including a 
    reasonable share of forward-looking joint and common costs, should 
    permit new entrants, including small entities, to interconnect with, 
    and acquire unbundled elements from, incumbent LECs at prices that 
    replicate, to the extent possible, those in a competitive market. 
    (Section VII.B.2--Pricing of Interconnection and Unbundled Elements, 
    Cost-Based Pricing Methodology, Rate Levels.) Our forward-looking 
    economic cost methodology for determining prices is designed to permit 
    incumbent LECs to recover their economic costs of providing 
    interconnection and unbundled elements, which should minimize the 
    economic impact of our decisions on small incumbent LECs.
        938. Our conclusion that embedded costs, opportunity costs and 
    universal service subsidies may not be included in the rates for 
    interconnection and unbundled elements is intended, in part, to avoid 
    distortions in investment decisions, which should lead to more 
    efficient allocation of resources, thereby reducing regulatory burdens 
    and economic impacts for some small entities and small incumbent LECs. 
    (Section VII.B.2--Pricing of Interconnection and Unbundled Elements, 
    Cost-Based Pricing Methodology, Rate Levels.) We reject proposals that 
    would have permitted incumbent LECs to recover their embedded costs in 
    prices for interconnection and unbundled elements as discussed above in 
    Section VII.B.2.a.(3)(b). As discussed in Section VII.B.2.a.(3)(b), we 
    reject the use of the efficient component pricing rule (ECPR) to set 
    prices for interconnection and unbundled elements.
        939. Our conclusion that forward-looking common costs should be 
    allocated in a reasonable manner should ensure that the prices of 
    network elements that are least likely to be subject to competition are 
    not artificially inflated by large allocations of common costs. This, 
    in turn, may also produce more efficient allocations of resources, 
    thereby minimizing regulatory burdens and economic effects for many 
    parties, including small entities and small incumbent LECs. (Section 
    VII.B.2--Pricing of Interconnection and Unbundled Elements, Cost-Based 
    Pricing Methodology, Rate Levels.) We permit, but do not require, 
    states to impose peak-sensitive pricing systems for
    
    [[Page 45613]]
    
    shared facilities as discussed in Section VII.B.3.b.
        940. We conclude that incumbent LECs should not recover access 
    charges from entrants that use unbundled network facilities to provide 
    access services to customers that they win from incumbent LECs. We do, 
    however, permit incumbent LECs to impose on purchasers of unbundled 
    local switching the carrier common line charge and a charge equal to 
    seventy-five percent of the transport interconnection charge for an 
    interim period that shall end no later than June 30, 1997, as discussed 
    in Section VII.B.2.a.(3)(b). As further explained in that section, this 
    mechanism should serve to reduce any short-term disruptive impact of 
    our decisions on incumbent LECs, including small incumbent LECs.
        941. We conclude that the Act requires rates for interconnection 
    and unbundled elements to be geographically deaveraged, using a minimum 
    of three geographic zones, in a manner that appropriately reflects the 
    costs of the underlying elements. (Section VII.B.3.c--Geographic/Class-
    of-Service Averaging.) We also conclude that distinctions between the 
    rates charged to requesting carriers for network elements should not 
    vary based on the classes of service that the requesting carriers 
    provide to their customers. We expect these decisions to lead to 
    increased competition and a more efficient allocation of resources.
        942. The default proxies we adopt for rates for interconnection and 
    unbundled elements, which states may use to establish prices, are 
    designed to approximate prices that will enable efficient competitors, 
    including small entities, to enter local exchange markets. (Section 
    VII.C.--Default Proxy Ceilings and Ranges.) We reject the use of rates 
    in interconnection agreements that predate the 1996 Act as proxy-based 
    ceilings for interconnection and unbundled element rates as discussed 
    in Section VII.C.1. We also decline to adopt a generic cost model at 
    this time, as discussed in Section VII.C.3.
        943. We determine that the nondiscrimination provisions in the Act 
    prohibit price differences that are not based on cost differences. This 
    should permit small entities to obtain the same terms and conditions of 
    agreements reached by larger carriers that possess greater bargaining 
    power without having to incur the costs of negotiation and/or 
    arbitration. (Section VII.D.3--Discrimination.)
    Summary Analysis of Section VIII--Resale
        944. Summary of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping, and Other 
    Compliance Requirements. Pursuant to section 251(b)(1), all LECs, which 
    may include small entity competing LECs and small incumbent LECs, may 
    not impose unreasonable or discriminatory conditions on, or limit the 
    resale of, their telecommunications services. Pursuant to section 
    251(c)(4), incumbent LECs are required to offer for resale at wholesale 
    rates any telecommunications services that they offer to subscribers 
    other than telecommunications carriers. Providing such services for 
    resale may require some small entities and small incumbent LECs to use 
    additional billing, technical, and operational skills.
        945. Under section 252(a), resellers, which may include small 
    entities, are required to prepare and present to incumbent LECs 
    requests for services to resell. We do not establish guidelines for the 
    content of these requests. Such requests may involve legal, 
    engineering, and accounting skills. Resellers may also have to engage 
    in arbitration proceedings with incumbent LECs if voluntary 
    negotiations resulting from the initial request fail to yield an 
    agreement. This may involve legal and general negotiation skills. Where 
    a reseller is negotiating or arbitrating with an incumbent LEC, the 
    reseller may choose to offer arguments concerning economic and 
    accounting data presented by state commissions or incumbent LECs. 
    Resellers may also choose to make legal and economic arguments that 
    certain resale restrictions are unreasonable. These tasks may require 
    legal, economic, and accounting skills.
        946. Steps Taken to Minimize Significant Economic Impact on Small 
    Entities and Small Incumbent LECs, and Alternatives Considered. As set 
    forth in Section VIII.B, above, our decision to adopt clear national 
    rules should reduce regulatory burdens and uncertainty for all parties, 
    including small entities and small incumbent LECs. Moreover, our 
    decision not to impose eligibility requirements on resellers should 
    minimize regulatory burdens for resellers. We reject proposals that the 
    Commission not require resale of bundled service offerings, promotions 
    and discounts lasting longer than 90 days, residential service, and 
    services offered at rates below cost for reasons set forth in Section 
    VIII.A.
        947. As discussed in Section VIII.B, we expect that the opportunity 
    to resell telecommunications services currently offered exclusively by 
    incumbent LECs will lead to increased competition in the provision of 
    telecommunications services. We also determine that non-cost-based 
    factors shall not be considered when arriving at wholesale discounts, 
    and we reject the argument that indirect costs should not be considered 
    avoided costs. We also reject proposals that we either require or 
    forbid a state to include a measure of profit in its avoided cost 
    calculation. As set forth in Section VIII.B, we considered the concerns 
    of small incumbent LECs and small entity resellers when adopting the 
    default range for wholesale discounts. In addition, we allow a state to 
    consider including in wholesale rates the costs that incumbent LECs 
    incur in selling services on a wholesale basis, which may minimize the 
    economic impact for small incumbent LECs.
        948. As discussed in Section VIII.C, we remove obstacles faced by 
    small businesses in reselling telecommunications services by 
    establishing a presumption, applicable to incumbent and non-incumbent 
    LECs, that most restrictions on resale are unreasonable. This 
    presumption should reduce unnecessary burdens on resellers, which may 
    include small entities. It may also produce increased opportunities for 
    resale competition, which may be expected to be beneficial for some 
    small entities and small incumbent LECs. We do not permit state 
    commissions to require non-incumbent LECs to offer their services at 
    wholesale rates for the reasons set forth in Section VIII.D. For the 
    reasons discussed in Section VIII.C, above, we decline to forbear from 
    the application of section 251(b)(1) to non-incumbent LECs. We also 
    conclude that incumbent LECs are to continue to receive access charge 
    revenues when local services are resold under section 251(c)(4) for 
    reasons set forth in Section VIII.E, and that such access services are 
    not subject to resale at wholesale rates for reasons set forth in 
    Section VIII.A.
    Summary Analysis of Section IX--Duties Imposed on ``Telecommunications 
    Carriers'' by Section 251(a)
        949. Summary of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping, and Other 
    Compliance Requirements. Small entities that provide telecommunications 
    services are subject to the same obligations imposed on all 
    telecommunications carriers under section 251(a)(1) and section 
    251(a)(2), and any reporting requirements that attend such obligations. 
    Among these duties is the duty to interconnect, directly or indirectly, 
    with requesting
    
    [[Page 45614]]
    
    telecommunications carriers. (Section IX--Duties Imposed on 
    ``Telecommunications Carriers'' By Section 251(a).) This will likely 
    require small entities to comply with the technical, economic, and 
    legal requirements involved with interconnection, including negotiating 
    contracts, utilizing engineering studies, and adding operational 
    capacity. (Id.) Small incumbent LECs may incur similar compliance 
    requirements to the extent they are required to interconnect with 
    entities that qualify as ``telecommunications carriers.''
        950. Small incumbent LECs and small entities providing 
    telecommunications services will also be under a duty not to install 
    network features, functions, and capabilities that do not comply with 
    standards and guidelines under sections 255 and 256. (Section IX--
    Duties Imposed on ``Telecommunications Carriers'' By Section 
    251(a)(2).) In addition, small entities that provide both information 
    services and telecommunications services are classified as 
    telecommunications carriers and are subject to certain requirements 
    under 251(a). (Section IX--Duties Imposed on ``Telecommunications 
    Carriers'' By Section 251(a)(2).)
        951. Steps Taken to Minimize Significant Economic Impact on Small 
    Entities and Small Incumbent LECs, and Alternatives Considered. Small 
    entities who provide for a fee local, interexchange and international 
    services are defined as telecommunications carriers and, thus, also 
    receive the benefits of section 251 including interconnection, 
    services, and network elements, which may increase their ability to 
    compete. (Section IX--Duties Imposed on ``Telecommunications Carriers'' 
    By Section 251(a)(2).) We reject the suggestion that CMRS providers, 
    some of which likely are small entities, should not be included in the 
    definition of a ``telecommunications carrier.'' (Id.) We determine that 
    entities operating private, internal or shared communications networks 
    do not qualify as telecommunications carriers, however, which excludes 
    them from the obligations and benefits under section 251(a). Small 
    entities providing information services but not telecommunications 
    services are also not classified as telecommunications carriers and, 
    thus, will not be bound by the duties of section 251(a). A carrier that 
    provides both information and telecommunications services is deemed 
    subject to the requirements of section 251(a). We also conclude that 
    telecommunications carriers that have interconnected under either 
    section 251(a)(1) or 251(c)(2) may offer information services through 
    the same arrangement or agreement. This will permit new entrants, many 
    of which may be small entities, to offer full ranges of services to end 
    users without having to provide some of those services inefficiently 
    through distinct facilities or agreements.
        952. We decide that competitive telecommunications carriers that 
    have the obligation to interconnect with requesting carriers may 
    choose, based upon their own characteristics, whether to allow direct 
    or indirect interconnection. (Section IX--Duties Imposed on 
    ``Telecommunications Carriers'' By Section 251(a).) This should allow 
    significant flexibility for small entities to choose the most efficient 
    and economical arrangement for their particular strategy. As set forth 
    in Section IX, we reject an argument to forbear, under section 10 of 
    the Communications Act, from imposing any interconnection requirements 
    on non-dominant carriers.
    Summary Analysis of Section X--Commercial Mobile Radio Services
        953. Summary of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping and Other 
    Compliance Requirements. We are applying sections 251 and 252 to LEC-
    CMRS interconnection at this time. (Section X.D--Jurisdictional 
    Authority for Regulation of LEC-CMRS Interconnection Rates.) We may 
    revisit our determination not to invoke jurisdiction under section 332 
    to regulate LEC-CMRS interconnection rates if we determine that the 
    regulatory scheme established by sections 251 and 252 does not 
    sufficiently address the problems encountered by CMRS providers, many 
    of which may be small entities, in obtaining interconnection on terms 
    and conditions that are just, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory.
        954. Pursuant to our findings in Section X.D, a small CMRS entity 
    seeking to enter into a reciprocal compensation agreement with an 
    incumbent LEC, which may be a small incumbent LEC, will have to comply 
    with sections 251 and 252, and state law. The reporting, recordkeeping, 
    and other compliance requirements associated with reciprocal 
    compensation are summarized in the following section concerning 
    obligations under section 251(b).
        955. Steps Taken to Minimize Significant Economic Impact on Small 
    Entities and Small Incumbent LECs, and Alternatives Considered. The 
    Commission's actions may minimize the economic impact on CMRS 
    providers, many of which are small entities, by declaring that CMRS 
    providers are not required to comply with the obligations of LECs under 
    section 251(b)(5). We decline to adopt the alternative of finding that 
    a CMRS provider is a LEC for the reasons set forth in Section X.A. We 
    also determine that CMRS providers are entitled to request reciprocal 
    compensation under section 251(b)(5), and that certain CMRS providers 
    are also entitled to request interconnection under section 251(c)(2). 
    As discussed in the following section concerning obligations under 
    section 251(b), these decisions may permit small entity CMRS providers 
    the opportunity to considerably expand their businesses.
    Summary Analysis of Section XI--Obligations Imposed on LECS by 251(b)
    A. Reciprocal Compensation for Transport and Termination of 
    Telecommunications
        956. Summary of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping, and Other 
    Compliance Requirements. All local exchange carriers, including small 
    incumbent LECs and perhaps some small entities offering competing local 
    exchange services, have a duty to establish reciprocal compensation for 
    the transport and termination of local telecommunications traffic, as 
    defined by state commissions. As such, small incumbent LECs and small 
    entities offering competitive local exchange services may be required 
    to measure the exchange of traffic, and to bill and collect payment 
    from other carriers. (Section XI.A--Reciprocal Compensation for 
    Transport and Termination of Telecommunications.) Reciprocal 
    compensation for the transport and termination of traffic may be based 
    on the incumbent LEC's cost studies, which may require small incumbent 
    LECs to use economic skills to perform cost studies. To the extent that 
    a competing provider of local exchange services, which may include a 
    small entity, believes its costs for the transportation and termination 
    of traffic differ from those of the incumbent LEC, it would also be 
    required to provide a forward-looking, economic cost study. (Id.)
        957. If a CMRS provider entered into an agreement with an incumbent 
    LEC prior to August 8, 1996 that does not provide for mutual 
    compensation, the CMRS provider may demand to renegotiate the 
    agreement. This may impose the burden of re-negotiation on small 
    incumbent LECs, which may require legal, accounting, and economic 
    skills. In addition, pending the successful completion of negotiation 
    or arbitration, symmetrical reciprocal
    
    [[Page 45615]]
    
    compensation shall apply, which may have the effect of raising the 
    amount small incumbent LECs currently pay CMRS providers to terminate 
    LEC-originated traffic. This may have the effect of increasing small 
    incumbent LECs' costs. Finally, a state commission may impose bill-and-
    keep arrangements between carriers if the state commission determines 
    that the amount of local telecommunications traffic from one network to 
    the other is approximately equal to the amount of local 
    telecommunications traffic flowing in the opposite directions, and is 
    expected to remain thus. This could have the effect of reducing small 
    incumbent LECs' revenues and decreasing the expenses of small entities. 
    It also might place a burden on small entities and small incumbent LECs 
    of establishing that traffic volumes are imbalanced, which might 
    require accounting, economic, and legal skills.
        958. We require paging companies seeking to recover fees for 
    terminating local calls to demonstrate to the state the costs of 
    terminating such calls. (Section XI.A.--Reciprocal Compensation for 
    Transport and Termination of Traffic.) Consequently, small entity 
    paging companies and possibly small incumbent LECs may be required to 
    use legal, economic, and possibly accounting skills.
        959. Steps Taken to Minimize Significant Economic Impact on Small 
    Entities and Small Incumbent LECs, and Alternatives Considered. Our 
    adoption of national default price ceilings and ranges for 
    transportation and termination of local traffic being arbitrated by the 
    states should provide all parties, including small incumbent LECs and 
    many new entrant small entities, with a clear understanding of the 
    terms and conditions that will govern should they fail to reach an 
    agreement. This should minimize regulatory burdens and economic impacts 
    for those companies, in part by reducing the transaction costs of 
    arbitration. (Section XI.A.3.c.(4)--Default Proxies.) Permitting CMRS 
    providers with non-reciprocal agreements to renegotiate their 
    agreements, and imposing symmetrical reciprocal compensation pending 
    completion of negotiation or arbitration, will provide all parties with 
    certainty as to applicable rates as of the date of this order, and 
    minimize litigation and regulatory costs. We believe this decision is 
    consistent with the pro-competitive goals of the 1996 Act.
        960. We define transport and termination as separate functions--
    each with its own cost calculation for the purposes of sections 251 and 
    252. This definition may permit interconnecting carriers, including 
    small entities, to obtain transport and termination services at lower 
    rates and avoid paying above-cost rates or rates for unneeded services. 
    (Section XI.A.2--Definition of Transport and Termination of 
    Telecommunications.) We also conclude that a LEC may not charge a CMRS 
    provider or other carrier, which may be a small entity, for receiving 
    and terminating LEC-originated traffic. (Section XI.A.4--Symmetry.) We 
    do not permit interexchange carriers to use transport and termination 
    services to avoid the obligation to pay access charges for terminating 
    interexchange traffic with incumbent LECs. (Section XI.A.2--Definition 
    of Transport and Termination of Telecommunications.)
        961. Our decision to permit new entrants to base reciprocal 
    compensation arrangements on incumbent LECs' cost studies may reduce 
    barriers to entry by permitting competing LECs to avoid performing 
    their own forward-looking, economic cost studies, which may be expected 
    to reduce the overall burdens and minimize the economic impact of 
    regulation on these small entities. (Section XI.A.4--Symmetry.) The 
    ability of state commissions to impose bill and keep arrangements where 
    the costs of terminating traffic are nearly symmetrical, traffic volume 
    is roughly balanced, and both are expected to remain so, may allow 
    small entities and small incumbent LECs to avoid the cost of measuring 
    traffic exchange. (Section XI.A.5--Bill and Keep.) For the reasons set 
    forth in Section XI.A.5 above, we reject the proposed alternative of 
    permitting states to adopt bill-and-keep arrangements for the transport 
    and termination of traffic where the cost of terminating traffic is not 
    nearly symmetrical.
        962. By requiring that rates for transport and termination be cost 
    based, we believe that all parties in telecommunications markets, 
    including small incumbent LECs and small entities, may benefit from 
    increased opportunities to compete effectively in local exchange 
    markets. (Section XI.A.3--Pricing Methodology.) In addition, we 
    conclude that termination rates for LECs, including small incumbent 
    LECs, should include an allocation of forward-looking common costs, but 
    not an element for the recovery of lost contributions. These decisions 
    may be expected to minimize the economic impact of our decisions on 
    small incumbent LECs and small entities.
        963. This Order eliminates certain charges paging companies may now 
    be assessed by LECs and enables paging companies to claim new revenues 
    from LECs for terminating paging calls. (Section XI.A--Reciprocal 
    Compensation for Transport and Termination of Telecommunications.) 
    Paging companies, including small entities, may thereby incur lower 
    costs. Such entities also may increase their revenues, depending on the 
    outcome of any proceedings concerning their termination costs. For the 
    reasons set forth in Section XI.A.3 above, we cannot conclude, at this 
    time, that a LEC's forward looking costs may be used as a reasonable 
    proxy for the costs of call termination by paging providers. We further 
    conclude that the default price for termination of traffic from the end 
    office that we adopt in this proceeding in Section XI.A.3 above does 
    not apply to termination of traffic by paging providers. This default 
    price is based on estimates in the record of the costs to LECs of 
    termination from the end office or end-office switching.
    B. Access to Rights-of-Way
        964. Summary of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping, and Other 
    Compliance Requirements. Small incumbent LECs that meet the definition 
    of a utility (The Act defines ``utility'' as ``any person who is a 
    local exchange carrier or an electric, gas, water, steam, or other 
    public utility, and who owns or controls poles, ducts, conduits, or 
    rights-of-way used, in whole or in part, for any wire communication.'') 
    and own poles, ducts, conduits and rights-of-way where access was not 
    previously mandated are now required to provide access to requesting 
    telecommunications carriers (other than incumbent LECs and cable 
    television systems) which may require the use of legal, engineering, 
    and accounting resources for evaluation and processing of attachment 
    requests. (Section XI.B.2--Section 224(f): Non-discriminatory Access.) 
    This may also require small incumbent LECs and small entities to employ 
    technical personnel to modify pole attachment arrangements.
        965. A complaint of unjustified denial of access must be supported 
    by a written request for access, the utility's response, and 
    information supporting the complainant's position. This will likely 
    impose some recordkeeping requirements on small incumbent LECs and 
    small entities seeking access to rights-of-way. Our requirements may 
    also impose administrative requirements, including legal and 
    engineering expertise, on small governmental jurisdictions (Under the 
    Regulatory Flexibility Act, a ``small governmental jurisdiction'' is 
    one type
    
    [[Page 45616]]
    
    of ``small entity,'' and is defined as the ``governments of cities, 
    counties, towns, townships, villages, school districts, or special 
    districts with a population of less than fifty thousand * * * .'' 5 
    U.S.C. 601(5).) that resolve disputes arising under section 224 of the 
    Communications Act. (Section XI.B.5.c.2--Dispute Resolution.) In 
    addition, small governmental jurisdictions that have established rules 
    and regulations for access to poles, ducts and conduits specifically, 
    and interconnection generally, are also likely to have some level of 
    reporting and recordkeeping requirements for competing 
    telecommunications carriers that use the poles, some of which may be 
    small entities. (Section XI.B.6--Reverse Preemption.)
        966. Steps Taken to Minimize Significant Economic Impact on Small 
    Entities and Small Incumbent LECs, and Alternatives Considered. In 
    placing the burden of proof on the denying utility with respect to the 
    propriety of a denial of access, we recognize that new entrants, which 
    may be small entities, are not likely to have access to such 
    information without cooperation from the utilities. Complaints should 
    not be dismissed where the petitioner was unable to obtain a written 
    response from the denying utility, or where the utility also denied the 
    petitioner any relevant information needed to establish a prima facie 
    case. These provisions should allow an entrant to pursue a claim 
    without the need for expensive discovery, and should not preclude or 
    discourage entities with limited resources from seeking redress where 
    access is denied. (Section XI.B.5--Dispute Resolution.) For the reasons 
    set forth in Section XI.B.5, we reject the recommendation that an 
    applicant be allowed to seek injunctive relief in federal court and 
    select federal jurisdiction for enforcement or appeal of any matter 
    regarding pole attachments. Our conclusion that state and local pole 
    attachment requirements are presumed reasonable may minimize burdens on 
    small governmental jurisdictions by preserving existing rules and 
    procedures, and the local government's expertise with its own rules. 
    (Section XI.B.2--Specific Rules.) In reaching this result, we reject 
    the alternative of invalidating such state regulations in favor of 
    federal rules for the reasons stated in Section XI.B.2. Our 
    determination not to prescribe numerous specific rules in this area 
    recognizes the varying technologies and facilities deployed by 
    incumbent LECs, including small incumbent LECs. For example, we 
    recognize that utilities, including small incumbent LECs, normally have 
    their own operating standards that dictate conditions of access. Thus, 
    we leave in place such conditions of access. For the reasons set forth 
    in Section XI.B, we reject the alternative of prescribing a 
    comprehensive set of substantive engineering standards governing access 
    to rights-of-way.
        967. When an attaching entity modifies poles for its use, it will 
    be entitled to recover a share of its expenses from any later-attaching 
    entities. (Section XI.B.4--Modifications.) This should permit attaching 
    entities that modify poles, some of which may be small entities, to 
    bear only their proportionate costs and prevent them from effectively 
    subsidizing their later-entering competitors. The requirement that 
    utilities provide attaching entities with 60 days' notice prior to 
    commencing modifications to any pole, duct or conduit should provide 
    attaching entities, some of which may be small entities, with 
    sufficient time to evaluate the impact of the proposed modification on 
    their interests and to plan and coordinate any modifications to their 
    own attachments. (Id.)
    C. Imposing Additional Obligations on LECs
        968. Summary of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping and Other 
    Compliance Requirements. Our decisions in this section of the Order do 
    not subject any small entities to reporting, recordkeeping or other 
    compliance requirements.
        969. Steps Taken to Minimize Significant Economic Impact on Small 
    Entities and Small Incumbent LECs, and Alternatives Considered. The 
    determination that the 1996 Act does not permit the particular 
    obligations for incumbent LECs set forth in section 251(c) to be 
    imposed on non-incumbent carriers, absent a finding by the Commission 
    under section 251(h)(2), should limit potential burdens on new 
    entrants, including small entities. (Section XI.C--Imposing Obligations 
    on LECs.)
    Summary Analysis of Section XII--Exemptions, Suspensions and 
    Modifications of Section 251 Requirements
        970. Summary of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping and Other 
    Compliance Requirements. Section 251(f)(1) grants rural telephone 
    companies, which may be small incumbent LECs, an exemption from the 
    requirements of section 251(c) (which only apply to incumbent LECs) 
    until the rural telephone company has received a bona fide request for 
    interconnection, services, or network elements, and the state 
    determines that the exemption should be terminated. Section 251(f)(2) 
    provides that LECs with fewer than two percent of the nation's 
    subscriber lines may petition a state commission for a suspension or 
    modification of any requirements of sections 251(b) and 251(c). The 
    latter provision, section 251(f)(2), is available to all LECs including 
    competitive LECs, which may be small entities.
        971. After a carrier has made a bona fide request under Section 
    251, a rural telephone company, which may be a small incumbent LEC, 
    seeking to retain its exemption under section 251(f)(1) must prove to 
    the state commission that it should retain its exemption. To remove the 
    exemption, a state commission must find that the bona fide 
    interconnection request is not unduly economically burdensome, is 
    technically feasible, and is consistent with section 254. The parties 
    involved in such a proceeding may need to use legal, accounting, 
    economic and/or engineering services. A small incumbent LEC or a 
    competitive LEC, which may be a small entity, seeking under 251(f)(2) 
    to modify or suspend the national interconnection requirements imposed 
    by section 251(b) or 251(c) bears the burden of proving that 
    interconnection would: (1) create a significant adverse economic impact 
    on telecommunications users; (2) be unduly economically burdensome; or 
    (3) be technically infeasible.
        972. Steps Taken to Minimize Significant Economic Impact on Small 
    Entities and Small Incumbent LECs, and Alternatives Considered. As set 
    forth in Section XII above, the determination whether a section 251(f) 
    exemption, suspension, or modification should be continued or granted 
    lies primarily with the relevant state commission. By largely leaving 
    this determination to the states, our decisions permit this fact-
    specific inquiry to be administered in a manner that minimizes 
    regulatory burdens and the economic impact on small entities and small 
    incumbent LECs. However, to further minimize regulatory burdens and 
    minimize the economic impact of our decision, we adopt several rules as 
    set forth in Section XII above, which may facilitate the efficient 
    resolution of such inquiries, provide guidance, and minimize 
    uncertainty. As set forth in Section XII above, we find that the rural 
    LEC or smaller LEC must prove to the state commission that the 
    financial harm shown to justify an exemption, suspension, or 
    modification would be greater than the harm that might
    
    [[Page 45617]]
    
    typically be expected as a result of competition. Finally, we conclude 
    that section 251(f) adequately provides for varying treatment for 
    smaller or rural LECs where such variances are justified. As a result, 
    we expect that section 251(f) will significantly minimize regulatory 
    burdens and economic impacts from the rules adopted in this Order.
    Summary Analysis of Section XIII--Advanced Telecommunications 
    Capabilities
        973. Summary of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping and Other 
    Compliance Requirements. Our decision to defer consideration of rules 
    in this section of the Order does not subject any small entities or 
    small incumbent LECs to reporting, recordkeeping or other compliance 
    requirements.
        974. Steps Taken to Minimize Significant Economic Impact on Small 
    Entities and Small Incumbent LECs, and Alternatives Considered. We do 
    not anticipate that our decision to defer consideration of rules in 
    this section of the Order will have any economic impact on small 
    entities or small incumbent LECs.
    Summary Analysis of Section XIV--Provisions of Section 252
    A. Section 252(e)(5)
        975. Summary of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping, and Other 
    Compliance Requirements. Pursuant to section 252(b)(1), a party to 
    negotiation may petition a state commission to arbitrate any open 
    issues. Small entities and small incumbent LECs negotiating 
    interconnection agreements may, therefore, participate in state 
    arbitration in order to obtain an interconnection agreement, which may 
    impose significant legal costs. (Section XIV.A--Section 252(e)(5).) 
    Section 252(e)(5) requires the Commission to assume the state's 
    responsibility under section 252 if the state ``fails to act to carry 
    out its responsibility'' under the section. We require an aggrieved 
    party, which may be a small entity or a small incumbent LEC, to notify 
    the FCC that a state commission has failed to act under section 252 by 
    filing a detailed written petition, backed by affidavit. As set forth 
    above in Section XIV.A, if the Commission, following a notice and 
    comment period, determines that the state has failed to act, the 
    Commission will assume authority under section 252(e)(5) and mediate or 
    arbitrate the dispute. This process may also entail significant legal 
    expertise.
        976. Steps Taken to Minimize Significant Economic Impact on Small 
    Entities and Small Incumbent LECs, and Alternatives Considered. In this 
    Order, the Commission adopts a minimum set of rules that will provide 
    notice of the standards and procedures that the Commission will use if 
    it has to assume the responsibility of a state commission under section 
    252(e)(5). These rules should benefit small entities and small 
    incumbent LECs by limiting uncertainty and minimizing transaction costs 
    associated with the arbitration process. (Section XIV.A--Section 
    252(e)(5).)
        977. The Commission concludes that, if it arbitrates agreements, it 
    will use a ``final offer'' arbitration method, whereby each party to 
    the arbitration proposes its best and final offer, and the arbitrator 
    chooses between the proposals. The arbitrator may choose either 
    proposal in its entirety, or could choose different parties' proposals 
    on an issue-by-issue basis. This method of arbitration should minimize 
    the economic impact on small entities and small incumbent LECs by 
    reducing the transaction costs associated with arbitration. Our rules 
    should also encourage parties, to negotiate after offers are submitted 
    which should provide additional flexibility for parties including small 
    entities and small incumbent LECs, to agree to a resolution tailored to 
    their interests. (Section XIV.A--Section 252(e)(5).)
        978. For the reasons set forth above in Section XIV.A, we reject 
    the alternative of adopting national rules governing state arbitration 
    procedures. We believe the states are in a better position to develop 
    mediation and arbitration rules that support the objectives of the 1996 
    Act. States may develop specific measures that best address the 
    concerns of small entities and small incumbent LECs participating in 
    mediation or arbitration.
        979. As set forth above in Section XIV.A, we reject the suggestion 
    that the Commission return jurisdiction over an arbitration to the 
    state commission. We further reject the argument that, once the 
    Commission has mediated or arbitrated an agreement, the agreement must 
    be submitted to the state commission for approval under state law. We 
    decline to adopt the alternative suggested by some parties that, if the 
    Commission steps into the state commission role, it is bound by state 
    laws and standards that would have applied to the state commission. 
    (Section XIV.A--Section 252(e)(5).).
        980. As explained above in Section XIV.A, we also reject the 
    alternative that an arbitrated agreement not be binding on the parties. 
    Finally, we reject the alternative of opening the arbitration process 
    to all third parties, which should minimize the costs involved in such 
    proceedings.
    B. Requirements of Section 252(i)
        981. Summary of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping and Other 
    Compliance Requirements. Our decisions in this section of the Order do 
    not subject any small entities to reporting, recordkeeping or other 
    compliance requirements. Incumbent LECs, including small incumbent 
    LECs, are required to file with state commissions all interconnection 
    agreements entered into with other carriers, including adjacent 
    incumbent LECs. Incumbent LECs must also permit third parties to obtain 
    any individual interconnection, service or network element arrangement 
    on the same terms and conditions as those contained in any agreement 
    approved under section 252. Moreover, incumbent LECs must prove with 
    specificity that terms and conditions contained in filed agreements are 
    legitimately related to the purchase of the individual element or 
    service being sought. Incumbent LECs must provide ``most favored 
    nation'' status with regard to subsequent carriers regardless of 
    whether they include ``most favored nation'' clauses in their 
    agreements. Complying with these requirements may require small 
    incumbent LECs and requesting small entities to use legal and 
    negotiation skills.
        982. Steps Taken to Minimize Significant Economic Impact on Small 
    Entities and Small Incumbent LECs, and Alternatives Considered. Our 
    decision to adopt national standards to implement section 252(i) should 
    minimize the economic impact of our decision on both small entities and 
    small incumbent LECs by expediting the resolution of disputes, thereby 
    reducing transaction costs associated with interconnection. Our 
    decision that section 252(i) permits requesting carriers to choose 
    among individual provisions contained in publicly-filed interconnection 
    agreements should minimize the economic impact for small new entrants 
    by permitting them to obtain the provisions they desire without having 
    to adopt entire agreements that would not reflect their costs or the 
    specific technical characteristics of their networks. (Section XIV.B--
    Section 252(i).) Moreover, small entities may be able to obtain the 
    same terms and conditions of agreements reached by larger carriers that 
    possess greater bargaining power without having to incur the costs of 
    negotiation and/or arbitration.
        983. We also determine that publicly-filed agreements need only be 
    made available to carriers who cause
    
    [[Page 45618]]
    
    incumbent LECs to incur no greater costs than did the original carrier, 
    which should minimize the economic impact on small incumbent LECs. We 
    also minimize the regulatory burden for small entities and small 
    incumbent LECs by finding that a new entrant seeking interconnection, 
    network elements, or services pursuant to section 252(i) need not make 
    such requests pursuant to the procedures for initial section 251 
    requests, but shall be permitted to obtain access to agreements on an 
    expedited basis.
        984. As set forth above, we conclude that section 252(i) permits 
    differential treatment of carriers based on differences in the costs of 
    serving those carriers, but does not permit incumbent LECs to limit the 
    availability of interconnection, services, or network elements only to 
    those requesting carriers serving a comparable class of subscribers or 
    providing the same service as the original party to the agreement. 
    (Section XIV--Section 252(i).) These decisions should minimize the 
    impact on small entities by preventing discrimination and enabling them 
    to obtain the same terms and conditions as larger carriers that possess 
    greater bargaining power. For the reasons set forth in Section XIV, we 
    reject the interpretation favored by commenters arguing that new 
    entrants should not be able to choose among provisions of 
    interconnection agreements filed with state commissions.
    
    E. Report to Congress
    
        985. The Commission shall send a copy of this FRFA, along with this 
    Order, in a report to Congress pursuant to the Small Business 
    Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act of 1996, 5 U.S.C. 
    Sec. 801(a)(1)(A). A copy of this FRFA will also be published in the 
    Federal Register.
    
    XVI. Ordering Clauses
    
        986. Accordingly, it is ordered that, pursuant to Sections 1-4, 
    201-209, 214, 218, 224, 251, 252, and 303(r) of the Communications Act 
    of 1934, as amended, and Section 601 of the Telecommunications Act of 
    1996, 47 U.S.C. 151-154, 201-209, 214, 218, 224, 251, 252, 303(r), the 
    Report and order is adopted, effective September 30, 1996. The 
    collections of information contained within are contingent upon 
    approval by the Office of Management and Budget.
        987. It is further ordered that Part 51 of the Commission's rules, 
    47 CFR Sec. 51 is Added as set forth below.
        988. It is further ordered that, to the extent issues from CC 
    Docket No. 95-185, In the Matter of Interconnection Between Local 
    Exchange Carriers and Commercial Mobile Service Providers, are resolved 
    here, we incorporate the relevant portions of the record in that 
    docket.
        989. It is further ordered that, to the extent issues from CC 
    Docket No. 91-346, In the Matter of Intelligent Networks, are resolved 
    here, we incorporate the relevant portions of the record in that 
    docket.
        990. It is further ordered, light of the United States Court of 
    Appeals for the District of Columbia Circuit in Pacific Bell v. FCC, 81 
    F.3d 1147 (D.C. Cir. 1996) (table) and the Telecommunications Act of 
    1996, that the rules and policies adopted in Expanded Interconnection 
    with Local Telephone Company Facilities, CC Docket No. 91-141, 9 FCC 
    Rcd 5154 (1994), shall remain in effect.
    
    List of Subjects
    
    47 CFR Part 1
    
        Access to rights of way, Telecommunications.
    
    47 CFR Part 20
    
        Communications common carriers, Interconnection.
    
    47 CFR Part 51
    
        Collocation, Communications common carriers, Interconnection, 
    Network elements, Pricing standard, Proxies, Reciprocal compensation, 
    Resale, Transport and termination.
    
    47 CFR Part 90
    
        Common carriers.
    
    Federal Communications Commission.
    William F. Caton,
    Acting Secretary.
    
    Rule Changes
    
        Parts 1, 20, 51 and 90 of Title 47 of the Code of Federal 
    Regulations are amended as follows:
    
    PART 1--PRACTICE AND PROCEDURE
    
        1. The authority citation for part 1 is revised to read as follows:
    
        Authority: 47 U.S.C. 151, 154, 251, 252, 303, and 309(j) unless 
    otherwise noted.
    
        2. Section 1.1401 is revised to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 1.1401  Purpose.
    
        The rules and regulations contained in subpart J of this part 
    provide complaint and enforcement procedures to ensure that 
    telecommunications carriers and cable system operators have 
    nondiscriminatory access to utility poles, ducts, conduits, and rights-
    of-way on rates, terms, and conditions that are just and reasonable.
        3. Section 1.1402 is amended by revising paragraph (d) to read as 
    follows:
    
    
    Sec. 1.1402  Definitions.
    
    * * * * *
        (d) The term complaint means a filing by a cable television system 
    operator, a cable television system association, a utility, an 
    association of utilities, a telecommunications carrier, or an 
    association of telecommunications carriers alleging that it has been 
    denied access to a utility pole, duct, conduit, or right-of-way in 
    violation of this subpart and/or that a rate, term, or condition for a 
    pole attachment is not just and reasonable.
    * * * * *
        4. Section 1.1403 is revised to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 1.1403  Duty to provide access; modifications; notice of removal, 
    increase or modification; petition for temporary stay.
    
        (a) A utility shall provide a cable television system or any 
    telecommunications carrier with nondiscriminatory access to any pole, 
    duct, conduit, or right-of-way owned or controlled by it. 
    Notwithstanding this obligation, a utility may deny a cable television 
    system or any telecommunications carrier access to its poles, ducts, 
    conduits, or rights-of-way, on a non-discriminatory basis where there 
    is insufficient capacity or for reasons of safety, reliability and 
    generally applicable engineering purposes.
        (b) Requests for access to a utility's poles, ducts, conduits or 
    rights-of-way by a telecommunications carrier or cable operator must be 
    in writing. If access is not granted within 45 days of the request for 
    access, the utility must confirm the denial in writing by the 45th day. 
    The utility's denial of access shall be specific, shall include all 
    relevant evidence and information supporting its denial, and shall 
    explain how such evidence and information relate to a denial of access 
    for reasons of lack of capacity, safety, reliability or engineering 
    standards.
        (c) A utility shall provide a cable television system operator or 
    telecommunications carrier no less than 60 days written notice prior 
    to:
        (1) Removal of facilities or termination of any service to those 
    facilities, such removal or termination arising out of a rate, term or 
    condition of the cable television system operator's of 
    telecommunications carrier's pole attachment agreement;
    
    [[Page 45619]]
    
        (2) Any increase in pole attachment rates; or
        (3) Any modification of facilities other than routine maintenance 
    or modification in response to emergencies.
        (d) A cable television system operator or telecommunications 
    carrier may file a ``Petition for Temporary Stay'' of the action 
    contained in a notice received pursuant to paragraph (c) of this 
    section within 15 days of receipt of such notice. Such submission shall 
    not be considered unless it includes, in concise terms, the relief 
    sought, the reasons for such relief, including a showing of irreparable 
    harm and likely cessation of cable television service or 
    telecommunication service, a copy of the notice, and certification of 
    service as required by Sec. 1.1404(b). The named respondent may file an 
    answer within 7 days of the date the Petition for Temporary Stay was 
    filed. No further filings under this section will be considered unless 
    requested or authorized by the Commission and no extensions of time 
    will be granted unless justified pursuant to Sec. 1.46.5. Section 
    1.1404 is amended by revising paragraphs (b) and (c) and by adding new 
    paragraph (k) to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 1.1404  Complaint.
    
    * * * * *
        (b) The complaint shall be accompanied by a certification of 
    service on the named respondent, and each of the Federal, State, and 
    local governmental agencies that regulate any aspect of the services 
    provided by the complainant or respondent.
        (c) In a case where it is claimed that a rate, term, or condition 
    is unjust or unreasonable, the complaint shall contain a statement that 
    the State has not certified to the Commission that it regulates the 
    rates, terms and conditions for pole attachments. The complaint shall 
    include a statement that the utility is not owned by any railroad, any 
    person who is cooperatively organized or any person owned by the 
    Federal Government or any State.
    * * * * *
        (k) In a case where a cable television system operator or 
    telecommunications carrier claims that it has been denied access to a 
    pole, duct, conduit or right-of-way despite a request made pursuant to 
    section 47 U.S.C. Sec. 224(f), the complaint shall be filed within 30 
    days of such denial. In addition to meeting the other requirements of 
    this section, the complaint shall include the data and information 
    necessary to support the claim, including:
        (1) The reasons given for the denial of access to the utility's 
    poles, ducts, conduits and rights-of-way;
        (2) The basis for the complainant's claim that the denial of access 
    is improper;
        (3) The remedy sought by the complainant;
        (4) A copy of the written request to the utility for access to its 
    poles, ducts, conduits or rights-of-way; and
        (5) A copy of the utility's response to the written request 
    including all information given by the utility to support its denial of 
    access. A complaint alleging improper denial of access will not be 
    dismissed if the complainant is unable to obtain a utility's written 
    response, or if the utility denies the complainant any other 
    information needed to establish a prima facie case.
        6. Section 1.1409 is amended by revising paragraphs (b) and (d) to 
    read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 1.1409  Commission consideration of the complaint.
    
    * * * * *
        (b) The complainant shall have the burden of establishing a prima 
    facie case that the rate, term, or condition is not just and reasonable 
    or that the denial of access violates 47 U.S.C. Sec. 224(f). If, 
    however, a utility argues that the proposed rate is lower than its 
    incremental costs, the utility has the burden of establishing that such 
    rate is below the statutory minimum just and reasonable rate. In a case 
    involving a denial of access, the utility shall have the burden of 
    proving that the denial was lawful, once a prima facie case is 
    established by the complainant.
    * * * * *
        (d) The Commission shall deny the complaint if it determines that 
    the complainant has not established a prima facie case, or that the 
    rate, term or condition is just and reasonable, or that the denial of 
    access was lawful.
    * * * * *
        7. Section 1.1416 is amended by revising the section-heading and 
    paragraph (b) to read as follows:
    
    
    Sec. 1.1416  Imputation of rates; modification costs.
    
    * * * * *
        (b) The costs of modifying a facility shall be borne by all parties 
    that obtain access to the facility as a result of the modification and 
    by all parties that directly benefit from the modification. Each party 
    described in the preceding sentence shall share proportionately in the 
    cost of the modification. A party with a preexisting attachment to the 
    modified facility shall be deemed to directly benefit from a 
    modification if, after receiving notification of such modification as 
    provided in subpart J of this part, it adds to or modifies its 
    attachment. Notwithstanding the foregoing, a party with a preexisting 
    attachment to a pole, conduit, duct or right-of-way shall not be 
    required to bear any of the costs of rearranging or replacing its 
    attachment if such rearrangement or replacement is necessitated solely 
    as a result of an additional attachment or the modification of an 
    existing attachment sought by another party. If a party makes an 
    attachment to the facility after the completion of the modification, 
    such party shall share proportionately in the cost of the modification 
    if such modification rendered possible the added attachment.
    
    PART 20--COMMERCIAL MOBILE RADIO SERVICES
    
        8. The authority citation for part 20 is revised to read as 
    follows:
    
        Authority: Secs. 4, 251-2, 303, and 332, 48 Stat. 1066, 1062, as 
    amended; 47 U.S.C. 154, 251-4, 303, and 332 unless otherwise noted.
    
        9. Section 20.11 is amended by adding paragraph (c) to read as 
    follows:
    
    
    Sec. 20.11  Interconnection to facilities of local exchange carriers.
    
    * * * * *
        (c) Local exchange carriers and commercial mobile radio service 
    providers shall also comply with applicable provisions of part 51 of 
    this chapter.
    * * * * *
        10. A new part 51 is added to read as follows:
    
    PART 51--INTERCONNECTION
    
    Subpart A--General Information
    
    Sec.
    51.1  Basis and purpose.
    51.3  Applicability to negotiated agreements.
    51.5  Terms and definitions.
    
    Subpart B--Telecommunications Carriers
    
    51.100  General duty.
    
    Subpart C--Obligations of All Local Exchange Carriers
    
    51.201  Resale.
    51.203  Number portability.
    51.219  Access to rights of way.
    51.221  Reciprocal compensation.
    51.223  Application of additional requirements.
    
    Subpart D--Additional Obligations of Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers
    
    51.301  Duty to negotiate.
    51.303  Preexisting agreements.
    51.305  Interconnection.
    51.307  Duty to provide access on an unbundled basis to network 
    elements.
    
    [[Page 45620]]
    
    51.309  Use of unbundled network elements.
    51.311  Nondiscriminatory access to unbundled network elements.
    51.313  Just, reasonable and nondiscriminatory terms and conditions 
    for the provision of unbundled network elements.
    51.315  Combination of unbundled network elements.
    51.317  Standards for identifying network elements to be made 
    available.
    51.319  Specific unbundling requirements.
    51.321  Methods of obtaining interconnection and access to unbundled 
    elements under section 251 of the Act.
    51.323  Standards for physical collocation and virtual collocation.
    Subpart E--Exemptions, Suspensions, and Modifications of Requirements 
    of Section 251 of the Act
    51.401  State authority.
    51.403  Carriers eligible for suspension or modification under 
    section 251(f)(2) of the Act.
    51.405  Burden of proof.
    
    Subpart F--Pricing of Elements
    
    51.501  Scope.
    51.503  General pricing standard.
    51.505  Forward-looking economic cost.
    51.507  General rate structure standard.
    51.509  Rate structure standards for specific elements.
    51.511  Forward-looking economic cost per unit.
    51.513  Proxies for forward-looking economic cost.
    51.515  Application of access charges.
    
    Subpart G--Resale
    
    51.601  Scope of resale rules.
    51.603  Resale obligation of all local exchange carriers.
    51.605  Additional obligations of incumbent local exchange carriers.
    51.607  Wholesale pricing standard.
    51.609  Determination of avoided retail costs.
    51.611  Interim wholesale rates.
    51.613  Restrictions on resale.
    51.615  Withdrawal of services.
    51.617  Assessment of end user common line charge on resellers.
    Subpart H--Reciprocal Compensation for Transport and Termination of 
    Local Telecommunications Traffic
    51.701  Scope of transport and termination pricing rules.
    51.703  Reciprocal compensation obligation of LECs.
    51.705  Incumbent LECs' rates for transport and termination.
    51.707  Default proxies for incumbent LECs' transport and 
    termination rates.
    51.709  Rate structure for transport and termination.
    51.711  Symmetrical reciprocal compensation.
    51.713  Bill-and-keep arrangements for reciprocal compensation.
    51.715  Interim transport and termination pricing.
    51.717  Renegotiation of existing non-reciprocal arrangements.
    
    Subpart I--Procedures for Implementation of Section 252 of the Act
    
    51.801  Commission action upon a state commission's failure to act 
    to carry out its responsibility under section 252 of the Act.
    51.803  Procedures for Commission notification of a state 
    commission's failure to act.
    51.805  The Commission's authority over proceedings and matters.
    51.807  Arbitration and mediation of agreements by the Commission 
    pursuant to section 252(e)(5) of the Act.
    51.809  Availability of provisions of agreements to other 
    telecommunications carriers under section 252(i) of the Act.
    
        Authority: Sections 1-5, 7, 201-05, 218, 225-27, 251-54, 271, 48 
    Stat. 1070, as amended, 1077; 47 U.S.C. 151-55, 157, 201-05, 218, 
    225-27, 251-54, 271, unless otherwise noted.
    
    Subpart A--General Information
    
    
    Sec. 51.1  Basis and purpose.
    
        (a) Basis. These rules are issued pursuant to the Communications 
    Act of 1934, as amended.
        (b) Purpose. The purpose of these rules is to implement sections 
    251 and 252 of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended, 47 U.S.C. 
    251 and 252.
    
    
    Sec. 51.3  Applicability to negotiated agreements.
    
        To the extent provided in section 252(e)(2)(A) of the Act, a state 
    commission shall have authority to approve an interconnection agreement 
    adopted by negotiation even if the terms of the agreement do not comply 
    with the requirements of this part.
    
    
    Sec. 51.5  Terms and definitions.
    
        Terms used in this part have the following meanings:
        Act. The Communications Act of 1934, as amended.
        Advanced intelligent network. ``Advanced Intelligent Network'' is a 
    telecommunications network architecture in which call processing, call 
    routing, and network management are provided by means of centralized 
    databases located at points in an incumbent local exchange carrier's 
    network.
        Arbitration, final offer. ``Final offer arbitration'' is a 
    procedure under which each party submits a final offer concerning the 
    issues subject to arbitration, and the arbitrator selects, without 
    modification, one of the final offers by the parties to the arbitration 
    or portions of both such offers. ``Entire package final offer 
    arbitration,'' is a procedure under which the arbitrator must select, 
    without modification, the entire proposal submitted by one of the 
    parties to the arbitration. ``Issue-by-issue final offer arbitration,'' 
    is a procedure under which the arbitrator must select, without 
    modification, on an issue-by-issue basis, one of the proposals 
    submitted by the parties to the arbitration.
        Billing. ``Billing'' involves the provision of appropriate usage 
    data by one telecommunications carrier to another to facilitate 
    customer billing with attendant acknowledgements and status reports. It 
    also involves the exchange of information between telecommunications 
    carriers to process claims and adjustments.
        Commercial Mobile Radio Service (CMRS). ``CMRS'' has the same 
    meaning as that term is defined in Sec. 20.3 of this chapter.
        Commission. ``Commission'' refers to the Federal Communications 
    Commission.
        Directory assistance service. ``Directory assistance service'' 
    includes, but is not limited to, making available to customers, upon 
    request, information contained in directory listings.
        Directory listings. ``Directory listings'' are any information:
        (1) Identifying the listed names of subscribers of a 
    telecommunications carrier and such subscriber's telephone numbers, 
    addresses, or primary advertising classifications (as such 
    classifications are assigned at the time of the establishment of such 
    service), or any combination of such listed names, numbers, addresses 
    or classifications; and
        (2) That the telecommunications carrier or an affiliate has 
    published, caused to be published, or accepted for publication in any 
    directory format.
        Downstream database. A ``downstream database'' is a database owned 
    and operated by an individual carrier for the purpose of providing 
    number portability in conjunction with other functions and services.
        Equipment necessary for interconnection or access to unbundled 
    network elements. For purposes of section 251(c)(2) of the Act, the 
    equipment used to interconnect with an incumbent local exchange 
    carrier's network for the transmission and routing of telephone 
    exchange service, exchange access service, or both. For the purposes of 
    section 251(c)(3) of the Act, the equipment used to gain access to an 
    incumbent local exchange carrier's unbundled network elements for the 
    provision of a telecommunications service.
        Incumbent Local Exchange Carrier (Incumbent LEC). With respect to 
    an area, the local exchange carrier that:
    
    [[Page 45621]]
    
        (1) On February 8, 1996, provided telephone exchange service in 
    such area; and
        (2)(i) On February 8, 1996, was deemed to be a member of the 
    exchange carrier association pursuant to Sec. 69.601(b) of this 
    chapter; or
        (ii) Is a person or entity that, on or after February 8, 1996, 
    became a successor or assign of a member described in paragraph (2)(i) 
    of this section.
        Interconnection. ``Interconnection'' is the linking of two networks 
    for the mutual exchange of traffic. This term does not include the 
    transport and termination of traffic.
        Local Exchange Carrier (LEC). A ``LEC'' is any person that is 
    engaged in the provision of telephone exchange service or exchange 
    access. Such term does not include a person insofar as such person is 
    engaged in the provision of a commercial mobile service under section 
    332(c) of the Act, except to the extent that the Commission finds that 
    such service should be included in the definition of the such term.
        Maintenance and repair. ``Maintenance and repair'' involves the 
    exchange of information between telecommunications carriers where one 
    initiates a request for maintenance or repair of existing products and 
    services or unbundled network elements or combination thereof from the 
    other with attendant acknowledgements and status reports.
        Meet point. A ``meet point'' is a point of interconnection between 
    two networks, designated by two telecommunications carriers, at which 
    one carrier's responsibility for service begins and the other carrier's 
    responsibility ends.
        Meet point interconnection arrangement. A ``meet point 
    interconnection arrangement'' is an arrangement by which each 
    telecommunications carrier builds and maintains its network to a meet 
    point.
        Network element. A ``network element'' is a facility or equipment 
    used in the provision of a telecommunications service. Such term also 
    includes, but is not limited to, features, functions, and capabilities 
    that are provided by means of such facility or equipment, including but 
    not limited to, subscriber numbers, databases, signaling systems, and 
    information sufficient for billing and collection or used in the 
    transmission, routing, or other provision of a telecommunications 
    service.
        Operator services. ``Operator services'' are any automatic or live 
    assistance to a consumer to arrange for billing or completion of a 
    telephone call. Such services include, but are not limited to, busy 
    line verification, emergency interrupt, and operator-assisted directory 
    assistance services.
        Physical collocation. ``Physical collocation'' is an offering by an 
    incumbent LEC that enables a requesting telecommunications carrier to:
        (1) Place its own equipment to be used for interconnection or 
    access to unbundled network elements within or upon an incumbent LEC's 
    premises;
        (2) Use such equipment to interconnect with an incumbent LEC's 
    network facilities for the transmission and routing of telephone 
    exchange service, exchange access service, or both, or to gain access 
    to an incumbent LEC's unbundled network elements for the provision of a 
    telecommunications service;
        (3) Enter those premises, subject to reasonable terms and 
    conditions, to install, maintain, and repair equipment necessary for 
    interconnection or access to unbundled elements; and
        (4) Obtain reasonable amounts of space in an incumbent LEC's 
    premises, as provided in this part, for the equipment necessary for 
    interconnection or access to unbundled elements, allocated on a first-
    come, first-served basis.
        Premises. ``Premises'' refers to an incumbent LEC's central offices 
    and serving wire centers, as well as all buildings or similar 
    structures owned or leased by an incumbent LEC that house its network 
    facilities, and all structures that house incumbent LEC facilities on 
    public rights-of-way, including but not limited to vaults containing 
    loop concentrators or similar structures.
        Pre-ordering and ordering. ``Pre-ordering and ordering'' includes 
    the exchange of information between telecommunications carriers about 
    current or proposed customer products and services or unbundled network 
    elements or some combination thereof.
        Provisioning. ``Provisioning'' involves the exchange of information 
    between telecommunications carriers where one executes a request for a 
    set of products and services or unbundled network elements or 
    combination thereof from the other with attendant acknowledgements and 
    status reports.
        Rural telephone company. A ``rural telephone company'' is a LEC 
    operating entity to the extent that such entity:
        (1) Provides common carrier service to any local exchange carrier 
    study area that does not include either:
        (i) Any incorporated place of 10,000 inhabitants or more, or any 
    part thereof, based on the most recently available population 
    statistics of the Bureau of the Census; or
        (ii) Any territory, incorporated or unincorporated, included in an 
    urbanized area, as defined by the Bureau of the Census as of August 10, 
    1993;
        (2) Provides telephone exchange service, including exchange access, 
    to fewer than 50,000 access lines;
        (3) Provides telephone exchange service to any local exchange 
    carrier study area with fewer than 100,000 access lines; or
        (4) Has less than 15 percent of its access lines in communities of 
    more than 50,000 on February 8, 1996.
        Service control point. A ``service control point'' is a computer 
    database in the public switched network which contains information and 
    call processing instructions needed to process and complete a telephone 
    call.
        Service creation environment. A ``service creation environment'' is 
    a computer containing generic call processing software that can be 
    programmed to create new advanced intelligent network call processing 
    services.
        Signal transfer point. A ``signal transfer point'' is a packet 
    switch that acts as a routing hub for a signaling network and transfers 
    messages between various points in and among signaling networks.
        State commission. A ``state commission'' means the commission, 
    board, or official (by whatever name designated) which under the laws 
    of any State has regulatory jurisdiction with respect to intrastate 
    operations of carriers. As referenced in this part, this term may 
    include the Commission if it assumes the responsibility of the state 
    commission, pursuant to section 252(e)(5) of the Act. This term shall 
    also include any person or persons to whom the state commission has 
    delegated its authority under section 251 and 252 of the Act.
        State proceeding. A ``state proceeding'' is any administrative 
    proceeding in which a state commission may approve or prescribe rates, 
    terms, and conditions including, but not limited to, compulsory 
    arbitration pursuant to section 252(b) of the Act, review of a Bell 
    operating company statement of generally available terms pursuant to 
    section 252(f) of the Act, and a proceeding to determine whether to 
    approve or reject an agreement adopted by arbitration pursuant to 
    section 252(e) of the Act.
        Technically feasible. Interconnection, access to unbundled network 
    elements, collocation, and other methods of achieving interconnection 
    or access to
    
    [[Page 45622]]
    
    unbundled network elements at a point in the network shall be deemed 
    technically feasible absent technical or operational concerns that 
    prevent the fulfillment of a request by a telecommunications carrier 
    for such interconnection, access, or methods. A determination of 
    technical feasibility does not include consideration of economic, 
    accounting, billing, space, or site concerns, except that space and 
    site concerns may be considered in circumstances where there is no 
    possibility of expanding the space available. The fact that an 
    incumbent LEC must modify its facilities or equipment to respond to 
    such request does not determine whether satisfying such request is 
    technically feasible. An incumbent LEC that claims that it cannot 
    satisfy such request because of adverse network reliability impacts 
    must prove to the state commission by clear and convincing evidence 
    that such interconnection, access, or methods would result in specific 
    and significant adverse network reliability impacts.
        Telecommunications carrier. A ``telecommunications carrier'' is any 
    provider of telecommunications services, except that such term does not 
    include aggregators of telecommunications services (as defined in 
    section 226 of the Act). A telecommunications carrier shall be treated 
    as a common carrier under the Act only to the extent that it is engaged 
    in providing telecommunications services, except that the Commission 
    shall determine whether the provision of fixed and mobile satellite 
    service shall be treated as common carriage. This definition includes 
    CMRS providers, interexchange carriers (IXCs) and, to the extent they 
    are acting as telecommunications carriers, companies that provide both 
    telecommunications and information services. Private Mobile Radio 
    Service providers are telecommunications carriers to the extent they 
    provide domestic or international telecommunications for a fee directly 
    to the public.
        Virtual collocation. ``Virtual collocation'' is an offering by an 
    incumbent LEC that enables a requesting telecommunications carrier to:
        (1) Designate or specify equipment to be used for interconnection 
    or access to unbundled network elements to be located within or upon an 
    incumbent LEC's premises, and dedicated to such telecommunications 
    carrier's use;
        (2) Use such equipment to interconnect with an incumbent LEC's 
    network facilities for the transmission and routing of telephone 
    exchange service, exchange access service, or both, or for access to an 
    incumbent LEC's unbundled network elements for the provision of a 
    telecommunications service; and
        (3) Electronically monitor and control its communications channels 
    terminating in such equipment.
    
    Subpart B--Telecommunications Carriers
    
    
    Sec. 51.100  General duty.
    
        (a) Each telecommunications carrier has the duty:
        (1) To interconnect directly or indirectly with the facilities and 
    equipment of other telecommunications carriers; and
        (2) To not install network features, functions, or capabilities 
    that do not comply with the guidelines and standards as provided in the 
    Commission's rules or section 255 or 256 of the Act.
        (b) A telecommunication carrier that has interconnected or gained 
    access under sections 251(a)(1), 251(c)(2), or 251(c)(3) of the Act, 
    may offer information services through the same arrangement, so long as 
    it is offering telecommunications services through the same arrangement 
    as well.
    
    Subpart C--Obligations of All Local Exchange Carriers
    
    
    Sec. 51.201  Resale.
    
        The rules governing resale of services by an incumbent LEC are set 
    forth in subpart G of this part.
    
    
    Sec. 51.203  Number portability.
    
        The rules governing number portability are set forth in part 52, 
    subpart C of this chapter.
    
    
    Sec. 51.219  Access to rights of way.
    
        The rules governing access to rights of way are set forth in part 
    1, subpart J of this chapter.
    
    
    Sec. 51.221  Reciprocal compensation.
    
        The rules governing reciprocal compensation are set forth in 
    subpart H of this part.
    
    
    Sec. 51.223  Application of additional requirements.
    
        (a) A state may not impose the obligations set forth in section 
    251(c) of the Act on a LEC that is not classified as an incumbent LEC 
    as defined in section 251(h)(1) of the Act, unless the Commission 
    issues an order declaring that such LECs or classes or categories of 
    LECs should be treated as incumbent LECs.
        (b) A state commission, or any other interested party, may request 
    that the Commission issue an order declaring that a particular LEC be 
    treated as an incumbent LEC, or that a class or category of LECs be 
    treated as incumbent LECs, pursuant to section 251(h)(2) of the Act.
    
    Subpart D--Additional Obligations of Incumbent Local Exchange 
    Carriers
    
    
    Sec. 51.301  Duty to negotiate.
    
        (a) An incumbent LEC shall negotiate in good faith the terms and 
    conditions of agreements to fulfill the duties established by sections 
    251(b) and (c) of the Act.
        (b) A requesting telecommunications carrier shall negotiate in good 
    faith the terms and conditions of agreements described in paragraph (a) 
    of this section.
        (c) If proven to the Commission, an appropriate state commission, 
    or a court of competent jurisdiction, the following actions or 
    practices, among others, violate the duty to negotiate in good faith:
        (1) Demanding that another party sign a nondisclosure agreement 
    that precludes such party from providing information requested by the 
    Commission, or a state commission, or in support of a request for 
    arbitration under section 252(b)(2)(B) of the Act;
        (2) Demanding that a requesting telecommunications carrier attest 
    that an agreement complies with all provisions of the Act, federal 
    regulations, or state law;
        (3) Refusing to include in an arbitrated or negotiated agreement a 
    provision that permits the agreement to be amended in the future to 
    take into account changes in Commission or state rules;
        (4) Conditioning negotiation on a requesting telecommunications 
    carrier first obtaining state certifications;
        (5) Intentionally misleading or coercing another party into 
    reaching an agreement that it would not otherwise have made;
        (6) Intentionally obstructing or delaying negotiations or 
    resolutions of disputes;
         (7) Refusing throughout the negotiation process to designate a 
    representative with authority to make binding representations, if such 
    refusal significantly delays resolution of issues; and
        (8) Refusing to provide information necessary to reach agreement. 
    Such refusal includes, but is not limited to:
        (i) Refusal by an incumbent LEC to furnish information about its 
    network that a requesting telecommunications carrier reasonably 
    requires to identify the network elements that it needs in order to 
    serve a particular customer; and
    
    [[Page 45623]]
    
        (ii) Refusal by a requesting telecommunications carrier to furnish 
    cost data that would be relevant to setting rates if the parties were 
    in arbitration.
    
    
    Sec. 51.303  Preexisting agreements.
    
        (a) All interconnection agreements between an incumbent LEC and a 
    telecommunications carrier, including those negotiated before February 
    8, 1996, shall be submitted by the parties to the appropriate state 
    commission for approval pursuant to section 252(e) of the Act.
        (b) Interconnection agreements negotiated before February 8, 1996, 
    between Class A carriers, as defined by Sec. 32.11(a)(1) of this 
    chapter, shall be filed by the parties with the appropriate state 
    commission no later than June 30, 1997, or such earlier date as the 
    state commission may require.
        (c) If a state commission approves a preexisting agreement, it 
    shall be made available to other parties in accordance with section 
    252(i) of the Act and Sec. 51.809 of this part. A state commission may 
    reject a preexisting agreement on the grounds that it is inconsistent 
    with the public interest, or for other reasons set forth in section 
    252(e)(2)(A) of the Act.
    
    
    Sec. 51.305  Interconnection.
    
        (a) An incumbent LEC shall provide, for the facilities and 
    equipment of any requesting telecommunications carrier, interconnection 
    with the incumbent LEC's network:
        (1) For the transmission and routing of telephone exchange traffic, 
    exchange access traffic, or both;
        (2) At any technically feasible point within the incumbent LEC's 
    network including, at a minimum:
        (i) The line-side of a local switch;
        (ii) The trunk-side of a local switch;
        (iii) The trunk interconnection points for a tandem switch;
        (iv) Central office cross-connect points;
        (v) Out-of-band signaling transfer points necessary to exchange 
    traffic at these points and access call-related databases; and
        (vi) The points of access to unbundled network elements as 
    described in Sec. 51.319;
        (3) That is at a level of quality that is equal to that which the 
    incumbent LEC provides itself, a subsidiary, an affiliate, or any other 
    party, except as provided in paragraph (4) of this section. At a 
    minimum, this requires an incumbent LEC to design interconnection 
    facilities to meet the same technical criteria and service standards 
    that are used within the incumbent LEC's network. This obligation is 
    not limited to a consideration of service quality as perceived by end 
    users, and includes, but is not limited to, service quality as 
    perceived by the requesting telecommunications carrier;
        (4) That, if so requested by a telecommunications carrier and to 
    the extent technically feasible, is superior in quality to that 
    provided by the incumbent LEC to itself or to any subsidiary, 
    affiliate, or any other party to which the incumbent LEC provides 
    interconnection. Nothing in this section prohibits an incumbent LEC 
    from providing interconnection that is lesser in quality at the sole 
    request of the requesting telecommunications carrier; and
        (5) On terms and conditions that are just, reasonable, and 
    nondiscriminatory in accordance with the terms and conditions of any 
    agreement, the requirements of sections 251 and 252 of the Act, and the 
    Commission's rules including, but not limited to, offering such terms 
    and conditions equally to all requesting telecommunications carriers, 
    and offering such terms and conditions that are no less favorable than 
    the terms and conditions upon which the incumbent LEC provides such 
    interconnection to itself. This includes, but is not limited to, the 
    time within which the incumbent LEC provides such interconnection.
        (b) A carrier that requests interconnection solely for the purpose 
    of originating or terminating its interexchange traffic on an incumbent 
    LEC's network and not for the purpose of providing to others telephone 
    exchange service, exchange access service, or both, is not entitled to 
    receive interconnection pursuant to section 251(c)(2) of the Act.
        (c) Previous successful interconnection at a particular point in a 
    network, using particular facilities, constitutes substantial evidence 
    that interconnection is technically feasible at that point, or at 
    substantially similar points, in networks employing substantially 
    similar facilities. Adherence to the same interface or protocol 
    standards shall constitute evidence of the substantial similarity of 
    network facilities.
        (d) Previous successful interconnection at a particular point in a 
    network at a particular level of quality constitutes substantial 
    evidence that interconnection is technically feasible at that point, or 
    at substantially similar points, at that level of quality.
        (e) An incumbent LEC that denies a request for interconnection at a 
    particular point must prove to the state commission that 
    interconnection at that point is not technically feasible.
        (f) If technically feasible, an incumbent LEC shall provide two-way 
    trunking upon request.
    
    
    Sec. 51.307  Duty to provide access on an unbundled basis to network 
    elements.
    
        (a) An incumbent LEC shall provide, to a requesting 
    telecommunications carrier for the provision of a telecommunications 
    service, nondiscriminatory access to network elements on an unbundled 
    basis at any technically feasible point on terms and conditions that 
    are just, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory in accordance with the 
    terms and conditions of any agreement, the requirements of sections 251 
    and 252 of the Act, and the Commission's rules.
        (b) The duty to provide access to unbundled network elements 
    pursuant to section 251(c)(3) of the Act includes a duty to provide a 
    connection to an unbundled network element independent of any duty to 
    provide interconnection pursuant to this part and section 251(c)(2) of 
    the Act.
        (c) An incumbent LEC shall provide a requesting telecommunications 
    carrier access to an unbundled network element, along with all of the 
    unbundled network element's features, functions, and capabilities, in a 
    manner that allows the requesting telecommunications carrier to provide 
    any telecommunications service that can be offered by means of that 
    network element.
        (d) An incumbent LEC shall provide a requesting telecommunications 
    carrier access to the facility or functionality of a requested network 
    element separate from access to the facility or functionality of other 
    network elements, for a separate charge.
    
    
    Sec. 51.309  Use of unbundled network elements.
    
        (a) An incumbent LEC shall not impose limitations, restrictions, or 
    requirements on requests for, or the use of, unbundled network elements 
    that would impair the ability of a requesting telecommunications 
    carrier to offer a telecommunications service in the manner the 
    requesting telecommunications carrier intends.
        (b) A telecommunications carrier purchasing access to an unbundled 
    network element may use such network element to provide exchange access 
    services to itself in order to provide interexchange services to 
    subscribers.
        (c) A telecommunications carrier purchasing access to an unbundled 
    network facility is entitled to exclusive use of that facility for a 
    period of time,
    
    [[Page 45624]]
    
    or when purchasing access to a feature, function, or capability of a 
    facility, a telecommunications carrier is entitled to use of that 
    feature, function, or capability for a period of time. A 
    telecommunications carrier's purchase of access to an unbundled network 
    element does not relieve the incumbent LEC of the duty to maintain, 
    repair, or replace the unbundled network element.
    
    
    Sec. 51.311  Nondiscriminatory access to unbundled network elements.
    
        (a) The quality of an unbundled network element, as well as the 
    quality of the access to the unbundled network element, that an 
    incumbent LEC provides to a requesting telecommunications carrier shall 
    be the same for all telecommunications carriers requesting access to 
    that network element, except as provided in paragraph (c) of this 
    section.
        (b) Except as provided in paragraph (c) of this section, to the 
    extent technically feasible, the quality of an unbundled network 
    element, as well as the quality of the access to such unbundled network 
    element, that an incumbent LEC provides to a requesting 
    telecommunications carrier shall be at least equal in quality to that 
    which the incumbent LEC provides to itself. If an incumbent LEC fails 
    to meet this requirement, the incumbent LEC must prove to the state 
    commission that it is not technically feasible to provide the requested 
    unbundled network element, or to provide access to the requested 
    unbundled network element, at a level of quality that is equal to that 
    which the incumbent LEC provides to itself.
        (c) To the extent technically feasible, the quality of an unbundled 
    network element, as well as the quality of the access to such unbundled 
    network element, that an incumbent LEC provides to a requesting 
    telecommunications carrier shall, upon request, be superior in quality 
    to that which the incumbent LEC provides to itself. If an incumbent LEC 
    fails to meet this requirement, the incumbent LEC must prove to the 
    state commission that it is not technically feasible to provide the 
    requested unbundled network element or access to such unbundled network 
    element at the requested level of quality that is superior to that 
    which the incumbent LEC provides to itself. Nothing in this section 
    prohibits an incumbent LEC from providing interconnection that is 
    lesser in quality at the sole request of the requesting 
    telecommunications carrier.
        (d) Previous successful access to an unbundled element at a 
    particular point in a network, using particular facilities, is 
    substantial evidence that access is technically feasible at that point, 
    or at substantially similar points, in networks employing substantially 
    similar facilities. Adherence to the same interface or protocol 
    standards shall constitute evidence of the substantial similarity of 
    network facilities.
        (e) Previous successful provision of access to an unbundled element 
    at a particular point in a network at a particular level of quality is 
    substantial evidence that access is technically feasible at that point, 
    or at substantially similar points, at that level of quality.
    
    
    Sec. 51.313  Just, reasonable and nondiscriminatory terms and 
    conditions for the provision of unbundled network elements.
    
        (a) The terms and conditions pursuant to which an incumbent LEC 
    provides access to unbundled network elements shall be offered equally 
    to all requesting telecommunications carriers.
        (b) Where applicable, the terms and conditions pursuant to which an 
    incumbent LEC offers to provide access to unbundled network elements, 
    including but not limited to, the time within which the incumbent LEC 
    provisions such access to unbundled network elements, shall, at a 
    minimum, be no less favorable to the requesting carrier than the terms 
    and conditions under which the incumbent LEC provides such elements to 
    itself.
        (c) An incumbent LEC must provide a carrier purchasing access to 
    unbundled network elements with the pre-ordering, ordering, 
    provisioning, maintenance and repair, and billing functions of the 
    incumbent LEC's operations support systems.
    
    
    Sec. 51.315  Combination of unbundled network elements.
    
        (a) An incumbent LEC shall provide unbundled network elements in a 
    manner that allows requesting telecommunications carriers to combine 
    such network elements in order to provide a telecommunications service.
        (b) Except upon request, an incumbent LEC shall not separate 
    requested network elements that the incumbent LEC currently combines.
        (c) Upon request, an incumbent LEC shall perform the functions 
    necessary to combine unbundled network elements in any manner, even if 
    those elements are not ordinarily combined in the incumbent LEC's 
    network, provided that such combination is:
        (1) Technically feasible; and
        (2) Would not impair the ability of other carriers to obtain access 
    to unbundled network elements or to interconnect with the incumbent 
    LEC's network.
        (d) Upon request, an incumbent LEC shall perform the functions 
    necessary to combine unbundled network elements with elements possessed 
    by the requesting telecommunications carrier in any technically 
    feasible manner.
        (e) An incumbent LEC that denies a request to combine elements 
    pursuant to paragraph (c)(1) or paragraph (d) of this section must 
    prove to the state commission that the requested combination is not 
    technically feasible.
        (f) An incumbent LEC that denies a request to combine elements 
    pursuant to paragraph (c)(2) of this section must prove to the state 
    commission that the requested combination would impair the ability of 
    other carriers to obtain access to unbundled network elements or to 
    interconnect with the incumbent LEC's network.
    
    
    Sec. 51.317  Standards for identifying network elements to be made 
    available.
    
        (a) In determining what network elements should be made available 
    for purposes of section 251(c)(3) of the Act beyond those identified in 
    Sec. 51.319, a state commission shall first determine whether it is 
    technically feasible for the incumbent LEC to provide access to a 
    network element on an unbundled basis.
        (b) If the state commission determines that it is technically 
    feasible for the incumbent LEC to provide access to the network element 
    on an unbundled basis, the state commission may decline to require 
    unbundling of the network element only if:
         (1) The state commission concludes that:
         (i) The network element is proprietary, or contains proprietary 
    information that will be revealed if the network element is provided on 
    an unbundled basis; and
         (ii) A requesting telecommunications carrier could offer the same 
    proposed telecommunications service through the use of other, 
    nonproprietary unbundled network elements within the incumbent LEC's 
    network; or
         (2) The state commission concludes that the failure of the 
    incumbent LEC to provide access to the network element would not 
    decrease the quality of, and would not increase the financial or 
    administrative cost of, the telecommunications service a requesting 
    telecommunications carrier seeks to offer, compared with providing that 
    service over other unbundled network elements in the incumbent LEC's 
    network.
    
    
    Sec. 51.319  Specific unbundling requirements.
    
        An incumbent LEC shall provide nondiscriminatory access in 
    accordance
    
    [[Page 45625]]
    
    with Sec. 51.311 and section 251(c)(3) of the Act to the following 
    network elements on an unbundled basis to any requesting 
    telecommunications carrier for the provision of a telecommunications 
    service:
        (a) Local Loop. The local loop network element is defined as a 
    transmission facility between a distribution frame (or its equivalent) 
    in an incumbent LEC central office and an end user customer premises.
        (b) Network Interface Device.
         (1) The network interface device network element is defined as a 
    cross-connect device used to connect loop facilities to inside wiring.
         (2) An incumbent LEC shall permit a requesting telecommunications 
    carrier to connect its own local loops to the inside wiring of premises 
    through the incumbent LEC's network interface device. The requesting 
    telecommunications carrier shall establish this connection through an 
    adjoining network interface device deployed by such telecommunications 
    carrier.
        (c) Switching Capability.
        (1) Local Switching Capability.
         (i) The local switching capability network element is defined as:
         (A) Line-side facilities, which include, but are not limited to, 
    the connection between a loop termination at a main distribution frame 
    and a switch line card;
        (B) Trunk-side facilities, which include, but are not limited to, 
    the connection between trunk termination at a trunk-side cross-connect 
    panel and a switch trunk card; and
         (C) All features, functions, and capabilities of the switch, which 
    include, but are not limited to:
         (1) The basic switching function of connecting lines to lines, 
    lines to trunks, trunks to lines, and trunks to trunks, as well as the 
    same basic capabilities made available to the incumbent LEC's 
    customers, such as a telephone number, white page listing, and dial 
    tone; and
         (2) All other features that the switch is capable of providing, 
    including but not limited to custom calling, custom local area 
    signaling service features, and Centrex, as well as any technically 
    feasible customized routing functions provided by the switch.
         (ii) An incumbent LEC shall transfer a customer's local service to 
    a competing carrier within a time period no greater than the interval 
    within which the incumbent LEC currently transfers end users between 
    interexchange carriers, if such transfer requires only a change in the 
    incumbent LEC's software;
         (2) Tandem Switching Capability. The tandem switching capability 
    network element is defined as:
         (i) Trunk-connect facilities, including but not limited to the 
    connection between trunk termination at a cross-connect panel and a 
    switch trunk card;
         (ii) The basic switching function of connecting trunks to trunks; 
    and
         (iii) The functions that are centralized in tandem switches (as 
    distinguished from separate end-office switches), including but not 
    limited to call recording, the routing of calls to operator services, 
    and signaling conversion features.
        (d) Interoffice Transmission Facilities.
         (1) Interoffice transmission facilities are defined as incumbent 
    LEC transmission facilities dedicated to a particular customer or 
    carrier, or shared by more than one customer or carrier, that provide 
    telecommunications between wire centers owned by incumbent LECs or 
    requesting telecommunications carriers, or between switches owned by 
    incumbent LECs or requesting telecommunications carriers.
         (2) The incumbent LEC shall:
         (i) Provide a requesting telecommunications carrier exclusive use 
    of interoffice transmission facilities dedicated to a particular 
    customer or carrier, or use of the features, functions, and 
    capabilities of interoffice transmission facilities shared by more than 
    one customer or carrier;
         (ii) Provide all technically feasible transmission facilities, 
    features, functions, and capabilities that the requesting 
    telecommunications carrier could use to provide telecommunications 
    services;
         (iii) Permit, to the extent technically feasible, a requesting 
    telecommunications carrier to connect such interoffice facilities to 
    equipment designated by the requesting telecommunications carrier, 
    including, but not limited to, the requesting telecommunications 
    carrier's collocated facilities; and
         (iv) Permit, to the extent technically feasible, a requesting 
    telecommunications carrier to obtain the functionality provided by the 
    incumbent LEC's digital cross-connect systems in the same manner that 
    the incumbent LEC provides such functionality to interexchange 
    carriers.
        (e) Signaling Networks and Call-Related Databases.
         (1) Signaling Networks.
         (i) Signaling networks include, but are not limited to, signaling 
    links and signaling transfer points.
         (ii) When a requesting telecommunications carrier purchases 
    unbundled switching capability from an incumbent LEC, the incumbent LEC 
    shall provide access to its signaling network from that switch in the 
    same manner in which it obtains such access itself.
         (iii) An incumbent LEC shall provide a requesting 
    telecommunications carrier with its own switching facilities access to 
    the incumbent LEC's signaling network for each of the requesting 
    telecommunications carrier's switches. This connection shall be made in 
    the same manner as an incumbent LEC connects one of its own switches to 
    a signal transfer point.
         (iv) An incumbent LEC is not required to unbundle those signaling 
    links that connect service control points to switching transfer points 
    or to permit a requesting telecommunications carrier to link its own 
    signal transfer points directly to the incumbent LEC's switch or call-
    related databases;
         (2) Call-Related Databases.
         (i) Call-related databases are defined as databases, other than 
    operations support systems, that are used in signaling networks for 
    billing and collection or the transmission, routing, or other provision 
    of a telecommunications service.
         (ii) For purposes of switch query and database response through a 
    signaling network, an incumbent LEC shall provide access to its call-
    related databases, including, but not limited to, the Line Information 
    Database, Toll Free Calling database, downstream number portability 
    databases, and Advanced Intelligent Network databases, by means of 
    physical access at the signaling transfer point linked to the unbundled 
    database.
         (iii) An incumbent LEC shall allow a requesting telecommunications 
    carrier that has purchased an incumbent LEC's local switching 
    capability to use the incumbent LEC's service control point element in 
    the same manner, and via the same signaling links, as the incumbent LEC 
    itself.
         (iv) An incumbent LEC shall allow a requesting telecommunications 
    carrier that has deployed its own switch, and has linked that switch to 
    an incumbent LEC's signaling system, to gain access to the incumbent 
    LEC's service control point in a manner that allows the requesting 
    carrier to provide any call-related, database-supported services to 
    customers served by the requesting telecommunications carrier's switch.
         (v) A state commission shall consider whether mechanisms mediating 
    access to an incumbent LEC's Advanced Intelligent Network service 
    control points are necessary, and if so, whether they will adequately 
    safeguard against intentional or unintentional misuse of
    
    [[Page 45626]]
    
    the incumbent LEC's Advanced Intelligent Network facilities.
         (vi) An incumbent LEC shall provide a requesting 
    telecommunications carrier with access to call-related databases in a 
    manner that complies with section 222 of the Act;
         (3) Service Management Systems.
         (i) A service management system is defined as a computer database 
    or system not part of the public switched network that, among other 
    things:
         (A) Interconnects to the service control point and sends to that 
    service control point the information and call processing instructions 
    needed for a network switch to process and complete a telephone call; 
    and
         (B) Provides telecommunications carriers with the capability of 
    entering and storing data regarding the processing and completing of a 
    telephone call.
         (ii) An incumbent LEC shall provide a requesting 
    telecommunications carrier with the information necessary to enter 
    correctly, or format for entry, the information relevant for input into 
    the particular incumbent LEC service management system.
         (iii) An incumbent LEC shall provide a requesting 
    telecommunications carrier the same access to design, create, test, and 
    deploy Advanced Intelligent Network-based services at the service 
    management system, through a service creation environment, that the 
    incumbent LEC provides to itself.
         (iv) A state commission shall consider whether mechanisms 
    mediating access to Advanced Intelligent Network service management 
    systems and service creation environments are necessary, and if so, 
    whether they will adequately safeguard against intentional or 
    unintentional misuse of the incumbent LEC's Advanced Intelligent 
    Network facilities.
         (v) An incumbent LEC shall provide a requesting telecommunications 
    carrier access to service management systems in a manner that complies 
    with section 222 of the Act.
        (f) Operations Support Systems Functions.
         (1) Operations support systems functions consist of pre-ordering, 
    ordering, provisioning, maintenance and repair, and billing functions 
    supported by an incumbent LEC's databases and information.
        (2) An incumbent LEC that does not currently comply with this 
    requirement shall do so as expeditiously as possible, but, in any 
    event, no later than January 1, 1997.
        (g) Operator Services and Directory Assistance. An incumbent LEC 
    shall provide access to operator service and directory assistance 
    facilities where technically feasible.
    
    
    Sec. 51.321  Methods of obtaining interconnection and access to 
    unbundled elements under section 251 of the Act.
    
        (a) Except as provided in paragraph (e) of this section, an 
    incumbent LEC shall provide, on terms and conditions that are just, 
    reasonable, and nondiscriminatory in accordance with the requirements 
    of this part, any technically feasible method of obtaining 
    interconnection or access to unbundled network elements at a particular 
    point upon a request by a telecommunications carrier.
        (b) Technically feasible methods of obtaining interconnection or 
    access to unbundled network elements include, but are not limited to:
        (1) Physical collocation and virtual collocation at the premises of 
    an incumbent LEC; and
        (2) Meet point interconnection arrangements.
        (c) A previously successful method of obtaining interconnection or 
    access to unbundled network elements at a particular premises or point 
    on an incumbent LEC's network is substantial evidence that such method 
    is technically feasible in the case of substantially similar network 
    premises or points.
        (d) An incumbent LEC that denies a request for a particular method 
    of obtaining interconnection or access to unbundled network elements on 
    the incumbent LEC's network must prove to the state commission that the 
    requested method of obtaining interconnection or access to unbundled 
    network elements at that point is not technically feasible.
        (e) An incumbent LEC shall not be required to provide for physical 
    collocation of equipment necessary for interconnection or access to 
    unbundled network elements at the incumbent LEC's premises if it 
    demonstrates to the state commission that physical collocation is not 
    practical for technical reasons or because of space limitations. In 
    such cases, the incumbent LEC shall be required to provide virtual 
    collocation, except at points where the incumbent LEC proves to the 
    state commission that virtual collocation is not technically feasible. 
    If virtual collocation is not technically feasible, the incumbent LEC 
    shall provide other methods of interconnection and access to unbundled 
    network elements to the extent technically feasible.
        (f) An incumbent LEC shall submit to the state commission detailed 
    floor plans or diagrams of any premises where the incumbent LEC claims 
    that physical collocation is not practical because of space 
    limitations.
        (g) An incumbent LEC that is classified as a Class A company under 
    Sec. 32.11 of this chapter and that is not a National Exchange Carrier 
    Association interstate tariff participant as provided in part 69, 
    subpart G, shall continue to provide expanded interconnection service 
    pursuant to interstate tariff in accordance with Secs. 64.1401, 
    64.1402, 69.121 of this chapter, and the Commission's other 
    requirements.
    
    
    Sec. 51.323  Standards for physical collocation and virtual 
    collocation.
    
        (a) An incumbent LEC shall provide physical collocation and virtual 
    collocation to requesting telecommunications carriers.
        (b) An incumbent LEC shall permit the collocation of any type of 
    equipment used for interconnection or access to unbundled network 
    elements. Whenever an incumbent LEC objects to collocation of equipment 
    by a requesting telecommunications carrier for purposes within the 
    scope of section 251(c)(6) of the Act, the incumbent LEC shall prove to 
    the state commission that the equipment will not be actually used by 
    the telecommunications carrier for the purpose of obtaining 
    interconnection or access to unbundled network elements. Equipment used 
    for interconnection and access to unbundled network elements includes, 
    but is not limited to:
        (1) Transmission equipment including, but not limited to, optical 
    terminating equipment and multiplexers; and
        (2) Equipment being collocated to terminate basic transmission 
    facilities pursuant to Secs. 64.1401 and 64.1402 of this chapter as of 
    August 1, 1996.
        (c) Nothing in this section requires an incumbent LEC to permit 
    collocation of switching equipment or equipment used to provide 
    enhanced services.
        (d) When an incumbent LEC provides physical collocation, virtual 
    collocation, or both, the incumbent LEC shall:
        (1) Provide an interconnection point or points, physically 
    accessible by both the incumbent LEC and the collocating 
    telecommunications carrier, at which the fiber optic cable carrying an 
    interconnector's circuits can enter the incumbent LEC's premises, 
    provided that the incumbent LEC shall designate interconnection points 
    as close as reasonably possible to its premises;
        (2) Provide at least two such interconnection points at each 
    incumbent LEC premises at which there are at least two entry points for 
    the incumbent LEC's cable facilities, and at which space is available 
    for new
    
    [[Page 45627]]
    
    facilities in at least two of those entry points;
        (3) Permit interconnection of copper or coaxial cable if such 
    interconnection is first approved by the state commission; and
        (4) Permit physical collocation of microwave transmission 
    facilities except where such collocation is not practical for technical 
    reasons or because of space limitations, in which case virtual 
    collocation of such facilities is required where technically feasible.
        (e) When providing virtual collocation, an incumbent LEC shall, at 
    a minimum, install, maintain, and repair collocated equipment 
    identified in paragraph (b) of this section within the same time 
    periods and with failure rates that are no greater than those that 
    apply to the performance of similar functions for comparable equipment 
    of the incumbent LEC itself.
        (f) An incumbent LEC shall allocate space for the collocation of 
    the equipment identified in paragraph (b) of this section in accordance 
    with the following requirements:
        (1) An incumbent LEC shall make space available within or on its 
    premises to requesting telecommunications carriers on a first-come, 
    first-served basis, provided, however, that the incumbent LEC shall not 
    be required to lease or construct additional space to provide for 
    physical collocation when existing space has been exhausted;
        (2) To the extent possible, an incumbent LEC shall make contiguous 
    space available to requesting telecommunications carriers that seek to 
    expand their existing collocation space;
        (3) When planning renovations of existing facilities or 
    constructing or leasing new facilities, an incumbent LEC shall take 
    into account projected demand for collocation of equipment;
        (4) An incumbent LEC may retain a limited amount of floor space for 
    its own specific future uses, provided, however, that the incumbent LEC 
    may not reserve space for future use on terms more favorable than those 
    that apply to other telecommunications carriers seeking to reserve 
    collocation space for their own future use;
        (5) An incumbent LEC shall relinquish any space held for future use 
    before denying a request for virtual collocation on the grounds of 
    space limitations, unless the incumbent LEC proves to the state 
    commission that virtual collocation at that point is not technically 
    feasible; and
        (6) An incumbent LEC may impose reasonable restrictions on the 
    warehousing of unused space by collocating telecommunications carriers, 
    provided, however, that the incumbent LEC shall not set maximum space 
    limitations applicable to such carriers unless the incumbent LEC proves 
    to the state commission that space constraints make such restrictions 
    necessary.
        (g) An incumbent LEC shall permit collocating telecommunications 
    carriers to collocate equipment and connect such equipment to unbundled 
    network transmission elements obtained from the incumbent LEC, and 
    shall not require such telecommunications carriers to bring their own 
    transmission facilities to the incumbent LEC's premises in which they 
    seek to collocate equipment.
        (h) An incumbent LEC shall permit a collocating telecommunications 
    carrier to interconnect its network with that of another collocating 
    telecommunications carrier at the incumbent LEC's premises and to 
    connect its collocated equipment to the collocated equipment of another 
    telecommunications carrier within the same premises provided that the 
    collocated equipment is also used for interconnection with the 
    incumbent LEC or for access to the incumbent LEC's unbundled network 
    elements.
        (1) An incumbent LEC shall provide the connection between the 
    equipment in the collocated spaces of two or more telecommunications 
    carriers, unless the incumbent LEC permits one or more of the 
    collocating parties to provide this connection for themselves; and
        (2) An incumbent LEC is not required to permit collocating 
    telecommunications carriers to place their own connecting transmission 
    facilities within the incumbent LEC's premises outside of the actual 
    physical collocation space.
        (i) An incumbent LEC may require reasonable security arrangements 
    to separate a collocating telecommunications carrier's space from the 
    incumbent LEC's facilities.
        (j) An incumbent LEC shall permit a collocating telecommunications 
    carrier to subcontract the construction of physical collocation 
    arrangements with contractors approved by the incumbent LEC, provided, 
    however, that the incumbent LEC shall not unreasonably withhold 
    approval of contractors. Approval by an incumbent LEC shall be based on 
    the same criteria it uses in approving contractors for its own 
    purposes.
    
    Subpart E--Exemptions, Suspensions, and Modifications of 
    Requirements of Section 251 of the Act
    
    
    Sec. 51.401  State authority.
    
        A state commission shall determine whether a telephone company is 
    entitled, pursuant to section 251(f) of the Act, to exemption from, or 
    suspension or modification of, the requirements of section 251 of the 
    Act. Such determinations shall be made on a case-by-case basis.
    
    
    Sec. 51.403  Carriers eligible for suspension or modification under 
    section 251(f)(2) of the Act.
    
        A LEC is not eligible for a suspension or modification of the 
    requirements of section 251(b) or section 251(c) of the Act pursuant to 
    section 251(f)(2) of the Act if such LEC, at the holding company level, 
    has two percent or more of the subscriber lines installed in the 
    aggregate nationwide.
    
    
    Sec. 51.405  Burden of proof.
    
        (a) Upon receipt of a bona fide request for interconnection, 
    services, or access to unbundled network elements, a rural telephone 
    company must prove to the state commission that the rural telephone 
    company should be entitled, pursuant to section 251(f)(1) of the Act, 
    to continued exemption from the requirements of section 251(c) of the 
    Act.
        (b) A LEC with fewer than two percent of the nation's subscriber 
    lines installed in the aggregate nationwide must prove to the state 
    commission, pursuant to section 251(f)(2) of the Act, that it is 
    entitled to a suspension or modification of the application of a 
    requirement or requirements of section 251(b) or 251(c) of the Act.
        (c) In order to justify continued exemption under section 251(f)(1) 
    of the Act once a bona fide request has been made, an incumbent LEC 
    must offer evidence that the application of the requirements of section 
    251(c) of the Act would be likely to cause undue economic burden beyond 
    the economic burden that is typically associated with efficient 
    competitive entry.
        (d) In order to justify a suspension or modification under section 
    251(f)(2) of the Act, a LEC must offer evidence that the application of 
    section 251(b) or section 251(c) of the Act would be likely to cause 
    undue economic burden beyond the economic burden that is typically 
    associated with efficient competitive entry.
    
    Subpart F--Pricing of Elements
    
    
    Sec. 51.501  Scope.
    
        (a) The rules in this subpart apply to the pricing of network 
    elements, interconnection, and methods of obtaining access to unbundled 
    elements, including physical collocation and virtual collocation.
        (b) As used in this subpart, the term ``element'' includes network 
    elements,
    
    [[Page 45628]]
    
    interconnection, and methods of obtaining interconnection and access to 
    unbundled elements.
    
    
    Sec. 51.503  General pricing standard.
    
        (a) An incumbent LEC shall offer elements to requesting 
    telecommunications carriers at rates, terms, and conditions that are 
    just, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory.
        (b) An incumbent LEC's rates for each element it offers shall 
    comply with the rate structure rules set forth in Secs. 51.507 and 
    51.509, and shall be established, at the election of the state 
    commission--
        (1) Pursuant to the forward-looking economic cost-based pricing 
    methodology set forth in Secs. 51.505 and 51.511; or
        (2) Consistent with the proxy ceilings and ranges set forth in 
    Sec. 51.513.
        (c) The rates that an incumbent LEC assesses for elements shall not 
    vary on the basis of the class of customers served by the requesting 
    carrier, or on the type of services that the requesting carrier 
    purchasing such elements uses them to provide.
    
    
    Sec. 51.505  Forward-looking economic cost.
    
        (a) In general. The forward-looking economic cost of an element 
    equals the sum of:
        (1) The total element long-run incremental cost of the element, as 
    described in paragraph (b); and
        (2) A reasonable allocation of forward-looking common costs, as 
    described in paragraph (c).
        (b) Total element long-run incremental cost. The total element 
    long-run incremental cost of an element is the forward-looking cost 
    over the long run of the total quantity of the facilities and functions 
    that are directly attributable to, or reasonably identifiable as 
    incremental to, such element, calculated taking as a given the 
    incumbent LEC's provision of other elements.
        (1) Efficient network configuration. The total element long-run 
    incremental cost of an element should be measured based on the use of 
    the most efficient telecommunications technology currently available 
    and the lowest cost network configuration, given the existing location 
    of the incumbent LEC's wire centers.
        (2) Forward-looking cost of capital. The forward-looking cost of 
    capital shall be used in calculating the total element long-run 
    incremental cost of an element.
        (3) Depreciation rates. The depreciation rates used in calculating 
    forward-looking economic costs of elements shall be economic 
    depreciation rates.
        (c) Reasonable allocation of forward-looking common costs.
        (1) Forward-looking common costs. Forward-looking common costs are 
    economic costs efficiently incurred in providing a group of elements or 
    services (which may include all elements or services provided by the 
    incumbent LEC) that cannot be attributed directly to individual 
    elements or services.
        (2) Reasonable allocation.
        (i) The sum of a reasonable allocation of forward-looking common 
    costs and the total element long-run incremental cost of an element 
    shall not exceed the stand-alone costs associated with the element. In 
    this context, stand-alone costs are the total forward-looking costs, 
    including corporate costs, that would be incurred to produce a given 
    element if that element were provided by an efficient firm that 
    produced nothing but the given element.
        (ii) The sum of the allocation of forward-looking common costs for 
    all elements and services shall equal the total forward-looking common 
    costs, exclusive of retail costs, attributable to operating the 
    incumbent LEC's total network, so as to provide all the elements and 
    services offered.
        (d) Factors that may not be considered. The following factors shall 
    not be considered in a calculation of the forward-looking economic cost 
    of an element:
        (1) Embedded costs. Embedded costs are the costs that the incumbent 
    LEC incurred in the past and that are recorded in the incumbent LEC's 
    books of accounts;
        (2) Retail costs. Retail costs include the costs of marketing, 
    billing, collection, and other costs associated with offering retail 
    telecommunications services to subscribers who are not 
    telecommunications carriers, described in Sec. 51.609;
        (3) Opportunity costs. Opportunity costs include the revenues that 
    the incumbent LEC would have received for the sale of 
    telecommunications services, in the absence of competition from 
    telecommunications carriers that purchase elements; and
        (4) Revenues to subsidize other services. Revenues to subsidize 
    other services include revenues associated with elements or 
    telecommunications service offerings other than the element for which a 
    rate is being established.
        (e) Cost study requirements. An incumbent LEC must prove to the 
    state commission that the rates for each element it offers do not 
    exceed the forward-looking economic cost per unit of providing the 
    element, using a cost study that complies with the methodology set 
    forth in this section and Sec. 51.511.
        (1) A state commission may set a rate outside the proxy ranges or 
    above the proxy ceilings described in Sec. 51.513 only if that 
    commission has given full and fair effect to the economic cost based 
    pricing methodology described in this section and Sec. 51.511 in a 
    state proceeding that meets the requirements of paragraph (e)(2) of 
    this section.
        (2) Any state proceeding conducted pursuant to this section shall 
    provide notice and an opportunity for comment to affected parties and 
    shall result in the creation of a written factual record that is 
    sufficient for purposes of review. The record of any state proceeding 
    in which a state commission considers a cost study for purposes of 
    establishing rates under this section shall include any such cost 
    study.
    
    
    Sec. 51.507  General rate structure standard.
    
        (a) Element rates shall be structured consistently with the manner 
    in which the costs of providing the elements are incurred.
        (b) The costs of dedicated facilities shall be recovered through 
    flat-rated charges.
        (c) The costs of shared facilities shall be recovered in a manner 
    that efficiently apportions costs among users. Costs of shared 
    facilities may be apportioned either through usage-sensitive charges or 
    capacity-based flat-rated charges, if the state commission finds that 
    such rates reasonably reflect the costs imposed by the various users.
        (d) Recurring costs shall be recovered through recurring charges, 
    unless an incumbent LEC proves to a state commission that such 
    recurring costs are de minimis. Recurring costs shall be considered de 
    minimis when the costs of administering the recurring charge would be 
    excessive in relation to the amount of the recurring costs.
        (e) State commissions may, where reasonable, require incumbent LECs 
    to recover nonrecurring costs through recurring charges over a 
    reasonable period of time. Nonrecurring charges shall be allocated 
    efficiently among requesting telecommunications carriers, and shall not 
    permit an incumbent LEC to recover more than the total forward-looking 
    economic cost of providing the applicable element.
        (f) State commissions shall establish different rates for elements 
    in at least three defined geographic areas within the state to reflect 
    geographic cost differences.
        (1) To establish geographically-deaveraged rates, state commissions 
    may use existing density-related zone pricing plans described in 
    Sec. 69.123 of this chapter, or other such cost-related
    
    [[Page 45629]]
    
    zone plans established pursuant to state law.
        (2) In states not using such existing plans, state commissions must 
    create a minimum of three cost-related rate zones.
    
    
    Sec. 51.509  Rate structure standards for specific elements.
    
        In addition to the general rules set forth in Sec. 51.507, rates 
    for specific elements shall comply with the following rate structure 
    rules.
        (a) Local loops. Loop costs shall be recovered through flat-rated 
    charges.
        (b) Local switching. Local switching costs shall be recovered 
    through a combination of a flat-rated charge for line ports and one or 
    more flat-rated or per-minute usage charges for the switching matrix 
    and for trunk ports.
        (c) Dedicated transmission links. Dedicated transmission link costs 
    shall be recovered through flat-rated charges.
        (d) Shared transmission facilities between tandem switches and end 
    offices. The costs of shared transmission facilities between tandem 
    switches and end offices may be recovered through usage-sensitive 
    charges, or in another manner consistent with the manner that the 
    incumbent LEC incurs those costs.
        (e) Tandem switching. Tandem switching costs may be recovered 
    through usage-sensitive charges, or in another manner consistent with 
    the manner that the incumbent LEC incurs those costs.
        (f) Signaling and call-related database services. Signaling and 
    call-related database service costs shall be usage-sensitive, based on 
    either the number of queries or the number of messages, with the 
    exception of the dedicated circuits known as signaling links, the cost 
    of which shall be recovered through flat-rated charges.
        (g) Collocation. Collocation costs shall be recovered consistent 
    with the rate structure policies established in the Expanded 
    Interconnection proceeding, CC Docket No. 91-141.
    
    
    Sec. 51.511  Forward-looking economic cost per unit.
    
        (a) The forward-looking economic cost per unit of an element equals 
    the forward-looking economic cost of the element, as defined in 
    Sec. 51.505, divided by a reasonable projection of the sum of the total 
    number of units of the element that the incumbent LEC is likely to 
    provide to requesting telecommunications carriers and the total number 
    of units of the element that the incumbent LEC is likely to use in 
    offering its own services, during a reasonable measuring period.
        (b)(1) With respect to elements that an incumbent LEC offers on a 
    flat-rate basis, the number of units is defined as the discrete number 
    of elements (e.g., local loops or local switch ports) that the 
    incumbent LEC uses or provides.
        (2) With respect to elements that an incumbent LEC offers on a 
    usage-sensitive basis, the number of units is defined as the unit of 
    measurement of the usage (e.g., minutes of use or call-related database 
    queries) of the element.
    
    
    Sec. 51.513  Proxies for forward-looking economic cost.
    
        (a) A state commission may determine that the cost information 
    available to it with respect to one or more elements does not support 
    the adoption of a rate or rates that are consistent with the 
    requirements set forth in Secs. 51.505 and 51.511. In that event, the 
    state commission may establish a rate for an element that is consistent 
    with the proxies specified in this section, provided that:
        (1) Any rate established through use of such proxies shall be 
    superseded once the state commission has completed review of a cost 
    study that complies with the forward-looking economic cost based 
    pricing methodology described in Secs. 51.505 and 51.511, and has 
    concluded that such study is a reasonable basis for establishing 
    element rates; and
        (2) The state commission sets forth in writing a reasonable basis 
    for its selection of a particular rate for the element.
        (b) The constraints on proxy-based rates described in this section 
    apply on a geographically averaged basis. For purposes of determining 
    whether geographically deaveraged rates for elements comply with the 
    provisions of this section, a geographically averaged proxy-based rate 
    shall be computed based on the weighted average of the actual, 
    geographically deaveraged rates that apply in separate geographic areas 
    in a state.
        (c) Proxies for specific elements.
        (1) Local loops. For each state listed below, the proxy-based 
    monthly rate for unbundled local loops, on a statewide weighted average 
    basis, shall be no greater than the figures listed in the table below. 
    (The Commission has not established a default proxy ceiling for loop 
    rates in Alaska.)
    
                                      Table                                 
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                                                      Proxy 
                                 State                               ceiling
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    Alabama.......................................................    $17.25
    Arizona.......................................................     12.85
    Arkansas......................................................     21.18
    California....................................................     11.10
    Colorado......................................................     14.97
    Connecticut...................................................     13.23
    Delaware......................................................     13.24
    District of Columbia..........................................     10.81
    Florida.......................................................     13.68
    Georgia.......................................................     16.09
    Hawaii........................................................     15.27
    Idaho.........................................................     20.16
    Illinois......................................................     13.12
    Indiana.......................................................     13.29
    Iowa..........................................................     15.94
    Kansas........................................................     19.85
    Kentucky......................................................     16.70
    Louisiana.....................................................     16.98
    Maine.........................................................     18.69
    Maryland......................................................     13.36
    Massachusetts.................................................      9.83
    Michigan......................................................     15.27
    Minnesota.....................................................     14.81
    Mississippi...................................................     21.97
    Missouri......................................................     18.32
    Montana.......................................................     25.18
    Nebraska......................................................     18.05
    Nevada........................................................     18.95
    New Hampshire.................................................     16.00
    New Jersey....................................................     12.47
    New Mexico....................................................     18.66
    New York......................................................     11.75
    North Carolina................................................     16.71
    North Dakota..................................................     25.36
    Ohio..........................................................     15.73
    Oklahoma......................................................     17.63
    Oregon........................................................     15.44
    Pennsylvania..................................................     12.30
    Puerto Rico...................................................     12.47
    Rhode Island..................................................     11.48
    South Carolina................................................     17.07
    South Dakota..................................................     25.33
    Tennessee.....................................................     17.41
    Texas.........................................................     15.49
    Utah..........................................................     15.12
    Vermont.......................................................     20.13
    Virginia......................................................     14.13
    Washington....................................................     13.37
    West Virginia.................................................     19.25
    Wisconsin.....................................................     15.94
    Wyoming.......................................................     25.11
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
        (2) Local switching. The blended proxy-based rate for unbundled 
    local switching shall be no greater than 0.4 cents ($0.004) per minute, 
    and no less than 0.2 cents ($0.002) per minute, except that, where a 
    state commission has, before August 8, 1996, established a rate less 
    than or equal to 0.5 cents ($0.005) per minute, that rate may be 
    retained pending completion of a forward-looking economic cost study. 
    The blended rate for unbundled local switching shall be calculated as 
    the sum of the following:
        (i) The applicable flat-rated charges for subelements associated 
    with unbundled local switching, such as line ports, divided by the 
    projected average minutes of use per flat-rated subelement; and
        (ii) The applicable usage-sensitive charges for subelements 
    associated with
    
    [[Page 45630]]
    
    unbundled local switching, such as switching and trunk ports. A 
    weighted average of such charges shall be used in appropriate 
    circumstances, such as when peak and off-peak charges are used.
        (3) Dedicated transmission links. The proxy-based rates for 
    dedicated transmission links shall be no greater than the incumbent 
    LEC's tariffed interstate charges for comparable entrance facilities or 
    direct-trunked transport offerings, as described in Secs. 69.110 and 
    69.112 of this chapter.
        (4) Shared transmission facilities between tandem switches and end 
    offices. The proxy-based rates for shared transmission facilities 
    between tandem switches and end offices shall be no greater than the 
    weighted per-minute equivalent of DS1 and DS3 interoffice dedicated 
    transmission link rates that reflects the relative number of DS1 and 
    DS3 circuits used in the tandem to end office links (or a surrogate 
    based on the proportion of copper and fiber facilities in the 
    interoffice network), calculated using a loading factor of 9,000 
    minutes per month per voice-grade circuit, as described in Sec. 69.112 
    of this chapter.
        (5) Tandem switching. The proxy-based rate for tandem switching 
    shall be no greater than 0.15 cents ($0.0015) per minute of use.
        (6) Collocation. To the extent that the incumbent LEC offers a 
    comparable form of collocation in its interstate expanded 
    interconnection tariffs, as described in Secs. 64.1401 and 69.121 of 
    this chapter, the proxy-based rates for collocation shall be no greater 
    than the effective rates for equivalent services in the interstate 
    expanded interconnection tariff. To the extent that the incumbent LEC 
    does not offer a comparable form of collocation in its interstate 
    expanded interconnection tariffs, a state commission may, in its 
    discretion, establish a proxy-based rate, provided that the state 
    commission sets forth in writing a reasonable basis for concluding that 
    its rate would approximate the result of a forward-looking economic 
    cost study, as described in Sec. 51.505.
        (7) Signaling, call-related database, and other elements. To the 
    extent that the incumbent LEC has established rates for offerings 
    comparable to other elements in its interstate access tariffs, and has 
    provided cost support for those rates pursuant to Sec. 61.49(h) of this 
    chapter, the proxy-based rates for those elements shall be no greater 
    than the effective rates for equivalent services in the interstate 
    access tariffs. In other cases, the proxy-based rate shall be no 
    greater than a rate based on direct costs plus a reasonable allocation 
    of overhead loadings, pursuant to Sec. 61.49(h) of this chapter.
    
    
    Sec. 51.515  Application of access charges.
    
        (a) Neither the interstate access charges described in part 69 of 
    this chapter nor comparable intrastate access charges shall be assessed 
    by an incumbent LEC on purchasers of elements that offer telephone 
    exchange or exchange access services.
        (b) Notwithstanding Secs. 51.505, 51.511, and 51.513(d)(2) and 
    paragraph (a) of this section, an incumbent LEC may assess upon 
    telecommunications carriers that purchase unbundled local switching 
    elements, as described in Sec. 51.319(c)(1), for interstate minutes of 
    use traversing such unbundled local switching elements, the carrier 
    common line charge described in Sec. 69.105 of this chapter, and a 
    charge equal to 75% of the interconnection charge described in 
    Sec. 69.124 of this chapter, only until the earliest of the following, 
    and not thereafter:
        (1) June 30, 1997;
        (2) The later of the effective date of a final Commission decision 
    in CC Docket No. 96-45, Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, 
    or the effective date of a final Commission decision in a proceeding to 
    consider reform of the interstate access charges described in part 69; 
    or
        (3) With respect to a Bell operating company only, the date on 
    which that company is authorized to offer in-region interLATA service 
    in a state pursuant to section 271 of the Act. The end date for Bell 
    operating companies that are authorized to offer interLATA service 
    shall apply only to the recovery of access charges in those states in 
    which the Bell operating company is authorized to offer such service.
        (c) Notwithstanding Secs. 51.505, 51.511, and 51.513(d)(2) and 
    paragraph (a) of this section, an incumbent LEC may assess upon 
    telecommunications carriers that purchase unbundled local switching 
    elements, as described in Sec. 51.319(c)(1), for intrastate toll 
    minutes of use traversing such unbundled local switching elements, 
    intrastate access charges comparable to those listed in paragraph (b) 
    and any explicit intrastate universal service mechanism based on access 
    charges, only until the earliest of the following, and not thereafter:
        (1) June 30, 1997;
        (2) The effective date of a state commission decision that an 
    incumbent LEC may not assess such charges; or
        (3) With respect to a Bell operating company only, the date on 
    which that company is authorized to offer in-region interLATA service 
    in the state pursuant to section 271 of the Act. The end date for Bell 
    operating companies that are authorized to offer interLATA service 
    shall apply only to the recovery of access charges in those states in 
    which the Bell operating company is authorized to offer such service.
    
    Subpart G--Resale
    
    
    Sec. 51.601  Scope of resale rules.
    
        The provisions of this subpart govern the terms and conditions 
    under which LECs offer telecommunications services to requesting 
    telecommunications carriers for resale.
    
    
    Sec. 51.603  Resale obligation of all local exchange carriers.
    
        (a) A LEC shall make its telecommunications services available for 
    resale to requesting telecommunications carriers on terms and 
    conditions that are reasonable and non-discriminatory.
        (b) A LEC must provide services to requesting telecommunications 
    carriers for resale that are equal in quality, subject to the same 
    conditions, and provided within the same provisioning time intervals 
    that the LEC provides these services to others, including end users.
    
    
    Sec. 51.605  Additional obligations of incumbent local exchange 
    carriers.
    
        (a) An incumbent LEC shall offer to any requesting 
    telecommunications carrier any telecommunications service that the 
    incumbent LEC offers on a retail basis to subscribers that are not 
    telecommunications carriers for resale at wholesale rates that are, at 
    the election of the state commission--
        (1) Consistent with the avoided cost methodology described in 
    Secs. 51.607 and 51.609; or
        (2) Interim wholesale rates, pursuant to Sec. 51.611.
        (b) Except as provided in Sec. 51.613, an incumbent LEC shall not 
    impose restrictions on the resale by a requesting carrier of 
    telecommunications services offered by the incumbent LEC.
    
    
    Sec. 51.607  Wholesale pricing standard.
    
        (a) The wholesale rate that an incumbent LEC may charge for a 
    telecommunications service provided for resale to other 
    telecommunications carriers shall equal the incumbent LEC's existing 
    retail rate for the telecommunications service, less avoided retail 
    costs, as described in Sec. 51.609.
        (b) For purposes of this subpart, exchange access services, as 
    defined in section 3 of the Act, shall not be considered to be 
    telecommunications services that incumbent LECs must make available for 
    resale at wholesale
    
    [[Page 45631]]
    
    rates to requesting telecommunications carriers.
    
    
    Sec. 51.609  Determination of avoided retail costs.
    
        (a) Except as provided in Sec. 51.611, the amount of avoided retail 
    costs shall be determined on the basis of a cost study that complies 
    with the requirements of this section.
        (b) Avoided retail costs shall be those costs that reasonably can 
    be avoided when an incumbent LEC provides a telecommunications service 
    for resale at wholesale rates to a requesting carrier.
        (c) For incumbent LECs that are designated as Class A companies 
    under Sec. 32.11 of this chapter, except as provided in paragraph (d) 
    of this section, avoided retail costs shall:
        (1) Include, as direct costs, the costs recorded in USOA accounts 
    6611 (product management), 6612 (sales), 6613 (product advertising), 
    6621 (call completion services), 6622 (number services), and 6623 
    (customer services) (Secs. 32.6611, 32.6612, 32.6613, 32.6621, 32.6622, 
    and 32.6623 of this chapter);
        (2) Include, as indirect costs, a portion of the costs recorded in 
    USOA accounts 6121-6124 (general support expenses), 6711, 6712, 6721-
    6728 (corporate operations expenses), and 5301 (telecommunications 
    uncollectibles) (Secs. 32.6121-32.6124, 32.6711, 32.6712, 32.6721-
    32.6728, and 32.5301 of this chapter); and
        (3) Not include plant-specific expenses and plant non-specific 
    expenses, other than general support expenses (Secs. 32.6110-32.6116, 
    32.6210-32.6565 of this chapter).
        (d) Costs included in accounts 6611-6613 and 6621-6623 described in 
    paragraph (c) of this section (Secs. 32.6611-32.6613 and 32.6621-
    32.6623 of this chapter) may be included in wholesale rates only to the 
    extent that the incumbent LEC proves to a state commission that 
    specific costs in these accounts will be incurred and are not avoidable 
    with respect to services sold at wholesale, or that specific costs in 
    these accounts are not included in the retail prices of resold 
    services. Costs included in accounts 6110-6116 and 6210-6565 described 
    in paragraph (c) of this section (Secs. 32.6110-32.6116, 32.6210-
    32.6565 of this chapter) may be treated as avoided retail costs, and 
    excluded from wholesale rates, only to the extent that a party proves 
    to a state commission that specific costs in these accounts can 
    reasonably be avoided when an incumbent LEC provides a 
    telecommunications service for resale to a requesting carrier.
        (e) For incumbent LECs that are designated as Class B companies 
    under Sec. 32.11 of this chapter and that record information in summary 
    accounts instead of specific USOA accounts, the entire relevant summary 
    accounts may be used in lieu of the specific USOA accounts listed in 
    paragraphs (c) and (d) of this section.
    
    
    Sec. 51.611  Interim wholesale rates.
    
        (a) If a state commission cannot, based on the information 
    available to it, establish a wholesale rate using the methodology 
    prescribed in Sec. 51.609, then the state commission may elect to 
    establish an interim wholesale rate as described in paragraph (b) of 
    this section.
        (b) The state commission may establish interim wholesale rates that 
    are at least 17 percent, and no more than 25 percent, below the 
    incumbent LEC's existing retail rates, and shall articulate the basis 
    for selecting a particular discount rate. The same discount percentage 
    rate shall be used to establish interim wholesale rates for each 
    telecommunications service.
        (c) A state commission that establishes interim wholesale rates 
    shall, within a reasonable period of time thereafter, establish 
    wholesale rates on the basis of an avoided retail cost study that 
    complies with Sec. 51.609.
    
    
    Sec. 51.613  Restrictions on resale.
    
        (a) Notwithstanding Sec. 51.605(b), the following types of 
    restrictions on resale may be imposed:
        (1) Cross-class selling. A state commission may permit an incumbent 
    LEC to prohibit a requesting telecommunications carrier that purchases 
    at wholesale rates for resale, telecommunications services that the 
    incumbent LEC makes available only to residential customers or to a 
    limited class of residential customers, from offering such services to 
    classes of customers that are not eligible to subscribe to such 
    services from the incumbent LEC.
        (2) Short term promotions. An incumbent LEC shall apply the 
    wholesale discount to the ordinary rate for a retail service rather 
    than a special promotional rate only if:
        (i) Such promotions involve rates that will be in effect for no 
    more than 90 days; and
        (ii) The incumbent LEC does not use such promotional offerings to 
    evade the wholesale rate obligation, for example by making available a 
    sequential series of 90-day promotional rates. r
        (b) With respect to any restrictions on resale not permitted under 
    paragraph (a), an incumbent LEC may impose a restriction only if it 
    proves to the state commission that the restriction is reasonable and 
    nondiscriminatory.
        (c)  Branding. Where operator, call completion, or directory 
    assistance service is part of the service or service package an 
    incumbent LEC offers for resale, failure by an incumbent LEC to comply 
    with reseller unbranding or rebranding requests shall constitute a 
    restriction on resale.
        (1) An incumbent LEC may impose such a restriction only if it 
    proves to the state commission that the restriction is reasonable and 
    nondiscriminatory, such as by proving to a state commission that the 
    incumbent LEC lacks the capability to comply with unbranding or 
    rebranding requests.
        (2) For purposes of this subpart, unbranding or rebranding shall 
    mean that operator, call completion, or directory assistance services 
    are offered in such a manner that an incumbent LEC's brand name or 
    other identifying information is not identified to subscribers, or that 
    such services are offered in such a manner that identifies to 
    subscribers the requesting carrier's brand name or other identifying 
    information.
    
    
    Sec. 51.615  Withdrawal of services.
    
        When an incumbent LEC makes a telecommunications service available 
    only to a limited group of customers that have purchased such a service 
    in the past, the incumbent LEC must also make such a service available 
    at wholesale rates to requesting carriers to offer on a resale basis to 
    the same limited group of customers that have purchased such a service 
    in the past.
    
    
    Sec. 51.617  Assessment of end user common line charge on resellers.
    
        (a) Notwithstanding the provision in Sec. 69.104(a) of this chapter 
    that the end user common line charge be assessed upon end users, an 
    incumbent LEC shall assess this charge, and the charge for changing the 
    designated primary interexchange carrier, upon requesting carriers that 
    purchase telephone exchange service for resale. The specific end user 
    common line charge to be assessed will depend upon the identity of the 
    end user served by the requesting carrier.
        (b) When an incumbent LEC provides telephone exchange service to a 
    requesting carrier at wholesale rates for resale, the incumbent LEC 
    shall continue to assess the interstate access charges provided in part 
    69 of this chapter, other than the end user common line charge, upon 
    interexchange carriers that use the incumbent LEC's facilities to 
    provide interstate or international
    
    [[Page 45632]]
    
    telecommunications services to the interexchange carriers' subscribers.
    
    Subpart H--Reciprocal Compensation for Transport and Termination of 
    Local Telecommunications Traffic
    
    
    Sec. 51.701  Scope of transport and termination pricing rules.
    
        (a) The provisions of this subpart apply to reciprocal compensation 
    for transport and termination of local telecommunications traffic 
    between LECs and other telecommunications carriers.
        (b) Local telecommunications traffic. For purposes of this subpart, 
    local telecommunications traffic means:
        (1) Telecommunications traffic between a LEC and a 
    telecommunications carrier other than a CMRS provider that originates 
    and terminates within a local service area established by the state 
    commission; or
        (2) Telecommunications traffic between a LEC and a CMRS provider 
    that, at the beginning of the call, originates and terminates within 
    the same Major Trading Area, as defined in Sec. 24.202(a) of this 
    chapter.
        (c) Transport. For purposes of this subpart, transport is the 
    transmission and any necessary tandem switching of local 
    telecommunications traffic subject to section 251(b)(5) of the Act from 
    the interconnection point between the two carriers to the terminating 
    carrier's end office switch that directly serves the called party, or 
    equivalent facility provided by a carrier other than an incumbent LEC.
        (d) Termination. For purposes of this subpart, termination is the 
    switching of local telecommunications traffic at the terminating 
    carrier's end office switch, or equivalent facility, and delivery of 
    such traffic to the called party's premises.
        (e) Reciprocal compensation. For purposes of this subpart, a 
    reciprocal compensation arrangement between two carriers is one in 
    which each of the two carriers receives compensation from the other 
    carrier for the transport and termination on each carrier's network 
    facilities of local telecommunications traffic that originates on the 
    network facilities of the other carrier.
    
    
    Sec. 51.703  Reciprocal compensation obligation of LECs.
    
        (a) Each LEC shall establish reciprocal compensation arrangements 
    for transport and termination of local telecommunications traffic with 
    any requesting telecommunications carrier.
        (b) A LEC may not assess charges on any other telecommunications 
    carrier for local telecommunications traffic that originates on the 
    LEC's network.
    
    
    Sec. 51.705  Incumbent LECs' rates for transport and termination.
    
        (a) An incumbent LEC's rates for transport and termination of local 
    telecommunications traffic shall be established, at the election of the 
    state commission, on the basis of:
        (1) The forward-looking economic costs of such offerings, using a 
    cost study pursuant to Secs. 51.505 and 51.511;
        (2) Default proxies, as provided in Sec. 51.707; or
        (3) A bill-and-keep arrangement, as provided in Sec. 51.713.
        (b) In cases where both carriers in a reciprocal compensation 
    arrangement are incumbent LECs, state commissions shall establish the 
    rates of the smaller carrier on the basis of the larger carrier's 
    forward-looking costs, pursuant to Sec. 51.711.
    
    
    Sec. 51.707  Default proxies for incumbent LECs' transport and 
    termination rates.
    
        (a) A state commission may determine that the cost information 
    available to it with respect to transport and termination of local 
    telecommunications traffic does not support the adoption of a rate or 
    rates for an incumbent LEC that are consistent with the requirements of 
    Secs. 51.505 and 51.511. In that event, the state commission may 
    establish rates for transport and termination of local 
    telecommunications traffic, or for specific components included 
    therein, that are consistent with the proxies specified in this 
    section, provided that:
        (1) Any rate established through use of such proxies is superseded 
    once that state commission establishes rates for transport and 
    termination pursuant to Secs. 51.705(a)(1) or 51.705(a)(3); and
        (2) The state commission sets forth in writing a reasonable basis 
    for its selection of a particular proxy for transport and termination 
    of local telecommunications traffic, or for specific components 
    included within transport and termination.
        (b) If a state commission establishes rates for transport and 
    termination of local telecommunications traffic on the basis of default 
    proxies, such rates must meet the following requirements:
        (1) Termination. The incumbent LEC's rates for the termination of 
    local telecommunications traffic shall be no greater than 0.4 cents 
    ($0.004) per minute, and no less than 0.2 cents ($0.002) per minute, 
    except that, if a state commission has, before August 8, 1996, 
    established a rate less than or equal to 0.5 cents ($0.005) per minute 
    for such calls, that rate may be retained pending completion of a 
    forward-looking economic cost study.
        (2) Transport. The incumbent LEC's rates for the transport of local 
    telecommunications traffic, under this section, shall comply with the 
    proxies described in Sec. 51.513(d) (3), (4), and (5) that apply to the 
    analogous unbundled network elements used in transporting a call to the 
    end office that serves the called party.
    
    
    Sec. 51.709  Rate structure for transport and termination.
    
        (a) In state proceedings, a state commission shall establish rates 
    for the transport and termination of local telecommunications traffic 
    that are structured consistently with the manner that carriers incur 
    those costs, and consistently with the principles in Secs. 51.507 and 
    51.509.
        (b) The rate of a carrier providing transmission facilities 
    dedicated to the transmission of traffic between two carriers' networks 
    shall recover only the costs of the proportion of that trunk capacity 
    used by an interconnecting carrier to send traffic that will terminate 
    on the providing carrier's network. Such proportions may be measured 
    during peak periods.
    
    
    Sec. 51.711  Symmetrical reciprocal compensation.
    
        (a) Rates for transport and termination of local telecommunications 
    traffic shall be symmetrical, except as provided in paragraphs (b) and 
    (c) of this section.
        (1) For purposes of this subpart, symmetrical rates are rates that 
    a carrier other than an incumbent LEC assesses upon an incumbent LEC 
    for transport and termination of local telecommunications traffic equal 
    to those that the incumbent LEC assesses upon the other carrier for the 
    same services.
        (2) In cases where both parties are incumbent LECs, or neither 
    party is an incumbent LEC, a state commission shall establish the 
    symmetrical rates for transport and termination based on the larger 
    carrier's forward-looking costs.
        (3) Where the switch of a carrier other than an incumbent LEC 
    serves a geographic area comparable to the area served by the incumbent 
    LEC's tandem switch, the appropriate rate for the carrier other than an 
    incumbent LEC is the incumbent LEC's tandem interconnection rate.
        (b) A state commission may establish asymmetrical rates for 
    transport and termination of local telecommunications traffic only if 
    the carrier other than the incumbent LEC (or the smaller of two 
    incumbent LECs) proves to the state commission on the basis of a cost 
    study using the forward-looking economic cost based pricing methodology 
    described in Secs. 51.505 and 51.511, that the forward-looking costs 
    for a network
    
    [[Page 45633]]
    
    efficiently configured and operated by the carrier other than the 
    incumbent LEC (or the smaller of two incumbent LECs), exceed the costs 
    incurred by the incumbent LEC (or the larger incumbent LEC), and, 
    consequently, that such that a higher rate is justified.
        (c) Pending further proceedings before the Commission, a state 
    commission shall establish the rates that licensees in the Paging and 
    Radiotelephone Service (defined in part 22, subpart E of this chapter), 
    Narrowband Personal Communications Services (defined in part 24, 
    subpart D of this chapter), and Paging Operations in the Private Land 
    Mobile Radio Services (defined in part 90, subpart P of this chapter) 
    may assess upon other carriers for the transport and termination of 
    local telecommunications traffic based on the forward-looking costs 
    that such licensees incur in providing such services, pursuant to 
    Secs. 51.505 and 51.511. Such licensees' rates shall not be set based 
    on the default proxies described in Sec. 51.707.
    
    
    Sec. 51.713  Bill-and-keep arrangements for reciprocal compensation.
    
        (a) For purposes of this subpart, bill-and-keep arrangements are 
    those in which neither of the two interconnecting carriers charges the 
    other for the termination of local telecommunications traffic that 
    originates on the other carrier's network.
        (b) A state commission may impose bill-and-keep arrangements if the 
    state commission determines that the amount of local telecommunications 
    traffic from one network to the other is roughly balanced with the 
    amount of local telecommunications traffic flowing in the opposite 
    direction, and is expected to remain so, and no showing has been made 
    pursuant to Sec. 51.711(b).
        (c) Nothing in this section precludes a state commission from 
    presuming that the amount of local telecommunications traffic from one 
    network to the other is roughly balanced with the amount of local 
    telecommunications traffic flowing in the opposite direction and is 
    expected to remain so, unless a party rebuts such a presumption.
    
    
    Sec. 51.715  Interim transport and termination pricing.
    
        (a) Upon request from a telecommunications carrier without an 
    existing interconnection arrangement with an incumbent LEC, the 
    incumbent LEC shall provide transport and termination of local 
    telecommunications traffic immediately under an interim arrangement, 
    pending resolution of negotiation or arbitration regarding transport 
    and termination rates and approval of such rates by a state commission 
    under sections 251 and 252 of the Act.
        (1) This requirement shall not apply when the requesting carrier 
    has an existing interconnection arrangement that provides for the 
    transport and termination of local telecommunications traffic by the 
    incumbent LEC.
        (2) A telecommunications carrier may take advantage of such an 
    interim arrangement only after it has requested negotiation with the 
    incumbent LEC pursuant to Sec. 51.301.
        (b) Upon receipt of a request as described in paragraph (a) of this 
    section, an incumbent LEC must, without unreasonable delay, establish 
    an interim arrangement for transport and termination of local 
    telecommunications traffic at symmetrical rates.
        (1) In a state in which the state commission has established 
    transport and termination rates based on forward-looking economic cost 
    studies, an incumbent LEC shall use these state-determined rates as 
    interim transport and termination rates.
        (2) In a state in which the state commission has established 
    transport and termination rates consistent with the default price 
    ranges and ceilings described in Sec. 51.707, an incumbent LEC shall 
    use these state-determined rates as interim rates.
        (3) In a state in which the state commission has neither 
    established transport and termination rates based on forward-looking 
    economic cost studies nor established transport and termination rates 
    consistent with the default price ranges described in Sec. 51.707, an 
    incumbent LEC shall set interim transport and termination rates at the 
    default ceilings for end-office switching (0.4 cents per minute of 
    use), tandem switching (0.15 cents per minute of use), and transport 
    (as described in Sec. 51.707(b)(2)).
        (c) An interim arrangement shall cease to be in effect when one of 
    the following occurs with respect to rates for transport and 
    termination of local telecommunications traffic subject to the interim 
    arrangement:
        (1) A voluntary agreement has been negotiated and approved by a 
    state commission;
        (2) An agreement has been arbitrated and approved by a state 
    commission; or
        (3) The period for requesting arbitration has passed with no such 
    request.
        (d) If the rates for transport and termination of local 
    telecommunications traffic in an interim arrangement differ from the 
    rates established by a state commission pursuant to Sec. 51.705, the 
    state commission shall require carriers to make adjustments to past 
    compensation. Such adjustments to past compensation shall allow each 
    carrier to receive the level of compensation it would have received had 
    the rates in the interim arrangement equalled the rates later 
    established by the state commission pursuant to Sec. 51.705.
    
    
    Sec. 51.717  Renegotiation of existing non-reciprocal arrangements.
    
        (a) Any CMRS provider that operates under an arrangement with an 
    incumbent LEC that was established before August 8, 1996 and that 
    provides for non-reciprocal compensation for transport and termination 
    of local telecommunications traffic is entitled to renegotiate these 
    arrangements with no termination liability or other contract penalties.
        (b) From the date that a CMRS provider makes a request under 
    paragraph (a) of this section until a new agreement has been either 
    arbitrated or negotiated and has been approved by a state commission, 
    the CMRS provider shall be entitled to assess upon the incumbent LEC 
    the same rates for the transport and termination of local 
    telecommunications traffic that the incumbent LEC assesses upon the 
    CMRS provider pursuant to the pre-existing arrangement.
    
    Subpart I--Procedures for Implementation of Section 252 of the Act
    
    
    Sec. 51.801  Commission action upon a state commission's failure to act 
    to carry out its responsibility under section 252 of the Act.
    
        (a) If a state commission fails to act to carry out its 
    responsibility under section 252 of the Act in any proceeding or other 
    matter under section 252 of the Act, the Commission shall issue an 
    order preempting the state commission's jurisdiction of that proceeding 
    or matter within 90 days after being notified (or taking notice) of 
    such failure, and shall assume the responsibility of the state 
    commission under section 252 of the Act with respect to the proceeding 
    or matter and shall act for the state commission.
        (b) For purposes of this part, a state commission fails to act if 
    the state commission fails to respond, within a reasonable time, to a 
    request for mediation, as provided for in section 252(a)(2) of the Act, 
    or for a request for arbitration, as provided for in section 252(b) of 
    the Act, or fails to complete an arbitration within the time limits 
    established in section 252(b)(4)(C) of the Act.
        (c) A state shall not be deemed to have failed to act for purposes 
    of section 252(e)(5) of the Act if an agreement is
    
    [[Page 45634]]
    
    deemed approved under section 252(e)(4) of the Act.
    
    
    Sec. 51.803  Procedures for Commission notification of a state 
    commission's failure to act.
    
        (a) Any party seeking preemption of a state commission's 
    jurisdiction, based on the state commission's failure to act, shall 
    notify the Commission in accordance with following procedures:
        (1) Such party shall file with the Secretary of the Commission a 
    petition, supported by an affidavit, that states with specificity the 
    basis for the petition and any information that supports the claim that 
    the state has failed to act, including, but not limited to, the 
    applicable provisions of the Act and the factual circumstances 
    supporting a finding that the state commission has failed to act;
        (2) Such party shall ensure that the state commission and the other 
    parties to the proceeding or matter for which preemption is sought are 
    served with the petition required in paragraph (a)(1) of this section 
    on the same date that the petitioning party serves the petition on the 
    Commission; and
        (3) Within fifteen days from the date of service of the petition 
    required in paragraph (a)(1) of this section, the applicable state 
    commission and parties to the proceeding may file with the Commission a 
    response to the petition.
        (b) The party seeking preemption must prove that the state has 
    failed to act to carry out its responsibilities under section 252 of 
    the Act.
        (c) The Commission, pursuant to section 252(e)(5) of the Act, may 
    take notice upon its own motion that a state commission has failed to 
    act. In such a case, the Commission shall issue a public notice that 
    the Commission has taken notice of a state commission's failure to act. 
    The applicable state commission and the parties to a proceeding or 
    matter in which the Commission has taken notice of the state 
    commission's failure to act may file, within fifteen days of the 
    issuance of the public notice, comments on whether the Commission is 
    required to assume the responsibility of the state commission under 
    section 252 of the Act with respect to the proceeding or matter.
        (d) The Commission shall issue an order determining whether it is 
    required to preempt the state commission's jurisdiction of a proceeding 
    or matter within 90 days after being notified under paragraph (a) of 
    this section or taking notice under paragraph (c) of this section of a 
    state commission's failure to carry out its responsibilities under 
    section 252 of the Act.
    
    
    Sec. 51.805  The Commission's authority over proceedings and matters.
    
        (a) If the Commission assumes responsibility for a proceeding or 
    matter pursuant to section 252(e)(5) of the Act, the Commission shall 
    retain jurisdiction over such proceeding or matter. At a minimum, the 
    Commission shall approve or reject any interconnection agreement 
    adopted by negotiation, mediation or arbitration for which the 
    Commission, pursuant to section 252(e)(5) of the Act, has assumed the 
    state's commission's responsibilities.
        (b) Agreements reached pursuant to mediation or arbitration by the 
    Commission pursuant to section 252(e)(5) of the Act are not required to 
    be submitted to the state commission for approval or rejection.
    
    
    Sec. 51.807  Arbitration and mediation of agreements by the Commission 
    pursuant to section 252(e)(5) of the Act.
    
        (a) The rules established in this section shall apply only to 
    instances in which the Commission assumes jurisdiction under section 
    252(e)(5) of the Act.
        (b) When the Commission assumes responsibility for a proceeding or 
    matter pursuant to section 252(e)(5) of the Act, it shall not be bound 
    by state laws and standards that would have applied to the state 
    commission in such proceeding or matter.
        (c) In resolving, by arbitration under section 252(b) of the Act, 
    any open issues and in imposing conditions upon the parties to the 
    agreement, the Commission shall:
        (1) Ensure that such resolution and conditions meet the 
    requirements of section 251 of the Act, including the rules prescribed 
    by the Commission pursuant to that section;
        (2) Establish any rates for interconnection, services, or network 
    elements according to section 252(d) of the Act, including the rules 
    prescribed by the Commission pursuant to that section; and
        (3) Provide a schedule for implementation of the terms and 
    conditions by the parties to the agreement.
        (d) An arbitrator, acting pursuant to the Commission's authority 
    under section 252(e)(5) of the Act, shall use final offer arbitration, 
    except as otherwise provided in this section:
        (1) At the discretion of the arbitrator, final offer arbitration 
    may take the form of either entire package final offer arbitration or 
    issue-by-issue final offer arbitration.
        (2) Negotiations among the parties may continue, with or without 
    the assistance of the arbitrator, after final arbitration offers are 
    submitted. Parties may submit subsequent final offers following such 
    negotiations.
        (3) To provide an opportunity for final post-offer negotiations, 
    the arbitrator will not issue a decision for at least fifteen days 
    after submission to the arbitrator of the final offers by the parties.
        (e) Final offers submitted by the parties to the arbitrator shall 
    be consistent with section 251 of the Act, including the rules 
    prescribed by the Commission pursuant to that section.
        (f) Each final offer shall:
        (1) Meet the requirements of section 251, including the rules 
    prescribed by the Commission pursuant to that section;
        (2) Establish rates for interconnection, services, or access to 
    unbundled network elements according to section 252(d) of the Act, 
    including the rules prescribed by the Commission pursuant to that 
    section; and
        (3) Provide a schedule for implementation of the terms and 
    conditions by the parties to the agreement. If a final offer submitted 
    by one or more parties fails to comply with the requirements of this 
    section, the arbitrator has discretion to take steps designed to result 
    in an arbitrated agreement that satisfies the requirements of section 
    252(c) of the Act, including requiring parties to submit new final 
    offers within a time frame specified by the arbitrator, or adopting a 
    result not submitted by any party that is consistent with the 
    requirements of section 252(c) of the Act, and the rules prescribed by 
    the Commission pursuant to that section.
        (g) Participation in the arbitration proceeding will be limited to 
    the requesting telecommunications carrier and the incumbent LEC, except 
    that the Commission will consider requests by third parties to file 
    written pleadings.
        (h) Absent mutual consent of the parties to change any terms and 
    conditions adopted by the arbitrator, the decision of the arbitrator 
    shall be binding on the parties.
    
    
    Sec. 51.809  Availability of provisions of agreements to other 
    telecommunications carriers under section 252(i) of the Act.
    
        (a) An incumbent LEC shall make available without unreasonable 
    delay to any requesting telecommunications carrier any individual 
    interconnection, service, or network element arrangement contained in 
    any agreement to which it is a party that is approved by a state 
    commission pursuant to section 252 of the Act, upon the same rates, 
    terms, and conditions as those provided in the agreement. An
    
    [[Page 45635]]
    
    incumbent LEC may not limit the availability of any individual 
    interconnection, service, or network element only to those requesting 
    carriers serving a comparable class of subscribers or providing the 
    same service (i.e., local, access, or interexchange) as the original 
    party to the agreement.
        (b) The obligations of paragraph (a) of this section shall not 
    apply where the incumbent LEC proves to the state commission that:
        (1) The costs of providing a particular interconnection, service, 
    or element to the requesting telecommunications carrier are greater 
    than the costs of providing it to the telecommunications carrier that 
    originally negotiated the agreement, or
        (2) The provision of a particular interconnection, service, or 
    element to the requesting carrier is not technically feasible.
        (c) Individual interconnection, service, or network element 
    arrangements shall remain available for use by telecommunications 
    carriers pursuant to this section for a reasonable period of time after 
    the approved agreement is available for public inspection under section 
    252(f) of the Act.
    
    PART 90--PRIVATE LAND MOBILE RADIO SERVICES
    
        11. The authority citation for Part 90 is revised to read as 
    follows:
    
        Authority: Secs. 4, 251-2, 303, 309, and 332, 48 Stat. 1066, 
    1082, as amended; 47 U.S.C. 154, 251-2, 303, 309 and 332, unless 
    otherwise noted.
    
        12. Section 90.5 is amended by redesignating paragraphs (k) and (l) 
    as paragraphs (l) and (m), and adding new paragraph (k) to read as 
    follows:
    
    
    Sec. 90.5  Other applicable rule parts.
    
    * * * * *
        (k) Part 51 contains rules relating to interconnection.
    * * * * *
        This Attachment A will not be published in the Code of Federal 
    Regulations
    
    Attachment A
    
    List of Commenters in CC Docket No. 96-98
    
    360 deg. Communications Company (360 Communications)
    Ad Hoc Coalition of Corporate Telecommunications Managers
    Ad Hoc Telecommunications Users Committee
    AirTouch Communications, Inc. (AirTouch)
    Alabama Public Service Commission (Alabama Commission)
    Alaska Telephone Association (Alaska Tel. Ass'n)
    Alaska Public Utilities Commission (Alaska Commission)
    Alliance for Public Technology
    Allied Association Partners, LP & Geld Information Systems (Allied 
    Ass'n)
    ALLTEL Telephone Services Corporation (ALLTEL)
    American Communications Services, Inc. (ACSI)
    American Foundation for the Blind
    American Mobile Telecommunications Association, Inc. (American 
    Mobile Telecomm. Ass'n)
    American Network Exchange, Inc. & U.S. Long Distance, Inc. (American 
    Network Exchange)
    American Personal Communications
    American Petroleum Institute
    American Public Communications Council
    American Public Power Association (APPA)
    America's Carriers Telecommunication Association (ACTA)
    Ameritech
    Anchorage Telephone Utility (Anchorage Tel. Utility)
    Arch Communications Group, Inc. (Arch)
    Arizona Corporation Commission (Arizona Commission)
    Association for Study of Afro-American Life and History, Inc. 
    (ASALH)
    Association for Local Telecommunications Services (ALTS)
    Association of Telemessaging Services International
    AT&T Corp. (AT&T)
    Attorneys General of Connecticut, Delaware, Illinois, Iowa, 
    Massachusetts, Michigan, Minnesota, Missouri, New York, North 
    Dakota, Pennsylvania, West Virginia and Wisconsin (Attorneys 
    General)
    Bay Springs Telephone Co., Crockett Telephone Co., National 
    Telephone Company of Alabama, Peoples Telephone Company, Roanoke 
    Telephone Co. & West Tennessee Telephone Company (Bay Springs, et 
    al.)
    Black Data Processing Associates
    Black Data Processors Association (Black Data Processors Ass'n)
    Bell Atlantic Telephone Companies (Bell Atlantic)
    Bell Atlantic NYNEX Mobile, Inc. (Bell Atlantic NYNEX Mobile)
    BellSouth Corporation, Bell Enterprises, Inc., BellSouth 
    Telecommunications, Inc. (BellSouth)
    Bogue, Kansas
    Buckeye Cablevision, Inc. (Buckeye Cablevision)
    Cable & Wireless, Inc. (Cable & Wireless)
    Cellular Telecommunications Industry Association (CTIA)
    Celpage, Inc. (Celpage)
    Centennial Cellular Corp.
    Chrysler Minority Dealers Association (Chrysler Minority Dealers 
    Ass'n)
    Cincinnati Bell Telephone Company (Cincinnati Bell)
    Citizens Utilities Company (Citizens Utilities)
    Classic Telephone, Inc. (Classic Tel.)
    Colorado Independent Telephone Association (Colorado Independent 
    Tel. Ass'n)
    Colorado Public Utilities Commission (Colorado Commission)
    COMAV, Corp. (COMAV)
    Comcast Cellular Communications, Inc. (Comcast Cellular)
    Comcast Corporation (Comcast)
    Communications and Energy Dispute Resolution Associates (CEDRA)
    Competition Policy Institute
    Competitive Telecommunications Association (CompTel)
    Connecticut Department of Public Utility Control (Connecticut 
    Commission)
    Consumer Federation of America & Consumers Union (CFA/CU)
    Consumer Project on Technology on Interconnection & Unbundling 
    (Consumer Project)
    Continental Cablevision, Inc. (Continental)
    Cox Communications, Inc. (Cox)
    Defense, Secretary of
    DeSoto County, Mississippi Economic Development Council
    District of Columbia Public Service Commission (District of Columbia 
    Commission)
    Economides, Nicholas (N. Economides)
    Ericsson Corporation, The (Ericsson)
    Excel Telecommunications, Inc. (Excel)
    Florida Public Service Commission (Florida Commission)
    Fred Williamson & Associates, Inc. (F. Williamson)
    Frontier Corporation (Frontier)
    General Communication, Inc. (GCI)
    General Services Administration/Department of Defense (GSA/DOD)
    Georgia Public Service Commission (Georgia Commission)
    Greater Washington Urban League
    GST Telecom, Inc. (GST)
    GTE Service Corporation (GTE)
    Guam Telephone Authority
    GVNW Inc./Management (GVNW)
    Hart Engineers/Robert A. Hart, IV (Hart Engineers)
    Hawaii Public Utilities Commission (Hawaii Commission)
    Home Telephone Company, Inc. (Home Tel.)
    Hyperion Telecommunications, Inc. (Hyperion)
    Idaho Public Utilities Commission (Idaho Commission)
    Illinois Commerce Commission (Illinois Commission)
    Illinois Independent Telephone Association (Illinois Ind. Tel. 
    Ass'n)
    Independent Cable & Telecommunications Association (Ind. Cable & 
    Telecomm. Ass'n)
    Independent Data Communications Manufacturers Association (IDCMA)
    Indiana Utility Regulatory Commission Staff (Indiana Commission 
    Staff)
    Information Technology Industry Council (ITIC)
    Intelcom Group (U.S.A.), Inc. (Intelcom)
    Intermedia Communications, Inc. (Intermedia)
    International Communications Association (Intl. Comm. Ass'n)
    Iowa Utilities Board (Iowa Commission)
    John Staurulakis, Inc. (J. Staurulakis)
    Joint Consumer Advocates
    Jones Intercable, Inc. (Jones Intercable)
    Justice, U. S. Department of (DoJ)
    Kansas Corporation Commission (Kansas Commission)
    
    [[Page 45636]]
    
    Kentucky Public Service Commission (Kentucky Commission)
    Koch, Richard N. (R. Koch)
    LCI International Telecom Corp. (LCI)
    LDDS Worldcom (LDDS)
    Lincoln Telephone & Telegraph Company (Lincoln Tel.)
    Louisiana Public Service Commission (Louisiana Commission)
    Lucent Technologies, Inc. (Lucent)
    Margaretville Telephone Co., Inc. (Margaretville Tel.)
    Maryland Public Service Commission (Maryland Commission)
    Massachusetts Assistive Technology Partnership Center World 
    Institute on Disability, Alliance for Technology Access, Trace 
    Research and Development Center, CPB/WGBH National Center For 
    Accessible Media (Mass. Assistive Tech. Partnership, et al.)
    Massachusetts, Commonwealth of Department of Public Utilities (Mass. 
    Commission)
    Massachusetts, Commonwealth of, Office of Attorney General (Mass. 
    Attorney General)
    Matanuska Telephone Association, Inc. (Matanuska Tel.)
    MCI
    Metricom, Inc. (Metricom)
    MFS
    Michigan Exchange Carriers Association (MECA)
    Michigan, Illinois, and Texas Communities, et al.
    Michigan Public Service Commission Staff (Michigan Commission Staff)
    Minnesota Independent Coalition (Minnesota Independent Coalition)
    Minnesota Public Utilities Commission (Minnesota Commission)
    Missouri Public Service Commission (Missouri Commission)
    Missouri Public Service Commissioner, Harold Crumpton (Missouri 
    Commissioner)
    Mobilemedia Communications, Inc. (Mobilemedia)
    Motorola Satellite Communications, Inc. and U.S. Leo Services, Inc. 
    (Motorola)
    Municipal Utilities
    National Association of the Deaf
    National Association of Development Organizations, Gray Panthers, 
    United Seniors Health Cooperative, United Homeowners Association, 
    National Hispanic Council on Aging, National Trust/Trustnet, 
    National Association of Commissions for Women, National Council of 
    Senior Citizens (NADO, et al.)
    National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC)
    National Association of State Utility Consumer Advocates (National 
    Ass'n of State Utility Advocates)
    National Bar Association (National Bar Ass'n)
    National Cable Television Association, Inc. (NCTA)
    National Exchange Carrier Association, Inc. (NECA)
    National League of Cities & National Association of 
    Telecommunications Officers and Advisors (NLC/NATOA)
    National Private Telecommunications Association
    National Telecommunications & Information Administration (NTIA)
    National Wireless Resellers Association (National Wireless Resellers 
    Ass'n)
    Nebraska Rural Development Commission
    Network Reliability Council, Secretariat of Second (Network 
    Reliability Council)
    New Hampshire Public Utilities Commission, New Mexico State 
    Corporation Commission, Utah Division of Public Utilities, Vermont 
    Public Service Board, and Vermont Department of Public Service (New 
    Hampshire Commission, et al.)
    New Jersey Cable Telecommunications Association, South Carolina 
    Cable Television Association & Texas Cable Telecommunications 
    Association (New Jersey Cable Ass'n, et al.)
    New Jersey, Staff of Board of Public Utilities (New Jersey 
    Commission Staff)
    New York State Consumer Protection Board (New York Consumer 
    Protection Board)
    New York State Department of Public Service (New York Commission)
    Nextel Communications, Inc. (Nextel)
    NEXTLINK Communications, L.L.C. (NEXTLINK)
    North Carolina Utility Commission Public Staff (North Carolina 
    Commission Staff)
    North Dakota Public Service Commission (North Dakota Commission)
    Northern Telecom, Inc. (Nortel)
    NYNEX Telephone Companies (NYNEX)
    Ohio Public Utilities Commission (Ohio Commission)
    Office of the Ohio Consumers' Counsel (Ohio Consumers' Counsel)
    Oklahoma Corporation Commission (Oklahoma Commission)
    Omnipoint Corporation (Omnipoint)
    Optel, Inc. (Optel)
    Oregon Public Utility Commission (Oregon Commission)
    Pacific Telesis Group (PacTel)
    Paging Network, Inc. (PageNet)
    Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission (Pennsylvania Commission)
    People of the State of California and the Public Utility Commission 
    of the State of California (California Commission)
    Personal Communications Industry Association (PCIA)
    ProNet Inc. (ProNet)
    Puerto Rico Telephone Company (Puerto Rico Tel.)
    Roseville Telephone Company (Roseville Tel.)
    Rural Telephone Coalition (Rural Tel. Coalition)
    SBC Communications Inc. (SBC)
    Scherers Communications Group, Inc. (SCG)
    Small Business Administration, U.S. (SBA)
    Small Cable Business Association (SCBA)
    SDN Users Association
    South Carolina Public Service Commission (South Carolina Commission)
    Southern New England Telephone Company (SNET)
    Southwestern Bell Telephone Company (SWBT)
    Sprint Corporation (Sprint)
    Sprint Spectrum & American Personal Communications (Sprint/APC)
    State of Maine Public Utilities Commission, State of Montana Public 
    Service Commission, State of Nebraska Public Service Commission, 
    State of New Hampshire Public Utilities Commission, State of New 
    Mexico State Corporation Commission, State of Utah Public Service 
    Commission and Division of Public Utilities, State of Vermont 
    Department of Public Service and Public Service Board, and Public 
    Utilities Commission of South Dakota (Maine Commission, et al.)
    TCA, Inc. (TCA)
    TDS Telecommunications Corporation (TDS)
    Telecommunication Industries Analysis Project
    Telecommunications Carriers for Competition (TCC)
    Tele-Communications, Inc. (TCI)
    Telecommunications Industry Association (TIA)
    Telecommunications Ratepayers Association for Cost-Based and 
    Equitable Rates (TRACER)
    Telecommunications Resellers Association (Telecomm. Resellers Ass'n)
    Telefonica Larga Distancia de Puerto Rico, Inc. (TLD)
    Teleport Communications Group, Inc. (Teleport)
    Texas Office of Public Utility Counsel (Texas Public Utility 
    Counsel)
    Texas, Public Utilities Commission (Texas Commission)
    Texas Statewide Telephone Cooperative, Inc.
    Texas Telephone Association (Texas Tel. Ass'n)
    Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. (Time Warner)
    Unicom, Inc. (Unicom)
    United Calling Network, Inc. (United Calling Network)
    United Cerebral Palsy Association
    United States Telephone Association (USTA)
    USTN Services, Inc. (USTN)
    U.S. Network Corporation (U.S. Network)
    U S West, Inc. (U S West)
    Utah Division of Public Utilities
    UTC
    Utilex, Inc. (Utilex)
    Vanguard Cellular Systems, Inc. (Vanguard)
    Vartec Telecom, Inc., Transtel, Telephone Express, CGI, & 
    CommuniGroup Inc. of Mississippi (Vartec, et al.)
    Virginia State Corporation Commission Staff (Virginia Commission 
    Staff)
    Washington Independent Telephone Association (Wash. Ind. Tel. Ass'n)
    Washington Utilities and Transportation Commission (Washington 
    Commission)
    Western Alliance
    WinStar Communications, Inc. (WinStar)
    Wisconsin, Public Service Commission (Wisconsin Commission)
    Wyoming Public Service Commission (Wyoming Commission)
    
    List of Commenters in CC Docket No. 95-185
    
    360 Degree Communications Co. (360 Degrees)
    AirTouch Communications, Inc. (Airtouch)
    Alaska 3 Cellular Corporation (Alaska CellularOne)
    Alaska Telephone Association (ATA)
    Alliance of Wireless Service Providers (Alliance)
    Allied Personal Communications Industry Association of California 
    (Allied)
    ALLTEL Corporation (ALLTEL)
    American Mobil Telecommunications Association (AMTA)
    
    [[Page 45637]]
    
    America's Carriers Telecommunications Association (ACTA)
    American Personal Communications/Sprint Spectrum (APC/Sprint)
    Ameritech
    Anchorage Telephone Utility (ATU)
    Arch Communications Group, Inc. (Arch)
    AT&T Corporation (AT&T)
    Bell Atlantic
    Bell Atlantic Nynex Mobile (Bell Atlantic-NYNEX)
    BellSouth Corporation (BellSouth)
    State of California & the Public Utilities Commission (CPUC)
    Cellular Communications of Puerto Rico, Inc. (CCPR)
    Cellular Mobile Systems of St. Cloud G.P. (CMS)
    Cellular Resellers Association (Cellular Resellers)
    Cellular Telecommunications Industry Association (CTIA)
    Celpage, Inc. (Celpage)
    Centennial Cellular Corporation (Centennial)
    Century Cellunet, Inc. (Century Cellunet)
    Cincinnati Bell
    CMT Partners (CMT)
    Comcast Corporation (Comcast)
    Competitive Telecommunications Association (CompTel)
    Concord Telephone Company (Concord)
    Connecticut Department of Public Utility (Connecticut)
    Cox Enterprises, Inc. (Cox)
    Florida Cellular RSA L.P. (Florida Cellular)
    Frontier Corporation (Frontier)
    GO Communications Corp. (GO)
    General Services Administration (GSA)
    GTE Services Corporation (GTE)
    GVNW Inc., Management (GVNW)
    Hart Engineers and 21st Century Telesis, Inc. (Hart Engineers)
    Home Telephone Company, Inc. (HomeTel)
    ICO Global Communications (ICO)
    Illinois Commerce Commission (Illinois)
    Illinois Independent Telephone Association (Illinois Ind. Tel. 
    Assoc.)
    Illinois Telephone Association (Illinois Telephone Assoc.)
    John Staurulakis, Inc. (JSI)
    LDDS WorldCom (LDDS WorldCom)
    MCI Telecommunications Corp. (MCI)
    MFS Communications Company, Inc. (MFS)
    Mercury Cellular & Paging (Mercury)
    Mountain Solutions
    National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC)
    National Exchange Carrier Association (NECA)
    National Telephone Cooperative Association (NTCA)
    New Par
    New York State Department of Public Service (New York)
    Nextel Communications, Inc. (Nextel)
    North Carolina 4 Cellular L.P. (North Carolina Cellular)
    NYNEX Telephone Companies (NYNEX)
    Public Utilities Commission of Ohio (Ohio)
    Omnipoint Corporation (Omnipoint)
    OPASTCO
    Pacific Bell, Pacific Bell Mobile Services, Nevada Bell (Pacific 
    Bell)
    Paging Network, Inc. (PageNet)
    Personal Communications Industry Association (PCIA)
    Point Communications Company (Point)
    Poka Lambro Telephone Cooperative (Poka Lambro)
    Puerto Rico Telephone Company (PRTC)
    Rural Cellular Association (RCA)
    Rural Cellular Corporation (RCC)
    SBC Communications, Inc. (SBC)
    Smithville Telephone Company (Smithville)
    Southeast Telephone Company (Southeast Telephone)
    Sprint Corporation (Sprint)
    Sprint Spectrum and American Personal Communications (Sprint/APC)
    Telecommunications Resellers Association (TRA)
    Teleport Communications Group (Teleport)
    Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. (Time Warner)
    Telecommunications Ratepayers Association for Cost-Based and 
    Equitable Rates (TRACER)
    Union Telephone Company (Union)
    United States Telephone Association (USTA)
    US West, Inc. (US West)
    Vanguard Cellular Systems, Inc. (Vanguard)
    Western Radio Services Co., Inc. (Western)
    Western Wireless Corporation (Western Wireless)
    Westlink Company (Westlink)
    List of Commenters in CC Docket No. 91-346
    
    List of Commenters in CC Docket No. 91-346
    
    Ad Hoc Telecommunications Users Committee (Ad Hoc)
    Allnet Communication Services, Inc. (Allnet)
    American Telephone and Telegraph Company (AT&T)
    Ameritech Operating Companies (Ameritech)
    Bell Atlantic Telephone Companies (Bell Atlantic)
    BellSouth Corporation (BellSouth)
    Cincinnati Bell Telephone (Cincinnati Bell)
    Ericsson Corporation (Ericsson)
    General Services Administration (GSA)
    Geonet
    GTE Service Corporation (GTE)
    Information Technology Association of America (ITAA)
    Joint Filers (includes Bell Atlantic, BellSouth, GTE, Lincoln, 
    Pacific Bell, Rochester, SNET, and US WEST)
    MCI Telecommunications Corporation (MCI)
    National Communications System (NCS)
    Nextel Communications, Inc. (Nextel)
    North American Telecommunications Association (NATA)
    Northern Telecom Inc. (Northern Telecom)
    NYNEX Telephone Companies (NYNEX)
    Pacific Bell and Nevada Bell (Pacific Bell)
    Pacific Telesis Corporation (Pactel)
    Services-oriented Open Network Technologies, Inc. (SONetech)
    Siemens Stromberg-Carlson (Siemens)
    Southern New England Telephone Company (SNET)
    Southwestern Bell Corporation (SWBT)
    Sprint
    Telecommunications Industry Association (TIA)
    Teleport Communications Group (Teleport)
    Teloquent Communications Corporation (Teloquent)
    United and Central Telephone Companies (United and Central)
    United States Telephone Association (USTA)
    US WEST Communications, Inc. (US WEST)
    
        This Attachment B will not be published in the Code of Federal 
    Regulations.
    
             Attachment B.--State Proxy Ceilings for the Local Loop         
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
                                                                      Proxy 
                                 State                               ceiling
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    Alabama.......................................................    $17.25
    Arizona.......................................................     12.85
    Arkansas......................................................     21.18
    California....................................................     11.10
    Colorado......................................................     14.97
    Connecticut...................................................     13.23
    Delaware......................................................     13.24
    District of Columbia..........................................     10.81
    Florida.......................................................     13.68
    Georgia.......................................................     16.09
    Hawaii........................................................     15.27
    Idaho.........................................................     20.16
    Illinois......................................................     13.12
    Indiana.......................................................     13.29
    Iowa..........................................................     15.94
    Kansas........................................................     19.85
    Kentucky......................................................     16.70
    Louisiana.....................................................     16.98
    Maine.........................................................     18.69
    Maryland......................................................     13.36
    Massachusetts.................................................      9.83
    Michigan......................................................     15.27
    Minnesota.....................................................     14.81
    Mississippi...................................................     21.97
    Missouri......................................................     18.32
    Montana.......................................................     25.18
    Nebraska......................................................     18.05
    Nevada........................................................     18.95
    New Hampshire.................................................     16.00
    New Jersey....................................................     12.47
    New Mexico....................................................     18.66
    New York......................................................     11.75
    North Carolina................................................     16.71
    North Dakota..................................................     25.36
    Ohio..........................................................     15.73
    Oklahoma......................................................     17.63
    Oregon........................................................     15.44
    Pennsylvania..................................................     12.30
    Puerto Rico...................................................     12.47
    Rhode Island..................................................     11.48
    South Carolina................................................     17.07
    South Dakota..................................................     25.33
    Tennessee.....................................................     17.41
    Texas.........................................................     15.49
    Utah..........................................................     15.12
    Vermont.......................................................     20.13
    Virginia......................................................     14.13
    Washington....................................................     13.37
    West Virginia.................................................     19.25
    Wisconsin.....................................................     15.94
    Wyoming.......................................................     25.11
    ------------------------------------------------------------------------
    
    [FR Doc. 96-21589 Filed 8-28-96; 8:45 am]
    BILLING CODE 6712-01-P
    
    
    

Document Information

Effective Date:
9/30/1996
Published:
08/29/1996
Department:
Federal Communications Commission
Entry Type:
Rule
Action:
Final rule.
Document Number:
96-21589
Dates:
September 30, 1996.
Pages:
45476-45637 (162 pages)
Docket Numbers:
CC Docket No. 96-98, CC Docket No. 95-185, GN Docket No. 93-252, FCC 96-325
PDF File:
96-21589.pdf
CFR: (72)
47 CFR 1.1401
47 CFR 1.1402
47 CFR 1.1403
47 CFR 1.1404
47 CFR 1.1409
More ...